You are on page 1of 16

J PROD INNOV MANAG 2010;27:725–740

r 2010 Product Development & Management Association

A Longitudinal Study of the Impact of R&D, Patents, and Product


Innovation on Firm Performance
Kendall W. Artz, Patricia M. Norman, Donald E. Hatfield, and Laura B. Cardinal

Because of increasing levels of competition and decreasing product life cycles, a firm’s ability to generate a con-
tinuous stream of innovations may be more important than ever in allowing a firm to improve profitability and
maintain competitive advantage This paper investigates several issues that are central to an examination of the
innovation productivity in a firm. First, the relationship between a firm’s commitment to research and development
and its innovative outcomes is examined. Two innovative outcomes are analyzed: (1) invention, which focuses on the
development of new ideas; and (2) innovation, the development of commercially viable products or services from
creative ideas. Invention is measured by the number of patents granted, and innovation is assessed by the number of
new product announcements. Second, because many inventions ultimately result in marketable innovations and
because patents may provide protection for new products, the relationship between patents and product announce-
ments is also investigated. Finally, the ability of a firm to benefit from its inventions and innovations is studied by
examining their separate effects on firm performance, measured as return on assets (ROA) and sales growth.
Drawing from a sample of 272 firms in 35 industries over 19 years, the results from a model of simultaneous
equations provided support for some of the hypotheses, but several other surprising findings were found. As expected,
R&D spending was positively related to patents. This finding is consistent with others who argue that internal
research capabilities, particularly those with a strong basic research component, is key to enabling a firm to generate
creative outputs. More surprising was the finding of increasing returns to scale to R&D spending. While this con-
tradicts much of the existing research, it is consistent with economic arguments for the advantages of scale in
innovation. Also interesting is the finding that, while a significant curvilinear relationship exists between R&D
spending and product announcements, it is not the predicted inverse-U but instead a U-shaped relationship. Con-
sistent with previous work, product announcements were found to be positively related to both performance mea-
sures. A negative relationship was found between patents and both ROA and sales growth. While these findings were
unexpected, they are intriguing and call into question the value of patents as protection mechanisms. In addition,
these results may be resulting from the rise of strategic patenting, where an increasing number of firms are using
patents as strategic weapons. As expected, a positive relationship was found between patents and new product
announcements.

Introduction innovation may be transitory (Greenhalgh and Lon-


gland, 2005). Conversely, a relatively rapid stream of

T
he ability of firms to develop and exploit their multiple innovations over time may enable the firm to
innovative capabilities is widely recognized as continue to generate high levels of profitability (Bar-
a critical determinant of firm performance czak, 1995; Roberts, 1999). For these reasons, effec-
and competitive advantage (Bettis and Hitt, 1995; tive management of the innovation process continues
Helfat and Peteraf, 2003; Voss, 1994). A firm’s abil- to be a focal concern for managers and business
ity to generate a continuous stream of innovations researchers (Bogner and Bansal, 2007; Marsh and
may be more important than ever in allowing a firm to Stock, 2003).
develop or maintain competitive advantage because of In this paper, several issues are investigated that are
the increasing levels of competition and decreasing central to an examination of the innovation produc-
product life cycles. In an environment whereby com- tivity in a firm. First, the relationship between a firm’s
petition is intense, the profits generated by any one commitment to research and development and its in-
novative outcomes is examined. In evaluating a firm’s
Address correspondence to: Kendall W. Artz, Hankamer School of innovative activities, it is recognized that the literature
Business, Baylor University, One Bear Place #98006, Waco, TX 76798-
8006. Tel.: (254) 710-4169. Fax: (254) 710-1093. E-mail: Kendall_
has differentiated between invention and innovation,
Artz@Baylor.edu. and thus both forms of innovation outcomes are in-
726 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

vestigated. Grant (2008, pp. 290–91) defines an inven- number of patents granted, is tested. A separate ex-
tion as distinct from an innovation: ‘‘Invention is the amination investigates the relationship between R&D
creation of new products and processes through the spending and a measure of innovation, the number of
development of new knowledge or the combination of new product announcements. Moreover, because
existing knowledge . . . . Innovation is the initial com- many inventions ultimately result in marketable in-
mercialization of invention by producing and market- novations and because patents may provide protec-
ing a good or service or by using a new method of tion for new products, the relationship between
production.’’ patents and product announcements is investigated.
Consistent with Grant (2008) and others (e.g., Hitt, Finally, the ability of a firm to benefit from its inven-
Hoskisson, and Nixon, 1993; Schumpeter, 1934), the tions and innovations is analyzed by examining their
definition of invention used here focuses on the de- separate effects on firm performance.
velopment of new ideas, whereas innovations are con- Although a number of previous studies have ex-
sidered the development of commercially viable amined some of the relationships investigated in this
products or services from creative ideas. Because in- paper, this analysis examines each of these relation-
vention and innovation represent different dimensions ships in a set of simultaneous equations rather than as
of creative outputs, the impact of research and devel- separate analyses. Estimating a set of simultaneous
opment (R&D) spending on each is analyzed sepa- equations allows researchers to model a more com-
rately. Specifically, the relationship between a firm’s plex set of relationships between variables than can be
R&D spending and one measure of its inventions, the modeled using one equation. Thus, this analysis yields
new insight into the ultimate impact of a firm’s inno-
vative investments and activities on firm performance.
BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCHES
Furthermore, for each of the individual relation-
Dr. Kendall Artzis professor at Baylor University. He is currently
serving as chair of the Department of Management and Entrepre-
ships studied, numerous gaps in the existing literature
neurship and as director of the Baylor Entrepreneurship Program. are addressed. For example, as Ahuja and Lampert
He has a B.S. in Finance from Montana State University, an (2001) point out, studies that examine inventions as
M.B.A. from Arizona State University, and a Ph.D. in strategic
management from Purdue University. His current research interests
an outcome of a commitment to R&D spending are
are in the area of corporate entrepreneurship, managing innovation, rare. Moreover, though numerous studies discuss the
and strategic alliances. managerial and organizational aspects for enhancing
Dr. Patricia Norman is associate professor of management in the new product development (e.g., Calantone, Garcia,
Department of Management and Entrepreneurship at Baylor Uni- and Droge, 2003; Hoopes and Postrel, 1999; Peterson,
versity. She has a B.A. in economics from the University of Penn-
Handfield, and Ragatz, 2005; Scott, 2000), little
sylvania, an M.S. in management from the Air Force Institute of
Technology, and a Ph.D. in strategic management from the Uni- empirical research exists that directly examines the
versity of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. Her research interests in- relationship between R&D spending and the number
clude innovation, strategic alliances, and downsizing. of new product introductions. The studies that have
Dr. Donald E. Hatfield is associate professor at Virginia Polytech- been conducted (e.g., Langowitz and Graves, 1992;
nic Institute and State University (Virginia Tech). He has a B.S. in McMillan, Mauri, and Hamilton, 2003) focused only
chemical engineering from Iowa State University, an M.B.A. from
the University of Iowa, and a Ph.D. in strategic management from
on the pharmaceutical industry, and thus the broad
the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA). Dr. Hatfield’s applicability of these studies is limited.
research has examined innovation, technology strategy, interna- It is also interesting to note that, although there are
tional management, and corporate-level strategy. He is currently on
the editorial boards of Academy of Management Journal, Organi-
convincing theoretical arguments suggesting a close
zation Science and Journal of Management. relationship between the issuance of patents and new
Dr. Laura Cardinal is professor of strategic management in the C.T.
product introductions, little recent empirical research
Bauer College of Business at the University of Houston. She earned validates this relationship. This gap in the literature is
her Ph.D. from the University of Texas at Austin. Her areas of particularly notable given the significant change in
expertise include managing innovation and research and develop-
patenting practices that has occurred over the past
ment (R&D) capabilities, diversification and performance, and
understanding the evolution and adaptation of control systems. two decades (MacDonald, 2004). Finally, while it ap-
She serves on the editorial boards of Organization Science and pears to be well established that new product intro-
Strategic Management Journal. Previously, she served as the chair ductions tend to positively impact firm performance
for the Competitive Strategy Interest Group of the Strategic
Management Society and as chair for the Technology and Innova-
(e.g., Cho and Pucik, 2005; Hua and Wemmerlov,
tion Management Division of the Academy of Management. 2006; Roberts, 1999), findings about the relationship
between a firm’s inventions (i.e., patents) and firm
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 727
2010;27:725–740

performance have been mixed. While some research- partments is one of the key predictors of a firm’s
ers (e.g., Cho and Pucik) have argued and empirically ability to generate inventive outputs (Cardinal and
validated that patents have a positive effect on firm Hatfield, 2000).
performance effective, others suggest that no relation- R&D spending and its outcomes have long been
ship exists (e.g., MacDonald). explored by economists in empirical studies (e.g.,
The present study attempts to address the previ- Mansfield, 1962). In general, this research has found
ously identified shortcomings. It does so by empiri- a positive impact of R&D spending on firm outcomes.
cally examining these research issues using For example, both Mansfield (1980) and Griliches
longitudinal data from a cross-industry study of 272 (1986) found that a commitment to R&D spending
firms over a recent 19-year period (1986–2004). Since was positively related to a firm’s innovative ability as
multiple industries are represented, controls for in- reflected in its productivity growth. Other researchers
dustry effects are included in the empirical analysis. have more directly examined the relationship between
This paper is structured as follows. The next section R&D spending and patenting practices, the measure
describes in greater detail the theoretical arguments of invention used in this study. In their seminal re-
concerning the framework that is developed and search across a broad range of firms and industries,
tested. The sample and methodology is then dis- Pakes and Griliches (1984) and Bound et al. (1984)
cussed. Finally, the results and conclusions from the found a strong relationship between R&D spending
study are presented. and the number of patents—results later confirmed by
Hall et al. (1986). Jensen (1987) found that the level of
R&D spending was key to determining that rate of
new drug discoveries, and in their study of the phar-
Theory and Hypotheses
maceutical industry Cardinal and Hatfield (2000)
The Influence of R&D Spending on Innovation found that firms with a greater emphasis on R&D
Outputs spending were more productive generating inventions,
as measured by patents, than firms with lower levels of
The commitment to developing the capabilities nec- R&D spending. A strong correlation between R&D
essary to generate and accumulate internal knowledge spending and patents has also been found in the
has been identified as a crucial factor in leveraging chemical (Ahuja and Katila, 2001) and computer
firm learning processes (Chiesa, 1996; Helfat and Pet- (Hagedoorn and Duysters, 2002) industries. More re-
eraf, 2003). Firms must also be able to understand cently, in their study of 150 manufacturing and service
and use the knowledge created if it is ever to be trans- firms, Peeters and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie
formed into an invention that can result in a market- (2006) found that firms that devote greater effort to
able product (Greenhalgh and Longland, 2005). basic and applied research experience higher levels of
Internal research capabilities, as indicated by a firm’s patenting.
commitment to funding R&D, enable a firm to create, Whereas the previous results support predications
understand, and use knowledge (Penner-Hahn and for a positive effect of R&D spending on the level of
Shaver, 2005). As stated by Hall, Griliches, and firm invention as measured by its patenting activity,
Hausman (1986, p. 265), ‘‘The annual research and others have suggested that the relationship between a
development expenditures of a firm are considered firm’s commitment to R&D spending and patenting
to be investments which add to a firm’s stock of activity is more nuanced and complex and theorize
knowledge.’’ In addition, strong R&D spending that firms experience decreasing returns to their R&D
capabilities not only play a direct role in creating spending (Acs and Audretsch, 1990). One explanation
the internal knowledge needed for product innovation for the possible diseconomies of size for invention is
but also allow evaluation of potential outcomes of the that the decision making, coordination, and resource
knowledge created (Rosenberg, 1990). Moreover, a allocation processes in large firms are more inefficient
strong set of internal competencies in research than in small firms. Thus, each additional dollar of
and development allows the evaluation and use of research yields less in the way of creative outputs
knowledge created outside the firm. Thus, the firms (Adams and Brock, 1986). As firms age, they tend to
can access knowledge in the public domain and become more conservative as the influence of the
bring that into the firm and use it to create new prod- group of founding entrepreneurs is diminished and
ucts. As such, the capability residing in research de- replaced by professional managers, ultimately making
728 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

it more difficult for truly inventive ideas to emerge link between R&D spending and the successful intro-
(Graves and Langowitz, 1993). Managers also face duction of new products, the ability of a firm to con-
increasing time demands overseeing existing product tinue to grow and develop is unlikely (Nerkar and
lines and, as a result, devote less time to developing Roberts, 2004).
new products. The reduction in the amount of ‘‘en- Empirical evidence supports the idea that a link
trepreneurial attention’’ (Acs and Gifford, 1996, exists between a firm’s R&D spending and the number
p. 216) devoted to creating new inventions has been of new products introduced in the market. In their
found to constrain the overall innovative capability study of 250 firms in the United States, Hitt et al.,
of larger firms. These arguments are supported by (1996) found that a firm’s level of R&D spending was
empirical research that finds declining innovative positively correlated with its new product announce-
productivity with respect to R&D. Both Cohen and ments, and Zahra (1993) found that a strategy that
Klepper (1996) and Acs and Audretsch (1990) dem- emphasized growth through internal commitment to
onstrated that productivity in innovation tends to de- R&D spending was positively related to the number
cline with firm size. Also, Graves and Langowitz of new product introductions. McMillan et al. (2003)
found evidence that increasing levels of R&D spend- examined the U.S. pharmaceutical industry and found
ing was counterproductive in terms of innovative out- that a firm’s R&D spending was a significant predic-
put in the pharmaceutical industry, and Jensen (1987) tor of the number of new products it developed. Sim-
found that firm size was not related to marginal in- ilarly, Langowitz and Graves (1992) found a positive
novative productivity. Consistent with this empirical relationship between R&D spending and new prod-
evidence, the following hypotheses posits a positive ucts in the pharmaceutical industry.
relationship between R&D spending and invention— Consistent with these earlier studies, this study ex-
as measured by patents (Ahuja and Lampert, 2001; pects to find that greater spending on R&D should
Pakes, 1985). However, it is recognized that this rela- translate into the development of a greater number of
tionship may not be so straightforward and indeed products. It is also anticipated that, just as was pre-
that returns to R&D spending may decline as spend- dicted in the relationship between R&D spending and
ing rises: patents, the relationship between R&D spending and
new product announcements will be nonlinear. This
H1a: R&D spending is positively related to the
nonlinear prediction is supported by some empirical
number of firm patents.
work. For example, Audretsch and Acs (1991) exam-
H1b: Firms experience decreasing returns to R&D
ined 1,700 U.S. firms and found a U-shaped relation-
spending with respect to the number of firm
ship between firm size and innovative activity,
patents.
measured as the number of new product introduc-
Much as R&D spending is expected to stimulate tions. In addition, Tsai (2005) found a U-shaped re-
firm invention, it is also anticipated that it will result lationship between R&D productivity, measured as
in more innovation, as measured by new product an- R&D output elasticity, and firm size, and Peeters and
nouncements. While a firm’s R&D spending is ex- van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie (2006) found the re-
pected to stimulate inventive activity, for many firms lationship between firm age and innovation activity to
its primary purpose is to develop inventions that are be U-shaped in their examination of 1,300 Belgian
transformed into commercializable products. This firms. While none of these studies directly examine the
centrality of R&D spending to new product develop- focal variables that are of interest here, they do sug-
ment is noted by Penner-Hahn and Shaver (2005, p. gest the likelihood of a nonlinear relationship in an
123) who state that ‘‘firms undertake R&D activities examination between commitment to R&D spending
in large part to create innovations that will ultimately and innovative output.
provide new products and therefore profits.’’ While More directly related to this study, both Acs and
the effectiveness of innovation for a firm depends on Audretsch (1987, 1988) and Graves and Langowitz
the technological capabilities that reside in its research (1993) found that increasing R&D spending yields
and development function, successful innovation is decreasing returns as measured by the number of new
not guaranteed (Tsai, 2005). A firm may have ‘‘great products. Similar to the arguments leading to H1b,
technological and inventive potential, but be relatively these researchers suggest that as R&D spending in-
unsuccessful in the commercialization of its product’’ creases so do bureaucracy and inefficiency, thus re-
(Fleming, 2002, p. 1064). In the absence of a strong ducing creativity and slowing efforts to introduce new
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 729
2010;27:725–740

products to market. Related to this, they argue that H3: Patents are positively related to product
the most talented and creative individuals can become announcements.
frustrated with their lack of autonomy in large re-
search and development operations and may leave for
smaller, less bureaucratic firms. Drawing from these
arguments, it is anticipated that R&D spending will The Relationship between Innovation Outputs and
increase new product announcements, although these Performance
returns will decrease with increased R&D. Stated
more formally: It is important to understand how a firm’s R&D
spending is related to its innovative activities (i.e., in-
H2a: R&D spending is positively related to new ventions and product introductions) as well as the re-
product announcements. lationship between inventions and production
H2b: Firms experience decreasing returns to R&D innovations. However, for a firm to improve its com-
spending with respect to product announcements. petitive position those outputs must also have a ben-
eficial effect on firm performance.
While R&D spending is directed at both inventions Theoretically, product innovations may allow the
and innovations, there are also links between a firm’s innovator to at least briefly earn monopoly profits
inventions and its product innovations. Researchers (Lieberman and Montgomery, 1988; Schumpeter,
have pointed out that invention is an important an- 1950). As innovative new products are introduced to
tecedent of new product development (Trajtenberg, the market, they initially face little direct competition
1990) and may play a role in stimulating further in- and are able to generate high profits. However, the
novative activity (Mazzoleni and Nelson, 1998; Rai, relatively high profits attract other firms, thus increas-
2001). By imposing a legal restriction on the use of ing competition and over time reducing profits. While
new knowledge embedded in new inventions, patents Schumpeter argues that the return from innovative
have generally been viewed as a valid instrument to new products will initially be high before tapering off,
allow inventors to recover the cost of their creative firm-level profits may not follow the same course. In-
efforts and to encourage the introduction of new deed, while high profits from any single innovation
products (Encaoua, Guellec, and Martinez, 2006). It may be transitory, relatively high firm-level profits
should be recognized, however, that because of the may persist over time if a firm can successfully intro-
expense involved not all inventions are patented. duce a stream of new products. In effect, a series of
Moreover, not all inventions that are patented will monopoly profits are earned by a firm if it is able to
result in marketable products, as the potential eco- regularly introduce new and innovative products
nomic significance of patented products varies signifi- (Montgomery, 1995).
cantly. Firms are more likely to patent inventions that The argument for a positive relationship between
demonstrate potential to be commercially exploited. firm innovativeness and performance has been gener-
Therefore, a link is expected to exist between firm ally validated in numerous studies. For example, in
patenting propensity and the products it ultimately his study of firms in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry,
brings to market (Ernst, 2001). Roberts (1999) found that the innovative propensity
Empirical investigations into the relationship be- of a firm positively influences the degree to which
tween the number of patents held by a firm and the above-average profits (return on assets; ROA) persist
number of new products that it introduces have largely over time, and in their examination of biotechnology
supported a positive association. McMillan et al. firms DeCarolis and Deeds (1999) found a positive
(2003) found that the number of patents a firm con- relationship between the number of products that
trolled was positively related to its development of new biotechnology firms had in their pipeline and market
products. While supporting the overall positive link valuation on the day of an initial public offering. Cho
between patents and new products, the fact that their and Pucik (2005) argue that firm innovativeness is
study was limited to the pharmaceutical industry raises positively related to firm growth and firm profitabil-
questions concerning the generalizability of their find- ity. Their empirical examination analysis of Fortune
ings. Therefore, the present study examines the same 1000 firms supported their argument. More recently,
question but broadens the context and applicability of Hua and Wemmerlov (2006) examined the relation-
the findings through the multi-industry sample. ship between the rate of new product introduction and
730 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

performance. Their examination of the personal com- While these theoretical arguments and empirical
puter industry confirmed a positive relationship be- evidence suggest that patents can have a positive im-
tween rate of new product introduction and pact on firm performance, there is also considerable
performance, thus providing support for the argu- evidence that in many contexts patents do not work in
ment that firms introducing a consistent stream of practice as well as they do in theory. In two well-
innovative products to the market can achieve sus- known studies conducted in 1983 and 1994 (i.e., the
tained levels of high performance. ‘‘Yale’’ and ‘‘Carnegie Mellon’’ studies), patents were
While these studies have focused on manufacturing reported by R&D managers in semiconductors to be
firms in the U.S. market, other researchers have con- among the least effective mechanisms for appropriat-
firmed the innovation–performance link in other con- ing the returns from R&D spending (Hall and Ziedo-
texts. For example, in their research of service firms in nis, 2001; Levin et al., 1987). Other researchers have
Greece and Australia, Salavou (2002) and Prajogo suggested that, although it is feasible for patents to
(2006) found that product innovation was an impor- play an important role in improving firm perfor-
tant determinant of firm growth and profitability. mance, this positive relationship is actually observed
Moreover, other research has also confirmed that in only a relatively small number of industries. For
more innovative firms tend to have higher perfor- example, Mansfield (1986) examined the patenting
mance (Geroski, Machin, and Van Reenan, 1993; practices of U.S. manufacturing firms and found
Klette, 1996; Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001; Price, that patents were important to innovation perfor-
1996; Wheelwright and Clark, 1995). mance in a limited number of industries such as phar-
maceuticals and chemicals but that patents were
H4: Product announcements are positively related to relatively unimportant in other sectors such as elec-
performance. trical products, primary metals, instruments, and the
like. Griliches, Hall, and Pakes (1991) examined the
While this research suggests that innovation output patenting practices of 340 U.S. firms in influencing a
can enable a firm to improve performance, it does not firm’s change in market value and found that patent
necessarily follow that the firm will capture all of the variables have virtually no influence on performance.
potential benefits from the innovation (Anton and Additional support was provided by Arora, Ceccag-
Yao, 2004; Teece, 1996). The appropriability of an noli, and Cohen (2003). Using the data from the Car-
innovation is also determined by the effectiveness of negie Mellon survey, they found that the additional
legal protection mechanisms such as patents. While return associated with a patented versus an unpat-
approved patents vary widely in their significance, ented invention was positive in only a few industries
patents have generally been regarded as a useful in- such as drugs and biotechnology.
strument to grant inventors temporary exclusionary There are numerous explanations given for patent
rights and allow them to recapture the value of their ineffectiveness in improving firm performance. These
development efforts (Bogner and Bansal, 2007; En- explanations frequently include the fact that patents
caoua et al., 2006). Indeed, firms often seek patents as can often be invented around relatively cheaply and
soon as feasible in the product development process in that the cost of upholding their validity or proving
an effort to delay the ability of competitors to imitate that the patent had been infringed upon is too high
the product and therefore to extend the period of time (Encaoua et al., 2006; Teece, 1996). For these reasons,
the original inventor can earn abnormal profits (Lee et the patent system may serve a few industries such as
al., 2000; McMillan et al., 2003). Some empirical ev- pharmaceuticals well. However, for firms in other in-
idence does exist supporting the contention that a dustries, particularly small firms, the beneficial effect
firm’s patenting activities are related to its perfor- of patenting on performance is elusive (MacDonald,
mance. For example, in his study of the German ma- 2004).
chine tool industry, Ernst (2001) found evidence that Moreover, some researchers argue that the intent
patents are effective instruments for protecting tech- of patenting for many firms has evolved so that the
nological inventions and have a positive impact on goal of patenting is no longer simply to encourage
firm sales. Mann and Sager (2007) also found that innovation by allowing inventors a temporary mo-
patenting in small software firms is positively corre- nopoly from which to earn a return on their invest-
lated with firm longevity, although they did not di- ments. There has been a large increase in the number
rectly examine any performance metrics. of U.S. patents over the past two decades (Cohen,
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 731
2010;27:725–740

Nelson, and Walsh, 2000; Ziedonis, 2004). Nonethe- to firms that reported at least $10 million in R&D
less, the intent of many of these new patents is not spending during the first five years of the time span
necessarily to protect a firm’s own innovation efforts studied. This provides a sample of 272 firms for 19
but rather to play a more strategic role in firm com- one-year periods.
petitiveness. Such practices as patent stacking (Heller
and Eisenberg, 1998), clustering (Rivette and Kline,
2000), and network arrangements (Kretschmer and Measures
Soetendorp, 2001) are responsible for a significant
portion of the increase in patents but have little to do Research and Development. Firm expenditures on
with encouraging a firm’s own innovation and much research and development each year were measured
to do with blocking a competitor’s innovation efforts using data from COMPUSTAT.
(MacDonald, 2004). It has also been suggested that,
because of the increased strategic importance of pat- Innovative Activity. Two measures of innovation
ents as a competitive tool, a significant amount of activity were used. The first measure, which represents
patenting may be defensive in nature, where patents inventions by a firm, was the number of patents
are taken out solely to preempt a competitor working granted to a firm each year. Patent data were gath-
in an area. This role of patents as ‘‘competitive posi- ered from the National Bureau of Economic Research
tioning’’ mechanisms, combined with courts expand- (NBER) Patent Citation Data Files (Hall, Jaffe, and
ing what can be patented, forces many firms to patent Trajtenberg, 2001) and the Patents BIB from the U.S.
things they normally would not and has little imme- Patents and Trademark Office (NBER Patent Cita-
diate impact on firm performance (ibid.). tion Data Files can be accessed at http://www.nber.-
Therefore, although a positive link between org/patents/, and information about Patent BIB can
patents and new product announcements efforts is be found at http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/cio/cis/
hypothesized, it is less clear that there is a direct prodsvc.htm). The second measure representing prod-
relationship between a firm’s patenting practices and uct innovation efforts by a firm was the number of
its performance. As Hall and Ham (1999, p. 9) state, new product announcements each year. These data
‘‘The reasons that patents are important often has were gathered from Factivia (a Dow Jones & Reuters
little to with whether patents provide an incentive to Company providing full-text access to more than
conduct R&D or enable the firm to profit from the 9,000 magazines, trade journals, newspapers, and
generation of products on which the invention was newswires as well as company and industry reports
based.’’ Based on the previous discussion, patents and websites) and was checked against the older F&S
are not expected to be a significant predictor of firm Predicast new product announcement data. The an-
performance: nouncements are introductions, reviews, previews, or
announcements of a new product or service. They do
H5: Patents are not directly related to performance. not include products still in the early developmental
stages or the opening of new facilities such as factories
or retail stores. The count is only for unique
Methods announcements.

The present study traces the R&D spending, patents, Performance. Because performance is a multidi-
new product announcements, and performance of a mensional construct (Murphy, Trailer, and Hill,
panel of firms. Performance outcomes are tracked 1996), two different aspects of firm performance in
from 1986 through 2004, and other measures are this study are measured: returns and growth. Innova-
lagged. The corporations for this study are drawn tive activities in firms should increase returns as well
from COMPUSTAT North America, a database of as stimulate growth. The first measure reported here,
financial information on U.S. and Canadian publicly after-tax ROA, is a measure of current returns. While
held companies. discussions concerning appropriate measures of firm
To minimize reporting problems that are often as- profitability are widespread (e.g., Scherer and Ross,
sociated with R&D spending in COMPUSTAT 1990; Venkatraman and Ramanujam, 1986), ROA is
(Bound et al., 1984) and to focus on larger firms a widely used profitability measure in innovation
with material R&D expenses, the sample was limited studies (Roberts and Amit, 2003; Sher and Yang,
732 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

2005) and captures the ability of a firm to develop model at one time. To control for multiple observa-
profits from its asset or investment base (no matter tions per firm, firm dummy variables were included in
whether the source of the investment was equity or each equation. Dummy variables were also added to
debt). In addition, the extent to which a firm’s inno- control for the year(t). The equations tested are as
vative activities are stimulating revenue growth is as- follows:
sessed by measuring average sales growth over a
three-year period. Data for both performance mea- PerformanceðtÞ ¼ B0 þ B1ðPatentsðt  2ÞÞ
sures were obtained from COMPUSTAT. þB2ðProduct Announcementsðt  1ÞÞ
þB3ðFirm SizeÞ þ B4ðPerformanceðt  1ÞÞ
Industry Controls. While patents may play a key
þIndustry Controls þ Firm Dummies
role in protecting a firm’s output stemming from its
þYear Dummies þ Error Term
innovative activity, researchers have also argued that
patents play a more important protection role in some
industries (e.g., chemical products, pharmaceuticals)
than in others (e.g., motor vehicles, rubber and tex- Product Announcementsðt  1Þ ¼ B0 þ B1ðPatentsðt  2ÞÞ
tiles) (Arora et al., 2003; Bettis and Hitt, 1995; þB2ðR&Dðt  3ÞÞ
Comanor and Scherer, 1969; MacDonald, 2004; þB3ðR&Dðt  3ÞÞ2
Mansfield, 1986). þIndustry Controls
A total of 35 industries classified by primary two- þFirm Dummies
digit standard industrial classification (SIC) codes are
þYear Dummies þ Error Term
in the sample. The majority of innovation activity is
clustered in just nine industries. These industries ac-
count for 91% of the total product announcements
and 83% of the total patents during the time period Patentsðt  2Þ ¼ B0 þ B1ðR&Dðt  3ÞÞ
studied. These nine industries and their respective þB2ðR&Dðt  3ÞÞ2 þ Industry Controls
two-digit SIC are food and kindred products (20), þFirm Dummies þ Year Dummies
paper and allied products (26), chemicals and allied
products (28), fabricated metals (34), industrial and þError Term
commercial machinery and computer equipment (35),
electronic, electrical equipment and components (36), Note that R&D spending was lagged by three years,
measurement/analyzing/control instruments, trans- patents by two years, and product announcements by
portation equipment (37), photographic/medical/op- one year. Lags among R&D spending, innovation ac-
tical goods, watches/clocks (38), and business services tivities, and performance are common in innovation
(73). Dummy variables for each of these industries studies (e.g., Ernst, 2001; Langowitz and Graves, 1992;
were included in the models tested. Masayuki, 1999). These lags were chosen because of
previous findings. For example, Ernst found that pat-
Firm Size. Firm size was initially used as a control ents had a two- to three-year lag in their effect on sales.
variable. However, R&D spending and firm size were Each of the performance measures in the study—ROA
significantly correlated (r 5 0.75). Thus, because of and sales growth—was used as the dependent variable
multicollinearity problems, firm size was dropped in separate regression analyses. Time-series regressions
when R&D spending was included in an equation. were also run to test the relationships between R&D
and each of the two indicators of innovative activities,
patents and product announcements. However, time-
Data Analysis series analysis did not allow all equations to be simul-
taneously tested. The relationships between R&D and
Several of the variables, including patents, products, patents and between R&D and product announce-
and R&D, were transformed because of error term ments in these regressions are consistent with findings
skewness problems. The model suggests a more com- from the 3SLS models reported here. A one-year
plex relationship than can be modeled using multiple lagged performance in each model was also included
regression models. Therefore, a three-stage least because a firm’s current performance depends to some
squares (3SLS) analysis was used to test the complete extent on its past performance.
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 733
2010;27:725–740

Results to be negatively associated with both ROA and sales


growth. Firm size was not related to ROA but was
The correlation matrix is shown in Table 1. Product positively related to sales growth. In each model,
announcements and patents are positively correlated, lagged performance was significantly related to cur-
which is not surprising given that both are indicators rent performance.
of a firm’s innovative activities. Similarly, R&D
spending is positively correlated with both product
announcements and patents. Not surprisingly, the two Discussion
performance measures—ROA and sales growth—are
positively correlated. The primary purpose of this paper was to explore the
Tables 2a and 2b contain the results of the struc- relationship between a firm’s R&D spending and its
tural models tested using 3SLS regressions. The first outputs in terms of inventions and innovations and
model (Table 2a) examines ROA as the outcome the impact of those outputs on firm performance.
variable in the third equation of the analysis. The Several of the results support previous empirical find-
second model (Table 2b) examines three-year sales ings and are in line with the hypotheses. However, the
growth in the third equation of the analysis. In both model of simultaneous equations revealed some sur-
cases, H1a is supported, but the evidence does not prising findings. Of note are results showing that a
lead to support of H1b. R&D spending is positively firm’s R&D spending is a very good predictor of its
associated with patents (H1a), but the significant patenting and new product announcements, although
quadratic term indicates a positive curvilinear rela- not always in the anticipated direction. Another sur-
tionship between R&D spending and patents (oppo- prising result is the negative relationship between pat-
site of the predicted relationship in H1b). H2a and ents and performance.
H2b are not supported. While a significant curvilin- As expected, R&D spending was positively related
ear relationship exists between R&D spending and to patents. This finding is consistent with others (e.g.,
product announcements, it is not the predicted in- Bogner and Bansal, 2007; Cardinal and Hatfield,
verse-U relationship. Instead, as R&D spending ini- 2000) who argue that internal research capabilities,
tially increases, new product announcements drop; particularly those with a strong basic research com-
however, product announcements begin to increase ponent, is key to enabling a firm to generate creative
as R&D spending climbs. Industry differences were outputs. The finding of increasing returns to scale to
evident with respect to the equations for patents and R&D spending was surprising. In formulating H1b,
product announcements. the present study drew heavily from growing evidence
H3, which predicted that patents would be posi- that suggests larger firms are proportionally less in-
tively associated with product announcements, was novative than smaller firms. While the number of pat-
supported in both analyses. H4, which predicted that ented inventions has been found to rise with increased
product announcements would be positively associ- spending on research and development, this occurred
ated with performance, was supported for both ROA at a decreasing rate (e.g., Graves and Langowitz,
and sales growth. H5, which predicted no direct 1993). In other words, the most common finding has
relationship between patents and performance, was been one of decreasing returns to scale of R&D spend-
not supported in either analysis. Patents were found ing on patenting.

Table 1: Correlation Matrixa


Variable Mean s.d. 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6.

1. Patentsb 3.20 1.62 1.00


2. Productsb 2.39 1.47 0.51 1.00
3. R&Db 4.27 1.48 0.77 0.67 1.00
4.Firm Sizeb 2.80 1.20 0.68 0.48 0.74 1.00
5. ROA 4.51 9.61 0.10 0.09 0.11 0.16 1.00
6. Sales Growth 7.04 12.61  0.14 0.01  0.13  0.02 0.25 1.00
a
n 5 4,002. R&D, research and development. ROA, return on assets.
b
These variables are log transformations.
 po.001.
734 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

Table 2a: Three-Stage Least Squares Regression Models


Variable Coefficient Z Hypothesized Sign
a
DV: ROA
Chi2 5 2355.37
Intercept  26.60  4.26
Products 3.52 2.62 H4 ( þ )
Patents  4.53  3.73 H5 (No Relationship)
Firm Size 0.03 0.06
Lagged ROA 0.21 11.85
a
Industry dummies for all industries, except for industrial/commercial machinery & computer equipment (35), are positive and significant at po.05
or greater. Year dummies for 1987, 1988, 1991, 1994, 1995, 1996, and 1997 are positive and significant at po.05 or greater. Year dummy for 2002 is
negative and significant at po.05. ROA, return on assets.

DV: Productsb
Chi2 5 11685.73
Intercept  0.31  0.55
Patents 1.29 8.31 H3 ( þ )
R&D Spending  0.78  8.65 H2a ( þ )
R&D Squared 0.04 4.38 H2b (  )
b
Industry dummies for food products (20), metals (34), and measure/analyze/control instruments (38) are positive and significant at po.05 or
greater. Year dummies for 1987, 1989, 1990, 1991, 1992, 1993, 1999, 2002, 2003, and 2004 are positive and significant at po.05 or greater. Year
dummies for 1996 and 1997 are negative and significant at po.05 or greater. R&D, research and development.

DV: Patentsc
Chi2 5 33500.30
Intercept 1.52 5.23
R&D Spending 0.32 6.20 H1a ( þ )
R&D Squared 0.04 6.93 H1b (  )
c
Industry dummy for paper products (26) is positive and significant at po.05. Industry dummies for food products (20), metals (34), industrial/
commercial machinery & computer equipment (35), and measure/analyze/control instruments (38) are negative and significant at po.05 or greater.
Year dummies for 1999 and 2004 are negative and significant at po.05 or greater. R&D, research and development.
 po.01.
 po.001.

The result showing increasing returns to scale con- research and development, they are likely to focus on
tradicts much of the existing empirical evidence but is patenting more—the inventions that they develop and
consistent with economic arguments for the advanta- intend to capitalize on and defensive patents to pro-
ges of scale in innovation (see Acs and Audretsch, tect their strategic position but that may not neces-
1990). For example, a large-scale research effort may sarily be related to specific proprietary products that
be necessary for a firm to pursue enough leads to find can generate returns. If the firm’s focus is on quantity,
those that can result in patentable inventions (Graves a patent arms race, or on defensive maneuvers rather
and Langowitz, 1993). Moreover, Hill and Hansen than on patents that are useful in conjunction with
(1991) suggest that larger research labs enjoy risk- other firm-specific resources, the pattern found in the
spreading benefits unavailable to smaller labs. As the present data would emerge.
research and development function increases in size, Also interesting is the finding that while a signifi-
the possibility of risk reduction across a portfolio of cant curvilinear relationship exists between R&D
projects enables managers to increasingly pursue a spending and product announcements it is not the
wider range of inventions. Others have argued that as predicted inverse-U but instead a U-shaped relation-
research and development departments continue to ship. As R&D spending initially increases, new prod-
grow their growing access to internal funds gives them uct announcements drop. At high levels of R&D
significant advantages in purchasing specialized labo- spending, however, product announcements begin to
ratory equipment or hiring specialized personnel re- climb. While these results seem to contradict the pre-
quired to facilitate a broad R&D portfolio (Acs and ponderance of existing evidence some research exists
Audretsch). While the results reported here support that support the findings. For example, a U-shaped
these explanations, it is also possible that increasing relationship has been found between firm size and in-
returns may be attributable to the overall increase in novative activity, measured as the number of new
patenting practices in firms. As firms spend more on product introductions (Audretsch and Acs, 1991); be-
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 735
2010;27:725–740

Table 2b: Three-Stage Least Squares Regression Models


Variable Coefficient Z Hypothesized Sign
a
DV: 3Yr Sales Growth
Chi2 5 5358.34
Intercept 17.92 1.96
Products 9.81 3.33 H4 ( þ )
Patents  17.91  6.46 H5 (No Relationship)
Firm Size 6.10 6.31
Lagged Sales Growth 0.58 29.68
a
Industry dummy for paper products (26) is positive and significant at po.05. Industry dummies for food products (20), chemical and pharma-
ceutical products (28), metals (34), and industrial/commercial machinery & computer equipment (35) are negative and significant at po.05. Year
dummies for 1994, 1995, 1996, 1997, and 2000 are positive and significant at po.05.

DV: Productsb
Chi2 5 11647.25
Intercept  0.31  0.56
Patents 1.30 8.36 H3 ( þ )
R&D Spending  0.78  8.68 H2a ( þ )
R&D Squared 0.04 4.34 H2b (  )
b
Industry dummies for food products (20), chemical and pharmaceutical products (28), transportation equipment (34), electronic, electrical equip-
ment and components (36), and measure/analyze/control instruments (38) are positive and significant at po.05 or greater. Year dummies for 1989,
1990, 1991, 1992, 1993, 1999, 2002, 2003, and 2004 are positive and significant at po.05. Year dummies for 1995 and 1996 are negative and
significant at po.05. R&D, research and development.

DV: Patentsc
Chi2 5 33515.80
Intercept 0.33 0.85
R&D Spending 0.32 6.21 H1a ( þ )
R&D Squared 0.04 6.92 H1b (  )
c
Industry dummy for paper products (26) and transportation equipment (34) are positive and significant at po.05. Industry dummies for chemical
and pharmaceutical products (28), industrial/commercial machinery & computer equipment (35), and business services (73) are negative and sig-
nificant at po.05. Year dummies for 1999 and 2004 are negative and significant at po.05 or greater. R&D, research and development.
 po.05.
 po.01.
 po.001.

tween R&D productivity, measured as R&D output edge that can accelerate product innovation (Tsai,
elasticity, and firm size (Tsai, 2005); and between firm 2005). It may also be that our findings are related to
age and innovation activity (Peeters and van Pot- the difference between spending on basic research and
telsberghe de la Potterie, 2006). spending on product development efforts. At very low
While none of these studies directly examined the levels of R&D spending more of the expenditures tend
relationship between R&D spending and new product to be directed at development of projects that have a
announcements, cumulatively they support the re- relatively high likelihood of producing commercializ-
sults. Small firms, with relatively low expenditures able products that can provide immediate payback for
on research and development, may have a competitive the firm. Thus, the level of new product innovation
advantage in R&D productivity. While R&D spend- would be relatively high for low levels of R&D spend-
ing may be limited, small firms are relatively efficient ing. As R&D spending begins to increase, the addi-
in decision making and coordination, allowing them tional funds are likely to be disproportionally directed
to rapidly respond to market needs and quickly de- toward basic research, possibly resulting in fewer
velop and launch new products. At the other end of product innovations. Eventually, as firms continue
the spectrum, firms able to support high levels of to grow and expand their R&D spending, the portfo-
R&D spending can also achieve high levels of inno- lio of commercializable products grows and the level
vative output as they take advantage of economies of of product innovation rises. Unfortunately, the data
scale to spread costs, can sustain a diverse portfolio of used here do not allow a separate evaluation of the
research projects, and are able to effectively gather research and development components of R&D
and use a broad range of internal and external knowl- spending. Future studies may shed more light on
736 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

these issues and relationships by gathering more fine- patents can vary greatly, with only a relatively small
grained data. number of patents being of such impact that they
It was also hypothesized and found that product generate significant economic returns (Schankerman
announcements would be positively related to both and Pakes, 1986). When one considers that the pro-
performance measures. These results are consistent cess of creating and defending patents is very costly
with previous work (e.g., Hua and Wemmerlov, 2006; (Encaoua et al., 2006), the combination of high levels
Roberts, 1999) and suggest that firms that can gener- of expensive patenting activity combined with low
ate a consistent flow of new products to the market returns from those patents can explain the present
enjoy higher levels of performance. While the study’s results.
improved performance that may result from a single The problem of high-cost patenting providing lim-
product introduction may not be long-lived, this ited economic benefit is exacerbated by the trend to-
research supports the argument that high profits ward strategic patenting, where the value of patents is
can persist if a firm is able to successfully introduce independent of the actual, or even potential, value of
to the market multiple innovations over an extended any innovation (MacDonald, 2004). An increasing
period of time. These multiple product introductions number of firms are using patents as strategic weap-
may allow a firm to continually enjoy brief mono- ons. For example, MacDonald highlights numerous
poly products from each of the new products it intro- examples of strategic patenting that may limit the
duces. Moreover, researchers also argue that persis- economic benefits a firm achieves. These include ex-
tent high levels of performance by a firm act as tensive patenting around a competitor’s key patents
an entry-deterring mechanism, effectively reducing to limit the value of its patents, building an extensive
the number of firms and level of competition in an patent portfolio around technologies of limited value
industry and allowing the innovating firm to capture to provide leverage to negotiate licensing agreements,
more of the industry’s sales and profits (Cho and and engaging in high levels of defensive patenting that
Pucik, 2005). require a significant number of patents be taken out to
It was also expected that patents would not be re- prevent rivals from using their patents or to prevent
lated to performance. This expectation was based on them from working in an area. These patent strategies
research suggesting that many patents provide only not only reduce the likelihood of creating potential
limited protection or were created for strategic pur- high-value innovations that can positively impact re-
poses only distantly related to firm’s own innovation turns and growth but also force all firms to engage in
efforts (Arora et al., 2003; Griliches et al., 1991). The high levels of expensive patenting that provides lim-
fact that a negative relationship was found between ited economic return. While it is possible that exten-
patents and both ROA and sales growth does not sive patenting serves a few industries well, the overall
support the hypotheses, but it is intriguing. Certainly, effect for many firms from high levels of patenting is
these results call into question the value of patents as to reduce performance.
protection mechanisms. While it is likely that patents Firm size was found to be positively correlated with
help firms recoup some of their research and devel- patents, product announcements, and R&D spending.
opment costs, there is no evidence of overwhelming This is not surprising, as large firms have more re-
direct performance benefits. The results do suggest, sources to devote to generating innovative activity.
however, that patents may boost firm performance Firm size was also positively related to sales growth,
indirectly through their positive effect on product in- although not to ROA. This suggests that while an
troductions. In addition, while it was argued that overall higher level of innovative activity results in
firms are most likely to patent commercializable prod- significantly higher sales it does not translate into dis-
ucts, not all patented technologies are actually con- proportionally higher return, perhaps because of
verted into products. It is possible that patenting greater inefficiencies in larger firms.
erodes a firm’s competitive position as managers in
the firm may feel invincible against the competition
and thus do not develop other complementarities and Limitations
skills needed to compete (e.g., management, produc-
tion, and marketing). A positive relationship was Two limitations of this study also point to future re-
found between patents and new product announce- search opportunities. This study used simple patent
ments. Yet the technological and economic impact of counts. This measure indicates the quantity of pat-
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 737
2010;27:725–740

enting activity without taking into account the impact Implications


of these various patents. The inability of patent
counts to distinguish between high-impact and low- These empirical findings have implications both for
impact patents is well documented (e.g., Hall et al., managers and researchers. For managers, there does
2001; Trajtenberg, 1990). However, Hagedoorn and appear to be increasing return to R&D spending with
Cloodt (2003, p. 1368) conclude that ‘‘it appears that, respect to patents. Large research and development
certainly in large parts of the economics literature, efforts can realize benefits in terms of lower risk,
raw patent counts are generally accepted as one of the broader technology portfolios, more specialized tal-
most appropriate indicators that enable researchers to ent, and the like that smaller labs may not. The ad-
compare the inventive or innovative performance of vantage of higher levels of R&D spending is also
companies in terms of new technologies, new pro- reflected in a greater number of new products intro-
cesses and new products.’’ The use of patent counts duced to the market. Yet even firms with relatively
and patent citations, highly correlated in some studies low levels of R&D spending can experience high in-
(e.g., Hagedoorn and Cloodt; Stuart, 2000) but not in novative output if they focus on remaining efficient
others (e.g., Rosenkopf and Nerkar, 2001), tap into and rapidly responding to changing market demands
different aspects of a firm’s inventive activities (quan- with new products.
tity vs. impact). Both aspects are worthy of study. The The importance of new products to a firm is also
empirical findings presented here suggest that the ab- highlighted by the finding that product announce-
solute level of patenting can detract from firm returns ments were significant in determining a firm’s sales
and growth, a finding that is important in light of re- growth as well as its profitability. This finding supports
cent increases in patenting, particularly defensive pat- other research suggesting that while the performance
enting. Future studies should examine the role of benefit of any one innovation may be short-lived mul-
patent impact. It is expected that higher patent im- tiple product innovations over time can consistently
pact may mitigate some of the negative effects found improve firm performance. Finally, the results provide
in the present study. a cautionary tale for managers as they consider their
Given the large size of the sample, this study relied patenting practices. Certainly, to some extent patents
solely on archival data. This did not allow for a have value as devices to protect proprietary technol-
disaggregation of R&D spending into finer compo- ogies. While not all of these patented technologies will
nents. Survey data allow researchers to determine result in significant economic returns, patents do limit
what percentage of a firm’s R&D spending is directed the extent to which rival firms may encroach in an
toward various types of activities. More specifically, area and can extend the time a firm has to exploit it
surveys can separate the percentage of R&D spending technologies. Yet the fact that patents are negatively
associated with basic and applied research rather than related to growth and returns suggest that firms need
development. Furthermore, surveys allow for a to reexamine the way they are managing their patent-
similar distinction between innovation efforts directed ing process. The fact that managers have expanded
at product development and efforts involving process their use of patents in ways that were never originally
development (e.g., Lager, 2002; Peeters and van intended may be having unanticipated consequences.
Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, 2006). Prior research Certainly, the results of this one study do not provide
suggests that firms vary in their relative emphasis conclusive evidence, and additional research is needed
on these elements of R&D spending and that innova- to examine in greater detail and in different contexts
tive outputs vary as a result. For example, Peeters the patent–performance link. However, it is interest-
and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie found that firms ing that rather than enhancing innovation and im-
were more likely to patent when they emphasized proving performance as patents were originally
product rather than process innovation and intended, they are now being used to constrain inno-
when they had a greater emphasis on basic and vation and are reducing performance.
applied research rather than development. Their
study, however, did not examine performance
outcomes. Future studies should use the fine-grained
data available from surveys to further explore the References
relationships between firm innovative activities and Acs, Z.J. and Audretsch, D.B. (1987). Innovation, Market Structure,
firm performance. and Firm Size. Review of Economics and Statistics 69(4):567–575.
738 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

Acs, Z.J. and Audretsch, D.B. (1988). Innovation in Large and Small Fleming, L. (2002). Finding the Organizational Sources of Technolog-
Firms: An Empirical Analysis. American Economic Review ical Breakthroughs: The Story of Hewlett-Packard’s Thermal Ink-
78(4):678–690. Jet. Industrial & Corporate Change 11(5):1059–1084.
Acs, Z.J. and Audretsch, D.B. (1990). Innovation and Small Firms. Geroski, P., Machin, S., and Van Reenan, J. (1993). The Profitability
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. of Innovating Firms. Rand Journal of Economics 24(2):198–211.
Acs, Z.J. and Gifford, S. (1996). Innovation of Entrepreneurial Firms. Grant, R.M. (2008). Contemporary Strategy Analysis, (6th ed.). Ox-
Small Business Economics 8(3):203–218. ford: Blackwell.
Adams, W. and Brock, J. (1986). The Bigness Complex. New York: Graves, S.B. and Langowitz, N.S. (1993). Innovative Productivity and
Pantheon Books. Returns to Scale in the Pharmaceutical Industry. Strategic Man-
Ahuja, G. and Lampert, C.M. (2001). Entrepreneurship in the Large agement Journal 14(8):593–605.
Corporation: A Longitudinal Examination of How Established Greenhalgh, C. and Longland, M. (2005). Running to Stand Still?—
Firms Create Breakthrough Innovations. Strategic Management The Value of R&D, Patents and Trade Marks in Innovating Man-
Journal 22(6–7):521–543. ufacturing Firms. International Journal of the Economics of Business
Ahuja, G. and Katila, R. (2001). Technological Acquisition and the 12(3):307–328.
Innovative Performance of Acquiring Firms: A Longitudinal Griliches, Z. (1986). Productivity, R&D, and Basic Research at the
Study. Strategic Management Journal 22(3):197–220. Firm Level in the 1970s. American Economic Review 76(1):141–154.
Anton, J. and Yao, D. (2004). Little Patents and Big Secrets: Managing Griliches, Z., Hall, B., and Pakes, A. (1991). R&D, Patents, and Mar-
Intellectual Property. Rand Journal of Economics 35(1):1–22. ket Value Revisited: Is There A Second (Technological Opportu-
Arora, A., Ceccagnoli, M., and Cohen, W.M. (2003). R&D and the nity) Factor? Journal of Economics of Innovation and New
Patent Premium. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Technology 1:183–201.
Paper Paper No. 9431. Hagedoorn, J. and Cloodt, M. (2003). Measuring Innovative Perfor-
Audretsch, D.B. and Acs, Z. (1991). Innovation and Size at the Firm mance: Is There an Advantage in Using Multiple Indicators? Re-
Level. Southern Economic Journal 57(3):739–745. search Policy 32(8):1365–1379.
Hagedoorn, J. and Duysters, G. (2002). The Effect of Mergers and
Barczak, G. (1995). New Product Strategy, Structure, Process, and
Acquisitions on the Technological Performance of Companies in a
Performance in the Telecommunications Industry. Journal of Prod-
High-Tech Environment. Technology Analysis and Strategic Man-
uct Innovation Management 12(3):224–234.
agement 14(1):67–85.
Bettis, R.A. and Hitt, M.A. (1995). The New Competitive Landscape.
Hall, B.H. and Ham, R. (1999). The Patent Paradox Revisited:
Strategic Management Journal 16:7–19 (Special Summer Issue).
Determinants of Patenting in the U.S. Semiconductor Industry,
Bogner, W.C. and Bansal, P. (2007). Knowledge Management as the 1980–94. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
Basis of Sustained High Performance. Journal of Management No. 7062.
Studies 44(7):165–188.
Hall, B.H., Jaffe, A.B., and Trajtenberg, M. (2001). The NBER
Bound, J., Cummins, C., Griliches, Z., Hall, B.H., and Jaffe, A. (1984). Patent Citation Data File: Lessons, Insights and Methodological
Who Does R&D and Who Patents? In: Patents and Productivity, Tools. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
ed. Z. Griliches. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 21–54. 8498.
Calantone, R., Garcia, R., and Droge, C. (2003). The Effects of En- Hall, B.H. and Ziedonis, R.H. (2001). The Patent Paradox Revisited:
vironmental Turbulence on New Product Development Strategy An Empirical Study of Patenting in the U.S. Semiconductor In-
Planning. Journal of Product Innovation Management 20(2):90–103. dustry, 1979–1995. RAND Journal of Economics 32(1):101–128.
Cardinal, L.B. and Hatfield, D.E. (2000). Internal Knowledge Gener- Hall, B.J., Griliches, Z., and Hausman, J.A. (1986). Patents and R
ation: The Research Laboratory and Innovative Productivity in the and D: Is There a Lag? International Economic Review 27(2):265–
Pharmaceutical Industry. Journal of Engineering & Technology 283.
Management 17(3–4):247–271.
Helfat, C. and Peteraf, M.A. (2003). The Dynamic Resources-Based
Chiesa, V. (1996). Managing the Internationalization of R&D activi- View: Capabilities Lifecycle. Strategic Management Journal 24(10):
ties. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 43(1):7–23. 997–1012.
Cho, H.-J. and Pucik, V. (2005). Relationship Between Innovativeness, Heller, M.A. and Eisenberg, R.S. (1998). Can Patents Deter Innovation?
Quality, Growth, Profitability, and Market Value. Strategic Man- The Anticommons in Biomedical Research. Science 280:688–701.
agement Journal 26(6):555–575.
Hill, C.W.L. and Hansen, G.S. (1991). A Longitudinal Study of the
Cohen, W.M. and Klepper, S. (1996). Firm Size and the Nature of Causes and Consequences of Changes in Diversification in the U.S.
Innovation within Industries: The Case of Process and Product Pharmaceutical Industry 1977–1986. Strategic Management Journal
R&D. Review of Economics and Statistics 78(2):232–243. 12(3):187–199.
Cohen, W.M., Nelson, R.R., and Walsh, J.P. (2000). Protecting Their Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., and Nixon, R.D. (1993). A Mid-Range
Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Theory of Interfunctional Integration: Its Antecedents and
Firms Patent (or Not). National Bureau of Economic Research Outcomes. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management
Working Paper No. 7552. 10(1–2):161–185.
Comanor, W.S. and Scherer, F.M. (1969). Patent Statistics as a Measure Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Johnson, R.A., and Moesel, D.A. (1996).
of Technical Change. Journal of Political Economy 77(3):392–397. The Market for Corporate Control and Firm Innovation. Strategic
DeCarolis, D.M. and Deeds, D.L. (1999). The Impact of Stocks and Management Journal 39(5):1084–1119.
Flows of Organizational Knowledge on Firm Performance: An Hoopes, D.G. and Postrel, S. (1999). Share Knowledge, ‘‘Gliches’’ and
Empirical Investigation of the Biotechnology Industry. Strategic Product Development Performance. Strategic Management Journal
Management Journal 20(10):953–968. 20(9):837–865.
Encaoua, D., Guellec, D., and Martinez, C. (2006). Patent Systems for Hua, S.Y. and Wemmerlov, U. (2006). Product Change Intensity,
Encouraging Innovation: Lessons from Economic Analysis. Re- Product Advantage, and Market Performance: An Empirical In-
search Policy 35(9):1423–1440. vestigation of the PC Industry. Journal of Product Innovation Man-
Ernst, H. (2001). Patent Applications and Subsequent Changes of Per- agement 23(4):316–329.
formance: Evidence from Time-Series Cross-Section Analyses on Jensen, E.J. (1987). Research Expenditures and the Discovery of New
the Firm Level. Research Policy 30(1):143–157. Drugs. Journal of Industrial Economics 36(1):83–95.
A LONGITUDINAL STUDY OF THE IMPACT OF R&D, PATENTS, AND PRODUCT INNOVATION J PROD INNOV MANAG 739
2010;27:725–740

Klette, T.J. (1996). R&D, Scope Economies and Plant Performance. Peeters, C. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2006). Innovation
Rand Journal of Economics 27(3):502–522. Strategy and the Patenting Behavior of Firms. Journal of Evolu-
Kretschmer, M. and Soetendorp, R. (2001). The Strategic Use of Busi- tionary Economics 16(1–2):109–135.
ness Method Patents: A Pilot Study of Out of Court Settlements. Penner-Hahn, J. and Shaver, J.M. (2005). Does International
Journal of e-Business 2(1):9–38. Research and Development Increase Patent Output? An Analysis
Lager, T. (2002). Product and Process Development Intensity in Pro- of Japanese Pharmaceutical Firms. Strategic Management Journal
cess Industry: A Conceptual and Empirical Analysis of the Allo- 26(2):121–140.
cation of Company Resources for the Development of Process Peterson, K.J., Handfield, R.B., and Ragatz, G.L. (2005). Supplier In-
Technology. International Journal of Innovation Management tegration into New Product Development: Coordinating Product,
6(2):105–130. Process and Supply Chain Design. Journal of Operations Manage-
Langowitz, N.S. and Graves, S.B. (1992). Innovative Productivity in Phar- ment 23(3–4):371–388.
maceutical Firms. Research Technology Management 35(2):39–52. Prajogo, D.I. (2006). The Relationship between Innovation and Business
Lee, H., Smith, K.G., Grimm, C.M., and Schomburg, A. (2000). Tim- Performance—A Comparative Study between Manufacturing and
ing, Order and Durability of New Product Advantages with Imi- Service Firms. Knowledge and Process Management 13(3):218–225.
tation. Strategic Management Journal 21(1):23–30. Price, R.M. (1996). Technology and Strategic Advantage. California
Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A.K., Nelson, R.R., and Winter, S.G. (1987). Management Review 38(3):38–56.
Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Develop- Rai, A.K. (2001). Fostering Cumulative Innovation in the Biophar-
ment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3:783–820. maceutical Industry: The Role of Patents and Antitrust. Berkeley
Li, H. and Atuahene-Gima, K. (2001). Product Innovation Strategy Technology Law Journal 16(2):813–854.
and the Performance of New Technology Ventures in China. Acad- Rivette, K. and Kline, D. (2000). Discovering New Value in Intellec-
emy of Management Journal 44(6):1123–1134. tual Property. Harvard Business Review 78(1):54–66.
Lieberman, M.B. and Montgomery, D.B. (1988). First-Mover Advan- Roberts, P.W. (1999). Product Innovation, Product-Market Competi-
tages. Strategic Management Journal 9:41–58 (Summer Special tion and Persistent Profitability in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Indus-
Issue). try. Strategic Management Journal 20(7):655–670.
MacDonald, S. (2004). When Means Become Ends: Considering the Roberts, P.W. and Amit, R. (2003). The Dynamics of Innovative
Impact of Patent Strategy on Innovation. Information Economics Activity and Competitive Advantage: The Case of Australian
and Policy 16(1):135–158. Retail Banking, 1981–1995. Organization Science 14(2):107–122.
Mann, R.J. and Sager, T. (2007). Patents, Venture Capital and Soft- Rosenberg, N. (1990). Why Do Firms Do Basic Research (with Their
ware Start-ups. Research Policy 36(2):193–208. Own Money)? Research Policy 19(2):165–174.
Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat’s Law, Innovation, and the Growth Rosenkopf, L. and Nerkar, A. (2001). Beyond Local Search: Bound-
of Firms. American Economic Review 55(5):1023–1051. ary-Spanning, Exploration, and Impact in the Optical Disk Indus-
Mansfield, E. (1980). Basic Research and Productivity Increase in try. Strategic Management Journal 22(4):287–306.
Manufacturing. American Economic Review 70(5):863–873. Salavou, H. (2002). Profitability in Market-Oriented SMEs: Does
Mansfield, E. (1986). Patents and Innovation: An Empirical Study. Product Innovation Matter? European Journal of Innovation Man-
Management Science 32(2):173–181. agement 5(3):164–171.
Marsh, S.J. and Stock, G.N. (2003). Building Dynamic Capabilities Schankerman, M. and Pakes, A. (1986). Estimates of the Value of
in New Product Development through Intertemporal Inte- Patent Rights in European Countries during the Post-1950 Period.
gration. Journal of Product Innovation Management 20(2): Economic Journal 96(384):1052–1076.
136–148. Scherer, F.M. and Ross, D. (1990). Industrial Market Structure and
Masayuki, K. (1999). R&D Dynamics of Creating Patents in the Jap- Economic Performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
anese Industry. Research Policy 28(6):587–600. Schumpeter, J.A. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development. Cam-
Mazzoleni, R. and Nelson, R.R. (1998). Economic Theories about the bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Benefits and Costs of Patents. Journal of Economic Issues Schumpeter, J.A. (1950). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New
32(4):1031–1052. York: Harper.
McMillan, C.S., Mauri, A., and Hamilton, R.D. III (2003). The Impact Scott, G.M. (2000). Critical Technology Management Issues of New
of Publishing and Patenting Activities on New Product Develop- Product Development in High-Tech Companies. Journal of Product
ment and Firm Performance: The Case of the US Pharmaceutical Innovation Management 17(1):57–77.
Industry. International Journal of Innovation Management 7(2): Sher, P.J. and Yang, P.Y. (2005). The Effects of Innovative
213–221. Capabilities and R&D Clustering on Firm Performance: The Ev-
Montgomery, C. (1995). Of Diamonds and Rust: A New Look at Re- idence of Taiwan’s Semiconductor Industry. Technovation
sources. In: Resource-Based and Evolutionary Theories of the Firm: 25(1):33–43.
Towards a Synthesis, ed. C. Montgomery. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Stuart, T.E. (2000). Interorganizational Alliances and the Performance
Academic Publishers, 251–268. of Firms: A Study of Growth and Innovation Rates in a High-
Murphy, G.B., Trailer, J.W., and Hill, R.C. (1996). Measuring Per- Technology Industry. Strategic Management Journal 21(8):791–
formance in Entrepreneurship Research. Journal of Business Ven- 811.
turing 36(1):15–23. Teece, D.J. (1996). Capturing Value from Technological Innova-
Nerkar, A. and Roberts, P.W. (2004). Technological and Product- tion: Integration, Strategic Partnering, and Licensing
Market Experience and the Success of New Product Introductions Decisions. In: Managing Strategic Innovation and Change, ed.
in the Pharmaceutical Industry. Strategic Management Journal M.L. Tushman, and P. Anderson. New York: Oxford University
25(8–9):779–799. Press, 287–306.
Pakes, A. (1985). On Patents, R&D, and the Stock Market Rate of Trajtenberg, M. (1990). A Penny for Your Quotes: Patent Citations
Return. Journal of Political Economy 93(2):390–409. and the Value of Information. RAND Journal of Economics
Pakes, A. and Griliches, Z. (1984). Patents and R&D at the Firm Level: 21(1):325–342.
A First Look. In: Patents and Productivity, ed. Z. Griliches. Chi- Tsai, K.-H. (2005). R&D Productivity and Firm Size: A Nonlinear
cago: University of Chicago Press, 55–72. Examination. Technovation 25(7):795–803.
740 J PROD INNOV MANAG K. W. ARTZ ET AL.
2010;27:725–740

Venkatraman, N. and Ramanujam, V. (1986). Measurement of Zahra, S.A. (1993). New Product Introduction in Established Compa-
Business Performance in Strategy Research: A Comparison of Ap- nies: Associations with Industry and Strategy Variables. Entrepre-
proaches. Academy of Management Review 11(4):801–814. neurship Theory and Practice 18(2):47–70.
Voss, C.S. (1994). Significant Issues for the Future of Product Inno- Ziedonis, R.H. (2004). Don’t Fence Me In: Fragmented Markets for
vation. Journal of Product Innovation Management 11(5):460–463. Technology and the Patent Acquisition Strategies of Firms. Man-
Wheelwright, S.C. and Clark, K.B. (1995). Leading Product Develop- agement Science 50(6):804–820.
ment. New York: Free Press.

You might also like