You are on page 1of 12

Journal of the Operational Research Society (2017) 68, 521–532 ª 2016 The Operational Research Society.

ociety. All rights reserved. 0160-5682/17

www.palgrave.com/journals

Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains


Margarita Protopappa-Sieke1* and Ralf W. Seifert2,3
1
Department of Supply Chain Management and Management Science, University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-
Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany; 2 College of Management of Technology, Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale de
Lausanne, 1015 Lausanne, Switzerland; and 3 IMD, Chemin de Bellerive 23, P.O. Box 915, 1001 Lausanne,
Switzerland
Supply chain finance and working capital management are important avenues to reduce supply chain costs. Small
suppliers may not have sufficient working capital to finance their operations and efficiently supply their
customers. We develop a model that captures the fundamental aspects of financial and operational planning in a
two-stage supply chain, with both strong and weak members. A strong member can negotiate for more favorable
financing rates, more advantageous payment terms, and shorter lead times than a weaker member. We investigate
two working capital allocation scenarios. In the dedicated working capital allocation scenario, the members of the
supply chain each have their own working capital. In the joint working capital allocation scenario, the members
of the supply chain have a joint pool of working capital. Our results demonstrate significant benefits when the
members of the supply chain share the working capital. We also show that extending payment delays to a supplier
upstream results in higher overall supply chain costs.
Journal of the Operational Research Society (2017) 68(5), 521–532. doi:10.1057/s41274-016-0009-2;
published online 7 October 2016

Keywords: financial supply chain management; supply chain finance; working capital management; payment delays;
inventory management

1. Introduction Even though, there exist a vast amount of literature on


supply chain management, however, financial flows and
Supply chain finance, a rather new and promising discipline, is
operational flows are often treated in isolation (Longinidis
increasingly receiving attention as a powerful instrument to
and Georgiadis, 2011). As ‘‘a company might have no
integrate the operational flows and the financial flows within
knowledge of its suppliers’ cost of capital and little knowledge
supply chains. Such techniques and solutions enable the
of the financial challenges its suppliers face; the typical supply
financing of supply chains. In the automotive industry for
chain is grounded in retailer, logistics and manufacturing
example, the increasing bargaining power of the Original
processes’’ (DiBenedetto, 2007). Efficient working capital
Equipment Manufacturers and the latest economic downturn
management can achieve significant cost savings as it enables
readily resulted in liquidity struggles and high bankruptcy
weaker members to secure the necessary financing. Under-
risks for the suppliers. The constant pressure from customers
standing the impact of upstream and downstream payment
for longer credit windows necessitates the search for new
delays within the supply chain can result in better interactions
financing solutions for supply chains as the availability of
between the supply chain members. Better visibility of both
credit is limited. Many small and medium size companies
cash and product flows can enhance working capital utilization
might not have the working capital reserves needed to finance
and reduce working capital requirements. Through better
their operations and thus cannot efficiently supply their
allocation of risk, supply chain financing solutions which
customers. Such deficiencies can have serious implications
focus on working capital collaboration can ensure a more
for the profitability and responsiveness of a supply chain.
stable supply of products, better relationship between the
According to Aberdeen Group’s 2008 State of Market in
involved parties, and thus new opportunities for business.
Supply Chain Finance, more and more companies are currently
Randal and Theodore Farris (2009) show how supply chain
engaging in supply chain financing solutions and the best in
financial management techniques, such as supply chain
class performers have already integrated the physical and
finance, can reduce overall supply chain costs and perfor-
financial supply chain (Bernabucci, 2008).
mance by benefiting from lower refinancing costs of another
member in the supply chain. However, some companies are
*Correspondence: Margarita Protopappa-Sieke, Department of Supply
Chain Management and Management Science, University of Cologne,
hesitating to adopt supply chain finance solutions because ‘‘it
Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany. is unclear how much buyers and suppliers really save,’’
E-mail: margarita.protopappa-sieke@uni-koeln.de (Seifert and Seifert, 2011). Thus, an in-depth overall
522 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

understanding of the benefits of supply chain financing and working capital. We also show that extending payment delays
working capital allocation in a supply chain is of substantial to a supplier upstream results in higher supply chain costs.
importance.
Motivated by the recent trend of banking products where a
joint cash pool is used among related companies (Danske 2. Literature Review
Bank, 2016), the purpose of this paper is to better understand
the benefits of interrelating operational and financial aspects Our paper is positioned at the interface of operations
within a supply chain. More financial institutions offer such management and corporate finance and we build on two
cash pools. For example, the People’s Bank of China offers literature streams: literature that incorporates financial deci-
now cash pool where companies can be connected together sions in inventory models and literature on supply chain
under specific rules (PWC, 2015). Our main objective is to financing methods.
investigate whether sharing working capital between members The theoretical foundation for the analysis of multi-echelon
of a supply chain and not just pooling resources between inventory systems is given by Clark and Scarf (1960). Over the
related companies can demonstrate significant cost savings, years, there have been numerous extensions and variations;
and how different working capital allocation scenarios impact however, the literature that incorporates financial decisions in
operational decisions and financial planning. We expect to inventory models is rather limited (Hausman, 2002). Many
find that collaborative working capital approaches exhibit articles focus on the cash-to-cash conversion cycles as a
greater performance than competitive approaches, similar to natural way to interrelate inventories and cash. Viskari and
the existing literature in supply chain collaboration (Cachon, Kärri (2012) introduce an inter-organizational working capital
2003). We account for financial considerations within the model based on the cash conversion cycle to discuss both
common setting of a two-stage supply chain. We differentiate collaborative and non-collaborative approach that is used as
between strong members and weak members in the supply benchmarking. The authors discuss five scenarios that enable
chain according to their relative bargaining power. A strong them to realize collaborative working capital management and
member can negotiate more favorable financing rates, advan- reduce the financing costs. From a qualitative perspective,
tageous payment terms, and shorter lead times than a weak empirical studies were used to elaborate on working capital,
member. In this context, we compare a dedicated working payment delays, and profitability (Farris II and Hutchison,
capital allocation scenario with a joint working capital 2002; Kaplan and Zingales, 1997). From a quantitative
allocation scenario. In the dedicated setting, the members of perspective, a first attempt to incorporate asset-based financ-
the supply chain each have their own working capital. In the ing into operational decisions is that of Buzacott and Zhang
joint setting, the members of the supply chain draw financing (2004). The authors quantify available cash as a function of
from a joint pool of working capital. Such settings would assets and liabilities and demonstrate the necessity of jointly
require a banking platform such as those used already in joint considering production and financing decisions. Randall and
cash pools offered by major financial institutions such as Theodore Farris (2009) show how cash-to-cash financial
Danske Bank, the People’s Bank of China, among others techniques can help increase profitability in a supply chain
(Danske Bank, 2016; PWC, 2015). The financial institution setting. Gupta and Dutta (2011) study the cash flows in a
should play the role of a moderator to ensure that limits are set supply chain and propose different heuristics that could be
on the borrowing amount of each company. Our paper used to solve real life dynamic problems. Li et al (2013)
discusses whether joint cash pools among companies are present a dynamic model that jointly considers inventory and
beneficial. We believe that such platforms can be based on financial decisions to maximize dividends under financial
already existing cash pool platforms or factory payment constraints. We extend the research of Protopappa-Sieke and
platforms. Furthermore, it is also possible that such platforms Seifert (2010) who develop an inventory model that consol-
are developed by companies such as Demica and PrimeRev- idates working capital restrictions and payment delays. The
enue. In our paper, we do not consider any costs for the supply authors quantify the benefits of joint consideration of physical
chain members for using such financial platform; however, our and financial flows, focusing on a single echelon setting.
model can be extended to consider the financial institution Various supply chain financing solutions have been consid-
view and adheres to our future research avenues. The main ered in the literature, such as trade-credit, factoring, reverse
contribution of our paper is that we examine the collaboration factoring, and supplier subsidy. Trade-credit is an essential
within supply chain members from a financial perspective. element of cash management, especially in times of economic
More specifically, we investigate how collaborative downturns when payment delays are used means of alleviating
approaches in working capital allocation may ensure a higher high working capital requirements. One of the first papers to
supply chain performance and lower costs. Furthermore, we introduce payment delays was Goyal (1985) who presents an
elaborate on the interrelation between operational decisions economic order quantity model with permissible delays in
and financial planning. Our results demonstrate significant settling the amount owned to the supplier. More and more
cost savings when the members of the supply chain share the studies included trade-credit in operational decisions in supply
Margarita Protopappa-Sieke and Ralf W. Seifert—Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains 523

chain management. Maddah et al (2004) and Seifert et al supplier who has infinite capacity. Both stages have working
(2013) provide an insightful literature review on trade-credit capital restrictions and cannot always satisfy all the orders
along with future avenues for research. Gupta and Wang demanded from downstream. For each stage, there is an
(2009) present a discrete-time stochastic inventory model with upstream and a downstream payment delay. More precisely,
trade-credit and finance charges. The authors prove that the when customers place an order with the retailer, they pay for
credit terms do not affect the structure of the optimal policy. their order after d1 periods, which corresponds to the
Kouvelis and Zhao (2012) examined the structure of trade- downstream payment delays of Stage 1. When the retailer
credit contracts and the optimal financing of the members in a places an order with his upstream supplier, he pays for his
supply chain, where they compare different supplier and order after u1 periods, which corresponds to the upstream
banking financing scenarios. Motivated by the financial payment delays of Stage 1. Similarly, an order placed by the
struggles of Delphi Corporation and Visteon, Babich (2010) supplier with his external supplier is paid after u2 periods,
discusses a form of financing where a company subsidizes its which corresponds to the upstream payment delays of Stage 2.
financial ailing supplier. He uses a dynamic, stochastic, Naturally, d2 = u1.
periodic-review model to find the optimal capacity ordering The unit ordering cost is ck , where k = 1, 2 is the number of
and subsidy policy. stages in the supply chain. The unit revenue for all orders sold
An increasing number of papers exist that discusses the downstream is rk . Leaving aside transportation cost, the unit
importance of factoring in supply chains. Factoring is a form ordering cost of the retailer equals the unit revenue cost of the
of supply chain financing where a company exchanges its supplier, i.e., c1 = r2. Customers’ demand nn in period n is
accounts receivables with cash at a specific fee (Mian and independently and identically distributed, with a probability
Smith, 1992; Sopranzetti, 1998; Klapper, 2006). Since distribution function u(.) with mean l and standard deviation
factors have to evaluate the buyers before agreeing to r. When orders are placed upstream, we assume that they
exchange the accounts receivables, factoring is often con- arrive after a delay of Lk periods. All unsatisfied orders are
sidered an expensive form of financing and is often used in backlogged with a unit penalty cost pk per period. Excess
emerging markets (Seifert and Seifert, 2011). An extension inventory at the end of a period results in a unit holding cost at
of factoring that overcomes these difficulties is reverse stage k which is denoted as hk : In our model, we consider
factoring or else known as supply chain finance. Tanrisever backorders in the system.
et al (2012) study and quantify the value of reverse factoring The sequence of events per period is as follows: (1) the
for the involved members in the supply chain. Wuttke et al’s inventory position and working capital position for both
(2013) is one of the first papers to discuss the adoption of stages are reviewed; (2) an order from each stage is placed
reverse factoring in supply chains. Van der Vliet et al (2015) upstream constrained by the expected working capital posi-
introduce a periodic-review inventory model to investigate tion when the payment for this order is due; (3) previously
whether reverse factoring is profitable. Wuttke et al (2016) ordered shipments arrive at both stages; (4) backorders at
consider the adoption of reverse factoring using a diffusion both stages are satisfied; (5) customers’ demand occurs; (6)
model and discuss how timing and payment terms can orders placed at both stages are satisfied, or else they are
influence adoption decisions. Our paper is discussing a backlogged; (7) revenue is received in both stages from
similar form of supply chain financing where the involved satisfied backorders and downstream orders of d1, d2 periods
parties share a joint pool of cash. We are interested in ago; (8) holding and shortage costs of this period at both
investigating how working capital restrictions affect the stages are realized and paid directly; (9) the order placed
operations of a supply chain and how different working upstream u1, u2 periods ago for both stages is paid; and (10)
capital allocation scenarios influence the operational and working capital restrictions are enforced and cash positions,
financial flows in a two-stage supply chain. Motivated by the which exceed a certain permissible threshold value, are send
aforementioned studies in trade-credit, we are also interested to an external depository, to avoid an undue accumulation of
how demanding longer payment delays impacts the overall working capital in the system overtime. Figure 1 illustrates
supply chain performance. the two-stage serial supply chain considered in our model
with the key assumptions.
The order amount for each stage in period n is qk;n ; where
qk,n C 0. The ordering decision in period n for each stage
3. Model depends on the optimal ordering decision of that period zk,n
To capture the essential aspects of financial and operational and the expected available working capital when the payment
planning in a two-stage supply chain, we consider a finite- is due. We denote as q~k;n the amount sent to Stage k in period
horizon, periodic-review inventory model. Our supply chain n. For the supplier, the order amount and the amount received
consists of one retailer and one supplier. Customers place are the same, i.e., q2;n ¼ q~2;n . This is because the outside
orders with the retailer (Stage 1), who places orders with the supplier has infinite capacity and therefore can satisfy all
supplier (Stage 2). The supplier places orders with an outside orders from the supplier. Conversely, the order placed by the
524 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

Infinite Lead time L2 2


L1 1 Customers’
capacity Payment delays demand
u2 d2 u1 d1 ( n)
Unit revenue: r2 r1
Unit ordering cost: c2 c1
Unit holding cost: h2 h1
Unit shortage cost: p2 p1

Key assumptions
• Finite-horizon, periodic-review inventory model
• Excess orders are backordered
• Stochastic working capital capacity restrictions for both stages

Figure 1 Our two-stage supply chain.

retailer might not always be satisfied due to working capital Table 1 Model parameters
constraints the supplier is facing and can lead to under-
Indices
stocking at Stage 1. The distinction between the order amount k Stage; k = 1, 2
and the actual amount sent is necessary for cost accounting n Time period; time horizon of N periods
purposes. Additionally, let bk,n be the amount on hand plus on Parameters
order xk,n after q~k;n . is sent but before downstream demand is Lk Lead time
uk Upstream payment delays
realized, bk;n ¼ xk;n þ q~k;n . The inventory position at the end of
P 1 1 dk Downstream payment delays
period n at the retailer’s site is b1;n  nn  Li¼0 q~1;ni , while ck Unit ordering cost
PL2 1 rk Unit revenue
at the supplier’s site is b2;n  q1;n  i¼0 q2;ni . Table 1
hk Unit holding cost
presents the notation of our model. pk Unit penalty cost
nn End customer demand; mean l; standard
deviation r
zk,n Optimal ordering decision
3.1. Joint Working Capital Allocation xk,n Amount on order
bk,n Amount on hd plus on order after q~k;n is sent but
In the joint allocation scenario, the members of the supply
before nn is realized
chain have a joint pool of working capital. In our model, Ik,n Inventory value
working capital accounts for on-hand inventory and cash Ck,n Cash generated
from an existing pool of cash, accounts receivables, and WPn, WPk,n Working capital position
accounts payables. Let Ik,n be the inventory value of stage k at A, An Working capital allowance
Dn, Dk,n External depository
the end of period n. The inventory value for each stage is
 P 1 1 þ a, ak Discount factor
I1;n ¼ ck b1;n  nn  Li¼0 q~1;ni for the retailer and WPln, WPk,n
l
Liquid working capital
 PL2 1 þ p, pk Accounting penalty cost
I2;n ¼ ck b2;n  q1;n  i¼0 q2;ni for the supplier, where s, sk Cash outflow target
i0 , i0 k Financing interest rate
(x)+ = max(0, x). We do not attribute any value for negative
Decision variables
inventory position. Let Ck,n be the cash generated by stage k in qk,n Order placed
period n after all cash transactions have been completed. The q~k;n Inventory sent to stage k
cash generated by the retailer is given in Eq. 1, while by the
supplier is given in Eq. 2, where (x)- = max(0, -x). In Eq. 1,
the first three terms represent the cash inflow for the retailer
for all sales he captured in period n - d1 given that his sales shortage costs. Similarly, for Eq. 2, the first three terms
are restrained by the external customer demand, his order to correspond to the cash inflow from sales to the retailer in
the supplier, and the product availability at the supplier. The period n - d2, given that his sales are restrained by the
fourth term is his cash outflow for his order to the supplier, retailer’s demand, his order to the supplier, and the product
while the last two terms are the corresponding holding and availability at the supplier.
Margarita Protopappa-Sieke and Ralf W. Seifert—Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains 525

!þ ! chain across all periods. We define the financial cost as the


X
nd 1 1

C1;n ¼ r1 min nnd1 ; b1;nL1 d1  ni cost of financing and the depository cash outflow cost. By cost
i¼nL1 d1 of financing, we mean the cost of financing our operations. In
!þ !
X
nd1 1 our model, we have assumed that the initial endowment equals
þ r1 min q~1;nL1 d1 ; x1;nL1 d1 þ ni the allowance. The cost of financing is Ni0 A, where i0 is the
i¼nL1 d1 financing interest rate and N corresponds to the number of

LX
1 1 periods taken into account. To account for cash outflows to the
 c1 q1;nu1  h1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni depository, we assume that in each period we need to meet a
i¼0
! cash outflow target, s; to the depository. If insufficient cash is
LX
1 1
generated to reach this target, then the system’s performance is
 p1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni ð1Þ
i¼0
penalized by an accounting penalty cost p. The total account-
P
N
!þ ! ing penalty cost is p ðs  Dn Þþ : The objective function is
X
nd 2 1 n¼1
C2;n ¼ r2 min q1;nd2 ; b2;nL2 d2  q1;i presented in Eq. 3.
i¼nL2 d2
!þ ! " !þ
X
nd2 1
X
N LX
1 1
þ r2 min q2;nL2 d2 ; x2;nL2 d2 þ q1;i min n
a h1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni
i¼nL2 d2 q;A
n¼1 i¼0
!þ !
LX
2 1 LX
1 1
 c2 q2;nu2  h2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni þp1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni
i¼0 i¼0
! !þ
LX
2 1 LX
2 1
 p2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni ð2Þ þh2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni ð3Þ
i¼0 i¼0
! #
LX
2 1
The working capital position, WPn at the end of period n is the þp2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni
aggregation of cash and inventory values. While working capital i¼0
can be build-up over time, we assume an upper limit on the X
N
working capital position at the end of any period, i.e., working þ Ni0 A þ p ðs  Dn Þþ
capital allowance A which cannot be exceeded. For simplicity, n¼1

we assume A to be known and constant for all periods. Any


working capital in the form of cash that exceeds this threshold is
sent to an external depository Dn , where Dn = max(0, WPn - 3.2. Dedicated Working Capital Allocation
A). An example of such a depository could be a dividend paid to
the shareholders. Cash sent to the depository cannot be used to In this allocation scenario, the members of the supply chain
finance further operations of the system. Note, however, that if each have a separate working capital pool and face individ-
at the end of period n we have backorders in a stage, this ually working capital restrictions. We also assume that each
assumption is relaxed. We include a discount factor a 2 ð0; 1Þ member can have a different discount factor ak 2 ð0; 1Þ:
which corresponds to the cost of capital. Differences in the discount factor between the members of the
We define as liquid working capital, WPln, the part of supply chain might depend on bargaining power and access to
working capital that is tied up as cash at the end of period n capital. Each member of the supply chain makes separate
after all working capital restrictions have been taken into decisions about his own allowance, Ak. The working capital
account and excess cash has been sent to the depository. With position is WPk;n ¼ a1k WPlk;n1 þ Ck;n þ Ik;n for all k, n and

joint allocation, the working capital is shared between the liquid working capital is WPlk;n ¼ min a1k WPln1 þ Ck;n ; A
supplier and the retailer and cash resources come from a joint 
pool of cash, where the working capital position is WPn ¼ Ik;n for all k; n: As with the joint pool, we seek to minimize
1 l
P2 P2
a WPn1 þ k¼1 Ck;n þ k¼1 Ik;n for all n, and the liquid
the expected net present value of the total cost of the whole
 P supply chain with respect to the ordering decisions and the
working capital is WPln ¼ min 1a WPln1 þ 2k¼1 Ck;n ; A
 allowances, Eq. 4. The depository target for each member is
P2 P  þ
k¼1 I k;n for all n. Our principal objective is to minimize pk Nn¼1 sk  Dk;n , where the depository in this case is
the total cost which includes the total operational cost and the Dk,n = max(0, WPk,n - Ak). For the dedicated case, the inter-
total financial cost, with respect to the ordering decision and est rate differs for each member in the supply chain and is
the allowance. The operational cost is the expected net present defined as i0 k. The financing cost for each member in the
value of the total holding and shortage costs of the supply supply chain is Ni0 kAk. In our model, the decomposition
526 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

technique of Clark and Scarf (1960) cannot be used (Heyman Figure 2 illustrates the optimal allowances for various CVs
and Sobel, 1984). Due to the dynamic nature of working and CRs. In the dedicated allocation, the supplier has a
capital, we resort to numerical analysis and simulation in order significantly lower optimal allowance than the retailer. This
to address our research questions and derive managerial difference is more pronounced the higher the CV. The
insights. retailer’s inventory value is higher due to the higher unit
" !þ ordering cost. Therefore, a higher allowance is required to
XN LX
1 1
compensate for the higher inventory value. Furthermore, the
n
min a1 h1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni
q;A difference in optimal allowances between the members of the
n¼1 i¼0
! supply chain increases for a higher CV. High-demand
LX
1 1

þan1 p1 b1;n  nn  q~1;ni volatility results in peaks in revenue inflows to the retailer.
i¼0 If for example we have high demand in a period, the retailer
!þ needs the next period to meet the demand. If, in the next
LX
2 1

þan2 h2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni ð4Þ period, the customer demand is not as high, then the revenue
i¼0
! # inflow is low and more working capital is required for the
LX
2 1 retailer to finance his operations. Additionally, if the optimal
þan2 p2 b2;n  q1;n  q2;ni allowance of the retailer was low, then the aforementioned
i¼0
revenue peaks would have been sent to the depository. Further
X
2 2 X
X N  þ
þ Ni0k Ak þ pk sk  Dk;n we conclude that a higher CR requires a higher optimal
k¼1 k¼1 n¼1 allowance, because a higher unit shortage cost requires a
higher inventory on stock.
Table 2 illustrates the cost savings achieved with the joint
4. Managerial Insights allocation compared with the dedicated allocation. It can be
In this section, we present our numerical results. The base seen that a joint pool of working capital demonstrates
model parameters we consider are based on the Hewlett significant cost savings. Our main insights are summarized
Packard printer data (Seifert et al, 2006), adjusted in order to in the following observations.
capture the two-stage supply chain nature of our setting, h1 ¼ Observation 1 The supplier has a lower optimal allowance
0:06; p1 ¼ 0:24; c1 ¼ 2:6; r1 ¼ 3:6; h2 ¼ 0:06; p2 ¼ 0:24; and than the retailer.
c2 ¼ 1:6; r2 ¼ 2:6: For the dedicated scenario, we assume
that both stages have the same accounting penalty cost Observation 2 The joint allocation scenario demonstrates
p1 ¼ 0:05; p2 ¼ 0:05. Furthermore, we assume that the depos- significant cost savings compared with the dedicated
itory target is s1 = 0.2A1 and s2 = 0.2A2. For the joint allocation. These savings increase as the CV increases.
scenario, the corresponding parameters are p = 0.05 and
s = 0.2A. Customers’ demand follows a Lognormal distribu-
tion with mean l = 100 and standard deviation r = 30. A 4.1. Both Members Equally Strong
wide range of model parameters is considered when perform- Figure 3 demonstrates the optimal allowance and the total cost
ing sensitivity analysis on the Critical Ratio (CR) and the for various interest rates for both allocations. The supplier’s
Coefficient of Variation (CV). A different CR is capturing the optimal allowance is lower than the retailer’s. However, the
sensitivity analysis on the product parameters and is defined optimal allowance is robust as the interest rate increases. We
similar to Porteus (2002) as p/(p ? h). A different CV is see that significant cost savings are achieved when the
capturing the sensitivity analysis on the demand and is defined members of the supply chain have a joint pool of working
as r/l. The considered interest rates are 1, 5, and 10%. capital. The cost savings decrease as the interest rate increases;
We base our numerical analysis and simulation on a however, we have to mention that the discounting formula
modified base-stock policy which is a policy that follows a contributes to this as well.
base-stock policy when possible and produces to capacity Since we have assumed that the members of the supply
when the prescribed production quantity exceeds the capacity chain are equally strong, they can negotiate trade-credit terms
(Federgruen and Zipkin, 1986). We do not claim that base- equally well, u1 = u2. Figure 4 demonstrates the percentage
stock policies are optimal in our setting, but we recognize that change in total cost for both allocation scenarios, compared
the implementation of the optimal policy is too complicated with a case of no payment delays. Longer payment delays
because of the stochastic nature of working capital. We result in higher total cost, because the impact of downstream
develop a discrete improving local search algorithm imple- payment delays is more significant than that of upstream
mented in MatLab. Large neighborhoods and various search payment delays. Longer downstream payment delays increase
directions were considered in order to increase the robustness the supply chain costs. The cost increase for the dedicated
of the algorithm. We consider a simulation time horizon of 100 allocation is more pronounced than that with the joint
periods and 50 repetitions (confidence interval of 90%). allocation scenario. This is similar to a phenomenon known
Margarita Protopappa-Sieke and Ralf W. Seifert—Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains 527

2500 1000

900

Optimal allowance
Optimal allowance

2000 800

700

1500 600

500

1000 400

300

500 200

100

0 0
Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint

0. 3 0.5 0.7 0. 2 0. 5 0.8

CV CR
(a) Supplier Retailer Joint (b)
Figure 2 Sensitivity analysis.

Table 2 Difference between joint and dedicated allocation

CR Optimal working capital allowance Total cost

CV CV

0.3 0.5 0.7 0.3 0.5 0.7

0.2 25.6% 13.7% -23.0% -14.5% -14.6% -32.0%


0.5 24.6% 10.0% -19.1% -12.1% -15.3% -30.0%
0.8 18.9% 3.0% -18.1% -14.3% -15.1% -36.9%

1000 1200

900 -12.6%
1000
800 -14.3%
Optimal allowance

-16.4%
700
800
Total cost

600

500 600

400

300 400

200
200
100

0
Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint 0
1% 5% 10%
1% 5% 10%
Interest rate
Interest rate
(a) (b)
Supplier Retailer Joint Dedicated Joint
Figure 3 Allowance and cost for symmetric interest rates.

as ‘‘double-marginalization’’ observed in decentralized supply delays result in higher optimal allowances, because longer
chains. With the dedicated allocation, the supplier is penalized payment delays result in higher total cost. Working capital
twice: (1) by the downstream payment delays he allows the utilization deteriorates with the dedicated allocation and
retailer and (2) by the downstream payment delays the retailer ameliorates with the joint allocation. Since with the joint
allows his customers. allocation scenario the penalization of the downstream
Figure 5 illustrates the corresponding percentage change in payment delays is only once, the working capital utilization
the optimal allowance. It can be seen that longer payment is better.
528 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

Dedicated Joint
Difference in total cost

Difference in total cost


50% 50%

40% 40%

30% 30%

20% 20%

10%
10%

0%
0%
1% 5% 10%
1% 5% 10%
Interest rate Interest rate
(a) (b)
3 periods payment delay 5 periods payment delay

Figure 4 Cost of symmetric payment delays.

Dedicated Joint

Difference in optimal
4%
Difference in optimal

30%

25%
3%
allowance
allowance

20%

15% 2%

10%
1%
5%
1%

0% 0%
1% 5% 10% 1% 5% 10%

Interest rate Interest rate


(a) (b)
3 periods payment delay 5 periods payment delay
Figure 5 Allowance for symmetric payment delays.

Dedicated Join t
600% 600%
Difference in total cost
Difference in total cost

500% 500%

400% 400%

300% 300%

200% 200%

100% 100%

0% 0%
1% 5% 10% 1% 5% 10%

Interest rate Interest rate

(a) (b)
3 periods lead time 5 periods lead time
Figure 6 Cost for symmetric lead times.

We assume that strong members can have same lead times. time. As expected, longer lead times result in higher total cost
Figure 6 illustrates the percentage difference in total cost for for both allocation scenarios, with the increase being more
various symmetric lead times, compared with a case of no lead pronounced for the dedicated allocation. Figure 7 presents the
Margarita Protopappa-Sieke and Ralf W. Seifert—Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains 529

Dedicated Joint

Difference in optimal
Difference in optimal

350% 350%

300% 300%

allowance
allowance

250% 250%

200% 200%

150% 150%

100% 100%

50% 50%

0% 0%
1% 5% 10% 1% 5% 10%

Interest rate Interest rate


(a) (b)
3 periods lead time 5 periods lead time
Figure 7 Allowance for symmetric lead times.

corresponding percentage increase in the optimal allowance. allocation scenario and (2) higher working capital uti-
Longer lead times result in higher allowances for both lization for the joint allocation scenario.
allocation scenarios. A higher allowance is required to hedge
Observation 6 onger symmetric lead times result in (1)
against the higher uncertainty a longer lead time entails, as
higher total cost, (2) higher optimal allowance, and (3)
both members need more inventory on stock to satisfy
lower average depository cash outflows, for both alloca-
customers’ demands as lead time increases.
tion scenarios.
The following observations summarize our main findings.
Observation 3 The joint allocation achieves significant cost
4.2. Strong Member vs. Weak Member
savings compared with the dedicated allocation scenario.
Those significant cost savings decrease when symmetric In this section, we investigate the impact of asymmetric
interest rates increase. interest rates, payment delays, and lead times on a supply
chain consisting of a strong and a weak member.
Observation 4 Longer symmetric payment delays result in
First, we look at the impact of asymmetric interest rates. We
(1) higher total cost, (2) higher optimal allowance, and
consider three different interest rate values: (1%, 5%), (5%,
(3) lower average depository cash outflows, for both
5%), and (10%, 5%). Figure 8 demonstrates the corresponding
allocation scenarios.
total cost and optimal allowance. Significant cost savings are
Observation 5 Longer symmetric payment delays result in observed with the joint allocation. The optimal allowance is
(1) lower working capital utilization for the dedicated robust in interest rate changes.

1000
-16.0% 1000
-10.6%
Optimal Allowance

900 -5.7% 900


16.8% 16.8% 16.8%
800
800
Total Cost

700
700
600
600
500
500
400
400
300
300
200
200
100
100
0
[1%,5] [5%,5%] [10%,5%] 0
Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint
[1%,5] [5%,5%] [10%,5%]

Interest rates Interest rates

(a) (b)
Dedicated Joint Supplier Retailer Joint
Figure 8 Cost and allowance for asymmetric interest rates.
530 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

1600

1600 1400

Optimal allowance
1400
1200
-42.8%
Total cost

1200
1000
-33.3%
1000
-6.9% -16.1% 18.9% 20.5%
800 800

600 600

400
400
200
200
0
(0, 0) (0, 3) (3, 0) 0
Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint

(0, 0) (0, 3) (3, 0)

(u1 , u 2 ) (u1 , u 2 )
(a) (b)
Dedicated Joint Supplier Retailer Joint

Figure 9 Cost and allowance for symmetric payment delays.

We assume that the strong member can negotiate for longer allocation. When the upstream payment delays increase, a
upstream or shorter downstream payment delays. We consider higher optimal allowance is required such that the cash benefit
three payment delays schemes: (1) no payment delays, (2) from the lower cash outflows is not sent to the depository.
3-period upstream payment delay for the supplier, and (3) When the retailer has upstream payment delays, a lower
3-period upstream payment delay for the retailer. We demon- optimal allowance is required for the joint allocation. The
strate our results for an interest rate of 5%. We examined both main reason is the dual role of these payment delays. On the
interest rates of 1% and 10% with similar results. Figure 9 one hand, the retailer requires a higher allowance in order to
illustrates the total cost and the optimal allowance. Significant compensate for his higher cash position due to his upstream
cost savings are achieved with the joint allocation, which are payment delays. On the other hand, the supplier requires a
more significant the more constrained the supply chain, significantly higher optimal allowance to make up for his
(u1 = 3, u2 = 0). Extending payment delays results in higher reduced cash inflows.
supply chain costs. When the retailer extends his upstream We assume that the strong member has shorter lead time.
payment delays, the total cost is higher for both allocation We consider three lead time schemes: (1) no lead time,
scenarios. When the supplier has upstream payment delays, the (2) 3-period lead time for the supplier, and (3) 3-period lead
optimal allowance increases for the joint allocation. This is time for the retailer. We demonstrate our results for a
because the upstream payment delays of the supplier are the symmetric interest rate of 5%. Figure 10 illustrates the
upstream payment delays of the whole supply chain in the joint corresponding total cost and optimal allowance. Significant

3000 1800

-41.2% 1600
2500
Optimal allowance

1400

1200 -36.8%
Total cost

2000
1000
-13.9%
18.9%
1500
-16.6%
800

600
1000
-6.9%
400

500 200

0
0 Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint Dedicated Joint
(0,0) (0, 3) (3,0)
(0,0) (0,3) (3,0)

( L1 , L2 ) ( L1 , L2 )
(a) (b)
Dedicated Joint Supplier Retailer Joint

Figure 10 Cost and allowance for asymmetric lead times.


Margarita Protopappa-Sieke and Ralf W. Seifert—Benefits of working capital sharing in supply chains 531

cost savings are achieved with the joint allocation. These cost Viskari and Kärri (2012) who present five scenarios that
benefits are higher when there is lead time between the retailer enable inter-organizational collaborative working capital man-
and the supplier, i.e., -41.2% compared with -16.6%. The agement and reduce the financing costs. The authors also find
optimal allowance decreases with the joint allocation scenario reduction of approximately 10%–20% depending on the action
compared with the dedicated allocation for asymmetric lead taken with respect to the cash conversion cycle.
times. From Figure 10b, it can be observed that the optimal The contribution of our paper is threefold: First, we discuss
allowance with the joint allocation is less than with the a promising way of financing the supply chain that can be used
dedicated allocation. to increase liquidity among the involved supply chain partners
and is based on a joint cash pool. Second, we discuss and
Observation 7 Extending payment delays to a supplier
quantify different working capital allocation scenarios and
upstream results in higher supply chain costs.
show their impact on operational decisions and financial
Observation 8 Significant cost savings are achieved with the planning. Third, we discuss a very practical problem that is
joint allocation for a supply chain with a strong and a highly intertwined to the existing supply chain financial
weak member. solutions and we are able to quantify its benefits. We present a
base model for including such allocation scenarios on
inventory decisions. Many limitations exist for this study
5. Conclusion due to the dynamic nature of working capital and the payment
delays. The optimality of a base-stock policy cannot be
Efficient working capital management in a supply chain can proven, which necessitates the use of simulation. In our model,
achieve significant cost savings as it enables weak members to we do not allow the members of the supply chain to resort to
secure the necessary financing. Better visibility of cash and any external financing from a bank, apart from the initial
product flows results in better utilization of working capital endowment. Furthermore, we only include cash and inventory
and a supply chain that is more responsive to market needs. In and exclude vital constituents of working capital. Many
this paper, we investigate the benefits when the members of a promising future research avenues exist, for example, dynamic
supply chain may make use of a joint pool of working capital, risk considerations, i.e., dynamically varying interest rates,
compared to current practices where each member of a supply financing terms, and working capital financing. In our
chain has its own dedicated working capital. We investigate research, we have assumed that the unit ordering and
the impact of interest rate, payment delays, and lead time on purchasing cost do not depend on the payment delay terms.
the supply chain costs. We also examine two settings of a two- However, a more representative approach would be to allow
stage supply chain. The first consisting of two strong members for unit ordering and purchasing costs to vary according to the
and the second consisting of one strong and one weak member. payment terms, i.e., a common trade-credit is 2–10 net 30
A strong member can negotiate better in terms of capital which indicates a 2% discount if payment is received within
financing, trade-credit, and lead time than a weak member. 10 days and that payment is expected in 30 days, or even to
In our paper, we illustrate how working capital restrictions consider external sources of financing.
affect the operations of a supply chain and how different
working capital allocation scenarios influence the operational
flows and the financial flows. More specifically, we demon-
References
strate that collaborative approaches can actually benefit the
operations of the supply chain. Our results demonstrate Babich V (2010). Independence of capacity ordering and financial
significant cost savings with a joint allocation compared with subsidies to risky suppliers. Manufacturing & Service Operations
a dedicated allocation. These cost savings are greater for Management 12(4): 583-607.
higher coefficient of variation. Since innovative products are Bernabucci RJ (2008). Supply chain gains from integrations. Finan-
cial Executive 24(3): 46–48.
characterized by high-demand uncertainty (Fisher, 1997), it is
Buzacott JA and Zhang RQ (2004). Inventory management with asset-
even more profitable for the members of a supply chain to based financing. Management Science 50(9): 1274–1292.
share working capital when the products delivered from this Cachon GP (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In de
supply chain are innovative. Last, we want to examine how Kok AG and Graves SC (Eds.), Handbooks in Operations Research
payment delays impact the overall performance and the supply and Management Science: Supply Chain Management (Vol. 11,
pp. 229–340). Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V.
chain costs. Through our results, we identify an effect similar
Clark AJ and Scarf H (1960). Optimal policies for a multi-echelon
to the ‘‘double-marginalization,’’ due to the double penaliza- inventory problem. Management Science 6(4): 475–490.
tion of the supplier from the customers’ downstream payment Danske Bank (2016). Cash pool. Retrieved from http://www.
delays. One important finding is that extending payment danskebank.lv/en/business/corporate/cash-management/cash-pool/.
delays to a supplier results in higher supply chain costs and, DiBenedetto, B. (2007). Spreading the wealth. Journal of Commerce
8(48): 24.
thus, a company should consider the overall impact on the
Farris II MT and Hutchison PD (2002). Cash-to-cash: the new supply
supply chain total cost when deciding to extend their payment chain management metric. International Journal of Physical
delays to their supplier. Our findings are aligned to those of Distribution & Logistics Management 32(4): 288–298.
532 Journal of the Operational Research Society Vol. 68, No. 5

Federgruen A and Zipkin P (1986). An inventory model with limited Protopappa-Sieke M and Seifert RW (2010). Interrelating operational
production capacity and uncertain demands I. The average-cost and financial performance measurements in inventory control.
criterion. Mathematics of Operations Research 11(2): 193–207. European Journal of Operational Research 204(3): 439–448.
Fisher ML (1997). What is the right supply chain for your product? PWC (2015). Cross-border RMB cash pooling. Retrieved from http://
Harvard Business Review 75(2): 105–116. www.pwccn.com/webmedia/doc/635592516794030922_chinatax_
Goyal SK (1985). Economic order quantity under conditions of news_feb2015_7.pdf.
permissible delay in payments. Journal of the Operational Randall WS and Theodore Farris M (2009). Supply chain financing:
Research Society 36(4): 335–338. using cash-to-cash variables to strengthen the supply chain.
Gupta D and Wang L (2009). A stochastic inventory model with trade International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Man-
credit. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 11(1): agement 39(8): 669–689.
4–18. Seifert, D and Seifert, R. W. (2011). Financing the supply chain.
Gupta S and Dutta K (2011). Modeling of financial supply chain. International Commerce Review 10(1): 32–44.
European Journal of Operational Research 211(1): 47–56. Seifert D, Seifert RW and Protopappa-Sieke M (2013). A review of
Hausman WH (2002). Supply chain performance metrics. In Billing- trade credit literature: Opportunities for research in operations.
ton C, Harrison T, Lee N and Neale J (Eds.) The Practise of Supply European Journal of Operational Research 231(2): 245–256.
Chain Management. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Seifert RW, Thonemann UW and Sieke MA (2006). Integrating direct
Heyman DP and Sobel MJ (1984). Stochastic Models in Operations and indirect sales channels under decentralized decision-making.
Research, Volume II. New York: Dover Publications Inc. International Journal of Production Economics 103(1): 209–229.
Kaplan SN and Zingales L (1997). Do investment-cash flow Sopranzetti BJ (1998). The economics of factoring accounts receiv-
sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints? able. Journal of Economics and Business 50(4): 339–359.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(1): 169–215. Tanrisever F, Cetinay H, Reindorp M and Fransoo J (2012). Value of
Klapper L (2006). The role of factoring for financing small and reverse factoring in multi-stage supply chains. Working paper.
medium enterprises. Journal of Banking and Finance 30(11): Available at SSRN, 2183991.
3111–3130. van der Vliet K, Reindorp MJ and Fransoo JC (2015). The price of
Kouvelis P and Zhao W (2012). Financing the newsvendor: supplier reverse factoring: Financing rates vs. payment delays. European
vs. bank, and the structure of optimal trade credit contracts. Journal of Operational Research 242(3): 842–853.
Operations Research 60(3): 566–580. Viskari S and Kärri T (2012). A model for working capital
Li L, Shubik M and Sobel MJ (2013). Control of dividends, capital management in the inter-organisational context. International
subscriptions, and physical inventories. Management Science Journal of Integrated Supply Management 7(1–3): 61–79.
59(5): 1107–1124. Wuttke, D. A, Blome, C, Foerstl, K and Henke, M. (2013). Managing
Longinidis P and Georgiadis MC (2011). Integration of financial the innovation adoption of supply chain finance—Empirical
statement analysis in the optimal design of supply chain networks evidence from six European case studies. Journal of Business
under demand uncertainty. International Journal of Production Logistics 34(2): 148–166.
Economics 129(2): 262–276. Wuttke DA, Blome C, Hesse HS and Protopappa-Sieke M (2016).
Maddah BS, Jaber MY and Abboud NE (2004). Periodic review (s, S) Supply chain finance: optimal introduction and adoption decisions.
inventory model with permissible delay in payments. Journal of International Journal of Production Economics 178: 72–81.
the operational research society 55(2): 147–159.
Mian S and Smith C (1992). Accounts receivable management policy: Received 1 February 2016;
Theory and evidence. The Journal of Finance 47(1): 169–200.
Porteus EL (2002). Foundations of Stochastic Inventory Theory. accepted 24 May 2016
California: Stanford University Press.

You might also like