You are on page 1of 9

Received: 9 February 2017 Revised: 23 April 2018 Accepted: 7 September 2018

DOI: 10.1002/pad.1838

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Incumbent bureaucrats: Why elections undermine civil service


reform in Indonesia
Ward Berenschot

Royal Netherlands Institute of Southeast


Asian and Caribbean Studies (KITLV), Leiden, Summary
The Netherlands This article develops an explanation for why democratisation processes sometimes fail
Correspondence
to foster effective civil service reform. Using ethnographic fieldwork on the evolving
Ward Berenschot, Royal Netherlands Institute
of Southeast Asian and Caribbean Studies relationship between civil servants and politicians in Lampung, a rural backwater in
(KITLV), Reuvensplaats 2, 2300 RA Leiden,
the southern tip in Sumatra, this paper attributes the ineffectiveness of bureaucratic
The Netherlands.
Email: berenschot@kitlv.nl reform measures in Indonesia to the way in which elections trigger competition over
Funding information control over state resources. I argue that a merit‐based bureaucracy is particularly dif-
Koninklijke Nederlandse Akademie van
Wetenschappen, Grant/Award Number:
ficult to institute when a local bureaucracy enjoys strong discretionary control over
SPIN3‐JRP‐56; Nederlandse Organisatie voor the distribution of state resources. During Suharto's authoritarian regime, this control
Wetenschappelijk Onderzoek, Grant/Award
Number: 451‐12‐013
rested largely in the hands of bureaucrats. This authoritarian legacy generates strong
incentives for politicians to prefer loyal bureaucrats over capable ones. Politicians
need to use bureaucratic appointments as a means to obtain campaign support and
to develop control over state resources. In developing these arguments, this paper
offers an approach to incorporate informal and clientelistic dimensions of politics
more explicitly into analyses of processes of bureaucratic reform.

KEY W ORDS

civil service reform, clientelism, democratisation, governance, Indonesia

1 | I N T RO D U CT I O N of good governance, because closer interaction between voters and pol-


iticians would further boost accountability (Crook & Manor, 1998).
It is often argued that democratisation and the institution of local This article discusses why, contrary to these expectations,
elections can serve to improve the quality of governance. A deepening Indonesia's democratisation process has largely failed to foster a more
of democratic accountability would pressurise politicians to introduce merit‐based bureaucracy. When Suharto's authoritarian regime ended
stricter oversight procedures and to engage in more merit‐based in 1998, he left Indonesia with a civil service that was not only highly
bureaucratic appointments. In order to boost their appeal to voters, corrupt but also very inward looking and unresponsive. One of the hopes
politicians would need to strengthen bureaucratic capacity and ensure of Indonesia's post‐Suharto reformasi (reform) was that decentralisation
a more effective implementation of government programmes and the institution of direct elections (in Nunberg & Taliercio, 2012)
(e.g., Besley, 2006). This “principal‐agent approach” underpins a range would serve to foster a more responsive bureaucracy staffed by civil ser-
of policy initiatives aimed at boosting “accountability relations,” such as vants appointed on the basis of merit rather than connections. Yet
those aimed at improving transparency, citizen participation, or achieving despite the adoption of a range of policies aimed at bureaucratic reform,
freedom of information (Brinkerhoff & Wetterberg, 2016; World Bank, various studies suggest that money and personal connections remain key
2003). Along these lines, decentralisation was promoted as a harbinger determinants of bureaucratic appointments. Kristiansen and Ramli

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided
the original work is properly cited.
© 2018 The Authors Public Administration and Development Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd

Public Admin Dev. 2018;38:135–143. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/pad 135


136 BERENSCHOT

(2006) find, for example, that aspirant bureaucrats still have to pay hefty 2 | BUREAUCRATIC REFORM IN
fees (of up to 27 times their starting salary) in order to enter the civil ser- PATRONAGE DEMOCRACIES
vice. Performance appraisals have little real impact, and promotions sim-
ilarly require sizable bribes (Turner, Imbaruddin, & Sutiyono, 2009). On Political clientelism refers to the practice of exchanging of personal ben-
the basis of interviews with civil servants, Blunt, Turner, and Lindroth efits (money, jobs, and privileged access to public services) for electoral
(2012a, p. 215; see also Blunt et al., 2012b) come to a particularly damn- support (Kitschelt & Wilkinson, 2007). The provision of state resources
ing conclusion: “[W] hat matters is who you know, what and who you can be termed clientelistic when recipients perceive these benefits to
pay, and to whom you pledge loyalty, [while] initiative, excellence and be contingent on their willingness to provide electoral support (Hicken,
results matter little” (see also Brinkerhoff & Wetterberg, 2013; Rosser 2011; Stokes, Dunning, Nazareno, & Brusco, 2013). The term “patronage
& Fahmi, 2016; Wihantoro, Lowe, Cooper, & Manochin, 2015). democracy” has gained currency to describe democracies where elec-
So why has Indonesia's democratisation process not been more toral mobilisation primarily takes such a clientelistic form (Chandra,
successful in fostering a merit‐based bureaucracy? Using ethnographic 2004). Here, the word “patronage” refers to the material benefits and
fieldwork on the evolving relationship between civil servants and pol- favours that politicians provide in exchange for electoral support.
iticians in Lampung, a rural backwater in the southern tip in Sumatra, In patronage democracies, a merit‐based bureaucracy is difficult
this article argues that the failure of bureaucratic reform measures in to institute because politicians face strong incentives to develop and
Indonesia is due to the way in which elections have triggered compe- maintain tight control over the appointments and promotions of civil
tition over control over state resources. In doing so, this article servants (Cruz & Keefer, 2015; Grindle, 2012; McCourt, Alarkoubi, &
responds to the call in recent literature on public sector management Bana, 2006). Studies on civil service reform increasingly highlight
for more “micro‐level studies of bureaucratic politics” (Berman, how the pervasiveness of clientelistic practices generates collective
2015; Brinkerhoff & Brinkerhoff, 2015; Pepinsky, Pierskalla, & Sacks, action problems that bedevil reform initiatives (Blunt, Turner, &
2017, p. 1316). Whereas this literature often focuses on technical Lindroth, 2013; Hodder, 2014; Nunberg & Taliercio, 2012; Srivastava
interventions and formal regulations, this article provides an approach & Larizza, 2013). These studies have in common that they all argue
to study how informal and clientelistic dimensions of politics shape that knowledge about the informal, inner workings of politics is essen-
prevailing incentive structures. I argue that a merit‐based bureaucracy tial to develop more effective policies that can “work with the grain”
is particularly difficult to institute when a local bureaucracy enjoys (Booth, 2011) of prevalent incentive structures.
strong discretionary control over the distribution of state resources. This literature offers two main reasons for why bureaucratic reform
In clientelistic political arenas, this discretionary control matters is difficult to enact in patronage democracies. First, for politicians who
greatly. When bureaucrats can use their control over distribution of rely on clientelistic practices to mobilise electoral support, bureaucratic
state benefits to cultivate their own support base, they develop an appointments are an important means to reward supporters (e.g.,
independent capacity to influence voting behaviour. In this context, Kopecký, Mair, & Spirova, 2012). Politicians need to use their discre-
politicians face strong incentives to appoint bureaucrats whose loyalty tionary control over such “jobs for the boys” (Grindle, 2012) to entice
is assured. The appointment of loyal bureaucrats serves politicians not and reward supporters. Second, in clientelistic political arenas, the
only to strengthen control over state resources but also to motivate appointment of loyal bureaucrats is an important instrument for politi-
bureaucrats to provide campaign support during elections. cians to strengthen their control over the distribution over state
I develop these arguments using ethnographic fieldwork on election resources. Politicians need the cooperation of bureaucrats to circum-
campaigns and their aftermath, undertaken between March 2013 and vent or ignore the formal procedures and criteria that stipulate an
August 2014 in Lampung, Banten, and Central Kalimantan (see Aspinall impersonal distribution of state benefits. Bureaucratic appointments
& Berenschot, 2019). While incorporating insights from research in these help to obtain that cooperation. The appointment of loyal bureaucrats
other regions (where my arguments are equally applicable), this paper serves politicians to manipulate the implementation of state policies to
focuses on North Lampung. During this fieldwork, I followed candidates direct state benefits to supporters (Golden, 2003; Piattoni, 2001).
for both district head and local parliament on the campaign trail while also There is a third, equally important reason why clientelistic politics
engaging a range of interviews with (in Lampung) about 35 civil servants, impedes bureaucratic reform: When bureaucratic actors are influential
politicians, and civil society actors. The advantage of such an ethno- vote brokers, politicians face strong incentives to use bureaucratic
graphic approach over purely interview‐based studies is that it enabled appointments as a means to cultivate their campaign support. When
the study of informal and sometimes secretive exchanges between politi- bureaucratic networks possess strong discretionary control over the dis-
cians and bureaucrats. As I hope this article will show, these informal tribution over state resources, they can accrue status and influence over
exchanges are crucial to understand the obstacles facing civil service voting behaviour. Democratisation processes incentivise politicians to
reform in clientelistic political systems. wrest this control and influence away from bureaucrats: Politicians need
This article proceeds as follows. The first section develops the to use bureaucratic appointments as both carrots and sticks to gain con-
paper's arguments in relation to the literature on clientelism and civil trol over resources and to entice bureaucrats to provide electoral support.
service reform. I then discuss the historical backdrop to civil service In the following, I use the term “discretionary control” to refer to
reform in Indonesia. The subsequent sections rely on fieldwork mate- the capacity to influence the allocation of state resources. In patronage
rial to identify continuities and changes in the relationship between democracies, political success depends to a large extent on a capacity
civil servants and the now‐elected district heads. The final section to influence the distribution of state resources. To be able to use state
concludes and highlights implications for civil service reform. resources to reward or entice voters in a clientelistic manner, politicians
BERENSCHOT 137

need to find ways to abolish or manipulate the formal, policy‐described During the New Order, the Indonesian State was described as a
manner of distributing state resources. This manipulation requires “bureaucratic polity” where “the bureaucracy [is] not accountable to
some degree of control over the implementation of such policies. This other political forces such as political parties (...) [P] arties, to the
makes (the establishment of) discretionary control an important deter- extent that they exist at all, neither control the central bureaucracy
minant of political success. Political parties compete against each other nor effectively organize the masses at the local level” (Jackson,
to establish this control. And they also compete with, particularly, 1978, p. 4). State resources were tightly controlled by the army and
bureaucrats who also derive considerable benefits from their control a powerful and centralised bureaucracy that seemed mainly concerned
over resources. The outcome of this competition differs from country with serving its own interests (Anderson, 1983). As political parties
to country. Particular trajectories of state and party formation enable and other outside pressures were too weak to impose discipline, the
different kinds of actors to gain the upper hand in this competition. state was seen as a “powerhouse” (Schiller, 1996) that dominated all
Shefter (1977) has influentially argued that when bureaucracies are other societal interests (see also Barker & Van Klinken, 2009).
completely autonomous and independent of political control, there can For analytical purposes, it is useful to compare such descriptions
be no clientelistic politics. Yet Shefter did not reckon with the possibility with the way in which Gunnar Myrdal famously described Third World
that autonomous bureaucrats themselves engage in clientelistic states in, particularly, South Asia. He considered countries like India
exchanges. As we shall see, an important legacy of the New Order— and Bangladesh as having “soft states” because of strong influence
Indonesia's period of authoritarian rule under Suharto (1965–1998)—is of outside social forces over the everyday functioning of the bureau-
that this capacity of Indonesian political parties and politicians to influence cracy. In these countries, politicians could use their control over
the allocation of state resources is relatively limited. This discretionary bureaucratic appointments to undermine the regulatory capacity of
control rests relatively strongly in the hands of bureaucratic actors who, the state (Myrdal, 1968). Not so in New Order Indonesia. Indonesian
during this period of authoritarian rule, became accustomed to distributing state institutions were seen as a “state‐for‐itself” as it could largely
state resources in a clientelistic manner. As we shall see, this history has focus on serving their own interests—not unlike the extractive, aloof
turned Indonesian state representatives into influential electoral agents. nature of its predecessor, the colonial state (Anderson, 1983). The
political party vehicle of the New Order, Golkar, was largely controlled
by the bureaucracy and the army. Its dependency on the bureaucracy
3 | CIVIL SERVICE REFORM AND THE NEW ORDER meant that the party never succeeded in establishing a capacity to dis-
cipline or control civil servants. Not only were most Golkar candidates
Bureaucratic reform has been an important element of the policy drawn from the bureaucracy, but the local government also basically
agenda of successive post‐Suharto governments. Spurred on by public manned its local branches (Liddle, 1985).
pressure and foreign donors, new laws—such as law 43/1999 on civil Government officials played an important role in maintaining sup-
service, law 32/2004 on local governance and most recently law 5/ port for Suharto's regime. Their capacity to withhold access to impor-
2014 on bureaucratic reform—have been adopted to establish a more tant resources, in combination with the status associated with their
merit‐based system of appointing and promoting civil servants. These position, meant that civil servants as well as village heads were gener-
laws outline new performance appraisal instruments, institute a civil ally considered capable of delivering a sizable portion of the votes at
service commission tasked with recruitment for the top echelons, the time the New Order's controlled elections. Under Suharto, it was
and pave the way for the appointment of outsiders to bureaucratic quite common for the civil service to use their control over the imple-
positions. A new Ministry for Manpower and Bureaucratic Reform mentation of government programs as a means to maintain support
was tasked with implementing these measures. At the same time, a for themselves and to quell resistance against the New Order. Local
massive decentralisation process has given local governments more state representatives were prone to present any provision of such
budgets and more freedom to carry out their own reforms (Nordholt benefits as entailing an obligation to reciprocate these favours—by
& Klinken, 2007). Some local politicians have displayed commitment supporting either Golkar or themselves (Antlöv, 1995).
for bureaucratic reform by adopting measures like “fit‐and‐proper This lack of outside pressure gave civil servants and state repre-
tests,” which require bureaucrats to pass certain benchmarks before sentatives considerable freedom to engage in various forms of rent
being appointed to more senior positions. Particularly Jakarta's previ- seeking, effectively imposing an informal tax system in most sectors
ous governor, Basuki Tjahaja Purnama (“Ahok”) made himself popular of the economy (McLeod, 2008). As long as orders from above were
with voters by engaging in unannounced spot checks and posting his faithfully executed and their superiors were kept happy, civil servants
subsequent scolding of underperforming bureaucrats online. faced little restraint—and often open encouragement—to supplement
Such reform measures were badly needed. During Suharto's their meagre budgets and salaries by exploiting state power.
authoritarian regime, a bureaucratic career was relatively safe as long Observers (Crouch, 1979) used the term “neo‐patrimonial” to describe
as civil servants supported Golkar and pleased their superiors. The the ways in which senior officials used their discretionary powers over
phrase rajin malas pendapatan sama (“the diligent and the lazy get the distribution of state resources to gain supporters and wealth and
the same salary”) was commonly used to describe the incentive struc- to cement their own position. Although Suharto's regime had achieved
ture, whereas the expression asal bapak senang (“as long as the boss is substantial economic growth and welfare gains, when Suharto stepped
happy”) captures the work ethic. Loyalty to one's superiors and skilled down in 1998, it had become apparent that the character of bureau-
internal politicking were considered more important for career cratic appointments was damaging for both bureaucratic capacity
advancement than actual performance. and public service delivery (Rohdewohld, 1995).
138 BERENSCHOT

For the purpose of this paper, two features of this very brief to vote for Zainal. One of the village heads I followed pasted campaign
description of the New Order bureaucracy are particularly important. stickers of Zainal Abidin above the door of each house where he felt
First, Indonesia embarked on its democratisation process with a he had convinced the inhabitants. At another village, the village head
bureaucracy that enjoyed high levels of discretionary power over the had gone as far as hanging a campaign poster of Zainal Abidin above
distribution of state resources. Indonesia's bureaucracy had remained the door of the village office—sparking an official complaint from the
largely independent of outside control from, for example, political campaign team of his adversary Agung, after which the poster was
parties. Second, an important heritage of Indonesia's recent authori- duly removed. A head of the education department justified his own
tarian past is the practice of local state representatives to use state campaign involvement by saying “In this election, we are all
resources to shore up political support. Their control over state incumbents.”
resources turned civil servants and the village and neighbourhood In fact, as the head of Zainal's campaign team acknowledged (I will
heads into influential local leaders, capable of delivering a considerable call him Fermin), the involvement of civil servants and village heads
number of votes. To illustrate how this particular inheritance shapes formed a cornerstone of Zainal's campaign strategy:
the current interaction between civil servants and the now‐elected
The incumbent district head makes use of his civil
district heads, we will now turn to North Lampung. In this rural and
servants, from his civil servants to the village heads.
relatively poor district, an unpopular incumbent, Zainal Abidin, lost
They become part of his campaign team. Bureaucracy
the 2014 election for district head against a low‐ranking bureaucrat,
should be apolitical, but they are manipulated by the
Agung Mangkunegara.
incumbent. Particularly the pejabat [civil servants
holding a higher‐level, fixed position), the department
heads, the section heads, the sub‐district heads
4 | B U R E A U C R A T S A S CA N V A S S E R S
(camats), they are all co‐opted. They need to protect
their position, so they want the incumbent to win.
When Zainal Abidin's campaign caravan pulled up in one of Lampung's
many remote villages, he was not welcomed by party members. Fermin's strategising helps explain why interviewed civil servants felt
Instead, when he—and the trailing researcher—got out of the car, we that they “were all incumbents.” If Zainal lost the elections, civil ser-
were welcomed by local members of Zainal's tim sukses (“success vants in senior positions would risk being transferred or, worse still,
team”), the Indonesian term for the largely ad hoc campaign organisa- be dinonjobkan, the Indonesian term for civil servants who are not
tions that candidates build up around them (see Aspinall, 2014). These assigned to any official position. “Nonjobbed” civil servants would still
tim sukses are usually made up of a varied mix of personal friends, fam- draw a small salary but they lose the (considerable) perks and side
ily members, professional contacts, and also community leaders and incomes that come with a position. The fear of losing these benefits
heads of local organisations. A candidate with good prospects gener- gave the sitting subdistrict heads (camats) and department heads con-
ally also attracts a large pool of local level volunteers who help out siderable interests in Zainal's victory.
with basic campaign tasks, often with the hope that this support will Particularly the most local representatives of Indonesia's govern-
translate into a favour—budgets for improving village amenities, a gov- ment, the village heads and neighbourhood heads (called RT and RW
ernment contract, or a job—after the elections. Zainal had a tim sukses heads), have become highly sought‐after brokers in Indonesia's post‐
in almost every village we visited. Before we arrived, they had put up Suharto patronage democracy. As elected and respected community
the stage, handed out the water to guests, and prepared the food that problem solvers, their role in controlling access to government pro-
would be served. These tim sukses members wore Zainal's campaign grams has increased. This provides them with a power to influence
t‐shirts that carried his picture and campaign slogan (lanjutkan!i.e., local electoral outcomes that is enjoyed by few other actors. In theory,
“continue!”), but it did carry any party logo's. Zainal had an impressive a sitting district head has less leverage over such village and
coalition of political parties supporting him, yet only some of these tim neighbourhood heads. They are not civil servants. They are elected
sukses members identified themselves as party members. by villagers and the district head cannot transfer them. Yet, as Fermin
Instead, Zainal Abidin's election campaign relied heavily on the described, there are other pressure points available: “The village heads
district's bureaucratic apparatus. At these village‐level campaign often also want to join [the campaign] because of the money that they
events, Zainal was generally introduced by the village head who never get from the government structure. If they do not support the bupati,
failed to mention the budgets and programs Zainal had granted to the the budgets [for infrastructure and public services] might be pulled
village. I regularly met department heads, police officials, and subdis- [from the village].” Rumour had it that Zainal Abidin had organised a
trict heads (camat) who were expected to talk about Zainal's programs. large gathering of all the village heads of North Lampung where he
During this particular campaign event, for example, the head of the promised them 50 million rupiah (approx. 4000 USD) if their village
public works department went around handing out official letters delivered a large majority. And for those village heads who would still
proving that Zainal Abidin had allocated a budget for the electrifica- not support Zainal, a subtle form of intimidation was applied. One vil-
tion of that particular village. lage head described the pressurising he experienced as follows: “It is
These bureaucrats did more than attending campaign events. difficult for the village head to remain neutral [during elections]. That
Many of them were members of his tim sukses. They were also is because the budget comes from the district government (…) And
involved in actual door‐to‐door campaigning, going around visiting the bupati has intel, he follows the village heads. If someone does
family members, friends, and dependents to remind them of the need not support him, he tries to find a fault in the implementation of a
BERENSCHOT 139

program. The police will be instructed to arrest him. I know a village and village heads], because they need them to get their KTP (identity
head who ended up in jail in this way.” card) or, for example, if they get married. So their loyalty can be forced
(terpaksa).” Fermin's formulation hints at an element of threat: If voters
went against the preferred candidate of their village head or subdis-
5 | I N C U M B E N T B U R E A U CR A T S trict head, their access to state benefits might be curtailed.
This influence of local state representatives is not just based on
This direct involvement of civil servants and village heads in election fear, however. Their influence is also bolstered by the feelings of grat-
campaigns is also observed in other parts of Indonesia (e.g., Buehler, itude and social obligations that the provision of state benefits gener-
2009; Ngusmanto, 2016). Yet it is actually illegal. In reaction to ates. By providing access to welfare programs, awarding an
Suharto's instrumentalisation of the bureaucratic apparatus, a clause infrastructure grant to a village, or simply helping to arrange an iden-
in law 32/2004 on Regional Government forbids civil servants from tity card, local state representatives accrue a form of hutang budi or
providing campaign support to candidates during election campaigns. “moral debt.” Their involvement in providing access to such benefits
The campaign involvement of civil servants is even more remarkable generates a sense of obligation among recipients that they should
in comparative perspective. In most countries, election campaigns reciprocate at election time. As a local academic observer put it in
are organised and staffed by party members and personal supporters, an interview: “If people do not vote according to their wishes [of civil
not by civil servants (see Stokes et al., 2013). Yet in Indonesia, perhaps servants] and their advice then they will feel dilecehkan (‘abused’ or
together with a few countries like the Philippines and Thailand (see ‘offended’). There is reciprocal relationship between people that will
Arghiros, 2001), parties are relatively marginal in the organisation of consequently be damaged [if this advice is not followed].” Such con-
election campaigns and organisation of clientelistic exchanges, siderations also regularly surfaced in the considerations of voters dur-
whereas local state representatives are relatively prominent. ing interviews. For example, one voter discussed his attitude towards
So what explains this illegal and, comparatively speaking, unusual vote buying in the following terms: “we take money from all [the can-
prominence of Indonesia's bureaucratic apparatus in election cam- didates], but we usually vote for the one close to pak [mr.] RT [the
paigns? The answer to this question lies in the considerable discretion- neighbourhood head]. Because he is close to us, and he manages
ary control that civil servants still exert over state resources, and the things for us.”
influence that, as a result of this control, civil servants still exert over With such observations, I do not mean to imply that bureaucrats
voters. As highlighted above, during Suharto's New Order, most state and village heads possess full control over voting behaviour. Voters
resources flowed through the bureaucracy with little grassroot pres- often do not heed their advice or they might be swayed by opinions
ence for political parties. This pattern endures. Although some frag- of other leaders such as religious leaders or customary leaders. In local
mentation has occurred, much discretionary control over the elections, the bureaucratic apparatus is just one among many social
distribution of state benefits still rests in the hands of bureaucratic networks that candidates tried to mobilise to obtain support (see
networks (Aspinall, 2013). Teachers and school principals can deter- Aspinall & Berenschot, 2019; Aspinall & Sukmajati, 2016; Erb &
mine the school admissions that can determine the future of students Sulistiyanto, 2009). For example, Agung—who, as a challenger, could
(Rosser & Fahmi, 2016). Local health workers, together with village hardly rely on the bureaucratic apparatus—incorporated a more varied
heads, make important decisions about who will get fast treatment mixture of his own extended family, customary leaders and the net-
of a doctor along with subsidised healthcare (Berenschot, Hanani, & works of his supporting parties into his campaign—which enabled
Sambodho, 2018). Village heads can influence the selection of recipi- him to win the elections. My point, however, is that in comparison
ents of welfare programs and cash transfers (Mulyadi, 2013). A little with such alternative networks, Indonesia's local bureaucratic appara-
higher up in the bureaucracy individuals like the camat (subdistrict tus remains a relatively strong instrument for electoral mobilisation
heads) or the department heads still control the rich fountain of gov- because their discretionary control over state benefits lends local state
ernment projects, grants, licences and subsidies on which many small representatives considerable influence.
businesses and their workers depend for their livelihood. Though in
theory all such programs and services are implemented according to
impersonal rules and criteria, in practice, they often involve 6 | A P O L I TI C I S E D B U R E A U C R A C Y
favouritism, bribes, and exchanges of favours. In this sense, the
imprint of Indonesia's authoritarian regime can still be observed: Civil This electoral importance of the local bureaucratic apparatus is, I
servants still hold the key to access important resources and benefits. argue, a key obstacle for bureaucratic reform in Indonesia because it
Because of this considerable discretionary control over state ben- incentivises politicians to use bureaucratic appointments as a means
efits, state representatives possess a considerable capacity to deliver to obtain and maintain the support of civil servants and, through them,
votes. In the context of a largely clientelistic political arena, this discre- village and neighbourhood heads. The travails of Taufik, a staff mem-
tionary control over the provision of welfare programs, public services, ber of the North Lampung fisheries department, can serve to illustrate
and government contracts (etc.) constitutes important political capital this relationship between bureaucratic appointments and the charac-
because civil servants (and village heads) can use the provision of ter of election campaigns. When I first met Taufik, he was full of anx-
these state benefits to influence voting behaviour. Pak Fermin, for iety. It was the week before the district‐head elections, and Taufik
example, discussed the political influence of the local bureaucratic kept asking me who I think would win. He had been openly supporting
apparatus in the following terms: “People follow them [civil servants the challenger Agung and was worried that his career would suffer if
140 BERENSCHOT

Agung lost. He lamented how most of his colleagues had been These practices motivate civil servants like Taufik to become
supporting the incumbent, Zainal Abidin, to protect their jobs. When involved in an election campaign. This involvement might reduce the
Agung actually won the elections, Taufik's anxiety was not yet over: costs of getting a promotion. Such exchanges might lead to other, less
In his remaining 2 months in office before Agung's appointment, Zainal supportive bureaucrats losing their position—who might have invested
Abidin effected a big transfer of a large number of civil servants. This a considerable amount of money to obtain that position. The result is
practice is referred to as rolling pejabat or the “rolling of officials.” This that particularly district head elections generate considerable anxiety
“rolling” was perceived as an attempt to reward and punish bureau- and internal divisions within local bureaucracies. Fermin describes
crats for their (lack of) support. Taufik was transferred to a remote vil- these divisions as follows:
lage, 20 km from the district capital.
the non‐structural civil servants tend to support the non‐
But that sacrifice had paid off. After Agung took office, he quickly
incumbents. Because they hope that if the incumbent
returned Taufik to the district capital and made him subdivision head.
loses, the positions will be changed. The civil servants in
When I interviewed him just after the transfer, he seemed happy with
structural positions defend their position and the non‐
himself for his decision to get involved in politics:
structural are hoping for a better position. (…) As they
Your career can develop through political involvement, say, “beda pendapat karena berbeda pendapatan” (“a
not through working. Throughout the coming five years difference of opinion because of a difference in salary”).
when they [i.e. Agung] are still in office my career will
Fermin refers to an important distinction in Indonesia's bureau-
be good. After that I have to make another effort [i.e.
cratic apparatus. With “structural,” he refers to civil servants or PNS
during elections] or I could be dumped. Now I can give
(pegawai negeri sipil) in management positions (“pejabat”) such as heads
orders to [my superior] while he used to give me orders.
of departments (kepala dinas) or subdistrict heads (camat). They face
He is my senior [and still] I can give him orders.
strong incentives to support the incumbent during elections to safe-
According to Taufik, his promotion had little to with performance, and guard their positions. This is different for staff members in junior posi-
all the more with his decision to support the challenger Agung during tions (like Taufik) and as well as civil servants in “nonstructural” or
the district head elections. Taufik's strategising and particularly his functional positions (usually involved in technical or specific low‐paid
delight needs to be interpreted in the context of the considerable tasks such as teaching and public service maintenance). As Fermin
sums of money that civil servants often have to pay to ensure a pro- pointed out, for this diverse group of junior bureaucrats, the electoral
motion or a transfer to a particularly “wet” position—something he victory of a challenger might lead to the kind of career leap that Taufik
could avoid by supporting Agung. The purchase of bureaucratic office experienced.
remains a common practice in post‐Suharto Indonesia. During the In this light, it is important to emphasise that these clientelistic
New Order, such fees were already the norm, but research suggests appointments do not only take place at the initiative of politicians—
that Indonesia's democratisation process has been accompanied by a common assumption in the literature on clientelism (e.g., Kopecký
an increase of such fees (see Blunt et al., 2012a; Kristiansen & Ramli, et al., 2012). Many bureaucrats, like Taufik, associate themselves with
2006). In early 2017, in an investigation of the national Corruption an election campaign at their own volition, as a conscious strategy to
Eradication Commission into graft in Klaten district in Central Java, it boost their career. Some of the civil servants I encountered put their
emerged that the local district head had been collecting fees, ranging own money into an election campaigns, reasoning that the money
from 5 to 15 million rupiah (about 1200 USD) for postings to adminis- they spend on vote buying would serve to curry favour with the dis-
trative jobs in local health centres to up to 400 million (30,000 USD) trict head. After the elections, such efforts serve to pressurise the
to head certain local government bureaus.1 district head or governor to provide the desired promotion. This is
This practice of levying fees on bureaucrats is an important driver why after the elections winning candidates often find themselves
of rent seeking and corruption. As civil servants generally put them- reeling under the constant lobbying of bureaucrats. The new district
selves in considerable debt in order to pay such fees, they face consid- head Agung admitted as much when I interviewed him about his
erable pressure to recoup this investment through the solicitation of bureaucratic appointments: “There were not many civil servants
pungli (“wild fees,”i.e., bribes) from citizens and businesses. The size who dared to support me [during the elections], only my family mem-
of these fees and their apparent increase over the last decade are bers. But look how the rolling has worked out. It is fifty‐fifty [i.e. the
closely related to the cost of election campaigns. The advent of direct ratio between appointments of his supporters and Zainal's]. Only in
elections for district heads and governors has forced politicians to some cases, when there are indications of misconduct, have I
engage in expensive election campaigns. As political parties hardly removed some of Zainal's people. Nowadays many people are disap-
contribute, candidates largely need to shoulder these costs themselves pointed with me, [they say] ‘Why have certain people not been
(Mietzner, 2013; author). As a result, incumbent regional government appointed?’”
heads often levy fees on bureaucrats as a way to recover the costs These internal tensions are generating nostalgia for the certainties
of their election campaigns. that civil servants enjoyed during the New Order. Even civil servants
who opt to remain neutral during election still experience considerable
anxiety at the prospect they might lose their position to supporters of
1
“Suap Bupati, Ini Daftar Harga Jabatan di Pemkab Klaten,” Tempo, January 6,
2017. At: https://m.tempo.co/read/news/2017/01/06/078833341/suap‐ the winning candidate. As one of Taufik's colleagues in North
bupati‐ini‐daftar‐harga‐jabatan‐di‐pemkab‐klaten Lampung's fisheries department said:
BERENSCHOT 141

During the New Order there was no internal conflict implementation of these new policies will be an uphill struggle in the
because everybody supported Golkar [Suharto's political coming years. As Grindle (2012) observed in the United States and
party]. Then, to get a promotion, the advice of the head Latin America, political actors can delay the actual implementation of
of the department was enough. He gave the letter and such reforms for decades if they do not serve their interests.
the [district head] signed it. Now if the department
head wants to promote someone, it is not guaranteed
that the district head will agree. Because it depends on
[this person's] political activities. If a civil servant does
7 | C O N C L U S I O N S : C I V I L SE R V I C E R E F O R M
not support and vote for the winner, that is gawat
AND DISCRETIONARY CONTROL
(“grave”) and dangerous. You can lose your position.
In this article, I discussed how and why democratisation processes
What emerges is chaos and confusion if a new [district
sometimes fail to foster a more merit‐based bureaucracy. Focusing
head] comes in. What happens is that people are often
on district‐level politics in Lampung, Indonesia, I showed that historical
not used any more, they are non‐jobbed.
patterns of control over state resources generate incentives that pre-
This kind of anxiety is acute during election campaigns, as bureaucrats vent politicians from engaging in merit‐based bureaucratic appoint-
worry about how the election result might influence their income and ments. Indonesia's democratisation process unfolded in the context
career opportunities during, at least, the coming 4 years. The situation of a bureaucratic apparatus with a, in comparison with political parties,
hardly improves in the months after the elections, when bureaucrats relatively strong control over the distribution of state resources. This
fiercely lobby winning candidate to secure promotions. As Taufik legacy is forcing politicians to use bureaucratic appointments as a
described the situation in his department 3 months after the elections: means to obtain campaign support and to develop control over state
“Right now, the government does not work. None of us work. Only 10 resources.
percent [of civil servants] supported Agung while eighty percent sup- These arguments tie into a growing perception that approaches
ported Zainal [the incumbent]. My friends are saying, ‘for what should associated with “New Public Management” are of limited use to deal
we work if we are all non‐jobbed tomorrow?’ Right now we cannot with the challenges facing reformers in developing countries
work. People are just marking time.” As another senior civil servant (Brinkerhoff & Brinkerhoff, 2015) as technical fixes and institutional
in Lampung remarked perhaps somewhat overly nostalgically, “before designs often fail to have the desired impact on prevailing incentive
[i.e. during the New Order] the people were placed in position accord- structures. In this paper, I provided an approach to incorporate infor-
ing to their skills and knowledge. Now a non‐technical person gets a mal dimensions of politics more explicitly into analyses of these
technical position. Here [in the fisheries department] we have a law incentive structures. Reform initiatives need to deal more explicitly
graduate, and a graduate in religious studies.” and effectively with the often fierce competition over discretionary
In making such transfers of bureaucrats, district heads and gover- control over state resources that democratisation processes unleash.
nors have benefited from the new regulatory frameworks that were It is not only in Indonesia that democratisation process spark largely
adopted as part of Indonesia's decentralisation process. When, after hidden, subterranean competition between bureaucrats and politi-
1999, local governments were entrusted with more budgets and reg- cians over the spoils of office. Politicians are trying to establish firmer
ulatory freedoms, regional government heads also acquired much free- control over the implementation of policies and government pro-
dom to move civil servants around between jobs (while their freedom grams, which boosts their electoral chances. For their part, bureau-
to appoint new civil servants is actually quite limited). The new Civil crats face powerful financial reasons to resist such political
Service Law (UU ASN 5/2014) attempts to curtail this discretionary meddling. In this ongoing competition over control over state
freedom of regional government heads. This law established civil ser- resources bureaucratic appointments are a powerful instrument that
vice committees with the authority to oversee recruitment and pro- might in Indonesia tip the balance in favour of politicians in the com-
motion of senior civil servants. Furthermore, a recent instruction ing decades. Until that time, politicians will prefer loyal bureaucrats
from the Ministry of manpower forbade district heads and governors over capable ones.
to transfer civil servants until 6 months after their inauguration as
regional head.2 As my fieldwork was conducted before these new reg- ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
ulations came into effect, I could not observe their impact. It is none- I thank Edward Aspinall and Gerry van Klinken for their support and
theless notable that regional government heads and parliamentarians helpful comments on earlier drafts. I am very grateful to Syarif Abadi
have actively resisted the installation of these committees, claiming for unequalled fieldwork assistance.
them to be unnecessary.3 The observations reported in this paper—
particularly concerning how regional government heads regularly FUNDING
ignore or circumvent existing regulation—suggest that the
This research project was funded by grants from the Netherlands
Organization for Scientific Research (Nederlandse Organisatie voor
2
See http://www.menpan.go.id/berita‐terkini/4437‐sebelum‐6‐bulan‐kepala‐
Wetenschappelijk Onderzoek, Veni Grant 451‐12‐013) and a SPIN
daerah‐dilarang‐ganti‐pejabat
grant from the Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences
3
See “KSP: Komisi Aparatur Sipil Negara Masih Diperlukan,” Kompas, Jan 23,
2017. http://nasional.kompas.com/read/2017/01/23/17535021/ksp.komisi. (Koninklijke Nederlandse Akademie van Wetenschappen, Grant
aparatur.sipil.negara.masih.diperlukan SPIN3‐JRP‐56).
142 BERENSCHOT

ORCID Erb, M., & Sulistiyanto, P. (Eds.) (2009). Deepening democracy in Indonesia?:
Direct elections for local leaders (Pilkada). Singapore: Institute of South-
Ward Berenschot http://orcid.org/0000-0002-5459-0785 east Asian Studies.
Golden, M. A. (2003). Electoral connections: The effects of the personal
RE FE R ENC E S vote on political patronage, bureaucracy and legislation in postwar
Anderson, B. R. G. (1983). Old State, new society: Indonesia's new order in Italy. British Journal of Political Science, 33(02), 189–212.
comparative historical perspective. The Journal of Asian Studies, 42(03), Grindle, M. S. (2012). Jobs for the boys: Patronage and the state in compar-
477–496. ative perspective. Harvard: Harvard University Press.
Antlöv, H. (1995). Exemplary centre, administrative periphery: Rural leader- Hicken, A. (2011). Clientelism. Annual Review of Political Science, 14(1),
ship and the new order in Java. Richmond: Curzon Press Ltd. 289–310. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.polisci.031908.220508
Arghiros, D. (2001). Democracy, development and decentralization in provin-
Hodder, R. (2014). Merit versus kinship: A category mistake? The case of
cial Thailand. Richmond: Curzon.
the Philippine civil service. Public Administration and Development,
Aspinall, E. (2013). A nation in fragments: Patronage and neoliberalism in 34(5), 370–388.
contemporary Indonesia. Critical Asian Studies, 45(1), 27–54.
Jackson, K. D. (1978). Bureaucratic polity: A theoretical framework for the
Aspinall, E. (2014). When brokers betray: Clientelism, social networks, and analysis of power and communications in Indonesia. In K. D. Jackson, &
electoral politics in Indonesia. Critical Asian Studies, 46(4), 545–570. L. Pye (Eds.), Political power and communications in Indonesia (pp. 3–22).
Aspinall, E., & Berenschot, W. (2019). Democracy for sale: Elections, Berkeley: University of California Press.
clientelism and the state in Indonesia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. I. (2007). Patrons, clients and policies: Patterns
Aspinall, E., & Sukmajati, M. (2016). Electoral dynamics in Indonesia: Money of democratic accountability and political competition. Cambridge:
politics, patronage and clientelism at the grassroots. Singapore: NUS Cambridge University Press.
Press. Kopecký, P., Mair, P., & Spirova, M. (2012). Party patronage and party gov-
Barker, J., & Van Klinken, G. (2009). Reflections on the state in Indonesia. ernment in European democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
In G. Van Klinken, & J. Barker (Eds.), State of authority: The state in soci- Kristiansen, S., & Ramli, M. (2006). Buying an income: The market for civil
ety in Indonesia (pp. 17–45). Ithaca: Cornell University Press. service positions in Indonesia, Contemporary Southeast Asia. A Journal
Berenschot, W., Hanani, R., & Sambodho, P. (2018). Brokers and citizen- of International and Strategic Affairs, 28(2), 207–233.
ship: Access to health care in Indonesia. Journal of Citizenship Studies, Liddle, R. W. (1985). Soeharto's Indonesia: Personal rule and political insti-
22(2). tutions. Pacific Affairs, 58(1), 68–90.
Berman, E. M. (2015). HRM in development: Lessons and frontiers. Public McCourt, W., Alarkoubi, K., & Bana, B. (2006). The human factor in gover-
Administration and Development, 35(2), 113–127. nance: Managing public employees in Africa and Asia. London: Palgrave
Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents?: The political economy of good govern- Macmillan.
ment. Oxford: Oxford University Press. McLeod, R. H. (2008). Inadequate budgets and salaries as instruments for
Blunt, P., Turner, M., & Lindroth, H. (2012a). Patronage, service delivery, institutionalizing public sector corruption in Indonesia. South East Asia
and social justice in Indonesia. International Journal of Public Administra- Research, 16(2), 199–223.
tion, 35(3), 214–220. Mietzner, M. (2013). Money, power, and ideology: Political parties in post‐
Blunt, P., Turner, M., & Lindroth, H. (2012b). Patronage's progress in post‐ authoritarian Indonesia. Singapore: Asian Studies Association of
Soeharto Indonesia. Public Administration and Development, 32(1), Australia.
64–81. Mulyadi. (2013). Welfare regime, social conflict, and clientelism in Indonesia
Blunt, P., Turner, M., & Lindroth, H. (2013). Morton's fork: “Democracy” (PhD dissertation), Australian National University, Canberra.
versus neopatrimonialism in developing countries. International Journal
Myrdal, G. (1968). Asian drama, an inquiry into the poverty of nations. New
of Public Administration, 36(1), 45–62.
York: Pantheon.
Booth, D. (2011). Introduction: Working with the grain? The Africa power
Ngusmanto (2016). Pilkada 2015 and patronage practice among bureau-
and politics programme. IDS Bulletin, 42(2), 1–10.
crat in West Kalimantan, Indonesia. Asian Social Science, 12(9), 236.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Brinkerhoff, J. M. (2015). Public sector management
Nordholt, H. S., & Klinken, G. v. (Eds.) (2007). Renegotiating boundaries:
reform in developing countries: Perspectives beyond NPM orthodoxy.
Local politics in post‐Suharto Indonesia. Leiden: KITLV Press.
Public Administration and Development, 35(4), 222–237.
Nunberg, B., & Taliercio, R. R. (2012). Sabotaging civil service reform in aid‐
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Wetterberg, A. (2013). Performance‐based public
dependent countries: Are donors to blame? World Development, 40(10),
management reforms: Experience and emerging lessons from service
1970–1981.
delivery improvement in Indonesia. International Review of Administra-
tive Sciences, 79(3), 433–457. Pepinsky, T. B., Pierskalla, J. H., & Sacks, A. (2017). Bureaucracy and ser-
vice delivery. Annual Review of Political Science, 20, 249–268.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Wetterberg, A. (2016). Gauging the effects of social
accountability on services, governance, and citizen empowerment. Piattoni, S. (Ed.) (2001). Clientelism, interests, and democratic representation:
Public Administration Review, 76(2), 274–286. The European experience in historical and comparative perspective.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Buehler, M. (2009). The rising importance of personal networks in Indone-
sian local politics: An analysis of district government head elections in Rohdewohld, R. (1995). Public administration in Indonesia. Melbourne:
South Sulawesi in 2005. In M. Erb, & P. Sulistiyanto (Eds.), Deepening Monash University Press.
democracy in Indonesia (pp. 101–125). Singapore: ISEAS. Rosser, A., & Fahmi, M. (2016). The political economy of teacher manage-
Chandra, K. (2004). Why ethnic parties succeed: Patronage and ethnic head ment in decentralized Indonesia. Washington: World Bank.
counts in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schiller, J. W. (1996). Developing Jepara: State and society in New Order
Crook, R. C., & Manor, J. (1998). Democracy and decentralisation in South Indonesia. Clayton, Victoria: Monash Asia Inst.
Asia and West Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Shefter, M. (1977). Party and Patronage: Germany, England, and Italy. Pol-
Crouch, H. (1979). Patrimonialism and military rule in Indonesia. World itics and Society, 7(4), 403–451.
Politics, 31(4), 571–587. Srivastava, V., & Larizza, M. (2013). Working with the grain for reforming
Cruz, C., & Keefer, P. (2015). Political parties, clientelism, and bureaucratic the public service: A live example from Sierra Leone. International
reform. Comparative Political Studies, 48(14), 1942–1973. Review of Administrative Sciences, 79(3), 458–485.
BERENSCHOT 143

Stokes, S. C., Dunning, T., Nazareno, M., & Brusco, V. (2013). Brokers, World Bank (2003). Making services work for poor people. Washington, DC:
voters, and clientelism: The puzzle of distributive politics. Cambridge: The World Bank.
Cambridge University Press.
Turner, M., Imbaruddin, A., & Sutiyono, W. (2009). Human resource man-
agement: The forgotten dimension of decentralisation in Indonesia. How to cite this article: Berenschot W. Incumbent bureau-
Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 45(2), 231–249. crats: Why elections undermine civil service reform in Indone-
Wihantoro, Y., Lowe, A., Cooper, S., & Manochin, M. (2015). Bureaucratic sia. Public Admin Dev. 2018;38:135–143. https://doi.org/
reform in post‐Asian Crisis Indonesia: The directorate general of tax.
10.1002/pad.1838
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 31, 44–63.

You might also like