You are on page 1of 8

Progress report

Progress in Human Geography


1–8
Political ecology III: The ª The Author(s) 2016
Reprints and permission:

commons and commoning sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav


DOI: 10.1177/0309132516664433
phg.sagepub.com

Matthew D. Turner
University of Wisconsin, Madison, USA

Abstract
Different intellectual strands within political ecology have analyzed changing forms of property institutions
and the commons in particular. While engaging these topics from a number of different perspectives, they
share common understandings of property rights as relational, contested, and shaped by broader political
economies. What is less acknowledged is that political ecologists have, in different ways, studied the hybrid
and mixed forms of property institutions that are often concealed or ignored in the tripartite division of
private, common, and national properties that dominates institutionalist literatures. These theoretical
commitments and research experiences are well-suited for understanding the proliferation of hybrid
property institutions associated with neoliberal forms of governance. By briefly reviewing their synergies, this
report seeks to bring these diverse strands in conversation. It concludes by highlighting useful avenues of
political ecological research and practice that are raised by commoning scholarship and activism.

Keywords
hybridity, neoliberalism, privatization, property

I Introduction Study of the Commons. Still, political ecology’s


theoretical commitments have always sat awk-
The ‘commons’ have figured prominently in the
wardly with those of institutionalist approaches
intellectual history of political ecology as an
that dominate the interdisciplinary commons
approach. Early political ecologists seriously
literature. While these approaches are not inher-
questioned the simplified, rational-choice treat-
ently incompatible, their emphases do differ
ments of society inherent in ‘tragedy of the
markedly – with political ecology focusing on
commons’ formulations. Arguably, the ‘solu-
differences in material interest and power and
tions’ to the tragedy offered by tragedy analysts
the institutionalists’ concern with the collective
– government control and privatization – have
action problem surrounding the benefits derived
served as major foils for political ecological
from a commonly-held good.1
analysis. Enclosures of all sorts including
Building from the same rational-choice
national parks, land titling, and assorted land
premises as Harden, Nobel Prize winner
grabs by private capital have figured promi-
Elinor Ostrom played an instrumental role in
nently in animating the social justice outrage
surrounding conservation and development pro-
grams that fueled and continue to fuel political
Corresponding author:
ecological analysis. Reflecting this, self- Matthew D. Turner, Department of Geography, University
described political ecologists have played active of Wisconsin, Madison, WI 53706, USA.
roles in the International Association for the Email: mturner2@wisc.edu

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


2 Progress in Human Geography

demonstrating that government control and pri- diversification of property regimes that deviate
vatization were not the only solutions for what from the tripartite divisions of national, common,
Harden eventually retitled ‘the tragedy of the and private properties. The premise of this report
mismanaged commons’. Ostrom and others is that their synergies are often under-appreciated
demonstrated that clearly-defined social groups or, at the very least, not openly recognized, thus
do self-organize to effectively manage circum- leading to a missed opportunity for the develop-
scribed sets of resources. Clearly, there are other ment of a common set of arguments. In exploring
forms of property and social organization that these synergies, I necessarily will engage with
could operate successfully outside of the binary bodies of scholarship that remain somewhat sep-
of government control and private property. The arate circles of scholarship within political ecol-
commons literature has provided both intellec- ogy: work that focuses on communities and the
tual argument and compelling case material to politics that surround their commonly-held
counter widespread arguments for land privati- resources and work concerned with questions
zation and the expansion of state-controlled of state governance and privatization.3 In review-
reserves and protected areas. This work has had ing the interface between these stands, I will
a significant effect on environmental govern- argue that political ecology’s historical engage-
ance, contributing to the spread of community- ment with the complexity of the phrase ‘access to
based approaches to resource management and resources’ provides a strong analytical frame-
conservation worldwide. work for addressing some of the deficiencies of
Despite these successes, concerns have been dominant institutionalist frameworks for under-
raised about the ability of the common property standing mixed property forms. I conclude by
framework to address the analytical and politi- relating political ecology to the expanding liter-
cal challenges created by the proliferation of ature and activism of ‘commoning’. In so doing, I
‘neoliberal’ models of governance. Neoliberal hope to plant some seeds (Robbins, 2004) for
environmental policy has not led to ubiquitous constructive engagement by political ecologists
privatization but a proliferation of hybrid forms in the (re)making of environmental governance
of property rights created by new enclosures of and property relations. Given the limits of space,
commonly-held resources without the elimina- my citations within these literatures are necessa-
tion of more public rights and responsibilities. rily incomplete and eclectic.
Strongly shaped by its reaction against ‘tragedy
analyses’, commons literature has been domi-
nated by studies that seek to demonstrate the
II Properties: Common
existence, characteristics, and functioning of and otherwise
common pool property institutions while gener- Scholars or activists seeking to support or create
ally ignoring or downplaying cases of mixed common property institutions in the industria-
institutional forms, ‘weak’ or nonexisting (e.g. lized world have expressed frustration with the
open access) property institutions.2 As a result, dominance of cases in the commons literature
its analytical tools are less suited for under- from rural developing world settings (e.g.
standing mixed public-private forms or consid- Bresnihan and Byrne, 2015). Their frustration
ering situations where formal property stems from the seeming lack of correspondence
institutions of any kind may not be warranted between cases of what are seen as closed soci-
or effective. eties of villages and clans organized around
In this report, I seek to bring together a commonly-held pastures, forests, or fisheries
number of strands within political ecology scho- portrayed within the commons literature with
larship that speak, in different ways, to the the realities that they are facing with socially-

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


Turner 3

porous groups organizing/negotiating around by a closed social group using a single set of rules
multiple sets of resources governed by multi- reflects more the framings of common property
layered rights and institutions. scholarship than the reality of commonly-held
As an Africanist, I would argue that cases of resources in the developing world.4 While insti-
‘pure’ common property – meeting the require- tutional contexts differ, the complexity and mul-
ments laid out by Ostrom (1990: 90) – are actu- tiplicity of commonly-held property in the
ally much rarer in developing countries than is Global South and North are similar (Blomley,
often thought. Empirical work has shown that 2008).
systems of common property governance often
include overlapping systems of rights – some
held by sovereigns on behalf of the community,
III Analysis and management
some shared by members of the community, and of the commons
some held by individuals. From multiple per- A range of scholars have critiqued development
spectives, such ‘confused’ systems of property and conservation efforts to improve common
rights are seen as ‘primitive’ with economic property management, as intentionally or unin-
development both demanding and leading to tentionally working to advance market principles
their demise (Demsetz, 1967; Glassman, 2006). to the detriment of the public good (Goldman,
These rights are strongly relational – with rights 1997).5 The concern is not about rule-making per
not solely private or solely communal, and the se6 but the common tendency to seek to improve
relative strength of property claims of a person or the management of resources by formalizing
community depending on who is making a com- rules of access and clearly circumscribing
peting claim (Bakker, 2013). This is consistent commonly-held resources and the social groups
with work on property as a social institution, one using them. Formalization and circumscription
best thought of as the control over a stream of by local communities can occur both in consort
benefits against the claims of others. Popular with and in resistance to territorialization pro-
notions of the physical parcel of land as property grams of the state (Peluso, 2005). This process
in the West are historically unique – shaped by has been described as ‘proxy privatization’ by
what Blomley (2015) describes as the territoria- Osborne (2015), since both formalization and
lization of property. While more likely ignored in circumscription can contribute directly to priva-
the West, property is inherently relational and tization and individualization (Mansfield, 2004)
thus deeply political. – two of six key elements of commodification as
Within the development literature, recogni- described by Castree (2003). In addition, other
tion of the limitations of institutionalist perspec- work has shown that these elements may contrib-
tives to address this complexity has grown with ute over time to changing views of land and other
terms such as ‘institutional bricolage’ and ‘criti- commonly-held resources themselves – contri-
cal institutionalism’ increasingly invoked (Hall buting to ideas that they could be seen as alien-
et al., 2014). As an approach, political ecology able with rights to them bought and sold (e.g. Li,
has long embraced the relational underpinnings 2007; Osborne, 2015; Green and Baird, 2016).
of property. This view of property rights as being
socially-mediated, over-lapping and contested,
and necessarily embedded within people’s liveli-
IV New forms of governance
hoods, has been further developed and articu- and the commons
lated by political ecologists and others since Over the past 25 years there has been an
(e.g. Leach et al., 1999; Ribot and Peluso, embrace of smaller government, privatization,
2003). The view of a singular resource managed liberalization of markets, and increased reliance

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


4 Progress in Human Geography

on market mechanisms for regulation. This resulting forms of privatization depending on


complex, contradictory, and conflicted set of the invocations of national interest if not types
processes has loosely been assigned the of nationalized property (Baird, 2011). Political
umbrella label of neoliberalism. Associated ecologists have contributed significantly to our
with these trends, there has been an emphasis understanding of: the complex politics underly-
on the privatization of government services and ing these dispossessions (McCarthy, 2004; Hart,
renewed efforts to formalize property rights. At 2006; Baird, 2011; Hall, 2012); the importance
the same time there are reports of a large expan- of the characteristics of the resource being dis-
sion of government-controlled protected areas possessed (Sneddon, 2007; Perreault, 2012);
with variable access rights accorded to individ- and how dispossessions can lead to a mix of
uals and groups (Deguignet et al., 2014) as well property rights held by different actors (Green
as the growth of government-recognized com- and Baird, 2016). If we see de-commoning
mon property areas (Agrawal, 2007). These (enclosure) as an ongoing contested process that
trends alone suggest that the neoliberalism has just as often produces property claims of mixed
not resulted in ubiquitous ‘full’ privatization. rather than pure form, we can see the process of
It is important to recognize that the expansion communing, which will be turned to later in this
of mixed forms of property with neoliberalism report, as a similarly contested process that
due to the uneven and incomplete expansion of seeks to expand shared rights and responsibil-
private rights is not surprising. Unfettered pri- ities within mixed property forms.
vate property and commodification, despite the
rhetoric, do not serve society or capital interests.
This reflects not only Polanyi’s double move-
V The proliferation of mixed
ment but the demands of capital for property relations
government-provided services that are critical Recent research has shown a proliferation of
for accumulation (Robertson, 2006; Robbins property forms in which the state, private indi-
et al., 2012). In short, the proliferation of viduals and various social groups of civil soci-
commons-like institutions is not necessarily ety hold rights and responsibilities over
anti-capitalist but actually can be seen as an different benefits/services provided by a bio-
attempt to sustain the functioning of capitalism physical feature or process (e.g. Brown, 2007;
(Caffentzis, 2010). Holder and Flessas, 2008; Bakker, 2010). More-
These points are illustrated by the case of the over, situations of overlapping rights of differ-
‘global land grab’ that most typically refers to ent forms held by different individuals and
the loss of often commonly-held lands in the groups are not new to the world but have been
Global South (Baird, 2014). This phenomenon, simplified or ignored by standard common
which suggests large-scale privatization of land, property analyses. At a basic level, we can think
has led to a revisitation of the concept of primi- of the production of mixed institutional forms
tive accumulation. New treatments of primitive under capitalism as resulting from barriers to
accumulation as well as the concept of accumu- full privatization (including lack of privatiza-
lation by dispossession emphasize that enclo- tion interest) and the incomplete layering of
sure is not a development stage of capitalism more private claims onto public goods and
but an ongoing process of privatization and pro- services.
letarianization (Harvey, 2003; Glassman, As common property scholars have long
2006). Moreover, state actions lie at the heart argued, practical difficulties in enclosing cer-
of extra-economic mechanisms of dispossession tain resources can inhibit the full development
of commonly and privately-held land, with the of private rights. The oceans or atmosphere are

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


Turner 5

often used as examples of common pool been capitalized on as another risk to be insured
resources that, because of the difficulties (or against in the form of catastrophe bonds or
high cost) of enclosure, may be better seen as index-based insurance schemes (Johnson,
public goods (despite the fact that their use sub- 2013a, 2013b). Arguably, the creativity of
tracts from the use of others). With technologi- efforts to create financial value reaches its most
cal change, information and knowledge flamboyant extreme (at least currently) in the
likewise have become increasingly difficult to stacking of ecosystem service credits where
enclose (Caffentzis, 2010; Hardt and Negri, spatially-overlapping credits for different eco-
2011). Still, if a resource in question is of suf- system services (e.g. biodiversity, carbon, and
ficient interest to capital, different services of water-quality) are bought/valued by various
even atmospheric or oceanic systems can be entities while being produced/maintained/
enclosed for private use through government owned by different social groups (Robertson
regulation (e.g. Mansfield, 2004, 2006). Thus et al., 2014). As Robertson and Wainwright
we may see the transformation but not elimina- (2013) argue, the proliferation of these new
tion of the commons through privatization, due abstracted assets and commodities exposes
to barriers and the resistance of people – the the limited attention by political ecologists
commons that persist are not the simple por- and others to longstanding debates over the
trayals of the pure commons but of hybrid form, question of value. Processes of valuation are
what Eizenberg (2012) describes as the ‘actu- important not only for the necessary quan-
ally existing commons’. It is most telling that it tification required for exchange but reflect
is generally resources of limited value to capital who values, pays for, and owns the ‘services’
– unproductive drylands or vacant lots in in question.
economically-depressed neighborhoods – These new property systems deviate strongly
where privatization pressures are low and ‘com- from visions of the tripartite division of private,
moning’ of the poor remains most visible common and national property. They often have
(Blomley, 2008; Foster, 2011). This can also mixed or hybrid forms and thus are similar to
be seen in the case of the privatization of gov- the forms of customary tenure where multiple
ernment services, with private firms only rights are held by different people to different
accepting those services and service areas that streams of benefits from agricultural land, for-
are profitable, shedding the unprofitable ser- ests, or fisheries. They are thus neither novel nor
vices and areas to governments or community necessarily unsuited for social and ecological
groups (Bakker, 2013; Harris, 2013). realities. In fact, it could be argued that they
The growth of mixed or hybrid property better reflect the true relational nature of prop-
forms cannot be explained by barriers to full erty where webs of social relations encircle con-
enclosure or commodification alone. The tested resources with value. The violence
growth of market-based environmental regula- associated with enclosure is mirrored by the
tion has been associated with the layering of use analytical violence done by those institution-
rights to different characteristics of nonhuman alists who overly simplify property systems
nature. For instance, while the atmosphere can- and in so doing exclude the rights of individ-
not be ‘owned’, regulatory attempts have cre- uals and communities in their portrayal of the
ated tradeable carbon offset credits, such as the collective action problem. One would hope
Clean Development Mechanism’s Certified that political ecology, whether First or Third
Emission Reduction Credits, or tradeable rights World, brings to these situations a sensitivity
to release SO2 or CO2 (emission permits). The to the micropolitics that surround these com-
vagaries of the atmosphere’s weather have also plex property systems.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


6 Progress in Human Geography

VI Political ecology constructively with communities and activists


and commoning in support of their attempts to develop condi-
tions that support shared use, management, and
The proliferation of ‘actually existing com-
production of needed resources. Such efforts
mons’ around the world illustrates how com-
would most likely be with ‘actually existing
mon property is a set of social institutions and
commons’ of mixed rather than pure property
interactions that not only allocate a stream of
form. Therefore, it would allow political ecolo-
benefits but produce and maintain them. A rec-
gists to grapple with illuminating how these
ognition of the ‘commons’ as a set of social
mixed institutional forms work in practice as
relations that are not fixed but changing has led
mediated by ideology and political power (see
some to argue that the term common(s) should
Noterman, 2016). One could point to a number
also be seen as a verb: ‘to common’ (Frederici,
of political ecologists that have been involved in
2010; Fournier, 2013; Bresnihan and Byrne,
such efforts but, as a field, political ecology can
2015; Noterman, 2016). Invocations of ‘com-
learn much from the new commoning literature
moning’ are most prevalent in the industrialized
and the theoretical understandings of property
world. In contrast to a rule-based allocative
that underlie it. Political ecology as well has
commons, these efforts embrace a political and
much to offer the commoning field – not only
moral commons of production in resistance to
through its history of scholarship on the social
the individualization and privatization inherent
mediation of resource access but through its suc-
to capitalism (McCarthy, 2005; Blomley, 2008;
cess of working through differences and com-
St. Martin, 2009; Foster, 2011).
monalities between the political ecologies of
Given that the commons can be seen as being
the South and North. This rich history provides
produced to support capitalism, there are clearly
political ecology with a depository of analyses
tensions with the new embrace of cooperatives,
and activism around the processes of de-
urban gardens, conservancies, and community-
commoning and commoning across a wide range
controlled resources. Some commentators dis-
of cultural and political-economic contexts.
tinguish actions that seek to defend or produce
communal rights under capitalism as pro- Acknowledgements
capitalist in contrast to anti-capitalist common- This report benefited from conversations with Leila
ing movements (Caffentzis, 2010). Moreover, Harris, Elsa Noterman, and Morgan Robertson. Its
rural indigenous groups defending their com- deficiencies are all mine.
munal rights are seen as reactive (defending
precapitalist claims) rather than proactive to Declaration of conflicting interests
capital (promoting alternatives). Unfortunately, The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of inter-
to this reader, it is far from clear how the devel- est with respect to the research, authorship, and/or
opment of community-based urban agriculture publication of this article.
in Detroit is any more anti-capitalist than strug- Funding
gles by West Africans to defend their ‘ancestral’
The author(s) received no financial support for the
village lands against the dispossession by inter- research, authorship, and/or publication of this
national concessionaires. Yes, the latter is reac- article.
tive, but not through simply an invocation of
tradition but through ever changing and creative Notes
ways. 1. Political ecological analyses of the commons generally
Commoning activism and scholarship offer fall into Johnson’s ‘entitlement’ scholarship on the
opportunities to political ecologists to work commons (in contrast to ‘collective action’ scholarship)

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


Turner 7

and McCay and Jentoft’s thick (versus thin) model of Blomley N (2015) The territory of property. Progress in
explanation in commons research (McCay and Jentoft, Human Geography. Epub ahead of print 30 July 2015.
1998; Johnson, 2004). DOI: 10.1177/0309132515596380.
2. Ostrom’s ‘polycentric’ framework is designed to Bresnihan P and Byrne M (2015) Escape into the city:
provide a means to analyze more complex property Everyday practices of commoning and the production
systems (Ostrom, 2010). of urban space in Dublin. Antipode 47: 1–19.
3. These bodies of work only loosely align with the pro- Brown K (2007) Understanding the materialities and mor-
blematic but commonly invoked distinction between alities of property: Reworking collective claims to land.
First and Third World political ecologies Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 32:
4. Common property scholarship has tended to treat 507–522.
common property management as a collective action Caffentzis G (2010) The future of ‘the commons’: Neoli-
problem with the need for clear and transparent rules to beralism’s ‘Plan B’ or the original disaccumulation of
contain free-riding and to avoid the conflict and social capital? New Formations 69: 23–41.
tensions that arise from unrestrained individualistic Castree N (2003) Commodifying what nature? Progress in
behavior. Human Geography 27: 273–297.
5. This is despite the fact that these efforts, except in the Deguignet M, Harrison J, MacSharry B, Burgess N and
case of some payment for ecosystem service schemes, are Kingston N (2014) 2014 United Nations List of Pro-
presented unambiguously as alternatives to privatization. tected Areas. Cambridge: UNEP-WCMC.
6. Although in some cases explicit formal rules may not be Demsetz H (1967) Toward a theory of property rights.
necessary for long-term successful management of American Economic Review 57: 347–359.
common-pool resources. It has been argued that such Eizenberg E (2012) Actually existing commons: Three
‘open-access’ situations can in fact work socially and moments of space of community gardens in New York
ecologically (e.g. Mansfield, 2006; Moritz et al., 2013). City. Antipode 44: 764–782.
Foster SR (2011) Collective action and the urban com-
mons. Notre Dame Law Review 87: 1–63.
References Fournier V (2013) Commoning: On the social organisation
Agrawal A (2007) Forests, governance, and sustainability: of the commons. M@n@gement 16: 433–453.
Common property theory and its contributions. Inter- Frederici S (2010) Feminism and the politics of the com-
national Journal of the Commons 1: 111–136. mons. The Commoner. Available at: http://www.com
Baird IG (2011) Turning land into capital, turning moner.org.uk/?p¼113 (accessed 6 August 2016).
people into labor: Primitive accumulation and the Glassman J (2006) Primitive accumulation, accumulation
arrival of large-scale economic land concessions in by dispossession, accumulation by ‘extra-economic’
the Lao People’s Democratic Republic. New Propos- means. Progress in Human Geography 30(5): 608–625.
als: Journal of Marxism and Interdisciplinary Inquiry Goldman M (1997) ‘Customs in common’: The epistemic
5: 10–26. world of the commons scholars. Theory & Society 26:
Baird IG (2014) The global land grab meta-narrative, 1–37.
Asian money laundering and elite capture: Reconsider- Green WN and Baird IG (2016) Capitalizing on compen-
ing the Cambodian context. Geopolitics 19: 431–453. sation: Hydropower resettlement and the commodifica-
Bakker K (2010) Privatizing Water: Governance Failure tion and decommodification of nature-society relations
and the World’s Urban Water Crisis. Ithaca: Cornell in southern Laos. Annals of the Association of Amer-
University Press. ican Geographers 106: 853–873.
Bakker K (2013) Constructing ‘public’ water: The World Hall D (2012) Rethinking primitive accumulation: Theo-
Bank, urban water supply, and the biopolitics of devel- retical tensions and rural southeast Asian complexities.
opment. Environment and Planning D: Society and Antipode 44: 1188–1208.
Space 31: 280–300. Hall K, Cleaver F, Franks T and Maganga F (2014)
Blomley N (2008) Enclosure, common right, and the Capturing critical institutionalism: A synthesis of key
property of the poor. Social and Legal Studies 17: themes. European Journal of Development Research
311–331. 26: 71–86.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016


8 Progress in Human Geography

Hardt M and Negri A (2011) Commonwealth. Cambridge, common-pool resources in the Chad basin. Human
MA: Belknap Press. Ecology 41: 351–365.
Harris LM (2013) Variable histories and geographies of Noterman E (2016) Beyond tragedy: Differential com-
marketization and privatization. In: Harris LM, Goldin moning in a manufactured housing cooperative. Anti-
JA and Sneddon C (eds) Contemporary Water Govern- pode 48: 433–452.
ance in the Global South: Scarcity, Marketization and Osborne T (2015) Tradeoffs in carbon commodification: A
Participation. London: Routledge, 118–132. political ecology of common property forest govern-
Hart G (2006) Denaturalizing dispossession: Critical eth- ance. Geoforum 67: 64–77.
nography in the age of resurgent imperialism. Antipode Ostrom E (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution
38: 678–705. of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cam-
Harvey D (2003) The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford bridge University Press.
University Press. Ostrom E (2010) Beyond markets and states: Polycentric
Holder J and Flessas T (2008) Emerging commons. Social governance of complex economic systems. In: Grandin
and Legal Studies 17: 299–310. K (ed.) The Nobel Prizes 2009. Stockholm: The Nobel
Johnson C (2004) Uncommon ground: The ‘poverty of Foundation, 408–444.
history’ in common property discourse. Development Peluso NL (2005) Seeing property in land use: Local ter-
and Change 35: 407–434. ritorializations in West Kalimantan, Indonesia. Geo-
Johnson L (2013a) Catastrophe bonds and financial risk: grafisk Tidsskrift-Danish Journal of Geography 105:
Securing capital and rule through contingency. Geo- 1–15.
forum 45: 30–40. Perreault T (2012) Dispossession by accumulation? Min-
Johnson L (2013b) Index insurance and the articulation of ing, water and the nature of enclosure on the Bolivian
risk-bearing subjects. Environment and Planning A 45: altiplano. Antipode 45: 1050–1069.
2663–2681. Ribot JC and Peluso NL (2003) A theory of access. Rural
Leach M, Mearns R and Scoones I (1999) Environmental Sociology 68: 153–181.
entitlements: Dynamics and institutions in community- Robbins P (2004) Political Ecology. London: Blackwell.
based natural resource management. World Develop- Robbins P, Martin S and Gilbertz S (2012) Developing
ment 27: 225–247. the commons: The contradictions of growth in
Li TM (2007) The Will to Improve: Governmentality, exurban Montana. The Professional Geographer
Development, and the Practice of Politics. Durham: 64: 317–331.
Duke University Press. Robertson M, BenDor TK, Lave R, Riggsbee A and Doyle
McCarthy J (2004) Privatizing conditions of production: M (2014) Stacking ecosystem services. Frontiers in
Trade agreements as neoliberal environmental govern- Ecology and the Environment 12: 186–193.
ance. Geoforum 35: 327–341. Robertson MM (2006) The nature that capital can see:
McCarthy J (2005) Commons as counterhegemonic proj- Science, state, and market in the commodification of
ects. Capitalism Nature Socialism 16: 9–24. ecosystem services. Environment and Planning D:
McCay B and Jentoft S (1998) Market or community fail- Society and Space 24: 367–387.
ure? Critical perspectives on common property Robertson MM and Wainwright JD (2013) The value of
research. Human Organization 57: 21–29. nature to the state. Annals of the Association of Amer-
Mansfield B (2004) Neoliberalism in the oceans: ‘Ratio- ican Geographers 103: 890–905.
nalization’, property rights, and the commons question. Sneddon C (2007) Nature’s materiality and the circuitous
Geoforum 35: 313–326. paths of accumulation: Dispossession of freshwater
Mansfield B (2006) Assessing market-based environmen- fisheries in Cambodia. Antipode 39: 167–193.
tal policy using a case study of North Pacific fisheries. St Martin K (2009) Toward a cartography of the
Global Environmental Change 16: 29–39. commons: Constituting the political and economic
Moritz M, Scholte P, Hamilton IM and Kari S (2013) possibilities of place. The Professional Geographer
Open access, open systems: Pastoral management of 61: 493–507.

Downloaded from phg.sagepub.com at CORNELL UNIV on August 27, 2016

You might also like