You are on page 1of 23

World Development Vol. 59, pp.

275–297, 2014
Ó 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.01.012

How Ethnic Diversity Affects Economic Growth


ERKAN GÖREN *
Carl von Ossietzky University Oldenburg, Campus Haarentor, Building A5, 26111 Oldenburg, Germany
Summary. — This paper investigates the empirical relationship between ethnic diversity, polarization, and economic growth. Ethnicity is
assumed to affect economic growth through a number of possible transmission channels that are generally included in cross-country
growth regressions. This paper provides an extensive empirical analysis shedding light on the various sources through which ethnic diver-
sity and polarization affects economic growth indirectly. It advances and empirically establishes the hypothesis that ethnic diversity has a
strong direct negative impact on economic growth, whereas ethnic polarization has non-negligible indirect economic effects through the
specified channel variables.
Ó 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — ethnic diversity, ethnic polarization, transmission channels, economic growth

1. INTRODUCTION Kurlat, and Wacziarg (2003), providing new, on a highly


disaggregated level, measures of ethnic, linguistic, and reli-
In recent years, there has been growing research interest in gious diversity for about 190 countries. They criticized the
the relationship between ethnic diversity and economic widely used ethnic measure from Atlas Narodov Mira for its
growth. In a seminal paper, Easterly and Levine (1997) inability to distinguish between ethnic and linguistic differ-
showed that the growth rate of GDP per capita is inversely re- ences. Such a distinction may well be unproblematic in African
lated to the degree of ethnic diversity within a country. They and European countries, where people identify themselves by
argued that the poor economic performance of most of the both ethnic group and language: in these contexts, the two cri-
African countries is due partly to the large number of different teria coincide. This is not the case in Latin American coun-
ethnic groups living in the same country and partly to the ab- tries, where people are more or less homogeneous in terms
surd borders drawn by former colonial powers. However, of language (e.g., Spanish or Portuguese) but distinct in terms
when controlling for other factors—namely, human capital, of ethnic membership. Alesina et al. (2003) reran the regres-
and political instability—the effect of the ethnic diversity mea- sions of Easterly and Levine (1997), but on their ethnic diver-
sure was weaker. This may have been due to the variables in- sity measure, which relies on ethnic distinctions rather than
cluded in a standard growth regression acting as transmission linguistic distinctions. As they controlled for variables that
channels for the indirect impact of ethnic diversity on eco- can be interpreted as channels through which ethnic diversity
nomic growth. 1 This point raises the question of whether affects growth (for example schooling, government consump-
highly diverse societies suffer indirectly from poor government tion, infrastructure quality, etc.), the magnitude of the ethnic
performance. Although Easterly and Levine (1997) addressed effect vanished and became statistically insignificant, suggest-
this important issue by means of ethnic diversity and govern- ing once again that ethnic diversity may affect economic per-
ment performance indicators, they also provided a regression formance indirectly through these channels. Besides the
of government performance indicators on the only explana- variable for market distortions, the authors found a statisti-
tory variable, ethnic diversity. They concluded that ethnic cally significant relationship of ethnic diversity with schooling,
diversity is indeed accompanied by low school attainment, political instability, financial depth, the fiscal surplus to GDP
financial depth, and infrastructure quality. Furthermore, they ratio, and infrastructure quality using the same econometric
showed that ethnic diversity also leads to higher market distor- specification as Easterly and Levine (1997). However, the lack
tions. of specified transmission channels leads to the conjecture that
A more comprehensive analysis of ethnic diversity and the the estimated effect of ethnic diversity in each of the loosely
quality of government was carried out by La Porta, Lopez- specified transmission channels suffers from omitted variables
de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1999). In their article, they bias. It is not clear precisely what the diversity measure cap-
investigated the influence of a broader set of possible determi- tures when the transmission channels are not well specified.
nants of the quality of good government performance. They Furthermore, the authors failed to explain the importance of
argued that good economic institutions, especially those in each of the transmission channels for real per capita income
the public sector, promote per capita GDP growth—for exam- growth.
ple, by limiting the private influence of the government and
establishing an uncorrupt bureaucracy and legal system that
protects property rights and enforces contracts. One of their
main conclusions is that ethnic diverse societies exhibit inferior
government performance. The findings in Collier (2001) also * I am grateful to Romain Wacziarg for sharing his data with me. Com-
suggest that ethnic diverse societies suffer from bad public sec- ments from three anonymous referees improved the manuscript substan-
tor performance, which in turn reduces economic perfor- tially. I would like, also, to thank Jürgen Bitzer, the seminar participants
mance. at the Carl von Ossietzky University Oldenburg 2011, the NIW workshop
An updated analysis of the findings in Easterly and Levine in Applied Economics in Hanover 2012 and the Tuborg Research Center
(1997) was performed by Alesina, Devleeschauwer, Easterly, 2013, Aarhus University, for useful comments and suggestions. Final
revision accepted: January 19, 2014.
275
276 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Another strand of literature investigates ethnic violence, role in the social and political institutions that influence eco-
especially civil wars, and its detrimental effects on economic nomic development. An analysis of the indirect economic ef-
performance. Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b) fects must, in a first step, formulate sound hypotheses
stressed the importance of political instability on economic explaining why ethnicity should affect economic growth
development when countries exhibit a high degree of potential through an explicit channel. For instance, it has been argued
ethnic conflict. The authors found that in ethnic diverse soci- that ethnic polarized societies may breed ethnic hatred, and
eties, the diffusion of ideas is impeded, especially when the dif- in the worst case, may end up in civil war. But civil wars hin-
ferent ethnic groups are in conflict. In such environments of der the economic development of countries. So far, the eco-
latent ethnic violence, business as usual is impossible because nomics literature on the indirect effects of ethnicity has
all levels of economic activity are affected. Empirical studies focused primarily on the channels of investment, government
of this problem by Collier (2001) and Garcia-Montalvo and consumption, and civil war. Further research is needed on
Reynal-Querol (2005b) reported no positive relationship be- the remaining channel variables in cross-country growth
tween ethnic diversity and the incidence of civil wars. Instead, regressions. For example, how do both ethnic measures affect
they found that high ethnic diversity makes societies safer be- economic growth through schooling, political instability, mar-
cause the coordination costs are higher and because no one ket distortions, foreign trade, and the fertility rate? All these
ethnic group is large enough to dominate the others. Garcia- variables are generally known to affect long-run economic
Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b) found that not ethnic growth and hence economic development of countries. This re-
diversity but rather polarization is one of the main factors search undertakes an elaborative attempt in trying to integrate
affecting the incidence of civil wars. Unfortunately, a measure the two so far separate literatures on ethnic polarization as a
of ethnic diversity is unable to capture ethnic polarization source of ethnic conflict and ethnic diversity as a factor for
across countries. As the authors stressed, there is less violence the macroeconomic performance of countries. Therefore, a
in highly homogeneous and highly diverse societies, and the closer examination of the involved transmission channels
incidence of civil wars is the highest in societies where the rul- seems necessary. The methodology chosen here is to specify
ing ethnic group dominates a non-negligible minority. Such all relevant channel variables that appear on the right-hand
cases require a measure of polarization, rather than diversity, side of the growth equation. In this paper, each channel vari-
that captures the latent danger of ethnic conflicts. 2 able affecting economic growth is specified on previous find-
Despite the fact that the ethnic composition of countries ings in the political and economics science literature. This
may have strong indirect effects on economic growth, the will serve to assess the direct and indirect effects of both ethnic
above articles deal primarily with its direct empirical quantifi- measures on economic growth for each of the channel vari-
cation. Campos and Kuzeyev (2007) confirmed that more re- ables. The empirical analysis suggests that ethnic diversity is
search is needed in order to identify the main transmission a strong predictive measure for the direct effect of ethnicity
channels through which ethnic diversity and polarization af- on economic growth, whereas ethnic polarization has strong
fects economic performance. 3 A first attempt to assess the predictive power for the indirect effects. Furthermore, test sta-
quantitative importance of possible transmission channels by tistics for the nonlinear combinations of estimators using the
which ethnic diversity and polarization indirectly affects delta method are provided. 4 Contrary to most economic
growth was made by Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol growth studies regarding ethnic diversity and polarization,
(2005a). They specified and estimated a comprehensive system an updated data set for the period 1960–99 is used. One pos-
of equations determining growth and possible transmission sible advantage of using an updated data set is that it allows
channels through which ethnic diversity and polarization to test whether the relationship between ethnicity and growth
may affect growth. They argued that ethnic polarization nega- can be confirmed. Furthermore, the updated data set delivers
tively affects growth because it reduces the rate of investment more observations for the extended econometric system and
and increases public consumption and the incidence of civil hence will improve the efficiency of the parameter estimates.
wars. By contrast, their results suggest that ethnic diversity The remaining part of the paper is organized as follows. Sec-
does not affect real per capita income growth indirectly tion 2 deals with the measurement of ethnic diversity and
through these channels but rather directly, for example, by polarization and highlights some important conceptual differ-
reducing the diffusion of ideas across the economy. These re- ences. Section 3 describes possible transmission channels
sults are in contrast to the estimates of Easterly and Levine through which both ethnic measures may indirectly influence
(1997) and Alesina et al. (2003), who find a negative associa- economic growth, and more importantly, discusses potential
tion between ethnic diversity on the one hand and fiscal stance reasons why these measures may be related to each of the
and political stability on the other. channel variables. Section 4 deals with the specification of
The starting point of this paper are the empirical findings of the relevant transmission channels from existing political
indirect effects of ethnic diversity and polarization on eco- and economics science studies. Furthermore, Section 4 also
nomic growth reported in Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Quer- provides a brief discussion of the underlying data sources
ol (2005a). Studies on the relationship between ethnicity and and highlights the econometric methodology in quantifying
economic growth have shown the importance of focusing on the economic effects of ethnicity on growth. The empirical re-
the effects of channel variables that are also important explan- sults are given in Section 5. Section 6 checks the robustness of
atory variables in reduced-form growth regressions. This issue the results and presents further insights into how ethnic diver-
deserves closer examination, both with regard to the ethnic sity and polarization are assumed to affect economic growth.
measures used and the specification of the relevant channels. Finally, Section 7 concludes.
Opening the black box on how both ethnic measures affects
economic growth can contribute a more thorough understand-
ing of its costs and allow its direct and indirect effects to be dis- 2. ON THE MEASUREMENT OF ETHNIC DIVERSITY
tinguished from its economic and political outcomes. The AND POLARIZATION
narrow focus on direct effects of ethnicity on social or political
outcomes neglects important indirect effects, as discussed The empirical literature pertaining to the determinants of
above. As will be shown, ethnicity directly plays an important socioeconomic outcomes generally relied on two different
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 277

ethnic measures. Because the underlying empirical analysis only one value for the constant ðK ¼ 4Þ restricts this measure
clearly distinguishes between ethnic diversity and polarization, between 0 and 1. Hence, the discrete polarization measure
this section describes both measures in some detail. As shown constructed by Reynal-Querol (2002) can be simplified to:
below, both measures are conceptually different and the choice G  2
X 0:5  pi
of the most appropriate index for empirical work depends on ETHPOL ¼ 1  pi : ð4Þ
the purpose of the study. i¼1
0:5
The index of ethnic diversity is a Herfindahl-based measure
of the following form: Ethnic polarization is maximized if there are two equally sized
groups. Furthermore, ethnic polarization decreases with the
X
G
number of equally sized groups.
ETHFRAC ¼ 1  p2i ; ð1Þ The following Figure 1 shows the relationship between eth-
i¼1
nic diversity and polarization for the 100 countries under
where pi is the proportion of group i and G is the number of study. According to the Figure, higher values for ethnic diver-
ethnic groups in the particular country. This index has a sim- sity up to 0.4 are associated with higher ethnic polarization. In
ple interpretation, it represents the probability that two ran- the intermediate part there is virtually no correlation between
domly selected people do not belong to the same ethnic ethnic diversity and polarization, whereas higher values of eth-
group. The main notion of this measure is to capture the de- nic diversity are accompanied with falling ethnic polarization.
gree of ethnic fragmentation in a society. Because this index Therefore, ethnic polarization is the lowest for highly homog-
is bounded between 0 and 1, higher values corresponds to enous and highly diverse countries.
more ethnic diversity. Furthermore, ethnic diversity increases From a theoretical and empirical standpoint it seems rea-
with the number of equally sized groups. sonable to distinguish these two ethnic concepts and its partic-
In contrast, the measure of ethnic polarization is primarily ular influence on economic growth. Therefore, this study
intended to capture the potential of latent social conflicts in undertakes an elaborate attempt quantifying potential direct
the society. The main idea behind this measure is, that social and indirect effects of ethnic diversity and polarization on eco-
conflict is the highest when the society consists of a finite num- nomic growth.
ber of highly distinguishable groups. The concept of polariza-
tion was firstly introduced by Esteban and Ray (1994) as the
sum of interpersonal antagonism, where the distinguishable 3. ETHNIC DIVERSITY AND GROWTH:
feature lies predominantly on income differences through the TRANSMISSION CHANNELS
different groups. Esteban and Ray’s (1994) general class of
polarization measures, ER, can be written as: The empirical analysis is based on the findings of Garcia-
Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a) regarding the indirect
X
G X
G
ERðy; KÞ ¼ K pi pj T ½Iðpi Þ; aðdðy i ; y j ÞÞ; ð2Þ effects of ethnic diversity and polarization on economic
i¼1 j¼1
growth through the channels of investment, government con-
sumption, and civil war. This kind of econometric methodol-
where y consists of a vector of intergroup differences and K is ogy is quite common in the economic and political science
an arbitrary constant. The term T ½Iðpi Þ; aðdðy i ; y j ÞÞ measures literature. For instance, Alesina and Perotti (1996) studied
the antagonism between group i and j. This antagonism de- the effects of income distribution on investment, choosing
pends positively on the degree of self-identification toward political instability as the channel that links these two vari-
the own group, Iðpi Þ, and the alienation felt toward the other ables. Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) analyzed the indirect ef-
groups, aðdðy i ; y j ÞÞ. The two authors narrow down the class of fects of democracy on economic growth through several
allowable functions by imposing three important axioms: 5 transmission channels in the framework of a simultaneous
X
G X
G equations model. Annett (2001) also used system estimates
ERða; D; KÞ ¼ K p1þa pj d ij ; ð3Þ to study whether ethnic diversity leads to higher political insta-
i
i¼1 j¼1
bility, in turn increasing government consumption to appease
conflicts between ethnic groups. The starting point of this
where d ij measures the cultural distance (alienation) between analysis is therefore the assumption that ethnic diversity and
group i and j. The antagonism between two particular groups polarization may influence economic growth through a num-
equals pai d ij . Because there is a proportion pj of group j the ber of possible transmission channels, which are generally in-
effective antagonism between group i and j is pai pj d ij . Given cluded in a standard growth equation. Despite the progress
the size of group i the total effective antagonism between made in Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a), several
group i and j equals pi1þa pj d ij . Therefore, Eqn. (3) refers to important questions remain unresolved. For instance, it has
the total effective antagonism between each pair of ethnic been argued that ethnic diversity may have a detrimental effect
groups within a country. The derived conditions under which on the level of schooling and hence economic growth (see be-
a polarization measure has to satisfy some crucial axioms, low), although no attempt has been made to include a fully
bound a between ð0; a , where a ’ 1:6. The constant factor specified channel for schooling testing this hypothesis. Fur-
K > 0 has no influence on the polarization order, but is used thermore, theoretical and empirical studies on the fertility rate
for population normalization. have predicted that countries with higher fertility rates will
A particular special situation is obtained if each group feel have lower per capita income growth. Hence, an open ques-
equally alien toward all groups other than their own. That tion is whether ethnic diversity and polarization is linked to
is, if d ij ¼ 0 for i ¼ j and d ij ¼ 1 for i – j. This measure of dis- economic growth through the fertility channel. The economic
crete polarization was firstly introduced by Reynal-Querol and political science literature provides explicit specifications
(2002) and has important impacts on the other parameters for each of the transmission channels. Therefore, in specifying
of the polarization measure in Eqn. (3). First, their is only each channel equation, it is possible to estimate a full econo-
one value for the polarization sensitivity ða ¼ 1Þ for which metric system to determine the direct and indirect effects of
the properties of a polarization measure are satisfied. Second, ethnic diversity and polarization on economic growth. All
278 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

1
TZA
UGA
IND LBR
KEN
CIV
MLIBEN
PHL
MOZGAB
CMR
SEN
.8 IDN COD
CAFSLE
ZMB
IRN CAN
TGO
GHA GMB
COGNER
SDN BOL
NPL MWIMYSCOL
PERTTO
ECU
BRA
Ethnic Diversity

PAK
.6

MEX USA
CHE FJI
ZWE VEN BEL
GTMKWT
JOR
NIC
BWA MUS MAR
ZAF
DOM LKA
ESP CHL
SGP
ARG
.4

IRQ
GBR
THAJAM CYP
PNG
MRT
AUS
DZA LUX
BDI ISR
URY
HND
EGY
CRI
RWA
.2

SYR
LSONZL
SWE
SWZTUR
PRY
FIN
FRA
SLV
AUT
NLD
HTI
GRC
TUN
ITA
IRL
BGD
SAU
DNK
NOR PAN
JPN
ISL
KOR
PRT
0

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Ethnic Polarization

Sub−Sahara Africa Latin America East Asia


OECD Other

Figure 1. Relationship between ethnic diversity and ethnic polarization.

channels used in the analysis are affected by ethnic diversity ments in productive sectors and thus inhibit economic growth.
and polarization from a theoretical and empirical point of As noted by Annett (2001), ethnic diverse countries may be
view. characterized by uncertain political environments, to which
In the following section, the transmission channels are dis- investment activities are sensitive. 7
cussed and explanations why these channels may be broadly
influenced by ethnicity. The selection of the transmission chan- (b) Civil war
nels relies heavily on economic or political indicators that have
a strong empirical relationship to long-run economic growth The potential causes of ethnic civil wars have been analyzed
and are widely used in cross-country growth regressions. extensively in Collier (2001), Reynal-Querol (2002) and
Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b). Civil wars are
(a) Investment accompanied by human capital destruction when the repres-
sion and killing of subversives who do not share their govern-
The allocation of talent in an economy is disturbed, when a ment’s ideology causes people to flee into exile. 8 If these
large proportion of people pursue high rent-seeking behavior. refugees are highly educated, the outflow of human capital will
Because of the lack in protecting property rights, especially in be severe and will hamper the country’s economic develop-
Sub-Saharan African countries, the most talented people are ment. Furthermore, the traumatic events of civil wars may
engaged in rent-seeking occupations (e.g., joining the army have lasting repercussions, requiring decades for social life
or becoming government officials). These activities generally to recover. Civil wars also lead to a destruction of physical
redistribute wealth from others without creating new wealth, capital and to lower investment ratios. The prevailing atmo-
leading to lower productivity and income growth. By reallo- sphere of uncertainty and risk may discourage investment in
cating people from entrepreneurial activities into rent-seeking both physical and human capital accumulation, factors that
activities, the accumulation of physical capital is hampered are crucial for economic development. As mentioned by Col-
due to lower technological progress and higher rent-seeking lier (2001), ethnic polarized societies may lead to dysfunctional
individuals. 6 Easterly and Levine (1997) have shown, that eth- politics—of which civil wars may be viewed as the extreme
nic diverse countries are more prone to rent-seeking behavior manifestation—if the different groups do not find cooperative
by different ethnic groups leading to difficulties agreeing on agreements. Therefore, societies divided along ethnic lines are
public goods such as infrastructure, education, and good gov- therefore more prone to ethnic violence, riots, and civil wars. 9
ernment policy. Furthermore, as emphasized by Garcia-Mont- However, the question remains why some countries have expe-
alvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a), when a society is divided rienced civil wars and others have not. Kanbur, Rajaram, and
along ethnic lines, tensions and other cleavages may emerge. Varshney (2011) argued that the potential consequences of
This in turn would lead some individuals to devote their re- ethnic cleavages are mediated by the kind of state, political,
sources (time, labor, capital, etc.) to achieving political influ- and civil institutions. Ethnically based politics in polarized
ence. These social costs, along with rent-seeking behavior, societies may lead to riots, which, in the worst case, may
imply a non-productive use of inputs and may reduce invest- end in ethnic civil wars. Political and economic factors in poor
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 279

and nondemocratic countries, can shape the identity of a par- government policies become less politically free, which may
ticular group and cause ethnic hatred. 10 end in politically unstable situations. Furthermore, as argued
by Annett (2001), when countries are strongly divided along
(c) Human capital ethnic lines, they are likely to experience situations of political
violence and are prone to frequent breakdowns of law and or-
The provision of public goods like education in ethnic di- der. Moreover, Easterly and Levine (1997) argued that the
verse countries are often not neutral but may be strategically politically unstable environment in ethnic diverse countries
designed to establish the state’s authority over a population. 11 provide evidence of strong rent-seeking behavior and the
However, the question arises whether these societies have low- inability to find cooperative agreements on the provision of
er schooling levels due to this non-neutral provision of educa- public goods.
tion. Easterly and Levine (1997) noted that public goods like
education may bring less satisfaction to everyone in a society (f) Market distortions
when the country is highly ethnically diverse because of dis-
agreements between ethnic groups on issues like the language La Porta et al. (1999) stressed that ethnic diverse societies
of instruction, the learning content, location, etc. This may are associated with less political freedom (e.g., less democracy)
lead the society to invest less in human capital. with the consequence that autocratic regimes may use their
An anthropological perspective on lower school perfor- power more arbitrarily. Moreover, as stressed by Easterly
mance in ethnic diverse societies is formulated in Ogbu’s cul- and Levine (1997), these societies may produce situations of
tural-ecological theory of minority school performance. 12 uncoordinated government ministries, each pursuing its own
The theory states that differences in school performance in eth- rent-seeking strategy without taking into account the effect
nic diverse societies may be caused by the treatment of minor- of its actions on others’ rents. For example, an overvalued offi-
ity groups, both in society at large and in the school system, as cial exchange rate and strict exchange rate controls benefit
well as by the minorities’ own perceptions and responses to those in power who resell foreign currency on the black mar-
school resulting from their treatment. Ogbu and Simons ket. Furthermore, an overvalued official exchange rate creates
(1998) argue that in the case of involuntary minorities, 13 their incentives to invest domestic capital abroad because of the fear
long experience of discrimination, racism, and conflict leads of devaluation.
them to distrust institutions of the ruling ethnic group.
Schools in particular are treated with suspicion because the (g) Trade openness
minorities believe that the public schools will not educate their
children as they do children from the ruling ethnic group. A series of studies by Alesina and Spolaore (1997), Alesina
Societal discrimination against minority groups (e.g., denigra- and Wacziarg (1998), and Alesina, Spolaore, and Wacziarg
tion of the minority culture and language, social and residen- (2000) emphasize the determinants of the number and size of
tial segregation, etc.) discourage them from investing in countries. Their argument is that country size emerges from
schooling because of the perceived lower rewards of employ- a trade-off between economies of scale in supplying public
ment and wages for educational accomplishments. goods in large countries and the costs of ethnic and cultural
diversity, which may increase with the size of countries.
(d) Government consumption According to their findings, in a world of free international
trade, the size of a country does not determine the size of
La Porta et al. (1999) have argued that the adverse effects of the market. Therefore, small and homogeneous countries
ethnic diversity on economic growth through government con- can benefit from free trade without sharing public policies over
sumption result from the fact that ethnic diversity captures to which they differ in opinion. 16 But, conditional on these deter-
some degree the predisposition of ethnic groups in power to minants, some ethnic diversity in a country may be beneficial
redistribute wealth. 14 Annett (2001) analyzed the relationship to international trade because of the existence of transnational
of ethnic diversity with political instability and government ethnic or cultural networks. 17 One reason may be that ethnic
consumption using a neoclassical growth model. The main diverse societies also have more diverse labor skills and are
hypothesis was that ethnic diversity inherently leads to higher therefore more engaged in open trade. A second reason would
levels of political instability and that this imposes a political be that ethnic diverse societies may also have diverse con-
cost on the government, which risks being overthrown and los- sumption preferences resulting in higher trade openness. Fur-
ing any rents from holding power. The government is forced to thermore, Parrotta, Pozzoli, Pytlikova, and Sala (2013) have
use government expenditures to appease the competing groups shown that firm-level ethnic diversity increases the probability
and mitigate the latent danger of ethnic conflicts in order to to export using a large sample of Danish firms.
reduce political instability and the resulting danger of being
overthrown. (h) Fertility

(e) Political instability Recent studies provide evidence that a large proportion of
variation in cross-country fertility and female labor force par-
Ethnic politics are more likely in societies divided along eth- ticipation can be explained by cultural norms and beliefs. 18
nic lines. 15 Alesina and La Ferrara (2005) emphasized that in Fernandez and Fogli (2009) showed that, even when control-
ethnic diverse countries, dictators use ethnic hatred to mobi- ling for various characteristics of women (age, education,
lize support for one group over others in repressing ethnic con- wealth, etc.), there remains a statistically significant effect of
flict. La Porta et al. (1999) argued that in ethnic diverse culture on women’s work and fertility choices. 19 Nevertheless,
societies, it is common for the groups that come to power to fertility rate choices in ethnic diverse societies may also bear
create government policies that expropriate (or kill) the ethnic an important political dimension. More recently, Janus
losers, restrict their freedom to organize opposition, and limit (2013) argued in favor of political causes in ethnic diverse soci-
the rights of ethnic groups outside the ruling group to con- eties in explaining cross-country net fertility rate differences.
sume public goods. Therefore, as ethnic diversity increases, Based on existing work, the author elaborate that in the
280 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

present of weak political institutions fertility may be a strategic premium (Market Distortions). Furthermore, the log of
choice for ethnic groups engaged in redistributive conflict. (1 + average schooling years in the total population over 25)
Indeed, competing ethnic groups may advocate higher fertility is used as a proxy for human capital accumulation (Human
rates in achieving higher voting power or increasing their com- Capital) instead of the percentage of secondary and primary
bat strength in situations of ethnic conflict. The empirical school enrollment. In addition, a full specification for the
analysis in Janus (2013) supports this theoretical view that eth- transmission channel Political Instability is included, which
nic diverse countries on average tend to have higher fertility is measured as the number of revolutions and coups per
rates, especially when political institutions are weak. year 24 and a transmission channel for the net fertility rate
(Fertility). The vector for the transmission channels therefore
consists of the following eight variables TC it ¼
0
4. DATA AND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY ðINV ; CW ; HC; GOV ; INS; DIST ; OPEN ; FERT Þit , where
INV ; CW ; HC; GOV ; INS; DIST ; OPEN ; and FERT refers
The data set used for the empirical study is an updated ver- to the transmission channels Investment, Civil War, Human
sion of the well-known Barro–Lee data set and consists of 100 Capital, Government Consumption, Political Instability, Market
countries with a total sum of 651 observations for the period Distortions, Trade Openness and the net Fertility rate. In every
1960–99. Because of the extended seemingly unrelated regres- equation, the initial value of the log of real GDP per capita is
sion (SUR) model, the updated data set will deliver more included to control how poor the countries are. Then a
observations and hence will improve the efficiency of the measure of ethnic diversity and polarization is included
parameter estimates. Table 7 gives a brief overview of the separately in each structural equation to assess the direct
countries included and their corresponding values for ethnic and indirect effects on growth. For completeness, the base
diversity and polarization taken from Garcia-Montalvo and specification used for each transmission channel with the
Reynal-Querol (2005b). Additional information regarding underlying source is given in the following: 25
the definitions and sources of the variables used are given in The transmission channel for Investment is similar to the
Table 14 in the Appendix. specification in Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol
The empirical analysis consists of the following Barro-type (2005a), where the variables for revolutions, coups, and polit-
growth equation 20: ical assassinations per year are replaced by a measure for
Political Instability introduced above:
GROWTH it ¼ aGR þ bGR GR
1 LNGDPC it þ b2 LNGDPCSQit
0 INV
þ TC0it cGR þ XGR GR
þ /GR GR INV it ¼ aINV þ bINV
1 LNGDPC it þ TCit c þ XINV
it h
INV
it h ETH ETH i þ uit ð5Þ
where GROWTH it ðGRÞ is the growth rate of real per capita þ /INV INV
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð6Þ
 0
GDP of country i from 1960 to 1999 averaged in five-year peri- INV INV INV INV INV INV INV
where c ¼ 0; cCW ; cHC ; cGOV ; cINS ; cDIST ; cOPEN ; 0 . No-
ods (t = 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–1999), LNGDPC is the
log of real GDP per capita at the beginning of every 5 year tice, that the form of cINV indicates that the investment channel
period and LNGDPCSQ is LNGDPC squared. 21 The vector does not incorporate the variable FERT as explanatory vari-
TC is a set of values for the transmission channels. These able. 26 To incorporate the potential effects of civil wars on
are, for example, the share of real investment 22 to GDP growth, the linear probability model in Garcia-Montalvo
(Investment), a measure for the political situation in countries and Reynal-Querol (2005a) for the incidence of civil wars is
proposed by the Barro–Lee data set (Instability), and the ratio used:
of real government consumption to real GDP (Government). 0 CW
CW it ¼ aCW þ bCW
1 LNGDPC it þ TCit c þ XCW
it h
CW
ETH refers to ethnic diversity and polarization, respectively,
and uGR is a country-specific error term. The parameter vector þ /CW CW
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð7Þ
cGR refers to the coefficients of the transmission channels in the   0
growth equation. For example, the parameter cGR INV measures where cCW ¼ 0; 0; cCW CW CW
HC ; 0; cINS ; 0; 0; cFERT .
the direct effect of the investment ratio on the growth rate of The transmission channel for Human Capital is specified as
real GDP per capita. The row vector XGR incorporates other follows:
control variables that do not belong to the transmission chan-
nels. These are, e.g., regional dummies for Sub-Sahara Africa, HC it ¼ aHC þ bHC 0 HC
þ XHC HC
1 LNGDPC it þ TCit c it h
East Asia, and Latin America countries, the number of polit-
ical assassinations per million population per year, the per- þ /HC HC
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð8Þ
centage of secondary and primary school enrollment, as well   0
as the absolute deviation of the PPP value for investment where cHC ¼ 0; 0; 0; cHC HC HC
GOV ; 0; 0; cOPEN ; cFERT . The trans-
goods relative to the United States (PPDEV). The latter is in- mission channel for Government Consumption is specified
tended to capture market distortions for capital goods to some according to Tavares and Wacziarg (2001), Annett (2001),
extent and therefore the consequences on growth. 23 and Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a):
Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a) add to this
basic growth regression the incidence of civil wars (Civil GOV it ¼ aGOV þ bGOV
1 LNGDPC it þ TC0it cGOV þ XGOV
it hGOV
War), ethnic diversity, and polarization. Note, that they only
þ /GOV GOV
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð9Þ
incorporate the variables for Civil War, Investment, and Gov-
ernment as fully specified transmission channels into their  0
where cGOV ¼ 0; cGOV GOV GOV GOV
CW ; 0; 0; cINS ; cDIST ; cOPEN ; 0 . The
SUR system. Based on their empirical findings two more empirical specification for Political Instability comes from
transmission channels proposed by Tavares and Wacziarg Tavares and Wacziarg (2001):
(2001) are included in the system. These are the share of im-
ports and exports to GDP (Trade Openness) to measure the ef- INS it ¼ aINS þ bINS 0 INS
þ XINS INS
1 LNGDPC it þ TCit c it h
fect of trade intensity on growth and a measure of
government-induced distortions captured by the black market þ /INS INS
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð10Þ
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 281
 0
where cINS ¼ 0; 0; 0; cINS
GOV ; 0; 0; 0; 0 . In addition, the specification error in each structural equation of the model
contribution in Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) also delivers an will be transmitted throughout the system. As mentioned by
empirical specification for the transmission channel Market Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a), the SUR
Distortions: estimator has the advantage that it is potentially less sensitive
to specification errors than the TSLS estimator.
DIST it ¼ aDIST þ bDIST
1 LNGDPC it þ TC0it cDIST
þ XDIST
it hDIST þ /DIST DIST
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð11Þ
  5. ETHNIC DIVERSITY, CHANNEL EFFECTS, AND
0
where cDIST ¼ 0; 0; cDIST DIST DIST DIST ECONOMIC GROWTH
HC ; cGOV ; cINS ; 0; cOPEN ; 0 . The
transmission equation for Trade Openness incorporates mainly
gravity variables, for example, country land area, landlocked Table 8 in the Appendix shows the system estimate of the
country dummy, island dummy, and oil exporter dummy. 27 base specification including the measure for ethnic diversity.
As can be seen, the estimated coefficients for each channel
OPEN it ¼ aOPEN þ bOPEN
1 LNGDPC it þ TC0it cOPEN have the expected signs. For example, a higher investment ra-
tio and schooling level is positively correlated with real per ca-
þ XOPEN
it hOPEN þ /OPEN OPEN
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð12Þ pita income growth, whereas higher government consumption,
  0 political instability, and the net fertility rate show a negative
where cOPEN ¼ 0; 0; cOPEN OPEN OPEN OPEN
HC ; cGOV ; cINS ; cDIST ; 0; 0 . Fi- association with economic growth. The coefficients on log ini-
nally, the specification for the transmission channel Fertility tial income and its squared value imply that the convergence
comes from Barro (1991) with important determinants such rate is the highest for countries with a per capita income level
as per capita income and schooling level: of about $324. Africa’s average initial per capita income aver-
aged from 1960 to 1999 is $2,002. Therefore, Sub-Saharan
FERT it ¼ aFERT þ bFERT
1 LNGDPC it þ TC0it cFERT African countries on average have already experienced the
maximum catch-up effect. Notice that the effect of Civil War
þ XFERT hFERT þ /FERT FERT
ETH ETH i þ uit ; ð13Þ
it is not statistically significant at the 10% level due to possible
 0 collinearity problems in the proxy for Political Instability. 30
where cFERT ¼ 0; 0; cFERT FERT FERT
HC ; cGOV ; cINS ; 0; 0; 0 . The empirical findings for the channel equations are in line
The econometric methodology used to highlight the trans- with existing results in the economics and political science lit-
mission effects of ethnic diversity and polarization on growth erature. For example, the results for the Investment channel
is based on panel data and SUR estimation procedures. The suggest that countries with higher log initial income and
model consists of the nine structural equations discussed schooling levels also will have higher investment ratios. On
above, that is, one cross-country growth equation and eight the other hand, factors like civil wars and market distortions
structural transmission equations, each describing one of the on capital goods are negatively associated with physical capi-
channel variables. Each of the M ¼ 9 relationships can be for- tal accumulation. Therefore, as stated above, countries with
mulated for each of T ¼ 8 time periods. The parameters of an uncertain economic environment also have on average low-
interest are the coefficients that describe the effect of a mar- er investment ratios and hence real per capita income growth.
ginal change in the ethnic diversity or polarization index, In addition, trade openness is accompanied with higher invest-
where ethnic diversity or polarization affects growth through ment rates. This may be due to the fact that countries inte-
the specified channel equations. To estimate the indirect effect grated into the world market, may also have better
of ethnic diversity or polarization through the transmission international financial institutions, hence fostering domestic
channels under consideration, the coefficient for ETHFRAC investments through higher inflow of foreign direct invest-
or ETHPOL in each transmission channel is multiplied by ments. 31 Proceeding in the same way for the Fertility channel,
the coefficient of each channel in the growth equation. The countries with higher schooling levels also have lower net fer-
standard deviation for this nonlinear combination of estima- tility rates and therefore, indirectly, higher real per capita in-
tors is then based on the delta method. The SUR estimator come growth. As predicted by cultural theories of fertility
used is different from ordinary least squares, particularly if rate differences, ethnically diverse countries seem to have on
each structural equation consists of a different set of exoge- average higher net fertility rates. One reason may be competi-
nous variables. 28 All equations are linked by their distur- tion among the various ethnic groups resulting in an increased
bances. This implies that for a particular country and time, net fertility rate in ethnic diverse countries. Furthermore, the
all structural equations regarding growth, investment, educa- results for the Openness channel are in line with the findings
tion, etc. are linked by their disturbances. The intuition behind in Alesina and Wacziarg (1998), where country size is very sig-
SUR estimation is that the disturbances in each structural nificantly related to the degree of trade openness. The negative
equation include factors that are common to all other struc- impact of the democracy dummy is in line with protectionist
tural variables in a particular country: that is, worldwide policies in democratic regimes. For example, groups that ben-
aggregate demand shocks, wars, the general health status of efit from restricting open trade tend to mediate their concerns
the economy 29, etc. are factors that affect every structural through political engagement, lobbying and public cam-
equation. Although the SUR estimator is superior to ordinary paigns. 32
least squares in efficiency, it neglects the possibility of simulta- Notice, that the R2 in some specifications is considerably
neous equations bias arising when some of the endogenous lower than in comparable empirical studies. One reason is that
variables appearing on the right-hand side of each structural the current study is based on a panel data set opposed to cross-
equation are correlated with the disturbance term. It therefore section data. Therefore, in addition to the cross-section varia-
seems reasonable to instrument the possible endogenous vari- tion there exists also a within country variation. Furthermore,
ables using adequate instrumental variables (IV) and to esti- because some of the dependent variables are measured either
mate the full system using Three Stage Least Squares as rates (e.g., the equations for Growth, Investment, and Gov-
(TSLS), which is an IV-GLS estimator. Despite the efficiency ernment Consumption) or levels (e.g., the equations for Human
and consistency gains that result from using TSLS, any Capital and the Fertility rate), it should be clear, that because
282 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

of the higher variation in growth rates the R2 in these specifi- Table 9 shows the empirical results including the measure
cations is considerably lower than in specifications where the for ethnic polarization in the base specification. The results
dependent variable is measured in levels. 33 are robust to the inclusion of ETHPOL, but the statistical sig-
The empirical results reveal that ethnic diversity has a neg- nificance of the transmission coefficients in the growth equa-
ative direct association with real per capita income growth. tion increases. Ethnic polarization has virtually no direct
This finding confirms the empirical results in Easterly and association with real per capita income growth. In contrast,
Levine (1997), Alesina et al. (2003), Garcia-Montalvo and there seem to be substantial indirect effects through the chan-
Reynal-Querol (2005a), among others. The results of the growth nels Investment, Civil War, Government Consumption, Political
equation state that, ceteris paribus, going from perfect ethnic Instability, Trade Openness, and the net Fertility rate. Inter-
homogeneity (an index of 0) to perfect ethnic diversity (an in- preting the channel equation Civil War, note first that the lin-
dex of 1), a fully diverse country (e.g., Tanzania) has a 1.96% ear probability model is somewhat inappropriate because it
lower real per capita income growth per year on average than does not restrict the probabilities between zero and one. Espe-
a fully homogeneous society (e.g., South Korea). The follow- cially the R2 cannot be interpreted in the usual form when the
ing Table 1 shows the indirect effects as well as the total effect dependent variable is binary and the explanatory variables are
going from full ethnic homogeneity to full ethnic diversity, for measured continuously (as is the case here). Apart from this
example, by redrawing the borders. The estimates suggest that shortcoming, a huge advantage of the linear probability model
a change in ethnic diversity from 0 to 1 is accompanied by a is its direct interpretation of the estimated coefficients. Taken
0.10%, but statistically insignificant, reduction in real per capi- literally, going from full to zero ethnic polarization decreases
ta income growth through the transmission channel Fertility the incidence of a civil war by about 15%. The remaining coef-
alone. The total indirect effect of ethnic diversity through the ficients are also of the expected signs: a higher population in-
transmission channels on growth is small (0.03%) compared creases the probability of a civil war because of the huge pool
to the total direct effect of 1.96%. The remaining transmis- available to rebel groups in such situations to recruit insur-
sion channels are not important for the indirect effects of eth- gents. Furthermore, a country with a high population is more
nic diversity on economic growth. In the case of the Investment difficult to govern and control than a small one. In addition,
channel, this does not mean that physical capital accumulation the coefficient on the democracy variable is positive and statis-
is not important for growth, but rather that this channel is not tical significant at the 1% level. This result is not surprising if
significantly affected by ethnic diversity. Alternatively, a one one takes into account that the dummy variable used for
standard deviation change of ETHFRAC (0.28), would bring democracy also incorporates democracies classified as inter-
about a 0.55% decrease in real per capita income growth per mediate, which seems to increase the risk of ethnic conflicts.
year. The estimated effect is statistically significant at the 1% For example, ethnically divided democracies in which ethnic
level and economically notable. The empirical results state parties that fail to reach a given threshold in general elections
that, all else equal, if Cameroon (0.82) had the same ethnic are likely to fall into violent ethnic conflicts outside of party
diversity as Botswana 34 (0.48) its real per capita income politics. 35 The following Table 2 shows the quantitative mag-
growth would be 0.68% higher. Taken literally, a 0.68% higher nitudes going from zero ethnic polarization (an index of 0) to
real per capita income growth would result in about 7% higher full ethnic polarization (an index of 1). The total effect of
real per capita income level after ten years. Nevertheless, the ETHPOL on growth is 1.38% and statistically significant
estimates suggest potential second-order indirect effects of eth- at the 1% level. The estimated magnitude is somewhat smaller
nic diversity on economic growth through the Human Capital to that of ETHFRAC, but there are qualitative differences.
channel. First, ethnic diverse countries on average have higher Ethnic polarization primarily affects growth indirectly through
net fertility rates. Second, the latter is negatively related with the channels Investment and Fertility. There is also weak evi-
education. Therefore, ethnic diversity, ceteris paribus, medi- dence that ETHPOL negatively affects growth through the
ates its negative impact on economic growth also through transmission channel Government Consumption. The total indi-
higher net fertility rates in the channel for Human Capital. rect effect of ETHPOL is about 0.59% and significant at the

Table 1. How ETHFRAC affects growth


Channel Effect of ETHFRAC on the Effect of the channel on growth Effect of ETHFRAC on
channel growth
Investment 1.6006 (1.1702) 0.0900*** (0.0144) 0.1440 (0.1078)
Civil war 0.0633 (0.0619) 0.3885 (0.3341) 0.0246 (0.0320)
Human capital 0.0499 (0.0468) 0.5848* (0.3405) 0.0292 (0.0322)
Government 1.6731 (1.4557) 0.0346*** (0.0131) 0.0579 (0.0549)
Instability 0.0097 (0.0620) 0.6004* (0.3164) 0.0058 (0.0374)
Distortions 0.0526 (0.0560) 1.9340*** (0.3378) 0.1018 (0.1098)
Openness 14.2083** (7.1136) 0.0032 (0.0026) 0.0459 (0.0435)
Fertility 0.3330** (0.1555) 0.3027** (0.1221) 0.1008 (0.0622)
Total indirect effect – – – 0.0288 (0.1922)
Total effect – – – 1.9883*** (0.5161)
N – – – 651
Notes: The second column shows the effect of ethnic diversity on the transmission channels. The third column corresponds to the channel effects on
growth. The fourth column presents the product of the two coefficients. Robust standard errors between parenthesis. Robust standard errors for the
products of the two coefficients in column four based on the delta method.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 283

Table 2. How ETHPOL affects growth


Channel Effect of ETHPOL on the Effect of the channel on Effect of ETHPOL on growth
channel growth
Investment 3.7221*** (1.2221) 0.0891*** (0.0146) 0.3317*** (0.1217)
Civil war 0.1492** (0.0586) 0.4566 (0.3391) 0.0681 (0.0573)
Human capital 0.0022 (0.0487) 0.6772** (0.3449) 0.0015 (0.0330)
Government 2.6297* (1.4979) 0.0355*** (0.0133) 0.0935 (0.0637)
Instability 0.0459 (0.0635) 0.6263* (0.3195) 0.0287 (0.0424)
Distortions 0.0444 (0.0575) 1.9260*** (0.3414) 0.0854 (0.1118)
Openness 15.7303** (6.7847) 0.0056** (0.0026) 0.0881 (0.0562)
Fertility 0.7684*** (0.1553) 0.3093** (0.1240) 0.2377** (0.1067)
Total indirect effect – – – 0.5877*** (0.2224)
Total effect – – – 1.3751*** (0.5223)
N – – – 651
Notes: The second column shows the effect of ethnic polarization on the transmission channels. The third column corresponds to the channel effects on
growth. The fourth column presents the product of the two coefficients. Robust standard errors between parenthesis. Robust standard errors for the
products of the two coefficients in column four based on the delta method.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.

1% level, whereas the direct effect of 0.79% is not statistically there seems to be no empirical evidence that ethnic diversity
significant. Alternatively, a one standard deviation increase of affects growth primarily through the specified transmission
ETHPOL (0.24) is accompanied by about 0.33% decrease of channels. The estimates suggest, that ethnic diverse countries
real per capita income growth per year. The estimates suggest are not prone to worse public good performance than
that, ceteris paribus, if South Africa (0.72) had the same ethnically homogeneous countries. Furthermore, the analysis
polarization index as South Korea (0.03), its real per capita suggests that ethnic polarization has non-negligible effects on
income growth per year would be about 1% higher. This the channels Investment, Civil War, Government Consumption,
growth difference is non-negligible and would result in a Openness and Fertility.
10% higher real per capita income level after 10 years. The
overall negative indirect impact of ETHPOL on real per capita
income growth is not due to the inclusion of the two channels 6. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS
Investment and Fertility. The following Table 3 restricts the
negative indirect effect of ETHPOL to the channels Civil The benchmark results regarding ethnic diversity and polar-
War, Human Capital, Government Consumption and Instabil- ization may be sensitive to time and region effects, to the elim-
ity. The estimates reveal that, although the individual indirect ination of per capita income, to the specification of the
effects through these channels seem to be statistically insignif- benchmark model and to the sample coverage. In this section,
icant, its total indirect effect of 0.19% is statistically signifi- the robustness of the results to several modifications of the
cant at the 10% level indicating that the primary results are benchmark model is examined. For ease of comparison, only
not driven by the inclusion of the channels Investment and Fer- the results in the growth equation and the coefficient for ETH-
tility. FRAC or ETHPOL in each channel equation as shown in
In summary, the comparison of both ethnic measures leads Tables 10 and 11 are reported. 36 The second column
to qualitatively different conclusions. Ethnic diversity primar- corresponds to the benchmark results shown above and is
ily affects economic growth directly, whereas ethnic polariza- given for comparison purposes. The third column shows the
tion has substantial indirect effects. Therefore, as also estimated effect of the ethnic variable, when the intercepts of
emphasized by Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005a), each structural equation are allowed to vary over time. The

Table 3. How ETHPOL affects growth


Channel Effect of ETHPOL on the Effect of the channel on growth Effect of ETHPOL on growth
channel
Civil war 0.1492** (0.0586) 0.4566 (0.3391) 0.0681 (0.0573)
Human capital 0.0022 (0.0487) 0.6772** (0.3449) 0.0015 (0.0330)
Government 2.6297* (1.4979) 0.0355*** (0.0133) 0.0935 (0.0637)
Instability 0.0459 (0.0635) 0.6263* (0.3195) 0.0287 (0.0424)
Total indirect effect – – – 0.1918* (0.0979)
N – – – 651
Notes: The second column shows the effect of ethnic polarization on the transmission channels. The third column corresponds to the channel effects on
growth. The fourth column presents the product of the two coefficients. Robust standard errors between parenthesis. Robust standard errors for the
products of the two coefficients in column four based on the delta method.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.
284 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

fourth column allows for regional dummies in each channel have non-negligible indirect effects in the remaining less heter-
equation, whereas column five allows for time and region ef- ogeneous countries through the channels Investment, Civil
fects in each equation. The direct effect of ETHFRAC is very War, Government Consumption, Openness, and Fertility. One
robust to these modifications. The magnitude of ETHFRAC implication of this analysis may be the different effects of
on real per capita income growth virtually remains unchanged. ETHFRAC conditional on the level of ethnic diversity in the
On the other hand, ETHPOL retains its insignificant direct ef- particular country. 38 Furthermore, the channel effects of
fect on real per capita income growth but shows a strong asso- ETHPOL remain important, also excluding Sub-Saharan
ciation with the channel variables. African countries.
The benchmark specification includes the log of per capita An important consideration is whether the results are driven
income in each channel equation. Since ethnic diversity and primarily by the inclusion of developed countries, for example,
initial per capita income are negatively correlated (0.51), it OECD members. Concentrating on less-developed countries is
may be hard to disentangle the indirect effects of ETHFRAC of great interest from the standpoint of policy because these
from the income effects. La Porta et al. (1999) argued that if are precisely the countries in which the economic effects of eth-
ethnic diversity undermines government performance, and nicity are most debated. Restricting the sample to non-OECD
poor government performance reduces per capita income, then members therefore leads to interesting results: Ethnic diversity
including per capita income together with variables of ethnic- in developing countries seems to have virtually no indirect ef-
ity in the same regression would reduce the estimated effect of fect on economic growth through the channels under consider-
ethnic diversity on the dependent variable. Therefore, for illus- ation. The indirect effect of ETHFRAC on the channels is not
trative purposes, initial per capita income is excluded from statistically significant, whereas the direct effect slightly in-
every channel equation. The above indications would lead creases. In addition, the results regarding ETHPOL state that
one to expect an overall rise in the statistical significance of polarized societies still suffer from a higher incidence of civil
ethnic diversity in each channel equation. But, the effect of wars, lower schooling levels, higher government consumption,
ETHFRAC through the specified channels does not change and higher market distortions. The results lead to the conclu-
substantially, indicating that concerns of collinearity are not sion that not ethnic diversity but rather ethnic polarization is a
justified. However, it remains interesting to test whether the strong predictive measure for the indirect effects of ethnicity in
exclusion of log initial income results in omitted variable bias. both developed and developing countries. This result is some-
If the results regarding ETHFRAC suffer from collinearity what puzzling and contradicts the findings in Easterly and
problems with initial income, then it will indeed be difficult Levine (1997) and Alesina et al. (2003) but is in line with the
to disentangle the income from the ethnic effect. Nevertheless, findings reported by Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol
the point estimates of ETHFRAC are still unbiased, also in the (2005a).
case of collinearity, but the standard error of the estimator Political instability is difficult to define and measure in a way
may be too large, which translates into less accurate hypothe- that can be used for econometric work. For example, Alesina
ses. Because of the lower negative correlation between ETH- and Perotti (1996) identifies factors of political instability that
FRAC and initial income, collinearity should not be a capture the idea of adverse effects on property rights and
serious problem causing the results excluding initial income abrupt changes in executive power. Because of these difficulties
to suffer from omitted variable bias. Consider, for example, in constructing an adequate measure of political instability,
the Investment channel: because of the negative correlation be- this measure is excluded from the benchmark model in order
tween ETHFRAC and initial income and the positive effect of to determine how the results change. The benchmark results
initial income on investment, excluding initial income from the are not affected by the exclusion of the Political Instability
Investment channel should result in a downward bias of ETH- channel for both specifications, aside from the fact that the
FRAC. Indeed, the estimate for ETHFRAC excluding initial channel effect for Civil War in the growth equation now be-
income decreases from 1.60 to 2.66. The remaining chan- comes statistically significant. This result may be due to the
nels can be interpreted in a similar way. Furthermore, if these politically unstable environment that generally accompanies
sensitivity results are mainly driven by collinearity problems civil wars, making it difficult to disentangle the effects when
between ETHFRAC and initial income, then one would expect both measures are included in the same regression.
an overall increase in the significance level of ETHFRAC in Another interesting point is to what extent greater or lesser
the Fertility channel, but this is not the case. Rather, excluding variations in the measures within regions drive the results. 39
initial income from the base specification leads to a statistically Table 6 in the Appendix shows the variation of both ethnic
insignificant effect of ETHFRAC on the Fertility channel. measures across regions. The lowest variation of ETHFRAC
Excluding initial income in the specification for ETHPOL re- is found in Latin American and OECD countries followed
sults in insignificant channel effects for Government Consump- by Sub-Saharan African and East Asian countries. Neverthe-
tion. But, as mentioned above, initial income is a strong less, Sub-Saharan African countries are among the highest
explanatory variable in each channel variable, and excluding diverse countries in the world, while OECD members seem
it would result in omitted variable bias. Indeed, the estimated to be among the least diverse countries in the world. Varia-
effect of ETHPOL in the Investment, Human Capital and Fer- tional differences across countries are more pronounced
tility channel changes substantially once initial income is focussing on the measures for ETHPOL. While Sub-Saharan
excluded. 37 African countries still have high values of ethnic polariza-
The analysis for each of the ethnic measures is also restricted tion, variational differences in ETHPOL are more prevalent
to geographic coverage by excluding Sub-Saharan African, among OECD member countries. Therefore, an interesting
Latin American, East-Asian, and OECD countries subse- robustness test would be to discover the effect of ethnic
quently to highlight whether the effect of ethnicity depends diversity and polarization on socioeconomic performance
on the regional pattern. Restricting the analysis to non-Sub- within regions. For example, since OECD members have
Saharan African countries, the overall magnitude of ETH- good installed political institutions it would be interesting
FRAC in the growth equation decreases substantially. Exclud- to detect whether the effect of ethnicity vary across regions.
ing countries from the benchmark model which are highly Such an analysis would be of great political interest in miti-
diverse reveals an interesting pattern: ETHFRAC seems to gating potential detrimental effects of ethnicity on the course
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 285

of economic development. Table 12 shows the results for the gate the detrimental effects of ethnic diversity through good
measure ETHFRAC. Restricting the sample on Sub-Saharan political institutions.
African countries results on a strong negative impact of eth-
nic diversity on real per capita income growth. The magni-
tude of ETHFRAC in this specification outpaces that in 7. CONCLUSIONS
the base model. Interestingly, ethnic diversity has a positive,
but statistically insignificant effect, on real per capita income This paper investigates the economic effects of ethnic diver-
growth in OECD countries. A possible explanation would be sity and polarization and explores the relative importance of
that the quality of installed political institutions and the ab- these two concepts through an extended SUR model. It con-
sence of ethnically based politics in highly developed OECD tributes to the existing literature in several ways. First, it
members make potential detrimental effects of ethnic diver- provides an updated analysis for 100 developed and develop-
sity on socioeconomic performance of minor interest. Ana- ing countries. Second, this paper deals with an extended
lyzing the effect of ETHFRAC on the transmission SUR model in which every transmission channel appearing
channels indicate substantial nonlinearities. For example, in the growth equation is specified on the grounds of existing
the negative impact of ETHFRAC on Government Consump- empirical work in the economic and political science litera-
tion is more pronounced in Sub-Saharan African than in ture. The SUR specification takes into account further equa-
OECD countries, while countries with intermediate values tions that seem to be important transmission channels for
of ethnic diversity (e.g., Latin America and East Asia coun- the effects of ethnicity on economic growth-namely, school-
tries) have higher government consumption shares. Further- ing, political instability, market distortions, trade openness,
more, while ethnic diversity seems to be unrelated with the and the fertility rate-but that have not been analyzed so
accumulation of physical capital in Sub-Saharan African far in the existing literature. Furthermore, the full system is
countries, it shows a negative effect in OECD countries indi- jointly estimated using the SUR estimator and presents de-
cating once again the impact of ethnic diversity conditional tailed evidence of direct and indirect effects of ethnicity on
on the level of ethnic diversity. 40 Table 13 shows the regio- economic growth with the corresponding significance levels.
nal results including the measure for ETHPOL. The direct The results suggest, for instance, that ethnic diversity pro-
impact of ethnic polarization on real per capita income duces positive indirect effects through international trade
growth retains its insignificant effect in all but one specifica- and leads to higher net fertility rates, which may be benefi-
tion. This result confirms the hypothesis that ethnic polariza- cial in advanced economies through higher international
tion do not affect real per capita income growth directly. trade integration and the possibility to rejuvenate the popu-
Interestingly, high ethnic polarization in Sub-Saharan Afri- lation. Third, this research undertakes an elaborative attempt
can countries is accompanied with higher investment rates, in trying to integrate the two so far separate literatures on
lower government consumption and fertility rates. This ethnic polarization as a source of ethnic conflict and ethnic
may be due to the fact that higher polarization measures diversity as a factor for the macroeconomic performance of
in these countries are inevitably associated with lower mea- countries. The distinction between ethnic diversity and polar-
sures of ethnic diversity, 41 which in turn improves the mac- ization seems to be empirically justified since it leads to qual-
roeconomic performance in these countries. Focusing on itatively opposite conclusions: ethnic diversity primarily
OECD countries, high ethnic polarization decreases physical affects economic growth directly, whereas ethnic polarization
capital investment and government consumption, while seems to have substantial indirect effects. The detailed anal-
increasing the fertility rate. ysis on direct and indirect effects of ethnicity on socioeco-
Overall, the sensitivity results underscore the general pattern nomic factors may support policy makers to undertake
of ethnic diversity showing a direct negative association with concrete political steps in mitigating the potential detrimental
economic growth, whereas ethnic polarization seems to have effects of ethnicity on economic growth. For example, as
strong indirect effects. Furthermore, differential impacts of shown in the sensitivity analysis, the impact of ethnicity on
ethnic diversity and polarization on economic growth and economic growth is substantially lower in OECD than in
the transmission channels across regions reveal possible non- Sub-Saharan African countries. This result shows the impor-
linearities. An interesting result is that the direct impact of eth- tance of political institutions in shaping ethnic identity and
nic diversity on economic growth is non-existent among highly hence its role for socioeconomic performance. Further re-
developed OECD countries indicating the possibility to miti- search should therefore investigate this issue in more detail.

NOTES

1. Nevertheless, Easterly and Levine (1997) used four additional 3. Campos and Kuzeyev (2007) analyzed for the first time the dynamic
measures of ethnic diversity to check whether their results depend on nature of ethnic, linguistic, and religious diversity on economic growth for
the particular choice of the ethnic measure. In contrast to the Soviet 26 former communist countries. The authors conclude, that exogenous
ethnic measure from Atlas Narodov Mira, three of the other four ethnic diversity seems to be unrelated with real per capita income growth,
measures showed a strong direct link to growth, even when controlling whereas their new (time-variant) ethnic diversity measure shows a
for the entire set of available explanatory variables, suggesting that statistically significant negative association with economic growth.
ethnic diversity may have a direct impact on growth, independent of
public policy decisions. 4. The delta method makes it possible to highlight the statistical
significance of the indirect effects of ethnic diversity and polarization
2. Easterly and Levine (1997) used a measure of ethnic diversity to through the proposed transmission channels on growth, providing the
investigate this issue, despite asserting the potential consequences of ethnic asymptotic distribution of the nonlinear combinations of the estimated
polarization on policies that affect economic growth. parameter values.
286 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

5. For a thorough discussion of these axioms the interested reader is 21. The inclusion of the square of log real GDP per capita in the growth
referred to Esteban and Ray (1994). equation incorporates the possibility that the rate of convergence depends
on the level of GDP per capita. A positive coefficient on LNGDPC and a
6. For a detailed discussion of the relationship of rent-seeking behavior, negative coefficient on LNGDPCSQ indicates that the convergence rate is
the allocation of talented people, and the implications for technological a concave function of real GDP per capita. Thus, initial real per capita
 GR 
b
progress and economic growth, see Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1991). I income that maximizes the catch-up effect lies around exp 2b1 GR .
2
thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point.

22. The investment share refers to the total economy investment share of
7. See, also the findings in Barro (1991), Alesina and Perotti (1996), and
real GDP.
Tavares and Wacziarg (2001).

23. See Barro (1991).


8. Collier (2001) argued that a large diaspora in Europe and America is
able to finance rebel groups in their home countries out of solidarity to
their people. Such outcomes can lead to long-term ethnic conflicts in the 24. This definition of political instability is adopted from the Barro–Lee
particular country, producing adverse effects on a wide range of social data set. In addition, the variable PPDEV in the growth equation is
activities. excluded because it appears to be statistically insignificant. The growth
equation therefore consists (besides the intercept, regional dummies, and
income variables) only of the variables for the transmission channels.
9. Vanhanen (1999) gave an overarching explanation of why so many
conflicts take place along ethnic lines: He argues that a society’s evolved
predisposition to ethnic nepotism will lead people to seek influence 25. I am grateful to two anonymous referees for their additional help in
allowing them to control the political situation for their own benefit. In specifying the transmissions channels.
this sense, the author noted that “the members of an ethnic group tend to
favor their group members over non-members because they are more 26. In contrast to the study in Mauro (1995), this specification dispenses
related to their group than to the remainder of the population.” Such a from the inclusion of a corruption index. The reason behind this decision
tendency toward ethnic nepotism eventually ends in ethnic struggle when is that corruption variables are only available for the 1980s onward, and in
the members of an ethnic group tend to support one another in situations most cases only as cross-section dimension. Nevertheless, using a
of conflict. composite index of the quality of government (taken from The Quality
of Government Dataset, version 6Apr11. University of Gothenburg: The
10. Collier (2001) argued that outbreaks of secessionist movements in Quality of Government Institute, http://www.qog.pol.gu.se), which is the
polarized societies increase when natural resources are discovered. mean value of the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) variables
Corruption, Law and Order and Bureaucracy Quality, does not change the
qualitative results. Overall, ETHPOL retains its significant indirect effect
11. Kanbur et al. (2011).
on economic growth, while ETHFRAC, in most cases, is still negatively
related with economic growth. The results are available in the online
12. See Ogbu and Simons (1998) for an overview. Appendix to this paper. Unfortunately, the number of observations due to
the inclusion of this single variable decreases substantially from 651 to
13. Involuntary minorities are people who have been conquered, 319. Because of serious data limitations, I have decided not to consider
colonized, or enslaved. Unlike immigrant groups, involuntary minorities corruption indices as an additional regressor.
are seen to be part of the ruling majority group against their will.
27. The specification for the Openness equation is an extended version to
14. The main idea is that higher government consumption is inevitably that in Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) with the exception that it dispenses
related with distorting tax policies and hence reduced per capita income with the variable measuring the distance from major trading partners. This
growth. variable is not available for many African countries and therefore would
lead to a reduction in sample size.
15. See, La Porta et al. (1999), Collier (2001), and Alesina and
Zhuravskaya (2011). 28. See Zellner (1962).

16. Alesina and La Ferrara (2005). 29. See Greene (2008, p. 252).

17. See Rauch (2001) for an overview. 30. The argument behind the inclusion of a political instability measure
separately from a civil war channel is, that political instability captures the
18. See Fernandez and Fogli (2006), who find that variation in fertility notion to observe major government changes that may be detrimental to
rates among US immigrants from different ethnic backgrounds can be property rights. Revolutions and coups d’etat may be seen as ways to
explained by the total fertility rate of the women’s country of origin as a change the political order which in turn creates an environment of political
proxy for culture. See also Fernandez (2007) for evidence on female labor uncertainty discouraging potential investment decisions. On the other
force participation. hand, civil wars capture the notion of social unrest that may be unrelated
to government changes. For example, the struggle of an ethnic group
19. The measures of ethnic diversity and polarization capture, to some gaining regional independence. Indeed, both, civil wars and political
extent, the degree of cultural diversity within a country. instability may be highly related. Section 6 will check the statistical
significance of the civil war channel by excluding Political Instability from
the base specification.
20. The growth equation is very similar to that of Barro (1991). This
specification is the widely used form for cross-country growth analysis.
Furthermore, it follows the argument of Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal- 31. I thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point.
Querol (2005a) in choosing the most common specifications for the growth
equation and for each of the transmission channels to avoid “variables 32. See, for example, Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) and the references
fishing.” therein.
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 287

33. I thank an anonymous referee for pointing out this issue. 38. Indeed, in a more theoretical study Cerqueti, Coppier, and Piga
(2012) have shown that the relationship between ethnic diversity,
34. Botswana is an African success story, with average growth rates in corruption, and economic growth may be nonlinear. They argue, that
per capita income of about 6.38% for the 1970–99 period and is, by corruption is high in homogenous or very diverse countries, but low in
African standards, ethnically homogeneous. In contrast, Cameroon intermediate diverse countries. The intuition behind their findings is that,
experienced a low growth rate of about 0.85% during the same period. despite its detrimental effect of ethnic diversity on growth, intermediate
diverse societies act as a balance check, limiting ethnically based
35. It remains an interesting question whether democratic institutions corruption. Their conclusion is that the effect of ethnic diversity on
lower the incidence of violent ethnic conflicts or help to institutionalize economic growth should be nonlinear, affecting growth in a hump-shaped
them in nonviolent form, in the sense that these conflicts take on political fashion. I thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point.
importance (see also Vanhanen (1999) and the references therein).
39. I thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point.
36. The compounding results regarding the indirect channel effects of
ethnic diversity and polarization on economic growth are available from 40. An alternative approach investigating potential nonlinearities of
the author upon request. ethnic diversity on economic growth and the transmission channels
would be to include ETHFRAC squared into each equation. In addition,
37. In general, the correlation matrix in Table 4 in the Appendix as noted by an anonymous referee, whether the impact of ethnicity
indicates that all variables analyzed are moderately correlated, especially if depends on the development status of the country could be addressed by
one focusses on both ethnic measures, indicating that multi-collinearity is the inclusion of an interaction term between ETHFRAC and the log of
not a serious problem in the empirical study. Additionally, multi- GDP per capita. However, addressing this point would open a complete
collinearity is not a problem for econometric inference as the coefficients new discussion on non-linearities and is therefore beyond the scope of
remain unbiased even if multi-collinearity is present. Finally, our ability to this paper.
estimate the coefficients with statistical significance indicates that the
variables contain enough variation for separating their influence. 41. See also Figure 1 above.

REFERENCES

Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. Doyle, M., & Sambanis, N. (2000). International peacebuilding: A
(2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155– theoretical and quantitative analysis. The American Political Science
194. Review, 94(4), 779–801.
Alesina, A., & La Ferrara, E. (2005). Ethnic diversity and economic Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (1997). Africa’s growth tragedy: Policies and
performance. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 762–800. ethnic divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4),
Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, 1203–1250.
and investment. European Economic Review, 40, 1203–1228. Easterly, W. (2001). The lost decades: Developing countries stagnation in
Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. spite of policy reform 1980–1998. World Bank.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1027–1056. Encyclopedia Britannica. (2000). Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica.
Alesina, A., Spolaore, E., & Wacziarg, R. (2000). Economic integration Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (1994). On the measurement of polarization.
and political disintegration. American Economic Review, 90(5), Econometrica, 62(4), 819–851.
1276–1296. Fernandez, R. (2007). Women, work and culture. Journal of the European
Alesina, A., & Wacziarg, R. (1998). Openness, country size and govern- Economic Association, 5(2–3), 305–332.
ment. Journal of Public Economics, 69(3), 305–321. Fernandez, R., & Fogli, A. (2006). Fertility: The role of culture and family
Alesina, A., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2011). Segregation and the quality of experience. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(2-3),
government in a cross section of countries. American Economic Review, 552–561.
101, 1872–1911. Fernandez, R., & Fogli, A. (2009). Culture: An empirical investigation of
Annett, A. (2001). Social fractionalization, political instability, and the beliefs, work, and fertility. American Economic Journal: Macroeco-
size of government. IMF Staff Papers, 48(3), 561–592. nomics, 1(1), 146–177.
Atlas Narodov Mira. (1964). Moscow: Miklukho-Maklai Ethnological Garcia-Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005a). Ethnic diversity and
Institute at the Department of Geodesy and Cartography of the State economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 76(3),
Geological Committee of the Soviet Union. 293–323.
Banks, A. S (2011). Cross-national time-series data archive. Jerusalem, Garcia-Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005b). Ethnic polarization,
Israel: Databanks International. potential conflict, and civil wars. American Economic Review, 95(3),
Barro, R. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. 796–816.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 407–443. Greene, W. (2008). Econometric analysis. New Jersey: Pearson Prentice
Barro, R., & Lee, J. (1993). International comparisons of educational Hall.
attainment. NBER working paper No. 4349. Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2006). Penn World Table Version
Barro, R., & Lee, J. (2010). A new data set of educational attainment in the 6.2. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and
world, 1950–2010. NBER working paper 15902 (accompanying data Prices, University of Pennsylvania.
are available at www.barrolee.com). Janus, T. (2013). The political economy of fertility. Public Choice, 155,
Campos, F. C., & Kuzeyev, V. S. (2007). On the dynamics of ethnic 493–505.
fractionalization. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 620–639. Kanbur, R., Rajaram, P. K., & Varshney, A. (2011). Ethnic diversity and
Central Intelligence Agency (1996). The CIA World Factbook. Washing- ethnic strife. An interdisciplinary perspective. World Development,
ton, DC. 39(2), 147–158.
Cerqueti, R., Coppier, R., & Piga, G. (2012). Corruption, growth and La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The
ethnic fractionalization: A theoretical model. Journal of Economics, quality of government. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organiza-
106(2), 153–181. tion, 15(1), 222–279.
Collier, P. (2001). Ethnic diversity – An economic analysis. Economic Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Econom-
Policy, 128–166. ics, 110(3), 681–712.
288 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1991). The allocation of Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, R. (2001). How democracy affects growth.
talent. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 503–530. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–1378.
Ogbu, J. U., & Simons, H. D. (1998). Voluntary and involuntary Vanhanen, T. (1999). Domestic ethnic conflict and ethnic nepotism: A
minorities: A cultural-ecological theory of school performance with .comparative analysis. Journal of Peace Research, 36(1), 55–73.
some implications for education. Anthropology & Education Quarterly, Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated
29(2), 155–188. regressions and tests for aggregation bias. Journal of the American
Parrotta, P., Pozzoli, D., Pytlikova, M., & Sala, D. (2013). Ethnic diversity Statistical Association, 57(298), 348–368
and firm’s exporting behavior. mimeo.
Rauch, J. E. (2001). Business and social networks in international trade.
Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1177–1203. APPENDIX A
Reynal-Querol, M. (2002). Ethnicity, political systems, and civil wars.
Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1), 29–54. See Tables 4–14.

Table 4. Correlation matrix for ETHFRAC, ETHPOL, growth and its determinantsa,b
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
(1) ETHFRAC 1.0000
(2) ETHPOL 0.5775 1.0000
(0.0000)
(3) Growth 0.2311 0.1343 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0006)
(4) Log initial income 0.4967 0.1424 0.0306 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0003) (0.4362)
(5) Investment 0.3050 0.1434 0.3283 0.4690 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0002) (0.0000) (0.0000)
(6) Civil war 0.1355 0.1219 0.1141 0.1686 0.1848 1.0000
(0.0005) (0.0018) (0.0036) (0.0000) (0.0000)
(7) Human capital 0.4237 0.1795 0.0872 0.7914 0.4595 0.1134 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0261) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0038)
(8) Government 0.0767 0.1302 0.0759 0.2096 0.0677 0.0504 0.1104 1.0000
(0.0503) (0.0009) (0.0530) (0.0000) (0.0843) (0.1987) (0.0048)
(9) Instability 0.1268 0.0937 0.1209 0.2314 0.1783 0.3761 0.1661 0.0790 1.0000
(0.0012) (0.0167) (0.0020) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0439)
(10) Distortions 0.1396 0.0333 0.2307 0.3145 0.2088 0.1725 0.2389 0.1303 0.1654 1.0000
(0.0004) (0.3960) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0009) (0.0000)
(11) Openness 0.0505 0.1322 0.0969 0.0995 0.1753 0.1248 0.0510 0.2116 0.0760 0.0361 1.0000
(0.1980) (0.0007) (0.0134) (0.0111) (0.0000) (0.0014) (0.1934) (0.0000) (0.0526) (0.3578)
(12) Fertility 0.4279 0.2751 0.1674 0.7378 0.4590 0.1337 0.7510 0.2177 0.1707 0. 2934 0.1346 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0006) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0006)
a
Number of observations: 651.
b
P-value of pairwise significance shown in parenthesis.

Table 5. Descriptive statistics for the main variablesa


Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
ETHFRACb 0.4630 0.2781 0.0100 0.9586
ETHPOLb 0.5246 0.2367 0.0199 0.9824
Growth 1.9079 3.1954 13.8274 15.5342
Log initial income 8.2983 1.0642 5.8054 11.0808
Investment 15.8787 9.1378 1.0249 91.9660
Civil war 0.1490 0.3564 0 1
Human capital 1.5507 0.5896 0.0764 2.5995
Government 20.3434 8.8690 5.6543 67.4266
Instability 0.1999 0.3743 0 2.800
Distortions 0.1778 0.3402 0.3013 2.6545
Openness 60.2787 46.7204 5.5812 559.1631
Fertility 4.0270 1.5366 1.1584 7.1145
a
Number of observations: 651.
b
Number of countries: 100.
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 289

Table 6. Descriptive statistics for ETHFRAC and ETHPOL by region


Region Na Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
ETHFRAC
Unrestricted sample 100 0.4630 0.2781 0.0100 0.9586
Sub-Sahara Africa 31 0.6755 0.2314 0.1777 0.9586
Latin America 21 0.4293 0.2108 0.0476 0.7084
East Asia 8 0.5050 0.2747 0.0139 0.8429
OECD 23 0.2348 0.2128 0.0100 0.7668
ETHPOL
Unrestricted sample 100 0.5246 0.2367 0.0199 0.9824
Sub-Sahara Africa 31 0.5465 0.1468 0.2710 0.8031
Latin America 21 0.6265 0.2080 0.2070 0.9547
East Asia 8 0.5827 0.2632 0.0278 0.9298
OECD 23 0.3568 0.2551 0.0199 0.8707
a
Number of countries.

Table 7. Measures for ETHFRAC and ETHPOL


Country ETHFRAC ETHPOL Sub-Sahara Africa Latin America East Asia OECD Frequency
Algeria 0.2986 0.5139 0 0 0 0 7
Argentina 0.4079 0.5788 0 1 0 0 8
Australia 0.3154 0.4918 0 0 0 1 8
Austria 0.1281 0.2398 0 0 0 1 8
Bangladesh 0.0684 0.1318 0 0 0 0 5
Belgium 0.5439 0.8707 0 0 0 1 8
Benin 0.8683 0.4364 1 0 0 0 5
Bolivia 0.7084 0.7666 0 1 0 0 8
Botswana 0.4845 0.6502 1 0 0 0 6
Brazil 0.6441 0.7732 0 1 0 0 8
Burundi 0.2859 0.5123 1 0 0 0 5
Cameroon 0.8166 0.5756 1 0 0 0 7
Canada 0.7668 0.6724 0 0 0 1 8
Central African Republic 0.7870 0.5778 1 0 0 0 6
Chile 0.4316 0.7226 0 1 0 0 8
Colombia 0.6747 0.7889 0 1 0 0 8
Congo, Dem. Rep. 0.7993 0.5859 1 0 0 0 5
Congo, Rep. 0.7214 0.6737 1 0 0 0 8
Costa Rica 0.2408 0.4204 0 1 0 0 8
Cote d’Ivoire 0.8743 0.4319 1 0 0 0 7
Cyprus 0.3565 0.6522 0 0 0 0 1
Denmark 0.0492 0.0967 0 0 0 1 8
Dominican Republic 0.4598 0.7254 0 1 0 0 7
Ecuador 0.6566 0.8372 0 1 0 0 8
Egypt, Arab Rep. 0.2468 0.4270 0 0 0 0 8
El Salvador 0.1453 0.2791 0 1 0 0 7
Fiji 0.5590 0.9298 0 0 1 0 1
Finland 0.1481 0.2941 0 0 0 1 8
France 0.1472 0.2944 0 0 0 1 8
Gabon 0.8338 0.5188 1 0 0 0 3
Gambia, The 0.7279 0.6893 1 0 0 0 5
Ghana 0.7310 0.6610 1 0 0 0 8
Greece 0.0988 0.1861 0 0 0 1 8
Guatemala 0.5201 0.9547 0 1 0 0 7
Haiti 0.1045 0.2070 0 1 0 0 6
Honduras 0.2541 0.4296 0 1 0 0 7
Iceland 0.0276 0.0552 0 0 0 1 1
India 0.9012 0.3482 0 0 0 0 8
Indonesia 0.7934 0.5288 0 0 1 0 6
Iran, Islamic Rep. 0.7563 0.5984 0 0 0 0 5
Iraq 0.3905 0.6649 0 0 0 0 4
Ireland 0.0723 0.1406 0 0 0 1 8
Israel 0.2856 0.5477 0 0 0 0 5
Italy 0.0798 0.1540 0 0 0 1 8
(continued on next page)
290 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 7 (continued)
Country ETHFRAC ETHPOL Sub-Sahara Africa Latin America East Asia OECD Frequency
Jamaica 0.3538 0.6002 0 1 0 0 7
Japan 0.0336 0.0672 0 0 0 1 8
Jordan 0.5152 0.9824 0 0 0 0 8
Kenya 0.8902 0.3813 1 0 0 0 7
Korea, Rep. 0.0139 0.0278 0 0 1 0 8
Kuwait 0.5130 0.9798 0 0 0 0 4
Lesotho 0.1850 0.3428 1 0 0 0 6
Liberia 0.8905 0.3904 1 0 0 0 4
Luxembourg 0.2978 0.5955 0 0 0 1 1
Malawi 0.6844 0.7359 1 0 0 0 7
Malaysia 0.6950 0.7616 0 0 1 0 8
Mali 0.8620 0.4199 1 0 0 0 6
Mauritania 0.3339 0.5361 1 0 0 0 5
Mauritius 0.4822 0.8031 1 0 0 0 5
Mexico 0.5765 0.6536 0 1 0 0 8
Morocco 0.4747 0.8974 0 0 0 0 8
Mozambique 0.8379 0.4986 1 0 0 0 3
Nepal 0.6822 0.6518 0 0 0 0 8
Netherlands 0.1133 0.2137 0 0 0 1 8
New Zealand 0.1959 0.3658 0 0 0 1 8
Nicaragua 0.4962 0.6809 0 1 0 0 6
Niger 0.7185 0.6977 1 0 0 0 6
Norway 0.0454 0.0902 0 0 0 1 8
Pakistan 0.6084 0.6976 0 0 0 0 6
Panama 0.0476 0.5862 0 1 0 0 7
Papua New Guinea 0.3537 0.6687 0 0 1 0 5
Paraguay 0.1739 0.3096 0 1 0 0 8
Peru 0.6581 0.8170 0 1 0 0 8
Philippines 0.8429 0.4965 0 0 1 0 8
Portugal 0.0100 0.0199 0 0 0 1 7
Rwanda 0.2213 0.4013 1 0 0 0 7
Saudi Arabia 0.0589 0.1139 0 0 0 0 3
Senegal 0.8093 0.5596 1 0 0 0 8
Sierra Leone 0.7927 0.6002 1 0 0 0 5
Singapore 0.4214 0.6663 0 0 1 0 1
South Africa 0.4693 0.7178 1 0 0 0 5
Spain 0.4359 0.6933 0 0 0 1 7
Sri Lanka 0.4519 0.7493 0 0 0 0 8
Sudan 0.7114 0.6994 1 0 0 0 4
Swaziland 0.1777 0.3184 1 0 0 0 5
Sweden 0.1891 0.3368 0 0 0 1 8
Switzerland 0.5604 0.7242 0 0 0 1 8
Syrian Arab Republic 0.2066 0.3726 0 0 0 0 7
Tanzania 0.9586 0.2710 1 0 0 0 7
Thailand 0.3608 0.5823 0 0 1 0 8
Togo 0.7325 0.6733 1 0 0 0 8
Trinidad and Tobago 0.6625 0.8417 0 1 0 0 5
Tunisia 0.0872 0.1673 0 0 0 0 7
Turkey 0.1851 0.3424 0 0 0 1 7
Uganda 0.9319 0.2786 1 0 0 0 6
United Kingdom 0.3730 0.5706 0 0 0 1 8
United States 0.5828 0.6913 0 0 0 1 8
Uruguay 0.2595 0.4264 0 1 0 0 8
Venezuela 0.5394 0.7579 0 1 0 0 8
Zambia 0.7874 0.6063 1 0 0 0 7
Zimbabwe 0.5338 0.6978 1 0 0 0 6
P
31 21 8 23 651
Table 8. System estimate of the base specification for ETHFRAC. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Growth Investment Civil war Human capital Government Instability Distortions Openness Fertility
***
Sub-Sahara Africa dummy 1.6451 (0.3841) 0.0144 (0.0512)
*** ***
Latin America dummy 0.8935 (0.3357) 0.1388 (0.0491)
**
East Asia dummy 0.2348 (0.4998) 0.1367 (0.0573)
** *** *** ** *** *** *** ***
Log initial income 4.0801 (1.9362) 2.2160 (0.4825) 0.0187 (0.0251) 0.2163 (0.0161) 0.9827 (0.4660) 0.0690 (0.0201) 0.0758 (0.0238) 8.4257 (3.0142) 0.1962 (0.0631)
***
Log initial income sq. 0.3529 (0.1159)
***
Investment 0.0900 (0.0144)
***
Civil war 0.3885 (0.3341) 2.9776 (0.8523) 0.3684 (1.0253)
* *** *** ***
Human capital 0.5848 (0.3405) 4.2662 (0.7875) 0.0207 (0.0409) 0.0251 (0.0421) 24.6579 (4.8150) 1.8389 (0.1321)

HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH


*** *** *** *** *** ***
Government 0.0346 (0.0131) 0.0278 (0.0337) 0.0074 (0.0013) 0.0044 (0.0016) 0.0060 (0.0015) 1.3563 (0.1785) 0.0209 (0.0043)
* *** ** ** *
Instability 0.6004 (0.3164) 1.3453 (0.8184) 0.3190 (0.0347) 2.3381 (0.9778) 0.0807 (0.0348) 7.1033 (4.2638) 0.0499 (0.0948)
*** *** ***
Distortions 1.9340 (0.3378) 0.5836 (0.8924) 4.1974 (1.0369) 22.2740 (4.8464)
*** * *** ***
Openness 0.0032 (0.0026) 0.0261 (0.0061) 0.0004 (0.0002) 0.0632 (0.0080) 0.0014 (0.0003)
** * ***
Fertility 0.3027 (0.1221) 0.0288 (0.0151) 0.2033 (0.0115)
***
PISH 5.6945 (0.5786)
***
PPDEV 5.7577 (0.6214) 0.0167 (0.0231)
*** *** ***
Log population 0.0776 (0.0146) 0.1698 (0.2814) 0.0380 (0.0114) 10.6929 (1.4779)
*** *** **
Democracy dummy 0.0875 (0.0328) 0.1221 (0.0259) 0.9572 (0.7883) 0.0388 (0.0344) 0.0484 (0.0323) 9.6361 (3.9888)
Island dummy 0.0720v (0.0419) 0.0499 (0.0419) 0.4868 (4.6837)
**
Landlocked dummy 0.0030 (0.0398) 0.0365 (0.0426) 11.4466 (4.5121)
Mountains 0.0001 (0.0007)
*** ***
Log area 0.0472 (0.0116) 4.8357 (1.2970)
*** *** ***
Ever a colony dummy 0.2290 (0.0541) 0.1819 (0.0304) 0.0475 (0.9955) 0.1452 (0.0431) 0.0351 (0.0385)
*** ***
Postwar dummy 0.0761 (0.0507) 1.1301 (0.9151) 0.1184 (0.0383) 0.0403 (0.0384) 15.8119 (4.1828)
***
Oil producer dummy 33.7947 (7.0458)
Muslim dummy 0.0659 (0.0438) 0.0312 (0.0533)
***
Confucian dummy 0.4644 (0.0599) 0.0686 (0.0776)
***
Catholic dummy 0.2580 (0.0404) 0.0074 (0.0529)
***
Other Christian dummy 0.3538 (0.0432) 0.0335 (0.0556)
Mortality rate 0.3798 (0.9896)
* *** *** *** *** ***
Constant 5.7808 (8.0101) 6.9886 (3.7019) 0.7747 (0.2832) 0.0568 (0.1706) 21.5742 (5.1200) 0.2898 (0.2348) 0.7128 (0.1949) 185.8909 (26.6580) 7.9482 (0.6143)
*** ** **
ETHFRAC 1.9595 (0.4783) 1.6006 (1.1702) 0.0633 (0.0619) 0.0499 (0.0468) 1.6731 (1.4557) 0.0097 (0.0620) 0.0526 (0.0560) 14.2083 (7.1136) 0.3330 (0.1555)
N 651 651 651 651 651 651 651 651 651
Adjusted R2 0.28 0.38 0.23 0.77 0.07 0.09 0.12 0.28 0.61

Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1,000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.

291
292
Table 9. System estimate of the base specification for ETHPOL. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Growth Investment Civil war Human capital Government Instability Distortions Openness Fertility
***
Sub-Sahara Africa dummy 2.1404 (0.3693) 0.0035 (0.0474)
*** ***
Latin America dummy 1.0121 (0.3462) 0.1589 (0.0488)
**
East Asia dummy 0.1108 (0.4972) 0.1439 (0.0569)
*** *** *** ** *** *** *** ***
Log initial income 5.3889 (1.9292) 2.5847 (0.4596) 0.0084 (0.0253) 0.2148 (0.0156) 0.9012 (0.4498) 0.0704 (0.0197) 0.0702 (0.0236) 10.0608 (2.9415) 0.2516 (0.0607)
***
Log initial income sq. 0.4277 (0.1156)
***
Investment 0.0891 (0.0146)
***
Civil war 0.4566 (0.3391) 2.7133 (0.8511) 0.3335 (1.0270)
** *** *** ***
Human capital 0.6772 (0.3449) 3.8359 (0.7884) 0.0145 (0.0408) 0.0225 (0.0424) 26.1492 (4.8260) 1.7166 (0.1298)
*** *** ** *** *** ***
Government 0.0355 (0.0133) 0.0463 (0.0335) 0.0072 (0.0013) 0.0042 (0.0016) 0.0063 (0.0015) 1.2566 (0.1784) 0.0169 (0.0043)
* *** ** ** *
Instability 0.6263 (0.3195) 1.1729 (0.8135) 0.3179 (0.0346) 2.2051 (0.9759) 0.0800 (0.0348) 7.8527 (4.2622) 0.0010 (0.0934)
*** *** ***
Distortions 1.9260 (0.3414) 0.5601 (0.8882) 4.4304 (1.0334) 22.1197 (4.8144)
** *** ** *** ***
Openness 0.0056 (0.0026) 0.0287 (0.0061) 0.0005 (0.0002) 0.0601 (0.0080) 0.0014 (0.0003)
** * ***
Fertility 0.3093 (0.1240) 0.0268 (0.0151) 0.2001 (0.0116)
***
PISH 5.9260 (0.5772)
***
PPDEV 5.9807 (0.6189) 0.0203 (0.0227)
*** *** ***
Log population 0.0808 (0.0145) 0.0705 (0.2732) 0.0374 (0.0110) 10.3541 (1.4910)
*** *** **
Democracy dummy 0.0844 (0.0327) 0.1271 (0.0260) 0.9663 (0.7867) 0.0388 (0.0344) 0.0461 (0.0324) 9.7972 (3.9793)

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
*
Island dummy 0.0735 (0.0415) 0.0508 (0.0417) 0.0717 (4.6891)
***
Landlocked dummy 0.0061 (0.0396) 0.0324 (0.0427) 11.7203 (4.5097)
Mountains 0.0004 (0.0007)
*** ***
Log area 0.0477 (0.0113) 4.3982 (1.2385)
*** *** ***
Ever a colony dummy 0.2174 (0.0539) 0.1969 (0.0308) 0.9657 (1.0228) 0.1283 (0.0445) 0.0431 (0.0399)
* *** ***
Postwar dummy 0.0921 (0.0503) 1.1025 (0.9016) 0.1172 (0.0376) 0.0295 (0.0377) 17.9236 (4.0139)
***
Oil producer dummy 34.2923 (7.0255)
Muslim dummy 0.0616 (0.0428) 0.0469 (0.0520)
***
Confucian dummy 0.4554 (0.0577) 0.0468 (0.0749)
***
Catholic dummy 0.2574 (0.0395) 0.0001 (0.0524)
***
Other Christian dummy 0.3522 (0.0425) 0.0420 (0.0548)
Mortality rate 0.0526 (0.9525)
*** *** *** *** *** ***
Constant 11.9158 (7.9436) 8.6698 (3.2751) 0.7433 (0.2819) 0.0432 (0.1593) 20.6263 (5.0533) 0.2959 (0.2328) 0.6492 (0.1834) 191.2786 (26.0828) 8.0162 (0.5931)
*** ** * ** ***
ETHPOL 0.7874 (0.5023) 3.7221 (1.2221) 0.1492 (0.0586) 0.0022 (0.0487) 2.6297 (1.4979) 0.0459 (0.0635) 0.0444 (0.0575) 15.7303 (6.7847) 0.7684 (0.1553)
N 651 651 651 651 651 651 651 651 651
Adjusted R2 0.27 0.39 0.23 0.77 0.08 0.09 0.12 0.28 0.63

Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital, and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1,000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.
Table 10. Sensitivity analysis for ETHFRAC. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Variables Base model Time effects Region effects Region/Times effects excl. initial income excl. Sub-S. Africa excl. Latin America excl. East Asia excl. OECD No Instability equ.
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Sub-Sahara Africa dummy 1.6451 (0.3841) 1.0413 (0.3769) 1.6217 (0.3851) 0.9988 (0.3776) 1.6074 (0.3840) – – 1.6967 (0.4119) 1.6392 (0.3973) 1.2976 (0.4446) 1.6671 (0.3853)
*** ** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Latin America dummy 0.8935 (0.3357) 0.8016 (0.3203) 0.9333 (0.3363) 0.8612 (0.3206) 0.8747 (0.3356) 1.1846 (0.2991) – – 0.9123 (0.3446) 0.3347 (0.4496) 0.9920 (0.3335)
East Asia dummy 0.2348 (0.4998) 0.4781 (0.4780) 0.2337 (0.5010) 0.5276 (0.4789) 0.2836 (0.4995) 0.0014 (0.4213) 0.1758 (0.5330) – – 0.7869 (0.6025) 0.1471 (0.4999)
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Investment 0.0900 (0.0144) 0.0610 (0.0147) 0.0902 (0.0144) 0.0608 (0.0147) 0.0909 (0.0144) 0.0915 (0.0171) 0.0748 (0.0165) 0.0899 (0.0153) 0.0821 (0.0174) 0.0906 (0.0145)

HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH


*
Civil war 0.3885 (0.3341) 0.0167 (0.3238) 0.3931 (0.3340) 0.0002 (0.3235) 0.3898 (0.3340) 0.3896 (0.3170) 0.2257 (0.4146) 0.3187 (0.3590) 0.0791 (0.3811) 0.5986 (0.3177)
* ** * *** ** ** *
Human capital 0.5848 (0.3405) 0.8606 (0.3411) 0.6075 (0.3405) 0.8991 (0.3411) 0.4185 (0.3403) 0.3685 (0.3651) 0.8587 (0.3791) 0.7154 (0.3612) 0.3451 (0.4087) 0.6150 (0.3415)
*** * *** ** *** *** ** *** * ***
Government 0.0346 (0.0131) 0.0230 (0.0126) 0.0359 (0.0131) 0.0248 (0.0126) 0.0339 (0.0131) 0.0395 (0.0138) 0.0368 (0.0147) 0.0365 (0.0135) 0.0267 (0.0152) 0.0361 (0.0131)
* ** ** ** * * ** * *
Instability 0.6004 (0.3164) 0.6410 (0.3053) 0.6247 (0.3163) 0.6546 (0.3053) 0.5778 (0.3164) 0.5277 (0.2859) 0.9145 (0.4564) 0.5592 (0.3389) 0.6736 (0.3694) – –
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Distortions 1.9340 (0.3378) 1.5086 (0.3295) 1.9311 (0.3377) 1.4883 (0.3294) 1.8913 (0.3376) 2.7156 (0.3814) 1.8508 (0.3803) 1.9484 (0.3431) 1.8061 (0.3779) 1.9803 (0.3382)
** * ***
Openness 0.0032 (0.0026) 0.0053 (0.0026) 0.0030 (0.0026) 0.0047 (0.0026) 0.0033 (0.0026) 0.0026 (0.0029) 0.0077 (0.0030) 0.0036 (0.0028) 0.0051 (0.0032) 0.0035 (0.0026)
** *** ** *** ** *** *** ** * **
Fertility 0.3027 (0.1221) 0.5058 (0.1208) 0.2942 (0.1221) 0.4874 (0.1207) 0.2922 (0.1220) 0.3091 (0.1179) 0.3936 (0.1446) 0.3040 (0.1290) 0.2488 (0.1495) 0.2883 (0.1223)
*** *** *** *** *** ** *** *** *** ***
ETHFRAC 1.9595 (0.4783) 1.8243 (0.4565) 1.9720 (0.4784) 1.8511 (0.4566) 1.8800 (0.4782) 1.0813 (0.4511) 2.3388 (0.5614) 1.8331 (0.5162) 2.3469 (0.6139) 1.9502 (0.4798)
**
Constant 5.7808 (8.0101) 6.5114 (7.6566) 5.8293 (8.0068) 6.6707 (7.6499) 6.7928 (8.0053) 20.2771 (10.1634) 5.4242 (8.4201) 6.6655 (8.2425) 6.7328 (10.2342) 6.1203 (8.0338)
N 651 651 651 651 651 469 496 606 484 651
Adjusted R2 0.282 0.350 0.281 0.349 0.283 0.361 0.311 0.258 0.257 0.277
Effect of ETHFRAC on the channel
** ** ***
Investment 1.6006 (1.1702) 0.7504 (1.1288) 0.7136 (1.2086) 0.3119 (1.1577) 2.6607 (1.1521) 2.6763 (1.1761) 4.0076 (1.3677) 0.5098 (1.2248) 1.3991 (1.3888) 1.5969 (1.1715)
***
Civil war 0.0633 (0.0619) 0.0709 (0.0609) 0.0671 (0.0620) 0.0707 (0.0609) 0.0602 (0.0620) 0.2188 (0.0775) 0.0486 (0.0647) 0.0037 (0.0625) 0.0357 (0.0859) 0.0594 (0.0658)
Human capital 0.0499 (0.0468) 0.0177 (0.0444) 0.0411 (0.0492) 0.0315 (0.0459) 0.0566 (0.0530) 0.0803 (0.0501) 0.0888 (0.0567) 0.0242 (0.0468) 0.0110 (0.0605) 0.0498 (0.0468)
*** **
Government 1.6731 (1.4557) 1.7886 (1.4482) 0.9377 (1.5438) 1.0232 (1.5350) 1.0888 (1.4135) 4.2267 (1.6316) 3.4379 (1.7302) 1.8057 (1.5647) 0.7095 (1.8758) 1.6912 (1.4573)
Instability 0.0097 (0.0620) 0.0093 (0.0613) 0.0318 (0.0666) 0.0214 (0.0660) 0.0298 (0.0611) 0.0938 (0.0845) 0.0610 (0.0582) 0.0150 (0.0641) 0.0010 (0.0775) – –
*
Distortions 0.0526 (0.0560) 0.0537 (0.0551) 0.0073 (0.0578) 0.0022 (0.0565) 0.0314 (0.0556) 0.0803 (0.0559) 0.0534 (0.0674) 0.0298 (0.0604) 0.1391 (0.0749) 0.0501 (0.0562)
** * ** ** *** ** *** *
Openness 14.2083 (7.1136) 13.8239 (7.0645) 16.2104 (7.5952) 17.1135 (7.4741) 18.6619 (6.9759) 15.1814 (7.0159) 24.9147 (8.2565) 5.2816 (7.1754) 6.9405 (9.1774) 13.8824 (7.1247)
** *** ** *** **
Fertility 0.3330 (0.1555) 0.4420 (0.1547) 0.0946 (0.1565) 0.1833 (0.1538) 0.1681 (0.1545) 0.3565 (0.1808) 0.5629 (0.1729) 0.2417 (0.1648) 0.0617 (0.1783) 0.3346 (0.1555)

Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital, and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1,000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.

293
294
Table 11. Sensitivity analysis for ETHPOL. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Variables Base model Time effects Region effects Region/Times effects excl. initial income excl. Sub-S. Africa excl. Latin America excl. East Asia excl. OECD No Instability equ.
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Sub-Sahara Africa dummy 2.1404 (0.3693) 1.5139 (0.3642) 2.1176 (0.3703) 1.4554 (0.3648) 2.0865 (0.3689) – – 2.2094 (0.4010) 2.1240 (0.3769) 1.8563 (0.4273) 2.1586 (0.3704)
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Latin America dummy 1.0121 (0.3462) 0.9325 (0.3303) 1.0413 (0.3467) 0.9799 (0.3307) 0.9797 (0.3459) 1.2280 (0.3056) – – 1.0480 (0.3533) 0.4339 (0.4589) 1.1114 (0.3438)
East Asia dummy 0.1108 (0.4972) 0.1443 (0.4758) 0.1400 (0.4986) 0.1694 (0.4766) 0.0636 (0.4966) 0.1811 (0.4135) 0.1929 (0.5324) – – 0.4492 (0.6066) 0.1944 (0.4972)
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Investment 0.0891 (0.0146) 0.0590 (0.0149) 0.0898 (0.0146) 0.0593 (0.0149) 0.0908 (0.0146) 0.0883 (0.0172) 0.0789 (0.0167) 0.0872 (0.0154) 0.0790 (0.0177) 0.0897 (0.0146)
**
Civil war 0.4566 (0.3391) 0.0441 (0.3287) 0.4546 (0.3391) 0.0568 (0.3286) 0.4460 (0.3387) 0.4201 (0.3186) 0.3445 (0.4217) 0.3709 (0.3640) 0.1755 (0.3876) 0.6702 (0.3225)
** *** ** *** ** ** **
Human capital 0.6772 (0.3449) 0.9869 (0.3457) 0.6837 (0.3449) 1.0147 (0.3457) 0.4648 (0.3446) 0.3944 (0.3675) 0.9651 (0.3854) 0.7934 (0.3642) 0.5170 (0.4149) 0.7068 (0.3458)
*** * *** ** *** *** ** *** * ***
Government 0.0355 (0.0133) 0.0248 (0.0128) 0.0362 (0.0133) 0.0255 (0.0128) 0.0345 (0.0133) 0.0406 (0.0140) 0.0345 (0.0150) 0.0390 (0.0136) 0.0292 (0.0156) 0.0372 (0.0133)
* ** ** ** * ** * *
Instability 0.6263 (0.3195) 0.6559 (0.3083) 0.6467 (0.3195) 0.6641 (0.3083) 0.6013 (0.3196) 0.5690 (0.2866) 0.8832 (0.4624) 0.5519 (0.3417) 0.6901 (0.3741) – –
*** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Distortions 1.9260 (0.3414) 1.4999 (0.3329) 1.9173 (0.3414) 1.4704 (0.3329) 1.8786 (0.3409) 2.7254 (0.3832) 1.8227 (0.3857) 1.9393 (0.3462) 1.7729 (0.3840) 1.9699 (0.3417)
** *** ** *** ** *** ** ** **
Openness 0.0056 (0.0026) 0.0078 (0.0026) 0.0056 (0.0026) 0.0073 (0.0026) 0.0057 (0.0026) 0.0008 (0.0029) 0.0095 (0.0031) 0.0064 (0.0028) 0.0077 (0.0032) 0.0059 (0.0026)
** *** ** *** ** ** *** ** **
Fertility 0.3093 (0.1240) 0.5259 (0.1228) 0.3031 (0.1240) 0.5068 (0.1227) 0.2989 (0.1239) 0.3058 (0.1190) 0.4018 (0.1475) 0.3090 (0.1309) 0.2260 (0.1516) 0.2952 (0.1242)
ETHPOL 0.7874 (0.5023) 0.6671 (0.4793) 0.7736 (0.5024) 0.6418 (0.4794) 0.8178 (0.5022) 0.6342 (0.4392) 0.9595 (0.5935) 0.6982 (0.5222) 0.7319 (0.7111) 0.7793 (0.5038)
* **
Constant 11.9158 (7.9436) 12.1125 (7.5985) 12.0505 (7.9435) 12.5433 (7.5962) 12.9900 (7.9329) 24.0008 (10.0128) 12.4719 (8.3423) 12.9501 (8.1133) 12.9312 (10.2401) 12.2317 (7.9659)

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
N 651 651 651 651 651 469 496 606 484 651
Adjusted R2 0.267 0.337 0.267 0.337 0.268 0.357 0.291 0.246 0.237 0.262
Effect of ETHPOL on the channel
*** *** ** *** *** ** ***
Investment 3.7221 (1.2221) 3.2876 (1.1729) 1.1220 (1.2649) 0.7465 (1.2121) 2.9174 (1.2662) 3.8437 (1.0798) 4.6124 (1.4832) 2.9332 (1.2565) 1.3983 (1.6705) 3.7800 (1.2225)
** *** ** ** *** *** ** ** **
Civil war 0.1492 (0.0586) 0.1551 (0.0577) 0.1406 (0.0587) 0.1453 (0.0577) 0.1500 (0.0578) 0.1878 (0.0645) 0.1225 (0.0621) 0.0759 (0.0591) 0.1902 (0.0865) 0.1588 (0.0622)
** ***
Human capital 0.0022 (0.0487) 0.0291 (0.0459) 0.0293 (0.0497) 0.0392 (0.0463) 0.1366 (0.0583) 0.0123 (0.0465) 0.0212 (0.0591) 0.0024 (0.0485) 0.1309 (0.0696) 0.0021 (0.0487)
*** *** ** ** *** *** ***
Government 2.6297 (1.4979) 2.5970 (1.4904) 3.0369 (1.4944) 3.0866 (1.4830) 2.2825 (1.5036) 5.2767 (1.4315) 2.5048 (1.8603) 2.1427 (1.6057) 6.7531 (2.1531) 2.7796 (1.4992)
Instability 0.0459 (0.0635) 0.0480 (0.0628) 0.0088 (0.0645) 0.0132 (0.0638) 0.0170 (0.0641) 0.0623 (0.0715) 0.0306 (0.0625) 0.0675 (0.0651) 0.0122 (0.0910) – –
**
Distortions 0.0444 (0.0575) 0.0389 (0.0564) 0.0536 (0.0584) 0.0449 (0.0571) 0.0674 (0.0577) 0.0815 (0.0514) 0.0578 (0.0703) 0.0372 (0.0616) 0.1900 (0.0847) 0.0380 (0.0577)
** ** *** *** ** *** *** **
Openness 15.7303 (6.7847) 14.2001 (6.7211) 26.2663 (7.0824) 26.0182 (6.9835) 15.6149 (6.8161) 18.9247 (5.7864) 26.4089 (8.5330) 7.1528 (6.7129) 1.0898 (10.2477) 14.7109 (6.7798)
*** *** ** *** *** *** *** *** ***
Fertility 0.7684 (0.1553) 0.8309 (0.1527) 0.3444 (0.1585) 0.4237 (0.1554) 0.6202 (0.1625) 0.7679 (0.1624) 0.6081 (0.1824) 0.8019 (0.1609) 0.0196 (0.2093) 0.7680 (0.1550)

Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital, and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1,000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis.
*
Significant at the 1% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 10% level.
Table 12. Sensitivity analysis for ETHFRAC. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Variables Base model Sub-S. Africa Latin America East Asia OECD
*** ** *** ***
Investment 0.0900 (0.0144) 0.0641 (0.0289) 0.1107 (0.0370) 0.0940 (0.0738) 0.1235 (0.0320)
Civil war 0.3885 (0.3341) 0.4646 (0.8471) 0.8172 (0.5719) 1.5576* (0.9383) 1.4264 (1.5488)
Human capital 0.5848* (0.3405) 0.1194 (0.6928) 0.6983 (0.8838) 1.3478 (1.3687) 0.0298 (0.6305)
Government 0.0346*** (0.0131) 0.0329 (0.0282) 0.0338 (0.0379) 0.0588 (0.1318) 0.0344 (0.0382)

HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH


Instability 0.6004* (0.3164) 1.6518* (0.9297) 0.3493 (0.3830) 0.2679 (0.9269) 0.7758 (0.5722)
Distortions 1.9340*** (0.3378) 0.6089 (0.6456) 2.8831*** (0.8251) 4.4531 (5.0598) 13.5862*** (3.7970)
Openness 0.0032 (0.0026) 0.0076 (0.0055) 0.0105 (0.0064) 0.0042 (0.0136) 0.0063 (0.0044)
Fertility 0.3027** (0.1221) 0.0750 (0.3727) 0.1330 (0.2870) 0.4789 (0.4548) 0.5382** (0.2623)
ETHFRAC 1.9595*** (0.4783) 4.6347*** (1.2648) 1.8165* (1.0915) 2.5359 (2.0079) 0.1945 (0.6597)
Constant 5.7808 (8.0101) 55.3536** (23.8431) 66.4576 (52.8518) 22.7851 (58.4827) 62.2949 (38.7281)
N 651 182 155 45 167
Adjusted R2 0.282 0.240 0.216 0.367 0.401
Effect of ETHFRAC on the channel
Investment 1.6006 (1.1702) 4.3231 (3.1297) 11.3334*** (2.1456) 14.9391*** (2.3829) 7.8662*** (1.5840)
Civil war 0.0633 (0.0619) 0.0106 (0.1621) 0.3773** (0.1826) 2.6428* (1.4588) 0.0204 (0.0357)
Human capital 0.0499 (0.0468) 0.0112 (0.1219) 0.1894** (0.0867) 0.5482 (0.8395) 0.0867* (0.0471)
Government 1.6731 (1.4557) 11.3205*** (3.4242) 5.0522** (2.5355) 6.7521** (2.7612) 6.7134*** (1.5659)
Instability 0.0097 (0.0620) 0.2046 (0.1406) 0.3649 (0.2361) 0.5661 (1.0095) 0.0615 (0.1046)
Distortions 0.0526 (0.0560) 0.2021 (0.1453) 0.3931*** (0.0989) 0.0496 (0.2086) 0.0134 (0.0125)
Openness 14.2083** (7.1136) 9.6010 (24.8154) 36.6986*** (12.2899) 210.5391*** (78.7544) 58.0732*** (8.8796)
Fertility 0.3330** (0.1555) 0.0329 (0.2622) 0.2005 (0.2827) 1.2633*** (0.3294) 0.3090* (0.1701)
Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69, . . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital, and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1,000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis.
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.

295
296
Table 13. Sensitivity analysis for ETHPOL. Dependent variable is per capita GDP growth (five-year averages)
Variables Base model Sub-S. Africa Latin America East Asia OECD
Investment 0.0891*** (0.0146) 0.0764** (0.0306) 0.0957*** (0.0370) 0.1696** (0.0654) 0.1184*** (0.0319)
Civil war 0.4566 (0.3391) 0.5422 (0.8767) 0.9491 (0.5827) 2.3475*** (0.8983) 1.5132 (1.5478)
Human capital 0.6772** (0.3449) 0.5587 (0.7140) -0.9596 (0.8860) 2.4390* (1.3541) 0.0050 (0.6336)
Government 0.0355*** (0.0133) 0.0149 (0.0291) 0.0426 (0.0382) 0.1405 (0.1217) 0.0411 (0.0374)
Instability 0.6263* (0.3195) 1.2931 (0.9567) 0.4066 (0.3854) 0.0980 (0.8908) 0.7950 (0.5720)
Distortions 1.9260*** (0.3414) 0.6655 (0.6663) 2.7688*** (0.8298) 12.8893** (5.8758) 13.9466*** (3.7909)
Openness 0.0056** (0.0026) 0.0086 (0.0057) 0.0048 (0.0058) 0.0230 (0.0170) 0.0060 (0.0044)
Fertility 0.3093** (0.1240) 0.1695 (0.4068) 0.1958 (0.2887) 0.0618 (0.4871) 0.5291** (0.2625)
ETHPOL 0.7874 (0.5023) 0.0375 (2.0752) 0.5184 (1.0483) 7.6393** (3.3175) 0.0071 (0.5534)
Constant 11.9158 (7.9436) 47.7260* (24.6574) 71.8594 (53.8346) 46.5847 (58.8804) 62.0112 (38.7871)
N 651 182 155 45 167

WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Adjusted R2 0.267 0.186 0.206 0.408 0.400
Effect of ETHPOL on the channel
Investment 3.7221*** (1.2221) 11.2641** (4.4451) 10.8254*** (2.0563) 6.2951 (5.7632) 6.2617*** (1.3411)
Civil war 0.1492** (0.0586) 0.0576 (0.1754) 0.3888** (0.1624) 0.7953 (1.9418) 0.0079 (0.0273)
Human capital 0.0022 (0.0487) 0.2201 (0.1944) 0.0810 (0.0845) 2.2703*** (0.5183) 0.0400 (0.0389)
Government 2.6297* (1.4979) 10.2618** (5.1215) 3.3248 (2.3016) 18.0190*** (2.9875) 4.7025*** (1.2996)
Instability 0.0459 (0.0635) 0.0891 (0.1857) 0.2225 (0.2146) 3.2898*** (1.0133) 0.0645 (0.0803)
Distortions 0.0444 (0.0575) 0.0710 (0.2262) 0.2216** (0.0922) 0.3246** (0.1313) 0.0132 (0.0102)
Openness 15.7303** (6.7847) 36.5795 (29.3167) 15.6689 (11.3656) 181.3010*** (53.9450) 41.9367*** (7.0156)
Fertility 0.7684*** (0.1553) 1.4904*** (0.3675) 0.3962 (0.2804) 1.0446** (0.4664) 0.2892** (0.1425)
Notes: The sample includes 100 countries for the period 1960–99. Investment, government consumption, political instability, market distortions, trade openness, and fertility are entered as five-year
averages (i.e., 1960–64, 1965–69,. . ., 1995–99). Log initial income, Human capital, and log population are measured at the beginning of each five-year period. Civil war dummy takes value 1 if the
country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. PISH and PPDEV refers to the price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) and the magnitude of the absolute deviation of PISH
from the sample mean, respectively. The democracy dummy takes value 1 if the Polity IV democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high) is equal to or higher than 4. Island dummy takes value 1 if country is an
island (Australia is not an island). Landlocked dummy takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Mountains is the percent of mountainous terrain. Log area is the log of area in 1000s of square
kilometers. Ever a colony dummy takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Postwar dummy takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Oil producer
dummy takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Muslim dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Confucian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism,
Confucianism, etc., excluding Hindus. Catholic dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Other Christian dummy takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not
Catholicism. Mortality rate is the children mortality rate (ages 0–4). The method of estimation is seemingly unrelated regression. Robust standard errors between parenthesis
*
Significant at the 10% level.
**
Significant at the 5% level.
***
Significant at the 1% level.
HOW ETHNIC DIVERSITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH 297

Table 14. Data description


Growth Growth of real GDP per capita (Chain) in %: rgdpch [Base year: 2000] for 1960–99, constant price
entries. Source: Heston et al. (2006), Penn World Table Version 6.2 (SH v. 6.2)
Sub-Sahara Africa dummy Dummy for Sub-Saharan African countries
Latin America dummy Dummy for Latin-American countries
East Asia dummy Dummy for East Asian countries
OECD dummy Dummy for OECD countries
Log initial income Log of per capita GDP at the beginning of each five-year period. Source: SH v. 6.2
Log initial income squared Log of per capita GDP squared at the beginning of each five-year period. Source: SH v. 6.2
Investment Investment share of real GDP per capita (Laspeyres): ki [Base year: 2000], constant price entries.
Source: SH v. 6.2
Civil war Takes value 1 if the country experienced a civil war during the five-year periods. Source: Doyle and
Sambanis (2000)/compiled by Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b)
Human capital Log of (1 + avg. schooling years in the total population over age 25). Source: Barro and Lee (2010)
Government Government share of real GDP per capita (Laspeyres) in %: kg [Base year: 2000], constant price
entries. Source: SH v. 6.2
Instability Measure of political instability. Unit: Number of revolutions and coups per year. Source: Banks
(2011)
Distortions Log of (1 + black market premium). Source: Easterly (2001)
Openness Exports plus imports divided by GDP (rgdpl) [Base year: 2000] in %, constant price entries. Source:
SH v. 6.2
Fertility Net fertility rate calculated as TFR(1-MORT04)
PISH Price level of investment (PPP I/Xrate relative to US) (US = 1.0). Source: SH v. 6.2
PPDEV Magnitude of the absolute deviation of the Price Level of Investment (PISH) from the sample mean.
Source: SH v. 6.2
Log poulation Log of the population at the beginning of each five-year period. Source: SH v. 6.2
Democracy dummy Democracy score (0 = low; 10 = high). The democracy score is transformed into a dummy variable
that takes the value 1 if the democracy score is equal to or higher than 4. Source: Polity IV data set/
compiled by Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b)
Island dummy Takes value 1 if country is an island (Australia is not an island). Source: Tavares and Wacziarg
(2001)
Landlocked dummy Takes value 1 if country has no coastline. Source: CIA World FactBook (1996)/compiled by Tavares
and Wacziarg (2001)
Mountains Percent mountainous terrain. Source: Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b)
Log area Log of area in 1,000s of square kilometers. Source: Barro and Lee (1993)/completed by Tavares and
Wacziarg (2001)
Ever a colony dummy Takes value 1 if the country was ever a colony since 1776. Source: Barro and Lee (1993)/completed
by Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Postwar dummy Takes value 1 if country gained independence after the Second World War. Source: Barro and Lee
(1993)/completed by Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Oil producer dummy Takes value 1 if country is oil exporter. Source: Barro and Lee (1993)/completed by Tavares and
Wacziarg (2001)
Muslim dummy Takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Muslim. Source: Encyclopedia Britannica/compiled by
Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Confucian dummy Takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Buddhism, Xintoism, Confucianism, etc. (excluding Hindus).
Source: Encyclopedia Britannica/compiled by Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Catholic dummy Takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Catholicism. Source: Encyclopedia Britannica/compiled by
Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Other Christian dummy Takes value 1 if majoritarian religion is Christian, but not Catholicism. Source: Encyclopedia
Britannica/compiled by Tavares and Wacziarg (2001)
Mortality rate Children mortality rate (ages 0–4). Source: World Bank
Total fertility rate Total fertility rate (children per woman). Source: World Bank
ETHFRAC Index of ethnic fractionalization calculated using the data from the World Christian Encyclopedia
(WCE). Source: Garcia-Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005b)
ETHPOL Index of ethnic polarization calculated using the data of the WCE. Source: Garcia-Montalvo and
Reynal-Querol (2005b)

APPENDIX B. SUPPLEMENTARY DATA

Supplementary data associated with this article can be


found, in the online version, at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
j.worlddev.2014.01.012.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

You might also like