You are on page 1of 17

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/46538638

Gross National Happiness

Article  in  Asian-Pacific Economic Literature · November 2009


DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-8411.2009.01235.x · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

73 359

1 author:

Winton Bates
Freedom and Flourishing
14 PUBLICATIONS   87 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Impact of technological change on human flourishing View project

Freedom, Progress and Human Flourishing View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Winton Bates on 16 October 2020.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8411.2009.01235.x

Gross national happiness apel_1235 1..16

Winton Bates*

This article considers the concept of gross national happinesss, as it has


evolved in Bhutan, against the background of literature on the pursuit of
happiness as a government objective and the problems associated with
different approaches to measuring well-being. It concludes that since all
measures of well-being are imperfect, including the measure of gross
national happiness currently being applied in Bhutan, the best approach is
to use a range of different measures, including conventional national
accounting indicators.

Some critics, including the present author,


Introduction have had difficulty in viewing the GNH
concept as more than a play on words. This is
The statement ‘Gross National Happiness is because the word ‘gross’ in GNH does not
more important that Gross National Product’ appear to have any meaning, and certainly
has been attributed to the former king of does not have a meaning corresponding to that
Bhutan, Jigme Singye Wangchuck. The former in national income accounting.1
monarch is said to have made gross national Such semantic quibbles have not prevented
happiness (GNH) the guiding philosophy of the GNH concept from becoming a national
Bhutan’s development process soon after his objective in Bhutan. Article 9 of the Constitu-
enthronement in 1972 (Thinley 2007). It was not tion of this new democracy states: ‘The State
until the late 1980s, however, that the king shall strive to promote those conditions that
began to use the GNH concept explicitly in an will enable the pursuit of Gross National
attempt to ensure that economic development Happiness’. The government of Bhutan has
was in harmony with Bhutan’s culture, insti- recently initiated efforts to measure GNH. In
tutions and spiritual values (Ura and Galay addition, GNH is widely discussed interna-
2004:viii). tionally. At least four international conferences
Opening Bhutan to outside ideas and insti- have been held specifically on GNH, attract-
tutions began in the early 1960s, and appar- ing participation by scholars from different
ently picked up pace in the 1970s (Ura and disciplines and different parts of the world.
Galay 2004:viii). In that context, the GNH In preparing this article the author has
concept probably evolved as a good-humoured viewed the recent evolution of GNH in
play on words to make the point that the devel- Bhutan against the background of literature
opment process ought not be directed toward relating to the pursuit of happiness as a gov-
increasing gross national product (GNP) if this ernment objective and the problems associated
is at the expense of traditional values. with different approaches to measurement of

* Independent researcher on issues relating to well-being and liberty. Prior to his retirement from full-time work he was an
economic consultant and, before that, First Assistant Commissioner for the Australian Industry Commission.
1 In national income accounting, ‘gross’ refers to the fact that depreciation of capital has not been deducted from the value
of production.

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

happiness. The first question considered is happiness is good and what promotes human
whether aggregate happiness is the right objec- misery is evil. The 18th-century philosopher,
tive. This is followed by a consideration of David Hume, based this judgement on the
national accounting approaches, indicators observation that ‘. . . it is impossible for such a
of subjective well-being, summary measures of creature as man to be totally indifferent to the
national progress and human development, well or ill-being of his fellow creatures’ (Hume
and the measurement of GNH in Bhutan. 1777:45).3
Jeremy Bentham is the historical figure most
closely associated with the view that the objec-
Is aggregate happiness the right tive of society should be to maximize aggre-
gate happiness. Although Bentham did not
objective?
claim authorship of the phrase, ‘the greatest
There is evidence that happiness has been happiness of the greatest number’, he certainly
widely viewed as of fundamental importance endorsed that objective. He also argued that an
for many centuries in Bhutan. According to action ‘may be said to be conformable to the
Jigmi Thinley, the 1729 legal code of Bhutan principle of utility . . . when the tendency it has
‘stressed that laws should promote happiness to augment the happiness of the community is
of the sentient beings’ (Thinley 2007:4). This greater than any it has to diminish it’ (Bentham
long history of emphasis on the goal of happi- 1789:I.7).
ness is consistent with the view that it is central Richard Layard, a modern-day Benthamite
to Buddhist teaching.2 In writing about the —also an eminent economist and member of
history of Bhutan, John Ardussi notes that as the British House of Lords—argues in favour
in other Himalayan states where traditional of maximizing aggregate happiness as follows:
Tibetan cultural values held sway, ‘it was the People are calling out for a concept of the
declared obligation of the civil head of state to common good—and that is exactly what
maintain law and order so that its subjects the Enlightenment ideal provides. It defines the
could devote themselves to leading a moral common good as the greatest happiness of all,
life and strive for a better rebirth in the requiring us to care for others as well as for our-
next’ (Ardussi 2005). Similar sentiments about selves. And it advocates the kind of fellow-feeling
ensuring necessary conditions for a moral for others that in itself increases our happiness
and reduces our isolation. (Layard 2005:5–6)
life have also been influential in European
history. Darrin McMahon notes that St Thomas Should the objective of enabling the pursuit of
Aquinas ‘recognized the necessity of means GNH be pursued by seeking to maximise
to promote higher ends. It was difficult to do aggregate happiness? Leaving aside the ques-
good in the world when one was starving or tion of whether it is possible with known tech-
sick, difficult to give alms without alms to give, nology to add the happiness of different
difficult to live a life of contemplation without individuals together to measure the sum of
the basic necessities of life fulfilled’ (McMahon their happiness, what objections could anyone
2006:132). have to maximisation of aggregate happiness?
The modern view that the state should strive One reason why some people object to
to promote conditions that will promote hap- maximisation of aggregate happiness has to do
piness of citizens is based on a widely shared with what Derek Parfit describes as the ‘repug-
value judgement that what promotes human nant conclusion’. It is likely that the sum total

2 Darrin McMahon, author of a widely acclaimed history of ideas about happiness, has suggested that it seems incongruous
for Buddhism to be associated with the art of happiness, as Buddhists believe that all life is suffering (McMahon
2006:471). However, Buddhists maintain that suffering can be overcome. Buddhism sets up nirvana as the final liberation
from the suffering of repeated embodiment (Honderlich, 1995:107).
3 I leave aside the question of whether the judgement that what promotes human happiness is good is the ultimate value
judgement. Rival considerations that are claimed by some to be of more fundamental importance include individual
liberty, human capability, a just society and conformity to God’s will (Yeager 2001:229).

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

of human happiness would be higher than at spontaneously. In the light of this he argues
present if the human population increased that ‘a benevolent government may find that it
massively, even though the members of that cannot maximize social welfare, evaluated
population might have lives ‘that are barely from some impartial viewpoint, without violat-
worth living’ (Parfit 1984:388). ing conventions that its citizens regard as prin-
This implication of aggregate happiness ciples of justice’ (Sugden 2004:8).
maximisation had previously been recognized A further set of objections to maximisa-
by Henry Sidgwick, who did not regard it as tion of aggregate happiness arises because it
repugnant. He argued that: implies that governments should adopt poli-
Strictly conceived, the point up to which, on Utili- cies that take into account the capacities of
tarian principles, population ought to be encour- people to adapt to the circumstances in which
aged to increase, is not that at which average they find themselves. Amartya Sen suggests
happiness is the greatest possible . . . but that that a focus on happiness rather than indi-
at which the produce formed by multiplying vidual well-being can be ‘deeply unfair’, as it
the number of persons living into the amount may lead us to be unconcerned about people
of average happiness reaches its maximum. who claim to be happy even though they are
(Sidgwick 1874/1907:415–6) suffering adverse circumstances. He notes:
The most obvious solution to the problem ‘desires and pleasure-taking abilities adjust to
identified by Parfit, namely maximising aver- circumstances, especially to make life bearable
age levels of happiness, would be viewed by in adverse situations’ (Sen 1999:62–3).
some as having implications that are even more Bruno Frey and Alois Stutzer note other
repugnant. Assuming that it is possible to undesirable implications of taking into account
choose between a future in which a tiny popu- different capacities for adaptation of different
lation live wonderfully happy lives and one in individuals. For example, if materialists with
which a much larger population live moder- high-income aspirations suffer a great deal
ately happy lives, who is to say which outcome from personal income tax, does this mean that
should be preferred? Value judgements are they should be exempted from the tax? Should
clearly involved here, and different people can courts award lower compensation to victims
obviously make different judgements. Many of accidents who can more readily adapt to
would argue that collective choices about such disabilities sustained, and higher damages to
matters are repugnant because decisions about those who cannot adapt so easily? (Frey and
family size are best left to the people who are Stutzer 2007:8).
most intimately involved in producing chil- None of these objections to maximisation of
dren and caring for them. aggregate happiness rule out the desirability
This brings us to another set of objections of the kind of utilitarian approach that, to use
related to the fact that maximisation of aggre- the words of Leland Yeager, ‘invokes facts and
gate happiness can only take into account logic to appraise institutions, policies, rules,
rights, ideas of justice and decision-making character traits and dispositions according
processes insofar as such matters influence the to how well they serve peaceful cooperation
perceived happiness of individuals. Amartya among individuals pursuing their own diverse
Sen comments: ‘It is sensible enough to take goals in life’ (Yeager 2001:299).
note of happiness, but we do not necessarily Following Henry Hazlitt, social cooperation
want to be happy slaves or delirious vassals’ may be viewed as ‘the great means by which
(Sen 1999:62). Bruno Frey and Alois Stutzer we all help each other to attain our individual
point to evidence from happiness research that ends, and so to attain the ends of “society” ’
‘people have preferences for processes over (Hazlitt 1998:14). Along similar lines, Friedrich
and above outcomes’ (Frey and Stutzer 2007:9). Hayek suggested that rules of conduct ‘can do
Robert Sugden suggests how some of our no more than to increase the opportunities for
ideas about rights, entitlements and justice are unknown people’. He wrote: ‘If we do the best
rooted in conventions that may have evolved we can to improve the opportunities for any
3

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

unknown person picked at random, we will ethics, in which conditions that enable indi-
achieve the most we can, but certainly not vidual strivings to succeed correspond to the
because we have any idea of the sum of utility ethics of respect while taking account of the
which we have produced’ (Hayek 1982:vol. 2, needs of others corresponds to the ethics of
23). caring.
It is common to see Hayek’s views associ-
ated with an extreme form of individualism
that he explicitly rejected (Hayek 1984:146).
For example, Ross McDonald argued at a National accounting measures
recent GNH conference that the ‘end result’ of Was GNP ever intended to be a well-being
Hayek’s views (and those of Adam Smith) is measure? Steve Dowrick and John Quiggin
‘an encouragement towards a form of self- assert: ‘The original motivation for the devel-
centredness’ in which individuals believe that opment of national accounts . . . was the need
they ‘can legitimately seek their own fulfilment for accurate measures of aggregate economic
without taking into account the corresponding activity as a basis for Keynesian macro-
interest of others—a dynamic that clearly vio- economic stabilisation policy’ (Dowrick and
lates the basic grounding of ethical maturity’ Quiggin 1998:94).
(McDonald 2008). Simon Kuznets—who was given the task of
Robert Nozick has observed that the ethics developing estimates of the national income of
of social cooperation has four levels or layers. the USA—warned that the ‘welfare of a nation’
The most fundamental level, the ethics of can ‘scarcely be inferred from a measurement
respect—mandating among other things of national income’ in his first report to the US
respect for the rights of others, as emphasised Congress in 1934 (Cobb et al. 1995).
by Hayek among others—is the level at which Prominent economist and former Chairman
people help each other to attain individual of the US Council of Economic Advisers,
ends. But this is also ‘the ground’ from which Arthur Okun, saw virtue in the fact that
higher levels of ethics may grow. The full national accounting conventions did not seek
development of Nozick’s third level of ethics, to measure welfare:
the ethics of caring, involves ‘love to all people,
perhaps to all living creatures’ (Nozick National accountants . . . would not assist by
2001:280).4 compromising on the proposition that [national
Such considerations seem particularly rel- income] is not a measure of total social welfare.
The beauty of [the present] practice is that no
evant in considering the goals of GNH in
sensible person could seriously mistake [national
Bhutan. In stating the goals of GNH, Karma income] for such a measure. (Okun 1971:132–3)
Ura, president of the Centre for Bhutan Studies,
expresses the view that ‘any government con- By contrast, Colin Clark, a pioneer of national
cerned with happiness must create conducive income accounting, seems to have been in-
conditions for happiness in which individual spired by A.C. Pigou’s view that the national
strivings can succeed’. He also expresses the dividend (national income) and economic
view that the ‘perception of happiness that welfare were closely related, as he quoted at
doesn’t take into account the needs of others’ length many passages on this subject written
happiness is irresponsible and egocentric, and by Pigou (Clark 1957:7). Pigou argued:
the pursuit of such happiness is likely to be Just as economic welfare is that part of total
unethical’ (Ura 2008). Applying Nozick’s per- welfare which can be brought directly or indi-
spective, those statements may correspond to rectly into relation with a money measure, so the
different levels of an inter-related system of national dividend is that part of the objective

4 Nozick’s second level of ethics, ‘the ethics of Responsiveness’, mandates acting in a way that enhances and supports the
inherent value of individuals. His fourth level, ‘the ethics of Light’, encompasses being a vessel and vehicle of truth,
beauty, goodness and holiness.

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

income of the community . . . which can be mea- overcome within a national accounting frame-
sured in money. The two concepts, economic work? A more accurate picture of well-being
welfare and the national dividend, are thus may be provided in moving from the most
co-ordinate, in such wise that any description of commonly used national accounting concepts
the content of one of them implies a correspond-
to concepts such as household disposable
ing description of the content of the other. (Pigou
income. A study by Boarini, Johansson and
1932:I.III.I)
Mira d’Ercole suggests that the difference
Economists have expressed a wide variety of between gross domestic product (GDP) and
views about national income and its relation- GNP is relatively small in OECD countries, but
ship to well-being. Some economists, such this is not likely to be so in countries where
as Amartya Sen, have emphasised that an substantial remittances are obtained from citi-
adequate conception of development must go zens who are working abroad (Boarini et al.
much beyond the accumulation of wealth and 2006:7–14).5 These authors also show that sub-
the growth of GNP (Sen 1999:14). W. Arthur traction of depreciation to obtain net national
Lewis suggested that economic growth is product does not make much difference to
important primarily because it increases the country rankings for OECD countries, if offi-
range of human choice (Lewis 1955:420). Some cial statistics are taken at face value. However,
economists, such as Ezra Mishan, have sug- adjusting for tax payments, etc., to obtain
gested that as a result of negative externalities household disposable income substantially
—such as environmental degradation—growth changes the ranking of OECD countries by per
of national income may reduce social welfare capita income levels. It seems likely that even
rather than increase it (Mishan 1967:171). larger differences would have been observed if
Benjamin Friedman has recently advanced more low-income countries had been included
the opposite view: that economic growth is in the study.
associated with positive externalities—such as The main problems with the use of per
tolerance of diversity, social mobility, commit- capita GDP as a well-being measure arise from
ment to fairness and dedication to democracy the limitations of the information available
(Friedman 2006:4). in standard national accounting systems.
There has been a long-running discussion These include failure to account for changes
among economists about the relevance of in natural resources and intangible capital
income distribution considerations. One influ- (including human capital), nonmarket house-
ential contributor, I.M.D. Little, argued that hold production (with some exceptions),
there can be no welfare significance in national leisure, external costs and benefits associated
income comparisons unless a value judgement with production and consumption, income dis-
about changes in distribution is presupposed tribution, economies of household size, social
(Little 1957:227). costs of unemployment, threats to national
At a practical level, however, economists security, democratic rights, and restrictions
have made widespread use of estimates of on liberty. There are also problems associated
per capita income in drawing inferences about with the measurement of government services,
material well-being. Writing in the 1950s, such as education and health, at the cost of
Gerald Meier and Robert Baldwin claimed: provision.
‘almost everyone would agree that real national Economists have made various attempts to
income and real per capita income are highly correct for the deficiencies of national income
significant for economic welfare’ (Meier and aggregates as measures of well-being. In the
Baldwin 1957:6). early 1970s, Nordhaus and Tobin sought to
How far can the problems in use of per correct for the most obvious deficiencies of
capita income as a well-being measure be national income aggregates and concluded

5 GDP is defined as the value of all final goods and services produced in a country in one year. GNP equals GDP plus
income earned by citizens living abroad minus income earned by foreigners in the country concerned.

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

that ‘the broad picture of secular progress the World Bank shows that some countries
which they convey remains after correction’ (for example, Nigeria and Azerbaijan) with
(Nordhaus and Tobin 1972:532). These conclu- high GDP growth rates had negative ‘genuine
sions were subsequently questioned by John savings rates’. In other words, despite the
Cobb, Clifford Cobb, and Herman Daly, who apparent high growth rates of these countries,
developed the Index of Sustainable Welfare their net savings rates were negative after
(ISEW) (Mathews 2006:12). The ISEW was sub- taking account of estimates of the value of
sequently modified slightly by an organisation depletion of minerals, energy, and forest
called Redefining Progress in order to develop resources, damages from air pollutants, and
the genuine progress indicator (GPI). Although investments in human capital (World Bank
estimates of ISEW and GPI have been made for 2006:45).
many countries, there is as yet no standard There seems to be a limit to how far the
methodology. The experimental nature of GPI deficiencies of national accounting indicators
estimation is evident, for example, in the seven of well-being can be overcome within a
case studies in a recent book discussing sus- national accounting framework. Few econo-
tainable welfare in the Asian-Pacific region mists would advocate attempting to incorpo-
(Lawn and Clarke 2008). rate indicators such as measures of democracy
In general terms, estimations of GPI use or liberty in measures of national income. As
aggregate consumption as a starting point—as Dowrick and Quiggin note: ‘Such attempts will
this is the aggregate in the national accounts always be subject to the criticism that the
most closely related to immediate well-being— scaling and weighting of the composite index
and then make allowance for other factors is arbitrary or represents a particular political
believed to contribute positively or negatively and value position’ (Dowrick and Quiggin
to well-being. For example, amounts are added 1998:106).
to account for the value of unpaid house- How much do the deficiencies of per capita
hold labour and services provided by con- income measures actually matter? The World
sumer durables, and amounts are subtracted Bank noted in the World Development Report for
to account for defensive and rehabilitative 2000/2001 that as countries become richer, on
expenditure (such as costs of crime prevention average, the incidence of poverty falls, and
and road accidents) depreciation of human- other indicators of well-being, such as average
made capital, the cost of depletion of natural levels of education and health, tend to improve
resources, and environmental effects. as well (World Bank 2000:45). Dollar and Kraay
Apart from the obvious difficulties in showed, using data for a large number of coun-
placing an appropriate monetary value on tries, that average incomes of the poorest fifth
many of the factors allowed for in GPI estima- of society rise proportionately with average
tions, acceptance of the results can also be incomes (Dollar and Kraay 2002). Pritchett and
adversely affected by such factors as the inclu- Summers showed that infant mortality and life
sion of contentious adjustments for changes in expectancy outcomes were much worse on
income distribution and foreign debt, as well average in countries with low per capita
as failure to allow for changes in human capital incomes than in other countries (Pritchett and
(Bates 2009). Summers 1996).
The World Bank’s efforts to measure wealth However, a study by Easterly has shown
and changes in wealth suggest that failure to that even though there is a great deal of evi-
account for changes in natural resources and dence that indicators of quality of life tend
intangible capital can seriously limit the extent to be positively associated with high per capita
to which economic growth, as conventionally incomes, there is no consistent pattern of
measured, reflects changes in well-being. This improvement in quality of life indicators
is particularly so in the case of low-income while countries are experiencing economic
countries that rely heavily on natural resources growth (Easterly 1999). The author reached this
for economic growth. Using estimates for 2003, conclusion using a panel data set of 81 indica-
6

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

tors (covering individual rights and democ- time they make their judgements rather
racy, political instability and war, education, than on all relevant factors. This means, for
health, transport and communications, inequa- example, that answers to survey questions
lity, and a range of other factors, including can be sensitive to the order in which ques-
crime and environmental pollution) for a tions are asked (p. 63).
large number of countries, for four time • The way accessible information is used to
periods (from 1960 to 1990). He suggests make global assessments depends on
several possible reasons for this result, includ- judgements about how it relates to the
ing the possibility that there may be long lags question that is asked. For example, if an
between income growth and quality of life extremely positive event that occurred last
improvements. year comes to mind, it could be judged to
Summing up, although there is strong evi- impact either positively or negatively on
dence that higher per capita income is gener- my assessment of ‘my life now’, depending
ally associated with higher life expectancy and on whether I am comparing my life now
improved quality of life, the deficiencies of per with my life 20 years ago or with my life
capita GDP may sometimes matter a great deal last year (p. 65).
when it is used to make comparative assess- • Individuals often draw on comparison
ments of well-being. Even so, there is little information that is made temporarily acces-
evidence to support the view that GDP is sible by the context in which they form
so fundamentally misleading that it should be their judgements rather than determined
abolished, as one commentator has suggested by relatively stable attributes of the respon-
(van den Bergh 2007). Despite all its limita- dent. For example, respondents tend to
tions, per capita income provides information assume that the ‘average’ response is rep-
that is relevant to assessing the material well- resented by values in the middle range of
being of people at different times and in differ- the scale of responses that they are asked to
ent countries. choose from (p. 73).
• Judgements of subjective well-being are
influenced by mood states at the time of
Indicators of subjective well-being judgement (p. 75).
• Respondents may edit their private judge-
Surveys in which respondents are asked to ments of subjective well-being before
provide a numerical rating of their happiness they communicate them, for example by
or satisfaction with life (sometimes referred to overstating their satisfaction with life in
as global well-being reports) are the most order to avoid appearing to be negative
common method used to measure subjective (p. 77).
well-being (Frey 2008:18). What are the main Comparisons of happiness ratings over time
limitations of this data? The most important may also be affected by problems that people
limitation for many purposes has to do with have in relating their subjective states to rating
the potential for responses to survey ques- scales. Yew-Kwang Ng makes the point that an
tions to vary according to the context in apparently unchanged happiness rating could
which the question is asked. Schwartz and hide a very large change in happiness if people
Strack have argued that ‘what is being change their descriptions of their subjective
assessed, and how, seems too context depen- states over time (Ng 2008:254). For example, a
dent to provide reliable information about a person rating herself initially as ‘very happy’
population’s well-being, let alone information —at the top of the rating scale—who subse-
that can guide public policy’ (Schwartz and quently experienced a large increase in happi-
Strack 1999:80). Schwartz and Strack (1999) ness would still have to describe herself as
cite evidence that: ‘very happy’. With the benefit of hindsight, she
• People base global well-being assessments might describe her previous state as ‘not too
on information that is most accessible at the happy’.
7

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

International comparisons of happiness He argues that ‘we can be confident that if we


ratings may be biased if the words used in ask enough people the same question, the
other languages to translate the English words average answer will be a roughly accurate
happy and satisfied do not have exactly the index of the average experience’ (Gilbert
same meaning. Anna Wierzbicka suggests 2006:77).
that such linguistic considerations pose a Gilbert is not impressed by the defence of
substantial problem. She also suggests that the survey measures on the grounds that they
the reliability of international comparisons of tend to be strongly correlated with more objec-
happiness levels is affected by differences in tive measures of happiness (see, for example,
cultural norms, for example, relating to the Brooks 2008:8–9; Layard 2005:17–20). Gilbert
extent to which people are willing to express argues that:
happiness and good feelings (Wierzbicka
The only reason why we take any of these bodily
2004). However, John Helliwell and others events—from muscle movements to cerebral
have found, as a result of their research using blood flow—as indices of happiness is that
an extensive international database, that (with people tell us they are. If everyone claimed to feel
the exception of an unexplained boost to raging anger or thick, black depression when
life satisfaction ratings in South and Central their zygomatic muscle contracted, their eyeblink
America) international differences in life satis- slowed, and the left anterior brain region filled
faction ratings can be attributed to the social, with blood, then we would have to revise our
institutional and economic circumstances of interpretations of these physiological changes
life rather than to cultural differences (Helli- and take them as indices of unhappiness instead.
(Gilbert 2006:72)
well et al. 2009:11).
More fundamentally, there is the question of Some economists take comfort from correla-
whether interpersonal comparisons of happi- tions between happiness ratings and other
ness levels are meaningful. The subjective feel- variables that can plausibly be claimed to be
ings that different individuals associate with associated with well-being. For example, Di
being ‘happy’ or ‘very happy’ might vary a Tella and MacCulloch cite research repor-
great deal. But as Bruno Frey suggests, it is ting that unemployed individuals tend to
possible that ‘interpersonal comparability may report relatively low happiness scores. They
be less problematic on a practical level than on comment: ‘This outcome seems reasonable
a theoretical level’ (Frey 2008:163). given that other “bads” like divorce, addic-
Another possible limitation of the useful- tion, depression and violence are correlated
ness of survey data on happiness and life sat- with unemployment. The findings also sug-
isfaction arises because of the potential for gest that happiness surveys are capturing
survey results to be biased if respondents something meaningful about true utility’ (Di
answer questions strategically with a view to Tella and MacCulloch 2006:28). Similarly,
the way information may be used. For example, Kahneman and Krueger discuss several dif-
if they think survey results will be used to ferent kinds of evidence in support of the
judge the performance of the government, validity of life satisfaction data, including evi-
some respondents are likely to use their dence that life satisfaction typically increases
responses to send messages to the government immediately following positive changes in
about its performance rather than about their circumstances and decreases immediately
own well-being. following negative changes. In addition, they
So, in view of these limitations, why does note that a person’s subjective evaluation
anyone believe that data on happiness and of his or her well-being is, to a significant
life satisfaction is anything more than noise? extent, a personality trait. Identical twins
Gilbert suggests that the law of large numbers separated immediately after birth show the
tends to cancel out the imperfections of same concordance on happiness, as on other
individual reports of subjective well-being. traits for which a genetic basis is well

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

established (Kahneman and Krueger 2006: gratitude or fortitude. Such considerations


7–9).6 would clearly affect use of life satisfaction
Do self-reports of satisfaction with life as a surveys to make well-being comparisons
whole provide a better indication of well-being where differing emphasis is given to particular
that self-reports of happiness? At first sight, it virtues—for example, in making well-being
might appear obvious that self-reports of satis- comparisons between cultures and over long
faction would be better for this purpose than time periods.
self-reports of happiness. When people are How do measures of subjective well-being
asked to rate how happy they are, the answers relate to utility, the concept of well-being con-
they give are presumed to relate mainly to ventionally used in economics?8
emotional states.7 It would seem reasonable to Conflicting views about the relationship
suggest that in attempting to assess well-being, between utility and survey measures of hap-
researchers would need to use a concept that piness have recently emerged as economists
involves more than just a positive emotional have sought to make use of this information.
state. Indeed, nearly all empirical work so far The first view considered is that the happi-
undertaken in economic happiness research ness surveys measure utility. For example,
has been based on survey respondents’ global Frey and Stutzer assert: ‘Utility can and
evaluations of their life satisfaction (Frey should be cardinally measured in the form
2008:20). of subjective well-being’ (Frey and Stutzer
However, an examination of the issues 2002:43). Under this view, any divergence
involved by Dan Haybron, a philosopher, sug- between revealed preference and changes
gests that the relationship between life satisfac- in measured happiness—for example, if a
tion and welfare is far more convoluted than person makes decisions that lead to a reduc-
we might tend to expect. Haybron points out tion in happiness—must be attributable to
that attitudes about life satisfaction are not either poor decision making or inaccurate
simple assessments of well-being. They have measurement of happiness. A recent article by
an ethical dimension as well: ‘such attitudes Clark, Frijters and Shields suggests that if
embody, not just our view of how well our subjective well-being measures are accepted
lives are going, but also our sense of how it is as a direct proxy for utility, the traditional
appropriate to respond to our lives’ (Haybron utility function can be readily modified to
2007:107). For example, you might be satisfied incorporate relative considerations that may
with your life, not because it is going well for account for the failure to observe increases in
you, but because you aspire to such virtues as average happiness with further increases in

6 However, if we accept survey data at face value, we are left with puzzles when it conflicts with other evidence about
human well-being. The most famous of these puzzles, the so-called ‘Easterlin paradox’, arose from Richard Easterlin’s
observation that despite increases in average incomes, there appeared to be no corresponding increase in average
happiness levels (Easterlin 1973, 1974). Additional data and subsequent research, particularly recent work by Betsey
Stevenson and Justin Wolfers, has greatly reduced the extent to which any part of this puzzle remains to be explained
(Stevenson and Wolfers 2008:1).
7 This is explicit in the Fordyce Emotions Questionnaire, used by psychologists, including Martin Seligman, in which
respondents are asked to rate their level of happiness from ‘extremely happy’ to ‘extremely unhappy’, and to indicate the
percentage of time in which they feel ‘happy’, ‘unhappy’ and ‘neutral’ (Seligman 2002:15).
8 Many economists use the terms ‘utility’ and ‘happiness’ interchangeably, as did Jeremy Bentham when he wrote: ‘By
utility is meant that property in any object, whereby it tends to produce benefit, advantage, pleasure, good, or happiness,
(all this in the present case comes to the same thing) or (what comes again to the same thing) to prevent the happening
of mischief, pain, evil, or unhappiness to the party whose interest is considered’ (Bentham 1789:I.III). When economists
speak of an additional unit of good A providing more utility to some person than an additional unit of good B, however,
they are not necessarily making any claims about the psychological states that might result from consumption of
additional units of A or B. The point was made clearly by Irving Fisher in 1892 when he stated: ‘the conception of utility
has its origins in the facts of human preference or decision’. He explained: ‘No-one ever denied that economic acts have
the invariable antecedent, desire. Whether the necessary antecedent of desire is “pleasure” or whether independently of
pleasure it may sometimes be “duty” or “fear” concerns a phenomenon in the second order remove from the economic
act of choice’ (Fisher 1892/1925:11).

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

income in high-income countries (Clark et al. per capita GDP or average life satisfaction.
2008:136–7). This approach can be pursued systematically,
Other researchers are opposed to the view for example, using an approach adopted by
that any divergence between revealed pre- the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS 2006).
ference and changes in happiness must be The ABS has identified three domains of
attributable to either poor decision making progress—economy, society and environment
or inaccurate measurement of happiness. For —and has provided indicators for various
example, I have previously suggested that dimensions of progress within each of these
successful pursuit of personal goals, such as domains.
having children, is not reflected in measures The ABS claims that its approach ‘provides a
of life satisfaction, because parents often look digestible selection of statistical evidence that
forward to satisfaction for decades to come will allow Australians to make their own
when they decide to have children, whereas assessment of whether life in Australia is
immediate sacrifices loom large when parents getting better’ (ABS 2006:6). This approach
appraise their current life satisfaction (Bates avoids imposing a particular set of values
2004:14). Gary Becker and Luis Rayo have (weights) in order to provide a single compos-
recently presented a more general argument ite indicator of national progress. It is consis-
that it is plausible for people to follow courses tent with the view that attempts to develop a
of action that would reduce their happiness but single composite indicator of national progress
nevertheless increase their utility. They suggest are fundamentally misconceived because there
that happiness should be viewed as a com- can be no single answer to the question of
modity in the utility function in the same way whether life in most countries is getting better
as health (Becker and Rayo, 2008:89–90). or worse (Castles 1998:352).
How can measurement of subjective well- Such views have not discouraged attempts
being be improved? Better measurement to develop composite indexes of the quality of
seems likely to require movement beyond the life and human development. One possible
current practice of reliance on global ratings of reason for the development of composite
happiness or life satisfaction. For example, indexes is a belief that the blending of compo-
Emma Samman suggests that current practice nents together makes a statistical feast more
‘largely overlooks more robust measures of easily digestible. An alternatively possibility,
psychological well-being’ (Samman 2007:5). given some support in remarks by Amartya
In arguing for a broader approach, she has Sen, is a desire to compete with the ability of
proposed that international comparisons of GDP numbers to grab public attention (Sen
well-being be based on previously tested 1999:318, n41).
indicators covering psychological well-being The best known composite indicator of
and domain-specific life-satisfaction, as well human well-being is the Human Development
as overall life satisfaction and happiness. The Index (HDI) developed by the United Nations
domain-specific questions would cover satis- Development Program (UNDP) and presented
faction with material well-being, health, pro- in the Human Development Report, since its
ductivity, security, community and spiritual inception in 1990 (UNDP 2006:263). The HDI
well-being. gives equal weight to three dimensions of
human development: living a long and healthy
life (measured by life expectancy), being edu-
Composite indexes of human cated (measured by adult literacy and enrol-
well-being ment at the primary, secondary and tertiary
level) and having a decent standard of living
When people want to obtain an overall picture (measured by per capita GDP at purchasing
of well-being, it often makes good sense to power parity). As improvements in life expect-
look at a suite of indicators rather than to rely ancy and education are usually closely asso-
exclusively on particular indicators, such as ciated with economic growth, it is hardly
10

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

surprising that high-income countries tend to The nine dimensions of well-being incorpo-
have high HDI ratings. rated in the index are: psychological well-
Sen, who contributed to the development of being, time use (whether respondents feel that
this index, has suggested that while it is useful they have sufficient time for various non-work
‘in rough and ready work’, it would be ‘a great activities), community vitality (strengths and
mistake to concentrate too much’ on the HDI weaknesses of relationships and interactions
‘or on any other such aggregative index’ (Sen within communities), culture (diversity and
2000:22). resilience of cultural traditions), health, educa-
The major conceptual problem in construct- tion, environment (perceptions and ecological
ing composite indexes is in deciding what knowledge), living standards, and governance
weight, if any, should be given to various (perceptions of equity, honesty, and quality).
factors that are relevant to well-being or human These dimensions ‘were selected on normative
development. Sen has argued strongly that grounds, and are equally weighted, because
what weights may emerge ‘is ultimately a each dimension is considered to be relatively
matter for social choice’ supported by ‘enlight- equal in terms of equal intrinsic importance as
ened public discussion’ (Sen 2000:21). a component of gross national happiness’ (Ura
Although transparent weights that emerge 2008).
from an enlightened social choice process The construction of the index gives greater
are likely to be viewed widely as having weight to large deficits in any dimension than
greater legitimacy than value judgements of to small deficits or shortfalls in several dimen-
technicians, the judgements of individuals— sions. This means that a large deficit in any
determined using survey techniques—could particular dimension has a magnified negative
be viewed as having even greater legitimacy. In impact on the GNH index. The sufficiency
this context, it is worth noting that the National cut-off points for particular dimensions could
Statistical Coordination Board of the Philip- thus have a substantial impact on the results
pines is proposing to ask individuals to iden- obtained. However, current cut-off points
tify domains of happiness from a list and may not be chiselled in stone, as Ura notes
assign weights to each domain in the process that each cut-off point ‘is a value judgement,
of deriving a happiness index (Virola and which can be a topic for public discussion’
Encarnacion 2008). (Ura 2008).
The method of construction of the GNH
index is an adaptation of one developed by
Sabina Alkire and James Foster for research into
Measurement of GNH in Bhutan multidimensional aspects of poverty (Alkire
and Foster 2008). Use of this methodology
The Centre for Bhutan Studies has recently enables the GNH index to be decomposed in
constructed a GNH index that is intended to various ways; for example, to indentify which
‘provide appropriate indicators for Bhutanese dimensions show the highest shortfalls for par-
development’ (Ura 2008). The way this index ticular regions or language groups. Ura com-
has been constructed reveals a great deal about ments that this characteristic makes the index ‘a
the way GNH is now perceived in Bhutan. good tool for tracking changes across time, or
Rather than attempting to obtain a measure of for guiding policies to address specific needs of
aggregate happiness or average happiness, different groups efficiently’ (Ura 2008).
researchers have sought to measure the extent Preliminary estimates of the GNH index
that the attainments of members of the popu- have been published using pilot data (Alkire
lation approach a ‘sufficient level’ in a range of et al. 2008). The data collection process is
dimensions. The underlying philosophy seems much more thorough than that usually associ-
to be that a range of minimum conditions must ated with happiness research. Ura notes that
be met before a person can be considered to be the pilot survey questionnaire was found to
happy. be too lengthy and was pared down to enable
11

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

interviews to be conducted in half a day. He appropriate consideration to the well-being


reports that 950 respondents were interviewed of others, is not confined to individualistic
in 12 districts (Ura 2008). western culture.
In my view, Bhutan’s GNH index is an Efforts to measure happiness or well-being
impressive contribution to measurement of do not necessarily presuppose maximisation of
human well-being. However, it is not yet clear aggregate happiness. Such efforts can be useful
to what extent the judgements implicit in its in considering the effects of different institu-
construction reflect the values of the people of tions or policy approaches wherever happiness
Bhutan: whether they reflect a consensus on and well-being are valued.
such matters as the dimensions of well-being A range of approaches to measurement of
that are important and the weighting that happiness and well-being have been consid-
should be given to each dimension, as well ered, including national accounting indicators
as the determination of the cut-off points for such as GNP and GDP. Such indicators are the
sufficiency in each dimension. It also unclear most commonly used measures of material
whether there is a consensus view within well-being, despite claims that they were never
Bhutan that if a greater number of people attain intended to be used in this way.
excellence, rather than just sufficiency, in The problems associated with the con-
particular dimensions of well-being that this ventional national accounting measures have
makes no contribution to GNH. been widely discussed. They include failure to
account for most nonmarket household pro-
duction, leisure, changes in natural resources
and human capital, external costs and benefits
Summary and conclusions of production, and income distribution.
We have to learn to live with the fact that the
Different views have been expressed on national accounting measures have important
whether maximising the sum total of human deficiencies. While progress has been made in
happiness would be an appropriate govern- dealing with some measurement deficiencies
ment objective. One of the problems discussed in particular studies, attempts to overcome all
in the literature is that maximising aggregate problems within a national accounting frame-
human happiness could involve governments work would involve an unacceptable sacrifice
in encouraging large increases in population, of measurement accuracy to produce results
even if members of this much larger popula- that are likely to be sensitive to controversial
tion lived lives that were barely worth living. assumptions.
This suggests that we cannot assume that the The deficiencies of per capita income should
outcomes of government decisions made to not be exaggerated, however. There is strong
maximise aggregate happiness are necessarily evidence that higher per capita income is gen-
superior to the outcomes of decisions made by erally associated with higher life expectancy
individuals and families without government and improved quality of life.
intervention. Surveys in which respondents are asked to
Problems associated with adopting maximi- provide a numerical rating of their happiness
sation of aggregate happiness as a government or satisfaction with life provide an alternative
objective do not rule out the goal of promoting approach to assessment of well-being. On the
peaceful cooperation among individuals pur- basis of the literature considered, however,
suing their own diverse goals in life. There is such measures could hardly be viewed as
obviously no consensus about the role of gov- having greater reliability than those derived
ernment in society, but the surveyed literature from national income accounting.
suggests that recognition of the desirability If we accept happiness ratings at face value
for governments to promote conditions in we are left with the question of how these
which individuals can succeed in striving to ratings relate to the concept of well-being
achieve worthwhile goals, provided they give (utility) used in economics. Some researchers
12

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

have viewed such ratings as a direct proxy for The recent approach adopted towards GNH
utility, whereas others have argued that happi- measurement in Bhutan is a major innovation,
ness, as an emotional state, should be viewed in that what is measured is the extent that
as a commodity in the utility function, in the members of the population approach a ‘suffi-
same way as health. cient level’ in a range of dimensions related to
Some researchers have suggested that well-being. As with other approaches to mea-
better measures of subjective well-being can surement of human well-being, this approach
be obtained through more extensive use of is imperfect. It will be interesting to observe to
complex questionnaires that seek to measure what extent it succeeds in providing reliable
psychological well-being and satisfaction with information on the well-being of the people of
various aspects of life including material well- Bhutan.
being, health and relationships. Few people would disagree with the
Various attempts have been made, with proposition that happiness is more important
varying levels of success, to develop composite than product. Yet when we come to assessing
indicators of human well-being to supplement human well-being, it is difficult to escape the
or replace conventional national accounting conclusion that the best approach is to gather
indicators. All such indicators, including the together a range of imperfect indicators—
widely used HDI, involve judgements about the including the conventional national account-
items included and the weights given to each ing indicators and objective indicators of
item. There may be merit in an approach being health, longevity, education, and quality of the
adopted in the Philippines that allows survey natural environment—rather than rely exclu-
respondents to identify items affecting their sively on imperfect measures of subjective
well-being and to assign weights to those items. well-being.

References
ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics), 2006. Measures in C. Cüppers (ed.), Proceedings of the Seminar on
of Australia’s progress, Catalogue No. 1370.0, Com- The Relationship Between Religion and State in Tra-
monwealth of Australia. Available at <http:// ditional Tibet; vol. 4., monograph series, Lumbini
www.ausstats.abs.gov.au/ausstats/subscriber. International Research Institute, Lumbini,
nsf/0/47132EE72AC3581DCA25717F0004ACE8/ 4–7 March 2000. Available at <http://www.
$File/13700_2006.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009. bhutanstudies.org.bt/admin/pubFiles/v11-2.
Alkire, S. and Foster, J., 2008. Counting and pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009.
multidimensional poverty measurement, OPHI Bates, W., 2004. ‘Is economic growth given too high a
Working Paper Series: No. 7, Oxford. Available at priority’, Policy, 20(4):9–17.
<http://www.ophi.org.uk/pubs/Alkire_Foster_
——, 2009. ‘Book review: Sustainable Welfare in the
CountingMultidimensionalPoverty.pdf>,
Asia-Pacific by Philip Lawn and Mathew Clarke
accessed 4 August 2009.
(eds.)’, Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 23(1):
Alkire, S., Santos, M. and Ura, K., 2008. Gross
117–8.
National Happiness and Poverty in Bhutan:
preliminary explorations using pilot data, Paper Becker, G. and Rayo, L., 2008. ‘Comment by Gary S.
presented to 4th International Gross National Becker and Luis Rayo’, Brookings Papers on Eco-
Happiness Conference, Thimphu. Available nomic Activity, 1:88–95.
at <http://www.bhutanstudies.org.bt/admin/ Bentham, J., 1789. An introduction to the principles of
pubFiles/13.GNH4.pdf>, accessed 4 August morals and legislation, Clarendon Press, Oxford,
2009. 1907. Available at <http://www.econlib.org/
Ardussi, J., 2005. ‘Formation of the state in Bhutan in library/Bentham/bnthPML1.html>, accessed 4
the 17th century and its Tibetan antecedents’, August 2009.

13

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

Boarini, R., Johansson, A. and Mira d’Ercole, M., —— and ——, 2007. Should national happiness be
2006. Alternative measures of well-being, OECD maximized, Working Paper No. 306, Institute for
Economics Department Working Papers No. 476, Empirical Research in Economics, University of
OECD Publishing. Available at <http://www. Zurich.
oecd.org/dataoecd/48/8/37046710.pdf>, Friedman, B.M., 2006. The Moral Consequences of Eco-
accessed 4 August 2009. nomic Growth, Vintage Books, New York.
Brooks, A., 2008. Gross National Happiness: why hap- Gilbert, D., 2006. Stumbling on Happiness, Random
piness matters for America—and how we can get more House, New York.
of it, Basic Books, New York. Haybron, D., 2007. ‘Life satisfaction, ethical reflec-
Castles, I., 1998. ‘Short response’, in R. Eckersley tion and the science of happiness’, Journal of Hap-
(ed.), Measuring Progress: is life getting better? piness Studies, 8(1):99–138.
CSIRO Publishing, Collingwood, Australia:351–53. Hayek, F., 1982. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Rout-
Clark, A., Frijters, P. and Shields, M., 2008. ‘A survey ledge, London.
of the income happiness gradient’, Journal of ——, 1984. ‘Individualism: true and false’, in C.
Economic Literature, 46(1):95–144. Nishiyama and K. Leube (eds), The Essence
Clark, C., 1957, The Conditions of Economic Progress, of Hayek, Hoover Institution Press, Stanford:131–
Macmillan, London. 159.
Cobb, C., Halstead, T. and Rowe, J., 1995. ‘If GDP Hazlitt, H., 1998. The Foundations of Morality, 3rd
is up why is America down’, The Atlantic edn, The Foundation for Economic Education,
Monthly, 276(October). Available at <http:// New York.
www.theatlantic.com/politics/ecbig/gdp.htm>, Helliwell, J., Barrington-Leigh, C., Harris, A. and
accessed 4 August 2009. Huang, H., 2009. International evidence on
Di Tella, R. and MacCulloch, R., 2006. ‘Some uses of the social context of well-being, Working Paper
happiness research in economics’, Journal of Eco- 14720, National Bureau of Economic Research,
nomic Perspectives, 20(1):25–46. Cambridge, MA. Available at <http://www.
econ.ubc.ca/helliwell/>, accessed 4 August 2009.
Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. 2002. ‘Growth is good for
Honderlich, T. (ed.), 1995. The Oxford Companion to
the poor’, Journal of Economic Growth, 7(3):195–
Philosophy, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
225.
Hume, D., 1777. An Enquiry into the Principles of
Dowrick, S. and Quiggin, J., 1998. ‘Measures of eco- Morals, Project Gutenberg Release 4320 (August
nomic activity and welfare: the uses and abuses 2003). Available at <http://onlinebooks.library.
of GDP’, in R. Eckersley (ed.), Measuring Progress: upenn.edu/webbin/gutbook/lookup?num=
is life getting better?, CSIRO Publishing, Colling- 4320>, accessed 4 August 2009.
wood, Australia:93–121.
Kahneman, D. and Krueger, A., 2006. ‘Develop-
Easterlin, R.A. 1973. ‘Does money buy happiness?’ ments in the measurement of subjective well-
The Public Interest 30:3–10. being’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1):3–24.
——, 1974. ‘Does economic growth improve the Lawn, P. and Clarke, M. (eds), 2008. Sustainable
human lot? Some empirical evidence’, in P. David Welfare in the Asia-Pacific: studies using the genuine
and M. Reder (eds), Nations and Households in progress indicator, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Economic Growth: essays in honor of Moses Layard, R., 2005. Happiness: lessons from a new science,
Abramowitz, Academic Press, New York:89–125. The Penguin Press, New York.
Easterly, W., 1999. ‘Life during growth’, Journal Lewis, W.A., 1955. The Theory of Economic Growth,
of Economic Growth, 4(3):239–75. Available at George Allen & Unwin, London.
<http://www.nyu.edu/fas/institute/dri/ Little, I.M.D., 1957. A Critique of Welfare Economics,
Easterly/File/life%20during%20growth.pdf>, Oxford University Press, London.
accessed 4 August 2009. Mathews, E., 2006. Measuring well-being and
Fisher, I., 1925. Mathematical investigations in the societal progress: a brief history and the latest
Theory of Value and Prices, Yale University Press, news, paper prepared for the joint OECD-JRC
New Haven, CT (original work published 1892). workshop, Milan, 19–21 June 2006. Available
Frey, B., 2008. Happiness: a revolution in economics, at <http://crell.jrc.ec.europa.eu/Well-being/
The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. papers/Matthews_Well-Being%20Measures_
Frey, B. and Stutzer, A., 2002. Happiness and Econom- Milan_final.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009.
ics: how the economy and institutions affect well- McDonald, R., 2008. The future of gross national
being, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. happiness, paper presented to 4th International

14

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
BATES — GROSS NATIONAL HAPPINESS

Gross National Happiness Conference, Thimphu. Stevenson, B. and Wolfers, J., 2008. ‘Economic
Available at <http://www.bhutanstudies.org.bt/ growth and subjective well-being: reassessing
admin/pubFiles/28.GNH4.pdf>, accessed 4 the Easterlin paradox’, Brookings Papers on Eco-
August 2009. nomic Activity, 1:1–87.
McMahon, D., 2006. Happiness: a history, Grove Press, Sugden, R., 2004. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation
New York. and Welfare, 2nd edn, Palgrave Macmillan,
Meier, G. and Baldwin, R., 1957. Economic Develop- Hampshire and New York.
ment, John Wiley and Sons, New York. Thinley, J., 2007. ‘What is gross national happiness’,
Mishan, E.J., 1967. The Costs of Economic Growth, Fre- in Rethinking Development—proceedings of the
derick A Praeger, New York, Washington. second international conference on gross national hap-
Ng, Y.-K., 2008. ‘Happiness studies: ways to improve piness, The Centre for Bhutan Studies, Bhutan.
comparability and some public policy implica- Available at, <http://www.bhutanstudies.org.
tions’, Economic Record, 84(265):253–66. bt/main/pub_detail.php?pubid=57>, accessed 4
Nordhaus, W.D. and Tobin, J., 1972. Is growth August 2009.
obsolete?, from Economic Growth, Fiftieth Ura, K., 2008. GNH index, paper presented to 4th
Anniversary Colloquium V, New York, National International Gross National Happiness Con-
Bureau of Economic Research, New York. ference, Thimphu. Available at <http://www.
Available at <http://www.nber.org/chapters/ bhutanstudies.org.bt/admin/pubFiles/12.
c3621.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009. GNH4.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009.
Nozick, R., 2001. Invariances: the structure of the objec- Ura, K. and Galay, K., 2004. ‘Preface’, in K. Ura and
tive world, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, K. Galay (eds), Gross National Happiness and
MA. Development: proceedings of the first international
Okun, A., 1971. ‘Social welfare has no price tag’, seminar on operationalization of gross national hap-
Survey of Current Business, July: 129–33. piness, The Centre for Bhutan Studies, Bhutan.
Parfit, D., 1984. Reasons and Persons, Clarendon Press, UNDP (United Nations Development Program),
Oxford. 2006. Human Development Report 2006, Palgrave
Pigou, A.C., 1932. The Economics of Welfare, Mac- Macmillan, New York. Available at <http://hdr.
millan, London. Available at <http://www. undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr2006/>,
econlib.org/Library/NPDBooks/Pigou/pgEW. accessed 4 August 2009.
html>, accessed 4 August 2009. van den Bergh, J., 2007. Abolishing GDP, Tinbergen
Pritchett, L. and Summers, L.H., 1996. ‘Wealthier is Institute Discussion Paper 2007-019/3, Tinbergen
healthier’, The Journal of Human Resources, 31(4): Institute, Amsterdam. Available at <http://www.
841–68. tinbergen.nl/discussionpapers/07019.pdf>,
Samman, E., 2007. Psychological and subjective well- accessed 4 August 2009.
being: a proposal for internationally comparable Virola, R. and Encarnacion, J., 2008. Gross National
indicators, Working Paper 5, OPHI Working Happiness Index: towards measuring progress of
Paper Series, Oxford. Available at <http://www. societies, paper presented to the First Session of
ophi.org.uk/pubs/Samman_Psych_Subj_ the Committee on Statistics, UNESCAP, Bangkok,
Wellbeing_FINAL.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009. Thailand, 15–17 December, National Statistics
Schwartz, N. and Strack, F., 1999. ‘Reports of subjec- Coordination Board, Philippines. Available at
tive well-being: judgemental processes and their <http://www.unescap.org/stat/cst/1/CST1-
methodological implications’, in D. Kahneman, INF21p-Philippines.pdf>, accessed 4 August
E. Diener and N. Schwartz (eds), Well-Being: the 2009.
foundations of hedonic psychology, Russell Sage Wierzbicka, A., 2004. ‘ “Happiness” in cross-
Foundation, New York:61–84. linguistic and cross-cultural perspective’, Daed-
Seligman, M. 2002. Authentic Happiness, Free Press, alus, 133(2):34–43.
New York. World Bank, 2000. World Development Report 2000/
Sen, A., 1999. Development as Freedom, Random 2001: attacking poverty, Oxford University Press,
House, New York. New York. Available at <http://web.worldbank.
——, 2000. ‘A decade of haman development’, org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/
Journal of Human Development, 1(1):17–23. EXTPOVERTY/0,,contentMDK:20195989~
Sidgwick, H., 1907. The Methods of Ethics, Macmillan, pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:336992~
London (original work published 1874). isCURL:Y,00.html>, accessed 4 August 2009.

15

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.
ASIAN-PACIFIC ECONOMIC LITERATURE

——, 2006. Where is the Wealth of Nations? Measuring Yeager, L. 2001. Ethics as Social Science: the moral
capital for the 21st century, The World Bank, Wash- philosophy of social cooperation, Edward Elgar,
ington, DC. Available at <http://siteresources. Cheltenham, UK.
worldbank.org/INTEEI/214578-1110886258964/
20748034/All.pdf>, accessed 4 August 2009.

16

© 2009 The Author


Journal compilation © 2009 Crawford School of Economics and Government,
The Australian National University and Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd.

View publication stats

You might also like