You are on page 1of 8

SELECTIONS FROM CORPORATE GOVERNANCE THE SECOND MITSUI LIFE SYMPOSIUM

IN JAPAN AND THE UNITED STATES ON GLOBAL FINANCIAL MARKETS—MAY 11, 1993

IS AMERICAN CORPORATE by Merton H. Miller,


University of Chicago*
GOVERNANCE FATALLY
FLAWED?

re the investment horizons of U.S. firms Surveys must never be taken too literally, of
A too short? Yes, was the conclusion of
Capital Choices, a report published in
course. Japanese managers surely cannot believe
that increasing market share is the overriding corpo-
August 1992 by 25 academic scholars rate goal. Achieving a 100 percent market share for
under the leadership of Professor Michael Porter of your product is too easy: just give it away! Profitabil-
the Harvard Business School. The Porter Report was ity must also and always be considered. And, indeed,
widely acclaimed not only by the U.S. financial press, the Japanese firms surveyed did give a rating of 1.24
but by many Japanese observers. Mr. Katsuro Umino, to Return on Investment—far less than the 2.43 rating
for one, Vice President of the Osaka-based Kotsu given by the American firms, but still much much
Trading Company, was quoted in the Chicago more than the virtually zero weight given to Higher
Tribune of August 24, 1992 as saying: Stock Prices.
For all its technical limitations, however, the
It’s interesting to see that somebody in America is survey does, I believe, accurately reflect differences
finally waking up to the real culprit behind the in managerial behavior in the two countries. Ameri-
decline of American corporate competitiveness. I can managers are more concerned with current
think many of us in Japan have known for a long time movements in their own stock prices than are
that America’s capital allocation system is inherently Japanese managers. And rightly so. The emphasis
flawed. American managers place on shareholder returns is
not a flaw in the U.S. corporate governance system,
The flaw seen by Messrs. Porter and Umino but one of its primary strengths.
and ever so many others is the overemphasis on Some of my academic colleagues believe, in fact,
stock prices and shareholder returns in the Ameri- that American big-business management has been
can system of corporate governance. By contrast, a putting put too little weight on stockholder returns,
survey of 1,000 Japanese and 1,000 American firms leading to massive waste of both shareholder and
by Japan’s Economic Planning Agency, reported in national wealth. Their argument has not, in my view,
the same Chicago Tribune story, finds that on a been convincingly established. The billion-dollar
scale of 0 to 3—3 being most important—Japanese losses of companies like IBM and General Motors in
firms give “Higher Stock Price” a rating of only recent years, offered by such critics as evidence for
0.02. “Increasing Market Share” gets a reported their case, testify less to failures in the U.S. gover-
rating of 1.43 in Japan, almost twice its rating in the nance system than to the vigorously competitive
United States. environment in which U.S. firms must operate.

*My thanks for helpful comments from my colleagues Steven Kaplan and Anil
Kashyap and from Donald Chew.

32
CONTINENTAL BANKOF APPLIED
JOURNAL JOURNALCORPORATE
OF APPLIEDFINANCE
CORPORATE FINANCE
MAXIMIZING SHAREHOLDER VALUE AS THE Current Market Values and Future Earnings
PRIMARY OBJECTIVE OF THE BUSINESS
CORPORATION Using the stock market’s response to measure
the true worth of the proposed new investments may
Let me begin my defense of U.S. corporate strike many here in Japan as precisely the kind of
governance by emphasizing that managerial con- short-termism that has led so many American firms
cern with shareholder value is merely one specific astray. Let it be clearly understood, therefore, that, in
application of the more general proposition that in a U.S.-style stock market, focusing on current stock
American society the individual is king. Not the prices is not short-termism. Focusing on current
nation, not the government, not the producers, not earnings might be myopic, but not so for stock prices,
the merchants, but the individual—and especially which reflect not just today’s earnings, but the earn-
the individual consumer—is sovereign. Certainly ings the market expects in all future years as well.
that has not been the accepted view of ultimate Just how much weight expected future earnings
economic sovereignty here in Japan, though the first carry in determining current stock prices always
signs of change are beginning to appear. surprises those not accustomed to working with
The connection between consumer sovereignty present-value formulas and, especially, with growth
and corporate governance lies not just in the benefits formulas. Growth formulas, however, whether of
customers derive from the firm’s own output. The dividends or earnings, rarely strike my Japanese
customers are not the only consumers the firm friends or my Japanese students as very compelling.
serves. The shareholders, the investors, the own- Many Japanese firms, after all, pay only nominal
ers—however one chooses to call them—are also dividends, and the formulas don’t make sufficiently
consumers and their consumption, actual and poten- clear what investors are really buying when they buy
tial, is what drives the shareholder-value principle. a stock.
To see how and why, consider the directors of Let me therefore shift the focus from a firm’s rate
a firm debating how much of the firm’s current of sales or earnings growth to where it ought to be—
profits, say $10 million, to pay out as dividends to the namely, to the competitive conditions facing the firm
shareholders. If the $10 million is paid as dividends, over meaningful horizons. And let me, for reasons
the shareholders clearly have an additional $10 that will become clear later, measure the strength of
million in cash to spend. Suppose, however, that the those competitive conditions by the currently fash-
$10 million is not paid out, but used instead for ionable market value-to-book value ratio (also known
investment in the firm—buying machinery, expand- as the “market-to-book” or “price-to-book” ratio).
ing the factory, setting up a new branch, or what have The book-value term in the ratio, based as it is on
you. The stockholders now do not get the cash, but original cost, approximates what management actu-
they need not be disadvantaged thereby. That will ally spent for the assets the market is valuing. A
depend on how the stock market values the pro- market-to-book ratio of 1.0 (abstracting from any
posed new investment projects. concerns about pure price inflation) is thus a natural
If the market believes the firm’s managers have benchmark, signifying a firm with no competitive
invested wisely, the value of the shares may rise by advantage or disadvantage. The firm is expected to
$10 million or even more. Stockholders seeking to earn only normal profits in the economists’ sense of
convert this potential consumption into actual con- that term, that is, profits just large enough to give the
sumption need only sell the shares and spend the stockholders the average, risk-adjusted return for
proceeds. But if the market feels that the managers equities generally.
have spent the money foolishly, the stock value will To sell for more than an unremarkable market-
rise by less than the forgone dividend of $10 to-book ratio of 1.0—that is, to have a positive
million—perhaps by only $5 million, or possibly not “franchise value,” as some put it—a firm must have
at all. Those new investments may have expanded long-term competitive advantages allowing it to earn
the firm’s market share; they may have vastly im- a higher than normal rate of return on its productive
proved the firm’s image and the prestige of its assets. And that’s not as easy to do as it may seem.
managers. But they have not increased shareholder Above-normal profits always carry with them the
wealth and potential consumption. They have re- seeds of their own decay. They attract competitors,
duced it. both from within a country and from abroad, driving

33
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 4 WINTER 1994
profits and share prices relentlessly back toward the governance in Japan. Many academic observers in
competitive norm. Investors buying into a firm are the U.S. (myself, in particular)2 have attributed MOF’s
thus making judgments not only about whether the famous P.K.O. (Price Keeping Operations, and a
firm and its managers have produced a competitive Japanese pun on the country’s participation in the
advantage over their rivals, but also about how far U.N.’s Peace Keeping Operations in Cambodia) to its
into the future that competitive advantage can be role as cartel manager for the Japanese brokerage
expected to last. industry. Another motivation traces, however, to the
Some specific numbers may help to fix ideas.1 Japanese banking industry. Japanese banks, unlike
Consider a U.S. firm with a market-to-book ratio of those in the U.S., can hold equity positions in the
3.0—and there still are many such. And suppose, companies to which they are also lending—a dual
further, that it will be plowing back its entire cash role that, in turn, has often been cited as the real key
flow into investments expected to earn twice the to Japanese managerial success. The bank connec-
normal competitive rate of return. By paying three tion is said to reduce corporate agency costs, provide
times book value for the shares, investors are in better monitoring of corporate decisions, and, above
effect anticipating that the firm will expand and stay all, allow management to undertake profitable but
that far ahead of its competitors for the next 20 years ! risky long-run ventures while confident of having
That’s really forward-looking—much too for- the continued financial support needed to carry
ward looking, some would say, in this highly uncer- projects through to completion.
tain world. And perhaps that’s why so many Japa- But any gains to the Japanese economy on the
nese managers are instinctively skeptical about using governance front have come at a substantial cost on
the stock market to guide or evaluate managerial other fronts. Corporate equities can be great assets
decision-making. They don’t really trust the prices in for banks when the stock market is booming as it was
the Japanese stock market where, at the height of the in Japan in the 1980s. The price appreciation then
stock market boom of 1989, market-to-book ratios provides the banks with substantial regulatory capi-
were not just 3.0 but, even after adjusting for real tal to support their lending activities. But when the
estate and for other corporate shares in cross- stock market collapses, as it did in Japan after 1989,
holdings, ran routinely to 5.0 or even 10.0. Such the disappearance of those hidden equity reserves
ratios implied that investors saw opportunities for can threaten the solvency of the banks and the
these companies to earn above-normal, competitor- integrity of the country’s payment system.
proof returns for centuries to come! The prospect becomes even more frightening
Prices and market-to-book ratios have fallen when we remember that shareholdings in Japan run
substantially since then, but are still hard to take in both directions. Not only do banks hold the firm’s
seriously because they are not completely free- shares but the firms—again, presumably with a view
market prices. The values are not only distorted by to better governance—also hold the banks’ shares.
the pervasive cross-holdings of nontraded shares, The result is a classic, unstable, positive-feedback
but the prices of the thinly-traded minority of shares asset pyramid. No wonder MOF must keep support-
in the floating supply often reflect the heroic scale of ing stock prices and always seems to be running
market intervention by the Ministry of Finance around, like the proverbial Dutch boy on the dikes,
(MOF). Japanese managers can be pardoned for plugging holes and leaks in its regulations.
wondering whether the stock market may be just a
Bunraku theater, with the bureaucrats from MOF Stock Prices and Information
backstage manipulating the puppets.
MOF’s notorious market support activities also To say that the stock market in the U.S. is much
interact in other ways with the issue of corporate closer to the free-market ideal than the Japanese

1. The calculations to follow are adapted from the finite growth model 2. For an account of how MOF systematically uses its regulatory powers to
presented in Merton H. Miller and Franco Modigliani, “Dividend Policy, Growth and sustain the Japanese brokerage industry cartel and to support the level of stock
the Valuation of Shares,” Journal of Business, Vol. 24, No. 4 (October 1961), pp. prices, see my articles, “The Economics and Politics of Index Arbitrage in the U.S.
411-433. I have taken the value of rho (the risk-adjusted cost of capital) as 10 percent and Japan,” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 1, No. 1 (May 1993), pp. 3-11; and
(what else?) and the value of k (the investment-to-earnings ratio) as 1.0. A firm with “Japanese-American Trade Relations in the Financial Services Industry,” Working
a market-to-book ratio of 1.0 corresponds to a “no growth-premium firm” with Paper, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago (September 1993).
average internal rate of return (rho-star) just equal to the cost of capital.

34
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Japanese stock prices, even at current levels, are still hard to take seriously because
they are not completely free-market prices. Japanese managers can be pardoned for
wondering whether the stock market may be just a Bunraku theater, with the
bureaucrats from MOF backstage manipulating the puppets.

stock market is not to suggest that valuations in the holder-disciplined counterparts. Note that I stress
U.S. are always correct. But at least those investors Japanese manufacturing firms. No one has ever
with bearish opinions about particular stocks or the suggested that Japanese market-share-oriented firms
market as a whole can express their pessimism by were superior in the service industries, notably
selling, even selling short, without encountering the retailing, or in commercial banking.
kind of anti-selling rules and taboos for which MOF And I should say that manufacturing was the
has become notorious. Those pessimists may well be main evidence for Japanese governance superiority
wrong, of course. And so in their turn may be those cited before the current recession hit Japan. That
who are optimistically anticipating a rise in future recession, painful as has been and still is its impact
earnings and prices. on the Japanese economy, has at least served to
No serious student of stock markets has ever remind us that myopia is not the only disease of
suggested that stock prices always “correctly” mea- vision afflicting business managers. They may suffer
sure the true “fundamentals,” whatever those words from astigmatism (distorted vision) or even from
might mean. The most claimed is that the prices are hyperopia or excessive far-sightedness. Looking
not systematically distorted, like those in Japan back over the last 20 years, one may well find cases
where MOF’s heavy thumb often tilts the scales in which American firms facing strong stockholder
against selling. Nor are the prices in the U.S. just some pressures to pay out funds invested too little in some
artificial numbers driven by whims and fads, as some kinds of capital-intensive technology. But many
academics have argued (and quite unsuccessfully so, Japanese firms, facing no such pressures, have
in my opinion). The evidence overwhelmingly sup- clearly over invested during that same period in
ports the view that prices reflect in an unbiased way highly capital-intensive plants that will never come
all the information about a company that is available close to recovering their initial investment, let alone
to the investing public. earning a positive rate of return. And I won’t even
The word “available” is worth stressing, how- mention the trillions of yen poured into land and
ever. Stockholders and potential outside investors office buildings both at home and abroad.
can’t be expected to value management’s proposed No form of corporate governance, needless to
investment projects properly if they don’t have the say, whether Japanese or American, can guarantee
information on which management has based those 20-20 vision by management. Mistakes, both of
plans. And management may well hesitate to dis- omission and of commission, will always be made.
close that information for fear of alerting competi- My claim is only that those American managers who
tors. This inevitable “asymmetry” in information, to do focus on maximizing the market value of the firm
use the fashionable academic jargon, is what many have a better set of correcting lenses for properly
see as the real flaw in the shareholder-value prin- judging the trade-off between current investment
ciple. Projects with positive net present values, pos- and future benefits than those who focus on maxi-
sibly even with substantial net present values, may mizing growth, market share, or some other, trendy,
not be undertaken because outside investors cannot presumed strategic advantage.
value the projects properly and will condemn man-
agement for wasting the stockholders’ money. That, MANAGEMENT OBJECTIVES AND
essentially, is the Porter position. As one way to deal STOCKHOLDER INTERESTS
with it, the Porter study recommends that U.S. gov-
ernance rules be changed to permit firms to disclose Glasses help you see better, of course, only if
proprietary, competitively-sensitive information se- you wear them. And the complaint of at least one
lectively to that subset of the stockholders willing to wing of American academic opinion, especially in
commit to long-term investing in the company. the field of finance, is precisely that U.S. managers
Can investment be discouraged by inability to don’t always wear their stockholder-corrected lenses
disclose selectively? Possibly. Has it happened? And to work. Because ownership of American corpora-
on what scale? That is much harder to say. The main tions is so widely dispersed among a multitude of
evidence cited for its pervasiveness in the U.S. is the passive individual and institutional investors, U.S.
supposedly superior earnings and growth perfor- managers, so the argument runs, are left free to
mance of bank-disciplined Japanese manufacturing pursue objectives that may, but need not, conform
firms relative to their impatient American stock- to those of the stockholders.

35
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 4 WINTER 1994
Shareholders, however, are not powerless. Al- able ownership interests: more efficient sharing of
though neither able nor willing to perform day-by- the business risks. But the managers are typically not
day monitoring of management operating decisions, diversified. A major fraction of their personal wealth
shareholders do have the right to elect the company’s and their human capital is tied to the corporation.
Board of Directors. And the Board, in turn, by its Caution, not boldness, inevitably becomes their
power to unseat management, and even more by its watchword.
power to design the program for executive compen- The executive stock option was invented in the
sation, has command over important levers for U.S. in the 1950s precisely to offset the play-it-safe
aligning management’s objectives with those of the tendencies of underdiversified corporate managers
shareholders. (though tax considerations and accounting conven-
tions have since blurred the original incentive-driven
Compensation Packages and motivation for options).3 Stock options, suitably
Management Incentives structured, work by magnifying the upside potential
for the manager relative to the down. A bet paying
The Board of Directors has a tool-box full of $1,000 if a coin comes up heads and losing $1,000
levers but not, alas, any simple or fool-proof set of if tails would hardly be tempting to the typical risk-
instructions for using them. In fact, academic “agency averse manager. But tossing a fair coin might well
cost” theory suggests that no all-purpose optimal seem attractive if heads brought $5,000 and tails cost
scheme—no “first-best” as opposed to, say, second- only $500.
best or even lower-best solution—really exists for Options and their many variations—including
aligning interests when success depends on luck as option-equivalents like highly leveraged corporate
well as skill. capital structures—not only can reduce management’s
To see why, ask yourself how the directors natural risk-aversion, but may overdo it and tempt
could make the managers accept the stockholders’ managers into excessively risky ventures. If these
attitudes toward risk. Suppose, to be specific, that the long-odds strategies do happen to pay off, the
directors try what may seem the obvious perfor- managers profit enormously. If not, the bulk of the
mance-based compensation strategy of giving the losses are borne by the shareholders, and probably
managers shares in the company. Will that make the bondholders and other prior claimants as well.
managers act like the shareholders would? More so, Many observers feel that a payoff asymmetry of
probably, than if the directors just offered a flat—and precisely this kind for undercapitalized owner-man-
presumably high—salary supplemented with gener- agers was the root cause of the U.S. Savings and Loan
ous retirement benefits. Managers so compensated disaster.
are more likely to be working for the bondholders The inability to align management interests and
than for the stockholders. Salaried managers clearly risk attitudes more closely with those of the stock-
have little incentive to consider projects with serious holders shows up most conspicuously, some aca-
downside risk. demic critics would argue, in the matter of corporate
Giving managers stock at least lets them partici- diversification. Corporate diversification does re-
pate in the gains from their successful moves, but still duce risk for the managers. But because stockhold-
does not solve the problem of excessive managerial ers can diversify directly, they have little to gain—
timidity—excessive, that is, relative to the interests of except perhaps for some tax benefits, large in some
the outside stockholders. Those stockholders are, or cases, from internal offsetting rather than carryforward
at least in principle ought to be, well diversified. of losses—when a General Motors, say, uses funds
They can thus afford risking their entire investment that might otherwise have been paid as dividends to
in the company even for only 50:50 odds because buy up Ross Perot’s firm, Electronic Data Services
their stockholding is only a small part of their total (EDS). In fairness, however, let it be noted that the
wealth. That, after all, is a key social benefit of the stockholders, by the same token, would have little
corporate form with fractional and easily transfer- to lose by such acquisitions unless the acquiring firm

3. See Merton Miller and Myron Scholes, “Executive Compensation, Taxes and
Incentives,” in Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner, William
Sharpe and Catheryn Cootner (Eds.), Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1982.

36
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Myopia is not the only disease of vision afflicting business managers. They may
suffer from astigmatism or even from excessive far-sightedness. Looking back over
the last 20 years, one will find cases in which American firms facing strong
stockholder pressures to pay out funds invested too little. But many Japanese firms,
facing no such pressures, have clearly overinvested during that same period.

FIGURE 1
SOCIAL VERSUS PRIVATE
COSTS OF LOSING
A CORPORATE
FRANCHISE PREMIUM

were to pay too high a price for control—which market and the company will sell for a high market-
certainly has been known to happen. to-book value premium.
Stockholders could also lose if diversification Now let the government win its anti-trust suit
predictably and consistently means sacrificing the against the company and immediately force the
efficiencies from specialization. Some evidence sug- company’s price and output to their competitive
gests that it does—although hardly enough, in my levels (OB for price and OK for quantity). The
view, to justify claims by some academic critics of abnormal profits will vanish, the stock price will fall,
corporate diversification that loss of corporate focus and the market-to-book value premium will disap-
and related failures of governance by GM or IBM or pear. Yet no net loss in national wealth or welfare
Sears in recent years have destroyed hundreds of has occurred in this instance. Wealth and economic
billions of dollars of their stockholders’ and, by welfare have simply been transferred from the
extension, of the nation’s wealth. company’s shareholders to its customers; producer
For those firms, certainly, aggregate stock mar- surplus has been transformed into consumers’ sur-
ket values have declined substantially. But to treat plus. In fact, in the case pictured, society is better off
such declines as a national disaster like some gigantic on balance, not worse off. Because output increases
earthquake is to overlook the distinction between to the competitive level, consumers gain additional
social costs and private costs. Consider, for example, consumers’ surplus in the form of the (“Harberger”)
the story told in Figure 1, which pictures an IBM-type triangle DFN.
firm about to be hit unexpectedly with an anti-trust The social and private consequences are easily
suit (and let it be clearly understood that this is an distinguished in this anti-trust scenario. But what if
illustration, and not necessarily a recommendation). the decline in stock-market value is a self-inflicted
The company’s initial demand curve is d1d1, and its wound? IBM, after all, did not lose its anti-trust case.
long-run marginal cost is BJ (assumed, for simplicity, Its market value was eroded by the entry of new firms
to be constant and hence equal to its average cost). with new technologies.
Because the firm had “market power,” it set its That kind of value erosion, however, surely
product price at OC (i.e., above average and mar- cannot be the national disaster to which the gover-
ginal cost), earning thereby the above-normal profits nance critics are pointing. Why, after all, should
indicated by the rectangle BCDF. Those above- society’s consumers care whether the new products
competitive profits will be capitalized by the stock were introduced by IBM or by Intel or Apple; by

37
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 4 WINTER 1994
Wal-Mart or by Sears; or, for that matter, by General requires specific empirical research of a kind not yet
Motors or by Toyota? The complaint of the critics found in the recent academic literature so critical of
may be rather that the managements of those firms U.S. corporate governance.
have failed to downsize and restructure fast enough That the losses suffered in recent years by firms
even after the new competition had penetrated the like IBM or Sears or General Motors may not be
market. Entrenched managements, unchecked by social losses will be of little comfort, of course, to
the hand-picked sycophants on their Boards, kept those stockholders who have seen so much of their
pouring money into the old, money-losing lines of retirement nest eggs in those companies vanish. One
the firm’s business rather than letting their stock- can hardly blame them for wishing that the directors
holders redeploy the funds to better advantage had somehow prodded management to abandon
elsewhere. their formerly successful strategies before the suc-
But continuing to make positive investments in cess of the newer competitive strategies had been so
a declining industry—“throwing good money after decisively confirmed. Fortunately, however, share-
bad,” as the cliché would have it—cannot automati- holders whose personal stake is too small to justify
cally be taken as evidence of economic inefficiency, costly monitoring of management have another and
and certainly not of bad management. Nothing in well-tested way to protect their savings from
economic logic or commonsense suggests the best management’s mistakes of omission or commission:
exit path is always the quickest one. A firm with- diversify! A properly diversified shareholder would
draws its capital by making its net investment nega- have the satisfaction of knowing that his or her loss
tive, that is, by holding its rate of gross investment on IBM shares or Sears or General Motors was not
below the rate of depreciation. The marginal rate of even a private loss since it was offset in the portfolio
return on that gross investment may well be high by gains on Microsoft, Intel, Apple, WalMart and
even though the average rate of return on the past other new-entrant firms, foreign and domestic, that
capital sunk in the division or the firm as a whole is did pioneer in the new technologies.
low or even negative. When the direct costs of exit
(such as severance payments) are high, and when CONCLUSION
the firm is at least covering its variable costs (unlike
many in Russia, so we are told), investing to reduce Summing up, then, we have seen two quite
a loss can often be a highly positive net-present- different views of what is wrong with American
value project indeed. corporate management. One view, widely accepted
Suppose, however, for the sake of argument in Japan and by the Michael Porter wing of academic
that some entrenched managers were too slow in opinion, is that American managers pay too much
downsizing. The losses reported by their firms still attention to current shareholder returns. The other
cannot be equated dollar for dollar with the social view, widely held among U.S. academic finance
costs of bad governance. To see why, turn again to specialists, is that American managers pay too little
Figure 1, which can also be used to show the new attention to shareholder returns.
condition of our original firm—that is, after the entry Which view is right? Both. And neither. Both
of the new competition attracted by its earlier high sides can point to specific cases or examples seem-
profits. The firm’s demand curve is now the much ing to support their positions. But both are wrong in
more elastic demand curve d2d2, and its new long- claiming any permanent or systematic bias for U.S.
run equilibrium level of output will be OL, smaller firms in the aggregate toward myopia or hyperopia,
than its earlier equilibrium output level OH. toward underinvestment or overinvestment relative
Should the firm seek to maintain its earlier either to the shareholders’ or to society’s best inter-
market share of OH, however, net losses of ABFG ests. There is no inherent bias because market forces
will be incurred, exactly as the critics insist. But only are constantly at work to remove control over cor-
the triangle MFG represents the social cost of the porate assets from managers who lack the compe-
failure to downsize. The rest, given by the area tence or the vision to deploy them efficiently.
ABMG is, again, merely a transfer to consumer We saw those forces most dramatically perhaps
surplus. How much of the reported loss goes one in the takeover battles, leveraged buyouts, and
way and how much goes the other cannot be settled, corporate restructurings of the 1980s and, more
of course, merely from a schematic diagram. That recently, in many well-publicized board-led insur-

38
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
There is no permanent or systematic bias for U.S. firms in the aggregate toward
myopia or hyperopia, toward underinvestment or overinvestment, because market
forces are constantly at work to remove control over corporate assets from
managers who lack the competence or the vision to deploy them efficiently.

gencies. But, for all their drama, those events (which pline for the managers of one firm in the U.S. will
often seem little more than struggles over how the always be the managers of other firms, including
corporate franchise premium is to be shared be- foreign firms, competing with them head to head for
tween the executives and the shareholders) repre- customer business. As long as we continue to have
sent only one part—and by no means the most plenty of that kind of competition in the U.S., I, for
important part—of the process of allocating society’s one, can’t become terribly concerned about the
productive capital among firms. The ultimate disci- supposedly fatal flaws in our governance system.

MERTON MILLER

is the Robert R. McCormick Distinguished Service Professor Business. Professor Miller won the Nobel Prize in Economics
Emeritus at the University of Chicago’s Graduate School of in 1990.

39
VOLUME 6 NUMBER 4 WINTER 1994

You might also like