You are on page 1of 17

American Economic Association

On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets


Author(s): Sanford J. Grossman and Joseph E. Stiglitz
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 70, No. 3 (Jun., 1980), pp. 393-408
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1805228 .
Accessed: 13/08/2013 15:24

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
On the Impossibility of Informationally
Efficient Markets
By SANFORD J. GROSSMAN AND JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ*

If competitive equilibrium is defined as a jectures concerning certain properties of the


situation in which prices are such that all equilibrium. The remaining analytic sections
arbitrage profits are eliminated, is it possible of the paper are devoted to analyzing in
that a competitive economy always be in detail an important example of our general
equilibrium? Clearly not, for then those who model, in which our conjectures concerning
arbitrage make no (private) return from the nature of the equilibrium can be shown
their (privately) costly activity. Hence the to be correct. We conclude with a discussion
assumptions that all markets, including that of the implications of our approach and
for information, are always in equilibrium results, with particular emphasis on the rela-
and always perfectly arbitraged are incon- tionship of our results to the literature on
sistent when arbitrage is costly. "efficient capital markets."
We propose here a model in which there
is an equilibrium degree of disequilibrium: I. The Model
prices reflect the information of informed
individuals (arbitrageurs) but only partially, Our model can be viewed as an extension
so that those who expend resources to ob- of the noisy rational expectations model in-
tain information do receive compensation. troduced by Robert Lucas and applied to
How informative the price system is de- the study of information flows between
pends on the number of individuals who are traders by Jerry Green (1973); Grossman
informed; but the number of individuals (1975, 1976, 1978); and Richard Kihlstrom
who are informed is itself an endogenous and Leonard Mirman. There are two assets:
variable in the model. a safe asset yielding a return R, and a risky
The model is the simplest one in which asset, the return to which, u, varies ran-
prices perform a well-articulated role in con- domly from period to period. The variable u
veying information from the informed to the consists of two parts,
uninformed. When informed individuals ob-
serve information that the return to a secur- (1) = +e
ity is going to be high, they bid its price up,
and conversely when they observe informa- where 9 is observable at a cost c, and e is
tion that the return is going to be low. Thus unobservable.' Both 9 and E are random
the price system makes publicly available variables. There are two types of individu-
the information obtained by informed indi- als, those who observe 9 (informed traders),
viduals to the uniformed. In general, how- and those who observe only price (unin-
ever, it does this imperfectly; this is perhaps formed traders). In our simple model, all
lucky, for were it to do it perfectly, an individuals are, ex ante, identical; whether
equilibrium would not exist. they are informed or uninformed just de-
In the introduction, we shall discuss the pends on whether they have spent c to ob-
general methodology and present some con- tain information. Informed traders' de-
mands will depend on 9 and the price of the
*University of Pennsylvania and Princeton Univer-
risky asset P. Uninformed traders' demands
sity, respectively. Research support under National Sci-
ence Foundation grants SOC76-18771 and SOC77- 'An alternative interpretation is that 0 is a "mea-
15980 is gratefully acknowledged. This is a revised surement" of u with error. The mathematics of this
version of a paper presented at the Econometric alternative interpretation differ slightly, but the results
Society meetings, Winter 1975, at Dallas, Texas. are identical.

393

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
394 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

will depend only on P, but we shall assume which the informed can gain relative to the
that they have rational expectations; they uninformed-is reduced.
learn the relationship between the distribu- (b) Even if the above effect did not
tion of return and the price, and use this in occur, the increase in the ratio of informed
deriving their demand for the risky assets. If to uninformed means that the relative gains
x denotes the supply of the risky asset, an of the informed, on a per capita basis, in
equilibrium when a given percentage, X, of trading with the uninformed will be smaller.
traders are informed, is thus a price function We summarize the above characterization
PA(O,x) such that, when demands are for- of the equilibrium of the economy in the
mulated in the way described, demand following two conjectures:
equals supply. We assume that uninformed Conjecture 1: The more individuals who
traders do not observe x. Uninformed are informed, the more informative is the
traders are prevented from learning 9 via price system.
observations of PA(O,x) because they can- Conjecture2: The more individuals who
not distinguish variations in price due to are informed, the lower the ratio of expected
changes in the informed trader's informa- utility of the informed to the uninformed.
tion from variations in price due to changes (Conjecture 1 obviously requires a defini-
in aggregate supply. Clearly, PA(O,x) reveals tion of "more informative"; this is given in
some of the informed trader's information the next section and in fn. 7.)
to the uninformed traders. The equilibrium number of informed and
We can calculate the expected utility of uninformed individuals in the economy will
the informed and the expected utility of the depend on a number of critical parameters:
uninformed. If the former is greater than the the cost of information, how informative the
latter (taking account of the cost of infor- price system is (how much noise there is to
mation), some individuals switch from being interfere with the information conveyed by
uninformed to being informed (and con- the price system), and how informative the
versely). An overall equilibrium requires the information obtained by an informed indi-
two to have the same expected utility. As vidual is.
more individuals become informed, the ex- Conjecture 3: The higher the cost of
pected utility of the informed falls relative information, the smaller will be the equi-
to the uninformed for two reasons: librium percentage of individuals who are
(a) The price system becomes more in- informed.
formative because variations in 9 have a Conjecture 4: If the quality of the in-
greater effect on aggregate demand and thus formed trader's information increases, the
on price when more traders observe 9. Thus, more their demands will vary with their
more of the information of the informed is information and thus the more prices will
available to the uninformed. Moreover, the vary with 9. Hence, the price system be-
informed gain more from trade with the comes more informative. The equilibrium
uninformed than do the uninformed. The proportion of informed to uninformed may
informed, on average, buy securities when be either increased or decreased, because
they are "underpriced" and sell them when even though the value of being informed has
they are "overpriced" (relative to what increased due to the increased quality of 9,
they would have been if information were the value of being uninformed has also in-
equalized).2 As the price system becomes creased because the price system becomes
more informative, the difference in their in- more informative.
formation-and hence the magnitude by Conjecture 5: The greater the magni-
tude of noise, the less informative will the
price system be, and hence the lower the
2The framework described herein does not explicitly
model the effect of variations in supply, i.e., x on expected utility of uninformed individuals.
commodity storage. The effect of futures markets and Hence, in equilibrium the greater the magni-
storage capabilities on the informativeness of the price tude of noise, the larger the proportion of
system was studied by Grossman (1975, 1977). informed individuals.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 395

Conjecture6: In the limit, when there is the conjectures provided above can be veri-
no noise, prices convey all information, and fied. The next sections are devoted to solv-
there is no incentive to purchase informa- ing for the equilibrium in this particular
tion. Hence, the only possible equilibrium is example.5
one with no information. But if everyone is
uninformed, it clearly pays some individual II. ConstantAbsoluteRisk-AversionModel
to become informed.3 Thus, there does not
exist a competitive equilibrium.4 A. The Securities
Trade among individuals occurs either be-
cause tastes (risk aversions) differ, endow- The ith trader is assumed to be endowed
ments differ, or beliefs differ. This paper with stocks of two types of securities: Mi,
focuses on the last of these three. An inter- the riskless asset, and Xi, a risky asset. Let P
esting feature of the equilibrium is that be- be the current price of risky assets and set
liefs may be precisely identical in either one the price of risk free assets equal to unity.
of two situations: when all individuals are The ith trader's budget constraint is
informed or when all individuals are unin-
formed. This gives rise to: (2) PXI+ Ml=Woi0Mi+ PXi
Conjecture 7: That, other things being
equal, markets will be thinner under those Each unit of the risk free asset pays R
conditions in which the percentage of indi- "dollars" at the end of the period, while
viduals who are informed (X) is either near each unit of the risky asset pays u dollars. If
zero or near unity. For example, markets at the end of the period, the ith trader holds
will be thin when there is very little noise in a portfolio (Mi,X), his wealth will be
the system (so X is near zero), or when costs
of information are very low (so X is near (3) Wli = RM, + uX,
unity).
In the last few paragraphs, we have pro- B. Individual's Utility Maximization
vided a number of conjectures describing
the nature of the equilibrium when prices Each individual has a utility function
convey information. Unfortunately, we have Vi(Wli). For simplicity, we assume all indi-
not been able to obtain a general proof of viduals have the same utility function and
any of these propositions. What we have so drop the subscripts i. Moreover, we
been able to do is to analyze in detail an assume the utility function is exponential,
interesting example, entailing constant ab- i.e.,
solute risk-aversion utility functions anid e-awl a>O
V(Wli)=
normally distributed random variables. In
this example, the equilibrium price distribu- where a is the coefficient of absolute risk
tion can actually be calculated, and all of aversion. Each trader desires to maximize
expected utility, using whatever information
is available to him, and to decide on what
3That is, with no one informed, an individual can information to acquire on the basis of the
only get information by paying c dollars, since no consequences to his expected utility.
information is revealed by the price system. By paying Assume that in equation (1) 9 and e have
c dollars an individual will be able to predict better a multivariate normal distribution, with
than the market when it is optimal to hold the risky
asset as opposed to the risk-free asset. Thus his ex- (4) Ee = 0
pected utility will be higher than an uninformed person
gross of information costs. Thus for c sufficiently low (5) EOe =O
all uninformed people will desire to be informed.
4See Grossman (1975, 1977) for a formal example of
(6) Var(u*19)= Vare*=_a~2>O
this phenomenon in futures markets. See Stiglitz (1971,
1974) for a general discussion of information and the 5The informational equilibria discussed here may
possibility of nonexistence of equilibrium in capital not, in general, exist. See Green (1977). Of course, for
markets. the utility function we choose equilibrium does exist.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
396 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

since 9 and e are uncorrelated. Throughout Then, we can write for the uninformed
this paper we will put a * above a symbol to individual
emphasize that it is a random variable.
Since Wli is a linear function of e, for a (7') E( V( W*i)P*) =-exp -a ttE[ W*IP*]
given portfolio allocation, and a linear func-
tion of a normally distributed random vari- a
able is normally distributed, it follows that -
2 Var[ W*IP*1])
LlJJ
W11is normal conditional on 0. Then, using
(2) and (3) the expected utility of the in-
formed trader with information 9 can be =-exp[-a RWoi+Xu(E[u*IP*]1RP)
written

(7) E( V(Wl*i)10)= -2X Var[u*IP*]}]

a
-exp(-a E[ Wl*10] _ Var[ Wl*1'] ) The demands of the uninformed will thus be
a function of the price function P* and the
actual price P.
=-exp( -a[ RWOi+ X1{E(u*I9)-RP} (8') Xu(P; P*)
E[ u*IP*(9,x) = P] -RP
X2 Var(u*I9)]) a Var[ u*IP*(9, x) =P]
-2
C. EquilibriumPrice Distribution
=-exp(-a[RJWoiV+X1( -RP)
If X is some particular fraction of traders
who decide to become informed, then define
x2 a, ])
-2 Xl an equilibrium price system as a function of
(9, x), PA(O,x), such that for all (9, x) per
capita demands for the risky assets equal
where X, is an informed individual's de- supplies;
mand for the risky security. Maximizing (7)
with respect to X, yields a demand function (9) XXI(PA(9,x),0)
for risky assets:
+ (1- X)XU(PA(9,x); PA) = x
(8) X,(P, 9) = aa2
The function PA(O,x) is a statistical
The right-hand side of (8) shows the familiar equilibrium in the following sense. If over
result that with constant absolute risk aver- time uninformed traders observe many re-
sion, a trader's demand does not depend on alizations of (u*,Px*), then they learn the
wealth; hence the subscript i is not on the joint distribution of (u*, P*). After all learn-
left-hand side of (8). ing about the joint distribution of (u*,P,*)
We now derive the demand function for ceases, all traders will make allocations and
the uninformed. Let us assume the only form expectations such that this joint dis-
source of "noise" is the per capita supply of tribution persists over time. This follows
the risky security x. from (8), (8'), and (9), where the market-
Let P*(.) be some particular price func- clearing price that comes about is the one
tion of (9,x) such that u* and P* are jointly which takes into account the fact that unin-
normally distributed. (We will prove that formed traders have learned that it contains
this exists below.) information.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 397

We shall now prove that there exists an For each replication of the economy, 9 is
equilibrium price distribution such that P* the information that uninformed traders
and u* are jointly normal. Moreover, we would like to know. But the noise x *
shall be able to characterize the price dis- prevents w* from revealing 9. How well-
tribution. We define informed uninformed traders can become
from observing Px* (equivalently wx*) is
a2 measured by Var[w*10]. When Var[w*10] is
(lOa) w,(9,x)=9 0- a (x-Ex*) zero, w,* and 9 are perfectly correlated.
Hence when uninformed firms observe w*,
for X> 0, and define wo(9,x) as the number: this is equivalent to observing 9. On the
other hand, when Var[w*10] is very large,
(lOb) wo(9,x)=x for all (9,x) there are "many" realizations of w,* that are
associated with a given 9. In this case the
where wXis just the random variable 9, plus observation of a particular w,* tells very
noise.6 The magnitude of the noise is in- little about the actual 9 which generated it.7
versely proportional to the proportion of From equation (11) it is clear that large
informed traders, but is proportional to the noise (high Varx*) leads to an imprecise
variance of E. We shall prove that the price system. The other factor which de-
equilibrium price is just a linear function of termines the precision of the price system
wx. Thus, if X>0, the price system conveys (a2a4'/X2) is more subtle. When a is small
information about 9, but it does so imper- (the individual is not very risk averse) or a,2
fectly. is small (the information is very precise), an
informed trader will have a demand for
D. Existence of Equilibriumand risky assets which is very responsive to
a CharacterizationTheorem changes in 9. Further, the larger X is, the
more responsive is the total demand of in-
THEOREM 1: If (0*,?*,x*) has a nonde- formedtraders.Thus small (a2a'4/X2) means
generate joint normal distribution such that that the aggregate demand of informed
9*, E*, and x* are mutually independent,then traders is very responsive to 9. For a fixed
there exists a solution to (9) which has the amount of noise (i.e., fixed Varx*) the
form PX(9,x)=a1+a2wX(9, x), where a1 and larger are the movements in aggregate de-
a2 are real numbers which may depend on A, mand which are due to movements in 9, the
such that a2 >0- (If X= 0, the price contains more will price movements be due to move-
no information about 9.) The exact form of ments in 9. That is, x* becomes less im-
PX(9,x) is given in equation (A 10) in Appen- portant relative to 9 in determining price
dix B. The proof of this theorem is also in movements. Therefore, for small (a2a,'/X2)
Appendix B. uninformed traders are able to confidently
know that price is, for example, unusually
The importance of Theorem 1 rests in the high due to 9 being high. In this way infor-
simple characterization of the information mation from informed traders is transferred
in the equilibrium price system: Px*is infor- to uninformed traders.
mationally equivalent to w*. From (10) w*
is a "mean-preserving spread" of 9; i.e.,
E[w*10]=9 and

(1 1) Var[IwxI Varx* 7Formally, wA is an experiment in the sense of


Blackwell which gives information about 9. It is easy to
show that, ceteris paribus, the smaller Var(wxI1) the
more "informative" (or sufficient) in the sense of
61f y'= y + Z, and E[Z Iy] =O, then y' is just y plus Blackwell, is the experiment; see Grossman, Kihlstrom,
noise. and Mirman (p. 539).

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
398 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

E. Equilibriumin the Information Market F. Existence of Overall Equilibrium

What we have characterized so far is the Theorem 2 is useful, both in proving the
equilibrium price distribution for given X. uniqueness of overall equilibrium and in
We now define an overall equilibrium to be analyzing comparative statics. Overall equi-
a pair (X,PA*)such that the expected utility librium, it will be recalled, requires that for
of the informed is equal to that of the unin- 0<X<1, EV(WI')/EV(Wu")=1. But from
formed if 0 <X < 1; X=0 if the expected (13)
utility of the informed is less than that of
the uninformed at Po*;X= 1 if the expected E V( Wjx)
(14)
utility of the informed is greater than the EV( Wui)
uninformed at P*. Let

(12a) WI'S=R(Woj-c) (U -y )
=eac
Vr(u*Iwx)
+ I u-RP,(9, x) ] X, (P.(9, x), 9)
Hence overall equilibrium simply requires,
( 12b) WuA-=R W0j
for 0<X< 1,
+ [ U- RPA(9, x) ] Xu(Px(0, x); PA*)
(15) y(X)=I

where c is the cost of observing a realization More precisely, we now prove


of 9*. Equation (12a) gives the end of period
wealth of a trader if he decides to become THEOREM 3: If 0< X< 1, y(X)= 1, and P*
informed, while (12b) gives his wealth if he is given by (A 10) in Appendix B, then (X,P*)
decides to be uninformed. Note that end of is an overall equilibrium. If y(1) < 1, then
period wealth is random due to the random- (1,P*) is an overall equilibrium. If y(O)> 1,
ness of W0i, u, 9, and x. then (0, P*) is an overall equilibrium. For all
In evaluating the expected utility of W,i, price equilibria Px which are monotone func-
we do not assume that a trader knows which tions of wx, there exists a unique overall
realization of 9* he gets to observe if he equilibrium(X,Px*).
pays c dollars. A trader pays c dollars and
then gets to observe some realization of 9*. PROOF:
The overall expected utility of W1?,averages The first three sentences follow im-
over all possible 9*, E*, x*, and W0i. The mediately from the definition of overall
variable W0i is random for two reasons. equilibrium given above equation (12), and
First from (2) it depends on P,(9,x), which Theorems 1 and 2. Uniqueness follows from
is random as (9,x) is random. Secondly, in the monotonicity of y(-) which follows from
what follows we will assume that Xi is ran- (Al 1) and (14). The last two sentences in
dom. the statement of the theorem follow im-
We will show below that EV( W,'')/ mediately.
E V(Wu) is independent of i, but is a func-
tion of X, a, c, and a2. More precisely, in In the process of proving Theorem 3, we
Appendix B we prove have noted

THEOREM 2: Under the assumptions of COROLLARY 1: y(X) is a strictly mono-


Theorem 1, and if Xi is independent of tone increasing function of A.
(u*, 9*, x*) then
This looks paradoxical; we expect the
ratio of informed to uninformed expected
(13) EV(W'') =e ac r(u*10) utility to be a decreasing function of X. But,
EV( Wui) Var(u*Iwx) we have defined utility as negative. Therefore

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 399

as X rises, the expected utility of informed EV(W)


traders does go down relative to uninformed
EV(W)) riX
traders.
Note that the function y (0) = eac(Var(u* I
9)/Var u*)l/2. Figure 1 illustrates the de-
termination of the equilibrium X. The figure
assumes that y(O)< 1 <y(l).
9
e ac |v ar (ut1l)
G. Characterizationof Equilibrium
0 A
e 1
We wish to provide some further char-
acterization of the equilibrium. Let us define FIGURE 1

/22 2
(16a) m=(
aa= X) Note that (19) holds for y(O)< 1 <y(l), since
these conditions insure that the equilibrium
X is between zero and one. Equation (19b)
(16b) n=aO2 shows that the equilibrium informativeness
ae2
of the price system is determined completely
by the cost of information c, the quality of
Note that m is inversely related to the the informed trader's information n, and the
informativeness of the price system since the degree of risk aversion a.
squared correlation coefficient between Px*
and 9*, p92is given by H. ComparativeStatics
I From equation (19b), we immediately ob-
(17) po2 =
tain some basic comparative statics results:
Similarly, n is directly related to the quality 1) An increase in the quality of infor-
of the informed trader's information be- mation (n) increases the informativeness of
cause n/(l + n) is the squared correlation the price system.
coefficient between 9* and uO. 2) A decrease in the cost of information
Equations (14) and (15) show that the increases the informativeness of the price
cost of information c, determines the equi- system.
librium ratio of information quality be- 3) A decrease in risk aversion leads
tween informed and uninformed traders informed individuals to take larger posi-
(Var(u*I9))/ Var(u*Iwx).From (1), (A1) of tions, and this increases the informativeness
Appendix A, and (16), this can be written as of the price system.
Further, all other changes in parameters,
(18) such that n, a, and c remain constant,
do not change the equilibrium degree of in-
Var(u*10) 1+ m = + nm formativeness of the price system; other
Var(u*lw,) l+m+nm Il m changes lead only to particular changes in X
of a magnitude to exactly offset them. For
Substituting (18) into (14) and using (15) example:
we obtain, for 0< X < 1, in equilibrium 4) An increase in noise (a2) increases
the proportion of informed traders. At any
(19a) e-
e2ac I
given X, an increase in noise reduces the
1+ n - e2ac informativeness of the price system; but it
increases the returns to information and
or
leads more individuals to become informed;
I e2ac_ the remarkable result obtained above estab-
2_e0
(19b\ lishes that the two effects exactly offset each

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
400 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

other so that the equilibrium informative- improvement in the precision of informed


ness of the price system is unchanged. This traders' information, with the cost of the
can be illustrated diagrammatically if we information fixed, increases the benefit of
note from (16a) that for a given X, an in- being informed. However, some of the im-
crease in a2 raises m which from (18) lowers proved information is transmitted, via a
(Var(u*J0))/Var(u*Iw,). Thus from (14) a more informative price system, to the unin-
rise in a2 leads to a vertical downward shift formed; this increases the benefits of being
of the y(X) curve in Figure 1, and thus a uninformed. If n is small, both the price
higher value of Xe. system m is not very informative and the
5) Similarly an increase in a2 for marginal value of information to informed
a constant n (equivalent to an increase in traders is high. Thus the relative benefits of
the variance of u since n is constant) leads being informed rises when n rises; implying
to an increased proportion of individuals that the equilibrium X rises. Conversely
becoming informed-and indeed again just when n is large the price system is very
enough to offset the increased variance, so informative and the marginal value of infor-
that the degree of informativeness of the mation is low to informed traders so the
price system remains unchanged. This can relative benefits of being uninformed rises.
also be seen from Figure 1 if (16) is used to 7) From (14) it is clear that an increase
note that an increase in a2 with n held in the cost of information c shifts the y(X)
constant by raising ad,leads to an increase in curve up and thus decreases the percentage
m for a given X. From (18) and (14) this of informed traders.
leads to a vertical downward shift of the The above results are summarized in the
yy(A)curve and thus a higher value of Me. following theorem.
6) It is more difficult -o determine what
happens if, say a9 increases, keeping a,2 con- THEOREM 4: For equilibrium X such that
stant (implying a fall in a2), that is, the 0<X< 1:
information obtained is more informative. A. The equilibrium informativeness of the
This leads to an increase in n, which from price system, P2, rises if n rises, c falls, or a
(19b) implies that the equilibrium infor- falls.
mativeness of the price system rises. From B. The equilibrium informativeness of the
(16) it is clear that m and nm both fall when price system is unchanged if a2 changes, or if
a,9 rises (keeping au2=a,9 + a2 constant). This a2 changeswithn fixed.
implies that the y(X) curve may shift up or C. The equilibriumpercentage of informed
down depending on the precise values of c, traders will rise if a2 rises, a2 rises for a fixed
a, and n.8 This ambiguity arises because an n, or c falls.
D. If n-satisfies (e2ac_1)/(in-(e2acDl))=
8From (14) and (18) it is clear that X rises if and only ni/(-+ 1), then n > ii implies that X falls
if Var(u*1j)4 Var(u*lwx) falls due to the rise in a3 for (rises) due to an increase in n.
a given X. This occurs if and only if nm/(l + m) rises.
Using (16) to differentiate nm/(l + m) with respect to PROOF:
a2 subject to the constraint that dao2=0 (i.e., da3=
- da2), we find that the sign of
Parts A - C are proved in the above re-
marks. Part D is proved in footnote 8.
d nm )sgn[m n+I _1
I. Price Cannot Fully Reflect Costly
[(2 n- n)( Information
dc~~
We now consider certain limiting cases,
where y _=-e2_1 and the last equality follows from for -y(O)< 1 < -y(l), and show that equi-
equation (19a). Thus for n very large the derivative is librium does not exist if c >0 and price is
negative so that X falls due to an increase in the fully informative.
precision of the informed trader's information. Simi-
larly if n is sufficiently small, the derivative is positive
1) As the cost of information goes to
and thus X rises. zero, the price system becomes more infor-

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 401

mative, but at a positive value of c, say c, all while if X>0, by (18)


traders are informed. From (14) and (15) e
satisfies EV(Wjs) _eac 1
EV(Wui) /l+n m+
eac Vr(u*1
Var(u*lwl) But if q2=0 or a,2=0, then m=O, nm=O for
X> 0, and hence
2) From (19a) as the precision of the
informed trader's information n goes to in-
finity, i.e., a2-*O and a92-u, a2 held fixed, (21) lim EV( W) =_ eac
the price system becomes perfectly informa- A-0EV(
Wul)
tive. Moreover the percentage of informed.
traders goes to zero! This can be seen from It immediately follows that
(18) and (15). That is, as q20, nm/(I + m)
must stay constant for equilibrium to be THEOREM 5: (a) If there is no noise (a.2=
maintained. But from (19b) and (17), m 0), an overall equilibrium does not exist if
falls as 2 goes to zero. Therefore nm must (and only if) eac< 1+ . (b) If information
fall, but nm must not go to zero or else nm/ is perfect (a,2= 0, n = x), there never exists an
(1+ m) would not be constant. From (16) equilibrium.
nm = (a/X)2q2a.2,and thus X must go to zero
to prevent nm from going to zero as a2--O. PROOF:
3) From (16a) and (19a) it is clear that (a) If eac < 1+ n , then by (20) and (21),
as noise a2 goes to zero, the percentage of y(X) is discontinuous at X = 0; X = 0 is not an
informed traders goes to zero. Further, since equilibrium since by (20) y(O)< 1; X >0 is
(19a) implies that m does not change as not an equilibrium since by (21) -y(X)> 1.
changes, the informativeness of the price (b) If a,2=0 and a 2= a2 so that informa-
system is unchanged as U2O. tion is perfect, then for X >0, nm = 0 by (16)
Assume that c is small enough so that it is and hence -y(Q)>1 by (21). From (20) y(O)=
worthwhile for a trader to become informed 0<1.
when no other trader is informed. Then if
a2=0 or a 2=0, there exists no competitive If there is no noise and some traders be-
equilibrium. To see this, note that equi- come informed, then all their information is
librium requires either that the ratio of ex- transmitted to the uninformed by the price
pected utility of the informed to the unin- system. Hence each informed trader acting
formed be equal to unity, or that if the ratio as a price taker thinks the informativeness
is larger than unity, no one be informed. We of the price system will be unchanged if he
shall show that when no one is informed, it becomes uninformed, so X> 0 is not an
is less than uipity so that X=0 cannot be an equilibrium. On the other hand, if no
equilibrium; but when X> 0, it is greater traders are informed, then each uninformed
than unity. That is, if a2 =0 or a2=0, the trader learns nothing from the price system,
ratio of expected utilities is not a continuous and thus he has a desire to become in-
function of X at X= 0. formed (if eac <(1 + n)"'2). Similarly if the
This follows immediately from observing informed traders get perfect information,
that at X= 0, Var(u*wo) = Varu*, and thus then their demands are very sensitive to
by (14) their information, so that the market-clear-
ing price becomes very sensitive to their
information and thus reveals 0 to the unin-
(20) W+_ eac
EV(W,) formed. Hence all traders desire to be un-
EV(Wug)2
informed. But if all traders are uninformed,
each trader can eliminate the risk of his
-eac ____
1+ n portfolio by the purchase of information, so
each trader desires to be infermed.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
402 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

In the next section we show that the non- ples' beliefs differ slightly, then the competi-
existence of competitive equilibrium can be tive equilibrium allocation that an individ-
thought of as the breakdown of competitive ual gets will be only slightly different from
markets due to lack of trade. That is, we will his initial endowment. Hence, there will
show that as a' gets very small, trade goes only be a slight benefit to entering the com-
to zero and markets serve no function. Thus petitive market. This could, for sufficiently
competitive markets close for lack of trade high operating costs, be outweighed by the
"before" equilibrium ceases to exist at cost of entering the market.
2 =o. The amount of trade occurring at any
date is a random variable; a function of 9
III. On the Thinnessof SpeculativeMarkets and x. It is easy to show that it is a normally
distributed random variable. Since one of
In general, trade takes place because the primary determinants of the size of
traders differ in endowments, preferences, markets is differences in beliefs, one might
or beliefs. Grossman (1975, 1977, 1978) has have conjectured that markets will be thin,
argued that differences in preferences are in some sense, if almost all traders are either
not a major factor in explaining the magni- informed or uninformed. This is not, how-
tude of trade in speculative markets. For ever, obvious, since the amount of trade by
this reason the model in Section II gave all any single trader may be a function of A as
traders the same risk preferences (note that well, and a few active traders can do the job
none of the results in Section II are affected of many small traders. In our model, there is
by letting traders have different coefficients a sense, however, in which our conjecture is
of absolute risk aversion). In this section we correct.
assume that trade requires differences in We first calculate the magnitude of trades
endowments or beliefs and dispense with as a function of the exogenous parameters, 9
differences in risk preference as an explana- and x. Let ha2 X-=Ex*, and 9 =E9*.
tory variable.9 (The actual trades will depend on the dis-
There is clearly some fixed cost in operat- tribution of random endowments across all
ing a competitive market. If traders have to of the traders, but these we shall net out.)
bear this cost, then trade in the market must Per capita net trade is 10
be beneficial. Suppose traders have the same
endowments and beliefs. Competitive equi- (22) X i h(
librium will leave them with allocations
which are identical with their initial endow- + [(m+ 1)n- 1](9-
ments. Hence, if it is costly to enter such a )+.xnm]
competitive market, no trader would ever
enter. We will show below that in an im- . [1+m+Xnm]
portant class of situations, there is continu-
ity in the amount of net trade. That is, when '0Calculation of distribution of net trades
initial endowments are the same and peo-
(0- RPA)
ah

9In the model described in Section II it was assumed (I-A)[(#- RP,)(1 + m)n+ - ah (x
that an individual's endowment Xi is independent of
the market's per capita endowment x*. This was done ah(l +m+nm)n
primarily so there would not be useful information in (0 -RPA) (I1-X)(1+ m)
an individual's endowment about the total market en- or ( A)(+ + ( (
ah I +m+nm
dowment. Such information would be useful in equi-
librium because an individual observes PX(O,x). If due 0- I m
to observing Xi, he knows something about x, then by RPA l+ +nmA
ah lI +m +nmJ
observing PX(O,x), Xi is valuable in making inferences
about 0. To take this into account is possible, but (1 -X)([(m+ l)n-1](_-#)+ a) (x
would add undue complication to a model already
overburdened with computations. ah(l +m+Xnm)n

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 403

Thus, the mean of total informed trade is the equilibrium X= 0. As c goes to co from
below X-A>, and from (14), (15), and (18)
limctco(I + nm/(l + m))- 1/2 = e-ac Hence
l + m +Xnm 1
limcTco(nm/ + m) is a finite positive num-
ber. Thus from (22) mean trade goes to zero
and its variance is as cTco. If the numerator and the denomina-
tor of (24) are divided by (1 + m)2, then
again using the fact that m/ I + m has a
(24) CF2(_X)222 [(m+ I)n-1]2 finite limit gives the result that as cTco
X-AO,and variance of trade goes to zero.
(b) By (14), (15), and (18), nm/(I +m) is
constant as n-* o. Further,from remark2)
+(nm+ A ) (l+m+Xnm)2n2 of Section II, Part I, X-AOas n-*o. Hence
from (23) and (24), the mean and variance
of trade go to zero.
In the last section we considered limiting (c) From remark 3) in Section II, Part I,
values of the exogenous variables with the m is constant and X goes to zero as a2--O.
property that X-AO.The following theorem Therefore mean trade goes to zero. In
will show that the mean and variance of (24), note that (nm + aa2/X)2a2/a2 =
trade go to zero as X-AO.That is, the distri- (nmax/a9+(m)'/2)2 by (16a). Hence the
bution of X(XI-x) becomes degenerate at variance of trade goes to zero as aX2-O.
zero as X-AO.This is not trivial because as
X-AO due to n-* co (very precise informa- Note further that X(X, - x) + (1 -)
tion), the informed trader's demand XJ(P, 0) (Xu - x) =0 implies that no trade will take
goes to infinity at most prices because the place as X-A1. Thus, the result that competi-
risky asset becomes riskless with perfect in- tive equilibrium is incompatible with infor-
formation. mationally efficient markets should be inter-
preted as meaning that speculative markets
THEOREM 6: (a) For sufficiently large or where prices reveal a lot of information will
small c, the mean and variance of trade is be very thin because it will be composed of
zero. (b) As the precision of informed traders' individuals with very similar beliefs.
information n goes to infinity, the mean and
variance of trade go to zero. IV. On the Possibilityof PerfectMarkets

PROOF: In Section II we showed that the price


(a) From remark 1) in Section II, Part I, system reveals the signal w* to traders,
A= 1 if c <c, which from (23) and (24) im- where
plies trade is degenerate at zero. From (14), a2
for c sufficiently large, say co, y(O)= 1, so - Ex*)
wA-0- A(

1 +m+nm Thus, for given information of informed


orX
1+ m +Anm traders 9, the price system reveals a noisy
version of 9. The noise is (aa,2/X)(x - Ex*).
(1-A)([(m + 1)-1](9-9 ) + Ah(x-xk)) Uninformed traders learn 9 to within a ran-
x LX+ ah(l + m + nm)n J
dom variable with mean zero and variance
(aas2/X)2 Varx*, where a,2 is the precision of
- x=
informed traders' information, Varx* is the
XI
amount of endowment uncertainty, X the
fraction of informed traders, and a is the
1-A)[(nm+ A )(x-x-)+[(m+l)-n](O-#)+x-nm degree of absolute risk aversion. Thus, in
(I +m +Anm)n general the price system does not reveal all

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
404 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

the information about "the true value" of There is a further conflict. As Grossman
the risky asset. (9 is the true value of the (1975, 1977) showed, whenever there are
risky asset in that it reflects the best availa- differences in beliefs that are not completely
ble information about the asset's worth.) arbitraged, there is an incentive to create a
The only way informed traders can earn a market. (Grossman, 1977, analyzed a model
return on their activity of information of a storable commodity whose spot price
gathering, is if they can use their informa- did not reveal all information because of the
tion to take positions in the market which presence of noise. Thus traders were left
are "better" than the positions of unin- with differences in beliefs about the future
formed traders. "Efficient Markets" theo- price of the commodity. This led to the
rists have claimed that "at any time prices opening of a futures market. But then unin-
fully reflect all available information" (see formed traders had two prices revealing in-
Eugene Fama, p. 383). If this were so then formation to them, implying the elimination
informed traders could not earn a return on of noise.) But, because differences in beliefs
their information. are themselves endogenous, arising out of
We showed that when the efficient mar- expenditure on information and the infor-
kets hypothesis is true and information mativeness of the price system, the creation
is costly, competitive markets break down. of markets eliminates the differences of be-
This is because when a,2=0 or Varx*=O, liefs which gave rise to them, and thus
WA, and thus price, does reflect all the infor- causes those markets to disappear. If the
mation. When this happens, each informed creation of markets were costless, as
trader, because he is in a competitive is conventionally assumed in equilibrium
market, feels that he could stop paying for analyses, equilibrium would never exist. For
information and do as well as a trader who instance, in our model, were we to introduce
pays nothing for information. But all in- an additional security, say a security which
formed traders feel this way. Hence having paid
any positive fraction informed is not an
equilibrium. Having no one informed is also Z= 1 if u>E9*
not an equilibrium, because then each O if u<EO*
trader, taking the price as given, feels that then the demand y for this security by the
there are profits to be made from becoming informed would depend on its price, say q
informed. on p and on 9, while the uninformed de-
Efficient Markets theorists seem to be mand depends only on p and q:
aware that costless information is a sufficient
condition for prices to fully reflect all avail- Xyj(q,p, 0) + (I - X)yu(q,p)= 0
able information (see Fama, p. 387); they
are not aware that it is a necessary condi- is the condition that demand equals (supply
tion. But this is a reducto ad absurdum, since is zero for a pure security). Under weak
price systems and competitive markets are assumptions, q and p would convey all the
important only when information is costly information concerning 9. Thus, the market
(see Fredrick Hayek, p. 452). would be "noiseless" and no equilibrium
We are attempting to redefine the could exist.
Efficient Markets notion, not destroy it. We Thus, we could argue as soon as the
have shown that when information is very assumptions of the conventional perfect
inexpensive, or when informed traders get capital markets model are modified to allow
very precise information, then equilibrium even a slight amount of information imper-
exists and the market price will reveal most fection and a slight cost of information, the
of the informed traders' information. How- traditional theory becomes untenable. There
ever, it was argued in Section III that such cannot be as many securities as states
markets are likely to be thin because traders of nature. For if there were, competitive
have almost homogeneous beliefs. equilibrium would not exist.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 405

It is only because of costly transactions where F(-) is a given function on the range
and the fact that this leads to there being a of X* (see Robert Ash, p. 260).
limited number of markets, that competitive
equilibrium can be established. APPENDIX B
We have argued that because information
is costly, prices cannot perfectly reflect the PROOF of Theorem 1:
information which is available, since if it (a) Suppose X=0; then (9) becomes
did, those who spent resources to obtain it
would receive no compensation. There is a (A6) Xu(Po(9, x), P*) = x
fundamental conflict between the efficiency
with which markets spread information and Define
the incentives to acquire information. How- EO*- axuu2
ever, we have said nothing regarding the
(A7) P0(9 x)_
social benefits of information, nor whether
it is socially optimal to have "information- where au2is the variance of u. Note that
ally efficient markets." We hope to examine PO(9*,x*) is uncorrelated with u*, as x* is
the welfare properties of the equilibrium uncorrelated with u*. Hence
allocations herein in future work.
(A8) E[u*IP&*=Po(9X)] =Eu*=EO*
APPENDIX A
and Var[u*P0*&=P0(9,x)]= Var[u*]
Here we collect some facts on conditional
expectations used in the text. If X* and Y* Substitution of (A8) in (8) yields
are jointly normally distributed then E
(A9) V Ru( )
Xu(P*,PO(9,x))=
(Al) E[X*Y* = Y]
Substitution of (A7) in the right-hand side
EX* + Cov(X*, Y*)
Var(Y*) of (A9) yields XU(P*(9, x), P*) = x which
was to be shown.
(A2) Var[X*IY*=Y] (b) Suppose 0 < X < 1. Let
2
Var(* [Cov (X* y*) (AIO)
-Va(X*)~ Var(Y*)
xWx (1 X)E[u*j w]_
(See Paul Hoel, p. 200.) From (Al) note that au +Var[u*I wx
E[X*J Y*] is a function of Y. If the expecta-
tion of both sides of (A1) is taken, we see RfX + (I-)
that La2 azru*lA
(A3) E { E[ X* Y*= Y] }=EX*
Note that from equations (1), (10), (Al) and
Note that Var[X* Y*= Y] is not a function (A2):
of Y, as Var(X*), Cov(X*, Y*), and Var( Y*)
are just parameters of the joint distribution (Al la)
of X* and Y*.
Two other relevant properties of condi- E(u* I wx)= E9* + V *-(WAE*)
w
Varw.
tional expectation are
(A4) rw
(Allb) Var(u*jwx)=ucr,2+crE2
V-
E{E[ Y*|F(X*)]|X*} = E[ Y*|F(X*)]
(A5) -
(AlIc) Varwx=(J@2 +( ) Varx*
E{E[ Y*|X]IF(X*)} = E[ Y*IF(X*)]

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
406 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

Since Px(9, x) is a linear function of wx, it Note that, as PA*(-)= P(9, x),
is immediate that E(u* Iwx) E(U* IPX),
Var(u*Iwx)= Var(u*IPx), etc. To see that PA* (A16) E(E[ V(W'IA)IXi X]lIPAXi
is an equilibrium, we must show that the
following equation holds as an identity in =E[ V(W'i.) IPA i
(9,x), for PA() defined by (A10):
(see (A5)). Note that since W0ois non-
(A 12) stochastic conditional on (Ph,Xi), equation
-RPx (Al 5) implies
9-RPA E[U *w,]
aac2 ) a Var[u* w1] (A17)

It is immediate from (10) that (A12) holds E V(WjI)IP,XJ] = -exp[ -aR(Wo-c)]-


as an identity in 9 and x.

PROOF of Theorem 2: E texp- (E(UJI-RPX)21})IpX


(a) Calculation of the expected utility of the
informed.Using the fact that W>?is normally
distributed conditional on (Xi,O,x) Note that by Theorem 1, conditioning on
wA is equivalent to conditioning on PA*.De-
(A13) fine
E[ V(W,,i)l _ASx]
(A18) hA-Var(E[u*j9]jw,)
= exp [-a E[ WX,9Xi,,x]
= Var(9 Iwx),ho--ae2-h

-2 Var[ WsiXi x] }]
(A19) ZE_ E[u*19-RPx
Using (8), (12), and the fact that (9,x) de-
termines a particular P,
Using (3) and (A 18), equation (A 17) can
(A14a) E[ W,'JiXl,9,x] =R( W0i-c) be written as

(A20) E [ V( WI ) IPASXi]
(E[ u* 1 RPx)2
aa,2 I
(A14b) e V(R Woi)E exp
-
2 IWA
]
Var[ WIIi x]~1 - (E[ u*1] -RPA)2
aa since Xi and WAare independent. Condi-
tional on WA, PA is nonstochastic and
Substitution of (A14) into (A13) yields E[u*19] is normal. Hence conditional on
WA,(Z*)2 has a noncentral chi-square dis-
tribution (see C. Rao, p. 181). Then for t>0
(A 15) E [ V( W,,i)IX-i ,x] the moment generating function for (Z*)2
can be written

=-exp[-aR(W0j-c) (A21) E[e - ZIWXl

1 F -(E[ZlWX])2t1
)2 = t exp 1
([E U*I ]RPA
~1+2t L ' 1

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 70 NO. 3 GROSSMAN AND STIGLITZ: EFFICIENT MARKETS 407

Note that E[u*10]= E[u*10,x]. Hence Taking expectations of both sides of (A27)
yields:
(A22) E[E[u*J0]JWX]=E[u*JWx]
(A28) E[ V(Wi) ] - E[ V( Wuxi)]
+ -V
=EO* (WA-,EO)
x
Varw Var
=eac ) lEV(Wi)
since Wx is just a function of (9,x). There-
fore
Equation (13) follows immediately from
E [ U*IWA
]-RPA (A28).
(A23) E[Z*IWx]E
REFERENCES
Since u =9+ ?
RobertB. Ash Real Analysis and Probability,
(A24) New York 1972.
Var(u*IwA)=
)a2 + Var(O*I wx)= ae2+ hx E. Fama, "Efficient Capital Markets: A Re-
view of Theory and Empirical Work," J.
The nondegeneracy assumptions on (x*, E*, Finance, May 1970, 25, 383-417.
u*) imply hx >0. Set t = (h,/2a,); and J. R. Green, "Information, Efficiency and
evaluate (A21) using (A23) and (A24): Equilibrium," disc. paper no. 284, Har-
vard Inst. Econ. Res., Mar. 1973.
(A25) _ , ""TheNon-Existence of Informa-
tional Equilibria," Rev. Econ. Stud., Oct.
E exp[ hx Z2 ]) r(u* 1977, 44, 451-64.
~~21a2-
W
Var
(u*Iwx)
L _ S. Grossman,"Essays on Rational Expecta-
tions," unpublished doctoral dissertation,
(-
(E(u* wx) - RPA)2 Univ. Chicago 1975.
expt 2 Var(u*lwx) ) , "On the Efficiency of Competitive
Stock Markets Where Traders Have Di-
This permits the evaluation of (A20). verse Information," J. Finance, May 1976,
(b) Calculation of expected utility of the 31, 573-85.
uninformed.Equations (8), (5), and the nor- , "The Existence of Futures Markets,
mality of WAi conditional on WAcan be Noisy Rational Expectations and Infor-
used to show, by calculations parallel to mational Externalities," Rev. Econ. Stud.,
(A13)-(A25), that Oct. 1977, 64, 431-49.
"Further Results on the Informa-
(A26) EE V(Wui )|WA,Xi] tional Efficiency of Competitive Stock
Markets," J. Econ. Theory, June 1978, 18,
( -(E(u* |w.) - RPx)2 81-101.
2 Var(u*lw,) , R. Kihlstrom, and L. Mirman, "A Baye-
=V(R W0i)exp~ )
sian Approach to the Production of Infor-
Hence mation and Learning by Doing," Rev.
(A27) Econ. Stud., Oct. 1977, 64, 533-47.
F. H. Hayek, "The Use of Knowledge in
Society," Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1945,
V(WI ) Iw, ]-e E V( Wu*i)
IwA1] 35, 519-30.
r(u10 Paul G. Hoel, Introduction to Mathematical
=eacA Statistics, New York 1962.
e r,wAw R. Kihlstrom and L. Mirman, "Information and
Market Equilibrium," Bell. J. Econ.,
Spring 1975, 6, 357-76.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
408 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1980

R. E. Lucas, Jr., "Expectations and the Neu- J. E. Stiglitz, "Perfect and Imperfect Capital
trality of Money," J. Econ. Theory, Apr. Markets," paper presented to the Econo-
1972, 4, 103-24. metric Society, New Orleans 1971.
C. Rao, Linear Statistical Inference and Its ,_____"Information and Capital Mar-
Applications, New York 1965. kets," mimeo., Oxford Univ. 1974.

This content downloaded from 161.45.205.103 on Tue, 13 Aug 2013 15:24:50 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like