You are on page 1of 14

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/286587109

Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and


Resources

Article  in  Geographische Zeitschrift · January 2011

CITATIONS READS

25 152

2 authors:

Peter Herrle Josefine Fokdal


Technische Universität Berlin Universität Stuttgart
14 PUBLICATIONS   65 CITATIONS    22 PUBLICATIONS   111 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

N-AERUS conference 2016 View project

Change agents laboratory View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Peter Herrle on 18 December 2020.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Geographische Zeitschrift, Band 99 · 2011 · Heft 1 · Seite 3–15
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart

Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse:


Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources1

PETER HERRLE and JOSEFINE FOKDAL, Berlin

In recent years informality has been defined and re-defined in the context of urban development. Evolving
from initially being understood as a ‘sector’ of the economy to currently being redefined as a ‘new way
of life’, ‘informality’ has become a rather ambiguous term. According to our understanding, many of the
current concepts of informality do not capture the complexity and importance of connectivity between sec-
tors, levels, and actors. In particular, they neglect the importance of power relations and the blurriness of
constantly negotiated and readjusted boundaries between the acceptable and the non-acceptable, legal and
non-legal. In this article, we question the usefulness of the term ‘informality’ and instead propose a set of
parameters in order to describe negotiation processes inherent to the term ‘informality’. We suggest a model
that tries to avoid the ambiguity of the informality debate. It offers a tool to understand the typically com-
posite pattern of actors and their interplay regarding the three dimensions: power, legitimacy, and resources.

Jenseits der Debatte über urbane Informalität – Muster der Verhandlung von Macht,
Legitimation und Ressourcen

In den letzten Jahren wurde der Begriff „Informalität“ im Kontext von Stadtentwicklung umdefiniert und
erweitert. Im Verlauf des Wandels von der ursprünglichen Definition als Wirtschaftssektor der städtischen
Armut zum derzeitigen Verständnis als ‘neue urbane Lebensform’ hat der Begriff seine Aussagekraft ein-
gebüßt. Die neueren Definitionen von Informalität sind zu vage, um die Komplexität der Beziehungen
zwischen Akteuren abzubilden. Insbesondere werden Aspekte wie Machtverhältnisse und die Grauzonen der
Verhandlungsspielräume zwischen akzeptablen und inakzeptablen, legalen und nicht-legalen Arrangements
nicht berücksichtigt. In diesem Aufsatz wird der Nutzen des Begriffs „Informalität“ für die heutige Stadt-
debatte in Frage gestellt und stattdessen – ausgehend von einem akteurszentrierten Ansatz – eine Reihe von
Parametern entwickelt, welche die Unschärfe des gegenwärtigen Informalitätsdiskurses vermeidet. Das vor-
geschlagene Modell bietet ein Werkzeug zur Abbildung typischer Muster der „formellen“ und „informellen“
Verteilung von Macht, Legitimation und Ressourcen zwischen Schlüsselakteuren der Stadtentwicklung an.

1 Introduction Since its introduction to the development


discourse in the 1970s the term has undergone
This is not another attempt to define or re-define considerable changes and refinements, but only
the term ‘informality’ in the context of urban in the last decade has it witnessed a revival char-
development. Instead, our intention is to propose acterized by a new level of ‘complexity’ and a
a set of parameters to describe processes that are prolific increase in meanings and contexts. Not
usually associated with the rather vague term only have various types of ‘informality’ been
‘informality’. Our claim is that these parameters identified, but also a wide range of fields where
deliver a more precise picture of what is usually concepts of ‘informality’ are employed as tools
labeled ‘informal’. to explain the functioning of economic, social
Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
4 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

and spatial urban development processes. In this 2 Informality as a ‘sector’


article we intend to question the usefulness of the
term ‘informality’, and to explore some of the The origin of the term ‘informal’ is widely
mostly unquestioned assumptions inherent to it. known and has frequently been reiterated
From the very beginning, concepts of infor- throughout the body of literature (e. g. Herrle
mality suffered from the bias caused by looking 1982, Komlosy et al. 1997, Hall/Pfeiffer 2000,
at certain phenomena from the ‘outside’ world. Maloney 2004). It may suffice here to trace
For the observers from the northern hemisphere some of the more influential contributions and
of the 1970s it looked like a sheer miracle that put them in the line of argument of this article.
people who were not represented in labor statis- The term ‘informal’ was coined in a dis-
tics were able to survive. Similarly, in the 1980s course on the economy of developing countries
and 1990s urban planners pointed to slums and as early as the 1970s. It was first suggested in
squatter settlements as solutions for those who a study by Hart (1973) on Ghana and it came
were obviously not serviced by the housing into general usage after being adopted by the
sector of national and local policies, a fact that International Labor Office (ILO) in a series of
gave rise to the term ‘informal settlements’. studies. The dichotomy ‘formal’ vs. ‘informal’
From understanding informality as a ‘sector’ of superseded earlier models such as ‘modern’
the economy via the ‘continuum’ concept up to vs. ‘traditional’ (Weeks 1975), ‘capitalist’ vs.
the recent re-conceptualizations as ‘subaltern ‘peasant production systems’ (McGee 1971) or
urbanism’ (Roy 20102), the term has retained the ‘firm economy’ vs. ‘bazaar economy’ (Geertz
ambiguity and middle-class outsider perspective 1963). The characteristic trait that made the
that make it so difficult to accept as a neutral new term so attractive was that it recognized
theoretical concept. the transformation of pre-colonial economic
This observation has led us to look at the rel- structures into those that had – at least to some
evant phenomena from a more ‘systemic’ view, extent – been ‘modernized’ without becoming a
bearing in mind that it is not possible to isolate part of the modern economic sector. Obviously,
‘informality’ from other important factors such these informal systems provided low incomes for
as the urban social, economic and institutional urban dwellers without formal contracts or social
systems that determine the formation of urban security and thereby helped migrants and poor
development. urban dwellers to survive under harsh economic
It may not be by chance that the trigger for and physical conditions. The proximity of ‘in-
our re-consideration of the term ‘informal’ is formality’ to poverty seemed to justify a concept
not the typical city of the global South showing of informality as a ‘survival economy’ (Herrle
signs of urban dualism such as slums vs. gated 1982). Evers and his team (e. g. Evers/Schiel
communities, impoverished masses vs. afflu- 1979, Evers 1981 on Jakarta, Evers/Korff 1986
ence, uncontrolled development vs. prestigious on Bangkok, Evers 1987) went a step further by
developer driven projects etc. Instead, the em- applying the concept of ‘subsistence production’
pirical ground on which the following arguments to the productive and consumptive patterns of
have been developed is the Pearl River Delta in the urban poor. They assumed that through self-
south China, a region not explicitly known for help construction of housing, infrastructure and
loose development controls, weak enforcement the ‘acquisition’ of land, subsistence production
of land use and building laws or ‘informal’ labor as a mechanism outside the market economy
arrangements. plays a major role in providing the urban poor
with basic goods and services.
However, as we concede in retrospect, the
limitation to poverty blanks out a whole range
of contextual conditions and phenomena that

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 5

equally escape statistics, formal procedures and by dependent clientele groups from the urban
regulations. Already in the early 1980’s, in our poor communities. The further down one looks
study on the informal economies of Davao City on the ladder of middlemen, the smaller the
in the Philippines, we were able to verify Santos’ radius becomes, the shorter the duration of the
three types of linkages to the outside world of credit, the higher the risk and the interest rate
‘informality’, i. e. capital, wholesale and trans- charged (cf. Santos 1979, 123-124) and – one
portation (Santos 1979). We also encountered may add – the higher the dependence and the
fairly big enterprises in these (and other) fields, degree of exploitation of the individual informal
which could obviously no longer be labeled enterprise.
as ‘survival activities.’ They showed signs of The advantage of Santos’ approach is that it
an economy of ‘scale’ – albeit on a modest gives up the biased one-way view on informality
level – but also a complex mixture of regulated and puts it in the framework of a two-tier system
and unregulated, controlled and uncontrolled, of mutual dependence from which both the ur-
registered and unregistered elements (Herrle/ ban poor clientele and the middle men benefit.
Lübbe/Rösel 1981). What we saw neither fit into He realized that “the ‘dualism’ identified by so
a simplifying juxtaposition of the ‘formal’ with many authors is nothing more than the general
the ‘informal’ nor into the patterns of subsist- manifestation of the upper circuit’s hegemony,
ence production. Similar observations may have which can be seen in more striking terms in
brought some researchers to see informality as the guise of monopoly, on the one hand, and
a ‘continuum’ (e. g. Hall/Pfeiffer 2000, 71). To underemployment on the other” (Santos 1979,
our understanding this concept does not capture 27). This is in line with a number of other au-
the composite patterns of certain economic thors who pointed at the structural ‘symbiosis’
activities, nor does it reflect the importance of (Bienefeld 1975) and the interdependency of the
connectivity between sectors, levels and actors. two circuits (Bose 1974). Building on his earlier
Moreover, it tends to harmonize the imbalances works McGee (2002) also refers to the issue of
and conflicts inherent in the social and economic inter-dependency.
transaction processes involved. While Santos’ analysis was correct for a
small part of what is understood by ‘informality’
today, namely the poverty-related phenomenon
3 From ‘sector’ to ’circuit’ and economic dependency, he overlooked i)
that certain patterns of informality also occur in
Milton Santos (1979) was among the first to places (and circuits) other than those dominated
widen the view from ‘activities’ to ‘systems’ by by poverty and ii) that informality cannot be
describing the mutual dependence of formal and limited to the economic systems of cities only.
informal economic circuits. He established the One of those areas is certainly the ‘informal
model of “the two circuits of the urban econo- urban development’ discussed below.
my”. A chain of middlemen links the informal
circuit with the formal part of the economy.
Key positions in this system are occupied by 4 Informal urban development
wholesalers, transport entrepreneurs and money-
lenders who have access to the modern banking In parallel with the declining interest in the
facilities. All three operate in both sectors of ‘informal sector’ debate in the 1990s, the term
the economy. They possess modern means of ‘informal’ was adopted by planners, architects
storage, credit procurement and the necessary and housing experts. Since then, it has been
supra-local radius of action to take advantage used to denote ‘unplanned’, ‘irregular’ or il-
of inter-regional price differentials. On the other legal settlements that are often (but not always)
hand their position is secured over the long term inhabited by low-income communities and/or

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
6 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

rural migrants. The term ‘informal settlement’ ing millions of people have been urbanized in
superseded a large number of euphemistic terms Asia, Africa, Latin America, and the Middle East
such as ‘spontaneous settlements’ (Oestereich following this pattern (See Payne 1997, 7ff., ES-
1980) or ‘unplanned settlements’ which gave CAP 1997, chapter III for general characteristics,
the misleading impression that these settlements Risbud 1989 on Delhi, India, Wehrmann 2005,
develop ‘spontaneously’ without planning or 45-46 and 157ff. on Accra, Ghana, Santos 2003,
strategic thinking. In many cases ‘informal set- 241ff. on Vilar Carioca, Brazil). What makes this
tlements’ illegally occupy private or public land transformation process special is the fact that it
and do not comply with existing subdivision and is widely tolerated by city officials or takes place
building regulations. However, since Turner’s beyond the control of city authorities, outside
early studies on Lima (Turner 1967, 1968, 1972) their administrative boundaries.
we know that most of these settlements are far While definitions of informality based on the
from being unplanned, un-organized or irregu- legality of land tenure and/or compliance with
lar. In Lima, up to the late 1990s new barriadas land use and building regulations may be easy
were not only planned by professional planners criteria for distinguishing ‘informal’ settlements
but also coordinated with the city government. from formal ones, again, they do not consider the
Although the early examples of Lima and typical mixture of the ‘informal’ and the formal,
other places show that there is a ‘gray zone’ nor do they reflect the ambiguous relationship
of government toleration in ‘informal’ urban between settlers, intermediaries and city govern-
development, the legality of tenure remained an ments that seems to be endemic in contemporary
issue both for political practice and academic urban development in the global South. Moreo-
research: For politicians, illegality provided the ver, they also tend to overlook the importance
pretext for massive evictions. Academics such of power relations and power plays between
as Payne (1999, 2002) and Durand-Lasserve/ various urban actors that increasingly define
Royston (2002) embarked on intense research on and constantly re-define the blurred boundaries
tenure issues proving that tenure security can be between the acceptable and the non-acceptable,
reached outside cumbersome and never-ending the legal and the ‘not-so-legal’3.
legalization procedures. The importance of legal-
izing land tenure for the urban poor was further
emphasized by writers such as Hernando de Soto 5 Informality as a ‘way of life’
(2000) who, through a neo-liberal approach,
cultivated a positive view on the ‘capacities’ of Meanwhile, although not always explicitly ex-
the poor. According to this line of argument the pressed, notions of ‘informality’ have become
stigma of poverty and exclusion could easily be part of a much wider and more theoretical de-
overcome, if the potentials of the marginalized bate, encompassing the sensitive and sometimes
were unleashed from restrictive government poli- precarious relationship between state organiza-
cies and rigid regulations and their interactions tions, civil society, and issues of planning and
were integrated into formal systems. Recogni- legitimacy (van Dijk/Noordhoek/Wegelin 2002,
tion, legalization and ‘regularization’ were the Mitlin/Satterthwaite 2004). This has added a new
standard strategies derived for urban policy. dimension to discussions about urban planning
From many countries, other forms of mid- issues and local governance (Goethert/Hamdi
dle class informality are reported: In India for 1997, Stratmann 1999) and instigated a new
example, many middle class families live in ‘il- wave of research into ‘informality’ culminat-
legal subdivisions’ in peri-urban neighborhoods ing in declaring informality a ‘new way of life’
of large cities. Land is provided by developers (AlSayyad 2004). This statement is reminiscent
who illegally subdivide agricultural land for of Louis Wirth’s famous article “Urbanism as a
residential purposes. Large tracts of land hous- Way of Life”, which drew our attention to “ur-

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 7

banism” as a “complex of traits making up the actors, and a growing disembeddedness of


characteristic mode of life in cities […]” (1938, local systems?
7). Whether deliberately or not, AlSayyad’s
Following Roy (2005), Altrock (2010) suggests a
statement also recalls Jocano’s well-known
‘conceded informality’4 approach, which points
book on ‘Slums as a Way of Life’ portraying
at the way by which privileges are granted or
the lives of slum dwellers in the Philippines
negotiated in direct and indirect ways, politi-
(Jocano 1975). All three authors generalize
cized and prone to conflicts. This comes quite
what had previously been considered a marginal
close to what we have earlier discussed as key
phenomenon. By declaring urbanism, slums,
determining factors in hybrid local governance
and informality a “way of life,” they include a
systems (Herrle et al. 2005).
seemingly marginal phenomenon, which had
In terms of placing the discussion of ‘infor-
earlier been discussed along the narrow paths
mality’ into the larger context of governance,
of physical or economic models, into a broader
Etzold et al. define ‘informality’ as a “continuum
social-science context.
of interrelated social processes and practices
According to AlSayyad/Roy urban informal-
with different degrees and qualities of (in)
ity is “an urban logic”. “It is a process of struc-
formality” (2009, 4). They suggest a concept
turation that constitutes the rules of the game
of “informality as agency”, which, based on
determining the nature of transaction between
Misztal (2000), highlights the importance of
individuals and institutions and between insti-
social interaction. Etzold et al. introduce the term
tutions” (2004, 5). Taking up Wirth’s language,
‘arena’ to denote the economic, social, temporal
it has also been epitomized as a “new mode of
and physical ‘space’ that is under consideration.
urban existence” (2004, 5). AlSayyad and Roy
Their article also concedes that “the question
go on to argue that urban informality as “a co-
what is ‘informal’ and what is formal, […] can
herent mode of life in an era of liberalization”
only be answered in perspective of the actors
is not really new, but has existed since the Mid-
involved” (2009, 9). Why then re-affirm the
dle Ages and has persisted in many parts of the
term ‘informality’ with a concept that obviously
developing world.
transcends its origins by offering a much wider
The review presented above raises a number
and more coherent analytical framework?
of questions:
Thus, the more we open the term ‘informality’
– Does ‘informality’ relate to phenomena only to an ever wider range of aspects of urban life,
in an ‘era of liberalization’? Or does it exist the more difficult it seems to keep it operational
as an almost ubiquitous aspect of any urban – not only in empirical but also in theoretical
life independent of its political or economic terms. If almost everything becomes ‘informal’
of even historical formation? – which obviously seems necessary – the widen-
– Is there really something persisting? Or has ing itself may eventually erode and destroy the
‘informality’ always – as AlSayyad/Roy usefulness of the term.
(2004) rightly concede – been there as an
integral part of urban formations?
– If ‘informality‘ is no longer associated with 6 Informality – a myth?
urban poverty nor with illegality, nor with the
control of processes, as in the early days of A myth typically tries to provide an explanation
the debate, what is it then? for things that are intransparent for one reason
– How can we operationalize the term ‘infor- or the other. Frequently myths help sustain tradi-
mality’ as a “mode of life” or a “mode of tions. In retrospect, i. e. once myths have been
urbanization” (Roy 2005, 147) in an era of revealed as such, they seem to have prevented a
globalization of production, growing impor- more rational view on certain phenomena, fresh
tance of networks, changing landscapes of thinking and new concepts. By definition, myths
Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
8 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

have to have a ‘soft’ core and be conservative. There is an increasing recognition of the
Without a certain degree of vagueness they importance of connectivity of various urban
would lose their attractiveness. Why then is the subsystems (at various levels) including interac-
concept of ‘informality’ a myth? tion between systems as factors determining the
To our understanding the term ‘informality’ patterns of how resources are distributed and how
helps sustain myths about urban phenomena for access to services in cities is granted; this calls for
a number of reasons: a shift of interest toward governance processes.
As many authors have stated – informality is
– The proliferation of new ‘informalities’ of-
nothing new. As an un- or less regulated part of
fered in recent writings provides ample evi-
state organization, it has been part of the every-
dence of the structural ambiguity of the term
day urban life in societies (not only in urban ar-
and its ever-changing formations. Current
concepts of ‘informality’ cross the border of eas) throughout history. Regulative mechanisms
the conventional stringent definitions at the were often kept to a minimum in ancient Asian
cost of giving up the claim for an exactness as well as medieval European cities5. Societies
and clarity. Some of them obviously play with were organized around ‘informal’ arrangements.
the vagueness of connotations and meanings Despite all efforts to formalize urban life and
in different fields of knowledge. development, the formal systems seem to rep-
– The concept still retains the problematic resent just the tip of the iceberg on a broad base
legacy of its founders: If not clearly defined of all kinds of unregulated, partly regulated or
(and narrowed down to operational terms), de-regulated subsystems of the urban society.6
‘informality’ remains something inside the
‘black box’. We do not know exactly what is
happening inside, but we assume that there 7 Beyond informality
must be something that does not follow the
logic of the outside. In trying to describe the If we leave the inherent deterministic conno-
inside we find ourselves among unique cir- tation of the formal-informal dichotomy (or
cumstances that cannot easily be generalized. the ‘continuum’ as its modification) behind,
– There is a tricky mechanism in using the we realize that in cities there are a number of
concept ‘formal-informal’: It almost inevita- mechanisms or subsystems that, in a more or
bly re-establishes a dichotomy that so many less permanent way, organize and secure the
observers claim to have overcome. (unequal) distribution of resources, the (unequal)
Our conclusion has not been to discard the at- access to services and the (unequal) distribution
tempts to further define and develop coherent of power. Depending on the political system,
concepts of ‘informality’ for specific sub-groups economic conditions, social and cultural tradi-
of an urban society, but rather to move towards tions, effectiveness of the administration etc.
a more complex explanatory model that tries there may be countless variations in how the
to avoid the latent ambiguity of the informality result is achieved, but in most cases there is a
debate. For a number of reasons the model we constant process of negotiation.
suggest cannot be developed from ‘inside’ the What we see here appears as a reiteration of
informality discourse. These reasons include: the 1980s debate, when the term ‘informality’
As emphasized in the recent informality was branded as an explanation of why so many
discourse, phenomena of ‘informality’ occur people still exist in cities with staggering econo-
beyond poverty and exclusion, economy and mies and live under devastating living condi-
settlement, private and public, state and civil tions. Currently we are encountering a similar
society. Following the recent debate, the term ‘miracle’ at the collective level. Why are cities
describes a ‘mode’ shaping physical as well as still functioning (and continuing to be attractive)
social and political environments in cities. although their government systems are weak,
Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 9

plans are not implemented, their population the common profit is just a side product of the
shows an increasing social divide, and a coherent maximized individual gain, as also described by
management structure is not in place? The gen- Börzel (2007). The concept proposed in chapter
eral experience is that in many countries, large 8 draws on these approaches.
cities would long have collapsed, had there not
been certain clandestine factors keeping them
together and granting economic progress and a 8 The regime-matrix: power, legitimacy,
minimum of coherence (cf. Mertins 2009, 59). resources
The reason seems to be that cities are being
produced by not just one group nor are they The regional focus of studies on ‘informality’ has
planned and implemented by planners or politi- mainly been on Latin America, South Asia and
cians alone; they are rather the common product the Middle East (AlSayyad/Roy 2004, Etzold et
of a wide range of actors, some of which are al. 2009, de Soto 2000) and on countries with a
known and understood, others are less known, significant degree of social exclusion and urban
but play an equally important role. The result poverty. In our study on the Pearl River Delta
is by no means a neutral one, it is rather based (PRD) in South China, we observed phenomena
on the power play and ‘negotiation’ between that may well be attributed to what is usually
‘collective actors’ as it has been suggested by labeled as ‘informal’: tolerated and systematic
scholars such as Scharpf (1997) and earlier by violation of building regulations, blurred re-
Mayntz (1963). Herrle et al. (2006) argue that sponsibilities, illegal land and labor markets,
negotiation and consensus-building form vital intransparent and fragmented decision-making
parts of contemporary local governance systems procedures, uncontrolled transfer of land use
particularly in the global South. This view is rights etc. However, in this environment neither
also reflected in propositions of the new insti- urban poverty nor subsistence production plays a
tutionalism which ascribes conflicting interests significant role. If at all, ‘informality’ can be de-
to actors that are interdependent. A theoretical tected as a mode of urbanity inherent to growth
concept supporting our approach is also the inter- patterns and processes. Under the special cir-
institutional model of clientelistic relationships cumstances of Chinese economic liberalization
developed by Pierre (1999) and DiGaetano/ since the mid 1980s and the special conditions
Strom (2003) and consolidated by Ley (2010). of the Pearl River Delta it seems that a certain
Negotiation as we understand this term does level of de-regulation was conducive to local
not necessarily involve face-to-face contact: initiative and economic growth. Especially the
There may be numerous forms of indirect in- ‘urban villages’ (chéng zhong cūn) as parts of
fluence on decision-making processes in which cities or located in peri-urban areas enjoy certain
media coverage, financial pressure, mobilization privileges and benefit from loose control (see
of masses may sometimes be the better than Herrle et al. 2008).
those made by representatives at the negotiating Our case of the urban villages in the PRD
table (see also Benz 2007). In the governance provides a good example for ‘negotiated’ assets.
discourse of negotiations, it is most often as- Urban villagers, as a collective, and based on
sumed that the aim of negotiations is to achieve their collective legitimacy (and as long as they
an optimized situation for the general public are ‘defined’ as rural) hold large resources of
(Benz 2007) however this is not always the land as an economic asset as well as a source
case. As found in our research in the PRD, ne- of power (Wu 2009, Liu et al. 2010, see also
gotiations between several stakeholders are often Fokdal/Herrle 2010 for a summary account
neither a matter of acting nor of solely reacting, on land legislation and negotiation processes).
but rather something in between. Furthermore, Investors and developers from Hong Kong
the individual interest is often the motivator and seek access to these resources, as do the local

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
10 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

authorities. However, the process of leasing land these processes occur. Drawing on an earlier at-
directly to investors and establishing industries tempt (Herrle et al. 2006) and backed up by our
(circumventing the local government) is illegal. research in the Pearl River Delta we suggest a
Moreover, on an individual level, the villagers set of three parameters that may help to describe
are seeking to optimize their profit by building the process of negotiation more precisely than
housing for legal and illegal migrants working ‘informality’ approaches can: access to 1) power,
in the surrounding industries. The emerging 2) legitimacy, and 3) resources. They form the
structures supersede the building regulations in key parameters of local governance systems
terms of height, densities, land use etc. The vil- (Herrle et al. 2006) and local regimes. Typi-
lagers thereby provide a service (housing) that cally, governance systems in large urban areas
is solving the housing problem of huge numbers show a composite pattern of antagonistic actors
of migrants who are not taken care of by the lo- collectively providing inputs related to these
cal government. Since economic development parameters in a more or less complementary
is generally welcome, local governments tend way that keeps the system as a whole together.
to tolerate the situation, even though it implies There may be more factors currently in use
violations of existing regulations and constitutes to describe the division of actors and their roles
‘informal’ processes. In fact, they are actively (see Risse et al. 2007). We assume, however, that
involved in those negotiation processes. They the three parameters shown in this matrix are
benefit from the informal housing provision sufficient to adequately depict specific constella-
since it lowers the risks of social unrest from tions of actors. For our purpose we have arranged
the side of migrant workers and at the same these three parameters in a matrix by combining
time saves resources for investment in basic in- them with a set of actors. It is meant to capture
frastructure (transportation, energy etc.) needed ‘formal’ as well as ‘informal’ interactions and
for the booming economy. The emerging system the key actors deriving from an actor analysis.
can be interpreted as a fragile and permanently It may be worth noting that what is presented
re-negotiated balance of interests involving vil- below is not a normative model, but a matrix
lage collectives, investors/developers and local displaying roles and relationships of various ac-
governments as the key actors. It is a process that tors in a certain field. There is neither an attempt
is self-‘regulated’ in the sense that it is driven by to derive a ‘best practice’ nor to conclude that
its inherent dynamics and ever changing rules, certain combinations of distributions of assets
and constantly oscillating between what is often are better compared to others. What has been
labeled as formal or ‘informal’. categorized as ‘formal’ or ‘informal’ appears as
Obviously, the classical concepts of ‘infor- a property or capacity ascribed to a certain group
mality’ cannot capture a situation as described of actors. As a standard matrix to demonstrate
above. This is one of the reasons why we resorted the concept we have correlated the parameters
to regime theory approaches as suggested by with three groups of generalized actors7 taken
Stone (1989, 1993). Although the growth ma- from our study on the Pearl River Delta. They
chine and the importance of the business sector present a simplified set of actors that may well
in the USA have influenced the regime theory be modified and specified from case to case.
approach suggested by Stone, it seems to provide Inasmuch as a setup of actors and their inter-
a valuable entry point for explaining the general play of roles and activities is able to grant basic
modalities of actors, their mutual relationships standards of security, social wellbeing, equity
and interactions. According to Stone, the regime and general economic prosperity, they are usu-
where interests and actors meet constitutes for- ally accepted as a way to organize resources,
mal and informal negotiation processes (1993). power and legitimacy in an efficient albeit com-
Starting from Stone’s approach we felt it nec- plex and sometimes confusing way. Moreover,
essary to further structure the regimes in which a ‘composite’ set of actors making differing

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 11

State Investors, Developers Urban villages


(City government) as collectives
Power Power to plan and imple- Power through capital to Power to implement
ment infrastructure, to negotiate with the city gov- projects and manage firms
acquire land classified as ernment and with the urban (global network), occa-
‘rural’, to demolish illegal villages. sionally strong negotiation
housing. power vis-à-vis city govt.
through media support.
Legitimacy Strong legal position by Limited (guarantor for Strong legitimacy base in
law. Decisions not always progress and modernity). village collectives/village
accepted by local people committees avoiding social
and villagers, pressure on unrest by housing migrants
participation, pressure on - allow for illegal building
modernization processes. and land use.
Resources Rich but not unlimited, Capital, knowledge. Limited financial resources
dependent on overall eco- (based on revenues from
nomic situation and rev- collectively run businesses
enues from land leasing of and rented factory build-
land classified as ‘urban’. ings).
Land (rural or EDL* - as
the most important asset is
dwindling).
High level of influence on the negotiation process
Moderate level of influence on the negotiation process
Low level of influence on the negotiation process
No or limited influence on the negotiation process
* The farmlands of former rural collectives are acquired by the city government and turned into state-owned land
(urban land). In return, the Guangdong provincial government requires 8-12% of the former farmland to be returned
to the urban village as economic development land (EDL) (Wu 2009, Liu et al. 2010)

Fig. 1: The regime matrix: power, legitimacy, resources, a simplified example from the Pearl River Delta

contributions to general welfare and basic values Although in a democratic state power is assumed
seems to form the rule rather than the exception to be vested with the government, there is plenty
in the governance of many countries including of room for investors, pressure groups and the
Europe8 and North America. It is typical that civil society to exercise power and thereby push
the equilibrium between actors and the level their own interests to the forefront. Power is also
of their command over power, legitimacy and needed to enforce regulations and maintain law
resources cannot be kept static for a long time. and order.
It is constantly being re-negotiated and part of The legitimacy parameter is an important
the development process itself. asset when it comes to implementation. In most
The power parameter tells us something about countries law-based legitimacy is not sufficient,
the distribution of power between various actor and even powerful actors would risk the break-
groups. Without a minimum of power there is no out of open conflicts if they have no legitimacy
implementation of projects and on the other hand base within the civil society or other powerful
no resistance against power from other groups. groups. Typically, in many cities of the global

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
12 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

South legitimacy bases are fragmented not only ing an economic phenomenon to include spatial
along party lines but also within social, ethnic structures and processes, towards ‘a new way of
and economic groupings. This may lead to al- life’, it has become a blurred term – a myth. What
ternative arrangements and alliances. has often been defined as ‘informality’ seems
The resources parameter indicates the avail- to be an almost ubiquitous aspect of any urban
ability of human, technical and financial re- life independent from its political or economic
sources (incl. information) needed to provide or even historical formation.
services and implement projects. In many cases Therefore, we suggest moving away from
local governments are poor both in terms of the term ‘informal’ with its inherent duality and
technical capacity and human resources and have poverty connotations, towards defining negotia-
to rely on financial support from investors. This tion processes by discussing related phenom-
in turn might undermine their legitimacy basis ena through a set of three parameters, namely:
with the civil society or certain groups therein. power, legitimacy, and resources and put these in
Obviously in cases where ‘informality’ be- the framework of an actor analysis. It may still
comes immoral, criminal and detrimental to gen- be too early to say whether these three dimen-
erally accepted values of human development, sions will suffice to capture urban development
or in the situation of ‘failing states’ the matrix trends elsewhere, but at least for the case of the
shows a shift of all three assets, i. e. power, Pearl River Delta we claim their usefulness for
legitimacy and resources towards fragmented understanding the urban dynamics. What we
(maybe rivaling) non-state actors. find in the PRD provides an example for vari-
We are aware that the parameters presented ous stages of development and different forms
here are not new. They have been brought up in of territorial organization of resources. It keeps
various discourses. However, in the context of systems incoherent, fluid and versatile, provid-
our discussion they have the potential to reveal ing the systemic potentials to quickly adapt local
the dynamic relationships between actors and economies and social systems as well as physi-
translate into more precise terms what has been cal structures to global forces of development.
disguised as ‘informality’. Now, where is ‘infor- The strength of those flexible systems derives
mality’, after all? As has been said at the outset from their ability to adapt and change and – at
of this paper: Our claim is not to add another the same time – conserve or develop the stabil-
definition for ‘informality’ but rather to develop ity and the level of coherence needed to create
a tool that contributes to a better understanding a reliable framework for social and economic
of the processes underlying phenomena super- interaction and investment. The emerging pat-
ficially labeled as ‘informal’. terns are characterized by permanent negotiation
among stakeholders and constantly shifting
power relations.
9 Conclusion In such an environment the search for ‘infor-
mality’ becomes a futile and obsolete exercise,
In rapidly changing societies, the half-value the term itself loses its relevance as an explana-
period of theoretical constructs describing tory model. In as much as basic characteristics
certain aspects of urban formations is becom- of urban development in the Pearl River Delta
ing shorter. This also applies to the concept of are also valid for contemporary urban develop-
urban ‘informality’ as it has developed since ments elsewhere we believe that it may be worth
the 1970s. Many of the ‘informality’ concepts applying the tool to other countries as well and
are transcending the original dichotomy and the thereby developing it further.
notion of urban poverty that has been associ-
ated with it in the early writings. As the term
‘informality’ has developed from solely defin-

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 13

References Evers, H.-D. and Korff, R. (1986): Urban Subsistence


Production in Bangkok. In: Development – Jour-
AlSayyad, N. (2004): Urban Informality as a “New” nal of the Society for International Development
Way of Life. In: AlSayyad, N. and Roy, A. (eds.): 4, 50-55.
Urban Informality. Transnational Perspectives Evers, H.-D. and Schiel, T. (1979): Expropriation der
from the Middle East, Latin America and South unmittelbaren Produzenten oder Ausdehnung der
Africa. Lanham, Maryland, 7-30. Subsistenzwirtschaft – Thesen zur bäuerlichen
AlSayyad, N. and Roy, A. (2004): Urban Informal- und städtischen Subsistenzreproduktion. In: Ar-
ity. Transnational Perspectives from the Middle beitsgruppe Bielefelder Entwicklungssoziologen
East, Latin America and South Africa. Lanham, (eds.): Subsistenzreproduktion und Akkumulati-
Maryland. on. Saarbrücken, 279ff.
Benz, A. (2007): Verhandlungen. In: Benz, A. et Fokdal, J. and Herrle, P. (2010): Negotiated Space:
al. (eds.): Handbuch Governance. Wiesbaden, Urban Villages in the Pearl River Delta. In: Tria-
106-118. log 102/103, 10-15.
Bienefeld, M. (1975): The Informal Sector and Geertz, C. (1963): Peddlers and Princes. Social
Peripheral Capitalism: The Case of Tansania. In: Change and Economic Modernization in Two
Institute of Development Studies Bulletin 6(3), Indonesian Towns. Chicago.
53-73. Goethert, R. (2005): Planning with People - Challeng-
Bose, A.N. (1974): The Informal Sector in Calcutta es to the Paradigm. In: Herrle, P. and Walther, U.-J.
Metropolitan Economy. In: WEP Urbanization (eds.): Socially Inclusive Cities. Münster, 9-22.
and Employment Research Program (eds.): Work- Goethert, R. and Hamdi, N. (1997): Action Planning
ing Paper 5. Geneva. for Cities: A Guide to Community Practice. West
Börzel, T. (2007): Regieren ohne den Schatten der Sussex, England.
Hierarchie: Ein modernisierungstheoretischer Hall, P. and Pfeiffer, U. (2000): Urban Future 21: A
Fehlschluss? In: Risse, T. and Lehmkuhl, U. Global Agenda for Twenty-first Century Cities.
(eds.): Regieren ohne Staat? Governance in New York.
Räumen begrenzter Staatlichkeit. Baden-Baden, Hart, K. (1973): Informal Income Opportunities
41-63. and Urban Employment in Ghana. In: Journal of
De Soto, H. (2000): The Mystery of Capital: Why Modern African Studies, March, 61-89.
Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Ev- Herrle, P. (1982): The Informal Sector: Survival
erywhere Else. New York. Economy in the Third World. In: Economics.
DiGaetano, A. and Strom, E. (2003): Comparative A Biannual Collection of Recent German Con-
Urban Governance: An Integrated Approach. In: tributions to the Field of Economic Science 26,
Urban Affairs Review 38(3), 356-395. 109-126.
Durand-Lasserve, A. and Royston, L. (2002): Hold- Herrle, P., Lübbe, H. and Rösel, J. (1981): Slums
ing Their Ground: Secure Land Tenure for the und Squatter-Siedlungen. Thesen zur Stadtent-
Urban Poor in Developing Countries. London. wicklung und Stadtplanung in der Dritten Welt.
ESCAP (1997): Urban Land Policies for the Uniniti- Stuttgart.
ated. Retrieved 5 October 2011, from http://www. Herrle, P. and Walther, U.-J. (2005): Socially Inclu-
unescap.org/huset/land_policies/index.htm sive Cities. Münster.
Etzold, B., Bohle, H.-G., Keck, M. and Zingel, W.- Herrle, P., Jachnow, A. and Ley, A. (2006): The
P. (2009 ): Informality as Agency – Negotiating Metropolises of the South: Laboratory for Inno-
Food Security in Dhaka. In: Die Erde 140(1), vation? Towards Better Management with New
3-24. Alliances. Development and Peace Foundation
Evers, H.-D. (1981): The Contribution of Urban (ed.), Policy Paper 25.
Subsistence to Incomes of Jakarta. In: Bulletin Herrle, P., Ipsen, D., Nebel, S., and Weichler, H.
of the Indonesian Economic Studies 17, 89-96. (2008): Wie Bauern die mega-urbane Landschaft
Evers, H.-D. (1987): Subsistenzproduktion, Markt in Südchina prägen. Zur Rolle der „Urban Vil-
und Staat. Der sog. Bielefelder Verflechtungsan- lages“ bei der Entwicklung des Perflussdeltas. In:
satz. In: Geographische Rundschau 39, 136-140. Geographische Rundschau 11, 38-45.

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
14 Peter Herrle / Josefine Fokdal

Jocano, F.L. (1975): Slum as a Way of Life. A Study Pierre, J. (1999): Model of Urban Governance. The
of Coping Behavior in an Urban Environment. Institutional Dimension of Urban Politics. In:
Quezon City. Urban Affairs Review 34(3), 372-396.
Komlosy, A., Parnreiter, C., Stacher, I. and Zimmer- Risse, T. and Lehmkuhl, U. (2007): Regieren ohne
mann, S. (1997): Der informelle Sektor: Kon- Staat? Governance in Räumen begrenzter Staat-
zepte, Widersprüche und Debatten. In: Komlosy, lichkeit. In: Risse, T. and Lehmkuhl, U. (eds.):
A. et al. (eds.): Ungeregelt und unterbezahlt. Der Regieren ohne Staat? Governance in Räumen
Informelle Sektor in der Weltwirtschaft. Frank- begrenzter Staatlichkeit. Baden-Baden, 13-37.
furt, Wien, 9-30. Rostalski, M. (2010): Gelebte Orte – Geplante Stadt.
Ley, A. (2010): Housing as Governance. Interfaces Informelle Nutzung urbaner Räume und parti-
between Local Government and Civil Society Or- zipative Stadtentwicklung. Das RAW-Gelände
ganisations in Cape Town, South Africa. Münster. in Berlin. Unpublished PhD thesis. Bauhaus
Liu, Y., He, S., Wu, F. and Webster, C. (2010): Ur- Universität Weimar.
ban Villages under China’s Rapid Urbanization: Risbud, N. (1989): Informal Sector Land Delivery
Unregulated Assets and Transnational Neighbour- and Servicing in Delhi. Report prepared by the
hoods. In: Habitat International 32, 135-144. Centre for Environmental Planning and Technol-
Maloney, W.F. (2004): Informality Revisited, Wash- ogy, Ahmedabad for USAID. Delhi
ington (USA). Roy, A. (2005): Urban Informality. Towards an Epis-
Mayntz, R. (1963): Soziologie der Organisation. temology of Planning. In: Journal of the American
Hamburg. Planning Association (JAPA) 71, 147-158.
McGee, T.G. (1971): The Urbanization Process in Santos, M. (1979): The Shared Space. The Two Cir-
the Third World. Explorations in Search of a cuits of The Urban Economy in Underdeveloped
Theory. London. Countries. London.
McGee, T.G. (2002): Reconstructing the Southeast Santos, P. (2003): Neue Instrumente der Stadtpla-
Asia City in an Era of Volatile Globalization. In: nung in Brasilien. Das Ende der illegalen Stadt?
Asian Journal of Social Science 30(1), 8-27. Münster.
Mertins, G. (2009): Megacities in Lateinameri- Scharpf, F.W. (1997): Games Real Actors Play. Ac-
ka: Informalität und Unsicherheit als zentrale tor-Centered Institutionalism in Policy Research.
Probleme von Governance und Steuerung. In: Boulder/Oxford.
Technikfolgenabschätzung – Theorie und Praxis Stone, C.N. (1989): Regime Politics. Governing
18(1), 52-61. Atlanta, 1946-1988. Lawrence, Kansas.
Mitlin, D. and Satterthwaite, D. (2004): The Role of Stone, C.N. (1993): Urban Regimes and the Capacity
Local and Extra-local Organizations. In: Mitlin, to Govern: A Political Economy Approach. In:
D. and Satterthwaite, D. (eds.): Empowering Journal of Urban Affairs 15, 1-28.
Squatter Citizen. London, 278-306. Stratmann, B. (1999): Stadtentwicklung in globalen
Misztal, B.A. (2000): Informality: Social Theory and Zeiten. Lokale Strategien, städtische Lebensqua-
Contemporary Practice. London. lität und Globalisierung. Basel.
Oestereich, J. (1980): Elendsquartiere und Wachs- Turner, J.F.C. (1967): Barriers and Channels for
tumspole. Beiträge zur räumlichen Planung in der Housing Development in Modernizing Countries.
Dritten Welt. Köln. In: Journal of the American Institute of Planners
Payne, G.K. (1997): Urban Land Tenure and Prop- 3, 167-180.
erty Rights in Developing Countries. A Review. Turner, J.F.C. (1968): Housing Priorities, Settlements
London. Patterns and Urban Development in Modernizing
Payne, G.K. (ed.) (1999): Making Common Ground. Countries. In: Journal of the American Institute
Public-Private Partnerships in Land for Housing. of Planners 6, 354-363.
London. Turner, J.F.C. (1972): Housing as a Verb. In: Turner,
Payne, G.K. (2002): Land, Rights and Innovation. J.F.C. and Fichter, R. (eds.): Freedom to Build.
Improving Tenure Security for the Urban Poor. Dweller Control of the Housing Process. London,
London. 148-175.

Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011
Beyond the Urban Informality Discourse: Negotiating Power, Legitimacy and Resources 15

Van Dijk, M.P., Noordhoek, M., and Wegelin, E. Wirth, L. (1938): Urbanism as a Way of Life. In:
(eds.) (2002): Governing Cities: New Institutional The American Journal of Sociology 44(1), 1-24.
Forms in Developing Countries and Transitional Wu, F. (2009): Land Development, Inequality and
Economies. London. Urban Villages in China. In: International Journal
Weber, M. (1921): Die nichtlegitime Herrschaft of Urban and Regional Research 33(4), 885-889.
(Typologie der Städte). In: Archiv für Sozialwis-
senschaft und Sozialpolitik 47, 621ff.
Weeks, J. (1975): Policies for Expanding Employ- Authors: Prof. Dr. Peter Herrle, Habitat Unit A53, Faculty
ment in the Informal Urban Sector of Develop- VI, Planning – Building – Environment Berlin, Institute
of Technology, Straße des 17. Juni 152, 10623 Berlin,
ing Countries. In: International Labour Review E-Mail: peter.herrle@tu-berlin.de
111(1), 1-13. Josefine Fokdal, Habitat Unit A53, Faculty VI, Planning
Wehrmann, B. (2005): Landkonflikte im urbanen – Building – Environment Berlin, Institute of Technology,
und peri-urbanen Raum von Großstädten in Ent- Straße des 17. Juni 152, 10623 Berlin, E-Mail: josefine.
wicklungsländern. Mit Beispielen aus Accra und fokdal@tu-berlin.de
Pnom Penh. Münster.

1 This article presents thoughts that have been developed in a research project on Urban Villages in the Pearl River
Delta within the framework of a DFG Priority Program on „Megacities – Megachallenge. The Informal Dynamics
of Global Change“. We wish to acknowledge the support provided by the DFG.
2 Ananya Roy on a colloquium of Priority Program „Megacities – Megachallenge. The Informal Dynamics of Global
Change“ in Berlin on May 10-11, 2010.
3 In many countries where an official land title is beyond the reach of poor settlers, paying water or electricity bills is
a common way to create some sort of tenure security. Subletting of structures in settlements on illegally occupied
land is another form of the blend of legal with illegal. “Invasions” that are publicly announced and even invited
by the mayor as was practiced in Lima in the 1990s (Klaus Teschner, personal communication 1999) are a way of
guiding development through ‘informal’ planning.
4 Uwe Altrock on a colloquium of the DFG funded Priority Program “Megacities – Megachallenge. The Informal
Dynamics of Global Change“ in Berlin on May 10-11, 2010.
5 Interestingly Max Weber’s writings on the city (1921) appeared under the title „Die nichtlegitime Herrschaft“ [The
Illegitimate Mode of Rule]. Weber saw the medieval bourgeois „Zweckverband“ as emerging outside the traditional
legitimate patrimonial system – i. e. in terms of the formal-informal dichotomy as something ‘informal’.
6 Goethert (2005, 19) asks himself: “The customary perspective has been from the formal sector. But in the context
of our helplessness and the dominant role of the informal [sic!], who then is excluding whom? Perhaps it is us, the
minority formal sector of development planners that are the excluded and irrelevant?”
7 For the purpose of simplification we have defined the actors according to the Chinese system, however, we are
aware of the dynamics and moving actors, shifting roles etc. (see Ley 2010).
8 Rostalski in his dissertation (2010) provided a detailed analysis about the inter-relationship between formal urban
planning and informal occupation in the process of re-developing an abandoned 19th century industrial area in
Berlin, the RAW-area.
Urheberrechtlich geschütztes Material. Jede Verwertung außerhalb der engen Grenzen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes ist unzulässig und strafbar.
Das gilt insbesondere für Vervielfältigungen, Übersetzungen, Mikroverfilmungen und die Einspeicherung und Verarbeitungen in elektronischen Systemen.
© Franz Steiner Verlag, Stuttgart 2011

View publication stats

You might also like