You are on page 1of 11

554 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO.

1, FEBRUARY 2010

Short-Term Trading for a Wind Power Producer


Juan M. Morales, Student Member, IEEE, Antonio J. Conejo, Fellow, IEEE, and Juan Pérez-Ruiz, Member, IEEE

Abstract—This paper presents a technique to derive the best of- Excess of energy (positive deviation)
fering strategy for a wind power producer in an electricity market incurred by the wind producer with respect
that includes various trading floors. Uncertainty pertaining to
to the schedule in time period and scenario
wind availability, market prices at the different trading stages,
and balancing energy needs are properly taken into account. Risk (in MWh).
on profit variability is suitably controlled at the cost of a small Deficit of energy (negative deviation)
reduction in expected profit. The proposed technique translates incurred by the wind producer with respect
into a linear programming problem of moderate size, which is
to the schedule in time period and scenario
readily solvable using commercially available software. A variety
of numerical case studies demonstrate the interest and effective- (in MWh).
ness of the proposed technique. Appropriate conclusions are duly Auxiliary variable used to compute the
drawn. conditional value at risk, CVaR [in ].
Index Terms—Optimal offering, risk, stochastic programming, Auxiliary variable in scenario used to
wind power. compute the CVaR [in ].

NOTATION C. Random variables


The main notation used throughout the paper is stated next Adjustment market price in time period
for quick reference. Other symbols are defined as required. (in /MWh).
Day-ahead market price in time period (in
A. Indices and numbers /MWh).
Index of time periods running from 1 to . Price for upward energy resulting from
Index of scenarios running from 1 to . the balancing market in time period (in
/MWh).
B. Continuous variables Price for downward energy resulting from
Power offered by the wind producer in the balancing market in time period (in
the day-ahead market for time period /MWh).
(in MW). Price of positive imbalances incurred in
Power offered by the wind producer in the time period (in /MWh).
adjustment market for time period and Price of negative imbalances incurred in
scenario (in MW). time period (in /MWh).
Power production scheduled for the wind Wind power production in time period (in
producer in time period and scenario MW).
(in MW). Ratio between positive imbalance price and
Total deviation of energy incurred by day-ahead market price in time period .
the wind producer with respect to the Ratio between negative imbalance price
schedule in time period and scenario and day-ahead market price in time
(in MWh). period .

These variables, if augmented with the subscript , represent


Manuscript received December 04, 2008; revised July 16, 2009. First pub- their realization in scenario .
lished January 08, 2010; current version published January 20, 2010. The work
of J. M. Morales and A. J. Conejo was supported in part by the Junta de Co-
munidades de Castilla-La Mancha through Project PCI-08-0102 and in part D. Constants
by the Ministry of Science and Technology of Spain through CICYT Project Duration of time period (in hours).
DPI2006-08001. Paper no. TPWRS-00893-2008.
J. M. Morales and A. J. Conejo are with the University of Castilla-La Installed capacity of the wind farm (in
Mancha, 13071 Ciudad Real, Spain (e-mail: juanmiguel.morales@uclm.es;
antonio.conejo@uclm.es).
MW).
J. Pérez-Ruiz is with the University of Málaga, 29071 Málaga, Spain (e-mail: Per unit confidence level.
jperez@uma.es).
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/TPWRS.2009.2036810
Probability of occurrence of scenario .

0885-8950/$26.00 © 2010 IEEE


MORALES et al.: SHORT-TERM TRADING FOR A WIND POWER PRODUCER 555

I. INTRODUCTION For the risk-neutral case, we provide the value of the stochastic
solution (VSS) and the expected value of perfect information
A. Motivation (EVPI). In addition, we illustrate the gains associated with risk
HE integration of wind power is increasing rapidly in control in terms of profit stability for a very moderate reduction
T many electric energy systems throughout the world
[1]–[4]. Two main driving forces motivate this raise: the in-
in expected profit. The VSS is a metric that allows assessing
the effectiveness of a stochastic programming approach (see
creasing price of fossil fuels (natural gas, oil, and coal) as less [5] or [7]). It is defined as the difference between the expected
and less reserves are available and the need to curtail carbon profit of the stochastic model and the expected profit obtained
emissions to preserve a functioning atmosphere. from the problem, where the decisions variables are fixed to
As the wind power technology matures and reaches break- those resulting from the associated deterministic problem, i.e.,
even costs, subsidies turn out to be less and less relevant, and the problem in which stochastic variables are replaced by their
wind producers become interested in participating in electricity respective expected values. On the other hand, the EVPI is an
markets to maximize their profits. This is particularly the case index measuring how much the wind producer would be willing
for producers owning wind farms at different network locations, to pay to know the future realizations of the stochastic processes
which have the possibility of combining their wind production under consideration (market prices and wind availability). It is
resources and offering power generation portfolios to partici- calculated as the difference between the expected profit resulting
pate in different short-term trading floors within a fully fledged from the problem, where the decisions to be made anticipate the
electricity market. subsequent outcomes of the random variables and the expected
However, wind power is undispatchable and plagued by the profit of the stochastic model (see [5]). Specifically, we compute
major uncertainty that constitutes wind availability. Thus, the this metric by assuming perfect information on each stochastic
market strategy of a wind producer must hedge against this un- process separately in order to quantify the relative importance
certainty to be profit effective and to dampen the profit vari- of each source of uncertainty that is considered.
ability due to very significant wind fluctuation. In addition to un-
certainty on wind availability, the wind producer must also cope C. Literature Review
with uncertain market prices. In this context, due to the nondis- To deal with the financial losses stemmed from the variability
patchable nature of wind power production, no risk-hedging in- and uncertainty of wind power, three main approaches have been
strument (e.g., a forward contract) is available for wind pro- proposed in the literature. One of them is based on the combined
ducers other than modifying their offers in short-term markets. and coordinated use of wind power and energy storage technolo-
The pernicious effect of production uncertainty is eliminated gies (pumped-storage facilities, compressed air facilities, etc.)
by a balancing mechanism that allows covering the lack of pro- [8]–[11]. Another relevant approach is presented in [12], where
duction of uncertain sources, such as wind power. The balancing financial options are introduced as a tool for wind producers to
mechanism is provided by energy sources that are generally ex- hedge against wind generation uncertainty. The third approach
pensive but dispatchable, such as combine cycle gas turbines. focuses on designing stochastic models intended to produce op-
As a wind producer needs to rely more and more on the bal- timal offering strategies for a wind producer participating in an
ancing mechanism, its profitability deteriorates quickly. Thus, electricity market on its own [13]–[15].
a key concern of a wind producer should be to reduce its need The research presented in this paper follows this last approach
for balancing energy. and, in particular, introduces significant advances in the line
of research initiated in [15], where stochastic programming is
B. Approach used to generate optimal offers for trading wind generation in
The uncertainty sources faced by a wind producer are specif- short-term energy markets. These advances have to do with im-
ically four: 1) wind availability; 2) the hourly price of the day- provements in the mathematical formulation of the problem, the
ahead market; 3) the hourly price of adjustment markets within consideration of risk management, and the analysis of the ben-
one day (one or several of these markets can be considered); efits of including an adjustment market within the market struc-
and 4) the hourly price of the balancing energy resulting from ture from a wind producer perspective.
the balancing mechanism.
We consider a fully fledged multimarket trading floor in- D. Contributions
cluding the day-ahead market, a single adjustment market The contributions of this paper are fourfold:
(sufficiently liquid and closing just prior to actual opera- 1) to provide a tool to derive hourly offering strategies
tion), and a real-time energy balancing mechanism. Also, (curves) for a wind producer operating within an elec-
the production mix is assumed to be compatible with such a tricity market involving various trading floors and a
market structure, i.e., the wind penetration allows the proper balancing mechanism;
functioning of the day-ahead and adjustment markets. Within 2) to express the tool in 1) as a linear programming problem,
this market framework, we develop a multistage stochastic which can be efficiently solved using commercially avail-
programming model (see [5] or [6]) that embodies risk control able solvers;
on profit variability and provides optimal offering curves for 3) to provide an effective way to limit the risk of the profit
the day-ahead market. The offering strategy is derived for the variability of the wind producer at the cost of a small re-
day-ahead market, but analogous offering strategies can be duction in its expected profit;
derived for the adjustment markets in a straightforward manner. 4) to analyze and discuss in detail a realistic case study.
556 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2010

II. PROBLEM DESCRIPTION In order to palliate the excess of generation in the system,
the operator uses the balancing market where producers
A. Market Framework submit offers to repurchase the energy previously sold
in the day-ahead market. Assuming a rational behavior,
Consider a wind power producer participating in a pool-based producers are only willing to repurchase the excess of
electricity market that includes three independent and succes- energy at a price smaller than the day-ahead
sive short-term trading floors: the day-ahead market, the adjust- market-clearing price . Thus, those market par-
ment market, and the balancing market. We consider that the ticipants causing the positive system imbalance are
wind producer has no market power capability in either of the remunerated for their overproduction at . As a result,
aforementioned markets, and that its objective is to maximize they obtain a profit smaller than the profit they would
its expected profits from trading energy in the day-ahead and have achieved if they had sold their overproduction in the
adjustment markets and minimize the imbalance cost incurred day-ahead market. On the contrary, those market partici-
in the balancing market. pants producing less energy than that resulting from the
Each one of the three markets is cleared through a single day-ahead market, and consequently helping to alleviate
auction process. The time framework for market clearing is as the positive system imbalance are just paid at for their
follows. The day-ahead market concerning the whole day d is actual production, and so they do not incur imbalance cost.
cleared at 10 A.M. of day . Because of the significant delay 2) If the system imbalance is negative (deficit of generation),
between the closure of this market and the beginning of the en- then
ergy delivery period (14 h), the electricity pool includes an ad- (3)
justment market, where it is possible to take corrective actions.
These actions are intended to reduce or eliminate the differences (4)
between the expected production and the schedule cleared in the In this case, the operator organizes a balancing market to
day-ahead market. This adjustment market is of especial rele- which producers submit additional selling offers. Again,
vance for wind producers, as it allows them to incorporate into assuming a rational behavior, producers are willing to
their offers the certainty gained during the time interval between produce the amount of energy required to cover the deficit
the closure of both markets by updating their generation fore- of generation at a price higher than the day-ahead
casts, thus reducing the associated uncertainty. In this paper, market-clearing price . The cost of this transaction
we consider that the adjustment market is cleared very close falls on those market participants responsible for the
to the delivery horizon (e.g., one hour or half an hour before). system imbalance. In this sense, note that, as the price of
It should be noted that additional adjustments markets can be this additional energy is higher than the actual price of
considered. Finally, the balancing market ensures the real-time the energy traded in the day-ahead market, the balancing
balance between generation and demand by offsetting the differ- process implies a profit loss for these market participants
ences between the real-time operation and the last energy pro- with respect to the profit they would have obtained by
gram cleared in the markets. For this reason, this market remains selling only their actual production in the day-ahead
open until 15 min before the delivery hour. Therefore, through market. On the other hand, those market participants
this last market, energy imbalances are corrected and priced ac- producing more than agreed on the day-ahead market, and
cording to the settlement mechanism for imbalance prices ex- consequently contributing to mitigate the negative system
plained below. The electricity market of the Iberian Peninsula imbalance are paid at for their overproduction, and
motivates this modeling framework [16]. hence they do not incur imbalance cost.
From the above discussion, it follows that and
B. Mechanism for Imbalance Prices .
It is important to emphasize that according to these criteria,
Imbalance prices result from the system balancing market, in those participants who offset the system imbalance, i.e., those
which the price of the energy replacing the deviation is deter- participants who contribute to restore the system balance, are
mined. not penalized, which is a rational and reasonable assumption.
In the wholesale electricity market of the Iberian Peninsula,
like in the rest of European electricity markets, a price for the C. Wind Producer Revenues
positive energy deviation (higher production or lower consump- Consider a wind power producer that offers and gets accepted
tion than scheduled) and a price for the negative energy devia- a level of energy into the day-ahead market for time period
tion (lower production or higher consumption than scheduled) , but actually generates . For the sake of simplicity, no ad-
are settled for each time period. These prices represent the cost justment market is considered in this exposition. The revenue
of the energy required to counteract the unplanned deviations, of this wind power producer for period is
and consequently, they depend on the sign of the imbalance as
a whole (system imbalance). Specifically, the following. (5)
1) If the system imbalance is positive (excess of generation),
then where is the imbalance income resulting from the balancing
process and may be negative, i.e., it may represent a cost. The
(1) total deviation incurred by the wind producer is defined as

(2) (6)
MORALES et al.: SHORT-TERM TRADING FOR A WIND POWER PRODUCER 557

and consequently, is given by of the market horizon are still uncertain. Therefore, in this
second stage, and for every day-ahead market price real-
(7) ization, decisions are made based on plausible scenarios
. of adjustment and balancing prices, and of wind power
According to expression (6), a positive deviation means produc- production. Note that the wind production scenarios, span-
tion surplus and a negative deviation represents a deficit of pro- ning the whole market horizon and available at this second
duction. Therefore, is the price at which the wind pro- stage, are generated knowing the actual wind production
ducer will be paid (charged) for its excess (deficit) of generation. in the periods between the closures of the day-ahead and
Lastly, if we define adjustment markets.
3) The last stage of the stochastic programming approach is
determined by the materialization of both the imbalance
(8)
prices and the wind power generated in the time periods
spanning the whole market horizon. Thus, the deviation
(9) incurred by the wind power producer in each one of these
periods is known and the consequent cost for imbalance
then
can be computed.
(10) E. Uncertainty Characterization
.
Seasonal autoregressive integrated moving average
Note that definitions (8) and (9) are valid under the assump-
(ARIMA) models [17] have been used to characterize the
tion that the hourly electricity prices in the day-ahead market
following.
are positive, i.e., . This is consistent with the price be-
1) The price series in the day-ahead market.
havior in most electricity markets, and particularly, with the one
2) The difference between the price series in the adjustment
in the Iberian Peninsula, which motivates this study. Ratios
market and the price series in the day-ahead market;
and would need to be redefined for other market structures
working on this difference allows preserving the strong
where zero prices in the day-ahead market do frequently occur.
correlation between both price series.
D. Stochastic Programming Approach 3) The series defined as:
. Note that the ratio series and can be directly
The wind producer problem described above is subject to four derived from by applying the rules (1)–(4) governing the
sources of uncertainty, namely the day-ahead market price, the mechanism for imbalance prices described in Section II-B.
adjustment market price, the wind power generation, and the In particular, it holds that, if , then , and
price for imbalance. Among these sources of uncertainty, the vice versa. In addition, note that series can be linearly
one associated with the wind power production constitutes the expressed as . Fig. 1 illustrates a graphical
keystone of the decision-making process. Given that the wind explanation of the modeling of imbalance price ratios.
production is characterized by zero generation cost, its unpre- To generate price (day-ahead, adjustment, and balancing)
dictable nature is directly responsible for the likely loss of gains scenarios, we use seasonal ARIMA models because these
incurred by the wind power producer through the imbalance models provide appropriate accuracy for moderate effort.
cost. Moreover, they are simple to derive and fit.
In order to account for the impact of these sources of un- To characterize the wind speed uncertainty, the following
certainty on the wind producer offer, we propose to charac- second-order autoregressive model is used:
terize them as stochastic processes and solve the wind producer
problem stated above by using a multistage stochastic program- (11)
ming approach, wherein each stage represents a market. The se-
quence of stages and decisions is as follows. where represents the wind speed in time period , is white
1) Design the offer strategy for the day-ahead market and noise, and , , and are parameters estimated from histor-
submit the resulting energy selling offers to this market for ical data. Autoregressive models have been proved to perform
each period of the market horizon. In this stage, decisions well for short time horizons. Giebel et al. [18] provide a good
are made based on plausible realizations of the stochastic summary of the state of the art in models for short-term predic-
processes involved, namely, market prices (day ahead, ad- tion of wind power.
justment, and balancing) and wind power production. Once the wind speed scenarios are generated, they are trans-
2) Once the day-ahead market price is known for each time formed into power scenarios through the power curve associated
period, decide the amount of energy to sell/buy in/from the to each turbine model installed in the wind farm. Then, under the
adjustment market. Specifically, at the moment that this assumption that the characteristics of the wind are the same all
decision is made, the 24-hourly day-ahead market prices over the plant at each instant, scenarios representing the power
and the wind power generated in the time periods between output of the wind farm can be obtained by just aggregating the
the closures of the day-ahead and adjustment markets are production of each available turbine in the plant. Note that it
known. On the contrary, the adjustment and balancing is not the purpose of this paper to develop an accurate charac-
market prices, and the wind power production for the rest terization of the wind speed uncertainty, neither to illustrate a
558 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2010

Fig. 1. Graphical representation complementing the explanation of the modeling of imbalance price ratios.

rigorous procedure to convert wind speed scenarios into wind alizations from which the corresponding wind speed sce-
power scenarios for a specific wind plant. narios are simulated according to model (11). Finally, also note
The aforementioned stochastic models can be used to gen- that .
erate price-wind power scenarios using a tree format. Note that For the sake of problem tractability, a fast-forward reduction
this paper does not focus on scenario generation, and thus, we algorithm as described in [19] is used in this paper to reduce the
do not deal with likely correlations among market prices (day number of scenarios while still retaining the essential features
ahead, adjustment, and balancing) and wind production. The of the original scenario tree.
study of such correlations constitutes a subject that is outside
the scope of this paper, requires further research, and affects III. MATHEMATICAL FORMULATION
solely the building of the scenario tree. Thus, the uncertainty A. Basic Model
characterizing the wind producer problem is modeled through a
symmetric scenario tree that is specifically built as follows. The optimization problem to maximize the expected profit of
1) Generate price scenarios for the day-ahead market. a wind power producer trading just in the day-ahead market can
2) For each realization of the day-ahead market prices, simu- be formulated as follows:
late price scenarios for the adjustment market.
3) For each scenario of the adjustment market prices, generate (12)
wind power realizations.
4) Finally, for each wind power realization, simulate im-
balance price ratio scenarios. (13)
Hence, the total number of scenarios composing the tree is
. (14)
An appropriate modeling of the uncertainty characterizing (15)
the wind producer problem should include the knowledge on
the wind generation stochastic process gained during the time Note that, assuming zero generation cost for the wind pro-
interval between the closure of the day-ahead and adjustment duction units, the expected profit, i.e., the objective function
markets. This gain of certainty is due to the fact that the en- (12), equals the expected revenue of the wind power producer.
ergy selling/buying offer to submit in the adjustment market Equation (13) constitutes the definition, per period and scenario,
can be decided taking into account the realized values of the of the imbalance income function. Constraints (14) limit the
wind generation stochastic process for the time periods after the amount of power that can be sold in the day-ahead market, and
day-ahead market clearing. In order to reflect this circumstance (15) defines the total deviation incurred by the wind producer in
within the scenario tree, we propose to generate wind speed each period and scenario.
scenarios as follows. In order to model the imbalance income function , a
1) Simulate wind speed scenarios for the periods making binary variable is used in [15] for each time period and
up the time interval between the closure of the day-ahead each scenario . The resulting model is then formulated as a
and adjustment markets. mixed-integer nonlinear programming problem. In this paper,
2) For each one of the wind speed scenarios generated in the an equivalent linear programming formulation is proposed
previous step, simulate wind speed scenarios for the with the consequent gain in robustness, simplicity, and com-
time interval spanning from the closure of the adjustment putational efficiency. This linear formulation is presented next
market and the end of the market horizon. [(16)–(21)] and is based on decomposing the energy imbalance
It should be noted that each one of the wind speed scenarios into the sum of a positive and a negative imbalances,
generated in step 1 constitutes a series of past wind speed re- and , respectively [see (19)]. Moreover, by means of this
MORALES et al.: SHORT-TERM TRADING FOR A WIND POWER PRODUCER 559

decomposition, no binary variables are required due to the C. Incorporating Risk Control
nature of the optimization problem tending to minimize the im- The risk measure used in this study is the conditional value
balance cost. In other words, for a given total energy deviation at risk at the confidence level ( -CVaR), because this metric
, the optimal solution is guaranteed to be can be expressed linearly within an optimization problem and
achieved with one of the variables or equal to zero exhibits good mathematical properties [22]. If maximizing a dis-
due to the fact that and . Constraints (20) and crete profit distribution, -CVaR can be defined approximately
(21) below impose caps on the positive and negative deviations, as the expected profit of the scenarios with lowest
respectively. The linear formulation is profit.
The risk-constrained formulation of the problem faced by the
wind producer is summarized as

(16) (24)

subject to constraints (17)–(23) plus the following ones required


for the linear formulation of the CVaR:
(17)
(18)
(19)
(20) (25)
(21) (26)

The objective function (24) to be maximized includes the ex-


Model (16)–(21) can be solved by decomposition into op- pected profit of the wind producer [ in (16)] and the CVaR
timization problems, one for each time period , because it does of the profit multiplied by the weighting parameter .
not contain any constraint or any decision variable coupling dif- This weighting factor enforces the tradeoff between expected
ferent time periods. profit and risk in such a way that the higher the value of , the
more risk averse the wind producer is. Thus, if the risk is not
B. Offer Curves considered (risk-neutral case), then the value of is set to 0.
The mathematical model presented before is intended to ob- Since risk is considered throughout the entire market horizon,
tain the optimal quantities (in a stochastic programming sense) then model (17)–(26) cannot be decomposed by time period.
to be sold in the day-ahead market (e.g., 20 MWh in hour 1, 65 This is so because variables and , used to compute the
MWh in hour 2, etc.). However, it may be convenient to derive CVaR over the total revenue distribution, couple the decisions
optimal bidding curves for every hour of the day-ahead market. pertaining to different hours.
For this purpose, variables representing the power traded D. Adding an Adjustment Market
in this market for each time period are made dependant on
scenarios , as in [20] or [21], and the following The offer model of a wind producer having the opportunity
constraints are added to model (16)–(21): to trade additionally in an adjustment market is as follows:

(22)
(23)

Constraints (22) make bidding curves nondecreasing, which is


a requirement in most markets. Equations (23) are nonanticipa- (27)
tivity constraints, which model the fact that only one bidding
curve can be submitted to the day-ahead market for each hour,
irrespective of the wind power and imbalance price realizations.
(28)
That is, this equation enforces nonanticipativity for the wind
power and imbalance price realizations. Note that this model (29)
is less constrained than the basic one. In fact, the basic model (30)
can be obtained from this one by rewriting the nonanticipativity (31)
constraints (23) as .
(32)
Despite including the aforementioned constraints, the offer
strategy model continues being decomposable by time period (33)
(hour). (34)
560 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2010

(35) TABLE I
STOCHASTIC PROCESSES FOR PRICES AND PRICE FUNCTIONS
(36)

(37)

(38)
are modeled using simplified seasonal ARIMA models. More
(39) refined multiseasonal models can be employed instead, as those
described, for instance, in [17]. Likewise, a more sophisticated
where is the number of time periods between the closures
modeling of balancing power market prices is proposed in [26],
of the day-ahead and adjustment markets.
where seasonal ARIMA and Markov processes are combined to
Note that the consideration of the adjustment market entails
capture the particularities of such prices as, e.g., the existence
three differences with regard to the mathematical model pre-
of periods with no demand for balancing power. The ARIMA
sented in Section III-C: the first one has to do with the objective
models fitted for the day considered in this case study (April
function (27) in which the term is included to account
1, 2008) are provided in Table I. The historical data used
for the revenue obtained from trading energy in the adjustment
for the fitting process belong to the electricity market of the
market. This revenue can be negative if the wind power pro-
Iberian Peninsula [16], and are publicly available in [23]. These
ducer decides to purchase energy from this market. The second
data correspond to the working days between October 2007
difference is related to the calculation of the total energy devia-
and March 2008. Only working days are considered in order
tion (31), which, in model (27)–(39), is carried out with respect
to simplify the ARIMA models by eliminating the weekly
to the final energy schedule , i.e., the summation (29)
seasonality.
of the amounts of energy traded in the day-ahead and adjust-
The numbers of scenarios for the day-ahead, adjustment, and
ment markets. The last change consists in adding the nonantici-
balancing markets are, respectively, 1000, 1000, and 1000. The
pativity constraints (37) for the decisions made in the adjustment
number of scenarios simulated to characterize the wind gener-
market. These constraints express that the amount of energy
ation uncertainty is also 1000, resulting from the combination
traded in the adjustment market may be different, depending on
of 20 scenarios representing the wind power realizations
the day-ahead market price realization and the wind power gen-
in time periods between the closures of the day-ahead and ad-
erated after and before the closure of the day-ahead and adjust-
justment markets, and 50 scenarios to embrace the pos-
ment markets, respectively. Furthermore, these constraints also
sible wind power realizations after the clearing of the adjustment
ensure nonanticipativity with respect to the adjustment market
market.
and imbalance price realizations, and the wind power realiza-
The total number of scenarios comprising the original sce-
tion after the closure of the adjustment market.
nario tree is therefore , which clearly yields an optimization
However, once the position in the day-ahead market is fixed
problem that is intractable. Hence, to achieve tractability,
by using model (27)–(39), a model analogous to the one pre-
a scenario reduction technique [19] is applied to each sto-
sented in Section III-C can be employed to build offers for the
chastic process, resulting in ten, five, and ten scenarios for
adjustment market.
the day-ahead, adjustment, and balancing markets, respec-
tively, and twenty scenarios for the wind farm production
IV. CASE STUDY . Thus, the reduced scenario tree includes
10 000 scenarios.
A. Data
Finally, a confidence level is used to compute the
We consider a wind farm having 40 2.5-MW commercial CVaR in all instances.
wind generators. The total installed wind power capacity of
the plant is therefore 100 MW. To convert wind speed into B. On Offer Curves and Risk Control
wind power, the power curve for a standard simulated turbine In this section, no adjustment market is considered. The VSS
(model Nordex N80/2500 with a hub height of 100 m) is used. (risk-neutral case, ) is 2.294%, expressed as a percentage
This power curve can be found in the manufacturer database of the expected profit obtained from model (17)–(26). This value
and is provided in [24]. All the turbines making up the wind justifies the interest in using a stochastic model for solving the
farm are assumed to be operating for the considered trading wind producer problem instead of a naïve deterministic one.
day. The wind speed stochastic process is modeled through the In this case, offers to the day-ahead market just consist of an
second-order autoregressive model (11), whose parameters are optimal energy quantity submitted at zero price for each time
fitted using the publicly available wind speed data collected period. This is the case analyzed in [15]. However, these single
by Johnson from a location in the state of Kansas (U.S.) [25]. quantities may turn into curves if the wind producer becomes
Specifically, the wind dataset used comprises average hourly risk averse . Table II shows the energy quantities offered
speed measurements from January 25 to March 31, 1996. to the market for different hours in the risk-neutral situation,
For clarity, the stochastic processes describing price be- and Fig. 2 depicts the resulting offer curves in the same hours if
havior in the day-ahead, adjustment, and balancing markets .
MORALES et al.: SHORT-TERM TRADING FOR A WIND POWER PRODUCER 561

TABLE II TABLE III


OPTIMAL ENERGY BIDS FOR =0 EXPECTED VALUES OF PERFECT INFORMATION

possibility of trading greater amounts of energy for high price


realizations. It should be noted that for a market requiring step-
wise offer stacks (the case of the market in the Iberian Penin-
sula), the linear blocks of the stacks shown in Fig. 2 should be
approximated by stepwise functions.
In Table III, the expected values of perfect information, EVPI
(risk-neutral case, ) are shown as improvements in per-
centage with respect to the expected profit obtained from model
(17)–(26). In light of the results presented in this table, the fol-
lowing two comments are in order. First, the economic improve-
ment produced by a perfect knowledge of day-ahead market
prices is smaller than the other two, which reveals that the uncer-
tainty associated with these prices plays a secondary role in the
wind producer offering problem. Moreover, this economic im-
provement is nil. This is due to the fact that, under the assump-
tion that wind generation is free, the maximization with
of the objective function (24) boils down to the minimization
of the imbalance cost. This cost depends on and , but is
Fig. 2. Optimal offer curves for = 0:3. independent of . Second, the economic improvements due to
perfect information on wind production and imbalance price ra-
tios are equal. The reason for this is that knowing the values of
and in advance is equivalent to know perfectly the future
wind production availability from a strategic point of view.
Finally, to assess the impact of the volatility level of the
imbalance price ratios on the VSS, the VSS is also computed
considering two additional volatility levels for these price
ratios, 0.40 and 0.58 (values averaged over the 24-h market
horizon), which result in VSS of 2.573% and 3.097%, respec-
tively. Taking into account that the original volatility level and
VSS are 0.22 and 2.294%, it can be concluded that the higher
the volatility of the imbalance prices, the higher the VSS, and
the higher the interest of the proposed model.

C. On the Effects of Including an Adjustment Market


Next, we analyze the advantages of including an adjustment
Fig. 3. Impact of risk aversion on expected deviations. market within the market structure from the perspective of a
wind producer. These advantages are contingent on the liquidity
of this market. In other words, adjustment markets with ade-
The changes undergone by the offer curves for increasing quate levels of liquidity are required to take full advantage of
values are intended to reduce the expected energy traded in the proposed technique.
the day-ahead market as the wind producer becomes more risk Roughly speaking, the effects produced by an adjustment
averse. In fact, the policy that can be adopted by a wind power market are twofold.
producer to hedge against profit variability basically boils down 1) As a trading floor, it provides the market participants with
to trading less energy in the day-ahead market in hopes that its additional trading options. As a result, the expected profit
additional production can be sold in the balancing market at a increases and/or its variability decreases.
still competitive price. Consequently, as the risk aversion in- 2) The clearing of this market is closer to the delivery time,
creases, the expected negative deviation incurred by the wind and therefore, trading can be carried out with a diminished
producer all over the market horizon decreases at the expense of level of uncertainty as for the availability of wind energy.
rising the expected positive deviation. This is shown in Fig. 3. This is of special relevance for a wind producer and consti-
Nevertheless, unlike submitting just a single energy value for tutes the key issue to be analyzed in this section. Hereafter,
each time period, offering curves allows reducing the expected this phenomenon is referred to as certainty gain effect and
energy placed in the day-ahead market while still keeping the is mathematically expressed through the last line of (37).
562 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2010

Fig. 4. Impact of the certainty gain on expected wind producer imbalances.

Fig. 6. Impact of the certainty gain on the energy amounts traded in both the
Fig. 5. Hourly reduction in expected deviation due to the certainty gain. day-ahead and adjustment markets.

Formally, the certainty gain effect can be defined as the energy schedule) decreases as the wind producer becomes more
economic surplus that the wind power producer obtains if risk averse. As already pointed out in Section IV-B, this is the
it builds its offering strategy for the day-ahead market, con- only possible policy that a wind producer can adopt to hedge
sidering that the subsequent energy trading in the adjust- against profit variability on its own. However, note that this de-
ment market can be done with a greater level of certainty crease is less pronounced if the certainty gain effect is consid-
on wind energy production. ered in the stochastic offer model. To understand the reason for
In order to isolate this second effect from the first one, the this, it should be taken into account that the certainty gain effect
analysis performed below is based on a comparison between the translates into a better knowledge on how to offer in the adjust-
results provided by model (27)–(39), depending on whether the ment market in order to decrease the expected level of imbal-
certainty gain introduced by the adjustment market is consid- ances. Thus, for low levels of risk aversion, for which the devi-
ered or not, i.e., depending on whether the second term of the ations incurred by the wind producer are predominantly nega-
AND condition in constraints (37) is included or not. tive (see Fig. 3), the amount of energy placed in the adjustment
To start with, if an adjustment market is considered in the market diminishes in relation to the amount that would be sold
stochastic model, the VSS for the risk-neutral case increases if the certainty gain were disregarded in the stochastic model
up to 3.273%, i.e., 0.979% more than the value obtained in the (see lower subplot in Fig. 6). The opposite effect is observed
previous section. However, the VSS is reduced to 2.906% if for higher levels of risk aversion in order to reduce
the certainty gain is not taken into account. This result reveals the expected amount of positive imbalances appearing as a way
that one of the most important advantages of using a stochastic to reduce profit variability. On the other hand, if the certainty
model, instead of just a deterministic one, is indeed to consider gain effect is modeled, the expected amount of energy traded in
this phenomenon. the day-ahead market (see central subplot in Fig. 6) drops so as
In Fig. 4, the expected total deviations incurred by the wind to prevent greater expected negative imbalances or/and uneco-
producer all over the market horizon are compared for different nomic energy purchases from the adjustment market.
values of the weighting factor . The reduction in the expected In terms of profit, the improvements due to the certainty gain
total amount of imbalances due to the certainty gain associated effect can be summarized by means of Fig. 7, which represents
with trading in the adjustment market is apparent. Fig. 5 shows the optimal pairs (expected profit, CVaR) obtained for different
the value of this reduction per time periods. Note that the de- values of the risk aversion paramater . The resulting curve is
crease in expected deviation is considerably more significant for usually referred to as an efficient frontier. Note that the certainty
the first few periods, in which the volatility pertaining to wind gain effect produces a displacement of the efficient frontier up-
power generation is comparatively smaller. Needless to say, the ward and to the right, i.e., a displacement in the direction of
reduction levels achieved in these first periods could be kept increasing expected profits and increasing CVaRs. Again, this
for the rest of hours by including additional adjustment markets displacement could be amplified by adding to the market struc-
throughout the scheduling horizon. ture additional adjustment markets throughout the scheduling
The certainty gain effect involves notable changes in the offer horizon in a sequential manner. Finally, observe that a signif-
strategy of the wind producer, as can be observed in Fig. 6. In icant CVaR gain is attained for a moderate expected profit de-
this respect, note that the expected amount of energy sold in the crease. For instance, if the certainty gain effect is included, the
electricity market (see upper subplot representing the resulting reduction suffered by the expected profit when is increased
MORALES et al.: SHORT-TERM TRADING FOR A WIND POWER PRODUCER 563

uncertainty level on wind power production, which result in a


comparatively higher profit and a smaller risk. A comprehensive
case study is used to illustrate how to identify the best offering
strategies and the beneficial effects of adjustment markets.
Needless to say, the proposed offering strategy model should
be supplemented with an appropriate methodology to generate
scenario sets representing the stochastic processes involved in a
precise manner. The higher the quality of these scenario sets is,
the more accurate and reliable the results provided by the pro-
posed model are, but the general conclusions presented earlier
are equally valid.
Lastly, the numerical results presented in this paper can be ex-
tended by using a chronological simulator to actually simulate
the wind producer market actions and their corresponding out-
comes during one-year horizon (or any other suitable time pe-
riod). Such a simulator requires scenario generation algorithms
for market prices and wind power spanning one year, which
Fig. 7. Impact of the certainty gain on risk management (efficient frontier). are algorithms still under research. All in all, developing the
referred simulator and conducting year-wide simulations con-
stitutes a subject of further research.
from 0 to 0.5 is 1.66%, which is considerably low in compar-
ison with the increment of 31.36% experienced by the CVaR. REFERENCES
The results presented in this case study support the use of [1] N. Hatziargyriou and A. Zervos, “Wind power development in Europe,”
adjustment markets as efficacious trading floors to enhance the Proc. IEEE, vol. 89, no. 12, pp. 1765–1782, Dec. 2001.
competitiveness degree of wind producers. [2] E. A. DeMeo et al., “Advances in insights and methods for wind plant
integration,” IEEE Power Energy Mag., vol. 5, no. 6, pp. 68–77, Nov./
However, if the proposed offering strategy model is extended Dec. 2007.
to consider longer time horizons, the results obtained by the [3] Global Wind Energy Council,, Global Wind 2005 Report. [Online].
wind producer are expected to be better in terms of risk con- Available: http://www.gwec.net.
[4] IEA WIND Task 25, Design and operation of power systems With large
trollability as the day-to-day profit volatility is greater than the amounts of wind power. [Online]. Available: http://www.ieawind.org.
volatility of profit over longer time horizons. An immediate [5] J. R. Birge and F. Louveaux, Introduction to Stochastic Programming.
New York: Springer-Verlag, 1997.
practical implication of this would be the flattening of the ef- [6] M. Carrión, A. B. Philpott, A. J. Conejo, and J. M. Arroyo, “A sto-
ficient frontier illustrated in Fig. 7. chastic programming approach to electric energy procurement for large
Likewise, the results derived from the proposed optimization consumers,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 22, no. 2, pp. 744–754, May
2007.
models are also contingent on the volatility of the stochastic pro- [7] L. F. Escudero, A. Garín, M. Merino, and G. Pérez, “The value of the
cesses involved (wind availability and market prices). In this re- stochastic solution in multistage problems,” TOP, vol. 15, no. 1, pp.
48–64, Jul. 2007.
spect, note that the higher such volatility is, the more advanta- [8] J. García-González, R. M. R. de la Muela, L. M. Santos, and A. Mateo
geous is the use of the proposed stochastic approach over a pre- González, “Stochastic joint optimization of wind generation and
diction-based one. Stochastic programming allows increasing pumped-storage units in an electricity market,” IEEE Trans. Power
Syst., vol. 23, no. 2, pp. 460–468, May 2008.
the expected value of the profit distribution while keeping the [9] E. D. Castronuovo and J. A. P. Lopes, “On the optimization of the daily
risk of profit variability under control, a risk that precisely stems operation of a wind-hydro power plant,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol.
from the volatility of the input stochastic processes. 19, no. 3, pp. 1599–1606, Aug. 2004.
[10] J. M. Angarita and J. G. Usaola, “Combining hydro-generation and
Concerning computational issues, all problems have wind energy biddings and operation on electricity spot markets,”
been solved using CPLEX 10.2.0 under GAMS [27] on a Electr. Power Syst. Res., vol. 77, pp. 393–400, 2007.
[11] G. N. Bathurst and G. Strbac, “Value of combining energy storage and
Linux-based server with four processors clocking at 2.6 GHz wind in short-term energy and balancing markets,” Electr. Power Syst.
and 32 GB of RAM. The CPU time required to solve the sto- Res., vol. 67, pp. 1–8, 2003.
chastic model (27)–(39) is lower than 4 s for all the simulations [12] K. Hedman and G. Sheble, “Comparing hedging methods for wind
power: Using pumped storage hydro units vs options purchasing,”
carried out. presented at the 9th Int. Conf. Probab. Methods Appl. Power Syst.
(PMAPS) 2006, Stockholm, Sweden.
V. CONCLUSION [13] G. N. Bathurst, J. Weatherill, and G. Strbac, “Trading wind generation
in short term energy markets,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 17, no. 3,
The methodology proposed in this paper allows to identify pp. 782–789, Aug. 2002.
bidding strategies for a wind power producer that entitle a high [14] P. Pinson, C. Chevallier, and G. N. Kariniotakis, “Trading wind gen-
eration from short-term probabilistic forecasts of wind power,” IEEE
decrease in the risk of profit variability for a comparatively low Trans. Power Syst., vol. 22, no. 3, pp. 1148–1156, Aug. 2007.
reduction in expected profit. Additionally, this paper provides [15] J. Matevosyan and L. Söder, “Minimization of imbalance cost trading
wind power on the short-term power market,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst.,
a procedure to quantify the beneficial impart of a sequence of vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 1396–1404, Aug. 2006.
adjustment markets following the clearing of the day-ahead [16] Market operator of the electricity market of the Iberian Peninsula,
market. These adjustment markets, cleared between the clearing OMEL, 2008. [Online]. Available: http://www.omel.es.
[17] A. J. Conejo, J. Contreras, R. Espínola, and M. A. Plazas, “Forecasting
of the day-ahead market and the real-time operation, allow the electricity prices for a day-ahead pool-based electric energy market,”
producer to identify and submit offers considering a reduced Int. J. Forecast., vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 435–462, 2005.
564 IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON POWER SYSTEMS, VOL. 25, NO. 1, FEBRUARY 2010

[18] G. Giebel, R. Brownsword, and G. Kariniotakis, The state of the art Antonio J. Conejo (F’04) received the M.S. degree
in short-term prediction of wind power: A literature overview. [On- from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
line]. Available: http://anemos.cma.fr (deliverable D.1.1 of ANEMOS Cambridge, in 1987 and the Ph.D. degree from the
Project). Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden,
[19] H. Heitsch and W. Römisch, “Scenario reduction algorithms in sto- in 1990.
chastic programming,” Comput. Optim. Appl., vol. 24, no. 2/3, pp. He is currently a Full Professor at the Universidad
187–206, Feb. 2003. de Castilla-La Mancha, Ciudad Real, Spain. His re-
[20] A. Baillo, M. Ventosa, M. Rivier, and A. Ramos, “Optimal offering search interests include control, operations, planning
strategies for generation companies operating in electricity spot mar- and economics of electric energy systems, as well as
kets,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19, no. 2, pp. 745–753, May 2004. statistics and optimization theory and its applications.
[21] M. A. Plazas, A. J. Conejo, and F. J. Prieto, “Multimarket optimal bid-
ding for a power producer,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 20, no. 4, pp.
2041–2050, Nov. 2005.
[22] R. T. Rockafellar and S. Uryasev, “Optimization of conditional
value-at-risk,” J. Risk, vol. 2, pp. 21–41, Spring, 2000. Juan Pérez-Ruiz (S’96–M’99) received the Elec-
[23] Red Eléctrica de España, S. A. Sistema de Información del Operador trical Engineering degree from the Universidad
del Sistema, e1sios, 2008. [Online]. Available: http://www.esios.ree.es. Pontificia Comillas, Madrid, Spain, in 1992 and
[24] Danish Wind Industry Association, Wind turbine power calculator. the Ph.D. degree from the Universidad de Málaga,
[Online]. Available: http://www.windpower.org. Málaga, Spain, in 2001.
[25] Electrical and Computer Engineering of Kansas State University, Dr. He is currently an Associate Professor at the Uni-
Gary Johnson’s renewable energy and Tesla coil page. [Online]. Avail- versidad de Málaga. His research interests include
able: http://eece.ksu.edu/~gjohnson/ (accessed Feb. 5, 2008).
operations, planning and economics of electric en-
[26] M. Olsson and L. Söder, “Modeling real-time balancing power market
ergy systems, as well as statistics and optimization
prices using combined SARIMA and Markov processes,” IEEE Trans.
theory and its applications.
Power Syst., vol. 23, no. 2, pp. 443–450, May 2008.
[27] A. Brooke, D. Kendrick, A. Meeraus, R. Raman, and R. E. Rosen-
thal, GAMS, a User’s Guide. Washington, DC: GAMS Development
Corp., 1998.

Juan M. Morales (S’07) received the Ingeniero


Industrial degree from the Universidad de Málaga,
Málaga, Spain, in 2006. He is currently pursuing
the Ph.D. degree at the Universidad de Castilla-La
Mancha, Ciudad Real, Spain.
His research interests include power systems
economics, reliability, stochastic programming, and
electricity markets.

You might also like