You are on page 1of 6

ENVIRONMENTAL VALUATION TECHNIQUES IN WATER RESOURCE

DECISION MAKING
By John B. Loomis1

ABSTRACT: Economic valuation of environmental uses of water resources has the potential to bring a more
balanced perspective to the allocation and management of water resources. Environmental valuation allows water
resource benefits received by nontraditional water users in society to be included in benefit-cost analyses. This
allows for a more formal consideration in the decision-making process that is on par with historic uses of water.
Some environmental valuation methods follow traditional economic approaches such as estimating the demand
curve for recreation as a function of water flow or water quality. Other environmental valuation approaches
utilize surveys to create simulated markets for public uses of water resources. These valuation methods are
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

capable of monetizing the economic values of instream flow and water-based recreation as well as the value of
preserving habitat for endangered species. Government-agency use of these environmental values and techniques
in their resource analyses is presented. Several case studies illustrate how environmental valuation has been used
to evaluate hydropower regulation at Glen Canyon Dam, hydropower relicensing, dam removal, and public trust
benefits of water versus municipal uses.

INTRODUCTION Fish versus 28,000 People?’’ The implication was that provid-
ing water for fish in the tributary streams flowing into Mono
How valuable is the economic valuation work of economists Lake deprived people of benefits. In addition to being an un-
is a good question, and one frequently heard (Vatn and Brom- productive way to view the issue, surveys of the California
ley 1994). Posed a different way, ‘‘Are the benefits of these citizenry showed this was a false dichotomy. People cared
studies, in terms of more efficient use of water resources, about the fish and the birds as well as the Mono Lake eco-
worth the costs of these studies?’’ This is a tough question, system (Loomis 1987). Using the hypothetical market method
one asked in many fields including weather forecasting and described below, the dollar sacrifice these people would make
flood prediction. Given that policy decisions are (and should to provide water for fish and birds could be quantified and
be) affected by many concerns in addition to economic effi- compared to the replacement cost of water from other sources
ciency (e.g., distributional equity, sustainability, etc.), it is rare including agricultural and municipal water conservation.
to be able to point to any one information source in the policy The state of California’s Water Resources Control Board
process and say it was the definitive factor. Nonetheless, the was sufficiently impressed with the initial household survey
increased scrutiny that environmental valuation techniques measuring the existence values from just knowing Mono Lake
such as contingent valuation surveys have received by the oil would be preserved, that they required the contractor preparing
industry and politicians suggests the results of these methods the state’s Environmental Impact Report to perform a far more
must matter. But, lest one has the impression that environ- thorough hypothetical market analysis. The economic values
mental valuation is the exclusive tool of natural resource pro- from that survey were published in the Environmental Impact
tection advocates, industry uses environmental valuation when Report. These dollars of willingness to pay to protect the
it suits their needs as well. For example, large power compa- Mono Lake ecosystem were counted dollar for dollar as equiv-
nies such as Pacific Gas and Electric (PG&E) and Idaho Power alent to hydropower and water supply benefits and costs in the
have relied upon environmental valuation techniques to pro- economic analysis of the different water allocation alternatives
vide some balance to the unconstrained demands of state agen- (Jones and Stokes Associates 1993). In the end, the state or-
cies for greater instream flows. Although valuation is not all dered the flows into Mono Lake to be increased and Los An-
that should matter, valuation can contribute to improving so- geles’s water rights to be reduced by nearly half (Loomis
cial decision making by balancing one-sided recommendations 1995). While air and water quality concerns were the driving
by industry or public agencies. force in this decision, being able to show that such water real-
Environmental valuation techniques can also have a more locations were not uneconomic probably aided in making such
profound role in water resource debates; in many cases, these a dramatic change. This is one of the many examples of the
valuation studies have changed the nature of those debates. utility of environmental valuation in water resource decision
Perhaps the best example of this is in the public trust case making that will be provided in the remainder of the paper.
involving tributary water flows into Mono Lake in California However, a description of the economic techniques used to
versus diverting such flows for municipal and industrial uses produce the estimates of environmental values will be given.
in Los Angeles. These diversions were drying up tributary
streams and lowering the lake level. In 1983 the California What Is Environmental Valuation?
State Supreme Court required a reevaluation of the city of Los
Angeles’s 1941 water rights and required a balancing of the Environmental valuation attempts to estimate the economic
public trust uses of water. The Los Angeles Department of value, in dollar terms, that members of society receive from
Water and Power cast the reevaluation debate in terms of ‘‘300 uses of natural resources that cannot be efficiently allocated
through markets due to their public good characteristics such
1
Prof. and Economist, Dept. of Agric. and Resour. Economics, Colo- as being nonrival (one person’s use of instream flow does not
rado State Univ., Fort Collins, CO 80523. diminish another person’s use) and nonexcludable (once drink-
Note. Discussion open until May 1, 2001. To extend the closing date ing water quality is improved for one resident in a city, another
one month, a written request must be filed with the ASCE Manager of city resident cannot be precluded from enjoying this same im-
Journals. The manuscript for this paper was submitted for review and
possible publication on June 14, 2000. This paper is part of the Journal
proved level of water quality). Yet recreational fishing and
of Water Resources Planning and Management, Vol. 126, No. 6, No- boating at higher instream flows or improved water quality
vember/December, 2000. 䉷ASCE, ISSN 0733-9496/00/0006-0339– provide an economic benefit to its participants even if a formal
0344/$8.00 ⫹ $.50 per page. Paper No. 22293. market does not exist. It is a benefit for which they would, if
JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000 / 339

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344


they had to, pay more than the current nominal, administra- this is due to the difficulty in relying upon cash contributions
tively set fishing license fee or boat launch fee. The fact that in a public good experiment as a valid measure of an individ-
they do not have to pay ‘‘what the market will bear’’ results ual’s true existence value (Randall 1998). This difficulty is
in the visitor retaining a ‘‘consumer surplus’’ as extra income. inherent in the characteristics of a public good that makes
Similar to irrigation water from publicly provided projects that possible (even encourages) free-riding behavior on the part of
is not priced at its market clearing price, neither is recreation, respondents. That is, why should you voluntarily contribute to
yet both have economic value. the good, if others will pay and provide it for you. This has
In the case of recreation, economists can rely on visitor been long noted in the public goods literature (Samuelson
travel behavior to statistically estimate a demand curve for 1954) and spoils attempts to use actual cash experiments to
water-based recreation at a particular site. From the demand validate existence values obtained from CVM (Randall 1998).
curve, economists can estimate the additional amount a visitor Nonetheless, the few experiments that exist result in stated
would pay, if required, for continued access to the water-based WTP amounts that may be two or more times higher than
recreation resource. Based on actual behavior, this approach is actual contributions or payments. Recent developments have
referred to as the travel cost method (TCM). Because different suggested inclusion of additional questions in the CVM survey
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

visitors live different distances from the site, the analyst can that appear to allow calibration of stated WTP amounts to
observe how the number of trips taken varies with variations actual cash contributions (Champ et al. 1997). However, con-
in travel costs to the site. Essentially, spatially varying prices cerns with CVM WTP responses are not limited to only di-
are observed. Thus the demand curve can be estimated by vergence between actual cash and hypothetical WTP. Concerns
multiple regression using this cross section data on travel costs also exist as to whether the stated WTP is responsive to var-
(as proxies for price) and number of trips taken each season. iations in the amount of the public good provided (i.e., what
By observing how recreation visitation changes with increased is known as sensitivity to scope). There are also concerns re-
river flows, higher reservoir levels, and improved water qual- garding the discouraging result that stated WTP is often sen-
ity, economists can statistically estimate the demand shifts for sitive to the format of the WTP question (e.g., open-ended
improved water resource conditions. From these demand versus closed-ended formats) and to the temporal duration of
shifts, the additional dollar amount a typical visitor would pay payments (e.g., monthly versus annual versus lump sum). Thus
for the improved water resource condition can be calculated. it is not surprising that decision makers often use results from
These incremental benefits can be compared to the opportunity CVM surveys of the general public as indicative of their in-
costs to other water resource users or to government agencies tensity of preferences, but the exact dollar values may not be
for bringing about these improvements in water resource char- as heavily relied upon as they are in recreation analyses.
acteristics. There are dozens of applications of the TCM for The importance of existence values is evident in the fact
estimating the economic value of instream flow and hundreds that they often dwarf the recreation use values and the oppor-
of studies on the economic value of fishing [see Gillian and tunity costs of protecting water resources in valuation studies.
Brown (1997), Loomis and Walsh (1997), and Industrial Ec- For example, in the original Mono Lake CVM analysis
onomics Inc. (1999) for summaries]. (Loomis 1987), even the lower-bound estimate of the benefits
Recreation, however, is only part of the story. As mentioned exceeded the cost by far more than the hypothetical bias pos-
in the Mono Lake case, many individuals who may never fish sible in CVM (e.g., $1.525 billion in benefits versus
or boat still receive some benefits from just knowing that free $26,500,000 in costs). The phenomenon of large benefits is
flowing rivers exist (Sanders et al. 1990) or that salmon mi- partly a result of what economists call the public good nature
grations will continue as part of the cycle of life in that region of existence values. Small values per household of $30–$150/
(Olsen et al. 1991). The benefits realized by those that never year when multiplied by 10,000,000 households in California,
visit the natural environment or never actively participate in for example, result in substantial aggregate estimates of total
on-site use of the resource are known as existence values or benefits. Recent empirical analyses suggest that for many nat-
passive use values (U.S. District Court 1989; Olsen et al. ural resources, such as protection of salmon in the Pacific
1991). In these cases, many households would be willing to Northwest, the benefits extend nationally to nearly
pay (WTP) for protection of water resources. Today, these val- 100,000,000 households (Loomis 1996).
ues are quantified through a hypothetical referendum, where
households are asked if they would vote in favor of a particular AGENCY AND COURT ACCEPTANCE OF
resource protection action, if it cost their household $X. The NONMARKET VALUATION
amount of $X varies across households, so that a demandlike Federal agencies were among the first government agencies
relationship can be statistically estimated. From this statistical to adopt CVM for use in benefit-cost analysis of water resource
relationship, the sample average WTP is calculated. This ques- issues. Beginning in 1979, federal agencies such as the U.S.
tioning technique is one form of what is commonly referred Army Corps of Engineers (COE) and the U.S. Bureau of Rec-
to as the contingent valuation method (CVM). CVM is based lamation were required to use the TCM and CVMs to value
on surveys, not actual consumption choices, and can be used recreation benefits at projects with high visitation levels (U.S.
to value either recreation or existence values. Water Resources Council 1979, 1983). During the 1980s the
There is of course some skepticism regarding the reliability COE had its economists attend training courses on TCM and
of statements of WTP. As such, CVM has been subjected to CVM. In addition, the agency published manuals on how to
more testing and scrutiny than most empirical methods in ec- perform the CVM (Moser and Dunning 1986). Since the early
onomics. For example, nearly every feature of survey design 1990s, the U.S. Forest Service has conducted annual training
has been tested to determine which approach yields the most sessions for its fisheries/wildlife biologists in nonmarket val-
reliable results. For estimating the nonmarket benefits of rec- uation theory and techniques. Today, the U.S. Bureau of Rec-
reation, CVM results in estimates of WTP that are slightly less lamation maintains a staff of several economists who are
than estimates based on actual behavior using methods such trained in and publish in the area of environmental valuation.
as the TCM. This has been a fairly consistent finding over When Congress passed the Comprehensive Environmental
dozens of CVM studies covering fishing, rafting, hunting, Response, Compensation and Liability Act (CERCLA) of
camping, etc. (Carson et al. 1996). 1980, the U.S. Department of Interior adopted TCM and CVM
The validity of CVM derived estimates of WTP for exis- as two methods for valuing the loss in recreation and existence
tence values or passive use values is less encouraging. In part, values from toxic waste sites and hazardous materials spills
340 / JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344


(U.S. Department of Interior 1986). The importance of using the first major passive use value studies being funded by a
CVM to measure existence values did not go unnoticed by federal agency. As it became clear that more than recreation
industry. Nonetheless, when industry challenged the use of was at stake in reregulation of the dam, it also became more
CVM, the Court of Appeals upheld CVM and ordered the U.S. obvious that citizens throughout the United States cared about
Department of Interior to broaden its use to measure existence how dam operations affected the natural resources of the
values (what the court called passive use values) even when Grand Canyon. In particular, people were concerned about en-
there was direct, on-site recreation use of the resource (U.S. dangered species, erosion, native vegetation, and birds, which
District Court of Appeals 1989). The court indicated that the were all being adversely affected by fluctuating flows resulting
congressional intent behind CERCLA allowed recreation use from a peaking power operation at the dam and lack of high
and passive use values to be summed together. Specifically the spring flows. The U.S. Bureau of Reclamation funded a major
Court of Appeals stated, ‘‘The statue’s command is expressly nonuse value study of households throughout the United States
not limited to use value; if anything, the language implies that to estimate their WTP for different flow regimes that would
DOI is to include in its regulations other factors in addition to protect the natural resources in the Grand Canyon. These re-
use value. . . . Option and existence values may represent ‘pas- sults showed higher WTP for the steady flow regime (Welsh
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

sive’ use, but they nonetheless reflect utility derived by humans et al. 1995). Although it is difficult to point to any one study
from a resource, and thus prima facie, ought to be included in as definitively affecting the management of Glen Canyon
a damage assessment’’ (U.S. District Court of Appeals 1989, Dam, the public support combined with concerns over endan-
p. 67). gered fish have resulted in substantial changes in the manage-
The Exxon Valdez oil spill of 1989 put CVM in the spot- ment of the dam. For example, large spills were made during
light. Fearing damage estimates of several billion dollars, the spring of 1995 to emulate the natural high spring flows.
Exxon spent heavily on economists, their studies, and a well-
orchestrated by invitation only workshop to try and discredit Maintaining Reservoir Levels for Recreation
CVM as a tool for measuring existence values. However, when
Congress passed the Oil Pollution Act of 1990, the responsible In the eastern United States, the Tennessee Valley Authority
agency, the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration operates a large number of dams for hydropower, flood con-
(NOAA), recommended that CVM be used to measure the rec- trol, and recreation. Historic operation involved operating res-
reation and passive use values lost due to oil spills. Given the ervoirs primarily for hydropower and flood control. The result
controversy surrounding this recommendation, NOAA ap- was that reservoir levels typically peaked in the spring and
pointed a ‘‘blue ribbon’’ panel chaired by two Nobel laureates early summer and were drawn down to produce peaking power
to assess the reliability of the CVM for measuring passive use in the summer (Cordell and Bergstrom 1993). This resulted in
values. In its report in 1993, the panel concluded that carefully reservoir drawdowns of 11–28 ft and 6–24% less surface area
designed and implemented CVM studies could provide esti- during the mid- to late summer season. In addition to reducing
mates of passive use/existence values that would serve as a aesthetics of the reservoir for recreation and crowding existing
useful starting point for administrative and judicial decisions users into a smaller reservoir area, the drawdown made some
(Arrow et al. 1993). [See Jones (2000) for a more detailed boat ramp and marina facilities inaccessible. The Tennessee
discussion of the use of nonmarket valuation techniques and Valley Authority and North Carolina Division of Water Re-
CVM in the natural resource damage assessment arena.] sources commissioned a CVM study of the benefits of alter-
native water management levels in the reservoirs to provide
EXAMPLES OF NONMARKET VALUATIONS USED IN estimates comparable to foregone hydropower costs. The
WATER RESOURCE POLICY ANALYSES CVM survey was conducted using photosimulations of the
lake at alternative levels. Visitors were asked if they would
Glen Canyon Environmental Studies pay for an annual recreation pass that would result in higher
water levels for 1 additional month, 2 months, and 3 months
One of the most prominent uses of CVM, sponsored by the of the summer season. Annual WTP increased from $42/year
U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, occurred in an evaluation of the with current early season drawdown to $75 with higher water
economic effects of reregulating the flow releases from Glen levels maintained for the full 3-month summer season (Cordell
Canyon Dam on the Colorado River. Peaking power opera- and Bergstrom 1993, p. 255). Annual benefits to the four res-
tions at the dam were having a deleterious effect on down- ervoirs alone where the interviews were conducted was
stream fishing and rafting at Glen Canyon National Recreation $13,580,000. The authors concluded the gain in recreational
Area and Grand Canyon National Park. The central question benefits at the four reservoirs from holding higher water levels
was about the worth of the recreation compared to the market longer in the prime recreation season exceeded the hydro-
values of the peaking power. The first studies carried out used power generation losses but not the sum of these losses and
CVM to quantify how the value of fishing in Glen Canyon the costs of replacing the power generation capacity (Cordell
National Recreation Area and rafting in Grand Canyon Na- and Bergstrom 1993).
tional Park would change with more even base flows as com-
pared to peaking power flows. Visitors were surveyed in the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Relicensing
mid-1980s. The economic effects were substantial, represent- Decisions
ing changes of $2,000,000 annually (Bishop et al. 1989). But
the impact of this analysis was greater considering the way it Environmental valuation has also been used in the Federal
helped change the perspective of the management issue than Energy Regulatory Commission’s (FERC) deliberations over
for the numerical values it provided. Rather than recreation the level of minimum instream flow conditions to attach to 50-
versus hydropower, the report turned the discussion toward year operating licenses. One of the strongest indications of the
finding a release pattern that increased the economic value of difference that environmental valuation could make was in the
all the multiple purposes, hydropower as well as recreation. FERC case involving whether to permit construction of a dam
For a variety of reasons, even more releases were put in place at Kootenai Falls in Montana. The economist who performed
while the final environmental impact studies took place. Con- the CVM analysis and presented it before the administrative
gress formalized these flows when it passed the Grand Canyon law judge in the court case wrote this about the outcome: ‘‘The
Protection Act of 1992. judge’s decision turned on the aesthetics and recreation values.
The Glen Canyon recreation study also resulted in one of This is an interesting case in that not only was contingent
JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000 / 341

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344


valuation the primary method, but additionally, a compensa- taking a rafting trip and on total rafting benefits. Their research
tion-demanded measure was apparently accepted as plausible. suggested that more frequent, but smaller flow releases might
The utility appealed the judge’s decision to the full Federal generate more total rafting benefits than the current few, but
Energy Regulatory Commission, which upheld the rejection of large releases from the dam.
the application. Our understanding is that this is one of only
two or three cases where FERC has not approved an appli- Dam Removals for Fishery Benefits
cation for a major hydroelectric project’’ (Duffield 1992, p.
314). Duffield’s reference to ‘‘compensation demanded’’ mea- As more and more anadromous fish species have been added
sure of value is especially noteworthy, for this willingness to to the endangered species list, serious consideration has been
accept the measure is a more inclusive measure of environ- given to complete removal of dams blocking salmon migra-
tion. Not only do the dams block upstream migration of adult
mental value as it is unconstrained by income, unlike WTP.
salmon, but the reservoir pools behind the dams substantially
Because willingness to accept measures frequently exceed
slow the migration of juvenile salmon to the ocean. Given the
WTP measures more than expected by theory, the large mag-
dams’ contribution to the decline of this symbolic species in
nitude of willingness to accept CVM responses are often
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

the Pacific Northwest, there has been a groundswell of support


viewed with some skepticism. Thus, a judge’s reliance on will-
from newspaper editors in Boise, Idaho, to the governor of
ingness to accept is a strong endorsement of CVM.
Oregon to remove the dams.
PG&E in California has repeatedly relied upon environ-
The first dams to receive a formal environmental impact
mental valuation studies to estimate the recreation benefits as-
analysis for removal are the Elwha and Glines dams on the
sociated with alternative instream flow requirements when
Elwha River on the Olympic Peninsula in Washington. These
making its FERC license renewal applications. PG&E’s sub-
are old dams and have no fish ladders. The 200-ft dams are
missions to FERC for relicensing two hydroprojects on the in such a narrow canyon that fish ladders are very costly and
North Fork of the Feather River have involved using a com- likely to be ineffective. Given the age of the dams and the fact
bination of recreational fishing valuation based on the TCM they block migration of fish to 70 mi of pristine spawning
(Loomis and Cooper 1990) and transfer of values from other grounds in Olympic National Park, their removal could more
river-based studies in the west for shore-based recreation and than triple salmon populations on the Elwha River.
potential rafting. These analyses presented the recreation ben- However, biological efficiency is not the same as economic
efits at alternative flow levels and temperature modifications. efficiency. The cost to remove the dams and the 50 years of
Attempts to reach agreement with the California Department sediment buildup behind the dams was estimated at
of Fish and Game on increasing minimum flows have been $100,000,000–$125,000,000. The recreational and commer-
contentious. An adaptive management approach has been pro- cial fishing benefits alone would not likely offset these costs.
posed to experimentally increase flows and then monitor vis- The National Park Service, U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, and
itor use. As the consultant to PG&E states, ‘‘All sides agreed the Indian tribes requested a contingent valuation survey that
that economic benefits and costs would be a major determining would estimate the existence and bequest values (benefits the
factor’’ in what flows to make permanent (M. Feldman, per- current generation receives from providing salmon to future
sonal communication, 2000). generations) from restoring the salmon stocks. The survey
Idaho Power Company commissioned a CVM study of the asked households if they would vote in favor of removing the
economic benefits of alternative flow releases over Shoshone dams and restoring the river so as to triple salmon populations
Falls on the Snake River. The company’s intention is to eval- (illustrated using a bar chart). The cost each household was
uate whether the gain in recreation benefits from more water asked to pay varied from $3 to $150. In addition to surveying
passing over the falls is worth the power foregone from not households in the state of Washington, households throughout
running the water through the turbines. Preliminary analysis the United States were also surveyed.
suggests that, during the summer months, triple the current The CVM survey was successful on a number of fronts.
minimum 50 cfs of bypass flow is economically efficient The survey response rate in Washington was quite high at
(Loomis and Feldman 1995). This, of course, illustrates the 68%, and it was 55% for the rest of the United States. The
‘‘double-edged sword’’ of nonmarket valuation. Although it internal validity of the results was indicated by the coefficient
demonstrates that huge increases in minimum instream flow on the dollar amount households were asked to pay being neg-
requests are not justified, it also suggests some increases in ative and statistically significant. This means that the higher
flows may enhance efficiency. Thus neither environmentalists the dollar amount the household was asked to pay the less
nor the utility may fully support the CVM results, as it may likely they would agree to pay. This conforms to basic eco-
be viewed alternately as too little or too much. nomic theory and also indicates households considered the
The importance of FERC relicensing for public natural re- dollar amount they were asked to pay quite seriously. The
sources has resulted in a rare coordinated interagency (the U.S. average values per household ranged from $73 for Washington
Fish and Wildlife Service and the U.S. Forest Service) effort households (90% confidence interval of $60–$99) to $68 for
to force FERC to explicitly require environmental valuation in rest of U.S. households (90% confidence interval of $56–$92).
its decision making. To facilitate the use of environmental val- Even just considering Washington residents, the $73/house-
uation in FERC relicensing, the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service hold times the number of households in Washington would
recently commissioned a comprehensive report that provides nearly cover the cost of removing the dams, restoring the river,
detailed guidance on estimating the economic value of in- and providing the replacement hydropower produced by the
stream flow and other water-related environmental resources dams. Given the 86,000,000 households in the rest of the
(Industrial Economics Inc. 1999). United States, national WTP was in excess of a billion dollars.
Instream flow concerns are also important in eastern rivers, Thus, even if there is an upward bias to the CVM estimates
and nonmarket valuation techniques have been employed there of WTP, the estimated national benefits were far in excess of
as well. Bowker et al. (1996) applied TCM to estimate the the costs.
value of river rafting on the Chatooga and Nantahala rivers in These results were included in the Environmental Impact
the southeastern United States. Roach et al. (1999) evaluated Statement (EIS) prepared by the National Park Service on dam
the rafting benefits for alternative patterns of flow releases removal. The recommendation was to remove both dams and
from Long Falls Dam on the Dead River in Maine. The flow restore the Elwha River. The Clinton administration included
levels had a statistically significant effect on the probability of in their 1999 budget request to Congress the money to pur-
342 / JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344


chase the dams from the private owners, with the intent to Without valuation studies, only those with sufficiently concen-
request funds for dam removal and restoration in subsequent trated costs or benefits who attend hearings and committee
fiscal years. meetings or make large campaign contributions will be heard.
Two of the most controversial dam removal proposals to Valuation studies have the potential to provide an effective
date are those addressing four dams on the Lower Snake River way to diminish the often bemoaned role of ‘‘special interests’’
and Glen Canyon Dam on the Colorado River. The Lower in the current policy process.
Snake River Dam removal study was requested by the Na-
tional Marine Fisheries Service as part of its biological opinion
APPENDIX. REFERENCES
about recovering several threatened and endangered salmon
species. As part of the EIS, the COE used the TCM to measure Arrow, K., Solow, R., Portney, P., Leamer, E., Radner, R., and Schuman,
reservoir recreation benefits that would be foregone with dam H. (1993). ‘‘Report of the NOAA panel on contingent valuation.’’ Fed-
removal. A survey-based contingent behavior TCM to measure eral Register, 58(10), 4602–4614.
the benefits a restored free-flowing river might provide was Bishop, R., Brown, C., Welsh, M., and Boyle, K. (1989). ‘‘Grand Canyon
also implemented. The results of the contingent behavior TCM and Glen Canyon dam operations: An economic evaluation.’’ W-133
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

benefits and costs in natural resources planning, Interim Report No. 2,


showed estimated visits with a restored free-flowing river of K. Boyle and T. Heekin, eds., Dept. of Agric. and Resour. Economics,
462,450/year with annualized benefits of $80,000,000 (Loomis University of Maine, Orono, Maine.
1999). A CVM question to measure the existence values of Bowker, J., English, D., and Donovon, J. (1996). ‘‘Toward a value for
increasing salmon and returning the river to a free-flowing guided rafting on southern rivers.’’ J. Agric. and Appl. Economics,
state was included in the original survey that was pretested. 28(2), 423–432.
However, after the pretest, Senator Slade Gorton of Washing- Carson, R., Flores, N., Martin, K., and Wright, J. (1996). ‘‘Contingent
valuation and revealed preference methodologies.’’ Land Economics,
ton sent an official letter to the commander of the COE and 72(1), 80–99.
to Pacific Northwest region commanders stating ‘‘The Corps Champ, P., Bishop, R., Brown, T., and McCollum, D. (1997). ‘‘Using
of Engineers should abandon this survey . . .’’ (S. Gorton, per- donation mechanisms to value nonuse benefits from public goods.’’ J.
sonal communication, 1998). This political pressure on the Envir. Economics and Mgmt., 33(3), 151–162.
COE resulted in elimination of the CVM question regarding Cordell, K., and Bergstrom, J. (1993). ‘‘Comparison of recreation use
existence value of salmon and dam removal. It is clear that values among alternative reservoir management scenarios.’’ Water Re-
sour. Res., 29(2), 247–258.
those who had publicly opposed dam removal, such as Gorton, Duffield, J. (1992). ‘‘Contingent valuation: Issues and applications.’’ Nat-
anticipated a large influence of the nonmarket valuation results ural resource damages: Law and economics, K. Ward and J. Duffield,
on the final decision. However, Gorton was unable to stop the eds., Wiley, New York, 311–350.
contingent behavior TCM recreation survey as it was essential Gillian, D., and Brown, T. (1997). Instream flow protection, Island Press,
to several other portions of the economic analysis and the EIS. Covello, Calif.
Industrial Economics Inc. (1999). ‘‘Economic analysis for hydropower
project relicensing: guidance and methods.’’ Rep. Prepared for U.S.
CONCLUSIONS Fish and Wildlife Service, Washington, D.C.
Does valuation matter? A reasonable case can be made that Jones, C. A. (2000). ‘‘Economic valuation of resource injuries in natural
resource liability suits.’’ J. Water Resour. Plng. and Mgmt., ASCE,
environmental valuation does matter in water resources deci- 126(6), 358–365.
sion making. The nature of the contribution is often case spe- Jones and Stokes Associates. (1993). ‘‘Draft environmental impact report
cific. In some of the cases reviewed above, the environmental for the review of the Mono Basin water rights of the city of Los An-
valuation changed the character of the debate from being a geles.’’ Rep. Prepared for California State Water Resources Control
‘‘people versus the environment’’ to one of recognizing people Board, Division of Water Rights, Sacramento, Calif.
care about the instream flows just as they care about inexpen- Loomis, J. (1987). ‘‘Balancing public trust resources of Mono Lake and
Los Angeles’ water right: An economic approach.’’ Water Resour. Res.,
sive drinking water or hydroelectricity. Thus, applications of 23(8), 1449–1456.
environmental valuation to water resource management con- Loomis, J. (1995). ‘‘Public trust doctrine produces water for Mono Lake.’’
flicts involving traditional uses of water (e.g., hydropower, J. Soil and Water Conservation, 50(3), 270–271.
municipal and industrial) versus environmental uses (e.g., in- Loomis, J. (1996). ‘‘Measuring the benefits of removing dams and re-
stream flow) illustrates that the impact of valuation was often storing the Elwha River: Results of a contingent valuation survey.’’
felt more in the way it offered a common metric showing that Water Resour. Res., 32(2), 441–447.
Loomis, J. (1999). ‘‘Recreation use and NED benefits technical chapter.’’
both uses contribute to society than in the exact dollar values Rep., Dept. of Agric. and Resour. Economics, Colorado State Univer-
it provided. In other cases, environmental valuation helped dif- sity, Fort Collins, Colo.
fuse the often heard mantra that ‘‘protecting the environment Loomis, J., and Cooper, J. (1990). ‘‘Economic benefits of instream flow
is just too costly.’’ What the environmental valuation studies to fisheries: A case study of California’s Feather River.’’ Rivers, 1(1),
often show is that protecting the environment provides more 23–30.
benefits than the value of commodities foregone. Finally, in Loomis, J., and Feldman, M. (1995). ‘‘An economic approach to giving
equal consideration to environmental values in FERC hydropower re-
the Elwha River Dam removal example, contingent valuation licensing.’’ Rivers, 5(2), 96–108.
was used to estimate the benefits to all citizens of the United Loomis, J., and Walsh, R. (1997). Recreation economic decisions: Com-
States from salmon restoration. This avoided viewing salmon paring benefits and costs, Venture Publishing, State College, Pa.
restoration narrowly as only increased commercial fishing rev- Moser, D., and Dunning, M. (1986). ‘‘A guide for using the contingent
enues or sport fishing benefits. valuation methodology in recreation studies.’’ National economic de-
What is the value of valuation? The value lies in providing velopment procedures manual—recreation, Vol. 2, IWR Rep. 86-R-5,
Institute for Water Resources, U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Fort
a more complete accounting of all of the benefits and costs to Belvoir, Va.
all of the people. For without valuation, the predictions of the Olsen, D., Richards, J., and Scott, D. (1991). ‘‘Existence and sport values
public choice economists are frequently realized: (1) Those for double the size of Columbia River Basin salmon and steelhead
who would bear concentrated costs can more easily block wa- runs.’’ Rivers, 2(1), 44–56.
ter resource management changes that would benefit society Randall, A. (1998). ‘‘Beyond the crucial experiment: Mapping the per-
as a whole; and (2) those few that stand to gain concentrated formance characteristics of contingent valuation.’’ Energy and Resour.
Economics, 20, 197–206.
benefits can spread even larger costs out over millions of tax- Roach, B., Boyle, K., Bergstrom, J., and Reiling, S. (1999). ‘‘The effect
payers. Valuation studies can make possible some considera- of instream flows on whitewater visitation and consumer surplus: A
tion of ordinary citizens through their benefits and costs, re- contingent valuation application to the Dead River, Maine.’’ Rivers,
gardless of how small those benefits may be per person. 7(1), 11–20.

JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000 / 343

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344


Samuelson, P. (1954). ‘‘Pure theory of public expenditure.’’ Rev. of Ec- U.S. Water Resources Council. (1979). ‘‘Procedures for evaluation of na-
onomics and Statistics, 36, 387–389. tional economic development (NED) benefits and costs in water re-
Sanders, L., Walsh, R., and Loomis, J. (1990). ‘‘Toward empirical esti- sources planning; Final rule.’’ Federal Register, 44(242), 72892–72976.
mation of the total value of protecting rivers.’’ Water Resour. Res., U.S. Water Resources Council. (1983). Economic and environmental
26(7), 1345–1358. principles and guidelines for water and related land resources imple-
U.S. Department of Interior. (1986). ‘‘Natural resource damage assess- mentation studies, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C.
ments; final rule.’’ Federal Register, 51(4), 27674–27753. Vatn, A., and Bromley, D. (1994). ‘‘Choices without prices, without apol-
U.S. District Court of Appeals (for the District of Columbia). (1989). ogies.’’ J. Envir. Economics and Mgmt., 26(2), 129–148.
State of Ohio vs. U.S. Department of Interior (Case No. 86-1529, July Welsh, M., Bishop, R., Phillips, M., and Baumgartner, R. (1995). ‘‘GCES
14, 1989). non-use value study.’’ Rep., Hagler Bailly Consulting, Madison, Wis.
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Universidad de Cantabria on 09/28/16. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

344 / JOURNAL OF WATER RESOURCES PLANNING AND MANAGEMENT / NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 2000

J. Water Resour. Plann. Manage., 2000, 126(6): 339-344

You might also like