You are on page 1of 12

chapter 8.

Economics of mycotoxins:
evaluating costs to society
and cost-effectiveness
of interventions

Summary is a lower risk of mycotoxins in the however, it is also important to


food supply. Losses related to health assess the technical feasibility of
The economic impacts of mycotoxins occur when mycotoxins are present interventions, particularly in low-
to human society can be thought of in in food at levels that can cause income countries, where funds and
two ways: (i) the direct market costs illness. In developed countries, such infrastructures are limited.
associated with lost trade or reduced losses are often measured in terms
revenues due to contaminated food or of cost of illness; around the world, 1. Introduction
feed, and (ii) the human health losses such losses are more frequently
from adverse effects associated measured in terms of disability- Two important topics are central to
with mycotoxin consumption. adjusted life years (DALYs). It is also a discussion of the economics of
Losses related to markets occur useful to assess the economics of mycotoxins: (i) the overall economic
within systems in which mycotoxins interventions to reduce mycotoxins impact of mycotoxins on society, and
are being monitored in the food and their attendant health effects; (ii) the benefits and costs of strategies
and feed supply. Food that has the relative effectiveness of public to control mycotoxins in food.
mycotoxin levels above a particular health interventions can be assessed A common misunderstanding
maximum allowable level is either by estimating quality-adjusted life about the overall economic impact
rejected outright for sale or sold years (QALYs) associated with each of mycotoxins on society is that only
at a lower price for a different use. intervention. Cost-effectiveness as- market impacts – losses from food
CHAPTER 8

Such transactions can take place sessment can be conducted to lots rejected due to excessively high
at local levels or at the level of compare the cost of implementing mycotoxin levels, as well as losses
trade among countries. Sometimes the intervention with the resulting related to livestock and poultry –
this can result in heavy economic benefits, in terms of either improved are included in this estimation. In
losses for food producers, but the markets or improved human health. estimating the economic impact of
benefit of such monitoring systems Aside from cost-effectiveness, mycotoxins, human health impacts

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 119


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions
matter just as much, if not more so, results should not be overinterpreted, to However, when the supply curve
particularly in low-income countries avoid the danger of making long-term is shifted left, to S1 (as happens
(LICs). Since the 1990s, the field of decisions based on analyses of current when food supply is decreased
health economics has developed (limited) information. due to excessively high mycotoxin
sufficiently that now improved levels), a new equilibrium is reached,
methods exist to evaluate human 2. Market and trade impacts of represented by the intersection of the
health impacts of diseases and mycotoxins demand curve with the new supply
conditions, including those associated curve, S1. The reduced quantity of
with mycotoxin exposure in food. To The primary way in which mycotoxins units of food sold, Q1, demands a
derive an estimate for the total cost affect markets is to lower the value higher price per unit of food, P1.
to society of mycotoxins in food and of the commodity being traded. The Thus, both producers and con-
feed, both market impacts and health price paid for a particular lot of food or sumers bear costs associated with
impacts must be included in the feed is reduced, or the lot is rejected mycotoxins. Producers sell less food
calculation. entirely, or the lot must be treated and thus have reduced revenue,
Strategies to control mycotoxin at additional cost before being sold and consumers must buy the food
contamination should also be subject at a higher price. This can occur at a higher price. Specifically, the
to economic analysis. Multiple strat- at multiple different levels of trade, decrease in food producers’ welfare
egies have been developed to reduce from local all the way to international. due to mycotoxin contamination is
mycotoxin risks before harvest (in Depending on the demands of the represented by the shaded area in
the field), after harvest (in storage, buyer, the stakeholder group that Fig. 8.1. This area represents the
transportation, or processing), in diets, bears the burden of mycotoxin cost difference between the producers’
and in clinical settings (see Chapter 9). can be individual farmers, handlers, initial welfare (area of triangle bounded
If these mycotoxin control strategies processors, distributors, consumers, by P0, Q0, and the demand curve) and
are to be adopted in the parts of the or government. their resulting welfare (area of triangle
world where they are most needed, bounded by P1, Q1, and the demand
then their expected benefits, or 2.1 Dynamics of market curve). The decrease in consumers’
effectiveness – in terms of both market supply and demand due to welfare because of mycotoxins
and health outcomes – should exceed mycotoxin contamination is represented by the difference
their costs. Moreover, their capital between their initial welfare (area
costs should not be so high that LICs Microeconomic theory explains how of triangle bounded by P0, Q0, and
would find it impossible to adopt the the overall market and trade costs of supply curve S0) and their resulting
strategies. Low-tech strategies may mycotoxins can be evaluated. Simply, welfare (area of triangle bounded by
prove the most economically feasible mycotoxin contamination decreases P1, Q1, and supply curve S1).
option to control mycotoxins in LICs. the available supply of acceptable food In practical terms, producers of
Finally, cultural acceptability of the to be sold or bought. Fig. 8.1 illustrates commodities vulnerable to mycotoxin
interventions is crucial, to ensure the dynamics of supply and demand contamination may suffer market
long-term adoption and effectiveness for food for human consumption when losses directly, if the buyers monitor
in mycotoxin reduction. supply is decreased. The demand and enforce limits for mycotoxins.
In addition to the overall economic curve represents the quantity of a Consumers suffer market losses
impact of mycotoxins and the cost- particular food that consumers are indirectly, by facing a reduced supply of
effectiveness of control strategies, willing to buy at a particular price. At the commodity and therefore a higher
another important economic con- very high prices, less demand will exist price. (In contrast, consumers may
sideration is the technical feasibility of for the food, whereas at lower prices, suffer health-related losses directly, as
these strategies, which includes risk demand will be higher. The supply discussed in Section 3.) Often, this cost
assessment of potential health and curves (labelled S0 and S1) represent to consumers is marginal, particularly
environmental impacts. These issues the quantity of food that producers will in developed countries, where the
are also discussed in this chapter. provide at different prices per unit of bulk of the cost of food is made up
It is important to remember that food. Hence, the original equilibrium of food processing rather than the
values for the different variables in of quantity of food supplied, Q0, and commodity itself. But in LICs, reducing
economic models can change sub- price per unit of food, P0, is the the supply of food by removing heavily
stantially with time. Hence, when the intersection of the demand curve contaminated commodities can result
models are used at any point in time, the with the original supply curve, S0. in food shortage crises. Moreover, for

120
Fig. 8.1. The impact of a strict food quality standard on supply and subsequent price. may sell their crops to grain elevators
Source: Wu (2008); reproduced with the permission of the publisher. (e.g. maize, wheat) or to shellers or
other handlers (e.g. groundnuts, tree
nuts), who may then further process
the crop and sell it to animal operations
or to food processors for human
consumption. After processing, the
food is sold to distributors, who then
sell it to retail markets to be purchased
by consumers.
For the USA, mycotoxin action
levels (for aflatoxin, specifically) or
industry guidelines (for fumonisin
and deoxynivalenol) set by the
United States Food and Drug
Administration are enforced at
different levels, such as at grain
elevators or by food handlers. Crops
with the lowest mycotoxin levels can
Fig. 8.2. Complexity of the value chain of maize in Kenya, and points at which be sold for human food or for feed to
aflatoxin control strategies could be implemented. NCPB, National Cereals and
Produce Board of Kenya. Source: Dr Jonathan Hellin, International Maize and Wheat
the most sensitive animal species at
Improvement Center (CIMMYT), personal communication. a higher price, whereas crops with
higher mycotoxin levels can be sold
for animal feed at a lower price or
are rejected outright. Within each
commodity, different stakeholder
groups are affected differentially by
mycotoxins. In the USA, producers
of grain commodities generally
bear the burden of costs related to
mycotoxins, whereas shellers and
handlers, not growers, bear the
largest burden of mycotoxin-related
costs associated with groundnuts
and tree nuts (Wu et al., 2008).
In other parts of the world, local
commodity markets are far more
complex. The value chain of maize
in Kenya is illustrated in Fig. 8.2, to
provide an example of trade of one
commodity in one country. Maize
growers (labelled in Fig. 8.2 as “Small-
staple food items such as maize, the 2.2 Mycotoxin costs in local scale farmers”) may sell their maize
price elasticity of demand is usually and regional markets to a wide variety of different local
very low, which means that demand will maize traders, who may travel from
not change significantly in response The complexity of local and re- household to household to purchase
CHAPTER 8

to a change in price; consumers will gional commodity markets varies maize. These traders, in turn, may sell
purchase staples even if the price considerably among countries, and the maize to large-scale traders or to
becomes much higher, because staple thus the extent to which mycotoxins a variety of millers. Each step further
foods are a necessity. may impose market costs varies. in the value chain of maize provides
In the USA, for example, crop value different opportunities for both buyers
chains are relatively simple. Farmers and sellers.

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 121


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions
This complexity of the value for the country that imposes the Third, the cost of a rejected food
chain of crops in Africa means that standard but also for countries that shipment is enormous (about $10 000
it can be very difficult to implement attempt to export foods there. per lot in transportation, storage, and
mycotoxin control strategies that From an international trade dockage fees; Wu et al., 2008), even if
would have widespread effects. standpoint, mycotoxin contamination the lot can be returned to the country
The control strategies would have inflicts heavy economic burdens. attempting to export the food.
to be implemented at multiple It reduces the price paid for crops These dilemmas led former United
points, and these points would and can cause disposal of large Nations Secretary-General Kofi An-
have to be coordinated. In the event amounts of food. In the USA, losses nan to recognize the magnitude of
of an outbreak of mycotoxicosis, from mycotoxins – in the hundreds of the problem of setting appropriate
interventions would need to be millions of US dollars annually – are aflatoxin standards worldwide. At the
distributed, and communication usually associated with these market Third United Nations Conference on
among different stakeholders is costs rather than with health effects the Least Developed Countries, held
absolutely crucial. Depending on because enforcement of mycotoxin in Brussels in 2001, he commented,
available communications infra- standards and pre-harvest and post- “The European regulation on afla-
structures, implementing interven- harvest control methods have largely toxins costs Africa $670 million each
tions may be a difficult task. eliminated harmful exposures in food year in exports. And what does it
in the USA (Wu, 2004). achieve? It may possibly save the
2.3 Mycotoxin costs in In LICs, impacts of mycotoxins life of one citizen of the European
international markets are far more severe. Many individuals Union every two years. Surely a more
are not only malnourished but also reasonable balance can be found.”
The issue of mycotoxin control is chronically exposed to high aflatoxin Annan had based his statement on
becoming increasingly important levels in their diet, resulting in deaths a report of the Joint FAO/WHO Expert
for LICs as international trade from aflatoxicosis, cancer, and other Committee on Food Additives (JECFA)
becomes more prominent in a world conditions (Wild and Gong, 2010). LICs (WHO, 1998), which assessed
of increasing demand for crops (to be often lack the resources, technology, the effect of aflatoxin regulations
used for food, animal feed, or even and infrastructure necessary for on HCC incidence, depending on
fuel). Hence, mycotoxin costs must routine tests of mycotoxin levels in HBV prevalence. JECFA developed
also be considered in the context of food. Further complicating the problem two scenarios to determine the
international trade. in the case of aflatoxin is that for a effect of moving from an enforced
More than 100 countries have given level of aflatoxin exposure, cancer aflatoxin standard of 20 µg/kg to a
established maximum tolerable levels risk may be more severe in LICs stricter standard of 10 µg/kg in two
for aflatoxins in human food (FAO, than in developed countries because hypothetical countries: one with an
2004), whereas relatively few countries of higher prevalence of chronic HBV prevalence of 1% and another
have established these levels for hepatitis B virus (HBV) infection, with an HBV prevalence of 25%. In the
other mycotoxins such as fumonisin, which synergizes with aflatoxins to first country, tightening the aflatoxin
ochratoxin A, and deoxynivalenol. significantly increase the risk of liver standard would yield a drop in the
Table 8.1, which lists maximum cancer (hepatocellular carcinoma estimated population HCC incidence
tolerated levels for foodborne [HCC]) (Groopman et al., 2008). by 2 cases per billion people per year.
aflatoxins in selected countries and Globalization of trade has In the second country, tightening
regions as of August 2010, shows exacerbated food losses due to the aflatoxin standard would yield
that aflatoxin standards vary greatly mycotoxins in three ways. First, strict a drop in the estimated population
among countries, even for a small mycotoxin standards mean that LICs HCC incidence of 300 cases per
sample of countries; this difference will export their best quality foods and billion people per year. Hence, in
may cause food trade barriers. keep more heavily contaminated foods high-income importing countries with
Indeed, the Council for Agricultural for domestic consumption, resulting low HBV prevalence, tightening the
Science and Technology states that in higher mycotoxin exposure in LICs aflatoxin standard would reduce HCC
one key goal for the 21st century (Cardwell et al., 2001). Second, even incidence by an amount so small
is to “develop uniform standards the best quality foods produced in as to be undetectable (Henry et al.,
and regulations for mycotoxin LICs may be rejected for export, 1999; Wu, 2004).
contamination” (CAST, 2003). These resulting in millions of US dollars in Now that a global push exists
standards have implications not just losses (Wu, 2004; Wu et al., 2008). to harmonize mycotoxin standards

122
Table 8.1. Maximum tolerated levels for aflatoxins in human food in selected countries where PDFi,j,k is the probability density
and regionsa function of the percentage of crop
i from country j having mycotoxin
Country Total allowable level of total aflatoxins in levels at or lower than standard k, and
or region human food (µg/kg)
its integral over k is the cumulative
Australiab 5 or 15 distribution function. Then, export
losses calculated for each country are
China 20 summed across major food exporting
countries to derive a total global
European Unionc 4, 10, or 15
burden of export loss at different
Guatemala 20
mycotoxin standards.

India 30 3. Health economic impacts of


mycotoxins
Kenya 20

Taiwan, China 50
Looking at the market and trade
impacts of mycotoxins is only one
USA 20 side of the story. The other important
facet to consider is the public health
a
A more complete list can be found in FAO (2004). impact of setting different mycotoxin
b
The Australian standard for maximum allowable aflatoxins in groundnuts is 15 µg/kg, more permissive than those
for other foods.
standards worldwide, assuming
c
The European Union standard for maximum allowable aflatoxins is 4 µg/kg for cereals and all products derived from they could be enforced. The human
cereals, except maize to be subjected to sorting, which has a standard of 10 µg/kg. The standard for groundnuts, diseases and conditions caused by
almonds, hazelnuts, and pistachios “ready to eat” is 10 µg/kg, whereas the standard for groundnuts, almonds, hazel-
nuts, and pistachios intended for further processing is 15 µg/kg. mycotoxin exposure must first be
evaluated.
Evaluating the human health
(CAST, 2003), it is important to consider is the total export amount (in metric economic impacts of mycotoxins is
on a global scale what the economic tons) of crop i from country j; and ri,j,k is crucial to understanding their total
impacts would be of harmonizing the fraction of export volume of crop i economic impact because mycotoxins
different standards, which range from from country j rejected at international primarily affect LICs, where trade-
relatively strict to relatively permissive. mycotoxin standard k. related losses are not nearly as
Wu (2004) provided a framework for A sensitivity analysis on k reveals prominent as adverse health effects
assessing losses related to markets, how export losses for food crops from consuming food contaminated
as outlined below. in a particular country change as a with mycotoxins. Subsistence farmers
Given a particular internationally function of the harmonized standard and local food traders occasionally
imposed mycotoxin standard, the total chosen. Values for ri,j,k are calculated have the luxury of discarding obviously
national export loss of a particular food by fitting probability density functions mouldy food, but in conditions of
crop can be calculated as the product PDFi,j,k, based on the relevant literature, drought or food insecurity, poor people
of the price of the food crop per unit of concentrations of fumonisin and/ often have no choice but to eat the
weight on the world market, the total or aflatoxin in crop i in country j. The contaminated food or starve.
amount of that crop exported, and particular country j to study is chosen by Until recently, it was difficult to
the fraction of the export crop that is looking at the most important exporting put an economic value on health
rejected as a result of that mycotoxin countries of crop i. Cumulative effects. Fortunately, the field of health
standard (Wu, 2004): distribution functions are estimated economics has made great strides
from the probability density functions in the past two decades. Health
Export lossi,j,k = Pi * Wi,j * ri,j,k, of the percentage of the crop having economics strives to quantify health
CHAPTER 8

mycotoxin levels at or lower than a benefits and costs in such a way as


where i is the crop (e.g. maize, given concentration. Then, the fraction to be comparable with monetary
groundnuts); j is the country; k is the of export volume rejected at that benefits and costs. Otherwise, it can
international mycotoxin standard (e.g. concentration is: be difficult to understand how much a
for fumonisin or aflatoxin); Pi is the world particular risk affects human society,
price for food crop i per unit weight; Wi,j ri,j,k = 1 – ∫ PDFi,j,k dk, especially if death is not a significant

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 123


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions
outcome, or, conversely, how much impacts are more difficult to evaluate. associated with the condition would
a public health intervention benefits The burden of human diseases, also be included in this category.
human society, if no direct market such as those caused by mycotoxin
outcomes exist. Putting monetary consumption, can be calculated 3.2 Disability-adjusted life
values on these health outcomes in two primary ways. The first is years
helps decision-makers to understand cost of illness (COI), which is more
how important a risky agent or a appropriate in developed countries The DALY, like COI, is a measure
disease is, how useful an intervention because a large portion of the of the overall burden of disease. It
might be, and how to compare the estimate is health-care cost. The extends the concept of potential years
relative importance of risks and the second is disability-adjusted life of life lost due to premature mortality
relative effectiveness of interventions years (DALYs), which is appropriate to include equivalent years of healthy
(Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010a). for both developed and developing life lost in states of less than full health,
Much of the literature in health countries. A third metric, quality- broadly termed disability (Havelaar,
economics focuses on medical adjusted life years (QALYs), is more 2007; Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010a).
treatments, with relatively few ap- often used to estimate the relative One DALY can be thought of as one
plications in food and agriculture. effectiveness of different public lost year of healthy life. The total
Some examples of health economic health interventions in improving DALYs associated with a particular
assessments of food additives overall quality of life. disease are calculated as follows:
include studies of the potential cost-
effectiveness of transgenic golden rice 3.1 Cost of illness DALYs = YLL + YLD,
in reducing vitamin A deficiency (Stein
et al., 2008) and the cost-effectiveness For an individual or for a particular where YLL is the years of life lost
of biofortifying foods in reducing population, COI caused by a disease due to premature mortality from the
micronutrient deficiency (Meenakshi or condition is calculated as the sum of disease and YLD is the years lost
et al., 2007). Havelaar (2007) provided three factors: direct health-care costs due to disability. YLD is estimated as
a notable example of estimating (DHC), direct non-health-care costs the number of years lived with the
the health costs of foodborne (DNHC), and indirect non-health-care disability multiplied by a weighting
zoonoses, such as those caused costs (INHC): factor, between 0 and 1, that reflects
by Campylobacter, Salmonella, or the severity of the disability.
Cryptosporidium in Europe. COI = DHC + DNHC + INHC. The World Health Organization
It is also important to consider (WHO), among other organizations,
the health economic impacts of DHC are costs associated with has estimated DALYs for many
mycotoxins, which can impose an medical services. These include gener- diseases and conditions in different
enormous socioeconomic cost. As al practice consultations, consultations parts of the world. DALYs for any given
stated above, in developed countries it with specialists, hospitalization, any disease are estimated separately for
is relatively straightforward to estimate surgery or treatments required, drugs, high-income, middle-income, and
the costs of mycotoxins because supplements (e.g. intravenous fluids), low-income countries. This strat-
these costs are primarily related to and rehabilitation. DNHC are costs ification is based on assumptions
markets. Commodities that contain associated with the disease that do not about how many years individuals will
mycotoxins at levels exceeding relate to the medical system. These live with a disability in different parts
regulatory guidelines for human food include travel costs to medical centres, of the world and what resources are
or animal feed are discarded or sold costs of childcare, and co-payments available to alleviate disability (Wu and
at a lower price for a different use by patients for medicines. Khlangwiset, 2010a).
(Wu et al., 2008). One can estimate INHC are defined as the value
the cost of mycotoxins to a particular of production lost to society due to 3.3 Quality-adjusted life years
commodity group by estimating the disease or condition, as a result
how much of the commodity must of temporary absence from work, The QALY is used to assess the
be discarded or discounted due to permanent or long-term disability, or value for money of a medical or
mycotoxin contamination. In LICs, premature mortality (Havelaar, 2007; public health intervention. It is based
in contrast, health-related costs are Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010a). To the on the estimate of the number of
usually much higher than market- extent that they can be evaluated, years of life that would be added by
related costs, and health economic the costs of pain and of suffering the intervention, and hence is used

124
to rank the relative effectiveness of specific human health end-points are 4. Evaluating total economic
different interventions for a particular difficult to attribute quantitatively or even impacts of mycotoxins
condition. Every year of “perfect qualitatively to a particular mycotoxin.
health” is assigned a value of 1, For example, fumonisins have been If both the market and the health
whereas a year not lived in perfect associated with oesophageal cancer economic impacts of mycotoxins can
health is assigned a value between and neural tube defects in humans, be estimated, the cost-effectiveness
0 and 1 that reflects the quality of but these associations are not clearly of different interventions to reduce
life (similar to the weighting factor for established and there are no human mycotoxin risk can then be assessed.
YLD in DALYs). dose–response data, i.e. doses of Various studies have attempted to
QALYs are calculated as follows. fumonisins causing particular levels of quantify the potential market losses
Individuals with a serious, life- disease incidence, by which to perform associated with mycotoxins in crops.
threatening condition (as is often a reliable quantitative risk assessment. In the USA, Vardon et al. (2003)
the case with excessive exposure Further complicating the issue is that estimated the total annual losses
to aflatoxin) can receive a standard each mycotoxin may have multiple due to three mycotoxins – aflatoxin,
treatment (which, in LICs, may be no health end-points, including cancer, fumonisin, and deoxynivalenol – to
treatment at all) that will allow them acute toxicity, and immunomodulation. reach as high as US$ 1 billion. Almost
to live for X more years with a quality Even if quantitative relationships could all of this loss was borne by maize,
of life of A. However, if they receive a be established for each end-point, groundnut, and wheat growers.
new treatment instead, they will live an analyst would need to ensure However, a small portion of this loss
for Y more years with a quality of life that every possible human health was estimated to be suffered by
of B. The difference between the new outcome of a mycotoxin was included livestock producers due to adverse
and the standard treatment in terms of in the calculation, to derive an accurate animal health effects.
QALYs gained is health economic estimate. In three Asian countries – Thai-
With aflatoxins, more progress land, Indonesia, and the Philippines –
QALYs gained = Y * B – X * A. has been made in quantifying the the total estimated annual loss due to
link between exposure and disease aflatoxin was about 1 billion Australian
To assess the relative effective- incidence. Aflatoxins cause a multi- dollars (Lubulwa and Davis, 1994).
ness of an intervention, the cost of the tude of conditions, including acute This loss was a combination of
new treatment must also be taken into aflatoxicosis and HCC, and are market impacts, through rejected
account. The difference in treatment believed to contribute to immu- lots with excessively high mycotoxin
costs divided by the QALYs gained is nosuppression and stunted growth in levels, and adverse health effects –
used to estimate the cost per QALY, children. In an aflatoxicosis outbreak specifically the impacts of HCC in
i.e. how much would need to be spent in Kenya in 2004 (Strosnider et al., these populations.
to provide one additional QALY. 2006), it was possible to estimate the Wu (2004) estimated the market
total number of cases, the number impacts to the world’s top maize-
3.4 Challenges to evaluating of deaths, and the concentrations of exporting and groundnut-exporting
health economic impacts of aflatoxins in the contaminated maize countries and regions of conforming
mycotoxins that caused the toxicoses. Decades to hypothetical harmonized standards
of work have likewise established for fumonisin in maize and aflatoxin
To use either the cost of illness dose–response relationships between in groundnuts. If the current United
or the DALYs method to calculate aflatoxins and HCC in HBV-positive States Food and Drug Administration
socioeconomic costs, one must first and HBV-negative individuals, from (FDA) total fumonisin guideline of
identify human health end-points, i.e. which aflatoxin cancer potency fac- 2 mg/kg were adopted worldwide,
diseases or conditions, to assess. tors can be derived for quantitative the total annual maize export losses
Otherwise, it is impossible to gather cancer risk assessment (WHO, 1998). for the USA, Argentina, and China
data on the necessary factors to The immunosuppressive effects of would be US$ 100 million, whereas
CHAPTER 8

assess the economic impact: mortality aflatoxins cannot yet be quantified in if a fumonisin standard of 0.5 mg/
and morbidity, incidence, duration, and humans, but limited quantitative data kg were adopted worldwide, those
severity associated with the disease. are available to assess the link between total annual losses would increase to
The challenge in calculating the aflatoxin exposure and stunted growth US$ 300 million. If the current FDA
socioeconomic costs of mycotoxins is in children (Gong et al., 2002). total aflatoxin action level of 20 μg/kg
that, with the exception of aflatoxins, were adopted worldwide, total annual

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 125


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions
groundnut export losses for the USA, levels in food. Dietary and clinical where Y is the crop yield per hectare,
Argentina, China, and Africa would be interventions can be considered P is the price differential for high-
US$ 92 million, whereas if an aflatoxin secondary interventions. They cannot quality use (low mycotoxin levels
standard of 4 μg/kg were adopted reduce actual mycotoxin levels in required) versus other uses, and R
worldwide, those total annual losses food, but they can reduce mycotoxin- is the percentage of the crop with
would increase to US$ 450 million. related illness either by reducing mycotoxin levels above the limit for
Liu and Wu (2010) and Liu et al. the bioavailability of mycotoxins high-quality use.
(2012) estimated the global burden (e.g. through enterosorption) or by This cost C is compared with
of aflatoxin-related HCC using two ameliorating damage induced by the benefits and costs of applying a
different approaches: quantitative mycotoxins (e.g. through inducing mycotoxin control method. The net
cancer risk assessment and pop- phase 2 enzymes that detoxify benefit per hectare, B, of applying
ulation attributable risk (PAR), metabolites of mycotoxins). These the intervention can be expressed as
respectively. The quantitative cancer control strategies are described in
risk assessment methodology (Liu and greater detail in Chapters 7 and 9. B = (E * C) – A,
Wu, 2010), relying on dietary surveys In developed countries, it is
and cancer potency factors, yielded relatively straightforward to estimate where E is the percentage efficacy
an estimate of 5–28% of total global the cost-effectiveness of controlling in reducing mycotoxins to levels that
HCC cases attributable to aflatoxin. mycotoxins because the costs and allow growers a premium, C is the
Similarly, the PAR approach (Liu et benefits are primarily market-related cost per hectare associated with
al., 2012), making use of a systematic (Wu et al., 2008). The cost of a mycotoxin contamination (as shown
review and meta-analysis of human particular mycotoxin to a particular in the previous equation), and A is the
biomarker studies on aflatoxin-related commodity group is calculated total cost of purchasing and applying
cancer, yielded an estimate of 21– by assessing how much of the the mycotoxin control strategy.
24% of global HCC cases attributable commodity must be discarded or In LICs, however, interventions to
to aflatoxin. Because the total number discounted due to contamination. reduce mycotoxins have both market
of new HCC cases worldwide is Then, measuring the benefit accrued and human health importance.
hundreds of thousands each year and from a particular intervention requires How can the cost-effectiveness of
each HCC case is associated with 13 estimating how much levels of the a health intervention be determined
DALYs (Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010a), mycotoxin are reduced as a result if no direct market benefits
aflatoxin-related HCC alone may of the intervention and how much exist? The WHO Commission on
cause > 2 million DALYs each year. more of the commodity can thus be Macroeconomics and Health has
sold. The difference between the total provided the following guideline for
5. Assessing cost- market value of the commodity with thresholds of cost-effectiveness
effectiveness of interventions and without the intervention is a rough (WHO, 2001). An intervention is
to control mycotoxins estimate of the cost-effectiveness of considered very cost effective if
that intervention. the monetary amount spent on the
Multiple public health interventions To calculate the cost of mycotoxin intervention per DALY saved is less
exist by which to control mycotoxins contamination in developed countries, than the per capita gross domestic
or their burden in the human body. three market economic factors need product (GDP) of the country in
Interventions to reduce illness induced to be considered: the expected cost of which the intervention is applied.
by mycotoxins can be roughly grouped mycotoxin contamination to growers An intervention is considered
into three categories: agricultural, or handlers in the absence of any moderately cost effective if the
dietary, and clinical. Agricultural interventions, the cost of purchasing monetary amount spent on the
interventions are methods or and applying an intervention, and the intervention per DALY saved is less
technologies that can be applied expected net benefit of applying the than 3 times the per capita GDP. An
either in the field (pre-harvest) or in intervention in terms of mycotoxin intervention is considered not cost
drying, storage, and transportation reduction. The cost per hectare, effective if the monetary amount
(post-harvest) to reduce mycotoxin C, of mycotoxin contamination to spent on the intervention per DALY
levels in food. Agricultural inter- growers in the absence of agricultural saved is greater than 3 times the per
ventions can thus be considered interventions can be expressed as capita GDP.
primary interventions because
they directly reduce mycotoxin C = Y * P * R,

126
As described in Section 3.4, the Fig. 8.3. Framework for assessing the technical feasibility of public health
health effects of the mycotoxin in interventions. Source: Wu and Khlangwiset (2010b); reproduced with the permission
of the publisher.
question must be identified to estimate
DALYs for this cost-effectiveness
calculation. DALYs for any given
disease are estimated separately for
high-income, middle-income, and
low-income countries. The DALYs
estimate for each kind of country is
based on assumptions about how
many years individuals will live with a
disability in different parts of the world
and what resources are available to
alleviate disability.
This WHO guideline is not without
controversy. First, the cut-off of 3
times the per capita GDP for the cost-
effectiveness of an intervention is a
debatable metric. Second, using the
average GDP in the estimation can vention? Is the intervention culturally and temporally, to allow maximum
be controversial in itself, especially appropriate and easily adopted by the effectiveness of the intervention
for countries in which income is target population? If an intervention to in a target population. To achieve
distributed bimodally rather than reduce mycotoxins fails in any or all of large-scale implementation, the
normally (i.e. average GDP can be these points, then it is not likely to be following characteristics of the
meaningless in a country with very adopted on the large scale, no matter basic intervention would influence
rich versus very poor populations how cost effective it may be. feasibility: (i) the stability of the
and no middle class). Third, DALYs A conceptual framework has been product, including its usable lifetime
can be a controversial measure, developed for evaluating the technical and its risk of degradation or
particularly in selecting a weighting complexity – and hence the feasibil- destruction; (ii) the degree to which
factor associated with each illness or ity – of public health interventions for the intervention can be standardized
condition. Finally, cost-effectiveness is LICs with limited resources (Gericke for production and sale; (iii) the
but one component of the feasibility of et al., 2005). The framework has four safety profile of the intervention,
aflatoxin reduction strategies in LICs. relevant dimensions (see Fig. 8.3): in terms of both adverse health
Many other factors are important, intervention characteristics, delivery and environmental effects and risk
including the technical feasibility of the characteristics, government capacity, associated with inappropriate use;
intervention, which is described next. and usage characteristics. Each of and (iv) the ease of storage and
these is discussed below. transportation of the intervention.
6. Technical feasibility of In considering safety, it is important
interventions to control 6.1 Intervention to recognize that implementing certain
mycotoxins characteristics mycotoxin control interventions in LICs
may result in health or environmental
The cost-effectiveness of a myco- What aspects of the intervention risks that would be less likely to occur
toxin control strategy is not enough to itself make it more or less feasible in developed countries. Items to be
ensure its successful adoption in the for large-scale adoption? Gericke considered include occupational haz-
parts of the world where it is needed. et al. (2005) pointed out that one of ards associated with producing or
More questions must be addressed. the most important aspects of the implementing the intervention, health
CHAPTER 8

Does the strategy entail countervailing feasibility of an intervention, once risks to workers, quality control of
health or environmental risks? What it has been proven to have some production and application, immune
would the delivery mechanism be, and level of efficacy in a field or clinical status of the target population, local
would local infrastructures support trial, is that it has the potential to ecologies, and potential side-effects
that mechanism? Do governmental be implemented on a much larger of dietary interventions (Wu and
regulations inhibit or promote the inter- scale. This is crucial both spatially Khlangwiset, 2010b).

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 127


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions
6.2 Delivery characteristics be adopted broadly in a region. If, challenges in implementing the
for example, regulations have been intervention – challenges in terms of
How will a particular intervention enacted against genetically modified human resource needs; equipment,
be delivered to a target population? organisms, certain food additives, or technology, and transportation require-
First, the target population must be certain chemical or microbial agents, ments; financial aid; and user adoption
identified, which can be a challenge then particular interventions related to constraints. Feasibility analyses can
in countries where food is grown agriculture and food safety cannot be indicate research and development
in smallholdings. Communication implemented on a scale that achieves priorities to increase the likelihood of
of a need to those able to respond widespread public health benefits adopting interventions that can improve
may pose difficulties. In addition, (Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010b). public health and market outcomes
there are requirements for facilities, (Wu and Khlangwiset, 2010b).
transportation, human resources, and 6.4 Usage characteristics
communication (Gericke et al., 2005). 7. Conclusions
Proper facilities are necessary to store Generally, the more readily a target
and to administer the intervention and population can use or adopt an For developed countries, it is relatively
must be distributed widely enough intervention, the more likely it is to be easy to estimate the cost to human
within the target population so that most adopted with a frequency that actually society of mycotoxins as well as to
people have reasonably easy access makes a difference to public health assess the cost-effectiveness and
to the intervention. Transportation (i.e. long-term use) and the more likely technical feasibility of interventions
may necessitate specific infrastructure people are to adopt it (i.e. breadth of to control them. This is because the
(e.g. cold storage in vehicles for use). Gericke et al. (2005) identified costs of mycotoxins and the benefits
vaccines, and power to maintain cold three crucial dimensions of usage: (i) of interventions are largely restricted
temperatures). Transportation issues the ease of usage; (ii) the pre-existing to the marketplace; human health
may also make a significant difference demand for the intervention; and (iii) effects can largely be considered
in cost if the intervention needs to the risk of diminished effectiveness negligible. Moreover, in developed
be imported rather than produced and efficiency because of illicit trade countries, the feasibility of mycotoxin
locally. Human resources and activities, such as counterfeit products. control becomes an issue only if the
communication are crucial when the Ease of usage includes the need for intervention is extremely expensive,
public, or any subgroup thereof (such consumer information and education or in which case another, less expensive
as farmers or food storage handlers), training on how to use the mycotoxin intervention is usually available.
must be educated on proper use of the control strategy effectively and safely. For LICs, including the impact of
intervention and why it is important for If no pre-existing demand exists for mycotoxins on human health results
health and economic reasons. the intervention, adoption might be in much more complicated economic
more difficult and would require more analyses. Health economic tools from
6.3 Government capacity time. Finally, illicit trade activities can the past two decades have improved
pose dangers, especially in the case of the ability to place monetized values on
How would national or local gov- dietary interventions. human health effects. This, in turn, aids
ernments either support or inhibit Understanding constraints on the cost-effectiveness analysis because
adoption of the intervention? Govern- feasibility of mycotoxin control inter- the monetary cost of interventions
mental financial support and other ventions helps scientists and policy- can be compared with the human
resource support, such as staff makers to think beyond efficacy, health benefits of implementing the
support and outreach activities, would and even beyond material costs. For interventions. Evaluating the technical
be crucial for at least the start-up interventions to succeed in LICs, feasibility of interventions is still
phase of an intervention. Moreover, governments, scientists, international complex because the many impeding
governmental regulations can deter- organizations, farmers, and consumers factors and external risks and benefits
mine whether an intervention can must work collaboratively to overcome need to be considered.

128
References

Cardwell KF, Desjardins A, Henry SH et al. Liu Y, Wu F (2010). Global burden of aflatoxin- WHO (1998). Aflatoxins. In: Safety Evaluation
(2001). Mycotoxins: The Cost of Achieving induced hepatocellular carcinoma: a risk of Certain Food Additives and Contaminants:
Food Security and Food Quality. St Paul, assessment. Environ Health Perspect, 118:818– Prepared by the Forty-ninth Meeting of the Joint
MN: American Phytopathological Society. 824. doi:10.1289/ehp.0901388 PMID:20172840 FAO/WHO Expert Committee on Food Additives
Available at http://www.apsnet.org/publications/ (JECFA). Geneva: World Health Organization
apsnetfeatures/Pages/Mycotoxins.aspx. Liu Y, Chang CC, Marsh GM, Wu F (2012). (WHO Food Additives Series, No. 40). Available at
Population attributable risk of aflatoxin- http://www.inchem.org/documents/jecfa/jecmono/
CAST (2003). Mycotoxins: Risks in Plant, related liver cancer: Systematic review and v040je16.htm.
Animal, and Human Systems. Ames, IA: Council meta-analysis. Eur J Cancer, 48:2125–2136.
for Agricultural Science and Technology (Task doi:10.1016/j.ejca.2012.02.009 PMID:22405700 WHO (2001). Macroeconomics and Health:
Force Report No. 139). Investing in Health for Economic Development.
Lubulwa ASG, Davis JS (1994). Estimating Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics
FAO (2004). Worldwide Regulations for the social costs of the impacts of fungi and and Health. Geneva: World Health Organization.
Mycotoxins in Food and Feed in 2003. Rome: aflatoxins in maize and peanuts. In: Highley E,
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Wild CP, Gong YY (2010). Mycotoxins and human
Wright EJ, Banks HJ, Champ BR, eds. Stored
Nations (FAO Food and Nutrition Paper No. 81). disease: a largely ignored global health issue.
Product Protection, Proceedings of the 6th
Carcinogenesis, 31:71–82. doi:10.1093/carcin/
Gericke CA, Kurowski C, Ranson MK, Mills A International Working Conference on Stored-
bgp264 PMID:19875698
(2005). Intervention complexity–a conceptual Product Protection, 17–23 April 1994, Canberra,
framework to inform priority-setting in health. Australia. Wallingford, UK: CAB International, Wu F (2004). Mycotoxin risk assessment for
Bull World Health Organ, 83:285–293. pp. 1017–1042. the purpose of setting international regulatory
PMID:15868020 standards. Environ Sci Technol, 38:4049–4055.
Meenakshi JV, Johnson N, Manyong VM et al. doi:10.1021/es035353n PMID:15352440
Gong YY, Cardwell K, Hounsa A et al. (2002). (2007). How Cost-Effective is Biofortification in
Dietary aflatoxin exposure and impaired growth Combating Micronutrient Malnutrition? An Ex- Wu F (2008). A tale of two commodities: how
in young children from Benin and Togo: cross ante Assessment. Washington, DC: HarvestPlus EU mycotoxin regulations have affected food
sectional study. BMJ, 325:20–21. doi:10.1136/ (HarvestPlus Working Paper No. 2). industries. World Mycotox J, 1:95–102.
bmj.325.7354.20 PMID:12098724
Stein AJ, Sachdev HPS, Qaim M (2008). Genetic Wu F, Khlangwiset P (2010a). Health economic
Groopman JD, Kensler TW, Wild CP engineering for the poor: golden rice in public health impacts and cost-effectiveness of aflatoxin reduc-
(2008). Protective interventions to prevent in India. World Dev, 36:144–158. doi:10.1016/j. tion strategies in Africa: case studies in biocontrol
aflatoxin-induced carcinogenesis in de- worlddev.2007.02.013 and postharvest interventions. Food Addit Contam
veloping countries. Annu Rev Public Part A Chem Anal Control Expo Risk Assess,
Health, 29:187–203. doi:10.1146/annurev. Strosnider H, Azziz-Baumgartner E, Banziger 27:496–509. doi:10.1080/19440040903437865
publhealth.29.020907.090859 PMID:17914931 M et al. (2006). Workgroup report: public health PMID:20234965
strategies for reducing aflatoxin exposure in
Havelaar A (2007). Methodological Choices Wu F, Khlangwiset P (2010b). Evaluating the
developing countries. Environ Health Perspect,
for Calculating the Disease Burden and Cost- technical feasibility of aflatoxin risk reduc-
114:1898–1903. doi:10.1289/ehp.9302
of-illness of Foodborne Zoonoses in European tion strategies in Africa. Food Addit Contam
PMID:17185282
Countries. Bilthoven, Netherlands: Med-Vet- Part A Chem Anal Control Expo Risk Assess,
Net, Network for the Prevention and Control of Vardon P, McLaughlin C, Nardinelli C (2003). 27:658–676. doi:10.1080/19440041003639582
Zoonoses (EU Report No. 07–002). Potential economic costs of mycotoxins in the PMID:20455160
United States. In: Mycotoxins: Risks in Plant, Wu F, Liu Y, Bhatnagar D (2008). Cost-
Henry SH, Bosch FX, Troxell TC, Bolger PM Animal, and Human Systems. Ames, IA: Council
(1999). Policy forum: public health. Reducing effectiveness of aflatoxin control methods:
for Agricultural Science and Technology (Task economic incentives. Toxin Reviews, 27:203–225.
liver cancer–global control of aflatoxin. Force Report No. 139), pp. 136–142. doi:10.1080/15569540802393690
Science, 286:2453–2454. doi:10.1126/
science.286.5449.2453 PMID:10636808

CHAPTER 8

Chapter 8. Economics of mycotoxins: 129


evaluating costs to society and cost-effectiveness of interventions

You might also like