You are on page 1of 27

!

!
!
!
!"#"$%&'()*+$,-./'$"/')/0$$
!
"#$%&!'!()!
!
!
*+,%!-%.!/0123242350#63171!30!!
895057391!#0:!;593565<=!>!!
!!
?=!@3925&!-%%!
!
%A9%&$2%:!B&57!!
!"#$!%&'()**+!*,!-.*'*/0.!1*.0*2*34!
!"&309%250!C03D%&132=!"&%11E!FGGH!
!!
!!
!!
!!
!
!!
!
3 The New Institutionalisms
in Economics and Sociology
Victor Nee

The focus on institutions as a foundational con- institutional analysis of economic life. This entails
cept in the social sciences has given rise to a variety revisiting Weber’s ([1904–5] 2002; [1922] 1968)
of new institutionalist approaches. Not since the view that rationality is motivated and guided by sys-
behavioral revolution of the 1950s has there been tems of shared beliefs (religious and cultural), cus-
so much interest in a cross-disciplinary concept, tom, norms, and institutions. A conceptual frame-
one that offers a common theme for exchange and work underscoring such context-bound rationality
debate. The writings of Ronald Coase, Douglass serves as the foundation for examining the emer-
North, and Oliver Williamson on the endogenous gence, persistence, and transformation of institu-
emergence and evolution of economic institutions tional structures.
have inspired a broadly based movement in econom-
ics. In sociology, neoinstitutionalists—principally
John Meyer, Richard Scott, Paul DiMaggio, and NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS
Walter Powell—have redirected the study of or-
ganizations by analyzing how institutional envi- In the view of new economic institutionalists, the
ronment and cultural beliefs shape their behavior. old institutionalism offered penetrating and in-
In a parallel shift of analytic attention, economic sightful descriptions of economic institutions (Ve-
sociologists—Peter Evans, Neil Fligstein, Richard blen 1909 [1899], 1934; Mitchell 1937; Com-
Swedberg, and myself—argue for a new focus to mons 1934, 1957), but ultimately failed in the bid
explain how institutions interact with social net- to shape the direction of modern economics. In-
works and norms to shape and direct economic ac- stead, it remained a dissident movement within
tion. The common starting point of these ap- economics, which, Coase (1984, 230) quipped,
proaches is the claim that institutions matter and produced a “mass of descriptive material waiting
that understanding institutions and institutional for a theory, or a fire.” With the limitations of the
change is a core agenda for the social sciences. old economic institutionalism in mind, he noted
This chapter does not seek comprehensiveness that “what distinguishes the modern institutional
in its coverage of the new institutionalisms in the economists is not that they speak about institutions
social sciences.1 Instead I focus selectively on the . . . but that they use standard economic theory to
new institutionalisms in economics and sociology analyze the working of these institutions and to
as a means to lay out core features of a new insti- discover the part they plan in the operations of the
tutional economic sociology, which brings back economy.” Kenneth Arrow (1987, 734) offers a
into the research agenda a crucial focus on ex- similar assessment in his answer to his rhetorical
plaining the workings of shared beliefs, norms, and question, “Why did the older institutionalist school
institutions in economic life. My aim is to integrate fail so miserably, though it contained such able an-
a focus on social relations and institutions into a alysts as Thorstein Veblen, J. R. Commons, and
modern sociological approach to the study of eco- W. C. Mitchell?” The new institutional economics
nomic behavior by highlighting the mechanisms has been influential, he thinks, not because it offers
that regulate the manner in which formal elements “new answers to the traditional questions of eco-
of institutional structures in combination with in- nomics—resource allocation and the degree of uti-
formal social organization of networks and norms lization,” but because it uses economic theory to
facilitate, motivate, and govern economic action.2 answer “new questions, why economic institutions
Thus both distal and proximate causal mechanisms emerged the way they did and not otherwise.”
are addressed and incorporated into a comparative Without question new economic institutionalists
50 Nee
have sought to differentiate themselves from the Institutional
old institutional economics by adapting, rather Environment
than rejecting, as did the earlier institutionalists,
neoclassical economic theory. First, Coase’s theory Shift Parameters Strategic
of transaction cost corrected an important omis-
sion in neoclassical economics, and shows that Governance
Pigou was wrong in arguing that taxation and reg-
ulation are the only effective way to deal with neg-
ative externalities.3 His use of transaction cost rea-
soning is not essentially different from Stigler’s Behavioral Attributes Endogenous
adding information costs to correct neoclassical Preferences
theory. Second, the idea that human agency is “in-
Individual
tendedly rational, but limitedly so” (Simon 1957,
xxiv) can be incorporated into a “thick” view of ra-
tional choice as context-bound; as Posner (1993, Figure 1. A model of new institutional economics
80) points out, “rationality is not omniscience.”4
Third, through concepts like “asset specificity” and environment—property rights, legal change, and
“opportunism,” Williamson extended microeco- norms—result in altering the relative prices for
nomic reasoning to understudied topics in eco- firms, this induces changes in governance struc-
nomics such as vertical integration, corporate gov- tures or efforts by the firm to lobby government.
ernance, and long-term contracts to show that The model includes a purposive actor whose be-
transaction cost economizing can generate predic- havioral attributes—“self-interest seeking with
tions about the organizational boundaries and guile”—lie behind many of the transaction costs
governance structures of firms competing for sur- that governance structures are designed to address.
vival and profit in a competitive environment.
Fourth, North’s account of institutional change The Place of Transaction Cost Reasoning
views organizations as rational actors in pursuing
marginal gains stemming from changes in relative The core concept of the new institutional eco-
prices. nomics is transaction cost—the cost of negotiat-
The differences between the old and new insti- ing, securing, and completing transactions in a
tutionalisms may have been overstated, however market economy. In Coase’s (1988, 15) view, neo-
(Rutherford 1994).5 The old economic institu- classical economics “is incapable of handling many
tionalists were not as lacking in theory as Coase’s of the problems to which it purports to give an-
quip suggests. Veblen’s concept of cumulative cau- swers” because it assumes a world of zero transac-
sation is consistent with modern ideas about ex- tion cost in which institutions are superfluous to
planation and path dependence. Mitchell (1927), economic analysis:
who founded the National Bureau of Economic
In order to carry out a market transaction it is neces-
Research (NBER), was not a dust-bowl empiricist,
sary to discover who it is that one wishes to deal with,
but espoused the idea of research driven by mid-
to inform people that one wishes to deal and on what
dle-range theory. Both old and new economic in-
terms, to conduct negotiations leading up to a bar-
stitutionalisms argue that the mathematical formal-
gain, to draw up the contract, to undertake the in-
ism of neoclassical economics has contributed little
spection needed to make sure that the terms of the
to understanding real-world economic behavior.
contract are being observed, and so on. These opera-
Both espouse a realist orientation, which, as Coase
tions are often extremely costly, sufficiently costly at
(1984, 230) writes, seeks to study economic be-
any rate to prevent many transactions that would be
havior “within the constraints imposed by real
carried out in a world in which the pricing system
institutions.”6
worked without cost. (Coase 1960, 15)
Figure 1 provides a schematic view of the causal
model posited by the new institutional economics, Hence in contrast to the world of zero transaction
as adapted by Williamson (1994, 80) from Richard costs assumed in neoclassical economics, transac-
Scott. In this model, the institutional environment tion cost reasoning provides a method enabling
is shaped by the rules of the game (see North economists to “study the world that exists.”
1981). The downward arrow indicates that if shifts In “The Nature of the Firm” (1937) Coase ap-
in the broad parameters of the institutional plied transaction cost reasoning to explain the en-
New Institutionalisms 51

dogenous existence of the firm in a competitive advantages in both production cost and gover-
market economy. If market transactions were cost- nance cost respects” Williamson (1981, 558).10
less, Coase argued, then there would not be suffi- Williamson’s contribution has been to build a
cient motivation for entrepreneurs to operate theory-driven research program in which core hy-
firms. But, in fact, all solutions to the problem of potheses derived from Coase have been empirical-
measuring the performance of agents and enforc- ly verified.
ing contracts are costly. Information asymmetry A second research program stimulated by
and uncertainty are found in all institutional envi- Coase’s seminal essays emphasizes the importance
ronments; hence the same agency problems found of property rights in shaping the incentive struc-
in markets also apply to the firm. The distinguish- ture (Cheung 1970, 1974; North and Thomas
ing characteristic of the firm is the suspension of 1973; Alchian and Demsetz 1973; North 1981).
the price mechanism. The entrepreneur has the Cheung showed that in a neoclassical world of
power and authority within the limits set by the zero transaction costs, private property rights can
employment contract to direct workers from one be dropped without negating the Coase theorem,
part of the firm to another. Thus “firms will an insight that North extended to develop a new
emerge to organize what would otherwise be mar- institutionalist property rights approach to explain
ket transactions whenever their costs are less than economic performance. Because transaction costs
the costs of carrying out the transactions through make up a significant part of the cost of production
the market” (1988, 7). In other words, the reason and exchange, North reasoned that alternative in-
for the firm’s existence is that the “operation of a stitutional arrangements can make the difference
market costs something,” and the firm saves on between economic growth, stagnation, or decline.
this cost. The first of the new institutionalists to explicitly
The new institutional economics includes a di- disavow the efficiency assumption of the function-
verse group of economists with important differ- alist theory of institutions (Schotter 1981), North
ences and ongoing debates.7 I focus here on three asserts that because incentives are structured in in-
distinctive approaches—pioneered by Williamson, stitutional arrangements, perverse incentives abound
North, and Greif—that are of interest to a new and give rise to property rights that discourage in-
institutional economic sociology. The unifying novation and private entrepreneurship. It is fre-
theme of all three is the proposition that social in- quently profitable and more rewarding for political
stitutions matter to economic actors because they actors to devise institutions that redistribute
shape the structure of incentives. wealth, which can dampen incentives for innova-
Williamson builds on Coase’s insight that infor- tion and private enterprise.
mation asymmetry and uncertainty make credible North’s approach is state-centered in that it fo-
commitment to agreements difficult to secure, in- cuses analytic attention on the role of the state in
tegrating this insight with other literatures.8 His devising the underlying structure of property
synthesis emphasizes that corporate governance is rights in society.11 In his view, the central task in ex-
principally concerned with addressing the problem plaining economic growth is to specify the events
of opportunism and reducing the risk of malfea- and conditions that provide incentives for political
sance in agents’ performance.9 By examining the actors to establish formal institutional arrange-
comparative costs of planning, adapting, and mon- ments supporting efficient property rights.12 In the
itoring agents’ performance, Williamson derives rise of the West, this entailed the dilution of state
testable predictions about alternative governance control over resources and the emergence of some
structures. His prediction turns on three types of form of political pluralism.13
asset specificity—site, physical, and human—that Conceived as “humanly devised constraints that
firms encounter. Because firms compete in Dar- structure political, economic and social interac-
winian-like selection in markets to survive and re- tions,” institutions in North’s view (1991, 97)
main profitable (Hayek 1945), they are under con- consist of formal rules like constitutions, laws, and
tinuous pressure to adapt by economizing on property rights and also informal elements such as
transaction costs. Hence, where asset specificity is “sanctions, taboos, customs, traditions and codes
greater, principals and agents “will make special of conduct.” Although he was among the first to
efforts to design” a governance structure with point to the informal elements of institutions,
“good continuity properties” to reinforce incen- North has consistently emphasized the “funda-
tives for credible commitments to agreements. By mental rules of the game” or the basic ground
contrast, if “assets are nonspecific, markets enjoy rules provided by constitutions and law. These are
52 Nee
the rules that govern political actors and shape the acknowledges the role of ideology, cultural beliefs,
structure of property rights that define and specify norms, and conventions, Greif contends that his
the rules for competition and cooperation in mar- approach to institutional analysis does not provide
kets. The importance of formal rules is amplified in an appropriate framework to study how actors are
modern market economies, where, North argues, endogenously motivated to follow rules not en-
the growth of long-distance trade, specialization, forced by the state. North relegates beliefs and
and division of labor contributes to agency prob- norms to a black box of informal constraints, and
lems and contract negotiation and enforcement is unable to show how informal rules and their en-
problems. Though interpersonal ties, social norms, forcement combine with formal rules to enable,
and sanctions such as ostracism are very important motivate, and guide economic behavior. Greif’s
elements of institutional arrangements, they are own approach, applying game theory to examine
not sufficient in themselves to enforce credible how cultural beliefs shape the principal-agent rela-
commitments to agreements, because “in the ab- tionship, giving rise to and sustaining distinct eco-
sence of effective impersonal contracting the gains nomic institutions, is discussed below, in the sec-
from defections are great enough to forestall the tion on the sociological turn in new institutional
development of complex exchange” in modern economics.
economies (North 1991, 100).
North’s theory of institutional change applies
standard marginalist theory in its emphasis on A COUNTERPERSPECTIVE FROM ECONOMIC
changing relative prices. His economic history of SOCIOLOGY
the rise of the West showed that institutional
change “comes from a change in the relative bar- In his influential article “Economic Action and
gaining power of rulers versus constituents (or Social Structure” (1985) Granovetter points out
rulers versus rulers), and, broadly speaking, changes that “Actors do not behave or decide as atoms out-
arise because of major, persistent changes in rela- side a social context, nor do they adhere slavishly
tive prices” (1984, 260). Changes in relative prices to a script written for them by the particular inter-
are in turn often driven by demographic change, section of social categories that they happen to oc-
change in the stock of knowledge, and change in cupy. Their attempts at purposive action are in-
military technology. The dynamics of institutional stead embedded in concrete, ongoing systems of
change in North’s theory stem from a continuous social relations” (487). He proffers the view that
interaction between institutions and organizations “social relations, rather than institutional arrange-
within the context of competition over scarce re- ments or generalized morality [e.g. shared beliefs
sources. Because institutions are self-reinforcing, and norms], are mainly responsible for the pro-
vested interests in the existing stock of institutions duction of trust in economic life” (491). He criti-
reinforce path dependence in efforts to revise the cizes Williamson’s use of transaction cost reason-
rules. Institutional innovations will come from ing in explaining the boundaries of firms for what
states rather than constituents because states gen- he views as unrealistic assumptions of under- and
erally do not have a free-rider problem (except oversocialized conceptions of human action, “both
sometimes in international affairs), whereas indi- hav[ing] in common a conception of action and
viduals and organizational actors are limited in decision carried out by atomized actors” (485).
their capacity to implement large-scale changes Williamson’s “state of nature” view of markets,
due to the problem of free riding.14 Entrepreneurs Granovetter contends, is devoid of reference to the
are the agents of change, and organizations are the history of concrete relationships and network
players who respond to changes in relative prices, structures, failing to take into account “the extent
which include changes in the ratio of factor prices, to which concrete personal relations and the obli-
changes in the cost of information, and changes in gations inherent in them discourage malfeasance,
technology. Organizations are agents of change quite apart from institutional arrangements” (489).
when they lobby the state to initiate institutional Williamson’s Hobbesian conception of hierarchical
innovations that enable economic actors to survive authority is also on shaky ground, given the extent
and profit from changes in relative price.15 to which congealed social networks in firms struc-
Critical of North’s approach, Greif (forthcom- ture power relations; hence, “Williamson vastly
ing) argues that its focus on formal rules and state overestimates the efficacy of hierarchical power
power does not illuminate why economic actors (‘fiat,’ in his terminology) within organizations”
follow some rules but not others. Although North (499).
New Institutionalisms 53

Granovetter thus contributed the seminal theme concrete social relationships to explain the work-
of embeddedness to the revitalization of the socio- ings of markets and firms, relies on a conceptual
logical study of economic life. Asserting that even framework that limits economic sociology’s ex-
when economics tries to take into account social planatory power to proximate causes.17 Moreover,
factors, its conception of human action remains the approach requires the construction of a taxon-
deeply flawed, since both the under- and over- omy of structural contexts as a necessary step to
socialized versions commonly found in economic become sufficiently abstract to generate a powerful
analysis assume atomized actors, Granovetter’s ar- analytical framework.18 By contrast, the classical
gument tended to frame this revitalization of eco- sources of economic sociology in the writings of
nomic sociology in terms of a disciplinary-based Weber, Schumpeter, and Polanyi outlined analyti-
competition with economics. In contrast to trans- cal approaches that pointed to a broad institution-
action cost economics’ emphasis on hierarchies in al canvass of distal and deeper causal forces.
solving the problem of trust, economic sociolo- Another limitation is the absence of a clear spec-
gists guided by the embeddedness approach “pay ification of mechanisms that explain why econom-
careful and systematic attention to the actual pat- ic actors sometimes decouple from ongoing
terns of personal relations by which economic networks to pursue economic interests. If, as Gran-
transactions are carried out” (504). The focus on ovetter asserts, a dense network of personal ties
concrete interpersonal ties is likely to show “that does more than institutional arrangements to se-
both order and disorder, honesty and malfeasance cure trust and useful information crucial for com-
have more to do with structures of such relations plex transactions, then why do economic actors
than they do with organizational form” (502–3). routinely decouple from interpersonal ties to trans-
Interpersonal ties play a crucial role in both mar- act in market exchanges? A defining feature of an
kets and firms in securing trust and serving as a advanced twenty-first-century market economy as
conduit for useful information.16 an institutional order is its capacity to enable eco-
We must note, however, that interpersonal ties nomic agents to switch virtually seamlessly be-
entail costs, whether in avoiding and resolving tween transactions within close-knit networks and
conflict, or in the accumulation of obligations. In- with strangers. In sum, the social relations rather
deed, social relations can be very costly when con- than institutions orientation of this embeddedness
flict, disorder, opportunism, and malfeasance erupt approach introduced an element of indeterminacy
in networks. Transaction cost analysis suggests that in the new economic sociology, especially in the
entrepreneurs will take such costs into account in context of a global market economy where the vol-
considering alternative forms of economic organi- ume of cross-national transactions has increased
zation, including network-based quasi firms. De- through innovations in information technology
spite the contrast in focus, the transaction cost and enabling complex transactions between strangers
the embeddedness approaches appear to agree that (Kuwabara, forthcoming).
firms generally prefer social contexts where negoti-
ating agreements is less problematic and costly. In
essence, the embeddedness approach differs from THE SOCIOLOGICAL TURN IN NEW
transaction cost economics in its emphasis on in- INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS
formal solutions to address the problem of trust, as
opposed to formal institutional arrangements. Not Central among sociology’s concerns from its
surprisingly therefore, Williamson’s (1994, 85) re- origins as a social science has been the goal of ex-
sponse to Granovetter’s essay was, “Transaction plaining institutions, as exemplified in Max Weber’s
cost economics and embeddedness reasoning are and Émile Durkheim’s seminal works on the sub-
evidently complementary in many respects.” ject. It is not surprising, therefore, that there has
While Granovetter’s embeddedness approach been something of a “sociological turn” in eco-
laid the basis for the revitalization of the sociolog- nomics, motivated by difficulties in explaining in-
ical study of economic life, his sole emphasis on the stitutions and institutional change within the
nature of interpersonal ties and the structure of framework of economic theory (Furubotn and
networks contributed to a narrowing of the scope Richter 1993). If a sociological turn is in progress,
of economic sociology from the broader insti- how is it manifested in the recent work of new in-
tutional canvass pioneered by its founders. The stitutional economists? To what extent has eco-
causal imagery of the embeddedness approach, nomic sociology influenced their thinking?
positing variation in the underlying structure of In his article “The New Institutional Econom-
54 Nee
ics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead,” Williamson know very little about how informal norms
(2000, 595) confesses that “we are still very igno- evolve” (North 1993, 20).
rant about institutions” despite the progress made A sociological turn is further evident in new the-
over the past quarter-century. “Chief among the orizing on the importance of cognitive mecha-
causes of ignorance is that institutions are very nisms. Because beliefs and norms are unobserv-
complex. . . . pluralism is what holds promise for able, Greif argues, integrating social variables has
overcoming our ignorance.” Williamson’s multi- been hampered by the fact that any behavior can
level causal model of the economy outlines “four be explained by ad hoc assertions about the beliefs
levels of social analysis” in which the higher level and norms that motivate it. The integration of so-
imposes constraints on the lower level. “The top cial variables in a manner consistent with econom-
level,” he writes, “is the social embeddedness level. ic methodology requires an analytical framework
This is where the norms, customs, mores, tradi- that can reconcile two seemingly contradictory
tions, etc. are located. . . . North poses the query, views of institutions: the view of institutions com-
‘What is it about informal constraints that gives mon in economics as constraints created by indi-
them such a pervasive influence upon the long-run viduals and the structural view of institutions as so-
character of economies?’ (1991, 111). North does cial facts external to the individuals common in
not have an answer to that perplexing question, sociology. Organizational new institutionalists focus
nor do I.” This embeddedness level influences the on diffusion of rules, scripts, and models (Meyer
lower three levels: level 2, institutional environ- and Rowan 1977), whereas some new institution-
ment; level 3, governance; level 4, resource alloca- al economists offer game theoretic models of en-
tion and employment.19 Hence it is important to dogenous motivation stemming from systems of
identify and explicate “the mechanisms through shared beliefs and norms (Greif [1994] 1998).21
which informal institutions arise and are main- Although game theory does not offer a theory of
tained” (596). Thus the embeddedness perspective institutions, Greif argues that it does offer an ap-
now is in the process of being incorporated into propriate analytical framework to incorporate soci-
the new institutional economics. But Williamson ological variables into economic analysis of insti-
acknowledges that though level 1 shapes the pa- tutions. It does not provide a theory of the
rameters of what economists study, it “is taken as constraints defining the parameters of strategic in-
given by most institutional economists.” teraction, but it offers deep insights on the dy-
A sociological turn is apparent in the influence namics of choice within constraints. It provides a
of Weber, Marx, Polanyi, and Parsons on North’s theory of social behavior in which actors’ optimal
conception of institutions as elaborated in Struc- course of behavior depends on the behavior and
ture and Change in Economic History (1981). expected behavior (cultural beliefs and social
More recently, in response to confronting the dif- norms) of others.22 It also incorporates a realistic
ficulties of implementing institutional change as an view of the social world in which information is
economic advisor to reformers in the transition asymmetric and actors are interdependent and mo-
economies of Eastern Europe, North acknowl- tivated to act in a particular manner. It offers a
edges a greater interest in understanding the infor- method to examine how strategic interactions give
mal elements of institutions embedded in social re- rise to and sustain self-enforcing institutions. Greif
lations. Devising new formal rules to institute ([1994] 1998) has extended its application to the
market economies in Eastern Europe and the for- comparative institutional analysis of economic be-
mer Soviet Union has had only limited success; this havior using cases studies drawn from medieval
has pointed to the intractable nature of social European and Mediterranean economic history.
arrangements embedded in interpersonal ties, cul- He models the recurrent strategic social interac-
tural beliefs, norms, and old regime institutional tions that sustain institutions in equilibrium.23
arrangements studied by economic sociologists.20 Overall, economists interested in studying social
Clearly, “Formal rules are an important part of the institutions have found that the more they come to
institutional framework but only a part. To work understand the workings of institutions as endoge-
effectively they must be complemented by infor- nous to social processes in society, the more their
mal constraints (conventions, norms of behavior) work must address questions that lead them to
that supplement them and reduce enforcement turn to sociology for answers. New institution-
costs. If the formal rules and informal constraints al economists apparently agree that advances in
are inconsistent with each other the resulting ten- understanding institutions requires integrating
sion is going to induce political instability. But we sociological variables—shared beliefs, norms, and
New Institutionalisms 55

social relationships—to understand motivation to grated into a framework of sociological research


follow rules. that examines context-bound rationality shaped by
custom, networks, norms, cultural beliefs, and in-
stitution arrangements, as in The New Institution-
NEW INSTITUTIONALISM IN ECONOMIC alism in Sociology, edited by Brinton and Nee
SOCIOLOGY (1998). The new institutional economic sociology
builds on the pioneering work of Barnard ([1938]
In 1898 Émile Durkheim founded the Année so- 1964), Homans (1950), and Blau (1955), analyz-
ciologique, establishing modern sociology as a dis- ing the manner in which interpersonal ties in firms
cipline dedicated to the comparative study of in- and markets interact with formal institutional
stitutions. Since then, Durkheim’s conception of arrangements (Nee and Ingram 1998).
institutions as systems of shared beliefs, norms, For a new institutional economic sociology to
and collective sentiments has persisted to shape the make advances in explaining the role of institutions
sociological approach to their study. Max Weber and institutional change, it is important to have a
similarly pioneered the interpretive study of socie- definition of institutions appropriate for analysis
tal institutions through his comparative analysis of from the sociological perspective that emphasizes
cultural beliefs, economy, and polity. Reinterpret- the causal effect of social structures. Institutions
ing the classics of European sociology, Talcott Par- are not simply the formal and informal constraints
sons later synthesized the institutionalist ideas that specify the structure of incentives, as defined
associated with Durkheim, Weber, Pareto, and by North (1981), or discrete institutional elements—
Tönnies into a structural-functionalist framework beliefs, norms, organizations, and communities—
for modern sociology. He too conceived of insti- of a social system (Greif, forthcoming), but funda-
tutions as organized systems of cultural beliefs, mentally they involve actors, whether individuals
norms, and values common to most individuals in or organizations, who pursue real interests in con-
a society, systems giving rise to socially structured crete institutional structures. An institution in this
interests that organize incentives for individuals. view is defined as a dominant system of interrelated
His outline of a theory of institutions adumbrated informal and formal elements—custom, shared be-
the idea of choice within institutional constraints. liefs, conventions, norms, and rules—which actors
Parsons’s Economy and Society (1956), coauthored orient their actions to when they pursue their inter-
with Neil Smelser, established economic sociology ests. In this view, institutions are social structures
as a subfield in American sociology. Like Parsons, that provide a conduit for collective action by fa-
Robert K. Merton viewed institutions as structures cilitating and organizing the interests of actors and
of opportunity, shaping the interests and strategic enforcing principal-agent relationships. It follows
action of individuals. from this interest-related definition that institu-
The new sociological institutionalism reformu- tional change involves not simply remaking the
lates the earlier European and American institu- formal rules, but fundamentally requires the re-
tionalist approaches in sociology through the lens alignment of interests, norms, and power.24
of a different generation of American sociologists. As economic sociology moves beyond the earli-
Sociological new institutionalism has been closely er perspective on embeddedness, the challenge is
identified with the perspective on organizational to specify and explicate the social mechanisms de-
analysis pioneered by Meyer and Rowan (1977) termining the relationship between the informal
and many other organizational theorists of the social organization of close-knit groups and the
Stanford “legitimacy” school, and canonized in a formal rules of institutional structures monitored
widely used anthology, The New Institutionalism and enforced by organizations and states. The new
in Organizational Analysis, edited by Powell and institutional economics has contributed to explain-
DiMaggio (1991). DiMaggio and Powell (1983) ing the emergence and maintenance of formal
introduce into neoinstitutional theory the influ- institutional arrangements that shape economic
ence of Max Weber’s and Herbert Simon’s ideas, behavior. However, as North (1993, 12) acknowl-
evident in their treatment of how organizational edges, economics has largely “ignored the infor-
fields emerge and then constrain the action of mal constraints of conventions and norms of be-
agents under conditions of uncertainty. The ele- havior.” Economists pose probing questions about
ments of a new institutional economic sociology I the social dimensions of economic life as they en-
lay out below include ideas and insights from this counter the limits of economic analysis of institu-
organizational research program, which are inte- tions (North 1991; Williamson 2000). Their ques-
56 Nee
tions address the manner in which informal social Institutional
Environment
organization and formal rules combine to shape the
performance of organizations and economies. Market Mechanism;
State Regulation
Collective Action

With recent advances in application of game theo- Production Market/


ry, economists recently have begun to incorporate Institutional
Organizational Field
Incentives;
informal institutional elements into their models Framework
Endogenous
Preferences
Organizations:
of economic performance (Greif, forthcoming). Firm/Nonprofit

While economic sociologists may not have all the Compliance; Monitoring;
answers, clearly in cross-disciplinary research Decoupling Enforcement

aimed at explaining the capacity of social institu- Social Groups

tions to facilitate, motivate, and govern economic Individual


behavior, sociology’s comparative advantage is to
address questions that focus on the social mecha- Figure 2. A model for the new institutionalism in
nisms that shape economic behavior. As Smelser economic sociology
and Swedberg point out, “the concept of embed-
dedness remains in need of greater theoretical underlying the supply-demand curve. The institu-
specification” (1994, 18). tional framework encompasses formal rules of the
Figure 2 provides a schematic representation of institutional environment and informal rules em-
the multilevel causal model for the new institu- bedded in ongoing social relations, which interact
tionalism in economic sociology, which is related to shape economic behavior.
to, but different from, the new institutionalist Organizations through collective action lobby
models proposed by Williamson (1994). The insti- for changes in the formal rules to make them in
tutional environment—the formal regulatory rules closer accord with their interests. Industry-based
monitored and enforced by the state that govern associations and professional lobbyists act as agents
property rights, markets, and firms—imposes con- representing their interests. Groups of organiza-
straints on firms through market mechanisms and tions are arrayed in an organizational field. The
state regulation, thus shaping the incentives struc- production market is a close-knit network of firms
ture. The institutional mechanisms operating at in an industrial sector arrayed in a status hierarchy
this level are distal, as opposed to the proximate of perceived quality.25 In White’s (2001) model of
network mechanisms at the micro- and meso-levels the production market, firms compete and maneu-
of individuals and their interpersonal ties. Institu- ver for advantage and status with peer firms in
tional mechanisms encompass the deeper causes a market niche. They are guided by the signals
because they shape the incentive structure for or- they read from the operations of their peers. In
ganizations and individuals, and thereby the con- competitive markets, pressures on firms stemming
texts in which proximate mechanisms operate. The from Darwinian selection processes necessitate an
institutional-level mechanisms posited by econo- interest-related logic of strategic action, differing in
mists and sociologists, despite differences in be- emphasis from the legitimacy-centered orientation
havioral assumptions and conceptual language, are of nonprofit organizations—public schools, muse-
not as far apart as is commonly perceived. New in- ums, day-care centers—which are dependent on
stitutional economists emphasize incentives struc- state and federal government and philanthropy for
tured by the monitoring and enforcement of for- resources. Legitimacy is also important for enter-
mal rules, a mechanism widely accepted by both prises, as manifest in firms’ investments in pro-
political economy and sociology. The new institu- moting brand-name recognition, reputation for
tionalism in economic sociology specifies the man- reliability and quality service or product, and com-
ner in which the norms of close-knit groups inter- pliance with federal and state laws, but legitimacy-
act with formal rules in the realization of interests. seeking is driven mainly by the firm’s interest in its
The variety of market mechanisms schematically survival and profitability in competitive markets.
represented in the downward arrow from the insti- For nonprofit organizations, especially, legitimacy
tutional environment to the organizations includes is essential social capital, increasing the chances for
those embedded in labor markets, capital markets, optimizing access to scarce resources. In both for-
raw material markets, and so on. Surprisingly per- profit firms and nonprofit organizations, legitima-
haps, economists generally do not focus on mar- cy can be viewed as a condition of fitness that en-
kets as such, but just assume their existence in the ables them to enhance their survival chances and
neoclassical view of perfect competition in markets secure advantages in economic and political mar-
New Institutionalisms 57

kets. Processes of conformity with the rules of the works in a federal bureaucracy, The Dynamics of
game and cultural beliefs in organizational fields— Bureaucracy, and theoretically in the network ex-
isomorphism—motivate and guide organizations, change literature pioneered by Homans ([1961]
endogenously giving rise to increasing homogene- 1974), Emerson (1962), and Blau (1964). Nu-
ity within an organizational field (DiMaggio and merous studies in natural settings and in laborato-
Powell 1983).26 ry experiments confirm the efficacy of social re-
The social mechanisms facilitating, motivating, wards and punishment in facilitating, motivating,
and governing the action of organizations in orga- and governing trustworthy behavior and absten-
nizational fields or production markets are not dis- tion from opportunism with respect to the norms
similar from those influencing strategic action of of the group.28 Enforcement of norms within close-
individuals in close-knit groups. Mechanisms of knit groups occurs spontaneously in the course of
conformity in close-knit groups have coercive, nor- social interaction among members through the ex-
mative, and mimetic aspects (Homans [1961] change of social rewards (i.e., esteem and status)
1974). Actors are motivated by interests and prefer- for behavior that conforms to the group’s norms,
ences, often formed and sustained within such and punishment (i.e., disapproval and ostracism)
groups. Rationality is context-bound and embed- for violating them. As Homans ([1961] 1974, 76)
ded in interpersonal ties. Individual interests and perspicaciously points out: “The great bulk of con-
preferences are enfolded in “welfare-maximizing” trols over social behavior are not external but built
norms, which, depending on the incentives struc- into the relationship themselves.” Frequency of in-
tured in the institutional environment, reinforce teraction, a characteristic feature of close-knit net-
compliance to formal rules through self-monitoring works, lowers the cost of monitoring members of
or give rise to decoupling arising from opposition the group, assuming they are in close enough con-
norms (as discussed below). tact with one another that information about
members’ conduct is common knowledge. Axel-
rod (1984) effectively simulated the operation of
Informal Institutional Elements
network mechanisms in his tit-for-tat model,
The bottom box of our causal model overlaps showing that reward and punishment in repeated
with the earlier embeddedness concept, which ar- exchanges—when actors take into account the
gues that the nature and structure of social rela- weight of the future, as in ongoing relationships—
tionships have more to do with governing eco- motivate cooperative behavior. In sum, trustwor-
nomic behavior than do institutional arrangements thiness and reliability as forms of cooperative be-
and organizational form. Specifically, Granovetter havior arise from rational action responding to
(1985, 490) refers to the “role of concrete per- social rewards and punishment in networks or
sonal relations and structures (or ‘networks’) of close-knit groups.
such relations in generating trust and discouraging In his detailed account of the interactions in the
malfeasance,” which he attributes to the human work group he studied made up of a supervisor, 16
preference for transacting with individuals known agents, and one clerk, Blau (1955) provides a rare
to be trustworthy and for abstention from oppor- illustration of how self-interested action of individ-
tunism. But what explains motivation for trust- uals endogenously produces the informal social or-
worthiness and abstention from opportunism in ganization of a close-knit work group. In the work
ongoing social relationships? Why is trustworthi- group Blau studied, agents consulted fellow agents
ness found more commonly in ongoing social rela- about the appropriate legal rules that applied to
tionships than in transactions between strangers? their case, rather than bring their questions to the
The answer is found in specifying the mecha- attention of the supervisor who evaluated their
nisms intrinsic to social relationships that develop work. Blau observed that the informal interactions
and maintain cooperative behavior within close- between agents involved a social exchange similar in
knit groups, enabling actors to engage in collective logic to a decentralized market exchange:
action to achieve group ends. These mechanisms
are rewards and punishment in social exchange and A consultation can be considered an exchange of val-
their use in the enforcement of social norms— ues; both participants gain something, and both have
shared beliefs and statements about expected be- to pay a price. The questioning agent is enabled to
havior.27 Social exchange theorists have explicated perform better than he could otherwise have done,
the mechanisms involved, empirically in Blau’s without exposing his difficulties to the supervisor. By
(1955) classic study of social exchange and net- asking for advice, he implicitly pays his respect to the
58 Nee
superior proficiency of his colleague. This acknowl- whose content serves to maximize the aggregate
edgement of inferiority is the cost of receiving assis- welfare that members obtain in their workaday
tance. The consultant gains prestige, in return for affairs with one another” (1991, 167).30 Norms co-
which he is willing to devote some time to the con- ordinating individuals’ activities, as in the conven-
sultation and permit it to disrupt his own work. The tion of arriving in a timely fashion at an agreed-
following remark of an agent illustrates this: “I like upon social engagement, are not difficult to explain
giving advice. It’s flattering, I suppose, if you feel that since it is easy to show that self-interested individu-
the others come to you for advice.” (Quoted in als share a common interest in complying with this
Homans 1974, 343) convention. But the prisoner’s dilemma norm is
more difficult to explain since self-interested indi-
Blau found that the more competent the agent, viduals derive a greater payoff for opportunism in a
the more contacts she had with other agents, and prisoner’s dilemma game. What makes this game so
the higher the esteem in which she was held. A few interesting is that this type of dilemma is such a
agents who were perceived as competent but who common feature of social and economic life. It is
discouraged others from consulting them were the prisoner’s dilemma aspects of human interac-
disliked and had fewer contacts. These findings tion that give rise to opportunism in contractual
highlight the importance of social rewards and agreements and in ongoing social relationships. To
sanctions (e.g., esteem and disapproval) in the nor- a degree, all social exchange resembles the prison-
mative regulation of informal social organization. er’s dilemma game insofar as there is always a temp-
Routine social exchanges, such as the one de- tation not to reciprocate a good turn provided by a
scribed by Blau, comprise the informal social or- friend or acquaintance (Hardin 1988). The prison-
ganization that emerges and sustains the perfor- er’s dilemma norm involves higher costs of moni-
mance of formal organizations (Nee and Ingram toring and enforcement than coordination norms
1998). because it is always in the self-interest of individu-
Norms are the informal rules that facilitate, mo- als to free ride or defect. Hence, prisoner’s dilem-
tivate, and govern joint action of members of ma norms must be welfare-maximizing in terms of
close-knit groups. They arise from the problem- the Kaldor-Hicks criterion in order to create suffi-
solving activity of individuals as rule-of-thumb cient rewards to individuals to overcome the temp-
guidelines for expected behavior. Throughout his- tation to do so (Ellickson 1991, 171; Posner 1986,
tory, norms have coordinated group action to im- 11–15).31
prove the chances for success—the attainment of The nature of the relationship between informal
rewards—through cooperation. As statements of social groups and formal organizations can sub-
shared beliefs about expected behavior, norms stantially affect the cost of monitoring and enforce-
evolved together with language, as in the norms ment of formal rules in institutional and organi-
uttered by early hunting parties to coordinate ac- zational environments. The norms of close-knit
tion during the course of the expedition. Norms groups can contribute to the realization of the or-
probably evolved through trial and error, with suc- ganization’s goal if the interests embedded in wel-
cess the arbiter of why a particular norm persists in fare-maximizing norms are, broadly speaking, con-
equilibrium across generations and diffuses to dif- gruous with the incentives embedded in the formal
ferent groups.29 Members of close-knit groups co- rules. This condition is met when members of
operate in enforcing norms because not only their close-knit groups or networks perceive that their
interests are linked to the group’s success, but their preferences and interests are aligned with the or-
identity as well (White 1992). ganization’s capacity to survive and profit. It is
strengthened when members of networks identify
with the organization’s goals. This gives rise to en-
The Relationship between Informal and Formal
dogenous motivation in networks to enforce formal
Institutional Elements
rules, which substantially lowers the cost for orga-
In uncovering the social norms of Shasta Coun- nizations to monitor and enforce through formal
ty, a sparsely settled rural county of northern Cali- sanctioning mechanisms, providing the necessary
fornia, where local ranchers and suburbanites main- and sufficient conditions for high-level group per-
tain ongoing multiplex relationships, Ellickson formance in line with formal organizational goals.
“was struck that they seemed consistently utilitari- However, close coupling between informal and for-
an”; from which he inferred that “members of mal rules does not necessarily give rise to efficiency
a close-knit group develop and maintain norms and high organizational performance. Indeed, pop-
New Institutionalisms 59

ulation ecologists argue that the environment se- governs competition and cooperation in a society.
lects adaptive organizational forms independent of The state has the power to enact and enforce laws
the collective will and effort of individuals acting and initiate institutional innovations to secure and
within the organization (Hannan and Freeman uphold public goods and respond to changing rel-
1989). For example, many high-technology firms ative prices (Stiglitz 1989).
renowned for the high morale and commitment of Laws, like norms, are statements of expected be-
management and employees to achieve corporate havior, ideas framed with moral and ethical au-
goals have fallen by the wayside. thority backed by state power. Whether as ideolo-
In contrast, when the formal rules are at odds gy or as cultural beliefs, they define the parameters
with the interests and identity of individuals in of legitimate behavior to which organizations and
close-knit groups, the welfare-maximizing hypoth- individuals adapt. In keeping with disciplinary
esis predicts the rise of opposition norms that fa- traditions, economists emphasize the costs of op-
cilitate, motivate, and govern the action of individ- posing the coercive forces of the state, and organi-
uals in those groups. Opposition norms enable zational sociologists emphasize the value of legiti-
networks to coordinate action to resist either pas- macy gained through compliance with the state’s
sively, through slowdown or noncompliance, or rules. But in actuality, whether the price of non-
actively, in manifest defiance of formal rules and compliance is perceived as costs imposed by fines
the authority of organizational leaders. This leads and penalties or as a loss of legitimacy is moot since
to increase in the cost of monitoring and enforcing both are costly to the firm.
formal rules as the incidence of opportunism and The institutional mechanisms of monitoring and
malfeasance increases. There is also a higher level enforcement operate directly on firms and non-
of uncertainty and information asymmetry as profit organizations through the costs of penalties
members of close-knit networks collectively with- and withholding of federal grants and contracts,
hold information that might lead to discovery of but also have indirect effects. The increase in costs
opportunism and malfeasance. When group per- of discrimination—loss of legitimacy and financial
formance facilitated, motivated, and governed by penalty—following institutional changes during
opposition norms reaches a tipping point, the nec- the civil rights era decisively opened American
essary and sufficient conditions for demoralization mainstream organizations to formerly excluded
and oppositional movements at the organizational ethnic and racial groups (Alba and Nee 2003). The
and institutional levels are met. The incentives and civil rights movement and the legislative changes
disincentives emanating from the institutional en- enacted by Congress created a normative environ-
vironment, in combination with interests, needs, ment in which legitimacy was conditioned on fair
and preferences of individuals, influence whether governance through formal protections of the
norms and networks give rise to a close coupling of principle of equality of rights (Edelman 1990,
informal and formal rules, or decoupling through 1992). Equal employment opportunity law (EEO)
opposition norms.32 defined broad parameters and guidelines of legiti-
In the new institutional economic sociology mate organizational practices with respect to mi-
purposive action by corporate actors and individu- norities and women. Because the civil rights laws
als (usually in close-knit networks) cannot be un- have weak enforcement features and are ambigu-
derstood apart from the institutional framework ously stated, organizations construct the meaning
within which incentives—including legitimacy— of compliance “in a manner that is minimally dis-
are structured. ruptive of the status quo” (Edelman 1992, 1535).
Despite differences in local and regional history This enables organizations to gain legitimacy and
and culture, the laws and regulations monitored hence resources through the appearance of abiding
and enforced by the federal government apply to by civil rights legislation. However, “once in place,
all regions of the United States, with very few ex- EEO/AA [affirmative action] structures may pro-
ceptions. Variations in locality and region may duce or bolster internal constituencies that help to
limit the effectiveness of monitoring and enforce- institutionalize EEO/AA goals” (1569). The civil
ment, but they do not give rise to different under- rights laws may have their largest impact indirectly
lying rules. Not only is the constitutional frame- through professionals who generate “ideologies of
work invariant, but federal rules aim to extend the rationality” or cultural beliefs about how organiza-
power of the central state uniformly. As North’s tions should respond to the law. Not only do high-
(1981) theory emphasizes, the state is the sover- profile landmark court cases (e.g., Texaco, Coca-
eign actor specifying the framework of rules that Cola)33 impose direct costs through penalties and
60 Nee
loss of legitimacy to specific firms, but a more far- ment state, as opposed to the predatory state, is
reaching effect of these court decisions, along with the presence of relatively well developed bureau-
legal advice about what organizations can do to in- cratic forms of public administration. As Weber ar-
sulate themselves from costly litigation, is to gen- gued in his theory of bureaucracy, the introduction
erate cultural beliefs about the rationality of self- of merit-based recruitment offering predictable ca-
monitored compliance with antidiscriminatory laws. reer ladders established the basis for long-term
This is manifested in the diffusion of EEO- commitments to bureaucratic service. Whether in
specified grievance procedures in organizations the Meiji bureaucracy in Japan or in late-develop-
(Edelman, Uggen, and Erlanger 1999). Thus ide- ing industrial economies like China, the develop-
ologies of rationality and cultural beliefs have ment of modern bureaucratic capacity at the service
combined with the incentives and disincentives of of reform politicians was critical to government’s
the institutional environment, mediated by state ability to monitor and enforce rules oriented to-
regulation and market mechanism. This is consis- ward promoting economic development. At the
tent with the causal model in figure 2, suggesting level of individual action, close-knit groups of elite
that mechanisms of isomorphism align with the bureaucrats share norms and goals shaped by mer-
structure of incentives stemming from formal rules itocratic rules for recruitment and promotion,
of the institutional environment.34 which reduces the attractiveness of corruption.
This Weberian model provides an alternative to
Shleifer and Vishny’s (1994, 1023) “grabbing
ILLUSTRATIVE STUDIES IN NEW INSTITUTIONAL hand of the state” model that conflates bureaucrats
ECONOMIC SOCIOLOGY and politicians, showing that politicians invariably
“try to influence firms to pursue political objec-
The causal model in the new institutional eco- tives” inconsistent with the objective of economic
nomic sociology integrates a micro-foundation growth. In the Weberian model, bureaucrats are
based on an account of the rational pursuit of in- distinct from politicians insofar as they are vested
terests, influenced by social relations and norms, with long-term careers governed by meritocratic
with the idea that each economy has an institu- rules of recruitment and promotion. Norms,
tional framework. As figure 2 indicates, causal mech- shared belief in meritocratic service, and national
anisms operate in both directions, from macro to development goals not only reduce the temptation
micro and micro to macro levels of analysis. The of corruption but over time give rise to compe-
multilevel causal model moves beyond the earlier tence and credibility of commitment to civil ser-
embeddedness perspective toward a social relations vice dedicated to the public good. The result is in-
and institutions approach to explanation of the creased organizational capacity of the state, which
emergence, persistence, and transformation of eco- in turn enables and motivates reform-minded
nomic institutions and behavior. As a conceptual rulers to increase revenues through economic
framework, the new institutionalism in economic growth rather than predation.
sociology offers an open architecture for generat-
ing theories at the middle range extending the so-
ciological approach to understanding economic
behavior. The central challenge in new institution-
al economic sociology is to specify and explicate
Institutional Bureaucratic Greater
the nature of the relationships between elements at Environment forms of economic
administrative growth in a
different levels of the multilevel causal model to apparatus country
explain how informal social organizations interact
with large institutional structures. Here are four il- Organizational Meritocratic recruitment A more successful and
lustrations of such use of a multilevel causal model. Level and predictable career
ladder with long-term
competent bureaucracy and
increased organizational ability
rewards to reach its long-term goals

Weberian Model of Economic Growth (Time Span)


years of development

Evans and Rauch (1999) specify a three-level Individual Shared norms and goals
causal model to examine the effect of Weberian Level and reduced attractiveness
of corruption among
state structures on economic growth in developing individual bureaucrats

economies. They argue that the characteristic fea- Figure 3. Evans and Rauch’s model on the effects of
ture of the institutional framework of the develop- Weberian state structure on economic growth
New Institutionalisms 61

A Dynamic Game-Theoretic Model of that sought to incorporate in the institutional


Deinstitutionalization framework of central planning increased reliance on
the market mechanism. But at the individual level of
A multilevel causal model provides analytic
party bureaucrats and officials, the growth of eco-
leverage in understanding the emergence of mar-
nomic and political markets increased the payoff
ket economies in postsocialist China, Eastern Eu-
for opportunism and malfeasance, which in turn
rope, and the former Soviet Union. When Western
sparked within close-knit groups of party members
economists traveled to Eastern Europe and the
a group-based social dynamic leading to declining
former Soviet Union to advise reformers at the
ideological and political commitment to the Com-
onset of market reforms, their advice consistently
munist Party. This is demonstrated in a tipping
emphasized big-bang approaches to instituting a
point model wherein opportunism and malfeasance
market economy by designing sweeping changes in
among party members, initially small, eventually
the formal rules governing property rights and
reaches a critical mass. The reform leaders in the
markets. They assumed that formal rules—that is,
party attempt to address the problem through cam-
constitution, civil law, and other regulations—
paigns aimed at punishing malfeasance. Over time,
instituted by administrative fiat would establish a
however, declining commitment reaches a critical
modern capitalist economy (Sachs 1995). Such ef-
tipping point, precipitating demoralization and col-
forts at capitalism by design overlooked the reali-
lapse of the Communist Party as an effective ruling
ties of power and interests vested in the ruins of
organization. This in turn paves the way for deinsti-
Communism.35 By contrast, the incremental re-
tutionalization of the party and far-reaching change
form approach taken by reformers in China al-
in political institutions, including political revolu-
lowed economic actors to base their choices of in-
tion, in reforming state socialism. This game-
stitutions on trial and error that balanced speed
theoretic model provides an explanation for de-
with a credible record of success. This more evolu-
clining organizational performance, highlighting
tionary approach to market transition soon gave
the embedded nature of ideological commitment
rise to the most dynamic economy in the world. In
among party members and specifying the social
China, institutional change was driven not so
dynamics that produce the tidal shift from commit-
much by top-down changes in the formal rules,
ment to the party’s rules and goals to widespread
but by bottom-up realignment of interests and
opportunism and defection. The model links
power as new organizational forms, private prop-
change in the incentive structure of the institutional
erty rights, and market institutions evolved in an
environment—from redistribution to market—to
economy shifting away from central state control
the emergence in close-knit party networks of belief
over economic activity to market-driven firm per-
in opportunism as the expected behavior, presently,
formance.36 Changes in formal rules governing the
in a ruling party founded on an ideology opposed
emerging market economy tended to follow ex post
to such behavior. This sociological explanation for
changes in the informal business practices, and
the rapid and relatively nonviolent collapse of
were therefore more in keeping with the real inter-
Communist polities in Eastern Europe and the
ests of political and economic actors.37 As in the
former Soviet Union, however, efforts to reform
state-owned enterprises through formal rule changes Institutional A rapidly growing technological Regime
Environment and economic gap between change in
in China also proved largely ineffectual because, in state socialist economies and reforming
part, ex ante changes in formal rules often ran the advanced market economies state socialism

counter to the vested interests and conflicting


sources of legitimacy of the Communist Party or- Organizational
Level
Communist reformers’
initiation of economic
Deterioration and collapse
of the Communist Party as
ganization entrenched in state-owned firms. reform in state socialist
economies
an effective political
organization
Nee and Lian’s dynamic game theory model
(1994) of declining ideological and political com- (Time Span)
years of market transition

mitment helps to explain deinstitutionalization of


the Communist Party in departures from central Individual
Level
Increasing opportunism
and declining commitment
planning in transition economies. The technological to the Communist Party
among agents of the state
and military gap that grew during the Cold War be-
tween the advanced market economies and state so-
cialist countries precipitated reform efforts by Com- Figure 4. Nee and Lian’s dynamic model of declin-
munist elites to narrow the gap through innovations ing political commitment in state socialism
62 Nee
former Soviet Union is an alternative to standard Institutional Emergent market Stable
Environment with upstream industrial
economic and political interpretations (Aslund suppliers and sector
downstream buyers
1995; Beissinger 2002). In China and Vietnam,
where Communist parties still retain power, the
model predicts a cumulative decline of ideological Organizational
Level
Firms, new and
established, gear up
Market profile of
firms arrayed
and organizatonal commitment to the party. production as they enter
the market
hierarchically in a
production market

years of market expansion


A Signaling Model of the Market Mechanism (Time Span)

White’s (2001) theory of production markets Individual


Level
Economic actors in firms
signal perceptions of
portrays them as social structures constructed by quality in industry

producers in response to uncertainty arising up- Figure 5. White’s model of production markets
stream and downstream in particular market nich-
es. When a new market niche emerges, new and es-
tablished firms gear up production as they enter
A Study of Close Coupling between Informal
the market. Inevitably they must make investment
Norms and Formal Organizational Goals
and production decisions in a state of uncertainty
with respect to upstream suppliers and down- In a classic ethnography of shop-floor work
stream buyers. Applying Spence’s (1974) signaling norms and the emergence of institutionalized rules
theory and Burt’s (1992) model of rational action of advanced capitalism, Burawoy (1979) integrates
in networks, White argues that firms watch for cues insights from the Marxist theory of the firm with
and clues emitted by rival firms, as each firm adapts the context-bound utilitarian view of rational ac-
products for the market niche. tion of managers and employees in a large indus-
Thus the social construction of a market com- trial firm. His organizational analysis shows that
prised of producers in a niche stems from the at- the emergence of internal labor markets and the
tempts by firms to interpret and use information shift of management styles to the image of an in-
from signals emitted by peers, as they maneuver ternal state grew out of the firm’s strategy of adap-
and compete for position in the production mar- tation to competition arising from global markets.
ket. Firms watch each other, and use signals from Introducing these characteristic institutional fea-
other firms to guide their choices and action. They tures of advanced capitalist firms induced a rise of
search for their identity through the signals from individualism among employees competing in in-
competitor firms about the quality of their prod- ternal labor markets for advancement and promo-
ucts or services. A firm’s reputation for quality is tion. Self-organized activity among employees also
crucial to its survival. Through mutual signaling of increased. Burawoy maintains that the informal
perceived quality, firms order themselves in a peck- games and norms of close-knit shop-floor work
ing order—their market profile—in the niche. In groups led to norm-based consent between em-
the production market firms may form strategic ployees and managers supporting the goals of
alliances to strengthen ties or decouple from spe- management. The informal employee consent in
cific ties with member firms to disengage from
dependencies. The outcome over time is an insti- Institutional As large industrial firms Monopoly
tutional framework of stable industrial sectors Environment adapt to global markets,
they shift from competitive
capitalism with
industrial peace and
comprised of networks of firms. White’s model to monopoly capitalism high productivity

specifies and explicates a market mechanism arising


endogenously from producers signaling each other Organizational Industrial firms develop Norms that tacitly support
Level internal labor markets and the goals of management;
in the production market. The identity of member consolidate management in close coupling of informal
firms in that market is framed by its roles and the image of an internal state and formal rules

norms. White proffers a sociological view of mar- (Time Span)


years of transition to monopoly capitalism

kets as social structures in which producers act as


the interface between upstream suppliers and Individual Rise of individualism among employees
Level as they compete and participate in
downstream buyers—an alternative model of mar- internal labor markets; expansion in self-
kets as a social institution, differing from the neo- organized informal games and activities

classical economic assumption of perfect competi- Figure 6. Burawoy’s model of shop-floor work
tion in markets. norms and monopoly capitalism
New Institutionalisms 63

turn gave rise to the institutional environment of and organizational life. Notwithstanding this shared
advanced capitalism characterized by industrial viewpoint, these institutionalist approaches should
peace and high productivity. be viewed as distinct but related research programs
with overlapping assumptions and shared con-
cepts. Table 1 offers a summary comparison be-
SUMMARY COMPARISON tween them.
Durkheim’s methodological holism has had a
Overall, the new institutionalisms in economics powerful influence on institutional theory in orga-
and sociology are unified around the view that nizational analysis, as has its origins in studies of
neoclassical economics is limited by its unrealistic nonprofit organizations. This is evident in its be-
behavioral assumption of individual utility maxi- havioral assumption emphasizing nonrational ac-
mization, its conception of homo economicus, and tion molded by codified and legitimated beliefs,
its unrealistic assumption of zero transaction costs, scripts, myths, rituals, and rationalized stories. In
as if institutions, social relations, and cultural be- the foundation essay by Meyer and Rowan (1977),
liefs were superfluous to understanding economic there is little mention of the pressures imposed on

Table 1. The New Institutionalisms in Sociology and Economics


New
Institutionalism in New Institutionalist
Organizational Economic New Institutional
Analysis Sociology Economics
Behavioral Emphasis on Rationality is “Intendedly rational,
assumption nonrational action context bound; but limitedly so”;
oriented to cultural actors motivated by information asymmetry
beliefs constitutive interests, usually and uncertainty give
of the institutional shaped by shared rise to hazards accruing
environment beliefs, norms, and to opportunism
network ties
Actors Professionals serve Organizations are Organizations and
as the agents of actors; individuals individuals are actors
institutionalization articulate interests
within organizations
and networks
Definition of Rationalized myths Interrelated system Humanly constructed
institution and routines, of institutional constraints—the
conformity to elements—informal formal and informal
which confirms and formal— rules that structure
legitimacy facilitating, incentives; discrete
motivating, and governance structures
governing social as contracting units
and economic action
Macro-level State regulation, State regulation, States seek revenue
mechanisms coercive and market mechanism, maximization;
normative collective action transaction cost
isomorphism economizing by firms
Micro-level Action oriented Interest-driven Self-interested
mechanisms to mimicking, action within principal/agents;
conformity, and organizations calculating hazards
decoupling and networks of opportunism
Sources Durkheim, Weber, Weber, Marx, Smith, Knight,
Berger and Polanyi, Homans Commons, Coase
Luckmann
64 Nee
organizations by the motive to survive and profit Although transaction cost economics assumes
in competitive markets. Rather, the organization’s individual opportunistic actors, its unit of analy-
practical action and strategy are principally moti- sis—economic transactions—is operationalized at
vated by concern for securing and maintaining le- the organizational and institutional levels. Individ-
gitimacy. Organizational neoinstitutionalists tend ual-level action is seldom a focus of analytic atten-
to reject utilitarian conceptions of purposive action tion. Economists unproblematically extend their
to embrace what they perceive as a cultural turn in conception of individual-level action to corporate
social theory. The behavioral assumption empha- actors in a conceptual framework that views insti-
sizing the nonrational cultural basis of social action tutions as the rules of the game and organizations
integrates Durkheim’s conception of institutions as as the players. North’s (1990) theory of institu-
social molds with insights from ethnomethodolo- tional change turns on the assumption that organi-
gy (Garfinkel 1967; Cicourel 1974; Giddens 1979) zations respond efficiently, even when gradually, as
and social theorists who are leading the cultural rational actors to changing relative prices, mounting
turn in sociology (Goffman 1967; Berger and collective action to pressure for changes in the for-
Luckmann 1967; Douglas 1986; Bourdieu [1972] mal rules of the game that enable them to adapt to
1977; Swidler 1986). Notwithstanding, DiMaggio the new price structure. North’s theory of institu-
and Powell (1983) incorporate bounded rationali- tional change, however, overlooks the powerful in-
ty in their conception of organizational actors, and ertial forces within organizations stemming from
hence their seminal essay provides a useful bridge past investments in stable formal rules, informal
linking new institutional economic sociology with social organization, and opposition norms (Stinch-
organizational theory. combe 1965).
At the other end of the continuum, new insti- Organizational new institutionalists emphasize
tutional economics explicitly assumes bounded professionals as actors driven by concern for legit-
rationality: individuals intend to be utility maxi- imacy in their relationship to particular organiza-
mizing, but are limitedly so, due to uncertainty, in- tional fields and to the broader institutional envi-
formation asymmetry, and imperfect cognitive ronment. Rules, scripts, myths, stories, and menus
ability. Its basic underlying view of human agency— provide the rationalized guidelines for strategic
“self-interest seeking with guile”—is, despite Pos- and practical action. But as in transaction cost eco-
ner’s (1993) remarks to the contrary, distinct from nomics, individual-level action is implicit in neoin-
and not readily incorporated into the neoclassical stitutional organizational theory, and is uncom-
view of homo economicus, who is wholly rational, monly a focus of empirical attention, except by
having complete information and perfect compu- reference to the role of professionals as occu-
tational skills. pational groups. Neoinstitutional theory shifts at-
New institutional economic sociology stands at tention away from informal social structures and
the center, between the economists’ assumption of processes inside the organization, emphasized by
bounded rationality and the cultural turn in orga- old institutionalists like Barnard, Selznick, and
nizational sociology. Despite differences in em- Blau, to focus on actors at the levels of the organi-
phasis, its conception of organizational action is zational field and the institutional environment.
complementary with core arguments advanced by The actors that matter are external to the organi-
DiMaggio and Powell (1983) on interest-driven as- zation, in professional associations and legitimacy-
pects of isomorphic adaptation by organizations to monitoring agencies.
their institutional environment. Despite similarities In accord with the embeddedness perspective’s
in emphasis, it differs from economics in building emphasis on proximate causes embedded in net-
on “a broader formulation of rational choice” works, new institutional economic sociologists
(Granovetter 1985, 506), in which rationality is often focus on individual-level actors, whether en-
viewed as context-bound—often decisively influ- trepreneurs or employees. Agency and the pursuit
enced by shared beliefs and norms monitored and of interests are facilitated, motivated, and gov-
enforced by mechanisms arising from social inter- erned by social relations, shared beliefs, norms,
actions in close-knit networks and groups. Thus ra- and institutions. Established organizations often
tional action in economic life is facilitated, motivat- appear inert, from this perspective, because they
ed, and governed by shared beliefs, social relations, face powerful inertial forces; instead new orga-
norms, and institutions—a view that is inconsistent nizational forms generate the pressures for insti-
with neoclassical economics’ assumption of an tutional change (Ingram 1998). In this respect
atomistic, utility-maximizing homo economicus. economic sociologists agree with organizational
New Institutionalisms 65

sociologists that rational action by organizational analysts, in turn, highlight organizations’ quest for
actors is problematic, not only because it is difficult legitimacy as the motor that drives conformity to
to measure, but because unintended consequences institutionalized rules and practices through coer-
of individual-level rational action and path depen- cive, normative, and mimetic mechanisms. The
dence at the institutional level greatly complicate mechanisms of isomorphism operate within the or-
matters at the organizational level. ganizational field, promoting increasing homo-
As DiMaggio and Powell (1991) point out, geneity among organizations. New institutional
there are many more definitions of institutions economic sociology once again occupies the cen-
than there are new institutionalisms in the social ter, drawing on insights on the role of the state in
sciences, because scholars have been casual in de- implementing institutional innovations and on le-
fining them. Despite the profusion of definitions, gitimacy as a motivating interest of organizations.
there is an underlying consensus about this matter Economic sociologists borrow insights from orga-
in economic and sociological new institution- nizational research on the importance of isomor-
alisms. Organizational new institutionalists con- phism as a macro-level causal mechanism, but their
ceive of institutions as systems of rationalized focus on firms and entrepreneurs as opposed to
myths and routines, conformity to which confers nonprofit organizations (i.e., public schools, local
legitimacy upon organizations. While their con- government, museums, hospitals) imparts greater
ceptual language may differ, the underlying theme attention to specifying and explicating how market
of institutions as rule-governed social construc- mechanisms and state regulation shape the way
tions is consistent with new institutionalist eco- economic actors compete for survival and profits.38
nomics and economic sociology, which share simi- With respect to specification of micro-level
lar definitions of institutions as dominant systems mechanisms, organizational sociologists emphasize
of interrelated formal and informal rules that facil- organizational action oriented to mimicking, con-
itate, motivate, and govern social and economic formity, and decoupling. New institutional eco-
behavior. Economic sociology differs from eco- nomists build on a modified version of the maxi-
nomics, however, in the view that institutions are mizing assumption of neoclassical economics. The
not simply the formal and informal constraints that integration of information asymmetry and uncer-
specify incentives and disincentives, as in North tainty confers a greater level of realism on bound-
(1981), but fundamentally encompass socially con- ed rationality. New institutional economic soci-
structed arenas in which actors identify and pursue ology conceives of micro-level mechanisms as
interests. Although economists acknowledge the stemming from the interest-driven action of indi-
importance of informal social organization, their viduals influenced by ongoing social relations,
analysis emphasizes the role of the state in enforc- shared beliefs, norms, and institutions.
ing formal rules. Economic sociologists emphasize The sources of the new institutionalisms in eco-
the norms produced and maintained in close-knit nomics and sociology are diverse, reflecting differ-
groups that comprise the informal social organiza- ences in emphasis, behavioral assumptions, and
tion in firms. As they see it, ongoing interpersonal core organizing concepts. Economic new insti-
ties and networks are crucial to understanding the tutionalists extend the Smithian classical tradition
nature of the relationship between informal social of economic reasoning through the writings of
organization and formal rules. Coase, Knight, Commons, North, and William-
New institutionalists in economics and sociolo- son, but they also borrow key insights from Weber,
gy concur that regulatory rules monitored and en- Marx, and Polanyi in their understanding of insti-
forced by the state and statelike organizations frame tutions and institutional change. In organizational
the underlying social structure of the institutional analysis, institutional theorists extend Durkheim’s
environment. Formal rules are important in eco- view of institutions as “social facts” that mold so-
nomic analysis insofar as they define the incentive cial behavior and Weber’s view of the importance
structure for organizations and firms, as in the of cultural beliefs in motivating social and eco-
rules governing property rights. Economists em- nomic action. New institutionalists in economic
phasize the monitoring and enforcement of formal sociology extend insights from Weber’s method-
rules by the state as the crucial macro-level mech- ological individualism and pioneering work in
anism. They simply assume markets and instead comparative institutional analysis focusing on sys-
focus explanatory attention on changes in the rela- tems of shared beliefs, law, bureaucracy, markets,
tionship between the economic and political actors and the state; from Marx’s theory of capitalist eco-
(e.g., North and Weingast 1989). Organizational nomic institutions, which anticipated the concept
66 Nee
of transaction costs in analyzing the nature of the dependence, bureaucracy, government regulation,
relationship between capitalists and workers; and state predation) using firm-centric data opens the
from Polanyi’s concept of social embeddedness way for a more differentiated account of how the
and analysis of the institutional mechanisms giving institutional environment influences economic be-
rise to and maintaining modern market economies. havior.40 Economic sociologists, for example, can
They also draw on insights from economics, espe- fruitfully extend the ecological reasoning of orga-
cially following the recent sociological turn in eco- nizational sociology to examine discrete patterns in
nomics that has increased the areas of overlapping institutional environments that support distinct or-
concerns. ganizational forms. For example, what features of
the institutional environment—“institutional ecolo-
gy”—support modern public-owned corporations
CONCLUSION as opposed to the traditional family-owned firms in
the global economy?
Sociological analysis of the nature of the rela- The idea of path dependence, imported into
tionships between networks, norms, and large in- economics from the physical sciences, has deep-
stitutional structures in economic life is at an early ened social science understanding of institutional
stage. As economic sociology refines and deepens change (Nelson and Winter 1982; David 1986;
its explanation of the nature of these relationships, Arthur 1988). Path dependence refers to the lock-
it will necessarily draw on a variety of method- in effects stemming from initial conditions on sub-
ological and theoretical tools. Insights from cogni- sequent development and change in the institu-
tive science, behavioral economics, game theory, tional environment. Economic historians have
and computer simulation of the emergence, diffu- used the idea productively to explain the stability
sion, and transformation of norms and beliefs can of institutions and the persistence of institutional
contribute to deepening understanding of the arrangements that may later be inefficient for eco-
micro-macro links (Marsh 2002). These methods nomic actors, given changes in relative prices
can also contribute to understanding the stability (North 1990; Greif [1994] 1998). Hamilton and
of customs, conventions, norms, and beliefs. Feenstra (1998, 173) show that the idea of path
Central to the research agenda of a new institu- dependence is adumbrated in Weber’s theory of
tional approach is to bring comparative institu- economic rationalization, which maintains that
tional analysis back into economic sociology. Much “entrepreneurial strategy is necessarily embedded
of this work to date has involved qualitative histor- in an array of existing economic interactions and
ical analysis of one or two case studies. While such organizations.” Further research is needed to deep-
work has led to advances in understanding the re- en understanding of path-dependent institutional
lationship between institutions and economic be- change and especially of the relationship between
havior, the use of quantitative methods moving the persistence of informal institutional elements
beyond case studies to engage systematic cross- and change in formal rules (Nee and Cao 1999). It
national firm-level studies can specify and explicate is the stability of informal institutional elements—
how variable features of the institutional environ- customs, networks, norms, cultural beliefs—that
ment affect firms’ behavior in the global economy. disproportionately accounts for path dependence
Comparative institutional analysis of firm-centric in institutional arrangements.
data on sources of perceived costs in the institu- Just as economists find it useful to incorporate
tional environment offers a promising approach to the idea of embeddedness in their models of the
the measurement of transaction costs. Though economy, so economic sociology can benefit from
transaction cost is the core theoretical concept of integrating economic ideas that are complementa-
new institutional economics, economists have yet ry to the modern sociological approach. Econom-
to measure this concept in a manner useful for em- ic exchange is a specialized form of social exchange
pirical analysis.39 As it refers to the costs stemming (Homans 1974, 68); hence the mechanisms facili-
from uncertainty and information asymmetry em- tating, motivating, and governing social processes
bedded in social relations (e.g., the principal-agent extend to economic behavior. Cross-disciplinary
relationship), it is a concept of significant interest trade with economics has been useful to sociology
to sociologists as well. The development of stan- in the past, as evident in the extensive borrowing
dardized indexes of transaction costs arising from a from economics by the founders of modern sociol-
variety of institutional sources (i.e., property ogy, and in the influence of imported ideas such
rights, uncertainty, transparency of rules, resource as human capital, social capital, and path depen-
New Institutionalisms 67

dence. New institutional economic sociology is 1974; Davis and North 1971; Demsetz 1967, 1968, 1983;
well positioned to benefit from, and contribute to, North and Thomas 1973; Barzel 1982, 1989; Williamson
1975, 1985; and Ostrom 1990. In a recent review, William-
intellectual trade with economists, especially in son (2000) includes six Nobel laureates among key figures
light of their turn to sociology for understanding in the new institutional economics: Kenneth Arrow, Fried-
about the social dimension of economic life. rich Hayek, Gunnar Myrdal, Herbert Simon, Ronald Coase,
and Douglass North. The founding of the International So-
ciety for New Institutional Economics by Coase, North, and
Williamson in 1996 has provided an annual forum for new
NOTES work, much of it empirical, and has greatly expanded the
scope of research addressed by new institutional economists.
I am very appreciative of the careful reading of an earlier 8. Specifically, Williamson makes use of the contract law
draft, and excellent comments generously provided by literature and the organization literatures of Barnard
Rachel Davis, Paul DiMaggio, Oliver Williamson, Paul In- ([1938] 1964) and especially the Carnegie school (Simon
gram, Sonja Opper, Rudolf Richter, Richard Swedberg, and 1957; March and Simon 1958, Cyert and March 1963).
Brett de Bary. Thanks to Wubiao Zhou and Suzanne Wright 9. “Problems of contracting are greatly complicated by
for their research assistance. economic agents who make ‘false or empty, that is, self-
1. Recent reviews provide overviews of the new institu- disbelieved threats or promises’ (Goffman 1959, p. 105),
tionalisms in economics (Eggertsson 1990; Williamson cut corners for undisclosed personal advantage, cover up
1994; Furubotn and Richter 1997), in organizational analy- tracks, and the like” (Williamson 1981, 554).
sis (DiMaggio and Powell 1991; Ingram and Clay 2000), in 10. Transaction cost economics concurs with population
rational choice political science (Ordeshook 1990; Weingast ecology’s core assumption that competition in a market
2003), and in historical institutionalism (Thelen and Stein- economy is the driving mechanism of adaptive fitness of or-
mo 1992; Hall and Taylor 1996; Pierson and Skocpol ganizational forms (Hannan and Freeman 1989) and offers
2003). Scott (2001) offers a useful conceptual inventory of a firm-level answer to their question, “Why are there so
advances in organizational new institutionalism. many kinds of organizations?” Its predictions have been
2. See Granovetter 1992 for an application of a social confirmed in empirical tests (Joskow 1988; Shelanski and
constructionist approach to the study of economic institu- Klein 1995; Masten 1993).
tions. Granovetter offers an interpretive account of institu- 11. Because the essence of property rights is the right to
tions amenable to historical studies of institutions and insti- exclude, North (1981) reasoned that the state, which has a
tutional change. comparative advantage in violence, plays a key role in spec-
3. Coase believes nonetheless that state intervention can ifying and enforcing property rights. North’s theory of the
be effective, but not always or automatically. state is neoclassical insofar as it assumes that rulers seek to
4. Furubotn and Richter (1997) show, however, that maximize revenue through an exchange of protection and
bounded rationality cannot be incorporated in neoclassical justice for revenue from constituents. Although the ruler
economics as such. has an interest in devising property rights to maximize state
5. A thoughtful review of the old economic institutional- revenues, the existence of rivals capable of providing the
ism by Hodgson (1998) argues that habitual behavior was same services constrains the state. Because the free-rider
the starting point of its institutional analysis. The old insti- problem limits the ability of constituents to carry out soci-
tutional economist examined patterns and regularities of ety-wide institutional change, the state, which as a monop-
human behavior—habits—as the basis for the approach to olist does not face a free-rider problem, is the source of in-
macroeconomic systems. It was not that the old institution- stitutional innovations.
alists failed to generate important findings, but they were 12. Campbell and Lindberg (1990) analyze how a weak
displaced by the rise of mathematical economics. See also state structure like the United States derives enormous
Yonay 1998 for an examination of the conflict between the power through its control of formal rules governing proper-
old institutionalists and neoclassical economists. ty rights.
6. Stinchcombe (1997) in fact views Coase’s “The Nature 13. North and Weingast (1989) argue that in the English
of the Firm” (1937) as an important contribution to the old case, the key events and conditions stemmed from the erup-
economic institutionalism’s core research agenda, identify- tion of the tension between ruler and constituent that gave
ing the institutional elements making possible the competi- rise to institutions limiting the capacity of the state to ex-
tive structure of capitalism. According to Stinchcombe, propriate resources from producers, and hence the needed
Coase’s analysis of the nature of firm boundaries comple- incentives to fuel economic growth through innovation and
ments Commons’s work on the noncontractual basis of the private enterprise.
contracts that constitute the firm. Williamson (1981, 14. Libecap (1994) integrates public choice theory with
549–50) explicitly acknowledges his own intellectual debt to new institutional economics to develop a property rights ap-
Commons (1934), who “recognized that there were a vari- proach to institutional change that takes into account polit-
ety of governance structures with which to mediate the ex- ical and economic interests.
change of goods or services between technologically separa- 15. For example, the demise of China’s planned economy
ble entities. Assessing the capacities of different structures to led to a change in the structure of industrial production and
harmonize relations between parties and recognizing that an increase in labor demand (changing relative prices). The
new structures arose in the service of these harmonizing state’s response was to liberalize rules on internal migration
purposes were central to the study of institutional econom- and household registration in rural areas.
ics as he conceived it.” 16. A second prong of Granovetter’s critique was to point
7. Significant early writings of the new institutional econ- to the limitations of the functionalist claim that institutions
omists influenced by Coase’s classic essays include Alchian and generalized morality are solutions to problems in eco-
1950; Alchian and Demsetz 1972, 1973; Cheung 1970, nomic life, a claim that “fails the elementary tests of a sound
68 Nee
functional explanation laid down by Robert Merton in community-based social institutions to solve principal-agent is-
1947” (1985, 488–89). In orienting economic sociology to sues: the problem of negotiating and securing contracts ex
study the effect of interpersonal ties and network structures ante and ensuring their compliance ex post given asymmetric
on economic performance, Granovetter is well aware of a information, partial contracting, and uncertainty. Genoese
slippery slope leading to functionalism within a social rela- traders guided by individualist cultural beliefs constructed for-
tions approach. It is not uncommon in the embeddedness mal institutional structures that enabled them to employ
literature, for example, to uncover arguments positing the nonkin agents. The Maghrebi traders were collectivist in their
advantages of networks as (1) solving efficiently the problem cultural beliefs and relied on ethnically bounded institutional
of trust, (2) providing ready access to fine-grained, timely, arrangements to organize long-distance trade. Greif points out
and reliable information, and (3) allowing collective prob- that although the historical record does not allow a test of rel-
lem solving by entrepreneurs. This leads to his methodolog- ative efficiency between the two trading systems, the Maghre-
ical emphasis on the need for economic sociology to study bis eventually disappeared from the Mediterranean world,
the history of concrete interpersonal relations. whereas Genoese traders flourished in late medieval Europe.
Because “enormous trust and enormous malfeasance may Greif ([1994] 1998, 96–97) observes that “it is intriguing that
follow from personal relations” (492), Granovetter argues it the Maghribis’ societal organization resembles that of con-
is impossible to determine ex ante whether reliance on temporary developing countries, whereas the Genoese societal
interpersonal ties will cement trust or give rise to opportu- organization resembles the developed West, suggesting that
nities for malfeasance ex post. It is necessary therefore to the individualistic system may have been more efficient in the
examine through historical case studies how specific inter- long run. . . . To the extent that the division of labor is a nec-
personal ties and network structures evolve (McGuire, essary condition for long-run sustained economic growth, for-
Granovetter, and Schwartz 1993). To succeed in its compe- mal enforcement institutions that support anonymous ex-
tition with new institutional economics, the embeddedness change facilitate economic development.”
approach needs to demonstrate that interpersonal ties have 24. Development of an interest-related approach to com-
more to do with shaping economic behavior and perfor- parative institutional analysis is being pursued by Nee and
mance in markets and hierarchies than do organizational Swedberg at the Center for the Study of Economy and So-
forms. Along these lines, Granovetter has proposed a rival ciety at Cornell University (see www.economyandsociety
hypothesis to transaction cost economics, which asserts that .org). The views expressed by Scott and Meyer (1983) are
variation in the structure and nature of interpersonal ties ex- complementary to an interest-related approach to institu-
plains vertical integration of firms: “we should expect pres- tional analysis.
sures towards vertical integration in a market where trans- 25. Clearly, organizational field and production markets
acting firms lack a network of personal relations that are overlapping and redundant concepts with respect to for-
connects them or where such a network eventuates in con- profit firms. Mechanisms of conformity to group norms and
flict, disorder, opportunism, or malfeasance. On the other beliefs about expected behavior operate in all close-knit
hand, where a stable network of relations mediates complex groups, whether of firms or individuals. Given the emphasis
transactions and generates standards of behavior between on for-profit firms in economic sociology, production mar-
firms, such pressures should be absent” (1985, 503). ket, as opposed to organizational field, is the more useful
17. As Richard Miller (1987) points out, proximate caus- concept.
es are often shallow when contrasted with the deep determi- 26. An early focus on nonprofit organizations may ac-
native causes identified with large structures and processes. count for why organizational sociologists specify legitimacy-
18. Here I use virtually verbatim a comment provided by seeking as the driving mechanism of organizational behavior.
Paul DiMaggio. DiMaggio and Powell (1983) specify three mechanisms—
19. Williamson’s multilevel model in which a higher level coercive, normative, and mimetic—promoting isomorphism
constrains the lower level differs from the multilevel model in organizational fields. They integrate their mechanisms of
I propose in figure 2 for new institutional economic sociol- isomorphism with resource dependence theory to specify
ogy, where each level is in mutual dependence with the hypotheses predicting the extent of isomorphism at the or-
other. As Paul DiMaggio has pointed out to me in a personal ganization and field levels. Coercive isomorphism integrates
communication, the latter approach offers a “co-evolution- resource dependence theory into organizational analysis;
ary model, with phenomena at different levels mutually con- normative isomorphism specifies how professional associa-
stituting contexts within which each evolves.” tions influence organizational behavior under conditions of
20. See Rona-Tas 1994; Eyal, Szelényi, and Townsley uncertainty; and mimetic isomorphism, as DiMaggio writes
1998. in a personal communication, “is about how . . . intendedly
21. New institutional organizational analysis represents rational actors, facing uncertainty under high stakes, satisfice
more diversity in viewpoints on agency than is often ac- by identifying successful peers and making reasonable but
knowledged. For example, DiMaggio, Powell, and Scott dif- incorrect attributions about the causes of their success.”
fer with Meyer and Rowan in their interest in taking into ac- 27. Social ties and norms do not themselves constitute
count agency—actors who share beliefs and norms; hence mechanisms insofar as they are concepts referring to elements
the former are closer to the position articulated by Greif of social structure—the relationship connecting two or more
than to the structuralism of Meyer and Rowan. actors and the informal rules governing the relationship.
22. Its use is restricted to analyzing social interactions in 28. See Roethlisberg and Dickson 1939; Whyte 1943;
equilibrium, a situation in which each player’s behavior is Festinger, Schachter, and Back 1950; Schachter et al. 1951;
optimal given the perceived and expected behavior of others Jennings 1950; Seashore 1954; Bott 1957; Riley and Cohn
in the game. 1958; Walker and Heyns 1962; Cook et al. 1983; Ellickson
23. In his influential study of the Maghrebi and Genoese 1991; Petersen 1992; Kollock 1994; Lawler and Yoon
traders in late medieval economic history, Greif ([1994] 1998) 1996.
demonstrated the use of game theory to explicate the manner 29. Shibutani (1978) provides detailed observations
in which social variables such as beliefs, norms, and networks about the emergence and maintenance of norms of a close-
motivate economic action. Both groups of traders relied on knit group of Japanese American soldiers in a military base,
New Institutionalisms 69

documenting norm emergence as a product of collective 34. In their study of the history of personnel practices in
problem-solving as members of the group socially construct 279 firms in California, Virginia, and New Jersey—localities
a definition of the situation and course of action that opti- with different institutional contexts— Sutton and Dobbin
mizes their welfare. (1996) confirm an endogenous motivation of personnel
30. Ellickson’s analysis of conflict arising from damage to professionals and affirmative action officers to develop
property caused by trespassing cattle showed that the resi- strategies for compliance with EEO guidelines. Federal ac-
dents of Shasta County commonly resorted to informal tivism through expanded legal and political pressures on
norms of cooperation to settle disputes. Ellickson reports firms increased the rate of adoption of legalization within
that ranchers and residents have only a vague grasp of the the firm of due-process governance. In general, the diffusion
formal litigation procedures involved in resolving disputes of legalized governance structures demonstrating compli-
over trespassing. Moreover, litigation is viewed as a costly ance with EEO/AA guidelines shows time-trends corre-
way to settle property disputes, both financially and with re- sponding to ups and downs of federal EEO/AA enforce-
spect to long-standing relationships in a close-knit commu- ment activities. Firms that contracted with the federal
nity. Ellickson’s narrative of the incidents of disputes be- government were more likely to file annual EEO reports to
tween ranchers and suburbanites shows that despite their demonstrate good faith in compliance with federal guide-
cultural differences, a common identity as residents of Shas- lines. Organizations closer to the public domain more read-
ta County sustains a live-and-let-live philosophy that enables ily complied with federal EEO/AA rules and guidelines.
parties to practice mutual restraint. As long as accounts bal- Significantly, findings by Sutton et al. “suggest that legaliza-
anced along multiple dimensions of interpersonal relations, tion is not aimed inward, toward specific employee demands
parties in disputes settled informally: or organizational requirements, but outward at the shifting
concerns of regulators and courts” (1994, 996). In a follow-
The landowners who were interviewed clearly regard their re-
up study using a different data set of 154 for-profit firms,
straint in seeking monetary relief as a mark of virtue. When
Sutton and Dobbin (1996) confirm the close coupling of
asked why they did not pursue meritorious legal claims arising
state regulation of formal rules and the normative pressures
from trespass or fence-finance disputes, various landowners
on management from human resource professionals inside
replied: “I’m not that kind of guy”; “I don’t believe in it”; “I
the firm to institute proactive governance strategies (i.e.,
don’t like to create a stink”; “I try to get along.” The
formal lawlike rules governing grievance procedures and in-
landowners who attempted to provide a rationale for this for-
ternal labor markets to protect equality of rights) in order to
bearance all implied the same one, a long-term reciprocity of
comply with federal EEO/AA guidelines.
advantage. Ann Kershaw: “The only one that makes money
35. For analyses of how institutional change by adminis-
[when you litigate] is the lawyer.” Al Levitt: “I figure it will
trative design and formal rule change faltered in Eastern Eu-
balance out in the long run.” Pete Schultz: “I hope they’ll do
rope and Russia, see Stark 1996; Gray and Hendley 1997;
the same for me.” Phil Ritchie: “My family believes in ‘live
Hellman 1997; Varese 2001.
and let live.’” (1991, 61)
36. For analyses by economic sociologists of realignment
31. Ellickson’s specification of welfare-maximization is of power and interests favoring economic actors in market
not Pareto-superior insofar as its criterion focuses on the transitions and institutional change in China, see Walder
question, do most people derive a net benefit from the 1995; Nee 1996; Cao 2001; Guthrie 1999; Keister 2000.
norm? According to the prisoner’s dilemma game, T > 37. See Shirk 1993; Naughton 1995; and Opper, Wong,
R > P > S, where T is the temptation to defect, R is the re- and Hu 2002 for analyses of how economic and political ac-
ward for mutual cooperation, P is punishment for mutual tors benefited from institutional change.
defection, and S is the sucker’s payoff. The condition for the 38. Economic sociologists whose work examines the ef-
prisoner’s dilemma norm to be in equilibrium is that the fect of markets include Saxenian (1994); Swedberg (1994);
total payoff for cooperation, after deducting the cost of Abolafia (1996); Uzzi (1997); Guillén (2001); White
monitoring and enforcement (C), must be greater than the (2001); Baron and Hannan (forthcoming); Freeman (forth-
payoff for defection (T) and the sucker’s payoff (S) : 2R − coming); and Davis and Marquis (forthcoming). Those ex-
C > T + S (Nee and Ingram 1998). amining the effect of both market and state regulation on
32. Nee and Ingram (1998) specify how informal norms economic actors include Nee (1992, 1996, 2000); Nee,
emerge and interact with formal institutional elements, per- Sanders, and Sernau (1994); Walder (1995); Fligstein (1996,
mitting predictions about organizational and economic per- 2001); and Guthrie (1999).
formance that can be empirically tested. 39. North and Wallis (1986) estimated the size of the
33. For example, in 1997 the landmark federal discrimi- transaction sector of the American economy; however, their
nation case against Texaco imposed a costly settlement of aggregate data is not useful for empirical analysis.
$175 million to minority employees, and the publicity aris- 40. Firm-centric data, rather than aggregate national-level
ing from the case also damaged the firm’s reputation. Texa- data, is needed to measure transaction costs, which are the
co was compelled to carry out extensive organizational costs to firms of negotiating, securing, and completing eco-
changes in personnel policy and practices in making credible nomic transactions. The problem with national-level aggre-
commitment to eliminating racial discrimination to avoid gate data is that it does not measure the effect of variation in
further fines and restore its legitimacy. The federal discrimi- institutional conditions on the firm and entrepreneur.
nation case against Coca-Cola was resolved at a cost of $192
million to the firm. Coca-Cola’s management, moreover,
agreed to ongoing external monitoring of its progress in REFERENCES
eliminating bias in all aspects of the firm’s operation. As with
the public response to the landmark Texaco discrimination
case, both damage to Coca-Cola’s brand name and the fi- Abolafia, Mitchell Y. 1996. Making Markets: Oppor-
nancial and organizational penalties of the settlement had tunism and Restraint on Wall Street. Cambridge:
the effect of reinforcing other firms’ belief in self-monitoring Harvard University Press.
for compliance with EEO/AA guidelines. Alba, Richard, and Victor Nee. 2003. Remaking the
70 Nee
American Mainstream: Assimilation and Contempo- ture of Competition. Chicago: University of Chicago
rary Immigration. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Press. Campbell, John L., and Leon N. Lindberg. 1990.
Alchian, Armen A. 1950. “Uncertainty, Evolution, and “Property Rights and the Organization of Econom-
Economic Theory.” Journal of Political Economy ic Activity by the State.” American Sociological Re-
59:211–221. view 55:634–47.
Alchian, Armen A., and Harold Demsetz. 1972. “Pro- Cao, Yang. 2001. “Careers inside Organizations: A
duction, Information Costs, and Economic Organi- Comparative Analysis of Promotion Determination
zation.” American Economic Review 62:777–95. in Reforming China. Social Forces 80:683–712.
———. 1973. “The Property Right Paradigm.” Journal Cheung, Steven N. S. 1970. “The Structure of a Con-
of Economic History 33:16–27. tract and the Theory of a Non-exclusive Resource.”
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1987. “Reflections on the Essays.” Journal of Law and Economics 13:49–70.
Pp. 727–34 in Arrow and the Foundations of the ———. 1974. “A Theory of Price Control.” Journal of
Theory of Economic Policy, ed. George Feinel. New Law and Economics 12:53–71.
York: New York University Press. Cicourel, Aaron. 1974. Cognitive Sociology. New York:
Arthur, Brian W. 1988. “Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Free Press.
Economics.” Pp. 9–32 in The Economy as an Evolv- Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Eco-
ing Complex System, ed. Philip W. Anderson, Ken- nomica 4:386–405.
neth J. Arrow, and David Pines. Menlo Park, Calif.: ———. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of
Addison-Wesley. Law and Economics 3:1–44.
Aslund, Anders. 1995. How Russia Became a Market ———. 1984. “The New Institutional Economics.”
Economy. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
Press. 140:229–31.
Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. ———. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chica-
New York: Basic Books. go: University of Chicago Press.
Barnard, Chester I. [1938] 1964. The Functions of the Commons, John R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its
Executive. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Place in Political Economy. New York: Macmillan.
Baron, James, and Michael T. Hannan. Forthcoming. ———. 1957. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. Madi-
“The Economic Sociology of Organizational Entre- son: University of Wisconsin Press.
preneurship: Lessons from the Stanford Project on Cook, Karen S., Richard M. Emerson, Mary R. Gill-
Emerging Companies.” In Economic Sociology of more, and Toshio Yamagishi. 1983. “The Distribu-
Capitalism, ed. Victor Nee and Richard Swedberg. tion of Power in Exchange Networks: Theory and
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Experimental Results.” American Journal of Sociol-
Barzel, Yoram. 1982. “Measurement Cost and the Or- ogy 89:275–305.
ganization of Markets.” Journal of Law and Eco- Cyert, Richard M., and James G. March. 1963. A Be-
nomics 25:27–28. havioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
———. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Prentice-Hall.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. David, Paul. 1986. “Understanding the Economics of
Beissinger, Mark R. 2002. Nationalist Mobilization and QWERTY: The Necessity of History.” Pp. 30–49 in
the Collapse of the Soviet State. Cambridge: Cam- Economic History and the Modern Economist, ed.
bridge University Press. William N. Parker. Oxford: Blackwell.
Berger, Peter L., and Thomas Luckmann. 1967. The Davis, Gerald, and Christopher Marquis. Forthcom-
Social Construction of Reality. New York: Double- ing. “The Globalization of Stock Markets and
day. Convergence in Corporate Governance.” In Eco-
Blau, Peter. 1955. The Dynamics of Bureaucracy. 2d ed. nomic Sociology of Capitalism, ed. Victor Nee and
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Richard Swedberg. Princeton: Princeton Universi-
———. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New ty Press.
York: John Wiley and Sons. Davis, Lance E., and Douglass C. North. 1971. Institu-
Bott, Elizabeth. 1957. Family and Social Network. Lon- tional Change and American Economic Growth.
don: Tavistock. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bourdieu, Pierre. [1972] 1977. Outline of a Theory Demsetz, Harold. 1967. “Toward a Theory of Property
of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rights.” American Economic Review 57:347–59.
Brinton, Mary C., and Victor Nee, eds. 1998. The New ———. 1968. “Why Regulate Utilities.” Journal of Law
Institutionalism in Sociology. New York: Russell and Economics 11:55–66.
Sage Foundation. ———. 1983. “The Structure of Ownership and the
Burawoy, Michael. 1979. Manufacturing Dissent: Changes Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Law and Economics
in the Labor Process under Monopoly Capitalism. 26:375–93.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell. 1983. “The
Burt, Ronald. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Struc- Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and
New Institutionalisms 71

Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” Granovetter, Mark. 1985. “Economic Action and Social
American Sociological Review 48:147–60. Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” Amer-
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. Syracuse, ican Journal of Sociology 91:481–510.
N.Y.: Syracuse University Press. ———. 1992. “Economic Institutions as Social Con-
Edelman, Lauren B. 1990. “Legal Environments and structions: A Framework for Analysis.” Acta Socio-
Organizational Governance: The Expansion of Due logica 35:3–11.
Process in the American Workplace.” American Gray, Cheryl W., and Kathryn Hendley. 1997. “Devel-
Journal of Sociology 95:1401–40. oping Commercial Law in Transition Economies:
———. 1992. “Legal Ambiguity and Symbolic Struc- Examples from Hungary and Russia.” Pp. 139–64
tures: Organizational Mediation of Civil Rights in The Rule of Law and Economic Reform in Russia,
Law.” American Journal of Sociology 97:1531–76. ed. Jeffrey Sachs and Katharina Pistor. Cambridge,
Edelman, Lauren B., Christopher Uggen, and Howard Mass.: Westview.
S. Erlanger. 1999. “The Endogeneity of Legal Reg- Greif, Avner. [1994] 1998. “Cultural Beliefs and the Or-
ulation: Grievance Procedures as Rational Myth.” ganization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical
American Journal of Sociology 105:406–54. Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Soci-
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic Behavior and In- eties.” Journal of Political Economy 102:912–50.
stitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Adapted for The New Institutionalism in Sociology,
Ellickson, Robert. 1991. Order without Law. Cam- ed. Mary Brinton and Victor Nee (New York: Rus-
bridge: Harvard University Press. sell Sage Foundation), 77–104.
Emerson, Richard. 1962. “Power-Dependence Rela- ———. Forthcoming. Institutions: History and Theory:
tions.” American Sociological Review 22:31–41. Comparative and Historical Institutional Analysis.
Evans, Peter, and James E. Rauch. 1999. “Bureaucracy Cambridge: University of Cambridge Press.
and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Ef- Guillén, Mauro F. 2001. The Limits of Convergence:
fects of ‘Weberian’ State Structures on Economic Globalization and Organizational Change in Ar-
Growth.” American Sociological Review 64:748–65. gentina, South Korea, and Spain. Princeton: Prince-
Eyal, Gil, Ivan Szelényi, and Eleanor Townsley. 1998. ton University Press.
Making Capitalism without Capitalists: The New Guthrie, Doug. 1999. Dragon in a Three-Piece Suit: The
Ruling Elites in Eastern Europe. London: Verso. Emergence of Capitalism in China. Princeton:
Festinger, Leon, Stanley Schachter, and Kurt Back. Princeton University Press.
1950. Social Pressures in Informal Groups. New Hall, Peter A., and Rosemary Taylor. 1996. “Political
York: Harper. Science and the Three New Institutionalisms.” Po-
Fligstein, Neil. 1996. “Markets and Politics: A Sociolog- litical Studies 44:936–57.
ical View of Market Institutions.” American Socio- Hamilton, Gary D., and Robert Feenstra. 1998. “The
logical Review 61:656–73. Organization of Economies.” Pp. 153–80 in The
———. 2001. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic New Institutionalism in Sociology, ed. Mary Brin-
Sociology of Twenth-first-Century Capitalist Societies. ton and Victor Nee. New York: Russell Sage
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Foundation.
Freeman, John. Forthcoming. “Venture Capital and Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1989. Organi-
Modern Capitalism.” In Economic Sociology of Cap- zational Ecology. Cambridge: Harvard University
italism, ed. Victor Nee and Richard Swedberg. Press.
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hardin, Russell. 1988. Morality within the Limits of Rea-
Furubotn, Eirik G., and Rudolf Richter. 1993. “The son. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
New Institutional Economics: Recent Progress; Ex- Hayek, Friedrich. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in So-
panding Frontiers.” Journal of Institutional and ciety.” American Economic Review 35:519–30.
Theoretical Economics 149:1–10. Hellman, Joel S. 1997. “Constitutions and Economic
———. 1997. Institutions and Economic Theory: The Reform in the Post-Communist Transitions.” Pp.
Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. 55–78 in The Rule of Law and Economic Reform in
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Russia, ed. Jeffrey Sachs and Katharina Pistor. Cam-
Garfinkel, Harold. 1967. Studies in Ethnomethodology. bridge, Mass.: Westview.
Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1998. “The Approach of Institu-
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Social tional Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature
Theory: Action, Structure, and Contradictions in So- 36:166–92.
cial Analysis. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University Homans, George C. 1950. The Human Group. New
of California Press. York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Goffman, Erving. 1959. The Presentation of Self in ———. [1961] 1974. Social Behavior: Its Elementary
Everyday Life. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday An- Forms. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
chor Books. Ingram, Paul. 1998. “Changing the Rules: Interests, Or-
———. 1967. Interaction Ritual. Garden City, N.Y.: ganizations, and Institutional Change in the U.S.
Anchor. Hospitality Industry.” Pp. 258–76 in The New In-
72 Nee
stitutionalism in Sociology, ed. Mary Brinton and Miller, Richard W. 1987. Fact and Method: Explanation,
Victor Nee. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Confirmation, and Reality in the Natural and the
Ingram, Paul, and Karen Clay. 2000. “The Choice-with- Social Sciences. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
in-Constraints New Institutionalism and Implica- Mitchell, Wesley C. 1927. Business Cycles: The Problem
tions for Sociology.” Annual Review of Sociology and Its Setting. New York: National Bureau of Eco-
26:525–46. nomic Research.
Jennings, Helen Hall. 1950. Leadership and Isolation. 2d ———. 1937. The Backward Art of Spending Money and
ed. New York: Longmans, Green. Other Essays. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.
Joskow, Paul L. 1988. “Asset Specificity and the Struc- Naughton, Barry. 1995. Growing out of the Plan: Chinese
ture of Vertical Relationships: Empirical Evidence.” Economic Reform, 1978–1993. Cambridge: Univer-
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4: sity of Cambridge Press.
95–117. Nee, Victor. 1992. “Organizational Dynamics of Market
———. 1991. “The Role of Transaction Cost Econom- Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and
ics in Antitrust and Public Utility Regulatory Poli- Mixed Economy in China.” Administrative Science
cies.” Journal of Law and Economic Organization Quarterly 37:1–27.
7:53–83. ———. 1996. “The Emergence of a Market Society:
Keister, Lisa. 2000. Chinese Business Groups: The Structure Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China.”
and Impact of Interfirm Relations during Economic American Journal of Sociology 101:908–49.
Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ———. 2000. “The Role of the State in Making a Mar-
Knight, Frank H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. ket Economy.” Journal of Institutional and Theoret-
Boston: Houghton Mifflin. ical Economics 156:64–88.
Kollock, Peter. 1994. “The Emergence of Exchange Nee, Victor, and Yang Cao. 1999. “Path Dependent
Structures: An Experimental Study of Uncertainty, Societal Transformations.” Theory and Society 28:
Commitment, and Trust.” American Journal of So- 799–834.
ciology 100:315–45. Nee, Victor, and Paul Ingram. 1998. “Embeddedness
Kuwabara, Ko. Forthcoming. “Affective Attachment in and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange, and Social
Electronic Markets: A Sociological Study of eBay.” Structure.” Pp. 19–45 in The New Institutionalism
In Economic Sociology of Capitalism, ed. Victor Nee in Sociology, ed. Mary Brinton and Victor Nee. New
and Richard Swedberg. Princeton: Princeton Uni- York: Russell Sage Foundation.
versity Press. Nee, Victor, and Peng Lian. 1994. “Sleeping with the
Lawler, Edward J., and Jeongkoo Yoon. 1996. “Com- Enemy: A Dynamic Model of Declining Political
mitment in Exchange Relations: Test of a Theory of Commitment in State Socialism.” Theory and Soci-
Relational Cohesion.” American Sociological Re- ety 23:253–96.
view 61:89–108. Nee, Victor, Jimy M. Sanders, and Scott Sernau. 1994.
Libecap, Gary D. 1994. Contracting for Property Rights. “Job Transitions in an Immigrant Metropolis: Eth-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. nic Boundaries and Mixed Economy.” American
Lin, Justin Yifu, Fang Cai, and Zhou Li. 1996. The Sociological Review 59:849–72.
China Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Nelson, Richard, and Sidney Winter. 1982. An Evolu-
Reform. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press. tionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge:
March, James, and Herbert Simon. 1958. Organiza- Cambridge University Press.
tions. New York: John Wiley and Sons. North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Eco-
Marsh, Barnaby. 2002. “Heuristics as Social Tools.” nomic History. New York: W. W. Norton.
New Ideas in Psychology 20:49–57. ———. 1984. “Government and the Cost of Exchange
Masten, Scott. 1993. “Transaction Costs, Mistakes, and in History.” Journal of Economic History 44:
Performance: Assessing the Importance of Gover- 255–64.
nance.” Management and Decision Sciences 14: ———. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and
119–29. Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge
McGuire, Patrick, Mark Granovetter, and Michael University Press.
Schwartz. 1993. “Thomas Edison and the Social ———. 1991. “Institutions.” Journal of Economic Per-
Construction of the Early Electricity Industry in spectives 5:97–112.
America.” Pp. 213–48 in Explorations in Economic ———. 1993. “Institutions and Credible Commit-
Sociology, ed. Richard Swedberg. New York: Russell ment.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Eco-
Sage Foundation. nomics 149:11–23.
Merton, Robert K. 1947. “Manifest and Latent Func- North, Douglass C., and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973.
tions.” Pp. 19–84 in Social Theory and Social Struc- The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic His-
ture. New York: Free Press: tory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Meyer, John, and Brian Rowan. 1977. “Institutionalized North, Douglass C., and John J. Wallis. 1986. “Measur-
Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Cere- ing the Transaction Sector in the American Econo-
mony.” American Journal of Sociology 93:340–63. my, 1870–1970.” Pp. 95–161 in Long-Term Factors
New Institutionalisms 73

in American Economic Growth, ed. Staley L. Enger- of Cohesiveness and Productivity.” Human Rela-
man and Robert E. Gallman. Chicago: University of tions 4:229–38.
Chicago Press. Schotter, Andrew. 1981. The Economic Theory of Social
North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
“Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Scott, Richard W. 2001. Institutions and Organizations,
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seven- 2d ed. Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage.
teenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic His- Scott, Richard W., and John W. Meyer. 1983. “The Or-
tory 49:803–32. ganization of Societal Sectors.” Pp. 129–54 in Or-
Opper, Sonja, Sonia M. L. Wong, and Ruyin Hu. 2002. ganizational Environments: Rituals and Rationali-
“Party Power, Market, and Private Power: Chinese ty, ed. John Meyer and Richard W. Scott. Beverly
Communist Party Persistence in China’s Listed Hills, Calif.: Sage.
Companies.” In “The Future of Market Transi- Seashore, Stanley E. 1954. Group Cohesiveness in the In-
tion,” ed. K. Leicht, special issue of Research in So- dustrial Work Group. Ann Arbor: Institute for Social
cial Stratification and Mobility 19:105–38. Research, University of Michigan.
Ordeshook, Peter. 1990. “The Emerging Discipline of Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots. Berke-
Political Economy.” Pp. 9–30 in Perspectives on ley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Ken- Shelanski, Howard A., and P. G. Klein. 1995. “Empiri-
neth Shepsle. Cambridge: Cambridge University cal Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Re-
Press. view and Assessment.” Journal of Law, Economics,
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evo- and Organization 11:335–61.
lution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cam- Shibutani, Tomatsu. 1978. The Derelicts of Company K:
bridge: Cambridge University Press. A Study of Demoralization. Berkeley and Los Ange-
Parsons, Talcott, and Neil J. Smelser. 1956. Economy les: University of California Press.
and Society: A Study in the Integration of Economic Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Re-
and Social Theory. Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press. form in China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: Universi-
Petersen, Trond. 1992. “Individual, Collective, and Sys- ty of California Press.
tems Rationality in Work Groups.” Rationality and Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1994. “Politi-
Society 4:332–55. cians and Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
Pierson, Paul, and Theda Skocpol. 2003. “Historical In- 109:995–1025.
stitutionalism in Political Science.” In The State of Simon, Herbert A. 1957. Models of Man: Social and Ra-
the Discipline, ed. Ira Katznelson and Helen Milner. tional. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
New York: W. W. Norton. Smelser, Neil J., and Richard Swedberg, eds. 1994.
Posner, Richard A. 1986. Economic Analysis of Law. Handbook of Economic Sociology. New York: Russell
Boston: Little, Brown. Sage Foundation; Princeton: Princeton University
———. 1993. “The New Institutional Economics Meets Press.
Law and Economics.” Journal of Institutional and Spence, Michael A. 1974. Market Signaling: Informa-
Theoretical Economics 149:73–87. tional Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening
Powell, Walter W., and Paul J. DiMaggio, eds. 1991. The Processes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Stark, David. 1996. “Recombinant Property in Eastern
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. European Capitalism.” American Journal of Sociol-
Riley, M. W., and R. Cohn. 1958. “Control Networks in ogy 101:993–1027.
Informal Groups.” Sociometry 21:30–49. Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1989. The Economic Role of the State.
Roethlisberger, F. J., and William J. Dickson. 1939. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Management and the Worker. Cambridge: Harvard Stinchcombe, Arthur. 1965. “Social Structure and
University Press. Organizations.” Pp. 142–93 in Handbook of Orga-
Rona-Tas, Akos. 1994. “The First Shall Be Last? Entre- nizations, ed. James G. March. Chicago: Rand
preneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transi- McNally.
tion from Socialism.” American Journal of Sociology ———. 1997. “On the Virtues of the Old Institutional-
100:40–69. ism.” Annual Review of Sociology 23:1–18.
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1994. Institutions in Economics: Sutton, John R., and Frank Dobbin. 1996. “The Two
The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge: Faces of Governance: Responses to Legal Uncer-
Cambridge University Press. tainty in U.S. Firms, 1955 to 1985.” American So-
Sachs, Jeffrey D. 1995. “Consolidating Capitalism.” ciological Review 61:794–811.
Foreign Policy 98:50–64. Sutton, John R., Frank Dobbin, John W. Meyer, and
Saxenian, Annalee. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture W. Richard Scott. 1994. “The Legalization of
and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. the Workplace.” American Journal of Sociology 99:
Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 944–71.
Schachter, Stanley, Norris Ellertson, Dorothy McBride, Swedberg, Richard. 1994. “Markets as Social Struc-
and Doris Gregory. 1951. “An Experimental Study tures.” Pp. 255–82 in The Handbook of Economic
74 Nee
Sociology, ed. Neil J. Smelser and Richard Swedberg. ———. [1904–5] 2002. The Protestant Ethic and the
New York: Russell Sage Foundation; Princeton: Spirit of Capitalism. Los Angeles: Roxbury.
Princeton University Press. Weingast, Barry. 2003. “Rational Choice Institutional-
———. 1998. Max Weber and the Idea of Economic So- ism.” Pp. 660–92 in The State of the Discipline, ed.
ciology. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Ira Katznelson and Helen Milner. New York: W. W.
———. 2003. Principles of Economic Sociology. Prince- Norton.
ton: Princeton University Press. White, Harrison. 1992. Identity and Control: A Struc-
Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and tural Theory of Social Action. Princeton: Princeton
Strategies. American Sociological Review 51:273–86. University Press.
Thelen, Kathleen, and Sven Steinmo. 1992. “Historical ———. 2001. Markets from Networks: Socioeconomic
Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Pp. 1–32 Models of Production. Princeton: Princeton Univer-
in Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in sity Press.
Comparative Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- Whyte, William Foote. 1943. Street Corner Society.
versity Press. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Uzzi, Brian. 1997. “Social Structure and Competition Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies:
in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of Embed- Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free
dedness.” Administrative Science Quarterly 42: Press.
35–67. ———. 1981. “The Economics of Organization: The
Veblen, Thorstein. 1909. “The Limitations of Marginal Transaction Cost Approach.” American Journal of
Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 17:620–36. Sociology 87:548–77.
———. [1899] 1934. The Theory of the Leisure Class: An ———. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism.
Economic Study of Institutions. New York: Modern New York: Free Press.
Library. ———. 1994. “Transaction Cost Economics and Orga-
Varese, Fedrico. 2001. The Russian Mafia: Private Pro- nization Theory.” Pp. 77–107 in The Handbook of
tection in a New Market Economy. Oxford: Oxford Economic Sociology, ed. Neil J. Smelser and Richard
University Press. Swedberg. New York: Russell Sage Foundation;
Walder, Andrew G. 1995. “Local Government as Indus- Princeton: Princeton University Press.
trial Firms: An Organizational Analysis of China’s ———. 2000. “The New Institutional Economics: Tak-
Transitional Economy.” American Journal of Sociol- ing Stock, Looking Ahead.” Journal of Economic
ogy 101:263-301. Literature 38:595–613.
Walker, Edward L., and Roger W. Heyns. 1962. An Yonay, Yuval P. 1998. The Struggle over the Soul of Eco-
Anatomy for Conformity. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: nomics: Institutionalist and Neoclassical Economists
Prentice-Hall. in America between the Wars. Princeton: Princeton
Weber, Max. [1922] 1968. Economy and Society: An University Press.
Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Ed. Guenther Roth Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. “The Role of Institutionaliza-
and Claus Wittich. Berkeley and Los Angeles: Uni- tion in Cultural Persistence.” American Sociological
versity of California Press. Review 42:726–43.

You might also like