You are on page 1of 9

Modeling Technological Change in Economic Models of Climate Change

A Löschel, Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim, Germany; University of Heidelberg, Heidelberg, Germany
M Schymura, Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim, Germany
ã 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Introduction technological progress in climate policy assessment models


have been achieved.
Assessment of climate change mitigation policies depends The purpose of this article is threefold. First the aim is to
mainly on three nonmutually exclusive modeling decisions. sketch the different options for modeling technological change
First, the discount rate to be used is critical as costs are incurred on both a microeconomic and a macroeconomic level, where
today and long-term benefits occur in the future. A low (high) the main focus lies on large-scale macroeconomic models. The
discount rate favors immediate (delayed) action. Second, mod- second objective is to give an overview of the different models
elers must decide how to handle the uncertainties related to the surrounding climate change and energy economics. How is
problem of climate change. This debate was revived by the technological change implemented in the models? How does
literature dealing with Martin Weitzman’s ‘dismal theorem,’ this affect the results? What efforts have been made to endo-
stating that the unknown unknowns could be too large for genize the technological progress previously treated as exoge-
cost–benefit analysis of long-term climate policy measures. nous? And the final aim is to present a brief discussion of open
Third, modelers must determine an appropriate treatment of research issues.
technological change in modeling of climate policy. This article is structured as follows. After this introduction,
Climate change, climate policy measures, and technological different ways to model technological change in climate-
change are highly intertwined matters. In general, the close energy-economy models are presented: exogenous technical
relationship lies in negative and positive economic externali- change, which relies heavily on the assumption of autonomous
ties. On the level of an individual firm as well as on a more energy efficiency improvements (AEEIs); semiendogenous
global scale, pollution and climate change are negative exter- specifications of backstop technologies; and endogenous speci-
nalities and, as Nicholas Stern noted, “must be regarded as fications of technological change via (price) inducement, invest-
market failure on the greatest scale the world has seen.” On ment in R&D, spillover effects resulting from innovations, and
the other hand, the generation of knowledge represents a finally learning-by doing. These ‘classical’ modeling approaches
positive externality. Knowledge often has the character of a are extended to endogenous technical change by a discussion of
public good, even more if this knowledge is general and directed technical change. The mechanisms described play a
usable by many firms. Nelson referred to the problem of crucial role in the understanding of why the exogenous treat-
externalities due to the public good character of knowledge. ment of technological change could be an oversimplification,
Hence, Adam Smith’s famous invisible hand allows too much leading to ‘black box’ results. Finally, a conclusion is drawn with
of the negative externality of pollution and provides too little suggestions for future research efforts, such as more careful
of the positive externality of new technology. The appropriate incorporation of uncertainties, consideration of potential path-
modeling of both is a crucial decision each modeler has to dependence and lock-in situations, and more realistic modeling
make. Many empirical studies have demonstrated the sensitiv- with respect to heterogeneity of firms and their investment
ity of long-term analysis to assumptions about technological decisions.
change. In the 1990s, most economic modeling was done
under the assumption of exogenous technological change sim-
ply happening. These models are unable to capture and exam- Technological Change and Economic Modeling
ine important links between policy and technical change. So
Bottom-Up Modeling
taking technical change as given could be an oversimplification
of this complex topic, leading to the precipitation of conclu- Modeling the impacts of climate policy on the economy, the
sions. The wider literature acknowledged that technical change energy system, and on the environment can be conducted from
is not autonomous and that it is possible to identify processes two basic perspectives. The first way, called ‘bottom-up,’ em-
(such as governmental research and development (R&D) phasizes a very detailed description of the technological treat-
spending, private sector investments, and economies of scale) ment of the energy system, treating the rest of the economic
that are responses to market conditions, expectations, and structure in a rudimentary way. By doing so, models of this
governmental regulatory standards. Important insights from type are often partial equilibrium models, focusing on the
innovation research can explain how innovations occur and energy sector and not taking into account potential repercus-
new technologies diffuse. These insights are of high impor- sion effects of climate policy measures on the rest of the econ-
tance because they may affect the optimal degree, nature, and omy. They use a large set of energy technologies, for example,
timing of abatement measures. To capture these developments, based on information provided by engineers, in order to rep-
models incorporating endogenous technological change were resent possible substitutions of one energy technology for
developed, but the empirical base for the linkage between another at the primary and final energy level, process improve-
environmental policy and technical change was weak. In the ments, or energy savings (incremental technical change).
past few years, significant improvements in the description of Furthermore, they allow for new technologies to suddenly

Encyclopedia of Energy, Natural Resource and Environmental Economics http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-12-375067-9.00063-2 89


90 Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change

Table 1 Summary of the different modeling approaches

Type Focus Technical change Models

Bottom-up
Energy system Exogenous, learning-by-doing, snapshots MARKAL, MESSAGE, POLES
Top-down
Macroeconometric Economy DGEM
Computable general Economy Exogenous, learning-by-doing, backstops, PACE, GTEM, GEM-E3, MIT-
equilibrium directed technical change EPPA, DEMETER
Integrated assessment Economy and energy system and DICE, WITCH, ENTICE, RICE,
environment PAGE

appear and penetrate the market (snapshot approach) and and damage functions. Examples of such models are the pop-
hence, in part, for radical technical change. These new technol- ular models of the DICE/RICE family, WITCH, MERGE, PAGE,
ogies and their penetration of the market are then based on and FUND (Table 1).
their costs and performance characteristics. In bottom-up
approaches, the final energy demand (or emission reduction
target) is usually determined outside the model and the model
tries to find the least-cost solution to satisfy the given con- Exogenous Technical Change
straints. Exemplary of this type of models are the MARKAL,
MESSAGE, and POLES families of models. The exogenous modeling of technological change is a very
common approach in the empirical assessment of long-term
climate change policy evaluation. Here, technological change
is represented as (exogenous) improvements of energy effi-
Top-Down Approaches
ciency. One can interpret technical change in such a framework
The second possible way, called ‘top-down,’ emphasizes a as being a function solely of the time that passes. In the case of
detailed description of the economy (e.g., a higher sectoral exogeneity, technological change is independent of policy
resolution, production structures, and interdependencies) measures such as a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade scheme for
and neglects particularly detailed information on the techno- emissions permits. Another modeling strategy of exogenous
logical issues of the energy system. The class of top-down technical change can be the implementation of a (known but
models can be subdivided into three different categories, very expensive) ‘backstop’ technology, a notion that was
namely, macroeconometric models, computable general equi- subtly hinted at in Hotelling’s seminal paper on resource eco-
librium (CGE) models, and integrated assessment models nomics, introduced formally by the equally seminal contribu-
(IAMs). tion by Dasgupta and Heal and labeled backstop technology by
Macroeconometric models are usually based on long-run Nordhaus. For instance, the technology of harnessing solar
time-series data and, hence, have a sound empirical base. They energy, fusion power, or carbon capture and sequestration
employ econometrically estimated equations without relying (CCS) can be perceived as a backstop technology to oil, coal,
on equilibrium assumptions. They are very rich in economic and natural gas. Both possibilities of modeling exogenous
detail and the traditional models follow a neo-Keynesian the- technical change, the AEEI and the ‘semiendogenous’ backstop
oretical approach assuming a demand-driven structure and the technology approach are frequently used.
possibility of underutilization of productive capacity. Exogenous growth theory has its roots in the work of Solow.
Therefore, they are especially suited for short-term and me- The easiest approach to technical change is to assume that
dium-term forecasting. Hicks-neutral productivity improvements determine the over-
CGE models are a widely used tool in the evaluation of all progress of the economy. Such an approach neglects the
climate policy measures. They are well-understood Arrow– possibility of technological progress enhancing the energy ef-
Debreu models that include the interaction of consumers, pro- ficiency of inputs. Many approaches to the economics of cli-
ducers, prices, markets, and repercussion effects from various mate change have, therefore, assumed a decoupling of
different policies. Most often, the household preferences and economic growth and energy use via an exogenous AEEI,
the production side are depicted by constant elasticity of decoupled from any policy decisions and price developments.
substitution functions. Their focus lies mainly on a detailed In more disaggregated models, such as IAMs or CGE models,
and structural picture of the economy and a large coverage of the AEEI parameter can be incorporated in a more sophisti-
countries. Models of this type are, for example, PACE, GTEM, cated manner. In this case, the AEEI depicts both technological
GEM-E3, MIT-EPPA, or DEMETER. progress and structural changes in the economy. Jacoby and
Finally, IAMs of climate change take the most comprehen- others use different AEEI parameters for different regions in the
sive approach toward the evaluation of climate change policies world in their MIT-EPPA model. Richels and Blanford investi-
by taking into account the impacts of particular policy mea- gate the role of technological progress in decarbonizing the US
sures and technological developments on the climate. They economy. To conduct sensitivity analysis, they use three differ-
incorporate climate-economy or climate-energy submodules ent values for the AEEI: a pessimistic value of 0, a moderate 0.8
Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change 91

based on historical observations, and an optimistic value of 1.


Technological Change in Large-Scale and Aggregated
As it turns out, the impact of different values for the AEEI is
Environmental Models
quite substantial with no growth for primary energy use until
2050 for 1, a slight increase for 0.8, and a 50% increase for 0. Price-induced technological change
The advantage of using the AEEI approach is obvious: it is The concept of (price-)induced innovations was first intro-
simple and transparent, and can be used with ease to perform duced by Hicks. Changes in relative factor prices cause firms
sensitivity analysis. A major problem of the AEEI is the ‘black to introduce technological change in production in order to
box’ character of technological change, which ignores price reduce the input of the factor that has become relatively more
inducements and innovation decisions and makes it difficult expensive. In practice, however, it is sometimes hard to dis-
to distinguish between technical progress and long-term price tinguish between factor price induced innovation and factor
effects. Another problem of the AEEI approach is the exclusion substitution. Assume, for example, the ‘putty-clay’ situation
of radical technical change by relying on incremental techno- where a firm is unable to substitute factors in the short run,
logical progress only. Given large technological uncertainties, for instance, because of the high costs of changing the pro-
this is not always a realistic assumption and new technologies duction technology. R&D also takes time so that factor input
can suddenly appear as a shock instead. relations remain constant despite changing relative input
A further step toward endogenizing technical change is the prices. Von Weizsäcker argues that in such a case, “. . . substi-
introduction of backstop technologies. These technologies are tution takes time and it can therefore not strictly be distin-
usually carbon-free energy sources that might be already guished from technical progress.” Salter arrives at an even
known but are not in commercial usage today. Modeling the stronger conclusion, stating that “it is simply a matter of
supply of a backstop technology is relatively simple as one words whether one terms new techniques of this character
needs only to determine the marginal cost hurdle and the inventions or a form of factor substitution.” After the two oil
date from which the technology will be available in the future. crises in 1973 and 1979, energy-saving technological change
In top-down models, it is usual to modify the production received a lot of interest from both politics and science. A
function to include the new backstop technology. However, strand of literature emerged dealing with the question
careful modeling in top-down models is necessary; otherwise, whether increasing energy prices also induced technical
the market will be completely dominated by the new technol- change to find cleaner production technologies. Kennedy,
ogy, whereas in reality, the old energy supply technology and von Weizsäcker, and Ahmad have formalized the qualitative
the new backstop technology will certainly coexist for a partic- argument postulated by Hicks and Binswanger. Ruttan offers
ular period in time. A solution to avoid such an unrealistic a comprehensive survey of the empirical literature of these
structural break in the model would be to limit the penetration early years. Owing to the increasing public awareness of cli-
rate of the newly available technology, and hence, treat the mate change, energy-saving technological change is again
‘old’ outputs and ‘new’ outputs as imperfect substitutes. receiving a lot of attention. Empirical studies investigating
Similar to the AEEI parameterization, this approach is partly the relationship between energy prices and technological pro-
dissatisfying. Because it is not possible to predict the specific gress are, for example, the seminal contribution by Popp or,
details and costs of possible new technology options that will more recently, research by Abadie and Camoro into carbon
be accessible in the far distant future, simplifying assumptions pricing and its effects on technology. In the case of applied
have to be made with regard to, for example, the resource economic models of price-induced technical change, rising
demand for the backstop technology, potential other negative energy prices induce technical change, which then leads to
environmental effects of such a technology, and so on. Sue energy efficiency improvements, most commonly conceptu-
Wing calls the backstop methodology semiendogenous be- alized through a productivity parameter tied to historic and/
cause of the fact that the backstop is exogenously specified by or current energy prices or through an earlier diffusion of
the modeler: the technology does not need to be developed energy-efficient technologies.
but its appearance is dependent on the (endogenously) deter- Several studies mainly employ the price-induced hypothe-
mined energy price. Additionally, it is often assumed that sis. In ICAM-3 (IAM), Dowlatabadi estimates the welfare costs
the cost of the backstop is decreasing at an exogenous rate or of different climate policies until 2010. Exogenous technolog-
due to learning-by-doing as, for example, in work by Manne ical change (through AEEI) is combined with price-induced
and Richards. Popp employs a further endogenization of the technological change (called ‘price-induced efficiency (PIE)’).
backstop technology and shows the importance of assump- This approach replaces the original AEEI as a more realistic
tions concerning the backstop price on welfare effects. assumption with respect to the development of energy effi-
ciency and energy prices. Depending on the model scenario
(learning-by-doing was also included in some runs), the dif-
Endogenous Technological Change ferences between exogenous and PIE models are significant.
While the purely exogenous treatment of technological im-
A considerable amount of research has been done in the past provement leads to a welfare loss of 0.23%, the corresponding
few years on endogenizing technological change. The efforts to loss is 0.14% when price-induced energy efficiency improve-
endogenize technological change can be roughly subdivided ments are taken into account, although energy use and also
into four parts, namely, price-induced technological change in emissions are substantially higher in the second model runs.
the spirit of Hicks, learning-by-doing introduced by Arrow, “[B]ut the costs of abatement are on a par [. . .], simply because
expenditures and subsidies of R&D, and, finally, directed tech- purposive technical change makes policy interventions more
nical change formalized by Acemoglu. potent,” notes Dowlatabadi.
92 Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change

The GTEM (CGE) by Jakeman and others investigates four these externalities in making investment decisions, and thus,
commitment periods until 2027. They compare their reference underinvests in knowledge capital from a social welfare per-
case (without price-induced technical change and without cli- spective. In Otto, Löschel, and Reilly, the authors investigated
mate policy measures) to a case with climate policy measures the effects of directed technical change on differentiated
included in the Kyoto Protocol (emissions trading and the climate policies. They calibrated their model on the Dutch
Clean Development Mechanism) and no price inducement as economy and ran three different climate policy simu-
well as a case with policy measures and price inducement. The lations. First, they investigated differentiated CO2 emission
authors assume a constant and fixed amount of technical constraints. Then, they analyzed differentiated R&D subsidies.
change in each of the nine modeled regions and over the And finally, they explored the effects of efficient combinations
whole time horizon. For 2010, they find a carbon price of US of both. They found that optimally differentiated R&D subsi-
$115 (2002) without price-induced effects and a substantially dies achieve a 10% reduction in CO2 emissions and simulta-
lower price of US$88 with price-induced effects, concluding neously improve the welfare of the Dutch economy by about
that “incorporating the induced innovations hypothesis results 11% relative to the reference case. These positive welfare effects
in a stronger bias in technical change toward economizing on until 2025 are even larger in the case of optimally differenti-
the use of inputs that create emissions.” ated R&D subsidies in combination with differentiated CO2
However, the inclusion of price-induced technological emission constraints (roughly 30%). Bye and Jacobsen use the
change, although being identified as one partial explanation model of Heggendal and Jacobsen, which is described in more
for technological change, is only a first step, and alternative detail in a later section, to investigate the effect of directed
ways of modeling technological change, as, for example, R&D technical change toward CCS in Norway. The authors find
or learning-by-doing, have been introduced in climate-energy- that, given a low carbon tax, reallocating R&D support to
economy models. These approaches are presented in the fol- general R&D improves welfare, while reallocating R&D sup-
lowing subsections. port to CCS R&D reduces welfare. The main reasons are de-
creasing returns to both scale and knowledge, which together
Directed technical change contribute to dampening the positive welfare effects of the
In 2002, Acemoglu revived the debate about induced and CCS-directed subsidy.
endogenous technological change with his model of directed Some cautious conclusions, which are relevant for the
technical change, in general and in the environmental case, in whole debate on directed technical change, have to be drawn:
particular. In his model, the same goods can be produced using “The difficulty, however, is how to design such technology
either clean or dirty technologies, and firms typically select the policy in reality. . . . So, the answer depends in part on perspec-
more profitable of the two because of profit maximization. As tive and in large part on the confidence one has that public
long as the dirty technology enjoys an initial installed base policy can effectively direct R&D.”
advantage, innovations will focus on further improvements
to the dirty technology. To put it differently, people prefer to Learning-by-doing
work at what they already know and the clean technology may The third possibility of introducing endogenous technical
never be used at all unless the government decides to intervene. change is the concept of technology learning. Such learning
Governments, therefore, need to influence not only the alloca- was first observed by aeronautic engineers in the 1930s. They
tion of production between clean and dirty activities but also found that as the quantity of manufactured units doubles, the
the allocation of R&D between clean and dirty innovation. number of direct labor hours it takes to produce an individual
This means that not one but two major issues must be dealt unit decreases at a uniform rate. In economics, technology
with: the standard negative environmental externality gener- learning was formalized by Arrow, and its empirical implica-
ated by polluting production activities as well as the fact that tions are still under investigation. Introducing a new technol-
past or current technological advances in dirty technologies ogy (e.g., CCS) can be very costly at the beginning, but as
make future production and innovation in clean technologies industries or individuals gain experience by using the new
relatively less profitable. Therefore, Acemoglu introduced the technology, its costs decline. The Boston Consultancy Group
approach of ‘directed’ technological change. Such a directed operationalized Arrow’s concept of learning-by-doing by intro-
technological change perspective introduces a new cost–benefit ducing experience or learning curves, which describe techno-
analysis to policy intervention. The cost of supporting cleaner logical progress as a function of accumulating experience (e.g.,
technologies is that this may slow down growth in the short measured by cumulative output) with either production
run, as cleaner technologies are initially less advanced. But (learning-by-doing in industries) or use (learning-by-doing
supporting cleaner technologies might bring about less dirty for consumers). One crucial decision the modeler has to
growth in the long run. make concerns the functional form and shape of the learning
A number of studies employ this directed technical change curve for a particular technology. Technology learning can
approach. The CGE models include technical change in the be segmented in different phases. While high learning rates
form of innovation possibility frontiers (IPFs), which describe can be observed in the research, development, and deployment
the investment in knowledge capital in different sectors and, phase, learning rates become lower in the commercialization
therefore, treat knowledge capital as sector specific. Technical (diffusion) phase. When the situation of market saturation is
change is ‘directed’ to a specific sector if its investment in reached, the learning rate may even drop to zero. The interested
knowledge capital increases relative to other sectors. They reader is referred to the surveys dealing with learning/experi-
also take into account the positive externality characteristic of ence curves in the energy sector carried out by Neij and Ferioli,
R&D so that the representative producer does not consider and others.
Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change 93

As mentioned above, bottom-up energy system models Studies relying on IAMs have been conducted, for example,
strongly emphasize the energy sector and the emissions oc- by Manne and Richels with their MERGE (IAM) or Alberth and
curring from energy production and consumption. Such de- Hope with PAGE2002 (IAM). Manne and Richels employ the
tailed modeling of the energy sector allows taking into MERGE IAM to evaluate the implications of learning-by-doing
account specific characteristics of different energy technolo- on climate policy until 2100. The authors include, besides
gies such as learning or experience curves. A variety of exogenous technological progress in more conventional tech-
bottom-up models have integrated technological change via nologies (e.g., pulverized coal without CO2 recovery), the en-
learning-by-doing. Examples are the TIMES model and the dogenous technology learning aspect in various ways. First,
closely related MARKAL and MESSAGE models. All models they incorporate learning-by-doing for the case of a carbon-
are very similar in their structure and their treatment of tech- free backstop technology. Their approach allows learning-by-
nological change. All models include learning-by-doing for doing through cumulative experience with this technology.
several technologies. They also allow ‘clustered learning,’ The authors assume that learning costs decline by 20% for
where several technologies use the same key technology (or every doubling of cumulative experience, that learning-by-
component), which in turn is itself subject to learning so that doing is based on global diffusion, and that the growth of
these models can take into account technology spillover ef- experience in one region will reduce the costs of a technology
fects. And finally, they also allow incorporation of technology in all regions (spillover effects). In order to conduct sensitivity
learning for technologies that are truly global (e.g., turbines analysis, the authors also assume two different cost scenarios
or innovations in the steel industry) in the sense that the same for the backstop technology (low-cost and high-cost). Further-
(or close to the same) technology rather rapidly becomes more, the authors allow for learning effects in other nonelectric
commercially available worldwide. In this way, global expe- sectors. The capital structure in the MERGE model can be
rience benefits worldwide users of the technology and learn- described as ‘putty-clay’ as ‘introduction and decline con-
ing creates global spillovers. Other examples of bottom-up straints are placed on new technologies. We assume that the
models using the learning-by-doing mechanism are the production from new technologies in each region is con-
PRIMES model and the POLES model. Capros and Mantzos, strained to 1% of the total production in the year in which it
for example, evaluate the Kyoto Protocol under three different is initially introduced and can increase by a factor of three for
scenarios of learning. The first implies no learning: the au- each decade thereafter. The decline rate is limited to 2% per
thors assume a lack of perception of emission reduction tar- year for new technologies, but there is no decline rate limit for
gets and, therefore, those targets do not affect decisions on existing technologies.’ This prevents situations in which a
new equipment. Then a scenario of normal learning is carbon-free backstop technology penetrates the market in
adopted. And finally, a fast-learning scenario is considered, a very rapid and seemingly unrealistic way. The results from
where consumers are assumed to fully understand the oppor- the empirical exercise of Manne and Richards show mixed
tunities offered by new technologies and are willing to as- evidence for the effects of learning-by-doing. When the authors
sume the corresponding opportunity costs without taking include a high price for the backstop technology, the effects on
into consideration issues related to technology maturity and global emissions are close to the effect with no learning-by-
reliability. The authors compare the costs of meeting the doing. But the learning-by-doing mechanism can at least help
Kyoto targets and find that in the fast-learning scenario, to substantially lower the costs of climate policy (by approx-
these costs are substantially lower than in the case without imately 42%, or from about UD$4 trillion to about US$2
learning, with approximately €19 billion and a carbon price trillion). If the low-cost backstop price is assumed, greenhouse
of €190 per tonne versus approximately €7 billion and a gas emissions will increase until 2070 and then drop to 20% of
carbon price of €117 per tonne of CO2, respectively. the level of the no learning-by-doing (high-cost) scenario. The
A study within the framework of CGE modeling that em- costs of climate policy are then cut back by about 72% to
ploys the learning-by-doing mechanism has been conducted approximately US$1 trillion.
by Gerlagh and van der Zwaan. The authors use the bottom-up Alberth and Hope use the PAGE2002 model (also used by
CGE model DEMETER, which has a detailed economic struc- Sir Nicholas Stern for his Report on the Economics of Climate
ture as well as energy-demand structure. They investigate the Change) to evaluate climate policy under a 450, 500, and
effect of a 2-degree climate policy until 2100 and compare their 550 ppm scenario and its effects on global emissions until
results which incorporate exogenous technical change (they the year 2200. The authors consider two different AEEI param-
include an AEEI parameter of 1.0% p.a.) to those with an eters (0.1% p.a. in a pessimistic case and 0.25% p.a. in a more
endogenous learning-by-doing approach “assuming [a] con- optimistic case). Furthermore, they include a learning param-
stant learning rate, which is the rate at which production eter coefficient of 0.04–0.36, which is tantamount to a learning
costs decline for each doubling of cumulative experience.” rate of 5–25%. Their approach toward sensitivity analysis is to
They find that “including endogenous innovation in a macro- incorporate two different initial experience stocks for the back-
economic model implies earlier emission reductions to meet stop technology (measured as cumulative historical CO2 abate-
carbon concentration constraints than in a model with exoge- ment realized by the carbon-free source). The authors find that
nous technological progress. We find that the effect is stronger “the three stabilisation scenarios modelled remain very similar
than suggested so far in the literature.” To briefly outline the to those of the standard PAGE2002 model. . . . The similarity of
magnitude, the costs of compliance with the 2-degree target are the two models, however, is heavily dependent on the coeffi-
a 0.19% welfare loss in the case of the exogenous specification cients used, and the sensitivity analysis further demonstrates
and a 0.06% loss in the case of endogenous technological that the learning coefficient has a strong impact on the calcu-
change (being roughly one-third of the first figure). lation of total abatement costs.”
94 Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change

However, there exist several problems with the learning-by- because the public sector might be motivated to introduce
doing approach. Learning-by-doing is often regarded as ad hoc, certain policies whereas the private sector responds to those
lacking transparency. This can be the case if there are several policies. To put it otherwise, “public R&D motivated by the
different technologies in the model (e.g., in bottom-up models), climate challenge is climate policy, whereas private R&D re-
whereby different learning rates and spillover effects are as- sponds to climate policy (e.g., prices on emissions, deploy-
sumed. Another problem can be the critical assumption “shared ment policies, R&D subsidies)”. Furthermore, R&D subsidies
by virtually all LBD studies that carbon-free technologies expe- by the government sector can help advance commercialization
rience the most rapid learning and cost reductions, while their of innovative technologies combining basic and applied re-
conventional counterparts enjoy little or no improvement. . . . search, a point taken up by Pizer and Popp. An important
Not only is this outcome quite speculative given our limited modeling issue can also be the fact that money supplied for
understanding of the association between unit cost reductions R&D is limited (as is the number of engineers and researchers)
and the diffusion of new technologies, it is virtually a pre- and increasing spending on one particular set of technologies
determined outcome of the simulation.” (such as decarbonization) can reduce or ‘crowd out’ R&D
spending on other sets of technologies such as medicine.
Research and development Investment in R&D is typically modeled via a variable
Technological change can be interpreted as an economic activ- representing R&D or knowledge, respectively. In non-
ity in which agents maximize their profits. By investing in R&D environmental models, the emphasis is usually on productivity
firms, they try to decrease production costs in the long run, and gains through research. In climate models, additional empha-
thus, establish market advantages. Following this train of sis is put on decreasing greenhouse gas emissions and reducing
thought, investment in R&D can be considered as a decision abatement costs.
about the stock of knowledge. Sue Wing and Popp, for in- The pioneering contribution incorporating R&D efforts by
stance, present an approach where knowledge is treated as Goulder and Schneider was based on a CGE model. They em-
capital, the accumulation of which is determined by its level phasize the effects of spillover effects and divide the knowledge
of investment and its depreciation rate. stock into nonexcludable knowledge (creating spillovers) and
The key problem of this view is the imperfection of knowl- appropriable knowledge. They also include a scaling factor to
edge markets. In particular, investment in R&D creates spill- determine the effect of spillovers on output. The authors find
overs, which drive a wedge between private and social returns “that the presence of endogenous technological change in their
to R&D. Spillovers from R&D, or positive technological exter- model leads to lower costs of achieving a given abatement target,
nalities, are an element of technological change strongly con- but higher gross costs of a given carbon tax.” Sue Wing extends
nected with investment in R&D. They arise when information the work of Goulder and Schneider by distinguishing between
obtained by the innovative activities of one economic agent several factors that may influence the innovation process, in
becomes public, so that other agents, not involved in the order to gain insight into the general equilibrium effects of
innovation process, profit by using this information or even these innovations. He distinguishes between ‘dirty’ and ‘clean’
copying the whole product. Since society in general benefits goods and finds that a carbon tax reduces aggregate R&D and
from spillover effects, it is now clear why social rates of return slows down the rate of technological change and output growth.
to R&D investments are higher than the private rates. Nordhaus More recently, Heggerdal and Jacobsen, using a CGE model
finds evidence for social returns of 30–70% p.a., while private calibrated on the Norwegian economy, focused on how the
returns on capital range between 6% and 15% p.a. in the timing of innovation policies affects carbon emissions until
United States. 2070. Their model contains two R&D industries. Growth takes
As Löschel finds, recent models treat knowledge as a non- place through dynamic spillovers from the accumulated knowl-
rival and not fully appropriable good. Research results cannot edge stemming from R&D production, though with decreasing
be completely predicted and R&D efforts frequently involve returns. A feature of their model is the production structure of
high costs. Both facts enhance the degree of uncertainty. Clarke R&D, which creates new patents. The patent production takes
and others call attention to the broad range of activities inher- place in two industries, one directed toward general technology
ent in R&D investments. Regarding the focus of research, they and the other toward environmental technology. The authors
distinguish basic research, that is, research focusing on funda- draw two conclusions. First, the welfare gain from subsidizing
mental scientific understanding, from applied research, which environmental R&D increases with the costs of emissions. This
attempts to improve specific technologies. Although the for- is due to the fact that the carbon tax does not induce a suffi-
mer basically deals with theoretical background work, it is not ciently large increase in private investment in environmental
free from application-oriented goals. Another distinction can R&D because of externalities in the innovation process. Second
be made with respect to the institutions funding R&D, so that and more interesting, the largest welfare gain comes from a
public research investment can be distinguished from corpo- falling time profile of subsidy rates for environmental R&D,
rate research investment. As mentioned above, private and rather than from a constant or increasing profile, when the
social rates of return usually differ greatly. Firms ‘underinvest’ economy faces increased emissions costs. ‘This means that
in R&D because they ignore the social returns. It is for this when faced with a future price on carbon, it is a better policy
reason that governments often finance research efforts. To put to take R&D action now than to distribute policy incentives
it otherwise, R&D needs to be subsidized at a rate equal to the evenly across time. The reason for this is that the innovation
marginal external benefit from knowledge spillovers. In this externalities are larger in early periods.’
circumstance, the private and social costs of R&D will become Incorporating R&D in IAMs can also be done in very differ-
the same. In climate policy models, this issue becomes relevant ent ways. Nordhaus specifies R&D expenditures in his
Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change 95

modified DICE model (R&DICE), creating an aggregate knowl- change as exogenous have been resolved, numerous questions
edge stock that has a negative effect on emission intensity (the still remain unanswered. As technological change is an uncer-
emission-output ratio). He rudimentarily accounts for spill- tain phenomenon, these uncertainties have to be incorporated
overs by assuming that the social and private returns on R&D in large-scale models more carefully. This holds particularly
diverge. Nordhaus adds R&D to his original DICE model by true for major innovations. First attempts to tackle this prob-
including an IPF in the spirit of Kennedy. His IPF relates R&D lem are the contributions by Löschel and Otto, Baker and Adu-
inputs to the carbon-energy sector. He compares his results to Bonnah, and Bosetti and others. The latter authors analyze
the earlier exogenous DICE attempts and finds that induced optimal responses to uncertainty in terms of investments in
innovation is probably less powerful in emissions reductions R&D and its implications for climate policy costs by modeling
compared to substitution. One explanation for this result innovation as a backstop technology characterized by either a
could be that Nordhaus implicitly assumes that the economy deterministic or an uncertain process. They find that uncer-
is currently on an optimal path and that any regulatory inter- tainty leads to higher optimal levels of R&D investment. An-
ference by the government must inevitably push the economy other important dimension of technical change that has to be
away from that path. Buonanno and others use the regional- taken into account is the potential for path dependency,
ized version of DICE (RICE) and extend it for endogenous inertias, and lock-in situations. Path dependency, a concept
technological change (ETC-RICE). Similar to, for example, coined by Arthur and also called ‘state dependency,’ captures
Nordhaus, they also model emission intensity as a function the notion that further technological change is dependent on
of knowledge stock that depends on R&D investment and de- prior technical change and hence that the process of technical
preciates at an exogenous rate. Additionally, the authors ac- change is inflexible in that once a dominant technology
count for knowledge spillover effects. In their empirical emerges, it might be difficult to switch to competing technol-
exercise, they evaluate climate policy under the Kyoto Protocol ogies. Environment-energy-economy models can account for
until 2100 and compare the results with exogenous technolog- such effects by careful inclusion of learning-by-doing, time
ical change to the endogenous treatment. In general, the costs lags, assumptions about the diffusion rates of innovations and
of domestic action are lower when environmental technical directed (or biased) technological change. Studies of these
change is endogenous, and they find a much larger role of effects have been conducted by Otto and Dellink, Otto and
induced innovation. However, their result is mainly driven by others, Otto and Reilly, and others. Another important aspect
the fact that “there is no potential for climate-friendly R&D to of the innovation process not appropriately accounted for is the
compete with or crowd out other R&D.” Popp investigates such heterogeneity of firms as different firms respond differently to
crowding out with his ENTICE model, also based on Nord- environmental policies. Approaches toward incorporating firm
haus’ DICE, by conducting three experiments. He simulates a heterogeneity can be found in other areas of economics, such as
scenario without crowding-out effects, which results in tremen- Melitz’ new trade theory, but the authors are not aware of
dous gains from induced innovation of 45% compared to the numerical studies incorporating such heterogeneity.
base case. Then he studies the case where 50% of other R&D is
crowded out by new energy R&D, resulting in a 9% welfare
increase. And finally, he assumes that 100% of other R&D is
crowded out, which in turn reduces the welfare gains of R&D
policies to 2%, hence emphasizing the importance of potential
Appendix: Models
crowding-out effects.
Table A1 Technical change in models
Bosetti and others use the WITCH model to explore the
effects of different innovation policies on carbon emissions Model Type Technological References
until 2100. In their 2011 article, Bosetti and others investigate change
three different innovation policies, namely, R&D in energy
efficiency; R&D in wind, solar, and carbon capture and storage; BYE2011 CGE DTC Bye and Jacobsen
and R&D in breakthrough (or backstop) technologies. An (2011)
DEMETER IAM LBD Gerlagh and van der
additional feature of their analysis is the consideration of
Zwaan (2003) and
international cooperation in R&D. The authors show that
Gerlagh (2008)
such cooperation could be accompanied by large additional DICE/RICE IAM AEEI Nordhaus (1994)
benefits (þ10% to þ30%, depending on the stringency of ENTICE IAM R&D Popp (2004)
climate policy). Their conclusion about innovation policies is ENTICE-BR IAM R&D, Popp (2005)
less optimistic than in other studies, stating that R&D policies Backstop
cannot be a substitution for pricing carbon. ETC-RICE CGE R&D, Buonnano et al. (2003)
Spillovers
FISCHER2003 CGE R&D Fischer et al. (2003)
Conclusion and Suggestions for Future Research GEM-E3 CGE AEEI Capros et al. (1997)
GOULDER CGE R&D, Goulder and Schneider
Spillovers (1999)
This survey has summarized alternative approaches toward
GOULDER2 ME LBD, R&D, Goulder and Mathai
modeling technological change in numerical models of climate Spillovers (2000)
change and the economy, and highlighted the importance of GTEM CGE PI Jakeman et al. (2004)
understanding the process of technological change. Although
many problems associated with modeling technological (Continued)
96 Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change

Table A1 (Continued) Ackerman F, DeCanio SJ, Howarth RB, and Sheeran K (2009) Limitations of integrated
assessment models of climate change. Climatic Change 95: 297–315.
Model Type Technological References Ahmad S (1966) On the theory of induced invention. The Economic Journal
change 76: 344–357.
Alberth S and Hope C (2007) Climate modeling with endogenous technical change:
HEGGERDAL CGE R&D Heggerdal and Stochastic learning and optimal greenhouse gas abatement in the PAGE2002
Jacobsen (2010) model. Energy Policy 35: 1795–1807.
Arrow K (1962) The economic implications of learning-by-doing. Review of Economic
IMAGE IAM AEEI, PIEEI Alcamo et al. (1998)
Studies 29: 155–173.
MARKAL- ES LBD Loulou et al. (2004) Arthur WB (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical
(MACRO) events. The Economic Journal 99: 116–131.
MERGE2004 IAM AEEI, LBD, Manne and Richels Arthur WB (1994) Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor,
Backstops (2004) MI: University of Michigan Press.
MERGE2008 IAM AEEI, PIEEI Richels and Blanford Ayres RU and Warr B (2009) The Economic Growth Engine. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
(2008) Publishing Limited.
MESSAGE– ES LBD Messner and Azar C and Dowlatabadi H (1999) A review of technical change in assessment of climate
MACRO Schrattenholzer policy. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 24: 513–544.
Baker E and Adu-Bonnah K (2008) Investment in risky R&D programs in the face of
(2000)
climate uncertainty. Energy Economics 30: 465–486.
MIND IAM LBD, R&D, Edenhofer et al. (2005) Baker E, Clarke L, and Shittu E (2008) Technical change and the marginal cost of
Backstops and Held et al. (2009) abatement. Energy Economics 30(6): 2799–2816.
MIT-EPPA CGE AEEI, Jacoby et al. (2006) Baker E and Shittu E (2008) Uncertainty and endogenous technical change in climate
Backstops policy models. Energy Economics 30(6): 2817–2828.
OTTO2008A CGE DTC Otto and Reilly (2008) Binswanger HP and Ruttan VW (1978) Induced Innovation: Technology, Institutions and
and Löschel and Otto Development. Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University Press.
(2009) Böhringer C and Löschel A (2006) Promoting renewable energy in Europe: A hybrid
OTTO2008B CGE DTC Otto et al. (2008) CGE approach. The Energy Journal 123–138. Special Issue: Hybrid Modelling: New
Answers to Old Challenges.
PACE CGE AEEI, Böhringer (1999)
Böhringer C, Rutherford T, and Tol R (2009) The EU 20/20/2020 targets: An overview of
Backstops the EMF22 assessment. Energy Economics 31: 268–273.
PAGE2002 IAM AEEI, LBD Alberth and Hope Bosetti V, Carraro C, Massetti E, Sgobbi A, and Tavoni M (2009) Optimal energy
(2007) investment and R&D strategies to stabilize atmospheric greenhouse gas
POLES ES LBD Kouvaritakis et al. concentrations. Resource and Energy Economics 31(2): 123–137.
(2000) Bosetti V and Tavoni M (2009) Uncertain R&D, backstop technology and GHGs
PRIMES ES LBD Capros and Mantzos stabilization. Energy Economics 31: 18–26.
(2000) Bosetti V, Carraro C, Duval R, and Tavoni M (2011) What should we expect from
R&DICE IAM R&D, Nordhaus (1999) innovation? A model-based assessment of the environmental and mitigation cost
implications of climate-related R&D. Energy Economics 33(6): 1313–1320.
Spillovers
Buonanno P, Carraro C, and Galeotti M (2003) Endogenous induced technical change
SMULDERS2003 CGE R&D Smulders and de Noij and the costs of Kyoto. Resource and Energy Economics 25(1): 11–34.
(2003) Bye B and Jacobsen K (2011) Restricted carbon emissions and directed R&D
SUEWING2003 CGE R&D Sue Wing (2003) support: An applied general equilibrium analysis. Energy Economics 33(3):
TIMES ES LBD Loulou et al. (2005) 543–555.
WITCH2009 CGE/ R&D, Bosetti and Tavoni Capros P and Mantzos L (2000) Endogenous learning in European post-Kyoto
IAM Backstop (2009) and Bosetti scenarios: Results from applying the market equilibrium model primes. International
et al. (2009) Journal of Global Energy Issues 14: 249–261.
WITCH2011 CGE/ R&D, Bosetti et al. (2011) Carraro C (2002) Climate change policy: Models, controversies and strategies.
In: Tietenberg T and Folmer H (eds.) The International Yearbook of
IAM Backstop
Environmental and Resource Economics 2002/2003. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Publishing Ltd.
Abbreviations: CGE, computable general equilibrium; IAM, integrated assessment
Carraro C, Massetti E, and Nicita L (2009) How does climate policy affect technical
model; ME, macroeconometric model; ES, energy system; AEEI, autonomous energy
change? An analysis of the direction and pace of technical progress in a climate-
efficiency improvement; LBD, learning-by-doing; PI, price-induced; R&D, research and economy model. Energy Economics 30: 7–37.
development; PIEEI, price induced energy efficiency improvements; DTC, directed Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation.
technical change. Review of Economic Studies 32: 233–240.
Source: Löschel A (2002) Technological change in economic models of environmental Clarke LE, Weyant J, and Birky A (2006) On the sources of technological advance:
policy: A survey. Ecological Economics 43: 105–126; Gillingham K, Newell R, and Pizer Assessing the evidence. Energy Economics 28: 579–595.
W (2008) Modeling endogenous technological change for climate policy analysis. Clarke L, Weyant J, and Edmonds J (2008) On the sources of technological change:
Energy Economics 30(6): 2734–2753; Popp D, Newell RG, and Jaffe AB (2009) Energy, What do the models assume? Energy Economics 30(2): 409–424.
Dasgupta PS (2008) Discounting climate change. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty
the environment, and technological change. NBER Working Paper, No. 14832, own
37: 141–169.
supplements.
Dasgupta PS and Heal GM (1974) The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources.
Review of Economic Studies 41: 3–28.
De Cian E, Carraro C, and Nicita L (2010) Modeling Biased Technical Change. Implications
For Climate Policy. Working Papers 2010.4, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.
Further Reading Dowlatabadi H (1998) Sensitivity of climate change mitigation estimates to assumptions
about technical change. Energy Economics 20: 473–493.
Abadie L and Chamorro J (2008) European CO2 prices and carbon capture investments. Edenhofer O, Bauer N, and Kriegler E (2005) The impact of technological change on
Energy Economics 30(4): 2992–3015. climate protection and welfare: Insights from the model MIND. Ecological
Acemoglu D (2002) Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 69(4): Economics 54: 277–292.
781–809. Ferioli F, Schoots K, and van der Zwaan BC (2009) Use and limitations of learning
Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Bursztyn L, and Hemous D (2012) The environment and curves for energy technology policy: A component-learning hypothesis. Energy
directed technical change. The American Economic Review 102(1): 131–166. Policy 38: 2525–2535.
Markets/Technology Innovation/Adoption/Diffusion | Economic Models of Climate Change 97

Gerlagh R (2008) A climate-change policy induced shift from innovations in carbon- Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. Journal of
energy production to carbon-energy savings. Energy Economics 30: 425–448. Political Economy 67: 297–306.
Gerlagh R and van der Zwaan R (2003) Gross world product and consumption in a Nordhaus WD (1973) The allocation of energy resources. Brookings Papers on
global warming model with endogenous technological change. Resource and Economic Activity 3: 529–570.
Energy Economics 25(1): 35–57. Nordhaus WD (1994) Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Global
Gerlagh R and van der Zwaan R (2006) Options and instruments for a deep cut in CO2 Warming. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
emissions: Carbon dioxide capture or renewables, taxes or subsidies? Energy Nordhaus WD (2002) Modeling induced innovation in climate change policy.
Journal 27(3): 25–48. In: Grubler A, Nakicenovic N, and Nordhaus W (eds.) Technological Change and the
Gillingham K, Newell R, and Pizer W (2008) Modeling endogenous technological Environment. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future Press.
change for climate policy analysis. Energy Economics 30(6): 2734–2753. Otto V, Löschel A, and Dellink R (2007) Energy biased technical change: A CGE
Goulder LH and Mathai K (2000) Optimal CO2 abatement in the presence of induced analysis. Resource and Energy Economics 29: 137–158.
technological change. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management Otto V, Löschel A, and Reilly J (2008) Directed technical change and differentiation of
39: 1–38. climate policy. Energy Economics 30(6): 2855–2878.
Goulder LH and Schneider S (1999) Induced technological change and the attractiveness Otto V and Reilly J (2008) Directed technical change and the adoption of CO2 abatement
of CO2 abatement policies. Resource and Energy Economics 21: 211–253. technology: The case of CO2 capture and storage. Energy Economics
Grimaud A and Rouge L (2008) Environment directed technical change and economic 30: 2879–2898.
policy. Resource and Energy Economics 41: 439–463. Pizer W and Popp D (2008) Endogenizing technological change: Matching empirical
Grubb M, Köhler J, and Anderson D (2002) Induced technical change in energy and evidence to modeling needs. Energy Economics 30(6): 2754–2770.
environmental modeling. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 27: 271–308. Popp D (2002) Induced innovation and energy prices. American Economic Review
Grübler A, Köhler J, and Anderson D (2002) Technological Change and the 92: 160–180.
Environment. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future Press. Popp D (2004) ENTICE: Endogenous technological change in the DICE model of
Heggerdal T-R and Jacobsen K (2010) Timing of innovation policies when carbon global warming. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
emissions are restricted: An applied general equilibrium analysis. Resource and 48: 742–768.
Energy Economics 33: 913–937. Popp D (2005) ENTICE-BR: The effects of backstop technology R&D on climate policy
Held H, Kriegler E, Lessmann K, and Edenhofer O (2009) Efficient climate policies under models. Energy Economics 28: 188–222.
technology and climate uncertainty. Energy Economics 31: 50–61. Popp D, Newell RG, and Jaffe AB (2009) Energy, the environment, and technological
Hicks J (1932) The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan. change. NBER Working Paper, No. 14832.
Hotelling H (1931) The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of Political Ramsey FP (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. The Economic Journal
Economy 39: 137–175. 38: 543–559.
Jacoby HD, Reilly JM, McFarland JR, and Paltsev S (2006) Technology and technical Richels RG and Blanford GJ (2008) The value of technological advance in decarbonizing
change in the MIT EPPA model. Energy Economics 28: 610–631. the US economy. Energy Economics 30: 2930–2946.
Jakeman G, Hanslow K, Hinchy M, Fisher B, and Woffenden K (2004) Induced Romer PM (1994) The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of Economic
innovations and climate change policy. Energy Economics 26(6): 937–960. Perspectives 8: 3–23.
Kennedy C (1964) Induced bias in innovation and the theory of distribution. The Salter WEG (1966) Productivity and Technical Change, 2nd edn. Cambridge:
Economic Journal 74: 541–547. Cambridge University Press (1st edn 1960).
Köhler J, Grubb M, Popp D, and Edenhofer O (2006) The transition to endogenous Smulders S and de Nooij M (2003) The impact of energy conservation on technology
technical change in climate-energy models: A technical overview to the innovation and economic growth. Resource and Energy Economics 25(1): 59–79.
modeling comparison project. Energy Journal 17–55. Special Issue: Endogenous Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of
Technological Change and the Economics of Atmospheric Stabilization. Economics 70: 65–94.
Kouvaritakis N, Soria A, Isoard S, and Thonet C (2000) Endogenous learning in world Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of
post-Kyoto scenarios: Application of the POLES model under adaptive expectations. Economics and Statistics 39: 312–320.
International Journal of Global Energy Issues 14: 222–248. Stern N (2006) The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge:
Löschel A (2002) Technological change in economic models of environmental policy: A Cambridge University Press.
survey. Ecological Economics 43: 105–126. Stokey NL (1988) Learning by doing and the introduction of new goods. Journal of
Löschel A and Otto V (2009) Technological uncertainty and cost effectiveness of CO2 Political Economy 96: 701–717.
emission reduction. Energy Economics 31: S4–S17. Sue Wing I (2003) Induced technical change and the cost of climate policy. MIT Joint
Loulou R, Goldstein G, and Noble K (2004) Documentation for the MARKAL Family of Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change, Report No. 102.
Models. http://www.etsap.org/tools.htm. Sue Wing I (2006) Representing induced technological change in models for climate
Loulou R, Remne U, Kanudia A, Lehtila A, and Goldstein G (2005) Documentation for policy. Energy Economics 28: 539–562.
the TIMES Model: Part I. http://www.etsap.org/tools.htm. Thornton RA and Thompson P (2001) Learning from experience and learning from
MacCracken C, Edmonds J, Son K, and Sands R (1999) The economics of the Kyoto others: An exploration of learning and spillovers in wartime shipbuilding. American
Protocol. The Energy Journal 25–72. Special Issue. Economic Review 91: 1350–1368.
Manne A and Richels R (1992) Buying Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Costs of van Zon A and Yetkiner IH (2003) An endogenous growth model with embodied
Co2 Emission Limits. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. energy-saving technical change. Resource and Energy Economics 25(1):
Manne A and Richels R (2004) The impact of learning-by-doing on the timing and costs 81–103.
of CO2 abatement. Energy Economics 26: 603–619. Verdolini E and Galeott M (2011) At home and abroad: An empirical analysis of
Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate innovation and diffusion in energy technologies. Journal of Environmental
industry productivity. Econometrica 71: 1695–1725. Economics and Management 61(2): 119–134.
Messner S and Schrattenholzer L (2000) MESSAGE–MACRO: Linking an energy supply von Weizsäcker CC (1966) Tentative notes on a two sector model with induced technical
model with a macroeconomic module and solving it iteratively. Energy progress. Review of Economic Studies 33: 245–251.
25: 267–282. Wilbanks T (2011) Inducing transformational energy technological change. Energy
Neij L (2008) Cost development of future technologies for power generation – A study Economics 33(4): 699–708.
based on experience curves and complementary bottom-up assessments. Energy Wright TP (1936) Factors affecting the cost of airplanes. Journal of Aeronautical
Policy 36: 2200–2211. Sciences 3: 122–128.

You might also like