You are on page 1of 18

Article

EPD: Society and Space


2019, Vol. 37(6) 1007–1024
“We’re building their data”: ! The Author(s) 2019
Article reuse guidelines:
Labor, alienation, and idiocy sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0263775819856626
in the smart city journals.sagepub.com/home/epd

Kafui Attoh
CUNY School of Labor and Urban Studies, USA

Katie Wells
Georgetown University, USA

Declan Cullen
The George Washington University, USA

Abstract
In 2017, Uber Technologies Inc. launched a new service called Uber Movement. Designed by a
team of 10 engineers, the new service provided a select number of cities access to Uber’s vast
trove of transportation data. One of the first cities to partner with Uber on this initiative was
Washington, DC. Playing directly to the city’s longstanding “smart city” aspirations, the initiative
was greeted warmly by city officials eager to market the region as a symbol of data-driven urban
growth and smart technology. Largely missing from this response, however, was any mention of
Uber drivers themselves. Over the course of the paper, and drawing on 40 interviews conducted
with Washington, DC-based Uber drivers, we examine the labor conditions that we argue are
central to the production of Uber’s smart data. Beyond placing labor more centrally in critiques
of the smart city, the paper suggests that the experience of Uber drivers offers us a window into
the type of smart city on offer. As we argue, the city that emerges from our interviews is less
a city defined by data-driven growth, than it is a city defined by alienation and isolation.

Keywords
Smart cities, labor, data, Uber, gig-economy, alienation, idiocy

Corresponding author:
Kafui Attoh, CUNY School of Labor and Urban Studies, 25 W 43rd Street, New York, NY 10036, USA.
Email: kafui.attoh@mail.cuny.edu
1008 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

Smart technology and intelligent use of data are critical to the success of the nation’s cities and
the District of Columbia is committed to using these tools to keep pace with the rapid growth of
our neighborhoods. We’re excited to be one of the early partners with Uber on this new plat-
form. We want to employ as many data sources as possible to mitigate traffic congestion,
improve infrastructure, and make our streets safer for every visitor and resident in the nation’s
capital. (Muriel Bowser, Mayor of Washington, DC, 8 January 2017)

I joke, people keep talking about driverless cars, which I still think [are] way far off, but honestly
if you look at it, we’re building their data, [. . .] Uber has monstrous data now to see what the
trends are, what times of day are people driving, what roads are they using, what roads does the
map recommend versus what way would a driver go. [. . .] They’re going to have that data to
make it happen. And I joke with people, we’re their guinea pigs now. We’re building that data
for them, and they have it. (Joe, Uber driver, interview with authors, 19 May 2016)

Introduction
In 2017, the global “ridesharing” company Uber Technologies Inc. began the year by
launching a service called Uber Movement. Designed by a team of 10 engineers, Uber
Movement was created as a free web-based service allowing users to access a vast trove
of city-specific transportation data—all of which had been collected through Uber’s
“ridesharing” app (Dwoskin and Siddiqui, 2017; Newcomb, 2017). Marketed to both
urban transportation planners and municipal policy makers, Uber Movement’s primary
selling point was clear. In short, and to paraphrase company representatives Joan
Golberston and Andrew Salzberg, Uber Movement promised to help “urban planners
and civic communities” use data to “crack their city’s commute” (Newcomb, 2017). One
of the first cities in the US to partner with Uber on this new initiative was Washington, DC.
Within months of its launch, DC residents were able to access a select cache of historic data
on congestion patterns and road usage. Of course, for local city officials the appeal of Uber
Movement went beyond transportation. Uber Movement not only marked an opportunity
to build on “smart city” initiatives like SmartDC—an early smart city initiative—but to
remake the city as a national symbol of data-driven urban growth, “smart technology” and
the intelligent use of data (Office of Chief of Technology, 2018).1 Indeed, for the city’s
mayor, Muriel Bowser, this was precisely the goal (Shueh, 2017).
While there was a great deal of excitement leading up to the launch of Uber Movement,
questions remained. What type of data were to be released? How many data would Uber be
willing to share?2 What exactly was meant by “smart technology”? In mitigating the city’s
traffic congestion or improving the city’s infrastructure, what type of information would
Uber really be willing to divulge? Of course, for yet other observers, the lead up to Uber
Movement’s launch was notable for another reason—namely the wholesale absence of any
mention of Uber drivers themselves. This absence was especially notable in light of the
comments made by Joe, the Uber driver quoted in the above epigraph. For Joe and any
number of other drivers in Washington, DC, Uber’s vast dataset was not simply a product
of 10 engineers, it was also a partial product of their labor. To quote Joe directly: “we’re
building that data for them, and they have it” (Interview with authors, 19 May 2016). This
paper starts from the presumption that Joe is, indeed, correct. When Uber drivers take the
wheel they are invariably producing more than a service called “ridesharing.” They are also
helping to produce a thing called “data.”3 For those engaged in debates on smart cities, this
Attoh et al. 1009

paper argues that there is a desperate need to pay attention to the laboring experience
of workers like Joe. For one, it allows us to see “data” not as a thing but, instead, as the
product of a definite set of social relations. These are relations between drivers and Uber,
between drivers themselves, and between drivers and the wider public. More importantly, it
allows us to see another side of the smart city—one defined less by “data-driven growth”
than by alienation and privatized isolation.
The paper proceeds as follows. In the first section we focus on the idea of the smart city.
We suggest that while there are many important critiques of the smart city, such critiques
have rarely touched on questions of labor. In building a critique that takes labor seriously,
we argue that one place to start is with the work of scholars like Christian Fuchs (2010) as
well as the recent work of Jim Thatcher et al. (2016). Such scholars have placed labor at the
center of their critiques of both platform capitalism and “big data.” Building on such work,
we argue that a labor critique of the smart city must also wrestle with the experience of
workers like Joe. After a brief comment on methods, we then move to our case study. Here
we draw from interviews conducted with 40 Uber drivers in the Washington, DC area.
Drawing on these interviews, we suggest, that to start with the labor process under Uber
is to get a rather dark picture of both Uber Movement and the smart city idea to which it
was designed to appeal. In our conclusion we draw on the Marxist inflected notion of idiocy
and alienation to both sketch out that picture, and to name the potential costs of the smart
city on offer—especially when built upon the shoulders of the workers that we profile below.

Where is labor in the smart city?


For city officials and policy makers eager to use data to improve the delivery of public
services—and often within an environment of increasing competition and budget con-
strains—initiatives like Uber Movement are invariably appealing. In many ways, their
appeal is that of the smart city more generally. As is commonly understood, a smart city
is simply a city capable of using the “data from connected devices [. . .] to keep traffic flowing
[. . .] and improve the delivery of public services” (Kitchin, 2014; Why HPC Matters: Smart
Cities, 2017). Given the increasing proliferation of sensors, smart phones, and information
communication technologies, proponents of smart cities are generally those who believe that
cities can put such technologies to good use. As they argue, to the degree that cities can
capture and analyze the data generated by ICTs or smart sensors, addressing the problems
that so often plague urban residents will be that much easier—be these challenges associated
with transportation, the delivery of public services, or public participation (Why HPC
Matters: Smart Cities, 2017).
Of course, as is always the case, there are those who take a more critical stance (see, inter
alia, Coletta and Kitchin, 2017; Greenfield, 2013; Hollands, 2008, 2015; Humphries, 2013;
Iveson and Maalsen, 2018; Kitchin, 2015; Leszczynski, 2016; Sennett, 2012; Soderstrom
et al., 2014; Townsend, 2013; Vanolo, 2014; Van Zoonen, 2016; Wiig, 2016; Wiig and
Wyly, 2016; Zook, 2013). Perhaps the most notable critiques of the smart city have come
from the scholars Robert Hollands and Rob Kitchin. As Hollands (2008) argues, the expe-
rience of “self-designated smart cities” has often been less than ideal. Despite their promise
to be more “livable, secure, functional, competitive and sustainable,” the reality can be quite
different (Kitchin, 2014: 2). Self-designated smart cities, Hollands asserts, are often merely
cities where the needs of global capital trump those of more “stationary ordinary citizens”
(Hollands, 2008: 311) Rob Kitchin (2014) has argued much the same thing. As Kitchin
asserts, the rhetoric of the smart city too often masks the production of cities defined by
1010 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

technocratic governance, corporate capture, and increased surveillance. Rather than pro-
ducing the smart city, we invariably find the production of the panoptic city, the post-
political city, the corporate city, or the technocratic one (Bartoli et al., 2011; Greenfield,
2006; Kitchin, 2014; Wiig, 2016).
Where the works of Hollands and Kitchin have echoed other critiques of the smart city
they have also revealed what is too often missing in those critiques—namely any discussion
of labor, particularly the labor that goes into producing data. While questions of privacy,
corporate capture, and governance remain important, this paper presumes that any critical
appraisal of smart cities also ought to take up the question implicit in comments like those
from Joe—namely, what type of labor goes into producing the smart city? And, just as
importantly, what are the conditions of that labor?
One potential way of addressing this question is to look to the work of scholars like
Christian Fuchs. Focused on the rise of what he has deemed “platform capitalism” or
“informational capitalism,” in his essay with Sebastian Sevignani, Fuchs argues that
much of the data so central to the accumulation strategies of companies like Facebook,
YouTube, and Google rest on both “the exploitation of ‘users’ unpaid labor,” as well as on
the ability of such companies to blur the distinction between leisure time and labor time
(Fuchs and Sevignani, 2013: 237; Fumagalli et al., 2018). According to Fuchs (2010, 2014),
when we browse YouTube videos, or connect with friends via Facebook, not only are we
producing value for these various companies but we are invariably doing so as unpaid
digital laborers (a category that he distinguishes from digital workers). As Fuchs argues,
and using the example of platforms like Facebook, “Capitalist Internet produsage is an
extreme form of exploitation, in which the produsers work completely for free and are
therefore infinitely exploited [sic]” (2010: 191).4 Scholars like Abigail de Kosnik (2012),
Mark Andrejevic (2012), and Trebor Sholz (2012), yet more recently, Shoshana Zuboff
(2019) have all offered similar analyses.
In their article “Data Colonialism through Accumulation by Dispossession” authors Jim
Thatcher et al. (2016) provide yet another possible approach to the question of labor in the
smart city. Their piece focuses on the process by which “individual data” generated by “an
individual user of technology becomes” the exchangeable market commodity called “big
data.” As Thatcher et al. point out, this process is not only defined by “asymmetrical power
relations” between technology providers and users, but also “the commodification and
extraction of personal information as data.” These data are ultimately alienated from the
very people who produce them—often through tacit data license agreements (2016:
991,995).5 According to Thatcher et al. this practice—whereby labor relations are extended
yet further into “previously private times and spaces”—is best described, as a process of
“data colonialism through accumulation by dispossession.” By appealing to Harvey’s (2004)
notion of “accumulation by dispossession,” in many ways, Thatcher et al. advance an
argument parallel to that Fuchs—namely, that “big data,” like platform capitalism, more
broadly, rests on “an extreme form of exploitation.”
In making sense of the relationship between smart city initiatives like Uber Movement
and the experience of Uber drivers like Joe, the ideas of both Fuchs (2010) and Thatcher
et al. (2016) are useful. In short, and as the case study will show, where Uber has accumu-
lated a vast trove of data on cities, it has done so through processes that are defined by
“asymmetrical power relations,” and by the “extension of labor relations into previously
private times and spaces” (Thatcher et al., 2016: 991). Of course, the work of Fuchs and
Thatcher et al. can only get us so far. Where such work may help us see the exploitation of
Attoh et al. 1011

Uber drivers as central to initiatives like Uber Movement, such work also tells us very little
about the nature of that exploitation, or what that exploitation looks like from the perspec-
tive of driver themselves. Such a perspective, we argue, is important. It is important because
it reveals, in visceral terms, what is required to produce Uber’s data, and what types of social
relations may be obscured in the demand for the smart city.6
Of course beyond placing labor and the experience of labor more centrally within schol-
arship on smart cities, the following case study also builds on the work of scholars like Alex
Rosenblatt (2018), Rosenblatt and Stark (2016), Rosaria Berliner and Gil Tal (2018), Ryan
Calo (2017), and Sarah Mason (2018)—all of whom have offered an inside look into the
lives of Uber drivers. While our case study uncovers many of the same labor conditions
explored in these studies, we suggest that these conditions also ought to matter for how we
think about data, the smart city, and the costs of data-driven urban growth.

A brief word on methods. . .


Before proceeding further, we might offer a brief comment on the case study itself. Our
initial research project aimed at exploring the work lives of Uber drivers based in
Washington, DC. We based our study in Washington, DC for several reasons. Not only
had the city emerged as one of Uber’s top markets, but it had also emerged as something of
a model city with respect to Uber-friendly legislation (Hall and Krueger, 2015; Interview
with authors, Uber Lobbyist, 28 July 2016). When we began our study in 2016, Uber had
already been operating in the city for five years. As in many municipalities, Uber first
appeared as a modified black car service—using a smart phone app to provide on-
demand trips to passengers via luxury sedans. In 2013, Uber expanded on this operation
with the launch of UberX. Where Uber’s black car service worked with drivers already
licensed to provide livery services, UberX opened the door to any individual with a private
automobile, a regular driver’s license, and a willingness to pick up strangers (Hendrix and
Aratani, 2013). As a low cost alternative to local taxis, Uber enjoyed almost immediate
popularity. Of course, Uber’s entry into the city raised any number of questions—the most
pressing for us being on the working conditions of the drivers.
Over the course of 2016, we conducted 40 interviews with Uber drivers in the DC area.
We also conducted an additional 22 interviews with local officials and stakeholders engaged
in debates on Uber’s role in the city. While many local officials and civic leaders were eager
to talk to us, enlisting drivers in our study was far more challenging. Ultimately we recruited
drivers through UberPeople.net—an online chat room frequented by DC-based Uber driv-
ers. These interviews were conducted in person and were roughly an hour in length. Our
questions ranged from the broad to the specific. In addition to exploring drivers’ motiva-
tions, their work history and their own feelings about Uber as a company, the bulk of our
questions explored the more quotidian elements of the job—from their daily routine to their
strategies for making money. Almost (34) all of our 40 informants also completed an online
survey giving us both basic demographic and financial data. When Uber Movement
launched in 2017 we had already finished our data collection. As a result, our interviews
rarely broached issues explicitly related to smart cities or smart data. With that said, it
quickly became apparent that our findings were relevant to debates on those very issues.
Indeed, our findings seemed to address a fundamental gap in the smart city literature—
namely, the absence of any discussion of the people we profile below—the workers, who we
argue, remain central to the production of Uber’s data.7
1012 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

Into the “data mill” we go!

[W]e’re their guinea pigs now. We’re building that data for them, and they have it. (Joe, inter-
view with authors, 19 May 2016)

When we met Joe in mid-May of 2016, he had already been driving for Uber for a year.8
Like many Uber drivers we interviewed, Joe had taken up Uber as a way to supplement his
income. As the first in his family to go to college, let alone graduate school, Joe was used to
picking up odd-jobs. Even so, as he explained, this last year had been especially full. On top
of spending roughly 20 hours a week behind the wheel for Uber, Joe reported working an
additional 55 hours a week as a security guard and as an outreach coordinator for a local
university. As Joe explained, the differences between the jobs could not be starker. As a
security guard, he observed “I’m paid the same rate all the time, whereas [with] Uber it can
fluctuate.” As Joe explained: “Uber is a strategy game, especially if you do it part time,
because you want to pick the hours that it’s going to be busy.” As Joe implied, picking those
hours could be difficult. On the day we met Joe, he had just worked a morning shift for
Uber. He was already regretting it.

This morning, I woke up randomly. It was 4:30 and I decided, I haven’t done a morning shift in
a while, I want to see how it is. Well, I got gas, [and] was on the road from my house [by]
approximately [. . .] 5:15. [I] turned the app on, and there was absolutely no business. And Uber
right now, Uber offers different incentives to get drivers out. And right now they’re offering,
your fares will be 1.4 for every fare more if you are out during this time, and that time was 5–10
am. Well, I made $8.78 for the hour that I was online, so I called it a day, that was about 7:15.
[. . .] So there’s times like that where it reinforced that I’m not going to do morning shifts ever
again, because it completely wasn’t worth it. (Interview with authors, 19 May 2016)

For Joe, the idea of doing another morning shift was out of the question. At $8.78 an hour,
the pay rate was simply too low. Of course, from Uber’s perspective, Joe’s morning had been
a raging success. In his 2016 article, “How Uber profits even while its drivers aren’t earning
any money” tech writer Jay Cassano (2016) explains why. As Cassano argues: “even when
drivers don’t have passengers” they are still generating data for Uber. More importantly,
these data are central to how Uber sets prices, directs drivers, and manages incentives.9 In
the case of Joe, the same argument applies. Over the course of 2 hours, Uber had not only
secured a 25% commission on Joe’s fare revenue, but it had gained valuable information
about city roads, about traffic patterns and about passengers themselves, specifically their
pickup and drop off locations—be these locations restaurants, nightclubs, hotels, or job
sites. Over those 2 hours, Joe had produced more than a service called “ridesharing.” He had
also produced data. These data were then mobilized by Uber to manage workflow, alter
incentives, or redirect drivers. Indeed, as some observers have argued, such data, may be
central to Uber’s stratospheric valuation—especially given its potential value to advertisers,
governments, and private retailers (Calvey, 2015; Hirson, 2015). Where services like Uber
Movement play directly to the hopes of smart city proponents—many of whom hope to put
such data to good use—the following section offers a caveat. Namely it starts from the
presumption that Uber’s data cannot be separated from the laboring conditions described
below. These conditions are not only defined by unpaid labor or asymmetrical power
relations—following Fuchs and Thatcher et al. and the work of writers like Cassano—but
by a labor process that encourages isolation and alienation.
Attoh et al. 1013

Chasing the surge


In early May 2016, we interviewed Diana. At the time, Diana was working as both an Uber
driver and as a server at the Fuddruckers fast food chain. As Diana explained, after only
four weeks of driving for Uber, she had already figured it out. The best way to make money,
she said, was to work weekday mornings from roughly 5 to 10 a.m., and weekends from
roughly 9 p.m. to 5 a.m. Weekend evenings, she added, were especially lucrative because
they invariably involved reaping the benefits of what Uber called “surge pricing.” As she
recounted, surges occurred at distinct times and in distinct areas of the city. During a so-
called “surge,” a driver might potentially double, triple, or even quadruple what they might
make under normal circumstances. For Diana, and many others, one of the central strat-
egies for making money as an Uber driver involved “chasing in the surge” (Interview with
authors, 11 May 2016). Another part-time driver named Jack noted the same thing. Jack
was an information technology specialist who had taken up driving for Uber to make some
extra money. For him, like Diana, driving during a surge was the only thing that made the
job worth it.

I just do it mainly when there’s huge demand with surge, or when I feel like driving. Because I do
enjoy driving sometimes. But since I work in downtown Arlington, off of a major road, there’s
always some sort of demand every now and then. So basically it’s like, I work my daytime job,
and then I turn [the app] on after I’m leaving my office to see if there’s a surge. And if there’s a
reasonable surge, then I’ll drive, because then it’s worth my time. (Interview with authors, Jack,
27 June 2016)

Jack and Diana were hardly alone in their reliance on the surge. In our survey, a driver
named Harry wrote: “Driving for base rates ¼ financial suicide.” In 2016, Uber modified its
surge pricing model by introducing a new system of “Boosts.” Boosts were automatic surges
granted to drivers who had successfully completed a predetermined number of trips during
the previous week. Uber’s “Boost system” consisted of four levels: Bronze, Silver, Gold, and
Platinum. As one driver explained, all drivers begin at Bronze. If a driver completes 35 trips
in a seven-day period, they are boosted to Silver for the following week. For drivers who
reach Silver, every fare within a designated area of the city is automatically “surge priced” at
1.4 or 1.6 times the base fare. The surge coefficients at the Gold and Platinum level are even
higher. For Ben, another driver we interviewed, Uber’s system of boosts reoriented his entire
strategy. Rather than simply “chasing the surge,” Ben aimed to “chase Platinum.”10 As
he explained:

So my first week driving, I literally hit the road. I think it was like July 4th weekend, and I had
some days off from work. So I was on the road. I mean, I just had coffee upon coffee, and I’m
just on the road. So I end up doing [. . .] 94 rides that week, and it was actually a short week. It
was 94 rides in essentially 3 days. So [. . .] I didn’t know this, but after you do 90 rides, I think its
90 or 95, they bump you to platinum. So at the time, I got lucky, when it came to timing, because
in the DC/Maryland/Virginia region, they have like an overlay on your Uber map. So they
literally gave me 2.2x every ride I picked up [. . .] that whole week. And then, basically, you’re
always chasing Platinum. So the minute you get it, then you have it for that whole week. So now
you’re motivated to go do another 100 plus or more, just keep going. So at the end of every
week, they’ll send you a text and tell you, “congratulations, you made Platinum.” (Interview
with authors, 9 August, 2016)
1014 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

For drivers unmoved by Uber’s “boosts” the company sought other methods of encour-
agement. One driver we interview named Mark had been driving for Uber for just under a
year. Over the course of that time he made note of what he called “Uber’s McMessages.”
To quote Mark directly:

They send me weekly emails on my earnings: how many trips I did, what the top drivers are
doing. I can benchmark myself in terms of revenue per hour, number of trips per hour, hours
online. They send a lot of what I call McMessages out to drivers, like “It’s raining, get ready
for big demand, have fun!” Or “There’s a [baseball] game tonight!” (Interview with authors,
11 May 2016)

Another driver named Anthony noted the same practice. As Anthony recalled, however,
Uber’s “McMessages” often carried with them a subtle reproach—especially when drivers,
for whatever reason, declined to pick up a passenger.

It’s interesting, they kind of do a little nudge. I don’t think they’re going to quit sending me
fares, but they say, “Oh you could have made more money today!” It doesn’t say how much, but
it does say, “You didn’t accept a fare! You could have more money!” Right, and it’s interesting
because it’s a psychological nudge. It’s saying, hey buddy. . . (Interview with authors,
25 July 2016)

While such messages might be annoying, they hardly elicited the fears so often associated
with yet another one of Uber’s practices—namely the company’s practice of suspending or
deactivating drivers for what they deemed a substandard performance. According to the
drivers we interviewed, one of the most common reasons that Uber might suspend a driver is
in response to their “star rating.” Ranked on a scale of 5 stars, a driver’s star rating is based
on reviews issued by passengers on everything from a driver’s navigation skills to the clean-
liness of the car. As many drivers recalled, a star rating below 4.2 put that them at risk of
deactivation. Uber had a similar policy related to a driver’s acceptance rate. Where drivers
are given the option of either accepting or rejecting a ride-request, too many ride rejections
over a given period might also prompt Uber to issue a suspension. In many ways Uber’s
deactivation policies—although far more punitive—served the same purpose as its use of
“surge pricing” or “boosts.” That purpose: to keep as many drivers working, and on the
platform as possible.
In making sense of Uber’s use of what one driver deemed “carrots and sticks and
incentives and prods and slaps on the hand” (Interview with authors, 11 May 2016) the
work of Sarah Mason (2018) is useful. In her essay “High score, low pay: why the gig
economy loves gamification,” Mason defines gamification as the “use of game elements
[. . .] to increase worker’s psychological investment in completing otherwise uninspiring
tasks.” These elements include: “point scoring, levels, competition with others, measurable
evidence of accomplishment, ratings and rules of play” (2018: 1). Borrowing from the work
of Michael Burroway, Mason argues that the gamification of work not only has the effect of
tapping into a “worker’s desire for self-determination,” but of directing that “desire towards
the production of profit for the employer” (2018: 1). Almost all of the game elements that
Mason identifies as part of the gamification process are a part of how Uber manages its
drivers. In the case of Uber, however, these elements not only direct drivers to work longer
hours, thus producing more data for Uber, but they direct drivers to work in ways that are
inherently isolating and that function to undermine anything approaching collective action
Attoh et al. 1015

(whether that action involves a collective appeal for higher wages, or safer work-
ing conditions).

Working alone
Of the 40 Uber drivers we interviewed, only a small handful had ever met another driver. Of
these same drivers, an even smaller number recalled having anything approaching a mean-
ingful interaction. Of course, given the incentives described above, this is hardly surprising.
There is little about the Uber platform that seems designed to foster collaboration or to
bring drivers together. Indeed, all evidence suggests the opposite. Where drivers are required
to engage in a zero-sum competition for passengers, and where they are rewarded for being
the quickest to respond to a surge bloom, Uber drivers are less likely to see each other as co-
workers than they are too see each other as competitors or, in some instances, as dupes who
haven’t figured the game out yet. A driver we interviewed named Noam argued that the
resulting isolation of drivers was precisely the goal. When we interviewed Noam he had just
moved to Washington, DC from Penang, Malaysia. According to Noam, DC-based Uber
drivers were especially isolated. This, he argued, was intentional:

Well, in the United States, here’s my cynical theory about this. In the United States, because to
be an Uber drivers is to be kind of exploited by Uber, to have them all connected like in Penang
would probably cause them to be easier to unionize, create lawsuits, and put more pressure on
Uber to create employees [. . .]. And so I think that’s probably something they foresaw when they
were planning, when they brought Uber to D.C. or to Baltimore. They said, yeah, we gotta make
sure they don’t know each other, that we just keep funneling them through the farm, so to speak.
(Interview with authors, Noam, 12 May 2016)

While it is hard to verify Noam’s account of Penang, his larger point is an important one. To
the extent that Uber can make sure that drivers “don’t know each other” they, invariably,
limit the possibilities for collective action.11 Mark, whom we quoted earlier, expanded on
this point. Although virulently anti-union, Mark was quick to admit that the very structure
of Uber’s work made such efforts difficult. It was not simply America’s cultural of
“everyman for himself,” as Mark put it, but the platform itself:

. . . there have been attempts at informal strikes, even in the D.C. Market. There was one
organized, and they promoted the heck out of it everywhere, trying to get a strike. But no
one, no other driver knows if you go online or not. It’s not enforceable, you know what I’m
saying? In a steel plant, [. . .] you have to scab, you have to cross a picket line. (Interview with
authors, 11 May 2016)

As Mark argued, the platform nature of the work, and the ability of drivers to log in and log
off anonymously, militates against the very types of collective actions that have long defined
unions and that have long been central to winning improved working conditions. Unlike
picketing a factory, fighting Uber requires picketing an algorithm. More centrally still, the
ability of Uber to surge price, or boost those drivers willing to “scab” poses yet another
barrier to the collective strategies that unions and other groups often rely upon.
Of course, to the degree that Uber has organized work in ways that seem to discourage
collective action, the alienation and antagonisms that define the labor process extend in yet
other directions. Mark’s own story shows precisely this pattern. When we interviewed Mark,
he was 59 years old. A father of four, he lived with his wife in McLean, Virginia. As Mark
1016 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

admitted, his career had been defined by reinvention. Before working as an Uber driver, he
had been a patent lawyer, a founder of a tech firm, and a radio technician. At the time we
interviewed him, he was balancing his work as an Uber driver with a full-time job as a mid-
level manager at a local research firm. When we asked Mark why he drove for Uber, his
response was an interesting one:

I think it was the interplay of several things . . . One was my commute from McLean to
Alexandria is long: 16, 17 miles. So I looked at Uber initially as a way to monetize my commute
. . . And then the second aspect was, my family is tightly budgeted. I mean, I have, as I said,
2 kids at college, 2 in high school. We live in McLean. My wife only works part time. Money is
hard to come by. We rent. We don’t own a house. My tax deductions are limited. And we’re not
exactly paycheck to paycheck, but we have no safety cushion. So I was thinking that this would
be a way to add to my income without really affecting my regular job. (Interview with authors,
11 May 2016)

As with the majority of the drivers we interviewed, Mark had never met another Uber driver
“face to face.” Indeed, Mark seemed rather uninterested in the prospect. As he freely admit-
ted, his own class sensibilities got in the way.

I see them on the streets, and I see them in airport lots, but I don’t have any real interest in
socializing with other Uber drivers. Partly, I think that—and I don’t know this—but partly,
I think that I’m, hmm, how to say this? Overqualified for the job. And my wife’s not completely
comfortable with it, because when I first started doing it, she kept saying, “You’re now a taxi
driver,” and I think she sees that maybe it’s a stereotype that everybody’s an immigrant, without
speaking English, and that kind of thing. (Interview with authors, 11 May 2016)

As Mark tried to make clear, given his background and status, socializing with other drivers
made little sense. Rather than building relations with other drivers, Mark seemed more
interested in shoring up his status with paying passengers. Indeed, one of his few complaints
about Uber was that the company did too little to reward drivers like himself—drivers who
performed at his level.

I think I’m one of the better drivers out there. I really do. I’m experienced, I’ve never been in an
accident in my whole life, I’m a very careful driver. And I’d like to be rewarded for that. I’d like
to have some upward mobility. Not just in, ok [Mark], you’re a VIP driver. But something
substantive that allows for some kind of a status with passengers. (Interview with authors,
11 May 2016)

As much as he enjoyed aspects of the job—especially meeting new people—as the interview
went on, it also became clear that Mark himself was beginning to have misgivings. Not only
did it seem “below” his class position, and not only did his wife disapprove because it took
him away from his family responsibilities, but whatever work-life balance he had struck
before taking up with Uber had largely disappeared. On a normal day, Mark explained, he
worked a 13-hour day—8 hours at his research job and then 5 additional hours as an Uber
driver. After leaving the house at 6 a.m., Mark returned home at 7 p.m. This schedule was
beginning to take a toll.

It’s adversely affected my work life balance, and I don’t do things that I used to do. For
example, I used to study a lot more in my field. I’m not really keeping up as much with my
Attoh et al. 1017

field. Secondly, I used to work longer hours at my current job. I used to work, say 7:30–6, and
now I don’t. Part of that is because I don’t like my current job and the people, I don’t feel like
they like me either. So I’m giving them everything they want but no more than that . . . Before I
started with Uber I used to ride my bike once a week, all the way from McLean to Alexandria.
It’s a long ride. And I really love it. Sometimes I would ride twice a week. But now since I started
Uber-ing, it now costs money if I ride my bike. So I found myself not riding as often . . .
Although I am basically healthy, knock on wood, I think I’m probably not as good aerobic
shape as I was . . . (Interview with authors, 11 May 2016)

While Uber’s impact on Mark’s quality of life was not wholly positive, the prospects of
making money were simply too great. Indeed, when we interviewed Mark in the spring of
2016, those prospects seemed even brighter. Washington, DC was on the cusp of what
would later be labeled the “Metropocalypse.” Following a series of track fires, officials in
DC were mandating extensive upgrades to the entire metro system. The impact on service
was projected to be dire—namely, countless delays and slower commute times. For drivers
like Mark, of course, this was hardly a problem at all. As he noted: “it’s going to be huge for
Uber. There’s nothing like a Metro glitch to send fares spiking.” Mark was not alone in this
belief. Diana, whom we quote earlier in the paper, expressed the same excitement: “I’m
ready . . . I’m so ready . . . I’m going to make so much money. So many customers. It’s going
to be a lot of riders out there, a lot of customers out there. I like when Metro don’t work,
that’s how I make my money” (Interview with authors, 11 May 2016).
Where Uber has organized work in such a way as to encourage a certain degree of
isolation, Mark’s story suggests that some drivers—whether as a result of their own class
sensibilities, or their desire for anonymity—may choose isolation on their own accord.
Mark’s story, however, also points to the ways in which the alienation that seems to char-
acterize the labor process also extends into other realms. Where Mark and other drivers find
themselves gleefully celebrating the potential of a “Metro glitch” because it might send
“fares spiking,” the alienation and isolation evidenced here is not the alienation of an iso-
lated driver from other drivers but the alienation of a driver from the public itself and the
collective good. Of course, perhaps the most significant takeaway from Mark’s story is how
Uber has reshaped his own sense of leisure time—which now appears to him with a price
tag. As Mark admitted: “since I started Uber-ing, it now costs money if I ride my bike.”
Such comments, of course, speak to an alienation directed inward—namely one’s alienation
from one’s own free time, one’s health and from one’s life outside of work. In this feeling,
Mark was hardly alone. Over the course of 40 interviews, stories of drivers working 13 hours
a day, missing meals, and putting themselves in danger were common. With such drivers, as
had been the case with Mark, free time and leisure no longer appeared as escapes from the
drudgery of work, they now appeared as sunk costs, lost wages, and a missed opportunity to
ride the surge or to reach the boost.
Uber has amassed an incredible amount of data on cities, data that cities like
Washington, DC want to put to use. This paper suggests that such smart data cannot be
separated from the laboring conditions described above. These are conditions that, to quote
Noam, keep drivers “funneling through the farm” (Interview with authors, Noam, 12 May
2016). Of course, to talk to any number of drivers, the experience of working for Uber is not
entirely negative. As we learned from our interviews, not only can working for Uber provide
supplemental income, but it can also be quite enjoyable. Even for those who have found joy
in working for Uber, the suspicions of drivers like Noam seem defensible and worth explor-
ing. For Noam, the reality of working for Uber in Washington, DC was a reality defined by
isolation and a lack of connection. For Noam, this was purposeful. By making sure that
1018 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

drivers “don’t know each other” Uber might inoculate itself from attempts by drivers to
unionize, “create lawsuits,” or demand that they be recognized as employees—as opposed to
independent contractors. If the precise degree to which Uber drivers have been atomized is
difficult to measure or verify—our own small sample of 40 drivers notwithstanding—the
design of the Uber platform itself does little to assuage the suspicion that isolation is a
feature rather than a bug. Citing Mason (2018: 1), the design of the Uber platform—
characterized by point scoring, levels, a zero-sum competition with others, and ratings—is
one that remains focused on individualizing work and discouraging anything approaching
collective action. Of course, the isolation that drivers face is certainly never total—see the
recent strike of Uber drivers in Los Angeles (Bhuiyan, 2019). Still, where drivers do establish
connections with other drivers, they often do so in spite of the platform itself. Recalling the
experience of drivers like Mark, we find a platform that not only seems designed to promote
alienation between individual drivers, or between drivers and the collective good, but
between drivers and their own “free time.”12
Returning to Uber Movement, the question remains: what do the above findings mean
for how we think about smart cities, or, how we think about labor in the smart city? In some
ways, the work of Fuchs (2010) and Thatcher et al. (2016) remain central. From their
reading, we might conclude that the smart city—which relies greatly on data collected
from sensors and smart phones—is necessarily a city built on asymmetrical power relations,
data colonialism, and the unpaid labor of people like Mark, Joe and Diana. The experiences
outlined above suggest that such a reading may not be too far off. Where drivers have little
say over the types of data that Uber collects from them, and where they produce such data
even when they are not collecting fare revenue, it is easy to see them, and the smart city to
which their data may serve, in precisely the terms that Fuchs (2010) and Thatcher et al.
(2016) describe. Indeed, to the extent that drivers begin to see their free time as a sunk cost,
Thacher et al.’s (2016) comment on the extension of labor relations into “previously private
times and spaces” seems apt. Of course, the above findings are also useful in making a far
narrower argument. That argument is about the social relations that emerge from the labor
process described above. Moreover, it is an argument about what those social relations
reveal about the type of smart city on offer. As the concluding section suggests, the
nature of that city is best described by turning to Marx and Engels.

Conclusion: The idiocy of the smart city

Social relations are closely bound up with productive forces. In acquiring new productive forces
men change their mode of production and in changing their mode of production, in changing the
way of earning, their living, they change all their social relations. The hand-mill gives you society
with the feudal lord; the steam-mill, society with the industrial capitalist. (Karl Marx, The
Poverty of Philosophy 1966[1847])

Where initiatives like Uber Movement have played directly to those taken by the promise of
the smart city, this paper has suggested that both proponents and critics of the smart city
idea ought to pay attention to the experience of Uber drivers themselves—many of whom
are well aware of their role in producing Uber’s data. The benefits of focusing on the labor
of such drivers are multiple. Not only do observers get a sense of the exploitation and
asymmetrical power relations central to the production of smart data, but they also get a
sense of the social relations that emerge from the production process itself. To look at the
experience of drivers like Joe is, we argue, to get a darker view of the smart city—especially
Attoh et al. 1019

where Uber is involved. Drawing on Marx’s (1966: 95) pithy anecdote from The Poverty of
Philosophy, this last section begins with a question. To the extent that the “hand-mill gives
you society with the feudal lord and the steam-mill, society with the industrial capitalist,”
the question for proponents of the smart city is clear: what type of smart city does the Uber
app give you?13
Based on the above case study, and once again drawing on Marx, one possible answer is
the idiotic city. Writing, as they were, in the midst of the industrial revolution, Marx and
Engels ([1848] 1998) penned their most famous work the Communist Manifesto while witness
to the emergence of enormous cities. Whether it was Manchester or Glasgow, the industrial
city of the 19th century was necessarily one of contradiction. Not only were such cities
defined by the unprecedented accumulation of wealth but also by the creation of unprece-
dented poverty and sprawling slums. For Marx and Engels, the contradictions at the heart
of the industrial city went deeper. If cities were central to the growth of industrial capitalism,
they also held out the promise of its negation through new forms of collective struggle. Part
of that promise rested on what Marx and Engels saw as the inventible role of cities in
rescuing workers from what they termed “the idiocy of rural life.” What Marx and
Engels meant by idiocy was, of course, not that rural life was stupid or dumb, but rather
that rural life was isolating, alienating, and fundamentally apolitical. As Hal Draper (2004:
220) argues in his re-translation of the Manifesto, Marx and Engels were drawing on the
classical meaning of idiocy to denote “privatized isolation.” As Marx and Engels implied, to
the extent that rural life was inherently isolating and apolitical, the city promised just the
opposite. It was in cities, as Engels (1936 [1844]: 122) wrote in The Condition of the English
Working Class, that “workers begin to feel as a class, as a whole” and where their
“consciousness of oppression awakens.” It was in these same cities that workers not only
came face to face with their shared immiseration but with their foreordained role as historic
actors in the fight against economic exploitation. As has been argued elsewhere (Attoh,
2017a, 2017b), the reality of the contemporary city suggests that Marx and Engels may
have been a bit optimistic. Rather than cities that provide a basis for collective class struggle,
we find cities defined by the same privatized isolation that Marx and Engels ascribed to the
country side. From the perspective of drivers like Joe or Mark—drivers who work in relative
isolation and who are incentivized to think of work as a game played against other drivers—
it is this latter city, the idiotic city that seems most resonant.
While Uber Movement has garnered little public attention since its launch, Uber con-
tinues to figure prominently in Washington, DC’s efforts to market itself as a smart city.
In late 2017, Mayor Muriel Bowser chose to highlight Uber as part of #ObviouslyDC
week—a seven-day campaign aimed at highlighting why Washington, DC should be selected
as the site of the new Amazon headquarters (Executive Office of the Mayor, 2017). As that
campaign was clear to note, the city had become “a leader in mobility and smart city
innovation” (ObviouslyDC, 2018). In 2018, Mayor Muriel Bowser joined Uber CEO
Dara Khosrowshahi for a panel discussion on the future of mobility. The panel was held
at Uber’s recently opened Uber Greenlight hub—a brick and mortar resource center for
local Uber drivers. At the event, and once again appealing to local smart city proponents,
Uber announced a “first of its kind partnership.” This partnership would be between Uber,
the city, and National Association of City Transportation Officials. Through the partner-
ship Uber would yield yet additional data to both the District Department of
Transportation and the Department of For Hire Vehicles (DFHV; Executive Office of the
Mayor, 2018). For smart city proponents in Washington, DC, once again, it appeared that
Uber’s data would lead the way.
1020 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

Whether in response to initiatives like Uber Movement, or to Uber’s new partnership


with the DFHV, this paper has emphasized the importance of returning to the comments of
Joe, the Uber driver we interviewed in 2016. As Joe claimed: “we’re building that data for
them, and they have it” (Interview with authors, 19 May 2016). Based on such comments,
we have argued for placing labor more centrally in how we think about smart cities. Where
the work of scholars on platform capitalism (Fuchs, 2010; Sholz, 2012), big data
(Leszczynski, 2016; Thatcher et al., 2016; Tufekci, 2014), and now surveillance capitalism
(Zuboff, 2019) offers one way of thinking about the relationship between labor and data, we
presume that there is equal value in examining the lives of workers like Joe—workers central
to the production of Uber’s smart data. For both critics and proponents of smart cities, the
above case study ought to be illuminating. Not only do we get a sense of the labor that goes
into producing Uber’s “smart data,” but we invariably get a sense of the type of smart city
that emerges. Despite the fears of critics like Hollands (2008) and Kitchin (2014) the city
that emerges from our interviews is as much the panoptic city, the post-political city, and the
corporate city, as it is the idiotic city—one defined by competition, alienation, and priva-
tized isolation. Where the above case study certainly lays the groundwork for further cri-
tiques of the smart city, it also arguably invites us to think about alternatives. Whether those
alternatives are modeled on the smart city experience of cities like Barcelona or Madrid—
cities that have attempted to use the proliferation of sensors and ICTs to expand civic
participation—our paper suggests that labor questions still ought to remain central
(Bakici et al., 2013; Capdevila and Zarlenga, 2015; Gutierrez, 2016). Indeed, part of imag-
ining a smart city that is less isolating, more democratic, and where workers like Joe remain
unalienated from the data they produce requires that we both take seriously the experience
of the workers described above as well the labor process itself.

Acknowledgements
In addition to the helpful guidance of the three reviewers we are also grateful to Don Mitchell, Joaquin
Villanueva, Penny Lewis, and Joe Nevins whose comments and support helped us clarify our argument
and contribution.

Declaration of conflicting interests


The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or
publication of this article.

Funding
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial support for the research, authorship, and/or
publication of this article: The authors received funding from the Kauffman Foundation under
Grant# 2015642.

Notes
1. In 2016, city leaders in DC also touted their relationship with Cisco Technologies—a big player in
the field of smart infrastructure for the same reasons (Chappellet-Lanier, 2016).
2. As Forbes writer Ellen Huet (2015) reported, the extent and scope of Uber’s data dumps often left
much to be desired. As of 2019, the data available to DC planners remain limited to those dealing
with travel times. Also see Siddiqui (2017).
Attoh et al. 1021

3. Where Marx referred to commodity fetishism as the process by which a “definite social relation
between men” takes, in their eyes, “the fantastic form of a relationship between things,” this paper
suggests that the fetishism of the smart city does the same thing – namely, a “definite social
relationship” between people like Joe, assumes, “the fantastic form of a relationship between”
users of data alone (Marx, 1990: 165).
4. For a critique of Fuchs, see the work of Jakob Rigi and Robert Prey (2015).
5. Regarding the economic import of “big data,” the revenue from “big data” and business analytics
are expected to climb from $130 billion in 2016 to $203 billion in 2020. As Forbes contributor Gil
Press writes: “There’s gold in them there mountains of data.” (2017).
6. Of course, by focusing on the experience of drivers alone, we run the risk ignoring the full breadth
of individuals whose labor—paid or unpaid—has gone into the production of Uber’s data. We
miss, for example, the unpaid labor of passengers. Under the framework of scholars like Fuchs
(2010), they too are engaged in digital labor. We have foregrounded the labor of Uber drivers for
two reasons. First, many drivers already understand themselves as engaged workers in an exploit-
ive relationship. This is not true with passengers. Second, drivers play two roles, they are both data
collectors and data producers.
7. For more on these shortcomings see Rob Kitchin’s (2015) paper “Making sense of smart cities:
addressing present shortcomings.”
8. In the interest of confidentiality, all driver names have been replaced by pseudonyms.
9. Based on interviews with some New York City-based driver, Cassano observes that this has been
point of contention for some drivers in New York City who argue that they should be paid for
producing such data.
10. For more on Uber’s “psychological tricks,” see Noam Scheiber (2017).
11. In March 2019, Uber drivers in Los Angeles held a 25-hour strike over pay and working con-
ditions. Such collective actions—and there have been others—suggest that Uber’s power to isolate
workers and individualize work is rarely total (see Bhuiyan, 2019). Also see Nellie Bowles (2016)
on how drivers fight back against isolation.
12. Rather than assuming that something would be different if Uber drivers were less isolated, much
of this paper has rested on a far more modest assumption—namely that conditions of isolation
make the very types of collective action long associated with workplace change less likely.
13. In some ways, this resembles the question posed implicitly by Agnieszka Leszczynski (2016:
1693)—namely “what kind of city [does] big data” anticipate?

References
Andrejevic M (2012) Estranged free labor. In: Sholz T (ed.) Digital Labor: The Internet as Playground
and Factory. London: Routledge, pp. 149–165.
Attoh K (2017a) Public transportation and the idiocy of urban life. Urban Studies 54(1): 196–213.
Attoh K (2017b, September 27) How poor public transit makes idiots of us all. In: USApp – American
Politics and Policy Blog. Available at: http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/usappblog/2017/09/27/how-poor-
public-transit-makes-idiots-of-us-all/ (accessed 16 May 2018).
Bakici T, Almirall E and Wareham J (2013) A smart city initiative: The case of Barcelona. Journal of
the Knowledge Economy 4(2): 135–148.
Bartoli A, Hernández-Serrano J, Soriano M, et al. (2011) Security and privacy in your smart city. In:
Proceedings of the Barcelona smart cities congress. Vol. 292, Barcelona, Spain, December 2011.
Berliner R and Tal G (2018) What drives Your Drivers: An In-depth look at Lyft and Uber Drivers. University
of California Davis: Institute of Transportation Studies. Presentation series UCD ITS PS 19 01.
Bhuiyan J (2019, March 23) I’m really struggling: Facing pay cuts, some ride-hailing drivers prepare
strike. Los Angeles Times. Available at: https://www.latimes.com/business/technology/la-fi-tn-uber-
driver-strike-la-pay-cut-20190323-story.html (accessed 20 April 2019).
Bowles N (2016, February 4) The Uber-loneliness of the sharing economy driver. The Guardian. Available
at: https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2016/feb/04/uber-protest-app-zello-sharing-economy
(accessed 19 April 2019).
1022 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

Calo R (2017) The taking economy: Uber, information and power. Columbia Law Review
112(6): 1623–1690.
Calvey M (2015, February 25) Now Uber rides can help you score a Starwood Hotel stay. San
Francisco Business Times. Available at: https://www.bizjournals.com/sanfrancisco/blog/2015/02/
uber-starwood-hotels-business-travel-hot-loyalty.html (accessed 16 May 2018).
Capdevila I and Zarlenga M (2015) Smart City or smart citizens? The Barcelona case. Journal of
Strategy and Management 8(3): 266–282.
Cassano J (2016, February 2) How Uber profits even while its drivers aren’t earning money.
Motherboard. Available at: https://motherboard.vice.com/en_us/article/wnxd84/how-uber-profits-
even-while-its-drivers-arent-earning-money (accessed 14 April 2019).
Chappellet-Lanier T (2016, October 21) DC is Cisco’s first US ‘Lighthouse City’. TechnicallyDC.
Available at: https://technical.ly/dc/2016/10/21/dc-smart-cities-cisco/ (accessed 15 March 2019).
Colleta C and Kitchin R (2017) Algorythmic governance: Regulating the ‘heartbeat’ of a city using the
Internet of Things. Big Data & Society 4(2): 1–16.
de Kosnik A (2012) Fandom as free labor. In: Sholz T (ed.) Digital Labor: The Internet as Playground
and Factory. London: Routledge, pp. 98–112.
Draper H (2004) The Adventures in the Communist Manifesto. Alameda, CA: Center for
Socialist History.
Dwoskin E and Siddiqui F (2017, January 8) Uber is finally releasing a data trove that officials say will
make driving better for everyone. Washington Post. Available at: https://www.washingtonpost.
com/news/the switch/wp/2017/01/08/uber/?utm_term¼.0d4fe38c48f1 (accessed 16 May 2018).
Engels F (1936[1844]) The Condition of the Working Class in England. London: George Allen and
Unwin LTD.
Executive Office of the Mayor (2017, October 17) Mayor Bowser celebrates Uber Greenlight Hub in
Ward 7 (Press release). Available at: https://mayor.dc.gov/release/mayor-bowser-celebrates-uber-
greenlight-hub-ward-7 (accessed 15 April 2019).
Executive Office of the Mayor (2018, April 11) Mayor Bowser joins Uber CEO to discuss future of
mobility (Press Release). Available at: https://owpi.dc.gov/release/mayor-bowser-joins-uber-ceo-dis
cuss-future-mobility (accessed 15 April 2019).
Fuchs C (2010) Labor in informational capitalism and on the internet. The Information Society
26(3): 179–196.
Fuchs C (2014) Digital Labour and Karl Marx. London: Routledge.
Fuchs C and Sevignani S (2013) What is digital labor? What is digital work? What’s the difference?
And why do these differences matter for understanding social media. Triplec: Communication,
Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society
11(2): 237–293.
Fumagalli A, Lucarelli S, Musolino E and Rocchi G (2018) Digital labour in the platform economy:
The case of Facebook. Sustainability 10(6): 1757.
Greenfield A (2006) Everyware: The Dawning Age of Ubiquitous Computing. Berkeley, CA: New
Riders Publishing.
Greenfield A (2013) Against the Smart City: The City Is Here for You Use. New York, NY: Do Publishers.
Gutierrez B (2016) The open source city as the transnational democratic future. In: Buxton N and
Eade D (eds) State of Power 2016: Democracy, Sovereignty, and Resistance. Amsterdam:
Transnational Institute, pp. 164–182.
Hall J and Krueger A (2015) An analysis of the labor market for Uber’s driver-partners in the United
States. Princeton University, Working Paper No. 587.
Harvey D (2004) The New Imperialism. New York, NY: Oxford University press.
Hendrix S and Aratani L (2013, August 13) Driving for Dollars: Thousands sign up tow work for
UberX and other ridesharing services. Washington Post. Available at: https://www.washingtonpost.
com/local/driving-for-dollars-thousands-sign-up-to-work-for-uberx-and-other-ride-share-services/
2014/04/13/1660cbce-bc07-11e3-9a05-c739f29ccb08_story.html?utm_term¼.446d618444ce (accessed
16 May 2018).
Attoh et al. 1023

Hirson R (2015, March 23) Uber: The Big data company. In: Forbes (tech blog). Available at: https://
www.forbes.com/sites/ronhirson/2015/03/23/uber-the-big-data-company/#75526d5818c7 (accessed
16 May 2018).
Hollands R (2008) Will the real smart city stand-up?. City 12(3): 303–321.
Hollands R (2015) Critical Interventions into the corporate smart city. Cambridge Journal of Regions,
Economy and Society 8(1): 61–77.
Huet E (2015, January 13) Uber hands-over sought after data trip data – On its own terms. Forbes
(online). Available at: https://www.forbes.com/sites/ellenhuet/2015/01/13/uber-boston-city-data/
#179b5a176222 (accessed 16 May 2018).
Humphries C (2013, May 19) The Too-smart city. Boston Globe (ideas section) Available at: https://
www.bostonglobe.com/ideas/2013/05/18/the-too-smart-city/q87J17qCLwrN90amZ5CoLI/story.html
(accessed 16 May 2018).
Iveson K and Maalsen S (2018) Social control in the networked city: Datafied dividuals, disciplined
individuals and powers of assembly. Environment and Planning D 37(2): 331–349.
Kitchin R (2014) The real-time city? Big data and smart urbanism. GeoJournal 79(1): 1–14.
Kitchin R (2015) Making sense of smart cities: Addressing present shortcomings. Cambridge Journal of
Regions, Economy and Society 8(1): 131–136.
Leszczynski A (2016) Speculative futures: Cities, data, and governance beyond smart urbanism.
Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space 48(9): 1691–1708.
Marx K (1966) The Poverty of Philosphy. New York, NY: Progress Publishers.
Marx K (1990) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Vol. 1. Trans. Ben Fowkes. New York,
NY: Penguin.
Marx K and Engels F ([1848] 1998) The Communist Manifesto. New York, NY: Signet Classic.
Mason S (2018, November 20) High score, low pay: Why the gig economy loves gamification. The
Guardian. Available at: https://www.theguardian.com/business/2018/nov/20/high-score-low-pay-
gamification-lyft-uber-drivers-ride-hailing-gig-economy (accessed 20 April 2019).
Newcomb A (2017, January 11) Why Uber is opening up a treasure trove of data. NBC News.
Available at: https://www.nbcnews.com/tech/tech-news/why-uber-opening-treasure-trove-data-
n705461 (accessed 16 May 2018).
ObviouslyDC (2018) #ObviosulyDC Campaign website. Available at: https://www.obviouslydc.com/
access (accessed 20 April 2019).
Office of the Chief Technology (2018) About us: SmarterDC. Washington, DC. Available at: https://
smarter.dc.gov/AboutUs.aspx (accessed 20 April 2019).
Press G (2017, January 20) 6 predictions for the $203 Billion Big Data Analytics Market. In: Forbes
(blog). Available at: https://www.forbes.com/sites/gilpress/2017/01/20/6-predictions-for-the-203-bil
lion-big-data-analytics-market/#c12c4fa20838 (accessed 1 January 2018).
Rigi J and Prey R (2015) Value, rent and the political economy of social media. The Information
Society 31: 392–406.
Rosenblatt A (2018) Uberland: How Algorithms are Rewriting the Rules of Work. Berkeley: University
of California press.
Rosenblatt A and Stark L (2016) Algorithmic labor and information asymmetries: A case study Uber’s
drivers. International Journal of Communication 10(3758–3784).
Scheiber N (2017, April 2) How Uber uses psychological tricks to push its drivers’ buttons.
In: New York Times (Technology Blog). Available at: https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/
2017/04/02/technology/uber-drivers-psychological-tricks.html (accessed 16 May 2018).
Sholz T (2012) Digital Labor: The Internet as Playground and Factory. London: Routledge.
Sennett R (2012, December 4) No one likes a city that is too smart. The Guardian. Available at: http://
www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2012/dec/04/smart-city-rio-songdo-masdar (accessed 16
May 2018).
Shueh J (2017, January 9) Uber launches open data platform revealing city traffic flows. In:
Statescoop. Available at: https://statescoop.com/uber-launches-open-data-platform-revealing-city-
traffic-flows/ (accessed 15 April 2019).
1024 EPD: Society and Space 37(6)

Siddiqui F (2017, January 11) Uber’s new tool is a glimpse of how much it knows about cities. Planners
want the full picture. Washington Post. Available at: https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/dr-
gridlock/wp/2017/01/11/ubers-new-tool-is-a-glimpse-of-how-much-it-knows-about-cities-planners-
want-the-full-picture/?utm_term¼.ecf0352f86d9 (accessed 16 May 2018).
Soderstrom O, Paasche T and Klauser F (2014) Smart Cities as corporate storytelling. City
18(3): 307–320.
Thatcher J, O’Sullivan D and Mahmoudi D (2016) Data colonialism through accumulation by dis-
possession: New metaphors for daily data. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space
34(6): 990–1006.
Townsend A (2013) Smart Cities: Big Data, Civic Hackers, and the Quest for a New Utopia. New York,
NY: W.W. Norton & Co.
Tufekci Z (2014) Engineering the public: Big data, surveillance and computational politics. First
Monday 19(7).
Vanolo A (2014) Smartmentality: The smart city as disciplinary strategy. Urban Studies 51(5): 883–889.
Van Zoonen L (2016) Privacy concerns and smart cities. Government Information Quarterly
33(3): 472–480.
Why HPC Matters: Smart Cities (2017) CIO Magazine (Online). Available at: https://www.cio.com/
article/3256282/analytics/is-your-city-smart-enough.html (accessed 16 May 2018).
Wiig A (2016) The empty rhetoric of the smart city: From digital inclusion to economic promotion in
Philadelphia. Urban Geography 37(4): 535–553.
Wiig A and Wyly E (2016) Introduction: Thinking through the politics of the smart city. Urban
Geography 37(4): 485–493.
Zook M (2013) Crowd-sourcing the smart city: Using big geosocial media metrics in urban gover-
nance. Big Data and Society. https://doi.org/10.1177/2053951717694384
Zuboff S (2019) The Age of Surveillance Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at the New Frontier
of Power. New York, NY: Public Affairs.

Kafui Attoh is an Assistant Professor at the CUNY School for Labor and Urban Studies.

Katie Wells is an Urban Studies Foundation Postdoctoral Research Fellow at Georgetown


University’s Kalmanovitz Initiative for Labor and the Working Poor.

Declan Cullen is a Visiting Professor in the Department of Geography at The George


Washington University.

You might also like