You are on page 1of 6

On the Integration of Financial Management and Strategic Management'

Benjamin M. Oviatt, Oklahoma State University

ABSTRACT atic risk. While not ignoring such risk, it is clear


that the financial literature has emphasized systematic
This theoretical exploration answers some questions risk in researching the implications of the CAPM (e.g.,
posed by Bettis (1983) in his examination of the inter- Myers, 1977). This emphasis is essential to satisfy
face between financial and strategic management. The corporate shareholders, and the CAFM assumes that the
integration of the two disciplines is extended through maximization of shareholder utility (wealth) is the
the introduction of transaction and agency cost theory. single goal of corporate managers.
The implications of the theory for managerial and
shareholder motivation are discussed, and the conclu- Bettis (1983) concluded that the strategic management
sion is drawn that managerial and shareholder interests literature, however, deals with a variety of goals and
may be more congruent than strategic management has nonmaximizing behavior. Yet, he did not recognize the
acknowledged, but less congruent than financial theo- significance of this conclusion; that is, goal variety
rists have assumed. necessitates the consideration not only of systematic
risk, but also of unsystematic risk. Thus, Bettis'
first conundrum can be solved by recognizing that the
INTRODUCTION differing assumptions of the CAPM and strategic manage-
ment concerning managerial goals lead directly to em-
Bettis (1983) called attention to the neglected inter- phases on different components of risk.
face between modern finance and strategic management.
While his aim of incorporating financial theory into 2. Information Disclosure
the strategic management literature was worthy, the
three conundrums he delineated may be less puzzling Information about firms is valuable to investors in
than he believed. The purpose of this paper is to making forecasts of firm performance. Investors will
solve two of the conundrums, briefly suggest an alter- pay a premium for the reduction in uncertainty that
native framework for investigating the third, and to relevant information provides. Managers can, there-
extend Bettis' (1983) quest for an integration of the fore, increase the value of their firms, ceteris pari-
disciplines of financial and strategic management. bus, by disclosing all the information possible that
will help investors be more certain of predictions of
superior performance. Bettis (1983) argued that such
THREE CONUNDRUMS conclusions are primarily a product of the efficient
market theories of modern finance.
1. Unsystematic Risk Management
Bettis (1983) also noted that the disclosure of that,
Bettis (1983) provided a selective and sufficient re- same information (e.g^, production secrets) may be
view of two important ideas in the finance literature: valuable to competitors in defeating the firm in the
the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and efficient marketplace for its products. Bettis' conundrum was:
capital markets. The review will not be repeated here.
Readers wishing a thorough analysis may consult Modern financial theory suggests that
Copeland and Weston (1983). disclosing additional information about a
project or strategy can positively affect the
Building on Salter and Weinhold (1979), Bettis (1983) value of the firm, but strategic management
noted an implication of the CAPM is that corporation has stressed only the value of such informa-
managers should be concerned with systematic risks, not tion to a firm's competitors, (p. 406)
unsystematic risks. Yet, the strategic management
literature has demonstrated the necessity for managers Bettis (1983) implied in the conundrum that the two
to address those unsystematic risks, as well. Bettis disciplines offer conflicting advice on the disclosure
was puzzled why strategic management and the CAPM had of information about corporate activities. But he
conflicting foci and stated a conundrum which he said seemed to recognize later that the real problem is the
needed a solution: calculus of the conflicting creative and destructive
values of information:
Modern financial theory suggests that the
equity markets will not reward unsystematic At some point, information disclosure will
(i.e., firm specific) risk management, but start to inhibit entrepreneurial and innova-
unsystematic risk management lies at the tive behavior to an extent not justified by'
heart of strategic management, (p. 406) the Improvement in investor forecasts. Re-
search is needed to establish the location of
Peavy (1984) solved Bettis' (1983) conundrum by showing this point, (p. 410)
mathematically that the CAPM does not ignore unsystem-
It seems unlikely that the disciplines would offer
conflicting advice on the matter—Bettis (1983) cited
iThe author wishes to thank Professor R. Dennis none. Unless Bettis intended that the conundrum is the
Middlemist of Oklahoma State University for a valuable calculus problem with possibly unmeasurable variables,
review of an earlier draft. Professors Alan the conundrum on information disclosure does not exist
Bauerschmidt and Philip Cooley both of the University (c.f. Peavy, 1984).
of South Carolina for contributions to the development
of this paper, and anonymous reviewers for useful
suggestions.

27
3. Global Competition own self interest. The manager's main role was seen as
a contract coordinator for the nexus of shareholders,
In international competition, some firms employees, customers, suppliers, managers, and other
outside the United States are demonstrably contractors. Two important implications for Fama
willing and able to accept returns that are (1980) were (1) no one—including equity suppliers—
below those necessary in the environment pos- really owned the modern large corporation, and (2)
ited by modern financial theory, but others entrepreneurs did not really exist in such a structure.
are not. Strategies and public policies for
dealing with such asymmetries need to be de- Agency cost theory makes no assumption that managers
veloped, (p. 406) maximize shareholder utility, and it has a power to
explain conditions of interest in financial management
On this conundrum, Bettis (1983) and the current author which have been intractable for some time (e.g., capi-
achieved some agreement. Bettis recognized as false tal structure). The idea now seems to be part of the
the assumption that the goal of eill the competitors in mainstream of theory building and theory testing in the
a global market is to maximize shareholder wealth. financial management literature (Barnea, Haugen, and
What Bettis did not state directly is that the CAPM is Senbet, 1981; Copeland and Weston, 1983; Weston,
an inappropriate model of a global product market. 1981).
While resisting the temptation to delve into a subject
tangential to this paper, it is suggested that cost- Transaction Cost Theory
benefit analysis might be a superior framework for the
analysis of global product markets. The benefits The theory of agency cost can be seen as a subdivision
(e.g., employment, protection of natural resources, of the broader framework of transaction cost theory (De
market dominance) that some nations seek from global Alessi, 1983). A transaction is an exchange of a good
markets are sometimes paid for by lower financial re- or service across a technologically separable inter-
turns on the sale of their corporate exports. face, and it is the basic unit of organizational analy-
sis in the theory (Williamson, 1981; Williamson and
Ouchi, 1981). A major objective of every party to a
TOWARD AN INTEGRATING THEORY transaction is to have an efficient (least cost) ex-
change. As Ouchi (1980) summarized the transaction
Although insight into two of the conundrums was cost perspective:
achieved by recognizing that strategic management and
the CAPM make different assumptions about the motiva- An organization, in our sense, is any stable
tion of managers, highlighting such differences does pattern of transactions between individuals
little to extend Bettis' (1983) quest for an integra- or aggregations of individuals. Our frame-
tion of the disciplines. In support of this quest, the work can thus be applied to the analysis of
remainder of this paper explores recent developments in relationships between individuals or between
financial theory, organization theory, and strategic subunits within a corporation, or to transac-
management that have an integrating potential so great tions between firms in an economy, (p. 140)
that Ouchi (1977) suggested the possibility of a "uni-
fied social science. . .during our lifetime." Agency The perspective assumes that the parties to an exchange
cost theory (Fama, 1980; Jensen and Meckling, 1976), are (1) intendedly, but boundedly rational (Simon,
from the discipline of financial management, and 1976; 1978; Williamson, 1981), and (2) sometimes are
transaction cost theory, given birth by economists given to opportunism, or are untrustworthy (Williamson,
(Williamson, 1970; 1975), nurtured by organization 1981). Thus, the individuals in an organization, in-
theorists (Astley and Van de Ven, 1983; Ouchi, 1980), cluding the managers, are promoting their own interests
and as yet a gleam in the eye of strategic management to the best of their ability, and these interests may,
scholars (Lenz, 1981; Porter, 1981; Rumelt, 1982; or may not, coincide with shareholder utility.
Wrigley, 1979), will be shown to be compatible frame-
works with strong conclusions about managerial motiva- The most important properties of transactions are (1)
tion and with the ability to integrate academic disci- the degree of uncertainty in the outcome, (2) the
plines. frequency with which transactions recur, and (3) the
degree to which durable, transaction specific invest-
Agency Cost Theory ments are required to achieve least cost supply
(Williamson, 1981). These properties determine the
Extending the work of Coase (1937) and Alchian and types of contracts which develop between the parties to
Demsetz (1972), Jensen and Meckling defined organiza- the transactions. A classical spot market contract
tions as "legal fictions which serve as a nexus for a will govern the transaction if the outcome is easily
set of contracting relationships among individuals" and quickly measured, the transaction does not continu-
(1976, p. 310). They noted that such a definition ously recur, and the assets involved are not unique to
established a firm as a complex process in which the the transaction.
conflicting objectives of individuals within the nexus
could be brought into equilibrium by the framework of The retail sale of beer would be an example of this
contractual relations. These financial scholars high- type of contract between the customer and the liquor
lighted the conflicting objectives of managers and store. An example of the opposite of the conditions
shareholders, and concluded that each was maximizing listed above would be the employment contract of the
her own utility. Characterizing the shareholder as a manager of the liquor store. The store owner is uncer-
principal and the manager as her agent, Jensen and tain of the exact work activities and outcomes that
Meckling (1976) made an extensive analysis of the prob- will be required at all times, and must rely on the
lems and costs (known as agency problems and agency manager's judgment in many circumstances. The employ-
costs) of maintaining mutually satisfactory behavior on ment relationship is a continuous one. The manager
the part of the principal and the agent within the possesses skills that are specific to the management of
nexus of contracts that is the organization. the owner's liquor store, and those skills would be
costly for the store owner to replace should there be a
Fama (1980) extended this line of thought. He turnover of managers.
conceptualized the manager and capital suppliers (both
debt and equity) of the modern large corporation as A major implication of transaction cost theory is that
separate factors of production, each motivated by their a norm of efficiency will dictate an organization's

28
boundaries and at least some of its strategic actions, are independent across the large number of firms in the
such as the degree of vertical integration (Williamson, market for outside financing. Thus, when the owner-
1975). Market type contracting will yield to internal manager seeks such financing, the price she receives
organizational contracting as the transaction costs of for bonds or equities is lowered by (1) the expected
obtaining relevant information, adjusting to change, value of managerial perks, (2) the expected cost to
monitoring the parties to the exchange, and harmonizing capital suppliers of any business decisions which bene-
the interface rise. Thus, the boundary between the fit the owner-manager and not the capital suppliers,
organization and its customers, suppliers, and competi- and (3) the expected costs to capital suppliers of mon-
tors is drawn (Williamson, 1981). itoring owner-manager behavior. The major point here
is that relatively efficient capital markets provide an
Although the implications of transaction cost theory incentive for owner-managers to consider the interests
for the study of organizations are rich, the limited of capital suppliers, else owner-managers will pay for
objective here is to explore its potential for the in- their failure to do so when they sell claims on the
tegration of modern financial theory and strategic man- firms' cash flow to outsiders.
agement . Other facets of the theory are examined in
the works of Williamson and Ouchi listed in the It has been noted that this form of incentive for
References of this paper. managers is weakened by the fact that firms use equity
markets infrequently (Ellsworth, 1983; Williamson,
1970). Thus, the incentive may only be intermittent.
INCENTIVES FOR CONGRUENT MANAGER AND
SHAREHOLDER INTERESTS Managerial Labor Market Incentives

The contrary assumptions of the CAPM and strategic Fama (1980) uses the managerial job market in
management, regarding managerial motivation, contrib- conjunction with the capital markets to generalize the
uted to two of Bettis' (1983) conundrums. But, finan- Jensen and Meckling (1976) approach to large corpora-
cial management and strategic management may be able to tions. According to Fama (1980) if managers act to
achieve some agreement about managerial motivation siphon off resources for their own benefit or act in
within the framework of transaction cost theory (and other ways that fail to maximize firm value, their
its subset agency cost theory). Williamson (1970), behavior will be reflected in depressed prices for
Jensen and Meckling (1976), and Fama (1980) were in their firms' shares and bonds. Stock and bond price
agreement that managers are motivated by their own self fluctuations serve as signals of managerial effective-
interest. Yet, together they exposed a surprising ness to the managerial labor markets. Those signals
number of incentives that tend to make managers' and are used by boards of directors to determine managers'
shareholders' interests congruent. Furthermore, the compensation. Therefore, the capital and labor markets
logic of these authors might satisfy the emphasis of operate together to influence compensation so that the
strategic management on descriptive goals (Bettis, manager is rewarded or penalized for her ability or in-
1983). ability to increase shareholder wealth.

Incentives Within the Multidivisional Structure Of course, much information about managerial
performance is hidden in the complex causality that
0. E. Williams' writings on the superiority of the determines any organizational outcome—including stock
multidivisional form (M-form) of organizational struc- price. Yet, that very uncertainty should bias manager-
ture to the unitary, or functional, form (U-form) first ial compensation down if directors are averse to re-
brought his ideas to the attention of organization warding behavior which is of uncertain benefit. Thus,
theorists and strategic management scholars (e.g., competent managers have an incentive to make the clear-
Williamson, 1975; 1970). In the M-form of semiautono- est possible association between their performance and
mous businesses, the performance of divisions is mea- the price of their firm's stock.
sured almost entirely by economic criteria such as ROI.
In addition, a closer monitoring and understanding of The Incentive of Intra-firm Managerial Competition
divisional performance is allowed in the M-form due to
the great amount of information available to corporate Fama (1980) also recognized that top managers were
executives, tbe familiarity of those executives with disciplined by other managers in the firm, especially
the corporation's portfolio of businesses, and the those near the top. Such managers want to provide as
close supervision by the expert corporate staff. Thus, many positive' signals as possible to markets for their
Williamson (1975; 1970) hypothesized managerial labor, and are aware that their performance is partial-
emoluments were attenuated and shareholder interests ly signaled by their firm's stock price. Therefore,
(efficiency of resource use) were emphasized in the managers near the top tend to support only competent
M-form as compared to the U-form. This hypothesis has top managers who are perceived to be raising the firm's
received moderate empirical support (Armour and Teece, stock price. In this way the hierarchy of managers may
1978). Williamson (1970) expressed his view that provide another incentive for managerial behavior which
profit maximizing behavior may be much more closely coincides with stockholder interests.
approximated than the critics of the neoclassical
theory of the firm have believed, since the M-form has
Director Incentives
been widely adopted by the large manufacturing firms in
many U.S. industries (Rumelt, 1974).
Fama (1980) hypothesized that outside directors were
especially useful in stimulating and overseeing the
Capital Market Incentives competition between managers within the firm, and
insuring that such competition contributes to stock
Jensen and Meckling (1976) ignored organization price increases. Fama (1980) believed the discipline
structure and stressed that owner-managers (a focus of the market for the services of outside directors
most appropriate in small to medium size firms) who re- would insure that directors provide this stimulation
duce organizational profits by increasing expenditures and monitoring. However, Fama (1980) recognized the
on perquisites will pay for this behavior when they typical weakness of boards of directors (Mace, 1971;
seek outside financing. The authors assumed that the Monsen and Downs, 1965) by putting less emphasis on
suppliers of outside capital have information that en- this form of discipline than on the managerial labor
ables them to develop unbiased estimates of the cost of market.
managerial perks, and that the errors in the estimates

29
Takeover Threat Incentives On another level, what is the integrating potential of
transaction cost theory? Can the theory provide a
Both Williamson (1970) and Fama (1980) recognized that solid framework for advancing Bettis' (1983) desire to
acquisition threats by outside firms may be an incen- integrate financial management and strategic manage-
tive for managers to maintain a high stock price. But ment? Even more important, how close can transaction
both also warned against the power of such a threat, cost theory take us to Ouchi's (1977) vision of a uni-
except in extreme circumstances, because of the great fied social science? The list of relevant questions
cost and uncertainty of a takeover effort that must be could be expanded, and it seems likely that the trans-
assumed by an acquiring firm. actions framework provides an interdisciplinary oppor-
tunity to advance our understanding of organizations.
Stock Options Incentives

Stock options have been viewed as powerful incentives REFERENCES


for managers to increase stock price for some time
(Lewellen, 1969). But again, the issue of the complex 1. Alchian, A. A. & Demsetz, H., "Production,
causality of organizational outcomes makes any Information Costs, and Economic Organization,"
connection between managerial behavior and stock price American Economic Review, Vol. 62 (1972), pp. 777-
difficult to observe (Williamson, 1970). Thus, the 795.
incentive is weakened.
2. Armour, H. 0. & Teece, D. J., "Organizational
Incentives for Shareholders Structure and Economic Performance: A Test of the
Multidivisional Hypothesis," Bell Journal of
The list of incentives has so far included only those Economics, Vol. 9 (1978), pp. 106-122.
impinging on managers. Yet, shareholders are also
inhibited from making excessive demands on organiza- 3. Astley, W. G. & Van de Ven, A. H., "Central
tions. The nexus of contracts that constitutes an Perspectives and Debates in Organization Theory,"
organization is a team of interdependent individuals Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 28 (1983),
(Ouchi, 1980). The individuals' shares of the total pp. 245-273.
organizational inputs are difficult to measure in many
circumstances, and the team's outputs are more than the 4. Barnea, A., Haugen, R. A., & Senbet, L. W.,
sum of individual inputs (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972; "Market Imperfections, Agency Problems, and
Ouchi, 1980). Because of measurement problems, moni- Capital Structure: A Review," Financial
toring costs (a type of transaction cost) are incurred Management (1981), pp. 7-22.
by team members to insure that the returns generated by
the organization are equitably distributed among team 5. Baumol, W. J., Economic Theory and Operations
members (Ouchi, 1980). No member (shareholder, man- Analysis, 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
ager, employee, etc.) can long enjoy recognized dispro- Prentice-Hall, 1977).
portionate returns without incurring the costs of
inferior inputs by the dissatisfied members of the team 6. Berle, A. A. & Means, G., The Modern Corporation
(Sherwin, 1983). Thus, it is self serving for each and Private Property (New York: Macmillan, 1932).
member to insure that all other members achieve some
minimum level of satisfaction (Cyert and March, 1963). 7. Bettis, R. A., "Modern Financial Theory, Corporate
Shareholders who insist on the superiority of their Strategy and Public Policy: Three Conundrums,"
claims to organizational rewards may disturb the team's
Academy of Management Review, Vol. 8 (1983), pp.
efficient functioning.
406-415.

8. Coase, R., "The Nature of the Firm," Economics,


CONCLUSION Vol. 4 (1937), pp. 386-405.

The list of incentives that may cause manager and 9. Copeland, T. E. & Weston J. F., Financial Theory
stockholder interests to coincide is a long one. Al- and Corporate Policy, 2nd ed. (Reading, Mass.:
though each incentive was seen as limited by counter- Addison-Wesley, 1983).
vailing forces, the sheer length of the list is impres-
sive. Even if the incentives are weak, or apply only 10. Cyert, R. M. & March, J. G., A Behavioral Theory
intermittently, their collective force may be strong. of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
These implications of transaction cost theory and Prentice-Hall, 1963).
agency cost theory suggest that there may be a greater
congruency in managerial and shareholder interests than 11. De Alessi, L., "Property Rights, Transaction
strategic management has generally acknowledged, but Costs, and X-Efficiency: An Essay in Economic
less congruency than some financial theories (e.g., Theory," American Economic Review, Vol. 73 (1983),
CAPM) have assumed. pp. 64-81.

The question of the degree of congruency is not a new 12. Ellsworth, R. R., "Subordinate Financial Policy to
one (Berle and Means, 1932), and a variety of factors Corporate Strategy," Harvard Business Review, Vol.
may foster incongruent managerial and shareholder 83, No. 6 (1983), pp. 170-182.
interests (Baumol, 1977). But transaction cost theory
may suggest a new framework for investigation. The 13. Fama, E. F., "Agency Problems and the Theory of
answers to newly framed questions may provide new in- the Firm," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88,
sights, and several new questions are apparent from the (1980), pp. 288-307.
preceding review of managerial and stockholder incen-
tives . What are the specific transaction costs in- 14. Jensen, M. C. & Meckling, W. H., "Theory of the
volved in the shareholder-manager relationship? Do the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
incentives for congruency in the relationship reduce Ownership Structure," Journal of Financial
those transaction costs? Which incentives are most Economics, Vol. 3 (1976), pp. 305-360.
powerful and involve the least transaction costs?
15. Lenz, R. T., "'Determinants' of Organizational
Performance: An Interdisciplinary Review,"

30
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 2 (1981), pp. 25. Rumelt, R. P., "Diversification Strategy and
131-154. Profitability," Strategic Management Journal, Vol.
3 (1982), pp. 359-369.
16. Lewellen, W. G., "Management and Ownership in the
Large Firm," in E. F. Brigham & R. E. Johnson 26. Salter, M. S. & Weinhold, W. A. Diversification
(Eds.), I88ues in Managerial Finance, 2nd ed. Through Acquisition (New York: The Free Press,
(Hinsdale, 111.: Dryden Press, [1969], 1980), pp. 1979).
3-21.
27. Sherwin, D. S., "The Ethical Roots of the Business
17. Mace, M. L., Directors: t^th and Reality (Boston: System," Harvard Business Review, Vol. 83, No. 6
Harvard Business School Division of Research, (1983), pp. 183-192.
1971).
28. Simon, H. A. Administrative Behavior, 3rd ed. (New
18. Monsen, R. J., Jr. & Downs, A., "A Theory of Large York: The Free Press, 1976).
Managerial Firms," Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 73 (1965), pp. 221-236. 29. Simon, H. A., "Rationality as Process and as
Product of Thought," American Economic Review,
19. Myers, S. C., "The Relation Between Real and Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 68 (1978), pp. 1-16.
Financial Measures of Risk and Return," in I.
Friend 4 J. L. Bicksler (Eds.), Risk and Return in 30. Weston, J. F., "Developments in Finance Theory,"
Finance, Vol. 1 (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, Financial Management, Vol. 10 (1981), pp. 5-22.
1977).
31. Williamson, 0. E. Corporate Control of Business
20. Ouchi, W., "Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Behavior (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall,
Antitrust Implications," Administrative Science 1970).
Quarterly, Vol. 22 (1977), pp. 540-544.
32. Williamson, 0. E. Markets and Hierarchies (New
21. Ouchi, W., "Market8, Bureaucracies, and Clans," York: The Free Press, 1975).
Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 25 (1980),
pp. 129-141. 33. Williamson, 0. E., "The Economics of Organization:
The Transaction Cost Approach," American Journal
22. Peavy, J. W., III, "Modern Financial Theory, of Sociology, Vol. 87 (1981), pp. 548-577.
Corporate Strategy, and Public Policy: Another
Perspective," Academy of Management Review, Vol. 9 34. Williamson, 0. E. & Ouchi, W. G., "The Markets and
(1984), pp. 152-157. Hierarchies Program of Research: Origins,
Implications, Prospects," in W. Joyce & A. Van de
23. Porter, M. E., "The Contributions of Industrial Ven (Eds.), Perspectives on Organizational Design
Organization to Strategic Management," Academy of and Behavior (New York: Wiley, 1981).
Management Review, Vol. 6 (1981), pp. 609-620.
35. Wrigley, L., "Commentary," in D. E. Schendel & C.
24. Rumelt, R. P., Strategy, Structure, and Economic W. Hofer (Eds.), Strategic Management: A New View
Performance (Boston: Division of Research, of Business Policy and Planning (Boston: Little,
Harvard Business School, 1974). Brown and Co., 1979), pp. 284-289.

31

You might also like