You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Association

The Institutions of Governance


Author(s): Oliver E. Williamson
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the
Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1998), pp.
75-79
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/116896 .
Accessed: 30/03/2011 22:24

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
The Institutionsof Governance

By OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON*

The new institutional economics (NIE) is provision for two background conditions: the
an idea whose time has come. That was evi- condition of societal embeddedness (to which
dent to R. C. 0. Matthews in 1986, who in his sociologists refer; [Mark Granovetter, 1985;
presidential address to the Royal Economic Victor Nee, 1997]) and the attributes of hu-
Society declared that the NIE was "one of the man actors (Herbert Simon, 1985; Leda
liveliest areas in our discipline" (1986 p. 903) Cosmides and John Tooby, 1994, 1996). I re-
and thereafterdescribed it as a body of think- turn to these two background conditions in
ing based in two propositions:institutionsmat- Section II. Suffice it to observe here that the
ter, and institutions are susceptible to analysis NIE is, by its very nature, an interdisciplinary
(1986 p. 903). The proposition that institu- undertaking.
tions matteris embracedby institutionalecon-
omists of all kinds, old and new. What I. The Governanceof ContractualRelations
distinguishes the NIE from earlier (and some
contemporary) work on institutions is that in- Transaction-cost economnicsis located on
stitutions are susceptible to analysis. Older- the branch of the NIE that is predominantly
style institutional economics was content to concerned with governance, the branch that
critique orthodoxy and collapsed for failure to has its origins in Ronald Coase's treatmentof
advance a positive research agenda (Ronald firms and marketsin his classic 1937 paper on
Coase, 1984; Matthews, 1986). The NIE has "The Nature of the Firm.3' Rather than take
responded to the challenge by (i) developing the organization of econoniic activity in firms
a comparative institutional logic of organiza- and markets as preexisting, defined largely by
tion to which (ii) many applications and re- technology, Coase described firms and mar-
futable implications accrue and in relation to kets as alternative means for doing the very
which (iii) many empirical tests have been same thing. The allocation of activity as be-
conducted and are broadly corroborative(Paul tween markets and hierarchies was no longer
Joskow, 1991; Howard Shelanski and Peter taken as given, but needed to be de-
Klein, 1995; Bruce Lyons, 1996; Keith rived. Should a firm make or buy? Which
Crocker and Scott Masten, 1996). transactionsgo where and why? The firm was
The institutions of principal interest to the reconceptualized for these purposes as a gov-
NIE are the institutionalenvironment(or rules ernance structure(which is an organizational
of the game-the polity, judiciary, laws of construction).
contract and property [Douglas North, 1991]) Much of the predictivecontentof transaction-
and the institutions of governance (or play of cost economicsworksthroughthediscrminating-
the game-the use of markets,hybrids, firms, alignmenthypothesis:transactions,which differ
bureaus). Although it has been customary to in their attributes,are aligned with governance
work at one level at a time, each level informs structures,which differ in theircost and compe-
the other, and recent work of a combined kind tence, so as to effect a (mainly) transaction-cost
has appeared as applications to economic de- economizng result. hnplementingthis requires
velopment and reform are attempted.Also, the that transactions, governance structures, and
study of economic institutions needs to make transaction-costeconomizing all be described.
What are the definingattributesof transactions?
Whatarethe attributeswithrespectto whichgov-
* Walter A. Hass School of Business, Department of ernance structuresdiffer? What main purposes
Economics, Law School, University of California,Berke- are served by economic organization?How is
lev. CA 94720-1900. transaction-cost economizingaccomplished?
75
76 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1998

According to John R. Commons (1932 p. although vertical integration is the archetype


4), "the ultimate unit of activity ... must con- transactionout of which transaction-costeco-
tain in itself the three principles of conflict, nomics works, labor, capital, corporate gov-
mutuality, and order. This unit is a transac- ernance, regulation/deregulation, vertical
tion." Transaction-cost economics concurs market restrictions, multinational and public-
that the transactionis the basic unit of analysis sector transactions are variations on a theme
and regardsgovernance as the means by which to which numerouspublic-policy ramifications
order is accomplished in a relation in which accrue. Finally, although bilateral dependency
potential conflict threatens to undo or upset (asset specificity) is a widespread condition,
opportunitiesto realize mutual gains. the basic transaction-cost setup, with its em-
The problem of conflict upon which phasis on ex post governance, applies to con-
transaction-costeconomics originally focused tractualhazards more generally.
is that of bilateral dependency (Williamson, Additional hazards that transaction-cost
1975; Benjamin Klein et al., 1978). Whereas economics has begun to addressinclude (i) the
the organization of transactions that are sup- hazards of weak property rights (David J.
ported by generic investments is easy (classi- Teece, 1986); (ii) measurement hazards of
cal market contracting works well because multiple-task (Bengt Hlolmstrom and Paul
each party can go its own way with minimal Milgrom, 1991), oversearching (Yoram
cost to the other), potential problems arise Barzel, 1982; Roy Kenney and Klein, 1983),
when nonredeployable investments are made. and multiple-principal(Avinash Dixit, 1996)
Parties that are joined in a condition of bilat- kinds; (iii) intertemporalhazards, which can
eral dependency (by reason of asset specific- take the form of disequilibrium contracting,
ity) and are confronted with contractual real-time responsiveness, long latency, and
incompleteness (by reason of bounds on ratio- strategic abuse; (iv) hazards that accrue to
nality) must confront strains(by reason of op- weaknesses in the institutional environment
portunism) when faced with the need to adapt (North and BarryWeingast, 1989; Brian Levy
cooperatively. How should such contracts be and Pablo Spiller, 1994; Weingast, 1995),
managed? which are pertinentto economic development
A comparative assessment of markets and and reform, and (v) weaknesses of probity,
hierarchiesis needed. Taking adaptationto be which are of special concern for what James
the central problem of economic organization, Q. Wilson (1989) refers to as "sovereign
of which autonomous and cooperative kinds transactions" (see also Williamson [1998]).
are distinguished, marketsenjoy the advantage To be sure, lenses other than transaction-cost
in autonomous-adaptation respects, and the economics can and have been brought to bear.
advantage shifts to hierarchies as the needs It is nonetheless noteworthy that transaction-
for cooperative adaptation build up. Discrete cost economics relates to all of these hazards
structural differences between markets and in the following four respects: (i) all of these
hierarchies in incentive intensity, administra- hazards would vanish but for bounds on ratio-
tive control, and contract-law regimes are re- nality and opportunism, (ii) the magnitude of
sponsible for these adaptive differences the hazards varies systematically with the at-
(Williamson, 1991). tributes of transactions, (iii) ex post gover-
Implicit in the foregoing and important to nance (as well as ex ante incentive alignment)
the transaction-cost economics enterprise is is an importantinstrumentin effecting hazard
the assumption that contracts, albeit incom- mitigation, and (iv) the discriminating-
plete, are interpreted in a farsighted manner, alignment hypothesis applies. Hazard mitiga-
according to which economic actors look tion through the ex post governance of
ahead, perceive potential hazards, and embed incomplete contracts is the general rubric.
transactionsin governance structuresthathave Whereas organizational variety was once
hazard-mitigating purpose and effect. Also, ascribedprincipally to monopoly purpose and/
most of the governance action works through or efficient risk-bearing, much of this variety
private ordering, with courts being reserved is usefully interpreted in transaction-cost-
for purposes of ultimate appeal. Furthermore, economizing terms. It matters a lot, as it turns
VOL. 88 NO. 2 THE NEW INSTITUTIONALECONOMICS 77

out, whetherfirms are describedas governance groups and nation states and operate as soci-
structuresratherthan production functions. etal supports, or the lack thereof, for credible
What came to be known as the "inhos- contracting. A recurringconcern is when and
pitality tradition'' in antitrust was the why do reputation-effect mechanisms work
public-policy consequence of treating the well and poorly?
firm as a production function (which is a Turning to the attributes of human actors,
technical construction). Because a techno- Simon (1985 p. 303) takes the position that
logical justification for nonstandard and un- "Nothing is more fundamental in setting our
familiar contractual and organizational research agenda and informing our research
practices was lacking under the neoclassical methods than our view of the nature of the
setup, such practices were presumed to be human beings whose behavior we are study-
anticompetitive. ing." The huge literatureon "psychology and
However, that is because the study of eco- economics," as recently summarized by
nomics was needlessly truncated.Technolog- Matthew Rabin (1996), speaks to many of the
ical economies of scale or scope and related issues. Of special interestis researchstemming
"technical or physical aspects" do not exhaust from Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky
the possibilities. Organizational economies (1982), in which the limits and biases of in-
that are attributableto the alignment of gov- dividual decision-makers in making probabi-
ernance structureswith the attributesof trans- listic choices are revealed. Also pertinent are
actions had been ignored or suppressed.Upon recent studies by cognitive anthropologists
working through the logic of discriminating (Edwin Hutchins, 1995) and evolutionary
alignment, an altogetherdifferent rationalefor psychologists (Cosmides and Tooby, 1996).
vertical integration, vertical market restric- Hutchins's book on Cognition in the Wild
tions, and otherforms of nonstandardcontract- makes the distinction between cognition "in
ing took shape. the laboratory, where cognition is studied in
Many of the hithertopuzzling economic in- captivity, and the everyday world, where hu-
stitutions of capitalism were interpretedmore man cognition adapts to its natural surround-
constructively as this broader approach to ings" (1995 p. xiv). Issues of organizationare
economizing progressed. Thus, although an- brought in by viewing individuals as "part of
ticompetitive purpose remains a concern if the a larger computational system" (Hutchins,
relevant market-power preconditions are sat- 1995 p. xv). Because, moreover, each generic
isfied, those are stringent preconditions. As a form of organization has both strengths and
consequence, anticompetitive effect is better weaknesses, organization needs to be studied
regarded as the exception ratherthan the rule. as both problem and solution. Cognitive an-
The concepts of credible commitment and thropology can help to inform both.
discriminating alignment that inform private- The evolutionary-psychology literature
sector governance have also turned out to be notes that cognitive methods "drawn from
instructive for understandingeconomic devel- logic, mathematics, and probability theory"
opment and reform. Viewing the institutional (Cosmides and Tooby, 1994 p. 319) and cog-
arrangements(rules of the game) through the nitive processes that had good survival prop-
lens of contract and governance has helped, erties for human agents operating in the
among other things, to disclose when and why Pleistocene sometimes differ. For example,
privatizationefforts will succeed or fail. framing problems of choice under uncertainty
in frequentist terms, which is the manner in
II. Background Conditions which they arise in the wild, rather than in
point estimates, which is the way they are
The two background conditions to which I posed by statistical decision theory, is conse-
referred earlier are the conditions of embed- quential. Cognitive biases and disabilities are
dedness and the attributes of human actors. often reduced when problems are presented in
The first of these is antecedent to the polity frequentistterms.
and refers to societal features (norms, cus- Evidence, moreover, that individuals on av-
toms, mores, religion) which differ among erage are poor probabilists speaks only to the
78 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1998

mean. If there is variance in the aptitude to view, May 1994 (Papers and Proceedings),
make probabilisticchoices among members of 84(2), pp. 327-32.
the population, and if it is cost-effective to _______. "Are Humans Good Intuitive Statis-
screen for differential competence, then an ef- ticians After All?" Cognition, January
ficient alignment of differential competence to 1996, 58(1), pp. 1-73.
tasks can be effected through specialization Crocker,Keith and Masten,Scott. "Regulation
(organization). Not only does organization and AdministeredContractsRevisited: Les-
matterin this respect, but it also relieves prob- sons from Transaction-CostEconomics for
lems of limited cognitive ability by permitting Public Utility Regulation." Journal of Reg-
composite tasks to be broken down into nearly ulatoryEconomics, January1996, 9( 1 ), pp.
separable parts, each of which is more tracta- 5-39.
ble, thereafter to be recombined (Simon, Dixit,Avinash.The making of economic policy:
1962). The upshot is that the study of individ- A transaction cost politics perspective.
ual decision-making needs to be extended to Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996.
make provision for the efficient deployment Granovetter,Mark."Economic Action and So-
of individuals and groups within an organiza- cial Structure:The Problem of Embedded-
tion. Cognitive anthropology, organization ness." American Journal of Sociology,
theory, and evolutionary psychology are all November 1985, 91(3), pp. 481-501.
implicated. Holmstrom,Bengt and Milgrom,Paul. "Multi-
task Principal-Agent Analysis." Journal of
III. ConcludingRemarks Law, Economics, and Organization, Special
Issue 1991, 7, pp. 24-52.
The papers and discussions at the inaugural Hutchins,Edwin. Cognition in the wild. Cam-
conference of the International Society for bridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995.
New Institutional Economics in September Joskow,Paul. "The Role of Transaction Cost
1997 record that the NIE continues to extend Economics in Antitrust and Public Utility
its analytical reach and inform new issues. RegulatoryPolicies." Journal of Law, Eco-
New conceptual challenges arise as new ap- nomics, and Organization, Special Issue
plications are attempted.A deeper understand- 1991, 7, pp. 53-83.
ing of complex economic organization is in Kahneman,Danieland Tversky,Amos. "On the
progress. Study of Statistical Intuitions." Cognition,
March 1982, 11(2), pp. 123-41.
REFERENCES Kenney,Roy and Klein, Benjamin. "The Eco-
nomics of Block Booking." Journal of Law
Barzel, Yoram. "Measurement Cost and the and Economics, October 1983, 26(3), pp.
Organizationof Markets." Journal of Law 497-540.
and Economics, April 1982,25(1), pp. 27- Klein, Benjamin;Crawford,T. A. and Alchian,
48. A. A. "Vertical Integration, Appropriable
Coase, Ronald H. "The Nature of the Firm." Rents, and the Competitive ContractingPro-
Economica, November 1937, 4(4), pp. cess." Journal of Law and Economics, Oc-
386-405. tober 1978, 21(2), pp. 297-326.
--e"The New InstitutionalEconomics." Levy, Brian and Spiller, Pablo. "The In-
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical stitutional Foundations of Regulatory
Economics, March 1984, 140(1 ), pp. 229- Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of
31. Telecommunications Regulation.'9 Journal
Commons, John R. "The Problem of Correlat- of Law, Economics, and Organization, Oc-
ing Law, Economics, and Ethics." Wiscon- tober 1994, 10(2), pp. 201-46.
sin Law Review, December 1932, 8(1), pp. Lyons, Bruce. "Empirical Relevance of Effi-
3-26. cient Contract Theory: Inter-firm Con-
Cosmides,Leda and Tooby,John. "Better than tracts." Oxford Review of Economic
Rational: Evolutionary Psychology and the Policy, Winter 1996, 12 (4), pp. 27 -
Invisible Hand." American Economic Re- 52.
VOL. 88 NO. 2 THE NEW INSTITUTIONALECONOMICS 79

Matthews, R. C. 0. "The Economics of Insti- Philosophical Society, December 1962,


tutions and the Sources of Growth." Eco- 106(6), pp. 467-82.
nomic Journal, December 1986, 96(384), . "Human Nature in Politics: The Di-
pp. 903-18. alogue of Psychology with Political Sci-
Nee, Victor. "Sources of the New Institution- ence." American Political Science Review,
alism in Sociology." Unpublished manu- January 1985, 79(2), pp. 293-303.
script, Cornell University, 1997. Teece,David J. "Profiting from Technological
North, Douglass. "Institutions.9" Journal of Innovation." Research Policy, December
Economic Perspectives, Winter 1991, 5(1), 1986, 15(6), pp. 285-305.
pp. 97-112. Weingast,BarryR. "The Economic Role of Po-
North, Douglass and Weingast, Barry. "Consti- litical Institutions: Market-PreservingFed-
tutions and Commitment:The Evolution of eralism and Economic Development."
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Journal of Law, Economics, and Organi-
17th Century England." Journal of Eco- zation, April 1995, 11( 1 ), pp. 1-31.
nomic History, December 1989, 49(4), pp. Williamson,OliverE. Markets and hierarchies:
803-32. Analysis and antitrust implications. New
Rabin, Matthew. "Psychology and Econom- York: Free Press, 1975.
ics." Unpublished manuscript, University _. "Comparative Economic Organiza-
of California-Berkeley, 1996. tion: The Analysis of Discrete Structural
Shelanski, Howard and Klein, Peter. "Empirical Alternatives." Administrative Science
Research in TransactionCost Economics: A Quarterly, June 1991, 36, pp. 269-96.
Review and Assessment." Journal of Law, _. "Public and Private Bureaucracies."
Economics, and Organization, October Unpublished manuscript, University of
1995, 11(2), pp. 335-61. California-Berkeley, 1998.
Simon Herbert. "The Architecture of Com- Wilson,JamesQ. Bureaucracy. New York: Ba-
plexity." Proceedings of the American sic Books, 1989.

You might also like