You are on page 1of 16

World Development Vol. 56, pp.

16–31, 2014
Ó 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.10.008

Does Commercialization Undermine the Benefits


of Decentralization for Local Services Provision?
Evidence from Mexico’s Urban Water and Sanitation Sector
VERONICA HERRERA *
University of Connecticut, USA
Summary. — Decentralization has been promoted as a means to better reflect citizen preferences and improve local services. Many
developing countries decentralized and promoted neoliberal policies such as commercialization simultaneously, leaving mayors with
the responsibility of improving public services through self-financing reforms. This study evaluates experiences in three Mexican cities
to assess whether decentralization and commercialization practices have resulted in improved water and sanitation services. It finds that
commercialization has increased social conflict surrounding urban services provision and that local institutional constraints further
undermine mayor’s ability to adopt politically contentious policies. The result has been stalled and uneven service improvements.
Ó 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — Latin America, Mexico, water, decentralization, commercialization, public services

1. INTRODUCTION takes” to improve public services through self-financing re-


forms that may face considerable political resistance?
Effective local government can be a catalyst for develop- This paper argues that when combined with neoliberal com-
ment. Democratic transitions and decentralization reforms mercialization practices, “bringing services closer to the peo-
have brought the importance of local government perfor- ple” can increase political conflict surrounding public
mance to the forefront of development studies (Andersson, services delivery, which can adversely affect public services
Gibson, & Lehoucq, 2006; Angell, Lowden, & Thorp, 2001; performance. In addition, the intense political conflict that
Crook & Manor, 1998; Grindle, 2007; Larson, 2002; Olowu commercializing public services occasions can undermine the
& Wunsch, 2004). Local government’s ability to “deliver” potential benefits of decentralization, such as increased user
increasingly determines citizens’ access to quality public ser- buy-in for services, participation, and accountability. This pa-
vices, economic development opportunities, and local environ- per makes two arguments based on evidence from Mexico’s
mental resources. Positive local government performance has urban water and sanitation (W&S) sector. First, following
not only been associated with important development out- decentralization, local governments were made to adopt com-
comes, but also with bolstering citizen’s perception of demo- mercialization practices as part of a wider neoliberal reform
cratic governance more broadly (Hiskey & Seligson, 2003; package that generated extensive social backlash. Commer-
Weitz-Shapiro, 2008). cialization featured dramatic tariff increases and stringent col-
Policymakers have argued that when services are “brought lection enforcement that were politically unpopular due to a
closer to the people,” citizens may be able to more effectively long history of subsidized or free water service. Although poor
hold governments accountable for service improvements. 1 service quality is not without political costs to mayors, the dis-
Proponents have reasoned that locally administered services satisfaction consumers have with services is often diffuse and
would better fit local needs and citizen preferences, increasing disperse, whereas price increases, particularly given the delin-
accountability and government responsiveness, because citi- quent services being provided, are more likely to generate
zens—as participatory agents—would have a more direct acute backlash. Second, important institutional constraints
interest in, and provide support for, better government. 2 at the municipal level further impeded the adoption of socially
While a broad literature has examined factors that shape contentious commercialization policies. These institutional
decentralization outcomes, less attention has been paid to constraints include three-year municipal administrations, a
how neoliberal policies shape decentralization 3 outcomes in prohibition on immediate re-election, administrative
local services provision. Neoliberal, or market-oriented, poli-
cies for public services include eliminating subsidies for service
provision, implementing commercialization strategies to re- * I would like to thank Colleen Phelan, Gabriela Tafoya, and Stephanie
cover costs of services through user fees, and generally apply- Ullrich for research assistance. The research for this project was supported
ing business management strategies. Decentralization and by the Fulbright Institute for International Education program, the
neoliberal policies for public services have been frequently University of California Institute for Mexico and the United States (UC
promoted in tandem, which makes the lack of attention to MEXUS) Dissertation Research Grant, and the Simpson Memorial
how these two processes interact surprising. This study at- Fellowship at the Institute for International Studies at the University of
tempts to fill this lacuna. How do neoliberal policies affect California, Berkeley. I am very grateful to Kent Eaton, Lindsay Mayka,
the potential benefits of decentralization when administered Jennifer Brass, Jefferey Sellers, and three anonymous reviewers for
at the local level? What types of institutional constraints do thoughtful suggestions on this draft, and Alison Post and Ruth Berins
municipal governments face when contemplating the adoption Collier for extended feedback on the overall project. Final revision acce-
of neoliberal policies? Do local governments “have what it pted: October 5, 2013.
16
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 17

appointments that follow the electoral calendar, and a lack of of W&S in each state would help to make this conclusion more
a civil service program. These constraints have shortened the definitive.
policymaking window of municipal government and further The next section situates the argument around debates in the
weakened its capacity to govern. Taken together, these politi- literature, and Section 3 reviews the federal promotion of
cal and institutional challenges have compromised the ability decentralization and commercialization in Mexico’s W&S
of urban governments to improve public services through sector. Section 4 presents available data for a wider range of
self-financing reforms after decentralization. cities in Mexico and Section 5 examines three urban cases to
evaluate the impact of commercialization policies and local
(a) Methods institutional context on W&S performance after decentraliza-
tion.
I utilize “process tracing” to examine how macro level pro-
cesses interacted with local level context to create disincentives
to improving local services. This study examines Mexico, a 2. DECENTRALIZATION, COMMERCIALIZATION,
country that has experienced an extensive amount of both AND GOVERNMENT PERFORMANCE
decentralization 4 and neoliberal policies, and selects the
W&S sector, which 79% of all Mexican mayors list as the most Despite its theorized benefits, much of the literature examin-
important municipal responsibility (Moreno-Jaimes, 2007a, p. ing decentralization and local government performance finds
142). Process tracing unpacks the causal mechanism as a se- that decentralization has not turned out to be a panacea in
quenced “chain of events” (Beach & Pedersen, 2013; Bennett, practice. Studies have found that decentralization may exacer-
2010, p. 209; Falleti & Lynch, 2009); specifically the study bate regional inequalities (Mizrahi, 2004; Prud’homme, 1995,
traces how two-macro-level processes—decentralization and pp. 202–205), be captured by local elites (Blair, 2000, p. 25;
neoliberal commercialization—interacted with the political Boone, 2003; J. Fox, 1994; Selee & Tulchin, 2004, pp. 309–
and institutional context within Mexican municipalities to dis- 310) or hampered by local-level corruption (Prud’homme,
incentivize the adoption of cost recovery, adversely affecting 1995, p. 211; Veron, Williams, Corbridge, & Srivastava,
service outcomes. This qualitative method allows me to under- 2006). Coordination problems within government (Fiszbein,
score the “decision process” actors used, what stimuli actors 1997, pp. 1039–1040; Francis & James, 2003, p. 333) as well
responded to, and the impact of institutions on behavior as aid agencies (Smoke, 2003, p. 13) may also undermine local
(George & McKeown, 1985, pp. 21–58). I utilize evidence performance. 7 Others have noted that decentralization strate-
gathered during extensive field research that entailed 180 in- gies have in some cases reinforced central control (Dickovick,
depth interviews, data collection from internal government 2007; Eaton, 2001; Wunsch, 2001), and in other settings made
documents, newspaper articles, and archival material. The municipalities dependent on intermediate tiers of governments
causal leverage of this study is gained from “within-case” anal- (Fenwick, 2010, pp. 166–176; Grindle, 2007, pp. 29–33).
ysis, which methodologists have recently noted provides great- A number of studies are more optimistic about local govern-
er causal inference than controlled case comparisons with a ment performance outcomes after decentralization. Numerous
small number of cases (Beach & Pedersen, 2013, pp. 81–82; studies have examined how participatory governance institu-
Brady & Collier, 2010, p. 10; George & Bennett, 2005, Chapter tions can bolster government performance, 8 and how strong
8; Goertz & Mahoney, 2012, pp. 87–90). civil society networks increase the effectiveness of local policy-
Three municipal cases are presented to demonstrate the dif- making after decentralization (Agrawal & Ostrom, 2001, p.
ferent pathways through which political conflict and institu- 508; Andersson et al., 2006, p. 580; Devas & Grant, 2003, p.
tional constraints can impede service improvements. 5 I select 315; Faguet, 2009; Fiszbein, 1997, pp. 1034–1035; Kauneckis
three of the largest urban centers within the same state govern- & Andersson, 2009; Tendler, 1997). Many studies emphasize
ment, Mexico State (Estado de México): Naucalpan, leadership as a key ingredient for improving local government
Nezahualcóyotl (Neza), and Toluca. Mexico State is an eco- performance after decentralization. Decentralization can ush-
nomic powerhouse: it has the highest Gross Domestic Product er in educated and capable mayors, whose leadership and
(GDP) contribution of any state, at 8.8% of GDP, and it is innovation may transform city hall (Cabrero-Mendoza,
also the most densely populated state in Mexico, with 13.8% 2000, pp. 377–378; Fiszbein, 1997, p. 1033; Gilbert, 2006,
of the population (CNA, 2011a, p. 16). Mexico State is a crit- pp. 404–405; Grindle, 2007, pp. 85–104). Mayors may play a
ical case for examining whether decentralization and commer- crucial role in determining whether decentralization man-
cialization policies have helped improve public services in dates—in many cases from above—will be implemented
Mexico more broadly. Such a wealthy state would be the least (Andersson et al., 2006, p. 577; Devas & Grant, 2003, p.
likely to have public services deficiencies, so if we identify ser- 315). Even instances of increased civic participation have been
vice problems within Mexico State’s urban centers, we are linked to mayoral initiative in sponsoring spaces for delibera-
likely to see them throughout the country in poorer and less tion and accountability (Andersson & Laerhoven, 2007; Fisz-
industrialized regions. Selecting cities within one state govern- bein, 1997, pp. 1034–1035; Van Cott, 2009; Wampler, 2007, p.
ment allows me to hold constant a number of important fac- 4). While mayoral will is important for municipal reform, I ar-
tors that would vary more widely in cross-national designs gue that decentralization strategies may be part of a larger
(Snyder, 2001), and further control for variation in state level package of policies that when taken together, hinder the abil-
policy toward urban services. 6 However, these cities, with var- ity of mayors to improve government performance despite
ied geographies and water availability, and varied political best intentions or innovative policymaking. Specifically, when
competition and socioeconomic class makeup, also reflect decentralization is accompanied by unpopular commercializa-
the type of geopolitical variation found throughout Mexico. tion policies, mayors may lack the political incentives to re-
Finally, I present data for a larger number of cases, including form services.
national averages, and taken together, I argue that the data Commercialization of public services has been a pervasive
suggest that the challenges faced by these three cities after policy initiative in many developing countries around the
these macro-level reforms plague the majority of Mexican world and has been promoted as part of a wider package of
municipalities, although future research into the conditions neoliberal policies for the public sector. These policies are
18 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

ideologically consistent with New Public Management Furthermore, mayors often control city council agendas with-
(NPM) 9 strategies designed to modernize government out counterweights, replicating systems of centralized control
through the application of market principles (Barzelay & at the local level (Cabrero-Mendoza, 2000, p. 380), and mak-
Armajani, 1992; Batley & Larbi, 2004, pp. 31–53; Islam, ing reform agendas overly dependent on the mayor’s will.
1993; Osborne & Gaebler, 1992). NPM strategies have in- These types of institutional constraints—all of which are per-
cluded managed competition, performance contracts, the cre- vasive in Mexico—weaken local policymaking capacity and
ation of autonomous service providers, 10 and promoted full make even the most innovative mayors’ reform agenda subject
cost recovery through the rigorous application of user fees. to policy reversal. The possibility of passing socially conten-
Based on these market-oriented tenets, the public sector has tious reforms and making them “stick” in the long-term is
also adopted private sector accounting and budgeting prac- an overwhelming challenge in this type of weak institutional
tices, the use of performance indicators, outsourcing of por- environment.
tions of services delivery, the use of external consultants,
and the concept of the citizen as customer. In the W&S sector,
commercialization has been widely adopted (Bayliss, 2008; 3. BACKGROUND: FEDERAL ADOPTION OF
Dagdeviren, 2008; Furlong & Bakker, 2010; Gilbert, 2007; DECENTRALIZATION AND COMMERCIALIZATION
Krause, 2009; Morgan, 2011; Nickson & Franceys, 2003; POLICIES IN W&S
Smith, 2004). These reforms have also been promoted in other
urban services, such as trash collection, electricity, and trans- (a) Conditions prior to reforms: centralization and subsidies
portation (Gilbert, 2006, p. 406; McDonald & Smith, 2004, (1946–1976)
pp. 1469–1470; Mehta & Pathak, 1998; Miraftab, 2004, pp.
876–877) and health care and education (Colclough, 1997; Gil- Like many countries in the west, the history of Mexico’s
son, 1997; Nolan & Turbat, 1995). While a handful of studies water management has vacillated between local (pre 1946),
stress that reforming services largely through cost recovery centralized (1946–1976), 13 and local (post 1980s). Although
provokes social backlash (McDonald & Ruiters, 2005; Mor- the 1917 constitution designated water services as a municipal
gan, 2011; Smith, 2004), less is known about why commercial- responsibility, Mexico’s federalist system was highly con-
ization of public services is politically unpopular and how the trolled by the center, and water services were no exception.
political challenges of commercialization may undermine The creation of the National Water Ministry (Secretarı́a de
decentralization objectives. Recursos Hidráulicos, or SRH) in 1946 centralized many exist-
Commercialization of services provision entails breaking ing local water systems and began a period of network expan-
with historic clientelist exchanges of subsidized services in ex- sion throughout the country under one-party Partido
change for political support. For W&S, commercializing ser- Revolucionario Institucional (PRI) rule. PRI officials recog-
vices implies steep tariff increases, stringent collection nized the role of water for irrigation as central to economic
practices that suspend service for non-payment, the elimination development, but also viewed developing urban water services
of clandestine (or informal) connections, and the introduction as fundamentally important for development objectives (Abo-
of metered service or pre-paid meters. These practices can be ites, 1998, p. 162; Whiteford & Melville, 2002, p. 16). By 1973,
especially contentious for the urban poor who are dispropor- the SRH operated water systems directly in 554 cities, and
tionately disadvantaged by tariff hikes and rely heavily on clan- indirectly financed and administered at least 400 other systems
destine connections. Commercialization of services can throughout the country (World Bank, 1976, p. 25).
engender extreme dissatisfaction, litigation, and mass mobili- Control of these systems from the center was pervasive: util-
zation. Mayors may also find commercialization unappealing: ities were managed from Mexico City in a top-down fashion,
they may want to avoid social backlash, continue to benefit making it difficult for local operators to even change a water
from clientelistic exchange, or prefer not to expend resources valve without authorization from the center. It was common
in collecting fees. These challenges can be exacerbated in new for the federal government to construct a local water project
democracies where new parties may be governing at the local without any input from local leaders or citizens, and then
level for the first time. If centralized governments thought it transfer systems to locals who felt little ownership of the pro-
politically expedient to subsidize services historically, I argue ject and had few system maintenance resources (World Bank,
that local governments are even less poised to adopt socially 1992, p. 45).
contentious commercialization practices. Centralized control of water systems was further reinforced
In addition, local governments often suffer from administra- by subsidized financing schemes. Water fee structures were
tive shortcomings that hinder performance, such as inexperi- outdated and there was no “consumer base;” citizens received
enced and under-qualified staff (Crook & Manor, 1998, p. water free of charge or for a token fee. One federal document
287; Wunsch, 2001, p. 281). Mexican municipal employees notes that payment was often not collected, metering was min-
are often inexperienced due to a lack of a local civil service, imal, and water prices remained low (SARH, 1976, p. 291).
and cronyism in personnel appointments (Cabrero Mendoza, Table 1 shows 1960s tariffs ranging from $MXP 0.68–0.74,
2007, p. 166; Camp, 2003, pp. 117–122; Moreno-Jaimes, but official figures indicate that the average cost of providing
2007b). Other shortcomings of municipal government are service ranged from $MXP 1.50–1.75 (SRH, 1973, p. 208).
structural, such as prohibitions on immediate re-election, short Prices were not only low for domestic consumers, one study
three year administrations, and the lack of legal authority to notes that commercial and industrial users were charged only
mandate legislative action, leaving municipal policies “non-rat- 30% of the long-run marginal cost of providing service (World
ified” in legislation and prone to policy reversal (Cabrero-Men- Bank, 1990, p. 13). A 1964 international mission notes that
doza, 2000, pp. 379–380). “even though operating agencies admit their water rates are
Examples of these institutional constraints are found too low, both in respect to costs and to the capacity of the peo-
throughout Latin America. 11 For example, re-election is pro- ple to pay, the rates have not been sufficiently increased be-
hibited in countries such as Mexico, Guatemala, Honduras, cause of inertia and political considerations” (World Bank,
and Paraguay. 12 And in many countries, local government 1964, p. 2). Another observer notes: “fees collected. . .seldom
administrations are relatively short, from 2 to 4 years. cover[ed] the maintenance costs of the water supply
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 19

Table 1. Water tariffs in 1960s Mexico Table 2. Private participation in Mexico’s water and sanitation sector
Population Price per m3 ($MXP) PP type Project count
>2,500 $0.68 Concession 5
2,500–5,000 $0.73 Greenfield projectsa 24
5,000–20,000 $0.67 Management & lease 1
20,000–50,000 $0.71 Total 30
50,000–100,000 $0.68 Source: PPIAF. Downloaded April 2012.
>100,000 $0.74 a
Includes build, lease & transfer (BLOT); build, operate & transfer (BOT)
Source: SRH (1973). and build, own & operate (BOO).

system. . .people are simply not accustomed to paying for


water” (Rodrı́guez, 1997, p. 120). loan conditions mandated operating rules that strengthened
Economic crisis and demographic growth revealed the cen- commercialization practices for urban utilities. APAZU re-
tralized era of water provision to be financially untenable by quired “performance based financing,” whereby urban utilities
the 1970s. Many connections suffered from poor service qual- were to raise “matching funds” through cost recovery in order
ity, leading the population to suffer a relatively high incidence to qualify for APAZU funds for infrastructure development.
of water-borne disease and a child mortality rate of over 70 IFI loan conditions mandated that the CNA eventually elim-
times that of the United States (World Bank, 1975, p. 10). inate grant based subsidies to the sector, and sector financing
70% of urban populations had access to piped water, and sew- derived from IFI loans follow APAZU operating rules (World
erage coverage was much lower at 40%. The unreliability of lo- Bank, 1990, p. 11).
cal systems led many businesses to operate their own In order to access APAZU funds, urban utilities would have
boreholes; indeed, the share of industrial and commercial con- to be decentralized to the municipal level and operate with le-
sumption totaled only 10% of total consumption in 1990 gal, fiscal, and administrative autonomy from city hall (World
(World Bank, 1990, p. 5). Bank, 1990, pp. 15–17). A legally autonomous water utility
has independent legal character in court (can sue or be sued).
(b) Decentralization and commercialization policies Fiscal independence implied the ability to generate internal
(1980s–2012) revenue from user charges, set budgets and determine expendi-
tures, and receive federal revenues directly. Administrative
Decentralization and commercialization practices were two autonomy signified independence in hiring decisions and oper-
distinct policies promoted in the urban W&S sector under a ational policy. Proponents hoped that by creating autono-
larger rubric of public sector reform in Mexico. 14 Decentral- mous utilities, mayors would be blocked from intervening in
ization of water services began with the dismantling of the daily operations and fiscal accounts. The policy objectives
SRH in 1976. In 1980, a presidential decree transferred for APAZU were reflected in the National W&S Program
1,549 federally administered systems to state and municipal for 1989–1994, which emphasized treating water as an eco-
governments (DOF, 1980; SAHOP, 1981), and in 1983, a con- nomic good, cost recovery, service suspension for non-pay-
stitutional amendment to Article 115 mandated decentraliza- ment, and “performance-based” financing schemes (CNA,
tion of water services to municipalities. By the time the 1993, pp. 47–48, 59–68). APAZU operating rules prompted
National Water Commission (CNA) was created in 1989, it most major metropolitan cities to create legally autonomous
was designed to be an institutional rector for (among other utilities 17 and as of 2009, a total of 2,571 legally autonomous
things) promoting decentralization and commercialization, utilities have been created, 637 of which serve populations
but unlike its predecessor, was not to deliver services directly. over 20,000 (IMTA, 2011). 18
In the event of municipalities being unable to provide services, Have decentralized W&S utilities been able to improve ser-
state governments became the “provider of last resort.” vice provision through commercialization reforms? The fol-
Concurrently, international financial institution (IFI) policy lowing section provides a general overview of utilities
influenced both decentralization and commercialization prac- performance in Mexico that suggests that utilities are, on aver-
tices in the urban W&S subsector, as part of a broader neolib- age, generally underperforming after the implementation of
eral multi-sector water reform (including urban, rural, these twin reforms.
irrigation, and watershed management) (Wilder & Romero
Lankao, 2006). IFI loans in the urban W&S subsector that be-
gan in 1975 15 and expanded in the 1990s promoted a new 4. MEASURING AND COMPARING W&S
market oriented federal policy in urban W&S. A National PERFORMANCE IN MEXICO
Water Law in 1992 reflected the changing global water policy
environment of treating water as an economic good, permit- Against what metrics should Mexico’s W&S sector be as-
ting private sector participation (PSP), and allowing for trad- sessed and how should performance or underperformance be
able water rights. Despite considerable promotion of measured? International benchmarking indicators for the
privatization in the 1990s, privatization contracts for W&S W&S sector measure performance by “core” indicators such
have been limited. Table 2 describes a total of 30 contracts, as coverage, physical efficiency of the network (volume con-
which account for less than 2% of all water services in the sumed/volume produced and volume billed/volume pro-
country (INEGI, 2009, p. 9). 16 duced), and fiscal indicators such as commercial efficiency
The more pervasive policy has been promoting commercial- (revenue collected/revenue billed) and % metering (see IB-
ization practices within the public sector for decentralized, NET, n.d.). Additional measures, such as service intermittency
municipal utilities; a policy agenda aided by IFI loans. In and water quality/potability, help provide a fuller picture of
the early 1990s, the federal government created a program service quality.
called APAZU (Programa Nacional de Agua Potable y Using these types of measures, I evaluate the level of
Alcantarillado en Zonas Urbanas) (see Appendix A), where “success” of the current state of Mexico’s W&S sector by
20 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

assessing whether there have been improvements over time consumer of bottled water, increasing from 157 liters per
with respect to the stated goals of federal level policymakers capita in 2003 to 480 liters per capita in 2010 (IADB, 2010,
implementing decentralization and commercialization. 19 p. 15). While water-related health indicators have improved
These goals were to increase coverage, the physical efficiency over time in Mexico, 24 they remain worse than other upper-
of systems, water quality and reliability, increase internal rev- middle income countries in Latin America; the mortality rate
enue generation, and decrease reliance on federal subsidies associated with intestinal infectious disease in Mexico in 2005
through cost recovery, and decrease environmental pollution was twice as high as in Argentina, four times as high as in
(CNA, 1994, pp. 9–10; World Bank, 1990, pp. 10–16). It is dif- Costa Rica, and 15 times as high as in Chile (World Bank,
ficult to measure performance in Mexico’s W&S because of 2005, p. 28, footnote 56). The pervasive “opting out” of tap
poor record keeping and the pervasive manipulation of perfor- water ingestion in Mexico suggests that widespread mistrust
mance figures by utilities attempting to access federal funds of municipal water may be due to poor water quality that
based on high performance. 20 The figures published by the has either decreased, or failed to noticeably improve over
CNA are self-reported, and there is no independent verifica- time. 25
tion to confirm their accuracy (Interviews #13, 19, 28). Never- Fourth, although there are no reliable figures on water util-
theless, CNA figures, while imperfect, provide the only ity revenue generation in Mexico, available data on the extent
available national averages of sector performance, and wher- to which utilities have become fiscally self-sufficient are dis-
ever possible, I have included other data collected during field couraging. While CNA data show a national average of
research that lends further evidence for the conclusions being 73.8% of commercial efficiency in 2012 (CNA, 2012, p. 60),
drawn. up from 46.2% in 2000 (CNA, 2000, p. 23), an analysis con-
Initial observations of increased performance seems promis- ducted by IMTA of CNA figures (using a different sample
ing: in 2010, Mexico had a national average of 91.2% water population) shows that commercial efficiency as a national
coverage and 89.9% sanitation coverage, increases from average has increased by only 1% in the last decade (IMTA,
81.9% to 65% respectively, since 1991 (CNA, 1992, p. 10, 2011). 26 In addition, the amount of metering as a national
2011b, p. 22). This varies by state, as evident in Appendix B. average has not increased substantially, with CNA figures reg-
However, coverage data can be misleading and obfuscates istering a considerable decrease from 67.4% in 2003 to 47.4%
serious deficiencies in service provision as measured in other in 2011, and IMTA figures (using a different sample popula-
types of performance figures. tion) registering a 3% increase during the same period (IMTA,
First, the amount of non-revenue water (volume billed/vol- 2011). These figures present limited increases or even decreases
ume produced) in urban centers is approximately 47% (CNA, in commercial efficiency and metering by the part of utilities
2010, p. 12) and in some cities considerably higher (CNA, and suggest limited to no improvements, on average, in fiscal
2012, p. Annex 1a; Universal., 2009b). Therefore, half of the self-sufficiency. Given that the total investment made in the
water being extracted is being diverted (an estimated 84% of sector since 2002 has doubled from 2002 to 2011, from .17%
lost water is due to leaky infrastructure and 16% to clandestine to .32% of GDP (IMTA, 2011), these data suggest that, on
connections) (CNA, 2010, p. 12). Problematically, the 2012 average, sector financing has not become less reliant on federal
non-revenue water figures have increased from reported num- transfers.
bers in 2000, which were 41% nationwide and 35% for urban Environmental degradation has also increased in terms of
centers (CNA, 2000, p. 26). A study by the Mexican Institute over extraction of underground aquifers and discharge of un-
of Water Technology (IMTA) finds that physical efficiency as treated wastewater. The number of over extracted aquifers (as
measured in terms of volume consumed/water produced has defined by extracting at a greater rate than annual replenish-
increased by less than 2% since 2002 (IMTA, 2011). 21 There- ment by the hydraulic cycle) has grown considerably in recent
fore, the physical condition of the network infrastructure, on decades, from 32 in 1975 to 100 in 2009 (CNA, 2011a, p. 34).
average, has worsened over time, or failed to noticeably Over extraction results in the entry of dangerous mineral com-
improve. 22 pounds in drinking water, and will have important negative
Second, intermittent service seems to affect a large portion consequences for future water security. Although wastewater
of the population and does not appear to be decreasing. In treatment capacity has increased, from 394 treatment plants
2000, one study estimated that 45% of households experienced in 1992 to 2,289 in 2011 (CNA, 2012, p. 49), field research re-
daily intermittency and 55% of households periodic intermit- vealed that a surprising number of these plants are not actually
tency in 2000 based on census data (World Bank, 2005, p. in operation, or are operating below their installed capacity due
27). Another survey in 2011 used a sample of utilities to esti- to disrepair, lack of technical expertise, or insufficient funds to
mate that intermittent service affected 24.2% of consumers in operate. While the CNA has commissioned experts to tackle
2002 and increased to 28.5% in 2011 (IMTA, 2011). Of the environmental degradation of watersheds, virtually no pro-
11 utilities surveyed during field research, only one of them graming exists for local utilities that promote lessening environ-
provided non-intermittent service, in the others many consum- mental degradation (Barkin, 2011, pp. 387–389).
ers receive water 2–3 times a week, a pervasive problem in Nevertheless, it is clear that some utilities in Mexico have
non-wealthy neighborhoods. While water intermittency is dif- performance figures that are quite high. For example Table 3
ficult to measure and data are sparse, taken together, these presents a sample of performance indicators for 12 utilities
data points suggest that water intermittency is a substantial published by the CNA 27 where cities like Mexicali, Monter-
service deficiency in Mexico, and seems to either be increasing rey, and Tijuana register relatively high levels of physical
or staying constant over time. and commercial efficiency. Indeed, there are a handful of
Third, water potability remains a serious problem through- “high” performers (e.g., CNA, 2011b, p. 93) throughout the
out the country. Water is contaminated throughout various country that have nearly full metering, over 90% commercial
points in the network: through pipes, in household cisterns, efficiency, over 70% physical efficiency, and that have man-
and due to ruptures in under-attended sewage lines. Danger- aged to decrease the amount of non-revenue water and service
ous compounds such as arsenic are routinely treated with little intermittency in the last decade.
more than chlorine. 23 Water potability has become such a However, I argue that barring a handful of these notable
concern that in 2010, Mexico became the world’s largest exceptions, the majority of urban utilities in Mexico have
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 21

Table 3. Comparing water and sanitation utilities performance in 12 cities


Cities Physical Commercial Global Metering No. employees/1000 Water
efficiencya (%) efficiencyb (%) efficiencyc (%) residential (%) connections availabilityd
Acapulco 34 82 28 41 9.6 419
Aguascalientes 64 92 59 2.5 304
Chetumal 37 68 25 8.8 390
Guadalajara 63 89 56 89 2.9 207
Hermosillo 63 68 43 3.7 333
Merida 35 86 30 3.5 306
Mexicali 87 75 66 3.9 284
Monterrey 70 95 67 100 4.1 250
Tijuana 81 96 78 3.2 166
Tlaxcala 56 93 52 1 5.3 366
Torreon 53 86 45 3.5 319
Xalapa 40 92 37 100 12.2 358
Source: CNA (2011b).
a
Water billed/water produced.
b
Revenue collected/revenue billed.
c
Physical efficiency  commercial efficiency.
d
m3/person/day.

Table 4. Water and sanitation utilities performance in three cities under study
Cities Water Sanitation Physical Commercial Non-intermittent Metering (%) No. employees/1000
coverage (%) coverage (%) efficiency (%) efficiency (%) service (%) connections
Naucalpan 97 95a 60 80 60 52 10.7
Toluca 88 92 55 64 60 7.6 5.5
Neza 87 98a 66.5 53 ND .18 4.12
Source: Author’s calculations based on CISA, 2007; AYS, 2008a, 2008b, 2008c; OAPAS, 2008a, 2008d; Interviews #62 and 76.
a
Due to a lack of available data for this indicator, official coverage figures are used from INEGI (2010).

not experienced considerable increases in service performance likelihood that commercialization policies will be adopted and
or commercial efficiency in the last decade, and many of them sustained over time. Naucalpan—due to a higher income con-
are fiscally insolvent. sumer base and innovative mayoral leadership—was some-
Table 4 documents performance indicators for the three what more successful than the other two cities in generating
cases under study in this paper. These figures are based on some internal revenue and making some service improve-
internal documents gathered during field research and in some ments, but the extent to which these reforms will endure over
cases contradict published “official figures” by the federal gov- time is uncertain. Toluca lacked strong leadership, but also
ernment. faced a greater amount of urban poor users, less industrial cli-
For example, although the national census claims that Ne- ents, and a greater amount of “non-billable” consumers such
za’s water coverage is 97% (INEGI., 2010), internal docu- as public institutions. Neza failed to initiate any cost recovery
ments indicate that coverage is closer to 87%, and that only reforms, encumbered by an urban poor consumer base, a
approximately 50% of the city has registered connections highly deficient network infrastructure, and extensive adminis-
(CISA, 2007, p. 24). Municipalities throughout Mexico State trative mismanagement.
have been unable to make important service improvements
due to insufficient cost recovery. A 2007 audit of Mexico (a) Implementing substantial commercialization in Naucalpan
state’s 36 utilities show that half of all utilities and 3=4 of metro-
politan utilities are fiscally insolvent and that most do not re- Naucalpan is peri-urban to Mexico City; an industrialized
cover enough revenue to invest in minimal service corridor where rapid industrialization in the 1950s gave rise
improvements (Poder Legislativo del Estado de México, to an influx of migration from surrounding states. As the need
2008). While reliable data are difficult to attain and interpret, for labor grew, irregular working class settlements developed
data triangulated through multiple sources suggest that the in the highlands of the city. Once settled, members of these
utilities analyzed in this study are representative of the types shantytowns petitioned municipal governments for public ser-
of service deficiencies found throughout the country. vices, but extending services to highly elevated geographies
The following section analyzes performance upgrades across was technically difficult and costly. Therefore, the water ser-
Naucalpan, Toluca, and Neza and demonstrates the political vices these working class settlements received prior to 1997
and institutional challenges of implementing commercializa- was irregular and of poor quality (Interview #75). There was
tion after decentralization. an understanding between PRI authorities and poor neighbor-
hoods that water prices would remain low, and collection of
user fees would be flexible. Also subsidized, “residential”
5. EVALUATING REFORM EXPERIENCES IN neighborhoods were middle class zones that had been incorpo-
THREE CITIES rated during the original urban planning process; middle class
groups had better, and less irregular, water service before cost
The three cases demonstrate the different pathways through recovery initiatives began. After services were decentralized
which political conflict and institutional constraints reduce the in 1992, PRI mayors were disinclined to implement cost
22 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

recovery, particularly given the reliance of PRI authorities on 1998f, 1998h). After extensive negotiations with neighbor-
political support from consumers receiving subsidized water, hood association leaders, functionaries lowered the initial
and by 1997, the water utility was bankrupt (Gaceta Munici- price increases by 20%, but insisted on continuing to imple-
pal, 1997). ment cost recovery measures (Reforma, 1998g, 1998d, 1998e).
After Mayor Durán left office, subsequent mayors adopted
(i) Political challenges of cost recovery similar “pressure valves” to mitigate social backlash. For
The historic election of a center-right PAN mayor, José example, mayors reinstated a 10% discount if paying in the
Durán Reveles, in 1997 spurred the introduction of cost recov- beginning of the year, and created a highly subsidized con-
ery reforms. The PAN considered Naucalpan to be a key vic- sumer block for consumers with intermittent service (popular
tory because its socioeconomic makeup—with relatively high tandeado). Periodic protest over price increases continued,
levels of literacy and white-collar employment—had some of with mediation through neighborhood association leaders.
the highest socioeconomic indicators in the state and mirrored The only public forums undertaken by the water utility during
the conservative party’s constituent base (Conde Bonfil, 1996, this period occurred in 2001 and 2002 (Gaceta, 2001, 2002;
p. 336; Hernández Corrochano, 2003, pp. 445–446). The rela- Reforma, 2001a), but were open only to neighborhood associ-
tively wealthier makeup of the city could be an important ation leaders (Gaceta, 2002, p. 19). City hall viewed direct civic
source of support for cost recovery. Another source of support participation through “town hall meeting” style forums as too
was the city’s industrial and business community who had pre- socially disruptive given the contentiousness of tariff increases
viously been underserved by the water utility, being asked to (Interview #151). Although some resistance from the urban
help finance flood controls and improve deficient drainage sys- poor continued (Reforma, 2000, 2004), organized protest
tems in their industrial parks (Reforma, 1996a, 1996b). Indus- waned over time and was less intense in future administra-
try accounts for 57% of the municipal economy, the majority tions.
of which depend on reliable water service for their manufac- PAN leaders implemented a series of concessions that were
turing. 28 By 2008, 1,313 industries were registered clients of ad hoc and improvisational in both content and timing. For
the water utility (OAPAS, 2008a). Water reliant industries example, functionaries provided some discounts in the begin-
constituted a critical mass of clients that had previously been ning of the year for all consumers, instituted debt forgiveness
subsidized, but underserved by deficient water service under programs, and chose to not install meters in irregular settle-
the PRI. The PAN could consolidate substantial middle class ments (Milenio, 2009a; Reforma, 1999; Interview #151). De-
and industrial support by improving services for a constituent spite the PAN’s original intention to undertake a complete
base of higher income groups that would be less likely to no- cost recovery process, reforms were only possible through ad
tice price increases, especially if service improvements were hoc negotiations and flashy inducements (such as raffling cars
quickly forthcoming and targeted to these higher income res- and household appliances to induce on time payment) rather
idential areas and industrial parks. than programmatic changes that could both sustain income
In 1998, Mayor Durán led the water utility in subsidies elim- generation for the water utility and protect the most vulnera-
ination for all consumer groups, tracking and eliminating ble consumer. While revenues have dramatically increased
clandestine connections, and threatening service suspensions since the mid 1990s, the city continues to struggle with solicit-
for non-payment. The PAN-led city council voted to eliminate ing payment and recovering debts from consumers (Reforma,
“Acuerdo 10,” an agreement for highly subsidized water prices 2008; Universal, 2008, 2009a).
that PRI leaders had previously signed with 82 working class
neighborhoods, and when repealed would represent an over- (ii) Overcoming administrative challenges and constructing
night price increase of as much as 266% for the irregular, poor policy continuity
quality water service they were receiving (Reforma, 1998a, Hiring and retaining qualified policymakers and implement-
1998b). ers over time is very challenging in Mexican municipal govern-
Urban protest was immediate and widespread. Neighbor- ment. Durán was able to circumvent some of the systemic
hood association leaders from working class neighbor- institutional constraints at the local level through informal net-
hoods—led by opposition PRI and PRD leaders works of personnel retention. Although Durán could not run
representing 82 neighborhoods and 75,000 families—orga- for immediate re-election as mayor of Naucalpan, he was able
nized three marches in March 1998 that shut down major to ensure personnel continuity. And as a PAN party leader, he
thoroughfares and threatened to March to the state’s capital supported PAN mayoral candidates who would be sympa-
city. After several appeals to the PAN administration went thetic to his reform agenda. The mayor from 2000 to 2003,
unheard, protest groups began to make widely publicized Eduardo Alfredo Contreras, was Durán’s secretariat in the
“symbolic payments” to city hall for their water bill. This 1997–2000 administration, and the 2003–2006 Mayor, Angel-
symbolic gesture suggested consumers were willing to pay ica Moya Marin, had been part of Durán’s inner circle. In fact,
for water received (Reforma, 1998i). One protestor explained: many of the local city hall appointments during this time were
“[We] are inclined to pay, but the amount being charged is PAN loyalists “recycled” from prior administrations (Ref-
disproportionate; we are suggesting an increase of 30%. . . orma, 2003). For example, the water utility’s general director
we receive water every third day, for barely three or four from 2006 to 2009, Manuel Gómez Morı́n was a party loyalist
hours, and sometimes it does not come until 11 pm” (Ref- (the grandson of the PAN’s founder by the same name) and
orma, 1998b). Opposition parties used water price increases had worked in Durán’s first administration (Interview #36).
as a referendum on the first ever PAN administration in Finally, Durán became mayor again in 2006, continuing a re-
the city, calling for Durán’s resignation and associating these form agenda he had begun in 1997. The institutional con-
measures with anti-poor policies (Gaceta, 2001, p. 33; Ref- straints endemic to municipal government were partially
orma, 1998c). Protestors claimed “viewing citizen’s payment overcome by Durán’s ability to remain influential in the poli-
as revenues for a business is totally absurd” (Reforma, cymaking process over time, a strategy that relies exclusively
1998g). These initial protests culminated in an opposition on informal and ad hoc arrangements, and may be difficult
led month long occupation of the municipal palace, leading to replicate or sustain when the original spear header is no
to multiple arrests and disbandment by police (Reforma, longer present.
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 23

(iii) Operationalizing service improvements ing programs (Interview #63). Functionaries admit that de-
Naucalpan was able to generate revenue to reinvest back spite the formal adoption of these practices, political
into improving service. Naucalpan’s sizeable number of indus- considerations remain relevant. For example, during elections,
tries and middle class communities allowed for increased rev- the government must consider how much the party’s constitu-
enue generation from high volume consumers, much of which ents can afford to pay (Interview #35), and in electoral cam-
was reinvested back into these communities. 29 These mea- paigns mayors promise water infrastructure construction for
sures allowed for highly visible service improvements that their constituencies that utilities are then pressured to deliver
when well advertised, were important electoral tools for the (Interviews #35, 41, 45).
PAN and Mayor Durán’s continued political success. 30 Mayors have been unwilling to support stringent collection
In 1997, Naucalpan pledged $MXP 75 million in hydraulic practices. By 2008, only 7.5% of users in Toluca had meters in-
construction (Reforma, 1997b). Many aspects of service provi- stalled, as compared with Naucalpan’s rate of 52% (AYS,
sion were modernized, including the introduction of auto- 2008b; OAPAS, 2008a). Mayors have hesitated to pursue
mated water extraction readings (macromedición) and large-scale meter installation due to fear of social backlash.
updating network infrastructure maps. The water utility initi- Functionaries also worried that the cost of meter installations
ated wide-scale pipe replacements and leak detection units in would be unrecoverable in poor neighborhoods (Interviews
order to reduce the amount of lost water (Interview #62). #42, 43). While some service suspensions for non-payment
One respondent explains that “we began to function like a pri- were begun in 2008, for years suspension policies were lax, de-
vate company, and we began to reinvest all of the revenues. . . spite water laws that permitted cut-off for non-payment. In-
[in the] water utility” (Interview #75). stead, functionaries have relied on “ad hoc” measures to
The PAN’s marketing campaign became quite sophisticated generate revenues, such as debt forgiveness programs that gen-
by the 2006–2009 administration. The water utility developed erate some revenue but are far from cost recovery (Reforma,
a mascot, a branded logo, and pricing comparatives pitting 2001b). The water utility has the legal authority to seize con-
water prices against the more expensive cost of common every- sumer’s property if they do not pay, but lawyers contracted
day items, including other utilities (OAPAS, 2008c). They to exercise legal action against non-paying customers have
carefully advertised and labeled construction projects as being only begun some action since 2008 (Milenio, 2008a; Interview
funded by user fees, and emphasized the connection between #154), and it is unclear whether legal sanctions would be pur-
increased fees and improved services (OAPAS, 2008d). sued by future mayors. Similar to many cities attempting cost
Because policy consolidation from 1997 to 2000 was recovery in Mexico, Toluca has a high amount of payment
achieved through informal mechanisms, ongoing reform is evasion (50% of its consumer base owes payment from prior
far from set in stone in Naucalpan. In 2009, the PRI won in years), and many people are paying tariffs that do not corre-
Naucalpan, and the water utility replaced all PAN loyalists spond to the amount being consumed (Milenio, 2008b, 2009e).
with PRI members, many of whom had no prior experience Mayors intervene regularly in water services delivery in Tol-
with commercialization practices or simple accounting (Inter- uca. Politicians campaign on the issue of guaranteeing water
view #151). The 2009–2012 PRI mayor, Azucena Olivares Vil- for the future; for example Mayor Sánchez (2006–2009) fa-
lagomez, upon entering office claimed that there was public mously campaigned—and later failed to deliver on—guaran-
dissatisfaction with prices many perceived to be too high teeing water for the next twenty years (Milenio, 2009d). All
(Milenio, 2009b). It remains unclear whether alteration of three mayors, particularly Mayor Sánchez, participated in
power between competing political parties will be conducive multiple photo opportunities advertising high profile works
to continuing to implement commercialization in Naucalpan. (Sol de Toluca, 2007, 2008b, 2008c, 2008d). Mayor Sánchez’s
team worked closely with the water utility’s public relations
(b) Incomplete commercialization and ad hoc service department to ensure that the mayor received press coverage
improvements: Toluca for hydraulic projects (Interview #49). Some functionaries
note that recent campaign promise of “water for the next
Toluca is the capital city of Mexico State, and is home to a twenty years” without willingness to shoulder political burden
disparate mix of users that draw from the city’s increasingly of increasing prices is similar to the PRI’s historic promise of
limited water resources. For example, industrial consumers free water. Functionaries also complain of having to provide
with their own boreholes extract 30% of local supply (Milenio, water for local committees outside of the water utility’s juris-
2007). As of 2008, 30% of the water utility’s water sources diction because they represent votes for the mayor (Interview
were used by peri-urban and rural residents that managed #53).
their own water supply due to preexisting legal arrangements
with the state government (AYS, 2008a, p. 1). In addition, (ii) Administrative challenges and lack of policy continuity
the capital city provides services to as many as 1,100 public The PAN’s historic win in Toluca in 2000 brought in a series
institutions such as schools, hospitals, and government offices, of mayors who paid lip service to hydraulic issues but did not
which are also exempt from water payment (Milenio, 2008c). take on sweeping reforms. The first PAN mayor, Juan Carlos
Because of the high amount of “non-billable” users of the ci- Nuñéz Armas (2000–2003) had prior hydraulic experience as
ty’s water resources, as well as the low amount of industrial former president of the state Aquifer and National Resources
consumers reliant on the utility, cost recovery has been more Commission and participated in the drafting of Mexico’s State
of an uphill battle for Toluca’s PAN mayors, despite their Water Law. During his term, Toluca became involved in the
shared “technocratic” and business oriented ideology. The state’s water tariffs working group, and city hall supported
limited amount of service improvements Toluca’s water utility the water utility through fiscal transfers for infrastructure con-
undertook were due largely to technocratic changes that side- struction at a consistently much greater level than the subse-
stepped the adoption of politically controversial policies. quent two mayors. 31 However, Mayor Nuñéz Armas
focused more on building new hydraulic works than imple-
(i) Political challenges of cost recovery menting maintenance or cost recovery. The following two
Toluca’s water utility has updated tariffs with support from PAN mayors, Armando Enrı́quez Flores (2000–2006) and
the state government and implemented performance-monitor- Juan Rodolfo Sánchez Gómez (2006–2009), also failed to
24 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

implement cost recovery. Instead they focused on more gen- recovery, under first the PRI party and later the left of center
eral large public works projects in other sectors, the latter PRD.
mayor famously beginning a series of expensive and high pro-
file modifications to the downtown historic area that were left (i) Political challenges of cost recovery
uncompleted (Sol de Toluca, 2008a). Despite some price increases led by a statewide initiative in
Despite the same party maintaining power for three admin- 2002, commercialization practices remain practically non-exis-
istrations, administrators changed continually due to patron- tent. Local leaders do not consider cut off of service for non-
age appointments. Both city council members and mayors payment a politically viable option. Functionaries admit that
distributed positions to their inner circle or based on campaign consumers are so resistant to pay for the poor quality service
promises. As one functionary noted, “here in local government they receive that the billing office has stopped issuing water
we say that we are born again every day. When I come to bills and simply rely on consumers initiating payment if they
work, I have to check to see if there is someone else in my are so inclined (Interview #70). Neza’s collection policies are
chair, if not. . .then I know I still have a job” (Interview purposefully casual: the water utility does not have to spend
#35). Functionaries admitted that projects stalled with new time or manpower issuing bills, tracking revenues, or demand-
administrative changes because employees were worried about ing payment. In order to generate some operating revenue, the
losing their jobs (Interview #35). By the time the PAN left Tol- municipality issues bi-monthly “debt forgiveness” programs
uca in 2009, their administrations were accused of mishandling that culminate in a large subsidy (often over 50%) around
public funds and increasing public debt to finance unnecessary the Christmas holidays. Additionally, all seniors receive 50%
public works projects that were never completed (Sol de discounts, and consumers who pay in the first two months
Toluca, 2009). of the year receive further discounts. Because of the many sub-
sidies administered directly by the municipality, the water util-
(iii) Ad-hoc service improvements ity admits that few consumers would choose to pay their bill
Toluca’s partial amount of service improvements focused on during non-discounted months. Small and medium sized busi-
accessing some revenues from the federal government for nesses and higher income users also do not receive water bills
infrastructure development but largely sidestepped the adop- (Interview #70).
tion of politically controversial commercialization policies. The Neza case study underscores patterns of inefficiency,
The general manager, Mauricio Ramı́rez Rosaldo (2000– corruption, and unresponsive local government found in many
2006) was controlled by mayors who allowed for some opera- urban W&S systems. A number of influential actors within the
tional autonomy as long as the mayor’s political commitments service provision process have benefited from maintaining dis-
were respected (Interview #35). He tracked performance indi- cretionary practices. First, the mayor and water utility director
cators that made the water utility eligible for federal financing receive side-payments from the repair of refurbished parts
for infrastructure updates. During the 2000–2008 period, the (e.g., electricity generators) (Interview #73). Therefore, the
water utility’s general construction budget increased by mayor and his colleagues are not interested in purchasing nec-
400% (AYS, 2008c). However, it remains unclear whether essary new generators, vehicles, and other hardware because
adopting the tracking of performance indicators has actually they profit from the side-business of repairing continually defi-
helped service improvements or just been a vehicle to access cient hardware. Second, because Neza’s water utility has little
federal infrastructure funds. control over their water supply and because workers are
Toluca’s network infrastructure is antiquated, has outdated underpaid, operations workers may sell water access, or re-
network maps, and high amounts of lost water through pipes. pairs to the system without any fear of recrimination (Univer-
The network infrastructure is as old as sixty years in some sal, 2005). Third, bill collectors may also pocket some revenues
areas, and approximately 75% of it is in dire conditions, losing when they collect consumer payment because the process is
up to 45% of conducted water daily (Milenio, 2009c). While not automated or regulated. Fourth, because the mayor di-
Toluca’s water utility has found it difficult to increase their ser- rectly controls the water utility unchecked, water revenues
vice coverage and service continuity, support from federal pro- may be diverted to other purposes. 32 Finally, service suspen-
grams has led to some improvements (Interview #43). As of sions are discretionarily administered: one water utility direc-
2013, Toluca’s water utility was not treating its wastewater tor who initially insisted that service suspension is not viable
(GMT, 2012). because water was a human right later revealed that he orders
suspension as retributions against those with whom he has
personal or political disputes (Interview #71).
(c) No commercialization and deteriorating services:
Nezahualcóyotl (ii) Administrative challenges and benefits of “discretion”
The city government’s ability to improve services is also
Ciudad Nezahualcóytl, also known as Neza, has over highly affected by staffing and human resources problems.
1.1 million inhabitants and ranks as Mexico’s fourth largest Undereducated and poorly trained civil servants are common
city. Neza began as a poor “bedroom community” when rural both because of the lack of a municipal-level civil service as
migrants flocking to work in Mexico City found more afford- well as the mayor’s use of positions in exchange for political
able housing in its nearby outskirts. Most residents of the city support. In addition, despite four consecutive left-of-center
did not have land titles upon settling in the 1960s, but instead PRD administrations (1997–2009), local government in Neza
lived in informal squatter settlements with no public services has been tumultuous during this time, with four elected
(Selee, 2011, pp. 132–144). By 2000, almost all properties in mayors and three interim mayors (GMN, 2009). As Board
Neza had electricity, water, and sewerage, but despite an offi- presidents, mayors single-handedly appoint the utility’s
cial 97% water coverage rate (INEGI, 2010), Neza’s water ser- general manager; these positions have routinely been used as
vices are highly deficient. Neza’s water utility was patronage appointments for party loyalists. Of the last four
administered as a public works department before becoming appointed general managers’, half have been replaced mid-
a legally autonomous decentralized water utility in 1993. Since season. While two have been engineers, Juan Herrera Moro
decentralization, Neza has found it difficult to introduce cost (1997–2000), and Juan Martin Bolaños Vela (2003–3006),
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 25

others have had a primary or secondary education and no maintaining the status quo to be less destabilizing than adopt-
prior professional experience in the sector. ing politically contentious cost recovery policies.
In all three cases, mayors found it politically challenging to
(iii) Services deterioration and public apathy adopt cost recovery policies after decentralization. A range of
Because of Neza’s inability to generate internal revenues, constituents, especially the urban poor, represented a potential
infrastructure development have stalled, operations and main- source of public backlash that could be socially disruptive, and
tenance have been neglected, and the city’s residents experi- cities without a strong middle class and industrial base of cli-
ence ever worsening service quality (CISA, 2007, pp. 24–28). ents were less likely to find cost recovery a viable financing
Two commonly cited service problems are low availability of strategy for sector reform. While cost recovery represented a
potable water and the ongoing flooding that occurs through politically contentious policy for all mayors, Naucalpan’s
the rainy season given the lack of suitable rainwater drainage Mayor Durán was more inclined to adopt commercialization
systems. The network infrastructure has received few upgrades policies because of the city’s relatively wealthier user groups,
since it was constructed in the early 1970s (Jornada, 1997). and he was able to appease urban poor protestors by imple-
Over half of the water that enters the network is lost through menting ad hoc concessions that allowed him to pass his re-
leaks and clandestine connections. Furthermore, the anti- form agenda. While innovative mayoral leadership—that
quated piped network leaks toxic materials from the pipes that requires savvy use of informal and ad hoc strategies to extend
routinely enter the water supply; it is common to see “yellow the short time horizon—may occasionally be able to circum-
sludge” when opening the tap. Between the large amount of vent poor institutional design, these instances are rare. Better
leaks and low water pressure throughout the grid, many con- aligning decentralization design to the local conditions and
sumers receive virtually no water despite being “officially” cov- political incentives for reform will increase the likelihood that
ered by the utility (Interviews #72, 68). Because functionaries more local politicians invest in public services reform.
do not have an updated map of the network infrastructure,
they are unable to even create a service-rationing schedule
(tandeo) that would provide service in hourly increments to 6. CONCLUSION
different neighborhoods. The water utility has had to resort
to manual water provision: trucks with tanked water (piperos) Decentralization has reinvigorated scholarly debate about
respond to some of the thousands of daily complaints of water what constitutes “good” local government and how to achieve
shortage (Interview #69). it. The need for effective local government is especially press-
Such poor service delivery generates a great deal of public ing in sectors where infrastructure is in disrepair and in need
dissatisfaction, yet citizens have become accustomed to sub- of expensive and technically complex updates. The effective-
standard service and unresponsive government. For example, ness of local government has important implications beyond
periodically, portions of the city’s water supply are shut down the local level. The ability of local politicians to successfully
due to ruptures within the network or even failure to pay the improve services provision, enforce environmental regulations,
electricity bill (Jornada, 2007, 2008, 2010; Reforma, 1997a, and provide social benefits to citizens determines whether
1998j; Universal, 2006a). During the rainy season, the many important development objectives are furthered.
high flood zones are inundated with flooding, or worse—sew- While local politicians play an increasingly key role in devel-
age that threatens to flood the city. Because Neza’s sewage dis- opment outcomes, the factors that lead to effective local gov-
posal system runs on electricity but has no back-up generators, ernment continue to be contested. Prior accounts have
power shortages and torrential rains makes sewage flooding a focused on the importance of participation, citizen account-
periodic threat (Reforma, 2005; Universal, 2002a, 2002b, ability, and innovative mayoral leadership for local govern-
2003, 2006b). These service failures are socially disruptive ment effectiveness. I argue that while mayoral innovation
and can induce intense dissatisfaction; consumers make and participation are important factors, they may be con-
2000–3000 complaints daily, some even threatening violent ac- strained by the poor fit between the decentralization design
tion (Interview #69). Yet these types of isolated complaints, and the local context in which decentralization strategies are
however explosive, have not culminated in organized collective carried out. In Mexico, decentralization was part of a broader
action. Rather, many customers have stopped attempting to neoliberal reform package that failed to consider the unique
reach the water utility because they do not feel that their com- constraints of local government. Commercialization policies
plaints result in improved service (Interview #69). Years of created political disincentives for reform adoption, especially
poor service quality have resulted in low citizen expectations in poor communities and in communities where services
regarding service quality. needed major capital investment before price increases could
be applied. Contentious commercialization policies were made
(d) Cases overview more difficult to implement because of institutional constraints
in local government that shortened the policymaking window,
Enforcing cost recovery has been politically unattractive for a particularly pressing problem in areas such as W&S that
left of center PRD mayors presiding over large numbers of ur- necessitate long-term planning.
ban poor residents in Neza and elsewhere. Instead, PRD may- I argue that neoliberal policies such as commercialization
ors have replicated the “vicious cycle” of poor quality services have undermined potential gains of decentralization and failed
for little fees that PRI officials used during the centralization to improve services systematically in Mexico. Alongside na-
era. While services were also politicized under centralization, tional averages that do not suggest considerable service
federal funds were periodically injected into systems in an ad improvements in the last decade, field research reveals a litany
hoc manner to keep them afloat, a practice local governments of service problems and under-financed utilities. An unfortu-
can no longer rely on. Centralization in Mexico coincided with nate paradox arises: while Mexico has reached the 2015 UN
a period of semi-authoritarian one-party rule, where local Millennium Development Goals to halve the population with-
leaders were interested in social harmony but did not have out access to piped water (CNA, 2012, p. 32), it has also be-
to win elections. In the context of electoral competition, cities come the world’s largest consumer of bottled water (IADB,
with a large number of urban poor residents have found 2010).
26 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

International agencies have emphasized the need for auton- whether, and how, to best implement a targeted subsidy in
omy in urban water management; decreasing mayoral inter- the sector would be a positive first step: subsidies could be tar-
vention was seen as a means to improve local services and geted by means or geography, and/or a connection subsidy.
widely promoted. My study shows that decreasing mayoral These mechanisms would help to more accurately identify con-
intervention after decentralization may not be feasible, or sumers’ ability to pay, providing “lifelines” for the poorest
desirable. In weak and short-term institutional contexts, effec- consumers and “un-subsidizing” the non-poor. 33 Targeted
tive policymaking may rely on informal networks and coali- subsidies would also help to offset the regressive nature of
tion building, something that mayors are in a better position increasing block tariffs as currently implemented in Mexico,
to do than appointed bureaucrats who wield less authority. where the first broad lifeline consumption is often so large that
Institutional autonomy may also compromise citizen account- it captures most domestic users, even those with the ability to
ability; technocrats are much more easily isolated from citizen pay (World Bank, 2005, p. 30). While there are many examples
demands than elected officials. of these types of programs in other middle income countries
The Naucalpan case suggests that relatively successful re- (Gómez-Lobo & Contreras, 2003), there is no such national
form under the current “rules” of the game favor rich cities program in Mexico. In addition, initial injections of infrastruc-
with strong industrial and middle class bases and politicians ture updates from the federal government—not linked to per-
who cater to these constituent groups. This is not surprising, formance—would have a dual benefit: user fees could be more
given that fiscal self-sufficiency requires a customer base that quickly translated into visible service improvements because
can generate sufficient revenue to finance service improve- the initial (costly) groundwork would already be laid, and
ments. Even in these cases, however, the institutional con- also, consumers may be less hostile toward price increases if
straints of local government make the likelihood of policy services are concurrently visibly improving.
reversal after reformers leave office high. Furthermore, the Finally, if federal and state governments played a greater
promise of increased participation after decentralization was role in supporting urban utilities, they could help extend the
not realized in the context of self-financing reforms, as mayors time horizon of local policymaking. For example, the CNA
in Naucalpan consistently limited the use of public and delib- could promote the creation of more inter-municipal utilities
erative forums while implementing commercialization. for cities that alone do not constitute a sufficient, or profitable,
The broader neoliberal reform package in W&S amounted economy of scale to fund improvements through cost recov-
to a “retreat of the state,” one that not only eliminated subsi- ery. The better performing utilities, for example, cities in the
dies for maintenance, but also reduced the oversight role of the states of Nuevo Leon or Querétaro, are often state-level oper-
federal government in service provision. Given the emphasis ators with important economies of scale, technical proficien-
on performance based financing, elimination of federal grants cies, a civil service, and a longer state government
and fiscal self-sufficiency, the onus for service improvement administration, six rather than three years. In addition, federal
has been left to the market: consumer fees are expected to or state level regulatory bodies could be created to oversee ur-
do the heavy lifting for improving service in urban centers. ban services. These bodies could help regulate investments,
But is this a reasonable expectation, especially given the insti- administer targeted subsidies, collect performance data, pro-
tutional constraints of municipal government and internal rev- vide technical assistance, and promote environmental preser-
enue generation policies as currently designed? vation. 34 These types of interventions would require greater
Urban W&S management would benefit from comprehen- financial investment by the federal government in sectoral
sive measures designed to help mitigate social backlash against organization and oversight, but would help to make better
cost recovery. For example, a federal initiative to study use of the funds currently being spent in the sector.

NOTES

1. Multilateral agencies, influenced by fiscal federalism theory (Oates, services responsibility from a central agency to a regional field office,
1972; Tiebout, 1956), reasoned that administrative decentralization to where services responsibility remains under the auspices of the federal
local governments would improve service provision through stakeholder government.
participation in decision-making and better matching of service to local
needs (Bird, 1994, p. 8; W.F. Fox, 1994, p. 23; Silverman, 1992, pp. 12–13; 4. For further reading on decentralization in Mexico, see Grindle (2007),
World Bank., 1994, p. 76). Mizrahi (2004), Rodriguez (1997), and Selee (2011).

2. See Speer (2012), Goldfrank (2011), pp. 11–33) and Blair (2000), pp. 5. I thank an anonymous reviewer for making this observation.
23–24) for further discussion of how decentralization and participation
may lead to improved government performance, responsiveness, and 6. For example, cities in Mexico State have all received the responsibility
accountability. for W&S provision through decentralization in the early 1990s (GEM,
1997), are governed by similar fiscal and administrative policies admin-
3. I define decentralization as a transfer of authority from the central
istered by the Mexico State Water Commission, and these three cities
government to a subnational unit of government and therefore do not
selected rely on water from the Cutzamala Dam administered by the
consider transfers of service responsibility to the private sector a form of
Mexico State Water Commission (CNA, 2006, p. 79).
decentralization (in contrast to some analysts, for example, see Cheema
and Rondinelli (2007, p. 7)). I concur with definitions of decentralization
that identify three types of decentralization: political, administrative, and 7. Eaton, Kaiser, and Smoke (2011) argue that different bureaucracies
fiscal (Falleti, 2010; Montero & Samuels, 2004). As such, W&S within multiple tiers of government have varying, and at times conflicting,
decentralization is an example of administrative decentralization, where preferences that makes coordination in policymaking after decentraliza-
the responsibility for services provision is transferred from national tion particularly challenging.
governments to subnational governments. I do not consider deconcentra-
tion a form of decentralization because this often refers to a transfer of 8. See Speer (2012) for a review of this literature.
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 27

9. NPM has also been referred to as “post bureaucratic paradigm,” 21. High non-revenue water and low physical efficiency are proxy
“managerialism,” “market-based administration,” and “entrepreneurial measures that reflect the condition of the piped network infrastructure and
government.” the amount of freshwater that is being wasted and contributing to the over
extraction of underground aquifers, but also are correlated with other
10. A related reform has been promoted, called corporatization, for the types of service quality measures, such as low water pressure in homes and
public sector. Corporatization can occur by incorporating public entities high service intermittency.
under a (Public) Corporations Act, or creating “ring-fenced,” public
companies or organizations, which are legally, fiscally, and administra- 22. These figures put Mexico well below the average of best performing
tively independent. In Mexico, the latter occurred in the urban W&S utilities in developing countries, which reach levels closer to 23% of non-
sector. revenue water (World Bank, 2005, p. 28).

11. Weak institutional capacity at the local level is not unique to 23. For example, one ex-mayor and ex-water utility citizen board
developing countries. Sellers and Lidström (2007) conceptualize several of president in a Guanajuato city noted in 2012 that, “Those of us who
the institutional constraints discussed in this article (such as term limits work in the water sector hide the issue of water quality. [For example,] you
and the presence of civil service) as dimensions of institutional capacity have an underground aquifer that emits an enormous amount of arsenic,
and document the pervasiveness of low institutional capacity even in and [we] mix it with water from another aquifer that has less arsenic, so
developed countries. that it will ‘just barely’ pass the [water quality standards]” (Interview #
170).
12. For a list of prohibitions on re-election in Latin America, see Zovatto
(2011). 24. The CNA reports that from 1990 to 2009, the childhood mortality
rate due to diarrheal disease has decreased, from 122.7 (for every 100,000
13. See Aboites (1998) for a description of this period. inhabitants) to 11.8 (for every 100, inhabitants) (CNA, 2011, p. 102).
However, while water coverage during this time has increased from 78.4 to
14. While neither reform has been a “one-shot” deal but instead has 90.8%, other nation-wide programs were implemented nearly simulta-
taken place over a period of time, decentralization efforts generally neously that likely impacted the instance of waterborne illness, such as a
preceded attempts to implement commercialization practices. vaccination program (begun in 1986), and a program of distributing
electrolytes solution (suero oral) to combat dehydration and diarrhea
(begun in 1984). Even the CNA’s reported data suggest that it is difficult to
15. Three World Bank loans during 1975–1983 were instrumental in
tease out the causal impact of increasing water coverage, as opposed to
shaping subsector policymaking, known together as FIFAPA (the
other programs such as the two just mentioned, on decreasing waterborne
Investment Fund for Water Supply and Sewerage Works). FIFAPA
illness (CNA, 2011a, p. 102).
created autonomous utilities in 33 cities and introduced the concept of
financing systems through user charges, an initiative that unearthed the
systemic challenges in raising water prices and the complex politics of 25. Therefore, it is quite possible that any gains that have been made in
creating autonomous utilities under municipal jurisdictions (Dau Flores, decreasing water-borne illness have been made due to widespread “opting
2008, p. 113; World Bank, 1992, p. 58). out” of the municipal water supply and extensive increases in bottled
water use.
16. See CNA (1993) and CNA (2003) for examples of promotion of PSP,
made legally permissable after the passing of the National Water Law 26. World Bank analysis of Mexico’s internal revenue generation
(Estados Unidos Mexicanos, 1992). For a discussion of privatization of confirms a low amount of revenue generated by water utilities in Mexico,
W&S in Mexico, see Wilder and Romero Lankao (2006), Pineda Pablos “the sector generates only a very modest cash surplus, which is well below
(2002) and Barocio and Saavedra (2004). Promotion of PSP in urban W&S the performance achieved by the top quartile of utilities in developing
has waned since the 1990s, although CNA continues to promote private countries” (World Bank, 2005, p. 30).
capital investment in wastewater treatment plants (Interviews #17, 26).
27. The CNA annually publishes figures for a sample of utilities that
17. Although reform architects’ original intention was to decentralize all submitted what appeared to be “credible” performance indicators.
urban utilities to the municipal level, several state governments (Nuevo León, However, the data are presented by indicator type (due to the amount
Tabasco, Querétaro, and Chihuahua) chose to not decentralize further, while of missing data) rather than in consolidated tables that allow for easy
others chose to sponsor inter-municipal utilities. Over time, APAZU rules comparison across cities. Therefore, I composed a chart of performance
changed to accommodate these additional arrangements and state govern- indicators across a range of cities that had the most data available.
ments were also able to utilize APAZU funds for their urban utilities.
28. For example, water-intensive industries such as chemicals, paper/
18. Five are state level operators (Nuevo León, Tabasco, Querétaro, pulp processing, metallics, clothing manufacturing, electronics, and food
Chihuahua, and Distrito Federal), approximately 10 are inter-municipal production all account for 46% of the municipal economy, and generate
(San Luis Potosı́, Guadalajara, Colima, Zacatecas, Pachuca, Monclava, approximately $MXP 32.2 million per year (INEGI, 2004).
Oaxaca, Apizaco, Veracruz, and Mérida), and the remaining are
municipal operators. (Author correspondence with National Water 29. Service-rationing schedules indicate that middle class neighborhoods
Commission, April 2, 2012; INEGI (2009, p. 9)). and industrial parks received non-intermittent service by 2008 (OAPAS,
2008b).
19. I thank an anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.
30. Mayor Durán became PAN candidate for state governor in 1999
20. Multiple author interviews revealed that utilities typically have three after leaving the Naucalpan mayorship, subsecretariat within the state
versions of performance indicators: one version for the CNA, one version government from 2000 to 2005, mayor of Naucalpan again in 2006, and
for fiscal auditors, and the “real” numbers. In particularly deficient utilities, remained a key candidate for the PAN governorship nomination after
functionaries may not have the resources to measure performance at all. leaving mayoral office in 2009.
28 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

31. Ramo 33 is a federal transfer to municipalities that can be used by 33. A means tested targeted subsidy, targeted by income level, or
municipalities for a large number of projects, according to priorities within geographically differentiated tariffs that are roughly based on poverty
city hall. During the Nuñéz 2000–2003 administration, the water utility levels, is argued to be more effective in reaching the poor than increasing
received $41,853,524 mxp million from Ramo 33, much higher than the block tariffs (World Bank, 2005, p. 31).
$6,960,153 mxp million received during the Enrı́quez 2003–2006 admin-
istration, and the $7,826,086 received by 2008 during the Sanchez 2006– 34. The majority of the existing state water commissions do not come
2009 administration (AYS, 2008c). close to fulfilling these roles, and there is virtually no federal coordination
or standardization of what the role of these commissions should entail.
32. See Davis (2004) for an analysis of corruption in W&S systems.

REFERENCES

Aboites, L. (1998). El agua de la nación: una historia polı́tica de México, Cabrero-Mendoza, E. (2000). Mexican local governance in transition:
(1888–1946). Distrito Federal, México: Centro de Investigaciones y fleeting change or permanent transformation?. The American Review of
Estudios Superiores en Antropologı́a Social. Public Administration, 30(4), 374–388.
Agrawal, A., & Ostrom, E. (2001). Collective action, property rights, and Camp, R. A. (2003). Politics in Mexico (4th ed). New York: Oxford
decentralization in resource use in India and Nepal. Politics & Society, University Press.
29(4), 485–514. Cheema, G. S., & Rondinelli, D. A. (2007). From government decentral-
Andersson, K., Gibson, C. C., & Lehoucq, F. (2006). Municipal politics ization to decentralized governance. In G. S. Cheema, & D. A.
and forest governance: Comparative analysis of decentralization in Rondinelli (Eds.), Decentralizing governance: Emerging concepts and
Bolivia and Guatemala. World Development, 34(3), 576–595. practices (pp. 1–20). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Andersson, K., & Laerhoven, F. V. (2007). From local strongman to CISA (2007). Municipio de Nezahualcóyotl, Estado de México: Diagnóstico
facilitator institutional incentives for participatory municipal gover- del subsector agua potable, resumen ejecutivo. CISA Solutions.
nance in Latin America. Comparative Political Studies, 40(9), CNA (1992). Situación del agua potable, alcantarillado y saneamiento.
1085–1111. Comisión Nacional del Agua.
Angell, A., Lowden, P., & Thorp, R. (2001). Decentralizing development: CNA (1993). Informe 1989–1993. Comisión Nacional del Agua.
The political economy of institutional change in Colombia and Chile. CNA (1994). Sintesis de la memoria de gestion 1988–1994. Comisión
Oxford: Oxford University Press. Nacional del Agua.
AYS (2008a). Información básica de los servicios de agua potable, CNA (2000). Situación del agua potable, alcantarillado y saneamiento.
alcantarillado y saneamiento en el municipio de Toluca. Agua y Comisión Nacional del Agua.
Saneamiento de Toluca. CNA (2003). La participación privada en la prestación de los servicios de
AYS (2008b). Metodologı́a para el cálculo de tarifas por suministro de agua agua y saneamiento: conceptos básicos y experiencias. Comisión
potable y drenaje diferentes a las establecidas en el código financiero del Nacional del Agua.
estado de México y municipios. Agua y Saneamiento de Toluca. CNA (2006). Estadı́sticas del agua, aguas del valle de México y sistema
AYS (2008c). Porcentaje de presupuesto para obras respecto al presupuesto Cutzamala Región XIII. Comisión Nacional del Agua.
general del organismo. Agua y Saneamiento de Toluca. CNA (2010). Cobertura universal: Suburbios urbanos conectados a redes.
Barkin, D. (2011). The governance crisis in urban water management in Comisión Nacional del Agua.
Mexico. In U. Oswald Spring (Ed.), Water resources in Mexico: CNA (2011a). Estadı́sticas del agua de México. Comisión Nacional del
Scarcity, degradation, stress, conflicts, management and policy. London, Agua.
UK: Springer. CNA (2011b). Situación del agua potable, alcantarillado y saneamiento.
Barocio, R., & Saavedra, J. (2004). La participación privada en los Comisión Nacional del Agua.
servicios de agua y saneamiento en México. In El agua en México visto CNA (2012). Situación del agua potable, alcantarillado y saneamiento.
desde la academia. Distrito Federal, México: Academia Mexicana de Comisión Nacional del Agua.
Ciencias. Colclough, C. (Ed.) (1997). Marketizing education and health in
Barzelay, M., & Armajani, B. J. (1992). Breaking through bureaucracy: A developing countries: miracle or mirage?. Oxford: Oxford University
new vision for managing in government. Berkeley: University of Press.
California Press. Conde Bonfil, C. (1996). El caso de Naucalpan de Juaréz, Estado de
Batley, R., & Larbi, G. A. (2004). The changing role of government: The México. In Los dilemmas de la modernización municipal: Estudios sobre
reform of public services in developing countries. Basingstoke, United la gestión hacendaria en municipios urbanos de México. Centro de
Kingdom: Palgrave Macmillan. Investigación y Docencia Económicas; Miguel Ángel Porrúa.
Bayliss, K. (2008). Namibia: Lessons from commercialization. In K. Crook, R. C., & Manor, J. (1998). Democracy and decentralisation in
Bayliss, & B. Fine (Eds.), Privatization and alternative public sector South Asia and West Africa: Participation, accountability, and perfor-
reform in Sub-Saharan Africa: Delivering on electricity and water. New mance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
York: Palgrave Macmillan. Dagdeviren, H. (2008). Waiting for miracles: The commercialization of
Beach, D., & Pedersen, R. B. (2013). Process-tracing methods: Foun- urban water services in Zambia. Development and Change, 39(1),
dations and guidelines. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan 101–121.
Press. Dau Flores, E. (2008). De las juntas federales y empresas de agua: la
Bennett, A. (2010). Process tracing and causal inference. In H. E. Brady, & evolución institucional de los servicios urbanos de agua en México
D. Collier (Eds.), Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared 1948–2008. In R. Olivares, & R. Sandoval (Eds.), El agua potable en
standards (2nd ed.). Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. México: Historia reciente, actores, procesos y propuestas. Distrito
Bird, R. (1994). Decentralizing infrastructure: For good or for ill? Federal, México: Asociación Nacional de Empresas de Agua y
Working Paper No. 1258. World Bank Publications. Saneamiento.
Blair, H. (2000). Participation and accountability at the periphery: Davis, J. (2004). Corruption in public service delivery: Experience from
Democratic local governance in six countries. World Development, South Asia’s water and sanitation sector. World Development,
28(1), 21–39. 321(2004), 53–71.
Boone, C. (2003). Decentralization as political strategy in West Africa. Devas, N., & Grant, U. (2003). Local government decision-making—
Comparative Political Studies, 36(4), 355–380. citizen participation and local accountability: Some evidence from
Brady, H. E., & Collier, D. (2010). Rethinking social inquiry diverse tools, Kenya and Uganda. Public Administration and Development, 23(4),
shared standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. 307–316.
Cabrero Mendoza, E. (2007). Polı́ticas públicas municipales: una agenda en Dickovick, J. T. (2007). Municipalization as central government strategy:
construcción. Distrito Federal, México: Centro de Investigación y Central-regional–local politics in Peru, Brazil, and South Africa.
Docencia Económicas; Miguel Ángel Porrúa. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 37(1), 1–25.
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 29

DOF. (1980). Diario Oficial de la Federación. Estados Unidos Mexicanos IBNET. (n.d.). International benchmarking network for water and
(November 5). sanitation utilities, “core indicators”. Retrieved from: <http://
Eaton, K. (2001). Political obstacles to decentralization: Evidence from www.ib-net.org/en/texts.php?folder_id=78>.
Argentina and the Philippines. Development and Change, 32(1), IMTA. (2011). Programa de Indicadores de Gestión de Organismos
101–127. Operadores del Instituto Mexicano de Tecnologı́a del Agua. Instituto
Eaton, K., Kaiser, K.-A., & Smoke, P. J. (2011). The political economy of Mexicano de Tecnologı́a del Agua. Retrieved from <http://www.
decentralization reforms: Implications for aid effectiveness. Washington, pigoo.gob.mx/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=91&Ite-
DC: World Bank. mid=>.
Estados Unidos Mexicanos (1992). Ley de Aguas Nacionales. Estados INEGI. (2004). Economic census 2004. Instituto Nacional de Estadı́stica y
Unidos Mexicanos. Geografı́a.
Faguet, J.-P. (2009). Governance from below in Bolivia: A theory of local INEGI. (2009). Panorama censal de los organismos operadores de agua en
government with two empirical tests. Latin American Politics and México. Instituto Nacional de Estadı́stica y Geografı́a.
Society, 51(4), 29–68. INEGI. (2010). Mexico en cifras. Instituto Nacional de Estadı́stica y
Falleti, T. G., & Lynch, J. F. (2009). Context and causal mechanisms in Geografı́a.
political analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 42(9), 1143–1166. Islam, N. (1993). Public enterprise reform: Managerial autonomy,
Falleti, T. G. (2010). Decentralization and subnational politics in Latin accountability and performance contracts. Public Administration and
America. New York: Cambridge University Press. Development, 13(2), 129–152.
Fenwick, T. B. (2010). The institutional feasibility of national–local policy Jornada. (1997, January 13). Neza: 33 años de olvido y corrupción.
collaboration: Insights from Brazil and Argentina. Journal of Politics Jornada. (2007, July 12). Hoy se reanudarı́a suministro de agua en
in Latin America, 2(2), 155–183. Nezahualcóyotl.
Fiszbein, A. (1997). The emergence of local capacity: Lessons from Jornada. (2008, March 5). Sin agua, 200 mil habitants de Neza, por
Colombia. World Development, 25(7), 1029–1043. ruptura en la red.
Fox, J. (1994). The difficult transition from clientelism to citizenship: Jornada. (2010, February 10). Colonos de Nezahualcóyotl protestan por
Lessons from Mexico. World Politics, 46(02), 151–184. falta de agua.
Fox, W. F. (1994). Strategic options for urban infrastructure management. Kauneckis, D., & Andersson, K. (2009). Making decentralization work: A
World Bank Publications. cross-national examination of local governments and natural resource
Francis, P., & James, R. (2003). Balancing rural poverty reduction and governance in Latin America. Studies in Comparative International
citizen participation: The contradictions of Uganda’s decentralization Development, 44(1), 23–46.
program. World Development, 31(2), 325–337. Krause, M. (2009). The political economy of water and sanitation. New
Furlong, K., & Bakker, K. (2010). The contradictions in “alternative” York: Routledge.
service delivery: governance, business models, and sustainability in Larson, A. M. (2002). Natural resources and decentralization in Nicara-
municipal water supply. Environment and Planning C: Government and gua: Are local governments up to the job?. World Development, 30(1),
Policy, 28(2), 349–368. 17–31.
Gaceta. (2001). Gaceta del Gobierno del Estado de Mexico. Gaceta del McDonald, D. A., & Ruiters, G. (2005). Theorizing water privatization in
Gobierno del Estado de Mexico (April 3). Southern Africa. In D. A. McDonald, & G. Ruiters (Eds.), The age of
Gaceta. (2002). Gaceta del Gobierno del Estado de Mexico. Gaceta del commodity: Water privatization in Southern Africa (pp. 13–42). Lon-
Gobierno del Estado de Mexico (April 8). don, UK: Earthscan.
Gaceta Municipal. (1997). Gaceta Municipal. Gobierno de Naucalpan, McDonald, D. A., & Smith, L. (2004). Privatising Cape Town: From
Estado de México (December 15). apartheid to neo-liberalism in the mother city. Urban Studies, 41(8),
GEM (1997). Evaluación 1997. Gobierno del Estado de México: Subsec- 1461–1484.
retarı́a de Infraestructura Hidraúlica. Mehta, D., & Pathak, P. (1998). Financing of urban services in India: A
George, A. L., & Bennett, A. (2005). Case studies and theory development case for appropriate pricing and cost recovery. Habitat International,
in the social sciences. Cambridge: MIT Press. 22(4), 487–502.
George, A. L., & McKeown, T. J. (1985). Case studies and theories of Milenio. (2007, May 4). Cinco industrias consumen 30% del agua potable
organizational decision making. Advances in Information Processing in de Toluca.
Organizations, 2, 21–58. Milenio. (2008a, November 18). Escuadrón jurı́dico de la capital mexi-
Gilbert, A. (2006). Good urban governance: Evidence from a model city?. quense, a cobrar el agua.
Bulletin of Latin American Research, 25(3), 392–419. Milenio. (2008b, November 18). Evaden pagar el agua 20% de los
Gilbert, A. (2007). Water for all: How to combine public management toluqueños.
with commercial practice for the benefit of the poor?. Urban Studies, Milenio. (2008c, November 25). No pagan agua potable mil 100 edificios
44(8), 1559–1579. públicos.
Gilson, L. (1997). The lessons of user fee experience in Africa. Health Milenio. (2009a, February 1). Mantendrá OAPAS de Naucalpan cuota
Policy and Planning, 12(3), 273–285. anual en zonas populares.
GMN (2009). Reseña historica. Gobierno Municipal de Nezahualcóyotl. Milenio. (2009b, March 19). Serı́a un retroceso bajar tarifas y regresar a
GMT (2012). Press release. Gobierno Municipal de Toluca (March 20). subsidias: OAPAS.
Goertz, G., & Mahoney, J. (2012). A tale of two cultures: Qualitative and Milenio. (2009c, March 20). Podrı́a colapsar red hidráulica.
quantitative research in the social sciences. Princeton: Princeton Milenio. (2009d, July 10). Quedaron inconclusos los trabajos para
University Press. garantizar el abasto de agua en Toluca.
Goldfrank, B. (2011). Deepening local democracy in Latin America: Milenio. (2009e, September 7). Debe agua 46% de los toluqueños.
Participation, decentralization, and the left. University Park: Pennsyl- Miraftab, F. (2004). Neoliberalism and casualization of public sector
vania State University Press. services: The case of waste collection services in Cape Town, South
Gómez-Lobo, A., & Contreras, D. (2003). Water subsidy policies: A Africa. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 28(4),
comparison of the Chilean and Colombian schemes. The World Bank 874–892.
Economic Review, 17(3), 391–407. Mizrahi, Y. (2004). Twenty years of decentralization in Mexico: A top-
Grindle, M. S. (2007). Going local: Decentralization, democratization, and down process. In P. Oxhorn, A. D. Selee, & J. S. Tulchin (Eds.),
the promise of good governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Decentralization, democratic governance, and civil society in compara-
Hernández Corrochano, D. (2003). In P. Ramı́rez Kuri (Ed.), Espacio público tive perspective (pp. 33–58). Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson
y reconstrucción de ciudadanı́a. México, DF: Miguel Ángel Porrúa. Center Press.
Hiskey, J. T., & Seligson, M. A. (2003). Pitfalls of power to the people: Montero, A. P., & Samuels, D. J. (2004). The political determinants of
Decentralization, local government performance, and system support decentralization in Latin America: Causes and consequences. In A. P.
in Bolivia. Studies in Comparative International Development, 37(4), Montero, & D. J. Samuels (Eds.), Decentralization and democracy in
64–88. Latin America. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.
IADB (2010). Determinants of bottled water consumption in Mexico. Moreno-Jaimes, C. (2007a). Do competitive elections produce better-
Executive summary. Inter-American Development Bank: Executive quality governments?: Evidence From Mexican municipalities, 1990–
Summary. 2000. Latin American Research Review, 42(2), 136–153.
30 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Moreno-Jaimes, C. (2007b). The political boundaries of institutional Reforma. (2004, April 15). Inconforme tarifa de agua; Comunidad.
capacity: An analysis of municipal governments in Mexico. Revista de Protestan vecinos de la zona popular por cuota anual del lı́quido.
Ciencia Politica, 27(2), 121–153. Reforma. (2005, October 14). Persiste riesgo en Neza.
Morgan, B. (2011). Water on tap: Rights and regulation in the transnational Reforma. (2008, January 20). Tienen 35% de morosos.
governance of urban water services. New York: Cambridge University Rodrı́guez, V. E. (1997). Decentralization in Mexico: From Reforma
Press. municipal to solidaridad to Nuevo Federalismo. Boulder: Westview
Nickson, A., & Franceys, R. (2003). Tapping the market: The challenge of Press.
institutional reform in the urban water sector. Basingstoke, United SAHOP. (1981). Entrega de los sistemas de agua potable y alcantarillado a
Kingdom: Palgrave. los gobiernos de los estados, fortalecimiento del federalismo. Secretarı́a
Nolan, B., & Turbat, V. (1995). Cost recovery in public health services in de Asentamientos Humanos y Obras Públicas (February 5).
Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank. SARH. (1976). Memoria de recursos hidráulicos 1970–1976. Secretarı́a
OAPAS. (2008a). Reporte de tomas por tipo de contratacion. Organismo Agricultura de Recursos Hidráulicos.
Público Descentralizado para la Prestación de los Servicios de Agua Selee, A. D. (2011). Decentralization, democratization, and informal power
Potable, Alcantarillado y Saneamiento de Naucalpan. in Mexico. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.
OAPAS. (2008b). Horarios de servicio de agua potable por colonia en Selee, A. D., & Tulchin, J. S. (2004). Decentralization and democratic
Naucalpan. Organismo Público Descentralizado para la Prestación de los governance: Lessons and challenges. In A. D. Selee, J. S. Tulchin, & P.
Servicios de Agua Potable, Alcantarillado y Saneamiento de Naucalpan. Oxhorn (Eds.), Decentralization, democratic governance, and civil
OAPAS. (2008c). Qué servicio es el más importante? Organismo Público society in comparative perspective (pp. 295–319). Washington, DC:
Descentralizado para la Prestación de los Servicios de Agua Potable, Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
Alcantarillado y Saneamiento de Naucalpan. Sellers, J. M., & Lidström, A. (2007). Decentralization, local government,
OAPAS. (2008d). Para prevenir inundaciones. Organismo Público Des- and the welfare state. Governance, 20(4), 609–632.
centralizado para la Prestación de los Servicios de Agua Potable, Silverman, J. M. (1992). Public sector decentralization: Economic policy
Alcantarillado y Saneamiento de Naucalpan. and sector investment programs. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Smith, L. (2004). The murky waters of the second wave of neoliberalism:
Jovanovich. corporatization as a service delivery model in Cape Town. Geoforum,
Olowu, D., & Wunsch, J. S. (2004). Local governance in Africa: The challenges 35(3), 375–393.
of democratic decentralization. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Smoke, P. (2003). Decentralisation in Africa: Goals, dimensions,
Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1992). Reinventing government: How the myths and challenges. Public Administration and Development,
entrepreneurial spirit is transforming the public sector. Reading: 23(1), 7–16.
Addison-Wesley Pub. Co. Snyder, R. (2001). Scaling down: The subnational comparative method.
Pineda Pablos, N. (2002). La polı́tica urbana de agua potable en México: Studies in Comparative International Development, 36(1), 93–
del centralismo y los subsidios a la municipalización, la autosuficiencia 110.
y la privatización. Region y Sociedad, 14(24), 41–67. Sol de Toluca. (2007, October 9). Entregó el alcalde de Toluca obras
Poder Legislativo del Estado de México. (2008). Informe sobre la revisión hidráulicas y de infraestructura escolar.
de la Cuenta Pública Municipal: Volumen 8: Resultados de la Sol de Toluca. (2008a, April 19). Le recuerdan al alcalde cumplir sus
Evaluación al Desempeño de los Organismos Descentralizados Oper- compromisos.
adores de Agua y Saneamiento y MAVICI. Sol de Toluca. (2008b, May 15). Supervisó el alcalde de Toluca el
Prud’homme, R. (1995). The dangers of decentralization. The World Bank entubamiento del canal La Vega.
Research Observer, 10(2), 201–220. Sol de Toluca. (2008c, May 22). Más de 640 mil pesos para obras de
Reforma. (1996a, June 20). Buscan empresarios mitigar inundaciones. drenaje y agua.
Reforma. (1996b, August 1). Solicita OAPAS la ayuda de colonos e Sol de Toluca. (2008d, October 17). Once obras hidráulicas para que no
industrials. falte agua en 20 años: Alcalde.
Reforma. (1997a, August 15). Cortarán agua 4 dı́as a 38 colonias de Neza. Sol de Toluca. (2009, January 27). Evaporó administración panista $42
Reforma. (1997b, November 5). Irán $75 milliones a obra hidráulica. milliones.
Reforma. (1998a, March 11). Rechazan aumento al agua-Protestan mil Speer, J. (2012). Participatory governance reform: A good strategy for
vecinos de zonas populares por alza de hasta 266%; proponen pagar increasing government responsiveness and improving public services?.
entre 15 y 30% más. World Development, 40(12), 2379–2398.
Reforma. (1998b, March 12). Rechaza PAN bajar agua. SRH. (1973). Los servicios de agua potable en México. Distrito Federal,
Reforma. (1998c, March 13). Cuotas de agua, a referéndum. México: Secretarı́a de Recursos Hidráulicos.
Reforma. (1998d, March 18). Bajan 20% cuota de agua. Tendler, J. (1997). Good government in the tropics. Baltimore: Johns
Reforma. (1998e, March 19). Rechazan rebaja en agua. Hopkins University Press.
Reforma. (1998f, March 20). Gritan, bloquean. . .y se van—Cierran 2 mil Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of
personas el Palacio Municipal, Periférico y Gustavo Baz; no logran Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.
nada. Universal. (2002a, May 16). Inundan aguas negras varias viviendas de
Reforma. (1998g, April 10). Exigen cuota fija de agua por $302—Solicita Neza.
frente de Convergencia Polı́tico Social solicitó el Alcalde José Luis Universal. (2002b, May 19). Inservible el cárcamo Villada en Neza.
Durán establecer pago anual en 131 colonias populares. Universal. (2003, July 11). Muerte y enfermedad por aguas negras.
Reforma. (1998h, April 15). Disuelve Policı́a protesta-Retiran a seis Universal. (2005, June 13). Señalan abusos por falta de agua en Neza.
manifestaciones de la alcaldı́a; asegura Durán que se actuó conforme a Universal. (2006a, March 17). Colonos de Neza dicen tener 15 dı́as sin
la ley. agua.
Reforma. (1998i, May 12). Pagan el agua ante Tribunal-Vecinos de Lomas Universal. (2006b, April 24). Lluvia deja 100 casas inundadas en Neza.
del Cadete garantizan pago mı́nimo mientras sigue su demanda en Universal. (2008, February 11). Adeudan agua 50 mil desde hace cinco
contra de OAPAS. años.
Reforma. (1998j, June 15). Quedarán sin agua en Neza por deber la luz. Universal. (2009a, February 5). Identifican a 14 mil que no pagan servicio
Reforma. (1999, November 8). Ofrecen descuentos para el pago de agua. en Naucalpan.
Reforma. (2000, February 16). Exigen ajustar precio del agua—Piden Universal. (2009b, May 28). Consumo irresponsable causa pérdida de 70%
vecinos aumentar precio a 392 pesos y no los 743 fijados por la de agua.
Alcaldı́a; anuncian movilizaciones. Van Cott, D. L. (2009). Radical democracy in the Andes. New York:
Reforma. (2001a, March 12). Termina sin acuerdo consulta sobre agua. Cambridge University Press.
Reforma. (2001b, July 9). Eximen a colonos de multas por agua—Otorgan Veron, R., Williams, G., Corbridge, S., & Srivastava, M. (2006).
en Toluca descuentos de hasta el 100 por ciento en multas y recargos a Decentralized corruption or corrupt decentralization? Community
clientes morosos. monitoring of poverty-alleviation schemes in Eastern India. World
Reforma. (2003, August 27). Reciclan funcionarios: gobierno, nuevos Development, 34(11), 1922–1941.
gabinetes, Naucalpan, recurre Moya a nueve elementos de la pasada Wampler, B. (2007). Participatory budgeting in Brazil: Contestation,
administración para armar su gabinete. cooperation, and accountability. University Park: Penn State Press.
EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO’S URBAN WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR 31

Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2008). The local connection local government perfor- APPENDIX B. WATER AND SANITATION COVERAGE
mance and satisfaction with democracy in Argentina. Comparative IN MEXICAN STATES
Political Studies, 41(3), 285–308.
Whiteford, S., & Melville, R. (2002). Water and social change in Mexico:
An introduction. In S. Whiteford, & R. Melville (Eds.), Protecting a State Water Sanitation
sacred gift: Water and social change in Mexico (pp. 1–28). La Jolla: coverage (%) coverage (%)
Center for US-Mexican Studies, University of California.
Wilder, M., & Romero Lankao, P. (2006). Paradoxes of decentralization: Aguascalientes 98.80 98.10
Water reform and social implications in Mexico. World Development, Baja California 95.50 93.10
34(11), 1977–1995. Baja California Sur 92.60 93.70
World Bank. (1964). An appraisal of the development program of Mexico: Campeche 90.00 84.90
Volume VII, Annex VI, water supply, sewerage and public health. Chiapas 77.30 81.00
Department of Operations, Western Hemisphere. Washington DC: Chihuahua 94.60 92.10
World Bank.
World Bank. (1975). Report and recommendation to the President (No. P- Coahuila de Zaragoza 98.30 95.40
1727-ME.). Washington DC. Colima 98.60 98.70
World Bank. (1976). Water supply and sewage: Sector study, Mexico (No. Distrito Federal 97.70 99.10
Report no. 1278-ME). Washington, DC: World Bank. Durango 93.90 87.60
World Bank. (1990). Staff appraisal report for loan 3271-ME (No. 8973- Guanajuato 94.40 90.30
ME). Washington, DC: World Bank. Guerrero 69.80 74.00
World Bank. (1992). Project completion report for loan 1186-ME, 1913- Hidalgo 90.70 85.00
ME, 2281-ME (Infrastructure Division, Country Department II, Latin
America and the Caribbean Regional Office No. Report No. 11448).
Jalisco 95.80 97.40
Washington, DC: World Bank. México 94.00 93.60
World Bank. (1994). World development report – Infrastructure for Michoacán 91.60 88.00
development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Morelos 91.50 95.00
World Bank. (2005). Mexico infrastructure public expenditure review Nayarit 92.40 93.10
(IPER). Washington DC: World Bank. Nuevo León 96.60 96.00
Wunsch, J. S. (2001). Decentralization, local governance and “recentral- Oaxaca 76.10 69.20
ization” in Africa. Public Administration and Development, 21(4),
277–288.
Puebla 87.20 86.30
Zovatto, D. (2011). The reelection trend in Latin America. Mundo Querétaro 94.70 90.40
electoral. Retrieved from: <http://www.mundoelectoral.com>. Quintana Roo 92.40 92.70
San Luis Potosı́ 85.50 79.70
Sinaloa 94.70 91.10
Sonora 96.60 89.20
Tabasco 81.20 95.40
Tamaulipas 95.90 86.90
Tlaxcala 98.20 94.50
Veracruz 80.30 82.60
Yucatán 97.20 78.80
Zacatecas 94.30 89.10
National Average 90.90 89.60
Source: CNA (2011a) (based on INEGI XIII Census, 2010).
Note: Percentages and sums do not match to 100 because of rounding.

APPENDIX A. LOAN HISTORY FOR MEXICO’S WATER AND SANITATION SECTOR

Year Loan number Project name Loan amount Federal program


($USD mil) in Mexico
1973 909-ME Mexico City Metropolitan Area Project 90 N/A
1975 1186-ME Medium Cities Water and Sewerage Project 40 FIFAPA 1
1980 1913-ME Second Medium Size Cities Water and Sewerage Project 125 FIFAPA 2
1983 2281-ME Third Medium Size Cities and Sinaloa State Water Project 100.3 FIFAPA 3
1991 3271-ME Water Supply and Sanitation Sector Project 300 APAZU
1992 ME0128* National Investment Program Potable Water 200 APAZU
1994 3751-ME Second Water Supply and Sanitation Sector Project 350 APAZU
2004 N/A Water Supply and Sanitation Technical Assistance Loan 15 N/A
2010 N/A Water Sector Development Policy Loan Project 450 N/A
2010 N/A Water Utilities Efficiency Improvement Project 100 N/A
2010 N/A Water Utilities Efficiency Improvement Project 100 PROME
Sources: Based on author’s calculations from World Bank and Inter-American Development Bank archives.
Note: The World Bank is the co-signor of all loans except for one loan from the Inter-American Development Bank (marked as *).

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

You might also like