You are on page 1of 14

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39


www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

An economic assessment of the Kyoto Protocol application


A.S. Dagoumas, G.K. Papagiannis, P.S. Dokopoulos
Power Systems Laboratory, Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering, Aristotle University of Thessaloniki, 54124 Thessaloniki, Greece
Available online 6 July 2004

Abstract

Scope of this paper is to investigate scenarios concerning the economic implications of the Kyoto Protocol (The Kyoto Protocol
to the Convention on Climate change, http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/convkp/kpeng.pdf) in its current version including the clean
development mechanisms (CDMs), the Marrakesh Accords (Seventh session of the Conference of Parties, 29 October–9 November,
Marrakesh, Morocco, http://unfccc.int/cop7/index.html) and the Conference of Parties 9 in Milan (Nineth session of the Conference
of Parties, 1–12 December, Milan, http://unfccc.int/cop9/index.html). The general equilibrium model, GTAP-E was used for the
investigation of the experiments which are focused on the cases of the USA participation and on the role of Russia as a major
emission credits seller. A significant issue in the Kyoto Protocol negotiations is the introduction of sinks in the Marrakech Accords.
This seems to weaken the initial targets by replacing CO2 emissions reduction with forestation activities and reduces the cost of the
Protocol compliance. It is also shown that the absence of the USA may reduce the costs for the other developed countries and may
influence the total costs more than the CDMs. A new scenario is studied by introducing a guaranteed minimum of 60% in the
emission credits sold by Russia. Results show that the profits of Russia are not significantly affected by the guaranteed minimum.
r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: GTAP-E; Climate change; Kyoto Protocol; Marrakech accords; COP 9; MAC; Emission trading

1. Introduction The signing of the Kyoto Protocol (KP) in December


1997 is perhaps an historic step in reversing the inexorable
Climate changes may affect human life and the increase in the emission of the greenhouse gases (GHG).
ecology of the planet in a variety of ways. Most The primary achievement of the Protocol is the commit-
countries have taken steps to address climate change ment of countries referred in the Annex I of the KP to
but more has been achieved, so far, in raising awareness reduce their emission of GHGs some 5% below their
than in bringing about reductions in emissions: globally country specific 1990 level, in the period 2008–2012 with
energy related CO2 emissions have increased nearly 10% penalization clauses in case of non compliance.
from 1990 to 1999. Overall growth in emissions from The Protocol establishes three market based mechan-
developing countries has been particularly significant, isms for achieving emission reductions.
although their per capita emission levels remain low. International emissions trading allows for a trade of
The analysis of the economic implications of the emissions among Annex I Parties or international. A
climate change mitigation policies has been ongoing for party with emissions lower than its target could sell the
over a decade by numerous research groups. Several remaining part up to the target (article 17 of the
significant issues, but sometimes with contradicting Protocol).
results, have been considered like localities, globaliza- Joint implementation allows for any Annex I Party
tion, economy, technology etc. to be credited for emissions reduction achieved by
investing in projects located in other Annex I countries
Corresponding author. Tel.: +30-2301-996356; fax: +30-2310- (article 6 of the Protocol).
996321. Clean development mechanism allows for any Annex I
E-mail address: dagoumas@auth.gr (A.S. Dagoumas). Party to be credited for emissions reduction achieved by

0301-4215/$ - see front matter r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.05.012
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 27

investing in projects located in developing countries economic system. But the models can be classified into
under specific conditions (article 12 of the Protocol). four major categories.
The initial vision of Protocol by the developed
countries was shadowed by the intention of the USA  Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models: These
not to ratify. In the Marrakesh 2001 COP a lot of effort models are also called ‘‘top-down’’ models and are
was invested and some important steps towards the either static or dynamic. The main characteristic of
application of the Protocol were succeeded. these models is their ability to capture the influence of
The important issue in Marrakech agreement was the energy policy on international trade and the
introduction of CO2 sinks. The key actor in these economy and the fact that the construction of the
negotiations was Russia. With the Marrakech Accords economic system is based on the assumption of
the following activities can be counted as sinks (IPCC, perfect markets. Representatives of this category are
2000): Afforestation, reforestation, deforestation, forest GTAP-E, GREEN, EPPA, GEM-E3, G-CUBED,
and agricultural management, revegetation and con- SGM, GTEM, MERGE, MS-MRT, PACE, WAGE,
servation activities. The carbon credits from sink-related WORLDSCAN and NEWAGE models.
activities are about 120 MtC per year, which effectively  Energy system models: These models represent the
weaken the originally stated targets. The new targets energy sector in much more detail than the CGE
seem to be more feasible. models. They are referred as bottom-up models
The cost of the Protocol implementation in each because they represent the energy sector by using a
region (USA, EU, etc.) depends on many factors which disaggregated data of existing and emerging technol-
were discussed in COPs. The essential among them seem ogies. Their main disadvantage is the fact that they
to be following: represent only the energy system and do not take into
account linkages of the energy sector with the rest
 The participation of the USA and Russia. economy. Typical in this category are MARKAL,
 The CO2 sinks. POLES, PRIMES, LEAP and ENPEP models.
 The trading mechanisms and the related trade  Integrated assessment models: These models consider
restrictions. human activities, atmospheric composition, climate
 The boycott movements. change and ecosystems and can be described as
environmental models. They are very useful when
A number of important studies (Bahn et al., 2001;
conducting studies that address the problem of
Bernard et al., 2002; Bohringer, 2002; Christopher et al.,
climate change because of the detailed representation
1999; Gusbin et al., 1999; Ellerman and Decaux, 1998;
of this change mechanism. Their economic structure
Hamasaki, 2002; Painuly, 2001; Viquier et al., 2003; den
belongs to one of the above categories. Main
Elzen and de Moor, 2002; McKibbin and Wilcoxen,
representatives of this category are the AIM,
2002; Kuik and Gerlagh, 2003; Criqui et al., 1999;
GRAPE, IGSM and RICE models.
Paltsev, 2001; Weyant and Hill, 1999; Springer, 2003;
Zhang, 2001: Chen, 2002) have assessed the cost of the
 Emission trading models: Models like CICERO, ECN,
MACGEM, ZHANG and ENEA belong in this
Kyoto Protocol at different times reflecting the con-
category. These models use MAC curves to analyze
sequences of the time relevant COPs decisions. They
International Emission Trading. MAC curves are
were mostly focused in the influence of several factors
usually produced by energy system models, by CGE
but there has not been an analysis of the cost of the
models or are estimated econometrically.
Kyoto Protocol considering all above factors simulta-
neously.
In this work the GTAP-E model (Burniaux and
Scope of this paper is to investigate the role of Russia
Truong, 2002) has been selected because it simulates the
on the cost of the Kyoto Protocol implementation
economy sectors and the energy systems in more details
taking into account the trading mechanisms and related
than the others. GTAP-E is an extension of the basic
restrictions, the participation or not of USA, the
GTAP model where E stands for energy. Generally,
introduction of sinks and of a boycott movement.
GTAP is a widely used, static, multisector, multiregion
applied general equilibrium model (Thomas, 1997). It is
based on a detailed database with a broad coverage of
2. Modeling trade distortions and explicit statistics on transport
margins. Import demand is modeled using the Arming-
2.1. Available models ton (1969) assumption of imperfect substitutability
between domestic and imported goods and between
There are several ways to analyze the effects of the imported goods from different regions. The model
climate policy on economic systems. Each model focuses assumes a global bank to mediate between world savings
on certain areas and has its own structure of the and investments, and a region-specific set of equations
ARTICLE IN PRESS
28 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

for consumer demand that allows for different responses 2.2.2. Consumption structure
to price and income changes across regions. On the consumption side, the existing structure of
One of its most notable features is its detailed GTAP assumes a separation of ‘private’ consumption
database. For this study the GTAP 5 database has been from ‘government’ consumption (consumption by
used consisting of 66 regions and 57 sectors (Dimaranan households of publicly provided goods) and private
and McDougall, 2002; Rutherford and Babiker, 1998) savings. Government consumption expenditure is then
GTAP-E has the same structure as GTAP, but its assumed to be Cobb–Douglas with respect to all
production structure includes a more detailed descrip- commodities. In the GTAP-E model, energy commod-
tion of substitution possibilities among different sources ities are separated from the non-energy commodities
of energy. with a nested-CES structure (Fig. 3).
Household ‘private’ consumption (i.e. consumption
2.2. Functional description of the GTAP-E model of private goods) is assumed to be structured according
to the constant-difference of elasticities (CDE) func-
GTAP-E model in order to incorporate energy tional form in the existing GTAP model. If the energy
substitution uses the so called bottom-up approach. commodities within the CDE structure have the same
The advantage of this approach is in the detailed income and substitution parameters, then according to
specification of the energy technologies, through which the theory of the CDE structure, these commodities can
newly developed or future technologies can be incorpo- be aggregated into a single composite with the same
rated into the analysis. parameters as that of the individual components. To
allow for flexible substitution between the individual
2.2.1. Production structure energy commodities, the energy composite is now
Energy substitution is incorporated in the structure of specified as a CES sub-structure (Fig. 4).
the GTAP-E model both in the production and the The values of the elasticities have been selected, based
consumption structure. As far as production is con- on detailed experiments and taking into consideration
cerned, energy is incorporated in the value added nest the values of other models such as GREEN (Burniaux et
(Fig. 1). This is done in two steps. Firstly, there is a al., 1992), EPPA (Babiker et al., 2001) and AIM (AIM
separation of energy commodities into ‘electricity’ and (Asian-Pacific Integrated Model)). A stochastic sensitiv-
‘non-electricity’ groups. Some degree of substitution ity analysis has been carried out so as to evaluate the
(Armington, 1969) is allowed within the non-electricity significance of every substitution elasticity. For this
group (sNELY) as well as between the electricity and reason a lot of experiments have been implemented
the non-electricity groups (sENER). On the second step based on current policies and the model has been
energy composite is combined with capital to produce adjusted so as to justify the targets of policies that have
energy-capital composite. Finally the combination of taken place from 1990 until 2000. The MURE database
energy-capital composite with other primary factors MURE Mesures d’Utilisation Rationelle de l’Ènergie
produces a ‘value-added-energy’ nest (VAE) through a has been also used as a database of measures that have
constant elasticity structure (CES) as shown in Fig. 2. been implemented in the EU. The values of elasticities
It is a zoomed presentation of the item in Fig. 1. that have succeeded results with great consistency with

Output
σ =0

All other inputs


Value-added- Energy
(Excluding energy inputs but
(including energy inputs)
Including energy feedstock)
VAE σD

Natural Capital-Energy Domestic Foreign


Land Labor Composite
Resource σM
LAB

Region 1 … Region r
Skilled Unskilled

Fig. 1. Production structure in the GTAP-E model used.


ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 29

Capital-Energy Composite
σ KE

Capital Energy Composite


σ ENER =1.0

Non Electric Electric


σD
σ NELY=0.5

Coal Non Coal Domestic Foreign


σD σ NCOL=1 σM

Region 1 … Region r
Gas Oil Petroleum
Domestic Foreign
… … products
σM
σD

Domestic Foreign
Region 1 … Region r σM

Region 1 … Region r

Fig. 2. Capital-energy composite structure in the GTAP-E model used.

Demand for composite


σ GENNE=0.5

Energy Composite Non energy composite


σ GEN=1 σ GNE=1

Coal … … … … …
σD

Domestic Foreign
σM

Region 1 … Region r

Fig. 3. Structure of government purchases in the GTAP-E model used.

the reality, have been selected for the structure of the scenarios and on the sectors that are used in order
model that was used in this paper. to incorporate energy structure in the model. The
model divides the world into 8 geopolitical regions.
2.3. Aggregations of regions and sectors in GTAP The model region and sector aggregation is shown in
Tables 1 and 2, respectively.
GTAP model can be adjusted to the needs of every
study. One important factor is the aggregation of the
database so as to focus on certain regions and sectors. 3. Reference case, assumptions
For the purposes of the present analysis the database
of the model was aggregated in 8 regions and 8 sectors. In the reference case, commonly called also the
The selection of these regions and sectors has been done Business As Usual (BAU) case, we assume that Kyoto
based on the regions that are included in the different Protocol does not apply. The production of CO2 as a
ARTICLE IN PRESS
30 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

Household demand for


Private Goods
CDE

Energy Composite Non energy commodities


σ GEN=1 σD

Coal … … Domestic Foreign


σD σM

Domestic Foreign Region 1 … Region r


σM

Region 1 … Region r

Fig. 4. Structure of household private purchases in the GTAP-E model used.

Table 1
Model region aggregation

EU (European Union) consists of: EEx (Net Energy Exporters) consists of: RoW (Rest of the World) consists of:
AUT Austria IDN Indonesia HKG Hong Kong
BEL Belgium MYS Malaysia KOR Korea, Republic
DNK Denmark VNM Viet Nam TWN Taiwan
FIN Finnland MEX Mexico PHL Philippines
FRA France COL Colombia SGP Singapore
DEU Germany VEN Venezuela THA Thailand
GBR United Kingdom XAP Rest of Andean BGD Bangladesh
GRC Greece Pact LKA Sri Lanka
IRL Ireland ARG Argentina XSA Rest of South
ITA Italy XME Rest of Middle Asia
LUX Luxemburg East XCM Central America and Caribbean
NLD Netherlands XNF Rest of North PER Peru
PRT Portugal Africa BRA Brazil
ESP Spain XSF Rest of Southern CHL Chile
SWE Sweden Africa URY Uruguay
XSS Rest of Sub-Saharan Africa XSM Rest of South America
XRW Rest of the world TUR Turkey
CEE(Central and Eastern Europe) consists of: RoAI (Other Annex I countries) consists of: MAR Morocco
HUN Hungary AUS Australia BWA Botswana
POL Poland NZL New Zealand XSC Rest of SACU
XCE Rest of Central CAN Canada MWI Malawi
European Assoc CHE Switzerland MOZ Mozambique
XEF Rest of EFTA TZA Tanzania, United Republic of
FSU (Former Soviet Union) consists of: CHIND (China and India) consists of: ZMB Zambia
XSU Former Soviet Union ZWE Zimbabwe
CHN China UGA Uganda
IND India USA (United States of America

function of time has been calculated for different regions countries, the GDP growth rate is assumed to be 4.4%
and sectors for the period 1990–2010. Emissions growth per annum over the same 20 year period. Baseline
in the different regions is due to the changes in the GDP, scenario was based on official reports (EIA (Energy
population and the carbon intensity of the output. The Information Agency and International Energy Out-
average growth in GDP in the Annex I countries in the look), 2003; IEA (International Energy Agency); IMF
baseline scenario is assumed to be 2.3% per annum over (International Monetary Fund), 2002; OECD (Organi-
the 20 year period 1990–2010. For the non Annex I sation for Economic Co-operation and Development)),
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 31

Table 2
Model sector aggregation

Agriculture: Primary agriculture, forestry and fishing


Paddy rice, wheat, cereal grains nec, vegetables, fruits, nuts, oil seeds, sugar cane, sugar beet, plant based fibers, crops nec, bovine cattle, sheep and
goats, animal products nec, raw milk, wool, silk worm cocoons, forestry, fishing
Coal: Coal mining
Oil: Crude oil
Gas: Natural gas extraction
Gas, gas manufacture, distribution
Oil_pcts: Refined oil products
Petroleum, coal products
Electricity: Electricity
En_Int_ind: Energy intensive industries
Minerals nec, chemical, rubber, plastic prod, mineral products nec, ferrous metals, metals nec
Oth_ind_ser: Other industries and services
Bovine cattle, sheep and goat, meat products, vegetable oils and fats, dairy products, processed rice, sugar, food products nec, beverages and tobacco
products, textiles, wearing apparel, leather products, wood products, paper products, publishing, metal products, motor vehicles and parts, transport
equipment nec, electronic equipment, machinery and equipment nec, manufactures nec, water, construction, trade, transport nec, water transport, air
transport, communication, financial services nec, insurance, business services nec, recreational and other service, public administration and defense,
education, ownership of dwellings

Table 3
CO2 emissions increase for the period 1990–2010 signing of the Kyoto Protocol. Results obtained were
Percentage annually calculated taking into consideration two basic assump-
tions. Firstly, the Kyoto Protocol targets for the
USA 1.38 development of CO2 emissions for the period
EU 1.05
1990–2010 and secondly the CO2 sinks as defined in
JPN 0.94
RoAI 1.9 the Marrakesh Accords in 2001. The development of
EEFSU 0.74 CO2 emissions is in Fig. 5 where it can be seen what
FSU 1.18 happens without and with the application of the Kyoto
CEE 0.45 Protocol and the required reduction in CO2 production
for this period. The results are region specific and are in
physical values, not in percent. USA and Russia
on national communications (UNFCCC (United Na- participate in this case. Fig. 6 shows for each region
tions Framework Convention on Climate Change)) and the available sinks for the period 1990–2010 as result of
on the results of a neural network that has been the Marrakesh Accords.
programmed for this reason. Fig. 7 shows the emission reductions in percentage
Global anthropogenic emissions of carbon dioxide are that have to be done to satisfy the targets of the Kyoto
projected to grow by approximately 64.2% between Protocol as modified by the introduction of sinks, i.e.
1990 and 2010. This is equivalent to an increase of Fig. 7 results out of combination of Figs. 5 and 6. The
around 14.2 billion tons of carbon dioxide. Emissions cases represented are split into two subscenarios. One
from developing countries are projected to increase shows the CO2 emission result in compliance with the
more rapidly than emissions from Annex I countries Kyoto Protocol in 1997 using as a base value the CO2
over the projection period in the reference case. emission for the year 1990 and the second subscenario
Emissions from Annex I countries are projected to rise shows the same quantities as in the first subscenario but
by an average of 1.2% per annum over the period related to the reference case which is dynamic.
1990–2010, while the corresponding annual increase for Key figure of this paper is the marginal abatement cost
the developing countries is 4.4%. Accordingly, the and the total cost in absolute values and as a percent of
Annex I share of world emissions is projected to fall GDP. The first one reflects the incremental cost to reduce
from 66% in 1990 to 51% in 2010. Table 3 shows the the carbon by one unit in the year 2010 and the second
annual CO2 emission increase for the studied regions. one provides a macroeconomic view of the consequences.

4.1. Evolution of the Kyoto Protocol with the


4. Experiments—results participation of the USA

Several scenarios beyond the reference case have been The cases that have been studied cover all possible
investigated covering all the phases from the initial actions that the participating countries may take. Kyoto
ARTICLE IN PRESS
32 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

Fig. 5. Development of CO2 emissions for the period 1990–2010, without and with measures according to the Kyoto Protocol in its initial form.

Fig. 6. CO2 Sinks according to the Marrakesh Accords for the period 1990–2010.

Protocol in its initial phase included domestic efforts reduced as shown in Fig. 5. Expressed as percent of
as the major action for the parties to satisfy the targets. GDP, this cost remains high although in Fig. 10 the
In Fig. 8 it is shown that the marginal abatement highest percentage of almost 0.5% of GDP appears for
cost is higher for Japan and the rest of the developed the Rest of Annex I (RoAI) countries. There are two
countries. It is zero for Russia due to its emissions main reasons for this. First, even if the absolute Kyoto
surplus and very small for the CEE countries target for these countries is low, it represents a high
which must invest on the reduction of low emission percentage of their total emissions because of their high
levels. emissions growth as represented in the reference
In Fig. 9 the total cost for the USA is the highest, due scenario. The second reason is that these countries show
mainly to the amount of emissions that has to be a relative low GDP.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 33

Fig. 7. Emissions reduction following the Marrakesh Accords.

Fig. 8. Marginal abatement cost for 2010 with the inclusion of USA.

The total cost for the implementation of the Protocol, introduced allowing the acquisition of emission credits
based only on domestic efforts, is high for the developed from other countries having a surplus of emission
countries. Therefore several trading mechanisms were credits. Emissions trading has been analyzed as a
ARTICLE IN PRESS
34 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

Fig. 9. Cost/Profit for implementation of the Kyoto Protocol for the period 1990–2010 with the participation of the USA. Plus means cost, minus
profits.

Fig. 10. Cost related to GDP for the period 1990–2010 if USA participates.

complementary action to domestic efforts for two shown that the marginal abatement cost is 67$/t C while
different cases. the total costs is almost 40% lower for the developed
According to a first scenario, only Annex I countries countries except for the USA where the cost reduction is
participate in the trading mechanism. From Fig. 8 it is little less. If all countries are participating in the trading
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 35

the relevant figures are 33.2$/t C and 50–65% reduction willingness of the other parties to offer significant
in the total cost. The problem in this case is located in bonuses to these two major countries in order to succeed
the reduction of the gains for Russia which are down the ratification of the Protocol by these two parties. This
almost to the 13 of the corresponding for Annex I trading. paper examines how the Marrakech Accords will affect
This is due to the fact that Russia is losing its dominant the total costs.
role in the trading mechanism as a large amount of As it can be seen in Figs. 9 and 10 the introduction of
emission credits are available in the trading mechanism sinks reduces the total costs for the developed countries.
from the rest of the developing countries. The total cost The cases that have been investigated are the same with
for the developed countries is low in such a case, as they those examined for the initial Protocol. The results for
tend to buy cheap credits from the market instead of the revised Protocol are almost the same with results
implementing expensive domestic actions. More specific, from the corresponding experiments on the initial
the developed countries manage to reach the Protocol scenario. The total cost for the revised Protocol is
targets by limiting domestic efforts near 30% and using nearly 10% less for all countries. The gains for Russia
the trading mechanisms for buying 70% of the emission are slightly increased by 2.5–10%. The most favorable
credits that the had to reduce. Developed countries in situation for Russia could be an Annex I trading system
fact sustain almost the same levels of emissions as in the with sinks also taken into consideration. The gains in
baseline case. Trading mechanism in this case acts as a such a case exceed 2.5% of the GDP. But also in the case
tool to cover the obligations towards the Protocol in a where a restricted trading system is introduced, the gains
cost effective way. for Russia reach 1.7% of the GDP. A restricted trading
The Kyoto Protocol does not quantify the percentage mechanism seems to be the most realistic case at this
of domestic actions in the total efforts to reduce period. This happens because EU focuses on domestic
emissions, but it declares clearly that domestic actions efforts and on the other hand Russia insists on
should be preferred. Moreover, it was shown that guaranteed gains, as it was clearly declared in the recent
trading is the preferred action for the developed COP 9 that took place in Milan, (UNFCC (United
countries and this actually counteracts to the Kyoto Nations Framework on Climate Change)). The intro-
targets. To overcome this, a restriction in the trading duction of sinks is also a cost beneficial option for the
quantities was assumed for the credit buying countries. other developed countries leading to a reduction of their
A limit of 30% of the region target was set for both total costs.
Annex I and International trading cases. The marginal
abatement cost is once again significantly lower than in 4.2. Evolution of the Kyoto Protocol without the
the case of domestic only efforts except for Russia and participation of the USA
the CEE countries which show a small increase. The
experiments showed that the gains for the developed The recent developments in the Kyoto Protocol
countries are substantial compared to the initial scenario ratification process related to the participation of the
but far away from those that could have been succeeded USA lead to an additional analysis of its evolution. As a
in the case that no restriction existed. The gains are 25% consequence of that a new structure of the cost is
and 50% for the Annex I countries (Fig. 9) compared to expected differentiating the profits and deficits between
the initial scenario for Annex I and International the regions. In this section of the paper we investigated
trading respectively. The corresponding gains for USA the evolution of the Kyoto Protocol without the
are a little less while the gains are decreased significantly participation of the USA. The cases that were examined
for Russia and the CEE countries. are the same with those in the previous sections. But
The most important step in the Kyoto Protocol additionally we investigate the case of a boycott
negotiations was the introduction of sinks which movement against USA because of its unwillingness to
weakens the initial Protocol and reflects the current ratify the Protocol.
form of the Protocol after the Marrakesh Accords. Figs. 11–13 when compared to Figs. 8–10 show that
Several authors have worked on the quantification of the USA absence influences significantly the economic
the sinks for every region. Jotzo and Michaelowa (2002) consequences from the Kyoto Protocol. The absence of
estimated the clean development mechanism market USA, which is the major emissions producing country
after the Marrakech Accords and helped significantly in limits the emission credits buyers and this leads to a
the estimation of the new targets of the revised Protocol. significant reduction in the marginal abatement cost in
The Marrakech agreement was a success mainly due to the trading mechanism. Marginal abatement cost
the satisfaction of Russia in its request of doubling the reaches 12.1$/t C in case of International trading and
sink credits. Sink credits reached 53.13 Mt C while the 10.2$/t C when also sinks are considered. Comparing
total sum is 192.2 Mt C. Also the USA sinks reached Fig. 8 with Fig. 11 it is shown that the marginal
62.9 Mt C and the sum of the sinks of Russia and the abatement costs are a little lower for the other cases,
USA exceed 60% of the total sinks. This reflects the compared with the corresponding experiments with the
ARTICLE IN PRESS
36 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

participation of the USA, and this leads to a reduction USA suffers from the boycott movement because of
in the loses for the other Annex I countries. The gains loses in the exports. In the other two cases, concerning
for Annex I countries are almost 50% for the cases Annex I and international trading, results show a slight
where no restriction exists in trading, while the gains in increase in total cost compared to the respective cases
the case where there exists a restriction in trading are without the boycott movement. This increase hardly
35% and lower. On the other hand Russia which is the reaches 0.1% of GDP. Loses in the USA economy are
major emissions credits seller, sustains significant losses increased and reach 0.6% of GDP. This result, though
compared to the case where the USA participates the significant, is less than the expected linear projection of
trading mechanism. The reduction in the gains of Russia the 10% reduction in the USA economy. This is due to
reaches almost 65% for the whole cases. It can be clearly the fact that trade with developed countries is less
understood that the participation of the USA influences important to the US than is trade with the US to these
the economic consequences of the Protocol more than countries. So, a boycott movement could become
the trading mechanisms. partially a possible reaction to apply pressure in the
One possible counter action that could be taken is a USA to ratify the Kyoto Protocol.
boycott movement against the countries that do not
participate. In this study a boycott movement against 4.3. An estimation of the profits for Russia
products from the USA was examined, by introducing a
‘tax like’ 10% increase in the price of products from the The key factor concerning the ratification of the
USA. Despite the World Trade Organization (WTO), Kyoto Protocol by Russia is that Russia will retain
that could invoke counter measures against such a certain profits by its participation. The current skeptical
movement, the experiment is possible in the sense that position of Russia is justified by a number of reasons.
citizens of other countries would not prefer USA The withdrawal of USA, the emphasis of EU in
products if they are properly informed about the domestic efforts and the inclusion of other eastern
negative attitude of the USA in the problem of global countries, such as Ukraine and Kazakhstan, in Annex I
warming. Boycott movement was examined for three group increases the carbon leakage, reduces the credit
cases. First the case with only domestic efforts is buyers and as a consequence it minimizes the marginal
examined, where results in Figs. 12 and 13 show a abatement cost and alleviates the dominant role of
slight increase in the total cost for the Annex I countries. Russia. It was attempted to reflect all these cases in this

Fig. 11. Marginal abatement cost for 2010 without the participation of USA.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 37

Fig. 12. Cost/profit for implementation of the Kyoto Protocol for the period 1990–2010 without the participation of the USA. Plus means cost,
minus profits.

contribution by studying the absence of USA, the from its early signing until now adding new elements in
restriction in trading and the participation of other existing publications. The GEM, GTAP-E, was selected
eastern countries in the trading mechanism, respectively. for this contribution because of its detailed representa-
Therefore, it would be of interest to estimate the tion of the energy system and its ability to capture the
expected incomes for Russia following its participation influence of energy policy in the economy. The different
with guaranteed gains. To account for this a guaranteed policies were evaluated and compared with a reference
minimum of 60% is set regarding the credits sold by scenario, which was based on national reports. Com-
Russia compared to its total available credits. Further- parison among different strategies showed the different
more investigation of the case that USA participates has economic consequences for every region of interest. The
shown that Russia will certainly export credits of more implementation of the Kyoto Protocol with only
than 60%. In the following experiments it was assumed domestic efforts proves to have significant costs for the
that the USA does not participate to the Protocol. developed countries. Trading mechanisms may lead to a
In Fig. 14 it is shown that the consideration of a considerable reduction of these costs and provide in
guaranteed minimum does not affect in general the gains parallel significant gains for Russia. Also the introduc-
for Russia, meaning that the credits sold are more than tion of sinks weakens the targets of the initial Protocol
60% in most cases. Only in the case of restricted and reduces the cost for the developed countries. The
international trading the inclusion of such a minimum participation of the USA seems to affect considerably
leads to an improvement in the gains of Russia by 10% the cost of every partner more than the participation of
and 23% for the cases without or with sinks, respec- any other involved region. The absence of the USA can
tively. The rest credit sellers share the losses introduced not be alleviated by any measure considered in this
by the secure minimum almost linearly. report, therefore it influences greatly the viability of the
Protocol. In absence of the USA, Russia must ratify for
the Protocol to be valid. Therefore we compared cases
5. Conclusions where a specific minimum trading of the emission credits
is guaranteed for Russia to the case of a free trading
This paper provides an integrated report of strategies, mechanism. Results show that Russia’s profits resulting
concerning the implementation of the Kyoto Protocol by its participation are present even with no warranties
ARTICLE IN PRESS
38 A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39

Fig. 13. Cost related to GDP for the period 1990–2010 if USA does not participate.

Fig. 14. Profits for Russia under consideration of a secure minimum in its surplus credits sales.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A.S. Dagoumas et al. / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 26–39 39

in the cases examined except few cases of restricted IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change), 2000. Special
international emission credits trading. But these cases report on land use, land-use change and forestry, http://
www.ipcc.ch/pub/srlulucf-e.pdf.
seem unlikely to happen.
IEA (International Energy Agency). Climate change. http://
www.iea.org/.
IMF (International Monetary Fund), 2002. World Economic Outlook,
References http://www.imf.org/.
Jotzo, F., Michaelowa, A., 2002. Estimating the CDM market under
Armington, P.S., 1969. A theory of demand for products distinguished the Marrakech Accords. Climate Policy 2, 179–196.
by place of production. IMF Staff Papers 16, 159–178. Kuik, O., Gerlagh, R., 2003. Trade liberalization and carbon leakage.
AIM (Asian-Pacific Integrated Model), http://www.nies.go.jp/social/ The Energy Journal 24 (3).
aim. McKibbin, W.J., Wilcoxen, P.J., 2002. The role of economics in
Babiker, M.H., Reilly, J.M., Mayer, M., Eckaus, R.S., Wing, I.S., climate change policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16,
Hyman, R.C., 2001. The MIT emissions prediction and policy 107–129.
analysis (EPPA) model: revisions, sensitivities, and comparisons of MURE (Mesures d’Utilisation Rationelle de l’Ènergie), http://
results. Report No. 71. www.mure2.com/.
Bahn, O., Barreto, L., Kypreos, S., 2001. Modeling and assessing inter- OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development).
regional GHG Emissions Trading. IEA information paper. Climate change, http://www.oecd.org/.
Bernard, A., Reilly, J., Vielle, M., Viguier, L., 2002. The Effects of the Painuly, J.P., 2001. The Kyoto Protocol, Emissions Trading and the
US Withdrawal from the Kyoto Protocol on International CDM: An Analysis from Developing Countries Perspective. The
Emission Trading. Paper prepared for the International Energy Energy Journal 22 (3), 147–169.
Workshop jointly organized by the Energy Modeling Forum Paltsev, S.V., 2001. The Kyoto Protocol and sectoral contributions to
(EMF), International Energy Agency (IEA) and IIASA. the carbon leakage. The Energy Journal 22 (4).
Bohringer, C., 2002. Climate politics from Kyoto to Bonn: from little Rutherford, T.F., Babiker, M.H., 1998. GTAP-E: A global energy-
to nothing?. The Energy Journal 23 (2), 51–71. economy dataset. Technical Report, Economics Department,
Burniaux, J., Nicoletti, G., Oliveira-Martins, J., 1992. GREEN: A University of Colorado.
global model for quantifying the cost of policies to curb CO2 Springer, U., 2003. The market for tradable GHG permits under the
emissions. OECD Economic Studies 19, 123–140. Kyoto Protocol: a survey of model studies. Energy Economics 25,
Burniaux, J.-M., Truong, T.P., 2002. GTAP-E: An energy- environ- 527–551.
mental version of the GTAP Model. GTAP Technical Paper No. 16. Thomas, H., 1997. Global Trade Analysis: modeling and applications.
Chen, W., 2002. Carbon quota price and CDM potentials after Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Marrakech. Energy Policy 31, 709–719. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework on Climate Change). The
Christopher, N.M., James, A.E., Son, H.K., Ronald, D.S., 1999. The Kyoto Protocol to the Convention on Climate change, http://
economics of the Kyoto Protocol. Special issue. ‘‘The Cost of the unfccc.int/resource/docs/convkp/kpeng.pdf.
Kyoto Protocol’’. The Energy Journal, 25–72. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework on Climate Change). COP 7.
Criqui, P., Mima, S., Viguier, L., 1999. Marginal abatement costs of Seventh session of the Conference of Parties, 29 October–9
CO2 emission reductions, geographical flexibility and concrete November, Marrakesh, Morocco, http://unfccc.int/cop7/in-
ceilings: an assessment using the POLES model. Energy Policy 27, dex.html.
585–601. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework on Climate Change). COP 9.
den Elzen, M.G.J., de Moor, A.P.G., 2002. Analyzing the Kyoto Ninth session of the Conference of Parties, 1–12 December, Milan,
Protocol under the Marrakech accords: economic efficiency and http://unfccc.int/cop9/index.html.
environmental effectiveness. Ecological Economics 43, 141–158. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Dimaranan, B.V., McDougall, R.A., 2002. Global trade, assistance, Change). National Communications from Parties included in
and production: The GTAP 5 data base, Center for Global Trade Annex I to the convention, http://unfccc.int/resource/natcom/
Analysis, Purdue University, http://www.agecon.purdue.edu/. nctable.html.
Ellerman, A.D., Decaux, A., 1998. Analysis of Post-Kyoto CO2 Viquier, L.L., Babiker, MH., Reilly, J.M., 2003. The costs of the
emissions trading using marginal abatement curves. MIT report 40. Kyoto Protocol in the European Union. Energy Policy 31,
EIA (Energy Information Agency, International Energy Outlook), 459–481.
2003. http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/ieo/. Weyant, J.P., Hill, J. (Eds.), 1999. The cost of the Kyoto Protocol: A
Gusbin, D., Klaassen, G., Kouvaritakis, N., 1999. Costs of a ceiling on Multi-Model Evaluation. Special issue, 1–390.
Kyoto flexibility. Energy Policy 27, 833–844. Zhang, Z.X., 2001. An assessment of the EU proposal for ceilings in
Hamasaki, H., 2002. The Economic and Environmental Impact of the the use of Kyoto flexibility mechanisms. Ecological Economics 37,
US Withdrawal from the Kyoto Protocol. 53–69.

You might also like