You are on page 1of 17

Unemployment and Crime Rates in the Post-World War II United States: A Theoretical and

Empirical Analysis
Author(s): David Cantor and Kenneth C. Land
Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 50, No. 3 (Jun., 1985), pp. 317-332
Published by: American Sociological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2095542 .
Accessed: 10/12/2014 12:49

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
American Sociological Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENT AND CRIME RATES IN THE POST-WORLD
WAR II UNITED STATES: A THEORETICAL
AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS*
DAVID CANTOR KENNETH C. LAND
Bureau of Social Science Research University of Texas at Austin

Using annual time-series data for the United States, 1946-1982, two hypotheses are
tested: (1) The level of the unemployment rate in any given year will have a negative
partial contemporaneous effect on detrendedfluctuations (increases or decreases) in
seven Index Crime rates (homicide, rape, aggravated assault, robbery, burglary,
larceny-theft, and motor vehicle theft) in that year. (2) Unemployment-rate
fluctuationsfrom one year to the next will have a positive partial effect on detrended
crime-rate fluctuations in the next year. These hypotheses are developed from a
theoretical model that identifies the former with a criminal opportunity effect, and
the latter with a criminal motivation effect, of aggregate unemployment on crime.
For burglary, robbery and larceny-theft, empirical support is found for the expected
pattern of partial effects. However, the relative sizes of the effects are such that the
total impacts of unemployment-through both partial effects-are negative. In
addition, only the negative-levels effect is exhibited for homicide and motor vehicle
theft, while rape and aggravated assault show no consistent association with either
levels orfluctuations in the unemployment rate. Interpretations for these findings are
discussed.

Does aggregate unemployment have a posi- unemployment rates on crime rates. Then,
tive, negative, or null effect on levels of crime using annual time-series data on the post-
in capitalist societies? This question is cen- World War II United States, we estimate and
trally important both to the construction of study the numericalimplicationsof this model.
sociological theories of crime and to the for- Before describingthe development, identifica-
mulation of social policy (U.S. Congress, tion and estimationof our model, however, we
1978). Accordingly, the unemployment-crime examine, in somewhat more detail, the results
relationship (hereafter denoted the U-C re- of recent empirical research.
lationship) has been the object of much re-
search attentionin sociology and related social
sciences. Yet this research has failed to pro- RECENT STUDIES OF THE
duce consensus about the direction of the re- U-C RELATIONSHIP
lationship: some studies find a positive U-C The existence of a strong relationshipbetween
effect, others conclude that the effect is nega- unemploymentand crime rates has been hy-
tive, and still others infer that the relationship pothesized for over a hundredyears in the so-
is essentially null. cial science literature(see, e.g., Bonger, 1916;
In this paper, we reexamineand clarify the Ehrlich, 1975; Ferri, 1881; Fleischer, 1966;
structureof the U-C relationship.To account Glaser and Rice, 1959; Phillips et al., 1972;
for the generally weak and often inconsistent Sellin, 1937;Thomas, 1925). Much of the cur-
findingsin the empiricalliterature,we develop rent interest in the U-C relationshipwas stim-
a theoreticalmodel that incorporatestwo dis- ulated by Brenner's(1971, 1976, 1978a, 1978b)
tinct and counterbalancingstructuraleffects of studies of the social consequences of national
economic policy. Brennerdraws upon several
traditionsof criminogenictheory to predict a
*Direct all correspondenceto: Kenneth C. Land, positive U-C connection, but the basic idea of
Population Research Center, 1800 Main Building, his approachis that an individual'sinabilityto
University of Texas, Austin, TX 78712. maintain a particularstandard of living as a
The researchreportedhere was supportedin part consequence of becoming unemployed will
by National Science Foundation Grant SES 81- cause a (rationalor irrational)reaction in the
04746andin partby the IC2Institute,The University
of Texas at Austin. However, the conclusionsdo not form of a criminalact. To test this proposition,
necessarily represent the views of the sponsoring Brenner(1976)studies the temporaldependen-
organizations. We are grateful to Lawrence E. cies of homicide rates and prison admissions
Cohen and anonymous referees for helpful com- (for various crimes) on three macroeconomic
ments on earlier versions of this paper. variables: (a) the unemploymentrate, (b) the
American Sociological Review, 1985, Vol. 50 (June:317-332) 317

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
318 AMERICANSOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
Gross National Productper capita, and (c) the ploymentrate is viewed as signalinga decrease
ConsumerPrice Index. Each of the three vari- in the economic status of a segment of the
ables is used as an index of macroeconomic population,one would expect, all other things
activity towardswhich nationalpolicies are di- being equal, a correspondingincreasein crime.
rected, namely, fluctuations in employment At best, however, econometric tests provide
levels, economic growth, and the rate of infla- ratherthin supportfor the hypothesized posi-
tion. All statisticalestimationwas done under tive effect. For instance, in his controversial
the assumption of polynomial (quadratic) study of U. S. trends in homicide and capital
distributed-lagrelationshipsover 5-yearlag pe- punishment, Ehrlich (1975) found a positive
riods between the economic indicators and effect of the unemployment rate on the
crime. This resultsin such conclusions as that, homicide rate. However, when controllingfor
for the period 1940-73, ". . . a one percent trends in gun ownershipin his reassessmentof
increase in the unemploymentrate sustained Ehrlich's study, Kleck (1979) concluded that
over a periodof six years has been associated this relationshipis statisticallyinsignificant.
... with [an increase] of approximately 648 Other time-series studies also tend to find
homicides . . ." (Brenner, 1976:5). thatthe U-C relationshipis weakerthanwould
The validity of this inference can be ques- be expected on the basis of utilitarianand most
tioned, however. For instance, Cohen and Fel- extant conventionaltheories of criminalmoti-
son (1979a)criticize Brenner(1976)for failing vation. For instance, Land and Felson (1976)
to control for noneconomic variables (e.g., conclude that the effect of the unemployment
changes in age structure) that affect crime rate on the violent crime rate is null, while the
rates, and they point to evidence of autocorre- effect for the property crime rate is weakly
lated errorterms in Brenner'sanalyses in sup- positive. Similarly,both Danzigerand Wheeler
port of this charge of misspecification. Bren- (1975)and Cohen et al. (1980)find weak nega-
ner's results seem even more sensitive to his tive effects for robberies and strong positive
lag specification. His second-degree polyno- effects for burglaries, but the latter inves-
mial, distributed-lagformulationincludes both tigatorsconclude that the impacton motor ve-
coincident (same year) and lagged effects of hicle theft is strong and negative, while the
unemploymenton crimefor lags of one through formerinfera weak negativeeffect for assault.
five years. With average durations of U. S.
economic recessions since 1940 being about A COMPLETESTRUCTURALMODEL
two years, it is entirely possible that the OF THE U-C RELATIONSHIP
summedeffects (over all six years) reportedby
Brennerconfoundan initialnegative impactof The very pervasivenessand persistenceof this
unemployment on crime rates with a sub- findingof weak, and often negative, U-C re-
sequent surge in crime due to recovery from lationshipssuggests that this fact itself should
recession (and the associated lower unem- be an importantobject of explanation.Why, in
ployment rates). This would be the case, for the presence of theories that predicta positive
example, if the estimated polynomial, U-C connection, do the empiricalstudies not
distributed-lagstructuresshow a negative ef- consistently support this expectation? In our
fect for the coincident and one-year-lagterms view, the answer is that traditional
followedby increasinglypositiveeffects for the criminogenic theories are incomplete structural
second- and higher-order lag terms. The characterizationsof the effects of unemploy-
applicabilityof this interpretationcannot be ment on crime, because they concentrateonly
determined,however, because Brennerreports on the effects of the unemploymentrate on the
only the summed effects. prevalence of motivated offenders in the
A second majorstimulusto recent research population.As Cohenand Felson (1979b)have
on the U-C relationshiphas been the devel- noted, however, the production of con-
opment, duringthe past decade and a half, of ventionalcrimes requiresthe presence of both
neoclassical macroeconomic models of (1) motivatedoffendersand (2) suitabletargets
crime-following Becker's (1968) seminal (individualsor their property) in (3) the ab-
theoretical analysis. While contemporary sence of effective guardians.2Thus, a complete
utilitarianapproachesto criminalbehaviorare
quite diverse, they essentially argue that the For a moredetailedreview of the time series and
lower one's economic status, the greater the cross-sectional literatureon the U-C relationship,
gains from illegitimate activity relative to see Long and Witte(1981).Suffice it to say here that
there is not much more consensus on the algebraic
legitimateactivity and the lower the perceived signof the relationshipamongcross-sectionalstudies
costs, through sanctions, if one is unsuc- than among time-series studies.
cessful at illegitimate activity (Block and 2 Cohen and Felson (1979b:589)state that these
Heinecke, 1975;Heinecke, 1978;Orsagh,1981: three elements necessarilyare present in the occur-
169). Accordingly, if an increase in the unem- rence of direct-contactpredatoryviolations, which

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENT AND CRIME RATES 319

structuralexplanationof the effects of unem- lationshipnecessarily must be viewed as prob-


ployment on crime must incorporateboth the abilistic.4To be more specific, consider a con-
impact on criminal motivation and the situa- tinuum of low to high motivation to commit
tional impact on the likelihood of motivated criminal offenses. Array the members of a
offenders interacting with ineffectively populationalong this continuumaccording to
guarded,suitabletargets. In other words, such their levels of such motivation. Then each of
an explanation must conjoin criminal- the theories cited in the preceding paragraph
motivation theories that relate unemployment leads to the assertion that, all other things
to the prevalenceof potentialoffenders in the being equal, an increase in the unemployment
population with criminal-opportunity theories rate producesa shift in the density distribution
that.relate unemploymentto the victim prone- of the populationalong this continuumtowards
ness of potential crime targets. its higher end. Thus, the central tendency
Many conventional criminogenic theories (mean, median) of the motivationdensity will
are motivationallyfocused, in that their main have shifted upward. Furthermore,if it is as-
objective is the explanationand identification sumed that the level of crime experienced by
of the forces that drive individuals toward the populationis an (unconditional)increasing
criminal a6ts. Causal mechanisms vary, of functionof the level of the centraltendency of
course, by type of theory. For example, strain this densitydistribution,then it follows thatthe
theories (e.g., Cloward and Ohlin, 1960; crime rate should increase.
Cohen, 1955;Merton, 1938)specify the causes Observethat this formulationdoes not assert
of crime and delinquency to be structurally that this upwardshift in the density distribution
induced frustrations resulting from the dis- is due solely to changes in motivationallevels
crepancy between aspirations and expecta- of individuals who are unemployed. Some
tions; utilitarian or rational-choice theory fraction of the density shift may be due to
(Becker, 1968;Block and Heinecke, 1975)em- individuals who, while not becoming unem-
phasizes an individual'srationalcalculationof ployed themselves, are nonetheless adversely
expectedcosts and benefits;conflict or Marxist impactedby economic downturns.5However,
theory (Bonger, 1916; Hughes and Carter, theories of crime have traditionally empha-
1981:10-11)dwells on the contradictionsbe- sized the motivationalprimacyof an individual
tween production and consumption in becomingunemployedrelative to the compos-
capitalist societies.3 Nonetheless, each of itionaleffect of groupeconomic hardship,even
these theories leads to the predictionthat the thoughaggregateindicators,such as the unem-
U-C relationship is positive (cf. Brenner, ployment rate, have been used in empirical
1978b:20-23). tests. Ourconcernwith the unemploymentrate
It shouldbe emphasized,however, that none is due to its correspondenceto aggregateeco-
of these theorieswould supportthe assertionof nomic activity patternsand the attentionit has
a deterministicU-C relationship,i.e., that be- garneredin previous research. The effects of
coming unemployed forces an individual to actually being unemployedon levels of crimi-
commit crimes. Rather, because, under the nal motivationare best tested when individual
same circumstancesthis would be the case for data are available for both offending and un-
some individuals but not for others, the re- employment (Thornberry and Christenson,
1984; Schmidt and Witte, 1984; Berk et al.,
1980).
are illegal acts in which someone definitely and in- Note that the unconditional impact of
tentionallytakes or damagesthe propertyof another
(followingGlaser, 1971:4),and in which there is di-
rect physical contact between at least one offender 4 It also should be noted that most criminogenic
andat least one personor object which that offender theoriesareorientedtowardthe explanationof crime
attempts to take or damage. Thus, this class of among the young. However, the unemploymentof
crimes includesthe conventionalFederal Bureauof parentsmay reduce the availabilityof financialsup-
Investigation Index Crimes-nonnegligible homi- portto juvenilechildrenwho thus may be morelikely
cide, forcible rape, aggravated assault, robbery, to engage in crime in order to recoup their losses.
motor vehicle theft, burglary, larceny-theft, and The indeterminatenessof this family multiplieref-
arson. Of these eight crimes, the last was added fect adds to the stochastic character of the U-C
in 1979.Therefore,only the first seven are amenable relationship.
to time-seriesanalyses. 5 Technically, this would require that the unem-
I Criminologycontains severalother criminogenic ployment rate for the population (i.e., the group
theories that lead to a positive U-C relationship. mean)have a positive impacton an individual'slevel
For instance,Hughes and Carter(1981:11-16)show of criminal motivation when the individual's em-
how labelingtheory (Becker, 1973) implies a posi- ployment status is controlled (Firebaugh, 1978).
tive U-C connection. Thornberryand Christenson Withonly aggregatedata, it is, of course, impossible
(1984)similarlyarguethat social-controltheory(e.g., to estimatethe relativesizes of the two effects. Thus,
Hirschi, 1969)implies a positive U-C relationship. the issue must be resolved theoretically.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
320 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
changes in the motivationdensity on crime is lower rates of concurrence of motivated of-
denied by recent criminal-opportunity fenders with ineffectively guarded, suitable
theories.6 Rather, as noted above, the latter property-crime targets, and hence, lower
assert that, for an increase in crime to occur, property-crimerates.
theremustbe an increasein the rateof physical Unlike property crimes, there is an exact
and temporal concurrence of motivated of- correspondence between the victims and
fenders with ineffectively guarded, suitable targets in all violent crimes (e.g.,, homicide,
targets for offenses. Thus, in recent criminal- rape, aggravatedassault). Consequently, the
opportunitytheories, it is the impactof unem- mainline of negativeinfluenceof levels of eco-
ployment on the rate of this concurrencethat nomic activity on violent crimes will be
determinesthe algebraicsign of the U-C con- throughthe types of situationsin which poten-
nection. tial crime victims will find themselves. Situa-
For crimeswith a propertycomponent(e.g., tions, in this context, refer to "who is involved
robbery,burglary,larceny-theft,motorvehicle ... , where the action is taking place and the
theft), this impact may be negative in two nature of the action or activities occurring"
ways. First, by removing some individuals (Monahanand Klassen, 1982:294).As noted in
from employment outside the household, a the precedingparagraph,a highunemployment
higher unemploymentrate may lead to an in- rate may lead to an increasedconcentrationof
creased concentration(in the population, on sustenance and leisure activities within such
the average) of sustenance and leisure activi- primary-grouplocations as homes and neigh-
ties within primary-group locations (resi- borhoods.
dences, neighborhoods),where individualsand This may lead to lower violent-crimerates,
their propertyare at reduced risks of victimi- because, contrary to the image promoted by
zation (Cohen et al., 1980:102).Second, as an the media and some social scientists, a sub-
indicatorwhose fluctuationsare roughlycoin- stantial fraction of violent crimes involve
cident with business cycles (Bober, 1968:48; causal acquaintances or strangers. For in-
Granger, 1980:144), a higher unemployment stance, victimization surveys indicate that
rate generally signals a general slowdown in about60o of the rapesand aggravatedassaults
production and consumption activities, both reported to the police involve total strangers
for employed and unemployedpersons. Thus, (computedfrom U. S. Departmentof Justice,
the unemploymentrate can be viewed as an 1981:44,77). The significanceof this statistic
index of total system activity, a lower level of derives from the fact that the empirical
which (i.e., a higherunemploymentrate) cor- analyses presented below necessarily must
responds to a lower rate of circulation of utilize data that are derivedfrom official police
people and property.7Both of these effects- reports.In the case of homicide, statisticsfor a
which may be termed the guardianship effect recentyear (1980;sources describedin the data
and the system activity effect, respectively- section below) show that 75.5%of all murders
lead to the inferencethat, all other thingsbeing were committed by a nonfamily member
equal, a higher unemploymentrate produces (26.4%), stranger (13.3%), or person(s) un-
known to the police (35.8%).Since murderby
close relation should be the easiest for the
6 Criminal-opportunity theory recently has been police to solve, many of the murdersby "un-
articulatedby Land and Felson (1976), Cohen and knowns" likely are committed by individuals
Felson (1979b),Cohenet al. (1980),and Cohenet al. unrelated to the victims. It also should be
(1981).However, these recentsystematicstatements noted that many violent crimes, especially
were preceded by a large body of descriptive and homicide,are the resultof propertycrimes (for
analytic evidence for the general proposition that robbery, see Kleck, 1979). Consequently, a
changes in crime rates are affected by changes in higher unemploymentrate may have an indi-
situational opportunities (see, e.g., Feeney and
Weir, 1973;Gibbons, 1971;Gould, 1969;Hindelang rect negative effect on violent crimes through
et al., 1978;Jackson, 1969;Mansfieldet al., 1974). lower property-crimerates.
7 This system-activity effect is essentially the In brief, there are two distinct and poten-
"businesscycle" effect studiedby sociologistsin the tially counterbalancingmechanisms-criminal
nineteenthand early twentiethcenturiespriorto the motivationand criminalopportunity-through
development of national unemployment statistics which unemploymentmay affect crime rates in
(see Vold, 1979:165-78,for a review). It is notewor- the aggregate.Most traditionalexplanationsof
thy, furthermore,that the more recent and relatively crime have emphasized the former, while re-
rigorous studies of this genre, such as Thomas's cent developments of criminal-opportunity
(1925) study of England and Wales for the period
1857-1913and Henryand Short's(1954)studyof the theory concentrate on the latter. Taken indi-
U.S. in the early twentiethcentury,generallyinfera vidually, however, each of these mechanisms
declinefor some types of crimesduringan economic constitutes an incomplete theory of the
downturn. structuralimpact of unemploymenton crime.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENTAND CRIME RATES 321
This situation can be represented in con- mated in empirical research is not the full
ventional path analysis diagram form, as in structuralmodel, representedby the solid ar-
Figure 1.8The upperhalf of the figurecontains rows of Figure 1, but ratherthe corresponding
the negative impact of unemployment on reducedform, indicatedby the dashed arrows.
criminal opportunity-through the guard- The reasons for this are very simple: the data
ianship and system-activity effects. The bot- necessary to estimate the full structuralmodel
tom half incorporates the positive criminal- simply do not exist. Because of obvious mea-
motivation effect postulated by the various surement problems, there are no national-
criminogenic theories cited earlier. Other sample surveys which contain the questions
exogenous factors (e.g., changes in age necessary to measure individuals' levels of
structure, lifestyles, etc.) also may affect the motivationto commit criminalacts, nor is the
opportunityand motivationconstructs, as in- data available to assess levels of criminalop-
dicatedin the figure. Finally, in orderto repre- portunities.9 Furthermore, it is difficult to
sent the possibility of direct relationshipsbe- think of meaningfulsurrogates.Consequently,
tween criminal opportunities and motivated the "criminal opportunity" and "criminal
offenders (e.g., as in victim-precipitated motivation" boxes in Figure 1 represent un-
crimes-see, e.g., Balkin and McDonald, measured, and essentially unmeasurable,
1981;Block, 1981), the figure incorporatesar- theoretical constructs, ratherthan operational
rows representingdirect effects between the variables.
two. In face of this data constraint,empiricalre-
searchers have proceeded by (1) ignoringone
or the other of the (opportunityand motiva-
Criminal
opportunity
_ 7
opportunty
tion) structuralrelationshipsand (2) collapsing
out the remainingtheoreticalconstruct. When
this is done, one obtains the reduced form of
the structuralmodel, indicatedin Figure 1 by
the dashed arrows. However, since the effect
U~~enp1~~yme~~t ? (?)
Rate - of unemploymenton crime in the reducedform
~~~~~~~~~~~~Rate Crime

combines two structural effects of opposite


algebraic sign, it is suppressed in absolute
value towardszero. This explainsthe generally
Other
weak U-C relationships found in empirical
\criminal
X Motivation
I
Moiato
studies. Furthermore,because the structural
Cr'mnal

-Pactors/ effects are counterbalancing,ratherthan rein-


forcing, it is quite possible for one reduced-
Figure 1. Path Diagramof StructuralRelationships form estimate of the U-C relationshipto be
and Reduced-Form Effects of Unem- positive while another is negative, depending
ploymenton Crime on the relative weight of the two structural
effects in the particulardata set and model
Notation:-denotes structuralrelationships specification under which each is produced.
-- denotes reduced-formrelationships This explains the indeterminateness of the
algebraicsigns of the empiricalU-C relation-
The structuralmodel representedin Figure ships estimated via the reduced form.
1 can now be used to explain the weak and
inconsistent U-C effects often found in em-
pirical studies. In brief, what is typically esti- PARTIALIDENTIFICATIONOF THE
U-C STRUCTURALEFFECTS
8 Causal relationships are represented by uni- At this point, it is clear that the structural
directional arrows; unanalyzed correlations (co- model diagrammedin Figure 1 is hopelessly
variances) among the predeterminedvariables are underidentifiedif it is maintained that both
denoted by two-headedarrows; epsilons represent structuraleffects of unemploymenton crime
randomerrorterms;and algebraicsigns (pluses and must be contemporaneous.But there is no rea-
minuses)indicatethe directionof the postulatedef- son why this must be assumed. On the con-
fects. Unlike the usual path model, however, the
model of Figure I is best conceived of as a condi- 9 While it has been shown that the risks of certain
tional, multiplicativemodel of the crime rate. That types of criminal victimization (assault, burglary,
is, following Cohen et al. (1980), we conceive of larceny-theft)as measured in the National Crime
motivatedoffendersand criminalopportunitieseach Surveys vary with criminal-opportuntty risk factors
as necessary, but not sufficient, conditions for (Cohen et al., 1981), risks themselves cannot be
crimes to occur. Thus, the model equation for the identifiedwith opportunitiesbecause the formerare
crime rate is a multiplicativepower function that the consequenceof the concurrentinteractionof op-
becomes linear in the logarithmof the crime rate. portunitiesand motivatedoffenders.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
322 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW

trary,thereis strongempiricaland institutional This suggests that the criminal-motivation


evidencethatthe two structuraleffects differin effects of unemployment are lagged. It is
the rapidity with which they have their im- doubtful, however, that the lagged effects ex-
pacts. tend as far back as specifiedby Brenner(1976).
In the case of the opportunitymechanism, Economic recessions in the U. S. since World
the impactsappearto be relativelyinstantane- War II generally have lasted only one to two
ous. As noted above, the unemploymentrate is years. While this is long enough to put severe
generallyconsideredto be a "coincident indi- financial stress on some individualsduring a
cator"with business cycles. It follows that an business downturn,many such individualswill
increase in this rate signals a concurrentde- be rehiredor otherwise recover economically
cline in total system activity. Furthermore, within two years after a recession begins."
such an increase likely will produce a concur- Thus, while the motivationaleffects of unem-
rent rise in the concentration of activities ploymentare lagged, they also are of relatively
within primary-group locations, as unem- short durationfor that fraction of the unem-
ployed individuals spend more time in their ployed populationthat is impactedby business
residences and residential neighborhoods cycles. 12
(Hyman, 1979). Thus, it can be expected that To operationalize these motivational im-
the opportunityimpacts of unemploymenton pacts, the level of unemploymentin one year
crime-through both the system activity and can be compared with that in the previous
guardianshipeffects-are contemporaneous. year. If the formeris higherthanthe latter, and
On the other hand, the criminal-motivation if this change in the level of employment re-
impactsof the economy seem less likely to be sults in a positive motivational impact on
contemporaneous.Of critical importancehere crime, then this shouldproduceupwardfluctu-
is the institutionalfact thatin modernindustrial ations in crime rates. Similarly,economic re-
societies, such as the U.S., economic hardship coveries and the associated declines in the un-
is cushioned by both institutionaland social employment rate should produce downward
supportsystems. Newly unemployedpersons perturbationsin crime rates.
usually are covered by government and/or In brief, the underidentificationof the model
union unemployment benefits for several diagrammedin Figure 1 can be attacked by
months after becoming unemployed. Further- distinguishingthe temporal order of its two
more, during relatively long economic slow- structuraleffects. Specifically, the foregoing
downs (as in 1981-1982),the durationof bene- discussion suggests that the effect of the level
fits may be extended by legislators. Other fi- of the unemploymentrate is relatively faster
nancialaid often is forthcomingfrom families, for the opportunitymechanismas comparedto
friends and charitableorganizations.Thus, it its motivational counterpart. In addition, in
cannot be argued that the financial stresses order to account for the length of the business
created by slowdowns in economic activity cycle, the motivationaleffect shouldbe asspci-
are likely to be so severe as to immediately ated with the size of fluctuationin the unem-
motivatepersons to commitcriminaloffenses. ployment rate ratherthan its level.
But, as benefits and other sources of financial It is still not possible to identifyand estimate
and psychological supportdecline and/or stop such structurallinkageon the model of Figure
during a recession, individualsmay be more 1 for two reasons. First, our hypothesis about
likely to engage in criminaloffenses.'0 the timing of each effect is in relative terms.
We are not proposingthat there are no motiva-
10
Space limitations preclude presentation of a tional or opportunity effects concurrent or
detailed summaryof the negative physical health, lagged to the business cycle. Rather, we are
mental health, psychological, and social conse- proposingthat the maximumeffects will occur
quences of unemploymenton unemployedindividu- under different timing schedules. By control-
als and theirfamilies. These deleteriouseffects have
been documentedin numerousstudiesdatingbackto
the GreatDepression(see, e.g., Aiken, 1968;Bakke, 11 The average duration of unemployment, as
1940;Cobb, 1974;Cohn, 1978;Gore, 1978;Jahodaet measuredby the U. S. Departmentof Labor,did not
al., 1933;Komarovsky, 1940). Suffice it to say that exceed 16 weeks during the post-World War II
these studiesdo not supportthe suppositionthat the period, 1946-78; for a detailed analysis of this
event of becomingunemployedhas a relativelycon- concept and its relation to business cycles, see
temporaneouscriminogeniceffect on an unemployed Akerloffand Main (1980).
individual'sbehavior. Rather, if such psychological 12 This is not to deny the existence of a large
consequencesas "increasingalienationfrom society population of chronically unemployed individuals
and its institutions"have criminogeniceffects on an who remain unemployedfor long periods of time.
unemployedindividual'sbehavior, it is likely that However, the crimininal-motivation impactof their
they, like the financial-stresseffects of unemploy- unemploymentstatus is accordinglyto be found in
ment, require substantialtime intervals to be ef- persistentand/orgrowinglevels of crime ratherthan
fected. in fluctuations.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENTAND CRIME RATES 323

ling for the differentiallag structure,therefore, This creates a potential discontinuity be-
we can at least partialout some of the motiva- tween pre- and post-1960 estimates. Hence,
tional effect and observe the signs of the con- there is a possibility that inferences from data
currentand lagged coefficients. Second, there analyses of these series may be sensitive to this
are still several unmeasuredconstructs. Con- discontinuity. In the case of the "larceny"
sequently, we can only partially identify: (a) category, moreover, this discontinuity was
the semi-reduced-formeffect throughthe op- made even more severe by a change in the
portunity construct and (b) the semi- UCR definitionin 1973from "larceniesof $50
reduced-formeffect through the motivational and over" to "larceny-theft."While the latter
construct.'3 In this sense, the model has be- definition has been applied in recent volumes
come partially identified. of the Uniform Crime Reports to produce a
consistent series of revised estimates back to
DATA 1960,there is a clear discontinuityat that point
because the "larceny-theft"definitionincludes
We will test this modelfor the post-World War a larger numberof crimes. Thus, we shall be
II U.S. for the Index crimes-nonnegligible particularlysensitive to the possibilitythat our
homicide, forcible rape, aggravated assault, analyses of the larceny series are affected by
robbery, motor vehicle theft, burglary and this definitional discontinuity. Furthermore,
larceny-theft-publishedin the FederalBureau for each of the seven Index Crime series, we
of Investigation's (FBI) Uniform Crime Re- examinethe extent to which the series exhibits
ports (UCR) and the revised series published a shift in level from 1959 to 1960.
by the Office of Management and Budget
(1974). In 1958 the UCR system instituted
major changes in the collection of their data MODELS AND METHODSOF
which make pre- and post-1958 data incom- STATISTICALANALYSIS
patible.14The OMB series accounts for this Ourreview of extant empiricalstudies suggests
discontinuityin ways consistent with the origi- that inferences about the U-C relationship
nal trend in the UCR (Cantor and Cohen, may be sensitive to two possible-"methodsef-
1980).Thus for the years 1946-1959,the crime fects." First, inferences may differ by type of
data analyzed herein were obtained from the crime studied and by whether trends in indi-
OMB publication. For the years 1960-1982, vidual crimes are analyzed separately or are
correspondingannualestimates for the first six groupedinto "violent," "property,"or "total"
Index Crimeswere obtainedfrom the most re- crime rates. Consequently, in order to ac-
cently revised estimates available in the UCR commodate possible differences in the U-C
publications.I5 structural relationships between crimes, we
13 Recall that path-analysisconventions state that
analyze each of the seven Index Crime time
series individually.
the semi-reduced-formeffect of variableA on vari- Second, inferences about the algebraicsign
able B consists of the sum of the directeffect of A on
B plus the indirecteffects throughcertain interven- of the U-C relationshipmay be conditionalon
ing variablesbetween A and B (see Duncan et al., the form and substance of the structural
1972:23-30,for a definitionof the concept of semi- equationsused in the estimation. Usually, the
reducedforms and effects). In the present case, the effects of unemployment-ratefluctuations on
model postulates no direct effect, and each of the crime rates are estimated in the context of
indirecteffects contains only two linkages. Conse- structuralequations that include several other
quently, the semi-reduced-formeffects are quite variables. Typically, the latter variables are
simple. chosen to accountfor secular changes in crime
14 It is not plausible that the trends and fluctua-
rates as opposed to the fluctuations around
tions in all of the Index Crime series for the post- secular trends in crime that unemployment
WorldWar II years can be accounted for solely by
administrativechanges in police departmentsand rates might explain.'6 However, the exact list
trends in crime reporting rates. For cogent
arguments to this effect, see Cohen et al. Table 2 of the following annual UCR publications:
(1980:94-96). Extendingthe analysis prior to 1946 1960-1966, UCR-1975; 1967, UCR-1976; 1968,
introducesproblemsassociated with separatingthe UCR-1977; 1969, UCR-1978; 1970, UCR-1979;
impacts of World War II on aggregate economic 1971, UCR-1980; 1972, UCR-1981; 1973-1982,
trends. In addition, Cantor and Cohen (1980) find UCR-1982.
that, in the case of homicide,the UCR data priorto 16 Variablesused by researchersto explainsecular
this periodare substantiallyaffectedby samplingand trends in crime include age composition of the
coverage problems. Since homicide is generally population(Wellford,1973),the proportionof young
consideredthe most reliablecrimemeasurecollected blackmalesin the populationandthe consumerprice
by the FBI, we do not feel analysis of any Index index (Fox, 1976), capital punishment (Ehrlich,
crime trend priorto 1946is warranted. 1973),residentialpopulationdensity and availability
'5 Data for each of the years were taken from of propertytargets (Cohen et al., 1980).

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
324 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
of such variablesusually differs from study to crease) in level); thirddifferencingeliminatesa
study, because different theories emphasize cubic trend; and so forth. All of the seven
different explanations of crime trends and Index Crimetime series studied herein exhibit
there is no single agreed-upontheory to deter- strongsecularincreasesin the 1960sand 1970s.
mine when the list is "complete." The conse- In some cases, they also show modest secular
quence is that variabilityin the specifications declines from the 1940sto the 1950s.This sug-
may be a source of variabilityin inferences gests thatfirst or second differencingshouldbe
about the U-C relationship.Furthermore,the sufficient to eliminatetrends in their levels.
emphasison findingthe optimalcombinationof In additionto long-termpatternsof increase
variablesto explain seculartrendsin crime de- and/ordecrease, it is possible that these series
tracts attention from estimationof the effects have moreyear-to-yearvariabilityat the higher
of unemploymenton crime. levels observed in recent years. A standard
To circumvent this, we adopt a statistical time-seriestechniquefor dealingwith trendsin
analysis strategythat eliminatesseculartrends the variabilityof a series as well as in its levels
in levels and variances from the seven Index is to log-transformthe series before differenc-
Crimetime series. Hence, inferencesaboutthe ing (cf. McClearyand Hay, 1980:48-53).As a
U-C structuraleffects based on our analyses check on the presence of this potential insta-
should be invariant'over all possible explana- bility in the Index Crime series, we adopt the
tions. procedurehereinof comparingresultsobtained
Our procedures can be described as fol- by differencing-onlyversus those obtained by
lows. 17 First, in order to eliminate secular log-transformingand then differencing.
trendsin levels of the Index Crimetime series, After eliminatingseculartrendsin levels and
we apply deterministicpolynomial difference possibly in variabilityfrom the Index Crime
filters (cf. McCleary and Hay, 1980:30-48). series, the residuals that remain represent
This is done by takingdifferencesof successive fluctuationsin each crime rate above or below
values of each series. For instance, if the value the seculartrend in its respective series. Since
of one of the Index Crimeseries at time (year)t the unemploymentseries is a cyclical series, it
is denoted by Ct, the value at time t- 1 (one is these fluctuationsthat unemploymentshould
year earlier)by Ct1, the value at time t-2 (two be associated with if the criminalopportunity
years earlier)by Ct2, andso forth,then the first and motivation effects described above are
differences of the'series are presentin the IndexCrimeseries. Accordingto
our earlier discussions, moreover, we expect
ACt Ct - Ct-1; (1) the former effect to produce a negative re-
lationshipbetween contemporaneousvalues of
second differences are defined by the unemploymentand detrended crime rate
A2Ct = A(ACt)= Ct -2Ct_1 +Ct-2; (2) series, while the latter should produce a posi-
tive association between fluctuations or
third differences are defined by changes in levels of unemployment(indexed
below by first-differencesin the unemployment
A3Ct = A(A2Ct) = Ct -3Ct- rate series) and detrendedcrime rates.'8
+ 3Ct-2 + Ct-3; (3) In order to determinewhether or not these
effects are exhibited in the detrended Index
and so forth. Crime rates, we estimate the following four
Generally,first differencingof a time series models for each of the seven series:
is sufficient to eliminatea linear secular trend
(increase or decrease in level); second dif- ACt = a + f31Ut+ I2AUt + Et; (4)
A2C = a + PAUt+ /32AUt+ Et; (5)
ferencing eliminates a quadratictrend (an in-
AlnCt = a + flnUt + /2A&nUt+ Et; (6)
crease (decrease) followed by a decrease (in- A21nCt= a + flnUt + f2A&nUt+ Et; (7)
17 To those readersfamiliarwith modernstatistical
18 A trivial algebraic manipulationshows that a
time-seriesanalysis procedures(see, e.g., Box and positive impactof changesin unemploymentlevels is
Jenkins, 1976;McClearyand Hay, 1980),these de- equivalent to a negative impact of unemployment
trendingprocedureswill be familiar.Our analyses laggedone year. Specifically,let Yt denote Ctor A2Ct
depart, however, from the conventional "Box- or their log-transformedequivalents.Then if 813< 0
Jenkins" ARIMA model-buildingprocedures after and 82 > 0,
detrending.In brief,we do not use correlogramsand
relatedtools to identifyplausibleclasses of modelsat Yt = a + PlUt + P2AUt + Et
that point. For one thing, our time series are too = a + glUt + 132 (Ut Ut-1) + Et
short to make that a reliablestrategy. Furthermore, = a + flUt + 162Ut- p2Ut-I + Et
the theoreticalargumentsgiven in the text are suffi- = a + (/31+132)Ut - 82Ut-l + Et,
ciently strong to lead to plausible models a priori,
and these should be subjectedto statisticaltest. as claimed.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENT AND CRIME RATES 325
Table 1. EstimatedCoefficientsand SummaryStatisticsfor the Effects of Unemploymenton CrimeRates
Panel A: Full Models
(df= 33, 32 for 1st and 2nd differencedequations, respectively)
DependentVariable Intercept Ut AUt DW R2
Murder 0.5614 -0.0936 0.0062 .7229a 0.0670
(First Difference) (2.0726)*** (1.8717)** (0.0928)
Murder* 0.3145 -0.0558 -0.0808 2.5302c 0.1452
(Second Difference) (1.3507) (1.3069) (1.4410)
Rape 0.7925 -0.0107 -0.2703 1.0412a 0.0211
(First Difference) (0.9991) (0.0738) (1.3877)
Rape* 0.3379 -0.0651 -0.2458 2.6400c 0.0349
(Second Difference) (0.4197) (0.4411) (1.2678)
Assault 6.7110 -0.1398 -0.1805 .9322a 0.0000
(First Difference) (1.4260) (0.1608) (0.1562)
Assault* 2.5633 -0.4758 -0.4031 2.5111c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.5540) (0.5609) (0.3617)
Robbery 23.519 -3.6401 4.7620 .8701a 0.1605
(First Difference) (3.0822)*** (2.5838)** (2.5413)**
Robbery* 20.975 -4.0080 1.3642 1.8659c 0.1371
(Second Difference) (2.5017)*** (2.6075)** (0.6755)
Burglary 134.50 -19.725 22.774 1.0449a 0.1403
(First Difference) (3.2288)*** (2.5649)** (2.2264)**
Burglary* 121.07 -23.510 9.0717 2.0516c 0.1428
(Second Difference) (2.5312)*** (2.6810)** (0.7875)
Auto Theft 39.860 -5.9379 0.3742 .9583a 0.1337
(First Difference) (2.9671)*** (2.3941)** (0.1134)
Auto Theft* 8.6023 -1.3330 -5.3405 2.3434c 0.0860
(Second Difference) (0.6312) (0.5334) (1.6268)**
Larceny-Theft* 145.33 -31.180 38.464 1.4612c 0.1979
(First Difference) (2.0704)*** (2.1566)** (2.1884)**
Larceny-Theft 149.96 -32.503 8.6505 1.7770c 0.0322
(Second Difference) (1.7321)*** (1.8670)** (0.4078)
Dummyfor Larceny-theft,First Difference:31.480 (t = .6531).

where Ct denotes the crime rate in year t, Ut In brief, if an Index Crime series exhibits a
denotes the unemploymentrate in year t, in linear seculartrendin levels but no trendin its
denotes the naturallogarithmtransformation, variability,then the residualsobtained by fit-
the first- and second-differenceoperators are ting the unlogged, first-differenced model of
as definedin equations(1) and (2), a, f31,and 12 equation (4) should exhibit less evidence of
are constantsto be estimated,and E is a zero- autocorrelationthan those that would be ob-
mean, constant variance, serially uncorrelated tained by fittingany of the other three models.
errorterm. Which of these alternativemodels Similarly, if the series contains a quadratic
"best fits" a crime rate series depends on the trend in levels but no trend in variability,the
type of variabilitythe series exhibits. By "best unlogged, second-differencedmodel of equa-
fits," we mean that alternative of models tion (5) should produce residuals with little
(4)-(7) which producesresidualsthat are most evidence of autocorrelation.By comparison,if
consistent with the white-noise specification
on the error term. This, of course, must be
also be noted that the Durbin-Watsontest can detect
assessed by computinga suitabletest statistic. only first-orderserial correlation of disturbances.
Because none of models (4)-(7) contains a Consequently,its use leaves open the possibilitythat
stochastic laggeddependentvariable,the con- the residualsof our estimatedequationscontain un-
ventional Durbin-Watsontest for autocorre- detected higher-orderdependencies. Based on the
lated disturbancesis suitable for this purpose computationof Box-JenkinsQ-statistics (Box and
(cf. Johnston, 1972:250-54).'9 Jenkins, 1976)for various higher-orderlags of the
residual correlations,we find no evidence for this
'9 Takingfirst differences,for example, is equiva- possibility for six of the seven Index crimes. The
lent to settingthe coefficientof the laggeddependent exception is larceny-theft,which has significantcor-
variable in a stochastic first-differencedequation relationsof residualsat lags 2, 3 and 5. Given the
equal to one. Since this is done a priori,there is no measurementproblems and discontinuitiesof this
coefficient to estimate and hence no stochastic series, however, we are not willing to rush to a
lagged dependent variable, as required for strict substantiveinterpretationof what may be a statisti-
applicabilityof the Durbin-Watsontest. It should cal anomaly.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
326 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 1. Continued
Panel B: ContemporaneousEffect RestrictedModels
(df= 34, 33 for 1st and 2nd differencedequations, respectively)
DependentVariable Intercept Ut DW R2
Murder 0.5500 -0.0912 .7308a .0942
(First Difference) (2.3276)*** (2.1542)**
Murder* 0.4718 -0.0874 2.2940C .1173
(Second Difference) (2.2575)*** (2.3495)**
Rape 1.3054 -0.1146 0.9415a 0.0000
(First Difference) (1.8350)*** (0.8983)
Rape* 0.8164 -0.1613 2.5188c 0.0172
(Second Difference) (1.1376) (1.2627)
Assault 7.0535 -0.2092 0.9137a 0.0000
(First Difference) (1.7187)*** (0.2842)
Assault* 3.3480 -0.6336 2.4648c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.8303) (0.8825)
Robbery 14.484 -1.8098 1.1389a 0.0256
(First Difference) (1.9913)*** (1.3875)**
Robbery* 18.319 -3.4742 2.0094c 0.1513
(Second Difference) (2.4944)*** (2.6571)**
Burglary 91.290 -10.972 1.3108b 0.0403
(First Difference) (2.3441)*** (1.5711)**
Burglary* 103.41 -19.960 2.1923c 0.1526
(Second Difference) (2.4619)*** (2.6691)**
Auto Theft 39.150 -5.7941 0.9705a 0.1589
(First Difference) (3.3424)*** (2.7585)**
Auto Theft* 18.988 -3.4231 2.1888c 0.0404
(Second Difference) (1.5401) (1.5587)**
Larceny-Theft* 71.662 -13.816 1.3745b 0.1050
(First Difference) (1.1019) (1.0826)
Larceny-Theft 133.12 -28.644 1.7804c 0.0565
(Second Difference) (1.7726)*** (1.9863)**
Dummyfor Larceny-theft,First Difference: 101.40 (t = 2.4557).
Dummyfor Larceny-theft,Second Difference:27.409 (t = 0.5901).

the crime series combines either a linear or a A reports the results of applyingthe full ver-
quadratictrendin levels with a secularincrease sions of the unlogged alternative models (4)
(or decrease) in variability, then the log- and (5)'21 Those equationsthat are considered
transformed, first-differenced and log-
transformed, second-differenced models of were made specific to subpopulationswith high of-
equations(6) and (7), respectively, shouldpos- fense rates-say, males age 15-29. However, since
sess residuals with the least evidence of au- time trends in the generaland group-specificunem-
tocorrelation. Our choice of the best-fitting ploymentrates are highly correlated,this change in
equation is based on that which has a the definitionof the unemploymentvariableswould
mainlyaffectthe size of the regressioncoefficientsof
Durbin-Watsontest statistic indicatingno au-
equations (4)-(7), not their statistical significance.
tocorrelationof disturbancesand is the most 21 The correspondinglogged versions (6) and (7)
parsimonious (i.e., has the fewest trans-
formations). produced similar substantive results. The primary
differenceswere: (1) the logged second-differenced
version for homicide did not have a significant
RESULTS negative contemporaneouscoefficient; (2) the fluc-
tuationtermfor the first-differencedversionfor rape
Numerical results from application of the was significantlynegative;(3) the fluctuationterm in
foregoing models to the seven Index Crime the first-differencedversion of larceny drops to in-
series, 1946-1982,are given in Table 1.20 Panel significance;(4) the contemporaneousterm in the
second-differencedversion of larceny was not sig-
20 The annual average unemployment rate and nificantlynegative;and (5) the first-differencedver-
changes thereinused in the estimationof equations sions of the rape and assault equationsborderedon
(4)-(7) are taken from annual governmentpublica- having an acceptable Durbin-Watsonstatistic (rape
tions (1946-1979 from U.S. Departmentof Labor, = 1.36 and assault = 1.31, which are both in the
1980,TableA-1; 1980-1982fromExecutive Officeof indeterminaterange for the one percent level of
the President,1984,Table B-29). It mightbe thought significance).The significanceof the coefficients in
that the relationshipsmodeled in equations (4)-(7) these equations, however, did not indicateany sub-
would be stronger if the unemploymentvariables stantialchange in the conclusions stated below.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENT AND CRIME RATES 327
Panel C: Lagged Effect Restricted Models
(df= 34, 33 for 1st and 2nd differenced equations, respectively)
Dependent Variable Intercept AUt DW R2
Murder 0.0704 -0.0575 .7967a .0000
(First Difference) (1.0072) (0.9702)
Murder* 0.0196 -0.1185 2.4587c .1269
(Second Difference) (0.3377) (2.4374)**
Rape , 0.7364 -0.2776 1.0451 a 0.0497
(First Difference) (3.7852)*** (1.6829)
Rape* -0.0062 -0.2898 2.6129c 0.0585
(Second Difference) (0.0318) (1.7642)**
Assault 5.9777 -0.2756 0.9443a 0.0000
(First Difference) (5.1775)*** (0.2815)
Assault* 0.0486 -0.7245 2.5047c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.0430) (0.7660)
Robbery 4.4232 2.2868 0.9899a 0.0204
(First Difference) (2.1556)*** (1.3145)
Robbery* -0.2089 -1.3430 1.9151c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.0930) (0.7151)
Burglary 31.020 9.3616 1.1366a 0.0000
(First Difference) (2.7727)*** (0.9869)
Burglary* -3.1890 -6.8078 2.0130c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.2476) (0.6323)
Auto Theft 8.7097 -3.6635 0.9984a 0.0131
(First Difference) (2.4402)*** (1.3106)
Auto Theft* 1.5571 -6.2408 2.3511c 0.1058
(Second Difference) (0.4674) (2.2409)**
Larceny-Theft* 7.1031 17.662 1.3826c 0.1083
(First Difference) (0.2355) (1.1407)
Larceny-Theft 1.8446 12.877 1.7470c 0.0000
(Second Difference) (0.0512) (0.6967)
Dummy for Larceny-theft, First Difference: 82.176 (t=2.1817).
Dummy for Larceny-theft, Second Difference: -6.2908 (t=0.1388).
Note: Estimates are OLS metric coefficients; figures in parentheses are t-ratios calculated from the
coefficients divided by their standard errors; df=degrees of freedom; R2 = squared multiple correlation
coefficient corrected for degrees of freedom; DW = Durbin-Watson autocorrelation test statistic.
a Reject the null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation of disturbances at a = .01.
b
Durbin-Watson test for autocorrelation disturbances is inconclusive at a=.01.
e Fail to reject the null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation of disturbances at a=.01.
* Denotes preferred equations.
** Significantly nonzero at a=.10, one-tailed test.
Significantly nonzero at a=.10, two-tailed test.

the best fitting,accordingto the above criteria, The finalequationswere chosen primarilyon
are starred.In order to ascertainthe extent to the basis of evidence of no autocorrelation,as
which the final coefficients may be spuriously indicated by the DW statistic. The first-
influencedby collinearity between the unem- differenced version for larceny and the
ployment and unemployment-changeseries, second-differencedversion for all the other
we also report the restricted models corre- crimes meet our criteria of displaying no au-
spondingto each of the equations in Panels B tocorrelation.Hence, it can be inferredthat the
and C.22 statistical relationshipsreported in these ver-
sions are not "spuriousregressions"(Granger
22
An examination of the data-series discon- and Newbold, 1974) and it is meaningfulto
tinuitiesat the 1960splicingdate noted earlierin the interpretthe starredequations substantively.
text revealedthat there is a change in level only for
the larceny-theftseries. Consequently,we estimated larcenies). Consequently, for the first-differenced
the larceny-theftmodels with a dummy variableto series, we substitutedthe observed mean first dif-
controlfor the changein level from 1959'andearlier ference after the 1960-1959differencefor use in the
to 1960andafter.The correspondingcoefficientsare regression. For the second-differencedseries, the
statisticallysignificantand are given in the footnotes observed mean of (C,) before the 1960-1959 dif-
of Table 1. Applying the transformations(4)-(7) ference was used for the 1960-1959difference.The
combines the discontinuousjump in larcen'-theft observed mean of (Ctl) after the 1960-1959 dif-
between 1959-1960in an illogicalway (i.e.. larcenies ference was used for the 1960-1959 difference for
of $50 and over, while 1960 and beyond is for all (C t-l-

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
328 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
In orderto measurethe degree of statistical A similarpatternemerges for burglary.The
significance of the relationships reported in first-differencedversion shows signs of sig-
Table 1, we reportboth t-statisticsfor the esti- nificantpositive and negativeeffects, while the
mated coefficients and multiple correlation preferred version only exhibits a significant
coefficients (correctedfor degrees of freedom) negative effect. A comparisonof the full first-
for the equations. The latter are smaller than differenced version shown in Panel A with
those often obtained in time-series analyses, those of the restrictedmodels in Panels B and
because seculartime trends (which usually ac- C suggests that the strengths of the negative
count for the sizeable R2s in time-series contemporaneousand positive fluctuation ef-
analyses) have been removed from the crime fects are suppressedwhen each is estimatedby
rates. Since the degrees of freedominvolved in itself.
the estimationof the relationshipsreportedin Unlike the effects of criminalmotivation, a
Table 1 are relatively modest, we use a = .10 negative contemporaneouseffect is indicated
as a criterionfor statistical significanceof the for all crimesexcept rapeand assault. It should
regressioncoefficients. For df = 32, 33, this be noted that this resultholds whetherthe first-
requirest-values greaterthan 1.309, 1.308, re- or second-differencedversion is selected. In-
spectively, for a one-tailedtest. In those cases spection of only the preferredequations shows
in which the coefficients have an algebraicsign a significantnegative contemporaneouseffect
opposite to that expected on the basis of our for murder, robbery, burglary, and larceny.
theoretical arguments, we use the corre- The staffed equationfor auto theft indicates a
spondingtwo-tailedtest, for which the df = 32, lagged negative effect, and inspection of the
33 criticalvalues are 1.695and 1.693.The latter restrictedequations in Panels B and C shows
test also is applied to the intercepts of the some suppression of the negative contem-
equations,for which we have made no specific poraneous effect.
directionalpredictions. The stronglaggedopportunityeffect for auto
The empiricalestimates in Table 1 provide theft might, in part, be the result of the associ-
mixed supportfor our theoreticalexpectations. ation between economic activity and the de-
The expected combinationof a negative con- mand for automobiles and auto parts. As the
temporaneous(criminalopportunity)and posi- demandfor new vehicles increases duringeco-
tive fluctuation (lagged criminal motivation) nomic recovery, there will likely be an
effect of unemploymenton crime rates shows eventual increase in the illegal demand for
up most stronglyfor crimes that have a prop- these commodities.23
erty component. This inconsistency is due The effects of unemploymenton homicide
primarilyto the lack of any positive effect for may be amplifiedthroughits effects on other
any of the purely violent crimes. crimes, especially those with a propertycom-
Larceny is the only crime that has a best- ponent. This is the case not only because many
fitting equation with significant negative and crimes eventually lead to a homicide, but the
positive effects. A comparisonof the full model FBI classification procedures only require
in Panel A with those of the restrictedmodels police to report a homicide in the case of
in PanelsB andC suggeststhatthe strengthsof events where homicide occurs in conjunction
the negative contemporaneous and positive with other crimes (U.S. Departmentof Justice,
fluctuationeffects are suppressedwhen each is 1980).
estimated by itself. To further investigate the inconsistencies
Robberyalso shows indicationsof both pos- noted between the first- and second-
itive and negative effects in the tnlogged first- differencedversions for robberyand burglary,
differencedmodel. However, this specification we reestimated the first-differencedversions
is flawedby the presenceof a DW indicativeof using the well-knownCochrane-Orcuttcorrec-
autocorrelation. This problem disappears in tion for autocorrelatederrors (Cochrane and
the second-differencedmodel, but the positive Orcutt, 1949; Johnston, 1972:261-62). This
coefficient for unemployment fluctuations allows us to assess whetherthe results in these
drops to insignificance.The results appearjust equations are significantly affected by serial
as confusing in the corresponding specifi- correlationof the residuals (see Table 2). For
cations of the restricted models in Panels B each crime, both the level and fluctuationef-
and C-the first-differencedversion suggests fects of unemploymentincrease in statistical
that the positive change effect is significant, significance.24The coefficients change more
while the second-differencedspecification in- 23 This explanationsuggests as muchof a negative
dicates a strong negative contemporaneous
motivationaleffect as one stemmingfrom increases
effect. These inconsistencies may arise be- in opportunities.
cause first differencing is not sufficiently 24 Because this is the second in a sequence of
strongto take out trends in levels of robbery, statisticaltests performedon these impacts,we raise
while second differencingis too strong. the a level from .10 to .05.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENT AND CRIME RATES 329
Table 2. Cochrane-OrcuttEstimatesof Coefficientsand SummaryStatistics for the Effects of Unemploy-
ment on Robberyand Burglary
DependentVariable Intercept Ut AUt R2 DW
Robbery 46.898 -8.3501 7.2727 0.4694 0.74 1.6531a
(First difference) (4.3799)** (4.7919)* (5.4350)*
Burglary 241.87 -41.685 36.613 0.3512 0.65 1.6711a
(First difference) (4.1191)** (4.1326)* (4.4712)*
Note: Estimatesare metriccoefficients;figuresin parenthesesare t-ratioscalculatedfromthe coefficients
divided by their standarderrors; R2= squared multiple correlation coefficient corrected for degrees of
freedom; j = estimated residual autocorrelation coefficient used in the Cochrane-Orcuttprocedure;
DW= Durbin-Watsonautocorrelationtest statistic.
a Fail to reject the null hypothesis of zero autocorrelationof disturbancesat a=.01.
* Significantly nonzero at a=.05, one-tailed test.
** Significantly nonzero at a=.05, two-tailed test.

for robberythan for burglary.This is expected cesses. We have argued that any inference
since the original robbery equation exhibited about the effect of the unemploymentrate has
strongersigns of autocorrelations. to account for both criminalopportunityand
For the three property crimes that exhibit criminal-motivationeffects. Neglect of both of
the predicted negative-positive pattern, the these factors has led to finding inconsistent
relative sizes of the estimated coefficients in empiricalresults on this topic, since the total
Tables 1 and 2 imply that the total impacts of a effect of the unemploymentrate is the sum of
cyclical increase in economic activity, as indi- positive motivationaland negativeopportunity
cated by changes in the unemploymentrate, impacts.
are negative.25For instance, suppose that the Our empirical results indicate a small, but
unemploymentrateincreasesfrom6 percentin significant, total effect of the unemployment
year t- 1 to 9 percent in year t-a not unrea- rate on five of the seven Index crimes tested
sonable example for the U.S. in recent years. here. Weak supportwas found for the timing
Then the coefficients imply that the larceny hypotheses proposed to identify the positive
rate is expected to decrease in year t by and negative effects. Unlike most of the previ-
145.33-31.180(9) + 38.464(3) = - 19.898 ous studies on this topic, therefore, this
crimes reported per 100,000 population. Cal- analysisfoundevidence for both a positive and
culations using the correspondingcoefficients negative effect of economic activity on crime.
for robberyand burglaryin Table 2 show simi- It is the case, however, that these results indi-
lar results. Thus, even though an increase in cate a negative partial effect across all the
the unemploymentrate has a positive fluctua- types of crimes showing a significant effect
tion effect on these crimes, the relativesizes of (i.e., homicide,robbery,burglary,larceny-theft
the estimated coefficients for the opportunity and motor vehicle theft). Evidence for a sig-
and motivationeffects are such that the total nificant positive partial effect was found
impacts of an increase in the unemployment primarilyfor crimes that contain a property
rate are negative-at least within the typical component (i.e., robbery, burglary and lar-
rangesof U.S. unemploymentlevels and fluc- ceny).26
tuations. The absence of any measurableeconomic-
hardshipinfluenceon the purelyviolent crimes
is not surprisingin light of the highly individu-
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS alistic factors that are associated with violent
Previous analyses of the U-C relationship behavior (Wolfgangand Weiner, 1982). While
have greatly oversimplified the causal pro- this fact has been recognized by at least one
theorist (Merton, 1938), very few recent em-
25 In econometric terminology, the distinctions pirical investigations (e.g., Brenner, 1976;
dealt with here pertainto the differences between Ehrlich, 1975)have attendedto this distinction.
impact (contemporaneous) and total multipliers(for It is, of course, not possible to rule out the
formaldefinitionsandexamplesof the concepts, see contingency that the findings reported herein
Theil, 1971:465-66).In the presentanalysis, the im- are spurious due to the inappropriatenessof
pact multipliersare given by the algebraicsums of
the coefficients of U. and AUt in Table 2 for each
26 Of course, as with all statistical analyses, our
equation;i.e., -0.0247 for robberyand +6.3450 for
burglary.These suggest an essentially null impact empiricalinferencesare conditionalon the observed
multiplierfor robbery and a small positive impact rangesof variationof the variablesin our data. Thus,
multiplierfor burglary.In both cases, however, the we cannot extrapolateour findings to situationsof
computationsgiven in the text show that the total extremely high levels or fluctuationsof unemploy-
effects are large and negative. ment.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
330 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
the statistical models and methods that we tunity effect. Future work.in this area, at a
have applied. Inspectionof Table 1, however, more disaggregatedlevel, is still requiredbe-
shows that within the types of models esti- fore more detailed conclusions can be drawn
mated here, our selection criteria make very with respect to either of the structuraleffects.
little differencewith respect to the basic con-
clusions stated above: (a) there is a small, but
REFERENCES
significant,effect of the unemploymentrate on
crime; (b) the contemporaneous effect is Aiken, Michael
primarilyan opportunity(negative) one; and 1968 Economic Failure, Alienation, and Ex-
(c) the only evidence of a lagged motivational tremism.Ann Arbor: University of Michi-
effect is for crimes that have a propertycom- gan Press.
ponent.27 Akerloff, G. A. and B. G. M. Main
1980 "Unemploymentspells and unemployment
To furtherexplorethis possibilityoutside the experience." American Economic Review
models used here, we have also conducted 70:885-93.
preliminarytests in the context of a family of Bakke, E. Wright
structuralequation models containingvarious 1940 Citizens Without Work: A Study of the
combinationsof variablesto explaintrendsand Workers' Social Relations and Practices.
fluctuationsin Index Crimerates. These mod- New Haven: Yale University Press.
els were estimated under the stochastic first- Balkin, Steven and John F. McDonald
difference-equation form recommended in 1981 "The marketfor street crime:an economic
Cohen et al. (1980). We concentrated on ex- analysis of victim-offender interaction."
Journalof Urban Economics 10:390-405.
amining the partial effect of unemployment Becker, Gary S.
when other variables, importantto the deter- 1968 "Crime and punishment:an economic ap-
minationof both secularandcyclical crimerate proach." Journal of Political Economy
changes, were controlled.These results gener- 76:169-217.
ally corroboratethe argumentsand inferences Becker, Howard S.
described above. Specifically, they confirm 1973 Outsiders:Studies in the Sociology of De-
that if both the level and fluctuationeffects are viance. Second edition. New York: Mac-
not controlled,it is impossibleto detect a posi- millan.
tive impact of the unemploymentrate. Also, Berk, RichardA., KennethJ. Lenihanand Peter H.
the patternof positive and negative partialef- Rossi
1980 "Crime and poverty; some experimental
fects for propertycrimesderivedin the present evidence from ex-offenders." American
paper generally is confirmedin the structural Sociological Review 45:766-86.
equation analyses, although the relative de- Block, R.
grees of significance depend on the precise 1981 "Victim-offender dynamics in violent
structuralspecificationsemployedand the type crime." The Journalof CriminalLaw and
of crime (Cantor, 1985). Criminology71:181-83.
In brief, the theory and analyses described Block. M. K. and J. M. Heinecke
above imply that the relationshipbetween un- 1975 "A labor theoretic analysis of the criminal
choice." American Economic Review
employmentrates and crime rates can be posi- 65:314-25.
tive, negativeor null, dependingon the type of Bober, Stanley
crime and on whether one focuses on the ef- 1968 The Economics of Cycles and Growth.
fects on criminalopportunityor criminalmoti- New York: Wiley.
vation. Withavailabletheory it is not possible Bonger, W.
to measureabsolutely the direct effects of un- 1916 Criminality and Economic Conditions.
employment on each of these two factors. Boston: Little, Brown.
Nonetheless, the evidence presentedhere indi- Box, George E. P. and Gwilym M. Jenkins
cates that for the post-World WarII U.S., the 1976 Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and
Control. Second edition. San Francisco:
net result of this process is a dominantoppor- Holden-Day.
Brenner,Harvey M.
27 Using the equation in footnote 18, the coeffi- 1971 Time Series.Analysis of RelationshipsBe-
cients in Table 1, Panel A, can be used to compute tween Selected Economic and Social Indi-
models that assume a full-year lag for the unem- cators. VolumeI. Final Reporton Contract
ployment rate (as opposed to using the difference No. 81-07-62-22. U. S. Department of
term).Overallindicationsof a net positive effect for Labor, ManpowerAdministration.
either the contemporaneousor lagged terms are 1976 "Estimating the social costs of national
similar to that discussed under our hypothesized economic policy: Implicationsfor mental
model. Only two of the laggedtermsare statistically and physical health and criminal aggres-
significantin a positive direction(murder,rape and sion." Paper No. 5, Joint Economic Com-
auto theft) and none of the contemporaneousterms mittee, Congress of the United States.
are significantin a positive direction. All other sig- Washington, D. C. : U. S. Government
nificanteffects are negative. PrintingOffice.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
UNEMPLOYMENTAND CRIME RATES 331
1978a "Economic crises and crime." Pp. 555-72 Ehrlich, Isaac
in Leonard Savitz and Norman Johnston 1975 "Thedeterrenteffect of capitalpunishment:
(eds.), Crimes in Society. New York: a question of life and death." American
Wiley. Economic Review 65:397-417.
1978b"Impact of economic indicatorson crime Executive Office of the President
indices." Pp. 20-54 in Unemploymentand 1984 Economic Reportsof the President.Wash-
Crime. Hearingsbefore the Subcommittee ington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing
on Crime of the Committee on the Office.
Judiciary,U. S. House of Representatives. Feeney, Floyd and AdreanneWeir
Serial No. 47. 1973 The Prevention and Control of Robbery.
Cantor,David Davis, CA: Center on Administrationof
1985 "Unemployment, economic activity and CriminalJustice.
crime rates: a re-examinationfrom an op- Ferri, Enrico
portunityperspective."UnpublishedPh.D. 1881 New Horizons of CriminalLaw and Penal
dissertation. Department of Sociology, Procedure.Turin.
University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign. Firebaugh,Glenn
Cantor,David and Lawrence E. Cohen 1978 "A rule for inferring individual-levelre-
1980 "Comparing measuresof thehomicidetrends: lationshipsfromaggregatedata."American
methodologicaland substantivedifferences Sociological Review 43:557-72.
in the vital statistics and uniformcrime re- Fleischer, B. M.
port time series (1933-1975)." Social Sci- 1966 The Economics of Delinquency. Chicago:
ence Research9:121-45. Quadrangle.
Cloward,R. A. and L. E. Ohlen Fox, James A.
1960 Delinquencyand Opportunity:A Theoryof 1976 An EconometricAnalysis of Crime Data.
DelinquentGangs. New York: Free Press. Ann Arbor: University Microfilms.
Cobb, Sidney Gibbons, Donald C.
1974 "Physiologic changes in men whose jobs 1971 "Some observationson the study of crime
were abolished."Journalof Psychosomatic causation."AmericanJournalof Sociology
Research 18:245-58. 77:262-78.
Cochrane,D. and G. H. Orcutt Glaser, Daniel
1949 "Applicationof least-squaresregressionsto 1971 Social Deviance. Chicago:Markham.
relationships containing auto-correlated Glaser, D. and K. Rice
error terms." Journal of the American 1959 "Crime, age, and unemployment.?Ameri-
StatisticalAssociation 44:32-61. can Sociological Review 24:679-86.
Cohen, Albert K. Gore, Susan
1955 DelinquentBoys: The Cultureof the Gang. 1978 "Theeffects of social supportin moderating
Glencoe: Free Press. the health consequences of unemploy-
Cohen, Lawrence E. and MarcusFelson ment.? Journal of Health and Social Be-
1979a "On estimatingthe social costs of national havior 19:157-65.
economic policy: a critical examinationof Gould, Leroy
the Brenner study." Social IndicatorsRe- 1969 "The changingstructureof propertycrime
search 6:251-59. in an affluent society." Social Forces
1979b"Social change and crime rate trends: a 48:50-59.
routine activity approach." American Granger,C. W. J.
Sociological Review 44:588-607. 1980 Forecasting in Business and Economics.
Cohen, Lawrence E., Marcus Felson and Kenneth New York: Academic.
C. Land Granger,C. W. J. and P. Newbold
1980 "Propertycrime rates in the United States: 1974 "Spurious regressions in econometrics?.
a macrodynamicanalysis, 1947-1977;with Journalof Econometrics2:111-20.
ex ante forecasts for the mid-1980s.' Heinecke, John M.
AmericanJournalof Sociology 86:90-118. 1978 "Economic models of criminal behavior:
Cohen,LawrenceE., JamesR. Kluegeland Kenneth an overview.? Pp. 1-33 in John M. Hein-
C. Land ecke (ed.), Economic Models of Criminal
1981 "Social inequality and predatorycriminal Behavior. Amsterdam:North-Holland.
victimization:an exposition and test of a Henry, Andrew F. and James F. Short, Jr.
formaltheory." AmericanSociologicalRe- 1954 Suicide and Homicide: Some Economic,
view 46:505-24. Sociological and PsychologicalAspects of
Cohn, Richard Aggression. New York: Free Press.
1978 "The effect of employmentchange on self Hindelang,M. J., M. R. GottfredsonandJ. Garofalo
attitudes?. Social Psychology 41:81-93. 1978 Victims of Personal Crime: An Empirical
Danziger,Sheldon and David Wheeler Formulationfor a Theory of PersonalVic-
1975 "The economics of crime: punishmentor timization.Cambridge:Ballinger.
income redistribution."Review of Social Hirschi, Travis
Economy 33:113-31. 1969 The Causes of Delinquency. Berkeley:
Duncan, Otis Dudley, David L. Feathermanand Universityof CaliforniaPress.
Beverly Duncan Hughes, Michaeland TimothyJ. Carter
1972 Socioeconomic Backgroundand Achieve- 1981 "A declining economy and sociological
ment. New York: SeminarPress. theories of crime: predictionsand explica-

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
332 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
tions." Pp. 5-26 in Kevin N. Wright(ed.), Weiner (eds.), CriminalViolence. Beverly
Crime and CriminalJustice in a Declining Hills: Sage.
Economy. Cambridge,MA: Oelgeschlager, Office of Managementand Budget
Gunn & Hain. 1974 Social Indicators 1973. Washington,D.C.:
Hyman, HerbertH. U.S. GovernmentPrintingOffice.
1979 "The effects of unemployment:a neglected Orsagh, Thomas
problem in modem social research." Pp. 1981 "A criminometricmodel of the criminal
282-98 in Robert K. Merton, James S. justice system." Pp. 163-87 in James A.
Colemanand Peter H. Rossi (eds.), Qual- Fox (ed.), Models in Quantitative Crim-
itative and QuantitativeSocial Research: inology. New York: Academic Press.
Papersin Honorof PaulF. Lazarsfeld.New Phillips, L., H. Votey and D. Maxwell
York: Free Press. 1972 "Crime, youth, and the labor market."
Jackson, Bruce Journalof PoliticalEconomy 80:491-504.
1969 A Thief s Primer.New York: Macmillan. Schmidt, P. and A. D. Witte
Jahoda,Marie, Paul F. Lazarsfeldand Hans Zeisel 1984 An Economic Analysis of Crime and Jus-
1933 Marienthal:The Sociolographyof an Un- tice. Academic Press: San Diego.
employed Community. New York: Sellin, Thorstein
Aldine-Atherton. 1937 Research Memorandumon Crime in the
Johnston, J. Depression.New York: Social Science Re-
1972 Econometric Methods. Second edition. search Council.
New York: McGraw-Hill. Theil, Henri
Kleck, Gary D. 1971 Principles of Econometrics. New York:
1979 "Capital punishment, gun ownership and Wiley.
homicide."AmericanJournalof Sociology Thomas, D. S.
84:882-910. 1925 Social Aspects of the Business Cycle. New
Komarovsky,Mirra York: E. D. Dutton.
1940 The Unemployed Man and His Family. Thornberry,Terence P. and R. L. Christenson
New York: Dryden. 1984 "Unemploymentand criminalinvolvement:
Land, Kenneth C. and MarcusFelson an investigation of reciprocal causal
1976 "A generalframeworkfor buildingdynamic structures."AmericanSociologicalReview
macro social indicatormodels: includingan 49:398-411.
analysis of changes in crime rates and United States Congress
police expenditures."AmericanJournalof 1978 UnemploymentandCrime.Hearingsbefore
Sociology 82:565-604. the Subcommitteeon Crime of the Com-
Long, Sharon K. and Ann D. Witte mittee on the Judiciary, House of Repre-
1981 "Currenteconomic trends:implicationsfor sentatives, Serial No. 47.
crime and criminaljustice." Pp. 69-143 in U.S. Departmentof Justice
Kevin N. Wright(ed.), Crimeand Criminal 1980 Uniform Crime Reporting Handbook.
Justice in a Declining Economy. Cam- Washington,D.C.: Federal Bureau of In-
bridge,MA: Oelgeschlager,Gunn& Hain. vestigation.
McCleary,Richardand RichardA. Hay, Jr. 1981 CriminalVictimization in the U.S. 1979.
1980 AppliedTime Series Analysisfor the Social Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Sciences. Beverly Hills: Sage. PrintingOffice.
Mansfield,Roger, Leroy Gould and J. Zvi Namen- U.S. Departmentof Labor
wirth 1980 Employment and Training Report of the
1974 "A socioeconomicmodel for the prediction President. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov-
of societal rates of propertytheft." Social ernmentPrintingOffice.
Forces 52:462-72. Vold, G. B.
Merton, Robert K. 1979 Theoretical Criminology.New York: Ox-
1938 "Social structureand anomie." American ford University Press.
SociologicalReview 3:672-82. Wellford,CharlesF.
Monahan,John and Deidre Klassen 1973 "Age composition and the increase in re-
1982 "Situationalapproaches to understanding corded crime." Criminology11:61-70.
andpredictingindividualviolent behavior." Wolfgang,M. E. and N. A. Weiner
Pp. 292-319 in M. E. Wolfgangand N. E. 1982 CriminalViolence. Beverly Hills: Sage.

This content downloaded from 128.235.251.160 on Wed, 10 Dec 2014 12:49:53 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like