You are on page 1of 9

Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Cities
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cities

Ridesourcing, the sharing economy, and the future of cities



Scarlett T. Jina, , Hui Konga, Rachel Wub, Daniel Z. Suia,c
a
Department of Geography, The Ohio State University, 1036 Derby Hall, 154 North Oval Mall, Columbus, OH 43210-1361, USA
b
Department of Economics, Yale University, New Haven, USA
c
Division of Social and Economic Sciences, The U.S. National Science Foundation

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: As an integral part of the emerging sharing economy, ridesourcing refers to transportation services that connect
Ridesourcing community drivers with passengers via mobile devices and applications. The spectacular growth of ridesourcing
Shared mobility has sparked a burgeoning literature discussing how it affects the future of cities. This paper presents a systematic
The sharing economy review of the existing literature concerning the impact of ridesourcing on the efficiency, equity, and sustain-
On-demand work
ability of urban development. Ridesourcing has a positive impact on economic efficiency. It both complements
Future cities
and competes with public transit, but its influence on traffic congestions near city centers is still unclear.
Regarding urban equity, ridesourcing further amplifies the issue of the digital divide and raises concerns over the
issues of discrimination and data privacy and security. It is also hotly contested whether prosumers (producers/
consumers) are exploited by the sharing economy platforms, whether ridesourcing drivers are reasonably
compensated, and how to better protect on-demand workers' rights. Even though ridesourcing has been pro-
moting a green image, its true environmental impact has not been thoroughly investigated. According to the
evidence reported in the literature so far, it is unlikely that ridesourcing will reduce private car ownership.
Ridesourcing's impacts on energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions are uncertain based on existing
research. This paper outlines the danger of conceptual confusion and the methodological issues in the existing
literature. Further research is sorely needed as the future of cities is indisputably tied to the sharing economy and
its impacts on shared mobility.

1. Introduction and bikesharing facilitate the sharing of a vehicle; whereas ridesharing,


on-demand ride services, and microtransit enable the sharing of pas-
The explosive growth of ridesourcing has sparked heated debate senger rides. Ridesharing, including carpooling and vanpooling, allows
over its impacts on future urban development (Rayle, Dai, Chan, et al., drivers and passengers with similar origins and destinations to share a
2016). Ridesourcing refers to transportation services that connect ride. Traditional ridesharing on a personal, organizational, or ad hoc
community drivers – people who drive private cars instead of com- basis has existed for decades. There are also mobile apps based ride-
mercial vehicles - with passengers via mobile devices and applications. sharing, such as BlaBlaCar in France and Didi Hitch in China. On-de-
There are many different terms used to describe this emerging trans- mand ride services involve the adoption of mobile technology to re-
portation option. Academic transportation researchers use ‘ridesour- quest and dispatch vehicles upon passengers' requests. There are three
cing’; practitioners describe themselves as ‘transportation network major forms of on-demand ride services. Ridesourcing is the largest
companies (TNCs) or mobility service providers (MSPs)’; the popular segment in on-demand ride services. Ridesplitting is a variation of ri-
press calls it ‘ride-sharing’ or ‘ride-hailing’ (Shaheen & Chan, 2016). desourcing, which allows passengers with a similar route to share a ride
Ridesourcing services have been expanding rapidly across the world, and split the fare. Many TNCs operate both ridesourcing and rides-
with a number of successful TNCs, such as Uber and Lyft in the U.S., plitting. For instance, Uber has UberPOOL and Lyft has Lyft Line. E-hail
Didi Express in China, Ola in India, and even UberMOTO (for motor- is taxi service equipped with mobile apps. It is different from ride-
cycle rides) in Thailand. sourcing as the vehicles are taxicabs instead of private vehicles. Lastly,
Ridesourcing is a particular form of shared mobility. Shaheen and microtransit is a form of private transit enabled by mobile technology.
Chan (2016) offer a classification of shared mobility based upon what is It mainly provides commuting services that connect residential areas
being shared (Fig. 1). Carsharing, motorcycle sharing, scooter sharing, with urban and suburban working and commercial areas, such as


Corresponding author at: Department of Geography, The Ohio State University, 1036 Derby Hall, 154 North Oval Mall, Columbus, OH 43210, USA.
E-mail address: jin.760@osu.edu (S.T. Jin).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2018.01.012
Received 19 October 2017; Received in revised form 9 January 2018; Accepted 10 January 2018
0264-2751/ © 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Jin, S.T., Cities (2018), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2018.01.012
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Carsharing paper contributes to a better and clear understanding of ridesourcing,


as a first step to comprehend the convoluted relationship between the
sharing economy and urban development.
Motorcycle Sharing
More specifically, this paper will conduct a systematic review of the
Sharing a Vehicle
existing literature concerning how ridesourcing affects the efficiency,
Scooter Sharing equity, and sustainability of urban development – three key goals that
urban scholars and policy makers aspire to achieve for our future cities.
Bikesharing In addition to academic literature, this article also reviews a variety of
Shared Mobility Carpooling materials such as news and magazine articles, blogs, websites, and re-
Ridesharing ports produced by non-academic sources, considering that research on
Vanpooling the sharing economy is in its infancy, and not many studies have been
done specifically about ridesourcing. Given that Uber is the most suc-
cessful TNC, it is used as an example by most literature analyzed in this
Sharing a Ridesourcing
Passenger Ride paper. It is worth mentioning that, even though we didn't intend to limit
On-Demand Ride our review to any specific country, the majority of the literature written
Ridesplitting
Services in English focused exclusively on the U.S., which in turn constrained the
scope of our review. That said, the goal of this paper is not to draw a
Microtransit E-Hail broad conclusion on how ridesourcing may impact urban development,
but rather to synthesize current understanding, identify problems, and
Fig. 1. Categories of shared mobility. point out directions for future research.
[Source: modified from Shaheen & Chan, 2016]
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses
how ridesourcing affects urban transportation efficiency and economic
Chariot in the U.S. efficiency. Section 3 examines the impact of ridesourcing on urban
Shared mobility is a fast-growing sector of the emerging sharing equity. Section 4 analyzes how ridesourcing influences urban sustain-
economy. The sharing economy has a number of different names such ability through altering private car ownership, energy consumption,
as on-demand economy, gig economy, collaborative consumption, and and emissions. This is followed by a discussion section that outlines
collaborative economy. This paper uses “the sharing economy” to de- problems in existing research and prospects of future urban develop-
scribe the economic activities and “on-demand work” to describe the ment influenced by ridesourcing and the sharing economy. The last
type of jobs provided by the sharing economy. There have been an section offers a summary and points out future research directions.
increasing number of studies discussing the social, economic, and en-
vironmental impact of the sharing economy (e.g., Cockayne, 2016; 2. Urban efficiency
Frenken & Schor, 2017; Martin, 2016). Undoubtedly, the sharing
economy is quickly becoming an important component of the economy, To assess how ridesourcing changes urban transportation efficiency
penetrating a growing number of economic activities (such as Airbnb, and economic efficiency compared to the status quo, it is essential to
TaskRabbit etc.) in both developing and developed countries. The identify what mode of transportation ridesourcing is replacing – known
sharing economy is transforming business operations and models in as the modal shift (Light, 2017). Ridesourcing is most conspicuously
many profound ways. competing with taxis. From March 2012 to July 2014, the number of
With accelerated urbanization in the developing world, more and taxi trips per month in San Francisco decreased by more than a half
more people will be living in our crowded cities worldwide. How to (San Francisco Municipal Transportation Agency, 2014). In Manhattan
make our cities more efficient, equitable, and sustainable has been the of New York City between April to June in 2015, taxi pickups dropped
focus of interdisciplinary research during the past half century (e.g., by 3.83 million compared to the same period in 2014 (Fischer-Baum &
Graham & Marvin, 2001; Vasconcellos, 2001). The rapidly growing Bialik, 2015). Many scholars and the popular press made comparative
sharing economy will inevitably exert its due impacts on the future of studies on taxi and ridesourcing (Anderson, 2014; Bialik, Flowers,
cities, and yet we have seen little work linking the sharing economy Fischer-Baum, et al., 2015; Glöss, McGregor, & Brown, 2016), all of
explicitly with urban studies, although most of the sharing economic which seemed to confirm this significant modal shift. Another major
activities are implicitly taking place in cities. More importantly, most modal shift caused by the emergence of ridesourcing is from public
studies examine the sharing economy in general, even though different transit (Rayle et al., 2016), even though there are also situations in
types of sharing economy platforms or shared modes of transportation which ridesourcing complements public transportation networks
exhibit distinct characteristics and impose diverse impacts on cities. By (American Public Transportation Association, 2016). In this section, we
focusing on one aspect of the sharing economy – ridesourcing – this will examine these two modal shifts in detail and discuss how they

Table 1
Uber's impact on urban efficiency.
[Source: Compiled by the authors]

Transportation efficiency Economic efficiency

Congestion Accessibility Safety

Ridesourcing vs. taxi (?) Reduces or increases (+) Reaches poor neighborhoods (+) Drivers and passengers (+) Better matching demand and supply
congestion in the city center? with insufficient taxi services feel safer than when in taxis (+) Reduces transaction cost
(−) Insufficient driver training
and insurance gap
Ridesourcing vs. public (−) High-density area: (+) Temporal: complements public (+) Low-density area: cost efficient to
transit competes with public transit transit at night and weekends substitute certain transit routes with
(+) Spatial: serves as feeders for ridesourcing
public transit

Note: “+” denotes positive impact on urban efficiency, “-” denotes negative impact, and “?” denotes uncertain impact.

2
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

affect urban efficiency. Table 1 provides a summary of the positive and According to the interviews conducted by Glöss et al. (2016) with Uber
negative impacts of ridesourcing on urban transportation and economic drivers and passengers, both drivers and passengers felt safer because of
efficiency under these two primary forms of modal shift. Uber's rating and tracking system. Uber drivers, especially female dri-
vers, perceived an increased sense of control and security, because
2.1. Ridesourcing vs. taxi customers were registered and rated, and the vehicle was tracked (Glöss
et al., 2016). Uber passengers also gained an extra sense of safety and
Ridesourcing is believed to provide higher economic efficiency than reliability knowing who the driver was and that the system was mon-
taxis. Taking Uber as an example, its surge pricing (a dynamic pricing itoring the real-time location of the vehicle (Glöss et al., 2016).
mechanism, in which fares increase when demand is high) efficiently Nevertheless, Edelman and Geradin (2016) contended that Uber drivers
meets the fluctuating transportation demand through the day (Edelman lacked sufficient training, even though there was no empirical evidence
& Geradin, 2016). Uber also significantly reduces transaction costs quantifying the correlation between lack of training with accident fre-
through lowering the costs of searching for a ride, since passengers no quency. Edelman and Geradin (2016) also pointed out that Uber cars
longer need to call a dispatcher or stand on the street to hail a taxi, and did not have mandatory regular inspections, and some of them were
instead, they can reserve a car from indoors (Rogers, 2015). Moreover, uninsured or underinsured.
passengers can monitor the vehicles' real time GPS locations, which
largely reduces the uncertainty and anxiety of waiting for a cab 2.2. Ridesourcing vs. public transit
(Edelman & Geradin, 2016).
Whether such economic efficiency can be translated into congestion Existing literature suggests that ridesourcing both complements and
reduction is another story. Anderson (2014) observed that ridesourcing competes with public transit. On the one hand, ridesourcing fills in the
brought more cars into the cities and has worsened congestion in the temporal and spatial gaps in urban public transit networks and by doing
city center, as people living outside San Francisco drove to the city to so improves transportation accessibility. Temporally, ridesourcing is
work for ridesourcing, while taxi drivers could not do the same thing most commonly used during late night hours and weekends (American
due to regulations. However, a study conducted by the popular media Public Transportation Association, 2016), when public transit services
website FiveThirtyEight based on data of Uber trips in 2014 found that are less frequent or waiting for transit makes people feel unsafe. Spa-
Uber was not substantially worsening the traffic congestion in New tially, ridesourcing might serve as feeders for public transits, alleviating
York during rush hours, because on average Uber created 682 addi- the first-mile/last-mile problem. Notably, quantitative evidence for this
tional trips between 4 p.m. to 5 p.m. per non-holiday weekday in claim mainly came from studies conducted by Uber's own policy re-
Manhattan, which was a very small amount comparing to the total search team, as they have the full access to Uber's rich trip data. For
number of vehicles on the streets (Bialik, Fischer-Baum, & Mehta, instance, one of their recent studies in Los Angeles found that Uber
2015). Similarly, Nie (2017) estimated that ridesourcing imposed a pickups surged when new train stations open, indicating that rail pas-
relatively mild impact on the traffic congestion in Shenzhen, China, sengers used Uber to bridge between these new stations and their
using taxi GPS trajectory data during 2013 to 2015. Given that ride- destinations (Williams, 2017). Their data showed that weekly Uber
sourcing is growing at an exponential speed, more research with up- pickups within 100 m of the new stations increased significantly one
dated data is needed to examine the impact of ridesourcing on con- month after the Expo Line extension opened on March 20, 2016
gestions in central urban areas. It is also crucial to take into (Williams, 2017). However, without additional information on the ac-
consideration the modal shift from public transit to ridesourcing, which tual trip origins, we cannot distinguish whether the trips were con-
is more likely to worsen congestions. necting to the new train stations or the new commercial or residential
In the popular media, ridesourcing has a positive image of im- developments in the vicinity of the new stations.
proving transportation accessibility in low-income or low-density areas On the other hand, ridesourcing also competes with public transit,
with insufficient taxi services (McArdle, 2015). This image is to a large especially in high-density areas. One survey with ridesourcing users in
extent fueled by a study commissioned by Uber. In this rider experiment San Francisco found that 33% of the ridesourcing users would have
study, riders were dispatched to low-income neighborhoods in Los taken public transit if ridesourcing were not available, and that per-
Angeles and traveled along predetermined routes in pairs using UberX centage (41%) was even higher for non-car owners (Rayle et al., 2016).
and taxi to compare costs and waiting time (Smart, Rowe, Hawken, Henao's (2017) study found that 22.2% of the passengers would travel
et al., 2015). Their results indicated that UberX was cheaper and faster with public transportation if Lyft/Uber were not an option. The
than taxis: on average, an UberX ride cost less than a half of a cab ride, American Public Transportation Association's (APTA, 2016) survey
and the waiting time of UberX was also less than half of taxis (Smart with shared mobility users in seven U.S. cities (including San Francisco)
et al., 2015). offered a lower percentage: if ridesourcing were not available, only
FiveThirtyEight's study offered similar results: using data of nearly 14% of respondents would use public transit. The difference amongst
93 million rides taken by Uber and taxi during April to September 2014, these three studies stems from their slightly different ways of asking the
it found that 22% of the 4.4 million Uber trips started outside of questions and their diverse sampling strategies. Clewlow and Mishra
Manhattan, in contrast to 14% of the 88.4 million taxi rides (Bialik, (2017), on the other hand, argued that the relationship between ride-
Flowers, et al., 2015). According to Pucher and Renne (2003) and sourcing and public transit depended on the type of transit in question.
Renne and Bennett (2014), low-income households used taxis more They found that ridesourcing pulled people away from public bus and
often than middle-income households in the U.S., probably due to a light rail, but complemented heavy rail (Clewlow & Mishra, 2017). In
lower level of car ownership. If ridesourcing provides services similar to addition to ridesourcing, many TNCs have developed ridesplitting ser-
taxis but with lower costs and shorter waiting time in low-income vices to enlarge their market share in commuting trips. For instance, in
neighborhoods, it could meaningfully improve the accessibility of low- 2016, Uber's ridesplitting service UberPool offered a summer deal for
income individuals (National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and New York inhabitants that allowed riders to pay $49 for two weeks or
Medicine, 2016). Nevertheless, it could also be argued that for low $79 for four weeks of unlimited rides within Manhattan during com-
income neighborhoods, the availability of taxi services might be less muting hours (Powers, 2016). UberPool's rate in this promotion cam-
important than the availability of public transit, considering the issue of paign was lower than public transit because a 30-day unlimited MTA
affordability. Instead of promoting ridesourcing, it might be more pass in New York City cost $116.50.
worthwhile to improve public transit coverage and service frequency in Even though some cities and public agencies attempted to prohibit
low-income neighborhoods. or regulate ridesourcing operations, many agencies started to cooperate
The safety issue surrounding ridesourcing is still contested. with TNCs to supplement public transportation networks or even

3
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

substitute some bus routes with subsidized or free ridesourcing rides Hughes and MacKenzie's (2016) study tested whether people in areas
(Shaheen & Chan, 2016). For example, in August 2016, the Pinnellas with lower average income experienced longer waiting time for ride-
Suncoast Transit Authority (PSTA) in Pinnellas County, Florida, began sourcing services than people in other areas, using the data of around 1
providing subsidies for Uber rides that end at nearly 20 designated million estimated waiting times for UberX vehicles in Seattle in 2015.
transit stops in the county (Brustein, 2016). The PSTA also launched a Their results indicated that waiting time for UberX was more dependent
separate program offering low-income residents free Uber rides after upon the population and employment density of the area rather than
9 p.m. when buses stop running (Brustein, 2016). In a similar example, the income level, and on average, waiting time was actually shorter in
in July 2016, Miami-Dade County in Florida applied for grants to areas with lower income. Nevertheless, most ridesourcing apps require
subsidize Uber and Lyft rides connecting to two train stations (Brustein, users to have a credit card or at least a bank account to register and pay
2016). Moreover, some transportation agencies saw the potential of for the rides, which excludes the financially underserved population
cost saving in replacing bus routes with ridesourcing trips. Running bus (National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine, 2016).
routes in areas with low density and low ridership is particularly ex- According to the World Bank Global Findex database (Demirgüç-Kunt,
pensive, making ridesourcing an attractive and cost efficient alter- Klapper, Singer, et al., 2015), globally, 38% of adults did not have a
native. For instance, Centennial, a suburb of Denver, Colorado, part- bank account in 2014; in OECD countries, 6% of the adult population
nered with Lyft in August 2016 to replace a shuttle bus route were unbanked; in developing countries, 45% of adults did not own a
connecting the Dry Creek light-rail station with free Lyft rides using bank account. Credit card ownership is even lower: in 2014, 47% of
public funds (Aguilar, 2016; Brustein, 2016). adults in OECD countries reported not owning a credit card, a figure
which rose to 90% in developing countries (Demirgüç-Kunt et al.,
3. Urban equity 2015).
Discrimination is another controversial issue surrounding the bur-
In this section, we examine the social impacts of ridesourcing from geoning TNCs. Ge, Knittel, MacKenzie, et al. (2016) carried out a study
three distinct and interrelated perspectives. Firstly, from consumers' on racial and gender discrimination of Uber and Lyft through sending
perspective, we analyze how ridesourcing serves different segments of passengers to take nearly 1500 rides on controlled routes in Seattle and
the society and discuss discrimination and data privacy and security Boston in 2015. They identified discrimination against African Amer-
issues. Secondly, from the prosumers' (consumers/producers) perspec- ican riders: in Seattle, African American passengers experienced longer
tive, we discuss how consumers are turned into co-producers and the waiting times, while in Boston passengers using African American-
meaning of such transformation. Finally, from producers' perspective, sounding names experienced higher cancelation rates (Ge et al., 2016).
we further examine the nature of on-demand work, with a particular They also noticed that female passengers were given extended rides and
focus on ridesourcing drivers. hence excessive fares in Boston, confirming the anecdotes that female
riders were exposed to profiteering and flirting (Ge et al., 2016). In
3.1. Transportation equity, discrimination, and data privacy and security addition to racial and gender discrimination, how ridesourcing serves
people with disabilities also brings up concerns. There used to be
It is acknowledged by many studies that younger, better-educated, lawsuits against TNCs for discriminating against disabled passengers in
and more affluent individuals are more likely to be ridesourcing users 2014 and 2015 (Rosenthal, 2014; Stempel, 2015; Wieczner, 2015).
(Clewlow & Mishra, 2017; McGrath, 2015; Rayle et al., 2016; and A. Nowadays Uber and Lyft offer special services for people with dis-
Smith, 2016). This is not surprising as research found that young people abilities (Lyft, 2017; Uber, 2017). Nonetheless, discrimination against
were more interested in shared-based transportation services (Davis & riders is not a practice invented by ridesourcing (Rogers, 2015). The
Dutzik, 2012; National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and taxi industry has long been criticized for racial or ethnic discrimination
Medicine, 2013). Such a user profile raises the question of transporta- (National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine, 2016).
tion equity – who are enjoying this new transportation option and who Still, the taxi industry is highly regulated and in many cities taxis need
are excluded from it. This question becomes more worrying when ri- to follow non-discrimination requirements. It is argued that, since many
desourcing substitutes public transit, a public service that supposes to TNCs receive monetary or non-monetary support from public agencies,
be available and accessible to all community members. the non-discrimination requirements should be extended to TNCs re-
The younger, better-educated, and more-affluent user character- ceiving such support (Shaheen, Cohen, & Zohdy, 2016). Yet if the non-
istics remind us of the digital divide, which originally referred to the discrimination requirements are ineffective for taxis, extending them to
unequal access to information and communication technology (ICT) TNCs does not make much sense. We should probably focus on making
and the requisite skills to use it amongst community members (Selwyn, these requirements effective first.
2004) and nowadays expands to the unequal access to smartphone and Lastly, data privacy and security have been key concerns of ride-
mobile data access. According to a survey conducted by Pew Research sourcing users, researchers and public agencies (Shaheen, Cohen,
Center in 14 advanced countries in 2016, nearly all people in these Zohdy, et al., 2016). TNCs maintain highly sensitive personal data of
countries owned a mobile phone, but not everyone had a smartphone their users and drivers, such as names, phone numbers, email addresses,
(Poushter, 2017). Amongst the countries surveyed, Sweden, the Neth- driver's licenses, credit card information, and trip information. Users
erlands, Spain and Australia had the highest smartphone ownership and drivers worry about the possible monitoring, exploitation, and
rates (79% to 80%). 77% of Americans owned a smartphone. The leakage of their personal data (Rogers, 2015; Shaheen, Cohen, & Zohdy,
smartphone ownership rates in France, Japan, Poland, Hungary, and 2016). TNCs' data collection policies (such as location tracking) often
Greece were below 60% (46% to 58%). In addition, the survey identi- receive criticism from users and privacy advocates, which constantly
fied sharp digital divide, as smartphone ownership rates were higher in pressures TNCs to make adjustments on their privacy policies (Volz,
people who were younger, with higher education, and with income 2017). Data leakage, on the other hand, draws more attention from
higher than the country median (Poushter, 2017). Such digital divide public agencies. For instance, in response to Uber's data breach in 2016,
also existed in developing countries, where smartphone ownership rate which exposed personal information of around 57 million users around
was much lower than the developed countries but was catching up the world, the European Union privacy regulators recently announced
swiftly (Poushter, 2016). plans to create a task-force to coordinate investigations (Fioretti, 2017).
There have been mixed perspectives regarding how ridesourcing
serves low-income populations. As mentioned in the previous section, 3.2. Prosumerism
the study by Smart et al. (2015) showed that UberX offered cheaper and
faster services than taxis in low-income neighborhoods in Los Angeles. The term prosumer originates from Alvin Toffler. In his book The

4
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Third Wave, Toffler (1981) contended that during the pre-industrial era peer-to-peer). An Uber-funded study observed that Uber drivers earned
(the first wave) most people consumed what they produced by them- at least the same as and in many cases more than taxi drivers and
selves, and thus might be called prosumers. It was followed by the chauffeurs through comparing their earnings per hour (Hall & Krueger,
second wave, in which the industrial revolution separated the functions 2015). Nevertheless, Hall and Krueger's (2015) study didn't take into
of production and consumption and thereby gave birth to producers consideration the benefits (such as healthcare insurance and paid leave)
and consumers. The contemporary society is moving towards the third and expense reimbursement (such as car insurance and gasoline) en-
wave that brings back the prosumers. In the third wave, more and more joyed by taxi drivers and chauffeurs but not by Uber drivers. Moreover,
companies are externalizing labor by asking customers to perform tasks the fluctuation of wages is threatening the income stability of on-de-
that had been previously done by employees, and most importantly, mand workers. For instance, when Uber launched price-cutting cam-
customers do not get paid for doing them (Toffler, 2013). In ridesour- paigns to enlarge market share and stimulate demand, drivers' earnings
cing, consumers are turned into prosumers by the rating system, which dropped significantly and even below minimum wages, which hap-
gathers ratings from consumers and tallies them up to monitor drivers' pened in multiple cities at multiple times (Kosoff, 2014; Lazzaro, 2016).
performance – consumers become TNCs' unpaid middle managers The problem is Uber can easily make changes to its pricing mechanism
(Dzieza, 2015). without seeking opinions from the drivers, while taxi companies cannot
There are mixed opinions upon whether prosumers are exploited: easily change their drivers' wages. This problem also relates to our next
some view prosumers as liberating figures; whereas others consider question on flexibility and security.
prosumerism as a new form of exploitation. In management and mar- As independent contractors or micro-entrepreneurs, on-demand
keting literature, prosumption is labeled as ‘value co-creation’ workers enjoy the flexible working schedule but sacrifice the benefits
(Prahalad & Ramaswamy, 2004) or ‘service-dominant logic of mar- that come with employee status – minimum wage, health insurance,
keting’ (Vargo & Lusch, 2004). Both labels center on the idea that overtime payment, paid sick days, paid family leave, protection from
consumers transform from passive recipients of information and com- discrimination, unemployment insurance, and workers' compensation
modities to active interpreters and co-producers of both, representing and contribution to Social Security (R. Smith, 2016). Some agree that
consumer empowerment and more equal relationships between pro- ridesourcing drivers do indeed enjoy the flexibility of arranging their
ducers and consumers. Another key argument contributing to the po- own schedules (Glöss et al., 2016; Hall & Krueger, 2015), which en-
sitive image of prosumerism is that prosumers engage in the co-pro- hances their adaptability to handle unpredictable shocks in everyday
ducing activities voluntarily and they seem to enjoy the work (Ritzer & life, such as a sick child (Chen, Chevalier, Rossi, et al., 2017). Others
Jurgenson, 2010). In contrast, scholars on the opposite side offer a more question the magnitude of flexibility on-demand workers actually have.
critical assessment on the idea of putting consumers to work. Zwick, For instance, Chen and Sheldon (2015) noticed that Uber drivers tend
Bonsu, and Darmody (2008), drawing upon Foucauldian and neo- to utilize the flexibility to increase their hourly earnings. Similarly,
Marxian theory, posit that the true meaning of co-creation is to exploit Cockayne (2016) found that drivers needed to work when the price is
the creative and valuable consumer labor. Even though the idea of co- high, so they still worked on the schedule set by consumer demand and
creation releases consumers' creativity and know-how, it also ex- the algorithm, not themselves. Cockayne (2016) also emphasized that
propriates surplus value from unpaid consumer labor (Zwick et al., TNCs had strong control over drivers because they could regulate the
2008). As consumer labor is recoded as an enjoyable consumption ex- behavior of drivers with the algorithm and the rating system and easily
perience, the exploitative nature of prosumption is made less obvious deactivate drivers that did not follow their instructions.
(Zwick et al., 2008). Similarly, Pauwels (2015) asserts that prosu-
merism obscures power struggles and labor issues through replacing the 4. Urban sustainability
old production model of coerced exploitative working conditions with a
more insidious but just as exploitative model. Even though there is widespread belief that the sharing economy
helps to improve sustainability, very little empirical evidence has been
3.3. The nature of on-demand work provided to support such belief (Schor, 2016). Ridesourcing imposes
both direct and indirect impacts on urban sustainability. Indirectly,
There has been heated debate over the nature of on-demand work in ridesourcing has a potential to alter consumer behavior towards pos-
both popular media and academia. Advocates view on-demand work as sessing fewer private vehicles. Directly, ridesourcing might reduce the
the rise of micro-entrepreneurs, a new generation of self-employed energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions of urban transpor-
workers who enjoy flexible work schedules, ideal work-life balance, and tation.
family-friendly lifestyles; whereas critics perceive the on-demand
economy as a disparaging race to the bottom, in which companies shift 4.1. Private car ownership
risks to individual micro-entrepreneurs, and workers work more hours
for less money and receive minimal job security and benefits (Reich, The sharing economy is thought to be green or environmentally
2015). There are two key issues embedded in the debate. The first one friendly because it can increase the use of pre-existing goods and reduce
concerns compensation – whether ridesourcing and the sharing the demand for new products (Botsman & Rogers, 2010; Cervero,
economy provide adequate compensation for workers compared to Golub, & Nee, 2007; Frenken & Schor, 2017). Following this line of
regular full-time jobs. The second issue is the tradeoffs between flex- thought, shared mobility is assumed to reduce private car ownership, as
ibility and employment status. it encourages consumers to use shared mode of transportation rather
Criticisms of the low compensation of on-demand work have been than purchase private vehicles. This assumption has been confirmed for
concentrated on one particular type of on-demand job – crowdsourcing. carsharing (Firnkorn & Müller, 2015; Martin & Shaheen, 2016; Martin,
Crowdsourcing refers to the practice in which companies divide jobs Shaheen, & Lidicker, 2010), but not for ridesourcing. Rayle et al. (2016)
into discrete micro-tasks and outsource these micro-tasks to workers via observed that the presence of ridesourcing might not affect car own-
business-to-peer platforms, such as Amazon's Mechanical Turk. It is ership behavior, based on the result that 90% of survey respondents did
argued that the online marketplaces increase competition on a global not change car ownership levels since they started to use ridesourcing,
scale and lower workers' wages, creating a new, digital generation of and those who did change ownership split into two even groups: one
sweatshops that make the public ignore the often-desperate conditions group owned more cars, the other owned fewer cars. Similarly, in
of on-demand workers (Aytes, 2012; Ettlinger, 2016). Nonetheless, the Clewlow and Mishra's (2017) study, 91% of ridesourcing users did not
compensation of on-demand work varies depending on the nature of make any changes to car ownership. Anderson (2014) raised that ri-
work performed and on the nature of the platforms (business-to-peer or desourcing might even encourage private car ownership because some

5
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

of the drivers used the ridesourcing income to subsidize their use of ridesourcing: consumers might use the cost saving from transportation
private vehicles, or even to buy cars. to purchase other high-impact goods or services (Schor, 2016).

4.2. Energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions


5. Discussions: problems and prospects
Apart from private car ownership, researchers have paid attention
to the comparison of energy efficiency and greenhouse gas emissions As the business models of TNCs are becoming increasingly sophis-
between ridesourcing and taxi. Using taxi and Uber trip data in five ticated, it is easy to confuse different forms of shared mobility, which
cities in the U.S., Cramer and Krueger (2016) found that Uber had a might lead to misleading study results. Amongst various types of shared
higher mileage-based capacity utilization rate (61%) than taxis mobility, the most easily confused pair is ridesharing and ridesourcing.
(49.1%). The capacity utilization rate was calculated as the ratio be- While ridesharing (both traditional and app-based) is proved to be re-
tween the miles drivers had fare-paying passengers in the vehicles and ducing VMT and greenhouse gas emissions (BlaBlaCar, 2015; Jacobson
their total working miles. Notably, Cramer and Krueger's (2016) cal- & King, 2009; Minett & Pearce, 2011), the environmental impact of
culation did not account for the mileage traveled by drivers to and from ridesourcing is uncertain. Ridesharing improves energy efficiency and
the working area from home when the ridesourcing app was not turned reduces emissions because the drivers will travel to the destinations
on. In Anderson's (2014) study, 16 out of 20 drivers interviewed lived in regardless of the presence of passengers, whereas ridesourcing has no
the outer areas of San Francisco and drove deadheading long distances such synergy effect, as drivers do not have destinations by themselves –
to and from the city to work as ridesourcing drivers. Under such cir- they provide taxi-like transportation services to passengers. The pop-
cumstances, Cramer and Krueger (2016) might overestimate the capa- ular media often use ridesharing to refer to the services provided by
city utilization rate of Uber. A later study conducted by Henao (2017) Uber and Lyft, which is harmless as long as the readers understand it.
partially solved this problem by taking into consideration the com- However, confusion of these two concepts in research can produce in-
muting distance of drivers after logging off from the apps and achieved accurate results. For instance, mistakenly defining all trips of Didi
a slightly lower capacity utilization rate (59.2%). Yet Henao's (2017) Chuxing as ridesharing trips, Yu, Ma, Xue, et al.'s (2017) study assumed
calculation was based on his own rides as an Uber and Lyft driver and that Didi Chuxing trips cause no additional energy consumption and
he had a careful research design that minimized the cruising time for emissions because the drivers will drive to their destinations even with
ride requests, refused rides that required long pickup distance, and no request for ridesharing. Therefore, they calculated the environ-
planed for conservative commuting distance at the end of shifts, making mental benefits of Didi Chuxing as the sum of energy consumption and
his driving experience less representative of the general driver popu- emissions of the alternative travel modes that passengers would have
lation. More research is needed to study whether ridesourcing has chosen if Didi Chuxing were not available. However, as can be seen
higher energy efficiency. In addition, there is a lack of study measuring from Fig. 2, Didi Chuxing offers a great variety of shared mobility op-
and comparing the exact level of emissions produced by ridesourcing tions, ranging from ridesharing, ridesourcing, ridesplitting, E-hail, to
and taxis. Instead, researchers express concerns over the lack of reg- microtransit. Only trips made through Didi Hitch could be defined as
ulatory control on the emissions of ridesourcing vehicles comparing to ridesharing. Therefore, Yu et al.'s (2017) study largely overestimated
taxicabs (Light, 2017). For instance, Anderson (2014) contended that in the environmental benefits of Didi Chuxing in Beijing. Future studies
San Francisco, nearly 100% licensed taxis were “clean air” vehicles, should exercise special caution to distinguish between different types of
owing to the local regulator's “Clean Taxi” program, in contrast to the shared mobility (especially those provided by a single TNC) when
estimation made by the San Francisco Police Department that only 17% measuring their environmental impacts.
of the ridesourcing cars reprimanded for dropping passengers at the In addition to concept confusion, methodological issues warrant
airport were clean air vehicles. caution over the conclusions made by existing literature. Studies on
However, ridesourcing replaces not only taxicabs, but also other ridesourcing primarily utilize three types of data: big data, rider/driver
modes of transportation, such as public transit, walking, biking, surveys and interviews, and rider/driver experiment. Big data (trip
driving, and ridesharing. It is essential to make distinctions between related information) kept by TNCs are the most crucial and valuable
different forms of modal shift when evaluating how ridesourcing affects data used by ridesourcing research, while data from government
energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions. Henao (2017) ac- agencies (such as taxi and limousine commission) often serve as com-
counted for the different modal shifts through combining driving in- plementary information. However, TNCs are often reluctant to release
formation with passenger surveys. Driving information keeps records of their data for independent research due to concerns about privacy and
the total vehicle miles traveled (VMT), while a passenger survey in- trade secrets (Frenken, 2017). Many TNCs commissioned their own
dicates what mode of transportation ridesourcing is replacing. Through studies (e.g. BlaBlaCar, 2015; Hall & Krueger, 2015) or participated in
comparing the total VMT of ridesourcing and the modes of transpor- the research team (e.g. Yu et al., 2017), but we need more independent
tation being replaced, Henao (2017) found that ridesourcing lead to an studies, independent research questions, and objective results. Open
84.6% increase in VMT compared to the status quo. access to high-quality big data is key to a better understanding of ri-
Existing literature also discusses the extent of rebound effects. In desourcing and the sharing economy. Nevertheless, the prevalence of
1865, William Stanley Jevons raised the argument that improvement in big data raises concerns over the risk of a new positivist and quanti-
energy efficiency will increase instead of reduce energy consumption tative turn that favors generality – universal laws independent of space
(Jevons, 1906). This happens because there are various mechanisms –
the so-called rebound effects – that offset the predicted energy savings Didi Chuxing
(Sorrell, 2009). There are direct and indirect rebound effects. A direct
rebound effect, in the case of transportation, indicates that improve-
Didi Hitch Didi Express Didi Chauffeur Didi Taxi Didi Bus &
ment in energy efficiency reduces the marginal cost of travel, thus the Minibus
Ridesharing Ridesourcing High-End E-Hail
quantity of travel may be expected to increase (Sorrell, 2009). This Ridesourcing Microtransit
means ridesourcing might generate additional travel demands, rather
than merely replacing existing transportation modes. Rayle et al.'s Didi Express
Pool
(2016) study found that 8% of the ridesourcing trips were induced Ridesplitting
travel, which is a small but not insignificant amount. Henao (2017)
identified an even higher induced travel rate (12.2%). In terms of the Fig. 2. Transportation services provided by Didi Chuxing.
[Source: Compiled by the authors]
indirect effects, the re-spending effect is most closely related to

6
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

and time – over particularity that varies across place and time increasing popularity of ridesplitting services that compete with public
(Schwanen, 2016). Location does matter in ridesourcing studies. For transit. Regarding the safety issue, ridesourcing increases trust between
instance, FiveThirtyEight's study shows that Uber is not substantially drivers and passengers but faces the problems of insufficient driver
worsening the traffic congestion in New York during rush hours (Bialik, training and uninsured or underinsured vehicles.
Fischer-Baum, & Mehta, 2015), but such a conclusion cannot be applied Even though ridesourcing improves the availability of transporta-
to cities like Los Angeles, where the public transit network is far less tion in poor and remote areas, it does not seem to provide equal access
sophisticated and car dependency is high. Rider/driver surveys and to all community members – people without a smartphone, mobile data
interviews could offer rich information for research on ridesourcing, access, a credit card, or at least a banking account are excluded from
but caution needs to be exercised on the data collection procedures and this transportation option. The problem of digital divide is not limited
the implications made from the results. For example, Rayle et al. (2016) to ridesourcing and the sharing economy; it is closely related to the
oversampled people who were likely to be present in the survey loca- smart city mentality, as urban governance shifted its focus from social
tions during night time and thus oversampled social and recreational well-being towards economic competitiveness energized by technology
trips. Lastly, rider/driver experiments face the problem of representa- advancement, which leads to social polarization and exclusion (Graham
tiveness. For instance, Smart et al.'s (2015) rider experiment found that & Marvin, 2001; Hollands, 2008). Issues of discrimination against riders
Uber provided faster and cheaper services than taxis in low-income and data privacy and security have raised concerns amongst ridesour-
neighborhoods in Los Angeles. However, in this study, riders were cing users, researchers, and policy makers. How to prevent dis-
provided with mobile devices, trained to use Uber's app, and supplied crimination and protect users' privacy is a continuing inquiry. The
with the ride fares to conduct the experiment, which made these riders question of whether ridesourcing (and the whole sharing economy)
different from residents in those low-income neighborhoods who might empowers or exploits prosumers probably cannot be answered by em-
not have smartphones, know how to use the app, or have a credit card pirical analysis, but it remains a critical question under the circum-
to use the ridesourcing app. Therefore, Uber might not serve the low- stances of a swiftly growing sharing economy. On the contrary, the
income neighborhoods as well as the study depicts. Future studies question regarding the compensation level of on-demand workers can
should make careful design of the experiments so that the rider/driver's and should be answered empirically. In addition, the nature of the
demographic profile is representative of the research population. flexibility and the problems of insecurity in on-demand work should be
Looking into the future of ridesourcing, two major trends might scrutinized by not only researchers but also policymakers. As argued by
significantly change urban transportation configuration: the further R. Smith (2016), flexibility and employment status are not in-
integration of ridesourcing and public transit and the adoption of au- compatible.
tomated vehicles by TNCs. Regarding the first trend, a deepening Even though ridesourcing and the sharing economy have been
public-private partnership in urban transportation networks or even a promoting a green image, their environmental impacts have not been
fully privatized public transit by TNCs would have a substantial impact robustly quantified. According to the very limited evidence offered by
on transit accessibility, equity, and reliability (Brustein, 2016). As for literature, it is unlikely that ridesourcing can reduce private car own-
the second trend, autonomous driving technology is a key competition ership. Other forms of shared mobility such as carsharing or ridesharing
area for TNCs as robots can work tirelessly, do not demand a salary, and have a higher potential to alter consumer behavior and discourage
don't care for employment status or benefits (Dudash, 2017). Having vehicle ownership. Ridesourcing's impact on energy consumption and
fleets of driverless cars on the street will not only affect congestion and greenhouse emissions is uncertain. The calculation of VMT and emis-
transportation accessibility and safety, but also have a strong impact on sions should consider different modal shifts and the rebound effects.
the livelihoods of ridesourcing drivers, and even drivers working for the The availability of high-quality big data and rider surveys are key to the
traditional transportation and logistics industry. evaluating of ridesourcing's environmental impact.
Considering the future of the sharing economy as a whole, Frenken As can be seen from Table 2, many questions remain unanswered in
(2017) articulates three possible scenarios depending on who will existing literature, calling for further research into the current as well as
regulate the sharing economy and who will benefit from it. The first the potential impacts of ridesourcing and the sharing economy on urban
scenario is platform capitalism, a capitalist future in which mono- development. Empirically, future studies should investigate whether
polistic large-scale sharing platforms (such as Uber and Airbnb) in- ridesourcing worsens congestion in central urban areas, quantify the
tegrate multiple businesses models to offer seamless services. The relationship between ridesourcing and public transit, assess the com-
second one is platform redistribution, a state-led future which redis- pensation conditions of on-demand workers, and measure the energy
tributes the gains of the sharing economy from capitalists to labor consumption and emissions of ridesourcing. Theoretically, future re-
through taxation. The last one is platform cooperativism, a citizen-led search should critically analyze the issue of social exclusion in the
future with cooperative ownership and democratic control over the sharing economy, the nature and future of prosumption, the pre-
sharing platforms. Each scenario has a distinct institutional logic, but cariousness of on-demand work, and the transforming nature of capit-
they may coexist in different sectors or spatial contexts (Frenken, alism under the growing sharing economy. Lastly, as most existing lit-
2017). erature on ridesourcing focused on what happened in the U.S.,
conclusions drawn by existing research might not be applicable to other
6. Conclusions contexts. Future research should pay attention to the development of
ridesourcing in other countries to bring in international perspectives on
In view of the substantial transformations that ridesourcing and the the understanding of ridesourcing as well as the sharing economy.
sharing economy bring to the everyday life of urban inhabitants and Perhaps even more importantly, we hope this paper will stimulate more
urban development, this paper systematically reviews the existing lit- discussions on our policy options in light of these empirical findings so
erature on ridesourcing's impacts on urban efficiency, equity, and sus- that we can make our future cities towards achieving the goals of
tainability. Table 2 provides a summary of the positive, negative, as economic efficiency, social equity, and environmental sustainability
well as uncertain impacts of ridesourcing on urban development. The with the growth of the sharing economy.
impact of ridesourcing on urban efficiency is more straightforward than
on the other two aspects. Ridesourcing improves economic efficiency. It
reaches low-income neighborhoods with insufficient taxi services. Ri- Funding
desourcing both complements and competes with public transit. It is
uncertain whether ridesourcing worsens congestion in city centers, and This research did not receive any specific grant from funding
if yes, to what extent, especially under the circumstances of the agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

7
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 2
Impacts of ridesourcing on urban development.
[Source: Compiled by the authors]

Positive impacts Negative impacts Uncertain impacts (remaining questions)

Efficiency • Reaches poor neighborhoods with


insufficient taxi services
• Competes with public transit, especially in high-
density areas
• Does ridesourcing worsen congestion in city
centers?
• Complements public transit during late
night hours and weekends
• Safety concerns: insufficient driver training and
uninsured/underinsured vehicle
• Tocompete
what extent does ridesourcing complement or
with public transit?
• Improves economic efficiency
• Increases
passengers
trust between drivers and

Equity • Digital divide: some segments of society have • How to prevent discrimination?
difficulty accessing ridesourcing services • How to protect users' privacy?
• Isor ridesourcing (the sharing economy) empowering
exploiting prosumers?
• How are on-demand workers paid?
• Are flexibility and security incompatible?
• How to protect on-demand workers' rights?
Sustainability • Can ridesourcing reduce energy consumption
and emissions?

References September 2017.


Dzieza, J. (2015). The rating game: How Uber and its peers turned us into horrible bosses.
In: The Verge. Retrieved from http://www.theverge.com/2015/10/28/9625968/
Aguilar, J. (2016). Centennial teams up with Lyft for free rides to light rail station. The rating-system-on-demand-economy-Uber-olive-garden, Accessed date: 1 July 2017.
Denver Post, 17 August. Retrieved from http://www.denverpost.com/2016/08/15/ Edelman, B. G., & Geradin, D. (2016). Efficiencies and regulatory shortcuts: How should
lyft-centennial-team-up-for-free-rides-light-rail-station/, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. we regulate companies like Airbnb and Uber? Stanford Technology Law Review, 19(2),
American Public Transportation Association (2016). Shared mobility and the transfor- 293–328.
mation of public transit. Report, American Public Transportation Association. Ettlinger, N. (2016). The governance of crowdsourcing: Rationalities of the new ex-
Retrieved from https://www.apta.com/resources/reportsandpublications/ ploitation. Environment and Planning A, 48(11), 2162–2180 (DOI: https://doi.org/
Documents/APTA-Shared-Mobility.pdf, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. 10.1177%2F0308518X16656182).
Anderson, D. N. (2014). “Not just a taxi”? For-profit ridesharing, driver strategies, and Fioretti, J. (2017). EU privacy regulators to discuss Uber hack next week. Reuters, 23
VMT. Transportation, 41(5), 1099–1117. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11116-014- November, 2017. Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/article/us-uber-
9531-8. cyberattack-eu/eu-privacy-regulators-to-discuss-uber-hack-next-week-
Aytes, A. (2012). Return of the crowds: Mechanical Turk and neoliberal states of ex- idUSKBN1DN1X4, Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
ception. In T. Scholz (Ed.). Digital labor: The internet as playground and factory (pp. 79– Firnkorn, J., & Müller, M. (2015). Free-floating electric carsharing-fleets in smart cities:
97). New York: Routledge. The dawning of a post-private car era in urban environments? Environmental Science
Bialik, C., Fischer-Baum, R., & Mehta, D. (2015). Is Uber making NYC rush-hour traffic and Policy, 45, 30–40. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2014.09.005.
worse? In: FiveThirtyEight. Retrieved from https://fivethirtyeight.com/features/is- Fischer-Baum, R., & Bialik, C. (2015). Uber is taking millions of Manhattan rides away
Uber-making-nyc-rush-hour-traffic-worse/, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. from taxis. In: FiveThirtyEight. Retrieved from https://fivethirtyeight.com/features/
Bialik, C., Flowers, A., Fischer-Baum, R., et al. (2015). Uber is serving New York's outer Uber-is-taking-millions-of-manhattan-rides-away-from-taxis/, Accessed date: 1 July
boroughs more than taxis are. In: FiveThirtyEight. Retrieved from https:// 2017.
fivethirtyeight.com/features/Uber-is-serving-new-yorks-outer-boroughs-more-than- Frenken, K. (2017). Political economies and environmental futures for the sharing
taxis-are/, Accessed date: 7 January 2017. economy. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and
BlaBlaCar (2015). BlaBlaCar contribution to climate change. Retrieved from https:// Engineering Sciences. (Epub ahead of print 21 May 2017) https://doi.org/10.1098/
www.blablacar.in/blablalife/reinventing-travel/environment/blablacar- rsta.2016.0367.
contribution-climate-change, Accessed date: 7 January 2017. Frenken, K., & Schor, J. (2017). Putting the sharing economy into perspective.
Botsman, R., & Rogers, R. (2010). What's mine is yours: The rise of collaborative consump- Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 23, 3–10. http://dx.doi.org/10.
tion. New York: Harper Business. 1016/j.eist.2017.01.003.
Brustein, J. (2016). Uber and Lyft want to replace public buses. Bloomberg, August 15. Ge, Y., Knittel, C. R., MacKenzie, D., et al. (2016). Racial and gender discrimination in
Retrieved from https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-08-15/Uber-and- transportation network companies. Working paper no. 22776, October. Retrieved
lyft-want-to-replace-public-buses, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. from http://www.nber.org/papers/w22776.
Cervero, R., Golub, A., & Nee, B. (2007). City CarShare: Longer-term travel demand and Glöss, M., McGregor, M., & Brown, B. (2016). Designing for labour: Uber and the on-
car ownership impacts. Transportation Research Record, 1992, 70–80. http://dx.doi. demand mobile workforce. 2016 CHI conference on human factors in computing systems,
org/10.3141/1992-09. Santa Clara, California, USA, 7-12 May 2016 (pp. 1632–1643). .
Chen, K. M., Chevalier, J. A., Rossi, P. E., et al. (2017). The value of flexible work: Graham, S., & Marvin, S. (2001). Splintering urbanism: Networked infrastructure, technolo-
Evidence from Uber drivers. Working paper no. 23296, March. Retrieved from http:// gical mobilities and the urban conditions. London: Routledge.
www.nber.org/papers/w23296. Hall, J. V., & Krueger, A. B. (2015). An analysis of the labor market for Uber's driver-
Chen, K. M., & Sheldon, M. (2015). Dynamic pricing in a labor market: Surge pricing and partners in the United States. The National Bureau of Economic Research. Working
flexible work on the Uber platform. Retrieved from http://www.anderson.ucla.edu/ paper no. 22843, November. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w22843,
faculty_pages/keith.chen/papers/SurgeAndFlexibleWork_WorkingPaper.pdf, Accessed date: 5 July 2017.
Accessed date: 1 July 2017. Henao, A. (2017). Impacts of ridesourcing – Lyft and Uber – on transportation including VMT,
Clewlow, R. R., & Mishra, G. S. (2017). Disruptive transportation: The adoption, utilization, mode replacement, parking, and travel behavior (PhD Thesis)U.S: University of
and impacts of ride-hailing in the United States. Report. Davis: Institute of Transportation Colorado.
Studies, University of California (UCD-ITS-RR-17-07). Hollands, R. G. (2008). Will the real smart city please stand up? City, 12(3), 303–320. DOI
Cockayne, D. G. (2016). Sharing and neoliberal discourse: The economic function of https://doi.org/10.1080/13604810802479126.
sharing in the digital on-demand economy. Geoforum, 77, 73–82. http://dx.doi.org/ Hughes, R., & MacKenzie, D. (2016). Transportation network company wait times in
10.1016/j.geoforum.2016.10.005. Greater Seattle, and relationship to socioeconomic indicators. Journal of Transport
Cramer, J., & Krueger, A. B. (2016). Disruptive change in the taxi business: The case of Geography, 56, 36–44. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2016.08.014.
Uber. The American Economic Review, 106(5), 177–182. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/ Jacobson, S. H., & King, D. M. (2009). Fuel saving and ridesharing in the US: Motivations,
aer.p20161002. limitations, and opportunities. Transportation Research Part D: Transport and
Davis, B., & Dutzik, T. (2012). Transportation and the new generation: Why young people Environment, 14(1), 14–21. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.trd.2008.10.001.
are driving less and what it means for transportation policy. Retrieved from https:// Jevons, W. S. (1906). The coal question: An inquiry concerning the progress of the nation, and
uspirg.org/sites/pirg/files/reports/Transportation%20%26%20the%20New the probable exhaustion of our coal-mines. New York: The Macmillan Company.
%20Generation%20vUS_0.pdf, Accessed date: 30 November 2017. Kosoff, M. (2014). Uber drivers speak out: We're making a lot less money than Uber is
Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Klapper, L. F., Singer, D., et al. (2015). The global Findex database telling people. In: Business Insider. Retrieved from http://www.businessinsider.com/
2014: Measuring financial inclusion around the world. World Bank Policy research Uber-drivers-say-theyre-making-less-than-minimum-wage-2014-10, Accessed date: 1
working paper no. 7255, April. Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=2594973. July 2017.
Dudash, S. (2017). Why Uber can't lose the driverless car race. Forbes(10 July), Available Lazzaro, S. (2016). Uber drivers plan boycott after fare cuts slash their earnings to below
at: https://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2017/07/10/uber-has-pole- minimum wage. In: Observer. Retrieved from http://observer.com/2016/01/Uber-
position-in-race-to-develop-driverless-cars/#6f00806c7ab0, Accessed date: 23 drivers-plan-boycott-after-fare-cuts-slash-their-earnings-to-below-minimum-wage/,

8
S.T. Jin et al. Cities xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Accessed date: 1 July 2017. news/houston-texas/houston/article/Texas-disability-advocates-sue-Uber-Lyft-30-


Light, S. E. (2017). Precautionary federalism and the sharing economy. Emory Law 5645520.php, Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
Journal, 66(2), 333–394. San Francisco Municipal Transportation Agency (2014). Taxis and accessible services
Lyft (2017). Accessibility vehicle dispatch. Retrieved from https://help.lyft.com/hc/en- division: Status of taxi industry. Report, San Francisco Municipal Transportation
us/articles/213584508-Accessible-vehicle-dispatch, Accessed date: 30 November Agency Board Meeting, 16 September. Retrieved from https://www.sfmta.com/sites/
2017. default/files/agendaitems/9-16-14%20Item%2011%20Presentation%20-
Martin, C. J. (2016). The sharing economy: A pathway to sustainability or a nightmarish %20Taxicab%20Industry.pdf, Accessed date: 1 July 2017.
form of neoliberal capitalism? Ecological Economics, 121, 149–159. http://dx.doi.org/ Schor, J. (2016). Debating the sharing economy. Journal of Self-Governance and
10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.11.027. Management Economics, 4(3), 7–22.
Martin, E., & Shaheen, S. (2016). The impacts of Car2go on vehicle ownership, modal Schwanen, T. (2016). Geographies of transport II: Reconciling the general and the par-
shift, vehicle miles traveled, and greenhouse gas emissions: An analysis of five North ticular. Progress in Human Geography, 41(3), 355–364 (DOI: https://doi.org/
American cities. Working paper, July. Retrieved from http://innovativemobility.org/ 10.1177%2F0309132516628259).
wp-content/uploads/2016/07/Impactsofcar2go_FiveCities_2016.pdf. Selwyn, N. (2004). Reconsidering political and popular understandings of the digital
Martin, E., Shaheen, S., & Lidicker, J. (2010). Impact of carsharing on household vehicle divide. New Media & Society, 6(3), 341–362 (DOI: https://doi.org/
holdings. Transportation Research Record, 2143, 150–158. http://dx.doi.org/10.3141/ 10.1177%2F1461444804042519).
2143-19. Shaheen, S., & Chan, N. (2016). Mobility and the sharing economy: Potential to facilitate
McArdle, M. (2015). Uber serves the poor by going where taxis don't. Bloomberg, 20 July. the first- and last-mile public transit connections. Built Environment, 42(4), 573–588.
Retrieved from https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2015-07-20/uber- http://dx.doi.org/10.2148/benv.42.4.573.
serves-the-poor-by-going-where-taxis-don-t, Accessed date: 7 August 2017. Shaheen, S., Cohen, A., & Zohdy, I. (2016). Shared mobility: Current practices and
McGrath, F. (2015). The demographics of Uber's US users. In: GlobalWebIndex. Retrieved guiding principles. Report, U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway
from https://www.globalwebindex.net/blog/the-demographics-of-Ubers-us-users, Administration. Retrieved from https://ops.fhwa.dot.gov/publications/
Accessed date: 1 July 2017. fhwahop16022/fhwahop16022.pdf, Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
Minett, P., & Pearce, J. (2011). Estimating the energy consumption impact of casual Shaheen, S., Cohen, A., Zohdy, I., et al. (2016). Smartphone applications to influence
carpooling. Energies, 4(1), 126–139. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/en4010126. travel choices: Practices and policies. Report, U.S. Department of Transportation,
National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (2013). Millennials and mo- Federal Highway Administration. Retrieved from https://ops.fhwa.dot.gov/
bility: Understanding the millennial mindset and new opportunities for transit providers. publications/fhwahop16023/fhwahop16023.pdf, Accessed date: 8 January 2018.
Washington, DC: The National Academies Presshttp://dx.doi.org/10.17226/22500. Smart, R., Rowe, B., Hawken, A., et al. (2015). Faster and cheaper: How ride-sourcing fills
National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (2016). Between public and a gap in low-income Los Angeles neighborhoods. Report, BOTEC Analysis
private mobility: Examining the rise of technology-enabled transportation services. Corporation, July. Retrieved from http://botecanalysis.com/wp-content/uploads/
Washington, DC: The National Academies Presshttp://dx.doi.org/10.17226/21875. 2015/07/LATS-Final-Report.pdf, Accessed date: 1 July 2017.
Nie, Y. (2017). How can the taxi industry survive the tide of ridesourcing? Evidence from Smith, A. (2016). Shared, collaborative and on demand: The new digital economy. In:
Shenzhen, China. Transportation Research Part C, 79, 242–256. http://dx.doi.org/10. Pew Research Center. Retrieved from http://www.pewinternet.org/2016/05/19/the-
1016/j.trc.2017.03.017. new-digital-economy/, Accessed date: 1 July 2017.
Pauwels, M. (2015). Work and prosumerism: Collaborative consumption. In O. Frayssé, & Smith, R. (2016). Flexibility in the on-demand economy. In: National Employment Law
M. O'Neil (Eds.). Digital labour and prosumer capitalism: The US matrix (pp. 66–84). Project (NELP). Retrieved from http://www.nelp.org/publication/flexibility-in-the-
Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan. on-demand-economy/, Accessed date: 1 July 2017.
Poushter, J. (2016). Smartphone ownership and internet usage continues to climb in Sorrell, S. (2009). Jevons' paradox revisited: The evidence for backfire from improved
emerging economies. In: Pew Research Center. Retrieved from http://www. energy efficiency. Energy Policy, 37(4), 1456–1469. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
pewglobal.org/2016/02/22/smartphone-ownership-and-internet-usage-continues- enpol.2008.12.003.
to-climb-in-emerging-economies/, Accessed date: 29 November 2017. Stempel, J. (2015). Uber must face lawsuit claiming bias against blind riders. Reuters, 20
Poushter, J. (2017). Smartphones are common in advanced economies, but digital divides April. Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/article/us-uber-blind-lawsuit/uber-
remain. In: Pew Research Center. Retrieved from http://www.pewresearch.org/fact- must-face-lawsuit-claiming-bias-against-blind-riders-idUSKBN0NB1W020150420,
tank/2017/04/21/smartphones-are-common-in-advanced-economies-but-digital- Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
divides-remain/, Accessed date: 29 November 2017. Toffler, A. (1981). The third wave. New York: Bantam Books.
Powers, M. (2016). Be jealous, New Yorkers are getting a month of unlimited Uber Toffler, A. (2013). Revolutionary wealth. New Perspectives Quarterly, 30(4), 122–130.
commutes for $79. The Washington Post, 12 July. Retrieved from https://www. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/npqu.11414.
washingtonpost.com/news/dr-gridlock/wp/2016/07/12/be-jealous-new-yorkers- Uber (2017). Accessibility at Uber. Retrieved from https://accessibility.uber.com/,
are-getting-a-month-of-unlimited-Uber-commutes-for-79/?utm_term=. Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
4f1d4b1aad3c, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. Vargo, S. L., & Lusch, R. F. (2004). Evolving to a new dominant logic for marketing.
Prahalad, C. K., & Ramaswamy, V. (2004). Co-creation experiences: The next practice in Journal of Marketing, 68(1), 1–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.68.1.1.24036.
value creation. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18(3), 5–14. http://dx.doi.org/10. Vasconcellos, E. A. (2001). Urban transport environment and equity: The case for developing
1002/dir.20015. countries. New York: Routledge.
Pucher, J., & Renne, J. L. (2003). Socioeconomics of urban travel: Evidence from the 2001 Volz, D. (2017). Uber to end post-trip tracking of riders as part of privacy push. Reuters,
NHTS. Transportation Quarterly, 57(3), 49–77. 29 August. Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/article/us-uber-privacy/uber-
Rayle, L., Dai, D., Chan, N., et al. (2016). Just a better taxi? A survey-based comparison of to-end-post-trip-tracking-of-riders-as-part-of-privacy-push-idUSKCN1B90EN,
taxis, transit, and ridesourcing services in San Francisco. Transport Policy, 45, Accessed date: 30 November 2017.
168–178. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2015.10.004. Wieczner, J. (2015). Why the disabled are suing Uber and Lyft. Fortune, 22 May.
Reich, R. B. (2015). The share-the-scraps economy. In: Robert Reich. Retrieved from Retrieved from http://fortune.com/2015/05/22/uber-lyft-disabled, Accessed date:
http://robertreich.org/post/109894095095, Accessed date: 1 July 2017. 30 November 2017.
Renne, J. L., & Bennett, P. (2014). Socioeconomics of urban travel: Evidence from the Williams, R. (2017). How Uber works together with Southern California's growing rail
2009 national household travel survey with implications for sustainability. World network. In: Medium. Retrieved from https://medium.com/uber-under-the-hood/
Transport Policy & Practice, 20(4), 7–27. how-uber-works-together-with-southern-californias-growing-rail-network-
Ritzer, G., & Jurgenson, N. (2010). Production, consumption, prosumption. Journal of fa8b1aba03b4, Accessed date: 21 September 2017.
Consumer Culture, 10(1), 13–36 (DOI: https://doi.org/ Yu, B., Ma, Y., Xue, M., et al. (2017). Environmental benefits from ridesharing: A case of
10.1177%2F1469540509354673). Beijing. Applied Energy, 191, 141–152. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.
Rogers, B. (2015). The social cost of Uber. Temple University Legal Studies Research paper 01.052.
no. 2015-28. Zwick, D., Bonsu, S. K., & Darmody, A. (2008). Putting consumers to work. Journal of
Rosenthal, B. M. (2014). Texas disability advocates sue Uber, Lyft, 30 other entities. Consumer Culture, 8(2), 163–196. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1469540508090089.
Houston Chronicle, 24 July. Retrieved from http://www.houstonchronicle.com/

You might also like