You are on page 1of 8

Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Research & Social Science


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/erss

Original research article

Historical institutionalist perspective on the shift from feed-in tariffs T


towards auctioning in German renewable energy policy
⁎,1
Merethe Dotterud Leirena, , Inken Reimerb
a
CICERO—Center for International Climate Research, Gaustadalleen 21, 0349 Oslo, Norway
b
Freie Universität Berlin, Environmental Policy Research Center, Ihnestraße 22, 14195 Berlin, Germany

A R T I C LE I N FO A B S T R A C T

Keywords: An early implementer of feed-in tariffs, Germany soon became feed-in champion, continuously resisting pres-
Europeanisation sures – from the European Commission in particular – to adopt a competition-oriented approach. The European
Germany Commission never approved of the German feed-in tariff, seeing it as illegal state aid. However, after the good
Historical institutionalism results in deployment of renewables, other countries followed suit and feed-in tariffs became the most popular
Renewable energy
support scheme for renewables in Europe. Despite this success, the nature of the Energiewende changed. Germany
broke with its feed-in tradition two and a half decades later, introducing pilot auctions for solar energy in 2014.
In 2016, it moved from a scheme under which every provider of renewable energy was entitled to support to a
competition-oriented approach based on auctioning. Drawing on perspectives of historical institutionalism and
adopting qualitative methods, we argue that the success of the feed-in tariff in terms of deployment of renew-
ables altered coalitions of interests in Germany. The German government introduced auctioning with a view to
controlling cost developments and protecting the conventional energy industries from insolvency. This happened
under considerable EU pressures, given the European Commission’s state aid guidelines, which prescribe a
competition-oriented approach.

1. Introduction democracy and public participation [1]. It also has implications for the
design of the energy system transformation [2]. This is because in-
Germany has received considerable attention since 2000, when the dividuals, small companies and communities that have installed solar
government introduced its policy plans for a pioneering energy transi- panels on their roofs and invested in windmills have driven the En-
tion, the Energiewende. The government had introduced strategies for ergiewende forward. This actor diversity has created widespread ac-
this ambitious transformation already in the 1970s and has con- ceptance. In contrast, auctions tend to favour big companies [3]. The
tinuously reinforced such strategies ever since. To enable this transi- shift has been instrumental in changing the power relations between
tion, the government has introduced various policy instruments, in- actors, because changes in support schemes influence the development
cluding generous feed-in tariffs. This policy instrument has been of small-scale energy providers [4]. It is an example of political polar-
globally important for the development and provision of renewable isation over sustainable energy transformation in Germany (see also the
energy technology, and Germany’s feed-in tariff instrument has at- Introduction in this special issue [5]).
tracted considerable attention as a role model for other countries. The policy change occurred at the same time as the European
However, in 2014 Germany introduced pilot auctions for solar energy. Commission (Commission) changed its state-aid guidelines in 2014.
Two years later, the government – controversially – decided to switch These new guidelines prescribe a competitive approach, one not com-
from feed-in tariffs to auctioning. That turn was decisive, marking a patible with feed-in tariffs. The EU has thereby been assumed to bear
fundamental shift from a scheme under which every provider of re- the responsibility for the introduction of auctioning [6,7]. This con-
newable energy was entitled to support to a competitive approach trasts with earlier studies holding that national governments tend to
based on auctioning. The turn changed the nature of the Energiewende, adopt support schemes voluntarily (see e.g. [8]). Why did Germany
which is exceptional in terms of being an ‘energy democracy’, a concept introduce major changes to its renewable energy policy two and a half
that merges the technological energy transition with a strengthening of decades after initiating it, thereby breaking with its feed-in tradition?


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: merethe.leiren@cicero.oslo.no, merethe.leiren@medoleir.oslo.no (M.D. Leiren), reimer@geographie.uni-kiel.de (I. Reimer).
1
https://www.linkedin.com/feed/.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2018.05.022
Received 13 January 2018; Received in revised form 11 May 2018; Accepted 18 May 2018
Available online 26 May 2018
2214-6296/ © 2018 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/BY-NC-ND/4.0/).
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

To explain this, we draw on insights from historical institutionalism one highlights triggering events or sudden punctuations such as ex-
and the Europeanisation literature. The Europeanisation literature is ternal shocks, crises or other events that disrupt periods of stability (e.g.
relevant for understanding whether and in what ways the EU has in- [15]); the other perspective emphasises the slow-moving, continuous
fluenced the development of renewables policy in Germany. processes of reforms [16,17]. The first perspective highlights ‘critical
Researchers in the Europeanisation literature no longer treat the EU as junctures’, defined as ‘brief moments in which opportunities for major
an independent force for change, but instead hold that existing in- institutional reforms appear, followed by long stretches of institutional
stitutional arrangements in the member states influence adaptations to stability’ ([13], 134f). The second perspective is a theory of gradual
the EU [9,10]. Thus, it is also important to draw on perspectives that institutional change developed by Kathleen Thelen and co-authors
highlight factors potentially causing change domestically. In this re- [16,17].
spect, the perspectives of gradual institutional change are particularly The model presented by [18] views the type of institutional change
relevant, as the German Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG) was as depending on the type of the dominant change-agent in the context
never meant to be static: it has been continuously evaluated and has of the political system and the characteristics of the ‘targeted’ institu-
changed accordingly. Since 2000, when the Act was first introduced, tion. The authors assume that actors who did not benefit from the old
the German Parliament has reformed the law five times. Therefore, we system will push for new institutions. Gradual displacement will ensue
assess whether the radical change in 2016 came about gradually or was if those who favour the old system are unable to prevent new rules.
propelled by a change in EU law. They note four key types of change: displacement, layering, drift and
The case study is important, given the increasing influence of the EU conversion. Our focus here is gradual displacement and layering, as we
on national policies. The selection of Germany as a case provides the are interested in the actual shift of rules, and not the interpretation of
possibility of learning something about the nature of the relationship rules or whether actors abide by them – aspects more prominent in
between a big member state with particularly strong interests in re- connection with drift and conversion. We find theories of gradual in-
newable energy policies and the EU, in a domain (i.e. energy policy) stitutional change useful for studying policy change, because policies –
that is primarily a national responsibility. Moreover, auctioning is on like institutions – entail rules.
the verge of becoming a predominant renewable energy policy instru- ‘Displacement’ refers to the replacement of existing rules. While
ment in Europe. This case study may help to explain why countries displacement may be radical and may seem abrupt, the gradual in-
introduce auctioning, emphasising how the EU may contribute towards stitutional perspective proposes that it has occurred slowly. ‘Layering’
strengthening change agents within the countries. differs from displacement as it entails revisions or additional ‘layers’ to
The following sections begin by presenting the theoretical frame- existing rules, rather than replacing them by completely new ones. Such
work. Second, we elaborate on the methods employed in this study, ‘differential growth’ [19] occurs when opponents, unable to shift the
before describing the development of Germany’s policy of support for original rules, manage to circumvent the rules from within the system
renewable electricity generation. Finally, we discuss the evidence in by introducing new voluntary rules on top of the existing ones [17].
light of our theoretical framework. We conclude that, while the Displacement is unlikely when the defenders of the existing rules are
European Union has helped to speed up the process of introducing powerful: under such circumstances, layering is more likely [18].
competition-oriented auctions for renewable energy support, an already The two perspectives within historical institutionalism suggest dif-
existing push for change in the German political system made this ferent ways by which to understand the role of the EU, and we are
possible. Due to increasing costs and insolvency issues that affected the particularly interested in such an understanding, given that the state aid
big utilities, the political majority wanted to control the pace of re- guidelines were changed about the same time as Germany introduced
newable energy development and gradually introduced changes that auctions: The EU can be considered as an external force or as an en-
radically changed the support policy for renewables. dogenous change-agent.
There is support for the external shock perspective in the
2. Theoretical perspectives Europeanisation literature. For example, court rulings are considered
important formative moments for affecting policy change in favour of
One approach that social scientists have used to explain the devel- liberalisation (e.g. [20,21]). Hence, court rulings or the threat of liti-
opment of the Energiewende is historical institutionalism. Christoph gation trigger policy change to otherwise stable institutional arrange-
Stefes [11] uses this approach, arguing that new policies have con- ments by bypassing reluctant member states or nudging them to com-
solidated the path of the Energiewende. Carol Hager [12] draws on in- promise. However, whereas researchers used to treat the EU as an
stitutionalism showing that the ‘push for renewables in Germany arose independent force for change, a new generation of literature holds that
almost entirely outside the prevailing channels of institutional power’. in a multilevel administrative system like the EU, the EU is not external
However, there is a need to update this literature and explore whether to the member states; instead, there is bureaucratic inter-penetration
historical institutionalism also contributes to explain the more recent across levels of governance (see [10]). One relevant example is state-aid
changes to the EEG, which seems to break with the path highlighted in guidelines, whereby the Commission ‘bans’ certain activities and ne-
the aforementioned literature. gotiates with the member states rather than simply implementing
Historical institutionalists focus on how institutions develop over formal decisions [22].
time and affect the positions of actors in ways that may have been Drawing on such an understanding of Europeanisation, the EU may
unintended or undesired by their creators. They study how institutions be considered a ‘change agent’ within the political system – or European
reinforce themselves, create path dependencies and lock-ins, and argue political order may have created a context that has benefited certain
that it may be difficult to alter certain institutions, as reversals are actors at the expense of others. Given the Commission’s promotion of
costly or difficult [13]. Hence, one virtue of historical institutionalism is competition and ‘dislike’ of feed-in tariffs, we expect the EU to have
the ability to explain the stability of political institutions. helped strengthen change agents that have promoted a change in the
An important notion is ‘path dependency’, defined as ‘social pro- existing feed-in tariff policy.
cesses that exhibit positive feedback’ ([13], 21). It implies that in-
stitutions over time are characterised by inertia. Path dependency 3. Methods
curtails policy options through self-enforcing mechanisms that con-
tribute to generating ‘increasing returns’ that benefit existing paths To explain the shift from feed-in tariffs towards auctioning, we
more than other solutions ([14], 94). perform an in-depth analysis, exploring a case where such a shift did
Despite the stability inherent in path dependency, policy change not seem likely. It did not seem likely due to the strong emphasis in
occurs. There are two distinct perspectives that explain policy change: Germany on energy democracy that has developed with the feed-in

34
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

tariff. Our data are primarily qualitative: official documents (e.g. policy system, it granted compensation covering at least 90 per cent of the
papers), consultancy reports, hearings, newspaper articles, and the average cost to private customers. However, the Commission chal-
homepages of state authorities such as the German Ministry of lenged the law. While the Commission’s DG Competition initially ar-
Economics (with in-depth information on the changes of the Renewable gued that Germany should decrease the rates, the Commission [27]
Energy Source Act) as well as the websites of various interest organi- later approved the law because the amount of the compensation offered
sations. We draw on secondary literature especially when describing and its impacts on electricity prices were minimal. In 1998, the German
the earlier phases, as there is an extensive literature on the court questioned the European Court of Justice about the interpretation
Energiewende. of EU law related to proceedings between the electricity suppliers
We have also collected data through 15 interviews conducted in PreussenElektra AG and Schleswag AG [28]. The renewables energy feed-
Berlin or by telephone in November and December 2016 and in tariff policy, as introduced through the Grid Feed-In Law, was
February–April 2017. The aim was to collect data that may not have challenged as it was deemed inappropriate ‘state aid’ [29]. This was the
been written in any documents, e.g. insights into the negotiations be- beginning of a long-lasting controversy between Germany and the
tween government and the Commission. Informants were chosen for the Commission.
purpose of integrating perspectives from the national and EU admin- The Grid Feed-In Law encouraged small, decentralised energy gen-
istrative levels, including relevant actors who are not part of govern- eration (involving the participation of individuals and citizen in-
ment administrations. Our informants include representatives of a ci- itiatives) and contributed towards creating jobs and boosting tax in-
tizens’ NGO (Interview 1), a renewable energy association (Interview come. This broad base of participation in renewables also led to
2), an environmental NGO (Interview 3), an economic association widespread acceptance among the public as well as politicians. In 1998,
(Interview 4), a large energy utility (Interview 5), as well as the poli- the Green Party campaigned with the slogan, ‘we want 100,000 roof
tical advisor to Green Party politician (Interview 6), an energy transi- photovoltaics’ (Interview 8). The campaign was inspired by the Social
tion policy advisor (Interview 7), a Green Party politician (Interview 8), Democrat Hermann Scheer, who together with Green Party politician
a civil servant in the Ministry of Economics (Interview 9), a former Hans-Josef Fell initiated the German feed-in tariff system. The topic
Green politician (Interview 10), a representative of a renewable energy became part of the coalition negotiations between the SPD and the
association (Interview 11), a consultant (Interview 11), a representative Green Party, leading to the first red-green coalition (Interview 8). The
of a Brussels-based renewable energy association (Interview 13), a re- SPD had close ties to trade associations, including miners, so coal was
presentative of an environmental NGO (Interview 14), and an energy an important issue. However, one central figure behind the law, Scheer,
expert (Interview 15). Topics included respondents’ perceptions of the was able to break the opposition from the coal interests in his party and
rationale behind the development of the policies, administrative or facilitate a coalition in favour of renewables by introducing mine gas
organisational factors, patterns of conflict, coordination among actors, into the discussions [1]. This led to the introduction of a more generous
influence from the EU, as well as economic aspects and structural fac- feed-in tariff.
tors of the national energy systems. Anonymity ensured that informants
could speak freely, which we deemed more important than the possible 4.2. EEG 2000
benefits gained from making known the source of each statement.
In 2000, the German government replaced the Grid Feed-In Law
4. From feed-in-tariffs to auctioning with the Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG 2000). The EEG provides a
feed-in tariff for not only renewables but also mine gas from coalmines.
It is important to know the roots of the German energy democracy In contrast to its predecessor, the EEG differentiated to a greater extent
to understand the emergence of the feed-in tariffs as well as the switch between the various renewable energy sources. The EEG tariffs differ-
to auctioning and the resistance to that change. Analysing the process, entiated between technologies, depending on the energy source, capa-
we pay attention not only to domestic political dynamics but also to city and/or location of the plant. The criterion of plant locations was
reactions from the European level and negotiations between domestic introduced to ensure the profitability of wind turbines, including in
and EU actors and institutions, searching for change agents to have Germany’s less windy regions, aiming to achieve a more even dis-
influenced the process. We begin with our empirical analysis in 1990, tribution of wind power plants throughout the country [30].
when the first law to deal with renewable energy was introduced in The new law became the key policy instrument for the Energiewende.
Germany. The aim was to strengthen and promote the sustainable development of
energy supply within climate and energy protection (§ 1 Abs. 1 EEG
4.1. 1990 Grid Feed-In Law 2000). The target set by the EEG was to increase the share of electricity
generated from renewable sources from 5 to 10 percent by 2010. To
In October 1990, Germany introduced the Grid Feed-In Law. Two achieve this, grid operators were obliged to prioritise renewable energy
backbenchers representing the conservative Christian Social Union facilities; and to ensure predictability, producers of renewable elec-
(CSU) and the Green Party proposed the feed-in tariff [23]. They gained tricity would get a fixed rate of return over 20 years from the initiation
support from other MPs interested in renewable energy, and eventually of a project, decreasing each year. This combination of a fixed rate and
from all factions in the Bundestag [24]. The Federal Council (Bundesrat) an annual decrease in support ‘has been of global importance for the
also favoured the support scheme, as it would reduce the financial re- introduction of renewables and the development of such technology’
sponsibilities of the German states [24]. The private utilities benefited (Interview 8; see also [23]). However, pressure against renewables
from exclusive supply contracts with the municipalities; they estab- grew, i.e. the Federation of German Industry was concerned about
lished regional monopolies and could refuse feed-in to their grid by national competitiveness, arguing that the EEG 2000 would create ex-
local renewable energy producers [25]. When the German reunification cessive burdens for the industry and drive up electricity prices [25].
occurred in 1990, the utilities sought to position themselves in the re- Similarly, the German Utilities Association criticised the law for im-
structuring of the East German power sector [26]. However, renewables posing higher costs on consumers (ibid). The Ministry of Economics
did not fit the utilities’ business models and the Grid-Feed-In Law of- recognised such concerns, but its role was weakened as the second red-
fered no incentives – financial or legal – for them to focus on renewable green coalition (elected in 2002) decided to shift responsibility for re-
energies, as corporations were excluded from its provisions (Interview newable energy to the Ministry of Environment. The transfer brought
5; StrEG 1990 §1.2; also EEG 2000 §2.1). greater awareness of renewable energy in the German governmental
The Grid Feed-In Law obliged power companies to purchase elec- administration and strengthened support for the feed-in tariff ([31], p.
tricity from renewable sources, and pay for it. To those who fed into the 15). This happened despite the increasing power of the utilities. Several

35
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

energy companies had merged at the turn of the millennium, eventually friendly model ([41], p. 18).
resulting in the ‘Big Four’: E.ON, RWE, EnBW and Vattenfall. This was a
result of the revision of the Energy Industry Act in 1998, which liber- 4.4. EEG 2009
alised the energy market so as to accommodate an EU market directive
[32]. While new firms took advantage of the feed-in tariffs and started After the 2005 elections, the CDU/CSU and SPD created the ‘grand
to expand in the renewables sector [32], the Big Four did not find it coalition’ under Angela Merkel, with Sigmar Gabriel (SPD) as Minister
particularly interesting to invest in renewables because the rates of of Environment. Although industrial interests like the German
return were too low (Interview 5; 8) and their key interest was in coal Chambers of Commerce and Industry called for Germany to abandon its
and nuclear. ambitions aimed at climate leadership [42], the coalition agreement
One major election promise of the Green Party had been to phase between CDU/CSU and SPD continued along the same path as its pre-
out nuclear power plants, and the SPD was not particularly keen on decessor, the red-green coalition, as regards climate and energy policy
nuclear energy either [33]. In 2000, the red-green coalition and the [43]. The grand coalition initiated a new policy formulation process
energy utilities reached a ‘nuclear consensus’ [34], a major political [44], leading to new amendments in 2009. The EEG 2009 increased the
accomplishment, which was transposed into law two years later. It gave renewables target (to 30% by 2020) and introduced a growth corridor
Germany’s remaining 19 nuclear power plants a lifetime of 32 years. with flexible degression. The 2009 amendment had made the EEG levy
This strengthened the case for proponents of renewables, as renewables jump abruptly, without providing compensation to those who had to
became the ‘only’ climate-friendly energy source. cover the costs of the support scheme (Interview 10).
At the EU level, the Commission incorporated concerns about re- Another important change in the legal framework for energy policy
newable energy in its state aid guidelines in 2001. The dispute between was the EU’s Third Energy Packet, which obliged member states to
Germany and the Commission about whether the feed-in tariff should separate energy supply and generation from the operation of trans-
be deemed ‘illegal state aid’ continued. The PreussenElectra verdict in mission networks so as to avoid unfair infrastructure access [45].
2001 settled the issue: the European Court of Justice decided that this Germany transposed these rules into its Energy Sector Law (enforced in
feed-in tariff, under the given conditions, did not constitute state aid, 2010). This regulation resulted in unbundling, forcing the integrated
because there was no involvement of financial sources by the state in- power companies to sell their electricity transmission network opera-
volved. tors [46,47]. The changes have been called ‘a big mistake’ because the
unbundling made the financial situation of the big utilities more diffi-
4.3. EEG 2004 cult (Interview 12).
After the Fukushima disaster in March 2011, German Chancellor
The second red-green coalition began to revise the EEG after re- Angela Merkel announced a temporary shutdown of the nuclear ex-
election in 2002. In 2003, the Bundestag, following an initiative from tension plan, a safety check of all nuclear power plants and the shut-
the Ministry of Economics, decided that energy-intensive industry down of the seven oldest ones [48]. Suddenly there was consensus
would be exempted from the EEG surcharge (Special Equalisation amongst all political parties in Germany that nuclear power was no
Scheme Act 2003). Industrial interests and power suppliers wanted longer an option [49]. The fact that this decision was made by a coa-
exemptions for industrial consumers to protect German firms so that lition government between CDU/CSU and FDP (elected in 2009), shows
they would continue to be able to compete internationally [35]. This that supporting nuclear was no longer politically feasible in Germany.
exemption was important for maintaining consensus about the EEG The FDP in particular had previously been a strong advocate for
(Interview 7). When the Bundestag decided to amend the EEG in 2004, keeping nuclear power. In July 2011, the Bundestag voted over-
cost-efficiency concerns were important. According to the revised act, whelmingly in favour of shutting down eight nuclear power plants and
plant operators were responsible for paying for grid connection, phasing out the remaining nine by 2022 at the latest [48].
whereas the grid operator would have to cover costs related to up- This was accompanied by a surge in electricity and heat generation
grading the grid [36]. The increased tariffs for PV lead to a solar boom from renewable sources – this rapid development was a cause for great
in 2004 [36]. EEG 2004 also broadened the applicability of the feed-in concern. In addition to the increasing surcharge on power, there were
tariffs so that bigger corporations and utilities were also allowed to technical challenges, high cable costs related to offshore wind-parks
participate (EEG 2004 §2). and a lack of grid infrastructure for transferring electricity from the
A political conflict ensued between the Minister of Environment Germany’s northern states to the southern states, where there is a de-
(Green Party) and the Minister of Economics (SPD) [36]. Arguing that mand for more energy [48].
the rates were too high, the latter disagreed with feed-in tariff as a The good financial situation of the Big Four began to change as
principle and proposed a tendering system, a proposal that was not demand for electricity decreased during the economic crisis. In 2004,
included in the amended EEG 2004, as the red-green majority in the the Big Four had generated 90 per cent of the electricity and owned 82
parliament opposed this proposal. per cent of electricity production capacity in Germany [50]. By 2010,
Criticism of the EEG arose among utility companies and the Free generation had fallen to 77 per cent and the share of the total capacity
Democratic Party (FDP). In addition, certain Christian Democratic of renewable energies was 6.5 per cent [51]. In 2009 and 2010, the
Union (CDU) politicians began to question whether a feed-in tariff with companies responded by cutting costs [32]. In 2011, the market effects
such high rates was still necessary. They argued, for instance, that the of the EEG became clearer; the economic crisis had also affected the
EEG was too expensive, that it contravened market rules, led to in- companies’ earnings in foreign markets. With these developments, in
creased regulation and a massive extension of the grid (see [36]). This addition to the phase-out of eight nuclear reactors, the Big Four were
played a role in the election campaign in 2005, when all parties (CDU, now faced with a crisis.
SPD, the Greens [Grüne], FDP, Linke) took up climate or energy con-
cerns and called for renewable energies as part of the country’s energy 4.5. EEG 2012
mix, but disagreed on nuclear phase-out and how to support renewable
energy [37]. The Green Party and the SPD foresaw that the EEG would The EEG was modified again in 2012 due to party preferences
make Germany an industrial world leader in PV and wind energy within the conservative-liberal coalition. The government introduced a
[38,39]; the CDU/CSU and FDP, however, wanted to change the scope German market premium scheme as an option to feed-in tariffs [52].
of German renewable energy policy. The CDU called for a 12.5 per cent Transmission network operators would no longer be responsible for
share of renewables in the overall electricity mix ([40], p. 19), whereas selling the electricity on the market; instead, the plant operators
the FDP wanted to abolish the EEG and replace it with a more market- themselves would market power. The intention was to create stronger

36
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

alignment to price signals in the market [53]. Politicians from the the one hand, environmentalists declared that the utilities had only
Green Party and the left-oriented Linke, as well as NGOs and many themselves to blame for not having invested in renewables, although
scholars criticised the introduction of direct marketing, holding that there was some understanding about bankruptcy concerns in the green
this would no longer benefit the diversity of renewable energy produ- camp. Highlighting the role of Germany as a role model for other
cers (Interview 14). The feed-in tariff had gained broad social accep- countries, one informant stated: ‘Mr. Gabriel made an argument that I
tance as it included a wide range of actors – from single households to can personally understand: if one of the Big Ones goes insolvent, then
corporations. the German Energiewende will no longer be a good role model to the
With investments in renewable energies continuing to grow, the outside world’ (Interview 3).
debate about whether to control the volume of renewable energy be- While Germany is able to pay the remuneration rates, following suit
came more heated (Interview 9). As anyone who produced electricity is too expensive for other countries (Interview 5). The grand coalition
from renewables was entitled to support, there was no control of those promised to revise the EEG scheduled for 2014 [61]. Their coalition
who had access to the feed-in tariff or how the costs would develop. agreement introduced a growth corridor and stated that the govern-
Opponents criticised over-supply and the remuneration for solar elec- ment would introduce measures to control the development of renew-
tricity, which was far above the market price for electricity [54]. ables within this corridor, mentioning procurements by tender as one
such measure. As argued by one civil servant, ‘At that point it was re-
4.6. EEG 2014 latively clear that we would get procurements by tender and goals
[volume] that would be controlled’ (Interview 9). One politician in the
A key topic in the federal election campaign in September 2013 was opposition agreed; ‘We realised early on what the deal was [auctioning]
the cost of the Energiewende. The Minister of Environment from May and could not change much’ (Interview 8). Here he was referring to the
2012 to December 2013, Peter Altmaier (CDU), indicated that it would fact that the influence of the opposition is limited under the conditions
cost about €1000 billion until 2030 [55]. Together with Philipp Rösler of the great coalition (Interview 6).
(FDP), he proposed reducing the feed-in tariffs for new plants by € 1 In the coalition agreement, the government stated that it would
billion each year. The German utilities RWE and E.ON favoured a strong initiate a dialogue with the Commission and other EU member states as
European internal market and emissions trading, arguing that such soon as possible on how to develop the support scheme for renewables
measures would serve to bring renewables forward [56]. in accordance with EU law. In fact, the interaction between the
Referring to the threatening cost scenario, Altmaier increased the Commission and Germany had already started. In December 2013, the
pressure on the opposition, the Green Party in particular [57]. Sigmar Commission had notified the German government that it would open an
Gabriel (SPD) followed suit by making costs a key topic, arguing that it inquiry into whether Germany’s EEG was compliant with the EU
was important to stabilise costs while also protecting the export-or- guidelines for state aid [62]. In the framing of its opening decision, the
iented German industry, not to endanger jobs [58]. Industrial compe- Commission noted the scope of inquiry and the remuneration for dif-
titiveness was a key topic (Interview 5): ferent technologies. Arguing that Germany had substantially amended
its EEG, the Commission doubted the compatibility of EEG 2012 and the
The Energiewende will become a model of success only if it is eco-
relevant Treaty articles related to state aid ([29], pp. 138–39). The
nomically feasible. And Germany […] can afford a lot of invest-
Commission considered the aid unlawful and pointed out that the
ments, but only if, in the end, the German industry becomes sub-
support scheme was considerably different from the PreussenElektra
stantially able to compete because of this transition, otherwise it
case.
fails. (Interview 7)
Among the issues that the Commission criticised was the levy re-
CDU/CSU won the 2013 elections and created another ‘grand coa- duction for energy-intensive industries. The intention behind this ex-
lition’ with the SPD. The new government decided to transfer respon- emption is to prevent such industries from relocating to other countries
sibility for renewable energy from the Ministry of Environment to the where electricity costs are lower [29]. The Commission’s focus on the
Ministry of Economics (Interview 15). The intention was to concentrate exemptions from the EEG levy for energy-intensive industries was
the energy responsibilities in one ministry, which the Vice Chancellor, particularly difficult for the German government, ‘because the in-
Sigmar Gabriel (SPD), wanted to head (Interview 7; 8; 15). Our re- dustrial exceptions from the EEG levy are central for creating political
spondents held that the emphasis on costs increased after the shift, due consensus for the Energiewende’ (Interview 7). Without the exemptions,
primarily to the person who became the new minister (Interview 4; 6; 7; energy-intensive industries would have to pay a much higher price for
8). electricity. For some companies, this price would be too high for them
The issue of how to control volume in order to lower the costs was to compete internationally [63]. Focusing on the exemptions meant
also disputed (Interview 9). In hearings, the organisations did not that the entire Energiwende was in danger, ‘because without the ex-
propose alternatives to auctioning: some (including the four transmis- ceptions for the industry, the EEG system and the whole transition
sion system operators, Industrial Energy Association) promoted auc- cannot achieve consensus in Germany. I have to say, their [the Com-
tioning; others (like the Friends of the Earth, Greenpeace, the German mission’s] focus was cruel, building up maximum pressure’ (Interview
Trade Union Federation) were critical. 7).
The large four utilities continuously lost market shares and volume Furthermore, according to this respondent, the legal consequence of
from 2010 until 2013 amounting to around 6 percentage points. The the formal letter that opened the inquiry into state-aid guidelines was
generated electricity of the four utilities together decreased by 16 per that, from that moment, a member state is no longer allowed to im-
cent ([59], p. 30). Of the four big utilities, E.ON was hit hardest. The plement further measures that may be viewed as aid that is prohibited.
company recorded a decline in their profits of 1.9 billion Euros in 2011 If the subsidy is found illegal, the companies’ mandatory repayment
– the year the German nuclear phase-out was decided [60]. In contrast, could amount to billions of Euros. The attack on the EEG levy exemp-
the share of renewables in gross power generation increased by up to tion therefore meant that the German government had less than a year
25.8 per cent in 2014, thereby also increasing competition in the power to respond to the requirements of the Commission, as the exemptions
market. The utilities, which were close to bankruptcy, favoured auc- are re-issued every year.
tions and put the Ministry of Economics under strong pressure (Inter- From that point, the government negotiated with the Commission,
view 3; 8). trying to find a ‘landing zone’ for the reformed EEG and at the same
Competition procurements by tender is considered advantageous for time trying to reform the EEG. The Ministry of Economics, while
large companies: because they have more large-scale projects, they can drafting the EEG amendment, was in constant contact with the
make more competitive offers than smaller companies (Interview 5). On Commission (DG Competition), to make sure the proposal would be in

37
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

line with the guidelines for state aid. One MP interviewed for this study (around 2000) cooperated to push for the feed-in tariff, in order to
held that the process was very opaque, because the Bundestag did not gather sufficient votes. Generous budgets for renewables, as well as
get continuous information and that the EU was a ‘shadow negotiator’ political experience and support from the Green Party and the Ministry
during the EEG discussions (Interview 15). In presenting the draft to the of Environment, all served to strengthen the lobby groups promoting
Bundestag in June 2014, the Minister of Economics argued that this renewables. Under these conditions, the feed-in tariff generated certain
could no longer be changed because it had already been negotiated increasing returns that historical institutionalists adopt to explain path
with the Commission [64]. dependency over time.
In 2014, the EEG was amended. The reform represented substantial However, the EEG also created certain effects that began to un-
changes, including growth corridors, caps and direct marketing. The dermine the feed-in tariff rather than re-enforce it. When historical
German government followed up its intentions to test tendering pro- institutionalists discuss increasing returns, they refer to factors such as
cedures in practice [61]. In order to test the viability of auctioning to actors’ strong incentive to stick with the solution that they have already
determine future support levels, the new EEG provided for the in- invested resources in. Yet the rapid deployment of renewables as a
troduction of a tendering process for freestanding PV installations, as a consequence of the feed-in tariff increased the costs to an extent that
pilot project. The first auctions were held in 2015. This was politically the investment costs eventually seemed minor compared to the costs
far more controversial than introducing the quantity control itself (In- that the feed-in tariff entailed. Rather than generating returns that
terview 9). benefitted the existing path, the rise in costs started to benefit other
solutions that would curb the deployment of renewable energy.
4.7. EEG 2017 One key change agent was the FDP, which paved the way for the
shift towards auctioning, voicing criticism of the EEG already in 2004,
In parallel to the inquiry in Germany, the Commission was re- and noting the cost issues related to its rapid deployment. The coalition
forming its state aid guidelines, which entered into force in August between CDU/CSU and FDP, formed in 2009, prepared the ground for
2014. In its 2014 state aid guidelines proposition, the Commission re- introducing auctioning, finally implemented by the grand coalition that
quired member states to align their renewable support schemes to came to power in 2013. FDP and CDU/CSU, and later SPD, used costs to
competitive bidding processes. Bidding procedures were already under legitimise the shift to auctioning. The evidence shows that from the
discussion in Germany, but the state aid inquiry contributed towards viewpoint of big industries, this cost argument was useful. While others
speeding up the process (Interview 7, 9, 15). One policy advisor in- argued that most energy costs were coming not from the EEG but from,
terviewed for our study argued that the transition to a tendering system for example, infrastructure, the cost argument proved effective espe-
‘would certainly not have been so fast, […] if the Commission had not cially as costs are more visible with renewables than with other energy
said, “no matter what you do, we need the tender as default”’ sources (this is itemised on every customer’s bill).
(Interview 7). The shift towards procurement by tender happened under the con-
In 2016, the government eventually transposed the auction system ditions of increasing encroachment on the market shares of the big
for different renewable technologies (photovoltaics, onshore wind, utilities by producers of renewable energy. Around 2013, it was clear
offshore wind, and biomass) into law. The auction design is tailored for that the big utilities could face future bankruptcy. This created in-
each of the different technologies. There are exceptions from the ten- creasing resistance to the support scheme and made organisational
dering system for small installations. Small renewables installations of actors more ‘utility-friendly’. Given the intermittent character of the
under 750-kilowatt (kW) capacity (in the case of biomass, under electricity provided by producers using renewable energy sources, it
150 kW) continue to receive feed-in tariffs [65]. The intention here is would simply not be in the interest of the energy system to let the es-
for citizen cooperatives and small project developers to continue to tablished utilities go bankrupt. In 2013, the grand coalition transferred
operate small renewables plants. However, there are no exceptions for the responsibility for renewable energy to the industry-friendly
wind-farms with fewer than six turbines. Instead, the government has Ministry of Economics. Under the dominance of the grand coalition, the
introduced simpler and more transparent rules for such onshore wind defenders of the feed-in tariff were a minority in the parliament.
installations. There are special rules for citizen energy projects. Unless The EU created a political context that benefited those agents that
they are very small, citizen energy projects must compete in auctions wanted to change the EEG. This was due to the state aid guidelines
but enjoy benefits such as automatically receiving the highest feed-in introduced by the Commission. Although the state aid guidelines are
tariff accepted in the tender (even if their own bid is lower) [65]. not EU law that mandates member states’ compliance, they are un-
derstood in practice as rules that the member states have to adhere to.
5. Discussion The state aid guidelines are therefore an example of what Jarle Trondal
[10] labels bureaucratic inter-penetration across levels of governance.
The previous section has described the origin and development of While there has been controversy related to the Commission’s
Germany’s feed-in support scheme for renewables and the shift to guidelines for state aid since 1990 when Germany first introduced a
auctioning. In the following, we relate the evidence to the theoretical feed-in tariff, a key ‘window of change’ opened around 2013. Over time,
perspectives, highlighting how layering serves displacement. Germany had made numerous changes to the EEG. The many EEG re-
In line with historical institutionalism, the EEG development af- forms and the high political attention given to costs in domestic poli-
fected the positions of actors in a way that was unforeseen when it was tical debates provided the Commission with an opportunity to attack
first introduced. No one had thought renewable energy would grow so the German feed-in tariff.
much and so quickly as a result of the feed-in tariff. Initially the feed-in The Commission did more than just create a political context fa-
tariff did not pose any threat to the established utilities’ market shares. vourable to change agents: it acted as a change agent itself. The evi-
For more than two decades, the feed-in tariff reinforced itself. Although dence shows that the notification by the Commission in 2013 was
the act was contested, it gained considerable support and was con- crucial: the notification that the Commission would open an inquiry
sidered stable [11]. The policy instrument re-enforced itself through its into compliance of the EEG with the guidelines for state aid. The
popularity among those who benefited from the policy instrument, Commission attacked the exemptions from the EEG levy for energy-
namely, interest groups promoting renewables, academics who em- intensive industries in its opening letter [62] and would not accept such
braced the successful deployment rates and other countries that con- exceptions before Germany would introduce procurements by tender
sidered Germany as an example to follow. In the early years of the [66].
policy development, politicians from unusual party constellations such However, in view of the long-lasting debates on cost and quantity
as CSU and the Green Party (until 1999) and SPD and the Greens control, the evidence indicates that the German government would

38
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

probably have introduced a tendering system even if the Commission Acknowledgements


had not pushed for this. Nevertheless, the Commission’s threat of liti-
gation helped pro-auctioning actors to speed up the process (see also The Research Council of Norway has funded this study through the
[64], p. 336). The possibility of putting the blame on Brussels (i.e. the Large-scale Programme for Energy Research ENERGIX (REMIX, project
Commission), which had served as a ‘shadow negotiator’ during the no. 243756). Statkraft, Statnett, The Norwegian Water Resources and
EEG policy-making process, made it possible for the government to Energy Directorate, Swedish Energy Agency and Energy Norway have
escape the decision-making trap (i.e. the many veto positions in the also funded this project and contributed with valuable feedback in
German political system) much sooner than would otherwise have been discussions. We are grateful to the interviewees, who have given some
expected. We therefore find support for the anticipation that the EU has of their time to talk to us, making it possible to accomplish this study.
contributed towards strengthening agents who have promoted a change The participants at the event ‘Germany: Energiewende at a crossroads?’
to the feed-in tariff policy. in Brussels, 26 April 2018, and the panel 'Climate and energy: EU re-
The evidence suggests that the policy change did not occur as a newable energy in comparison’ (P046) at the General ECPR Conference
sudden punctuation via an external shock, as commonly suggested by 2018 in Oslo have contributed to improve our work by challenging us
many historical institutionalists, but rather incrementally, over time, with questions. We also thank our colleagues in the REMIX project and
where layering ended up as displacement. The EEG was never meant to the three anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments to earlier
remain fixed and unchanging. The German system has regular evalua- versions of this article.
tions of many of its laws, among others the EEG. Therefore, there was a
certain degree of openness to change endogenous in the EEG. This References
gradual process of change is best described with the type of change that
[18] label layering: the revisions of the EEG increasingly added ele- [1] C. Morris, A. Jungjohann, Energy Democracy: Germany’s Energiewende to
ments of increased market-orientation; for example, voluntary direct Renewables, Palgrave Macmillan, 2016.
[2] M. Burke, J. Stephens, Energy democracy: goals and policy instruments for socio-
marketing in 2012, which was made compulsory in 2014, and auction technical transitions, Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 33 (2017) 35–48, http://dx.doi.org/10.
pilots within one technology (solar) before the feed-in tariff for large- 1016/j.erss.2017.09.024.
scale electricity generation was radically displaced in 2016. [3] E. Hauser, A. Weber, A. Zipp, U. Leprich, Bewertung von Ausschreibungsverfahren
als Finanzierungsmodell für Anlagen erneuerbarer Energienutzung, IZES gGmbH,
2014.
[4] T.H.J. Inderberg, K. Tews, B. Turner, Is there a prosumer pathway? Exploring
6. Conclusions household solar energy development in Germany, Norway, and the United
Kingdom, Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 42 (2018) 258–269, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
erss.2018.04.006.
This study has described the development of the German support [5] C. Fraune, M. Knodt, Sustainable energy transformations in an age of populism,
policy for electricity generation, and explained the shift from a feed-in post-truth politics, and local resistance, Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 43 (2018).
[6] K. Tews, Europeanization of energy and climate policy: the struggle between
tariff support scheme to auctioning. Although it did not get much at-
competing ideas of coordinating energy transitions, J. Environ. Dev. 24 (3) (2015)
tention when the first feed-in tariff was introduced in 1990, the Grid 267–291, http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1070496515591578.
Feed-in Law created a surprisingly powerful political and societal dy- [7] J. Beermann, K. Tews, Decentralised laboratories in the German energy transition.
namic. For almost three decades, the feed-in tariff survived external Why local renewable energy initiatives must reinvent themselves, J. Clean. Prod.
169 (2016) 125–134, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.08.130.
pressures from the Commission and internal pressures from industrial [8] D. Jacobs, Renewable Energy Policy Convergence in the EU: The Evolution of Feed-
interests, from the Ministry of Economics, liberals, conservatives and in Tariffs in Germany, Spain and France, Ashgate, Aldershot, 2012.
eventually also social democrats, all urging a shift to a more market- [9] J.P. Olsen, The many faces of Europeanization, J. Common Mark. Stud. 40 (5)
(2002) 921–952, http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-5965.00403.
oriented support scheme. However, the fact that the support scheme [10] Conceptualizing common political order: an introduction, in: J. Trondal (Ed.), The
was successful also gave rise to concerns about costs, and fears that the Rise of Common Political Order. Institutions, Public Administration and
utilities would go bankrupt. Brussels was aware of the increasing con- Transnational Space, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, 2017.
[11] C. Stefes, Energiewende: critical junctures and path dependencies since 1990,
cerns and the wish of organisational and political field actors to revise Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft 6 (2014) 45–68, http://dx.doi.org/10.5771/
the system. The Commission therefore found an appropriate time to 9783845250083_48.
instigate its inquiry into state aid and the German feed-in tariff law, [12] C. Hager, Germany’s green energy revolution. Challenging the theory and practice
of institutional change, Ger. Polit. Soc. 33 (3) (2015) 1–27, http://dx.doi.org/10.
putting pressure on the German government. This was in 2013, which 3167/gps.2015.330301.
represents the key turning-point year of the policy-change to auc- [13] P. Pierson, Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis, Princeton
tioning. Having raised concerns, framing the feed-in tariff as entailing University Press, Princeton, 2004.
[14] D.C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,
unreasonable costs, the FDP had prepared the ground for the following
Cambridge University Press, New York, 1990.
grand coalition government to introduce auctioning, first as a pilot for [15] F.R. Baumgartner, B.D. Jones, Agendas and Instability in American Politics,
solar energy in 2014 and full-scale in 2016. University of Chicago Press, London, 1993.
The EU emerges as important because it created a political context [16] J. Mahoney, K. Thelen (Eds.), Explaining Institutional Change. Ambiguity, Agency,
and Power, Cambridge University Press, New York, 2010.
(i.e. when initiating a process of reforming the state aide guidelines) [17] W. Streeck, K. Thelen, Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced
that benefited those agents who wanted to change the EEG. The EU (i.e. Political Economies, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2005.
the Commission) also acted as a change agent itself, opening an inquiry [18] A theory of gradual institutional change, in: J. Mahoney, K. Thelen (Eds.),
Explaining Institutional Change. Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, Cambridge
into compliance of the EEG with the guidelines for state aid and at- University Press, New York, 2010, pp. 1–37.
tacking elements related to the EEG that are central for creating poli- [19] M.D. Leiren, Differential growth and how liberalization was achieved in the postal
tical consensus for the Energiewende (i.e. exemptions from the EEG levy services sector, J. Contemp. Eur. Res. 11 (4) (2015), https://www.jcer.net/index.
php/jcer/article/view/706.
for energy-intensive industries). We find that the shift to auctioning, [20] K.J. Alter, Who are the “masters of the treaty”? European governments and the
although seemingly abrupt, came about gradually through a process of European court of justice, Int. Organ. 52 (1) (1998) 121–148, http://dx.doi.org/10.
layering. Politicians were continuously revising the EEG, incrementally 1162/002081898550572.
[21] S.K. Schmidt, Beyond compliance: the Europeanization of member states through
adding elements of greater market-orientation – including voluntary negative integration and legislative uncertainty, J. Comp. Policy Anal. 10 (3)
direct marketing in 2012, which was made compulsory in 2014, and (2008) 299–308, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13876980802231016.
auction pilots within one technology (solar), before more radically re- [22] A.E. Töller, Measuring and comparing the Europeanization of national legislation: a
research note, J. Common Mark. Stud. 48 (2) (2010) 417–444, http://dx.doi.org/
placing the feed-in tariff for large-scale electricity generation in 2016.
10.1111/j.1468-5965.2009.02058.x.
New actors manage to unsettle dominant practices and impose their [23] A. Berchem, Das unterschätzte Gesetz (2006, 22 September) Retrieved 14 March
own preferences. The issues of costs and insolvency made defenders of 2017 from: Zeit Online, 2006, http://www.zeit.de/online/2006/39/EEG/
the feed-in-tariff vulnerable to displacement. komplettansicht.

39
M.D. Leiren, I. Reimer Energy Research & Social Science 43 (2018) 33–40

[24] C.H. Stefes, Bypassing Germany's reformstau: the remarkable rise of renewable Retrieved 7 April 2017 from: Süddeutsche Zeitung, 2010, http://www.
energy, Ger. Polit. 19 (2) (2010) 148–163, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/ sueddeutsche.de/wirtschaft/eon-verkauft-stromnetz-leiser-abschied-von-der-netz-
09644001003793222. ag-1.148422.
[25] S. Jacobsson, V. Lauber, The politics and policy of energy system transformatio- [47] K. Kloc, D. Koska, Competition law mechanisms as additional tool of the III energy
n—explaining the German diffusion of renewable energy technology, Energy Policy package implementation, in: R. Zajdler (Ed.), EU Energy Law, Cambridge Scholars
34 (3) (2006) 256–276, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2004.08.029. Publishing, Newcastle upon Tyne, 2012, pp. 27–52.
[26] Agora, Understanding the Energiewende: FAQ on the Ongoing Transition of the [48] M.A. Schreurs, The politics of phase-out, Bull. Atom. Sci. 68 (6) (2012) 30–41,
German Power System, Retrieved 1 March 2017 from: (2015) https://www.agora- http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0096340212464359.
energiewende.de/fileadmin/Projekte/2015/Understanding_the_EW/Agora_ [49] J. Huenteler, T.S. Schmidt, N. Kanie, Japan’s post-Fukushima challenge—implica-
Understanding_the_Energiewende.pdf. tions from the German experience on renewable energy policy, Energy Policy 45
[27] European Commission, Commission Closes Investigation into Grid-Feed in Law (2012) 6–11, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.02.041.
(Germany) (2001, 28 February) Retrieved 23 March 2017 from: (2001) http:// [50] Bundesnetzagentur, Monitoringbericht, Retrieved 9 July 2017 from: (2007) https://
www.google.no/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&cad=rja& www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/Sachgebiete/Energie/
uact=8&ved=0ahUKEwjWw73frL3UAhXKAJoKHbd-DI4QFggkMAA&url=http Unternehmen_Institutionen/DatenaustauschUndMonitoring/Monitoring/
%3A%2F%2Feuropa.eu%2Frapid%2Fpress-release_IP-01-277_en.pdf&usg= Monitoringbericht2007.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=2.
AFQjCNGEnMwrw2tNrVmdOGMMERneI7VlpQ&sig2=5RMi88f6ulFxtBp2vfl0jA. [51] Bundesnetzagentur, Monitoringbericht, Retrieved 9 July 2017 from: (2011) https://
[28] I. de Lovinfosse, How and Why Do Policies Change? A Comparison of Renewable www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/Allgemeines/
Electricity Policies in Belgium, P.I.E. Peter Lang., Denmark, Germany, the Bundesnetzagentur/Publikationen/Berichte/2011/MonitoringBericht2011.pdf?__
Netherlands and the UK. Brussels, 2008. blob=publicationFile.
[29] E. Gawel, G. Strunz, State aid dispute on Germany’s support for renewables. Is the [52] BEE, Hintergrundpapier zur EEG-Umlage 2014, Retrieved 27 March 2017 from:
Commission on the right course? J. Eur. Environ. Plann. Law 11 (2014) 137–150, (2013) http://www.bee-ev.de/fileadmin/Publikationen/Positionspapiere_
http://dx.doi.org/10.1163/18760104-01102005. Stellungnahmen/20131015_BEE-Hintergrund_EEG-Umlage-2014.pdf.
[30] D. Ohlhorst, Germany’s energy transition policy between national targets and de- [53] A. Purkus, E. Gawel, M. Deissenroth, K. Nienhaus, S. Wassermann, Market in-
centralized responsibilities, J. Integr. Environ. Sci. 12 (4) (2015) 303–322, http:// tegration of renewable energies through direct marketing – lessons learned from the
dx.doi.org/10.1080/1943815X.2015.1125373. German market premium scheme, Energy Sustain. Soc. 5 (1) (2015), http://dx.doi.
[31] E. Bruns, D. Ohlhenorst, B. Wenzel, J. Köppel, Renewable Energies in Germany’s org/10.1186/s13705-015-0040-1.
Electricity Market. A Biography of the Innovation Process, Springer, Berlin, 2009. [54] Vorholz, Rösler macht Krawall (2012, 19 January) Retrieved 9 January 2017 from:
[32] G. Kungl, Stewards or sticklers for change? Incumbent energy providers and the Zeit Online, 2012, http://www.zeit.de/2012/04/Energie-Solar-Subvention.
politics of the German energy transition, Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 8 (2015) 13–23, [55] P. Altmaier, Energiewende könnte bis zu einer Billion Euro kosten (2013, 19
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2015.04.009. February) Retrieved 7 January 2017 from: Frankfurter Allgemeine, 2013, http://
[33] J.-F. Hake, W. Fischer, S. Venghaus, C. Weckenbrock, The German Energiewende – www.faz.net/aktuell/politik/energiepolitik/umweltminister-altmaier-
history and status quo, Energy 92 (2015) 532–546, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. energiewende-koennte-bis-zu-einer-billion-euro-kosten-12086525.html.
energy.2015.04.027. [56] G. de Clercq, B. Lewis, UPDATE 1-European Utilities Urge Policy Reform to Avert
[34] Bundesregierung, Vereinbarung zwischen der Bundesregierung und den Black-Outs (2013, 11 October) Retrieved 9 July 2017 from: Reuters, 2013, http://
Energieversorgungsunternehmen vom 14. Juni, Berlin. Retrieved 1 December 2017 uk.reuters.com/article/utilities-renewables-ceos-idUKL6N0I11UF20131011.
from: (2000) http://www.energie-fakten.de/pdf/kernenergie-konsens.pdf. [57] Der Spiegel, Teure Energiewende. Altmaier warnt vor Kosten von einer Billion Euro
[35] W. Gründinger, The renewable energy sources act (EEG), Chapter 6, Ibid What (2013, 20 February) Retrieved 7 January 2017 from: (2013) http://www.spiegel.
Drives the Energiewende?: New German Politics and the Influence of Interest de/politik/deutschland/altmaier-energiewende-koennte-eine-billion-euro-kosten-a-
Groups, PhD Dissertation, (2016). 884411.html.
[36] M. Mendonca, Feed-in Tariffs: Accelerating the Deployment of Renewable Energy, [58] D.F. Sturm, Gabriel entdeckt den Industriestolz der SPD wieder (2014, 8 April)
World Future Council, Earthscan, London, 2007. Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: Welt, 2014, https://www.welt.de/politik/
[37] Greenpeace, Energie- und klimapolitische Aussagen der Parteien: Auszüge aus den deutschland/article126722606/Gabriel-entdeckt-den-Industriestolz-der-SPD-
Parteiprogrammen zur Wahl September 2005, Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: wieder.html.
(2005) https://www.greenpeace.de/sites/www.greenpeace.de/files/ [59] Bundesnetzagentur, Monitoringbericht, Retrieved 9 July 2017 from: (2014) https://
vergleichparteienenergiewahl05_0.pdf. www.bundesnetzagentur.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/Allgemeines/
[38] SPD, Vertrauen in Deutschland: Das Wahlmanifest der SPD, Retrieved 21 March Bundesnetzagentur/Publikationen/Berichte/2014/Monitoringbericht_2014_BF.
2017 from (2005) https://ia902605.us.archive.org/9/items/ pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=3.
VertrauenInDeutschlandDasWahlmanifestDerSpd/wahlmanifest2005.pdf. [60] bpb; Bundeszentrale für politische Bildung, Die Großen Vier (2013, 1 March)
[39] Bündnis 90/Die Grüne, Eines für alle: Das Grüne Wahlprogramm 2005, Retrieved Retrieved 15 March 2017 from: (2013) http://www.bpb.de/politik/wirtschaft/
21 March 2017 from: (2005) http://www.portal-sozialpolitik.de/uploads/sopo/ energiepolitik/152780/die-grossen-vier.
pdf/2005/2005-07-10_bt_wahlprogramm_gruene.pdf. [61] Bundesregierung, Deutschlands Zukunft gestalten. Koalitionsvertrag zwischen CDU,
[40] CDU, Regierungsprogramm: Deutschlands Chancen nutzen. Wachstum. Arbeit. CSU und SPD. 18. Legislaturperiode, Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: (2013)
Sicherheit, Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: (2005) http://www.kas.de/upload/ https://www.bundesregierung.de/Content/DE/_Anlagen/2013/2013-12-17-
ACDP/CDU/Programme_Bundestag/2005-2009_Regierungsprogramm_ koalitionsvertrag.pdf?__blob=publicationFile.
Deutschlands-Chancen-nutzen_Wachstum-Arbeit-Sicherheit.pdf. [62] European Commission, State Aid: Commission Opens in-Depth Inquiry into Support
[41] FDP, Deutschlandprogramm 2005: Arbeit hat Vorfahrt, Retrieved 21 March 2017 for Energy-Intensive Companies Benefitting from a Reduced Renewables Surcharge
from (2005) https://ia801408.us.archive.org/2/items/ArbeitHatVorfahrt/fdp- (2013, 18 December) Retrieved 23 March 2017 from: Press release, 2013, http://
wahlprogramm.pdf. europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-13-1283_en.htm?locale=en.
[42] M. Jänicke, Die Umweltpolitik der Großen Koalition, in: C. Egele, R. Zohlnhöfer, [63] n-TV, Zweifel an Gabriels Energiekonzept. Industrie Sieht 900.000 Jobs bedroht
Die zweite (Eds.), Große Koalition: Eine Bilanz der Regierung Merkel 2005–2009, (2014, 2 February) Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: (2014) http://www.n-tv.de/
VS Verlag, Wiesbaden, 2010, pp. 487–502. politik/Industrie-sieht-900-000-Jobs-bedroht-article12193626.html.
[43] Bundesregierung, Koalitionsvertrag zwischen CDU, CSU und SPD für die 16, [64] S. Fischer, Die Energiewende und Europa: Europäisierungsprozesse in der deut-
Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: Wahlperiode des deutschen Bundestages: schen Energie- und Klimapolitik, Springer, Berlin, 2016.
Gemeinsam für Deutschland. Mit Mut und Menschlichkeit, 2005, https://www. [65] K. Apunn, EEG Reform 2016 – Switching to Auctions for Renewables. CLEW
bundesregierung.de/Content/DE/_Anlagen/koalitionsvertrag.pdf?__blob= Factsheet (2016, 8 July) Retrieved 26 March 2017 from: Clean Energy Wire, Berlin,
publicationFile&v=2. 2016https://www.cleanenergywire.org/factsheets/eeg-reform-2016-switching-
[44] A. Seibt, Lobbying für erneuerbare Energien. Das Public-Affairs-Management von auctions-renewables.
Wirtschaftsverbänden während der Gesetzgebung, Springer VS, Köln, 2014. [66] European Commission, State Aid: Commission Approves Auction Scheme for
[45] European Commission, Market legislation, Retrieved 21 March 2017 from: (2017) Electricity from Renewable Sources in Germany (2016, 20 December) Retrieved 25
https://ec.europa.eu/energy/en/topics/markets-and-consumers/market- March 2017 from: Press Release, 2016, http://ec.europa.eu/denmark/node/
legislation. 1206_en.
[46] M. Hesse, M. Bauchmüller, Leiser Abschied von der Netz AG (2010, 17 May)

40

You might also like