You are on page 1of 13

World Development Vol. 28, No. 4, pp.

617±629, 2000
Ó 2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/00/$ - see front matter
PII: S0305-750X(99)00151-5

The Micro®nance Schism


JONATHAN MORDUCH*
Princeton University, New Jersy, USA
Summary. Ð Leading advocates for micro®nance have put forward an enticing ``win-win''
proposition: micro®nance institutions that follow the principles of good banking will also be those
that alleviate the most poverty. This vision forms the core of widely-circulated ``best practices,'' but
as a general proposition the vision is fully supported neither by logic nor by the available empirical
evidence. Recognizing the limits to the win-win proposition is an important step toward reaching a
more constructive dialogue between micro®nance advocates that privilege ®nancial development
and those that privilege social impacts. Ó 2000 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words Ð poverty, credit, microenterprise, Bangladesh, Indonesia

1. INTRODUCTION households demand access to credit, not


``cheap'' credit. Thus, programs can charge
Few recent ideas have generated as much high interest rates without compromising
hope for alleviating poverty in low-income outreach.
countries as the idea of micro®nance. Micro®- If the argument is right, much poverty alle-
nance promises both to combat poverty and to viation can be achieved at no cost to govern-
develop the institutional capacity of ®nancial ments and donors±or perhaps even at a small
systems through ®nding ways to cost-e€ectively pro®t. The vision has been translated into a
lend money to poor households.1 Poor house- series of ``best practices'' circulated widely by
holds are typically excluded from the formal the Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest
banking system for lack of collateral, but the (CGAP; a donor consortium housed within the
micro®nance movement exploits new contrac- World Bank), the US Agency for International
tual structures and organizational forms that
reduce the riskiness and costs of making small,
uncollateralized loans. Micro®nance programs
have also demonstrated that even poor house- * The paper was initially prompted by a meeting with
holds can save in substantial quantities. Success representatives of the Consultative Group to Assist the
stories are being written around the world, Poorest, the US Agency for International Development,
from Jakarta to Dhaka to Nairobi to La Paz. ACCION International, and the Harvard Institute for
Advocates have broadcast these successes International Development, convened in Cambridge in
widely, and donors have been quick to pledge Spring 1997. My views have evolved through conversa-
billions of dollars to support the expansion of tions with Abhijit Banerjee, Gregory Chen, Monique
programs in the next decade. Cohen, Peter Fidler, Mike Goldberg, Claudio Gonzalez-
Much of the enthusiasm rests on an enticing Vega, Albert Park, Marguerite Robinson, Richard
``win-win'' proposition: micro®nance institu- Rosenberg, Jay Rosengard, J. D. von Pischke, Jacob
tions that follow the principles of good banking Yaron, and participants at lively seminars at Ohio State
will also be those that alleviate the most and the World Bank. I have particularly bene®ted from
poverty. By eventually eschewing subsidies and input from practitioners in Bangladesh, Indonesia, and
achieving ®nancial sustainability, micro®nance China, and from Christopher Dunford and his collea-
institutions will be able to grow without the gues at Freedom From Hunger. Throughout, Mark
constraints imposed by donor budgets. In the Schreiner has provided particularly comprehensive and
process, according to the argument, these thoughtful criticisms. The paper was completed during a
institutions will be able to serve more year as a National Fellow at the Hoover Institution,
poor people than can be served by programs Stanford University. The views expressed here are mine
fueled by subsidies. A key tenet is that poor solely. Final revision accepted: 30 June 1999.
617
618 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Development, the United Nations Develop- cally making high margin, quick turnaround
ment Program, and other key donors. investments. As a result, the clients are capable
While some ®nd the win-win argument to be of paying real interest rates approaching 50%
self-evident, most practitioners appear to be per year on 3±4 month loans (as is true for
convinced by only part of the message. Despite clients of BoliviaÕs well-known BancoSol).4
keen awareness of ``best practices,'' nearly all Elsewhere, in contrast, the best available
programs remain substantially subsidized. This investments of many micro®nance clients
is especially so for those with explicitly social involve longer term loans for moderate-return
objectives. For example, the most careful and activities like livestock raising, handicrafts, and
comprehensive recent survey shows that the agricultural processing. Programs fear that
programs that target the poorest borrowers increasing the costs of borrowing will put these
generate revenues sucient to cover just 70% of investment opportunities beyond the reach of
their full costs (MicroBanking Bulletin, 1998).2 their target clients. Not surprisingly, donor
While subsidy rates will surely fall as more exhortations to follow the full slate of ``best
programs gain age and scale, even many older, practices'' have frustrated many NGOs. Until
larger programs are far from being able to make recently, consideration of who is being served
ends meet with their own revenues. Some donors has been almost entirely absent from the ``best
believe that little more than 5% of all programs practices'' conversation.
today will be ®nancially sustainable ever.3 Instead, socially-minded practitioners have
Why are programs not raising interest rates had to contend with the assertion that those
and moving over to ``best practices'' more clients that cannot pay the kinds of charges
quickly? Much of the answer is that the win- required for programs to break-even then
win proposition turns out to be far more certainly must be destitute, in need of direct
complicated than it would seem at ®rst. It rests health and education programs (or simple
on a series of empirical assumptions and logical charity) rather than credit (e.g., Gonzalez-
connections that do not generalize easily and Vega, 1998). But socially-minded practitioners
which have yet to be demonstrated through argue that their target group of clients is
careful empirical studies. Almost no studies somewhere between destitute households and
provide comparable and reliable evidence on richer households. These target households
attributes as basic as the incomes, occupations, (termed here the ``core'' poor) can potentially
or loan uses of clientsÐand of comparable bene®t from micro®nance services, even if
nonparticipants (the Hulme & Mosley, 1996, average loan sizes are too small to allow the
studies are an important exception). So while kinds of economies of scale that have delivered
advocates continually trumpet the advantages ®nancial sustainability for well-known
and successes of one program or another, programs such as BancoSol and Bank Rakyat
practitioners concerned with who they serve IndonesiaÕs unit desa system.5
have inevitably discounted the success stories Confronting the schism between rhetoric and
for fear that someone elseÕs oranges are being actionÐand between ®nancially-minded
compared to their apples. donors and socially-minded programsÐwill
By far, loan size has been the predominant ®rst require that both donors and practitioners
metric for comparison of outreach. But loan pay greater attention to who is being served
size is a rough and indirect measure (Hatch & (Woller, Dunford & Woodworth, 1999; Rhyne,
Frederick, 1998). A poverty-focused nongov- 1998). Constructing pro®les of clients by
ernmental organization (NGO) in Nepal or occupation, loan use, and income level is an
Malawi will be understandably reluctant to important ®rst step. The call to best practices
assume that lessons can be learned directly will only be convincing if backed by a series of
from the experience of say, the Badan Kredit well-documented examples of institution that
Desa of IndonesiaÐa series of village-based are (truly) breaking even ®nancially while
®nancial facilities that are ®nancially self-su- serving clients with pro®les very close to those
cient despite serving clients with an average served by socially-minded NGOs. BangladeshÕs
loan balance of just $38 (relative to $101 for the Association for Social Advancement (ASA)
Grameen Bank; Christen, Rhyne, Vogel & provides one promising example, as do some
McKean, 1995). The practitioners are probably programs built on the village banking model.
right. The main clients of the BKD system are But these cases need to be expanded upon and
petty traders or owners of small service enter- more carefully documented with an eye to
prises like restaurants and tailor shops, typi- crosscountry comparisons.6
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 619

Second, much could be gained by focusing transparency, and appropriate management


more sharply on the mechanisms through incentives. Although excessive subsidies were a
which ®nancial services are delivered, as well as large part of the problem, these key program
the menu of services provided. Best practices attributes can be achieved with or without full
have centered on important but general aspects ®nancial sustainability. For some programs,
of institutional performance, such as main- ongoing subsidization can be an important
taining ®nancial transparency, standardizing means through which social missions are
products, and achieving scale. A high level of achieved.
generality has been natural given the diversity If such programs lose access to government
of contexts and programs at issue. But, spurred or donor funding, they will have no option but
by win-win optimism, one result has been to close down, attempt radical cost-cutting
widespread replications of standard models innovations, or attempt to cross-subsidize. But
(especially the Grameen Bank model and it is not clear why the starting point for so
FINCAÕs village banking model) in a wide many is the belief that, as a matter of course,
diversity of economies. Many of these direct funding will be pulled away from programs,
replicates appear however to do far better in even those able to demonstrate sustained social
terms of outreach than ®nancial sustainability. e€ectiveness. Moreover, there has never been a
Instead, programs like DhakaÕs SafeSave general presumption that the most e€ective
have found that it has been necessary to go poverty alleviation programs can beÐor
back to the drawing board and create new should beÐself-®nancing. Despite early opti-
®nancial services products that can be sold at mism to the contrary, the micro®nance experi-
interest rates high enough to allow the institu- ence so far presents little to change that view.
tion to break even while maintainingÐor even The aim of this paper is not to argue for one
improvingÐoutreach.7 SafeSave has found it type of program over another. To the contrary,
necessary to depart from standard models in evidence suggests that achieving the richness of
Bangladesh and make safe and ¯exible savings programs appropriate for broad and changing
accounts, including the possibility of daily populations will require a diversity of programs
deposits, a key part of their services. In this at varying levels of outreach and ®nancial
they have drawn on lessons from informal sustainability. The aim is to help clarify
institutions in DhakaÕs slums, as well as on discussions, to examine the logic of critical
successful experiences with deposit mobiliza- arguments, and to highlight salient tensions.
tion in Indonesia (Rutherford, 1997). Bangla- The next section brie¯y reviews lessons and
deshÕs ASA has similarly departed from inferences from subsidized credit programs of
GrameenÕs model to develop a simple the 1960s and 1970s. The following section
management structure and accounting system takes apart the arguments underlying the win-
that have reduced costs substantially, making it win proposition. The ®nal section puts forward
possible to approach ®nancial sustainability an agenda for research on issues at the heart of
without imposing excessively high costs on the micro®nance schism.
clients (Rutherford, 1995). Other programs,
such as the village banks initiated by Freedom
from Hunger, have found substantial bene®ts 2. THE SUBSIDY TRAP
in bundling ®nancial services with client edu-
cation (MkNelly & Dunford, 1996 and 1998). All sides agree on the importance of avoiding
These examples show that mechanisms mistakes of the past. Earlier attempts to
clearly matter. But the power of the win-win address gaps in ®nancial markets focused on a
visionÐthat clients demand credit access at now-familiar set of problems: First, banks face
whatever the costÐhas hindered the broader high transactions costs per loan when lending
encouragement of experimentation, innovation, at small scales. Second, determining the riski-
and the exchange of experiences that can lead ness of potential borrowers and monitoring the
to (a) new ®nancial products for which the progress of clients is particularly dicult when
``core'' poor are willing and able to pay rela- clients are poor and in the informal sector.
tively high charges and (b) cheaper ways to Third, many low-income households lack assets
deliver ®nancial services to poor clients. to put up as collateral.
Third, the most important lessons to be The early programs recognized that many
learned from the failures of subsidized credit households could generate high returns if given
programs of the past are the need for eciency, credit and that, by starting small enterprises,
620 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the households could earn enough income to ciency, and limited scale necessarily go hand in
exit poverty, expand their businesses, and hand. The second is that government involve-
improve the quality of their lives. As a result, ment means trouble. The third is that e€ective
governments subsidized banksÕ loans to poor savings mobilization is incompatible with
households, providing incentives to overcome subsidized credit. As described below, none of
banksÕ reluctance to lend. Recognizing the these is ideas is fully consistent with logic or
social mission of the project, interest rates were experience. The challenge is to draw appropri-
also kept below market-clearing levels. ate lessons from both the mistakes of the past
Despite the promise, the subsidized credit and the successes of the present.
programs of the last three decades failed nearly
universally, and disaster stories are well-cata-
logued (Adams, Graham & von Pischke, 1984).
The costs of these programs mounted quickly 3. THE LOGIC OF THE WIN±WIN
and, since no way was found around the PROPOSITION
collateral problem, default rates ballooned,
with many borrowers expressing ambivalence The win±win proposition has been a power-
about defaulting on government-backed loans, ful piece of rhetoric, and it has kept many
especially when most everyone else was doing programs from repeating past disasters. But
so. Either the programs quickly ran out of if it was fully convincing, the micro®nance
money or they drained government accounts. landscape would look very di€erent from its
Moreover, because banks were losing money present stateÐwhere subsidized programs far
so steadily on the lending-side but were amply outnumber sustainable programs. Why has it
capitalized by governments, they had little not been fully convincing?
incentive to mobilize savings: deposit mobili- The win-win proposition rests on a series of
zation is costly and re-lending the deposits supporting arguments. The most important is
would just lead to greater losses. Instead, the argument that households require access to
saving accounts were weighed down with credit, not cheap credit. This is joined by eight
restrictions and downward pressure was put on principal claims. First, that raising the costs of
interest rates on deposits, generally to keep ®nancial services does not diminish demand.
interest rates paid to depositors below the rates Second, that due to their scale, ®nancially
charged to borrowers. The result was that real sustainable programs can make the greatest
rates on deposits fell to zero or below and dent in poverty. Third, that ®nancial sustain-
savers had little incentive to build up accounts. ability will give programs access to commercial
Ultimately, little saving was generated, and ®nancial markets. Fourth, that since they come
money stayed under mattresses or was moved at no cost to donors, ®nancially sustainable
into non®nancial assets. programs are superior weapons for ®ghting
Government involvement had another ne- poverty. Fifth, that subsidized programs are
gative consequence. Loans often ended up inecient and thus bound to fail. Sixth, that
subsidizing well-o€, politically-connected entre- subsidized credit most often ends up in the
preneurs rather than poor households, and few hands of the nonpoor. Seventh, that successful
mechanisms were in place to stem the leakages. micro®nance programs must be nongovern-
The ultimate result was high costs and little ment programs. And, eighth, that subsidizing
bene®t for the intended bene®ciaries. credit undermines savings mobilization.
The new programs have set out to avoid Not all of those who believe in the impor-
these traps. Foremost, they have seen the tance of ®nancial sustainability will accept each
importance of maintaining high repayment claim. But the claims are often heard together,
rates. By employing contractual innovations and they form a core set of ideas. Each is
like group-lending and by exploiting dynamic rooted in the experience of some programs in
incentives, many programs have achieved some places and at some times. But as general
repayment rates above 95% (Christen et al., propositions they each rest on problematic
1995; MicroBanking Bulletin, 1998). They have logical extrapolations, inappropriate assump-
also kept an armÕs length from government tions, or misreadings of evidence. In taking
involvement, and most programs are run by them apart, my objective is not to push for
NGOs. subsidized credit at all costs. Rather, it is to
The successes have bred false generalizations, illustrate the ``disconnect''Ði.e., why these
however. The ®rst is that subsidization, ine- arguments have not translated into action.
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 621

(a) Interest-insensitive credit demand tions that appear to be served well by


moderately-subsidized micro®nance programs
Claim: Raising interest rates does not versus other economic development initiatives.
substantially diminish demand for loans. Programs inevitably point to anecdotal evi-
In Las Vegas, pawnshop owners charge dence to support their claims, but even without
borrowers e€ective annual interest rates of harder data, it is clear that considering only
120%, while in the gambling town of Biloxi, aggregate demand is inadequate for programs
Mississippi, typical rates are 300% per year seeking to maximize social welfare.
(New York Times, December 13, 1997). The argument is allied to another logical
Demand remains high in both settings. But no stretch. The assertion above implicitly invokes
one would argue that the typical small entre- the principle of declining marginal returns to
preneur in the United States can repay loans at capital as a defense of charging high interest
those rates. This, though, is the sort of argu- rates to poor clients while charging lower rates
ment that is commonly made in the micro®- to richer clients.8 The idea is that there are a
nance contextÐthat since moneylenders charge limited number of great projects in which to
high interest rates, micro®nance programs can invest. The ®rst units of capital go to the best
too. But while poor households in low-income projects and subsequent units go to projects
countries may borrow from moneylenders at with increasingly lower returns. The principle is
rates above 100% per year, they are generally generally right, but its application is wrong.
doing so to meet short-term consumption The basic principle applies to a single ®rm,
needs, not to make long-term productive holding all else ®xed. It does not necessarily
investments. hold across ®rms (or across household
Moreover, the distinction between which microenterprises) as in the application here.
poor households are served by micro®nance Producing and selling goods requires more than
programs is obscured by observations that capital. It requires skills, other materials,
®nancially sustainable programs reach some information, connections, transportation, etc.
poor households. For example, it is asserted in Since richer households tend to have more of
CGAP (1996; prepared by Richard Rosenberg): these inputs, marginal returns to capital are
often far higher for them than for poorer
CAN microborrowers pay high interest rates? households. These richer households will thus
¼ [Micro®nance institutions] charging very high be willing to pay far higher interest rates than
interest rates almost always ®nd that demand far out- poorer households. (In fact, the basic principle
strips their ability to supply it. Most of their customers is unclear even when controlling for other
repay their loans, and return repeatedly for new loans: inputs, since scale economies alone can yield
this pattern demonstrates the customersÕ conviction
that the loans allow them to earn more than the inter- higher marginal returns to later increments of
est they have to pay. ¼ Thus, there is abundant proof capital than earlier increments.)
that poor peopleÕs tiny businesses can often pay inter- The ability to pay high interest rates is thus
est rates that would strangle a larger business. Still, an empirical issue, dependent on the amount of
this proposition strikes many as counterintuitive. capital being used, as well as the amount of all
other inputs available. It cannot be inferred
The argument above makes the point that there that because one group of poor households can
are poor households that are able to pay high pay high rates then even poorer households can
rates. The concern of many subsidized pay those interest rates as well. Moreover,
programs, however, is that there are also many sensitivity to the costs of ®nancial services is
borrowers who cannot pay high rates. (This has not likely to be common across economies. For
been a particular concern in South Asia.) These example, practitioners argue that sensitivity
latter households tend to be poorer and harder tends to be much greater in South Asia than in
to reach with traditional programs, and they Latin America. But careful studies have yet to
constitute a large fraction of client bases. They demonstrate this in either context.
are not the petty traders that can repay at rates
above 50% per year. If these programs raised
interest rates, they might not su€er for lack of (b) Advantages of scale
demand either. But that is not the point. The
programs fear losing much of their current Claim: Financially-sustainable programs can
client base, including the particularly vulnera- achieve greater scale than subsidized programs.
ble and underserved segments of poor popula- Thus, they can make a bigger dent in poverty.
622 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

The diversity within poor households is sustainable program has 75,000 clients (roughly
similarly obscured by common arguments on the size of BoliviaÕs BancoSol). How large
the advantages of achieving a broad scale of would the subsidized program need to be to
operations. Again, the argument is put well in have an equivalent impact (under the assump-
CGAP (1996): tions above)? When measuring poverty with the
Watts measure, the subsidized program would
Some people treat [the question of how high to set need to reach at least 42,000 clients. When
interest rates] as if it comes down to a value judge- measuring poverty with the squared poverty
ment: which do you care more about±poor people or gap, the subsidized program would need to
pro®ts (¼ or ®nancial system ¼ or neoliberal ideol- reach 15,000 clients. It would also need to serve
ogy). To avoid any such confusion, letÕs assume that just 3,000 clients as measured by the cubed
the only objective we care about is maximizing bene®t
to poor people. From this perspective, the argument
poverty gap.
for high interest rates is straightforward. In most The exact comparison is a matter of value
countries, donor funding is a limited quantity that will judgementÐwhich poverty measure best
never be capable of reaching more than a tiny fraction captures the social value of poverty reduction?
of those poor households who could bene®t from The initial claim above makes sense only under
quality ®nancial services. speci®c assumptions about objective functions,
relative outreach, and the elasticity of credit
The argument has greatest power if concern demand with respect to interest rates. Under
with poverty rests exclusively with minimizing plausible assumptions, the claim could hold,
the number of people below the poverty line but it is not a general proposition. Well-tar-
(making no distinction between groups within geted programs can often do more for poverty
the working poor population). But it loses reduction than much larger programs reaching
power if we also consider the distribution of mainly better-o€ households.
income below the poverty lineÐand this makes
value judgements paramount. Value judge- (c) Access to commercial ®nance
ments cannot be so easily swept away.
Consider tradeo€s in scale and outreach Claim: Financial sustainability is critical for
when the objective is to minimize a poverty institutions as it is the route to being able to
measure that is sensitive to the distribution of access capital from commercial ®nancial markets
incomes below the poverty line. Since clients in rather than donors.
subsidized credit programs tend to be much The argument in CGAP (1996) continues:
poorer than those in sustainable programs, for
illustration assume that the typical client in a We can hope to reach most of those households only if
subsidized program has an income of, say, 50% [micro®nance institutions] can mobilize relatively
of the poverty line, while the typical client of a large amounts of commercial ®nance at market rates.
sustainable (high interest rate) program has an They cannot do this unless they charge interest rates
income of 90% of the poverty line. To focus the that cover [total costs].
comparison, assume that borrowers receive
identical net returns (after repaying loans with This claim also requires re-examination. This
interest).9 step in the argument goes beyond the unteth-
One metric of social welfare is the poverty ering from donor strings. The vision described
rate as measured by a distributionally-sensitive is one in which the equity of programs is
index like the Watts measure or ``average exit multiplied through access to commercial
time'' of Morduch (1998). By this measure, ®nanceÐi.e., the creation of leverage. The
raising the poorer borrowerÕs income by one vision opens up exciting prospects, but as
dollar has 1.8 times greater impact than doing Conning (1999) argues, they are not likely to be
the same for the less poor borrower. The same shared as amply by programs focused on
calculation for the commonly-used ``squared poorer householdsÐeven if the programs
poverty gap'' of Foster, Greer and Thorbecke charge ``market rates.''
(1984) gives a ratio of 5 to 1. The ``cubed The scenario parallels that of a poor
poverty gap'' yields a ratio of 25 to 1. borrower unable to obtain loans from formal
The numbers can be put in perspective by sector banks for lack of collateral (e.g.,
comparing the required scale of subsidized and Banerjee & Newman, 1994). The story is well-
sustainable programs that would have equiva- known: banks are reluctant to lend because it is
lent impacts on measured poverty. Say that the dicult to identify the truly reliable borrowers,
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 623

to then monitor borrowersÕ behaviors, and, if just one interest rate policy and one sort of
needed, to implement e€ective punishments. program in an area. Sustainable programs may
Combating this phenomenon has been the have advantages in achieving scale. Subsidized
driving impetus for the micro®nance move- programs appear to have advantages in
ment. outreach. Just as all diners are not forced to
The same kinds of diculties emerge when drink the same beverages, general social welfare
the micro®nance program itself seeks commer- perspectives suggest that it can make sense to
cial funds, since it lacks collateral to back its support multiple programs within the same
portfolio. As the borrowers found, merely region, some focusing on scale and others on
being able to generate positive expected returns outreach.
is not enough to secure commercial credit.
Thus, even ®nancially sustainable banks will
not necessarily be able to gain sucient access (e) Subsidies reduce eciency
to wider capital markets. As Conning argues,
banks focused on poor borrowers are likely to Claim: Subsidized credit programs are ine-
face the greatest diculties in creating leverage cient and ultimately bound to fail.
since their portfolios are likely to appear that A much sharper criticism of subsidized credit
much riskier to capital suppliers. Relying on programs is that they cannot survive over the
commercial ®nance can thus lead to further long term. Nancy Barry of WomenÕs World
reductions in the depth of outreach. Banking (CGAP, 1995) asserts, for example,
As a point of economic logic, of course, it is that ``few low income entrepreneurs end up
not incompatible to both subsidize interest bene®ting from subsidized programs, because
rates charged to clients and to obtain these programs fail before they reach signi®cant
commercial ®nance. The Grameen Bank, for numbers.'' She argues further that ``microen-
example, has sold bonds (guaranteed by the terprise ®nancial intermediaries have learned
government) while not passing all costs on to that they cannot depend on governments and
clients. While there is debate about whether the donors as reliable, long-term sources of subsi-
price of the bonds is at market rates, the prin- dized funding.''
ciple remains that subsidization does not rule BarryÕs assertion evokes the lessons of past
out tapping commercial ®nance for partial failures. But micro®nance advocates have
funding. The chief constraint is not subsidiza- argued strenuously that the new programs are
tion per se but the ability to limit perceived radically di€erent from those of the past.
riskiness. Subsidized programs like the Grameen Bank
and Bangladesh Rural Advancement Commit-
(d) Irrelevance of cost-bene®t comparisons tee together, for example, have together
reached around four million borrowers and
Claim: Since sustainable programs do not face substantial competition from other groups
require outside funding, consideration of costs like the Association for Social Advancement
and bene®ts is irrelevant. There are no costs and Proshika. BarryÕs ®rst assertion is hard to
borne by governments or aid agenciesÐthere are reconcile with the experience in Bangladesh to
only bene®ts. Sustainable programs are thus date.
superior to subsidized programs. The second issue is whether subsidized
The idea of cost-free poverty alleviation is funding will dry up. Since donors and govern-
appealing, but consider this simple analogy. ments remain committed to poverty alleviation
When diners go to a restaurant, they have the as a top priority, advocates are not unreason-
option of drinking water or purchasing a able in arguing for allocating some poverty-al-
beverage. The water is free and adequate, but leviation funds to support innovative and
most diners also buy wine, beer, or soft drinks e€ective micro®nance programs over the long-
to complement their meal. To them, the zero- term. How this will play out exactly is a matter
cost option is not always the one that leads to of speculation, but there is no reason to think
the greatest satisfaction, and the same logic that concern with poverty alleviation will
holds here. When funding is available, subsi- quickly whither. Nor is there reason to think
dizing credit beats the zero-cost option as long that support for subsidized micro®nance
as bene®ts outweigh costs. programs will whitherÐas long as they remain
A problem with the ``best practices'' vigilant in containing costs and maximizing
approach is that it proceeds as if there has to be outreach.
624 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

A third issue is whether subsidized programs A common experience in the credit programs
can be ecient. Barry (CGAP, 1996), for of the 1960s and 1970s was that subsidized
example, argues that ``ecient ®nancial inter- credit was often diverted away from poor
mediaries need to charge high rates to cover the households. Since the subsidies were valuable,
costs of making small loans.'' politically powerful groups, usually not poor,
Typically, judging institutional performance muscled their way in and managed to grab a
by pro®tability gives managers the right share. The problem was compounded by the
incentives. But appropriate incentives can also fact that most programs were government-run,
be provided in nonpro®t enterprises. Main- providing further incentives for misfeasance as
taining ``hard'' budget constraints is the key, the granting of loans was often partly a politi-
not maximizing pro®ts. The two mechanisms cal payo€ (this is discussed further below).
are often confused, but it is the former that is These problems are fully avoided when
critical for eciency, not the latter. If budget subsidies are eliminated. But the problems may
constraints are soft and performance criteria also be greatly reduced by just partial elimina-
are not carefully speci®ed, managers can expect tion of subsidies. The concern with targeting
to be bailed out after poor performances. If introduces a ¯oor to interest ratesÐit does not
constraints are kept hard and performance mean that interest rates need be at break-even
criteria are made clear, managers must cope rates. The ¯oor is determined by the rates at
with failures, and eciency can be maintained, which others (the politically powerful, say) can
even in nonpro®t programs. get loans.
One important mechanism for achieving Consider a program lending exclusively to
eciency in subsidized programs is to use poor borrowers. It would have to charge, say,
socially-determined transfer prices and to be 30% per year in order to break even. In
rigid in evaluating performance according to contrast, a formal sector program aimed at
those prices. Transfer prices are the internal richer borrowers could break even when
prices used by institutions to value capital and charging, say, 15% per year since it can more
determine relative performance at branch easily take advantage of returns to scale. Loans
levels. In a pro®t-making enterprise, the trans- at 5% per year will seem appealing to all
fer prices re¯ect the full value of capital, a households when the alternative, formal sector
system used very e€ectively by the Bank sources charge 15%. Nearly without fail, such
Rakyat IndonesiaÕs unit desa program. In a absolutely cheap credit has led to subsidy traps.
subsidized program, they are shadow prices, Loans around 20% will seem however much
adjusted downward so that prices re¯ect the less appealing to the richer households. Rates
social gains delivered by lending. The transfer around 20% provide meaningful subsidies for
prices can be used to calculate shadow pro®ts. poor households, and are not seen as gifts. The
Thus, while bank managers may not be able to loans are cheap relative to full costs, but they
lend at an actual pro®t, they may be able to are not absolutely cheap. Mistargeting has thus
lend at a net social gain, and eciency can be not been a major concern for those programs
achieved by tying their compensation to providing moderate-sized subsidies. The lesson
performance on the basis of transfer prices and from the failures of the 1960s and 1970s is to
shadow pro®ts. avoid excessive subsidies. The lesson is not to
Translating the theory into practice takes avoid subsidies altogether. Discussions of
creativity and experimentation, but the basic interest rates in micro®nance programs often
idea can be implemented with simple rules of equate subsidized credit with cheap credit, and
thumb. This is not an academic dream: most this has created considerable confusion. Abso-
universities and many hospitals run on a not- lutely cheap credit is typically the problem.
for-pro®t basis with purely social objectives. Relatively cheap credit can, in principle, work.
Managers of not-for-pro®t micro®nance insti-
tutions can learn from their weaknesses and (g) Minimal role of government
build on their successes.
Claim: Micro®nance has been and should
continue to be a movement with minimal govern-
(f) Subsidies lead to mistargeting ment involvement.
Governments in low-income countries have
Claim: Subsidized credit most often ends up in played very little direct role in the micro®nance
the hands of nonpoor households. movement, and this has been no accident. The
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 625

movement is fundamentally an NGO move- number of reasons (Robinson, 1995). First, it


ment, free of many of the political biases of can provide a relatively inexpensive source of
earlier subsidized programs. This creates its capital for re-lending. Second, todayÕs deposi-
own problems, of course. There are good and tors may be tomorrowÕs borrowers, creating a
bad NGOs and often little apparatus for e€ec- natural client pool. Third, savings deposits o€er
tive oversight, but so far the micro®nance track important advantages to low-income house-
record has allayed most fears. holds, allowing low-income households to build
Governments, though, have played critical up assets to use as collateral, to reduce
indirect roles. The Bank Rakyat Indonesia and consumption volatility over time, and to self-
ThailandÕs Bank of Agriculture and Agricul- ®nance investments rather than always turning
tural Cooperatives, for example, are state- to creditors (Wright, Hossain & Rutherford,
owned although run as standard commercial 1997).
banks. The Grameen Bank, which sometimes Thus, a savings program may be an essential
®nds itself at odds with Bangladeshi politicians, feature of both subsidized and sustainable
nonetheless has obtained loans at concessional programs. It has been sustainable programs
rates from the Bangladesh Bank (and began as however, that have been most aggressive in
a special project of the Bangladesh Bank).10 mobilizing savings, partly because mobilization
The spread of micro®nance in China will also can greatly aid the ®nancial bottom line.
of necessity proceed with heavy government Subsidized programs have tended to focus on
involvement, at least in the near term ``forced saving'' programs, forcing borrowers
(Morduch, Park, & Wang, 1997). to put aside a ®xed percentage of borrowed
While sustainable programs can a€ord to money to draw upon in case repayment di-
eschew government involvement, subsidized culties arise, rather than mobilizing voluntary
programs cannot. Subsidized programs need savings.
NGOs, foundations, international donors, or Maintaining savings deposits can be expen-
their own governments for funding. If subsi- sive for programs, and when programs are
dized programs are to continue at current losing money in their lending operations, they
funding levels, they will likely need to rely have little incentive to mobilize deposits if
increasingly on their own governments. Rather capital can be obtained more cheaply from
than backing away from governments, subsi- donors. This was part of the subsidy trap
dized programs will need to build constructive described above. If, however, programs can
relationships. Lessons from past failures generate capital from depositors more cheaply
suggest that this will require a clear under- than donors can generate capital, it can be in all
standing of the (sharp) limits to direct govern- partiesÕ interests to encourage programs to
ment involvement and a commitment to the mobilize savings. One way to do so is to split
transparency and accountability of programs. the di€erence between programsÕ costs of
generating capital and donorsÕ costs of obtain-
(h) Subsidies limit savings mobilization ing capital. For every dollar that programs
mobilize, donors can then reduce their loans to
Claim: Mobilizing savings is not likely to the programs by one dollar. The arrangement
make sense for subsidized credit programs. can reduce costs for both donors and programs
Household welfare can be greatly improved and at the same time encourage savings mobi-
through the chance to mobilize savings. Early lization.
micro®nance programs were not e€ective in For example, the Grameen Bank obtained
mobilizing savings and showed little interest in funds from the Bangladesh Bank at just 5±6%
doing so. Partly, it was thought that poor in the mid-1990s while alternative sources of
households were too poor to save. One of the funds would have cost 12±15%. If Grameen
lessons from the recent micro®nance experi- could have mobilized savings at a cost below
ence, however, is that, even poor households the Bangladesh Bank's opportunity cost of
are eager to save if given appealing interest funds, the social cost of subsidization could
rates and/or ¯exible accounts. The Bank have been reduced. Under early, failed credit
Rakyat Indonesia, for example counted over 16 schemes, everyone lost out through savings
million low-income depositors by the end of mobilization. Under the proposed scheme,
1996. however, everyone can bene®t.
Incorporating savings mobilization in Practical constraints to savings mobilization
micro®nance programs makes sense for a must be worked out, though. The most
626 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

important constraint is that NGOs are not The role of competition is an additional issue
chartered to hold savings deposits. Prudence of growing importance. Practitioners need to
dictates that only tightly-regulated institutions know much more about problems that arise
are given the privilege and responsibility of when multiple programsÐsome subsidized,
holding savings. This thus creates a problem for some notÐcoexist. Here, the issue is a supply
micro®nance programs (except those that are elasticity: how sensitive is the performance of
fully chartered banks). One answer is that fully- ®nancially sustainable programs to the pres-
chartered savings banks could operate inde- ence of targeted, subsidized programs?
pendently but alongside NGOs engaged in Another set of questions surrounds the
lending. A contractual link to exploit the rebate functioning of speci®c program features. All
opportunity above could still be used to reduce types of programs may be able to learn from
costs of subsidization on the lending side. studies that explore the e€ectiveness and cost-
Both the rebate proposal and the savings liness of various lending mechanismsÐfor
bank/microcredit partnership proposal are example, weekly versus bi-weekly versus
straightforward in principle but require careful, monthly payment schedules, lending to indi-
transparent contracts to work well. The ideas viduals versus lending to groups, intensive
are speculative but suggest that there may be versus minimal group-lending operations, and
creative ways around roadblocks. increasing loan size quickly or slowly with
successful repayment. Systematic experimenta-
tion and evaluation with household-level data
can be critical along these lines.
4. THE CHALLENGE AHEAD: A
RESEARCH AGENDA
5. CONCLUSIONS
The arguments above suggest holes in the
win-win logic that help to explain why ``best The optimism of the win-win vision has
practices'' have not been adopted more widely. generated much energy for the micro®nance
But subsidization raises its own tensions, movement, and it has helped to discourage
particularly surrounding issues of governance. repetitions of the costly mistakes of the past.
Among the key questions are: Can new product But the past decade shows that it has also
development and program design suciently discouraged constructive dialogues and the
improve ®nancial performance without sorts of serious empirical studies that can help
compromising outreach such that subsidies are to resolve continuing debates. As a result, the
not needed? If not, are the costs of subsidies empirical agenda remains wide open and the
typically justi®ed by the social bene®ts of schism persists, fueled by competing anec-
programs? Can innovations be implemented to dotes.
help subsidized programs maintain eciency The micro®nance movement encompasses
and e€ective targeting? Which groups among diverse programs, all of which focus on
the poor are best served by which types of providing ®nancial services to poor households.
programs? Can social bene®ts be easily and Some programs have made ®nancial sustain-
reliably measured on an ongoing basis? Can ability the chief goal, and others have centered
funding be sustained over the long run?11 on economic and social impacts. While there is
The socially-oriented programs should have much common ground, there are also critical
careful economic and social evaluations at the di€erences. There appears to be ample room,
top of their research list. The Grameen Bank however, for a diversity of programs, with
and BRAC have been pioneers in this area, competing methods and ®nancial arrange-
with a large, comprehensive survey completed ments.
in 1991±92 and a follow-up survey underway. Addressing the schism opens up the chance
The key to this survey has been use of a sample to address misconceptions. It is not pro®t
frame that incorporates strati®ed randomiza- maximization that makes a program ecient.
tion and the collection of data on both partic- Instead, what matters is having a hard budget
ipants and nonparticipants, including random constraint, something possible even with
samples from villages not served by any subsidies. Nor is it so that subsidization
program.12 The survey, though, has been necessarily leads to mistargeting. Fear of
expensive, and devising ways to complete mistargeting may limit the size of the optimal
cheap, ongoing surveys is the next step. subsidy, but it does not necessarily make it
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 627

zero. Nor is it so that savings mobilization is Perhaps more problematically, those interested
necessarily held down by charging interest rates in replicating the well-known success stories
on loans that are below levels needed to break have only had partial and unreliable evalua-
even. Moreover, as Conning (1999) has argued, tions on which to base their plans.
the need to preserve management incentives The arguments above stand in opposition to
means that even ®nancially sustainable, social- ``lessons'' of failed programs of the past. And
ly-minded programs will likely have ongoing the arguments suggest that there is much yet to
diculties raising substantial amounts of capi- learn.
tal on the open market. As Hulme and Mosley (1996, p. 135)
While these arguments run counter to hard- conclude,
line positions on ®nancial sustainability, open-
ing up the discussion may also help foster Ironically, it is the success of the ``®rst wave'' ®nance-
continued e€orts to develop new ®nancial for-the-poor schemes, and particularly the Grameen
products that ultimately are ®nancially Bank, that is the greatest obstacle to future experi-
sustainable. Addressing the schism may also mentation. Most designers and sponsors of new initia-
mitigate the emerging backlash against the tives have abandoned innovation, and ``replication'' is
micro®nance movement. The insistence on the leading to a growing uniformity in ®nancial interven-
tions.
win-win proposition has alienated many
potential supporters. Those willing to trade o€
costs for bene®ts have become frustrated as This paper has mapped avenues to pursue in
micro®nance institutions stretch accounting rethinking micro®nance to date and in
data in order to claim pro®tability while constructing foundations for a next wave of
simultaneously eschewing social evaluations. micro®nance innovation.

NOTES

1. See, for example, Brugger and Rajapatirana (1995), speculations concerned NGO programs only, excluding,
Hulme and Mosley (1996), Otero and Rhyne (1994) and for example, credit unions, the Indonesian BKDs, or
Morduch (1999) for broader discussions of micro®nance private banks that are serving poor clients. Even if
programs. experience shows the correct number to be 10%Ðor 15%
or 25%Ðthere remains a fundamental ``disconnect''
between rhetoric and action. In the end, the most
2. The relevant groups are those whose clients main-
important measure concerns the number of clients
tain average loan balances under $150 or loans as a
served, not the numbers of particular types of programs.
percentage of GNP per capita under 20%; they include,
for example, village banks such as FINCA programs
and exclude programs like BancoSol and the Bank 4. Information is from the unpublished notes of Don
Rakyat Indonesia unit desa system. The ®gures are after Johnston. His calculation shows average BKD loan sizes
adjustments to account for subsidies on capital costs, the to be $71 at the end of 1994, still well below the
erosion of the value of equity due to in¯ation, and Grameen Bank level.
adequate provisioning for non-recoverable loans. As
best possible, the ®gures are comparable to data for
5. A growing list of examples demonstrates the ability
standard commercial enterprises. The included
to serve these richer households without ongoing subsi-
programs all have a ``commitment'' to achieving ®nan-
dies, and their experiences hold important lessons for
cial sustainability and voluntarily submitted the ®nancial
programs with poorer target clients. But, as docu-
information, so they are already a self-selected group.
mented in a recent study of BancoSol, typical clients are
Some of the programs are young and their ®nancial
among the ``richest of the poor'' and the nonpoor (where
performance will likely improve over time.
poverty is based on access to a set of basic needs like
shelter and education; Navajas, Schreiner, Meyer,
3. This speculation has been widely cited, and Richard Gonzalez-Vega & Rodriguez-Meza, 1998). Average loan
Rosenberg reports that its origin is a micro®nance panel balances for BancoSol and BRI are around $500, while
discussion at Boulder, Colorado. The consensus among they are around just $100 for well-known poverty-
a group of (sustainability-minded) panelists was that 1% focused programs in Bangladesh like the Grameen Bank,
or fewer of programs were presently sustainable and that Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC),
no more than 5% would ever be. These rough and Association for Social Advancement (ASA).
628 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

6. Apart from the Indonesian BKDs (caveats aside), 9. Hulme and Mosley (1996) suggest that impacts may
no programs that I know have achieved demonstrably be greater for less poor households. This provides
outstanding outreach while achieving clear ®nancial additional support for sustainable programs in the
sustainability, but some like ASA appear to be doing calculation.
remarkably well on both fronts (Rutherford, 1995).
MexicoÕs Compartamos and El SalvadorÕs Financiera
10. While Grameen no longer receives concessional
Calpia also deliver impressive ®nancial performance
loans from the Bangladesh Bank, they do receive
while serving poor (but not close to the poorest) rural
guarantees from the government for the bonds that they
clients. In urban Bolivia, both BancoSol and Caja los
now rely upon for the majority of their funding.
Andes serve a broad range of clients, including a
minority that are among the ``core'' poor (Navajas et
al., 1998). IndonesiaÕs BRI provides savings facilities to 11. A related series of questions has been raised by van
many relatively poor clients, although they are excluded de Walle (1997), and Morduch (1999) provides a more
from borrowing for lack of collateral. comprehensive discussion of the empirical research
agenda and cost-bene®t studies.
7. At present SafeSave is covering operating costs but
is not fully ®nancially sustainable. It has only been
operating since August 1996 and trends appear prom- 12. See also MkNellyÕs and DunfordÕs (1998) work in
ising (SafeSave, 1998). Ghana. The argument about whether ®nancially sustain-
able or subsidized programs have the greatest impact on
8. The idea is related to Hulme and MosleyÕs (1996) poverty comes down to a question about the elasticity of
idea to charge ``tapered'' interest rates that fall with loan demand for ®nancial services with respect to their costs.
sizeÐalthough the proposition would appear to con¯ict This elasticity (and social impacts more broadly) can
with their evidence that poorer households do not in only be estimated with information on both participants
general receive higher returns than richer households. and non-participants.

REFERENCES

Adams, D., Graham, D., & von Pischke, J. D. (1984). Wieland, & J. D. von Pischke (Eds.), Strategic Issues
Undermining rural development with cheap credit. in Micro®nance. Aldershott, UK: Ashgate Publishing.
Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Hatch, J., & Frederick, L. (1998). Poverty assessment by
Banerjee, A., & Newman, A. (1994). Poverty, incentives micro®nance institutions: a review of current practice.
and development. American Economic Review (AEA Microenterprise Best Practices Report, Development
Papers and Proceedings), 84 (2), 211±215. Alternatives, Inc., Washington, DC.
Brugger, E., & Rajapatirana, S. (1995). New perspectives Hulme, D., & Mosley, P. (1996). Finance against poverty.
on ®nancing small business in developing countries. London: Routledge.
San Francisco: ICS Press. MkNelly, B., & Dunford, C. (1996). Are credit services
Christen, R., Rhyne, E., Vogel, R., & McKean, C. e€ective against hunger and malnutrition? ± a liter-
(1995). Maximizing the outreach of microenterprise ature review and analysis. Freedom From Hunger
®nance: an analysis of successful programs, program Research Paper No. 1, Davis, CA.
and operations. Assessment Report No. 10, United MkNelly, B., & Dunford, C. (1998). Impact of credit
States Agency for International Development, Wash- with education on mothers and their young chil-
ington, DC. drenÕs nutrition: Lower Pra Rural bank credit with
Conning, Jonathan (1999). Outreach, sustainability and education program in Ghana. Freedom From
leverage in microlending: a contract design ap- Hunger Research Paper No. 4, Davis, CA.
proach. Journal of Development Economics, 60 (1), Morduch, J. (1998). Poverty, growth, and average exit
October. time. Economics Letters, 59, 385±390.
Consultative Group for Assistance to the Poorest Morduch, J. (1999). The micro®nance promise. Journal
(CGAP). (1995). The missing links: ®nancial systems of Economic Literature, 37 (4).
that work for the majority. CGAP Focus, No. 3, Morduch, J., Park, A., & Wang, S. (1997). Micro®nance
October. in China. Poverty and Development. Beijing.
Consultative Group for Assistance to the Poorest Navajas, S., Schreiner, M., Meyer, R., Gonzalez-Vega,
(CGAP), (1996). Microcredit interest rates. CGAP C., & Rodriguez-Meza, J. (1998). Microcredit and the
Occasional Paper, No. 1, August. poorest of the poor: theory and evidence from Bolivia.
Foster, J., Greer, J., & Thorbecke, E. (1984). A class of Department of Agricultural, Environmental, and
decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica, 52 Development Economics, Ohio State University,
(3), 761±766. Columbus, OH.
Gonzalez-Vega, C. (1998). Do ®nancial institutions have New York Times (1997). In Gulf casinosÕ wake, a
a role in assisting the poor? In M. Kimenyi, R. pawnshop boom. December 13, A1, A13.
THE MICROFINANCE SCHISM 629

Otero, M., & Rhyne, E. (1994). The New World of needs credit? Poverty and ®nance in Bangladesh.
Microenterprise Finance. West Hartford, CT: Dhaka: University Press.
Kumarian Press. SafeSave, (1998). 30 September 1998 Update, Dhaka.
Rhyne, E. (1998). The yin and yang of micro®nance: van de Walle, D. (1997). Comment on rural ®nance in
reaching the poor and sustainability. MicroBanking Africa: institutional developments and access for the
Bulletin. poor by Ernest Aryeetey. In Annual World Bank
Robinson, M. (1995). Indonesia: The role of savings in Conference on Development Economics 1996 (pp. 52±
developing sustainable Commercial ®nancing of small 56). Washington, DC: World Bank.
and micro enterprises. In E. Brugger, & S. Rajapatir- Woller, G., Dunford, C., & Woodworth, W. (1999)
ana (Eds.), New perspectives on ®nancing small busi- Where to micro®nance? International Journal of
ness in developing countries. San Francisco: ICS Press. Economic Development.
Robert, C., & Jennifer, M. D. (1998). MicroBanking Wright, G., Hossain, M., & Rutherford, S. (1997).
Bulletin. Boulder CO: Economics Institute. Savings: Flexible ®nancial services for the poor. In
Rutherford, S. (1995). ASA: the biography of an NGO. G. Wood, & I. Sharif (Eds.), Who needs credit?
Dhaka: Association for Social Advancement. Poverty and ®nance in Bangladesh. Dhaka: University
Rutherford, S. (1997). Informal ®nancial services in Press Limited.
DhakaÕs slums. In G. Wood, & I. Sharif (Eds.), Who

You might also like