You are on page 1of 6

Applied Economics Letters, 2013, 20, 452–456

J-curve disparity between the goods


sector and the services sector:
evidence from Australia
Albert Wijeweeraa,* and Brian Dolleryb
a
Business School, Southern Cross University, Tweed Heads, NSW, Australia
b
UNE Business School, University of New England, Armidale, NSW,
Australia

The J-curve effect phenomenon suggests that the currency devaluation


would worsen the trade balance in the short run, but improve it in the
long run. This article uses quarterly Australian data over the period 1988
to 2011 to examine whether J-curve effects are different between the two
main components of the trade account: the goods sector and the services
sector. Using the bound testing approach to cointegration and error
correction modelling, we find some evidence to support the J-curve
phenomenon, but the impact of real exchange rate on the trade account
seems complex. While the services sector displays a J-curve effect, the goods
sector response is quite the opposite: it has a positive response in the short
run, but a weak negative response in the long run.
Keywords: J-curve; bound testing approach; trade account; Australia

JEL Classification: F31

I. Introduction II. The Analysis of the J-Curve Phenomenon

This article explores whether the J-curve effect varies In a seminal article, Magee (1973) suggested that,
between the services sector and the goods sector in following devaluation, the trade balance will keep
Australia. While many empirical studies have examined deteriorating in the short run, but will improve in the
this phenomenon, to our knowledge, no published arti- long run. He described this phenomenon as the J-
cle has examined whether the J-curve effect is different curve effect. Magee attributed this behaviour to
between the two main components of the trade account: many factors, such as adjustment lags in currency
the goods sector and the services sector. One would contracts, periods of pass through and sluggish quan-
expect a stronger J-curve effect from the services sector
tity adjustments. This line of thought prompted many
compared with the goods sector, because the services
researchers to empirically examine the J-curve effect
sector contraction in areas such as education, shipping,
for various countries with mixed results. Details of
insurance and the like may be more rigid and has longer
lag effects relative to the goods sector. As illustrated in these studies and their specific findings have
Fig. 1, the goods sector and the services sector appear to been omitted in this article because of space limita-
follow different paths to each other for most of the time. tions. Interested readers are referred to an excellent
This anomaly is worthy of investigation. While there Applied Economics article ‘The J-curve: A Literature
are some studies that have used disaggregated trade Review’ by Bahmani-Oskooee and Ratha (2004).
data, they have mostly disaggregated data into trading Several studies have also employed Australian data
partners and not into trade account components per se. to examine the J-curve phenomenon (see, e.g. Arndt
*Corresponding author. E-mail: albert.wijeweera@scu.edu.au

452 Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350–4851 print/ISSN 1466–4291 online # 2013 Taylor & Francis
http://www.tandfonline.com
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2012.707765
J-curve disparity between the goods sector and the services sector 453
1.2 where  refers to the first difference of each respective
variable and ut is the disturbance term. Equation 2 is an
1.1
error correction model. However, instead of using an
Export to import ratio

1.0 error correction term, the linear combination of lagged


variables has been included in the equation. We use
0.9
three lag periods in each and note that the chosen lag
0.8 length is sufficient to approximate the data-generating
TBG process using the Akaike Information Criterion.
TBS
0.7

0.6
1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
IV. Results
Year
We estimated Equation 2 for two major components of
Fig. 1. Australian time trend for goods and services sectors: the trade account. Model 1 is for the goods sector
1988–2011 balance and the Model 2 is for the services sector
Note: TBG, trade balance in the goods sector; TBS, trade balance. The results for the goods sector and the
balance in the services sector.
services sector are shown in Tables 1 and 2, respec-
tively. We have highlighted the results for the exchange
and Dorrance, 1987; Flemingham, 1988; Bahmani- rate variable and the long-run relationships. As the
Oskooee and Wang, 2006). results show, two of the short-run coefficients obtained
for log(RER) are significant at the 10% critical value.
III. Model This suggests that there is statistical evidence to sup-
port the proposition that depreciation of the Australian
The theoretical framework for dealing with the dollar has short-run effects on the goods sector balance
J-curve effect derives largely from Rose and Yellen of the trade account. However, the finding of a short-
(1989). In this article, we follow the empirical model run effect does not necessarily support the existence of
used by Bahmani-Oskooee and Wang (2006). The the J-curve because we do not have statistical support
relationship between the trade balance and its deter- for a significant long-run relationship between the
minants is given by the following equation: goods sector balance and the real exchange rate. As
the results show, the long-run coefficient is statistically
logðTBt Þ ¼ a þ b log YAUS;t þ  log YROW;t insignificant at conventional levels.
þ l log RERt þ et ð1Þ As far as the other coefficients are concerned, the
relationship between the goods sector trade balance
where TBt is the ratio of Australia’s nominal exports and the Australian income is negative. This is what we
to its nominal imports, YAUS,t is the Australian Gross expected because as Australian income rises, imports
Domestic Product (GDP), YROW,t is rest of the world will increase, which in turn worsens the goods sector
income and RERt is the real bilateral exchange rate trade balance. It is interesting to note that the rest of
between the Australian dollar and the US dollar. We the world income does not seem to be a significant
use quarterly data from Q1-1988 to Q2-2011 to esti- variable, although it has the anticipated sign. This
mate the model. Data for these variables were could be attributed to the low-income elastic nature
obtained from sources such as Australian Bureau of of some of the goods that Australia exports.
Statistics, World Development Indicators, and Inter- The services sector seems to behave differently from
national Financial Statistics. Since Equation 1 provides the goods sector. For instance, short-run estimates on
only long-run elasticities, we use the Autoregressive the coefficients of the log(RER) are not statistically
Distributed Lag (ARDL) model to estimate both the significant at conventional levels. However, at least
short-run and long-run coefficients. The ARDL model one coefficient is statistically significant at a slightly
is given by the following equation: higher level of significance. Thus, we cannot strongly

X
n1 X
n2   Xn3  
 logðTBt Þ ¼ a þ ok  logðTBtk Þ þ bk  log YAUS;tk þ pk  log YROW;tk
k¼1 k¼0 k¼0
ð2Þ
X
n4    
þ lk  logðRERtk Þ þ a þ b log YAUS;t þ  log YROW;t þ l logðRERt Þ þ ut
k¼0
454 A. Wijeweera and B. Dollery
Table 1. Results for the goods sector

Variable Coefficient SE t-Statistic Probability

C 0.17 0.20 0.84 0.41


log(TB-1) –0.06 0.12 -0.49 0.63
log(TB-2) 0.26 0.11 2.29 0.02
log(YAUS) 1.68 0.77 2.17 0.03
log(YAUS,-1) -0.36 0.75 -0.48 0.63
log(YAUS,-2) -0.92 0.73 -1.25 0.21
log(YROW) 0.30 0.25 1.19 0.24
log(YROW,-1) 0.58 0.24 2.38 0.02
log(YROW,-2 -0.42 0.25 -1.67 0.10
log(RER) 0.28 0.14 1.94 0.06
log(RER-1) 0.25 0.15 1.76 0.08
log(RER-2) -0.02 0.15 -0.15 0.88
log(TB-1) -0.27 0.09 -2.97 0.00
log(YAUS,-1) -0.07 0.11 -0.67 0.50
log(YROW,-1) 0.07 0.11 0.60 0.55
log(RER-1) -0.07 0.06 -1.09 0.28
Adjusted R2 0.31

Notes: All these variables have been defined in Equation 1. Negative


subscripts of the variables represent lagged values. For instance, log
(RER-1) means logarithm of one period lagged real exchange rate. Long-
run results and results relating to the exchange rate are shown in the box.

Table 2. Results for the services sector

Variable Coefficient SE t-Statistic Probability

C -0.46 0.38 -1.21 0.23


log(TB-1) -0.09 0.10 -0.83 0.41
log(TB-2) -0.53 0.10 -5.48 0.00
log(YAUS) 0.34 0.81 0.41 0.68
log(YAUS,-1) -1.89 0.78 -2.42 0.02
log(YAUS,-2) 0.02 0.75 0.03 0.98
log(YROW) 0.39 0.27 1.44 0.15
log(YROW,-1) 0.23 0.27 0.84 0.40
log(YROW,-2) -0.41 0.25 -1.64 0.11
log(RER) -0.04 0.15 -0.27 0.79
log(RER-1) 0.00 0.16 0.03 0.98
log(RER-2) -0.24 0.16 -1.45 0.15
log(TB-1) -0.25 0.11 -2.36 0.02
log(YAUS,-1) -0.09 0.11 -0.83 0.41
log(YROW,-1) 0.14 0.13 1.11 0.27
log(RER-1) 0.19 0.09 2.26 0.03
Adjusted R2 0.50

Note: Long-run results and results relating to the exchange rate variables
are given in the box.

reject the existence of short-run effects of the real contrasting findings of no J-curve effects for the goods
exchange rate on the services sector balance of the sector, but reasonably strong evidence of the J-curve
trade account. The real exchange rate exerts a highly effects in the services sector need to be investigated in
significant effect on the services sector balance of the greater depth and warrant further research.
trade account. The impacts are not only significant, There are two method-specific tests to confirm the
but also have the anticipated effects of improving the robustness of our findings. The first is the bound test
services sector of the trade balance. We thus have for the long-run coefficients. As shown by Pesaran et al.
negative coefficients for the early lags, followed by (2001), the results based on Equation 2 are valid only if
positive coefficients for the long-run effects suggesting the level variables are, in fact, a part of the model. We
J-curve effects in the case of the services sector. These perform the F-test to test the null hypothesis that
J-curve disparity between the goods sector and the services sector 455
b =  = l = 0 or no level relationship exists between The second diagnostic test involves estimating the
the variables under consideration. Pesaran et al. (2001) ARDL model substituting an error correction term
suggest a bound testing approach for the F-test in for the variables in levels. The significance of the
making the decision. Critical values are given for two error correction term is considered as a further proof
bands: upper bound assuming I(1) variables and lower for the long-term relationship between the chosen
bound assuming I(0) variables. The upper bound value variables. As shown in Pesaran et al. (2001), this
for our specification is 3.77 and the F-test statistics are method is advisable in the subsequent estimation of
outside this range for both the goods and services sector short-run dynamics because it has a more parsimo-
balances so that we can draw conclusive inferences nious specification than the version given in
from the results based on the error correction modelling Equation 2. The model with an error correction term
framework shown in Equation 2. is given by the following equation:

X
n1 X
n2   Xn3  
 logðTBt Þ ¼ a þ ok  logðTBtk Þ þ bk  log YAUS;tk þ pk  log YROW;tk
k¼1 k¼0 k¼0
ð3Þ
X
n4
þ lk  logðRERtk Þ þ rECTt1 þ ut
k¼0

Table 3. Error correction results for the goods sector trade balance

Variable Coefficient SE t-Statistic Probability

C -0.02 0.02 -1.19 0.24


log(TB-1) -0.06 0.12 -0.48 0.63
log(TB-2) 0.28 0.11 2.60 0.01
log(YAUS) 1.66 0.77 2.16 0.03
log(YAUS,-1) -0.17 0.72 -0.23 0.82
log(YAUS,-2) -0.85 0.70 -1.20 0.23
log(YROW) 0.44 0.23 1.95 0.05
log(YROW,-1) 0.66 0.23 2.89 0.01
log(YROW,-2) -0.33 0.24 -1.37 0.18
log(RER) 0.33 0.14 2.35 0.02
log(RER-1) 0.21 0.14 1.50 0.14
log(RER-2) -0.08 0.14 -0.60 0.55
ECTG-1 -0.26 0.09 -2.87 0.01
Adjusted R2 0.31

Note: ECTG-1 is the one-period lag residuals from Equation 1 using goods
sector trade balance data.

Table 4. Error correction results for the services sector trade balance

Variable Coefficient SE t-Statistic Probability

C 0.04 0.02 2.61 0.01


log(TB-1) -0.02 0.11 -0.17 0.86
log(TB-2) -0.48 0.10 -5.05 0.00
log(YAUS) 0.13 0.77 0.16 0.87
log(YAUS,-1) -1.90 0.74 -2.57 0.01
log(YAUS,-2) 0.23 0.72 0.33 0.75
log(YROW) 0.07 0.24 0.30 0.77
log(YROW,-1) -0.58 0.24 -2.37 0.02
log(YROW,-2) -0.50 0.24 -2.11 0.04
log(RER) -0.17 0.14 -1.21 0.23
log(RER-1) 0.03 0.15 0.17 0.86
log(RER-2) -0.25 0.15 -1.68 0.10
ECTS-1 -0.27 0.10 -2.77 0.01
Adjusted R2 0.52

Note: ECTS-1 is the one-period lag residuals from Equation 1 using service
sector trade balance data.
456 A. Wijeweera and B. Dollery
where ECTt-1 is the one-period lag residuals saved with ex ante expectations, we found no statistical
from Equation 1 and ut is the disturbance term. The support for the J-curve phenomenon for the goods
choice of the second-order lag is based on the Akaike sector. These results are in accord with the intui-
Information Criterion. The results of the error correc- tively plausible assumption that depreciation may
tion models for the goods and services sectors are help to improve the services sector component of
shown in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. the trade account in the long run, but not the goods
Borders have been drawn around the estimates sector component. Hence, studies based on aggre-
related to the error correction terms in Tables 3 gate data alone may not be helpful in policy analy-
and 4. The error correction term for the goods sector sis and policy prescription.
trade balance equation is -0.26. This is significant at
5% level. Its value suggests that, after a shock in the
goods sector, approximately 26% of the deviation is
corrected within one quarter. The results are even References
stronger for the services sector of the trade balance. Arndt, H. W. and Dorrance, G. (1987) The J-curve,
The error correction term for the services sector is Australian Economic Review, 1st quarter, 9–19.
significant at 1% level and converges to the equili- Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Ratha, A. (2004) The J-curve: a
brium at a faster rate of 27% in the first quarter. literature review, Applied Economics, 36, 1377–98.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and Wang, Y. (2006) The J-curve:
China verses her trading partners, Bulletin of Economic
Research, 58, 323–43.
V. Summary and Conclusion Flemingham, B. S. (1988) Where is the Australian J-curve?,
Bulletin of Economic Research, 40, 43–56.
This article has employed an error correction mod- Magee, S. P. (1973) Currency contracts, pass-through, and
elling approach, together with an ARDL specifica- devaluation, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1,
tion, to estimate the short-run and long-run 303–25.
Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R. J. (2001) Bounds
behaviour of the Australian goods/services sector testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships,
trade balance in response to exchange rate deprecia- Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, 289–326.
tions. We found some evidence of the existence of Rose, A. K. and Yellen, J. L. (1989) Is there a J-curve?,
J-curve effect in the services sector. However, in line Journal of Monetary Economics, 24, 53–68.
Copyright of Applied Economics Letters is the property of Routledge and its content may not be copied or
emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.
However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like