You are on page 1of 7

This article was downloaded by: [Columbia University]

On: 14 November 2014, At: 19:41


Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,
37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied Economics Letters


Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rael20

A note on the subprime mortgage crisis: dynamic


modelling of bank leverage profit under loan
securitization
a a a
Mark Adam Petersen , Mmboniseni Phanuel Mulaudzi , Janine Mukuddem-Petersen & Ilse
a
Schoeman
a
Department of Mathematics and Applied Mathematics , North-West University
(Potchefstroom Campus) , Private Bag X 6001, Potchefstroom, 2520, South Africa
Published online: 10 Nov 2009.

To cite this article: Mark Adam Petersen , Mmboniseni Phanuel Mulaudzi , Janine Mukuddem-Petersen & Ilse Schoeman
(2010) A note on the subprime mortgage crisis: dynamic modelling of bank leverage profit under loan securitization, Applied
Economics Letters, 17:15, 1469-1474, DOI: 10.1080/13504850903035907

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504850903035907

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained
in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no
representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the
Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and
are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and
should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for
any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever
or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of
the Content.
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic
reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any
form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://
www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions
Applied Economics Letters, 2010, 17, 1469–1474

A note on the subprime mortgage


crisis: dynamic modelling of bank
leverage profit under loan
securitization
Mark Adam Petersen*, Mmboniseni Phanuel Mulaudzi,
Janine Mukuddem-Petersen and Ilse Schoeman
Department of Mathematics and Applied Mathematics, North-West
University (Potchefstroom Campus), Private Bag X 6001, Potchefstroom
Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

2520, South Africa

In this brief research article, we consider the financial modelling of the


process of mortgage loan securitization that has been a root cause of the
ongoing Subprime Mortgage Crisis (SMC). In particular, we suggest a
Levy process-driven model of bank leverage profit that arises from the
securitization of a pool of subprime mortgage loans. To achieve this, we
develop stochastic models for mortgage loans, mortgage loan losses,
credit ratings and mortgage loan guarantees in a subprime context.
These models incorporate some of the most important issues related to
the SMC and its causes. Finally, we provide a brief analysis of the
models developed earlier in our contribution and its relationship with
the SMC.

I. Introduction Step 1: The bank lends money to mortgagors.


Step 2: The bank creates a mortgage pool from a
To understand the current Subprime Mortgage Crisis group of similar mortgages and sells the MBSs to
(SMC), a deeper investigation of bank profitability the investors.
under asset securitization is required. The latter entails Step 3: The mortgagors pay periodic payments to
the pooling of assets, usually with similar cash flow the bank.
characteristics and issuance of securities whose pay- Step 4: The bank collects mortgage payments,
ments are derived from the underlying pool cash flow. extracts servicing fees, pays mortgage loan guaran-
Financial institutions use securitization to realize the tee fees to the guarantor and pays the interest rate
value of cash-producing assets such as mortgage charged by investors.
loans, credit card loans, traded receivables and study Step 5: When the mortgagor defaults, the guarantor
fees. From being virtually nonexistent 40 years ago, covers the (secondary) mortgage loan losses faced
the US securitization industry had grown to be worth by investors.
an estimated $6.6 trillion by the end of 2004. Our
particular focus is on the securitization of subprime A diagrammatic overview of the mortgage loan
mortgage loans into Mortgage-Backed Securities securitization suggested above is represented in Fig. 1.
(MBSs) by the steps below (see Fig. 1 for a diagram- From Fig. 1, we have that 1a is the rate of cash
matic overview). flow, I, from investors to the financial institution

*Corresponding author. E-mail: Mark.Petersen@nwu.ac.za

Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350–4851 print/ISSN 1466–4291 online  2010 Taylor & Francis 1469
http://www.informaworld.com
DOI: 10.1080/13504850903035907
1470 M. A. Petersen et al.

Fig. 1. Diagrammatic overview of mortgage loan securitization


Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

(which in our case we consider to be a bank) for the beyond two periods is limited. A further motivation is
express purpose of securitizing the portfolio of the fact that profitability is a major indicator of finan-
mortgage loans. In addition, 1b represents the inter- cial crises for households, companies and financial
est rate, rI, paid to investors while 1c is the rate of institutions (Demirgüc-Kunt and Detragiache, 1999;
cash flow, k, from the bank for financing the MBSs Mukuddem-Petersen et al., 2008). An example of the
portfolio. The cash flow 1d is the interest rate latter, from the SMC, is that both the failure of the
received from the MBSs portfolio while 1e repre- Lehmann Brothers investment bank and the acquisi-
sents the payment made by the mortgagor. In tion in September 2008 of Merrill Lynch and Bear
Fig. 1, 1f is the mortgage loan guarantee fee pay- Stearns by Bank of America and JP Morgan, respec-
ments to the guarantor by the servicer (bank) of the tively, was preceded by a decrease in leverage
securitized mortgage loan. Finally, 1g represents profitability. A similar trend was discerned for the
payments made by the guarantor in the case where US mortgage companies, the Federal National
mortgagors default. Mortgage Association (Fanie Mae) and Federal
In our article, we introduce a Levy process-based Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac),
model of bank leverage profit under mortgage loan who had to be bailed out by the US government at
securitization. Here, leverage refers to the degree to the beginning of September 2008. By way of addres-
which the bank utilizes borrowed money. Banks sing the aforementioned issues, we construct stochas-
that are highly leveraged may be at risk of failure tic models for mortgage loans, loan losses, credit
if they are unable to make debt payments or find ratings, mortgage loan guarantees and securitization
new lenders in the future. Leverage profit (also in a subprime setting. From these models, we deduce a
called financial leverage profit) refers to the stochastic dynamic model for bank leverage profit
mechanism whereby the bank creates profit by under securitization of a pool of mortgage loans. In
leveraging itself. We note that our contribution dif- this article, the costs of the guarantee is related to
fers from Mukuddem-Petersen et al. (2008) in that transaction costs to participate in the guarantee pro-
it investigates the dynamics of bank leverage profit gramme like the open or study rate (usually paid only
from securitization activities while Mukuddem- once) and the maintenance rate (paid annually in
Petersen et al. (2008) studied the bank profit proportion to the credit risk). In conclusion, our arti-
which arises from both on- and off-balance sheet cle provides a brief analysis of some of the financial
activities. modelling issues and their connections with the SMC
A motivation for studying the aforementioned topic as well as possible future investigations.
is to extend discrete-time models used in the analysis The problem that we address in our article may be
of subprime credit (see, e.g., Altug and Labadie, 1994; stated as follows.
Chami and Cosimano, 2001) to a more general class of
models. Despite the extent of the existing literature on Problem 1 (Modelling of bank leverage profit under
these issues, the use of discrete-time banking models mortgage loan securitization): Can we construct a Levy
Dynamic modelling of bank leverage profit under loan securitization 1471
process-based model to describe bank leverage profit where a ¼ E½L1 ; ðb Zt Þ0t is a Brownian
under mortgage loan securitization? (‘Bank leverage motion with SD, b  0. From Equation 2 it follows
profit under mortgage loan securitization’). that
Z
dLt ¼ a dt þ b dZt þ   e
yMðdt; dyÞ
II. Subprime Banking Models <

In this section, we first discuss SMC. Then we construct Furthermore, we have that
a stochastic model of the bank leverage profit under
securitization of a pool of mortgage loans. To model
e
Mðdt; dyÞ ¼ Mðdt; dyÞ  ðdyÞdt;
the uncertainty associated with these items, we consider
the filtered probability space, ð; F; ðF t Þ0tT ; PÞ,
throughout. is the compensated Poisson random measure on
[0, 1) · < \ {0} related to Lt, M (dt, du) is the Poisson
random measure on <+ · < \ {0} with intensity mea-
Subprime mortgage credit
sure dt · . Here dt is the Lebesgue measure and  is the
Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

In this subsection, we consider the mortgage loans, Levy measure. The measure dt ·  (or sometimes just )
loan losses, credit ratings, mortgage loan guarantees is called the compensator of M (dt, dy).
and securitization in the context of the SMC. Because of the expenses related to monitoring and
screening, we assume that subprime mortgage loans
incur a constant marginal cost, c . Then the stochastic
Subprime mortgage loans. A subprime mortgage dynamics of the subprime mortgage loan price pro-
loan is a loan granted to mortgagors who do not cess, P, may be described via a geometric Levy
qualify for market interest rates owing to various process as
risk factors, such as income level, size of the down
 Z 
payment made, credit history and employment status. e
dPt ¼ Pt t dt þ t dZt þ t yt Mðdt; dyÞ ð3Þ
Approximately 80% of US mortgages issued in the <
last 5 years to subprime mortgagors were Adjustable-
Rate Mortgages (ARMs). When US house prices where t ¼ rt  ct þ at , t ¼ t bt and t ¼ t  t
began to decline in 2006–2007, refinancing became are the total expected return, volatility and constant
more difficult and as ARMs began to reset at higher jump coefficient, respectively. In addition, Zt is a stan-
rates, mortgage delinquencies soared. Securities dard Brownian motion with respect to a filtration,
backed with subprime mortgages, widely held by ðF t Þt0 , of the probability space ð; F; ðF t Þ0tT ; PÞ.
financial firms, lost most of their value. The result
has been a large decline in the capital of many banks
and US government-sponsored enterprises (e.g. Subprime mortgage loan losses. In this subsection,
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) and a tightening of we discuss random (unexpected) primary and second-
credit around the world. ary mortgage loan losses. In addition, we shall express
In the sequel, we suppose that, after providing the total unexpected mortgage loan losses as the sum
liquidity, the bank lends in the form of subprime of primary and secondary losses. The settlement pro-
mortgage loans, t, at the bank’s own adjustable loan cess related, for instance, to securitization during the
rate, rt . This loan rate, for profit-maximizing banks, is SMC may also involve multiple losses in the form of
determined as follows: write-downs, restitution, legal liability, fines and
others. For example, the bankruptcy of Lehman
et ¼ rt  rt ð1Þ Brothers (due to primary losses) caused secondary
losses via a depreciation in the price of commercial
where rt is the base rate and et is the risk premium. real estate. Fears of the bank liquidating its holdings
In the sequel, we define the Levy–Itô decomposition in such real estate led to other holdings being sold in
associated with the subprime mortgage loans by anticipation. Furthermore, many banks, real estate
investment trusts and hedge funds suffered significant
Zt Z secondary losses during the SMC as a result of mort-

Lt ¼ a t þ b 
Zt þ  e
yMðds; dyÞ ð2Þ gage payment defaults or mortgage asset devaluation
0 < (primary losses).
1472 M. A. Petersen et al.
In the sequel, we assume that both unexpected their subprime mortgage loans and hence to calculate
primary and secondary losses are recorded at the minimum capital requirements. In the sequel,
times
; 0  ðtÞ  1;
0 ¼ T0 <T1 <T2 <T3 <   
is a credit rating compensatory term that coincides with
where the corresponding unexpected primary and the actual rating of the subprime mortgage loans by a
secondary losses amounts are described by the non- Credit Rating Agency. In principle, the value of rises
negative random variables l p1 <l p2 <l p3 <    and when perceived credit risk (probability of default) is low
l s1 <l s2 <l s3 <    , respectively. In particular, we and decreases when perceived credit risk is high.
call these random variables the size of unexpected However, in general, there is substantial evidence to
primary and secondary losses. Let suggest that credit rating changes exhibit procyclical
behaviour or systematic variation (see, e.g., Borio et al.,
Nt ¼ supfn  1 : Tn <tg; supðÞ;0 2001). This phenomenon accentuates the difference
between perceived and actual credit risk. For instance,
be the number of mortgage loan losses recorded dur- in the period before the SMC, procyclicality caused the
ing the interval [0, t]. The aggregate unexpected mort- value of to rise even though actual credit risk was high.
Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

gage loan losses is modelled by a compound Poisson


process as Subprime mortgage loan guarantees. The investment
 in MBSs may yield substantial returns but may also
Spt þ Sst ; Nt >0 result in losses as suggested in section ‘Subprime
St ¼ ð4Þ
0; Nt ¼ 0 mortgage loan losses.’ The party that suffers from
these losses are the investors in MBSs. In this regard,
where our dynamic model allows for mortgage loan losses
for which guarantee payments against loan losses can
X
Nt X
Nt be made. In other words, we assume that in the process
Spt lpj s
t ; St ¼ Ssjt and St ¼ Spt þ Sst of servicing the MBSs, the bank pays guarantee fees to
j¼1 j¼1
the guarantor. When a mortgagor defaults, the guar-
X
Nt X
Nt
antor covers the mortgage loan losses faced by inves-
¼ lmj
t ¼ ðlpj sj
t þ lt Þ
j¼1 j¼1
tors in MBSs. The accompanying default risk is
modelled as a compound Poisson process where N e is
Here ðlmn Þn2N is a sequence, independent of N, of a Poisson process with a deterministic frequency para-
meter, (t). Here, N e is stochastically independent of
positive i.i.d. random variables with a distribution
function F and a mean  = E[lm] , 1, modelling the Brownian motion, Z, given in Equation 3.
the values of the unexpected mortgage loan losses. Furthermore, we assume that the guarantee for mort-
The times between mortgage loan losses gage loan losses takes the form of a continuous con-
tribution that can be expressed as
Tn  Tn1 ; n1
½1  ðuÞ ðuÞE½Gu ðSs Þ ð5Þ
are i.i.d. exponentially distributed random variables
with parameter  . 0. The processes (Tn)n1 and where  is given as above, Ss is the secondary mortgage
(lmn)n1 are independent. It follows that the unexpected loan losses and Gt is the actual guarantee for such loan
mortgage loan loss number process, N = (Nt)t0, losses. This means that if the investor suffers a loss of
is a homogeneous Poisson process with an intensity Ss = l at time t, the guarantee, Gt(l), covers these losses.
 . 0, i.e., The actual manner in which the bank pays the guaran-
tee for mortgage loan losses can differ greatly.
ðtÞi
PðNt ¼ iÞ ¼ expftg ; i ¼ 0; 1; 2; . . . Bank leverage profit under mortgage loan
i!
securitization
so that (St)t0 is a compound Poisson process. Following the work in Fouche et al. (2008), let

represent the fraction of securitized mortgage loans.


Credit ratings. Concerns about credit ratings have Then 1 –
denotes the fraction of unsecuritized mort-
resurfaced during the SMC, where banks have been gage loans, where
[0, 1]. In the sequel, when
= 0
allowed to use ratings to determine the risk attached to then 100% of a portfolio of mortgage loans is
Dynamic modelling of bank leverage profit under loan securitization 1473
unsecuritized. On the other hand, if
= 1, then 100% III. Dynamic Subprime Modelling Issues
of the mortgage loan portfolio is securitized as in the and their Connections with the Subprime
case of true-sales securitization. Mortgage Crisis
In the securitization process, the bank sells the pool
of mortgage loans to the investors at the transaction In this section, we briefly discuss some issues ema-
(securitization) cost, cs. By prior agreement, the inves- nating from the subprime banking models and their
tor will be entitled to part of the mortgage loan pay- relationship with the SMC. This crisis is character-
ments. This is as if the bank sold the interest rates on ized by shrinking liquidity in global credit markets
mortgage loans to the investors or as borrowing and banking systems. A downturn in the US hous-
against the pool of mortgage loans. As was mentioned ing market, risky practices by lenders and borrowers
before, the bank collects mortgage payments; extracts and excessive individual and corporate debt levels
servicing fees, f s; pays guarantee fees (see Section have affected the world economy adversely on a
‘Subprime mortgage loan guarantees’ above) to the number of levels. The SMC has exposed pervasive
guarantor and pays the interest rate, rI, to investors. weaknesses in the global financial system and reg-
Below, we denote the mortgage loan rate by r, the ulatory framework.
rate of cash flow from the bank for financing the
portfolio of unsecuritized mortgage loans by rc, the Subprime mortgage credit
Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

total expected return by  , the marginal cost of


securitization by cs, the servicing fee for mortgage The risk premium, et, from Equation 1 has had a part
loans by f s, the interest rate paid to investors by rI, to play in the SMC. This premium is part of the
the fraction of securitized mortgage loans by
, the dynamic of mortgage loan price in Equation 3 via
primary mortgage loan loss by S p and the secondary the bank’s own adjustable loan rate, rt , and its size is
mortgage loan loss by Ss. In this case, the stochastic an indication of perceived credit risk. According to a
study by the US Federal Reserve, the average differ-
model of bank leverage profit, which incorporates
ence in mortgage interest rates between subprime
both unsecuritized and securitized mortgage loans,
~ at time, u  t, may be given by (‘subprime markup’) and prime mortgages declined
,
from et = 2.8 percentage points (280 basis points) in
  2001 to et = 1.3 percentage points in 2007. In other
~ u ¼ ð
d uu  cs  fs  rIu Þ
u þ ðu  fs Þð1 
Þu
 words, the risk premium, et, required by lenders to
þIu  ½ku þ rcu   ½1  ðÞ ðuÞE½Gu ðSs Þ du offer a subprime loan declined dramatically during
þ  u dZu þ  u the aforementioned period (see, Wikipedia, 2009 e.g.,
Z for more information). This occurred even though the
e
yMðdu; eu ;
dyÞ  Sp ðu ; uÞ dN credit ratings of subprime borrowers and subprime
< loan quality declined overall during the period 2001
u  t; 0 
 1; ~ t ¼ 
 ð6Þ to 2006. In fact, this state of affairs should have had
the effect of increasing the risk premium, et, from
The stochastic model of unsecuritized bank profit, where Equation 1. However, it is clear that the combination

= 0, Gu(Ss) = 0 and ku = 0 in Equation 6 is given by of declining risk premia and credit standards is con-
sistent with boom and recession fluctuations to be
   found in credit cycles (Demyanyk and Van Hemert,
dns u  fs Þu  rcu du þ  u dZu þ  u
u ¼ ð
Z 2008).
e
yMðdu; dyÞ  Sp ðu; uÞdNeu ; During the SMC, the probability of default on
< mortgage loans was very high. As a result, the interest
u  t; ns
t ¼ ð7Þ rate on mortgage loans in Equation 3 was at an ele-
vated level. In this situation, there was a natural reduc-
In our contribution, we note the special case of bank tion in the demand for mortgage loans. On other
leverage profit under true-sales securitization, where words, a high interest rate deterred potential bor-

= 1 and rc = 0 in Equations 6 and 7. Here, we have that rowers (individuals, businesses and corporations)
from applying for mortgage loans. On the other
hand, when the probability of default is lower, the

du ¼ ðu  cs  fs  rIu Þu þ Iu  ku  ½1  ðuÞ mortgage loan demand will increase as it would not
cost much for the borrowers to obtain loans (due to
ðuÞE½Gu ðSs Þdu þ  u dZu þ  u
Z lower interest rates).
e
yMðdu; dyÞSp ðIIu ; uÞdN eu ; u  t; IIt ¼ ð8Þ A combination of factors resulting from the SMC
< have led to problems in the commercial real estate
1474 M. A. Petersen et al.
2 T
market as regards to loan demand. According to Z
t; 4
the National Association of Realtors there was a Jð ; tÞ ¼ max E expfr ðu  tÞgUð1Þ ðku Þdu
fkt ;t g
slowing in the commercial real estate market due to t
tightening credit and sluggish growth, the former a #
direct result of the SMC. Although capital remained r ð2Þ
þ expf ðT  tÞgU ðT Þ
available for residential loans, the credit crunch was
pronounced in commercial lending (see, e.g.,
Wikipedia, 2009 for more information). where U(1) and U(2) are increasing, concave utility
functions and r . 0 is the rate at which the utility
functions of the rate of cash outflow and terminal
Bank leverage profit under mortgage loan profit are discounted. In addition, we could also
securitization extend our study by incorporating banking regula-
In the previous section ‘Bank leverage profit under tion via the Basel II Capital Accord (Basel
mortgage loan securitization,’ we have seen that the Committee on Banking Supervision, 2006; Fouche
dynamic model of bank profit given by Equation 8 et al., 2008) because there is a strong connection
involves credit ratings and guarantee payment. In between asset securitization and minimum capital
this regard, our model shows that when the credit regulatory requirements.
Downloaded by [Columbia University] at 19:41 14 November 2014

ratings, (t), is high then the guarantee payment is


low because high credit ratings mean that a low
credit risk is associated with the MBSs. Low credit
References
risk will create liquidity in the credit market as
everyone will be more willing to lend. This liquidity Altug, S. and Labadie, P. (1994) Dynamic Choice and Asset
Markets, Academic Press, San Diego, CA.
will cause some of the financial institutions to more Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006) International
readily lend to subprime mortgagors because of convergence of capital measurement and capital stan-
competition in the credit market. During the SMC, dards: a revised framework. Bank for International
a depreciation of house prices also contributed to a Settlements. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/
bcbs107.pdf/ (accessed 17 June 2009).
decline in the profits of many banks in the USA. In Borio, C., Furfine, C. and Lowe, P. (2001) Procyclicality of
this regard, profits at the 8533 US banks insured the financial system and financial stability: issues and
by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation fell policy options. Working Paper, Bank for International
from $35.2 billion to $646 million (effectively by Settlements. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/
bppdf/bispap01a.pdf (accessed 17 June 2009).
89%) during fourth quarter of 2007 when compared
Chami, R. and Cosimano, T. F. (2001) Monetary policy with
with the previous year. This was largely because of a touch of Basel, International Monetary Fund,
escalating loan losses and provisions for loan losses. Working Paper WP/01/151.
This decline in profits contributed to the worst bank Demirgüc-Kunt, A. and Detragiache E. (1999) Monitoring
and thrift quarterly performance since 1990. In banking sector fragility: a multivariate logit approach.
IMF Working Paper No. 106.
2007, these banks earned approximately $100 billion, Demyanyk, Y. and Van Hemert, O. (2008) Understanding the
which represented a decline of 31% from the record subprime mortgage crisis. Available at SSRN: http://
profit of $145 billion in 2006. Profits decreased ssrn.com/abstract=1020396 (accessed 19 August 2008).
from $35.6 billion to $19.3 billion during the first Fouche, C. H., Mukuddem-Petersen, J., Petersen, M. A. and
Senosi, M. C. (2008) Bank valuation and its connections
quarter of 2008 versus the previous year, a decline
with the subprime mortgage crisis and Basel II Capital
of 46%. Accord, Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2008,
In future, the dynamic model 8 could possibly be Article ID 740845, 44 pp.
used to study an optimal securitization problem, Mukuddem-Petersen, J., Petersen, M. A., Schoeman, I. M.
which aims to optimize the rate of cash outflow, and Tau, B. A. (2008) Dynamic modelling of bank
profits, Applied Economics Letters, 1, 1–5.
k, and bank’s investment in MBSs, , for a fixed Wikipedia: The Free Encyclopedia (2009) Subprime
term [t, T]. In this case, the objective function may Mortgage Crisis. Available at http://en.wikipedia.org/
be given as wiki/subprime_mortgage_crisis (accessed 15 April 2009).

You might also like