You are on page 1of 97

Chapter 11

Competitive Equilibrium
in an Exchange Economy
Exchange
‹ Two consumers, A and B.
‹ Their endowments of goods 1 and 2
are A A A
ω = (ω 1 , ω 2 ) and ω = (ω 1 , ω 2 ).
B B B

A
‹ E.g. ω = ( 6,4 ) and ω = ( 2, 2 ).
B

‹ The total quantities available


A B
are ω 1 + ω 1 = 6 + 2 = 8 units of good 1
A B
and ω2 + ω2 = 4 + 2 = 6 units of good 2.
Exchange

‹ Edgeworth and Bowley devised a


diagram, called an Edgeworth box, to
show all possible allocations of the
available quantities of goods 1 and 2
between the two consumers.
Starting an Edgeworth Box
Starting an Edgeworth Box

A B
ω
Width = 1 + ω 1 = 6+2= 8
Starting an Edgeworth Box

Height =
A B
ω2 + ω2
= 4+2
=6

A B
ω
Width = 1 + ω 1 = 6+2= 8
Starting an Edgeworth Box

Height =
A B The dimensions of
ω2 + ω2 the box are the
= 4+2 quantities available
=6 of the goods.

A B
ω
Width = 1 + ω 1 = 6+2= 8
Feasible Allocations
‹ What allocations of the 8 units of
good 1 and the 6 units of good 2 are
feasible?
‹ How can all of the feasible
allocations be depicted by the
Edgeworth box diagram?
Feasible Allocations
‹ What allocations of the 8 units of
good 1 and the 6 units of good 2 are
feasible?
‹ How can all of the feasible
allocations be depicted by the
Edgeworth box diagram?
‹ One feasible allocation: the
endowment allocation.
The Endowment Allocation
OB

6
4

OA A
ω = ( 6,4 )
6
8
The Endowment Allocation
2
OB
2

6
4

OA
6 B
ω = ( 2, 2 )
8
The Endowment Allocation
2
OB
2

6 The
4 endowment
allocation
OA A
ω = ( 6,4 )
6 B
ω = ( 2, 2 )
8
The Endowment Allocation

More generally, …
Other Feasible Allocations
A A
‹ ( x1 , x 2 ) denotes an allocation to
consumer A.
B B
‹ ( x1 , x 2 ) denotes an allocation to
consumer B.
‹ An allocation is feasible if and only if

x1A + xB1 ≤ ω 1
A
+ ω B
1
A B A B
and x 2 + x 2 ≤ ω 2 + ω 2 .
Feasible Reallocations
B
x1
OB
A
ω2 xB
2
+
B
ω2
A
x2
OA
x1A
A B
ω1 + ω1
Feasible Reallocations
B
x1
OB
A B
ω2 x2
+
B
ω2 A
x2

OA
x1A
A B
ω1 + ω1
Feasible Reallocations

‹ Allpoints in the box, including the


boundary, represent feasible
allocations of the combined
endowments.
Feasible Reallocations

‹ All points in the box, including the


boundary, represent feasible
allocations of the combined
endowments.
‹ Which allocations will be blocked by
one or both consumers?
‹ Which allocations make both
consumers better off?
Adding Preferences to the Box
xA For consumer A.
2

A
ω2
OA
ω 1A x1A
Adding Preferences to the Box
xA For consumer A.
2 M
or
e
pr
ef
er
re
d

A
ω2
OA
ω 1A x1A
Adding Preferences to the Box
xB For consumer B.
2

B
ω2

OB
ω 1B xB
1
Adding Preferences to the Box
xB For consumer B.
2 M
or
e
pr
ef
er
B re
ω2 d

OB
ω 1B xB
1
Adding Preferences to the Box
B
xB For consumer B. ω 1 OB
1

M B
ω2
or
e
pr
ef
er
r ed

xB
2
Adding Preferences to the Box
xA For consumer A.
2

A
ω2
OA
ω 1A x1A
A
Edgeworth’s Box
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Pareto-Improvement

‹ DEFINITION: An allocation is Pareto-


improving if it improves the welfare
of a consumer without reducing the
welfare of another.

‹ Where are the Pareto-improving


allocations?
A
Edgeworth’s Box
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
A
Pareto-Improvements
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
The set of Pareto-
improving allocations xB
2
Pareto-Improvements

‹ Since each consumer can refuse to


trade, the only possible outcomes
from exchange are Pareto-improving
allocations.
‹ But which particular Pareto-
improving allocation will be the
outcome of trade?
A
Pareto-Improvements
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
The set of Pareto-
improving reallocations xB
2
Pareto-Improvements
Pareto-Improvements
Pareto-Improvements

Trade
improves both
A’s and B’s welfares.
This is a Pareto-improvement
over the endowment allocation.
Pareto-Improvements

Trade
improves both
A’s and B’s welfares.
This is a Pareto-improvement
over the endowment allocation.
Pareto-Improvements
Further trade cannot improve
both A and B’s
welfares.
Pareto-Optimality
A is strictly better off
but B is strictly worse
off
Pareto-Optimality
A is strictly better off
but B is strictly worse
off

B is strictly better
off but A is strictly
worse off
Pareto-Optimality
Both A and
B are worse A is strictly better off
off but B is strictly worse
off

B is strictly better
off but A is strictly
worse off
Pareto-Optimality
Both A and
B are worse A is strictly better off
off but B is strictly worse
off

B is strictly better Both A


off but A is strictly and B are
worse off worse
off
Pareto-Optimality

The allocation is
Pareto-optimal since the
only way one consumer’s
welfare can be increased is to
decrease the welfare of the other
consumer.
Pareto-Optimality
An allocation where convex
indifference curves are “only
just back-to-back” is
Pareto-optimal.

The allocation is
Pareto-optimal since the
only way one consumer’s
welfare can be increased is to
decrease the welfare of the other
consumer.
Pareto-Optimality

‹ Where are all of the Pareto-optimal


allocations of the endowment?
A
Pareto-Optimality
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
A
Pareto-Optimality
x2 All the allocations marked by
a are Pareto-optimal.
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Pareto-Optimality

‹ DEFINITION: The contract curve is


the set of all Pareto-optimal
allocations.
A
Pareto-Optimality
x2 All the allocations marked by
a are Pareto-optimal.
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
The contract curve
xB
2
Pareto-Optimality

‹ But to which of the many allocations


on the contract curve will consumers
trade?
‹ That depends upon how trade is
conducted.
‹ In perfectly competitive markets? By
one-on-one bargaining?
A
The Core
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
The set of Pareto-
improving reallocations xB
2
A
The Core
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
A
The Core
x 2 Pareto-optimal trades blocked
by B
B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
Pareto-optimal trades blocked
by A xB
2
A
The Core
x2 Pareto-optimal trades not blocked
by A or B
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
A
The Core
x2 Pareto-optimal trades not blocked
by A or B are the core.
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
The Core
‹ DEFINITION: The core is the set of all
Pareto-optimal allocations that are
welfare-improving for both consumers
relative to their own endowments.

‹ Rationaltrade should achieve a core


allocation.
The Core

‹ Butwhich core allocation?


‹ Again, that depends upon the
manner in which trade is conducted.
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ Considertrade in perfectly
competitive markets.

‹ Eachconsumer is a price-taker trying


to maximize her own utility given p1,
p2 and her own endowment. That is,
...
Trade in Competitive Markets
xA For consumer A.
2
p1x1A + p 2x A
2 = p ω
1 1
A
+ p ω
2 2
A

A’s income

*A
x2
A
ω2
OA
x*1A ω 1A x1A
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ So given p1 and p2, consumer A’s net


demands for commodities 1 and 2
are
*A A *A A
x1 − ω 1 and x 2 − ω 2 .
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ And, similarly, for consumer B …


Trade in Competitive Markets
xB For consumer B.
2
B B B B
p1x 1 + p 2x 2 = p1ω 1 + p 2ω 2

B
ω2
x*2B

OB
ω 1B x*1B xB
1
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ So given p1 and p2, consumer B’s net


demands for commodities 1 and 2
are
*B B *B B
x1 − ω 1 and x 2 − ω 2 .
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ A Walrasian equilibrium is a vector


(x, p) such that for each consumer:

1) X is an optimal bundle
2) X is affordable
3) Markets clear
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Can this PO allocation be
achieved?
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A

B
xB ω1 OB
1

*A
x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

*A
x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
B
x
Budget constraint for consumer B 2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B
*A
x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
B
x
Budget constraint for consumer B 2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B
*A
x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
But *A *B A B
x1 + x1 < ω1 + ω1 xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B
*A
x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
and *A *B A B
x2 + x2 > ω2 + ω2 xB
2
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ So at the given prices p1 and p2 there


is an
– excess supply of commodity 1
– excess demand for commodity 2.
‹ Neither market clears so the prices
p1 and p2 do not cause a general
equilibrium.
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 So this PO allocation cannot be
achieved by competitive trading.
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade in Competitive Markets

‹ Since there is an excess demand for


commodity 2, p2 will rise.
‹ Since there is an excess supply of
commodity 1, p1 will fall.
‹ The slope of the budget constraints
is - p1/p2 so the budget constraints
will pivot about the endowment point
and become less steep.
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB ω1 O
1 B

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
* A ω 2A
x2 ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
* A ω 2A
x2 ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
Budget constraint for consumer B xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B

B
* A ω 2A
x2 ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
Budget constraint for consumer B xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B

B
* A ω 2A
x2 ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
So *A *B A B
x1 + x1 = ω1 + ω1 xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB ω1 OB
1

x*2B

B
* A ω 2A
x2 ω2
OA A
*A ω1 A
x1
x1
and *A *B A B
x2 + x2 = ω2 + ω2 xB
2
First Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
‹ Giventhat consumers’ preferences
are well-behaved, trading in perfectly
competitive markets implements a
Pareto-optimal allocation of the
economy’s endowment.
Second Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
‹ Giventhat consumers’ preferences
are well-behaved, for any Pareto-
optimal allocation there are prices
and an allocation of the total
endowment that makes the Pareto-
optimal allocation implementable by
trading in competitive markets.
Second Fundamental Theorem
A
x2

B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1
The contract curve
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A
x2

*B B
xB x1 ω1 OB
1

*A *B
x2 x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA *A A
x1 ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Implemented by competitive
x2
trading from the endowment ω.
*B B
xB x1 ω1 OB
1

*A *B
x2 x2
B
ω 2A ω2
OA *A A
x1 ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Can this allocation be implemented
x2
by competitive trading from ω?
B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Can this allocation be implemented
x2
by competitive trading from ω? No.
B
xB ω1 OB
1

B
ω 2A ω2
OA A
ω1 A
x1

xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A But this allocation is implemented
x2
by competitive trading from θ.

xB θ1
B
OB
1

θ2
A
θ2
B

OA
θ1
A A
x1

xB
2
Walras’ Law
‹ Walras’Law is an identity; i.e. a
statement that is true for any
positive prices (p1,p2), whether these
are equilibrium prices or not.
Walras’ Law
‹ Every consumer’s preferences are
well-behaved so, for any positive
prices (p1,p2), each consumer spends
all of his budget.
‹ For consumer A:
*A *A A A
p1x1 + p 2x 2 = p1ω 1 + p 2ω 2
For consumer B:
p1x*1B + p 2x*2B = p1ω 1B + p 2ω 2B
Walras’ Law
p1x*1A + p 2x*2A = p1ω 1A + p 2ω 2A
p1x*1B + p 2x*2B = p1ω 1B + p 2ω 2B
Summing gives
p1 ( x*1A + x*1B ) + p 2 ( x*2A + x*2B )
= p1 ( ω 1A + ω 1B ) + p 2 ( ω 2B + ω 2B ).
Walras’ Law
p1 ( x*1A + x*1B ) + p 2 ( x*2A + x*2B )
A B B B
= p1 ( ω 1 + ω 1 ) + p 2 ( ω 2 + ω 2 ).
Rearranged,
*A *B A B
p1 ( x 1 + x 1 − ω 1 − ω 1 ) +
p 2 ( x*2A + x*2B − ω 2A − ω 2B ) = 0 .
That is, ...
Walras’ Law
*A
p 1 ( x1 + x1
*B
− ω1
A
− ω1 ) +
B

p 2 ( x *2A + x *2B − ω 2A − ω B2 )
= 0.
This says that the sum of the excess
demands across market is zero for
any positive prices p1 and p2 --
this is Walras’ Law.
Implications of Walras’ Law

So one implication of Walras’ Law for


a two-commodity exchange economy
is that if one market is in equilibrium
then the other market must also be in
equilibrium.
Implications of Walras’ Law

So a second implication of Walras’ Law


for a two-commodity exchange economy
is that an excess supply in one market
implies an excess demand in the other
market.

You might also like