You are on page 1of 19

World Development. Vol. 22, No. 9, pp.

1393-141 I, 1994
Pergamon Elsevier Science Ltd
Printed in Great Britain

0305-750x(94)00053-0

The Informal Sector and the Macroeconomy:


A Computable General Equilibrium Approach
for Peru
BRUCE KELLEY *
Florida International University, Miami

Summary.- This paper examines the macroeconomic implications of the informal sector in Peru
through the use of a structuralist, computable general equilibrium model. The lack of formal sector
employment drives informal activity while formal and informal output are treated as imperfect
substitutes. Simulations show that informal activity reduces the Keynesian multiplier and complicates
distributional issues as the income of formal workers and informal producers can move in opposite
directions. A final simulation highlights the limitations of strategies designed to promote the informal
sector. Total output and income of informal producers decline following an increase in productivity in
these processes.

1. INTRODUCTION the informal sector, a common policy designed to


help informal producers.
In recent years the informal sector has drawn con- The simulations illustrate the various channels
siderable attention due to a congruence of political, through which informal activity affects the macro
economic and social forces. In general the bulk of this economy. The first simulation shows how competi-
research has focused on the microeconomic aspects of tion between formal and informal output reduces the
the informal sector or provided descriptive case stud- Keynesian multiplier. The second simulation high-
ies of informal sector workers or firms.’ Little is lights the role of relative prices and the importance
known about the macroeconomics role of the informal of substitution between the two sectors in the prod-
sector such as its effect on the macro adjustment uct and labor markets. Following an increase in for-
process or the impact of macro policy on these activi- mal sector wages, informal output rises and formal
ties. One consequence of this is that programs production falls. Informal activity complicates politi-
designed to aid informal producers in the developing cal economy issues in these simulations since the
world are adopted without regard to their macroeco- real incomes of informal producers and formal sector
nomic implications. workers move in opposite directions. The final simu-
This paper analyzes the macroeconomic role of lation examines the argument, popularized in Peru
the informal sector through the use of a multisector, by de Soto (1986) and his Institute de Lihertud J
computable general equilibrium (CGE) model for Demouacia (ILD), that free of government imposed
Peru. The model follows the structuralist tradition barriers, informal producers would prosper. The
formalized by Taylor (1979, 1983 and 1991). but macroeconomic implications of this much-touted
extends these models by differentiating between for- “other path” are seen to undermine the microeco-
mal and informal production in both the labor and nomic logic as higher informal sector productivity
product market. The advantage of the CGE method- results in a deterioration of the terms of trade and
ology for this study is that it captures the structural income in this sector. Thus, while informal activity
aspects that drive informal activity as well as differ- will continue to play an important role in Peru, the
ences between the informal and formal sector and paper concludes that this sector should not be viewed
heterogeneity within the informal sector. In the as the key to economic growth and improved living
model, the lack of formal sector employment is standards for Peruvians.
responsible for informal activity while output of the Section 2 discusses the definition of the informal
two sectors are treated as imperfect substitutes. sector, identifies the linkages between the informal
Model simulations are then used to analyze how
informal activity affects the macroeconomic and dis-
tributional impact of the heterodox policies imple- *The author would like to thank Bill Gibson, Robert Cruz,
mented by Alan Garcia in 1985. A final simulation Maria Willumsen and the anonymous referees of the journal
examines the effects of capital accumulation within for valuable comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

1393
1394 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

sector and the rest of the economy and establishes differentiate between production processes based on
the stylized facts to be incorporated into the model. profitability while Portes. Castells and Benton
In section 3 the mode1 is presented where special (1989) look at the informal sector in a manner paral-
attention is given to the informal sector’s role. lel to segmented labor market theories.
Section 4 develops the Social Accounting Matrix In this paper the informal sector is limited to cer-
(SAM) with emphasis on data issues regarding the tain legal goods and services that are exchanged in
informal sector. The model is then used to simulate markets. This condition excludes production for own
the economy’s response to three policy shocks: a rise consumption as well as illicit goods, such as cocaine,
in investment, formal sector wage increases and from the informal sector since the unique structure
greater informal sector productivity. The goal of and motivation of these activities would significantly
these simulations is to understand how the informal muddle the concept.’ In our model informal produc-
sector affects the macroeconomic adjustment tion is limited to six goods and services that arc
process, and in turn how macroeconomic changes listed, along with some relevant characteristics (See
affect the informal sector. The conclusion summa- Table I).”
rizes these results and draws out some of the associ- While the preceding discussion limits the goods
ated political implications. produced by the informal sector, it does not provide
a definition of such production. In the literature
informal processes have been defined by legal status
2. THE INFORMAL SECTOR (de Soto, 1986). production technology (Carbonetto
and Carazo. l986), non-normal profit rates (Gibson
One of the most striking features of the informal and Kelley, 1994) or the organization and control of
sector literature is the number of way in which this production (Kelley, 1990) while empirical studies
term has been used. Surveying the literature, Peattie typically use firm size as a proxy for the informal
(1987) suggests that the term’s ambiguity is largely sector. This paper will incorporate a number of these
responsible for its wide acceptance. Differences characteristics into the picture of the informal sector
appear at the most basic level. the unit of analysis, developed here.
where the informal sector has been defined with First, informal production is organized around an
respect to commodities, markets, activities. enter- individual, family or small group of friends. This
prises, institutions and individuals. Even where the means that the direct producer controls the produc-
informal sector’s domain is agreed upon, competing tion process and receives the net product whereas
definitions and motivations exist. These difficulties formal sector workers earn a wage. The technical
expand considerably when evaluating data issues as aspects of production also differ between sectors
discussed below. with informal processes characterized as labor-inten-
The CGE model is compatible with various con- sive reflecting the scarcity of both physical and
ceptualizations of the informal sector.’ Given that human capital. For Peru, Carbonetto and Carazo
CGE methodology is built around markets (both ( 1986) estimate the capital-worker ratio to be $500
goods and factor) and production (processes) it is in the informal sector and $20,000 in the formal sec-
necessary to define the informal sector with respect tor while labor productivity in the latter is twice that
to both of these dimensions. This can be done in a of the former. A third stylized fact associated with
variety of ways following the theoretical work on the informal sector involves its relationship with the
this topic. For example, Peattie defines informal state. De Soto (1986) is largely responsible for the
goods such as housing. Gibson and Kelley (1994) current popularity of this theme. but the informal

Informal ‘/c of output


process Type of product from IS

Light manufacturing simple metalworking furniture 40 II X


Textiles tailored suits sweaters 37 14 12
Diverse services food preparation personal services 19 12 26
repair services
Consruction housing 7 3 5
Surface transportation taxis. buses light trucking 43 23 I0
Commerce mostly retail 36 36 38

*As a percent of total output of each good in base SAM. Numbers do not sum to IOO% due to rounding. Figure\ developed
by author as described in section 4.
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1395

sector’s legal status has long been noted.’ Although develop alternative income sources. While some turn
his thesis of excessive government regulation as the to criminal or other activities, the vast majority of
sole cause of informal activity remains controversial, this surplus labor pool in developing countries enters
few deny that informal enterprises typically violate the informal sector. “Full employment” exists, but
regulatory statutes and pay little taxes. While such this is achieved through changes in the level of infor-
behavior results in higher disposable income in the mal activity rather than by adjustments in the formal
short run, it also introduces problems regarding labor market.
investment, property rights and security that limit
growth. Estimates concerning the income of infor-
mal producers always indicate informal producers 3. THE MODEL
earn less than formal workers.h Theoretical explana-
tions of these differences include formal sector This section describes the CGE model and how it
unionization and labor legislation (Mazumbar, 197.5) reflects the major structural characteristics of the
labor heterogeneity and efficiency wage arguments Peruvian economy and the stylized facts of the infor-
(Bardhan, 1988). mal sector discussed above. Before exploring the
A final difference to discuss involves the output model it is helpful to discuss the CGE methodology
of the respective sectors. While formal and informal and its suitability for analyzing this issue. CGE mod-
output are similar, examples of product differentia- els are essentially complicated versions of the circu-
tion and imperfect substitutability between the two lar flow diagram taught in introductory economics
sectors abound. Informal merchants sell goods in where the system of equations maps the flow of
smaller quantities, offer different quality goods goods, services and factors of production between
(fresher fruit) and occupy different locations (streets) the various economic agents in the economy for a
than formal retailers.’ Another example involves given time period. Markets clear ex-post since actual
goods, such as alpaca sweaters or expensive furnish- supply and demand must be equal, but this identity
ing, where limited market size precludes efficient can be fulfilled by changes in output, price or some
formal sector production, The small size and flexible other variable where the specific adjustment mecha-
nature of informal production give these producers nism reflects the characteristics of the respective
an advantage in filling such niche markets. Repair market as well as macroeconomic conditions. Along
services and customized manufacturing are concen- with these sectoral balances, the budget constraints
trated in the informal sector for this reason. In order for the respective economic agents as well as macro-
to capture these differences in the model, the output economic identities, such as the savings-investment
of the two sectors are treated as imperfect substitutes balance, form the core of the CGE model.
and aggregated into a composite good that is In addition to the internal consistency require-
exchanged in the market. Relative prices and the ments, there are several other advantages of the CGE
degree of substitution between the output of the methodology for our study of the informal sector.
respective sectors determine the composite good’s First, the model captures both the microeconomic
makeup and each sector’s output. As relative prices reaction of individuals to, and the macroeconomic
shift, the composition of the composite commodity impact of, an exogenous shock. For example, a
changes which has important macroeconomic change in relative prices causes migration within the
impacts in the simulations. informal sector, altering the level and composition of
These unique characteristics of the informal sec- output, which affects other variables such as income
tor suggest that the motivation of production, invest- distribution. The CGE methodology also allows sig-
ment and savings decisions, supply elasticities and nificant sectoral disaggregation which is necessary to
distributional issues will vary between formal and capture the technological and structural differences
informal sector. Such differences, however, do not that exist across industries in a developing economy
provide the motivation for, or a theory of, informal such as Peru. Sectoral disaggregation is particularly
activity. This is found in the relationship between the important in this study since it allows the model to
informal sector and labor market. Higher wages, capture differences within the informal sector, a crit-
greater stability of income and superior working ical feature of these activities. The drawback of such
conditions make formal sector employment more disaggregation is that it makes the model too compli-
desirable than informal activity. Due to rapid popula- cated to solve analytically so empirical simulations
tion growth, economic stagnation and the capital- are required. The CGE methodology also forces the
intensive nature of formal production, however, the modeler to be explicit about market structure and the
formal sector does not employ the entire labor force. connection between the empirical model and eco-
With minimal savings and the absence of govern- nomic theory. Not only does this demystify the
ment-sponsored transfer payments, workers who underlying economic assumptions, it also makes the
cannot find formal sector employment are forced to transmission mechanism and the connections
I396 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

between the endogenous variables more transparent. fixed exogenously. The government is also rcsponsi-
Finally, and most relevant for this study, the CGE hle for two production processes (public infrastruc-
model has distinct advantages regarding data ture and government services) where the difference
requirements. Instead of requiring a long time series between revenue and cost is the profit (or loss) of
as in an econometric study, the CGE model only parastatal enterprises. I0 The fiscal deficit is consid-
needs data for one point in time which are incorpo- ered to be nonbinding and determined endogenously.
rated into a consistent macroeconomic framework in the external sector. resource-based goods
according to explicit assumptions concerning the (agriculture, minerals and petroleum) account for
informal sector, parameter values and economic 75% of export earnings reflecting Peru’s reliance on
theory. While the data requirements are still daunt- traditional exports. Structural constraints determine
ing. the alternative of an extended time series does this supply in the short run and price is given by the
not exist making econometric analysis impossible. world market following the small country assump-
With this understanding of CGE methodology. tion. Exports adjust to clear these markets. The
we can turn to the actual model. To save space, the remaining 25% of exports come from nonresource-
actual equations are given in Appendix A. The based production. Since exports are a relatively
model has IX domestic goods, six of which are com- small portion of demand for these goods, they can be
posite goods made up of formal and informal output, fixed in real terms. All imports are considered to be
and one noncompetitive imported good. There are noncompetitive and treated as a separate good. The
five economic actors: three domestic classes (formal external account is balanced by changes in foreign
sector workers, capitalists and informal producers) savings.”
plus the government and foreigners. Total capital Labor is considered to be homogeneous which
stock and its distribution across industries is fixed. avoids differences retlecting skill, gender and spatial
Labor is assumed to move costlessly across pro- factors. Due to excess capacity in the formal sector.
cesses and between the formal and informal sector. labor-output coefficients in this sector are taken as
In the goods market sectoral balance is given by constant. Labor productivity is also assumed to be
the equality of supply and demand where supply is constant in the informal sector since these processes
determined according to structural characteristics. use so little capital that the marginal product of labor
For each good or service except commerce, total will not change significantly as workers enter or
demand is made up of intermediate, consumption, leave these processes. In informal processes that
investment, government and export demand. require a significant amount of capital, workers typi-
Intermediate demand is given by the Leontieff tech- cally use personal or household assets. For example,
nology while consumption is linear in expenditure.” drivers frequently use their own personal vehicles to
Both investment and government demand are given provide informal transportation services. In this
in real terms while export demand depends upon the sense entry into this process is restricted to individ-
type of good as described above. uals who own their own car which means capital-
Commerce. good IS, is treated differently since labor ratios. and thus productivity. will not change
demand for this service is a derived demand based significantly as the number of workers in these
on commercial margins associated with the purchase processes change.”
of other goods4 Commercial margins are fixed in Despite the common assumption concerning
physical units and given in the National Accounts for labor productivity, issues concerning income distrib-
each good and type of demand. The commercial ution differ between the two sectors. In the simula-
markup is determined by the physical margin multi- tions the formal sector wage is fixed by institutional
plied by the price of commercial services where the factors while the imputed wage of informal pro-
difference between producer and retail price goes to ducers is the net product which is determined
merchants for their services. If H,, represents the endogenously as the difference between price and
physical margin on good i when purchased by intermediate costs. Based on Peruvian data, formal
process ,;. H,, the physical margin on good i when sector employment is more remunerative than infor-
purchased by final demand type/’ and D,, the final mal activity in the base SAM.” This difference. con-
demand of good by demand type,/: total demand for sidered the formal sector wage premium, varies
commercial services is given by: across processes and changes during the simulations
as relative prices and income within the informal
sector shift. Changing relative income within the
xi, = ; ; a&X,+ ;j ;: O,,Di, informal sector induces informal producers to switch
,=I ,=I ,=I ,=I processes which alters the composition of informal
output as well as the distribution of income between
The government collects income and sales tax formal and informal scctorx.
from the formal sector while their expenditures are As discussed ahove. formal and informal output
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1397

are treated as imperfect substitutes and combined while ~1, is a parameter which reflects barriers to
into a composite good using an Armington function entry for the respective informal process. Since the
(Armington, 1969). This technique is frequently used first 18 processes are formal, the term in parentheses
in CGE models to account for differences between on the left-hand side represents the total size of the
domestic and imported goods (Dervis et al., 1982, p. informal sector labor force. The term in parenthesis
224). The strength of such an approach is that it on the right-hand side corresponds to the value of the
allows relative prices and the elasticity of substitu- net product of the informal process which deter-
tion between formal and informal sector output to mines the income of the informal producer. As barr-
determine the composition of the composite good. If ers to entry decline, a, increases so income differ-
P’, represents the informal-formal price ratio for ences between informal processes play a larger role
good i and o, the elasticity of substitution between in deciding where labor goes to within the informal
formal and informal output of this good, the portion sector. As with the a, term discussed above, no
of informal output in the ith commodity, $,, can be empirical estimates for this parameter exist so we
expressed as: will run simulations to check the model’s sensitivity
to this parameter. This will also illustrate how the
4, = f (P, ‘90;) (&ml? <0 reaction of informal producers to a change in relative
prices can alter the macro adjustment process.ls
As P’, (the relative price of informal output) The presence of informal activity, as well as
increases, formal output replaces informal produc- other structural characteristics, determine how prices
tion in the composite commodity where the magni- are formed and markets clear. For resource-based
tude of this change depends upon the elasticity of goods which face a given world price, domestic
substitution between formal and informal output. As prices follow directly since export tariffs, commer-
output becomes more homogeneous (u, increases), a cial margins and the exchange rate are all fixed.
given change in relative prices will have a larger With price determined in this manner and output
effect on the composition of the composite commod- fixed in the short run due to structural constraints,
ity. In the extreme case where u, = CCthe goods are exports adjust to clear these markets. For the other
homogeneous and therefore prices must be equal. formal processes, price is determined by an exoge-
Given the limited data for the informal sector, values nous markup over costs which is defended by high
for this parameter cannot be obtained from the litera- tariff barriers and idle capacity.lh For markets limited
ture. Instead simulations will be run using several to formal production, capacity utilization and output
values for this variable in order to show how adjust to equate supply and demand at this price.
changes in this parameter alter the adjustment In other markets with both formal and informal
process and change the simulation results.‘” production, market clearing is mediated by the
The final aspect concerning the informal sector to Armington function and the makeup of the compos-
be discussed at this point involves how workers are ite good. Formal sector prices are still given by a
distributed between the respective informal pro- markup equation, but the price of informal output is
cesses. From our theory of the informal sector, the determined endogenously in order to clear each mar-
number of informal producers is given by the differ- ket while maintaining full employment. For a given
ence between total labor force and formal sector set of relative prices, if there is excess supply of a
employment. Due to the disaggregated nature of the good produced by the informal sector, the price of
informal sector in this study, however, we need a this output will fall causing the informal sector’s
mechanism to allocate producers to the respective weight in the composite commodity to increase. The
informal processes. This mechanism should reflect price of the composite good will also fall since it is a
the relative income and barriers to entry associated weighed average of informal and formal sector
with each informal process. The labor allocation prices. Equilibrium is reached when a price vector is
equation can be written as: found where full employment exists and all markets
clear.
18 17 To understand the model’s behavior and the
liy/CE- C I& = r,(P, - C k,aJJ informal sector’s role in the adjustment process con-
!=I i= I sider an exogenous fall in investment. For resource-
j=l9,20,...,24 based goods, the fall in domestic demand translates
into greater exports since price is given by the small-
where 1, is the labor-output coefficient for process j. country assumption and output is fixed in the short
X, the output of process j, z th: total labor force, c, run due to structural considerations. Elsewhere for-
(the output price of process j, rl, the cost of input i mal sector firms respond to this fall in demand by
to process j and a, the input-output coefficient. The cutting back production and reducing employment
F, term is a scale term taken from the base SAM which translates into a larger informal sector labor
139x WORLD DEVELOPMENT

force and is allocated across the respective processes dies net of other taxes. Profits are determined residu-
according to the labor allocation equation described ally to balance the row and column totals. One
above. An increase in the number of informal pro- unusual aspect of the SAM i\ that commodity flows
ducers and lower demand for their output causes the are measured in producer prices with a separate entry
price of informal goods to fall which, from the for commercial services which reflects the commer-
Armington function, increases the informal sector’s cial markup or the difference between producer and
weight in the composite commodities. The decline in retail prices as explained above.
informal sector price is not uniform which causes All imported goods are treated as noncompetitive
migration within the informal sector as producers with domestic production which allows them to be
move to where relative prices have increased. treated as a separate good and occupy a separate row
Formal sector output and employment both fall. but in the SAM. Structuralist literature emphasizes the
the effect on informal sector output is ambiguous. role of non competitive imports and this assumption
Although the number of informal producers has is common in CCE models of small countries such
increased, the sector’s output could fall if there was as Peru.” Import and sales taxes occupy separate
enough movement within the sector from high to low rows in the SAM and differ according to final desti-
productivity processes. nation. Without capital flows, imports minus exports
The macro savings-investment balance now holds (the trade balance) equals foreign savings which is
at the lower level of investment as all three forms of assumed to be endogenous.
savings (private, government and foreign) fall. The There are three domestic classes or economic
government balance falls since both direct and indi- groups: formal sector workers in both private and
rect taxes depend directly on formal sector output. stateowned enterprises. informal producers, and cap-
The trade balance improves as exports of resource- italists. Formal sector workers receive wages, pay
based goods increase while imported intermediate income taxes and do not save. Informal producers
goods fall with formal production. Lower formal receive the net product of the process they operate.
output is also responsible for the fall in private sav- and do not pay income taxes or save.ls Capitalists
ings. receive their income as a residual between the rev-
enue and costs of privately owned firms. They pay a
fixed percentage of their income in taxes. and since
4. THE SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX the model lacks a financial side. a constant savings
propensity is imposed.‘” Consumption ad.justs to bal-
Before examining the simulation results, it is nec- ance the household budget equation for each group
essary to discuss the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) and is allocated between 17 domestic goods and the
which serves as the database for the CGE model as imported good. based on household consumption
well as the benchmark from which the simulation surveys (INE, 1981). Several domestic commodities
results are measured. The SAM, given in Appendix B. as well as the imported good are treated as luxuries
is built from the latest Peruvian input-output tables and are only consumed by capitalists.
(INE, I986a) and updated from I979 to I985 using the The government is the I’inal economic actor and
RAS procedure developed by Stone ( 1954) as well as receives its revenue from profits on government-run
additional data provided by the National Accounts processes ( IO and I I ). indirect taxes net of subsidies.
(INE, l986b and 1986~) and BCR (1986). The princi- import taxes and other taxes. Government expendi-
pal challenge was to collapse the 70 processes and IO3 ture\ are distributed between domestic goods and
commodities of the National Accounts into a more imports where the difference between expenditures
workable number that reflect the major structural fea- and revenue is the government deficit or surplus.
tures of the Peruvian economy while incorporating Without a monetary side, the model implicitly
data on the informal sector. assumes any deficit is completely monetized. The
The SAM consists of I8 domestic goods produced macro savings-investment balance, which must hold
by IX formal processes and six informal processes via Walras’s Law, can be derived so that total sav-
plus the noncompetitive imported good. Reading ings, the sum of private. government and foreign
across the row of the SAM give\ the revenue savings plus depreciation (business savings) equals
received by the producer from the various sources of the fixed level of investment.
demand; intermediate, consumption, investment. gov- Up to this point, the construction of the SAM has
ernment and export demand. This total must equal the been fairly standard. This changes with the incorpo-
payments made by the respective processes which are ration of informal activity, however, as a number of
given by reading down the column. For formal sector assumptions must be made in order to maintain the
firms total costs include intermediate cost\. noncom- internal consistency of the SAM and separate value-
petitive imports, wages, profits, a depreciation term added between formal and informal sector. The first
(savings by the firm), indirect taxes minus any subsi- assumption excludes informal output not captured by
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1399

the National Accounts from the SAM. Although this this process understates the informal sector’s actual
imparts a downward bias to the size of the informal size.
sector, it is essential in order to maintain the SAM’s Once the size of formal and informal output is
internal consistency. The informal sector’s smaller established, the value-added reported in the National
size should only change the magnitude, not the Accounts must be assigned to the respective process-
direction of change, of the simulations.*” Other es. This is done by incorporating certain stylized
assumptions, built on the stylized facts of the infor- facts of the informal sector as well as several addi-
mal sector, help divide value-added between formal tional assumptions. From the stylized facts of the
and informal processes. In the model, informal informal sector all depreciation, imported intermedi-
processes pay no taxes, do not use imported interme- ates, indirect taxes and wage income can be attri-
diates and operate with so little capital that all depre- buted to the formal sector. Informal income, the net
ciation is attributed to the formal sector. product of informal processes, is subtracted from
While these simplifications are a starting point, total profits given in the National Accounts. Thus,
more information is required in order to derive rea- the separation of value-added between formal and
sonable estimates for the size, income flows and pro- informal sector can be reduced to estimating infor-
duction coefficients for each of the six informal mal income or net product for each of the six
processes that are consistent with the overall totals of processes.
the National Accounts. First, the labor force is sepa- In this task, government data on wage and inde-
rated into formal and informal sectors based on the pendent producer’s income are of limited use since
National Accounts category of paid and unpaid the latter group usually includes peasants which are
employment where the latter group represents infor- not part of our definition of the informal sector. In
mal producers. These figures provide a reasonable addition, most studies do not account for income dif-
size for both the total size of the informal labor force ferentials within the informal sector due to the com-
as well as the distribution between the respective modity or service produced and the possibility that
processes.?’ With the informal sector limited to the formal workers also work in the informal sector.
six commodities described above, this rule placed Estimates of informal income in Peru suggest uni-
more than 900,000 workers or 90% of the “unpaid,” form methodology and definition of this sector has
nonagricultural labor force in the informal sector not been established. For example, Rizo Patron
which is close to other estimates of informal ( 198 1) has independent producers earning more than
activity.” wage earners in the corresponding formal activity.
Once formal and informal sector employment are Carbonetto (1985) estimates the average income in
determined, their respective output can be deter- the informal sector to equal the minimum wage in
mined from the relative labor productivities. the formal sector or 50% of the average formal sec-
Estimates of labor productivity, however, are spotty tor wage while Carbonetto, Hoyle and Tueras (1987)
and subject to definitional and other problems. For put this figure at 67%. De Soto (1986) estimates
example, Carbonetto and Carazo (1986) estimate informal producer’s income to be less than half of
productivity in the formal sector to be five times what workers make in the formal sector.
greater than the informal sector, but they define the Further complicating the data issue is the require-
informal sector by low productivity. Furthermore, ment that figures used for the informal sector must
they do not differentiate according to commodity so be consistent with the overall data provided by the
productivity differences could reflect differences in National Accounts while reflecting the general char-
type of output rather than production technologies. acteristics of the informal sector. Since data on the
De Soto and his ILD are another source of data on informal sector come from a number of sources, the
the informal sector. Although there are methodologi- actual figures used in the model had to be estab-
cal errors in their estimates of the informal sector’s lished via an iterative process in order to make them
overall size (Rossini and Thomas, 1990) their fig- consistent with the National Accounts. For example,
ures for productivity differences between formal and formal sector workers were initially assumed to earn
informal processes for individual commodities are twice as much as informal sector producers, and this
reasonable. Combining these estimates with the out- income was subtracted from the profits recorded in
put and employment data for each commodity from the National Accounts. With all depreciation, sales
the National Accounts gives the relative size of for- tax and imported intermediates attributed to the for-
mal and informal output for each commodity. The mal sector, intermediate consumption is given as the
absolute levels are then adjusted to match the total residual between total output and value-added in the
level of output. Note that this approach does not informal sector. This meant, however, that several
account for differences in hours worked between for- informal processes used more domestic intermedi-
mal and informal enterprises as reported by ates per unit of output than their formal counterparts,
Carbonetto, Hoyle and Tueros (1987) which implies something that is strongly at odds with the literature
I400 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

on the informal sector. In order to solve this prob- relatively large amount of capital so when the return
lem. estimates of the productivity differences on capital is added to labor income, informal pro-
between the two processes were increased in order to ducers earn more than their formal sector counter-
reduce the absolute size of the informal sector. The parts.” Again the ability to differentiate between
income of informal producers relative to the formal informal processes and incorporate stylized facts that
workers in the corresponding process was also reflect the heterogeneity of the informal sector is a
increased in order to increase value-added of the clear advantage of the CGE methodology.
informal sector. Since intermediate demand is the These revised estimates produce figures for the
difference between total output and value-added. informal sector’s relative size and usage of inter-
both of these changes help to reduce intermediate mediate goods that are more consistent with the
demand by informal processes. National Accounts. Once the total intermediate cost
The final figures concerning the relative income for formal and informal process is determined as
and productivity figures for the informal sector are explained above, the actual composition of interme-
given in Table 2. Several figures merit special atten- diate usage must be specified. Again, data on the
tion. First. the difference in productivity between the input-output structure of informal enterprises are
formal and informal process responsible for the ser- nonexistent which limits this disaggregation. Formal
vice “commerce” is much greater than the differ- and informal processes producing the same good
ences for other processes. This reflects the lack of were assumed to have the same relative input-output
capital and seasonal nature of many r~nhularztes who structure so if a formal process used twice as many
swell Lima’s sidewalks, but generate very few sales. intermediate goods per unit of output as its informal
The difference in productivity is also consistent with counterpart, then each of its input-output coefficients
the absence of barriers to entry to this process. Note, would be double that of the informal sector. These
however. that despite much lower productivity the coefficients were then adjusted slightly where casual
income of informal merchants equals 908 of formal empiricism suggested that the relative intensity of
sector wages in commerce: the same ratio as most intermediate demand for certain products should dif-
other informal processes. This assumption can be fer between the two processes.
defended in several ways. First, the nature of com- The process described above produced a balanced
merce demands relatively few skills so formal sector SAM for Peru for 1979, the base year for the input-
employers are not likely to offer a large wage premi- output table. The SAM was updated to 1985. the
um to attract workers. Furthermore. the nature of year for this study. using more recent aggregate data
informal commercial activity forces informal mer- while the RAS procedure was used to update the
chants to work very long hours which lowers the input-output coefficients.” Formal sector labor
income differential. Finally. informal merchants also coefficients are assumed to be constant during this
deal in wholesale trade and to the extent they receive period, but several changes are likely to have
a return on the capital used in this process, such as a occurred in the informal sector due to Peru’s eco-
vehicle. they might even earn more than formal nomic problems. Although data do not exist, such
workers. changes include an increase in the relative size of the
The possibility that informal producers receive a informal sector and a corresponding decrease in the
return for the capital used in these processes also relative income of these activities due to the large
explains why informal producers of transportation number of new informal sector producers. As a
services earn more than workers in the comparable result. slight adjustments where made in these fig-
formal process. The nature of this process requires a ures for 19X5.

5. THE SIMULATIONS

The simulation results obtained using the CGE


model developed above are discussed in this section.
During the period covered in these simulations the
Garcia government followed a heterodox economic
program built around expansionary fiscal and mone-
tary policy, explicit income redistribution and direct
price controls. The initial results of this package
were encouraging, output increased by 8.5% and
inflation was cut in half during Garcia’s first year in
office. An alliance appeared to be developing
between the government and the private sector
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1401

which seemed to have potential regarding medium- election. The two simulations differ with respect to
term growth. Unfortunately after two years of expan- a, the parameter which reflects the barriers to entry
sion, cracks appeared in the heterodox program and for the respective informal process. In simulation B
when the government failed to address these imbal- the value of a was doubled for two informal pro-
ances, the recovery collapsed and Garcia barely cesses (commercial and diverse services) to reflect
completed his term amid hyperinflation, tumbling the lower entry barriers for these processes.
output and social chaos.25 Both simulations indicate that expansionary pol-
The first two simulations, an increase in exoge- icy is effective which is not surprising given the
nous demand and higher nominal wages, involve model’s basic Keynesian structure. One interesting
aspects of the heterodox package. Although Garcia result is that both formal and informal output
implemented these policies simultaneously, the pol- increased which seems to violate the full-employ-
icy simulations are done separately in order to isolate ment constraint since formal and informal sector
the effects of the respective shock. In these simula- employment are inversely related. This apparent
tions heterodox policy is shown to successfully reac- inconsistency can be explained by labor migration
tivate production, but efforts to improve income dis- within the informal sector as producers move from
tribution are complicated by the presence of informal low to high productivity processes as relative prices
activity. The last simulation examines the macro- within the informal sector change.
economic effects of capital accumulation in the The initial increase in demand causes formal sec-
informal sector. The results here suggest that policies tor firms to increase output and draw workers from
which promote the informal sector are likely to have the informal sector. At the same time, however,
adverse indirect effects on informal producers demand for informal output is rising due to the initial
through the macro adjustment process. shock and associated multiplier. Higher demand and
lower supply drive up the price of informal output
which is reflected in the 7.3% and 5.3% gain in
(a) A 10% increase in exogenous demand terms of trade for the informal sector in the two sim-
ulations. The increase in informal prices, however, is
The first set of simulations examines the effects not uniform since initial shock and subsequent
of a 10% increase in government and investment increase in demand varies across commodities. This
demand. This corresponds to the initial heterdox causes informal producers to move to informal
shock and mini-investment boom following Garcia’s processes where relative prices and income have
increased the most. Because this shift also reflects a

Table 3. A 10% increase in government and investment demand (o/ochange from base SAM)

A* BI

Total GNP 3.0 2.9


Formal sector output 3.1 3.3
Informal sector output 0.2 1.1
Employment
Formal sector employment 3.6 3.4
Informal commerce -1.4 0.0
Savings
Government deficit as % of FS outputS 1.0 0.9
Trade balance 43.2 -40.2
Prices
Overall price level 1.3 1.0
Real exchange rate -6.0 -5.3
Informal sector terms of trade 1.3 5.3
Distribution
Formal sector wages and IS Income as a proportion of total Income 2.4 2.2
IS income as a proportion of total Income 4.8 3.6
FS wages as a proportion of total Income 0.0 0.0
Change in the imputed wage of the IS relative to the FS wage rate 22.2 19.1

*all a and cr equal to one


tall o = 1, some a = 1 and other a = 2
SThis value expressed in absolute terms not percentage change
1402 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

movement from low to high productivity processes, ma1 activity does not change the basic expansionary
total informal sector output increases despite impact of the heterodox package. Formal output
a decline in the number of informal producers. increases in response to higher aggregate demand.
Migration within the informal sector also but informal activity reduces the multiplier since
explains the difference between the results of simu- informal producers move into the formal sector. The
lation A and B. In the latter CX,was increased for decline in the number of informal producers alters
informal commerce and diverse services to reflect relative prices, and thus output, within the informal
the relatively low entrance barriers for these pro- sector which has important distributional effects.
cesses. As a result workers who migrated to more Informal producers who either moved to the formal
remunerative informal processes in simulation A sector or experienced terms of trade improvements
now enter these processes. This is reflected in the benefit. On the other hand workers who already held
constant number of informal merchants in simulation formal sector jobs saw their real wages decline due
B after falling 1.4% in simulation A. Because the to the increase in the general price level ( 1.2% and
processes with lower entry barriers in simulation B 1.0% in the two simulations). With the ruling APRA
also have lower productivity and income, the expan- party relying upon this group for political support,
sionary impact of the initial shock is smaller than in such a reduction in real wages was politically un-
simulation A. This is apparent in the 3.3% increase acceptable. In fact, in order to solidify his base of
in formal sector employment in simulation B com- support, Garcia needed to increase real wages for
pared to the 3.6% increase in simulation A. The those already employed. The consequences of such a
smaller gain in formal sector employment is then policy within this model are examined next.
responsible for the larger (1.1%) increase in informal
output as informal producers still move to the more
productive informal processes. Finally. note that the
larger increase in informal output in simulation B is
responsible for the smaller gain in the terms of trade The second set of simulations examines the
for the informal sector here. These results highlight effects of a 10% increase in the formal sector wage
how the microeconomic responses of informal pro- rate. Wage-led growth is a common theme in struc-
ducers, as well as macroeconomic conditions, affect turalist models where redistributing income toward
the structure of informal production. classes with higher consumption propensities sparks
The presence of informal activity also affects increased demand and output (Taylor, 1983). With
issues of income distribution. In both simulations the Garcia’s promises to improve Peru’s distribution of
distribution of income improves as the share of income and the influence of structuralist thought on
income received by formal and informal sector his government, this policy found a receptive audi-
workers increased. In simulation A. however, this ence. Simulations show, however, that when infor-
share rose by 2.4% while in simulation B it was mal activity is included, this policy has the exact
limited to 2.2% due to the smaller gain in formal opposite result. Higher nominal wages lead to
sector employment and informal sector terms of stagflation and a deterioration in most measures of
trade. Within the working class the distribution of income distribution in Table 4.
income also improved as informal producer’s The key to these surprising results is found in the
income increased relative to the formal sector wage behavior of the informal sector. Higher formal wages
rate by 22.2% and 19.1%. respectively. are passed along in the form of higher prices for for-
Finally, total savings increase so that the savings mal output which, from the Armington function,
investment balance holds at the higher level of allows the informal sector to increase its weight in
investment although the various types of savings the composite commodity. While higher formal
respond differently. Private savings increased since wages do cause demand and formal sector output to
this is directly related to formal sector profits which increase, this is exactly offset in simulation A by the
increased with formal sector output. This increase, reduction in output reflecting lower output due to
however, is partly offset by a larger government competition from the informal sector. As u, the elas-
deficit which increased from 0. I% to I .O% of formal ticity of substitution between formal and informal
sector output in simulation A. This combination output, changes, the relative magnitude of these two
means the trade balance must fall. Rising demand forces also changes. Simulation B shows that an
reduces exports of resource-based goods while increase in o,, reflecting greater similarity between
greater formal output requires more imported-inter- formal and informal sector output, increases the
mediates. Combined with a 6.0% appreciation in the importance of price differences and competition
real exchange rate, these factors produce a 43% between sectors causing formal sector output to
decrease in the trade balance. decline in simulation B.
In sum. these two simulations indicate that infor- The informal sector also changes the distribu-
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1403

Table 4. A 10% increase in formal sector wages (% change from base SAM)

A* Bt CS
Total GNP 0.4 0.3 0.2
Formal sector output 0.0 -0.1 a.1
Informal sector output 2.3 2.6 2.5
Employment
Formal sector employment 0.2 0.1 0.0
Informal commerce 2.4 2.9 3.0
Savings
Government deficit as % of FS outputs 0.8 0.8 0.6
Trade balance -8.6 -6.9 -5.2
Prices
Overall price level 3.3 3.2 3.4
Real exchange rate -5.5 -5.3 -5.5
Informal sector terms of trade -0.2 4.8 -0.8

Distribution
Formal sector wages and IS Income as a proportion of total Income 4.3 4.2 4.2
IS income as a proportion of total Income 0.3 0.0 0.0
FS wages as a proportion of total Income 5.1 5.2 5.2
Change in the imputed wage of the IS relative to the FS wage rate -4.8 -5.5 -5.8

*A - all a and cr equal to 1.


tB-alla= l,someu= landothero=2.
$C-alla= l,someu= 1andothera=2.
§This value is expressed in absolute terms, not percentage change.

tional impact of this policy. Higher nominal wages itive since partial equilibrium analysis holds that as
increase formal sector workers share of output by products become more homogenous, their prices
5.1%, but informal producers are adversely affected should converge. The macroeconomic consequences
due to the decline in their terms of trade. In simula- of the initial shock, however, outweigh this effect on
tion A, the informal sector’s terms of trade falls by output prices which once again highlights the advan-
0.3% which, combined with higher nominal wages tage of analyzing informal activity within a macro-
in the formal sector, results in a 4.8% decline of the economic framework.
informal producer’s imputed wage relative to the Simulation C analyzed the model’s sensitivity to
formal sector wage. Thus while the popular class’s barriers to entry for the various informal processes
share of total income increased by 4.3%, inequality by increasing a,for two informal processes (com-
within this group also increased. These results high- merce and diverse services). A higher a, increases
light the difficulty of improving the distribution of the importance of income differences between infor-
income in the presence of a large informal sector. mal processes in the labor allocation process and
Simulation B and C test the model’s sensitivity to thus reflects lower entry barriers. This reduces the
these values as well as illustrate how these parame- expansionary impact of higher nominal wages since
ters affect the adjustment process. In simulation B, u the reduction of entry barriers into processes with
was doubled to show the effect of greater similarity low productivity will increase migration into these
between formal and informal output. Not surpri- processes. For example, the number of informal mer-
singly, the expansionary impact of higher wages was chants rose by 3.0% in simulation C compared to
reduced as the importance of competition between 2.4% in simulation A. The larger increase in these
formal and informal output increased. From the two informal processes is also responsible for the
Armington function, a higher u results in a larger greater decline in the real income of informal pro-
share of informal output in the composite commo- ducers in simulation C since these are low-income
dity for a given increase in formal sector prices. As a processes. The different results highlight the reaction
result, total formal sector output fell slightly (a.1 %) of informal producers to a change in economic con-
while informal output rose by 2.6%. The larger ditions and shows the importance of differentiating
increase in informal output produces a greater between informal processes as well as between the
decline in the terms of trade in simulation B, -0.8% formal and informal sector.
vusus -0.3% in simulation A. This is counter intu- An examination of the macro savings-investment
I404 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

labor productivity for all informal processes in order


to capture the effects of programs designed to pro-
mote capital accumulation here. Such programs have
A*
been popularized by De Soto who sees the informal
Total GNP
sector as the only alternative or “other path” to the
a.1
Formal sector output 3.3 failed statist policies of the past. In this view once
Informal sector output 4.6 government barriers facing the informal sector arc
lifted, investment will flow into these processes
Employment
resulting in economic growth and greater economic
Formal sector employment -0.2
Informal commerce -6.6 welfare for these producers. This simulation exam-
ines whether capital accumulation in the informal
Savings
sector, as reflected in higher labor productivity, is
Government deficit as % of FS outputt -0.8
sufficient to fulfill such promise\. As Table 5 indi-
Trade balance I .6
cates. the macroeconomic impact of such a change is
Prices likely to undermine its microeconomic logic. In this
Overall price level 0.9
simulation total output falls. the informal sector’s
Real exchange rate I .9
Informal vector terms of trade
terms of trade deteriorate and income distribution
-5.2
worsens.
Distribution The initial response to this exogenous shock is an
Formal sector wages and IS Income -0.4
expansion of informal output, but without new injec-
as a proportion of total Income
IS income as a proportion of total Income
tions this causes the price of informal output to fall.
4.0
FS wages as a proportion of total Income 0.4 From the Armington function this change in relative
Change in the imputed wage of the IS -6.4 prices leads to an increase in the informal sector‘s
relative to the FS wage rate share and a corresponding decrease in the formal
sector’s share of the composite good. This means
*A - all CIand (r equal to I. formal sector employment decreases which leads to
tThia value is expressed in absolute terms. not percentage a further increase in informal output as displaced
change. workers enter this sector. A second round of change\
in relative prices and formal sector output follows.
balance indicates other potential problems with this At the new equilibrium formal sector output ha\
strategy as the government deficit and foreign savings fallen by 4.X+, but this is not spread evenly across
both rise. The trade balance deteriorates as the real the processes. In fact some formal processes, those
exchange rate appreciates and domestic demand for that do not compete with the informal sector. experi-
resource-based goods increases following the rise in ence an increase in demand due to lower output
nominal wages. The government deficit also increases prices reflecting the savings on intermediate costs.
as expenditures rise in line with domestic inflation. With the decline in formal output. the govern-
and tax revenue stagnates along with formal output. ment deficit is expected to increase. Table 5 indi-
This simulation clearly shows how informal cates. however, that the government deficit. which
activity limits the potential of wage-led growth as a equaled 0. I% of formal sector output in the ba\c
short-term strategy for increasing output and improv- SAM. actually moved into a small surplus (0. I %,) in
ing the income distribution. Higher formal sector the simulation. This is the result of lower nominal
wages and prices allow the informal sector to expenditures reflecting the 0.9% decline in prices
increase their share of the composite good which off- which more than offset the 0.3% fall in tax revenue.
sets the expansionary impact of higher wages on for- One reason why tax revenue held up relatively well
mal output. Formal sector employment can actually despite the sharp fall in formal output is that export
decline and while the real wage increases, other mea- taxes on resource-based goods increased since
sures of income inequality do not improve. The role exports rose as domestic demand fell. Higher export\
of the informal sector in these disappointing results along with lower intermediate imports due to the for-
suggests the need to develop programs which directly mal sector contraction. are responsible for the
focus on this sector in order to promote growth with improved trade balance. Once again. the CGE
equity. The macroeconomic effects of one such alter- methodology, and the corresponding disaggregation
native are investigated in the next section. of production across industries, allows us to see this
surprising result.
The results also indicate that significant changes
(c) A 10% increase in ir$>rmal sector productivig occurred within the informal sector following this
exogenous shock. While total informal etnployment
The final simulation involves a 10% increase in and production both increased. the number of infor-
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1405

mal merchants fell by 6.6% as producers fled this The model’s response to various exogenous
process. The combination of inelastic demand for shocks depends on competition between formal and
commercial services and the labor-intensive nature informal output, inter and intrasector labor migration
of production caused the price and income asso- as well as macroeconomic conditions. The first set of
ciated with this service to fall relative to other infor- simulations showed that while the informal sector
mal processes. As a result, informal producers left did not change the model’s basic Keyneisan charac-
this process for other informal processes where price ter, it does affect the adjustment process and have
and income held up better. distributional consequences. The second set of simu-
While this movement within the informal sector lations examined the possibilities of wage-led
toward “productive” activities and away from ter- growth in light of Garcia’s goal of solidifying public
tiary processes can be interpreted favorably, the real support through improvements in the income distrib-
income of informal producers is adversely affected. ution. In contrast to standard structuralist models, the
Individual informal producers initially benefit from results here are disappointing as both formal output
greater productivity. but the subsequent indirect and informal sector income fall as higher formal sec-
effects associated with the macroeconomic adjust- tor wages cause informal output to replace formal
ment process are overwhelming. The terms of trade sector production. Workers who maintain their for-
for informal output declined by 5.2% which causes mal sector employment experience higher real
the sharp deterioration in the income distribution. wages, but displaced workers and informal pro-
The only bright spot appears to be a higher real wage ducers both suffer losses in real income. The last
in the formal sector, but even this is tainted since it simulation points out one problem with the argument
reflects lower prices for informal output rather than that the informal sector is the key to economic
increased productivity here or gains in the distribu- growth in the developing world. Total output and
tional struggle with owners. informal sector income both fell following an
This simulation highlights the macroeconomic increase in informal sector productivity.
limitations of strategies that promote capital accumu- Several general implications of this paper bear
lation in the informal sector. An exogenous increase special comment. The simulations have highlighted
in productivity causes total output to fall and reduces the role of the informal sector in the adjustment
the real income of informal producers. Informal out- process and shown how informal activity alters the
put does increase. but this does not increase the wel- effectiveness of macro policy. By disaggregating
fare of informal producers since price of informal informal production, the paper allows the informal
output falls. Without income gains for its target sector to react to changes in macroeconomic condi-
group. it is unlikely that such a policy will be able to tions and relative prices within the informal sector.
generate and sustain the necessary political support. These latter effects are often overlooked in discus-
Thus despite the rhetorical appeal of this policy, sions of the informal sector, yet they are important in
those concerned with the informal sector should order to understand the macroeconomic impact of
look elsewhere for economic strategies to help this the informal sector. The ability to capture such
sector. effects highlights one of the principal advantages of
the CGE methodology for this study. The paper has
also shown how the informal sector complicates dis-
6. CONCLUSION tributional issues since formal sector wages and the
income of informal producers often moved in oppo-
Despite the large size and economic importance site directions in the simulations. Such results are
of the informal sector in the developing world, rela- important in that they highlight how informal acti-
tively little is known about the macroeconomic vity compounds the difficulties associated with poli-
implications of these activities. Part of this reflects cies that are designed to improve the income distrib-
inherent data limitations, but the lack of a macroeco- ution in developing countries. Thus despite the polit-
nomic approach to the question of informal activity ical significance attached to rising real wages and
has also been responsible. This paper addresses this rhetoric calling for aid to the informal sector, this
issue by developing a CGE model that explicitly paper argues the macroeconomic and distributional
incorporates informal production where the lack of impacts of such policies are likely to be negative for
formal employment drives this activity and the out- much of the population. In fact, by placing informal
put of the two sectors are treated as imperfect substi- activity within a macroeconomic framework, the
tutes. Informal output is divided into six processes paper shows that informal producers are better
and simulations show how differences within the served by policies which reduce informal production
informal sector, as between formal and informal through formal sector growth.
processes, have important macroeconomic and distri-
butional effects.
1406 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

NOTES

I. See for example the book by Portes et al. (I 989). or final demand. Obviously some informal output serves as
intermediate goods for formal firms, but this is given by the
2. Dervis, de Melo and Robinson (1982) provide a makeup of the composite commodity rather than explicit.
detailed development of the CGE methodology. detailed links between the two sectors.

3. It is possible to include these goods in a CGE model. 15. This setup is sufficiently flexible to include other
Gibson and Godoy (1993) develop a CGE model of Bolivia important characteristics of the informal sector. For example,
with cocaine production while Reardon (1984) includes agri- many women who work in the informal sector also have
cultural production for own use in a CGE of Peru. childcare responsibilities which makes it impossible for them
to work away from the home. This could be modeled by
4. It should be pointed out that small contribution by the assigning some workers to certain informal processes perma-
informal sector to total output of certain goods reflects the nently or dividing the informal sector between work inside or
requirement that informal output must be sold. For example, out of the home. For these workers, the relative income of
to the extent that dwellings in pueblo jovenes are constructed each informal process would not play a role in deciding
by residents, this output would not be counted in our defini- which informal process to operate. The impact of this restric-
tion of the informal sector. While this limits our analysis, tion on the simulation results would depend on the produc-
such an assumption is necessary in order to make the data tivity of these processes as well as how the income of these
requirements reasonable. workers was affected by the exogenous shock.

5. Weeks (1975) also defines the informal sector by its 16. These are standard structuralist assumptions as devel-
legal status. It is interesting that while de Sota works within a oped in Taylor (1979).
neoclassical framework and Weeks a Marxian, they define
the informal sector in a similar manner. 17. Daly (1976) and Reardon (1984). among others, make
the same assumption in their CGE models of Peru.
6. See Carbonetto and Carazo ( 1986) Carbonetto, Hoyle
and Tueros (1987) and De Soto (1986) for various estimates 18. This implies that if informal processes need capital,
of the income of informal producers. they must borrow, through intermediaries, the savings of
capitalists. In actual practice the informal sector is served by
7. It is estimated that 43% of informal vendors work a complex and well-developed system of financial interme-
without a fixed location (Carbonetto, Hoyle and Robinson, diation. Without a full-fledged financial side to this model,
1987, p. 340). such questions cannot be analyzed.

8. Taylor ( 1979, Appendix 6) provides a good description 19. This is a common assumption in CGE models and
of the linear expenditure system. made by Rizo-Patron and Reardon in their CGE models of
Peru.
9. See Gibson, Lusteg and Taylor (1986) for a similar
treatment of commerce. 20. It should be pointed out that reliable estimates of the
overall size of the informal sector in Peru vary considerably
IO. This is obviously a skelatized view of public enter- due to definition, methodology and other factors. Furthermore,
prises, but is sufficient given this model’s focus on the infor- reliable estimates of informal production at the sectoral level i\
mal sector. even more problematic. As a result, the assumption made here
is certainly defensible and provides a size of the informal sec-
II For a foreign exchange constrained model of the Peru- toral that is similar to other overall estimates.
vian economy with informal production see Kelley (1990).
21. Note this division does not correspond perfectly with
12. Carbonetto. Hoyle and Tueros (1987, p. 343) estimate the definition of the informal sector used in this paper. For
that 62% of the informal sector in Lima do not use machinery example, household help would be included in the National
and that the majority of equipment that is used in these activ- Accounts as paid labor. but is part of the informal sector in
ities is also use for domestic purposes. this paper.

13. Although measurements of informal sector income dif- 22. For example Carbonetto and Carazo estimate the size
fer according to definitional and methodological issues. a of the urban, informal sector in 198 I to be I .2 million. The
reasonable estimate places IS income at 67% of formal sec- difference however is partly attributed to the different defin-
tor income (Carbonetto, Hoyle and Tueros, 1987). Of course ition of the informal sector as well as the fact informal activ-
this does not account for differences according to industry, ity in this study is limited to six processes. Estimates by ILD
location or length of the working day. place the size of the informal sector much higher, but again
the different definition combined with their inconsistent esti-
14. Note that with the Armington function, all purchasers mates described by Rossini and Thomas suggest these fig-
of the composite commodity buy the same combination of ures are not reliable.
formal and informal output of that good. While the makeup
of the composite commodity can change, it is not possible to 23. Carbonetto and Carazo (I 986, p. 138) estimate the cap-
differentiate output based on whether it goes to intermediate ital stock associated with various informal processes.
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1407

24. This procedure was developed by Stone (I 954) and is deficit which lead to the rapid depletion of international
explained in Taylor (198 1). reserves. See Dombush (1988) for a description of this
period.
25. The two major problems were the fiscal and external

REFER :ENCES

Armington, P., “A theory of demand for products distin- Metodologia Empleada en el Calculo de1 Indice de
guished by place of production,” IMF StaffPapers, Vol. Precios al Consumidor de Lima Metropolitana. (Lima:
16 (1969), pp. 159-178. INE, 1981).
Banco Central de Reserva de1 Peru (BCR), Memoria (Lima: Jagannathan, N.V., Informal Markets in Developing
BCR, 1986). Countries (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987).
Bardhan, P., “Alternative approaches to development eco- Kelley, B.. “The informal sector and alternative closure rules
nomics” in Hollis Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (Eds.)., in a computable general equilibrium model of the Peru-
The Handbook of Development Economics (Amsterdam: vian heterodox experience,” Ph.D. dissertation
North Holland, 1988), pp. 39-72. (Amherst, MA: University of Massachusetts-Amherst,
Carbonetto, D. “El sector informal urbano: Estructura y evi- 1990).
dencias” in German. Alarco (Ed.), Desajios pat-a la Leidholm, C., and D. Mead, “Small scale industries in devel-
Eronomia Peruano 1985-1990 (Lima: Centro de oping countries: Empirical evidence and policy implica-
lnvestigacion de la Universidad de1 Pacifico, 1986), pp. tions,” International Development Paper, No. 9 (East
203-232. Lansing: Michigan State University, 1987).
Carbonetto, D., and M. Ines Carazo de Cabellos, Litan. R., L. Morales-Bayro and J. Femandez-Baca,
Heterogencidad Tecnologica y Desarrollo Economico: “Internal structural reforms in Peru: A promising road
El Sector Informal. (Lima: lnstituto National de out of the debt crisis,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol.
Planiticacion, 1986). I, No. 2 (1986). pp. 28-35.
Carbonetto, D., Jenny Hoyle and Mario Tueros, Lima: Sector Mazumdar, D., “The urban informal sector,” Working Paper
Informal (Lima: CEDEP, 1987). #21 I (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1975).
Daly, J., The Political Economy of Devaluation: The Case of Peattie, L., “An idea in good currency and how it grew: The
Peru 1975-1978. (Boulder: Westview Press, 1983). informal sector,” World Development, Vol. 15, No. 7
De Soto, H., El Otro Sendero. (Lima: lnstituto de Libertad y (1987). pp. 85 I-860.
Democracia, 1986). Portes, A., M. Castells and L. Benton (Eds.), The lrzformal
Dervis, K., J. de Melo, and S. Robinson., General Equili- Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developed
brium Models for Development Policy (Cambridge: Countries (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1989).
Cambridge University Press, 1982). Reardon, T., “Agricultural price policy in Peru,” Ph. D.
Dombush, R., “Peru on the Brink,” Challenge (January disssertation. (Berkley, CA: University of Califomia-
1988) pp. I-IO. Berkeley, 1984).
Gibson, B., and R. Godoy, “Alternatives to coca production Rizo Patron, J., Politica Economica y Grupos de Bajos
in Bolivia: A computable general equilibrium approach,” Ingresos (Lima: Centro de Investigation de la
World Develrjpment, Vol. 21. No. 6 (June 1993) pp. Universidad de1 Pacifico, 198 I).
1007-1022. Rossini, R., and J. Thomas “The size of the informal sector in
Gibson, B., and B. Kelley, “A classical theory of the informal Peru: A critical comment on Hemando de Soto’s El Otro
sector,” The Manchester School, Vol. LXII, No. 1 Sender-o, ” World Development, Vol. 18, No. I (I 990).
(March, 1994). pp. 8 l-96. pp. 125-135.
Gibson, B., N. Lustig and L. Taylor, “Terms of trade and Sethuraman, S.V. (Ed.), The Urban Informal Sector in
class conflict in acomputable general equilibrium model Developing Countries (Geneva: ILO, I98 I).
for Mexico,” Jounral of Develotmzent Studies, Vol. 23, Stone, R.A., “Linear expenditure systems and demand analy-
(1986)pp.40-59. - sis: An application to the pattern of British demand,”
lnstituto de Libertad y Democracia (ILD), “La actividad eco- Economic Journal, Vol. 64 ( 1954), pp. 5 1 l-527.
nomica informal en el Peru y las estructuras legales,” Taylor, L., Income Distribution, Inflation and Growth
fndustria Peruana, No. 6 19 (1986) pp. 1 13-I 18. (Cambridge: MIT Press, I99 I).
Institute National del Estadistica de1 Peru (INE), Tab/as Taylor, L.. Structuralist Macroeconomics (New York: Basic
Insumo-Product0 de la Economia Peruana Aiio 1979 Books, 1983).
(Lima: INE, 1968a). Taylor, L., Macromodels for Developing Countries (New
lnstituto National del Estadistica de1 Peru (INE), Cuentos York: McGraw Hill, 1979).
Nacionales del Peru 1950-1985 Tahlas Insumo- Tokman, V., “Informal-formal sector interrelationships,
Productor (Lima: INE, 1986b). “CEPAL Review, (I 978), pp. 99-134.
lnstituto National de1 Estadistica del Peru (INE), Qferta y Weeks, J. “Policies for expanding employment in the infor-
Demanda Global 1985 (Lima: INE, 1986~). mal urban sector of developing economies,” Inter-
lnstituto National de1 Estadistica de1 Peru (INE), Analysis national Labour Review ( 1975), pp. I- 13.
de1 Ingreso y Gasto Familias de la ENAPROM y
1408 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

APPENDIX A: EQUATIONS OF THE MODEL

1. Supply and demand balances for domestic goods (18 equations)

24
x b,,X,= 2 a,,X,+C,+I,+G,+E,+E, i=l,2,...,12
,=I ,=I

18 24 24

~(&~,b,~,-“‘+(I -6,) x b,J,m”‘)m”p’= Z a,,X,+C,+I,+G,+X, i = 13, 14,. ., 17


j= 19 j=I

19 24
p(S, ‘; b,,X;“+(l -6,) ‘; b,,X,m”‘)m”“‘= I; ( 1 g,,x,+ ;: B,,D,,) i= 18
,=I j= 19 ,=I ,=I f= I

2. Consumption demand (54 equations)

C,h=%+(‘h,,@,(l +p,,%,)))[(l -&)y,,- ; p,(l +f,&,)E,,-P&,1 i=l.2 ,.__, 17,19


,=I

3. Price equations (36 equations)

j=5.6....,18

p,=p,*e(1 -t,,)(l -P,,8,,) i= 1,2,3,4


f=4

P, = P, i=j=l.2,...,12

P, = 6,P, + (1 - 6,) P,,, i=j= 13. 14,. ., 18

4. Informal sector equations ( 12 equations)

X,lX,+, = (PJP,,,)’ [(S,Kl - 6,)l”’ i=j=l3,14,...,18

1,x,/L- t r,x,,=r,(P,-‘; P,,‘aJ’J j=l9,20....,24


j= I ,=I

5. Full-employment constraint (1 equation)

6. Income equations (3 equations)

Y, = zf
j= 19
(P, - ; I;,,ll,,, x,
,=I

Y,= C 1 ; P,b,,-(1 +T,,) ; $,a,,-yI,-P/*)X,-Z/l j=l,2 ,..., 9, 12. 13 ,.__, 18


I ,=I I=,
INFORMAL SECTOR AND MACROECONOMY 1409

7. Government sector (3 equations)

,I 17
rP = c [ 1 P,,‘a,,+ w,l, + P,*m,,x, - z,
.,=I0 !=I
21 3 17 18 3
RR = 2 t,(wl, + P,,a, + P,*m,) X, + c t, Y, + Z t, P,*E, + 1 t,*P,*m,X, + C tr*P*eDT, + II8
j=l h=l i=, j=l f= I

9 = ; G, - R,
,=I

8. External balance (1 equation)

3 IX 4
P*e(CD~+~m~,=Z,*eE,+~ gk&+S*
f= I j= I i=l .f=4 i=5

Total number equations = 128, total number of variables = 127 where one of the labor allocation equations for the informal
sector is redundant.

Variable Name # of Variables

X; - primary output of process j 20


C,,, - consumption demand for good i by class h 54
6 - export demand for resource based good i 4
P, - output price for process j 24
p, - wholesale price of good i 18
K - income of class k 3
s* - foreign savings I
SE - government savings I
R’ _ total government revenue 1
fP - profit of government-run enterprises 1
Parameters
a, input of good i per unit of primary output of processj
m/ import-output coefficient for process j
1, - labor-output coefficient for process j
b,, - output of good per unit of primary output of process j
1, - Investment demand for good i
G - Government demand for good i
E, - Export demand for non-resource based good i
% - subsistence consumption of good i by class j
hi - marginal consumption propensity for good i by class h
8*,J - physical commercial margin on good i per demand type
$ - physical commercial margin on good i for process j
P* - international price of imports
P,* - international price for resource-based good i
5 - markup in process j
t, - indirect tax on output of processj
t* - tax on imported good used in process j
:, - export tax on good i
t’h - income tax rate on class h
6, - informal sector parameter i
I4 elasticity of substitution between formal-informal output
8, - constant for Armington function
QI - coefficient for informal sector labor allocation
5 constant for informal sector labor allocation equation
L - total labor force
- average savings propensity for class h
2 - total depreciation for process j
e - exchange rate
M’ - nominal wages
APPENDIX B: SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX FOR 1985
P
z
Food/Process

M-Int M-Int H.Man. FOIilUl Inf


Food Colt Int K w/few Govt. Govt. Prof. Light Light FOtTllkll Inf Formal
Agric. Fish Petrol Mining PrC%eSS Goods Goods Good5 Imports Infrast Serv. Serv. Man. Matl. Text Text Const

Agriculture 1730 4 0 24 7452 1904 40 0 I 0 62 20 I98 138 644 486 x3


Fish 0 415 0 0 395 0 0 0 0 0 9 3 II 0 0 0 0
Petroleum 121 98 16226 512 23X 53 1154 23 416 477 I84 XI2 74 56 52 51 129
Minerals 57 3 6 3140 I5 1 940 593 IX9 7 1 9 206 I21 0 0 169
Food 2462 27 s 26 1130 306 330 I 0 I 201 I03 68 45 71 53 0
Imp-Int con goa% 235 2 8 30 157 1756 16 2 0 4 119 597 5 2 3 0
Imp-Int int. goods 979 119 136 634 525 174 6556 484 160 90 129 271 546 234 379 204 745
K goods 24 I9 28 77 92 39 359 225 73 215 XX 299 X6 2x 32 I0 69
Heavy man 0 3 0 II2 66 61 186 13 306 6 IX 103 36 I6 4 0 964
Govt infrast 3 25 13.5 659 293 63 x90 so 174 163 II.5 624 85 70 45 45 13
Govt services 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Prof services 739 150 IO24 655 242 I75 1227 146 77 452 313 10962 I53 60 132 44 580
Light manuf 52 19 I7 4x 231 II8 476 77 I78 139 I92 122x 1324 1006 61 75 294
Textiles x9 7 2 24 154 89 XX 45 II 21 103 59 133 xx 2186 1788 0
Construction 0 0 116 2 I9 7 53 II 5 II9 202 422 I3 s 8 5 0
Commerce X27 7s 761 412 I543 XXI 1651 273 244 I54 333 657 591 305 533 372 s4x
Surface tramp 250 40 2131 402 404 137 898 93 374 31 IS 480 133 75 50 33 I04
Diverse services 66 IO 41 22 I40 Y4 352 76 32 76 I46 819 41 27 26 I9 60
Total int. cons 7634 I(116 20696 6784 13096 5864 15216 2112 2240 1955 2236 1746X 3692 2276 4226 3185 3758
net Joint production -1157 -90 -534 -743 648 -306 -1514 30 -156 89X -68X 661 -63 0 -14 1243
Total value added 22918 858 I x073 9753 4965 1664 8120 I660 1976 3291 10779 22339 2323 I964 I446 2026 57%
Private income 22753 77s 10791 x374 3049 IX20 6881 1537 2034 1611 I0266 21452 2128 1964 136X 2026 5470
Wages 4822 307 IW 1555 1003 622 2733 654 533 I611 1026h 7924 823 689 235 I
IS income 1964 2026
Profits 17931 468 9727 6819 2046 1198 4148 8X3 1501 13528 1305 679 31 I9
Government income
Indirect tax\ 165 X3 72X2 1379 1916 -156 1239 123 -58 I h8ll 513 X87 I95 78 285
Sales tax I5 3 s214 60 1582 I52 x77 123 214 403 0 505 173 I59 9
Tax on exports -x 65 2006 119Y 293 -3 -382 -98 -342 0 0 X 46 -153 0
Other tax IO I2 I4 31 93 46 I48 31 39 77 173 227 44 3x 83
Impon tax 148 3 JX X9 -52 -3s I 596 67 31 I? 340 I47 44 34 lY3
Direct taxes
Profit on govt firm\ I241

23x 66 72X 243 90 525 74 II4 310 I IX1 II4 0 I36 340

Imports (FOB value) 827 494 760 1881 3586 414 I52 57 251.1 I X42 362 0 197 0 2138
TOTAL 30361) 17016 19712 ‘)I93 2.5933 12YO 4326 651 I I+)60 1349 I 642X 4240 599 I 521 I 13534

Appendix B. Cont.
APPENDIX B: Continued.

FOlllltd Inf Formal Inf Total Total


Inf FOl-lKd Inf surf surf DiV Div Int Formal IS Capit- Private Govt. Total Final Total
cons Comm Comm Trail TKitl Sen’ Serv Demand Wrks Wrks abst Consump. Expend Invest Exports Demand Demand

Agriculture 6 I 0 0 0 342 85 I3220 7091 5045 4303 16439 7 218 576 17240 30460
Fish 0 0 0 0 0 41 10 873 I31 72 95 298 0 0 699 997 1870
Petroleum 23 90 39 1273 1273 32 8 23414 2078 1366 3007 6451 0 0 8939 15390 38804
Minerals I3 2 0 3 0 0 0 5487 0 0 0 0 0 0 II529 II529 17016
Food 0 0 0 0 0 1682 474 6985 4516 2342 3838 lo696 0 0 2031 12727 19712
Imp-Int con goods 0 0 0 2 0 233 26 3197 2462 1916 1569 5947 0 0 49 5996 9193
Imp-Int int. goods 23 122 22 377 94 577 64 13644 2670 676 4702 8048 101 2034 2106 12289 25933
K goods 2 3 0 9 4 109 I2 1902 0 0 611 611 38 1377 362 2388 4290
Heavy man 72 24 4 0 0 71 8 2073 0 0 1039 1039 0 0 1214 2253 4326
Govt infrast I I82 I21 IO 8 I35 55 3964 842 296 1409 2547 0 0 0 2547 6511
Govt services 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 14960 0 0 14960 14960
Prof services 44 1509 226 710 395 583 146 20744 5655 I910 8494 16059 0 0 6688 22747 43491
Light manuf 33 173 II5 41 40 64 39 6040 I502 725 1485 3712 67 300 549 4628 10668
Textiles 0 67 44 I2 7 120 40 5182 1806 793 2222 4821 I3 59 1127 6020 11202
Construction 0 0 0 80 22 0 0 1149 0 0 0 0 6131 7237 0 13368 14517
Commerce 50 101 39 140 81 690 130 II691 7875 4396 9289 21560 124 2181 2064 25929 37620
Surface transp I7 3176 1427 I82 I21 I7 4 10594 4687 2456 3217 10360 0 0 0 10360 20954
Diverse services 5 496 169 2411 2230 432 I44 7934 4465 2050 8237 14752 0 1293 242 16287 24221

Total int. cons 289 5946 2206 5250 4275 5128 1245 138093 45780 24043 53517 123340 I4699 38175 197655 335748
net joint production 1636 -43 192
Total value added 694 16193 1407 5656 4647 12927 174739

Private income 694 15903 1407 5602 4647 12519 158376 174773
wages 4223 1451 3788 46419
IS income 694 1407 4647 24043 158376
II680 4151 873 1 52969

Government income 21370


Indirect taxes 290 0 54 408 16363
Sales tax 221 0 0 164 9874 9874
Tax on exports -239 0 0 0 2280 2280
Other tax 292 0 I9 48 1370 1370
Import tax I6 0 35 196 1598 1300 1300 32 0 2396 3994
Direct taxes 639 1972 2611 2611
Profit on govt firms 1241 1241

Savings 23256
sav bus I44 984 5962 26885 26885 5962
sav HH -358 26885
wv Govt 4240 4240 255 -9233 -358
sav For 0 -9233

Imports (FOB value) 0 88 0 I85 0 967 16954 4240 4240 255 7493 0 11988 28942

TOTAL 983 24007 13613 12032 8922 19671 335748 24043 87914 158376 21370 23256 28942

You might also like