You are on page 1of 11

Macroeconomics.

Lectures

Тopic 1. Macroeconomics as a science.

1. Subject matter of Macroeconomics, its development and Major Problems


(interrelation with other economic sciences).
2. Macroeconomic Goals, tools and indicators.
3. Macroeconomic methods and models.

KEY CONCEPTS
Macroeconomics Inflation and deflation Recession Models
Microeconomics Unemployment Depression Flexible and sticky prices
circular-flow diagram business sector stocks and foreign sector
flows
government sector household sector aggregate

1. Subject matter of Macroeconomics and its Major Problems (interrelation with


other economic sciences)

Why have some countries experienced rapid growth in incomes over the past century
while others have stayed mired in poverty? Why do some countries have high rates of
inflation while others maintain stable prices? Why do all countries experience recessions
and depressions—recurrent periods of falling incomes and rising unemployment— and
how government policy can reduce the frequency and severity of these episodes.
Macroeconomics attempts to answer these and many related questions.
To appreciate the importance of macroeconomics, you need only head over to some
online news Web site. Every day you can see headlines such as INCOME GROWTH
REBOUNDS, FED MOVES TO COMBAT INFLATION, or STOCKS FALL AMID
RECESSION FEARS. These macroeconomic events may seem abstract, but they touch all
of our lives. Business executives forecasting the demand for their products must guess
how fast consumers’ incomes will grow. Senior citizens living on fixed incomes wonder
how fast prices will rise. Recent college graduates looking for jobs hope that the economy
will boom and that firms will be hiring.
Because the state of the economy affects everyone, macroeconomic issues play a
central role in national political debates. Voters are aware of how the economy is doing,
and they know that government policy can affect the economy in powerful ways. As a
result, the popularity of president often rises when the economy is doing well and falls
when it is doing poorly.
Macroeconomic issues are also central to world politics, and the international news is
filled with macroeconomic questions. Although the job of making economic policy
belongs to world leaders, the job of explaining the workings of the economy as a whole
falls to macroeconomists.
Toward this end, macroeconomists collect data on incomes, prices, unemployment,
and many other variables from different time periods and different countries. They then
attempt to formulate general theories to explain these data. Like astronomers studying the
evolution of stars or biologists studying the evolution of species, macroeconomists cannot
conduct controlled experiments in a laboratory. Instead, they must make use of the data
that history gives them.
Macroeconomists observe that economies differ across countries and that they change
over time. These observations provide both the motivation for developing macroeconomic
theories and the data for testing them.
To be sure, macroeconomics is an imperfect science. The macroeconomist’s ability
to predict the future course of economic events is no better than the meteorologist’s ability
to predict next month’s weather. But, as you will see, macroeconomists know quite a lot
about how economies work. This knowledge is useful both for explaining economic events
and for formulating economic policy.

Many subjects are studied on various levels. Consider biology, for example.
Molecular biologists study the chemical compounds that make up living things.
Cellular biologists study cells, which are made up of many chemical compounds and,
at the same time, are themselves the building blocks of living organisms.
Evolutionary biologists study the many varieties of animals and plants.
Economics is also studied on various levels.
Usually Economists develop economic principles and models at two levels.
According to this Economic Science consists of two main parts: microeconomics and
macroeconomics.
Microeconomics is the study of how households and firms make decisions and how
these decisionmakers interact in the marketplace.
Microeconomics is the part of economics concerned with decision-making by
individual consumers, households, and business firms.
At this level of analysis, we observe the details of their behavior. We measure the
price of a specific product, the number of workers employed by a single firm, the revenue
or the expenditures of a specific firm.
A central principle of microeconomics is that households and firms optimize—they
do the best they can for themselves given their objectives and the constraints they face. In
microeconomic models, households choose their purchases to maximize their level of
satisfaction, which economists call utility, and firms make production decisions to
maximize their profits.
Macroeconomics examines either the economy as a whole or its basic subdivisions
or aggregates, such as the government, household, business and foreign sectors. It
examines the forces that affect firms, consumers, and workers in the aggregate.
An aggregate is a collection of specific economic units treated as if they were one
unit. Macroeconomics speaks of such economic measures as total output, total
employment, total income, aggregate expenditures, and the general level of prices in
analyzing various economic problems. In using aggregates, macroeconomics seeks to
obtain an overview of the structure of the economy and the relationships of its major
aggregates.
Because economy-wide events arise from the interaction of many households and
firms, macroeconomics and microeconomics are inextricably linked. When we study the
economy as a whole, we must consider the decisions of individual economic actors. For
example, to understand what determines total consumer spending, we must think about a
family deciding how much to spend today and how much to save for the future. To
understand what determines total investment spending, we must think about a firm
deciding whether to build a new factory. Because aggregate variables are the sum of the
variables describing many individual decisions, macroeconomic theory rests on a
microeconomic foundation.
Although microeconomic decisions underlie all economic models, in many models
the optimizing behavior of households and firms is implicit rather than explicit.
The micro–macro distinction does not mean that every topic can be readily labeled as
either micro or macro; many topics and subdivisions of economics are rooted in both.
Microeconomics and macroeconomics are closely intertwined because changes in
the overall economy arise from the decisions of millions of individuals. So it is
impossible to understand macroeconomic developments without considering the
associated microeconomic decisions.
Example: While the problem of unemployment is usually treated as a
macroeconomic topic (because unemployment relates to aggregate production),
economists recognize that the decisions made by individual workers, and the way specific
labor markets encourage or impede hiring are also critical in determining the
unemployment rate.
So Macroeconomics studies the behavior of the economy as a whole.
Macroeconomics is primarily concerned with two topics: a) long-run economic growth,
and b) the short-run fluctuations in output and employment that are often referred to as
the business cycle. These phenomena are closely related because they happen
simultaneously.

The subject matter of macroeconomics is a mechanism of functioning of the entire


economy; factors that determine changes in this mechanism, and government methods of
influence on economic processes.
The object of macroeconomic analysis is the economic system and its aggregated
parameters.

Basic subdivisions or aggregates of economy or in other words macroeconomic


actors include:
1) household sector forms labor supply and demand for goods and services,
consumes one part of income and saves another part;
2) business sector is the aggregate of all companies in the country that form demand
for factors of production, create supply of goods and services, and make investments.
3) government sector creates specific goods and services such as security, science,
healthcare, education, develops infrastructure, buys goods, collects taxes, pays transfers,
creates money supply.
4) foreign sector is the aggregate of all companies, governments and institutions
abroad.

The development of macroeconomics was one of the major breakthroughs of


economics in twentieth century, leading to a much better understanding of how to combat
periodic economic crises and how to stimulate long-term economic growth. In response to
the Great Depression 1923-33, John Maynard Keynes developed his revolutionary
theory, as he tried to understand the economic mechanism that produced the Great
Depression.
This theory helped explain the forces producing economic fluctuations and suggested
how governments can control the worst excesses of the business cycle.
After World War II, influence of Keynesian views increased, and his theory has been
popular until 1960’s.

Well, the functions of Macroeconomics or the reasons to learn it properly are:


1. Cognitive function – economists investigate economic occurrences, facts and
then formulate principles and laws of macroeconomic development.
2. Prognostic function – economists create predictions and construct national
economy’s development trends.
3. Practical function: a) economists help the government to develop economic
policy; b) knowledge in Macroeconomics helps people to understand the effects of
government economic policy.

2. Goals, tools (инструмент) and indicators of Macroeconomics.

Economic growth is the major objective of macroeconomic development of every


country. That’s why Governments usually set and try to manage certain goals of
macroeconomic policy.
The main goals of macroeconomic policy are:
1. A high and growing level of national output
2. High employment with low unemployment
3. A stable or gently rising price level
Governments usually use two major kinds of policies that can be implemented to
pursue its macroeconomic goals—fiscal policy and monetary policy, which often use such
instruments as: Government expenditures, Taxation, Buying and selling bonds, regulating
financial institutions etc.
Indicators
In order to understand how economies operate and how their performance might be
improved, economists collect and analyze economic data.
A lot of data items can be looked at, including the amount of new construction taking
place each month, and how many new inventions have been patented in the last few
weeks. But macroeconomists tend to focus on just a few statistics when trying to assess
the health and development of an economy. Chief among these are real GDP,
unemployment, and inflation.
1. Real GDP, or real gross domestic product, measures the value of final goods and
services produced within the borders of a given country during a given period of time,
typically a year.
2. Unemployment is the state of a person, when he or she cannot get a job despite
being willing to work and actively seeking work.
3. Inflation is an increase in the overall level of prices.

3. Macroeconomic methods and models.

Macroeconomics uses both general and specific methods of research. General


methods –are the ones inherent in any economic science. For ex.:
1. Induction – transition from facts to theoretic principles
2. Deduction - formulating and testing hypotheses to obtain theories
3. Analysis – dividing complicated phenomenon into simple parts
4. Comparison – revealing common features and differences in economic
occurrences (facts)
5. Model building – using mathematical models and graphs.
6. Abstraction method – omitting details

Specific methods –are the ones inherent in Macroeconomics only. They are:
aggregation is joining of phenomena and processes into one, concerning economic
actors and markets;
method of stocks and flows accounting
Many economic variables measure a quantity of something—a quantity of money, a
quantity of goods, and so on. Economists distinguish between two types of quantity
variables: stocks and flows. A stock is a quantity measured at a given point in time,
whereas a flow is a quantity measured per unit of time.
A bathtub, shown in Figure 2-2, is the classic example used to illustrate stocks and
flows. The amount of water in the tub is a stock: it is the quantity of water in the tub at a
given point in time. The amount of water coming out of the faucet is a flow: it is the
quantity of water being added to the tub per unit of time. Note that we measure stocks and
flows in different units.
We say that the bathtub contains 50 gallons of water but that water is coming out of
the faucet at 5 gallons per minute.
Stocks and flows are often related. In the bathtub example, these relationships are
clear. The stock of water in the tub represents the accumulation of the flow out of the
faucet, and the flow of water represents the change in the stock.
When building theories to explain economic variables, it is often useful to determine
whether the variables are stocks or flows and whether any relationships link them.
Here are some examples of related stocks and flows that we study in future later:
■ A person’s wealth is a stock; his income and expenditure are flows.
■ The number of unemployed people is a stock; the number of people losing their
jobs is a flow.
■ The amount of capital in the economy is a stock; the amount of investment is a
flow.
■ The government debt is a stock; the government budget deficit is a flow.

equilibrium or balance method, on which the system of national accounts is built.


Method of exceptions (savings, tax payments and imports) and injections (investment,
government spending and exports) from income-expenditure stream. "
Macroeconomic Model building.
circular-flow diagram
Macroeconomic models are formalized (logically, graphically or algebraically),
descriptions of the various economic phenomena and processes in order to identify
functional relationships between them. All models—in physics, biology, and economics -
simplify reality to improve our understanding of it.

Economists use models often composed of diagrams and equations. Economic


models omit many irrelevant details for studying the particular question and do not
include every feature of the economy to allow us to see what is important. All the models
are built with certain assumptions.

Macroeconomic models also clarify many important questions about the powers
and limits of government economic policy. These include:
• Can governments promote long-run economic growth?
• Can they reduce the severity of recessions by smoothing out short-run fluctuations?
• Are certain government policy tools like manipulating interest rates (monetary
policy) more effective than other government policy tools such as changes in tax rates or
levels of government spending (fiscal policy)?
• Is there a trade-off between lower rates of unemployment and higher rates of
inflation?
Maybe one of the most famous Macroeconomic models is the circular-flow diagram
– a visual model of the economy that shows how amounts of money flow through markets
among households and firms. Because of its simplicity, this circular-flow diagram is
useful for a basic understanding of how the economy is organized, and how the pieces of
the economy fit together. A more complex and realistic circular-flow model would
include, for instance, the roles of government and international trade.

Figure 3-1 more accurately reflects how real economies function. It shows the
linkages among the economic actors—households, firms, and the government—and how
dollars flow among them through the various markets in the economy.
Let’s look at the flow of dollars from the viewpoints of these economic actors.
Households receive income and use it to pay taxes to the government, to consume goods
and services, and to save through the financial markets. Firms receive revenue from the
sale of the goods and services they produce and use it to pay for the factors of production.
Households and firms borrow in financial markets to buy investment goods, such as
houses and factories. The government receives revenue from taxes and uses it to pay for
government purchases. Any excess of tax revenue over government spending is called
public saving, which can be either positive (a budget surplus or negative (a budget deficit).
Summary

1. Macroeconomics is the study of the economy as a whole, including growth in incomes,


changes in prices, and the rate of unemployment. Macroeconomists attempt both to explain
economic events and to devise policies to improve economic performance.
2. To understand the economy, economists use models—theories that simplify reality in order
to reveal how exogenous variables influence endogenous variables. The art in the science of
economics lies in judging whether a model captures the important economic relationships for
the matter at hand. Because no single model can answer all questions, macroeconomists use
different models to look at different issues.
3. A key feature of a macroeconomic model is whether it assumes that prices are flexible or
sticky. According to most macroeconomists, models with flexible prices describe the economy
in the long run, whereas models with sticky prices offer a better description of the economy in
the short run.
4. Microeconomics is the study of how firms and individuals make decisions and how these
decisionmakers interact. Because macroeconomic events arise from many microeconomic
interactions, all macroeconomic models must be consistent with microeconomic foundations,
even if those foundations are only implicit.
EXTRA INFORMATION
Nobel Macroeconomists

The Nobel Prize in economics is announced every October. Over the years, many
winners have been macroeconomists. Here are a few of them, along with some of their own
words about how they chose their career paths.
Milton Friedman (Nobel 1976): “I graduated from college in 1932, when the United
States was at the bottom of the deepest depression in its history before or since. The dominant
problem of the time was economics. How to get out of the depression? How to reduce
unemployment? What explained the paradox of great need on the one hand and unused
resources on the other? Under the circumstances, becoming an economist seemed more
relevant to the burning issues of the day than becoming an applied mathematician or an
actuary.”
James Tobin (Nobel 1981): “I was attracted to the field for two reasons. One was
that economic theory is a fascinating intellectual challenge, on the order of mathematics or
chess. I liked analytics and logical argument». The other reason was the obvious relevance of
economics to understanding and perhaps overcoming the Great Depression.”
Franco Modigliani (Nobel 1985): “For a while it was thought that I should study
medicine because my father was a physician. I went to the registration window to sign up for
medicine, but then I closed my eyes and thought of blood!
I got pale just thinking about blood and decided under those conditions I had better
keep away from medicine. Casting about for something to do, I happened to get into some
economics activities. I knew some German and was asked to translate from German into
Italian some articles for one of the trade associations. Thus I began to be exposed to the
economic problems that were in the German literature.”
Robert Solow (Nobel 1987): “I came back [to college after being in the army] and,
almost without thinking about it, signed up to finish my undergraduate degree as an
economics major.
The time was such that I had to make a decision in a hurry. No doubt I acted as if I
were maximizing an infinite discounted sum of one-period utilities, but you couldn’t prove it
by me. To me it felt as if I were saying to myself: ‘What the hell.’”
Robert Lucas (Nobel 1995): “In public school science was an unending and not very
well organized list of things other people had discovered long ago. In college, I learned
something about the process of scientific discovery, but what I learned did not attract me as a
career possibility. . What I liked thinking about were politics and social issues.”
George Akerlof (Nobel 2001): “When I went to Yale, I was convinced that I wanted
to be either an economist or an historian. Really, for me it was a distinction without a
difference. If I was going to be an historian, then I would be an economic historian. And if I
was to be an economist, I would consider history as the basis for my economics.”
Edward Prescott (Nobel 2004): “Through discussion with my father, I learned a lot
about the way businesses operated. This was one reason why I liked my microeconomics
course so much in my first year at Swarthmore College. The price theory that I learned in that
course rationalized what I had learned from him about the way businesses operate. The other
reason was the textbook used in that course, Paul A. Samuelson’s Principles of Economics. I
loved the way Samuelson laid out the theory in his textbook, so simply and clearly.”
Edmund Phelps (Nobel 2006): “Like most Americans entering college, I started at
Amherst College without a predetermined course of study or without even a career goal. My
tacit assumption was that I would drift into the world of business— of money, doing
something terribly smart. In the first year, though, I was awestruck by Plato, Hume, and
James. I would probably have gone into philosophy were it not that my father cajoled and
pleaded with me to try a course in economics, which I did the second year. . . . I was hugely
impressed to see that it was possible to subject the events in those newspapers I had read about
to a formal sort of analysis.”
Christopher Sims (Nobel 2011): “My Uncle Mark prodded me regularly, from about
age 13 onward, to study economics. He gave me von Neumann and Morgenstern’s Theory of
Games for Christmas when I was in high school. When I took my first course in economics, I
remember arguing with him over whether it was possible for the inflation rate to explode
upward if the money supply were held constant. I took the monetarist position. He questioned
whether I had a sound argument to support it. For years I thought he was having the opposite
of his intended effect, and I studied no economics until my junior year of college. But as I
began to doubt that I wanted to be immersed for my whole career in the abstractions of pure
mathematics, Mark’s efforts had left me with a pretty clear idea of an alternative.”
If you want to learn more about the Nobel Prize and its winners, go to
http://www.nobelprize.org.1

You might also like