You are on page 1of 163

)(

)(
)(
)(
"State Building in Latin America can only be described as a magisterial book. Vl )(

Soifer provides both a rich theoretical explanation for why states develop o )(
)(
)(
)(
or not and then presents a wealth of data to support his claims. Bringing in )(
)(
the poli ti cal origins and consequences of bureaucratic recruitment links it to )(
)(
the best work in a Weberian tradition . Important for both those interested )(

in state development and students of the region."


- Miguel Angel Centeno, Professor of Sociology and
STATE ~
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(
International Relations, Princeton University )(

BUILDING
)(
)(
)(
)(
"The biggest obstaCie to public goods delivery around the world is not )(
)(
authoritarianism but state weakness. In a model example of comparative- )(
)(
historical social science, Hillel Soifer traces subtle contemporary variations
~
in Latin American state capacity to fascinatingly divergent historical
constellations of political geography, ideology, and strategy. Buoyed by
IN )(
)(
)(
)(
)(
original theorizing and buttressed by a wealth of qualitative and quantitative )(
)(
evidence, State Building in Latin America is a book that will last."
- Dan Slater, Associate Professor of Political Science,
University of Chicago
LATIN )(
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(

~
"This book is a majar contribution to our understanding of state building in
Latin America. Soifer shows, as no one else has, that state-building outcomes
AME RICA )(
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(
depended on both early decisions to build the state and the fate of these
~
efforts when undertaken. The explanation neatly combines factors empha- )(
.)(
)(
sizing ideology and political choices with those stressing the centrality of )(
)(
urban centers during the liberal era. The overaII account offers powerful )(

generalizations while simultaneously remaining sensitive to the particulari- ~


)(
)(
ties of state building in Chile, Colombia, Mexico, and Peru." )(
)(
)(
- James Mahoney, Gordon Fulcher Professor in Decision-Making, ' )(
Northwestern University ~
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(
)(

~
)(
)(

Cover design by James F. Brisson Hillel David Soifer )(


)(
)(
)(
'w'
State Building in Latin America

State Building in Latín America diverges from existing scholarship


in developing explanations both for why state-building efforts in the
region emerged and for their success or failure. First, Latin American
state leaders chose to attempt concerted state building only where
they saw it as the means to political order and economic develop-
ment. Fragmented regionalism led to the adoption of more laissez-faire
ideas and the rejection of state building. With dominant urban centers,
developmentalist ideas and state-building efforts took hold, but not
ali state-building projects succeeded. The second plank of the book's
argument centers on strategies of bureaucratic appointment to explain
this variation. Filling administrative ranks with local elites caused even
concerted state-building efforts to flounder, while appointing outsiders
to serve as administrators underpinned success. Relying on extensive
archiva! evidence, the book traces how these factors shaped the differ-
ential development of education, taxation, and conscription in Chile,
Colombia, Mexico, and Peru.

Hillel David Soifer is an assistant professor of political science at


Temple University. His research has been published in journals such
as Comparative Political Studies, Studies in Comparative International
Development, and Latín American Research Review. He was awarded
the 2013 Alexander George Award for Best Article by the Qualitative
and Multi-Method Section of theAmerican Political ScienceAssociation,
and has served as the Peggy Rockefeller Visiting Scholar at the David
Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies at Harvard University.
State Building in Latin America

HILLEL DAVID SOIFER


Temple University

CAMBRIDGE
UNIVERSITY PRESS
CAMBRIDGE Contents
UNIVERSITY PRESS

32 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10013-2473, USA

Cambridge University Press is part of the University of Cambridge.


lt furthers the University's mission by disseminating knowledge in the pursuit of
education, learning, and research at the highest internacional levels of excellence.

www.cambridge.org
lnformation on this title: www.cambridge.org/978no7107878
© Hillel David Soifer 2015
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception Acknowledgments
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, page ix
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written Abbreviations
Xlll
permission of Cambridge University Press.
Annual Official Government Publications
First published 2015 Used, by Library!Archive Location XV
Printed in Great Bátain by Clays Ltd, St !ves ple
Introduction: The Origins of State Capacity in Latin Arnerica I
A catalog record for this p11blication is available from the British Library. Two Questions
3
Library of Congress Cataloging in Pztblication Data The Emergence of State-Building Projects
4
Soifer, Hillel David The Success of State-Building Projects
Sta te building in Latin America I Hillel David Soifer, Temple University. 5
Studying Intra-Regional Variation 6
pages cm
State Capacity: Concepts and Measures
ISBN 978-1-107-rn787-8 (hardback) 9
I. Nation-building - Latin America. 2. Political development - State Capacity in Latín America: Historical Trends II
Latín America. I. Title. Research Design: Thick Measures, Detailed Case Studies r5
JL966.s74 2015 Explaining Variation in State Capacity
320.98-dc23 2015004870
r7
The Emergence of State-Building Projects r7
ISBN 978-1-107-rn787-8 Hardback Theorizing State-Building Failure 20
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of URLs Applying the Argument
23
for externa! or third-party Internet Web si tes referred to in this publication and <loes not r The Emergence of State-Building Projects
guarantee that any content on such Web sites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate. 24
Geography and State Development
27
Size
29
Terrain
30
Urban Primacy, Regional Salience, and State Development 32
Chile
38
Mexico
Peru 39
40
Colombia
4r
The Ideational Foundations of State-Bui/ding Projects 46
The Varied Content of Mid-Century Liberalism 46

V
Contents Contents vii
VI

The State and Progress in Chile 48 Institutional Change and Education Development in Peru 143
"Order" and "Progress" in Mexico 49 Explaining Cross-State Divergence in Mexican Education 147
The State and "Progress" in Peru SI Statistical Analysis 148
Colombia's Anti-Statist Consensus 52 Sonora 154
55 Michoacán 155
Conclusion
Conclusion 156
2 A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 59
Administrative Institutions and the Outcomes of 5 Political Costs, Infrastructural Obstacles, and Tax State
State-Building Efforts 61 Development 158
Ca usa! Mechanisms 62 Operationalizing Tax State Development 160
Scoring Cases on the Forros of Rule 65 TaxTypes 160
The Public Administration of State Building 82 Tax Burden 162
Patrimonialism 82 Comparative Development 162
Overlapping Bureaucratic Networks 83 TaxTypes 163
Technical Expertise 84 Tax Burden 172
Customary Law 85 Explaining Variation in Tax Capacity 179
Conclusion 86 Deciding to Tax: Resource Rents and Political Costs 179
87 Implementing Taxation: Forros of Rule and Effective
3 Alternative Historical Explanations and Initial Conditions 88 Administra tion 181
Colonial Legacies
88 Peru: Local State Agents and the Failure to Tax after the
Mechanisms of Colonial Impact
The Bourbon Reforms: State Power at the Twilight of Guano Boom 181
89 Chile: Deployed Rule and the Recovery of Taxation after
Colonial Rule
94 the Nitrate Boom 186
Foundational Wars, New States?
96 Federalism and Tax State Development in Colombia and
Post-Independence Crisis
97 Mexico 193
Education
100 Laissez-Faire Liberalism and Reluctance to Tax in Colombia 193
Taxation
103 Mexico: Deployed Rule and the Expansion of Federal
Monopoly of Force
Explaining State Administrative Appointment Practices 107 Taxation 195
Perceived Threats to Systemic Stability 108 Conclusion 200
The Place of Traditional Authority in National Projects II6 6 Local Administration, Varieties of Conscription, and
The Currency of Patronage 120 the Development of Coercive Capacity 202
Conclusion 123 War and the State: Limits of the "Bellic" Approach 204
124 The Capacity to Mobilize 206
4 State Projects, Institutions, and Educational Development Chile
Educational Development and State Power: Dimensions and 207
Indicators 126 Peru 209
Indicators of Primary Schooling Provision 126 Colombia 211
Indicators of Control over Public Primary Schooling 126 Mexico 214
Comparative Development 127 Local Of{icials and Military Recruitment 220
Provision 127 Deployed Rule, Legal-Formal Conscription, and Chilean
Systematization 130 Military Effectiveness 222
Inspection 133 Mexico: Voluntary Enlistment and Legalistic Recruitment 224
Lack of Educational Initiative in Colombia 134 Delegated Rule and Peruvian Military Weakness 227
A Structural Alternative: Inequality and Education Development 138 The Absence of Systematic Recruitment Efforts in Colombia 229
Deployed Rule and State Power: The Development of School Conclusion 230
Inspection in Chile 140
Vlll
Contents

2
Conclusion 32
The Emergence and Outcomes of State-Building Efforts 2 32
Alternative Explanations 234
A Broader Perspective on Latín American State Building 2 35
Acknowledgments
Urban Primacy and the Origins of State-Building Projects 2 35
Forrns of Rule and the Outcomes of State-Building Efforts 246
The End of the Liberal Era 249
Theorizing State Building 2 52
Bringing Ideas in to State Development 2 52
Separating Emergence and Success 2 55
Causal Importance _ 259
Historical State Building and Contemporary "Nation Building" 260

Works Cited
Index
1 don't know why authors seem to leave the most important acknowledg-
ments for last; in my case there is one person to whom clearly 1 owe the
most. Annie has supported me, made me laugh, joined me on much-needed
outings, challenged my ideas, and taught me about hers. Though this
book would not have been completed without her, her impact goes far
beyond that. 1 don't know what stroke of luck has allowed me to share
my life with such a smart, warm, adventurous, and patient partner, but
1 count my blessings daily.
Sanity during the long road to completing this book was also main-
tained by the support and distraction of old friends near and (alas, too
often) far, including Emma and Mike, Abbie and Willy, Steph and Mike,
and Sean and Sam. l'd also like to thank Lance for always greeting me
with a wagging tail and the eternal hope for a walk and a snack, and
to acknowledge the distraction of political debates on email with Alex,
David, and Matt. Academia has the wonderful quality of turning col-
leagues into friends. Sorne of my closest friendships - with Casey, Fiona,
Mark, Will, Magda, Diana, and Shannon date back to the beginning of
graduare school, and it has been a real pleasure to have known these good
people, their partners, and their farnilies over the years. I'm also grateful
to my family: my parents, my brother and his three great kids, and my
in-laws Pam, Robbie, JP, Coley, and Lizzie, including even those individu-
als who asked when the book would be done every time we talked.
This book began as a dissertation supervised by Jorge Domínguez,
Steven Levitsky, John Coatsworth, and Paul Pierson. My hope is that the
final product on these pages shows just how much 1 got from their care-
ful reading and helpful feedback even as it barely resembles that initial

lX
X Acknowledgments Acknowledgments XI

foray into these issues. I'm also grateful to various institutions at Harvard their helpful comments, 1 thank Alisha Holland, Jamie Loxton, Rache!
University for funding the dissertation research on which much of the Riedl, Ryan Saylor, Erica Simmons, Prerna Singh, Dan Slater, Rich Snyder,
book is based. Early in my research, 1 imposed myself on scholars in both Annie Stilz, and Alberto Vergara. A few generous souls - Steve Levitsky,
Chile and Peru, who patiently answered my incoherent questions and Ryan Saylor, and especially Matthias vom Hau - have each seen more
steered me away from making even more fundamental errors. For their iterations of this project than 1 care to adrnit and than they rnight care to
time and kindness, 1 thank Sol Serrano, Rafael Sagredo Baeza, Carlos remember, yet each has patiently offered helpful and thorough comments
Contreras, Patricia Ames, and Aldo Panfichi. Jen Tobin has (1 believe) not on many different occasions. l'm truly lucky to have such colleagues.
read a word of this manuscript, but her company made my research in Much of the writing of this book was accomplished during my time
Lima more enjoyable. at Temple University, and 1 consider myself very lucky to share space and
Thanks to generous invitations from colleagues, 1 was able to present community on the fourth floor of Gladfelter Hall with such a smart and
serninars on this project as it developed and to benefit from the feedback generous group of folks. l'm particularly grateful to Rich Deeg and Gary
I received. In approximate cbronological order, starting from the ear- Mucciaroni who have served as wonderful department chairs during my
liest (and probably painfully incoherent) version, 1 thank audiences at time at Temple, to Sandra Suarez, Robín Kolodny, and Orfeo Fioretos
Dartrnouth University, the Princeton Program on Latin American Studies, for their wisdom and advice, and to Kevin Arceneaux, Sarah Bush, Ryan
the University of Michigan, St. Antony's College of Oxford, SUNY-Stony Vander Wielen, and Megan Mullin (even though she left us for warmer
Brook, Brown University, The College of New Jersey, CDDRL at Stanford dimes!) for joining me to get coffee, helping me explore Philadelphia,
University, the University of New Mexico, and Trinity College. l'd like to and otherwise being good company. Thanks, too, to Cassie Emmons and
single out Eduardo Dargent and Juan Pablo Luna, who also provided Travis Blemings for their careful research assistance.
welcome opportunities for me to present research related to this book Bates College was my fust home in professional academia. l'd like
at their institutions, to exchange ideas about our shared interests, and to to thank my colleagues there, especially John Baughman, Áslaug
benefit from their hospitality in Lima and Pirque. 1 look forward to con- Asgeirsdottir, and Karen Melvin, for their friendship and for understand-
tinuing to work with both of these generous colleagues, and to returning ing my reasons for leaving. Befare arriving at Temple, I also spent a year
the favor to the extent possible by welcorning them to our small town in at Princeton University, where thanks to the generosity of the University
New Jersey. Center for Human Values and the Politics Department, 1 was able to
The advice, reading suggestions, comments, and criticisms of many enjoy a semester to focus on my research. The final revisions on the book
friends and colleagues have shaped this book in important ways. 1 am manuscript were completed during ayear of leave funded by the Peggy
grateful to Nancy Appelbaum, Michael Bernhard, Max Cameron, Rockefeller Visiting Fellowship at the David Rockefeller Center for Latin
Giovanni Capoccia, John Carey, Ryan Carlin, Miguel Centeno, Sarah American Studies at Harvard University, and 1 thank Merilee Grindle
Chartock, Mark Copelovitch, Jorge Domínguez, Angelica Duran and Edwin Ortiz for their generosity and for welcorning me back into the
Martínez, Kent Eaton, Andres Estefane, Gustavo Flores-Macías, Daniel community where 1 spent severa! years as a graduate student. Thanks to
Gingerich, Agustina Giraudy, Paul Gootenberg, lvan Jaksic, Rob Jansen, Rich Snyder, 1 spent much of that year in residence at Brown University,
Diana Kapiszewski, Robert Karl, Alan Knight, Kendra Koivu, Marcus where the graduate students, visiting scholars, and faculty at CLACS and
Kurtz, Mara Loveman, Lauren Morris MacLean, James Mahoney, Reo the Watson Institute helped make my time rewarding and intellectually
Matsuzaki, Conor O'Dwyer, Maritza Paredes, James Robinson, Joshua stirnulating. 1 thank Rich, the staff at the Watson Institute and the Center
Rosenthal, Andrew Schrank, Gay Seidman, Dan Slater, Maya Tudor, Kurt for Latin American and Caribbean Studies, and especially Kate Goldman
Weyland, Nicholas Wheeler, Sean Yom, and Daniel Ziblatt. for welcorning me to Providence.
For kind advice about the revision process, 1 thank Miguel Centeno, Eric Crahan originally expressed interest in this manuscript many
Steve Levitsky, Rache! Riedl, Rich Snyder, and Deborah Yashar. For the years ago, and he and Robert Dreesen shepherded it tbrough the review
time they took to carefully read large portions of the manuscript (in most process. 1 am grateful to both for their efficiency and their guidance.
cases, when it was much longer than the version in your hands!) and for Robert in particular irnproved the book with his urging to lea ve out sorne
Acknowledgments
Xll

extraneous material that was not ready for primetime. I'm also grate-
ful to Liz Janetschek and the production team at Cambridge Uni:ersity
Press for their efficiency and professionalism. The anonymous rev1ewe~s
were careful and generous with their time, and 1 thank them for the1r Abbreviations
comments on several iterations of the manuscript; though it took me ~
long time to address their comments, 1 am truly grateful for the add1-
tional work 1 was encouraged to do, and I'm confident that the book has
improved as a result of their urgings. 1, of course, bear exclusive respon-
sibility for ali of the errors it still contains.

[Note that while 1 use a consistent label to refer to each publication over
time, government reorganizations at various points in time in each coun-
try led to changes in ministerial names and portfolios.]

AE Anuario Estadístico, Chile (Annual Statistical


Extract, Chile)
CNR Compañía Nacional de Recaudación, Peru (private firm
with which the national government contracted for tax
collection after 1902, as discussed in Chapter 5)
HEC Estado Mayor General del Ejército (various
years) Historia del Ejército Chileno (ro volumes)
(Santiago: Colección Biblioteca Militar) (official history
of the Chilean Army)
MED Memoria del Ministerio de Instrucción Pública,
Peru (Annual Report of the Ministry of Public
Education, Peru)
MGOB Memoria del Ministerio de Gobierno e Interior, Peru
(Annual Report of the Ministry of Governance and the
Interior, Peru)
MGUERRA Memoria del Ministerio de Guerra, Peru (Annual Report
of the War Ministry, Peru)
MHAC Memoria del Ministerio de Hacienda, Chile (Annual
Report of the Finance Ministry, Chile)
MILIMA Memoria de la Dirección de Instrucción Pública
del Departamento de Lima (Annual Report of the
Directorate of Public Education, Department of Lima)
MINT Memoria del Ministerio de Interior, Chile (Annual Report
of the Interior Ministry, Chile)

Xlll
XlV
Abbreviations

MIP Memoria del Ministerio de Justicia, Culto, e Instrucción


Pública, Chile (Annual Report of the Justice, Religion,
and Public Education Ministry, Chile)
Annual Official Government Publications U sed,
by Library/Archive Location

[Note this list does NOT include individual government documents


accessed, which are cited as necessary in the text.]

CHILE

Archivo Nacional Histórico


Boletín de Leyes (various years)
Memoria del Ministerio de Guerra 1848, 1856-1858, 1860, 1868,
1873,1875-1877,1881,1882,1884,1885
Memoria del Ministerio de Industria y Obras Públicas, 1891-1895
Memoria del Ministerio de Interior 1852, 1854, 1856, 1859, 1860,
1864-1866

Biblioteca Nacional
Anuario Estadístico de la República de Chile 1848-1858, 1861-1912
Memoria del Ministerio de Guerra 1887-1900
Memoria del Ministerio de Hacienda 1834-1836, 1839, 1884-1900
Memoria del Ministerio de Interior 1875-1878, 1880-1881,
1884-1902,1904, 1908-1910
Memoria del Ministerio de Justicia, Culto, e Instrucción Pública
1840-1851, 1868-1900
Mensajes Presidenciales (various years)

XV
xvi Annual Of{icial Government Publications

PERU

Archivo Nacional
Memoria del Ministerio de Gobierno 1890, 1896, 1898, 1901, 1902,
Introduction
1904, 1905,1907, 1908,1911,1913
Memoria del Ministerio de Guerra 1874, 1889, 1890, 1893, 1897,
The Origins of State Capacity in Latin America
1900-1929.
Memoria del Ministerio de Instrucción Pública 1853, 1862, 1864,
1890-1893, 1896-1898,1900-1910, 1912-1922

Instituto DeNegri
Memoria de la Dirección de Instrucción Pública del Departamento de
States are crucial to nearly every aspect of our lives. The ability of state
Lima 1875
institutions to effectively exert authority throughout the national terri-
Memoria del Ministerio de Gobierno 1831, 1847, 1860, 1870, 1872,
tory underpins variation in access to economic opportunity, the provision
l874,1878,1879,1883,1885,1888,1897,1899,1906,1920,l921
of public goods, and the protection of legal rights. Yet in Latin America,
Memoria del Ministerio de Guerra 1829, 1845, 1853, 1870, 1872,
variation in state capacity has only recently become an object of serious
1879
scrutiny. Much of our understanding of the state has come from studies
Memoria del Ministerio de Hacienda 1828, 1849, l8SI, 1853, 1862,
of its origins in Europe, where a vigorous debate among scholars has gen-
1864, 1867, 1868, 1874, 1876, 1878, 1879, 1885, 1886, 1890,
erated extensive cumulation of knowledge in both theoretical and empiri-
1892, 1896, 1903
cal terms. r This school of research has been complemented in recent years
Memoria del Ministerio de Instrucción Pública 1847, 1883
by a growing literature exploring the "failure" of sorne contemporary
Mensajes Presidenciales, various years
states to fulfill even their basic functions. 2
This dual focus on the world's strongest and weakest states ignores
Government Documents Collection, Harvard University much of the contemporary variation: no state in Latin America, for
example, could be described as a Hobbesian Leviathan or a Scandinavian
Censo Escolar l 902
cradle-to-grave provider, nor is any as vestigial as those of Chad or
Somalia. Yet within Latin America, state capacity varies quite widely
across countries. Sorne countries, like Chile and Uruguay, provide basic
public goods and security to their citizens, and are able to extract rev-
enues and enforce laws. But illiteracy in Bolivia is about five times as
high as in Uruguay. For every child not vaccinated in Chile, about ten go
unvaccinated in Ecuador. While the 2on census in Uruguay was admin-
istered effectively, the 2005 census in Peru was so flawed it had to be

' Among the many important contributions to this literature, sorne central works are Tilly
(r975), Tilly (r992), Ertman (r997), Downing (r992), Spruyt (r994), and Gorski (2003).
, Herbst (2000); Bates (2008).

I
2
Introduction Introduction 3

repeated two years later. The homicide rate in Venezuela is about ten contemporary variation. Thus in devising a historical account of contem-
times as high as that of Uruguay. How can we account for this variation porary variation in state capacity, the argurnent advanced in this book
in the state's ability to carry out a set of core functions? falls in the mainstream of scholarship on state development.
Even more striking is the territorial unevenness in state capacity in the But this book diverges from existing scholarship in an important
region's weaker states, which is concealed by national average measures way: I argue that we must explicitly separare the theoretical accounts
of state capacity (Snyder 200Ib). In Colombia, for example, the national of the factors that cause state-building efforts to emerge and the factors
literacy according to the 2005 census was 85.9 percent, but schooling that lead to success or failure. Making this separation, the framework
only reached 60 percent of the residents of La Guajira, and 78.4 percent I develop charts three paths to contemporary outcomes: those in which
of the residents of Córdoba. By contrast, in Chile, which had a national state-building efforts never emerged, those in which state-building efforts
literacy rate in 2002 of 87.5 percent, every province's literacy rate was failed, and those in which state-building efforts succeeded. As I discuss
more than 80 percent. In Bolivia, the national vaccination rate for chil- later, accounting for ali three paths is necessary for a theoretically com-
dren in I997 was 74.I percent, but at the department level, vaccina- plete explanation of variation in state capacity. Most existing scholarship
tion rates ranged from more than 9 5 percent in Chuquisaca to less than falls short of this goal because it tends to limit itself to explaining why
50 percent in Pando.3 state-building efforts emerge, and fails to theorize the set of causal factors
This subnational variation in the provision of basic services reflects a underlying state-building success.
crucial aspect of stateness: the state's reach over territory and ability to This book follows the evolution of the state in four Latín American
implement its chosen policies. Today, Latín America's states share many countries during the Liberal era, running from the end of the
features of institutional design, a certain degree of bureaucratic profes- post-independence crises in each to the early twentieth century. Colombia
sionalism in the halls of ministries and executive agencies, and enjoy followed the first path described previously, and Peru the second: these
basic stability.4 The most striking difference across states in the region is are two logically distinct routes to contemporary state weakness.s I select
in the performance of basic functions, and in particular, in the reach of Mexico and Chile as my two cases of successful state building because
the state agencies that provide those functions over a territory. the many differences in historical, social, econornic, and political terms
The goal of this book is to explain why in sorne Latin American coun- between these cases help me to isolate the factors they had in common
tries, state institutions reach across the national territory and operate that were necessary for state-building efforts to succeed. These three tra-
with a degree of capacity, while in others, the state is vestigial and inef- jectories leading to the outcomes of state strength and weakness account
fective. Rather than assuming that contemporary variation has contem- for variation in state capacity in Latin America, and are the topic of
porary roots, I begin by examining the historical record. I show that this book.
contemporary rankings of countries on various aspects of state capac-
ity are very strongly associated with their ranking in I900. This finding TWO QUESTIONS
resonares with a central aspect of the scholarship on state strength more
generally: nearly ali research on this question points to historical causes The theory developed in this book is designed to answer the two key
(such as war, colonial rule, or early institutional choices) to account for questions about the development of state capacity: What are the factors
that cause state-building efforts to emerge? And what are the factors that
1 Data are from Instituto Nacional de Estadística de Bolivia, 1997 data on immunizations lead to success? The answers I develop to these questions, which I pre-
by province. I generare average immunization rate figures as follows: average the number view in this brief discussion and present in Chapters I and 2, are shown
of each of five types (Polio fust and third dose, BCG, and DPT fust and third <lose) given
in each province, and divide by the number of one-year-old residents (estimated as 2.9%
in Figure o. I.
of total population, based on population pyramid in 2007 census).
• Both Dargent (2015) and Gingerich (2013) show that bureaucratic professionalism and
institutional capacity vary more across agencies within states than they do across states 5 As discussed later, Peru saw sorne gains in state capacity during the Aristocratic Republic
within Latín America. The same is not true for the state's performance of basic functions (1895-1919): the contrasting trajectories of state development during two historical peri-
and its reach across its territory. ods in Peru helps isolate the factors necessary for state building to succeed.
Introduction Introduction 5
4
developrnent could take hold. By contrast, where rnultiple regional cen-
ters each sat astride a distinct regional political econorny, the construc-
tion of central state authority <lid not seern a propitious developrnent
strategy. This was so for two reasons: first, elites clashed because each
region had distinct public good preferences. Second, where regions had
self-contained econornies and could generate sufficient econornic produc-
tion on their own to rnaintain and even increase standards of living with-
out the need for national integration, visions of developrnent centered on
the prornotion of regional progress, which <lid not depend on the exten-
'
'
' ' v sion of the authority of the central state.
"
V
"' As the left half of Figure 0.1 indicates, Colombia diverged frorn the
Weak
Colombia No No \No 1
Weak
other three cases at this point: its trajectory of state weakness across the
Yes Yes Local 1845-1895 State Building Fails 1845-1895
Peru \Yes century after independence can be explained by its polycentric econornic
Mixed 1895-1920 State Building Succeeds 1895-1920

Mexico Yes Yes j Yes Outsiders State Building Succeeds Strong geography. Fragmented into rnultiple regions, it saw the consolidation of
Chile Yes Yes j Yes Outsiders State Building Succeeds Strong a strikingly laissez-faire elite consensus that brought to power a series
FIGURE o. r. The emergence and success of state-buikling projects in LatinAmerica. of efforts to pursue developrnent by disrnantling, rather than building,
the state. In the other three cases, the broadlyJiberal consensus after
rnid-century had a developrnental core, and concerted state-building
efforts ensued.
The Emergence of $tate-Building Projects
The first puzzle is why state-building projects emerge. In the absence of The Success of State-Building Projects
the wars that force state leaders to rnobilize resources and manpower or
risk defeat and devastation, we cannot take for granted the decision to But accounting for the emergence of state-building projects is insuf-
undertake rnajor investments in extending the reach of state institutions. ficient to explain the variation we observe in state capacity. Arnong
Here, I focus on the role of geography and broad ideas about develop- our cases, Peru saw majar state-building efforts, yet its state is quite
ment. I argue that in a clirnate of relative stability that emerged a~er weak by regional standards. We need, therefore, an explanation for why
the post-independence crisis eased, state leaders opted for state brnld- only sorne state-building efforts succeed, and sorne fail. The failure of
ing if and when they saw it as a means to the developrnental goals they such efforts is not only a logical possibility but a historical reality, yet
6
sought - econornic growth, social peace, and political stability. Whether explaining why state-building efforts fail has been alrnost cornpletely
state building seemed propitious depended, in turn, on the nature of neglected by political scientists and historical sociologists. For more
political and econornic geography: where a single dorninant urban core than three decades after 1845, state leaders in Peru presided over a
existed and development was seen in a center-periphery dynarnic, an concerted effort to extend the reach of the state across the national ter-
elite consensus about the irnportance of extending central authority for ritory, and funded this effort with irnrnense revenues frorn the guano
monopoly the country enjoyed. Yet despite consistent policies and more
• In pursuing state building as a meaos to seU:ing "on ~n opportun~ty~ I argue that Latin than adequate spending, the results were rninimal. How can we explain
American state leaders acted more like Olsoman stat10nary band1ts (Olson I993) and why state-building efforts succeeded in Mexico and Chile, but failed in
that state building was largely proactive rather than emerging as a reaction to threats,
whether interna! or externa!. Interna! threats do enter into the explanation for success Peru? In answering this question, the greater success of state building
and failure of state-building projects, as discussed later - where they were present~ ~ey in Peru after 1895 provides an opportunity for contrast within a single
affected the design of administrative institutions in ':'ª'.s that imp~cte~ state-build~g country over time, in addition to the analytical leverage gained from
efforts - but I argue that they did not spur state-bmldmg efforts m Liberal-era Latm
analytical comparison.
America.
Introduction Introduction 7
6

Relying on both cross-national and within-nation comparison, I argue variation. Although he <loes devote part of his account to explaining
that the fate of state-building effarts depended on the design of the insti- intra-regional variation in the capacity of African states, Herbst (2000),
tutions of local administration that extended the state's reach into the too, facuses on explaining why African states do not resemble those of
national periphery. More specifically, I argue that state-building effarts Europe. These studies have made important contributions to our under-
failed where local elites were tasked with administering them, but saw standing of the limits to the scope of theories derived from European
more success where local administrators were outsiders in the commu- history, but in logical terms, regional characteristics cannot account far
nities in which they served. Two logics underpin this claim: I argue that the intra-regional variation I seek to explain.
local elites were both less invested in state building, and less accountable A second set of studies have set aside comparisons with Europe to
to their superiors in the national bureaucracy. In Peru, especially befare facus on explaining intra-regional variation. Holding regional character-
l 89 5, state leaders delegated administration to local elites, and the result
istics constant where possible, these works ha ve sought to account far the
was that the state-building initiatives emanating from the center bore lit- distinct trajectories taken by individual countries. Slater (20rn) and Vu
tle fruit. By contrast, in Chile and Mexico, state leaders deployed bureau- (2orn) explain the evolution of state-making in postwar Southeast Asia.
cratic outsiders across the national territory; this led to greater success in Downing (1992), Ertman (1997), and Gorski (2003) identify differences
among countries in early modern Europe that account far the distinct
state building.
In combination, then, the account I develop far variation in state trajectories taken by their states within a broadly similar regional con-
capacity in Latin America is causally complex in two senses. First, varia- text marked by intensified military competition. Fernando López-Alves
tion cannot be accounted far in a univariate model: it depends on ide- (2000) engages in the same sort of intra-regional comparison within
ational factors (and their geographic underpinnings) and the design of Latin America. Like this book, he facuses on the nineteenth century as
local administrative institutions. Second, these two sets of factors are the crucial moment in which variation in state capacity emerged among
not analytically equivalent independent variables: instead, the farmer Latin American countries. López-Álves argues that the nature of internal
set accounts far the emergence of state-building effarts, while the latter, conflicts in the aftermath of independence was the crucial factor underly-
causally relevant only where state-building efforts emerge, accounts far ing variation in the subsequent evolution of states, although the ultimate
goal of his study is to explain the type of regime that was consolidated.
success and failure.
This book traces this account through the faur cases highlighted in This book differs from his in two crucial ways. First, I argue that the cru-
Figure o.r. It is based on material in the volurninous collection of national cial moment in which state building was possible occurred only after the
and regional histories of these cases, and on extensive primary source post-independence conflicts carne to a clase and a modicum of stability
research in archives of various government ministries. In the Conclusion, emerged. Second, I do not explore regime dynamics at all in this book; my
I use this framework to consider the state-building trajectories of other facus is on the power of states, independent of the regimes that rule them.
Latin American countries, showing that they can also be explained by Kurtz (2013), Saylor (2012), and Paredes (2013) also explore
this argument. I begin in this chapter by defining state capacity and col- intra-regional variation in state capacity within Latin America, although
lecting systematic data to substantiate the broad regional trajectories. both Kurtz and Saylor also extend their argument to cases outside the
I then develop the research design and describe what is to come in the region. Saylor and Paredes argue that commodity booms are windows of
chapters that fallow, which facus on the four cases in detail. opportunity far state building, moments in which state capacity can be
built if certain conditions hold. Both emphasize the nature of elite coali-
tions in explaining when commodity booms spur the state's creation of
STUDYING INTRA-REGIONAL VARIATION new public goods: Saylor argues that state building occurs in the context
Studies of state capacity in the developing world can be crudely sorted of commodity booms when insiders (members of the ruling coalition)
into two categories. A first set of works, such as Centeno (2002), explain seek new public goods in arder to maximize their gains from commodity
why the states of a particular region differ from those in early modern exports, or when booms benefit outsiders sufficiently to scare insiders
Europe, and downplay or set aside the determinants of intra-regional into state building to lock in their distributional advantage. Paredes also
8 I ntroduction Introduction 9

emphasizes the divisions between ex:isting elites and newly rising sectors of so many similarities in historical and structural conditions, allows us
that benefit from commodity revenues in preventing coordination around to identify causal factors that remain obscured in comparisons of cases
concerted, planned, state-building efforts. with a wider range of seores on the dependent variable. Thus, this book
Kurtz, too, focuses on relations among societal actors, but in addition eschews claims of global generality to focus on careful comparison and
to relations between elites, he argues that interest in state building on within-case analysis of a set of countries that diverge on the outcome of
the part of rural elites depends on rural labor relations: where agrar- interest without representing extreme cases (Slater and Ziblatt 20I3).
ian labor is marketized, he argues, elites will be more amenable to state
building than when it is more akin to serfdom. My account differs from STATE CAPACITY: CONCEPTS AND MEASURES
these important studies in two fundamental ways. First, whereas Kurtz
and Saylor focus on the political motives for state building, I also unpack Building on Michael Mann's concept of infrastructural power, the
its administration. As I argue in more detail in Chapter 2, to explain object of interest in this study is the state's ability to exercise control
the breadth of elite support for a state-building project is insufficient to and implement policy choices throughout the territory it claims to gov-
account for variation in state capacity; a full theory of variation in state ern. 8 Guillermo O'Donnell (I993) identified the importance of the spatial
capacity must also explain the fate of the state-building projects that are reach of state authority in a seminal article, which has formed the foun-
undertaken, and that fate (as 1 show in this book) is determined by factors dation of much concern about "stateness" in Latín America in the last
independent from those that determine the choice to build state capacity. two decades. Yet while many indices of state capacity ex:ist, few capture
Second, 1 see the motives behind state-building projects as shaped more this aspect of the state; few measure the territorial reach of state institu-
by ideology and less by the narrow elite interests emphasized by all three tions, or the ability of the state to consistently and effectively perform a
authors. As I show in Chapter I, the onset of state building was propelled set of core basic functions throughout its realm.
not by narrow interests in the provision of particular public goods, but Ex:isting indices of state capacity are fraught with problems. This is
by a belief that increased state capacity would serve a broad range of particularly true of the industry of indicators of state weakness, state
interests in the long term.7 I argue that state building was a state project failure, and state fragility that has emerged in recent years. Among other
rather than a sectoral or class project. problems, these datasets lack the historical data needed to trace state
Explaining variation within a single region has both advantages and capacity over the long term, often rely on expert assessments rather than
limitations. Restricting the analysis to Latín American cases truncates on objective data, and fail to make careful and transparent choices about
the range of state capacity being investigated. At fust glance, this may conceptualization and scoring (Mata and Ziata 2009). As Kurtz and
be seen as a disadvantage in terms of generalizability. Yet the extent of Schrank (2007) have shown, cross-national indicators of state capacity,
intra-regional variation to be explained is still sizable, and it is quite strik- such as the World Bank Governance Indicators, also suffer from prob-
ing, especially given that the cases shared similar (if not identical) experi- lems of conceptual clarity and validity. The same is true of the Putterman
ences under Spanish colonial rule, similarly low levels of international Index of state antiquity, which has seen increasing usage in cross-national
war, and similar trajectories of integration into the global economy. scholarship (Chancla and Putterman 2005).
Exploring this more fine-grained variation, which emerges in the presence Since even the most minimal core of state functions contains multiple
dimensions, a single indicator of state capacity is too crude for all but
1 As I discuss further in Chapter l, this should not be misread as a claim that state lead- the most general analyses. Thus single indicator measures of state capac-
ers were benevolent rather than self-interested. I simply claim that their interests in sta- ity are also inappropriate for attempts to capture the overall concept
bility and economic development, which would serve both their interests in generating
legitimacy and a hold on power as well as broader societal interests, are not reducible to
(Hanson and Sigman 20II). This is true not only when the indicators are
interests of particular social actors. Underlying, perhaps, my differences with Kurtz and
8
Saylor's accounts is the fact that I attribute more autonomy to Latín American state lead- The concept of infrastructural power is first developed in Mann (1984). See Soifer and
ers than do either of my interlocutors, who see the state as serving the interests of a ruling vom Hau (2008) and Soifer (2008) for a more detailed unpacking of this concept and
elite coalition. My position here echoes that of Mahoney (2001), who studies the Liberal approaches to its study. For stylistic reasons, I use the terms "state strength," "state
era in Central America. This issue is discussed in Chapters l and 2. power," and "state capacity" interchangeably throughout.
IO I ntroduction Introduction II

crude, like GDP per capita (Fearon and Laitin 2003) or state antiquity is assessed in the realm of taxation - Chapter 5 examines the tax burden
(Chancla and Putterman 2005), but even for indicators like road den- per capita imposed on the population, and the types of taxes collected by
sity (Herbst 2000) or the tax ratio, which tap a particular dimension of the state, differentiated by the extent of spatial reach and adrninistrative
the state. In response to these concerns, 1 choose not to rely on existing development needed for their assessment and collection. The coercive 11

indices or on single indicators of state capacity. lnstead, my approach dimension is assessed in Chapter 6, which examines military mobiliza-
assesses state capacity by examining the presence of various state institu- tion in response to internal and externa! threats, and the state's capacity
tions across the national territory, and their systematization and efficacy to conscript in a consistent and reliable manner. Here, too, I focus on
in enforcing state authority. 1 focus on three categories of core functions the spatial reach of conscription practices, which are associated with the
of the state: the administration of a basic set of services (primary public extent to which the army can serve as a "school for the nation" by mixing
education), the mobilization of manpower, and the extraction of revenue. conscripts from across the country within its ranks.
These are, of course, closely related to Charles Tilly's (1975, 50) disag-
gregation of state power into regulatory, extractive, and coercive dimen-
STATE CAPACITY IN LATIN AMERICA: HISTORICAL TRENDS
sions.9 Because all states sought to perform these functions, assessing
their performance on these dimensions captures the core content of While the succeeding chapters examine the four cases using the detailed
Mann's concept of infrastructural power: the state's ability to implement operationalization scheme described previously, I begin by using a
its chosen policies. By focusing on these core functions, 1 ensure that my somewhat less nuanced approach to map the broad trends in the devel-
operationalization of state capacity does not conflate the state's strength opment of state capacity across the region. Table o.r seores the ten
with the scope of functions it performs (Fukuyama 2004). major countries of South America and Mexico on various simple mea-
Rather than capturing each of these three dimensions with a single sures of state strength. The first two columns provide indicators of
indicator, 1 develop a more nuanced measurement scheme for each. These coercive capacity - military mobilization (measured as the average of
indicator-level measures are designed to capture the reach of state insti- the share of the population in the armed forces and military spending
tutions over territory and their penetration of society, rather than just per capita) and the homicide rate. The next two columns provide
12

relying on national-level seores. They are also designed to measure as indicators of the provision of basic public goods - the literacy rate and
closely as possible the empirical outputs of the state, avoiding scoring the rate of provision to children under the age of one of immunizations
based on the de jure content of legislation, the design of state institu- for measles and DPT. 1 3 The final indicator used is road density, which
tions, or the outcomes of state policy. 10 The chapters that follow focus captures the ability of state agents to penetrare the territory within a
on a small number of cases and take a more nuanced approach to the country's borders. 4 1

measurement of state capacity, focusing on the service provision, extrac-


tive, and coercive dimensions in turn. The power of the state to provide
lI For reasons further explained in Soifer (2013a), Ido not believe that the tax ratio (taxes/
and adrninister basic public services is assessed in the realm of primary GDP) is a valid measure of state infrastructural power. Its numerator, the arnount of
public education. Chapter 4 evaluates the spatial spread of public pri- taxes (or direct taxes) collected by the govemment, is often lowered by political consider-
mary schooling, as well as the systematization of education: textbook a tions since govemments choose not to tax as muchas they can. As a result, the tax ratio
always under-represents extractive capacity, which acts as an upper bound on taxation
and currículum standardization, teacher training, and the construction rather-than shaping the leve! of taxation.
2
of centralized inspection and oversight. The extractive power of the state ' Military mobilization is calculated for the decade 1990-1999 by averaging annual seores
in that timespan for rnilitary spending per capita and rnilitary size per capita, both of
which are drawn frorn the Correlates of War dataset. The hornicide data come frorn
• For a similar application of Tilly's three dimensions to rneasure state power, see Ziblatt Mainwaring and Scully (2010), Table r.5, p. 32.
(2006). Hanson and Sigrnan (20II) perforrn a factor analysis of more than thirty exist- '
3
Data for the literacy rateare drawn frorn Thorp (1998, 3 54) and are based on calcula-
ing rneasures of state capacity and find that they cluster on the dimensions of extraction, tions of the illiterate percentage of the population above the age of fifteen. Vaccination
administration, and coercion. data are drawn frorn the World Development Indicators.
'º On the trade-offs involved in using outputs, outcomes, and institucional design to mea- 14
Road density data are drawn from the International Road Federation World Road
sure state capacity, see Soifer {2008) and Fukuyarna (2013). Statistics, using data frorn as close to 1999 as possible.
Introduction
13

TABLE 0.2. State capacity rankings c.1900

Military* Literacy RR dens. Census Average St dev.


Argentina 2.5 2 3 3.625
7 2.29
Bolivia 9 11 8 8.25
5 2.50
Brazil 7.5 4 5 3 4.875 r.93
Chile l 3 4 l 2.25 r.50
Colombia 10 5 10 8
7 2.45
Ecuador 6 6 11 11 8.5 2.89
Mexico 8 9 2 6.5
7 3.II
,.¡ l"-<f'lV>O O O <f'lÑ " " " '
V>CO "<t"CO <'l
Paraguay 4.5 7 9 9.5
"<t"\D <f'll"-V>O
.;.,a.,.;.,tñ..¡,..¡, .;.,r-:._r-:._....¡..¡, 7.5 2.27
Peru 9.5 10 6 9.5 8.75 r.85
Uruguay 2.5 l l 3 r.875 r.03
Venezuela 5·5 6 7 3 5-375 r.70
Ties are indicated by .5; for exarnple, for literacy, Colombia and Paraguay tied for fifth and
each receive a score of 5. 5.
i::
* "Military" is an average of the rankings for rnilitary participation ratio and rnilitary
o spending percapita. It is calculated as the average of seores on each rneasure for each year
-~ with available data between 1900 and r9rn.
N

J <f'l "'
r-:._ H
H
Ñ r-:._ "'
"' V.,"<:!" 0
H When these rankings are averaged across each dirnension, as shown in
the rightrnost colurnn in the table, they conforrn quite well to our prior
findings about intra-regional variation in state capacity: Uruguay and
N H o "'
<f'l.;.,l"-CO
":'
V">O\H ..,¡- Chile score as the strongest states, with Brazil, Argentina, and Mexico
H H
lagging sornewhat behind. is The weakest states are Peru, Bolivia, and
Paraguay. This ranking of countries is quite similar to how they were
arrayed nearly a century ago. Despite sorne significant data lirnitations
and problerns with cornparability across countries, we can assernble a
similar set of indicators for state capacity as of 1900 (See Table 0.2).
Coercive capacity is captured by the sarne rnilitary rnobilization rneasure
used in Table o. I. The literacy rate captures the provision of basic pub-
lic services. Railroad density is used, like the road density rneasure in
Table 0.1, to reflect the spatial reach of state agents and infrastructure.
Finally, census irnplernentation is used as an indicator of the state's over-
all ability to reach over the national territory and collect inforrnation
about its residents. Drawing on data in Goyer and Dornschke (1983),

xs The Governrnent Effectiveness and Rule of Law cornponents of the World Bank
Governance Indicators provide similar rankings as those in Table o. r; I choose not to
include thern because of the conceptual and rnethodological concerns raised by Kurtz
and Schrank (2007).

12
14 Introduction Introduction

10 the origin. Countries falling below the line, most notably Mexico, saw
O Bolivia
their ranking improve over the course of the twentieth century, while
those located above the line (like Argentina) saw their ranking decline.
Although there are sorne deviations from the line, the general pattern is
8 O Paraguay
9Peru
one of striking stability over the past century: just as Mahoney .(2orn)
has shown far social and economic development indicators, ordinal
o O Colombia rankings of state capacity are also durable over the course of the twen-
o
o O Venezuela
O Ecuador
C\I
..X:
6 tieth century. Thus, the findings of this section point to the fact that rel-
e: e Argentina e Mexico
<ti
a:
O Brazil ative levels of state capacity in 2000 are very well predicted by those in
1900. This implies that the origins of contemporary variation lie in the
4 pre-1900 era. The stark historical continuities demonstrated in this dis-
O Chile
cussion justify my turn to history to account far the divergence across
countries in state capacity, and far my facus on the nineteenth century
in the chapters that fallow.
2 OUruguay

2 4 6 8 10
RESEARCH DESIGN: THICK MEASURES, DETAILED CASE STUDIES
Rank 1900

FIGURE 0.2. Persistence of rankings over time. Rather than approaching the explanation of this variation through
Data in this graph are drawn from the "Average" column in Tables o.r and 0.2. time-series, cross-sectional quantitative analysis, I choose to investigate a
smaller set of cases through detailed historical study. Ido this far two rea-
sons. First, as discussed previously, while the crude indicators deployed
I rank countries based on the number of censuses implemented between sketch broad trends, the concept of state capacity is not adequately cap-
1840 and 1920! 6 tured in existing cross-national data. Nor can it be sufficiently precisely
Table 0.2 shows a clear gap between leaders and laggards in state assessed through simple indicators that can be compiled into a dataset
capacity by 1900. Argentina, Uruguay, and Chile perfarm better than do far cross-national analysis. Instead, I opt far the detailed study of the
the other countries on all dimensions, scoring in the top faur of rank- development of various dimensions of state capacity in a small number
ings for every measure. At the other end of the spectrum, Bolivia, Peru, of cases. By exploring each of these dimensions separately, I trace the
Colombia, and Ecuador are among the weakest states in the regían. development of state capacity in a nuanced fashion. Although each state
Mexico, Brazil, Paraguay, and Venezuela fall in the middle of the pack. generally develops along similar trajectories far each dimension (as seen,
A comparison of the rankings for 1900 and 2000 shows that they far example, in the fairly low standard deviations across dimensions in
are very strongly correlated; the Pearson correlation of the two sets of Tables 0.1 and 0.2) this multi-faceted approach to state capacity allows
rankings is 0.83. Figure 0.2, which arrays the rankings far 1900 and me to identify instances of within-case variation, to highlight moments in
2000, shows that the relative levels of state capacity across the regían which a given state perfarms well on one dimension but not others, and
have remained strikingly stable over the past century. Perfect stabil- to leverage this variation far theory development and testing.
ity would place all countries on a line emanating at 45 degrees from Secondly, as commonly argued by scholars who use case study meth-
ods, detailed investigations of small numbers of cases allow scholars to
'6 Other sources produce slightly different numbers of censuses for certain countries; the identify evidence of causality through process-tracing, a tool unavail-
overall rankings are unaffected by this. Scoring countries based on census iterations in able in cross-national regression analysis, which relies heavily on cor-
different time periods (1820-1900, for example) also has little effect on the rankings.
For a more detailed justification of the census as an indicator of state capacity, see Soifer
relational evidence (George and Bennett 2005). The separate analysis of
(2or3a). each dimension also allows me to better address alternative explanations
16 Introduction Introduction 17

by considering them where they are most likely to hold. Rather than TABLE 0.3. Cases and alternative explanations
evaluating an alternative explanation on a particular dimension of state Chile Mexico Peru Colombia
capacity that I have chosen as my operationalization, a multi-dimensional
operationalization of state capacity can be used to evaluate alternative State capacity c.1900 High High Low Low
Victory in major war Yes No No No
explanations on their own most favored terrain. To the extent that these Intensity of colonial Low High High Low
alternatives are shown to fall short precisely where scholars have staked penetration
their claim to explain state capacity, I have more convincingly identified Ethnic diversity Low High High Low
their shortcomings. Thus, a multi-faceted conceptualization and measure- Commodity booms Yes No Yes Yes
ment scheme for state capacity, in addition to better description, increases Territorial System Unitary Federal Unitary Federal
the analytical power of explanations for its development.
To account for the full range of state power outcomes in the region,
and for a variety of different trajectories of state development, I select Another important alternative explanation for varied levels of state
four cases for protracted investigation in the remainder of the book. The capacity is geography. Chapter 1 investigates the causal role of a variety
first cardinal rule of case selection in theory testing is to ensure that cases of geographic factors, identifying urban prirnacy as a necessary condition
vary on the dependent variable. I select cases that follow the full set of for the emergence of state-building projects, but showing that mountain-
trajectories outlined at the beginning of this book: Chile and Mexico's ousness, population density, national size, and complexity of terrain can-
gains in state capacity, the state weakness of Colombia, and the case of not account for variation in state capacity. Finally, each chapter illustrates
Peru, which saw periods of both successful and failed state building. cross-time variation in Peruvian state-building: sorne marked gains, par-
As Table 0.3 shows, the variation in state strength across these cases is ticularly in the realm of education, were made during the Aristocratic
not correlated with a range of commonly cited alternative explanations, Republic of 1895-1919. This cross-time variation illustrates the limita-
such as victory in war, intensity of colonial penetration, ethnic diversity tions of accounts that posit a time-invariant factor, such as geography, as
or social inequality, and distortionary commodity booms. The fact that the cause of state development.
state-building outcomes do not align in expected ways with any of these
factors suggests that we could reject them in studying the Latin American
EXPLAINING VARIATION IN STATE CAPACITY
context. But instead of making that move in too hasty a manner, I grant
these alternative explanations, which have great credence in the existing The Emergence of State-Building Projects
scholarship on state capacity, the respect that they merit and test each in
The first question addressed in this book is why state-building projects
detail in the empirical chapters to follow.
are undertaken. The decision to invest política! capital and huge amounts
Based on this logic, I explore the role of colonial institutions, colonial
of money in extending state authority is theoretically inlportant not only
legacies, and the nature of the independence conflict (in Chapter 3), the
effects of colonial institutions and social inequality (in Chapter 4, which because leaders have other possible uses for these resources, but because
extending state authority has fiscal and política! costs beyond these direct
studies educational development), commodity booms (in Chapter s on
extractive capacity), and the role of war (in Chapter 6 on coercive power) outlays. One current of scholarship accounts for the onset of state build-
to show that even in the cases where they might be correlated with the ing by identifying a threat to which state leaders respond by extending
their authority. That threat can be externa!, as in the "bellic" school of
outcome we expect, and even in examining the aspect of infrastructural
state building that originated in studies of early modern Europe, or inter-
power they are most likely to explain, they are not causally connected. 1 7
Thus I use within-case evidence, and not just cross-case comparison, to nal as in Slater's (2010) account of state building in Southeast Asia. A sec-
ond view sees state building as a decision shaped purely by fiscal costs and
rule out alternative explanations.
benefits (Levi 1988; Herbst 2000). A third view looks for a social (usu-
ally class or sectoral) actor or coalition that benefits from the expansion
'7 The relevant literature is discussed and cited in each of the empírica! chapters.
r8 Introduction Introduction 19

of particular aspects of the state's writ, and attributes state-building reduced to fiscal cost-benefit calculatíons. Instead, state leaders pursued
policies to the influence of that actor (Waldner 1999; Anderson 1974; long-terrn political stability. Where they believed that this required new
Spruyt 1994). roles for the state in promoting domestic and international trade, and
My approach to accounting for the emergence of state-building projects in molding the population into citízens, they undertook concerted state
departs from these existing currents in severa! important ways. In contrast building. State-building projects emerged where elites saw them as the
to the fust view, I frame state building as a rneans of accessing opportuni- means to goals they described as civilization, order, and progress, rather
ties, rather than only as a means of responding to threats. Threats, I argue, than in the direct pursuit of revenue. This explains why these projects
did not drive Latín American state building. As Miguel Centeno has shown, included not only taxation, but also education and other dimensions of
international wars were rare, and limited in scope in the region, and unlike state capacity that fall outside the fiscal realrn. 18
in early modern Europe, state builders did not have to impose authority Thus far I have argued that state building was neither driven by war
on society in order to avoid being wiped off the map. Por Centeno, this nor reducible to the revenue irnperatíve. It might seem, then, that I side
explains why Latín Arnerica has weaker states than does Europe. But in with scholarship that sees state-building projects as serving the interests
trying to understand variatíon among Latín American states in the nine- of dominant sectors in society, a view which has a long tradition in stud-
teenth century, the overall absence of war in the region cannot be helpful. ies of state building (Anderson 1974; Waldner 1999; Saylor 2012). Yet
Nor does variation across states in their involvement in war adequately the interests of dorninant sectors do not provide a general account for
account for variatíon in the onset of state building: Chile and Peru, for why state-building projects emerged in sorne places but not others in
example, not only were each involved in two major nineteenth-century mid-nineteenth-century Latin Arnerica. Although Saylor (2012) is cor-
wars, but faced one another in both. And yet major differences in state rect to argue that satisfying the demands of exporting elites for pub-
capacity emerged. War-rnaking, in short, did not spur state-building efforts lic goods did spur the construction of state capacity at sorne moments,
in Latín Arnerica; nor did (as I discuss in Chapter 6) international threats state-building projects also emerged in the absence of major export-
falling short of war as Thies (200 5) argues. ing sectors - this was the case in Mexico, one of the cases I explore in
If international threats did not prod política! elites into state-building detail. State-building projects also emerged in cases like Peru, where there
initiatives, could dornestic threats have played the same role? Slater (20 lo) was no dominant elite coalition driving state actívity until the l89os.
argues that Southeast Asían state leaders undertook state-building efforts Dominant-class argurnents like that of Kurtz (20 l 3) struggle to explain
where the threats they faced from subaltern actors seemed particularly this case of prewar Peru, and mis-characterize it as one in which state
dire: contentious politícs drove state building in the postwar era in that building never emerged rather than its correct classification as a case in
region. Yet the Latín American record looks quite different: state-building which a concerted state-building effort failed. Against this third view,
projects emerged not when interna! threats were severe, but after a míni- I argue that state-building projects did not simply reflect the interests of
ma! level of order had been established and a rnodicurn of political stabil- particular class actors or the social compositíon of ruling coalitions. State
ity had emerged. In all four cases, as detailed in Chapter 3, the imrnediate building was a state project, nota class or sectoral project. My argurnent
aftermath of independence brought severe instability. In response, state endows state leaders with a degree of autonomy in shaping not only goals
leaders prioritized order - in the famous phrase appearing on the Chilean for state policy, but in choosing the means by which those goals are to
official coat of arms, they ruled "by reason or by force." State building - be pursued.
in the sense of the territorial extension and institutionalizatíon of state The determinant of whether the state was seen as the means to devel-
administration - began only after order had been achieved. opment was fundamentally ideational. Ideas explain why political elites
Rather than emerging as a response to threats, I argue that state build-
ing emerged in pursuit of opportunities. State leaders leveraged moments
8
of stability to develop long-term development projects. Thus, in contrast ' Thus, whereas European state building saw a sequencing in the development of state
functions, Latín America saw the simultaneous development of education, taxation, and
to the second, fiscally motivated, current of scholarship about state build- coercive capacity. On the sequencing of state development in Europe, see Tilly (r992) and
ing, I show that the interests and decision-making calculus cannot be Weber (r976).
20 Introduction Introduction 2I

in different countries opted for different responses to the same opportuni- discussed further in Chapter 2, has been a question largely ignored in the
ties. Where laissez-faire development visions dominated the political and existing scholarship. ' 9 That failed efforts by state leaders to extend con-
intellectual arena, state leaders responded to identical opportunities by trol over territory within their borders are rarely theorized is surprising;
choosing not to undertake state building. State-building projects emerged we would expect attention to the question, in particular given contem-
only when state leaders held a set of statist liberal views and believed that porary events, which revea! how difficult state building is in Afghanistan,
the power of the state was needed to achieve econornic development and Iraq, Libya, and elsewhere.
political stability. In sorne studies, this failure to consider the possibility of state-building
Finally, I account for the difference in ideology among cases, which failure raises the specter of functionalism. Herbst (2000) simply dis-
shapes whether state-building efforts emerge, by bringing geography into regards the issue, directly linking the cost-benefit calculations of state
the story. Against simple, cost-based accounts of geography's effect on leaders to the outcomes of state capacity. Although he writes that "the
state-building, I argue that urban primacy - the extent to which a coun- viability of African states depends on leaders successfully meeting the
try is dominated demographically and econornically by a single urban challenges posed by their particular environment" (3 l ), he never com-
center - affects the emergence of state-building projects through its effect plica tes the question of success. Instead, for Herbst, the cost structure
on which ideas about development take hold. Only countries marked by posed by the environment shaped the varied inclination of state leaders,
high levels of urban primacy saw an elite consensus about state building. whether colonial or post-independence, to build state capacity. The weak-
But where multiple cities aspired to national status, more laissez-faire ness of many African states is seen as a strategic response to structural
views tended to emerge. Here, regional differences in public good prefer- factors on the part of state leaders; it is the most efficient way to con-
ences were more salient, which made consensus around a limited role solidate their hold on power. My point here is not to critique Herbst on
for the state a least-bad solution to fiscal priorities. Because regions had empírica! grounds; instead I seek to point out that the possibility of bad
self-contained econornies, visions of development centered on the promo- choices or poor implementation of their chosen policies by state leaders
tion of regional rather than national progress, which did not depend on is something that his framework is unable to consider.
the extension of the authority of the central state. To my knowledge, the only existing study of state-building outcomes
Thus, state-building emergence was shaped by geographic and ide- that incorporates an explanation for failed state-building efforts is
ational factors. Chapter l further develops this portian of the theoretical 2
Downing {1992). º Downing shows that Poland, despite encompassing as
framework, and explains why state-building projects emerged in three late as 1634 the largest territory in Europe, and its great wealth, failed to
of the cases but not in Colombia. The chapter argues that Colombia's effectively mobilize in response to modernized rnilitary competition from
polycentric political economy made the extension of central state author- Prussia, Russia, and Austria. This failure, and the partition that resulted,
ity seem less relevant to the development projects envisioned by political can be traced to the institutions that Poland inherited from its early mod-
leaders than it did in Peru, Mexico, or Chile, and thus shaped the emer- ern era, which prevented any state-building effort from taking hold. The
gence of a more laissez-faire liberal consensus in that country. I trace the most famous of these, the liberum veto, allowed any single objection
conversations among political elites and intellectuals about the role of the to stop the proceedings of the sejm (national council of nobles) until it
state in national development in each case, showing that ali sought simi- could be resolved (Downing 1992, 14off). Whereas Downing argues that
lar goals. But the Colombian consensus diverged in the overall reluctance Sweden and the Dutch Republic were able to fight majar war without
to use state capacity in pursuit of development. This explains the absence intensified taxation, and that England did not need to raise taxes because
of a state-building project in Colombia.
19
The work of Ian Lustick (I993) is a partial exception, alrhough ir focuses on failed
efforts by srares to incorporare new territories into rheir countries, rather than on failure
Theorizing State-Building Failure to extend control over territory already forrnally within the state's jurisdiction. For a
Latin American accounr of such an effort, see Skuban (2007).
The second puzzle of variation in state capacity is accounting for the suc- 1
º Failed state building is, of course, not the sarne thing as state failure, about which there
cess and failure of state-building efforts where they do emerge. This, as is a robust scholarly debate.
22 Introduction Introduction 23

it avoided war, he argues that Poland's state leaders tried but failed to allowed state leaders to turn to long-terrn developrnent projects that
increase state capacity in response to rising externa! threat. would consolidate political stability and econornic growth.
My theoretical frarnework accounts far state-building failure as a
route to state weakness in Chapter 2, which provides a theory of the suc~
cess and failure of state-building projects. I argue that success depended Applying the Aigurnent
on local adrninistrative institutions, and in particular on whether or not Chapters 4 through 6 trace the origins of variation in state capacity
the bureaucrats were prorninent rnernbers of the local cornrnunity. The across the faur cases. They explore the fate of the state-building effarts in
relative weight of salary as a proportion of their incorne rnakes outsiders Chile, Mexico, and Peru, showing how the choice of deployed adrninis-
(that I call deployed bureaucrats) more responsive in general to the policy tration was crucial far their success in the farrner two countries, and how
preferences of the central state than are local elites who hold identical delegation to local elites led to failed state-building effarts in Peru. The
positions. Additionally, their greater reliance on the institutions of the chapters also show absence of state-building effarts, and concornitant
state as a source of legitirnacy and power gives the deployed bureaucrats weakness, in Colombia. The chapters facus, as described previously, on
an independent interest (not shared by their local elite counterparts) in education (Chapter 4), taxation (Chapter 5), and coercían (Chapter 6).
seeking increased state presence in their cornrnunities. Where state agents Each chapter describes the trajectories each country took in terrns of the
are deployed frorn outside the cornrnunity, their interests more closely relevant dirnension of state power. It then shows how the farrn of adrnin-
align with state builders than do the interests of local elites appointed istration shaped the outcorne, and considers the causal power of a corn-
to adrninistrative posts. The result is a greater degree of collaboration pelling alternative explanation that rnight be rnost likely to hold far that
with - and even prornotion of - state-building effarts. particular dirnension of state capacity.
Chapter 2, then, accounts far success and failure by exploring the pub- The Conclusion shows that the theoretical frarnework developed in the
lic adrninistration of state building. It argues that only where state leaders book can account far the trajectories of state developrnent region-wide,
opted to exclude local elites frorn adrninistering the national periphery and can also shed sorne light on the policy challenges of conternporary
were their effarts to extend the reach of the state successful. This was "nation-building." 1 also return to theoretical terrain, exploring the place
the case in Mexico and Chile, and to a lesser extent in Peru after I 89 5. of ideational and material factors, addressing issues of causal cornplexity
Chapter 3 traces the deterrninants of the choice to delegate adrninistra- and causal irnportance in theories of statebuilding, and showing the pay-
tion to local elites, orto deploy bureaucrats, showing that it derived frorn offs of the argurnent far scholarship on state developrnent more generally.
a cornbination of historically contingent factors including the perceived
threat of indigenous revolt, the specific content of liberal ideology, and
the currency of patronage cornrnonly used to bind political coalitions in
a given case.
Chapter 3 also sets the stage far the ernpirical analysis of state-building
ernergence and success in the rernainder of the book by describing the faur
cases in the decades prior to the onset of state building at rnid-century. By
showing that little difference rnarked the cases befare the rnid-nineteenth
century, it provides evidence against alternative explanations far varia-
tion in state capacity centered on the nature of colonial adrninistration
or the conflicts of the independence era. 1 show that independence was
fallowed by several decades of instability and state weakness in all faur
cases, as governrnents struggled to irnpose arder, extract resources, and
extend the reach of state institutions in unfavorable dornestic and inter-
national clirnates. Only the rnid-century ernergence of econornic stability
The Emergence of State-Building Projects

this concern, I preface the discussion of ideas by identifying the condi-


I
tions that shaped the divergence in the content of the ideas that took hold
across countries.
I argue that ideas about the place of the state in development efforts
The Emergence of State-Building Projects were shaped by the nature of political and economic geography. My
account centers on a novel aspect of geography, unexplored by previous
scholarship. I argue that urban primacy - the extent to which a coun-
try was dominated demographically and economically by a single urban
center - affected the emergence of state-building projects. In countries
marked by high levels of urban primacy, where a single dominant urban
core existed and development was seen in a center-periphery dynamic, an
elite consensus about the extension of central authority could take hold.
By contrast, where multiple regional centers each sat astride a distinct
regional political economy, the construction of central state authority did
This chapter explains why state-building projects emerged in sorne not seem a propitious development strategy. This was so for two reasons.
countries in post-independence Latin America but not in others. It thus First, elites clashed because each region had distinct public good prefer-
provides the first central element of a theory of variation in state capac- ences. Attempts to satisfy all parties were fiscally unsustainable, and this
ity; a theory of the fate of those state-building projects is the subject made a consensus around a lirnited role for the state more palatable than
of Chapter 2. Existing scholarship simply assumes that the decision to the conflict-prone alternatives. Second, where regions had self-contained
undertake state building is determined by structural conditions that economies and could generate sufficient economic production on their
translate directly into incentives to increase state capacity. By contrast, own to maintain and even increase standards of living without the need
I problematize the decision by political elites to undertake the concerted for national integration, visions of development centered on the promo-
effort of building state institutions and extending their reach. In so doing, tion of regional progress, which did not depend on the extension of the
I show that the conditions prompting state building in sorne countries authority of the central state.
had no analogous effect in others. Given largely similar structural condi- Geographic explanations for state-development outcomes have tended
tions, elites pursued the same ends of economic development and politi- to center on cost-based arguments, holding that size or terrain make the
cal stability with different means - in sorne cases, these means included extension of state authority more costly. 1 Based on this cost-based con-
state building, while in others, the means centered on minimizing state ception of geography, scholars expect that state-building projects will see
interference in prívate life. more success in smaller countries with less complex terrain - thus geog-
I argue that the responses of political elites to the post-independence raphy explains variation in the success of state-building projects. Another
context were shaped by their distinct ideas about the role of the state in current of scholarship holds that leaders decide whether or not to pursue
social transformation. Where elites carne to believe that the state was state building based on the costs imposed by geography and the fiscal
the essential agent of "order and progress," they sought to increase its gains from state building. My a~gument diverges from both of these posi-
capacity. Where, by contrast, they saw the state as an obstacle to eco- tions. Against the first group, I show that geography affects the decision
nomic development and social peace, no state-building efforts emerged. to undertake state-development projects but has no consistent impact on
The claim that ideas shaped whether political leaders chose to undertake their success. Against the second group, however, I argue that geogra-
state-building projects raises an important logical concern. The funda- phy shapes the decision to undertake state development not by influenc-
mental issue is one of causal depth: to say that ideas were the crucial ing a cost-benefit fiscal calculation, but by shaping leaders' beliefs about
independent variable explaining policy choice can be seen as tautological,
since cause and effect fall so close together in logical terms. To alleviate ' Citations to the relevant literature appear later, where it is discussed in more detaiL
State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 27

whether the increase of central state authority will serve their broader in which state leaders pursued their cornrnon goal of social pacification,
goals of political arder, social progress, and econornic developrnent. econornic developrnent, and política! stability, and confronted similar
The argurnent in full, then, unfolds as follows in this chapter. I first challenges to doing so.
discuss alternative geography-based explanations for variation in state
capacity, focusing on territorial size and characteristics of terrain. I show
GEOGRAPHY AND STATE DEVELOPMENT
that the correlations between these factors and rneasures of state capac-
ity are weak, and that they cannot account for the variation we observe Most scholarship on geography focuses on the costs of state-developrnent
in Latin America. By contrast, the statistical evidence for the clairn that efforts. Argurnents about territorial size and terrain (whether jungle,
urban prirnacy is necessary for state capacity is rnuch stronger. rnountains, or srnall-scale ruggedness) clairn that each aspect of geogra-
Based on that finding, the second part of the chapter argues that urban phy affects the cost of extending the reach of the state, and thus explains
prirnacy, or the absence of salient regionalisrn, is a necessary condition variation in the extent of state authority. 2 All else equal, the sarne invest-
far the ernergence of a consensus arnong national political elites that rnent in state building will produce fewer results where the geographic
increasing central state authority is a prornising developrnent strategy. costs are higher. Herbst (2000) builds on these accounts in arguing that
In its absence, regional divergences in public good preferences and the state leaders take the expected geography-induced costs into account in
prornotion of regional, rather than national, strategies generate an elite deciding whether or not to invest in state building. He argues that high
consensus around rninimizing central state authority as a developrnent geographic costs induce state leaders to choose not to undertake state
strategy. building at all; thus, their rational calculation should lead to state build-
Third, I show that these distinct patterns of elite consensus - which ing where conditions are favorable and to its absence where they are not.
I call statist and anti-statist or laissez-faire visions of developrnent - By contrast, I show ernpirically that the correlations between these
shaped how political elites approached the cornrnon threats and opportu- aspects of geography and levels (or rankings) of state capacity across
nities they faced. Where statist views dorninated, increasing state capacity Latín Arnerica are generally quite weak. The characteristics of territorial
was central to the development projects of state leaders. But in contexts size, jungles, mountains, and srnall-scale ruggedness in our four cases do
where anti-statist views dorninated, developrnent projects had a strik- not line up well with the variation observed arnong thern in state capacity.
ingly rninirnal vision of the place of the state in political development. Thus, the argurnent that geography affects the success of state-building
These patterns of elite consensus account for variation in the ernergence efforts by shaping the costs of administrative extension finds little sup-
of state-developrnent projects after the rnid-nineteenth century. Whether port in Latín Arnerica. In response, I introduce a novel aspect of geogra-
state building emerged during the liberal era had to do with the character phy to the literature in showing that urban prirnacy is strongly associated
of liberalisrn, as shaped by urban prirnacy. with state capacity. To explain this association, I depart frorn existing
In empírica! terms, this chapter explains why, in the face of simi- cost-based frarneworks, and argue that geography affects the decision to
lar political, econornic, and social conditions, a state-building project undertake state building rather than the success of state-building efforts.
emerged in Chile, Mexico, and Peru, but not in Colombia. I show that But this effect on the choice to undertake state building, irnportantly,
Colombia was unique arnong the four cases in the presence of rnultiple does not operate through calculations about the cost of state building
salient regions, which had self-contained econornies and sharply diver- as suggested by Herbst (2000), but through a distinct set of rnechanisrns
gent public good preferences, especially when it carne to the developrnent I elaborate. Cross-national evidence for the discussion that follows, cov-
of transportation infrastructure. By contrast, the other three countries ering the ten majar South American countries and Mexico, appears in
were dorninated by a single center and more closely resernbled a single Tables I.I and I.2.
national econorny. A center-periphery dynarnic dorninated political rela-
tionships across national territories and shaped the developrnent of trans- 2
On the effect of jungles, see Albertus and Kaplan (2013). On rnountainous terrain, see
port infrastructure in these cases, while regionalist tensions were rnuted. Fearon and Laitin (2003). The argurnent far srnall-scale ruggedness is rnade by Nunn and
The chapter traces the impact of this geographic difference for the ways Puga (2012).
.s The Emergence of State-Building Projects 29

""' V) ""' .,,.....,,


TABLE I.2, State capacity ranking and geography: region-wide correlations
Ñ tr,['.lr> tr,['.['.
\O Ñ CXl Ñ " ' " ' " ' ['-. CXl ""'
,;.,CÓ .,j-<icoco\O t-'.-có H"' -o RANKS State Military Literacy Railroad Census
B capacity rate density regularity
::;"'
u
-¡:::: oo \:O' -;;; H' -;;; o o;; ~ oo ~ -; Elev -o.r50 -o.04r -0.099 -o.r26
u -o.r98
..¡- "' \O \O "' CXl " ' ['-. \O o ['-. Clim
CXl _
_ CXl _
CXl_CXl_CXl
_CXl
_CXl
__ CXl ['-. O\ CXl
H...__..__. 0.338 0.247 0.374 o.2r4 0.224
H H H H H H H H 00 H H
Biomes o.r6o o.2r4 0.459 o.or5 -o.r79
\0\0 «"\«"\-.tt'--lr>O\~-.tO\
\O -.tt'--lr>-.t-.t-.t«"\\OCXl""' Ruggedness 0.075 o.r28 -o.r36 o.r6r 0.083
ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó Mountainousness -0.230 -o.r52 -0.304 -o.r67 -0.096
Size o.r49 -o.r90 o.r56 o.2r5 0.268
Jungle -o.7r8 -0.730
~
-0.523 -0.759 -0.239
o Primacy 0.607 o.3r6 0.584 0.649 0.338
N
Calculated from geographic indicator data in Table I.I, and tables measuring individual
dimensions of state capacity in the lntroduction. Positive correlations mean that a higher
score for the geographic factor is associated wit!Í a stronger state. Ali correlations with
absolute value greater than o. 5 are bolded. Results are little changed when numerical rather
.,; than ordinal measures of state capacity are used .
....
"
-o
....
o
..o
co oco t---0 -.t<'l t---<'l t'--0
N"\Ñ Q\«"\H\O 0\-.tCXl ['.\O
HN.HHÑHH{'("'\HÑH Size
ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó ó
Several arguments support the claim that smaller territories facil-
itate state development. First, larger territories are more costly to
administer (Herbst 2000). Second, size of territory increases the
transportation and information costs associated with representative
government, and therefore the accountability that facilitates rulers'
access to revenue (Stasavage 2011). All else equal, then, we might
"!"O\H lr>H
O\
Ñ H\O '<;'
expect that governments overseeing smaller territories should come
co .;..,;.,t-'.-t-'.-co i-< H t-'.-o H to be more effective.
Ñ""' "'""'""'"' ..¡- Ñ
The evidence linking territorial size and state building, however, is
weak in the Latin American context. Impressionistically, we can see in
Table r.1 that the two smallest countries in the region (Uruguay and
Ecuador) are the strongest state and the second weakest. More systemat-
ically, Table r.2 (using the rankings for state capacity as of 1900, elabo-
rated in the Introduction and size data from Table l. l) shows that size is
correlated with the overall state-development ranking at only 0.15, and
not strongly correlated with rankings on individual dimensions of state
capacity. Among our four cases, Mexico is by far the largest, with a ter-
ritory about 50 percent larger than that of Peru, and yet it is one of the
stronger states. If there is a relationship between size and state develop-
ment, it is a tenuous one.

28
30 State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 31

Terrain developrnent. Chile - our strongest state - has both the rnost rnountain-
Scholars have also often claimed that terrain poses challenges to state ous and the rnost rugged terrain of our cases, and indeed of the region
building and have identified severa! aspects of terrain that are said to as a whole. While we rnight disrniss Chile's rnountainousness score as
rnatter. Mountainous terrain is said to be difficult for the state to pene- º!
an artifac~ the fact that its border traces the spine of the Andes, rug-
trate, which explains why it acts as a facilitating condition for insurgency gedness d1d mcrease the challenge of infrastructure developrnent. Travel
(Fearon and Laitin 2003 ). Jungles, too, have recently been said to have the between Santiago and the coast at Valparaíso was so daunting that the
sarne effect and thus increase the costs of state development. (Albertus and route of fewer than roo miles took days to cover (Saylor 2or2, 30 7 ).
Kaplan 2or 3) Finally, terrain ruggedness - small-scale terrain irregularities Ruggedness posed daunting engineering challenges to the country's rail-
as opposed to rnountains - is said to make transportation and infrastruc- road b~lders, who had to fashion sorne of the largest railroad bridges
ture developrnent more costly and challenging (Nunn and Puga 2or2). to date m the annals of world engineering to cross the rough terrain of
Evidence for this relationship is again limited. Using the data in the southern heartland (Thomson and Angerstein 2000). Indeed, terrain
Table I.I, Table r.2 shows that rnountainousness is correlated in the posed such challenges to interna! cornrnunication in Chile that a geog-
expected direction, but weakly, with ali four dirnensions of state develop- rapher of the r94os described the country asan archipelago rather than
ment.3 Ruggedness is very weakly correlated with state development at a landmass (Lovernan 2oor, ro). And yet the Chilean state was strik-
-0.08. 4 In addition to the weak overall relationship, we also see that while ingly powerful by comparison to the region as a whole, including, by
it is positively associated with sorne dirnensions of state development the I 8 Sos, rnuch of the terrain south of the· Bio Bío River that had never
(military mobilization, railroad developrnent, and the census), ruggedness come under Spanish colonial control.
is negatively associated with the literacy rate. This is more evidence that Little differentiates the other three cases, which score similarly on
the putative link between ruggedness and state capacity doesn't hold for both of these measures of terrain. In all three, sornewhat rugged terrain
Latín American cases, since its effect is only in the predicted direction for increased the costs of infrastructure development and cornrnunication,
the aspect of state capacity it is least likely to affect. The jungle measure, and mountains divided the country and hampered unification. This simi-
by contrast to these, performs very well, with a correlation of -0.72 with larity, then, cannot explain the variation in state development - it cannot
state-development ranking overall, and similarly high correlations with account for the fact that the Mexican state became substantially stronger
railroad development (-0.76), literacy (-0.53), and military mobilization than the other two by the end of the liberal era.
(-0.73).5 The role of the Amazon basin, which includes large parts of our The presence of jungles seerns a more likely direction for further inves-
two weak state cases, is worth exploring further. ~igation; whe:eas Chile has none, Peru and Colombia both have a rnajor-
Looking at our four cases, we find scant evidence that the ruggedness 1ty of the nat10nal territory covered by tropical forest. Mexico falls in an
and mountainousness aspects of terrain can explain variation in state intermediate category, with I9 percent of its territory covered by tropical
forest. We can conclude from this discussion that while size, mountain-
3 Mountainousness is measured, using the data from Fearon and Laitin (2003), as the per-
ousness, and ruggedness are unlikely candidates, the role of the Amazon
centage of a country's terrain that is mountainous. This measure is calculated using con- (and of tropical forest more generally) in undermining state developrnent
temporary rather than historical borders. is an issue that is worthy of further exploration. This is supported by the
Ruggedness seores are drawn from diegopuga.org/data/rugged as described in Nunn and
o~vious_ difficulties posed by the jungle to infrastructure development,
4

Puga (2012). These, once again, use contemporary borders.


5 Jungle seores for each country, followingAlbertus and Kaplan (2013) are measured as the d1fficult1es that caused travel between Lima and !quitos, for exarnple,
percentage of the national territory (using contemporary rather than historical borders) to take "weeks if not rnonths" (Pike r967, 3) and which leave rnany
falling in climatic zones l-4 (tropical rain forest or tropical monsoon type, ground wet ali towns in the Peruvian Amazon unconnected to the national road net-
year), using the PLACE 11 Dataset available at sedac.ciesin.columbia.edu/place (CIESIN
2007). Tables I.l and I.2 also show HHI Indices for climatic zones and biomes, as sug-
work even today.
gested in Nunn and Puga (2012), but these are quite weakly correlated with ali measures Because the Amazon was scarcely populated and marginal in eco-
of state development. nomic terrns for rnuch of the nineteenth century, the regions it spanned
32 State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 33

were of low priority to state leaders in both Colombia and Peru. 6 Yet the But what about countries where there is no single center, but instead mul-
state in these two countries was equally weak in non-Amazonian regions; tiple spheres of influence that reach across sizable portions of the national
thus the presence of the Amazon cannot be sufficient to explain overall territory? In these cases, where we cannot conceptualize the process of
state weakness. Evidence of this can be seen, for example, in Chapter 4, state building in terms of a center-periphery dichotomy, but instead as
where I show that education lagged not only in the Amazonian provinces the knitting together of separare and salient regions, how is state building
of Peru and Colombia, but in the highlands as well. The cost of adminis- affected? I argue that, ali else equal, the ímpetus to increase central state
trative extension into the Amazon is insufficient to account for why these authority will be weaker in countries that h'ave multiple salient regions
states are weaker than those of Mexico and Chile.7 This is confirmed by with cities that have the potential to be centers of gravity for political
the fact that when rubber and oil booms made the Amazon an important centralization. I identify two mechanisms that make the absence of a sin-
site for states, they were unable to extend their reach to these territories gle dominant center sufficient for state weakness in the absence of exter-
(Yashar 2005). na! motivations for state building.
The first mechanism relates to the likelihood that distinct regions will
have divergent preferences about the location and type of public goods
Urban Primacy, Regional Salience, and State Development
provided by the state. Location matters because willingness to contribute
If size and terrain cannot account for variation in the implementation to public goods is likely to be correlated with proximity to them, which
of state-building projects, are there any aspects of geography that can? facilitares access to the benefits they generate (Alesina and Spolaore 2005).
I argue that a population structure marked by urban primacy (the pres- Given the scarcity of governmental resources, cho ices about where to locate
ence of a single dominant city) was necessary for state-building efforts in state services will create high stakes conflict over basic state-building pri-
Latín America to emerge. This relationship holds because where urban orities.9 As conflict over public good provision priorities intensifies, state
primacy is present, state building - the extension of authority from the building is diluted. Additionally, the presence of multiple urban centers
center to the periphery - is both more likely to be seen as a means to often derives from the presence of distinct regional economies, each of
política! and economic development, and less likely to be diluted by which has elites with distinct preferences over the types of public goods
regionalist tensions. the state is to provide. Rodríguez (I985) traces the turmoil that resulted
Urban primacy has received little attention in political science scholar- from this conflict in nineteenth century Ecuador, where state building was
ship. Instead, theories of state building begin from the presumption that undermined by regional tensions between Quito and Guayaquil that cen-
it unfolds as the center extending its control o ver the national periphery. 8 tered on the distinct policy preferences of each region's dominant eco-
nomic sector. A similar dynarnic can be found in the United States, which
6 There is an echo here of Herbst's argument about countries with large unpopulated saw sectionalist tensions undermine state-building efforts both during
regions; he would expect that because these regions lacked population that can be a
source of revenue or a threat that needed to be controlled, the state had little incentive to and after the Civil War (Bensel (I984, I990). Tensions between multiple
extend its reach into them. Yet this would suggest that more resources were available far salient regions over public good priorities contribute to political instabil-
establishing effective state control outside the Amazon, and the observed weakness of the ity, and these tensions can only be resolved through compromises that sat-
Peruvian and Colombian state in non-Amazonian regions casts doubt on this possibility.
I am grateful to Richard Snyder far suggesting this line of argument. isfy actors from ali regions (logrolling) and the resulting dilution of policy
1 Were the object of study in this project subnational variation in the reach of the state priorities, or through regionalist conflict, which may escalare to secession.
in a single case, one might facus on the obstacles posed by the jungle to administrative
extension. But given that national seores far state capacity diverge sharply even if the
Amazonian regions are excluded from the analysis, one must facus attention on other
variables. contrast I propase to examine the effects of purely spatial factors on state-development
8 This approach characterizes a wide range of accounts of state building, including Weber outcomes.
(1976), Spruyt (1994), and Alesina and Spolaore (2005). Herbst (2000) is a partía! excep- 9 Alesina and Spolaore (2005) argue that this dynamicmight even genera te conflict over the
tion in that he lumps size, terrain, and the presence of regional challengers together into location of a capital city, since the seat of government generares a set of public goods as
the category of "dif:ficult" political geographies. Much scholarship, including Herbst, well as jobs. Thus, countries lacking urban primacy may even see conflict over the loca-
conflates regionalism with ethnic diversity in linking regionalism to political conflict; by tion of the capital city - we see this, far example, in Bolivia.
34 State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 35

In the best case scenario, then, sufficiently high tensions over divergent size of the largest city in a country to the sum of the four largest cities.
public good preferences dilute state-building priorities. The seores for each country shown in Table r.2 use the standard mea-
The second mechanism relates to the fact that the absence of sure; the results that follow are unchanged with alternative measures.
urban primacy is often accompanied by the presence of salient and The standard measure of primacy divides the population of the larg-
self-sufficient regional economies. Where regional economies are est city by the sum of that of the four largest, and the primacy score can
self-enclosed and self-sufficient, the gains seen from overcoming vary between 0.25 (if the four cities are equal in size) to l (if the largest
regional tensions and knitting the country together are smaller. 1 º In city contains the entire population of the country). In Latin America,
this context, centralization of authority is seen as less propitious for urban primacy seores vary from Uruguay at 0.84 to Venezuela and
economic development, political stability, and social peace than pol- Paraguay at 0.39. The regional average is 0.54, with a standard devi-
icies that allow already salient regional economies and identities to ation of o. l 5. Primacy, as seen in Table I.2 is strongly correlated with
flourish. The result is that development efforts, where they do emerge, state development, with a correlation coefficient of 0.61 with the over-
unfold at the regional and local level, and the extension of national all ranking, and coefficients of o.6 5 with the railroad development
state authority is not seen as a means to "arder and progress." In short, ranking, 0.58 with the literacy ranking, and about 0.3 with census
state building simply appears less important, all else equal, to politi- iterations and military mobilization. Higher rates of urban primacy
cal leaders. The salience of regionalism, then, may be compatible with are associated with stronger states. This correlation remains robust
robust local or regional political authority and indeed with local public even with the exclusion of Uruguay, which is an outlier in its high
good provision, but it is not a propitious context for the construction primacy score.
of national state power. Yet given that I argue that urban primacy is causally necessary but
insufficient for state development, it is not logically appropriate to
Measurement assess the face validity of this relationship with simple correlations,
To explore this proposed relationship between regionalism and state as I have done in Table I.2 for the other dimensions of state capacity.
weakness, we need a measure of the economic and political importance Instead, a scatter plot can be used to assess the face validity of claims
of each region relative to the country as a whole. Because this impor- of causal necessity. We should see, in the binary plots that follow, only
tance is hard to measure, the crude but telling indicator of population low levels of state capacity when urban primacy is low. By contrast, at
is commonly used as a form of measure of the extent of urban primacy high levels of urban primacy, state-development seores can vary across
in a given country. To rule out the possibility that state development the full range. If my claim about this causal relationship is correct, all
affects urban primacy for example, by drawing population to the points (or nearly all, given the possibility of outliers) should fall below
capital city - 1 measure primacy for the earliest post-independence the imaginary 4 5 degree line extending outward from the origin in
date in each country for which I could find data on the population of each graph. Figure I.l shows scatter plots for five indicators of state
at least eight cities. I I The degree of urban primacy of a country refers capacity. All five charts confirm that only low levels of state capacity
to the concentration of a disproportionate share of its population in are found at low levels of urban primacy, while in countries with pri-
a single city, and there are standard measurement strategies for cal- marily urban distributions, values of state capacity from across the
culating national seores for the distribution of population. (Acles and spectrum can be found. It is reasonable to propase, then, that the rela-
Glaeser 199 5; Zipf 1941) Most classically, one calculates a ratio of the tionship between urban primacy and state capacity is worthy of further
exploration.
10
This argurnent is not unrelated to that of Spruyt ( 1994) about how different forrns of The population-based measure of primacy, of course, lacks nuance
trade underpinned the ernergence of distinct political institutions across early rnodern for two reasons: first, it <loes not account for the distance between
Europe.
the cities included and thus the extent to which polycephaly reflects
" For the sake of consistency, ali population data was drawn frorn the Populstat web data-
base, available online at populstat.info, rather than frorn estima tes by country specialists. the presence of distinct regions - thus, for example Lima and Callao,
State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 37
36

GCHI
(d) .008
(a) 8
GURU
GCHI

.006
6 GCOL

GMEX
w
N
rn (jj
:> ..J
rn
4 OBRA .004 GPAR
e: OVEN
~ OECU
"'
()
GPER GARG GURU
OARG
MEXGGBOL
OVEN OBOL GPER
2 .002 OBRA

OCOL

o OPAR GECU
o
.4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8
PRIMACY PRIMACY

(e) GCHI
(b) 10 GURU
1.5 GURU
OARG
OMEX
8

OMEX
Cl
U) 6 OARG z
z OCHI w
w a.
U) .5
Cl ..J
cr: ~
cr: 4 OBRA
OBOL
o ·~: OPER
2 OBRA OECU
GPER
OVEN GBOL OCOL

o
0PAR
~OL OECU -.5

.6 .7 .8 .4 .5 .6 .8
.4 .5
PRIMACY
PRIMACY

FIGURE r.r. (continued)


OURU
(e) 70 GARG

OCHI

60

which abut but are jurisdictionally separare, are counted as distinct


>-
ü
<( 50 cities in Peru. As a result, seores for Peru are artificially depressed in
cr:
w
1--
GPAR
GCOLOECU
this measurement strategy since the dominance of the capital city is
::;
40 understated when Callao is not counted as part of the Lima metropolis,
OBRA
OMEX
GPER and likewise for Buenos Aires and Argentina. Second, and likely more
OVEN
30 significant, this measure fails to fully capture the nature of regionalism
OBOL
that drives the political effects described previously. Thus, in investi-
20 gating the role of primacy in state development in our four cases, we
.5 .6 .7 .8
.4 must explore the city network of each country and its regionalism in a
PRIMACY
more careful manner.
FIGURE I.I. Scatterplots of state capacity and urban primacy.
State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 39

Urban Primacy in Our Cases Santiago and its peripheries facilitated a concerted state-building pro-
In Peru, Chile, and Mexico, the national territory was dominated by a ject. The liberal-conservative "fusion" governments of the 1861-1891
single city. Although each country had peripheries not tightly linked to era reflect this deep elite consensus (Scully 1992). The result was the
the urban core, regional tensions over public good priorities were lim- construction of a railroad network that linked grain-producing regions
ited, and all economically productive and politically salient areas were to Santiago and Valparaíso; while this was not the most economically
deeply embedded into the national economy with the capital at its cen- efficient path, it sufficed to satisfy producers while further reinforcing
ter. This was not the case in Chile; therefore I discuss regional tensions the hegemony of the capital and its port. As Bauer (1975, 65) shows,
and economic self-sufficiency in that case in more detail in the following Valparaíso's flour exports as a share of the national total rose from l per-
section. cent in the early l 8 5os to more than 5 2 percent by the late l 8 6os. Over
time, the demographic centralization of Chile deepened, and the state
building described in the chapters that follow unfolded as the extension
Chile of authority from the central valley into the national periphery.
Chile's urban primacy score of 0.53 shows that Santiago was more than
the size of the next three largest cities combined. Not only was Santiago
Mexico
by far the largest city, but the only other large center of population,
Valparaíso, was nearby and deeply embedded in the capital's economic Mexico's raw score for urban primacy is quite low: data from the 1850
circuit. While Santiago and Valparaíso combined had nearly 200,000 census generates a score of 0.4 5, or somewhat below that of Chile. Yet this
residents, only four other cities had more than lo,ooo. Of these four, understates the centrality of Mexico City in national life; its sizable con-
two (Talca and La Serena) were likewise furnly tied to Santiago in polit- temporary importance was only reinforced by centuries of colonial his-
ical and economic terms by the early nineteenth century. Not only did tory, and by the pre-colonial dominance of the Aztec empire centered on
these regions provide grain to Santiago but they depended on production the same site (Hardoy 1967). Its l 8 50 population of 170,000 made it per-
from the central valley around the capital to fulfill basic needs (Saylor haps the largest city in Spanish America, and it was nearly twice the size
2012). The other two, Concepción and Copiapó, were the focal points of Guadalajara, the country's second city. None of the country's secondary
of the country's northern and southern regions. Regional tensions were cities was important enough to emerge as an alternative core of politi-
not completely absent in Chile: in the l84os, southern landowners, for cal power. The distribution of urbanization closely matched the classic
example, pressed the government for improved transportation, and mine primate pattern: secondary cities like Guadalajara, Puebla, Guanajuato,
owners in the north were negatively impacted by tax increases on copper Colima, and Querétaro were located in the environs surrounding the capi-
exports, and infuriated by the refusal of the government to subsidize rail- tal and were deeply bound to it in both economic and political terms. By
roads from mines to ports (Saylor 2014, 61-62). These tensions were one 1867, urban primacy had risen sharply to 0.53, which places Mexico on
spark in the short-lived civil wars of the l85os, as both north and south the same level as Chile; it would continue to rise thereafter.
sought greater regional fiscal autonomy and a more favorable allocation Although Mexico's territory was immense by comparison to the other
of governmental resources. cases, even far-flung regions were tied to Mexico City rather than to alter-
But with these brief exceptions, the political salience of regionalism native centers of authority. Veracruz, which controlled the vast majority
was limited, and Santiago dominated. Deep ties between elites across of ocean-going trade, was deeply connected to the capital, and even sisal
rural and urban sectors, along with the consensus on economic open- from the Yucatán traveled on small boats to the port of Veracruz to be
ness, stemmed regionalism. Mine owners in the north, agriculturalists in loaded into large ships for export (Coatsworth 1981, 25). Railroad con-
the southern heartland and the central valley, and merchants in the cap- struction, the rise of cattle, and the recovery of mining tied the northern
ital and in Valparaíso had no deep divisions in trade preferences. While desert into Mexico City economically, as the north became a zone of
there was sorne dispute about infrastructure priorities and in particular transir between the United States and the capital. The deep tensions that
railroad construction (Saylor 2012), the broad elite coalition that united made Mexican politics so unstable in the decades after independence,
State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 41

while fundamentally connected to disagreement over how much power arena. In this way, a crucial facilitating condition for state development
the center should have, did not divide along regional lines. They pitted emerged by the mid-184os in Peru.
center (Mexico City and Veracruz) against periphery rather than regions
against one another. Conflict was for control over an unquestioned cen-
Colombia
ter, and over the policies that would emanate from it, rather than between
Mexico City and challengers for national power. Although its raw score for urban primacy is quite similar to that of
Mexico, Colombia's regional demography was in fact quite different
from the other three cases. Colombia was a stark outlier in that it lacked
Peru
a single predominant urban center. 12 The country's population was dis-
Peru's primacy score is the highest among the four cases. A skeptic might persed widely, as reflected in the fact that while Bogotá as of l 8 5.1 had
suggest this is an artifact of its calculation based on data from a later cen- just shy of 30,000 residents, thirty other municipalities had between
sus, since population data from befare 1876 is spotty. But data from earlier 8,ooo and 15,000. These medium-sized cities included regional centers
census iterations shows the dominance of Lima. Gootenberg's (1995) recon- like Popayán, Socorro, and Medellín. This meant that regions were, much
struction of the 1827 census shows that Peru hada national population of more than those in the other countries, oriented around their central cit-
slightly more than r. 5 million, of whom more than ro percent lived in the ies rather than linked to the national capital. As of 1870, Cundinamarca,
department of Lima and its port of Callao. Centuries of colonial rule, which Bogotá's state, ranked only fourth among Colombian states in popula-
placed Lima and Callao at the center of not only national but continental tion, behind Boyacá, Cauca, and Santander (Park 1985, 25). The city
life, reinforced its dominance. Although the highland province of Jauja, cen- of Bogotá remained the same size in 1870 as it had been in the l84os
ter of the mining industry, had a larger population than did Lima, it was (Urrutia 2oro, 8), as its share of national population fell over the course
deeply embedded in the capital's economic circuir as its production traveled of the fust fifty years after independence (Flórez and Romero 2oro, 4ro).
by mule train clown the Andes to exit the country from the port of Callao. This had two effects. First, instead of Bogotá dominating the country,
Initially, Peru did have a more salient regional cleavage than did it "had to share economic power with important rivals in other regions"
either Mexico or Chile. This divide separated the southern highland (Safford and Palacios 2002, 9). The lack of dominance of Bogotá was
region centered on Arequipa, which depended on free trade, from the perhaps reflected most clearly in a proposal debated during the 1863
protectionist regions of the north coast, central highlands, and Lima Constitutional Convention to move the national capital to the state
(Gootenberg 1989). Southern free traders were not powerful enough of Panama (Park 1985, 40). Second, because regional cities were large
to seize power nationwide, but they made two concerted, although enough to absorb much of local economic production, trade within the
failed, attempts at secession in the l83os. These were central to Peru's country was lirnited. Palacios (2006, 5) describes Colombia as a "mosaic
early post-independence instability, and Gootenberg argues that they of isolated regions." Even plans to develop interna! commerce as a means
"prevented the consolidation of a national state in Peru" in the l83os to economic development tended to focus on fairly local projects rather
(ibid., 44-45). than ones that crossed regions (Rosenthal 2012, 125). There was simply
By the mid-184os, this cleavage eroded dramatically for three reasons. no vision of Colombia as a national economic unit centered on Bogotá -
The fust was the victory of a pro-free trade coalition in Lima, which this was reflected, for example, in Christie's argument that "there was
removed one of the core tensions between the two regions. Second, the little to draw [elites] automatically to the capital" (Christie 1979, 44).
onset of the guano boom after 1845 led to massive cuts in domestic tax- What distinguishes Colombia from the other cases is not that these
ation, which also diluted tensions as described in Chapter 5. Third, the regions were separated by geographic obstacles - that describes significant
center of gravity and population in the country shifted dramatically
toward Lima, which grew sharply after mid-century. The result was that a 12
Deas (1993, 207) argues that this is still the case today; indeed, contemporary urban
center-periphery dynamic of Lima extending into the interior, rather than primacy seores would still place Colombia far below the other cases in terms of the
one of competition among regions, had firmly taken hold in the political demographic dominance of its largest city.
State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 43

portions of the territories of our other three cases. Instead, the key is Tensions were so high that "prominent Colombians were contemplat-
that Colombia's regions both had distinct political economies and were ing national dismemberment" in the late l86os and early l87os (Park
economically self-sufficient. As a result, Colombia "differs from other l 9 8 5, 7 l-72). Most centrally, conflict revolved around proposals to
countries of similar size in the deep imprint its regionalist sentiment has improve links from highland production centers to the Magdalena River,
left on the pattern of national development" (Park 1985, 7). Because this since transport far the 150 miles between Bogotá and Honda, the capital's
"regionalist sentirnent" was so powerful and so unique in comparative river port, cost more than shipping all the way from Honda to Liverpool
perspective, it needs to be explored more carefully. Later, I show that it (Safford and Palacios 2002, 13). Each potential route favored sorne parts
underpinned the two mechanisms outlined previously that prevented the of the states through which it would pass at the expense of others. 7 The 1

emergence of a state-building consensus. City size information far each coast and Cauca were horrified by the scale of funding entailed far a
case is shown in Table r.3, 57. project that would not benefit them (Safford 1988, 53 ). This railroad was
the central issue in the 1875 elections, and tension over the "feasibility
Divergent Preferences across Colombia's Regions and location" of railroad projects also spurred the 1876-1877 civil war
Most scholars of Colombia portray itas divided into faur salient regions - (Safford 2010, 5 5 5 ).
the Atlantic coast, Cauca, the Central Cordillera, and the Eastern A common means of defusing tensions was to fund enough projects to
Cordillera - during the first century after independence. 1 3 Because of their keep all important regional interests satisfied. While it reduced (but did
distinct political economies, Colombia's faur salient regions had quite not eliminate) conflict, this strategy drove budget deficits and diluted any
divergent preferences about public good priorities. 1 4 This was reflected concerted effort at infrastructure development (Junguito 2oro, 91). Yet
most clearly in the divergent infrastructure improvements prioritized by this type of logrolling was a consistent practice in Colombia throughout
each region 1 5 (Gallup et al. 2003, 90). the second half of the nineteenth century. The 1864 Transport Law, far
The Atlantic coast prioritized infrastructure development linking example, listed "fifteen projects deemed most worthy of federal aid" and
the regían to the interior since that would increase the flows of exports was refarmed in subsequent years to add yet more proj ects to the list (Park
through its ports of Cartagena, Barranquilla, and Santa Marta. The 1985, 65). The 1871 law listed twenty-eight priority projects, and this
Central Cordillera (centered on the states of Antioquia and Tolima) and list, too, grew over time (ibid., 66). As deficits worsened, and majar infra-
the Eastern Cordillera states of Cundinamarca, Boyacá, and Santander structure projects fell incomplete, the national government was farced
also prioritized transport on the Magdalena River that would allow in the mid-188os to make massive cuts in public works appropriations.
mining and agricultural production to reach export markets. 16 But these A second strategy was devolving public works decisions to the states.
co-partisans of improved Atlantic trade infrastructure were torn apart Devolution can be seen as far back as the 1836 Ley de Caminos, which
by severe disputes over the specifics of transport improvements. A faurth distributed funds to provinces based on population as a way to avoid con-
regían, Cauca, diverged sharply. Here, transport to the Pacific port of flict over road priorities, and it was institutionalized under the 1863 con-
Buenaventura was the central goal. stitution (Safford 2oro, 531). As part of the settlement of the 1876-1877
civil war, funding was allocated to each state far transport projects it
chose (Junguito 2oro, 89). Despite a constitutional ban on the practice,
1
The description in the succeeding paragraphs represents a consensus view arnong schol-
J states funded them through road taxes on goods in transit. This internal
ars, drawing most directly on Park (1985, 24-34). "tariff warfare," as described in contemporary press accounts, highlights
'4 Posada-Carbó (1996, 3) argues that regional divisions in Colombia were fundamentally

economic rather than about "subjective identity."


the centrality of regional rather than national interests (quote from Park
1
s Trade policy was also quite contentious; tariffs on imports burdened the interior almost 1985, 253). Rather than a national development plan, Colombia saw a
exclusively. Regional tensions were pararnount in tax policy debates, shaping both the
initial l85os decentralization and the mid-187os demands far another round of decen-
tralization Uunguito 2010, 68, 83). " Befare railroad technology became available, similar tensions stymied plans to connect
16
Santander's coffee and cacao was exported via the Venezuelan port of Maracaibo, which the highlands to the Magdalena by the way of roads in both the colonial and early repub-
generated unique priorities far economic development. lican eras (Safford 2010, 530).
44 State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 45

litany of state-level projects designed and implemented independently, as a certain amount of infrastructure development in particular locations.
"interstate railroads were thus abandoned" (Park 1985, 157-158). This Tobacco, far example, led to improvement of Magdalena River steam nav-
both reflected and reinforced the salience of its regional divisions. igation. But none of these resulted in attempts to "promote other sorts of
exports or promote regional integration by trade" (McGreevey 1971, 236).
Self-Sufficient Regions and the Locus of Development Even the coffee booms had limited effects on infrastructure: roads remained
Efforts in Colombia undeveloped, mules remained pivotal to getting coffee to export markets,
Because each of Colombia's regions had a large enough population and and most of the coffee producing regions remained unconnected to the
a diverse production pro:file, they were largely self-sufficient. As a result, railroad network as late as 1920 (Palacios 1980, 12). The limited trans-
the gains perceived from the potentially costly process of integration port development that did occur linked each region to the external mar-
were quite limited, and there was no imperative to undertake an effort ket, rather than unifying the country and its economy. Perhaps the starkest
to overcome the regional tensions described previously. The fact that evidence of this absence of unification was the failure to coordinate track
Colombia was "economically invertebrate" (Safford 1988, 53) made the widths across regions. Even where multiple train lines intersected, goods
payoffs from establishing a powerful state unclear, and made the path to could not easily pass from one region to another (Safford 2orn, 563). The
development through the fastering of regional self-sufficiency seem plau- self-sufficiency of Colombia's regions led policy makers to see "arder and
sible. As a result, "the integration of a national market, and therefare progress" as goals to be pursued at the regional, rather than nacional, level.
transportation improvement, may have been less fundamentally impor- Geography shaped state development in Latin America, then,
tant to Colombians" than it was to political elites in our other cases because it affected the role for the state envisioned by political lead-
(Safford 1988, 37). Instead, regions were tied into the world economy ers when they sought to promote political arder, economic progress,
"without the presence and involvement of the central state" (Palacios and social change. Where a country was characterized by a dominant
1980, ix). urban center, linked to most of its populated and economically pro-
Trade between Colombia's regions was minimal throughout the nine- ductive regions, the extension of the center's authority into the periph-
teenth century (Ramírez and Salazar 2010, 427). One exception was ery seemed like a propitious development strategy. But where multiple
textiles from Santander, which did provide clothing in other states. But cities stood astride regional economies and divided the country into
faod and other basic commodities were rarely exchanged across regions salient zones, building central state capacity was hampered by conflict
(Safford 2010, 530). Even as the coffee export boom took off, peasants over public good priorities, and by the fact that it did not seem like a
continued to grow faod far local consumption, and larger haciendas necessary step toward these goals.
cushioned against fluctuating coffee prices by producing faod, sugar, and These factors (regional tensions and self-sufficiency) explain not
beef far local markets (Palacios 1980, 93-4). only the variation in the development of transportation infrastruc-
Instead, regions evolved largely independent of one another in eco- ture discussed previously. They also explain, as Chapters 4 to 6 illus-
nomic terms, and pursued economic policies chosen with regional rather trate, why a broader state-building project failed to emerge in liberal
than national imperatives in mind. One clear instance of this regionalist Colombia; why education, taxation, and conscription were not pursued
emphasis can be seen late in the nineteenth century, when a prominent in any systematic manner. The establishment of arder and progress did
politician in Antioquia spoke of the need to promote "industries produc- not seem to Colombian political elites to depend on the imposition of
ing goods which we unnecessarily bring from other states" (Park 1985, central authority, nor could they agree on what that central author-
254). He was not referring to the need to protect Colombian markets ity, if empowered, should do. Instead, arder and progress would come
against imports from abroad, but Antioquian markets against imports from creating political conditions that would encourage regional and
from other Colombian states. individual initiative to flourish. The uniquely anti-statist liberalism of
Colombia enjoyed a series of minar commodity booms over the course mid-century Colombia explains why a state-building project failed to
of the period under investigation, culminating with the much larger. cof- emerge in that case, and thus accounts far the roots of Colombia's
fee booms. Because each boom was regionally concentrated, they drove weak state.
State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 47

project cut across the liberal-conservative divide, which was the major
THE IDEATIONAL FOUNDATIONS OF STATE-BUILDING
cleavage of nineteenth-century politics. Both groups agreed, despite the
PROJECTS
heated debates on other fronts, that the state should actively promote
The remainder of this chapter digs more deeply into the role of ideas "progress" within its borders. Conservatives generally accepted broadly
in the four cases, showing in more detail their causal weight in shap- liberal beliefs, with a particularly broad and stable consensus about the
ing state-building trajectories. Here I dig further into the mechanisms central role of primary product exports as the means to econornic devel-
discussed previously that make urban primacy necessary for state build- opment (Mahoney 2001, 31; Hale 1989, 8). One important exception
ing. I emphasize the divergence between Colombia and the other cases was church-state relations, which divided liberals and conservatives. Yet
in the ideas held by political leaders about the policy instruments they a focus on this small portian of the political agenda obscures the broader
would use to pursue political and econornic development, and show that consensus that marked even Colombia and Mexico, where liberals were
the content of this consensus links urban primacy to the divergence in particularly anti-clerical and conflict over church-state relations particu-
state-building efforts between Colombia and the other cases. 18 Elsewhere, larly intense.
liberalism was more statist and a consensus around state building as a But positions on the policy means by which "development" should
means to development emerged. But in Colombia, liberalism took a more be pursued varied across countries in crucial ways, with Colombia a
anti-statist tone, and a consensus emerged around a laissez-faire develop- major outlier. In Chile and Peru, a consensus held that the state's abil-
ment project. Thus urban primacy, by shaping the ideas of political elites ity to create "progress" and "civilization" depended on expanding its
about how to pursue development, determined whether state-building role through the national territory. The state, in their view, should pro-
efforts emerged in rnid-nineteenth-century Latin America. To comple- mote "development" by fulfilling functions such as security provision,
ment the exploration of other dimensions of state capacity in Chapters 4 infrastructure development, and school construction. In Mexico, too,
to 6, I highlight how this dynamic played out in the development of pub- liberal reformers envisioned the state as a central actor in dramatic
lic transportation infrastructure in this section. social transformation. In their view, the main obstacles to stability
were the corporate power of the Church, and the social and economic
stagnation of the indigenous population. They planned to build the
The Varied Content of Mid-Century Liberalism power of the national state to overcome these obstacles. Thus, in these
Across the ideological spectrum in rnid-century Latín America, a con- three cases, political power carne into the hands of leaders who sought
sensus emerged that política! "order" had econornic and social roots. to expand the reach of the state as a means to "'order," "progress," and
Politicians believed that states should promote domestic and interna- "civilization."
tional trade as a means of econornic "progress," requiring a new role for In Colombia, on the other hand, a consensus held that the state should
the state in the economy. l9 A broad consensus among política! elites also promote development by minirnizing its intervention, which would allow
held that the population needed to be molded into citizens that could individual initiative and market incentives to create social change and
participate in the "order" and "progress" being created. This implied econornic development. Political elites in Colombia diverged from those
state action to "civilize" the population. The consensus on this state elsewhere who saw state building as the means to those ends, seeing it
instead as an obstacle to the individual initiative that would bring the
progress they sought.
'8 My focus neither explains the content of ideas held by particular individuals, nor the
The following descriptions of the content of the liberal consensus in
dissemination of the ideas - those issues have been amply explored by the historians on
whom I draw. Following Hall (1993) and Goldstein and Keohane (1993 ), I conceptualize each country case highlight both the goals envisioned by leaders and
ideas as policy instruments, or mental roadmaps. ideologues, and the means by which they believed these goals should
19 Against those who claim that the liberal reforms were an instance of state capture by be pursued. The contrasting content of liberal ideas between the statist
exporting elites, I show that most (but not ali) of these efforts involved an explicit
attempt to increase the power of the state to penetrate society and effectively implement liberalism of Chile, Peru, and Mexico and the laissez-faire liberalism of
policies (Bushnell and Macaulay 1994, 191). Colombia, shaped by the divergences in política! geography described
State Building in Latin America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 49

previously, explains why state-developrnent efforts only emerged in the there was once again a broad - although not unanirnous - consensus)
farrner set of cases but not in the latter. was a massive state intervention to incorporare the indigenous popu-
lation by assirnilation, a process explicitly modeled on the reservations
policy of the United States (Janes 1999). By the l86os, state builders in
The State and Progress in Chile
Chile had arnbitions to extend their control through the entire national
Chilean political leaders sought to create social conditions that favored territory, a rnassive expansion of the presence and weight of the state.
the expansion of prirnary product exports. The country's Anuarios
Estadísticos and census publications, reflections of the vision of
"Order" and "Progress" in Mexico
high-ranking state officials far their country's future, reflect the vision
of "progress," "developrnent," and "civilization" held by state officials After its defeat by the United States and the devastation caused by the
and the audiences far their writings (Estefane Jararnillo 2004). In their Yucatan Caste War, both liberals and conservatives were unsure of "the
constant cornparative references to Europe, rather than to other countries survival of Mexico as a nation" Hale (1989, 16). This farged a consen-
in Latin Arnerica, the Anuarios clearly reflect the aspirations of state lead- sus arnong political elites that sweeping refarrns involving increased state
ers. The Chilean political elite believed that expanding state authority and power were needed (Topik 1988, 121). But while the depth of the crisis
extending its reach into the national periphery was the rnost appropriate spurred a consensus about the need far refarrns, deep divisions remained
rneans far pursuing these goals (Silva 2008, chapter l). Consensus on this about their content. The first atternpt to increase state power as a rneans
prograrn stretched across the entire ideological spectrurn of the political of exiting the crisis carne during Santa Anna's last terrn (1853-1855).
class. Both the Portalian conservatives and the liberals who took power This conservative project was built around a radical centralization of
after the l85os shared a desire to rationalize society (Lovernan 1993, public adrninistration to generate order. Santa Anna's atternpts at cen-
330). Unlike their counterparts in both Mexico and Colombia, Chile's tralization and the irnposition of a constitutional rnonarchy led to revolts
liberals accepted that the Church would continue to play a central role by local elites. These revolts, once they succeeded in deposing Santa Anna
in society, including in education (Collier 2003, n5). This rneant that in l 8 5 5, brought to power a group of liberals who had a very differ-
state-building efforts were less conflictual, keeping the church and state ent prescription far curing Mexico's ills. º But divisions between liberals
2

as partners in the "civilizing" of a largely rural, poor society. A broad and conservatives about the content of refarrns then spurred the greatest
consensus also held that the state needed to undertake the infrastructural dornestic conflict since independence: the Refarrn War of l 8 5 8-18 6 l and
developrnent necessary to end econornic stagnation, including railroad the subsequent French Intervention.
developrnent. (Thornson and Angerstein 2000) State building was at the Yet in looking beyond the ideological differences with the conservatives
core of the developrnent project pursued by Chilean political elites. they defeated, we can see that the liberal project continued an ernphasis
As discussed further in Chapter 3, the state-building vision eventually on state building. Liberals saw corporate privilege (of the church, the
expanded to include the territory controlled by the Araucana, across the army, guilds, and Indian cornmunities) asan obstacle to jurídica! unifor-
southern frontier. With the wheat boom of rnid-century, elites believed mity, and thus to liberty. In response, they leveraged state power to dis-
that Araucanía's fertile land and the easier rnountain passes across the mantle these institutions and ernphasized the expansion of central state
Andes to Argentina would allow wheat production far export to spread authority as a means to these ends. Most scholarship has ernphasized the
southward, generating revenue and economic stirnulus if exploited with anti-clerical cornponent of the liberal project, which sparked the most
sufficient labor and capital. This spurred legal changes replacing corpo- intense resistance. But at its core, the liberal project intended to use the
rate land rights with individual property rights. Indigenous refusal to power of the state to create a "class of yeoman farmers in Mexico that
fallow these new legal norrns rnade pacification a pre-condition far devel-
oprnent (Pinto Rodríguez 2003). Por the first time, "progress" becarne 20
Thus, "what began as a traditional barracks revolt ended up as full-scale conflict between
incompatible with indigenous autonorny, and the solution (on which disparate política! ideologies" (Sinkin r979, 34).
50 State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects

would serve as the basis far a stable and farward-looking economy and The State and "Progress" in Peru
polity" (Haber 1989, 19). . ..
The guano export boom starting in the l84os gave Peru's elites an oppor-
Although it took a less confrontational tone in addressmg trad1t10nal
tune context far their developmental priorities. A broad consensus held
structures of power, the Porfuian regime that fallowed also sought to
that social and econornic transfarmation depended on expanding adminis-
build an effective state to overcome the obstacles to econornic develop-
tration and infrastructure. State intervention would overcome obstacles
21

ment. The Porfuiato was the most classically positivist regime among
to econornic development by substituting far the lack of private capital,
our cases, particularly under the influence of the Científicos after 1892,
encouraging imrnigration, and better integrating the indigenous popula-
who believed that economic development required state intervention to
tion into the market economy (Gootenberg 1993, 27ff). Ramón Castilla,
remove the obstacles of "crime, alcoholism, illiteracy, squalor, and dis-
the fust guano-era president, facused on free trade and diversification into
ease" (Knight 1986, 1, 23). The goal was to create "an educated populace,
rnining and agriculture. He emphasized boosting production in the heavily
a democratic polity, anda commonwealth as civilized as those of Europe"
indigenous southern highlands as a way to give local elites an econornic
anda propitious climate far the fareign investment that would bring eco-
incentive to ally with the national government (Larson 2004, 150).
nornic development (Haber 1989, 22). A consensus among elites was
Peruvian elites (especially the Civilistas) saw railroads as fundamen-
that the country needed "more, better, responsible government" (Knight
tal to development and national unification. The most important case
1986, 1, 30).
far railroad building as the means to "progress" appeared in the writ-
As in Peru and Chile, railroads were seen as a central plank of the
ings of Manuel Pardo, who faunded the Civilista party, served as Finance
activity that government should emphasize. lmproved transport was
Minister, and became president in the early l87os. In econornic terms,
22

seen as crucial far promoting econornic development: "the country's elite


Pardo argued that railroads would facilitate exports from the Andes.
viewed transport improvements in general and railroads in particular as
Railroads were also seen as a means to national "moral uplifting" as
the most important pre-requisite to progress" (Coatsworth 1981, 175).
they accelerated "rural mobility, cultural contact, and thus enlightenment
And state action to facilitate their construction was a consistent prior-
among peasants" (Gootenberg 1993, 87). Malinowski, the Polish engi-
ity of the Porfuiato (1876-19rn). Railroad building was perhaps more
neer contracted far much of the railroad construction, claimed that train
concerted in Mexico than in any of our other cases. Construction was a
lines would resolve the fact that "two thirds of the country has yet to
sizable enough effort, according to Coatsworth, to have a visible effect
be made Peruvian" (91). Trains, the Civilistas believed, would help turn
on unemployment and under-employment, and thus promote political
peasants into Peruvians. Railroads would also facilitate troop transport to
stability in an indirect manner (ibid., 43). Because Mexico's economy <lid
the highlands far the suppression of revolts - this argument became more
not center on commodity export, a truly nationwide network was needed
prominent after the Huancané revolt of 1866 (Larson 2004, 157-158). In
to promote development, and during the Porfuiato, construction linked
many ways, then, railroad development was explicitly an effart to increase
all of the country's most important regions to Mexico City, the United
the state's infrastructural power. But the program of social transfarma-
States border, and the port of Veracruz (ibid., 145).
tion spread beyond railroads. For example, in implementing what Larson
Much as in Chile, Mexico saw a group of elites come to power in
(2004, l 59) describes as "the fust state-directed civilizing project in the
rnid-century seeking to strengthen the state as a means to ending instabil-
lndian sierra," the Pardo government of the early l87os sought assimi-
ity, econornic stagnation, and social turmoil. Their state-building effarts
lation of the indigenous population via the spread of schooling into the
bore sorne fruit, and were reinforced during the Porfuiato even as sorne
highland regions and construction of roads linking more remate commu-
of the strikingly anti-clerical content was diluted. Five decades of con-
nities to the railroad.
sistent state-building effarts that emphasized the centralization of civil-
ian political authority and the extension of its control, overshadowing
2
sorne inconsistencies in priorities, marked the late nineteenth century in ' Gootenberg (1993), on which this discussion draws, explores the range of development
projects envisioned in guano-era Peru.
Mexico (Topik 1988, 121). 22
On Pardo's developrnent vision, and his writings more broadly, see McEvoy (1994).
52 State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 53
This first phase of state building was cut short by the fiscal collapse of a new and puriíied white population on which 'true nationhood' could
the mid-187os and the subsequent war with Chile; efforts would resume be built" (Larson 1999, 581). "Development" and "civilization" implied
with the reestablishrnent of arder after l 89 5. The war with Chile and the integrating the indigenous population politically, econornically, and cul-
decade of chaos that followed, which included Chilean occupation, civil turally into the broader society. In econornic terms, elites believed that
war, and a multitude of subaltern uprisings, harnrnered home to elites a Colombia was hampered by its lack of both international trade and a
sense of impending doom and the need for "national renovation" (Hale domestic market (Safford 1988). These positions were largely unques-
1989, 275-276). The result was a strengthening of developmental efforts, tioned by broad segments of the Colombian elite, showing that across
centered on the construction of a more effective state, during the period the board, elites sought the same outcomes of arder and progress as in
known as theAristocratic Republic (1895-1919 ). A nearly universal posi- our other cases.
tion among Peru's elites at this time was that a crucial step toward "arder Where Colombian political thought diverged from the other cases was
and progress" would involve state initiative in the construction of roads in the means it proposed. In the econornic realm, elites espoused the -elim-
and railroads (Quiroz 1988, 52). Not only state-building politicians in ination of state intervention in the domestic economy; this was "virtually
Lima, but regional elites in the southern highlands viewed infrastructure a dogma" across the political spectrurn from the l84os to 1870 (Safford
as crucial for development (Jacobsen 1988, 158). 1988, 36). In addressing political stability too, liberalism was taken to
Tensions between local elites who sought state intervention for market an extreme in a series of policy choices supported by both liberals and
access and state-building officials who hada broader vision of develop- conservatives. The result of three decades of explicit fragmentation of
ment that included education and increased taxation drove conflict dur- national power, by l 8 80, was a strikingly impotent state.
ing the Civilista era. These tensions constrained the success of this second Although factions of the liberal party had particularly doctrinaire
phase of Peruvian state building, as described in detail in Chapters 4 to 6. stances on state intervention, most conservatives "were also econornic lib-
With a gap during the years 1875-1895, when instability precluded any erals from the late l84os through the l87os" (ibid., 58). Upan corning to
initiative on the part of the state, let alone quotidian policy initiatives, power in 1849, the liberal project of freeing individual incentives to allow
the Peruvian política! class for the entire period between 1845 and 1920 market competition began. As described in Chapter 5, perhaps their most
sought the extension of state authority as the means to political stability, important initiative was the near-elirnination of federal taxation. But the
social peace, and econornic development. liberal project also included a transition to federalism that began with
the l 8 5 3 constitution. A constitutional amendrnent allowed Panama to
Colombia's Anti-Statist Consensus be a "self-governing entity" except for policy relating to self-defense and
foreign relations (Bushnell and Macaulay 1994, 216). This led to analo-
As in the other cases, politicians influenced by broadly liberal views gous demands from other provinces, subsequently codiíied in the 1858
sought to transform Colombia after the rnid-nineteenth century. Elites Constitution. The weakening of the federal system quickly spiraled out
shared the views dorninant in the other countries about the problems of control, as Cauca attempted to withdraw from the federation entirely
they faced, seeing ethno-cultural diversity, econornic backwardness, and in 1860.
political instability as deeply connected (Jararnillo Uribe 1964). But After liberal victory in the 1860 Civil War that Cauca's withdrawal
unlike the other three cases, Colombian elites did not see state building attempt triggered, the "heyday" of liberalism began (Park 1985, l). The
as a means to those ends, and this would place this country on a distinct 1863 Constitution was described by Bushnell and Macaulay (1994,
state-building trajectory. 217) as "in every respect ... the most advanced form of liberalism that any
The late l83os War of the Supremes (which saw both subaltern mobi- Latín American nation achieved (or was afflicted with) in the [nineteenth]
lization and foreign incursion) highlighted for elites across the ideolog- century." As Chapter 6 explores in detail, this constitution allowed each
ical spectrurn the harm done by political instability (Safford 1991, 29; state to control its own rnilitary, which fundamentally underrnined the
Earle 2000). In response, "Liberal and Conservative elites were united national state's monopoly of force. An 1867 ruling forced the national
in a cornrnon concern: how to create out of ethnic and cultural diversity governrnent to remain neutral in case of civil war within a state. This left
54 State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 55

the national government "virtually powerless" when state governrnents and church as promoters of development, alongside the state, reveals the
were threatened by rebellion (Delpar 1981, 13). laissez-faire emphasis that continued to domínate the Colombian politi-
Under the 1863 Constitution, Colombia's states had an "existence cal sphere.
independent of the nation," holding all powers not specifically delegated Concerted state action was still absent. In the realm of transport, for
to the national governrnent. Individual states operated independently example, Núnez believed that construction simply required the creation
in the international realm, signing treaties and exchanging diplomatic of an attractive investment dimate (Bergquist 1986, 222). One conserva-
representatives (Park 198 5, 43-44). The national governrnent oversaw tive president revealed the lirnited ambitions of the state by dairning that
nothing more than foreign relations, national defense and trade policy, improved river transport "was in the hands of the heavenly powers" (cited
the regulation of weights and measures, and coinage. It shared responsi- in Posada-Carbó 1996, 157-158). Another, speaking even more broadly
bility with state governrnents for the postal system and public education about the lirnited ambitions of the governrnent, stated that he "should
(Delpar 1981, 12). Beyond these basic functions, all power was delegated not be judged for the new bricks that [he] laid, but fonhe tremendous
to the states. ruins that [he] avoided" (cited in Bushnell 1993, 164). This quote shows
Many perceived a pervasive weakening of national feeling and a sense that the state continued to be seen primarily as an obstacle to develop-
that national ties were fragile. Talk of "national dismemberment" became ment even as its positive role became evident, and even during nearly five
common (Park 1985, 71-72). A conservative newspaper in 1870 wrote decades of conservative rule. As Bushnell (1993, 160) writes, the state's
that "the idea of national unity has been almost totally lost," and the activity under Núñez was "impressive only by Colombian standards."
fear of secession was endemic (ibid., 72-73). A brief and reluctant shift Although the conservatives won the vast majority of elections between
to re-centralization in the early l87os was prompted by this sense that 1886 and 1930, they carne to comprornise with their liberal opponents.
national collapse loomed. But after the 1876-1877 civil war, laissez-faire The decay of the intra-elite violence of the War of l,ooo Days into
saw a resurgence. As described earlier, transportation spending was dass-based guerrilla warfare taught elites on both sides that stable gov-
once again removed from the purview of the national governrnent and ernrnent could not emerge without the incorporation into policy the pref-
decentralized to the states. The central governrnent's power became even erences of the losers (Bergquist 1986, 248; Safford and Palacios 2002,
weaker in the first half of the l 8 Sos. Miguel Samper, a prorninent liberal, 266). Liberals carne to believe that "sorne strengthening of central author-
wrote in l 8 8 l that Colombia resembled medieval Europe, with its states ity ... had in fact been necessary." (Bushnell 1993, 162) Conservatives,
akin to feudal fiefdoms (Delpar 1981, 85). The situation was described in turn, were amenable to a broadly liberal political economy because
as "organized anarchy" and observers commented that "national unity they had strikingly little interest in an activist state outside the realm
[did] not exist, except in name" (Park 1985, 207). of public works. Although the post-Regeneration Colombian state was
Although rhetoric changed a bit with the Regeneration (1886-1899), not completely absent as it had been at the height of liberal control, it
the fundamental anti-statism of Colombian development remained. played little role in promoting development beyond sorne lirnited efforts
Rafael Núñez, the driving force behind this centralizing reaction, believed to reduce transport costs. The consensus on "liberal political ideology,
that Colombia needed a process of national consolidation. In a state- social conservatism, and pro-export econornic policy" was far from an
ment that reveals his quasi-positivist conception of development, Núñez aggressive state-building agenda (Bergquist 1986, 261). The hegemony
described the key to arder as "scientific peace." The 1886 constitution, of anti-statist views in Colombia befare 193º underlay the lack of a con-
written in the aftermath of civil war by the victorious conservatives, certed state-building project during the first century after independence,
was built on the belief that strong institutions (farnily, church, and state) and differentiates it from the other three cases.
"were needed to control roen susceptible to evil passions and anti-social
behavior" (Bergquist 1986, 16). One prorninent means of control was
CONCLUSION
the dause in the 1886 Constitution that (for the first time!) gave the
national governrnent a monopoly on the importation, manufacture, and Ideas about the role of the state in development (the content of the liberal
possession of munitions (Park 1985, 265). But the emphasis on farnily consensus - laissez-faire or developmentalist) influenced the comrnitment
State Building in Latín America The Emergence of State-Building Projects 57

of state leaders to extend its authority. Arguments for the causal role of TABLE I.3. Urban primacy in each case
ideas, however, face two analytic challenges. One relates to the question
Chile Colombia Mexico Peru
of whether there are causal forces underlying the ideas that make the lat- 1865 1851 1850
ter epiphenomenal - are ideas an intervening or independent variable?
The second relates to the possibility that alternative factors actually cre- Largest city Santiago Bogotá Ciudad de México Lima
115,400 43,000 170,000 100,100
are the outcome that I have attributed to ideas - is there an omitted var- 2nd largest city Valparaíso Popayán Guadalaj ara Callao
iable lurking? 70,400 20,000 90,000 34,500
In dealing with the first challenge, I have argued in this chapter that 3rd largest city Talca Socorro Puebla Huaraz
ideas about the place of the state in development were shaped by urban 17,900 20,000 64,600 17,000
primacy. Where a single center was absent, as in the Colombian case, 4th largest city Concepción Medellín Guanajuato C. de Paseo
interventionist state building did not seem to respond to the particular 14,000 14,000 49,000 13,000
National l,819,200 2,223,800 7,485,200 2,469,000
problems the country faced in the same way as it did in the other cases. 2 3 population
But what is the relationship between ideas (laissez-faire liberalism) and Primacy score 0.53 0.44 0.45 0.60
structure (polycentric urbanism) in Colombia, or in the other cases? Are
these alternative explanations for the onset of state-building projects?
I argue that this is not the case, since they operare together to explain regions, but ideas shape the emergence of state-building projects. Thus,
why state-building efforts emerged in sorne countries but not in others. ideas do play an independent causal role in this framework, although
My claim, following the theoretical work of Sheri Berman and others, is their salience cannot be understood without reference to geography.
that post-independence Latín Arnerica was a context where old ideolo- The second challenge relates to the relationship between ideas and
gies were "slowly delegitimized" by the chaos engendered in the after- interests; it proposes interest-based arguments as an alternative explana-
math of independence (Berman 200I, 234; Gootenberg I988, 80-84). tion. A more rationalist and perhaps more parsimonious account would
In this common regional context where what Berman describes as a link geography to state-development projects through an account of
demand for ideas had emerged, "local política! contexts" (II) determine regional interests rather than through ideas. Indeed, my earlier account
the ideas that take hold in a given case. Laissez-faire ideas took hold in incorporares interests in identifying the divergence of public good pref-
Colombia (while more interventionist ones took hold in the other cases) erences over regions, and the self-suf:ficiency of regional economies as
because they fit with the distinct política! and economic context shaped the crucial consequences of the absence of urban primacy in Colombia.
by spatial factors. In a polycentric context where regional tensions over We might be concerned, then, that the account provided here could be
public good provision caused further strife, a laissez-faire liberal proj- reduced to a purely material one.
ect seemed more plausible than the interventionist one that took hold I want to suggest, however, two reasons why the role of ideas can-
elsewhere. not be removed from the account of the origins of state-building proj-
A skeptic of ideational accounts might suggest that urban primacy ects. First, as discussed previously, laissez-faire and statist liberals shared
was the underlying cause and the content of liberalism at best the mech- common goals - ali sought to generare política! stability via economic
anism linking it to state building projects. But my argument is not that development and social peace. Were they to differ on ends, we might
urban primacy explains which ideas emerged into the public sphere, or be able to identify certain interests that were being served - this can be
that laissez-faire ideas in Colombia were a direct reflection of regional seen, for example, in the concurrent debate between free trade and pro-
interests. Instead, I claim that polycentric urbanism and the presence of tectionism in Latin Arnerica, which pitted sectoral and (in sorne coun-
salient regions helps to account for which ideas took hold among a broad tries) regional interests against one another (Gootenberg 1989 ). In the
segment of political elites, including actors both in the capital and in the context of política! development, however, the advocates of laissez-faire
and statism did not align with particular sectoral or regional interests
,J I draw the language ofideas "responding to particular problems" from Berman (2001, 23 6). (Hale I989; Bushnell and Macalay I994l· Instead, the debates among
State Building in Latín America

politicians and intellectuals were theoretical debates about the optimal 2


role of the state. Second, and more centrally, the development projects
and the political coalitions behind them that dorninated each of these
countries for decades at a time had a core ideological component that A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure
gave them coherence and legitimacy, and their "fantastic staying power"
(Gootenberg r988, 83 ). Liberal politicians appealed to potential allies
and to voters not on the basis of specific interests and policy proposals,
but on the basis of broad ideological visions. Ideas about arder, prog-
ress, and development explain how a broad spectrum of political interests
could coalesce around development projects; thus ideational factors are a
central component of the emergence of state-building projects.

Regional evidence presented in the Introduction showed that a wide


gap in state capacity between Latin American countries was present by
r900. The fust part of an explanation for that variation, presented in
Chapter r, was a theory of the emergence of state-building efforts. The
second part appears in this chapter, where 1 develop an account of the
success and failure of state~building projects. My argument, evaluated in
an exarnination of successful (Chile and Mexico), failed {pre-r895 Peru)
and intermediate {post-r89 5 Peru) cases in Chapters 4 to 6, centers on the
public adrninistration of state-building efforts. 1 argue that state-building
efforts failed where local elites were tasked with adrninistering them in
the national periphery, but saw more success where local administrators
were outsiders in the communities in which they served.
1 describe my account of success and failure as centering on the
public-adrninistration of state-building efforts because 1 argue that the
deterrninants of state-building outcomes are found within the state,
rather than in the resistan.ce from societal actors. 1 Most scholarship on
state building ignores the inner workings of the state and focuses on the
relationship between state and society. One view takes state-building
projects as serving the interests of segments of society, usually dorni-
nant sectors {Kurtz 2or3; Spruyt r994). A second view, tracing back
to Charles Tilly's (r985) broad conception of "negotiation" as struggle

1
Matthias vom Hau, in a series of contributions, has placed a similar emphasis on the
intrastate determinants of state-building success and failure, with a focus on educational
change and the transformation of nationalism. See vom Hau (2008, 2009) and Abbott
et al. (2013).

59
60 State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 6r

between state and society over state control and getting new vigor in the those filled with outsiders deployed into the community. I discuss the
work of Joel Migdal (1988) and James Scott (1998, 2009), presumes relationship between this and broader categories of administration such
that state building is imposition on a recalcitrant society. The first view, as direct and indirect rule, and develop two causal mechanisms linking
which facuses on which social groups have their interests represented deployment to more successful implementation of state-building projects.
in state-building projects, tends to facus on the priorities of state lead- The second part of the chapter turns to coding the three cases on this
ers and takes far granted the success of their undertakings. The second, independent variable -.the type of administrative appointment that pre-
by contrast, is more relevant far our purposes, since resistance to the dominated in each. I also discuss evidence about bureaucratic profession-
imposition of state-building efforts might explain their failure. But, as alism, administrative oversight, and the use of customary law, showing
Chapter 4 on education shows most clearly, many aspects of state build- no variation across cases in these aspects of their state administrations.
ing are welcomed, rather than resisted by societal actors (Slater 2008). I postpone a discussion of the origins of this institutional difference far
While the role of societal resistance in undermining state-development the next chapter, where I also begin addressing possible alternative expla-
efforts may be important, scholarly accounts of the constraints on state nations far variation in state capacity. There I show that it cannot be
building ignore dynamics internal to the state. Often, state-building attributed to preexisting variation in state capacity, and thus rule out the
efforts are supported, by broad sectors of society, but face resistance possibility of reverse causation.
from within the state. This issue has been little explored by existing
scholarship.
ADMINISTRATIVE INSTITUTIONS AND THE OUTCOMES OF
This chapter addresses this gap by developing a theory of the condi-
STATE-BUILDING EFFORTS
tions under which local bureaucrats will act more or less effectively to
implement state-building endeavors. There are several types of features of States are composed of networks of administration that extend over ter-
bureaucratic agencies that might determine the compliance and effective- ritory and penetrare society, reaching from the central bureaucracy into
ness of their rank and file. One is the professionalism, skill, or training communities where the state seeks control. Particularly where technolo-
of the bureaucrats - what we might call bureaucratic quality. A second gies of communication, transportation, and administration are of poor
set of features is the extent of oversight by central state agencies through quality, the national leadership must rely on representatives of sorne
overlapping networks of control or other characteristics of institutional sort to carry out administrative functions throughout the national terri-
design. A third, commonly cited by scholars of colonialism, relates to tory (Waldner 1999, 21ff). The central bureaucracy cannot eliminate the
the extent of reliance on customary law at the local level within state autonomy of those representatives, which derives from their discretion in
institutions. the execution of their work, and from the logistical challenges to over-
Finding no variation across my cases in these three elements of state sight by central bureaucrats who are their nominal superiors (Hechter
bureaucracies, I facus instead on a different characteristic. In explaining 2000, 27). This autonomy becomes important when local officials have
variation in the success and failure of state-building efforts, I investigate interests that diverge from those of their superiors.
the interests and incentives of these local bureaucrats themselves. I argue The uneven implementation of state policies (including state-building
that variation in the relationship between bureaucrats and the commu- efforts) is shaped by the incentives of local administrators (Lipsky 1980;
nities in which they serve determines the variation in the benefits they Callaghy 1984). Where they can be induced to collaborate with their
perceive from state building, and therefare their inclination to enforce superiors in increasing the state's power in their bailiwicks, state-building
it and to pursue it in their appointed roles as state agents. I argue that efforts will succeed. But where the interests of local officials are not
this variation explains the success and failure of state-building efforts in served by state-building effarts, they undermine or subvert these projects
Mexico, Peru (distinguishing between two historical periods with differ- in their implementation. Here, state building, even with a commitment
2

ent outcomes), and Chile.


The first part of this chapter develops a distinction between two types ' Kaufman (1967) shows that bureaucracies can shape the interests (not just the institu-
of administrative appointments - those delegated to local elites, and tional incentives) of their agents th10ugh recruitment, training, and other mechanisms.
State Building in Latín America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

from national leaders, is likely to fail. This was the factor that separated deployed rule. These mechanisms do not rely on the extent of formal
Peru from Mexico and Chile during the nineteenth century. It does not, hierarchy, qualifications (whether educational or otherwise), the esprit
however, account for state weakness in Colombia, where (for reasons de corps, or other aspects of bureaucratic professionalization discussed
explained in Chapter r) a state-building project never emerged. later. Nor do they rely on the power of customary law in the hands of
State adrninistration was similar in many ways in Chile, Mexico, and local elites, or the oversight capacity of the central state.3 1 show later
Peru: all saw the use of prefectoralism in their appointment of authori- that these are similar across country cases, and the causal logic 1 describe
ties to oversee all governrnent activities in a given region. And all three assurnes that all these are held constant across deployed and delegated
cases exercised a great deal of de jure centralization, which can be seen in rule. Instead, these mechanisms work through the relationship between
the fact that local officials were regularly required to obtain perrnission bureaucrats and the cornrnunities in which they serve, and derive from
from national agencies for a wide variety of actions (Hutchcroft 2000, the individual incentives of the bureaucrats, which diverge depending
280). But administration in these cases, while similar in these and other on whether or not the bureaucrat is a prorninent member of the local
ways, was characterized by a crucial difference: variation in the iden- cornrnunity.
tity of administrators populating the national bureaucracy. As Hechter
(2000, 27) writes, the state's agents "can be recruited from two quite Income and the Dynamics of Collaboration
different sources. Sometirnes the ruler selects a culturally alien agent .... The first mechanism that ties the collaboration of local state agents to
At other times the traditional authority in the territory is selected as the the effective implementation of state-building efforts derives from their
central state's representative." Where the state relies (as in Hechter's first income. When state agents are deployed to cornrnunities from outside,
category) on local elites to adrninister in their territories, 1 label adrnin- they genera te much of their income from access to their position. 4 These
istration as delegated rule. These elites, including indigenous cornrnunity officials are therefore vulnerable to sanction by the national govern-
leaders but most often large landowners, ha ve a degree of private power ment: should performance be lacking, the central governrnent can remove
in their cornrnunities. Alternatively, the state might fill its ranks with them from their post, depriving them of an important component of their
bureaucrats deployed from outside the cornrnunity; Hechter's second income. This provides the central governrnent with a certain degree of
category of "culturally alien agents." 1 call this model of adrninistration control over local officials.5 We should therefore expect that deployed
deployed rule and refer in the discussion that follows to "outsiders" or bureaucrats will be more likely to comply with edicts received from the
"deployed officials." Hechter does not discuss whether this difference in national governrnent. State-building initiatives, like any other edict sent
the relationship between administrators and the local cornrnunity can
shape their cornrnitment to state development. 1 argue that the distinction
J I assume here rhat rhe oversighr capaciry of rhe central state is invariant under deployed
between deployed and delegated rule has fundamental implications for and delegated rule. As discussed later, rhis assumption is reasonable in rhe cases under
the fate of state-building projects, and identify two chains of causal logic study, because ali cases were characterized by overlapping networks of oversighr within
underpinning that clairn. the bureaucracy, and because high-level bureaucrats (regional prefects) were always
appointed from ourside rhe communiry, meaning rhat ar least sorne elemeot of rhe bureau-
cracy operated ourside local power networks.
4 This income may come in rhe form of salary, or in rhe forrn of a share of revenues gener-
Causal Mechanisms
ated by rhe local goverornent. Both forrns of incorne were common in nineteenth-century
My key claim in this chapter is that this fairly subtle distinction between Latín America. On rhe importance of rhe Latín American srate as a source of incorne, see
Veliz (1980).
types of adrninistrative institutions turns out to be crucial in underpin- s As discussed later, the lower rungs of territorial administration in borh Chile and Peru
ning the success and failure of state-building projects. Two mechanisms were unsalaried positions seen as civic dury. This mechanism, rhen, would not apply to
make state-building efforts less effective under delegated rule than under holders of those offices. Neverrheless, rhe effecrs of rhe incorne mechanisrns should be seen
rhrough rhe actions of holders of offices in functional arms of rhe administration; rhese
salaried actors play a rnajor role in rhe state-building projecrs observed in Chapters 4
But I find no evidence that administrative organs in nineteenth-century Latín America through 6. And the local power mechanisrn discussed later should apply ro borh salaried
were able to exercise similar levels of control over their raok and file. and unsalaried officials.
State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

out from the capital, will be pursued more reliably by local bureaucrats authority, to pursue the increased penetration of the state into their com-
under deployed rule. munities. This increased penetration can serve to upgrade coercive power,
In a system of delegated rule, positions in the local bureaucracy are to provide the public goods that win support from the community, or (in
given to local elites. In this context, even as they receive a government a longer-run manifestation of this mechanism) to shape identities and
salary or access to profits from their office, officials continue to be able to communities in ways that make them easier to control. In ali these ways,
generate much of their income from non-salary means such as landhold- the increased infrastructural power of the state has benefits that accrue
ing. These externa! sources of income make these officials less vulner- to deployed bureaucrats much more than to their delegated counterparts.
able to the sanctions of the national government. The fact that they have The independent interest of local officials in increased state infrastruc-
access to externa! sources of income makes them less likely, ali else equal, tural power can lead them to champion its development by seeking to
to comply with the edicts of the national government by implementing maxirnize the implementation of policies handed clown from their superi-
the policies chosen by the central bureaucracy. 6 ors, and even by undertaking independent initiatives to press the central
government for a greater emphasis on state building. Because both of
Legitimacy, Local Power, and Shared Interests these types of actions can be quite costly - whether due to conflict with
In addition to the income mechanism, the other difference between social actors in the former instance, or with superiors and central offices
deployed and delegated rule derives from the relationships between in the latter - state officials will not undertake them unless they see an
officials and the communities in which they serve. In their interactions advantage to doing so. Thus, I argue that where deployed rule has been
with their communities, local bureaucrats must draw on various sorts instituted, local officials will go beyond compliance with central efforts at
of authority to achieve their goals. Ali have access to a certain degree of state building to prodding the central state to increase its effective pres-
legal/rational authority from the very possession of their titles, but given ence in their communities. Under delegated rule, state agents are indif-
that this is true of ali officials, I set it aside for the purposes of this discus- ferent, and even hostile, to state-building initiatives undertaken by the
sion. Other sources of authority can be status-based (deriving from their central state.7
standing vis-a-vis the community) or positional (deriving from their posi-
tion as state officials). Status-based authority derives from the prestige
Scoring Cases on the Forms of Rule
accorded to important members of the community, and from the prívate
sources of power available to local elites. Positional authority derives Assessing the type of adrninistrative appointments that characterize a
most importantly from the fact that state officials' orders can be backed particular country's adrninistration is complex, since these types of broad
up with the power of the central state. patterns emerge from the aggregation of a myriad of individual appoint-
When a bureaucrat cannot rely on status-based authority, he has no ment decisions taken by executives and rninisters, rather than from the
option but to invest in building positional authority as he seeks to gener- product of a single explicit institutional choice. This has two implica-
ate compliance from local society. Therefore, he will have more indepen- tions for how cases can be coded. First, because state leaders rarely make
dent interest in increasing the state's rational-legal or coercive authority in any explicit statement about patterns of appointment, they must instead
the community where he serves, and in heightening the profile of the state be imputed from the aggregation of individual appointment decisions.
in the local community. This creates an incentive for outsiders, absent Second, it means that the patterns are probabilistic rather than deterrnin-
for their delegated counterparts who have more access to status-based istic: what we observe are tendencies rather than absolute rules. Thus, the

6
It should be noted that this incorne rnechanisrn <loes not only apply to state-building 7
Unlike the incorne rnechanisrn described earlier, I do not expect the authority rnechanisrn
efforts: the observable irnplication of the argurnent I put forward is that ali types of poli- to be relevant to other kinds of policy: it is lirnited to those policies that increase the
cies instituted by the national governrnent will see greater irnplernentation at the local positional authority of local officials, those that increase the state's presence in their corn-
leve! by bureaucrats who depend on the national governrnent far their incorne. Under rnunities. Far a similar argurnent to mine that traces how local elites appointed to local
deployed rule, I predict less adrninistrative slippage between policy choice and irnplernen- política! and adrninistrative posts underrnined state-building efforts under U.S. colonial
tation of ali types of policy than under delegated rule. rule in the Philippines, see Hutchcroft (2000).
66 State Building in Latín America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

claim that a state leadership practices deployed rule does not imply that the appointment must have involved deployment. First, sorne decrees list the
each and every appointment we examine must go to an outsider, nor does appointee's previous post in a different region of the country. Second, sorne
a coding of delegated rule imply that outsiders are completely absent. decrees order that the relevant agency pay the costs of the appointee as he
Instead, the comparison is of broad patterns of appointments in a case. or she relocates across regions to take up a posting. Logically, each of these
In assessing the bureaucratic model in place in each case, 1 draw on a pieces of information signals deployed rule, since the appointee must have
variety of types of evidence. Most centrally, far Chile and Peru, 1 rely on been an outsider either in the previous posting or in the new assignment.
evidence drawn from appointrnent decrees issued by the central government Third, sorne decrees explicitly state that the position was vacant because the
and printed in its official publication of record. 1 also draw on an analysis of previous occupant was transferred to a different region, meaning that the
several thousand entries in dictionaries of political biography from all three previous occupant must have been deployed. Any decree that contains one
countries, as well as evidence gathered from both primary and secondary or more of these pieces of information is therefare coded as clearly deployed.
sources about individuals, particular agencies, and particular regions. Coding was based on the largest subnational unit (department
in Peru; province in Chile) in each country. This lowers the rate of
Decree Analysis appointments coded as deployed, since any move within a subnational
Methods: Far the cases of Peru (both befare and after l 89 5) and Chile, unit (far example, from one district to another in a given Chilean prov-
I draw on the analysis of hundreds of appointrnent decrees to exam- ince or Peruvian department) is not coded as "clearly deployed." Thus,
ine the rates of reliance on deployed outsiders to fill bureaucratic posts even though the appointee may be an outsider in the local community
throughout the national territory. These decrees are issued by agency to which they are sent, 1 do not consider this clear evidence of deploy-
heads, approved by the national executive, and published in each coun- ment unless the appointment crosses the boundaries of the largest sub-
try's official government newspaper of record - El Peruano in Peru national unit. This coding rule is designed to underestimate the rate
and El Araucano, which became Diario Oficial after 1876 in Chile. of reliance on outsiders across ali cases, and thus to bias against the
Unfartunately, an analogous source far Mexico does not exist and far cross-case variation 1 predict.
that case we have to rely principally on the other, less direct, farms of evi- The analysis of decrees cannot provide information about the abso-
dence described later. 1 drew a random sample of years and analyzed each lute rates of reliance on delegated and deployed rule, since the "clearly
decree of appointment involving a bureaucratic posting. 8 Only two kinds deployed" cases represent nothing more than a logical mínimum of the
of posts were excluded: the appointments of prefects (the highest ranking overall instances of deployment. This is so because the vast majority of
officials in the periphery) who were nearly always active-duty military decrees provide no clear information far coding the type of adrninistrative
officers, and those located within the capital city, since many of these appointment. Many provide only the name of the appointee and no other
posts were within the adrninistrative headquarters rather than represent- information that allows us to determine whether or not the appointment
ing what Joel Migdal (2001) called the "local face" of the state. Thus, the was an instance of deployed rule. The percentage of all appointments
dataset is limited to bureaucrats who were appointees in positions that that fall in the "clearly deployed" category as a share of all appointments
had a direct role in implementing state policies at the local level. must understate the extent of overall reliance on deployed rule, and we
1 proceed as fallows to code an appointrnent as an instance of dele- can't tell by how much it does so, since we cannot assume that decrees
gated or deployed rule: each decree is examined far three pieces of infor- without information are a random sample of all decrees. We cannot, then,
mation, of which the presence of any one is sufficient far concluding that use the appointment decrees to calculare a figure far the share of all post-
ings filled via deployed rule in a given case. Nor can we compare the rate
8
The analysis of Peru used El Peruano for I845, I855, I873, I908 Oanuary, February, of clearly deployed appointments to the rate of appointrnents that are
November, and December), and I9I2 Oanuary-May). The Chilean analysis relies on El clearly delegated: although sorne decrees do state that the appointee is a
Araucano from I846-I849, I856-I857, I862-I863, and I869-I870, and the Diario native of the community in which he or she is appointed, these instances
Oficial for I877. These years were randomly selected from among available years or rolls
of microfilm; for the date ranges indicated, I reviewed each issue of the publication, and occur only rarely (fewer than ten times out of the hundreds of decrees
included every decree that contained enough information to be coded. analyzed in each country case).
68 State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

But we can draw comparisons across cases about the frequency of TABLE 2.r. Clearly deployed appointments in Peru, r845-r895
"clearly deployed" bureaucratic appointments, which can be used to Arena Deployed Total % Deployed
assess the relative importance of deployed rule. This inference can be
made so long as we believe that there is no difference across cases in Education 9 79 II.4
Customs and other fiscal I 3r 3.2
the propensity of decrees to contain information about appointees and
Courts II 93 rr.8
that the selection mechanism (the deterrninants of which decrees con- Roads/public works/engineering 6 20 30
tain information about place of birth or location of previous office held) Police/national guard o r8 o
is similar across cases. An exarnination of the publications, and of the Subprefects, assistant prefects, and 3 r68 r.8
decrees, suggests that this is not a concern. The publications provide simi- regional official staff
lar information about the day-to-day adrninistration of various rninis- Mail I 34 2.9
OVERALL TOTAL (includes other 36 47I 7.6
tries, including appointment decrees, regulations, and statistics. There is appointments)
no variation across countries or across time.
By comparing the relative prevalence of "clearly deployed" rule across
cases, we can therefore draw conclusions about the relative prevalence
of deployed rule in general. This, along with the other forms of evidence Tables 2.1-2.3 break clown the country-level data by sectors of state
about farms of rule that follow, lets us code cases in a transparent manner. activity. Table 2.1 provides data on appointments in pre-1895 Peru. lt
This coding, once again, is based not on an absolute figure of the extent of shows that clearly deployed appointments fell largely into two cate-
reliance on deployed or delegated rule, but on a comparison across cases of gories: education (where lI.4 percent of appointments were clearly
the proportion of all appointments that can clearly be coded as instances deployed) and courts (n.8 percent). Notably, even these rates, sorne of
of deployed rule. Peru's highest, are below the average in Chile. Nearly all other instances of
Findings: The findings of this analysis are that clearly deployed clearly deployed rule in Peru were appointments to inspect roads, public
appointments are more than twice as cornmon in Chile as in Peru befare works, and other engineering projects. The decrees themselves make clear
189 5. While the rate of clearly deployed appointments doubles in post- that many of these were short-term rnissions to carry out a particular task
war Peru, it still remains somewhat below the Chilean rate. Of the 750 on behalf of the national government (such as inspecting the construction
bureaucratic appointments exarnined in Chile, 19.5 percent were clearly on a particular bridge) rather than term or career appointments. With the
filled via deployment, while in Peru befare l 89 5, only 7. 6 percent of the exception of sorne limited service in schools and courts, then, the state
471 appointments studied were filled in this manner. After 189 5, the rate appears to ha ve relied on outsider appointments only quite infrequently.
of clear deployment in Peru doubled to 16.3 percent of the 766 appoint- Table 2.2 provides data on post-1895 Peru. It shows that while sorne
ments identified in decrees. As discussed previously, we cannot conclude facets of the bureaucracy saw real changes in appointment patterns, little
anything about the absolute rate of deployed rule in any of these cases. change took place in others. The table shows that positions among the
But by assurning that the "clearly deployed" rate is an undercounting of ranks of jefes at the provincial or departmental level (43.9 percent), and
the overall rate of deployment in a consistent way across cases, we can in the education (18.1 percent) and coercive (20.2 percent) apparati, were
observe that local and regional bureaucratic appointments in Chile were most likely to be filled through deployment, while deployment was non-
2. 5 times more likely to go to an outsider than they were in prewar Peru. existent in the courts, and rare (8.1 percent) among territorial appointees
This strongly suggests that Chile relied more heavily on deployed rule, like governors, subprefects, and their staff.
while adrninistration in prewar Peru relied more heavily on delegation to This variation across state agencies is important, and will be discussed
locals. That the rate of appointments that clearly went to outsiders more in more detail later, since it sheds light on the politics of adrninistrative
than doubled after 1895 in Peru strongly suggests a shift to greater reli- refarm and patterns of state-building success after l 89 5. First, it shows
ance on deployed rule in Peru that distinguishes the Aristocratic Republic an attempt by the state to layer new institutions dominated by deployed
from earlier periods in Peruvian state development. rule (the jefes) over existing ones (the governors and subprefects) that were
70 State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 71

TABLE 2.2. Clearly deployed appointments in Peru, post-r895 Evidence from Política! Biographies
Arena Deployed Total % Deployed Methods: As a cornplernent to the analysis of individual appointrnent
decrees, and in particular to allow the coding of the Mexican case, far which
Education 70 387 I8.I appointrnent decrees were not available, I also examine evidence frorn an
Customs and other fiscal 9 56 I6.I
Courts o o
analysis of the patterns of appointrnents in the careers of all individuals
37
Roads/public works/engineering 3 I7 I7.6 included in the rnost prominent diccionaries of policical biography far each
Police/gendarmes/guardia civil I7 84 20.2 country.9 For each country's biographical diccionary, I reviewed every entry
Public health 2 I3 I5.4 far mentions of a bureaucratic appointrnent outside the nacional capital. 1 º
Jefes de provincia/dept I8 4I 43.9 I then cornpared the locacion of the administrative posicion to the place of
Subprefects, assistant prefects, and 6 74 8.I
birth and/or schooling far the individual. rr Where the appointrnent was in
regional official staff
OVERALL TOTAL (includes other !25 766 the sarne subnational political unit (province, departrnent, or state) as the
appointments) place of birth or schooling, I coded the posicion as an instance of delegacion.
Otherwise, it was coded as an instance of deployed rule. 12 As in the decree
coding earlier, coding was based on the largest subnational unit in each ·
TABLE 2+ Clearly deployed appointments in Chile country, thus lowering the prevalence of deployed rule across the board. 1 3
Arena Deployed Total % Deployed
These sources were chosen because they represent the most systematic
scholarly effort in each case to collect biographical information about
Education 64 478 I3.4 government officials. Despite sorne differences, all three center on promi-
Customs and other fiscal 40 87 46.0
nent individuals who served the state. Camp ( l 99 l) is most explicit about
Courts 26 r40 !8.6
Roads/public works/engineering 2 4 50
9 The sources for this analysis were Camp (r99r) for Mexico, Milla Barres (r994) for
Police/national guard 8 8 IOO
Peru, and de Ramón (r999) for Chile.
Public health o I o 'º I include Mexican appointroents between r855 and r9ro, Peruvian appointroents
Governors, subprefects, and regional 2 I4 r4.3 between r845 and r920, and Chilean appointroents from befare r9ro.
office staff " Records without place of birth or education were dropped from the analysis.
Mail and telegraph 7 I8 '" The use of place of education along with birthplace to define someone's place of origin
OVERALL TOTAL (includes other !46 75° also leads to an underestimation of deployed rule. This is true because, especially in the
appointments) early post-independence period, secondary schools only existed in a small number of
regional centers. As a result, I have coded as "delegated" appointroents that fall within
either the province of birth or the province of education, which ioflates the count of del-
egated appointroents. This especially affects coding in Chile, where (for example) nearly
firmly in the hands of local elites. Second, as discussed further in Chapters 4 twenty appointroents of teachers to the Liceo in Concepción were coded as delegated
through 6, the patterns in the decrees reveal a willingness to challenge sorne because appoiotees were educated at that institution - one of the few liceos in the entire
aspects of elite interests (in the realrn of educacion, far exarnple) but not southem half of the country - even though they were boro and received primary school
education in locations spread across the southem third of the country.
their core interests irnplicated in the revenue realrn.
'3 A few additional caveats about this analysis are also in arder. First, I exclude (as in the
Table 2.3 shows the pattem of appointments in Chile. Here, the irnpor- analysis of decrees) ali positions in the top rung of the bureaucracy (prefects in Chile
tance of deployed rule is especially clear. The custorns agency(4 5.9 percent), and Peru, and governors in Mexico) since in all three cases these appointroents were
policing ( rno percent - but an N of only eight appointments) and telegraph commonly filled by deploying former or active-duty military officers. Second, I once
again exclude all positions in the capital city and its province or departroent, since my
and rnail agencies (38.9 percent) saw high rates of deployed rule, while the interest is in how the design of the administrative apparatus affected the reach of the
rate was sornewhat lower in the judicial (18.6 percent) and educacional state into the national periphery. Third, I exclude all Chilean appointroents befare r885
(13.4 percent) realrns. Even these last two, realrns in which deployed rule in the region seized frorn Peru and Bolivia in the War of the Pacific, and all appointrnents
in Peru between r879 and r885, since anomalous factors may drive appointrnents by
was less cornrnon in Chile, saw it used far more than in the highest-scoring occupying forces. Fourth, I only include adrninistrative positions, excluding all elected
realrn of the pre-189 5 Peruvian administration. positions.
72 State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 73

the criteria far inclusion, writing that his choices were based on "posi- TABLE 2.4. Patterns of bureaucratic appointment based on biographical
tional and reputational criteria and on the completeness and accuracy of entries
information available" (xvii). In positional terms, individuals included Delegated % of total Deployed % of total Deployed %
had to hold a sufficiently high-ranking of:fice in the executive, legislative, from decree
or judicial branch of government, or in the military or civil service, or to analysis*
have been a major figure in one of Mexico's política! parties. After com- Chile 280 55.8% 222 44.2% r9.5%
piling a list of sorne two thousand people who fit these criteria between Mexico 44 56.4% 34 43.6%
r884 and r934, Camp dropped all individuals far whom information Peru pre-r89 5 36 66.7% r8 33-3% 7.6%
was lacking on three or more of his data categories. The approximately Peru post-r89 5 r5 50% r5 50% r6.3%
seven hundred individuals who remained comprise the full dataset he * Drawn from Tables 2.r-2+
presents; he suggests that the results meet his goal of "portraying collec-
tively" the leaders of Mexico's fundamental institutions (xviii).
De Ramón (r999) takes a similar approach to the case of Chile, seek- relied heavily on genealogical records to compile biographical informa-
ing to include ali individuals who held high-ranking posts in the three tion, the figures included in the dictionaries tended to be descendants of
branches of government between r875 and r973. The source used far prominent families rather than typical bureaucrats. One indication of this
Peru, Milla Batres (r994), takes a slightly different approach. Rather oversampling of elites can be seen in comparing the types of of:ficial posi-
than a dictionary of political biography, this is instead a historical dictio- tions mentioned in the biographical entries with those in the appointrnent
nary. lt includes both prominent individuals who never held government decrees. The most common bureaucratic of:fices mentioned in dictionary
of:fice (including writers, artists, and various socially prominent figures) entries were governor, subprefect, and (far Mexico) jefe político, while
as well as important events and other aspects of Peruvian historf. The the analysis of all appointrnent decrees discussed earlier contained more
goal, as stated in the introduction, is to paint a portrait of the construc- appointrnents of lower-status bureaucrats like teachers. But the range of
tion of Peru since the conquest by including a full range of prominent positions faund in the biographic entries is quite broad: it includes many
shapers of national history. of those central to the administrative state, such as tax collector, school
While the Chilean and Mexican sources select individuals to include inspector, telegraph inspector, sanitation of:ficer, and customs of:ficial.
based on explicit positional criteria, Milla Batres does not spell out such Given that the same concerns about selection effects are present far ali
clear decision rules in the case of Peru. Nevertheless, all three volumes countries, we can safely make cross-national comparisons even if we can-
emphasize individuals who rose to positions of political or administrative not draw inferences about absolute rates of delegation and deployment.
prominence. Given our limited knowledge about the career trajectories of As in the analysis of decrees, we can draw conclusions from the analysis
bureaucrats, we must allow far the possibility that access to such posi- of biography entries about cross-national differences, but not inferences
tions was affected by family background, wealth, or social prominence, about absolute rates of delegation and deployment in any given case.
and that these were not typical bureaucrats. Selection effects based on Findings: As shown in Table 2.4, the rates of deployed rule in Chile,
career trajectories, in other words, may exist. Mexico, and Peru after r 89 5 were higher than that of Peru in the earlier
The availability of biographical information also leads to selection period. These differences are statistically significant as well: a one-tailed
effects in ali three sources that bias the sample of bureaucrats included. t-test confirms that the sample of appointments in Peru befare r89 5 saw
Camp makes the size of the data problem clear in stating that two-thirds significantly more reliance on delegated rule than did the other cases,
of his potential entries had to be dropped due to missing information. although the substantive differences between cases are fairly small. 1 4 Thus,
De Ramón goes further in talking explicitly about selection, writing that we have further support far the clairn that the pattern of administrative
many of:ficials who met the positional criteria, but who lacked com-
plete biographical information, carne from modest socioeconomic back- 14 This difference, despite the small sample sizes, is significant at the .ro leve! for Chile and
grounds (r 2). Because he, like his counterparts in the other countries, Peru after 1895, but not quite for Mexico (significance leve! is o.u).
74 State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 75

appointments was unique in this case. Additionally, a two-tailed t-test Importantly, as I emphasize in Chapter 4, this absence of elites from the
confums that the extent of reliance on deployed rule was similarly impor- bureaucracy does not mean that these elites were weak. Indeed, Chilean
tant in the other three cases, suggesting that these patterns of administra- elites were wealthier, and had more control over land and labor than did
tive appointment had a great deal in common and that we should expect their counterparts in Peru (Bauer 1975; Saylor 2012). More to the point,
similar impact in their effect on state building in Mexico, Chile, and Peru they also held absolute sway over the country: top government positions
after 1895. like the presidency, congress, and ministerial portfolios were firmly in the
hands of Chile's tightly knit oligarchy (Loveman 2001, 139). Elites, then,
Qualitative Evidence had total control over the rural areas, massive wealth, and a stranglehold
In addition to these attempts to quantitatively assess broad patterns of on the "commanding heights" of the state. But they played little part in
appointrnent practices, a variety of qualitative evidence also sheds light the bureaucracy through which the state administered its territory. Instead,
on patterns of administrative appointrnents. This evidence is drawn from the state administration at the local level was populated with state agents
the official newspapers of record in Chile and Peru, other government who arrived with no ties to the communities to which they were deployed
documents, and a range of secondary sources that discuss appointrnent to serve.
practices in particular agencies, administrations, or regions. Peru r845-r895: Colonial adrninistration in Peru had relied on indig-
Chile: In making bureaucratic appointments at the regional and local enous authorities to adrninister many parts of the country. After indepen-
level, Chilean state leaders tended not to select regional elites far these dence, the new republican adrninistration chose to establish a new regional
positions. Instead, local communities were penetrated by "powerful adrninistrative apparatus and rely on non-Indian petty state officials. 1 s
officials appointed directly by the president" (Valenzuela n.d., 3). The These officials were almost exclusively local elites. The most important set
absence of bureaucrats among elite sectors of Chilean society was quite of officials, the linchpins of administration at the local level who "linked"
striking. Arnold Bauer, far example, studies several notable rural elite the hinterland with the regional and national state, were governors (Walker
families, finding that while their ranks included a presidential candidate, r999, 137). Governors and their small office staff had tax collection as their
congressional deputies, senators, bank presidents, mine owners, and a pres- central responsibility, but they also recruited soldiers, extracted supplies far
ident of the national agricultura! lobby (Sociedad Nacional de Agricultura), the army in times of civil war, exercised surveillance over political oppo-
not a single bureaucratic post was held by a member of their ranks (Bauer nents, and disseminated political information and propaganda on behalf of
1975, l81ff). Maurice Zeitlin, sirnilarly, collects biographical information the government. In other words, they were the key agents of the state at the
on forty-four insurrectionary leaders in the l 8 5 l and l 8 59 Civil Wars, who local level.
carne from the country's economic elite (Zeitlin 1984; Table 2.1). He finds The importance of the governors can be seen in the fact that they, the
that only faur were state officials: two military officers, and two judges. subprefects, and other regional staff made up more than one-third of all
None had ever held any other appointed position in the regional bureau- bureaucratic appointments in the sample of decrees discussed earlier. That
cracy. It was uncommon far social and economic elites to serve as cogs only three of the I 68 regional official appointments in the El Peruano
in the Chilean adrninistrative machine, although they did more commonly sample were clearly deployed strongly supports the claim that local elites
hold offices in agency headquarters in Santiago. held sway over these appointments. Contreras (200 5, I l 8) describes the
We can also draw inference about the extent of central government con- pattern quite clearly: while prefects and regional officials "belonged to
trol over local appointrnents from the instances in which officials requested a kind of caste of mobile public functionaries whose true home base
to be sent to a particular location. In these cases, such as one of three vacci- was the army," governors "were local figures, chosen primarily far their
nation officials requesting permission to work where his family lives (Diario knowledge of Spanish and also far their potential loyalty to the govern-
Oficial March 17, 1877, p. 125), the request trickled up all the way to the ment of the day."
minister of the interior himself. This, too, suggests that the central govern-
ment held a great deal of control over appointrnents, rather than letting 15
Thurner (1997) describes the removal of chiefs as tribute collectors and their replace-
regional officials make appointrnent decisions. ment with non-Indian officials in the Huaylas region.
State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 77

In addition to the subprefects, the state-building governments of refusing to relocate from Paseo to lea (El Peruano March 22, 1845, p.1).
the guano era created a wide range of new positions at the local and lnterestingly, claims of health as an obstacle to a posting were commonly
regional level, such as public health inspectors and school officials deployed both by coastal residents seeking to avoid appointments in the
(Jacobsen 1993, 147). Muecke (2004, 166) finds that tax collectors, Andes and by those unwilling to be sent to the coast from their highland
school inspectors, teachers, district governors, and other officials were homes. Health-based excuses were so common that government minis-
positions populated almost exclusively by local elites. Other accounts of tries began to demand and assess evidence for health-related appeals of
this period agree. School inspectors, as discussed further in Chapter 4, appointments (El Peruano ]une 7, 1873, pp. 3-4).
were nearly universally residents of the local community. Rural security, Compromise between ministries and appointees was also common -
too, was provided by corps of landowners organized into rural police attempts to deploy appointees to new regions often resulted in agree-
(El Peruano July 12, 1873, p. 7). The 1856 national census was admin- ments allowing various appointees to swap jobs to head off the need to
istered by commissions of local residents, who completed forms about relocate. Indeed, much of the lirnited evidence of deployed rule that I did
their community and returned them to Lima (El Peruano October 6, find in the Peruvian case took the form of local officials swapping jobs so
l 8 5 5, p. l). Similar procedures were also used to compile and update that they could leave deployed postings and return to their homes. Much
tax rolls. Thus, delegation to local notables dominated many aspects of more often than in Chile, these requests for swaps seem to have been
administration in Peru. granted (see, among many other examples, El Peruano ]une 25, 1873,
This administrative arrangement was beneficial to local elites. Befare p. 11 and June 21, 1873, p. II). In other words, local state agents in Peru
the agricultural and mining booms that began in the l89os, most elites seem to have resisted deployment in a way not seen in Chile, further rein-
were fairly poor, and relatively weak vis-a-vis their local communities. 16 forcing the dominance of delegated rule.
Positions in regional administration were useful to these elites in consol- Resistance to deployment in the ranks of médicos titulares or regional
idating their positions in local society and in power struggles at the local medical officials is particularly interesting to note. Because most of
or regional level. 1 1 This could be done via the use of appointments to these officials were army officers, I excluded them from the quantita-
cement local alliances, or via the leverage provided by control of taxing tive analysis of appointment decrees. Yet examining the appointment of
or policing. It was because Peruvian elites were fairly weak that positions medical officers - whether sent to respond to an epidemic or to oversee
in the administration appealed to them. public health in a particular jurisdiction - reveals significant resistance
The pattern of heavy reliance on delegation in Peru was reinforced by to deployed rule. In 1873 alone, the records in El Peruano show eight
the high rate of refusal in the rare attempts where the national government instances of refusal of appointments. Given that 1873 saw only 38 medi-
did attempt to deploy a bureaucrat to a remate region. Refusals took the cal officer appointments, and that most appointees were military officers,
form of explicit rejection of a transfer or appointment, or more passively this is a strikingly high rate of refusal. Five of these refusals resulted in
they sometimes manifested in the failure of an appointee to appear at the cashiering of the officer, one in a resignation, one in failure to appear
a new posting. 18 This posed a severe challenge to the national govern- at a new post, and the eighth in a successful health-related appeal, which
ment, which had to either punish the appointee for refusal, or compro- resulted in reassignment to a post open within the department in which
mise and keep them in a post close to home. Such cases included not only the officer was currently posted.
low-ranking officials but even those more senior, such as the judge fired for Overall, we can conclude that deployed rule was fairly rare in Peru,
and when it was implemented, it faced resistance from appointees, who
'
6
Evidence in Nugent (I997) for the Chachapoyas region, and in Thorp and Bertram seemed to prefer to remain in their home regions. But resistance by
(I978) for the country as a whole suggests that Peru's elites were fairly weak until the appointees only explains a certain amount of variation. Explicit evidence
export booms of the I89os. of delegation to local residents appears regularly in the record of Peruvian
'7 For examples of this pattern, see Nugent (I997, 34-35) and Taylor (2006, 57).
'
8
For one of many examples of the latter, see El Peniano July 5, I873, p. I7 for the discus-
administration, and Lima's role in populating its administration was lim-
sion of the failure of a school director deployed to Puno to appear for the beginning of ited to rubber-stamping decisions made by local residents. At the local
the school year. level, in many cases, the decrees indicate that only a single individual was
State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 79

even considered far the job in rnany cases, whereas decrees in Chile more provincia and jefes de departamento, which would be populated with
cornrnonly referred to the range of candidates considered far a position. a class of "career politicians" (Nugent 1997, 48). Among appointments
The result was that it was cornrnon to see local residents shifting to these positions in the decrees analyzed earlier, nearly half were clearly
across governrnent agencies to take posts - rnuch more cornrnon than deployed, a rate far higher than that far any other office. This practice
in Chile. In 1873 alone, appointrnents in El Peruano include instances created a new corps of regional and local bureaucrats, deployed from
of a rnail official being appointed subprefect (July 19, p. 10), a teacher Lima, to sit alongside the subprefects and governors who continued to be
getting a postal supervisor post (May 3, p. 13), and the aide of a prefect drawn frorn arnong the local elites.
becorning a gendarme (July 12, p. l). In one instance, a court official in The practice of deployrnent during the Aristocratic Republic
Arequipa was appointed prefect - this indicares that even these positions, (1895-1919) expanded rnost where it <lid not directly challenge the inter-
usually the exclusive purview of outside officials such as rnilitary officers, ests of local elites. In addition to creating the jefes, we see that the state
were filled by local residents in sorne cases (July 26, p. 4). Local residents, inserted outsiders into education and policing at a rnuch higher rate than
rather than outsiders with relevant skills and qualifications, were favored in the past, while deployrnent was cornpletely absent frorn the courts, and
far a wide variety of positions across Peru during the guano era.-· from the officialdorn that oversaw rnining, irrigation, and river transport.
Peru after 1895: Appointment patterns after 1895 were rnarkedly dif- The developrnents in schooling (discussed further in Chapter 4) were
ferent than those in the preceding era. This can be seen in the quantita- particularly striking: while school inspection at the local level remained
tive analysis of decrees presented earlier, which showed that the rate of in the hands of appointees from the local cornrnunity, provincial and
"clearly deployed" appointrnents more than doubled frorn that of the departrnental inspection was systematically turned over to outsiders,
pre-189 5 perio d. Moreover, this figure alrnost certainly represents an who were rotated through different jurisdictions during their careers
undercounting of the rate of deployed rule after l 89 5, since rnany more (MIP 1910, v.2, 35ff). This was a significant rnove toward deployed rule.
appointrnent decrees frorn this period include infarrnation stating that On the other hand, since conscription remained in the hands of the sub-
the previous occupant had been relocated to a post in a different loca- prefects and governors, and these positions continued to be overwhelrn-
tion. Without inforrnation about the destinations of the farrner holders, ingly given to locals, this aspect of the state rernained weak, as shown in
I could not code those transfers as instances of clearly deployed rule. But Chapter 6.
this pattern - that so rnany positions were vacant due to the transfer of The revenue realrn was a more complicated story, as discussed in detail
the previous officeholder to a position elsewhere - suggests that deployed in Chapter 5. On the one hand, deployrnent increased among the ranks of
rule must have been more cornrnon than the "clearly deployed" figure the custorns service as officers were rotated to limit fraud and srnuggling.
reported earlier indicares. Given the state's heavy reliance on custorns revenues, the refarrns in that
The Civilistas who carne to power after 1895 undertook an explicit arena were crucial to its fiscal survival. On the other hand, the Civilista-era
effort to cut local elites out of adrninistration. This was rnotivated by regimes made very few appointments at ali in the realrn of internal taxa-
their belief that the decentralization of the preceding Cáceres regirne and tion. Learning frorn the conflict spurred by atternpts to deploy tax corn-
the delegation cornrnon in the prewar period were responsible far Peru's rnissioners in the late l88os and "exclude local authorities frorn fiscal
developmental failures. But the Civilista project of adrninistrative refarm adrninistration," the Civilistas abolished that office in 1893 and faund a
and state building sought to avoid directly challenging these powerful new strategy. 19 Rather than threaten the interests of local elites directly
actors, as sorne short-lived postwar governrnents had done. Rather than by deploying tax inspectors and collectors to the periphery, or continu-
taking the more politically difficult step of wresting control of existing ing to rely on local elites to oversee tax collection, the Civilistas opted
offices away frorn local elites, the central state chose instead to layer a instead to contraer tax collection to the prívate Compañia Nacional de
new set of positions above these offices, and to continue to appoint local Recaudación discussed in Chapter 5. Despite the hopes that privatization
elites as governors and subprefects while trying to underrnine the extent would eliminare the influence of local elites over collection, they retained
of their authority. The rnost important element of the Civilista refarrns
19
was the creation of a new series of bureaucratic offices - the jefes de On this conflict, see Contreras (2005, 12off); quote from p.12I.
80 State Building in Latín America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure 81

appointments in this realm. First (as discussed in Chapter 5) the CNR loyalists with them when they assumed leadership of a state (Perry 1978,
relied on local elites to take up many positions in its ranks. Second, local 89). Thus, many of the appointments at the governors' disposal went to
tax rolls continued to be updated by cornmissions of local notables (see outsiders as well. For example, as discussed in Chapter 4, educational
El Peruano January lo, 1912, p. 13 for the case of Contumazá). Thus, appointments remained in the hands of state governors, who often filled
this shift had a smaller effect than state leaders intended. them vía deployed rule.
The attempt to implement deployed rule can be seen in the statistical Yet many aspects of adrninistration remained under the control of
realm as well. Having come to realize that leaving data collection in the the national government. This centralization increased over the course
hands of local officials fundamentally underrnined any chance of gener- of the Porfiriato. Here, too, we can see the importance of deployed rule.
ating any systematic information, the state shifted toward more central The taxation administration, for example, as discussed in Chapter 5,
control over these practices. This included the 1902 education census was steadily centralized. A series of national-level tax corps - the tim-
explored in Soifer (2012b), as well as other initiatives. For example, the bre inspectors, the visitadores, and the inspectores - were deployed from
1903 census of the province of Lima, which was carried out by comrnis- Mexico City to adrninister taxes at the state leve! throughout the country.
sions of local notables, was deemed a failure, and scheduled in 1908 to be Thus, despite Mexico's federal institutions, the state-building era saw a
repeated by the Ministerio de Fomento (El Peruano February 27, 1908, steady increase of central control over bureaucratic appointment in many
p. 7). In a related initiative, the rise of labor unrest in the sugar regions on aspects of adrninistration.
the north coast prompted the deployment of a series of inspectors from The same pattern of increasing central control over appointments in
Lima who were charged with reporting on the roots of tensions - another the periphery also unfolded at the municipal level. Porfirio Díaz created
example of the shift of the national government away from relying on the position of jefe político as a means of exerting federal control at the
local elites as it managed the challenges of governance. municipal level. These officials were in charge of implementing a wide
Thus, the national government in the post-1895 period made an range of federal policies in their cornmunities including conscription,
explicit effort to increase the incidence of deployed rule. Although as discussed in Chapter 6. The men appointed to these positions "were
national leaders wanted to cut local elites out of the adrninistration, they often from outside the state with few local ties" (Haber et al. 2003, 45).
were lirnited by political constraints in their ability to do so. The result Appointment of outsiders "predorninated" (Knight 1986, vol. l, 27-28).
was variation across arenas of adrninistration. Sorne types of positions The rise of the jefes políticos broke the monopoly of local control that
remained the exclusive domain of local elites. Others, such as educational had marked the early decades after independence (Chowning 1999, 10).
offices, were transformed during these decades. The central state also cre- Elites, in a relationship similar to that which we saw in Chile, often
ated new organs of administration to indirectly underrnine the hold of "accornmodated themselves" to giving up political power at the local
local elites over their communities, filling posts in these with outsiders level in return for government policies that broadly aligned with their
as well. The result was a mixed pattern of administrative organization, a interests in economic development and security (Voss 1982, xv). Mexico
real change from the previous half century of delegation to local notables, saw little delegation of these positions at the fulcrum of local adrninistra-
but far from a complete shift to deployed rule. · tion to local elites (Pittman 1989, 32).
Mexico: In Mexico, appointments in the federal bureaucracy were Mexico was not as clear-cut a case of deployed rule as was Chile. We
cornmonly filled through deployment. Although no collection of appoint- see variation across bureaucratic agencies and issue areas, as described
ment decrees is available, the reports of historians about appointment briefly here, but also across regions. Bobrow-Strain (2007, 78-79), for
practices are unanimous in supporting this assessment. Governors, who example, shows that in Porfirian Chiapas "landowners themselves were
oversaw much local and regional adrninistration, cornmonly were out- called to serve as direct agents of state rule." These landowners not only
siders in the states where they served (Knight 1986, vol. l, p. 17). The actively resisted state-building efforts (78) cites a landowner driving
position saw high geographic mobility, as governors were commonly off his estate at gunpoint two fellow landowners serving as tax collec-
rotated among states (Haber 2003, 88-89). As governors built "bureau- tors - but also revealed their disinterest in broader development projects:
cratic machines loyal to themselves" at the state level, they often brought landowners tried to bribe the governor of Chiapas to stop construction
State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

of a road connecting coffee and sugar estates to the national road net- hierarchy, with terms of office, formal appointment procedures, and req-
work (65). Yet even in Chiapas, there were serious efforts by Porfirian uisites for service in all cases.
officials to "challenge landowners' mediator position by extending the
reaches of its legal system .... " (78). The governor, an outsider, sought
Overlapping Bureaucratic Networks
to use roads, census collection, and the intervention of bureaucrats and
state agents to weaken the hold of landowners and impose the state's A second set of similarities relates to the network of bureaucratic institu-
power despite their opposition. The uneven patchwork of administra- tions in each case. Mexico's federal system meant that its system diverged
tive forms in Mexico explains the intermediate outcome of state devel- from the other two cases in sorne ways, but it was quite similar in terms
opment in that case; evidence presented in Chapters 4 to 6 highlights of the presence of territorial administration overseen by the center, and
variation in state-building success across states and agencies in the the overlap of this network of state institutions with a set of functional
Liberal and Porfirian eras. institutions. In Mexico, as described in detail in the relevant case chapters,
these functional institutions often operated at the state level of Mexico's
federal system, while Chile and Peru were unitary systems.
THE PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION OF STATE BUILDING In all cases, the national territory was divided into a territorial grid
of various levels of subunits. Although these had different names, and
Variation in several characteristics of the administrative apparatus of the varied in whether the territorial regime was federal or unitary, in all
state have been linked to its capacity in existing scholarship. Yet these of the countries, local and regional administrative positions were filled
aspects of public administration are similar in our cases, providing fur- via presidential appointment (whether directly or, in sorne branches
ther evidence for the causal importance of the more subtle distinction of the Mexican administration, through appointment by presidential
discussed earlier - that between delegation to local officials or deploy- appointees). The appointment procedure for territorial administrators
ment of outsiders. This difference unfolded within very similar formal (intendants, governors, subdelegates, and inspectors in Chile; prefects,
bureaucratic structures in each case, in cases with similarly low levels of subprefects, governors, and deputy governors in Peru) was identical
bureaucratic professionalization, and in cases with similarly little entry of in Chile and Peru - appointments were made at higher levels in the
customary rule into bureaucratic practices. territorial hierarchy on the recommendation of officials closer to the
ground. 20
In both countries, the two higher rungs of territorial administrators
Patrimonialism
were salaried positions, and the office of intendant and prefect were
One way in which the cases were similar was the absence of formal patri- commonly filled by former or current military officers, who composed
monial office-holding, which (as Ertman [1997] and others have argued) what Contreras (2005, n8) describes as a "caste of mobile public func-
was associated with state weakness in early modern Europe. This elimi- tionaries whose true home base was the army." The offices of subdelega te
nation of patrimonialism, as discussed further in Chapter 3, was a con- and inspector in Chile and the analogous positions of governor and dep-
sequence of the Bourbon Reforms. Sorne characteristics of patrimonial uty governor in Peru were unsalaried. They were seen as part of the civic
offices did exist, especially in the realm of taxation: officials at times duty of citizens, and service was obligatory for those who did not qualify
received a share of the revenues that passed through their hands in lieu for exemptions based on age or holding another public office concur-
of a salary, and sorne positions were filled by auction. These details of tax rently or previously. In addition to civic duty or sanction for not serving,
administration are discussed in Chapter 5. But in general, officials were these offices served two other purposes for their occupants. The first was
appointed and removed from office by their superiors and thus patrimo- as an entry in.to public service; citizens took these positions in the hopes
nial administration, in the sense of ownership of an office, had no place
in Spanish America after the mid-eighteenth-century Bourbon Reforms 2
º On the Peruvian case, see Contreras (2005, 117ff); on the Chilean case see Vera
discussed in Chapter 3. Instead, bureaucracies had a formal and complex {1886, 29).
State Building in Latin America A Theory of State-Building Success and Failure

of using them to gain access to paid offices in the future. The second, as Customary Law
described most clearly in Nugent (1997) for the Peruvian case, was as a
means of exercising local power against rivals. In both Chile and Peru, Scholars of colonial rule have focused on the extent of reliance on custom-
elite dorninance of localities was fairly weak, and competition among ary law asan axis of variation in adrninistrative institutions (Young 1994;
the locally wealthy unfolded to sorne extent through the manipulation of Lange 2009 ). Whereas direct rule is said to ha ve integrated all members of
state institutions. African colonial society under European laws, indirect rule is said to have
This regional apparatus overlapped with functional. adrninistr~tive enforced customary authority, with the consequence of unifying traditional
institutions (most commonly rninistries) headquartered m the nat1onal and customary authority in the community leader (Mamdani l 996). Scholars
capital in realms of state activity such as education and consc:iption. In of Africa are divided about the contemporary impact of customary law -
Chile, for example, the l 8 8 6 Ley de Régimen Interior made mtenda~ts whereas Herbst (2000, 81) sees itas in practice insignificant, Lange (2009)
responsible for overseeing state functions such as public health, se~un_ry, shows that the divergence between direct and indirect rule in the British
public works, and education in their regions. Because both terntonal Empire underlies variation in the strength of the postcolonial state. But cus-
and functional adrninistrators reported to superiors and eventually to tomary law did not play a similar role in Latin America, where the nature
the capital, each class of state institutions could serve as a means ?f. ~~er­ of the conquest ruled out reliance on traditional authority. Demographic
seeing the other. This overlapping of state institutional res~o~s1b~llt1es, collapse in its immediate aftermath, followed by centuries of exploitation in
because it is identical in both cases, cannot account for vanation m the mining and agriculture, crippled traditional indigenous structures of author-
effectiveness of state institutions. ity (Coatsworth 2008). The resulting relationship between indigenous and
national society was much more complex than the sharply defined group
categories created by indirect rule in Airica (Mamdani 1996; Walker 1999,
Technical Expertise II). As a result, even where indigenous authorities held sway over large
Nor can the technical qualifications of the rank and file, another way portions of the population, states sought and succeeded in removing indig-
in which the cases were quite similar. In both Chile and Peru, the for- enous authorities as mediators in the state-society relationship. Instead, 21

mal requirements for holding territorial adrninistrative posts w~re ~uite they relied largely on non-indigenous mediators in a model that does not
few: appointees had only to be of a certain age (twenty-five ~ smgle; fit the category of indirect rule (Scarritt 2005, 3 5-3 7). Reliance on custom-
twenty-one if married in Chile), male, and able to read and wnte. The ary law was also precluded by the comrnitment of state leaders, even in
blind deaf mute and those convicted of certain crimes were excluded the colonial era, to goals of "civilization" and "progress." Colonial, rather
22

from ~ubli~ servi;e in the territorial adrninistration. Even service in Chile's than customary, law played a significant effort in state-indigenous relations
ministries had few official requirements (Urzúa Valenzuela 1970, 64ff} - even before independence (Walker 1999). Custornary law never regained
candidates had to meet a mínimum educational threshold and sorne basic the place in official adrninistration that it had lost before independence, as
skills (math or foreign languages, depending on the position) but little individualistic state-society relations replaced corporate rights. Unlike other
in the way of specific knowledge or training was required. In the l89os,
reformers like Valentin Letelier were still calling for a civil service reform
" The central aspect of state-indigenous relations was the tribute or head ta:x, assessed
that would list for the first time explicit knowledge/skill criteria for each on the community as a whole with indigenous leaders responsible for its extraction. Its
position (Silva 2008, p. 45ff}. There were sorne exceptions to this rule: for elimina tion in the rnid-nineteenth century was part of a Liberal effort to disrnantle the
example, telegraph operators had to have completed the relevant course at remaining structures of indirect rule (Thurner 1997; Larson 2004). These changes in tax-
ation are explored in Chapter 5.
the Instituto Nacional and to pass a series of exarninations (El Araucano 22
Here I refer to a commitrnent dating back to the original "civilizing mission" of the
January II, 1870, p. 4). But overall, adrninistration in Libe~al-era L~tin conquest, which rnarked Spanish adrninistration throughout the colonial era. Colonial
America was far from a professional bureaucracy peopled w1th technical authorities, even as they prioritized exploitation of resources both human and phys-
ical, sought with sorne success to starnp out customary law and practice, in favor of
experts. Christianity and Spanish legal practice.
86 State Building in Latin America

postcolonial contexts, then, variation in Latin American state strength does


not derive from a reliance on indirect rule and customary law. 3

CONCLUSION Alternative Historical Explanations and


This chapter has developed an institutional explanation for why Initial Conditions
state-building efforts succeed and fail. Whereas existing accounts of state
building draw a direct link between incentives for state building and out-
comes, I problematize the adrninistrative challenges that state leaders face
in seeking to impose control. Where state building was undertaken, it did
not always succeed - and this is a crucial point rnissed by most existing
scholarship. I trace the success and failure of these projects to dynarnics
interna! to the state by focusing on the incentives of local adrninistrators.
Where these local officials ha ve independent power in the communities in
which they serve - power which derives from their status as local elites - My focus on the Liberal era as the key moment for state-building
they are less dependent on the state's power, and less likely to take an challenges accounts that highlight characteristics of earlier historical
active role in implementing state-building policies. By contrast, where moments, such as colonialism and the independence era, as crucial in
local officials are deployed into a community from outside, and depend shaping state-development outcomes. This chapter begins by sketching
on the state for income and standing, they have independent incentives to the nature of colonial rule and the independence conflicts to show that
participate actively in state-building efforts. As I have shown in this chap- these were not fundamental in shaping the states that emerged. Thus the
ter, Mexico and Chile saw deployed rule, as did Peru after l 89 5, while first purpose of this chapter is to provide evidence that challenges alterna-
guano-era Peru saw delegated rule. These patterns of local adrninistration tive explanations for variation in state capacity based on earlier critica!
align with the fate of state-building efforts: success in Mexico and Chile, junctures.
as well as gains during the Aristocratic Republic (1895-1919) in Peru, as The second purpose of this chapter is to explore the post-independence
opposed to stagnation during the preceding guano years (1845-1895) in decades in all four countries, showing that their states were deeply weak,
that country. and political and econornic crises severe, in these initial decades after
The result of this difference in adrninistration is nothing less than the independence. Only the emergence of a basic level of stability after about
success and failure of the state-building efforts discussed in Chapters 4 1840 set the stage for mid-century leaders to turn to the projects of politi-
to 6. There, I show that the composition of the adrninistration accounts cal development and social transformation that are the focus of the book.
for variation in state-building outcomes in these cases better than do By showing that the states in the four cases were quite similar - sirnilarly
alternative explanations such as ethnic diversity, access to resource rents, weak - as of about l 840, this chapter provides a baseline from which
and war. Befare proceeding to the comparative analysis of different subsequent deviation on the outcome of interest can be assessed. Within
aspects of state capacity, Chapter 3 investigates the origins of delegated this broad sirnilarity, I also highlight a few differences in state capacity
and deployed rule. It also addresses a set of alternative explanations that predate the onset of concerted state building.
for state-development outcomes that are based in historical differences The third purpose of the chapter is to explain the choices of deployed
between the cases. and delegated rule shown in Chapter 2. Like any causal claim, my argu-
ment must withstand two threats to inference. The fust is reverse causa-
tion, which would hold if preexisting levels of state capacity made states
more likely to choose deployed rule. The second is the possibility of an
ornitted variable. This would hold if there were systematic differences
88 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence

between the cases that underlay the choices made by state leaders about developmental state to the transformations enacted under Japanese colo-
populating their adrninistration and also underlay the success and failure nial rule (I994, 2004). His study is valuable for our purposes because it
of state-building projects. The task, then, is to show that the form of rule focuses explicitly on the state's infrastructural power. Yet Latin America
is neither justan intervening variable nor an outcome of preexisting dif- saw nothing resembling the Japanese colonization of South Korea; as
ferences in state capacity. I address this in the final section of the chapter Kohli acknowledges, the Japanese colonial state was both uniquely pow-
by explaining why state leaders in sorne countries chose deployed rule erful and uniquely committed to the political transformation of the soci-
while others chose delegation to local elites. eties it controlled. Thus we are left with Young's (I994) more general
claim that the hangover of political institutions into the republican era
is crucial in explaining divergent development outcomes, but without a
COLONIAL LEGACIES
general theory that can link colonial and post-independence state power
Mechanisms of Colonial Impact in Latin America.
Yet to convincingly set aside colonial state legacies, a brief explora-
Simple models that trace post-independence development to the extent of tion of the pre-indepedence era is warranted. The Bourbon Reforms pro-
colonial penetration, like that of Palmer (I977), cannot account for the vide a propitious context for examining the nature of the colonial state
divergent outcomes in the colonial centers of Mexico and Peru, or for the
for two reasons. First, because they irnplanted identical institutions of
divergence between Chile and Colombia, which were both colonial periph-
colonial rule region-wide, the existence of the Bourbon Reforms belies
eries. Nor can more recent scholarship, which has focused on the nature theories that explain variation in development by focusing on the type
of colonial rule rather than its intensity, account for variation in state of colonial institutions. 1 Second, because the Reforms took place on
capacity. One current of scholarship focuses on the economic institutions
the very eve of independence, they reveal the nature of colonial institu-
of colonial rule and how they shape trajectories of post-independence
tions and their capacity at the twilight of colonial rule. The comparison
development (Acemoglu et al. 200I; 2002; Coatsworth I998, 2008). that follows shows that Spanish administration was largely relatively
Mahoney (20Io) provides the most nuanced version of this account, weak; able to effectively implement its reforms only in Mexico. Thus
showing that social and economic development in Spanish America were
neither the institutional character nor the capacity of the colonial state
determined by the interaction of the type of colonial rule anq its inten-
can explain variation in post-independence state capacity outcomes in
sity. As the intensity of mercantilist colonialism increased, development Spanish America.
suffered, while intensive liberal colonialism set off positive development
trajectories. Mahoney also provides a more precise account of the causal
mechanism linking colonial rule to development outcomes by showing The Bourbon Reforms: State Power at the Twilight of
how different patterns of colonial institutions distributed resources and Colonial Rule
differentially empowered collective actors. Yet Mahoney <loes not explain The Bourbon Reforms are a case in which international threats promoted
variation in political development. Indeed, by moving directly from the state building. Part of a pattern that unfolded sirnultaneously across the
constellations of actors shaped by colonial institutions to development
colonial world, these policies were an attempt to respond to international
outcomes, Mahoney removes politics from his account altogether.
pressures by irnproving adrninistration in the colonies, particularly in the
Among studies that focus more explicitly on the political effects of
realm of revenue extraction (Elliott 2006; Young I994, 70). As such, the
colonial institutions, Lange (2004, 2009) finds that, within the British reforms had both institutional and policy components. 2

Empire, direct rule is associated with positive outcomes in terms of politi-


cal development. Yet the categories of direct and indirect rule do not apply
in Spanish colonial America, where colonial institutions tended to "blur ' As described later, the Colombian case represents a partía! exception to this general claim.
' Here I set aside another central component of the reforms the expulsion of the Jesuits -
both categories" so this finding cannot be applied to our cases (Mahoney to focus on those that relate to the state's penetration of society rather than its relation-
20Io, 23). Kohli traces the emergence of South Korea's strikingly effective ship with other structures of authority.
State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence 9r

The centerpiece of the institutional component was an alteration Another indication of the weakness of the Chilean colonial state was
of administrative organization: the creation of the intendancy as an reception of the administrative reforms. Because Chile was enjoying
appointed position designed to "weaken regional and local networks of growing prosperity in the late eighteenth century, and because they cre-
interest and influence" (Stein r98r, 4). This model was introduced ini- ated new administrative posts in Santiago which were largely filled by
tially in the peripheral colonies in r765 and thereafter in Peru (r784) and creoles, the Bourbon Reforms faced relatively little opposition from elites
Mexico (I?86). The establishment of intendancies was a means of ratio- (Barbier r980). And the reforms simply had little impact on the life of the
nalizing, systematizing, and centralizing political authority (Dornínguez broader population of the Chilean colony, revealing the weakness of the
r980, 7r). For our purposes, the key policy component of the Bourbon colonial state. Rather than leading to majar revolts, as they did in Peru and
Reforms was the effort to increase ex:traction from colonial society. The Colombia where they impinged on local de facto autonomy, the Bourbon
particular tax policies used varied somewhat across countries, but there Reforms caused little disruption in Chile (Pinto Rodríguez 2003).
was a general move to direct tax collection instead of the tax farming of the
earlier colonial period, to more effective administration of state monopo- Colombia
lies, and to greater imposition of direct taxes. Because these greater impo- Compared to most other parts of the Spanish Empire, colonial New
sitions prompted unrest, the Bourbon Reforms also involved an increase Granada (the territory that would become Colombia) was "lightly
in the size of colonial militaries (Dornínguez r980). In all, the Bourbons governed" (Deas r982, 293). The colonial state relied on four main
attempted a "second conquest" of Spanish America (Lynch r986, 7), and sources of finance: the indigenous head tax, the a/cábala or domestic
their success reveals the power of the colonial state. The discussion that transactions tax, customs revenue, and the tobacco monopoly. To sup-
follows evaluates the extent of institutional reform, increased ex:traction, plement these, it relied on subsidies from the colonial centers of New
and control of protest and threats to Spanish control in the last decades Spain and Peru. Rather than institute new forros of taxes, the Bourbon
befare independence in the four cases. I present the cases in arder of what administration sought to better collect those already on the books
they reveal about the capacity of the colonial state - from weakest in Chile (McGreevey r97r, 25). Efforts to modernize taxation set off a series
to strongest in Mexico, with Colombia and Peru (in that arder) in the of revolts, of which the r78r Comunero Rebellion was the largest. It
middle. This ordering shows quite clearly that variation in the extent of culminated in a massive march on Bogotá by as many as twenty thou-
Spanish control cannot account for the state-building outcomes sketched sand, as rebels controlled one-third of the national territory. Colonial
in the Introduction. We see neither continuity nora "reversa! of fortune" authorities had to rely on provincial militias to stem revolts in the
in the development of state capacity (Acemoglu et al. 2002). absence of the army.
While the Comunero revolt was neither as bloody nor as long-lasting
Chile as Peru's Tupac Amarú revolt, it resulted in both coercive and conces-
The fundamental purpose of the Bourbon Reforms was to increase the sionary responses from colonial authorities who feared endemic unrest
revenue that the Spanish Crown could extract from its colonies. Measured (McFarlane r984). The Bourbon state increased the number of troops
on this dimension, it becomes clear that the reforms' effect in Chile was in Bogotá, of which a majority were brought from Spain to ensure their
limited at best. Befare the reforms, the administration of the Chilean col- loyalty. But it also backed away from efforts to transform the tax system
ony generated so little revenue for the crown that colonial administra- in New Granada in arder to placate the restive popular sectors. Finally,
tion depended on the situado, a sizable subsidy from Peruvian colonial it opted not to institute the intendancy system, which allowed local elites
revenues, to support its army and pay the salaries of administrators. The to retain their positions in colonial administration3 (McFarlane r993).
reformers eliminated the situado and established a tobacco monopoly to While the Bourbon Reforms were salient enough to spark revolt in
generate revenue. The reliance on a monopoly, rather than on the direct New Granada, the fact that the colonial state was unable to impose its
taxation imposed elsewhere by the Bourbons, and the inability to turn a
profit from it (largely because of smuggling), reflect the limited extractive 3
This is the one exception to the claim that colonial political institutions were invariant
capacity of the colonial state in Chile. across the four cases.
92 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence
93
preferred policies or administrative institutions reflects its lack of author- presence during the colonial period, and this presence escalated during
ity in this part of its empire. the Bourbon era.
The most striking manifestation of the strength of the Bourbon state
Peru was in taxation. The colonial state relied heavily on interna! taxation
The most notable impact of the Bourbon Reforms in Peru was an increase rather than port taxes. High sales taxes on domestic commerce, the head
in taxation (Walker I999, I22). This included an increase in the number tax on the indigenous population, and rnining taxes made up the largest
of goods under state monopoly, such as gunpowder, tobacco, and playing components of revenue (Chowning I999, 47). In all, by I79º residents
cards as well as an increase in the head tax imposed on the indigenous of New Spain paid eighty-four categories of taxes (Tenenbaum I986,
population (Contreras and Cueto I999, 80-84). Reformers installed cus- 3). The amount of tax collected more than doubled from I?60 to I790,
toms houses and tax collectors even in the remote region of Puno, which with particularly large revenue increases coming from sales taxes, and
was more than a week's travel time from Lima. The result is aptly summa- from a tobacco monopoly created in I766 6 (ibid., 4-5). Knight (2002,
rized by Walker: the Bourbon Reforms "dramatically changed relations 246} describes late Bourbon New Spain as "an overtaxed and overgov-
between Andean society and the state" in their initial phase (I999, 22). erned society" a description that could not apply to Chile, Colombia,
The Tupac Amarú revolt of the I78os, the most significant df a series or most regions of Peru.
of revolts that swept the heavily indigenous highlands, was a direct The colonial state's strength was also reflected in its rnilitary rnight.
response.4 The remainder of the colonial era was marked by state absence Boasting in I 800 an army largely brought from Spain of nearly w,ooo
in the highlands, as the Spanish colonial adrninistration "failed to recon- as well as a militia composed of members of the upper sectors of colonial
quer the region after the defeat of the rebels" (Walker I999, I3). In all, society that numbered greater than 22,000, the state was able to repress
the evidence suggests that the Bourbon Reforms initially greatlyincreased any unrest triggered by its exactions (Tenenbaum I986, 2; Knight 2002,
the intensity with which the colonial Spanish state imposed its presence 252). Revolts in Guanajuato in I767 (in response to the tobacco monop-
on the highlands, but that after the massive revolts this sparked, the state oly), and other, less severe uprisings in I798 and I804 (in response to
suffered a massive retreat which was not reversed before independence. 5 financia! impositions on the church) were met with intense repression
Thus, on the eve of independence, the Peruvian colonial state was just as (Tutino I986, w7). The control of the state did waver at its northern
weak as its Chilean and Colombian counterparts, and far weaker than frontier, where it exercised only lirnited oversight of its borders, and failed
the Spanish state in late colonial Mexico. to effectively subdue indigenous unrest (Knight 2002, 253ff). In addi-
tion, the army, where Spanish soldiers served alongside forced conscripts,
Mexico suffered from "demoralization and desertion" (253). But despite these
In New Spain, the Bourbon Reforms resulted in increased internal taxa- lirnitations, the coercive apparatus of the Spanish crown, like its extrac-
tion and a dramatically more powerful colonial administration as the tive power, was far more powerful in New Spain than anywhere else in
new royal dynasty sought to replace the "old give and take of Habsburg mainland South America. The unique success of the Bourbon Reforms
rule" with greater centralization (Knight 2002, 240). Of the four cases here is reflected in Domínguez's claim that they "brought unprecedented
under consideration, Mexico experienced the most intensive Spanish government control over the people" (I980, 74). Nothing of the kind
could have been said about any of the other cases.
In all, the record of the Bourbon Reforms reveals the fact that the
• The causes of the Tupac Amarú rebellion are the subject of majar debate among scholars.
Whereas Mallan (1983, 47-48) and Jacobsen (1993, 45) attribute ir to resistance to the Spanish colonial state had a very weak hold on much of its American
economic impositions of the Bourbons, Walker (1999) and others see ir as fundamentally territory. In Chile, the colonial state had little impact on society, while in
proto-nationalist. Yet ali agree that the Bourbon reforms were a key trigger.
s Mallan (1983, 48-49) characterizes the state as much more powerful in the silver mining
regions of the central highlands, where an earlier uprising had led the state to heavily 6
Unlike in Chile, where the tobacco monopoly generated little profit, ir quickly became
fortify the region. The remainder of the interior, however, saw significant retreat in the (despite, as in New Granada, facing sorne resistance) a significant revenue source in
decades befare independence. New Spain.
94 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence 95

Colombia and (especially) Peru attempts to increase penetration through royalists and patriots cut across class lines in Colombia, these divi-
colonial reform efforts prompted massive unrest, which led to state sions meant that independence quickly deteriorated into civil war during
retreat in the decades befare independence. The intensity of colonial rule the Patria Boba, as the period I8rn-I8I6 is known (Domínguez I980,
in Mexico was an exception. This pattern cannot account far the varia- 204). In all four cases, rather than a unifying force, the cause of indepen-
tion in state capacity observed as of I900, which saw the states of Chile dence deeply divided society. This division contributed to the ability of
and Mexico as far stronger than those of either Peru ar Colombia. the Spanish state to hold on to the colonies far so long despite the dam-
age it had suffered in the Napoleonic Wars. It also underlay the severe
post-independence crises in each case. 8
FOUNDATIONAL WARS, NEW STATES?
The decisive blows far independence (in all cases but Mexico) were
Nor can the nature of the wars far independence account far variation struck by a patriot army composed mostly of foreign nationals. The result
in state capacity. The independence conflicts in all four cases followed was that in no case <lid the mobilization of independence arrnies engen-
the same basic pattern. Overthrow of Spanish rule began with a sizable der signi:ficant state building. San Martín's march over the Andes into
revolt by part of colonial society, which divided the colony into royal- Chile - in which Chilean units "played no real part" :-led to the defeat of
ists and patriots as it succeeded in taking power and declaring indepen- Spanish forces in I8I8 (Collier and Sater I996, 3 5). Both San Martín and
dence.7 This was followed by a reconquest by Spanish forces, after which later Bolívar led arrnies into Peru. San Martín was urged by Lima's elites
brutal reprisals were committed against patriots and their supporters. to declare independence prematurely (royalist forces still controlled a
Royalist forces held power far several years, but as their base of sup- majority of the national territory) in the hopes that his mainly indigenous
port narrowed, they were overthrown, often by patriot forces invading troops and the perceived threat they posed - would withdraw from
from outside the colony. In all cases, the conflicts failed to generate the the city (Lynch I986, I79). Peruvian soldiers were present at the I824
national unity ar the infrastructural and extractive capacity by which Battle of Ayacucho that culrninated the independence conflict, but many
wars are said to make states, while inflicting massive econornic and social fought on the royalist side. The two armies of independence commanded
costs on the newly independent societies. Thus, the independence con- by Bolívar and San Martín were composed mostly of foreign troops, and
flicts founded independent countries, but not effective states to rule them. the Peruvian troops that <lid join these forces were particularly prone to
In all four cases, the struggle over independence created deep divisions desertion, being relatively clase to home (Bonilla 200I; Lynch I986). The
in society. In Mexico and Peru, the specter of class and ethnic conflict Bolivarian army that marched through the Llanos and over the Andes to
was raised from the moment independence appeared on the horizon. The defeat the Spanish at the I8I9 Battle of Boyacá and liberate Colombia
war of Mexican independence began with the Hidalgo revolt of I 8 rn, was composed of Venezuelan troops. It added Colombians - but only at
which started as protest against high food prices and rural labor market gunpoint: forced conscription, particularly of slaves from the gold mines,
conditions, but quickly turned into "vengeance" by the poor against the was used to :fill out the ranks. Only in Mexico was independence achieved
landed elites (Tutino I986, I29). In Peru, a wave of highland revolts after without foreign intervention. But it carne not due to massive domestic
I8o8 (highlighted by the I8I4 Pumacahua rebellion in Cuzco) made mobilization in support of the nationalist cause, but only after the col-
elites wary of the risks of social upheaval that could accompany the inde- lapse of Spanish forces, and by the decree of rnilitary leader Agustín
pendence conflict (Bonilla and Spalding 200I [I972]). In both cases, the Iturbide, who promptly crowned himself emperor. The foreign interven-
fear of lower-class revolt drove elites to the royalist cause initially, and tion and the internecine conflict that marked the independence period
made them reluctant to switch allegiance to the cause of independence. shows that these wars, which made the new Latín American countries
In Colombia and Chile, where the threat of indigenous revolt was lower,
independence arrived more quickly. In both cases, divisions between
8
This societal division casts doubt on the nationalisrn that is said (by Anderson [1983]
and Padgen [1987]) to ha ve fostered (or at least accornpanied) the ernergence of indepen-
1 In Mexico, as discussed in more detail later, the original revolt did not succeed in dence rnovernents. For views that persuasively question the extent of this nationalisrn, see
taking power. Harnnett (1977) and Adelrnan (2006).
State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence 97

in the sense of producing their independence, did not rnake states in the At the time of independence, then, states in all four countries were
sense of effective and powerful governing entities. largely unable to exercise any significant authority over population and
territory. This state weakness would persist for the next severa! decades,
as Latín Arnerica entered a profound crisis rnarked by regirne instabil-
POST-INDEPENDENCE CRISIS
ity, econornic stagnation, and social conflict (Halperín Donghi I973l· In
After independence arrived, the new states had to reckon with continued these decades of crisis, the quest for arder was pararnount: state lead-
fighting, and with the econornic and social costs of the preceding decade ers were unable to turn to other policy projects until the fundamental
of conflict. In Colombia and Chile, royalist holdouts engaged in guerrilla instability that rnarked all four countries had been resolved. Only after
warfare in large swaths of the national territory. The Guerra a Muerte arder had been achieved - more or less at rnid-century - did state leaders
in southem Chile (described in more detail later in this chapter) devas- undertake the efforts at state developrnent that are the subject of the next
tated the econorny's agricultura! base, lasting until I830 (Herr 200I). three chapters.
In Colombia, royalist guerrillas held on to the strategic region of Pasto Befare describing these efforts and explaining their success and failure,
until I825, preventing direct access between Bogotá and Quito. In Peru, we rnust consider the initial conditions frorn which state developrnent
a rnassive rebellion in the Huanta region took up the royalist banner and began. In so doing, an irnportant altemative explanation - that Chile and
established a quasi-state, collecting taxes, adrninistering justice, and even Mexico already had stronger states than did Peru or Colombia, which
rnobilizing rnanpower for road and bridge repair (Méndez 2005). rnade the efforts at state developrnent more likely to succeed - can be
No analogous regional rebellion plagued Mexico after indepen- disrnissed. The evidence shows that in the irnrnediate afterrnath of inde-
dence, although this would change by the I83os. Instead, the largest pendence, states in all four countries were weak: they were unable to
burden of the independence war in that country was the rnassive eco- effectively extract taxes frorn their populations, unable to provide secu-
nornic and social cost of the fighting: nearly IO percent of the popu- rity by preventing interna! conflict, banditry, and other forrns of violence,
lation was killed, rnining declined by 75 percent, and agriculture and and played no role in the education of their populations. 1 briefly surn-
industry fell by sirnilarly drarnatic levels as a result of pillage and cap- rnarize the record of the strength of these aspects of the state for the four
ital flight (Lynch I986, 326). Peru and Chile suffered signi:ficant but cases that follow, and highlight sorne exceptions to these broadly similar
lesser social and econornic darnage frorn the conflict; Colombia, on levels of weakness.
the other hand, suffered little when cornpared to these countries or to In showing that Chile and Mexico's states were no stronger than those
Venezuela (Bushnell I993, 48-49). These econornic costs were exacer- of Colombia and Peru in the early decades after independence, this dis-
bated as Spanish troops held on to key ports and coastal regions until cussion casts doubts on clairns that this variation predated the Liberal
the rnid-I82os, including Callao in Peru, Veracruz in Mexíco, and the era. The sirnilarly weak states found across all four cases also challenge
island of Chiloé in Chile. an objection to the institutional argurnent 1 developed in Chapter 2.
A final burden of the independence conflict was :fiscal: rather than lead- A skeptic rnight argue that the distinction between deployed and del-
ing to the developrnent of tax capacity, the necessities of the patriot cause egated rule is epiphenornenal because states varied in their capacity to
led to loans (forced and foreign) and seizure of property, arnong other deploy adrninistrators to the interior, and thus the recourse to deployed
forrns of ernergency finance. This had long-terrn consequences in terrns of rule reveals higher levels of state capacity. But this counterargurnent is
capital flight, dornestic and intemational debt, and political tensions as debunked by evidence of the abject weakness of state institutions in cases
the new states were unable to rnake salary payrnents to the rnilitary or to where deployed rule would emerge, like that of Chile and Mexico.
civil servants (Bushnell I954, 76ff). A particularly striking consequence
was the sale of Chile's naval vessels to Argentina irnrnediately after the
Education
end of the war. In Peru, the state's coffers were so ernpty that early years
after independence saw no governrnent dornestic spending whatsoever Although sorne schooling existed in each of the cases, it was vestigial at
(TantaleánArbulú I983). best. Public schools were rare outside the capital, standardization was
State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence 99

absent, and in all cases private education providers played a larger role Mexico
than did the state. In Mexico, too, education development was slow befare rnid-century.
Although national statistics are lacking, evidence suggests that public
primary education was lirnited. For example, Tanck de Estrada (1977,
Chile
197) cites a figure of only thirteen public primary schools in Mexico City
The first census of Chilean schools, carried out in January 1813, faund
in 1838, with an enrollment of l,240. Vaughan (1987) finds tenor fewer
only seven schools and 664 students in Santiago (Campos Harriet
public schools in Puebla, an important regional center, at various points
1960, 12). By 1830, Santiago still had only twenty-six schools (only
near mid-century.
faur of which were public) with a total enrollment of l,723. There was
Local jurisdictions and prívate actors, rather than the national gov-
little in the way of education elsewhere in the country, with the excep-
ernment, dominated primary schooling. Municipalities retained much
tion of a concentration of religious schools in Chiloé. (ibid., 16). The
authority over primary education far much of the nineteenth century,
l 8 3 3 Constitution declared public education a "subject far preferential
although the legal locus of policymaking varied across states. No single
attention from the state." A flood of legislation appeared to confirm this,
standard far teachers existed even within states. Teacher qualifications
as convents and monasteries were required by law to open schools, and
were assessed based on an exarnination given by local officials and nota-
a series of decrees guaranteed free education, textbooks, and school
bles, and the criteria varied widely (Bazant 1998, 63). Although normal
materials to all children. Yet the national governrnent devolved respon-
schools were opened in a variety of states, Staples (1992, 87) describes
sibility far education funding to municipalities, and its concrete actions
them as "ephemeral" and teacher training was far from systematized.
were nearly nonexistent. The state of Chilean education was aptly
More than any of the other cases explored in this study, prívate com-
summarized by Encina (vol. X, 3 lo, cited in Campos Harriet 1960,
panies were central to primary education in particular, the Compañia
lo): "the diligent effarts of governrnents to transfarm and extend the
Lancasteriana. This organization was faunded in 1822 by five prorninent
various branches of the education system represent ... a fireworks of
Mexico City residents, with the goal of bringing "modern" schooling to
laws, decrees, and measures which died befare they touched reality or
Mexico (Tanck de Estrada 1973). In 1842, the Santa Anna governrnent
remained latent waiting far better times." This would change beginning
placed all primary education in the country under its aegis, a role it main-
in the l84os, but befare that date, public primary education in Chile
tained until l 84 5. Even after that point, priva te actors played a central
was neither widely spread nor systematically organized.
role in teacher training. While education did grow slightly in the decades
after independence, the lack of state intervention and oversight is striking.
Colombia
Colombian education faundered after independence. Like many other Peru
aspects of administration, it was devolved to the local level, where it Despite lofty goals - espoused, far example, in Article 184 of the 1823
was overseen by officials who "appeared to be indifferent to the state of Constitution, which called far opening a university in every department
education" (Lay 1971, 276). Finance was also a majar issue, as munic- capital and a school in every town, and in the 1828 and 1834 consti-
ipal governrnents were unable to find the funds to open schools. The tution which guaranteed ·.free education to all citizens schooling in
church played a majar role in schooling, but even church schools were early republican Peru remained virtually nonexistent. Basadre (cited in
limited in number and poor in quality. In many provinces, enrollment Barrantes 1989, 69-70) cites primary schools in Lima and faur other
and even the number of schools declined in the decades after indepen- cities and three normal schools as the sum total of primary education
dence. In Casanare, far example, the number of schools fell from nine- in Peru in about 1840, and (as discussed in more detail in Chapter 4) in
teen to nine between 1839 and 1850, and the number of students from 1847 ten of the country's sixty-five provinces (and more than half of its
285 to 223 (Rausch 1993, 69). In all, public schooling was at least as 5 l 3 departments) contained not a single primary school. Thus, in terms
limited in Colombia as in the other countries in the early decades after of education, the Peruvian state in the early decades after independence
independence. had an extremely limited capacity to exercise control over its population.
roo State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence IOI

Taxation the least taxable economies of Latin America" (Deas 1982, 292 ). The lack
The weakness of the state's extractive capacity was particularly dramatic of commercial activity in the country led the state to limit taxation such
in Colombia and Mexico, although the states in Chile and Peru also as t?e a/cábala tax on sales transactions for fear that it would discourage
underwent severe fiscal crises in the fust two decades after independence. buswess development. Efforts to develop direct taxes during the Santander
In none of the four cases was the state able to extract revenue from society regime (r8r9-r826) foundered because of the lack of trained officials and
in the form of direct taxes, nor even genera te significant revenue from any the ease of evasion, and there was no significant progress made on this front
source other than customs revenues. The only deviation from this overall over the next several decades (Bushnell l 9 54, 8lff). Without significant cus-
pattern of state extractive weakness was the indigenous head tax in Peru, toms revenues, the state sought to fill its coffers with the salt, tobacco, and
which revealed that the Peruvian state was able to impose sorne degree of ~lcohol mo~opolie~ (in order of importance) that had been so unpopular
extraction on sorne segment of its population. rn the colomal penad. The head tax on the indigenous population failed
to generate si~c~nt revenues before its elimination in 1832 (Deas 198 2,
Chile 297-298). The limited revenue of the state is reflected in the fact that in
During the fust two decades after independence, government spend- 1835-1836, seignorage represented 29.9 percent of government revenues
ing was financed largely with debt, although the government struggled (McGreevey r97r, 40). Unable to tax internally, and without access to rev-
at times to make payments to foreign and domestic creditors. By the enues from a flourishing export sector, the Colombian state was forced to
mid-r83os, the state was able to generate sorne non-debt revenue, which turn to foreign loans, and to forced exactions of domestic wealth (Bushnell
carne mainly from duties on imports and exports. It also relied on rev- 1954, rr2). In all, the Colombian state's extractive power was minimal for
enues from its monopolies on salt, tobacco, and playing cards, but col- the fust decades after independence.
lections from these sources were limited because of smuggling (MHAC
Mexico
1835, 15-17). The tobacco monopoly was particularly troubled, suffer-
ing from a major corruption scandal in the late l82os and failing to gen- ~aving eliminated the Indian head tax immediately after independence
erate significant revenue. Although internal taxes were on the books, the m search of popularity, and having cut other domestic taxes to stimulate
state generated little revenue from them, finding the tithe (diezmo) hard the recovery of business, early republican governments in Mexico had
to collect because it required the assessment of property, and the excise to find alternative sources of revenue. A tobacco monopoly and taxes
tax (a/cábala) ineffective for revenue generation.9 Other revenue sources on exports generated more than 50 percent of total government collec-
such as stamps, official paper and seignorage generated negligible reve- tions in all but one year between l 8 2 5 and r 83 5. Export taxes failed to
nue. A real estate tax (the catastro) was introduced in 1834 in an effort ge?~rate the projected revenues, mostly because of the collapse of silver
to reduce reliance on customs duties and increase revenue, but its effects rmmng. They :ve~e assessed only in three ports, of which Veracruz was by
were limited. The Chilean state, in short, was unable to exercise sufficient far the most s1gmficant. Massive smuggling through other ports reduced
authority over its population in order to extract taxes, reflecting its lim- revenue. Another limit on federal revenue was posed by weak federal-
ited infrastructural power and forcing it to rely very heavily on revenues ism in the pre-1834 period: Tenenbaum estimares that 46 percent of tax
from foreign trade. revenue went into the coffers of individual states (1986, 23 ¡. Centralist
ª.dminist:ations after 1834 did no better, also failing to develop domes-
Colombia t1c taxat10n (Voss 1982). Direct taxes, originally imposed on property
Because of its limited export production and domestic commerce, and the and business during the 1836 Texas war, only generated between 3 and
long tradition of popular resistance to taxation, Colombia was "one of r7 percent of tax collections between 1836 and 1844, and once the costs
of collection were deducted, the contribution to government revenue was
9 Mamalakis (1976, vol. 6, 213) suggests that the alcábala was eliminated with indepen-
minimal. 10

dence and only reintroduced in l 83 5, but the records of the Ministerio de Hacienda show
evidence of its collection in earlier years. 'º Unless noted, ali figures in this paragraph come from Tenenbaum (1986).
102 State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence 103

Governments were forced to rely particularly heavily on short-term revenue (Gootenberg 1989, lOl). Actual revenue collections, however,
domestic loans with interest rates that sometimes reached 300 percent.II rarely matched these projections, demonstrating the lirnited ability of the
The providers of these loans, known as agiotistas, took over many state to extract revenue from the indigenous population. lJ Nevertheless,
state functions as a way to secure repayment, including road repair (in to the extent that the contribución indígena was collected, the Peruvian
exchange for toll receipts), currency conversion, negotiation of foreign state demonstrated greater extractive capacity in the early decades after
debt schedules, the postal service, and customs collections (Tenenbaum independence: it was the only one in which interna! taxation was at all a
1986). Although New Spain (as discussed previously) had seen effective significant imposition on the population, or a significant source of gov-
taxation imposed by the colonial state, the collapse of this system dur- ernment revenue.
ing the independence conflict was not followed by a post-independence
recovery. The fust decades after independence saw a weak state, suffering
Monopoly of Force
from "pernicious financia! anemia" and reliant on short-term loans and
other forms of emergency finance (Knight 1992, rn1). In all four countries, the inability to tax in the early decades after inde-
pendence was matched by an inability to impose order. All four cases saw
Peru states that were completely unable to exercise anything like a monopoly
The pattern of revenue sources in early republican Peru suggests that of coercion. The domestic disorder addressed here goes beyond com-
the state had a greater ability to extract taxes from its population than mon crime and insecurity to pose a challenge to the state's authority,
did states in the other cases. Yet its capacity should not be exagger- showing that the problem of establishing order was paramount in the
ated: as in the other cases, short-term finance and customs revenues post-independence crisis.
were crucial revenue sources. Short-term finance was generated by the
sale of state bonds on future customs duties to the merchant class, as Chile
well as forced loans. 12 Customs revenues (including both import and In addition to the Guerra a Muerte that dragged on for years after inde-
export duties) comprised a large proportion of state revenue for the pendence, lirnits to the Chilean state's monopoly of force were high-
period befare 1845 (Tantaleán Arbulú 1983, Appendix, Table 4). To lighted by a massive wave of banditry that swept the southern half of the
the extent that the state relied on these two types of revenue, we can country. The Pincheira brothers led a band of outlaws fighting a guerrilla
conclude that its reach over the national territory was lirnited, as it was war against the Chilean state until 1832. Their raids extended as far as
in the other cases. Mendoza, Argentina, and gripped the entire southern region (Herr 2001,
But the head tax on the indigenous population was also a major rev- 67ff). Their hold over such a vast territory made these bandits not only a
enue source, and this did make Peru an outlier. Collection of this tax regional menace but an obstacle to state organization and stability at the
required a significant capacity to oversee and penetrate society. This tax, nacional level. Only with the capture of the last Pincheira in 1832 was a
a fee imposed on each male of a certain age twice per year, was a leg- degree of arder achieved.
acy of the colonial era. Elirninated during the independence conflict as Another obstacle to establishing arder in the early decades after
a way to win indigenous support for the patriot cause, it was reinstated independence was that disputes among political elites often devolved
in 1826 and remained one of the largest sources of projected govern- into mass struggle. In the fighting between proponents of federalism
ment revenue until its elirnination in l 8 54. For example, the l 8 3 l bud- and centralism that culminated in the Battle of Lircay in 1830, both
get estimated that the head tax would generate one-third of government factions, particularly federalists, "enlisted provincial troops, local
peasants, and bandits to their causes" (ibid., 40). The state retained no

" Forced loans comprised another significant share of government revenues.


,, The extent of reliance on short-term debt is the subject of debate among historians. Its '3 A massive historiography debates the importance of the head tax for government rev-
role in state finance is emphasized by Gootenberg (1989, ro4ff) and minimized by Klarén enues in early republican Peru, although ali concede that it was a major imposition on
(2000, 138). highland society until its abolition. See Hünefeldt ( l 9 89) for a particularly skeptical view.
ro4 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence ro5

monopoly of force, and at times found an army (or at least individual Mexican state never enjoyed a monopoly of force in this entire period. It
officers and their units) unwilling to enforce the rule of law. The culmi- was only after mid-century that relative stability arrived.
nation of this trend was the military conspiracy of r 8 3 7, when Diego Two secessionist incidents posed majar domestic challenges to national
Portales, the country's most important political figure, was kidnapped integrity in the early years after independence; challenges more severe
and killed by a group of officers in the midst of the war against the than those that emerged in any of the other cases. The first began when
Peru-Bolivian Confederation. Thus, the state's monopoly of force was Texas declared independence shortly after the r 83 5 decision to enshrine
challenged by both non-state actors and divisions within its coercive centralism rather than federalism in the new constitution. Texan forces
apparatus. defeated local units of the Mexican army, as well as a punitive expedi-
tion led by Santa Anna himself, achieving and maintaining independence
Colombia with the help of the United States. This help, of course, resulted in the
Public arder was "nearly impossible" to establish in Colombia during the Mexican-American War of r846-r848, which saw Mexico lose a huge
decades after independence (McGreevey r97r, 87). Conflict was endemic share of its territory.
through the r82os, receding only in the r83os and r84os, which still saw Yucatecan autonomy movements, too, sought to separare the region
significant conflict in approximately ro percent of months and greater from its de jure attachment to the Mexican state on many instances
than 7,000 conflict deaths (ibid., Table 9 ). One attempt to limit the con- throughout the early decades of independence. For example, they issued
flict was to keep the peacetime army small and thus defuse central-federal their own constitution in r84r, created a flag, and declared Yucatán a
tensions, but this backfired as regional elites took advantage of the weak- sovereign nation (Reed r964, 29). Mexican troops were defeated twice
ness of the central state to assert their clairns to provincial autonomy. in their attempt to subdue restive regional elites. Yucatecan elites were
In response, as Posada-Carbó has argued for the case of the Caribbean only willing to place the region under national sovereignty when they had
provinces, the state often "had no choice but to rule with leniency" when exhausted every alternative means of defeating the Maya rebels of the
confronted by regional elites claiming authority (r996, 28-29). When Caste War. Even after formal sovereignty returned, the state's hold over
conflict emerged more along class and ethnic lines, the overwhelmed the region remained tenuous at best.
forces of the central state turned to provincial milicias to reassert arder. Order was also challenged by nearly constant peasant revolts. 4 In 1

Although effective, these forces were "defending [local] property rather addition to causing localized economic damage and loss of life, these
than [national] government" (Halperín Donghi r973, 9). In all, the peasant revolts often "provoked or merged with larger regional move-
Colombian state after independence enjoyed nothing like a monopoly of ments" (Coatsworth r988, 55). This peasant unrest, joined with and
force; it was more akin to a significant, and only sometimes dominant, facilitated by elite political conflicts, was a majar factor in the political
actor in a fairly competitive protection market. instability of the early republican period. Perhaps the most serious of
these revolts was the Caste War of the Yucatán. l5 Both fed by and con-
Mexico tributing to state weakness, peasant revolts would remain a feature of
Perhaps more than any of the other cases, the Mexican state's inability to Mexico for the whole of the nineteenth century (Katz r988, 9).
exercise a monopoly of force led to dramatic instability over the course
of the decades after independence. This time period was marked by wars Peru
of secession, waves of peasant revolts, and endemic banditry in many The limitations of the state's monopoly of force at independence were
regions. Even Fowler, who seeks to minimize the irnpact of this violence, quite severe in Peru. Long after the Spanish left the interior, and even
concedes that elites feared both loss of property and "social dissolution"
(2000, 66). His chronology of unrest (72ff) in the years r82r-r857 finds
14
episodes of political violence in every year, totaling at least 330 over the For an overview of these revolts, see Coatsworth (1988).
15
Although this conflict divided Yucatecan society on ethnic lines, Tutino (1986, 250--252)
period. Of these, thirty-two resulted in at least twenty deaths, and twelve highlights the fact that in its causes and process it closely resembled peasant revolts else-
directly resulted in changes of government. This data suggests that the where in Mexico.
106 State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence 107

after their 1826 abandonment of the fortress of Callao, highland com- in terms of public order. If the overall sirnilarity across cases shows that
munities continued to claim allegiance to the Spanish crown and refused the great gap in state capacity only emerged after mid-century, these few
to recognize independence. The most severe episode of this resistance differences show that legacies of the colonial era are not likely candidates
took place in Uchuraccay, a community in the highland province of for explaining it.
Huanta' 6 (Méndez 2005). Over severa! years in the l82os, rebels created
a "regional government of sorts run by its own laws and ruled by its own
EXPLAINING STATE ADMINISTRATIVE APPOINTMENT PRACTICES
authorities" (156). They were able to adrninister justice, mobilize man-
power for road and bridge repair, and even deploy tax collectors across If the post-independence context was so similar across the cases, what
a wide region to generate revenue from local landowners. As a result, were the origins of the divergent adrninistrative practices shown in
the Peruvian state was unable to exercise any control whatsoever in this Chapter 2? Why do we see the reliance on delegation to local elites
region, and although the movement was defeated, the state never pene- so much more often in sorne cases than in others? Without an answer
trated deeply enough into the rural areas to capture many of its leaders. to this question, the correlational evidence linking deployed rule and
The Huanta rebellion was unique only in the breadth of its challenge state-building success cannot be interpreted as supporting the claim that
to the state: many other regions of the country saw revolts, unrest, and deployed rule causes state-building success. '7
the inability of the state to maintain order. Security was a major issue, Although appointment decisions were made on a case-by-case basis,
for example, in the rnining regions of the central highlands, where mule three factors shaped the thinking of decision makers, leading them to
trains carrying rninerals to the port of Callao were often attacked. rely to a greater or lesser extent on delegation. State leaders knew that
The sfate's ability to establish a monopoly of force was lirnited because deployed rule would ensure more effective government. But this knowl-
of the nature of the army. Rather than a national force, Peru's army was a edge could not be translated into institutional choice, since appointrnent
poorly cohesive agglomeration of forces controlled separately by regional decisions were shaped by the context in which they were made. Three
caudillos. The presence of multiple regional armies in the country led to aspects of the context mattered in shaping the choices of administrative
constant conflict. There were, for example, at least seventeen revolts and appointment in these cases. First was the perception that revolts by the
conspiracies between 1829 and 1833. To prosecute these struggles, both lower classes and indigenous populations posed a systernic threat to the
regional caudillos and the national state were willing to rely on irregu- stability of the national state. Where this perceived threat was absent,
lar forces of peasants, conscripted by force or (less often) with prom- leaders could simply choose deployed rule. Where this threat was present,
ises of shares in the spoils of victory. These troops were poorly trained, state leaders would nevertheless take what they saw as a risk and turn to
unequipped, and prone to desert. Thus, the early republican army in Peru, deployed rule if they believed that their development projects depended
divided and reliant on conscripts, struggled to establish order in the coun- on underrnining local elites. The place of traditional elites in their vision
try, and faced severe challenges from non-state actors. Indeed, until the of development, in other words, was the second crucial factor. Third,
guano boom of the l 84os, achieving order would be the paramount con- where leaders feared upheaval from subaltern revolt, and were willing
cern of governments in Lima. to ally with local elites,· the currency of patronage used to cement this
The most important finding here is of an overall pattern of similar state alliance mattered. Where local elites were incorporated into ruling coali-
weakness in the aftermath of independence. But a few differences can be tions through political offices, deployed rule was possible because state
seen: the Peruvian state was something of a positive outlier in its extrac- leaders could reserve administrative positions for their appointees. But
tive capacity, and the Mexican state was something of a negative outlier
17
It is important, for the purposes of assessing concems about reverse causation, to empha-
size that the outcome of interest in this book is the state's ability to effectively imple-
16
Uchuraccay would become a beacon of the failure of the Peruvian state in the 198os, ment policies across its national territory. Thus evidence that sorne other aspect of state
when its residents murdered eight journalists in the apparent belief that they were mem- "strength" (which is a broad umbrella concept used in many divergent ways) faci!itates
bers of the Sendero Luminoso guerrilla forces. Méndez (2005) argues that the roots of deployed rule is a direct threat to my argument only to the extent that the two aspects of
the state's absence in this region are fundamentally historical. state strength are closely related.
I08 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence I09

TABLE 3.I. Explaining the emergence of deployed and delegated rule systemic unrest (as in Chile) was sufficient to induce state leaders to opt
Guano-Era
for deployed rule. Where this fear was intense, leaders' choices depended
Chile Liberal Post-I895 Porfirian
Mexico Pero Mexico Peru on the other factors discussed later.

Subaltern threat to No Yes Yes Yes Yes


Chile
systemic stability? As Chilean national leaders built their bureaucracy during the second
Traditional elite No No Yes Yes
power seen as
half of the nineteenth century, they did so without any fear of systernic
compatible with upheaval. To sorne degree, this belief was based on the historical record.
development In Chile, no majar insurgency colored the late colonial period, and the
project? independence conflict cut across social divisions in the country, rather
Elite support bought No Yes
than polarizing thern. Although it was an intemecine conflict, it did
via political
not include a rnajor uprising by the rural poor as it had in Mexico, nor
patronage?
Outcome Deployed Deployed Deployed Deployed Delegated did it divide elites as deeply as did the independence conflict in Peru.
But crucially, this perception that national institutions were not threat-
This table shows that the three factors are individual/y necessary and jointly sufficient ened by subaltem uprisings took hold despite two types of significant
to explain the choice of delegated rule. Unless ali three were present, the outcome was
deployed rule.
upheaval: rnassive waves of banditry in the southem heartland, and
waves of conflict with the Mapuche indigenous population on the as-yet
unclosed southem frontier. Chile was far frorn calrn in the fust half cen-
where coalitions were cernented with administrative posts, leaders had no tury after independence, but unrest and violence did not scare state lead-
choice but to opt for delegated rule. These three factors, as scored for the ers enough to affect their institutional design choices.
cases, are arrayed in Table 3.I, which shows the logic of the discussion The rnost drarnatic rnanifestation of violence was nearly a decade of
that follows. guerrilla war after the final declaration of independence in Santiago. This
war, known as the Guerra a Muerte (War to the Death), was first fought
by Mapuche communities who were concemed with the changes that
Perceived Threats to Systemic Stability independence might bring to the entente they had developed with the
Where state leaders feared that revolt by rural subaltem populations Spanish colonial state, and then by bandits, rnost notably the Pincheira
would be truly destabilizing, they needed powerful allies at the local level, brothers, in an alliance with a Mapuche subgroup (Bengoa I985).
and this led thern to fortify their ties to local elites. A likely option for More generally, Chile's countryside was assailed by rnassive waves of
state leaders was to incorpora te local elites into the bureaucracy - i.e., by crirne against persons, property, and state institutions throughout the
establishing delegated rule. Delegation would build an alliance between mid-nineteenth century; reports by governrnent officials frorn the fust
the central state and these elites, reducing the chances of elite defection decades after independence refer to a great deal of banditry. But this was
that could turn subaltern unrest into regional rebellion. Administrative never seen as a threat to the national state but solely as a threat to local
positions would also strengthen the hand of local elites in responding order and econornic stability. Police were scarce outside urban areas, and
to unrest in their communities by adding the legitirnacy that carne with the arrny was often called into duty to cornbat these depredations, which
office-holding to their reservoir of local authority. State leaders had to were rnost severe in the south. As Bengoa (I999, I54) described, the
consider forgoing the benefits of deployed rule when they needed to but- "state of the south" was not consolidated to the sarne extent as the "state
tress the power of elites who would help maintain order and social hier- of the center," as state leaders focused on the booming mining regions of
archy at the local level. On the other hand, where this fear was absent the north. Through rnuch of the mid-nineteenth century, there were years
and state leaders -C:onsidered the political context to be fairly stable, they in which one could not travel between Talca and Chillan, or through the
saw no reason to adopt delegated rule. Thus, the absence of a threat of province of Aconcagua, beca use of bandits (Monteverde I999 ). Insecurity
llO State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence lll

in this region intensified in the aftermath of the l 8 59 Revolution, when than as a separate ethnic group, and until the rnid-nineteenth century "the
members of the defeated forces took to the hills to wage a campaign of dorninant view was that Araucanía formed part of the national territory
guerrilla warfare against the Chilean state, and made "pillage" and armed and that the Mapuche, although a different nation, should forro part of
robbery common in various parts of the country, mainly the southern the broad national brotherhood" (ibid., 87).
agricultura! regions between Santiago and the Mapuche frontier (MINT The rise of liberal-positivist ideas in the l 84os began to alter this
1860, 19). The rural regions of the province of Talca, for example, were view, emphasizing that the lack of legal uniforrnity that allowed the
"notorious" as the refuge for bandits who plagued landowners and small Mapuche to govern themselves under long-outdated colonial laws was
communities in the surrounding area (MINT 1865, Vol. II, 137). a threat to equality. The Mapuche decision to side with the rebels in the
Yet despite this clear lack of calm in much of the country, elites in failed 1851 Revolution provided the pretext of a "threat'? that could
Santiago didn't fear for national stability. Even the Guerra a Muerte, motívate occupation by land speculators supported by the state, but this
which swept large sections of the southern heartland for a full decade, threat was more a justification than a real concern (Pinto Rodríguez
did not scare state elites, despite the fact that recent commentators have 2003, l51ff). The assirnilation policy that followed was driven largely
described itas a threat to national stability (Bengoa 198 5 ). This conflict by econornic changes rather than by the perception that the indigenous
was seen not as a case of an oppressed group, but as a problem of public posed a fundamental threat to the state orto social order. º The expan- 2

order where the state confronted "traitors who broke established rules of sion of the Chilean agricultura! economy and of state institutions into
conduct and therefore needed to be eliminated." 18 Officials in Santiago the territories occupied by the Mapuche prompted serious unrest on the
were confident that extirpating individual bandit leaders would elirninate southern border. The insecurity was highest in three waves: an "almost
the source of the conflict. This conflict, in short, was seen as episodic, total uprising of the mapuches" (Bengoa 1999, 169) coincident with the
rather than endernic. 1 9 1859 Civil War, a majar insurrection in 1868-1869, and another upris-
Tensions with the Mapuche, too, were seen in the same light. Chile ing that began in l 8 8 l. 21
is often erroneously lumped in with Argentina as an ethnically homoge- The first significant wave of unrest in the region began with the par-
neous "European fragment" in which the indigenous population, already ticipation of many bands of Mapuche in the 18 59 Civil War. The "gue- 22

small, was elirninated. And we rnight imagine that homogeneity rnight rilla war" this prompted lasted until the end of 1861, and the army was
account for this perception of relative security among Chilean elites. But "unable to do anything but resist sorne of the attacks" (Ruiz-Esquide
this was not the case Chile was far more ethnically complex than was 2000, 123 ). The effects of the violence cut a broad swath through the
Argentina, and relations between the state and the indigenous population southern frontier: the important town of Los Angeles (as well as other
were tense. Most important for our purposes was the Chilean state's com- communities) had to be abandoned, and every Chilean settlement south
plicated relationship with the Mapuche community, which occupied ter- of the Bio-Bio was destroyed. Ruiz-Esquide (2000, 128) claims that
ritory on the southern frontier that the Chilean state had never effectively 35,000 cows, 50,000 sheep, and 5,000 horses were lost, as well as more
penetrated. The Mapuche and the state had a long entente (since about than l rnillion pesos of damage to agricultura! production. This was the
1640) on the unfinished frontier dating back to the early colonial era, and
thus the waves of unrest described previously were seen as continuity in
a fluid and complex relationship (Pinto Rodríguez 2003, 31ff). Until the '"' The efficacy of the post-186os assimilation effort, although beyond the scope of this
rnid-nineteenth century, the Mapuche were seen as fundamentally Chilean. project, reveals the strength of the Chilean state. Until a certain degree of indigenous
rnobilization in the last severa] decades (Mallon 2005 ), the limited salience of indigenous
O'Higgins and other independence-era leaders had talked of the Mapuche identity in Chile reveals a state that (as in Eugen Weber's [1978] landmark study of
(and other indigenous communities) as citizens of the new republic rather France) was able to assert control over its population and impose homogeneity on its
national cornmuniry.
2
' HEC 7, 265-266 refers to another such wave of banditry during the 1891 Civil War and
'8 Herr (2001, 92) cites this language in state docurnents of the time. its aftermath, although it seems to have been less severe.
•9 I borrow the language of episodic and endernic conflict frorn Slater (2010) who argues 22
The participation of indigenous groups on both sides of this conflict mirrored the pattern
that only the latter will drive the ernergence of state-building coalitions. of the less significant fighting during the l 8 51 Civil War.
112 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence 113

most significant outbreak of violence in southern Chile since the Pincheira lived far from the frontier. 4 This equanimity also had ideational roots -
2

revolts three decades earlier. as liberal positivism took hold in Chile, it brought a belief that progress
The increased southward pressure of Chilean agriculture prompted a would obviate the ethnic divisions over time, bringing a natural end to
second majar wave of violence in 1868-1869. 2 3 Indigenous communities fighting.
amassed a force of about 6,ooo to attack settlers, a force much larger The important thing far our purposes, however, is that political elites'
than the Chilean army presence in the region of sorne l,400 men. This perception of systemic stability existed despite rather intense unrest in the
prompted a harsh response from the Chilean army. In late 1868 and early south. This perception did not derive from the fact that the Chilean state
1869, Chilean army units of lOO to l,200 soldiers carried out twenty-one already enjoyed effective control over its national territory. It derived,
expeditions against Mapuche communities, killing more than 200, injur- instead, from the belief that unrest and violence in the south posed no
ing a similar number, taking nearly lOO prisoners, and capturing more endemic and unmanageable threat. Because Chilean state leaders did not
than 12,000 animals (which were sold to pay far the operations) at the perceive the same degree of social unrest and política! instability as did
cost of thirty-five killed soldiers. their Mexican and Peruvian counterparts, the choice to rely on deployed
The third wave of violence on the southern frontier coincided with rule, which promised reliably laya! bureaucrats, was an easy one. This
the War of the Pacific, which saw the deployment of the Army of the alone, then, was suf:ficient to determine the institutional outcome of
South to Peru and its replacement with less effective National Guard deployed rule in Chile.
units from the communities of Angol, Malleco, Tijeral, and Curaco
(HEC 4, 279). This opportune context fostered a wave of Mapuche Mexico
uprisings in 1881 and 1882, which escalated to include the cutting Nineteenth-century state leaders in Mexico, by contrast, perceived majar
of telegraph lines and attacks on many Chilean settlements. Chile threats from peasant unrest. These views were shaped both by memo-
responded with a determination to achieve the final pacification of ries of revolts past and by majar indigenous revolts in the present. The
the region. This final conflict involved thousands of troops recently Mexican independence struggle was the "most plebeian of the Spanish
returned from the fighting in Peru, and culminated with the capture of American revolutions," marked by a massive lower-class uprising that
Villarica in l 8 8 3. threatened to eliminate elite control (Halperín 1973, 4). The memory
Yet despite decades of violence, contention, and massive military cam- of the independence-era Hidalgo rebellion lived on in the minds of state
paigns on the southern frontier, and despite the fact that the Mapuche leaders, and its salience was reinforced by active indigenous unrest that
conflict was seen as endemic, it was not perceived as a threat to Chilean persisted long after the independence era.
state stability. Pinto Rodríguez (2003, 84-8 5) shows that presidents carne The most salient instance of indigenous uprising was undoubtedly the
into of:fice concerned about it, but it became less of a policy priority (as "Caste War" of the Yucatan, but early republican Mexico also saw vio-
reflected in public speeches) over the course of their terms. The equa- lence by indigenous populations along the northern border and in the
nimity with which this conflict was viewed may have had geographic mountain regions of central Mexico (Bazant 1991). Indeed, early repub-
roots. There was no sense that the Mapuche were interested in, or capa- lican Mexico saw nearly constant peasant revolts (Coatsworth 1988).
ble of, marching on Santiago, ar that the conflict could spread north- Beyond causing localized economic damage and loss of life, these peas-
ward to important population centers. Indeed, the location of the conflict ant revolts often "provoked or merged with larger regional movements"
moved steadily further from the national center over time as the frontier (Coatsworth 1988, 55). Rebellions by indigenous and peasant commu-
expanded southward. It posed no direct threats to elites in the capital, or nities remained endemic well into the Por:firiato, including the Yaqui
to any signi:ficant portian of the wealthy sectors of Chilean society, who Rebellion of 1896 (DeHart 1984) and a majar revolt in Chihuahua in
1891 (Vanderwood 1998).
'3 My discussion of this wave of fighting draws on the detailed account in Esquide-Ruiz
(2000, I94ff), which summarizes the findings of Bengoa and other scholars as well as '-' Bauer (I975), in his survey of rural life in Chile's central valley during the nineteenth
prirnary source accounts of the violence. century, never rnentions the issue.
II4 State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence II5

The salience of conflict involving lower classes dampened política! such as Thurner and Mallan about negotiation between the state and
conflict between elites, which emerged only when "social subversion" subalterns find particular resonance in highland Peru. This fear also led
was no longer an imminent danger (Bazant I99I, 27). The fear of revolts to the surveillance and control of the indigenous population by local and
among elites can be seen in their política! behavior. Most dramatically, national officials, including careful observation of popular participation
it was revealed in the reluctance of Liberals and Conservatives to rally in festivals in Cuzco (Walker I999, I79ff). Passports for domestic travel
Mexico's massive indigenous peasantry to their cause throughout their were required of the indigenous population until I8 5I (Davies I970, 28).
decades of intra-elite conflict. Only the war against the French led elites Fear also underlay the projects pursued by guano-era state leaders and
to risk unrest by calling on the lower classes to join the struggle - and their Civilista analogs: in addition to prosperity, the goal of development
"again, once organized, the popular movements did not show signs of efforts was a transformation of the "savage" indigenous population,
subsiding quickly" (Katz I99I, 53). to turn them from a threat and economic deadweight into productive
members of a "civilized" and "modern" society. While the thinking of
Peru state leaders often emphasized the need to protect and incorporare the
As in Mexico, the specter of systemic revolt loomed large in the minds indigenous population, the threat posed by this group was omnipresent
of Peruvian state leaders. Memories of the Tupac Amaru revolt of the in their calculations. 26 The threat of indigenous unrest, in other words,
I78os "served as an example of what could happen" (Davies I970, 4). was just as salient in the minds of Peruvian leaders as it was among
Independence era rebellions in Cuzco and elsewhere also reminded lead- their Mexican counterparts. In both countries, leaders had to weigh the
ers of the unrest that appeared constantly latent in highland regions. stability of social hierarchies against the establishment of reliably loyal
Upsurges of contention from below seemed to emerge whenever gaps bureaucracies. Yet while Peruvian and Mexican leaders faced the identi-
opened in national stability, whether during the Bourbon Reforms, the cal dilemma, they responded differently.
independence era, moments of elite conflict, or (most notably) the period A skeptical reader might argue that the perception of threat was
of Chilean occupation that followed the War of the Paci.fic. The fear of related to demography - the size of the indigenous population, in a more
another Tupac Amaru revolt persisted even during the period of "remark- parsimonious argument than the one I develop, might explain adminis-
able indigenous quiescence" that !asted from the unrest in the after- trative choice. After ali, Chile did have a smaller and more geographically
math of the independence struggle to the Huancané rebellion of I866 isolated indigenous population than did the other countries. But even if
(Gootenberg I993, I99). we grant this claim, the demographic argument cannot account for the
When signi.ficant violence of any kind did break out, it was consis- difference in form of rule between Mexico and Peru, which had different
tently seen by large sectors of Lima of:ficialdom through the lens of "caste forros of rule despite sirnilarly sized indigenous populations. Nor can it
wars," "Indian massacres," and "racial terror." The I88 5 Atusparia rebel- account for change over time in Peru. The choice of institutions of state
lion, the largest since independence, reignited these fears first instilled administration is not simply reducible to demographic factors.
by the Tupac Amaru revolt and "left an indelible mark of dread on elite Nor is deployed rule, as one might expect, a function of preexist-
consciousness" (Thurner I997, rn3). Elsewhere in the highlands, land- ing levels of state capacity. Indeed, there are severa! reasons to doubt
owners "constantly feared attacks" (Jacobsen I993, 327), and were thus this claim of reverse causation. First, as the earlier parts of this chapter
reluctant to mobilize the indigenous population. 2 5 showed, the Chilean state was fundamentally weak in the decades after
When considering policies that impinged on the indigenous independence, differing little from the other cases. Second, the histori-
population - most notably taxation and forced labor - of:ficials were con- cal record shows serious unrest in Chile, but this unrest did not trans-
stantly sensitive to the threat of revolt. Indeed, the insights of historians late into elite fear. Third, the Mexican state was particularly weak in
terms of coercive capacity, but (for reasons discussed later) its leaders
2
s Elites did mobilize indigenous commumnes in episodes of domestic conflict in
26
post-independence Huanta and sorne parts of the Central Highland (Méndez 2005; Thus Gootenberg's claim of a "national amnesia" about the indigenous population dur-
Mallan 1983, 48-49). ing the guano era seems a bit overstated (1993, 199-200).
116 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence 117

opted for deployed rule. Finally, deployed rule was introduced in Peru 25; Haber 1989, 19). During deliberations at the 1857 Constitutional
after 1895 in a moment of state crisis far more severe than any of the Congress, many politicians decried the power of caudillos, and the docu-
guano-era moments, an outcome that cannot be explained by preexisting ment that emerged included many clauses that challenged the power of
state capacity. local elites (ibid., 67-68). It was clear after 1857 that the full flourishing
of the Liberal project would depend on reducing the authority of provin-
The Place of Traditional Authority in National Projects cial elites. This "antielite rhetoric" worsened relations between Liberals
and elites, even as many elites "approved of key elements of the Liberal
Where indigenous populations and lower classes did pose a fundamental program" (Chowning 1999, 245).
threat to stability, state leaders confronted a complex tradeoff. In Mexico Sinkin argues that the Liberals initially "sought the total destruc-
and Peru, state leaders had to choose between deployed rule, which had tion" of the local power of provincial elites (1979, 97). The radical
the risk of undercutting local elites and facilitating mass uprising, and rhetoric of Liberal leaders, and their threatening actions, left elites
delegated rule, which weakened state power by diluting the implemen- disenchanted with poli tics and "drove many of them to the politi-
tation of state policies. State leaders were swayed toward delegation or cal sidelines" during the Liberal era (Chowning 1999, 246). Liberal
deployment depending on two factors. The first, discussed here, was the land reforms inflicted majar costs on longtime, cash-poor landown-
place of traditional elites in the ideological views of national leaders. ers by replacing the church with prívate creditors (Chowning 1999,
Where state leaders' view of the means to "arder" and "progress" saw 271-273 ). Liberals "most approved" of haciendas "that were being
traditional elites as a central obstacle, they were unwilling to ally with worked intensively by owners or renters willing to experiment with
them. But where local elites were not seen as a threat to the transforma- new crops and new activities, buy new equipment, and invest large
tions sought by state leaders, an alliance based on administrative delega- sums in increasing production" (ibid., 237). There, practices were not
tion was possible. characteristic of traditional landowners. ¡¡
Because early and late state-builders in Mexico and Peru saw local Liberals did come to need many local powerholders, including tradi-
and regional elites differently, here 1 periodize the discussion into two tional landowners, as allies in the Reform War and the subsequent strug-
eras in each country. In Liberal Mexico (1857-1876) and Civilista Peru gle against the French lntervention. The decade of conflict that followed
(189 5-1919 ), state leaders believed that development depended on the proclamation of the 18 57 Constitution made Liberals "almost totally
underrnining local elites; to ally with them would undo a core element of dependent on the good will and rnilitary expertise of these local chiefs"
their state-building efforts. Despite their fears of unrest, they were unwill- (Sinkin 1979, rn5 ). Thus, although "the ultimate goal of the Reform pro-
ing to ally with local elites, choosing instead to risk revolt and supplant gram was the destruction of the traditional caudillo system of politics,"
them in pursuit of what they saw to be long-term development projects. Liberals were forced to temper their transformationist zeal and ally with
By contrast, state leaders during the Mexican Porfiriato (1876-19rn) and traditional elites. As Hale (1989, 22) pithily states, "liberalism ceased
the guano era (1845-1879) in Peru did not see traditional elites asan [after 1867] to become a combative ideology." lndeed, by the end of the
obstacle to their visions of development, and thus they were willing to Restored Republic, elites and liberals had mended their relationship.
consider delegation as a solution to the unrest they feared. Liberals emphasized "relatively uncontroversial, indeed greatly desirable
projects from the elite point of view" such as material improvements,
Anti-Traditional Ideology in Liberal Mexico (I857-I876) tax reductions, and the abolition of ludian communities, and many eco-
During the Restored Republic, tensions between Liberal state leaders nornic elites aligned themselves firmly in the Liberal camp (Chowning
and traditional elites were significant. Although they were also fixated on 1999, 304). This version of liberalism was "discursively inclusive" (ibid.,
the power of the church and the communal landholding institutions of 3 32) and modera te in comparison to the pre-reform version.
Indian communities, Liberals believed that transforrning Mexico required During the period of Liberal rule, then, state leaders believed that
elirninating the hacienda, replacing it with small landholders, to create their state-building project depended on the weakening of traditional
the rural social conditions for economic modernization (Sinkin 1979, authority. This made them reluctant to delegate administration to local
II8 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence ll9

caudillos. Direct threats to their hold on power forced the Liberals to ally on them to represent the state in the national periphery. 7 Gootenberg 2

with these opponents of their project in order to defeat the French and finds that they developed a project of "traditional modernization" (1993,
consolidate power. But crucially, even as this alliance endured through 8) that was practical and flexible rather than ideological. None of the
the Restored Republic, state leaders sought ways to weaken the local thinkers he discusses - which include many irnportant members of the
power monopolíes of caudillos, and they made significant progress by guano-era political class such as Manuel Pardo - saw rural elites as an
1876. This focus on weakening traditional elites made Liberal leaders in obstacle to development. Many (including Pardo) believed that guano
Mexico reluctant to rely on delegated rule despite their concerns about wealth provided an opportunity to transform society precisely by improv-
systemic stability. This was sufficient to explain why they tended to opt ing the economic condition of these oligarchs through the promotion of
for deployed rule. non-guano exports. 28 This project of regional developmentalísm would
draw the country together, bringing local elites into alliance with the state
The Absence of Ideology in Porfirian Mexico (I877-I9Io) and repairing the breaches of regionalist tensions from the pre-guano era.
Unlike the Liberals he succeeded, Porfirio Díaz did not see economic (Larson 2004, 150) Elites in the central and southern highlands were a
elites asan obstacle to the change he sought in Mexico. In turn, elites sup- particular focus of this effort.
ported the "order and progress liberalism" that Díaz promised to bring In political terms, the Civilista project of the l86os and l87os "was an
(Chowning 1999, 305). Justo Sierra and other Porfirian political thinkers attempt to extend the fundamental accord that existed [among the bour-
believed that economic elites, who had a stake in the decisions made by geoisie] to notables throughout the country." (Muecke 2004, 37) Indeed,
the government, should be involved in it (Hale 1989). Unlike their Liberal Pardo's party organization and campaign for the 1872 presidential elec-
predecessors, these self-styled "Conservative Liberals" (also known as tion created a national community of notables, integrating "regional and
científicos) believed that elites were a "great potential force" for stabil- provincial elites" into the state. (ibid., 38) The 1873 decentralization was
ity (ibid., 35). Thus while two prominent Liberals in 1893 decried the a demonstration of this development model. As Muecke (38) describes,
"tyranny of the upper classes" (Hale 1989, n7), Díaz was assiduously it gave "the provincial elites a free rein in their districts." Because their
building ties with elites who controlled state and local politics. Although vision of development did not depend on weakening the local authority
the state intervened little if at all in providing social policy, it engaged in of traditional elites, state leaders in Peru were willing to rely on these
what Haber (1989, 23) describes as extensive government intervention notables as local and regional administrators.
to benefit the powerful. As Chowning shows, elites were happy to be
courted by the regirne, although they remained outside the formal politi- Anti-Traditional Ideology in Postwar Peru (r895-r9r9)
cal arena (1999, 334-335). Horrified by the loss in war to Chile and the tumult that followed, the
The Liberals had been reluctantly pulled to focus on practicality Civilistas were determined to take a different approach to national
as opposed to grand ideas. But Porfirio Díaz represented "the end of reconstruction than that of their predecessors. The Cáceres government
ideology." As Knight writes, he "displayed more appetite for power than of the immediate postwar period had sought political stability and fis-
adherence to principie" (1986, 1, 15). Thus he had no commitments to cal recovery vía radical decentralization that empowered local elites.
grand social transformation that precluded alliances with local power- The consequences, both in fiscal terms and in terms of stability, were
holders. Ideology, then, played no crucial role in determining the forro strikingly negative, as highlighted by the weakness of the state during
of local administration during the Porfiriato. State leaders were willíng this period shown in Chapters 4-6. The Civilistas concluded from this
to cement security by allying with local elites, although this did not (for experience that decentralization was a fundamentally flawed administra-
reasons explained later) lead to delegated rule. tive model, and that the empowering of local elites had also undermined

Accomodationist Ideology in Guano-Era Peru (r845-I875) 27 In the same vein, Peruvian liberals also incorpora red church and Indian communal struc-
Because state leaders during the guano era in Peru did not see local elites tures in their visions of progress and social transformation (Muecke 2004, 13).
as an obstacle to development, they did not find it inappropriate to rely 28 Pardo's "national project" is similarly described in McEvoy (1994).
I20 State Building in Latín America Colonialism and Independence I2I

state-development effarts during the prewar period. The crisis of the building, elites could be incorporated through seats in elected office. This
preceding decades farged a broad consensus that Peru needed drastic allowed state leaders to cement alliances with local elites and ameliorate
changes in arder to survive as a nation, and that "the country had squan- their fears of revolt, while still allowing administration to be populated in
dered seventy years of independent existence" (Contreras and Cueto a manner likely to produce more effective governance. Porfirian Mexico
1999, 142-143). Thus, they were determined to chart a new course. followed this pattern, leading to deployed rule. But where the currency of
For Piérola and the Civilistas, national reconstruction depended on the patronage was administrative office, those positions were given to local
removal of local elites from positions of authority and the establishment elites, and were not available far deployed rule. Alliances in guano-era
of centralized administration. 2 9 Although centralization was in part an Peru were cemented with administrative appointments, and this (along
ad hoc response to the failures of administrative and fiscal decentraliza- with the two factors discussed previously) explains why delegated rule
tion and to the weakening of local elites during the preceding decades, was adopted in that case alone among those studied in this book.
its central place in the Civilista governing program was a consequence of
their ideological commitment to national transfarmation through state Political and Federal Patronage in Mexico
building (Contreras 200 l). Thus, an explicit plank of Civilista adminis- Mexican state leaders had access to three patronage options in wooing
tration was an effart to weaken the hold of local elites over the peripheral elites to their coalitions: regional and local power in Mexico's federal
regions of the country. State leaders saw the power of local elites as prob- system, elected office in the national government, and appointments to
lematic in two senses. First, it allowed these elites to abuse the indigenous the national bureaucracy. Both Liberal and Porfirian state leaders used
population, which contributed to unrest (Mallan 1983 ). Second, local only the first two to build ruling coalitions. Few positions in the national
elites were seen as ineffective administrators by contrast to the educated bureaucracy were used to buy elite loyalty, and this allowed the national
coastal core of the Civilista coalition, a view buttressed by the failures state to fill its administration with deployed rule because the need far
of education development, tax collection, and the suppression of revolts patronage had already been satisfied.
in the postwar period (Thurner I997). The view that empowering local The most important mode of incorporation of elites into the ruling
elites was an obstacle to state development led to an effort to eliminare coalition took place through elected office (Knight 1986, I, 20). The cen-
delegated rule. Instead, the Civilistas explicitly sought to transfarm Peru's tral axis of Restored Republic politics was ins against outs, and the posi-
administration with the imposition of deployed rule where they could. tions at stake were largely political. Perry (1978) argues that the política!
Thus in post-1895 Peru and Liberal Mexico, deployed rule emerged machine built by Juárez and his successors in Mexico revolved around
because of beliefs that traditional elites were an obstacle to political elected offices. The introduction of the Senate in 1874 was one exam-
development and stability. But in Porfirian Mexico and guano-era Peru, ple of Liberal efforts to use elected office to win over elites: it "provided
the choice of farm of rule was not fully accounted far by the factors dis- fifty well-paid sinecures to be distributed among hand-picked partisans"
cussed thus far. To account far the different patterns in these cases, we (Perry 1978, 183). Díaz continued this pattern: he ensured elite access to
need to examine the nature of patronage. most national political positions (Camp 199 5, 173ff). The centrality of
political office in state-elite relations in Mexico can be seen most clearly in
the salience of the slogan of "no re-election." As Perry (1978, 187) traces,
The Currency of Patronage
this slogan carne into use in 1867 because elites such as Porfirio Díaz
The third and final factor shaping the choice of deployed or delegated resented exclusion from the Liberal political machine.
rule was the nature of patronage used to incorporate local elites into rul- Another means of incorporating elites was state-level patronage. Both
ing coalitions. Where political positions were the currency of coalition Liberals and Porfirio Díaz faced opposition from local and regional-level
elites. To co-opt these caudillos and hacendados, national leaders often
2
9 Civilista concems about local power monopolies were centered oo the highlands regions
appointed them as governors (Perry 1978, 5-6). The governor had con-
that had seeo the most unrest in preceding decades. Less concern was expressed about the trol over state-level bureaucratic appointments (ibid., 97). Importantly,
power of local elites in the north coast regioos from which most Civilistas were drawn. however, governors themselves were often deployed to states where they
122 State Building in Latin America Colonialism and Independence 123

had few local ties. While they built local bureaucratic machines, state centralized and hierarchical nature of the party made local and regional
executives owed much of their power to the president rather than to party officers subject to national offices, giving those outside the national
local society. Thus, elites were rewarded far supporting the regime, but junta little power. Because they sought to domínate elected office, politi-
in a way that removed them from their local bases. Knight estimares that cal party leaders chose not to use access to those positions as they built
70 percent of Díaz-era gubernatorial appointments were "presidential their coalitions. The resulting reliance on administrative patronage is
favorites imported into alíen states where their prime allegiance was to the final element in accounting far the adoption of delegated rule in
their president and maker rather than to their provincial subjects" (1986, guano-era Peru.
I, 17). Pittman (1989) provides a detailed account of tensions around the
deployment of a governor in Morelos. Conflict between the governor and
CONCLUSION
local elites revolved around administrative appointments, as governors,
too, used deployed rule to consolidare authority against the large land- Befare proceeding to the coming chapters, which provide a comparative
owners in the state (pp. 32, 39-40, 122-123). analysis of state building in the faur cases, it is worth reinforcing what
Thus, Mexican political machines encompassed elected office at the we've learned so far. First, this chapter has shown that Latín or American
national level and many subnational positions. But many subnational states in general were quite weak at independence, and little changed in
administrative positions were filled via deployment, and positions in the the first few decades after c9lonial rule ended. The evaluations of three
national bureaucracy were less commonly allocated to local elites. This dimensions of state capacity across four countries in the third part of
allowed Porfirian state leaders to both fill the ranks of the bureaucracy this chapter showed striking sirnilarities, with partial exceptions appear-
through deployed rule, and to combine robust ties with elites and the ing in the greater extractive capacity of the Peruvian state (through the
pursuit of administrative efficiency. institution of the head tax) and the lower level of security provided by the
Mexican state in comparative perspective. The overall similarity cannot
Administrative Patronage in Peru explain subsequent variation in state capacity, nor can the two outliers.
National politicians in Peru relied on administrative patronage, drawing Second, there are no differences in state capacity across cases in the
local elites into their coalitions by distributing bureaucratic offices and colonial or independence-era trajectories that line up with subsequent
reserving political appointments far Lima-based elites. Economic elites variation. Without claiming that these four cases are identical, this chap-
multiplied their success by investing in political coalitions, receiving in ter has shown that they entered the mid-nineteenth century as similar,
return access to administrative positions (Jacobsen 1993, 332). Politicians and this similarity is especially striking given the degree of variation that
built networks of support in their local and regional constituencies by emerged over the succeeding decades. Variation <lid not emerge until
ensuring the appointment of local elites to administrative offices at the after l 840; our search far its origins in the Liberal era that began severa!
local and regional level (ibid., 239-240). Indeed, Nugent (1997, 47-48) decades after independence unfolds in the next three chapters.
claims that elected office was only valuable insofar as it provided access
to control over administrative appointments.
By contrast to the composition of the administration, the composi-
tion of political office-holders incorporated few regional elites. Residency
requirements far elected office were limited, and politicians often were
elected from multiple jurisdictions in the course of their careers (Peloso
1999). As Muecke's study of the 1868 and 1872 elections shows, the
Civilista party leadership excluded regional elites: it was "composed
entirely of Lima residents who claimed to represent the interests of the
entire country" (Muecke 2004, 65-66). Party statutes "impeded the
integration of the regional elites into the national executive" (67). The
Educational Development 125

they were able to do so because theír polícies were ímplemented by


4 deployed bureaucrats. Moreover, the case study of the development of
Chilean school ínspection shows that these deployed bureaucrats went
beyond implementing policíes that systematized educatíon: these local
State Projects, Institutions, and Educational agents of the state pushed the central state to íncrease íts oversight and
Development penetratíon of the prímary school classroom, and thus, for theír own pur-
poses, drove Chilean state building. This supports the claím, put forward
in Chapter 2, that deployed bureaucrats have an independent ínterest in
state building.
The Peruvían case also provídes within-case evidence showing that
deployed rule is crucial for the success of state-development efforts. The
development of Peruvian education divides into two periods: one of stag-
nation of national government efforts (1845-1895) and one of striking
success (1895-1915). After fifty years of thwarted efforts at educational
As the first part of this chapter shows, our four cases display wide varia- development, a shift to educational administration through deployed rule
tion in the development of public primary education. The spread and sys- led to dramatic gains in the public primary school system after 1895,
tematization of public primary education in Chile and in sorne (but not even as social conditions made educational development less likely.
all) of Mexico's states far outstripped that in Peru and Colombia. This Social conditions have formed the basis of the most compelling exist-
reflects a divergence in the state's ability to incorporate citizens into pub- ing arguments for variation in educational development. Scholars have
lic schools and to control educational content, and this variation provídes claimed that the econornic inequality engendered by plantation agricul-
an opportunity to test the explanation for the origins of state capacity ture or rníning, and the social inequality associated with the presence
developed in the first two chapters against an alternative víew (sketched of a large índigenous population, have kept national governments in
in the second section of the chapter) that príoritizes social diversíty and the hands of actors (the wealthy) who oppose educational devélopment
econorníc inequalíty as the fundamental causes of lirníted progress in because of its redistributive properties. The result, these scholars claim, is
schoolíng. I do so in the remaínder of the chapter by drawíng on a com- that the development of primary schooling is negatively correlated with
bínation of within-case process-tracing, cross-temporal comparison, and inequalíty and social diversity. The switch in forms of administration in
Peru after 1895 provídes an opportunity to assess the relative weight of
within-case statistícal analysís.
I find that the failure of educational development in Colombia can be this structural argument and my institutional alternative. If, as I find, the
traced to the lack of interest by state leaders in íts spread or systematiza- fate of educational development alters sharply with institutional change,
tion. While education was seen as crucial to the country's development, this should lead us to favor the role of adrninistrative institutions in medi-
a broad range of political elites believed it best to leave its ínstallation in ating the ability of elites to block state-building efforts.
the hands of local government, the church, or prívate actors. Just as in Mexico, too, provides a propitious climate for testing these claims.
the dimensíons of Colombian state building explored in Chapters 5 and Because educational policy was in the hands of the states in Mexico's
6 there was no effort to íncrease the state's control of education. This federal system, we can examine cross-state variation in trajectories of the
'
confirms the argument developed in Chapter l tracing Colombian state growth of the school system. I present statistical evidence that shows the
weakness to the absence of a state-buildíng project. lirníted effect of social diversity (the indigenous proportion of the popula-
Efforts to build public educational systems in the other three cases tion) and urbanization to explain the diverging cross-state trajectories in
succeeded and foundered depending on the form of adrnínistration, as Mexican educational development. In a paired comparison of two states
theorized in Chapter 2. When Chilean state leaders sought to increase the that have similar proportions of rural and indigenous population, I show
provísíon of schools, and to shape the content and conduct of educatíon, that the divergence in educational development can be explained by the

124
I26 State Building in Latin America Educational Development I27

institutions of local administration, by the preponderance of local elites inculcation, were efforts to overcome poor teacher quality and heteroge-
in administrative positions in the stagnating case of Michoacán, and by neity of instruction, which were crucial obstacles to educational develop-
their replacement with deployed bureaucrats in Sonora, which saw sharp ment. Where the state designed and enfarced a standard curriculum, and
growth in schooling during the second half of the nineteenth century. oversaw the content and distribution of texts, it directly shaped the con-
Befare I proceed to those tasks, however, I begin the chapter by describ- tent of education, reflecting its growing infrastructural power. Perhaps
ing the aspects of primary public schooling to be explored in this chapter, most irnportantly, as school inspectors visiting classrooms reported back
and by presenting a succinct comparison of the trajectories fallowed in to the capital about the content and provision of education wherever
the faur cases. they went, the central state could assess the extent of implementation of
its policies, and exercise oversight and control. Together, these aspects
of public prirnary education reflect its systematization and control, and
EDUCATIONAL DEVELOPMENT AND STATE POWER:
thus, combined with the extent of educational provision, shed light on
DIMENSIONS AND INDICATORS
this aspect of the state's infrastructural power.
The development of public prirnary education in the faur cases can be
compared along two dimensions: the provision of public schooling, and
COMPARATIVE DEVELOPMENT
state control over the classroom. I use both qualitative and quantitative
data to assess various indicators of each. Befare proceeding to the case studies, I provide in this section a sum-
mary of the comparative development of the provision and systematiza-
tion of public primary schooling in the faur cases. As Table 4.1 shows,
Indicators of Prirnary Schooling Provision
the cases exhibited striking variation: educational development in Chile
Using data from both prirnary and secondary sources, I measure the far outstripped that of Peru and Colombia, while Mexico represents an
growth of schooling by examining trends in the number of public schools, intermediare case, characterized by more subnational variation than in
the number of teachers, and the size of the student body (both enrollment any of the other cases.
and attendance.) In addition to national-level data, I examine the extent
of territorial inequality in the provision of education. I facus on regional
Provision
variation and the extent of urban bias in schooling. To assess the farmer,
I examine the extent of concentration of schooling in sorne regions of the The first difference between the cases can be seen in the rate of schooling
country. The latter is evaluated by comparing the provision of schools per and enrollment growth during the late-nineteenth and early-twentieth
capita across urban and rural areas. 1 centuries. Chile saw an increase in the number of primary schools from
2

276 in 1853 to 2,716 in l9IO, arate which far outpaced the growth of
population. Mexico, too, saw school provision grow faster than popula-
Indicators of Control over Public Prirnary Schooling
tion: while the number of schools rose sharply from 2,424 in l 8 5 7 to
A more complete picture of the development of state power is obtained by 12,068 in 1908, population only doubled during the same period. By
combining data on provision with an investigation of the extent of state contrast, school growth in Colombia and Peru, which proceeded more
oversight of the content of education. To do so, I examine three aspects slowly, lagged behind population growth well into the twentieth century.
of the systematization of public prirnary schooling: teacher training, text- Variation in enrollment rates can be seen in the second row of Table 4.1,
book and curriculum standardization, and the development of an inspec-
torate. Teacher academies, which provided both pedagogical training and
, The data surnrnarized in Table 4.1 and the succeeding paragraphs were compiled frorn a
1
Both of these indicators rely on subnational data, which is rnarred by uneven quality. variety of prirnary and secondary sources, including but not limited to those cited else-
Nevertheless, the findings are indicative of broader trends. where in the accornpanying text.
Educational Development 129

which draws on data from Newland (1994) to show a sharp divergence


?f2. ?f2. across the four cases by 1900.
o o This divergence persists when we turn to the regional unevenness of
o!'<"\ o,.¡
ú ú schooling - the extent to which school provision and enrollment vary
¡:__;..;
O\ ,.¡ across subnational units. In Chile, schooling was equally provided
00 O\
H H throughout the country. In fact, schooling grew more quickly between
J.._ J.._
et~":'
1865 and l9IO in regions outside Santiago than in the capital. Mexico,
H H N where educational development was largely in the hands of subnational
authorities, saw significant cross-state variation in enrollment rates.
?f2.
o While school provision stagnated in states like Morelos, Campeche, and
o
""'
ú Guerrero between 1878 and 1907, it more than doubled in eight oth-
t1S "'
o
ers (Estadísticas Sociales del Porfuiato (1956), pp. 42ff). Colombia, too,
O\
saw large variation across its federal subunits, but even high performers
1o H
1
"'
OJ
i:: among Colombian subnational units saw relatively low levels of school-
8 00""'
H z o
ing: as late as 1922, none had more than n percent of the population
enrolled in school (Helg 1987, 37).
Peru saw a sharp transition in territorial inequality before and after
?f2. 1895. In 1862, Lima had about 50 percent more schools per school-age
o population than did the remainder of the country. By 1897, school pro-
o
"tj-
ú vision had nearly doubled in Lima, while it fell by nearly 50 percent in
00
o the rest of the country to about one-fifth of the Lima rate. Growth in
O\
H
J.._
schooling before 1897, then, was concentrated in Lima. Between 1897
00"' and 1921, by contrast, school provision per capita declined in Lima while
H
it increased in the rest of the country - although at a slower pace in the
heavily indigenous southern highland regions.3
?f2.
o Similar patterns can be observed when the urban bias of educational
o
O\
ú provision is addressed. Here, too, Chile remains an outlier: school provi-
o
H
sion per capita rose in nearly every department between 1874 and 1909.
O\
H The unweighted average of schools per l,ooo residents in eighty-one
1
""' departments rosefrom o.6 to 0.9, a 50 percent increase.4 This is strong evi-
00
H
"' dence that school provision in Chile increased nationwide, growing even
in departments with small, mainly rural populations.s Urban schools, by
.s
oo J The claims in this paragraph are based on rny calculations frorn school provision and
...e::
1....o "'
u census data.
4 This analysis includes every departrnent with available data for both I874 and I909.

00 These years were chosen frorn the few with departrnental education figures because both
El
.s
o :3
u
:::l §
·eu fall close to years of national census adrninistration, allowing better estimates of school-
ing rates. The difference of the two rneans is statistically significant at p < .o 5.
o ·;;:::
....
Q.)
o.
...e::
u :::l "'
s Even as schools spread into srnall towns and rural villages, it did continue to exclude
CfJ u E * ** remote rural populations (Serrano I995-I996, 462). Nevertheless, the spread of school-
ing in Chile was far broader than in the other cases.

128
State Building in Latin America Educational Development

contrast, were massively over-represented in Colombia's school system. produced relatively few teachers (Lay 1971, 286-287). State oversight
Helg (1987, 48-49) claims that in 1931, while 82 percent of Colombia's over teacher training was absent; it contracted the operation of the peda-
population was rural, only 52.2 percent of schools were located outside gogical academies to the Church in r892 (Silva Olarte 1989, 8r-82}. As
urban areas. The rural schools that did exist were far from beacons of of 193 r, fewer than one in four teachers had any certification, and the
learning, as they were lacking in comparison to urban schools. Most cen- rate in rural areas was 7.5 percent (Obregón et al. r999, vol. 2, p. 5 56).
trally, they provided only three years of schooling as opposed to the six Peru had an equally meager record of teacher training. The men's
provided in urban primary schools (Silva Olarte 1989, 76). teacher training academy in Lima produced two graduates between r 8 59
In Mexico too, urban areas saw greater school provision than did rural and 1869, and closed again in 1877, returning to operation only in r905
areas - but the extent of this bias (as of 1910} varied across Mexico's (Barrantes r989, 79 }. After 1905, teacher training began to take hold,
states. The territory of Baja California (where education was adminis- as 49 graduates of the Lima academy were serving in public schools by
tered by the federal government} and Tamaulipas actually favored rural l 909, and severa! more normal schools had opened by r 9 r 5. Yet the vast
areas in school provision, but these were the only exceptions to a general majority of Peruvian teachers continued to lack pedagogical training, and
pattern of bias toward urban schools. Nevertheless, schools had spread many had little more than a primary school education.
into rural areas by a significant extent: the available evidence (from Systematizing teacher training was a subject of great debate in
Bazant r993, 9r and 94) supports Vaughan's rejection of claims that "no Mexico. Liberals questioned whether imposing training requirements
rural schools existed at the time of the Revolution" (r982, 49). far teachers would interfere with the freedom to exercise professions,
As with the more general patterns of educational development, Peru is which was a touchstone of Liberal values (Casio Villegas r956, 537ff).
a tale of two distinct phases. In r897, after fifty years of failed national Once these debates were resolved in favor of standardization early in the
policies, only eight of the country's eighty-seven provinces - none of Porfiriato, progress was dramatic. The first normal school in the Federal
which were rural areas - had more than one school per l,ooo school District opened in 1880. Sorne states had moved more quickly than
age children. By r921, only eight provinces remained below this level. had the national government: according to Galván de Terrazas (r985,
The initial striking urban bias of school provision was eroded sharply, 174), normal schools existed in San Luis Potosí, Zacatecas, Guanajuato,
although not eliminated entirely, during the Aristocratic Republic. Nuevo León, and Sinaloa befare r87+ By r9ro, Mexico had 45 normal
schools with more than 2,000 students, up from seventy-two in r878,
and approximately one in faur teachers nationwide had normal school
Systematization
degrees (Vásquez de Knauth 1970, 59; Vaughan 1982, 63).
As we move from the provision of schooling to its standardization and Textbook standardization and distribution was another element in the
systematization, the gap between the cases remains apparent. It can be systematization of primary schools. Here, too, Chile saw much greater
seen clearly in the development of teacher training. Here, too, Chile was development during the period under study. By the l86os, the Chilean
a leader. Between 1867 and r875, nearly r50 normal school graduates government was distributing hundreds of thousands of texts, providing
joined the ranks of public school teachers, bringing the proportion of between faur and eleven texts per student over the subsequent decade.7
teachers who had been trained in the country's pedagogical academies to The state was also heavily involved in overseeing the content of texts
37 percent by 1875. A variety of policies (including earmarked scholar- (Woll r975}. After 1877, sealed-bid auctions were held far national con-
ships, retention bonuses, salary increases, and moving subsidies} were in tracts on school materials including furniture, paper, and ink, which could
place to retain trained teachers, and to encourage them to take jobs at then be allocated according to national government priorities (MIP r877,
schools throughout the country. 6 Colombia's record of teacher training
was poor: although nine normal schools were established in r872, they
7 This figure is based on data from various ministerial Memorias that show the number of
books distributed by province. For seven fiscal years between 1868-1877 for which data
6 For more detail on these, and citations to govemment documents describing the programs is available, the average number of primary school textbooks distributed nationwide was
and their achievements, see Soifer (2009, 168-170) and Egaña Baraona (2000). more than 190,000.
132 State Building in Latin America Educational Development 133

3 5 ). Alongside these developments, Chilean officials developed a detailed education development remained quite limited at the end of the Porfiriato,
primary school curriculum, which was so precise that (as discussed later) as texts were lacking in many parts of the country (Vaughan 1982, 62).
it was standardized clown to the individual lesson. The standardization of currículum at the national level was hotly debated
Colombia remained at the opposite extreme, as it never declared a par- at the third national pedagogical conference in 1891, and by the end of
ticular text to be mandatory or official. A small number of school mate- the Porfiriato, the "basic structure of primary schooling" was in place
rials, including texts and maps, were distributed after the 1870 school (Díaz Zermeño 1979, 63-64).
reform (Loy 1971, 287). By 1921, the national government was distribut-
ing materials ranging from chalk to catechisms (19,899 copies), reading,
Inspection
history, and math textbooks (in smaller numbers), and 2,000 copies of
the national anthem (Helg 1987, 55). Compared to Chile - and evento The inspection of the day-to-day operation of primary schools by trained
Peru - these numbers are paltry. A national curriculum was never set: the officials who report to the national education ministry was the linch-
content and organization of instruction remained at the departmental pin of control over primary education. Here the divergences between the
level. The only consistency in teaching carne in the realm of religion, cases are particularly stark. And because inspection is so central to the
where practice was set by the church, not the state. state's infrastructural power - its ability to implement policy- differences
In Peru, teachers had free rein over texts before 1891, when usage in this dimension are particularly significant. Here Chile is a dramatic
was standardized at the province level. It would only be standardized at outlier. As discussed in detail later, it had by the 189os a fully regimented
the national level after 1895. To be approved, texts had to use the met- inspection system that visited essentially every public school in the coun-
ric system, use Peruvian examples whenever possible, and use maps that try, reporting back to Santiago on the nature of schooling.
reflected the country's international claims (MIP 1897, 27ff). The Pardo Colombia only established a vestigial inspection system with the Uribe
administration (1904-1909) undertook the first efforts to standardize education reform of 1903. Unlike the professionalized system in Chile,
textbooks, opening contests for a new reader, and distributing copies of inspection in Colombia was carried out by local elites (including the par-
the winning entry widely. By 1909, the Peruvian government distributed ish priest), and its function was blurred with teacher training. Evidence
textbooks ata limited level: an average of 22.8 texts per thousand resi- about the effectiveness of Colombian inspection is fragmentary. Helg
dents to schools throughout the country. 8 Peruvian policymakers only (1987, 60-61) finds it to be uneven: its frequency varied from once per
systematized primary education at the subject level after 1900, and never month to once per year, and that in sorne areas, it was carried out by
developed a program of history instruction, limiting the extent to which self-reporting on the part of teachers.
the classroom inculcated national values. Peru, too, saw limited inspection capacity during the nineteenth cen-
Mexican state builders were concerned with the "heterogeneity of tury, as the system in place relied heavily on self-reporting by teachers
habits" that they saw as the cause of the country's social turmoil. But, (see, for example, MILIMA 1875, pp. 4-6). Primary school inspection
as Bazant (1993, 23) discusses, their primary focus was making primary was established only in 1891 - but inspectors only covered about half
schooling free, obligatory, and secular as a way to make Mexican society the country, and visited schools about once per semester (MED 1891,
unifonn. As a result, little effort to standardize or distribute texts was xxxviii and 192). Oversight capacity, as discussed in detail later, increased
made before the Porfiriato. The 1861 education law called for the use sharply after 1895, culminating in the 1902 Censo Escolar. By 1907, a
of the Liberal constitution as a reading text in primary schools, and that regimented inspection system was in place, and state oversight capacity
Mexican history be taught (Vásquez de Knauth 1970, 61-62). Further increased sharply thereafter.
national standardization was debated, but textbook policy emerged at Mexican schools saw a general "trend" toward systematization and
the state level (Covarrubias 1993; Bazant 1993, 54ff). This aspect of centralization of control under Liberal governments (Vaughan 1987, 59).
By the 18 5os, most states had created inspection systems of varying qual-
8 This figure is based on my calculation from enrollment and distribution data in MED ity, which oversaw the administration of primary schools (Staples 1998,
1909, 398-399. 53-54). The 1888 education law gave the national government the right
134 State Building in Latin America Educational Development 13 5

to inspect municipal schools, and by 1896 the Federal District hada regi- to meet this responsibility (Hanson 1986, 30). Even as education was
mented inspection system. As with other aspects of education develop- declared the "basis and foundation of representative government" and
ment, national government policies diffused to the states, and by 1910, knowledge the root of freedom, efforts to establish primary education
inspection had spread through the whole country (Bazant 1993, 48). Its saw the state's role as limited to removing barriers to prívate initiative in
nature varied by state: in México state, it relied heavily on self-reporting school-building efforts rather than active involvement in building public
by teachers, as inspectors only visited schools that self-reported "anoma- schools.9 Schooling became obligatory for the fust time only with the pas-
lies" (Bazant 1998, 65). Overall, by 1910, inspection was "skeletal and sage of the 1863 constitution and the subsequent 1870 education reform,
embryonic," as national systematization continued to be limited, and per- and this would be reversed in fairly short arder, as described later (Silva
formance at the state level varied (Vaughan 1982, 60). Olarte 1989, 63). Strikingly, however, the Hilaría López government that
In all, we can reach three conclusions about the patterns of state presided over these reforms focused on weakening the role of the church
development across the cases. First, Chile and (to a lesser extent) Mexico in schooling, and chose not to increase state education provision. Instead
had more developed public primary education systems than did Peru or officials hoped that the requirement that all children enroll in school
Colombia. Second, Peru saw a dramatic shift in fortunes, as education would lead to the opening of secular prívate schools (Helg 1987, 23).
development initiatives that stagnated between 1845 and 1895 bore These policies, which led to sorne growth in enrollment during the
fruit for two decades thereafter. Third, Mexico was marked by striking l87os, were reversed in 1886 when the new constitution made educa-
patterns of subnational variation, as schooling grew much more rap- tion "free but not obligatory" (Article 41). This policy was motivated by
idly in sorne of its states than in others. The rest of this chapter turns to the belief that mandatory education would obstruct the free market in
accounting for this cross-national, cross-time (in Peru) and subnational schooling. 'º Proponents believed that education should be the work of
(in Mexico) variation, showing that it is best explained by the two-part prívate actors, and that the state should intervene only when prívate inter-
argument about the origins and outcomes of state-building efforts I out- est was lacking (Silva Olarte 1989, 67). Indeed, Helg (1987, 28) argues
lined in Chapters l and 2. that política! elites in the Regeneración era viewed the state as having
no ambit over moral issues, and therefore believed that it had no right
to intervene actively in education. The 1903 education reform, a prod-
LACK OF EDUCATIONAL INITIATIVE IN COLOMBIA
uct of Antioquia elites, gave up on creating a nationally unified primary
Even in comparison to a laggard like Peru, Colombia saw little education education system, focusing instead on secondary schools at the national
development befare 1930. Indeed, Ramírez and Tellez (2007, 475) show leve! while ceding control of primary schools to the departments. Liberal
that as late as 1950, only about 8 percent of the country's population was proposals in the l92os to make education mandatory (while allowing
enrolled in school. The failure of Colombian primary education develop- parents to choose between public and prívate schools) were defeated,
ment was also reflected in the absence of any standardization or oversight meaning that as of 1930, primary schooling was still optional rather than
by the national government. Although fiscal constraints played a role, the mandatory in most of Colombia.
limited growth of education was a direct reflection of the lack of com- In part, the failure of the Colombian state to institute mandatory
mitment by state leaders throughout the period 1830-1930 to building a schooling reflects pressure from church officials, who were strongly
universal, systematized education system. opposed to mandatory primary schooling even when they were guar-
The most striking reflection of this half-hearted commitment to anteed control over the content of the currículum and the classroom. 11
education development can be seen in the interpretation of universal
schooling by politicians and education policy makers. The notion of uni- 9 The quote appears in Báez Osario (2006, 26) and is attributed to the Congreso Nacional
versalism in Colombia focused on making exclusion from schools (chiefly of l82I.
1
on financia! grounds) illegal rather than on making schooling manda- º The fact that this logic was put forward by Conservatives shows the breadth of the
laissez-faire consensus in Colombia described in Chapter I.
tory. Education was seen primarily as a family responsibility, and the " Far example, in 1872 the Archbishop of Popayán thieatened to excommunicate alto-
state's role was to provide a context in which its citizens could choose gether any Catholic who attended public schools (Silva Olarte 1989, 65).
136 State Building in Latin America Educational Development 137

Indeed, the challenges that the church perceived to its hegemony over This disinclination derived from the Colombian consensus about the
Colombian schools were pivotal in triggering the 1876 civil war. place of the state in bringing "order, progress, and development": the
Throughout the first century after independence, the church retained a state's role was seen to be limited to removing obstacles to private initia-
great amount of influence over education. At times, this was the result tive. Just as in other countries, education was seen as a necessary piece
of the failure of the state to build primary schools, leaving a void filled of development efforts. But in Colombia, state officials were satisfied
by religious schools. Even when it did not directly operate schools, the with policies that encouraged residents to enroll in school, rather than
church often funded them (Báez Osorio 2006, 34). In practice, local requiring them to do so. Unlike any of the other cases, political elites
priests often served on the municipal inspection councils, placing them in Colombia never made a concerted effort to build a national school
in a position of oversight over public schools, particularly in smaller system.
communities (Obregón et al. 1999, vol. l, p. 379). The 1887 Concordato Even when national leaders sought to increase school provision, they
restoring relations with the Vatican prohibited the state from interven- placed financing and administration in the hands of local and regional
ing in church schools, and it gave the church the power to intervene officials. The policies of the 1903 education reform were typical in this
in public schooling. After this time, the state continued to fund edu- light: the national government mandated that schools be provided, and
cation while ceding control over it to the church (Lebot 1978, 125). committed itself to paying for school materials such as textbooks and
Many schools were run by Catholic priests and church officials (Silva paper. But it placed responsibility for teacher selection, and for teacher
Olarte 1989, 73-74). This meant not only that the church oversaw the salaries, on the departments, and the financing for school buildings on
content of religious education, and incorporated the study of Catholic the municipal governments (Helg 1987, rn3). Left free to design edu-
doctrine and practice into the curriculum, but that the church unilater- cation policy as they saw fit, and responsible for paying for schooling,
ally imposed texts in other courses as well, and operated the country's departmental and municipal governments commonly dragged their feet,
normal schools after 1892 (ibid., 81-82). The control of education was and "limited themselves to the law" (ibid; 48). At other times, state gov-
particularly dominant in the frontier regions, where the preponderance ernments went so far as "rejecting" national policy (Silva Olarte 1989,
of political power was ceded to the church (Rausch 1993). But church 65). The result was low school provision nearly everywhere in Colombia,
control reached far beyond this territory, leading Lebot (1978, 125) to with only scattered outliers.
argue that the 1887 Concordato "turned Colombia once again into a Alongside the low levels of provision, the Colombian state also failed
country of missions as in the l6th and l7th centuries." to undertake oversight and systematization efforts. This, too, reflected
Yet the power of the church cannot fully explain the failure to institute its lack of interest in using primary schools to penetrate and transform
mandatory schooling. Instead, it is a consequence of the failure of state society and build a national community. Instead of nation-building or
building. In Peru and Chile, too, as we will see, the church had signifi- the inculcation of "Colombian-ness" among the population, schools were
cant influence over education policy, curricular content, and other aspects seen as a means of providing skills for economic activity (Ramírez and
of instruction. The central place of religious instruction in primary edu- Tellez 2007, 464).
cation was unquestioned in all the cases except Mexico. Throughout In all, the limited development of Colombia's education system is strik-
Latin America, the church operated many schools in the early decades ing in comparative perspective. But more notable is that the Colombian
after independence - in fact, post-independence laws in all four coun- state never undertook a project of education development. While politi-
tries required religious organizations to operate schools. But over time cal leaders of all stripes valued schooling as a necessary component of
in Chile and Peru, the direct operation of schools by religious orders modernization and progress, they never undertook a systematic effort to
was phased out and replaced by public administration of a school sys- build public schools, monitor the quality of education, or standardize the
tem deeply infused with Catholic values. In Colombia, the fact that the school system. The Colombian state lagged far behind its counterparts in
church operated the nominally public school system throughout the nine- education development throughout the first century after independence, a
teenth century reflects the unique disinclination of Colombian state lead- reflection of its lack of commitment to increasing its control over society
ers to build a public bureaucracy. and territory.
State Building in Latin America Educational Development 139

diversity were higher during the nineteenth century, the Sokoloff argu-
A STRUCTURAL ALTERNATIVE: INEQUALITY AND EDUCATION
ment would not expect local promotion of education.
DEVELOPMENT
In Latín America, where local inequality was high, the Sokoloff
The other three cases - Chile, Peru, and Mexico - diverged from hypothesis expects that the initiative for education development would
Colombia in that all saw state-building efforts in the education realm only come from national governments. But it expects that initiative to
tbroughout the nineteenth century. Yet as described previously, the fruit emerge only in societies that were fairly equal and homogeneous at the
of those efforts varied. In the remainder of this chapter, I weigh two pos- national level. Mariscal and Sokoloff (2000) find a negative correlation
sible explanations for this variation, putting the institutional account between the indigenous composition of the population and the provi-
developed in Chapter 2 against a structural account common in the lit- sion of education. They conclude that the relatively low social inequality
erature on education development. r 2
of societies without large indigenous or slave populations promoted the
This structural account begins from the fact that public education construction of democratic institutions (or at least low barriers to suf-
spending redistributes wealth by creating econornic opportunities for the frage) that favored the development of education.
lower classes, paid for by taxes which fall more heavily on the wealthy If this argument is to hold, we should expect that national political
even if they are regressive in nature (Mariscal and Sokoloff 2000, 159; elites would be more likely to seek to supply education in societies where
Ansell 2010). As inequality increases, then, the burden of taxation to fund social homogeneity was low. We will see, however, that this was not the
education development falls on the rich in a more concentrated fash- case: in both Peru and Mexico, where indigenous populations were large
ion, making them less willing to support education development. 1 3 This and social inequality high, state leaders made efforts to develop public
means that we should expect the growth of public primary schooling to primary education. The roots of variation are not in the choices made
be negatively associated with inequality. Moreover, because social actors by state leaders, but in the extent to which they were able to effectively
shape political institutions to protect their interests, inequality should convert policy initiatives into outcomes. This failure to account for the
be associated with suffrage restrictions (Engerman and Sokoloff 1997). determinants of the success of state-building efforts is a crucial limitation
These lirnits on participation limit the ability of the poor to organize and of the Sokoloff argument, and of other arguments that draw direct con-
press for education development in the political arena. nections between the motivations of state leaders and the outcomes of
In this view, successful education development requires "great equal- state capacity.
ity or homogeneity among the population [that] led over time to more The evidence presented later challenges this view. It shows that state
democratic political institutions, to more investment in public goods and leaders in Chile, Mexico, and Peru all sought to build primary educa-
infrastructure, and to institutions that offered relatively broad access to tion systems. The extent of implementation varied with the form of
econornic opportunities" (Engerman and Sokoloff 2002, 4). Where soci- adrninistration: where school building and oversight were delegated to
ety is largely equal and homogeneous in preferences - as in the northern local elites, as in sorne parts of Mexico, and in Peru befare 1895, these
United States or Canada during the early decades after independence - state-building efforts foundered. But when states relied on deployed rule
education development is said to have resulted from the initiative of local and sent bureaucrats out to implement education reform, their efforts
communities, in which the burden of funding education is evenly distrib- were more successful. It is this variation, and not the preferences of elites
uted. But in Latín America, where both econornic inequality and ethnic about public school development, that explains the divergence across
cases. Across all cases, the historical record shows that econornic elites
" Because of the central place of Kenneth Sokoloff in developing this argurnent, I refer to
it later as the Sokoloff hypothesis. It was developed by Sokoloff and his collaborators
continued to oppose the taxation and spending that accompanied educa-
in Mariscal and Sokoloff (2000) and Engerrnan and Sokoloff (1997, 2002). A slightly tion development. In the racist language and thought of the time period,
different argurnent, which ernphasizes the exogenous origins of institutions rather than they wondered whether the indigenous population could be educated,
tracing thern directly to the degree of inequality, has been rnade by John Coatsworth
and whether that education would serve any purpose. But where they
(1998, 2008).
'l The logic here builds on the Meltzer and Richard (1981) rnodel of taxation and had no influence over policy implementation, their opposition to educa-
redistribution. tion reform was left on the margins and school building continued. This
State Building in Latin America Educational Development

institutional divergence, and underlying structural conditions, explains the Education Ministry decreed on June 3, 1868 the creation of com-
why Chile saw precocious school building, despite high social and eco- rnissions of local notables to oversee education. These emerged by 1871
nomic inequality. 1 4 It also better explains the sharp change in the trajec- in big cities such as Santiago and Valparaíso, in local centers such as
tory of Peruvian education development befare and after 189 5. Finally, Vallenar and Freirina in the north and Angeles and Ligua in the south,
the nature of adrninistration, and not econornic and social inequality, and in a few small towns, most notably in Chiloé, and efforts were made
better explains the variation in education development across Mexico's to create comrnissions in other communities (MIP 1871). The comrnis-
states. sion members' lack of knowledge or training about education quickly
became apparent asan Achilles' heel of their effectiveness. An 1869 visit
DEPLOYED RULE AND STATE POWER: THE DEVELOPMENT OF
by a special inspector to sorne of the provinces in the center of the coun-
SCHOOL INSPECTION IN CHILE
try faund that the only local comrnission that was effective was that
of Caupolicán - and it was no coincidence that this commission was
Explanations far education development in Chile have facused on several also unique in being headed by the department governor (El Araucano
factors: most prorninently, the role of individual leaders and the broad 1869, 4).
elite consensus about education among its political elites, Chile's homo- Local bureaucrats regularly expressed concern about these comrnis-
geneity relative to its neighbors, and societal demands far education. s 1
sions to their superiors in Santiago. Their concerns revolved around two
While these factors all played a significant role in education development, issues: (1) effective oversight of education and (2) disputes over who had
an exarnination of the origins of school inspection reveals another central the authority to hire and fire teachers. The complaints of local officials
factor: the actions of Chilean bureaucrats in pursuing the development of trickled up through the bureaucracy, and bureaucrats at the national level
an effective system of oversight of schools in the communities in which confronted evidence of the lirnitations of local commissions. The 1869
they served. Inspection represented the backbone of state-controlled pri- special inspector's report urged the bureaucrats in Santiago to rely more
mary schooling. The development of the inspection system, which rein- on the opinion of local officials, as the success of the project of educa-
farced the control of state officials over the school system, was the product tion development was "entirely in their hands" (El Araucano 1869, 2-3).
of the establishment of deployed rule. We cannot understand the growing By the rnid-187os it was generally acknowledged within the education
systematization of Chilean primary education, or its nationwide spread, bureaucracy that these commissions were a total failure (see, e.g., MIP
without taking into account the role played by deployed local bureau- 1875, 214).
crats in pressing the state far more effective oversight of schooling. 16 The authority to hire and fire teachers was a significant bone of con-
In the late l86os, national education officials expressed repeated con- tention. The comrnissions of local notables were seen as overstepping
cern about the fact that the system relied on a few inspectors who had their bounds by taking on this role, and in the context of their acknowl-
huge territories to cover (MIP 1869, 53). In response to these concerns, edged ineffectiveness, this jurisdictional conflict turned the national
bureaucracy against the inspections. By the rnid-187os the government
« Mariscal and Sokoloff (2000, 197) clairn that inequality was relatively low in Chile
sought to establish a more effective system of oversight, but this effort
in regional perspective. They approximate inequality by measuring the rate of suffrage
and the proportion of the population identified as indigenous. It is true that on both of was styrnied far the remainder of the decade as a result of the severe eco-
these indicators, Chile seems more equal than many other Latín American countries. nornic crisis. This crisis saw the creation of a protector de escuela, a single
But accounts of rural life in nineteenth-century Chile (such as Bauer 1975) suggest that overseer far each school (MIP 1877, 38-39), but this was a temporary
economic and social inequality was very high.
" The importance of the elite consensus and individual leaders is highlighted by Yeager
measure during the time of penury.
(2005) and Britton (1994), while (as discussed earlier) Engerman and Sokoloff (2002) As the econornic crisis lessened during the War of the Pacific, pressures
and Mariscal and Sokoloff (2000) see homogeneity and low inequality as crucial. Cruz far the development of inspection mounted. The rninistry was pressed by
(2002) authored one of the few studies of the societal demand for schooling in Chile,
although Malina and Palmer (2004) see this as central in their study of Costa Rica.
inspectors themselves to increase the number of inspectors and to equal-
16 This section is based on Soifer (2009 ), which explores the development of Chilean school ize the number of schools each had to cover (MIP 1882, l27ff). By 1883,
inspection in more detail. there were twenty-three inspectors, including one far the new territories
State Building in Latin America Educational Development 143

of Antofagasta and Tarapacá, which had been taken from Bolivia and Thus, while the central education bureaucracy sought to maximize
Peru during the War of the Pacific. At this point, the last local cornrnis- its control of education by pushing inspection outward from the capital,
sions were eliminated and school inspection turned over entirely to the local state agents criticized the type of inspection first introduced. By
professional inspectorate, which increased effective control over schools arguing that local cornrnissions were ineffective and overstepped their
throughout the national territory, including the regions newly conquered bounds, state agents convinced the Education Ministry of the need to
in the war. reform the system. Had these agents not been so critical of the local com-
The criticisms of local state agents were effective in pressing the missions, they likely would have been retained. At the time, the priorities
national governrnent to professionalize the education system. But why of the central education bureaucracy (as reflected in their memorias and
were local officials so concerned with the quality of inspection? Their budgets) were increasing the nurnber of schools in underserved areas of
statements of concern about the quality of education cannot be taken the country (mainly rural areas) and irnproving teacher quality. The pres-
at face value, as these reflect their attempts to couch their demands in sures of local state agents placed the regimentation of school inspection
terms that they thought would appeal to their audience. Instead, we on the national agenda, and the transformation of the inspection system
can suggest two motives that drove local officials to seek to increase that resulted was fundamental in increasing state control of education.
the presence and power of the professional inspectorate. First, local Tracing the development of education inspection shows that economic
state agents saw professional inspectors as allies in a project of edu- factors alone cannot explain this growth of state control, although the
cation development. Egaña Baraona (2000, 235ff) shows that the two recovery from economic crisis did allow funds for increased profession-
types of bureaucrats collaborated on raising funds for schools from alization. Actions of officials in Santiago cannot be seen in a vacuurn, as
citizens, and on increasing school attendance. Increasing the provision they made policy choices relying on and responding to the reports they
and quality of education was a way for state officials to satisfy the received from the state agents in the periphery.
cornrnunities in which they served. State agents were besieged with Education was one of the fronts on which deployed officials pushed
demands for increased school provision and school quality, demands for an expanded state role in their cornrnunities, and the ability of the
they passed on to the national bureaucracy. Providing schools and over- Chilean state to penetrate and shape society on a national level through
seeing the quality of education was a way to deliver concrete results to the school system developed as a result of their efforts. Thus, the success
the cornrnunities in which they served. Beca use they were appointed by of state efforts to develop Chilean schooling depended on the actions of
the president or ministries, local officials were not accountable to the local officials in a system of deployed rule who pushed the central state to
cornrnunities. But their ability to provide services in response to their intensify and centralize the oversight of the country's schools.
demands increased their legitimacy, and improved their relationships
with these cornrnunities. Under deployed rule, local state agents could
INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND EDUCATION DEVELOPMENT
thus benefit from state strength, which motivated them to pursue its
IN PERU
development.
Second, local state agents saw education development as a means of Peru is a particularly propitious case in which to evaluate the power of
inculcating the youth of their district with national identity and civiliza- the institutional explanation, because the administration of public pri-
tion. Local officials were so interested in education development that they mary education varied sharply over time. From 1845 to 1895, during
regularly took it upon themselves to regulate all aspects of schools within the state-building efforts of the guano era and its aftermath, Peru relied
their jurisdictions, and they had to be restrained by the education law of heavily on local elites in a system of delegated rule. Despite a consen-
1883, which gave authority over local education to the inspectorate and sus among policymakers (Contreras 1996) that advances in education
limited local officials to appeals to the inspector general. The develop- were necessary to achieve national integration and prosperity, and large
ment of professional inspection was one front in a struggle for increased investrnents in schooling facilitated by the huge guano revenues the state
state presence in society, state presence that local officials sought because enjoyed for 25 years (Tantaleán Arbulú 1983, Appendix Table 4; Hunt
it would transform society in ways that increased their control. 1984), few schools were built outside Lima, and the quality of education
144 State Building in Latín America Educational Development 145

remained low. Systematization was so lacking even in the capital city that indigenous community "lacked all culture and had no notion of nation-
an 1872 government report described educational "disorder" as "com- ality." He wondered what effect education could have on those who, to
plete," writing that "each teacher teaches what they want, and to whom him, "were not yet people, who did not know how to live like people, and
they want, the school year ends when they see fit, and the length of vaca- had not managed to differentiate themselves from the animals" (Montero
tion is only measured by the teacher's will or love for their job" (MED 1990, 8 5-87). Deustua was far from alone in this view- it was regularly
1872, 6). By contrast, after 1895, even as economic changes strengthened expressed in the pages of El Comercio and other elite media. Many elites,
local elites, the governments of the Aristocratic Republic bypassed them to whom oversight of education policy had been delegated over the past
in placing education administration in the hands of deployed bureaucrats. fifty years, held the view that the indigenous population under their pur-
The effects of this change are striking, providing compelling evidence for view could not, and should not, be educated (Muecke 2004, r8r). These
the limitations of the structural account that centers on elite preferences attitudes had underpinned the failure of education development under
and social inequality. Unlike their predecessors, the governments of the delegated rule, and they led to tension as the central state undertook edu-
Aristocratic Republic ( l 89 5-19 l 9) established deployed rule in the realm cation development through deployed administration after I 89 5.
of primary education. The first steps taken by Piérola were a series of national education
The decision to shift from delegation of administration to a system of inspections ordered in r897 and r898. For the first time, inspectors were
deployed rule resulted from severa! factors. First, the War of the Pacific deployed from Lima to the provinces. The difference from earlier inspec-
drastically weakened local elites in highland regio ns, breaking their "rural tions was dramatic: inspectors began to file reports that highlighted the
hegemony" (Contreras and Cueto 1999, 145). Peruvian governments had shortcomings of the education system and criticized the actions of local
long relied on traditional elites to maintain stability in the interior of the government in the realm of education. Most strikingly for the central gov-
country, but these elites were overwhelrned by the extent of rural unrest ernment, inspectors noted that many communities lacked schools alto-
(Mallon 1995; Thurner 1997). Disturbed by the level of chaos under the gether: for example, the inspector found that children in the border town
Cáceres government that followed the end of the war, a broad coalition of Desaguadero crossed into Bolivia to attend school there. 1 7 A comrnis-
emerged behind the Piérola government that succeeded him. At the cen- sion on school hygiene, formed in r899, also delivered stark findings,
ter of this coalition was a new coastal elite, mainly invested in sugar describing the conditions in rural schools as not only "unhealthy" but
plantations, and a new class of industrialists, rniners, and merchants who "homicida!" (MED r900). The complete disarray of schooling, revealed
gained power as exports grew (Thorp and Bertram 1978). The experi- in these overwhelrningly negative reports, led the national government to
ence of turmoil under Cáceres raised the specter that econornic recovery take control of education development.
would be threatened by the lack of control over rural areas. Chastened As a prelude to this effort, Piérola's government undertook an edu-
by the poor performance of delegated rule, Piérola's government began a cation census in r902, the first assessment of education at a national
shift to deployed rule. This shift quickly led to increased state reach into level since the r876 census. 18 Despite sorne resistance from local officials,
the highlands, and for much of the period 1895-1915, steady progress in greater than 90 percent of the population and 75 percent of the national
education was seen. territory were covered by this census (Contreras 2004, 243). The results
The Civilista project of education development sparked resistance showed no progress in education since r876. In response to these sober-
from highland elites, who regained strength as the rural economy recov- ing findings, the Piérola government and its successors undertook mas-
ered from war. Elite resistance to deployed rule derived from the threat it sive efforts to expand education. From r897 to r920, the number of
posed to their efforts to restore hegemony over the rural population. But
in the realm of education, resistance also resulted from elite distaste for '7 This anecdote appears in the MED 1898, p. 424. The general clairns in this paragraph
educating Peru's indigenous population. Pamphlets, newspaper arrides, about the content of this new wave of inspectors' reports is based on a cornparison of
and other sources reveal disbelief that the indigenous population could the reports appearing in ali twenty-nine available annual ministerial Memorias over the
period 1864-1919, as well as various reports of regional officials frorn the same time
be educated or effectively integrated into a "modern" Peru. One exam- period.
ple appears in the writings of Alejandro Deustua, who argued that the '
8
For a detailed study of this census, see Soifer {2013b).
State Building in Latin America Educational Development 147

primary schools in the country nearly quadrupled from 852 to 3,338. 19 increased rural unrest after 1915, national governrnents developed closer
Enrollment doubled as well, reaching more than 120,000. This growth ties with local elites, and ceded ground on education. This can be seen
far outpaced the growth of population, and was truly national, as schools in the disappearance of systematic inspection reports from the archives
per capita increased throughout the country, unlike in earlier periods of the Ministry of Education after this time, and in the return of annual
where school construction was focused in Lima. ministerial reports to their old focus on policy design rather than on the
The Pardo governrnent (1904-1909) complemented expanded provi- shortcomings of implementation.
sion by focusing on the content of textbooks. A contest opened on May 9, Despite this retreat, the Civilista governrnent shift to deployed rule
1905 to write a reader for primary school students that would be "truly underlay a dramatic increase in the state's provision of education, over-
Peruvian," and by 1907 more than 150,000 copies of the winner were sight of its quality, and control of its content. Thus, the form of rule
printed and distributed (MED 1905, pp. xlvi, 877-878, 904ff; MED shaped both the gains and the limitations in education development dur-
1906, xxxii; MED 1907, 644-649). In all, the education ministry dis- ing the Aristocratic Republic (1895-1919) in Peru. Despite the fact that
tributed more than twenty-two books per l,ooo residents nationwide in elite preferences did not change during this period, their influence varied
1908, and implemented a curriculurn designed to inculcare students with with the institutional design of local administration. While delegated rule
knowledge of Peruvian geography and history (including the Inca heri- allowed elites to dilute education development, the deployed rule imple-
tage, the colonial period, the independence conflict, and the republican mented during this period lirnited their ability to do so, and this allowed
era) as well as moral, physical, and military education. Moral education the central state to substantially increase this aspect of the state's power.
was designed to transmit the "principal duties" of man to students: clean-
liness, work, temperance, school attendance, honor, honesty, courage, sav-
EXPLAINING CROSS-STATE DIVERGENCE IN MEXICAN
ings, payment of taxes, electoral duties, and military service (MED 1902,
EDUCATION
670-671; MED 1905, 905-906). These efforts to use schooling to unify
the population under the national banner represented a direct response Patterns of local administration also explain cross-state vanat10n in
to the chaos of the l88os and early l89os, and were seen as the means to Mexico. Policy design and implementation was largely left to the states
the "civilization of the indigenous and by that route their incorporation in Mexico's federal system. The fact that states set their own education
into the Peruvian nation." º 2
policy even for much of the Porfuiato makes this an ideal site to assess
The Civilista governrnents were pioneers in the deployment of educa- the relative power of institutional and structural factors in explaining the
tion officials from Lima to the nation's interior. The effects of this new variation in education development.
policy were dramatic in terms of increased education provision and state The national governrnent began to intervene in education only after
oversight. Local elites, however, remained hostile to education devel- the Liberals carne to power: a series of regulations issued after 1861 gave
opment. But the shift to deployed rule eliminated the opportunity they it influence over schooling in the Federal District and territories, serving
had to dilute its implementation. Instead, their hostility revealed itself as the model for similar consolidations in many Mexican states. By the
in active resistance to education officials deployed to their cornrnunities, l89os, many states had stripped municipalities of control over primary
which at times turned violent (see, for example, Jacobsen 1993, 212). schooling, and the national governrnent did so in the Federal District in
A more sweeping limitation of education development turned on the fact 1896. Despite the fact that policy was not formally coordinated across
that "despite its increased authority and reach, the central governrnent states, there was a great <leal of diffusion as states adopted policies similar
nevertheless continued to rely on the regional power of the gamonales to those introduced by the national governrnent in the Federal District.
[rural elites] to keep arder in the provinces" (Klarén 2000, 218). With Yet similar policies produced widely divergent results. The statisti-
cal analysis that follows uses state-level data on the composition of the
population and education development to show that social inequality
'' The figures that appear here are collected from various annual ministerial reports.
10
This quote is drawn from a r9or statement by Pedro Cisneros, president of the Supreme did not determine the development of schooling in Mexico. Neither the
Court of the Department of Ancash, cited in Contreras (1996). proportion of the population identified as indigenous, nor the extent of
State Building in Latin America

urbanization (used as a proxy for the repressive labor relations and social
inequality often associated with large-scale agriculture) has the effect
that the Sokoloff hypothesis would predict on literacy, primary educa- v<'l
vv
tion spending, or enrollment during the Porfuiato. A subsequent paired J' C'ln
00 00
comparison of education development in Michoacán and Sonora shows
........
°' °'
that where state governments delegated adrninistrative offices to local i:: i::
elites, education development lagged. By contrast, where bureaucrats ~ "' "'
ibib
::J ::J ::J
were deployed from outside the state, and had independent reasons to o
Vl ~~
seek education development, schooling thrived even in a context of high
social and economic inequality.
""
O°'C'lv
l'.\O "".,..,
""
v
00 C'l
....
....
.,..,
ó ó r-:. ó ó °' ""
oó ó ...; o ....
00
00 o ....
""
00 "" 00
v
Statistical Analysis ""'°'l'- C'l C'l C'l C'l
o \O o .... °'
.,.., o ....
The dependent variables are various measures of education development, o ó ó ó ó ó .;.., ó ó 00
.... 1 ....
most of which are available for twenty-seven of Mexico's thirty-one
H\OHH \O .... ('. v C'l o
states. (See Table 4.2 for descriptive statistics.) The central independent 00 l'. l'. C'l
........ o ....
00
o
\O 00 °' 00 o o
\O ""o C'l \O
""
,.¡
variables are the level of urbanization (drawn from Bazant I993, 94) and ó ó .._¡.. ó ó .... oó ó ó .,..,
""
..: .... 00
....
the proportion of the population identified as indigenous in the I 89 5 Vl °'

census. 21 .,.., v
00 ('.
C'l ,_.
Table 4.3 reports the results from six OLS regression analyses of the óC'l ó
effects of urbanization and social diversity on education provision by
state during the Porfuiato. Model I examines the determinants of enroll-
ment growth between I874 and I907. While spending growth is the most
significant contributor to enrollment growth, urbanization also has a sig- o ....
°'00 ('.
"""" C'l C'l C'l
nificant effect - although, surprisingly for the arguments of economic
historians discussed earlier, lower urbanization is associated with more
rapid enrollment growth. Model 2 repeats the analysis in Model I while
adding enrollment levels in I875 and state and municipal revenues in
I907 to the analysis. Here, urbanization remains significant and signed in
the unexpected (negative) direction. In neither model does the proportion
of the population that is identified as indigenous ha ve a significant effect.
Model 3 assesses the determinants of literacy rates in I9Io. Here, three
factors are significant: urbanization, school enrollment rates in I907, and
the proportion of the population that is identified as indigenous in I 89 5.

11)
" The r89 5 census provides data on the proportion of the population that spoke indig- 8
enous languages. This is, of course, a problematic way to conceptualize identity - in
particular because literacy in Spanish is itself a way to assess education development - z *
but it is the best available data. Repeating the analysis with data from the r92r census
produces very similar results (not shown here) to those presented here, in terms of both
significance and size of effects.

149
v Educational Development
H
o r5r
ci

** Urbanization - unlike in Models l and 2 - has a positive effect on lit-


* eracy. At first glance, the statistically significant finding far the effect of
the indigenous population appears to support the Sokoloff model. But
the data on indigenous population is based on linguistic categorization,
V V H H O\
o
H
r--..
which makes it particularly likely to be related to this measure of educa-
t'l'58g)' o o tion development, and thus this finding's irnport is limited.
ci ci ci ci ó ci
Models 4 and 5 examine the determinants of school enrollment in
* **
*O\ *CO co o ""' 1907. Model 4 examines the effect of social and economic inequality,
H H
O v o
H
H Ñ oO "'H O\
V
oO\ "'
o O v o H \DOt--..\D revenues, and spending on enrollment, and finds that only spending has
ci ci ci ci ó ci r--.. ci ci ci ci
1 1 Ñ H
an effect. Strikingly, the model is much more poorly :fitted than any of
«"\ Ñ Ñ Ñ O\ the others, which suggests the presence of an omitted variable in explain-
o oO\ oo
""' H O\
o o
ci ci ci ci ci ing state-level school enrollment. Adding the level of enrollrnent in 1875
** drastically alters the results: it is signi:ficant at the 99 percent level, and
*r--..
H
O\
«"\
Ñ
0
Ñ
o
*O\
co
sharply increases the R-squared. This suggests that there is something
Ñ o o o H
"sticky" about school enrollrnent: something structural that shapes its
ci ci ó ó ó
1 1 1
level that is not included in the models. 22

H
co
O\
Model 6 is perhaps the most direct test of the structural inequality-elite
O\ ~
ci co preferences argurnent, since it examines education spending levels in
r907. The analysis shows that state and municipal revenues and the
"°'
om vr--.. «"\ indigenous proportion of the population have a negative effect on pri-
"'
O\
«"\
o V \D
H
['.....Q\D
In
ci
1
r--..r-:.cicici
Ñ
mary school spending, the latter of which is significant at the 9 5 percent
level. But a l percent increase in the proportion of the population that
Ñ CO H
v ""' co
o
\D
tri
O
O\ V
t--..
('C"\
Ñ
o o speaks indigenous languages is predicted to reduce education spending
r-:. có ,.¡ r-:. ci ci
CO H
H
CO
H
H by .0044 pesos per capita, and since the standard deviation of 1907 edu-
cation spending levels is .28 pesos per capita, this is a negligible effect in
* substantive terms.
** *r--..
Ñ o "'«"\ "'Ñ
«"\ Ñ co o voo Overall, these results suggest that there is reason to doubt that social
H CO H 0 t'--. \D
ci r-:. r--.. c-Í ci ci ci
H Ñ H and economic inequality have a sizable linear effect on the development
of primary schooling. The scatterplots in Figure 4. l confirm this find-
H '<!" "°' «"\
ing: with a few exceptions (Campeche and the Yucatán) the data are
co "' r--.. Ñ

°'
""'v
\D \Ó
H
H
"°'
,.¡
o
ci consonant with the possibility that a low indigeneity rate is necessary
far schooling to develop. But given the wide variation among cases with
*
**
* similar levels of indigeneity, much of the variation across cases remains
*Ñ *
""' O\ *O\ unaccounted far by the demographic factor.
H H \D
Q v \D ""'
H

""'
v coó ..¡.
1
ci
Ñ 1 11
It is interesting to note that spending rates are not sticky over time in the same way
that enrollrnent rates are: the correlation between enrollrnent rates in r875 and r907 is
0.629, while the correlations for spending in r874 and r907 is only 0.248. Mariscal and
Sokoloff claim that social inequality matters because it shapes the institutions making
spending decisions, but this evidence suggests that schooling provision is more consistent
* over time than is school spending.
* ** **

r50
State Building in Latin America Educational Development 153

(a) 1.2 (e) 40


e COL
9COA

GSON
9CAM
9CHI 9SON GNL
GCOA
30

¡-...
o
())
.8 9TAM
eYUC
o
uw GCHI

GMOR
GCAM
,--
1 9NL o; GSIN eTLX evuc
-o ,-- 20 OZAC
e: .COL 1 GDUR
CD .6 SIN :.:::¡
a. QUEeOSLP MEXOOVER GHID
(/)
~gR 9TAB 9MOR OGUi'O MICH OPUE
e VER
.4 GAGU GHID 10 GOAX
GTLX GCHP
9JAL OGUE
GMEX GPUE
GSLP
9CHP GOAX
eTAB
.2 9GUAoQUE 9GUE
GMICH o
o .2 .4 .6 .8 o .2 .4 .6 .8
lndig 1895 lndig 1895
FIGURE 4.r. (continued)
(b) .5

To explore this further, we can leverage the fact that the forro of admin-
GTLX
e COA istration varied across Mexican states during the Porfuiato to examine
.4
whether it affected education developroent. To do so, 1 conduct a paired
GMOR
coroparison of the states of Sonora and Michoacán. As Figure 4.r shows,
¡-... Gfilr.M
o
())
GCOL similar proportions of the population in these two states spoke indige-
,-- GTAB
.3 nous languages in r 89 5 - in fact, Sonora hada larger indigenous segroent
,__1
e: ISJW GYUC
UJ 9CHI GSO~MEX GHID of its population, and was less urbanized than was Michoacán. Both of
GPUE
AGU
GCAM these characteristics roake it an unlikely site for education developroent.
eOUR GVER
.2 OJAL
GSLP Yet its levels of spending, enrollment, and literacy were rouch higher by
9GUE
eOAX
the eve of the Revolution in Sonora than in Michoacán. 3 2

The paired coroparison discussed later shows that in Sonora, econoroic


•GuA\~8~ eCHP
elites were excluded froro adrninistrative positions and thus unable to act
.1
on their preferences about taxation, spending, and policy. 4 By contrast, 2

o .2 .4 .6 .8
elites in Michoacán, although they held few political positions, did con-
lndig 1895
tinue to control adrninistrative positions and thus influence policy in a
FIGURE 4.r. Indigenous population and education indicators, Mexico
variety of realms. Deroonstrating that the forros of rule are correlated
Spending by state and municipal governments, 1907
Enrollment, 1907
i3 I chose to compare these two states because of the availability of excellent regional his-
Literacy, 1910
tories for both cases: DeHart (1984) and Voss (1982) for Sonora, and Chowning (1999)
for Michoacán.
'-! See García Alcaraz and Martínez Moya (2006) for a state-level education history of
Jalisco that emphasizes similar factors.
154 State Building in Latín America Educational Development 155

with education outcornes across Mexican states, particularly in conjunc- adrninistrators' preference for indiscrirninate deportation of the Yaqui
tion with the cross-national and cross-time findings in Chile and Peru, conflicted with local elites, who valued the Yaqui as "diligent, skilled, and
further buttresses the argurnent that they are crucial to the developrnent cheap workers in a sparsely populated region" (DeHart 1984, 180). In
of state power. irnplernenting their policies of pacification by force after 1902, the state
adrninistration (controlled by Luis Torres, an "outsider irnported into the
state") failed to consider "the opinions or interests of local hacendados
Sonora
and other Yaqui ernployers" (ibid., 183).
The Restored Republic and the Porfiriato - the era of state-building efforts This reliance on deployed rule affected educational developrnent. Whereas
in Mexico saw steady patterns of conflict between progress-seeking local notables were reluctant to fund prirnary education by approving new
adrninistrators and autonorny-craving local elites in Sonora. During the taxes, the state governrnent "had arnbitious plans" to spread education to
Porfiriato in particular, the governor irnposed policies on the state that rural areas (Voss 1982, 201 and 238). Because policy was irnplernented
inflicted significant costs on elites, and effectively irnplernented those pol- largely by the prefects, to the exclusion of local elites, educational spending
icies despite their opposition. Adrninistrators were able to do so because and educational developrnent were fairly high in Sonora.
"old landed elite farnilies ... were for the rnost part deliberately excluded
frorn the higher echelons of state power" (DeHart 1984, 183). While they
Michoacán
rnaintained their social standing, the "traditional gentry" were excluded
frorn state-level political and adrninistrative positions. This rneant that In Michoacán, on the other hand, power at the state level rernained in the
they were unable to prevent state officials frorn "rnaking policy decisions hands of "entrenched oligarchs" (Knight 1986, 38). Although Chowning
without sufficient consideration for local elite interests" (ibid., 191). (1999, 10) describes less overlap between political and econornic elites
Thus, DeHart argues, it is no surprise that Sonora was one of the centers than we rnight anticipate, the extent of elite influence over policy in
of elite opposition to the Díaz regirne after l 9 IO. Michoacán was rnuch higher than in Sonora. As a result, despite the fact
The exclusion of elites frorn crucial policy choices was a pattern dur- that local elites held few elected positions during the Restored Republic
ing the Restored Republic. Voss (1982) describes how state officials chal- or the Porfiriato, they continued to exercise influence over the policies
lenged local notables as they sought to institute econornic policies that of the state and local governrnents - although in "more oblique ways"
transcended local concerns. To do so, Governor Pesqueira relied heavily (ibid., 261) than befare the Liberal era.
on the power of the prefects, who he appointed, to reduce the autonorny Thus, while Sonora was characterized by deployed rule, Michoacán
of the rnunicipalities, and the influence of the "prorninent farnilies that saw rnuch more significant delegation of adrninistration to local elites
dorninated thern" (ibid., 208). Conflict between the prefects deployed by by the Liberal and Porfirian adrninistrations. It is not surprising, then,
the governor and the rnunicipalities dorninated state politics throughout that educational developrnent lagged in Michoacán - despite the fact that
the Restored Republic. Local elites sought to reforrn the state constitu- the state had a srnaller indigenous population, a more urban popula-
tion to rnake prefects accountable to elections, an effort defeated by the tion, and fewer fiscal constraints than did Sonora. "Despite rnany years
Governor, who sought to retain the power of appointrnent, and to use of state budget surpluses" (ibid., 333), educational developrnent lagged
it to deploy loyal bureaucrats to irnplernent his chosen policies (ibid., throughout the Porfiriato, and by l9IO the state was one of the laggards
251). By the time Díaz carne to power, policyrnaking was centralized in in the country as a whole in the number of schools, the number of trained
the hands of the governor and irnplernented largely by deployed bureau- teachers, and the developrnent of pedagogical training - although it had
crats - rnost notably the prefects, who acted as "underlings" and "hench- rnany private schools (Vaughan 1982, 55 and 61). Governors and adrnin-
rnen" of the governor (ibid., 2 79 ). istrators in Michoacán placated the state's elites by appointing thern to
Tensions between Sonoran elites and state officials were particu- "plurnrny offices" such as prefectures (Chowning 1999, 261). Frorn those
larly acute in regard to the Yaqui indigenous cornrnunity. While both positions, they would ha ve been able to disrupt policies airned at prirnary
groups saw the need to develop the Yaqui River valley for agriculture, school expansion, as well as other aspects of state building.
State Building in Latin America Educational Development 157

Educational development in Sonora outpaced that of Michoacán not development of education in Chile. They underlie the altered trajectory of
because Sonaran elites were more amenable to it. Instead, the difference educational development in Peru after l 89 5. And they also are correlated
was that Sonaran elites had been more broadly pushed out of the admin- with the state-level variation observed in Mexico. All this evidence, com-
istration by Liberal and Porfirian politicians, leaving them with less influ- bined with that presented about the development of taxation and mili-
ence over policy implementation. While economic elites in Michoacán tary development in Chapters 5 and 6, suggests strongly that the public
retained a degree of influence over policymaking in the state government, administration of state building was crucial for the fate of state-building
Sonaran elites saw even their hold over municipal administration chal- efforts.
lenged, as prefects deployed by the governor cut into the autonomy of
ayuntamientos and implemented policies (including school-building)
that impinged on the economic interests of the state's elites. This find-
ing confirms the overall results of this chapter: against explanations that
emphasize structural conditions in explaining patterns of educational
development in Latín America, evidence from Chile, Peru, and Mexico
supports the importance of the forro of rule in determining the outcomes
of efforts at school-building.

CONCLUSION

Only in Colombia was the absence of educational development the result


of a failure to undertake efforts to build this aspect of state power. 2 s Here,
national leaders never sought to build a primary school system - nor, as
we will see in the succeeding chapters, <lid they try to build other aspects
of state power. But in Peru befare 1895, and in sorne parts of Mexico,
educational development efforts failed because their implementation was
delegated to local elites. The Sokoloff hypothesis is correct to argue that
economic elites were reluctant to fund educational development, which
imposed taxation on them in the service of a goal they questioned. Where
they could dilute the grand plans of state-builders - as in Michoacán
and in Peru befo re l 89 5 - they did so. But where state builders bypassed
local elites and deployed bureaucrats to implement this aspect of their
state-building projects, the Sokoloff hypothesis is debunked, and school-
ing was built and standardized even in contexts of high social inequal-
ity. The institutions of local rule were the foundation of the precocious

is Unless one can show that Colombia was marked by substantially greater social inequal-
ity than were any of the other cases, the Sokoloff hypothesis is not sufficient to explain
the absence of efforts to build schools in that case. Although the large Afro-Colombian
population did create a degree of social inequality, its smaller indigenous population
(in comparison with the proportion of indigenous population in Peru or Mexico) casts
doubt on the possibility that Colombia saw dramatic levels of inequality by regional
standards.
Tax State Development I59

partial explanation for the divergent trajectories of the two countries in


5 which these were important historically: Chile and Peru. The presence of
resource booms explains the absence of taxation: 1 show that both states
dismantled their tax apparati as resources flowed in. But resource-based
Political Costs, Infrastructural Obstacles, and Tax explanations tell us little about what happens when resource rents dry
State Development up. Thus, the puzzle of why Chile recovered fiscally from the end of
the nitrate boom within a decade (despite significant political upheaval)
while Peru's fiscal crisis !asted half a century remains. A paired com-
parison of the post-boom efforts to tax in the two countries shows
that as opposed to the political costs of taxation that form the core of
resource-based explanations, the greater ability of the Chilean state to
overcome the infrastructural obstacles to taxation explains its quicker
recovery. The Chilean state's ability to tax derived from the fact that it
relied on deployed bureaucrats, while by contrast, the Peruvian state's
This chapter compares the development of the tax states in the four cases. post-guano efforts to tax were undermined by the unwillingness of
It finds that the Chilean and Mexican states established much greater local elites serving as state agents to overcome analogous obstacles to
extractive capacity than did their Peruvian and Colombian counterparts, taxation.
as reflected in the greater impositions they could place on the popula- A second explanation for variation in tax state development is the
tion, and in the wider range of types of taxes they could collect. The role of federalism. Mexico and Colombia provide a propitious context
chapter shows that the ideational and institutional arguments outlined in for examining this issue, since federal systems in both countries gave
Chapters I and 2 account for this variation in state development. Ideas subnational interests a platform to restrict taxation by the national gov-
about the role of the state in development shaped tax policy choices, ernment. Yet while federalism explains the origins of a distinct political
underlying the striking dismantling of the Colombian fiscal states and dynamic of taxation that was absent in Peru and Chile, it cannot explain
efforts to build extractive capacity in the other three cases. Institutions of the much greater tax state development in Mexico than in Colombia.
local administration determined the effectiveness of tax assessment and Here, again, we must turn to the role of ideas. Central governments in
collection where it was implemented. Colombia chose to pursue development through limited state interven-
As in all of the empirical chapters, the ideational and institutional tion, and to finance this small government with import duties, which
account 1 develop is counterposed here against a set of alternative expla- remained until the late I920S the dominant source of revenue. In Mexico,
nations that are particularly relevant for this aspect of state development. by contrast, state leaders drew on a more interventionist version of lib-
This chapter addresses two such alternatives - commodity booms and eralism, and sought the power to collect a wide range of other taxes. By
federalism - and shows that neither can account for the full pattern of negotiation and innovation, they steadily expanded the range of taxes
variation in tax state development. 1 argue that the key gap in both alter- collected by the federal government at the expense of the states. Thus
native explanations is similar - they both focus on political obstacles, while federalism established similar challenges in Mexico and Colombia,
which relate to formal political institutions, and ignore the infrastructural it cannot explain the divergent outcomes. Additionally, the Mexican case,
challenges of taxation, which relate to state capacity. like that of Chile, shows the crucial role of deployed rule, which ensured
Perhaps the most important alternative explanation for variation in the effective collection of taxes. Even more than in the realm of edu-
tax state development is that the presence of easily tapped revenue from cation (discussed in Chapter 4), the Porfirian state aggressively central-
commodity booms accounts for the absence of extractive capacity. Later, ized control over tax administration, and removed it from the hands of
1 show that booms and busts in nitrates and guano can provide at best a subnational government and local elites. The result, like in Chile, was
r6o State Building in Latín America Tax State Development r6r

significant development of a tax state; something that Colombian leaders TABLE 5.r. Revenue sources ranked by implications far state power
<lid not seek, and Peruvian leaders could not accomplish.
Tax type Nature of assessment Intensity of Territorial reach
Thus, the ideational and institutional arguments advanced in Chapters r needed penetration required
and 2 can better account for variation in tax state development than either required
of these two alternative explanations. To develop this argument, 1 begin by
Import duties Customs inspection at Low Low
discussing how we should measure the state's extractive capacity. The sec- port(s) of entry
ond part of the chapter describes the trajectories of tax state development Export taxes Inspection at Low Low
in the four cases. 1 then engage in two paired comparisons of the cases, production site or
each of which is designed to evaluate the power of my argument against port of exit
one of the alternative explanations. As discussed earlier, Peru and Chile Monopoly Control of Low Medium
production distribution
are paired to evaluate the commodity boom explanation, and the limits
Consumption taxes Control of Low Medium
of federalism as an explanation for variation in tax state development are distribution
explored in the narratives on Colombia and Mexico. Tolls, interna! duties, Inspection on roads/ Low Medium
and fees for rivers at certain
service points
OPERATIONALIZING TAX STATE DEVELOPMENT Professional license Audit of services Low Medium
fe es
Taxation is central to the study of state power and state-society relations. Sales taxes Audit of bills of sale Medium* Medium
But as Lieberman (2002) shows, different aspects of taxation shed light on Head taxes Census of population Medium High
different aspects of the state. Care is therefore needed in extrapolating from Land area taxes Land survey or Medium High
evidence about taxation to conclusions about the state. To assess the state's cadastral maps
infrastructural power, we must design measures that capture its ability to Income taxes Income data High High
Land value taxes Detailed land census High High
extract taxes from its population, and how that ability varíes across society
Taxes on non-land Detailed property High High
and territory. To do so, this study explores two dimensions of taxation: the wealth census
types of revenue collected by the state and the tax burden per cap ita imposed
on the population. Because the commonly used tax ratio conflates the state's * This assessment is based on the limited set of transactions that were subject to sales taxes
in the cases under investigation. As this set of transactions expands, this tax would move
capacity to tax with the regime's willingness to do so, 1set it aside and opt for higher in the rankings of intensity.
these more fine-grained assessments of the extractive capacity of the state.

TaxTypes a state that relies heavily on customs duties - collected only at major
ports of entry and exit requires little in terms of extractive capacity
Scholars often draw conclusions about state power from information on throughout the vast remainder of its national territory, while the taxa-
the types of taxes collected by the national government (Chaudhry 1999 ). tion of domestic commerce, wealth, or income likely requires the state to
The requirements for collection vary across tax types in two ways rele- have a much greater reach. Second, taxes vary in the difficulty of assess-
vant to infrastructural power. First, taxes vary in their spatial distribution ment and collection required to extract revenue. For example, it is easier
of incidence. Those taxes that can be collected in a small number of cen- (although less precise) to impose a tax based on the area of land owned
tral locations require a more skeletal administrative apparatus than do than a tax on the value of land, or to impose customs duties by weight
those that require the presence of agents throughout the territory. r Thus, rather than by value (Scott 1998).
By combining these two dimensions, as shown in Table 5.1, we can
' In addition to the implications of a tax type for the spatial reach of the state, I also discuss
the available evidence about spatially uneven imposition and collection of taxes. array the range of state revenue sources by the extent of infrastructural
State Building in Latín America Tax State Development

power required for their collection. 2 Each row of the table represents a the discussion of Chile and Peru to parse out the effects of the commod-
significant source of state revenue in the countries investigated in this ity booms in those cases. I also highlight how the federal institutions in
study. They are listed in increasing arder of infrastructural power: those Colombia and Mexico posed obstacles to tax collection by the national
at the top of the chart require only minimal levels, while those at the state. Yet once these factors are accounted for, we will see that the cases
bottom imply a truly capable state. The second colurnn briefly describes follow patterns similar to those seen in our investigations of educa-
typical collection procedures as they are reflected in records examined for tion and coercion: the absence of a state-building project in Colombia,
the four cases; the rightmost two columns assess the two dimensions of state-building efforts in Peru stymied by reliance on delegation to local
collection challenges for that tax type. In the remainder of this chapter, elites, which allowed those actors to block fiscal imposition, and con-
I use the distribution of state revenues according to this ranking to assess certed, successful state building in Mexico and Chile that depended cen-
its ability to penetrate society for extractive purposes. While there may be trally on the implementation efforts of deployed local officials.
sorne debate over the scoring of particular tax types, the overall pattern
for any case should be robust to any disputes about where an individual
Tax Types
tax type should be placed in this table.
Chile
Extractive capacity grew sharply in Chile in the first century after inde-
TaxBurden
pendence, as reflected in the growth of direct taxation, and in the rise of
I also use the tax burden: the amount of taxation imposed by the state internal taxation as a complement to customs revenues, which neverthe-
directly on its citizens as a second measure of the extractive dimension less remained the most important source of state revenues throughout
of state power.3 I exclude duties on the exports of raw materials, monop- the period. Although direct taxation declined with the nitrate boom after
oly profits, and customs duties because they are not imposed directly on I88o, gains in the state's extractive capacity were not lost. The changing
the population. Thus, the tax burden is calculated by summing taxes on composition of the Chilean tax structure is summarized in the series of
income, property, and wealth, sales taxes, inheritance taxes, and various snapshots in Table 5.2.
fees for service and permits, and dividing this quantity by the size of the Pre-nitrate tax state development: After independence, the Chilean
population. This provides a measure of the average amount of revenue state relied heavily on foreign debt and asset confiscation, reflecting its
extracted by the state per capita directly from its citizens. This amount weakness 4 (MHAC I834, 3ff). Limited revenues carne mainly from cus-
can be calculated at the national leve!, and compared across time or toms takings and monopolies: the state lacked the capacity to assess and
across countries with appropriate adjustments for inflation and purchas- collect taxes directly from the population. In I840, only about 2 percent
ing power where possible. By combining information on the tax burden of government revenue carne from internal taxation. But interna! taxa-
with information on the broader set of revenue sources of the state, we tion increased almost forty-fold between I840 and I875, rising to 20%
can get a nuanced picture of its power to tax. of total revenue by I 84 5 and remaining steadily above rn percent until
I885. Thus, between about I840 and the War of the Pacific (I879-I883),
the Chilean state developed extensive tax capacity.
COMPARATIVE DEVELOPMENT
This period also saw a change in the types of interna! taxes col-
I begin with a surnmary of the comparative development of taxation in lected. In I 840, interna! tax revenue carne entirely from monopoly rents
the four cases so that the variation to be explained is clearly shown. The on tobacco, playing cards, and salt. A tithe collected from the heads of
discussion that follows reveals striking variation across cases. I periodize households rose in prominence, and made up the majority of tax collec-
tion in Chile in both I845 and I850. In I853, the contribución territorial
, Lieberman (2002, table 3) produces a similar list, butTable 5.r arrays the actual revenue
sources that were used by states in the four cases.
J A helpful discussion of how to choose among the myriad options for operationalizing this
4 Data in this discussion draws on the MHAC for various years and the statistical series in
concept appears in Lieberman (2002). Mamalakis (1976) and Wagner et al. (2000).
State Building in Latin America Tax State Development

TABLE 5.2. Chilean revenue sources, selected years nitrate revenue, in 1902 a tax on alcohol was introduced, followed by
Tax type I84I r86o r875 r895 r927 a tax on insurance companies in 1905, on tobacco, playing cards, and
inheritances in 1910, and on banks in 1912 (Bowman and Wallerstein
Customs duties 59.0% 59.r% 57.3% 3r.6% 28.2%
1982, 451). The introduction of these taxes, however, does not undo the
Resource rents 7.3% 62.3% 28.3%
Monopoly production 2r.2% 14.5% r3.1% overall trend of heavy dependence on nitrate revenues during the early
Consumption taxes twentieth century.
Tolls, interna! duties, and 3.9% Nitrate exports began to falter during World War I befare collaps-
fees for service ing in 1920, and government revenues plumrneted. In response, the state
Professional license fees turned back to internal taxation, which tripled between 1913 and 1920,
Sales taxes 3.5%
Head taxes II.6% at which point it was fifty times the 1900 level. By 1920, the Chilean
Land area taxes o.o% state was generating over 25 percent of its income from internal taxa-
Income taxes 9.J'Yo tion, relying heavily on a property tax introduced in 1915 that generated
Land value taxes 7.1% 7.9% over 5 million pesos annually. By the mid-192os, the Chilean state had
Taxes on non-land 7.9% not just returned to its pre-nitrate levels of extractive capacity, but was
wealth
actually stronger than it had been prior to the nitrate boom. Although
Source: Wagner et al. (2000). the capacity-intensive taxes introduced between 1840 and the onset of
the nitrate boom disappeared during the boom, they quickly reemerged
thereafter. Rather than being replaced by customs revenues, the lost
(a 7.II percent tax on the value of landholdings) was introduced, which resource rents were replaced with increases in domestic taxation. In
by I 8 5 5 made up the largest portian of internal taxation, about 3 7. 5 per- Chile, the nitrate boom had limited long-term effects on the fiscal state. It
cent of the total internal tax collected. This tax represented a significant is this strikingly fast recovery from the collapse of the nitrate boom that
leap in the state's infrastructural power, since it inaugurated the assess- sets Chile apart from the Peruvian experience.
ment of property holdings by the state - sorne 3 l,ooo properties, for
instance, in 186r. In the 187os, as the country was gripped by economic Peru
crisis, taxes on inheritance, property, and income were introduced (Sater As discussed in Chapter 3, the Peruvian state was unique in that domestic
1976, 326ff). By 1882, these taxes were the third most important source taxation actually made up a significant share of its revenue in the initial
of revenue. While this trajectory of increasing capacity was cut short by decades after independence. The head tax on the indigenous population
the onset of the nitrate boom after l 8 8 5, it is clear that extractive capac- represented the second largest share of tax revenue in 1846, suggesting a
ity had grown sharply since 1840. state that could impose extraction on its population. Head tax collection
The nitrate boom and national government taxation: With victory in was actually rather effective in the l 84os as the government was able to
the War of the Pacific, Chile seized massive nitrate fields from Peru and collect more revenues than it had projected.s With the onset of the guano
Bolivia. Nitrate proceeds drove a near-doubling in government revenues boom in the l84os, interna! taxation was eliminated. The state's extrac-
between 1886 and 1890, and dominated them until the end ofWorld War tive capacity would remain vestigial long after the boom ended in the
l. In response, the national government eliminated nearly all other forms 187os. The trends are sumrnarized in the snapshots in Table 5-3-
of taxation (Mamalakis 1976, 213). Internal taxes declined to a tenth of Guano and the decay of the Peruvian tax state, 1845-1875: As guano
their l 8 8 5 level by l 89 5, and by l 900, the only one remaining was the revenues flowed after the mid-184os, the state began a "step-by-step
papel sellado. dismantling of surviving direct taxes" (Gootenberg 1989, 122). The
Reliance on nitrate duties left state revenues vulnerable to fluctua- most drama tic step was the l 8 54 elimination of the head tax. This shift
tions in the nitrate market, and this concern drove state leaders to begin
to reintroduce taxation even at the height of the boom. To supplement 5
Data in Tantaleán Arbulú (I983), Appendix, Table Four, rny calculations.
166 State Building in Latin America Tax State Development

TABLE 5 .3. Peruvian revenue sources, selected years r997). Postwar governments also introduced consumption taxes on
1890 1923-1924
alcohol, tobacco, opium, matches, and salt. None of these required sig-
Tax type 1846 1865
nificant intensity of penetration, since they were assessed on distributors
Customs duties 26.3% 22.0% 48.2% 42.5% rather than on sellers and consumers. The costs these taxes imposed
Resource rents 8.4% 75. 2 % on the population also prompted majar revolts, and collection also suf-
Monopoly production
Consumption taxes 15.3% 24.4% fered from smuggling and evasion. Thus, after guano collapsed, the state
Tolls, internal duties, and fees remained strikingly weak, a sharp contrast to the recovery of extractive
for service capacity seen in Chile.
Professional license fees The civilista tax state and its limits, r895-I9I9: The recovery of
Sales taxes extractive capacity was strikingly slow by comparison to Chile. One
Head taxes
set of obstacles was political. In an attempt to generate revenue, state
Land area taxes
Income taxes officials confronted political opposition as they sought to tax recover-
Land value taxes ing commodity exports: mine owners gained a fifteen-year exemption in
Taxes on non-land wealth r890, and sugar producers blocked any export tax on agricultura! prod-
ucts (Thorp and Bertram r978, 30). But the most important obstacle was
So11rces: Tantaleán Arbulú (r983, Appendix), Extracto Estadístico del Perú r929-r930,
and Contreras and Cueto (r999, 2r8). the simple inability to effectively extract revenue from the population.
This forced the state to continue to fill its coffers mainly from consump-
tion taxes, import duties, and foreign loans.
"significantly lessened the presence of the guano-era state in the high- The state did generate significant revenue from what its records call
lands" where the indigenous population was concentrated (Klarén 2000, "direct taxes" in the early twentieth century: these generated 14.6 per-
163 ). As the state carne to rely more heavily on guano revenue, its ability cent of annual government revenue between r899 and r939 - about
to penetrate the national periphery disappeared, and its extractive capac- half the level of consumption taxes (28.8 percent) and customs revenues
ity sharply eroded. Dependence on guano even replaced customs as a (3 2.8 percent). 6 While this appears to reflecta state with significant infra-
source of income. Guano revenues became a form of emergency finance, structural power, a more detailed look undercuts that view.7 The label
as state dependence on loans rose. To maximize up-front revenue, the "direct tax" was deeply misleading: revenue in this category included fees
state auctioned off gross export rights to whoever could provide the larg- on mining and agricultura! exports, charges for professional and indus-
est up-front loan most quickly, rather than collect even per-ton taxes on trial licenses (collected only in Lima and Callao), and a tax on indus-
the guano (Gootenberg r993). There was, in short, no fiscal state in Peru trial company revenue. Thus although "direct taxes" contributed to the
by the end of the guano era. recovery of the Peruvian tax state after about r9r5, this does not reflect
Post-guano crisis, r875-r895: In the aftermath of the guano collapse, increased infrastructural power. Instead, the Peruvian tax state remained
Peru entered a majar crisis of state that incorporated defeat in the War of vestigial, depending for the vast majority of its revenues on customs,
the Pacific, the resulting loss of its nitrate :fields, severa! years of Chilean tobacco and salt monopolies, and consumption taxes on alcohol and
occupation, and a decade of interna! conflict. Given this litany of disas- other commodities. The contrasting post-boom trajectories of Chile and
ters, it is no surprise that the state found taxation difficult. Postwar Peru are explored in detail later.
governments sought revenue by reintroducing a head tax and by fis-
cal decentralization that made departments responsible for their own 6
These figures are based on rny calculations frorn data in various years of the Extracto
expenses. The head tax made up about 50 percent of budget projections, Estadístico.
7 Unfortunately, little data about the cornposition of the category labeled "direct taxes" is
but collection fell far short of this amount (Thurner r997, ro5). While available before r925. The discussion here is based on data frorn r925-r93r, and its util-
generating little revenue, the introduction of the head tax, as discussed ity depends on the assurnption that infrastructural power was not lower in r925 than in
further later, triggered the largest uprising since independence (Thurner preceding decades - a reasonable clairn given a holistic view of Peruvian history.
168 State Building in Latin America Tax State Development

Commodity booms did not sharply distort fiscal development in our TABLE 5 .4. Colombian revenue sources
other two cases, so the presentation of their fiscal evolution does not Tax type 1835-1836 1870 1911 1927
require the same periodization. It does, however, require addressing the
role of federalism, which affected tax policy in both countries. Customs duties 36.4% 54.6% 65.3% 62%
Resource rents
Monopoly production 53.1% 26.3% 7.8% 5.5%
Colombia Consumption taxes
The limited development of Colombia's tax state can clearly be seen in Tolls, Interna! duties, and fees for 8.8% rr.5%
Table 5 .4. In the first quarter century after independence, the Colombian serv1ce
state generated most of its revenue from three sources: customs reve- Professional license fees
Sales taxes 0.4% 4.8% 2.4%
nue (3 r.3 percent), the tobacco monopoly (24.5 percent), and the salt
Head taxes
monopoly (12. 3 percent). 8 As of l 8 50, the Colombian state collected no Land area taxes
direct taxes. This pattern continued throughout the first century after Income taxes
independence: the state continued to rely heavily on customs revenue and Land value taxes
monopoly production. This failure to develop any tax capacity left the Taxes on non-land wealth
state vulnerable to fluctuations in world trade, and unable to impose any Sources: Deas (1982, 326 fnrno), McGreevey (1971, 40), Park (1985, 56), Cruz Santos
taxes on its population. (1966, 141). Sales taxes were primarily generated from papel sellado, and fees for service
The Liberal Refarms after r849 involved two significant changes to are overwhelmingly from railroads.
taxation. Both reflect the disdain far the state held by Colombia's Liberals
in their development vision. First, a wide range of taxes (most impor- in 1865 (Park 1985, 57-58). Although the salt monopoly violated the
tantly the tax on alcohol) were devolved to subnational authorities, who Liberal edict of mínima! government, and was highly unpopular, it was
would thereafter retain a great degree of fiscal autonomy. Despite spo- retained because it was "simply too important to be eliminated" once
radic policy initiatives and the nominally centralist character of the l 8 8 6 other revenue sources were gane (Rosenthal 2001, 28). Another signifi-
constitution, taxation thereafter remained largely in the hands of subna- cant source of revenue was the degüello tax on cattle slaughter. Deas
tional units (Cruz Santos 1966, 40-41). Second, the tobacco monopoly describes this tax as both progressive (since the poor did not eat beef)
and many other taxes were eliminated in l 8 50, resulting in a 4 7 per- and fairly easy to collect since it was rare far cows to be slaughtered
cent decline in national government revenues between 1849 and 1851 9 exclusively far personal consumption, meaning that they had to be
(McGreevey 1971, 86). Refarmers hoped that eliminating the tobacco brought to market.ro In 1874, it was the main revenue source far the
monopoly would spur economic growth via tobacco export, allowing the country's subnational entities (Deas 1982, 305-307). When the national
national government to draw revenue from duties on increased imports. government claimed jurisdiction over it in the 1886 constitution, it
Absent other sources of revenue, dependence on customs increased after quickly became the third largest source of revenue in the budget (Cruz
1850. These generated 63 percent of national government revenues Santos 1966, 38-41).
from 18 50 to1900 (Rosenthal 2001, 3 3-34). Import duty collection was Although the economy was transfarmed by the boom in coffee pro-
limited by the rampant smuggling in Caribbean ports (Posada-Carbó duction after l 8 8 7, no direct revenue far the state resulted. An l 89 5
1996, 228). propasa! to tax coffee exports was met with majar opposition not only
Salt taxes also remained significant, making up 16 percent of national from coffee producers but from those who saw the tax as a violation
revenues between 1850 and 1900, and reaching as high as 29 percent of laissez-faire principies (Bergquist 1986, 52). With the trade crisis of
8 These figures are drawn from Rosenthal (2001) and are based on annual data for
World War I, an income tax was introduced in 1918, but it generated
twenty-one years between 1824 and 1850. l. 7 percent of government revenues in l 9 l 9 and remained marginal
• Park (1985, 54) cites an 1870 calculation claiming that the reforms cost the govemment
half its potential income between 1850 and 1870. 'º Posada-Carbó (1996, 217) disagrees.
170 State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 171

well into the 193os. Even in the late 192os, customs represented 62 per- TABLE 5.5. Mexican revenue sources, selected years
cent of government revenue, and railroad fees l r. 5 percent. Salt sales Tax type 1856 1873 1895 1910
remained significant at 5. 5 percent of revenues, while papel sellado
and the income tax remained of minimal importance, at 2.4 percent Customs duties 67.4% 68.5% 44.9% 44.4%
Resource rents
and r. 5 percent, respectively (Deas l 9 8 2, 3 2 5). The composition of
Monopoly production
tax types continued to reflect a strikingly weak state. Although this Consumption taxes
was in part a function of the devolution of taxes to the subnational Tolls, interna! duties, and fees 7.0% n% 6.3%
leve!, it also reflected the belief of Colombian political elites that for service
increasing state fiscal capacity would not promote the development Professional license fees
they sought. Sales taxes 12.8% 35.7% 29.6%
Head taxes
Land area taxes
Mexico Income taxes
Mexico's federal constitution, like Colombia's, limited the taxes available Land value taxes 3.2% 3.2% 5.7%
to the national government. Yet its trajectory of tax state development Taxes on non-land wealth
was distinct, as Liberal and Porfirian officials made aggressive efforts to
Source: Carmagnani (1994, Appendix 3), Tenenbaum (1986, Appendix, Tables A and C).
reduce their reliance on customs revenues by developing the capacity of Despite its changing composition over time, I ceded the timbre as a sales tax for ali years.
the national state to tap many revenue streams. The evolution of tax This coding decision is chosen in order to understate the capacity of the Mexican state,
types in Mexico reveals two broad trends (see Table 5.5). First, it reveals since over time, the timbre carne to encompass a range of tax types. The land value tax, the
contribución predial, was collected only in Mexico City and the federal territories.
a steady increase in reliance on interna! taxation. Second, this interna!
taxation is increasingly composed of revenue sources that require sig-
nificant infrastructural power. Together, these changes show that the The centerpiece of reform was the introduction of the timbre in l87r.
Mexican state increased its capacity to extract from its population dur- Generating atleast 29 percent of revenue every year between 1890 and the
ing the Liberal and (especially) the Porfirian eras. This increase was also revolution, the timbre became the most important interna! tax collected
reflected in the penetration of land surveys, census adrninistration, and by the federal government. The timbre contained multiple components,
state regulation of property rights even into remate regions like Chiapas which carne over time to include more infrastructurally demanding tax
(Bobrow-Strain 2007, 52ff). types. In its original forro, it was comprised of the contribución federal, a
In the post-independence era (1821-1867) 62.3 percent of state rev- surcharge on ali state and local taxes, and a stamp tax levied on official
enues carne from customs duties (Pérez Siller 2004, 50). Endernic internal documents and the consumption of certain luxury goods. An important
conflict often prevented customs revenues from reaching federal cof- institutional innovation in the contribución federal was a shift in the bur-
fers, and allowed challengers to national power to use customs revenue den of this surcharge from state governments to taxpayers, which ended
to fund insurrection (Ludlow 2002, Vol. l, p. 336). Beginning with the conflict between levels of government over tax revenues (Castañeda
first Liberal governments, leaders sought to reduce dependence on cus- Zavala 2001; Uhthoff 2004). Between 1867 and l9IO, it represented 7 to
toms, driven by these concerns, but also by a belief that export taxes l 3 percent of total federal revenue. In nominal terms, contribución fed-
were an obstacle to econornic development. Early efforts fell victim to eral revenues grew fivefold between 1867 and 1906, declining slightly on
political instability, and interna! taxation by the federal government the eve of the revolution. This tax appears consonant with a weak state,
largely remained limited to duties on the transit of goods into the Federal since it required little penetration of the economy by the federal govern-
District and the territories of Baja California and Tepic (the a/cábala). But ment. But Uhthoff (2004) shows that the contribución federal led to the
after 1867 política! stability allowed state leaders to begin the building construction of a direct relationship between the central state and its
of extractive capacicy. citizens because it relied on federal tax collectors to inspect the state and
172 State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 1 73
local tax bilis of citizens throughout the national territory. This process 14
of revenue centralization shows how the Mexican state steadily worked El TAX SURDEN
to overcome the obstacles of federalism to fiscal capacity. 1111 DIRECTTAX SURDEN
12
Over time, the set of revenue sources included in the timbre increased,
revealing a state inserting itself into an increasingly wide range of eco-
nomic activity. Taxes on tobacco, alcohol, and perfume were added in 10
1881 (Carmagnani 1989, 478). State officials responded to complaints
from producers of these goods about the unfair burden imposed on their
sectors by this new tax: rather than exempting the complaining indus- 8
tries, they increased the scope of the tax to also include soaps, pharma-
ceuticals, playing cards, textiles, and sorne foods. The renta interior, a tax
6
on the consumption of all domestic manufactured goods beyond basic
needs, was introduced in 1887 (Carmagnani 1989, 483). As discussed
later, this tax was eliminated in 1893 in negotiations between federal
4
and state governments over the balance of fiscal federalism. Yet its intro-
duction and the collections that resulted reflect a sharply more powerful
central state than existed severa! decades earlier. 2
Thus, the increasing revenues generated from interna! taxes and the
broader range of economic activity and wealth on which they fell reflect
significant growth in the state's extractive capacity. Whereas at the begin-
ning of the Liberal period, the state generated no revenues from interna!
taxation outside the Federal District, it generated more than 40 per-
FIGURE 5.I. Clúlean tax burden in pesos per capita, selected years, 1833-1938.
cent of its revenues from domestic taxation in 1910. This trajectory is a
Data from Wagner et al. (2000).
sharp contrast from what was observed in Colombia, where federalism
also created political obstacles to the extractive power of the national
government. built the ability to impose taxes on its population. The onset of the
nitrate boom led the tax burden to disappear as interna! taxation was
essentially eliminated, although it slowly crept up as the instability of
TaxBurden nitrate revenues spurred diversification of revenue streams. With the
In addition to the types of taxes a state collects, we can also assess its nitrate collapse, the tax burden leaped back up. By 1920, real interna!
capacity to extract by examining the tax burden it imposes on its pop- taxation per capita was already 50 percent higher than its pre-nitrate
ulation. As explained earlier, this tax burden is measured by per cap- leve!, and by 1930, the Chilean state's extraction from its population
ita interna! taxation. A comparison of the four countries (to the extent had tripled once again. Thus we see a state that developed the power to
allowed by data limitations) reveals striking divergence, even after the tax befare the nitrate boom, stopped taxing as resource rents flowed in,
effects of the resource booms in Chile and Peru are taken into account. but quickly and aggressively reasserted its power to tax once the nitrate
The tax burdens in Chile and Mexico far outstripped those in Peru and boom ended.
Colombia. Municipal taxation in Chile: In addition to national government tax-
ation, Chileans were subject to municipal taxes. Municipalities could get
Chile national government permission to impose certain taxes, most of which
The inflation-adjusted trajectory of the Chilean tax burden is shown were earmarked for a particular purpose such as the operation of butch-
in Figure 5. I. O ver the course of the pre-18 8 5 era, the state steadily eries, street lighting, and street cleaning. From the mid-185os through
174 State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 1 75

1881, these taxes grew steadily. 11 The average municipal tax burden 12
per capita (nominal data, based on a population-weighted average of
sixty-two rnunicipalities) rose frorn slightly over 0.5 pesos per capita in
10
l 869 to over 2 pesos perca pita during the War of the Pacific. As explored
l 11 TAX BURDEN 1
in more detail later, municipal taxation rose after the 1891 decentral-
ization and continued to do so throughout the nitrate boom. In 1903, 8
municipal taxes were two pesos per capita, rising to 4.2 pesos per capita
in 1911, and 9.9 in 1920. 12
6
Municipal taxes were one way in which revenue was extracted frorn
the Chilean population even during the resource boom. The revenues gen-
erated by municipal taxation flowed into the coffers of local adrninistra- 4
tion, not those of the central state. Thus, at first glance it appears that this
taxation is irrelevant to an analysis of national state developrnent. Yet
2
there are two reasons to ternper this view. First, this taxation was under
the authority of the national state: it had to be explicitly authorized by
the national governrnent. Municipal authorities had to explain the type
of tax they wanted to collect, and the purpose far which it would be
,cor¡,'<>,con;,~,93'-'<>,9!-'\._93'-co,93'-°",co<o~,co<o~co<or¡,,co<o<>:>,co<o"'",co<o<o,co<o'<>,co<o'\._co<oco,co<o°",co'<>~,co'<>~co'<>\co'<><>:>,co'<>co,q;.~q;.'1-,q;.<>:>
earrnarked, in arder to be authorized to irnpose it. l3 Second, as explored
in more detail later, this municipal taxation was pivota! in the rapid reas- FIGURE 5.2. Peruvian tax burden, soles per capita, selected years, 1849-1873.
sertion of national taxation when the nitrate trade collapsed. Because Sources: Memorias of Ministerio de Hacienda, various years and Tantaleán Arbulú (198 3 ).
rnunicipalities continued to collect taxes and rnaintain the relevant infra-
structure, the challenges to reirnposing taxation that national authorities
faced were greatly reduced. a few cities. During the guano era, the provinces were abandoned as sites
of revenue collection even though de jure their population was subject
Pern to the few taxes that rernained on the books. This absence of the state
The evolution of the tax burden over time shows very clearly the weak- frorn the interior can be seen in various kinds of tax collections. Table 5 .6
ness of the Peruvian state. The contrast with Chile during and after the shows no collection of license fees far businesses and industries in ten
cornrnodity boorns in both countries is especially striking, and will be of the nineteen departrnents, and no taxation at ali in sorne Arnazonian
explored in detail la ter. The data in Figure 5 .2, calculated frorn the surn departrnents. The overwhelrning rnajority of collections were frorn just
of all direct interna! taxes far the years available during the guano boom, five departrnents: Lima and its port of Callao, and Arequipa, Junín, and
show that the elimination of the contribución indígena reduced internal Cuzco, which contained the largest secondary cities in the country. The
taxes per capita by nearly 90 percent. Thereafter, the state irnposed a tax state sirnply <lid not exist outside a few large cities.
rninirnal burden on its population. After the end of the guano boom, as discussed earlier, the Peruvian state
The territorial unevenness of tax collection also reveals the tax state's struggled to re-irnpose taxes. Befare 1900 it was unable to generate any
weakness. Taxation during the guano era was alrnost nonexistent, outside revenue at all frorn irnpositions on its population. The tax burden rose
tenfold between 1899 and 1920 - and although this data (in Figure 5.3)
" Based on twenty-one years of municipal tax data, r8 56-r89r, collected from various are not corrected far inflation, this <loes represent a real increase. 4 This 1

governrnent sources. reveals a state that gradually gained the ability to irnpose taxes on its
., Calculated from nominal municipal tax data from Marnalakis (1976). The value for
r920 is calculated using r92r population data. 1 14
' l This was true even after the r89r decentralization law. The price index needed in order to correct for inflation during this period does not exist.

1
Tax State Development 177

O\
\.O
00 12
H
1 Jlil Tax Surden 1

10
,..... .!!!
\.O
00
·o.
al
H (} 8
(¡;
c.

~~
(/)
'O
§ 6
o
a..
e:
-~ 4

~~j
2Q)

:~~~I~
a..

,.....
\.O 1899 1901 1903 1905 1907 1909 1911 1913 1915 1917 1919
00
H Year
FIGURE 5.3. PeruviantaxburdeninPeruvianpoundspercapita, 1899-1920.
o o~
o o Sources: Memorias of Ministerio de Hacienda, various years.
Ñ >-:
00 Ñ
\.O \.O

population, overcoming significant obstacles, both political and infra-


structural. Yet this finding must be tempered, as discussed earlier, by a
realization that most of these taxes were far from capacity-intensive: the
Peruvian state <lid increase its ability to extract during the Civilista
era, but could only rely on certain kinds of revenue. Thus its cápacity
remained far lower than that of its southern neighbor.

Colombia

~°&~
O\
00
H
Because it relied primarily on import duties, the Colombian state never
\.O
00
H
imposed a significan! burden in direct taxes on its population. Indeed, even
H
including indirect taxes and all other sources of revenue, the "weight" of the
,.....
\.O
O~~<'l
v-.
H
o rn
H H
V-.
~ m~n ~
state was quite limited. An 1871 estímate, quoted by Malcolm Deas (1982,
3 lo) was that government revenues, at less than one peso per capita, were
00 H
H one-third the level of Mexico's, one-fifth those of Chile, and one-twelfth
"'
00

...
O\
those of guano-flush Peru. Revenues only declined from this level: an 1898
estímate pegged the per capita tax income of the national government,
~
\O 00 00 "<!"
Ñ \O O rn O\
<'l \O \O
H
including both interna! and customs revenues, at 80 centavos, a decline in
real terms of 20 percent over the previous twenty years (ibid., 313).
\.O
Additionally, as in Peru, many parts of Colombian society and
1
territory remained exempt from even this limited tax burden. The
state never developed any tax capacity in the Llanos federal territo-
ries, which were under national government control. Property rights

176
l
1
1
State Building in Latin America Tax State Development 179

3.5 they had grown to 3.2 3 pesos, as seen in Figure 5.4. This increase of nearly
1 l'lil Taic Burden 1
800 percent must far exceed the inflation rate. Thus the trend of increasing
3 the tax burden is still quite clear, and is consonant with the overall pattern
of increasing fiscal capacity in Mexico described earlier.
2.5

EXPLAINING VARIATION IN TAX CAPACITY


2
Because taxation lies at the core of the state's capacity, scholars have
focused on its development in studying state building and state-society
1.5
relations. Two robust currents of literature - one on the effects of com-
modity booms and the other on federal institutions as an obstacle to tax
state development - have received much attention in recent years. In the
following paired comparisons, I show the lirnitations of each of these
0.5 explanations in accounting for variation across our four cases.
I begin with the comparison of Chile and Peru, both of which saw
o 111111111 1 1 their fiscal development distorted by massive commodity booms. The
paired analytic narrative that follows reveals the lirnits of "resource
curse" explanations in their inability to account for variation in tax state
FIGURE 5 .4. Mexican tax burden in pesos per capita, 1867-1910.
development outside these exceptional periods. To account for the rapid
Sources: Interna! raxarion is calculared from data in Carmagnani (1994, Appendix 3).
Popularion data are taken from Meyer and Sherman (1995, 466). recovery of Chile from commodity collapse, and the absence of a similar
trend in Peru, I show that we must shift from the politics of taxation to its
adrninistration, and highlight the role of local state agents in deterrnining
were completely absent from the region of Casanare, and a land the state's capacity to tax.
transfer tax could not be collected because no titles were on file with
the government (Rausch 1993, r74, 306). The limited spatial reach
of the state was also reflected in customs collections: over 90 per- Deciding to Tax: Resource Rents and Political Costs
cent of customs revenues carne from only four ports: Santa Marta,
Resource endowments are perhaps the factor most commonly cited to
Sabanilla-Barranquilla, Cartagena, and Buenaventura (Park r985,
explain the state's extractive capacity. 1 s As Dunning (2008, 46) writes,
56). Little tax was collected from the steady flow of cattle and other
a broad consensus holds that "resource booms lead to a decline in tax-
goods across the Venezuelan border. Sixty-two and a half percent of
ation anda decimation of extractive efforts on the part of the state." 16
salt revenue between I 8 5 5 and I 897 was generated from a single
The logic is that because taxation is more politically costly than the
salt mine complex, Zipaquirá (Rosenthal 2001, 34). In all, the state
generated much of its revenue from a few isolated locations where 1
s Mosr scholars use resource dependence (share of government revenue generared from
it enjoyed sorne degree of control; much of the rest of the country resource renrs) rarher rhan resource abundance (share of GDP generated from resource
remained outside the reach of its fiscal bureaucracy. rents) ro idenrify cases where commodiry booms affecr state developmenr. But there is,
of course, a problem wirh endogeneiry here - a state dependent on resources by defini-
tion has low infrastructural power because it generares little revenue from other sources
Mexico (Kurtz 2009 ).
16
Calculating the tax burden in Mexico is difficult beca use only nominal data Chaudhry (1997) makes a similar argumenr. Notice thar resource booms need nor have
are available. Nevertheless, its growth over the course of the Porfiriato is a similar effect on orher elemenrs of state capaciry - see Saylor (2014) for an account of
how commodiry booms can, under certain condirions, lead to the development of other
striking. In r874, interna! taxes per capita were 0.37 pesos, while by r910 1
elements of the sta te.

1
180 State Building in Latin America Tax State Development 181

alternative of relying on resource rents to fund public good provision, Implementing Taxation: Forms of Rule and Effective
when leaders have an alternative source of revenue, they will substi- Administration
tute away from taxation. Indeed, this may be sufficient to explain the
elimination of national taxation during certain periods in both Peru When states do try to tax -whether after resource booms or more broadly-
and Chile. 17 their ability to do so depends on the extent of the infrastructural or admin-
But as the description earlier of the dismantling of taxation during istrative challenges posed by taxation. Here, again, we see the importance
the booms in Peru and Chile suggests, this argument is convincing in of delegated and deployed rule. Where states administer their periphery
accounting for state weakness while resources provide revenues. ~e through delegated rule, as in Peru, the argument of this book predicts that
should be cautious, however, about applying this argument to explam efforts to tax will founder because of the disinclination of local officials to
overall variation in tax state development. While resource depen- implement tax policy. But under deployed rule, 1 expect that local officials
dence is sufficient to explain the lack of taxation, its absence tells us will ha ve incentives to maintain a level of state power in their communities,
nothing about levels of taxation. We can draw no conclusio~s abo:it which induces them to play an active part in tax state development.
why post-boom recovery took so much longer in ~eru t?an. m e.hile The decision to tax, and the ability to implement tax policy, then, are
despite booms that were equivalent in length and m the1r ~ts~ort1on­ each partial explanations for tax state development in Chile and Peru.
ary effects on the economy. ' 8 The political costs un~er?1~mg the The former is sufficient to explain the elimination of taxes, and explains
resource-dependence argument cannot account for vanat1on m taxa- why commodity booms distort the tax state. But when resource rents dis-
tion in non-boom conditions. appear, local administration matters. During and after the nitrate boom
In addition to the political costs, 1 argue that a complete theory of in Chile, the actions of local state agents were central to overcoming
tax state development must also take into account another kind of the infrastructural obstacles to taxation. In post-guano Peru, by contrast,
cost of taxation: the infrastructural or administrative obstacles that local elites serving as state agents in fact created many of these road-
must be overcome for taxes, once legislated, to be collected. 19 These blocks to tax administration. Even when the state sought to cut local
administrative challenges - the existence of tax records and accounting elites out of tax administration, their central role in other aspects of local
infrastructure, the presence of police able and willing to enforce the governance allowed them to undermine taxation. As a result, whereas
rulings of tax collectors, and the like - explain the i~plementation of Chile recovered its ability to tax its population within a decade after
tax policy, and thus the relationship between tax pohcy an~ .tax º.ut- nitrates ran out, Peru took fifty years to undergo an analogous transition
and was left with a much weaker tax state.
comes. This shift of the focus to the capacity to tax, to admm1strat10n
rather than politics, can account for variation in tax state development
outside boom times. Peru: Local State Agents and the Failure to Tax after the
Guano Boom

The absence of taxation in Peru after the guano ran out demands expla-
17 Notably, resource dependence is not the only explanation for the ~ecision ~ot to ta~: as
shown la ter, the laissez-faire ideology of Liberal leaders in Colombia expla10s the fa1lure nation. An examination of this period reveals the important role of
to introduce taxation in that country. . . . infrastructural obstacles to taxation in addition to the political costs
lB Paredes (2013 ¡ disputes ths comparability of these two booms, argu10g that .the1r d1ffer- highlighted by existing scholarship. lt highlights how administration
ential tirning led them to have different effects on tax state develo~ment. Th1s .argurnent
depends on the counterfactual clairn that, had the guano boom 10 Peru arnved later, through delegation to local elites diluted collection efforts, meaning that
it would have had a different effect because the Peruvian state would have developed those internal taxes that made it through the political process were inef-
greater capacity. The development of education and coercion (discus.sed in Chapters 4 fectively implemented and failed to generate projected revenue.
and 6), which were less distorted by the guano boom than was taxat10n, cast doubt on
this clairn.
Political Costs
19 Although her focus is on what I have called the "political costs" ª.r~ent, Ka.rl.(1997,
61) hints at the irnportance of the adrninistrative costs of taxat10n 10 expla1010g the Much analysis of Peru's post-guano fiscal failures has focused on the
weakness of petro-states. political obstacles to taxation. Scholars point to one notable instance in
State Building in Latín America Tax State Development

particular: the refusal of Congress to approve taxes to fund the defense This can be seen most clearly in the l 8 8 5-18 8 6 Atusparia uprising
of Lima during the Chilean invasion of 1879 (Kurtz 2009, 496). Political in Ancash, the largest revolt in nineteenth-century Peru. 2 º The central
opposition also explains the failure to tax primary product exports after actors in this revolt were indigenous authorities, who were responsible
these sectors recovered in the l89os. The mining lobby managed to gain far collecting from their jurisdictions. The state, in other words, did not
a fifteen-year exemption in 1890, and sugar producers were able to block penetrate these communities, relying instead on the mediation of com-
any export tax on agricultura! products (Thorp and Bertram 1978, 30). munity leaders. 21 Unrest was triggered when these local officials publicly
No export taxes were introduced until 1916, preventing the state from petitioned the government for relief from the burden of tax collection,
generating revenue from this source. asking for reduced payments (Thorp and Bertram 1978, 55). When this
But political opposition to taxation only goes so far in explaining the protest was met with repression, a massive insurgency broke out. A cen-
failure of the state to tax. For during the years after the collapse of the tral part of ensuring regional peace in Ancash was the negotiation of tax
guano trade - and after 1895 in particular - a range of taxes was insti- payments over the subsequent decade. In other words, the government
tuted in Peru. Yet the Peruvian state was unable to generate any reve- largely conceded in its attempts to tax; this reflects the weakness of the
nue from the taxes on its books. This failure revealed sizable gaps in the Peruvian state. Each year, local officials refused the taxation schedules
state's infrastructural power: its absence of records and administration, sent from Lima, and forced the nacional government to bargain with the
and the absence of effective policing to enforce taxation. In the discussion threat of further uprising. As a result of this annual bargaining, taxes fell
that follows, I highlight how the reliance on local elites to administer the far short of expectations, with collections averaging about l 5 percent of
national periphery shaped these failings. Because of the failure of local assessed levels between l 8 8 6 and l 89 5 in Huaraz, and reaching a low of
state agents to effectively impose taxation, the state struggled to generate l percent in 1887 (Thorp and Bertram 1978, 104ff). Thus the fust majar
revenue from a head tax, consumption taxes and monopolies, and other attempt to reimpose taxation, after the War of the Pacific and Chilean
direct and indirect taxes. Although revenue did grow (in nominal terms) occupation, ended in abject failure because of the inability of the state to
over the fust two decades of the twentieth century, the painful process of force its local representatives to make the population pay. 22
tax collection further reflected the weakness of the Peruvian state. We might think that since revolts reflect opposition to taxation, they
should be seen as a political rather than infrastructural obstacle. Yet there
Failure of the Head Tax are two reasons to see these as an indicator of the state's inability to
As described earlier, the fust efforts to restare taxation after the War of implement tax policy effectively. First, they arose at the time of imposi-
the Pacific centered on the reintroduction of a head tax which now, tion rather than as policy is being made - thus, in Michael Mann's terms,
unlike in previous iterations, would fall on the entire population rather they are related to the infrastructural rather than the despotic power of
than just the indigenous segment. But collections fell far short of assess- .! the state. Thus, they contrast with instances of political obstacles to tax-
ments. The failure to generate revenue cannot be blamed on decentraliza- ation, such as the refusal of Congress to pass a tax bill for the defense of
tion: in Chile, as shown earlier, local governments continued to generate Lima in 1879 cited earlier. Second, a state with greater coercive capac-
taxes even during decentralization. Nor were the fiscal shortfalls driven by ity would have been able to overcome this opposition, highlighting once
political costs. The Cáceres government, ruling in a context of abject crisis again the interconnected nature of the various aspects of infrastructural
and allowing little voice to the population, had no trouble imposing this
tax. The problems carne in its collection. Important to this failure was the "" Thumer (r997) offers a definitive account, on which this discussion is based. He argues
that this revolt was not motivated purely by fiscal causes; nonetheless, the attempt to
lack of policing power, another aspect of the infrastructural weakness of impose a tax seen as illegitimate and overly burdensome did play a pivota! role.
the state. Collection was also hampered by the absence of reliable popula- 11
In this insrance, rhe delegation of authoriry ro local elites resembles whar is elsewhere
tion statistics (Thorp and Bertram 1978, 121). But even more central was described as indirecr rule, since rhese local elites - indigenous leaders - adminisrered
rhe communities using customary law. As discussed in Chapter 2, however, most local
the fact that the state was unable to penetrate indigenous society to orga- adminisrrarion in Peru did not take rhis form.
nize collection. Forced instead to rely on local elites, its ability to induce 1
11
Although Thurner's evidence about rhe absence of collections comes from Huaraz, a
them to impose a new tax on their communities was limited. more general pattern of illusory budgers can be seen in the narional-level data as well.
1
State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 185

power. The enforcement of taxation depends on the ability to effectively TABLE 5.7. Anti-fiscal revolts in Peru, 1885-1896
deploy policing power and because the Peruvian state could not do Location Year Location Year
the latter, it could not do the former. Thus, it is appropriate to see this
generalized pattern of uprising against taxation as an infrastructural Ancash 1885 Cuzco 1894
Puno 1886-1887 La Mar 1895
obstacle to tax collection. The absence of effective coercion, discussed in
Huánuco 1886 Cerro de Paseo 1896
Chapter 6 and traced to the role of local elites in security adrninistration, Castrovirreyna 1887 llave 1896
underrnined the state's efforts to tax. Chiclayo 1887 Huanta 1896
Andahuaylas 1892 Cuzco 1896
Resort to Consumption Taxes Cerro de Paseo 1893 Juli 1896
The failure of the head tax became complete with its abolition by the Source: Kapsoli (1977).
Piérola government shortly after its ascension to power in 1896. With the
failure of the head tax, and export taxation precluded due to the political
power of producers, the government turned to a series of consumption Despite the fact that these taxes were on the books, they generated little
taxes. Here, too, the fundamental obstacles to taxation were infrastruc- in the way of revenue due to the reluctance of local elites charged with
tural: the inability to induce compliance with taxes legislated in Lima. tax collection to impose on their coalition of local allies and clients.
While these consumption taxes were fairly easy to assess, they prompted Delegated rule facilitated these practices by peopling the adrninistration
major revolts, the most important of which are listed in Table 5. 7. with bureaucrats who had deep local ties, and by reducing the salience of
Notably, these revolts took place in significant regional centers, reflect- sanctions from the national government. Thus it in severa! ways reduced
ing the inability of the state to impose taxes even in large and important the effectiveness of tax adrninistration.
cities such as Cuzco, Chiclayo, and Puno. Most galling for the population
was the imposition of the salt monopoly by Piérola in 1896, as can be Tax Reform Efforts
seen from the large number of revolts that year. The monopoly increased To remedy these faults, as they did with education, the Civilistas sought
salt prices by as much as 400 percent. As a result, despite appeals to to remove tax adrninistration from the hands of local elites. In 1902, tax
nacional pride in prornises that its revenue would allow the rescue of collection was contracted to a privare firm, the Compañia Nacional de
Tacna and Arica from the Chileans, the salt tax led to a wave of unrest. Recaudación (CNR). 2 3 Officials hoped that privatization would eliminate
It was only with a massive show of force that the state generated revenue the obstacle that local elites posed to tax adrninistration. Indeed, it should
from these taxes, although they remained a significant stream of revenue have done so, since the firm tended to appoint nonlocal departrnent heads
through much of the twentieth century. Thus, we see nothing in Peru like to adrninister tax collection (Nugent 1997, 51). At the provincial level,
"quasi-voluntary compliance" with taxation (Levi 1988). however, the CNR relied on locally chosen officials, which tended to
Another, not unrelated, factor underrnining the collection of con- underrnine tax collection. Moreover, these company agents were chosen
sumption taxes was the willingness of local adrninistrators to grant tax in consultation with the subprefect, who was deeply rooted in the local
relief for política! gain. Nugent (1997) shows that local state agents in community. Additionally, the officials had to be escorted by police to pro-
Chachapoyas used their control over taxation to win the support of local tect them and the funds they collected, and the police were under the
lower classes. As elites competed for access to administrative positions, aegis of the subprefect. Nugent finds evidence that the subprefect "could
one strategy of coalition building was granting tax relief. Nugent (1997, withhold protection for tax collections" or "instruct his governors not to
69) argues that "tax relief was a favor that could be withdrawn at any cooperare with the tax collection process" (51). Despite the privatization
time, and thus was an effective way of disciplining peasants and artisans."
Relief from consumption taxes on staples like salt, tobacco, and marches
,3 In 1912, the CNR was replaced by another prívate firrn, the Compañía Recaudadora de
represented a significant econornic boon, and the dilution of tax adrninis- Impuestos, and taxation rernained in the hands of prívate firrns well into the twentieth
tration for política! gain sharply reduced the funds entering state coffers. century. To rny knowledge, no systernatic study of this cornpany has been written.
I86 State Building in Latin America Tax State Development

of tax administration, it remained firmly in the control of delegated state Decentralization and Municipal Taxation
agents and therefare suffered in terms of implementation. The beginning of the nitrate boom coincided with a decentralizacion refarm
that devolved many powers to local governments 4 (Eaton 2004, 93ff). 2

Conclusion Scholars have facused on its policical manifestation: not only the eleccion
By the end of the Civilista era, the Peruvian state had regained sorne abil- of local authoricies but the end to presidencial interference in eleccions
ity to tax. Interna! taxation recovered to its pre-boom levels by 1920, (Valenzuela 1977, l93ff). But its administracive dimension was also cru-
marking the end of the post-guano crisis. But effarts to build the tax state cial. The 1891 Municipal Autonomy Law (Ley de Comuna Autónoma)
had faundered. The CNR, established in an effart to remove local elites transferred many taxes to municipal governments, including ali majar
from tax administration, had failed to do so. Proposals to develop more non-customs sources of government revenue. Ea ton (2004, 9 5) claims that
infrastructurally complex taxes on income and wealth failed to generate rather than taxing, local authoricies used their leverage over the election of
any revenue, and state coffers continued to depend on customs and con- nacional legislators to demand the delivery of revenue far local projects.
sumption taxes. Although (nominal levels of) taxation rose, the state's Thus, he argues that the decentralizacion led to significant state weakening.
infrastructural power - as reflected in the ability to extract revenue from Yet there are two reasons to believe that municipal taxation was cru-
its population - saw little development. That Civilista taxation was lim- cial far state extractive capacity. First, tax collection, independent of reve-
ited to infrastructurally "easy" taxes reflected the continuing weakness nue generated, implied a concinuity in record-keeping and administration
of the Peruvian tax state, leaving it largely dependent on trade taxes and that would la ter reduce the infrastructural costs of restoring national tax-
fareign loans far subsequent decades. ation. Second, the historical record shows, in contrast to Eaton's claims,
that municipal taxacion was quite significant. As Table 5. 8 shows, munic-
ipal taxation reached between 5 and lO percent of customs revenues far
Chile: Deployed Rule and the Recovery of Taxation after the
the period l903-19rr, climbing to one-quarter of customs revenues by
Nitrate Boom
1920. Until 1915, municipal taxes were higher than was the interna! tax-
In striking contrast to Peru, the Chilean state recovered fairly quickly ation of the national government. 5 2

from the dramatic collapse of nitrate revenues, overcoming the infra- With decentralization, municipalities assessed property values, moni-
structural obstacles to taxation when it needed to do so. This strikingly tored the sale of alcoholic beverages, and regulated the exercise of pro-
rapid recovery poses a puzzle far scholars of state development. The fessions and activities. 26 Property records included lists of each property
roots of this outcome -which diverged sharply from the Peruvian experi- owner with the values of his lands and structures. 7 Municipal review 2

ence can be faund at the local leve!. I argue that even as resource booms commissions responded to citizen complaints about the valuations, and
filled nacional state coffers, and local elites who dominated municipal revised the rolls on a regular basis. 28 Although the schedule far revision
governments displayed unwillingness to tax themselves, local state agents
sought continued taxation because they depended on the reach of the 24
In terms of the typology of decentralization developed in Falleti (20Io), this was a polit-
state far legitimacy and power vis-a-vis the communities in which they ical and fiscal decentralization, with only a limited adrninistrative component.
>s Although data lirnitations prevent a systematic analysis, evidence suggests that the
served. In this section, 1 show that pressures from deployed bureaucrats federal subsidy to municipalities as a share of municipal revenues dec/ined during the
both pushed the national government to devolve taxes to the local leve! nitra te years.
26
rather than elirninating them, and pressed municipal authorities (who On the introduction of municipal fees for the sale of alcoholic beverages, see, for exarn-
were elected from their communities after 1891) to enforce the laws on ple, MINT I89I, I46ff for decrees instituting alcohol taxes in the municipalities of
Pisagua, !quique, Tacna, Arica, Copiapó, Antofagasta, Chañaral, and Caracoles.
the books and collect the taxes devolved to them. Thus, Chile's reliance on >1 For a detailed account of the kinds of property subject to and exempt from this tax, see
deployed administration limited the distortionary effects of the resource the Ley de Comuna Autónoma, Articles 36-39. For administrative procedures of this and
boom and decentralization on its fiscal state. Because of the pressures of other taxes, see Articles 44ff.
8
' For a list of municipal taxes authorized as of I892, see Fondo Ministerio de Hacienda
local state agents thioughout the boom, municipal governments concin- vol. 2I73 for text ofJanuary 29, I892 law. On property value rolls, see Fondo Ministerio
ued to tax, and this sharply reduced the infrastructural obstacles to the de Hacienda vol. 2009 for partial records of the I889 Aváluo de propiedades urbanos,
post-nitrate reassertion of Chile's tax state. MINT I892, 9 for complaints by the Intendente of Tacna about the need for a new
State Building in Latin America Tax State Development
188

data for 1908 and 1909 (AE 1909: III, 14ff) show that sorne 30 percent
TABLE 5.8. National and municipal taxation, Chile, I903-r920
of municipal revenue carne from the impuesto de haberes that was lev-
Year Customs revenues Internal taxation Municipal taxation
ied on wealth, the second largest revenue source after the many perrnits
69,587,478 l,907,763 6,234,120 issued. This tax only applied to holdings over 2,000 pesos - in other
1903
1904 82,373,479 l,870,277 6,405,915 words, it only fell on the most wealthy segment of local society. This
90,804,726 2,473,901 6,214,258
1905 suggests that something made municipal governments willing to impose
1906 103,275,273 3,230,042 6,775,820
8,686,735
taxes on the wealthy and locally powerful.
1907 II l,970,973 4,338,287
3,992,589 lo,702,546 The pressure this required carne from local agents of the central state.
1908 ro7,929,384
1909 II3,28l,315 3,206,771 9,376,322 In this newly decentralized context, the incentives of local state agents
1910 129,18 5,901 9,270,906 7,159,567 became crucial. The historical reliance on deployed rule had created a
l9II 136,356,438 12,145,679 14,331,709 class of local state agents who gained power vis-a-vis the communities in
1912 148,719,3 5 5 l3,2n,788 16,468,138
which they served as the state's presence in their communities increased.
1913 158,483,825 17,635,439 19,782,838
15,236,512 21,074,442 Thus, whereas resource dependence could have turned the state's pres-
1914 ro7,879,784
90,558,998 33,250,023 21,977,145 ence in the interior into a "fiction" as it did in Peru, local state agents
1915
1916 139,052,723 30,149,294 24,480,935 prevented this outcome. First, they pressed national authorities with their
1917 163,3 58,723 34,267,559 27,643,229 concerns about the post-decentralization decay of state development
1918 185,877,910 40,555,98 1 32,897,564 in their communities and demanded intervention. Second, they pressed
1919 74,528,194 45,660,075 34,1 2 0,351
37,097,779
municipal authorities to continue taxation in order to fund those services,
1920 149,212,638 50,430,507
and intervened (where the constitution allowed them to do so) to ensure
Data is in current year (nominal) pesos.According to Remmer (1984, 154), inflation ran that taxes were collected and services delivered.
between 5 and 9 percent per year between 1891 and 1924.
Source: Anuario Estadístico de Chile, various years.
Pressure on the National Government
In the pre-nitrate era, local state agents had drawn on earmarked portions
was not systematic, municipal documents in the national archives sh~"." of the taxes they collected to pursue their local priorities. They feared
that individual municipalities did issue new tax rolls. 29 Another mumc1- that the elirnination of national taxation would force them to depend on
pal tax, the impuesto de mercados, required daily collection of fees from nitrate revenues from Santiago to fund the increased policing, primary
market stall occupants (MINT 1887, 60). Thus the infrastructural capac- education, and transportation improvements that increased the reach of
ity required for intensive taxation continued to exist at the municipal the central state into their jurisdictions. Thus as momentum gathered for
level during the nitrate era. decentralization, governors and intendentes pushed for new tax respon-
sibilities for local government (see, for example, MINT 18 8 7, 2 5 5).
Deplayed Rule and the Continuity of State Extractive Capacity . Concern also manifested itself in consistent outcry against decentralized
Municipal authorities were composed of wealthy members of their com- adrninistration in their reports to the Ministry of the Interior, before and
munities, and were often unwilling to impose taxes on themselves. 3 º Yet after its 1891 implementation. Governors and other local officials used
the platform of their reports to authorities in Santiago to highlight the fail-
ures of municipal adrninistration and call for a degree of recentralization.
provincial tax roll, and MINT 1894: II, 408 for mentían of a new survey in Vichuquén,
Because national officials saw decentralization as an unquestioned good,
among many other examples. . . .
,9 For example, a new rol de avaluos was issued in 1912 in Malloa (Fondo Murnc1pahdad local officials chose not to tilt at windrnills by calling for its abolition.
de Malloa, vol. 1, p. 1 83). Wright (1973, 244) notes the existence of rolls of the value of Instead they pressed for piecemeal reform, often pointing to specific mea-
agricultura! properties for 1874, 1888, and 1908. . sures where centralized authority was particularly necessary. One example
10 See, for example, the refusal of Coquimbo landowners m 1892 to pay taxes that funded
the rural police (MINT 1892, 3 r4).
was the poor quality of the 189 5 census, in which data collection at the
State Building in Latín America Tax State Development

local level was carried out by municipal authorities rather than by central had veto power over any municipal legislation they judged as "harmful to
state agents as in past iterations (MINT 1897, 41-42). public arder" (Ley de Comuna Autónoma, Article rn4). Although munic-
Governors also offered criticism of decentralization. They claimed to ipal officials could appeal vetoes to the Supreme Court, this still gave
be unable to comment on many aspects of governance in their depart- national government officials significant leverage. Using this power, gov-
ments because it was in the hands of local authorities (see, for exam- ernors resolved conflict and deadlock over municipal budgets. In Búlnes
ple, MINT 1894: II, 266). Governors and other officials complained in 1893, for example, the municipality's failure to agree on a budget led to
that local administration was "disorganized" (MINT 1895, 314), that the elimination of a police force that could not be funded. The governor
it had no benefits for citizens (458), and that "it is impossible to know intervened to decree that the previous year's budget would apply, rein-
on what its revenues are spent because nobody has been able to observe stated taxation, and restored the police force (MINT 1894: II, 529-530).
what services it fulfills" (MINT 1910, rn29 ). Municipal authorities were Additionally, local state agents used their platform to press municipal
criticized for being disinterested in effective governance: the governor of authorities to increase taxation. This pressure most commonly revolved
Petorca, for example, complained that his department had no rural police around the impuesto de haberes, because municipal authorities (Ley de
"through the fault of the mayores contribuyentes, who considered them Comuna Autónoma, Arride 3 5) could choose the rate at which this tax
unnecessary" (MINT 1893-1894, 218). This concern about the "lack of was assessed, between 0.1 percent and 0.3 percent of wealth. State agents
public spirit" of municipal authorities (MINT l 899, 6) was a trape of the often complained about the failure of municipal authorities to raise the
Memorias of Governors during the years after decentralization. Another rate, and raised this issue in municipal council meetings (see MINT 1910,
trape was a critique of partisan and patronage politics in municipal 4 5 for one example from the department of Achao). A parallel dynamic
administration, which was cited as a font of poor public good provision emerged in the funding of education. Although municipal authorities
(see, for example, MINT 1894, II: 3 78, on the partisan nature of rural were responsible for funding primary schools, the national government
police, and MINT 1895, 625, on the use of public funds for patran- continued to oversee and inspect education. As a result, when taxes were
age rather than for public good pravision). Another axis of criticism was insufficiently collected for schooling, complaints trickled up through the
the misallocation of funds: governors and other local officials reported education bureaucracy as described in Chapter 4 (see, for example, MIP
that municipal authorities failed to spend revenues on the services for 1894, xxi).
which they were earmarked (MINT l9rn, 943ff). This complaint often Third, national government inspectors reviewed municipal accounts
centered on raad building, which had become a municipal responsibility to ensure that taxes were collected without irregularities, and intenden-
after 1893. By their constant reminder of the failures of decentralization, tes pravided more general oversight and pressure for policy implemen-
local state agents kept the national government aware of administration tation with their regular visits through their provinces, on which they
throughout the country even as state coffers filled with nitrate rents. were required to report to the Minister of the Interior.JI This meant that
although municipal authorities made tax policy, they were accountable
Intervention at the Municipal Level to the national government. The quality of reports by local state agents
Chile's intendentes and governors, and their representatives at the munic- during this period (as compiled in the various ministerial Memorias and
ipal level also spurred the collection of municipal taxes. These interven- intendants' reports) remained high, as municipal governments were held
tions to continue collection prevented the erosion of extractive capacity to a high standard of public service provision.
that often accompanies both resource booms and fiscal decentralization
in a context of high social inequality. This influence operated through The End of the Nitrate Boom and the Leap in Interna[ Taxation
severa! channels. When the nitrate boom collapsed during World War I with the inven-
Perhaps most important was the formal power that the central state's tion of a chemical process for praducing artificial fertilizers, the Chilean
local agents retained after decentralization. Although decentralization
limited their formal participation in municipal decision making, central
state agents still presided over all municipal government sessions, and J' Far one exarnple of this oversight, see Fondo Municipalidad de Malloa, vol. 1, p. 33I.
State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 1 93

state entered into a deep fiscal crisis that also fostered política! insta- Federalism and Tax State Development in Colombia
bility. Without any majar export commodity that could generate cus- andMexico
toms duties, the state had to rely on interna! taxes the same kinds of
The comparison of Colombia and Mexico, both federal systems with
taxes that had resulted in widespread riots and ineffective collection for
much tax authority initially assigned to the states rather than to the
decades after the end of the guano boom in Peru.
national government, reveals the lirnits of that institutional factor in
By contrast to Peru, the Chilean state quickly and effectively restored
accounting for trajectories over time. In both cases, the federalist con-
the collection of interna! taxation. Sorne of this effort was carried out
stitutions restricted the range of taxes that the federal government could
by placing new fiscal levers in the hands of municipal governments.
institute, and allowed subnational authorities to use their influence over
A tax on the value of household possessions was added in I9I9, which
the national legislature to underrnine efforts to tax. In both cases, fed-
generated over 3 million pesos in its first year and 5 million in the
eralism acted as a political obstacle to fiscal policymaking (Rodden and
second. By increasing the rate of collection of taxes already on the
Wibbels 2002).
books, and by adding new taxes that were easy to collect based on
Yet the difference between Mexico and Colombia is striking. While
information already collected, the municipalities were able to generate
Colombian national leaders regularly introduced policies reinforcing the
significant additional revenue to make up for the shortfall in customs
fiscal autonomy of their states, Mexican leaders, comrnitted to a project
revenues.
of concerted state building, sought to underrnine those lirnits by pushing
The state also began to re-nationalize the taxes that municipalities had
for changes in the balance of fiscal federalism. By contrast, as in the devel-
collected throughout the nitrate era, increased the rates, and relied for
opment of coercive power and primary education, the disinclination of
collection on the state infrastructure that had survived the fiscal distor-
state leaders to expand the powers of the state is sufficient to explain the
tions of the nitrate boom (Eaton 2004, 23). A national tax on property
absence of effective taxation in Colombia. This can be seen both in the
was introduced in I9I5 and generated over fifteen rnillion pesos for each
dismantling of natio.nal taxation in the initial Liberal Reform period and
of the next five years. By I9I9, with the nationalization of the tax on
in the lirnited efforts to centralize the country's fiscal federalism by more
household possessions, interna! taxation reached more than half the leve!
moderare governments thereafter. The laissez-faire vision of development,
of customs revenue (which included nitrate exports).
not federalism, accounts for Colombia's failure to develop tax capacity.
These taxes were able to generate significant revenues very quickly
In Mexico, state leaders faced perhaps the biggest set of obstacles to
because the state was able to rely on the property records and land
taxation, as they confronted the legacy of decades of post-independence
surveys that had already been carried out when these taxes were col-
chaos and a federal system that sharply limited the taxes they could
lected at the municipal leve! during the nitrate boom. Even as taxes
institute. Yet a concerted state-building project used creative legislation,
were eliminated at the national leve!, more than 200 municipalities
negotiation, and the full range of its constitutional powers to expand its
had continued to gather data about the economic activity, wealth, and
ability to tax at the expense of the states. The expansion in the extrac-
occupation of their residents, and to collect significant quantities of
tive capacity of the central state, as the evidence that follows shows in
tax throughout the twentieth century. As the externa! sources of reve-
detail, derived from the increasing bureaucratization of tax adrninistra-
nue collapsed, the Chilean state had detailed information at its fingertips
tion, and from the placement of this developing bureaucracy in the hands
on land values and even the furniture and other property of residents
of deployed state agents rather than those of local elites.
throughout the country. Municipal governments had kept these records
largely because of the pressures and interventions of the deployed
agents of the central state. The continued infrastructural power of the Laissez-Faire Liberalism and Reluctance to Tax in Colombia
state during the nitrate era - and not only its ability to overcome the
política! costs of imposing taxes on its citizens - underlay its quick Perhaps nowhere was the comrnitment to laissez-faire liberalism among
recovery. Colombian elites more apparent than in the realm of taxation. Although
r94 State Building in Latin America Tax State Development r95

the Hilario López tax refarms that began in r850 were the most dramatic revenues fell particularly far short of expenditures, the state regularly
instance in this pattern, there was never a sustained effort to build a tax turned to the expedients of domestic and fareign loans, farced loans,
state in Colombia befare the López Pumarejo government of the r93os. As and the sale of vacant lands to fill its coffers with extraordinary revenues
a result of this disinclination toward state building, central authority never rather than ever try to develop tax adrninistration.
developed in Colombia. Deas (r982) argues that, due to the poverty of its residents and the
The Hilario López government that carne to power in r849 believed country's limited domestic and international trade, Colombian govern-
that "individuals left alone to pursue their intellectual and material interests ments faced an uphill battle in trying to tax. Yet the record of the period
would contribute to the progress of civilization and the well-being of society between r850 and r930 reveals a striking disinclination by the national
'in general" (Rausch r993, 62). In the realm of taxation, this view underlay government to insert itself into the economic lives of its citizens. As in
the belief that taxes were "detrimental to national growth" (ibid., 68). The the other aspects of the state, no effort was made to develop taxation in
result, as discussed earlier, was the elimination of the tobacco monopoly and Colombia befare the Great Depression. Once again, Colombia is a case
severa! other revenue sources, and the cession of others - most notably the where no state-building project emerged; its state weakness can be traced
alcohol tax - to the provinces, "with the expectation that many provinces to the uniquely anti-statist worldview of its political elites.
would abolish them altogether and that those which were retained would
provide on the regional level the few services that Liberals were willing to
adrnit were indeed the responsibility of the government" (ibid., 68). As a Mexico: Deployed Rule and the Expansion of Federal Taxation
result of these changes, historians find that the state ceded half of its revenue Mexico and Colombia faced similar challenges to tax state development
in pursuit of its liberal principies. In r870, state and local governments took in the farm of federal institutions. But Mexican state leaders, who did
in more revenue than did the national government (McGreevey r97r, 88). not share the laissez-faire bent of their Colombian counterparts, pur-
The "Regeneration" of r886 saw centralization of political authority sued the centralization of fiscal authority. And as in Chile, taxation was
in the national government. But even during this period, tax administra- implemented by deployed state agents, who could be pressured to comply
tion remained decentralized (Santos r966, 40-4r). Only sporadic crises with the state-building initiatives of the national government. The result
drove attempts to raise taxes: the Civil War of r895, the collapse of inter- was that as the federal government asserted its authority to collect taxes,
national trade after r9r7, and the Great Depression and war with Peru in its local representatives carried this authority into their jurisdictions and
r932. The first of these saw a proposal to tax coffee exports defeated by generated revenue.3 3 Over time, the increased professionalization and
growers. The second saw the establishment of an income tax (which gen- centralization of tax collection reinforced this pattern, giving the cen-
erated negligible revenue), as well as imposts on medicine, marches, car- tral state greater power to collect the taxes it chose. While in Chile the
bonated beverages, and beer (Junguito and Rincón 2007, 246). Yet direct mechanism linking deployed rule to tax state development was the initia-
taxes only became a significant source of revenue after further refarms tive of local agents, the more important mechanism in Mexico was that
under López Pumarejo in the r93os. deployed rule facilitated the state's ability to ensure that tax collectors
Befare that period, a laissez-faire approach to taxation marked fulfilled their duties.
Liberals and Conservatives both. This can be seen in their proposals to This section explores various pieces of evidence that show the increas-
refarm revenue generation. No influential proposal broached the possi- ingly effective implementation of taxation by the central state's officials.
bility of building a powerful tax state. Instead, they proposed alterations Additionally, it explores the evolving nature of Mexican fiscal federal-
of import duties, taxes on vices like alcohol and tobacco, and the nation- ism: over time, the federal government's penetration of local society grew
alization of revenue sources (cattle slaughter tax, alcohol tax, and the at the expense of that of its component states. The increased central-
like) that had been devolved to subnational authorities.32 When ordinary ization of tax administration, and its increasing reliance on deployed

l' See Deas (1982, 3 loff) for severa! nineteenth-century proposals, and Junguito and 33
By contrast, in places where tax administration remained in the hands of local elites, it
Rincón (2007, 241-249) for details of proposed and implemented reforms during the foundered. Far clear evidence of this in the case of Porfirian Chiapas, see Bobrow-Strain
fust thirty years of the twentieth century. (2007, 78-79),
State Building in Latin America Tax State Development 197

rule, turned tax policy into reality. As the state relied increasingly on its Administrative Reforms of the Timbre
bureaucracy deployed throughout the national territory, its capacity to As the most important component of interna! taxation, the timbre is
tax increased. Yet this upward trend in infrastructural power left Mexico particularly fertile ground far the study of extractive capacity.34 Befare
behind its Chilean counterpart far three reasons: first, the state chose 1893, the timbre was collected by state and local officials, who remitted
not to tax wealth, exports, ar domestic commerce, believing that to do funds to the finance ministry. The result was significant irregularity in its
so would impinge on domestic economic growth. Second, the abject fail- collection, and the failure of the tax to translate into "a real, daily pres-
ure of the state to tax befare l 8 57 left its fiscal power at strikingly low ence of the federal state" (Carmagnani 1989, 486). After 1893, a series
levels when the Liberals took power. And third, the central government of refarms would begin to insert the central state directly into the full
faced significant political obstacles to taxation from its constituent states, range of transactions to which it applied. A first measure imposed a layer
which could use their power in Congress to protect their autonomy from of federal timbre inspectors, who oversaw its administration by local
the central state's reach. and state officials. This was fallowed, in 1900, by the establishment of a
Thus, this section highlights both the role of central state bureaucrats corps of federal contractors to carry out collection in place of the local
in increasing the state's tax capacity, and the limits of those gains in com- authorities. In 1906, a further refarm created a tax inspection system
parative perspective. Drawing on detailed studies by historians of the that divided the country into six regions, appointing two layers of inspec-
administration of particular revenue sources, 1 trace the increased reli- tors to oversee tax administration throughout the country. Thus by the
ance on deployed bureaucrats and the consequences far extractive capac- end of the Porfiriato, the timbre was collected by the federal government
ity in two specific arenas of taxation: the timbre, and the assessment and rather than states, in a system that (although reliant on contractors) was
sale of vacant land by the state. 1 conclude by exploring the unique polit- overseen by federal inspectors. Along with the increasingly wide range of
ical challenges of federalism far extractive capacity in Mexico, show- tax streams included in the timbre that was described earlier, this greater
ing how central state extractive capacity increased despite the political systematization and centralization of taxation represented the increased
obstades of federalism. infrastructural power of the federal state, as it removed both subnational
Beyond these two specific administrative histories, a broader exami- authorities and local elites from the extractive apparatus.
nation of tax state development shows a series of Liberal and Porfirian
refarms that gave federal state agents increasing power over taxation. Suroeying Vacant Land
By the late Porfiriato, tax administration was firmly in the hands of fed- As political stability became cemented, rural land in many parts of
eral bureaucrats. In 1906, two corps of oversight were created: inspec- Mexico rose in value, which led to state intervention in the land market.
tores, who supervised tax collection, and visitadores, who oversaw the In l 8 5 5, the Liberal government made the alienation of public lands -
inspectors and other tax officials (Carmagnani 1989, 489). Tax admin- their identification, mapping, and sale - a federal responsibility, nullifying
istration overall was overseen by federal agents stationed in "nearly local and state power to intervene in their allocation. Unclaimed land was
every" state capital, who operated alongside officers responsible far assigned to the federal government, which had the power to distribute it
each tax type (Ludlow 2002: 11, 208). Alongside these improvements as it saw fit. Most importantly far the state, this land could be sold to
to interna! taxation, a parallel series of customs refarms improved the generare revenue. The survey of land was also a pre-requisite far the con-
efficiency of collection in that arena as well (ibid., 11, l 5 8ff). Overall, struction of a system of land taxation, which had been stymied by "the
the Mexican state sharply increased its extractive capacity during the cloudy and disordered state of property relations in rural areas" (Holden
Liberal and Porfirian eras. This stemmed from the placement of taxa- 1994, 11). But the conversion of vacant land into a source of revenue
tion in the hands of the federal bureaucracy, which extended its reach required a land survey to identify its extent. The process of surveying
through the national territory. The reliance on deployed rule meant reflects the broader trend in state finance: its progressive centralization in
that, as Pérez Siller (2004) concludes, the state was able to effectively
generate revenue from the taxes on its books by the end of the nine-
teenth century. 34
This discussion is based on Carmagnani (I989, 486ff).
State Building in Latin America Tax State Development I99

the hands of the federal government, the exclusion of local elites from its from the practice, reserving it (and all of the vacant land identified) far
adrninistration, and the growing effectiveness of central state oversight.35 the nacional government (Holden I994, rn8). This growing assertion of
The survey of vacant land in Mexico began in earnest in the I87os and federal government intervencion in the land market reflects the broader
peaked between I883 and I893. The scale of the endeavor can be seen trends of state centralization of finance through the Porfiriato, a reflec-
in the fact that the sale of vacant land generated an average of 5 .9 per- tion of its cornrnitment to building its infrastructural power.
cent of all federal revenue between I867 and I9IO, and 23 .5 percent of
revenue between I883 and I890.3 6 Surveys were conducted by prívate The Federal Government and Mexico's States
firms, compensated far their services with one-third of the vacant land As it sought to expand its extractive capacity, the central state confronted
they mapped.37 This model of adrninistration, analogous to tax farrning, institucional obstacles to taxation posed by federalism. Reflecting the
was chosen because it kept both local interests and the nacional govern- autonomy of the states, the I 85 7 constitution restricted the federal gov-
ment out of the potentially explosive demarcation of prívate property. ernment to certain taxes, and allowed the states to generate any other form
Accepting prívate contracting of the survey implied accepcing the most of revenue they chose. Because of its desire to promote trade and thus its
common mode of surveying private firms used. This was the "deductive revenues, the federal government long sought to abolish states' rights to
method," in which companies surveyed an area, subtracted prívate hold- tax the domescic commerce that crossed their borders: the alcábala.3 8
ings (based on the information on the titles of landowners) and arrived State elites resisted repeated federal efforts to do so, using their influence
at a number of vacant hectares. This method was inaccurate, but politi- in Congress to thwart bills proposing bans on this important source of
cally and infrastructurally less costly since it <lid not involve measuring their revenue, which in I 890 represented more than half the revenue of
the bounds of prívate property (49ff). Survey firms tended to be disin- many states (Ludlow 2002, vol. 2, p. I95). This was the most salient
terested in surveying locations with small or complicated vacant lands, instance of the political difficulties of taxation under Mexico's federal
which were not worth the cost, meaning that many regions remained system.
unmapped. In other words, this was far from a "real cadastral survey" Yet as federal taxation grew, an opportunity to settle this conflict
{56), a reality that the Porifirian regime was willing to accept. So long as appeared. States protested increased federal taxation - and in particular
the survey process generated vacant land that could be sold by the federal the renta interior introduced in I887 that applied to the consumption of
government to generate revenue, and generated little unrest, the govern- domestic manufactures - as double taxation on their cicizens. In response
ment accepted its limitations. to the outcry by state governors and their congressional representatives,
Yet despite the lirnits of the survey process most importantly the the federal government offered to elirninate the renta interior if states
reliance on prívate firms and the lirnited accuracy - it <lid represent a would drop the a/cábala. To assure states of its good intentions, the fed-
dramatic insertion of the federal government into rural Mexico, part of eral government moved first, dropping one of its new revenue streams. In
the Porfirian project of broadening the reach of "civilization" and state turn, the states allowed the a/cábala to be banned in I896. Once internal
authority across the national territory (Meyer I986, I87). Approximately commerce duties were elirninated, the federal government irnmediately
30 percent of Mexico's land was surveyed between I883 and I893, raised import duties accordingly, and this revenue went directly into fed-
including large proportions of the more remate, thinly populated states eral coffers.
of Campeche, Chiapas, Chihuahua, Sonora, Sinaloa and Tabasco, and There is significant debate among historians about the implicacions
the territories of Baja California and Tepic (Holden I994, I]). Surveying of this agreement. On the one hand, Carmagnani (I989, 486) sees it
was further centralized in I902, when a decree banned private companies as a "significant retreat of fiscal modernization" because the consump-
tion tax on manufactured goods was abolished. In his view, the early
JS This discussion is based on Holden (1994).
8
36 My calculations from Carmagnani (1994), Appendix III, using his data on uventas y 3 Pérez Siller (2004, 149-150) suggests that the timing of efforts to eliminare the a/cábala
arriendos." relates to federal fiscal crises, hinting that the federal government was interested in
31 Notably, these privare firms were rarely local elites: see Holden (1994, Appendix) for expropriating this revenue stream rather than receiving the benefit of domestic commerce
details on the composition of survey firms. from its elimination.
200 State Building in Latín America Tax State Development 20!

189os saw a shift from fiscal modernization to revenue maximization, the nitrate boom in Chile resulted from the roles of local state agents in
as the state gave up efforts to develop new tax streams and facused on pressing far increased taxation in the communities in their jurisdiction.
improved administration of existing sources (principally the timbre) and The Porfirian state in Mexico understood this, as can be seen from its
the promotion of increased economic activity to increase its revenue. By aggressive efforts to place fiscal administration in the hands of deployed
contrast, Uhthoff (2004) argues that the central state was strengthened bureaucrats.
by the elimination of the a/cábalas because the central state raised its The evidence presented here becomes more compelling in conjunction
revenues at the expense of the states, while eliminating what was (in both with the evidence far a similar argument in explaining the variation in
ideological and pragmatical terms) a less than optima! source of revenue. education development. A similar set of factors can account far variation
In either case, this active pursuit of central tax authority on the part of in these two distinct aspects of state development, and can do so bet-
the Mexican state is in sharp contrast to its counterpart in Colombia. ter than can the prominent alternative explanations developed by schol-
Although Mexico's states retained significant fiscal autonomy through- ars who treat each dimension independently. This suggests that rather
out the pre-Revolutionary period, we can conclude that this did not than treating the evolution of taxation and education separately, scholars
prevent the increased strengthening of the central state. The federal gov- should pursue unified explanations far why states expand their capacity
ernment claimed the right to a wide range of tax streams, expanded that in sorne contexts but not others. I continue the effort to do so in the next
claim at the expense of the states, and collected those taxes directly and chapter, which considers the development of the coercive dimension of
in an increasingly effective manner. The federal system posed an obsta- state power.
cle to taxation by the central government, largely because the legislature
created a farum in which state governments could veto policy initiatives
designed to increase the power of the federal state while claiming certain
taxes far themselves. But through negotiation, compromise, and institu-
tional refarm, the Liberal and (particularly) the Porfirian federal state
was able to wear away this opposition, setting the stage far even greater
centralization of fiscal authority in the post-revolutionary era. The gains
of the pre-revolutionary era, which would become consolidated after
1920, were the result of a concerted effart to build a tax state, which was
implemented by deployed bureaucrats who put legislation into practice
in a concerted manner throughout the national territory.

CONCLUSION

While resource booms and federalism shape the challenges faced by tax
state builders, this chapter shows that they are insufficient to account far
variation in tax state development. Instead, we must look to the role of
ideas to explain why Colombian leaders were content to continue to rely
on customs revenues, and why they were unwilling to impose a wider
range of taxes even in times of fiscal crisis. Additionally, we must look
to institutions of local rule to explain why sorne effarts to tax succeed
while others fail. The foundering of Peruvian efforts to tax when guano
revenues ran out can be traced to the fact that administration was depen-
dent on local elites. On the other hand, the striking fiscal recovery after
Conscription and Coercive Capacity 203

The second part of the chapter explores how each of the four states
6 mobilized in response to international and domestic crises. The differ-
ence between cases in state capacity begins to emerge: at moments of
crisis, variation among the cases is revealed in the state's ability to mobi-
Local Administration, Varieties of Conscription, and lize troops in response to a threat. The case studies show, for example,
the Development of Coercive Capacity that in the War of the Pacific Chile was able to deliver twice as many
troops to Peruvian territory than Peru could muster in defense of its
own capital. The Colombian and Peruvian states struggled (and some-
times failed) to defend themselves against threats, yet by comparison the
Chilean state shone in response to challenges and the Mexican state per-
formed increasingly effectively, although in the end it fell at the hands of
a 1910 uprising.
Having shown the lirnits of a key alternative explanation and described
the extent of variation in state capacity, the third part of the chapter
In parallel to Chapters 4 and 5, this chapter explores the development moves to explain this variation. To do so, I focus on the means of mili-
of coercive capacity, which I define as the ability to mobilize force and tary recruitment as a place to isolate the effects of ideas and institutions
exercise it effectively. All four countries had strikingly small armies across on state capacity. The means of recruitment varied across cases, and had
the period under investigation, and their mobilization for war had no implications for the efficiency of mobilization. Where conscription was
lasting effect on military development, as armies were disbanded and sol- systematic and routine, populations accepted the burden of military par-
diers released in the immediate aftermath of combar. However, coercive ticipation to a greater extent. But where it was ad hoc and coercive, mili-
capacity diverged in two important ways. Cases varied sharply in their tary service remained conflictual rather than being marked by what Levi
ability to mobilize fighting forces when needed, and in the existence of a famously described as "quasi-voluntary compliance" (Levi 1997).
truly national army rather than the forces of a particular region or cau- Systematic, routine, legalized conscription emerged in Chile. As
dillo. While over time the Chilean and Mexican states carne to be able I show, this derived directly from its administration by deployed bureau-
to summon an increasingly effective and national army, the Peruvian and crats, who had an interest in military effectiveness and were willing to
Colombian states could not. overcome the unpopularity of conscription. The result was an army that
This chapter shows that the ideational and institutional explanation (in comparative perspective) could mobilize large numbers of troops,
I advance can account for patterns of variation across the four cases. saw low desertion rates, and integrated Chileans from nationwide into a
It begins by addressing an important alternative explanation common single fighting force. These are three characteristics of an effective army.
in accounts of state building the claim that war makes states. I show By contrast, conscription in Colombia and Peru was forcible andad hoc,
that participation in war cannot explain the divergent paths of military and tended to be carried out by military units on an as-needed basis. The
development, since all four states were embroiled in similar levels of result in both cases was that mobilization was difficult, desertion and
international and domestic conflict and faced similar challenges to their resistance to conscription were commonplace, and troops tended to be
authority. War did not make states in Latín America. The effects of war unmotivated in combat outside their home region. Because units were
on coercive capacity are a more direct test of this relationship than is the populated with troops from particular locations, nothing like a national
more indirect effect of war on extraction, which can be mediated by a army emerged; instead the national military was little more than a series
set of alternative means of war finance (Downing 1992; Centeno 2002). of regional militias. In Peru, this outcome resulted from the unwillingness
The finding later in this discussion that war had no effect on army size of local elites serving as administrators under delegated rule to comply
casts doubt on the presence of a causal link between war-making and with conscription edicts from the capital, leaving military units with no
state-making in Latín America. choice but to fill their ranks by forcible recruitment. In Colombia, this

202
204 State Building in Latin America
H \!) O\ 00 1:-- Ir> 1:--
1:-- lr> C'<"\ H
'1-<'l O
VH00H00
outcome derived from the disinclination of the national government to ó ó ó ó ó ó ó
increase its coercive capacity; military recruitment was first systematized *
* * O\o 1:--
0\'1-0\'1-<'l
only in r9n, and even then only to a minimal extent. ir,
1:--'1-lr>l:--C'<"\O 00
H «"\ «"\
o 0\00
qqqr-:qqU) \D 0 Ñ H
Mexico represents an intermediate case, where state builders inher- 000000µ;< ;:'.;' <"Í ó ó ó
1 1 1 ;:>-< H
ited a war-torn polity with fragmented armed forces that had local and
regional loyalties. Here, in other words, the preexisting weakness of the 1:--HOO tr,0 l:--C'<"\
O\DC'<"\Olr><'lO
H H 0 0 H 0 0
state in coercive terms (described in Chapter 3) played a role. The compe- ó ó ó ó ó ó ó
tition among military forces far recruits led to less forcible conscription
*
* *
practices; but among these were often guarantees that service could be -~ *V"\ co t'---. V"\ ('(") V"\ *i:--...
o
Ñ
1:--
00 \!)
o
locally based and under locally selected officers, a practice that would ~ ~0'88~88 0\D\D
o o
('<"\ Ñ
H

8
need to be changed far military development to be complete. Porfirio < óóóóóóóO
1 1 1 1 z ;:'.;',.; ó ó ó
H

Díaz was able to undermine these locally focused forces and begin a
Ñ H Ñ
transition to a national army even under these difficult circumstances, \!)
H
H
H
H
H
largely because of his alliance with the jefes políticos, who tended to be ó ó ó
o
deployed from the capital and therefore cooperative in military moderni- N
·¡;; * <Ll
u
* i::
zation efforts. Thus, Mexican state building, facilitated by deployed rule, * ·¡;;

allowed it to partially overcome the legacies of its particularly severe ~ '-<

"'
¡;:
< .....o
post-independence state crisis. o Ñ \!) \!)
V"\ V"\('("\ H
V H 0 0
ó ó ó ó
WAR AND THE STATE: LIMITS OF THE "BELLIC" APPROACH
* *
* * 1:-- 00
Perhaps the most commonly cited explanation far state building is war. *H V H rn * 0 lr>OO
O\

H ft"\ ('("\V"\ 1:-- o 1:-- 00


Most accounts of state formation in early modern Europe assert that H
<"Í
0
ó ó ó
0 0 ('("\
H
H
. 0. .
«"\
.
0
0 0
Ñ H

1 1
(to use one-half of Tilly's felicitous phrase) "war made the state" (Tilly H

1975, 42). Because the prosecution of war required the construction of <'l
\!)
v
H
ir,
0
0 H H
a bureaucracy that could extract resources and manpower from society, ó ó ó
and because weak states were wiped off the map, war is said to have cre-
.,., O\ .,.,
.,.,
ated strong states in the European context. But Centeno (2002) has shown O\ .,.,
vo o
that this argument does not apply to Latin America. The region has never ó ó ó o
seen total war (with the exception of Paraguay's effort in the War of the
1 z
O\ o .,., .,.,
Triple Alliance), and therefore states have not had to develop the mobi- 00\D
00 H
""'º
0 0
lizational and extractive capacity that characterizes the European states. ó ó ó ó
O v \D
Latin America's wars could more aptly be described as skirmishes than \!) O\\!)
o
\D Ñ \!) o
.,., Ñ
('<"\ H H H H
as major conflicts. They required few soldiers, and were funded by inter- .,., o o o \D \000
ó ó ó ó o f(') ••••

national and domestic debt rather than by the development of taxation. 1 1 z H


H
0 0 0 0
1

Thus, Centeno concludes that the absence of total war in Latín America
explains why its states are universally weaker than are their European
counterparts.
But we might suppose that conflict can still help to explain why
sorne states within the region have more infrastructural power than do
206 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 207

others. To examine this possibility, I conduct a simple region-wide statis- states could only deploy smaller forces and mobilize troops in a scatter-
tical test. Using data in Centeno (2002), I compile a dataset of wars in shot fashion, we can conclude that they were weak. The evidence from
Latin America since independence, and the size of the army at the end threats in the four cases can be compared synchronically and diachroni-
of each decade since 1850 as a proportion of the population. Under 1
cally. Within-case comparison highlights the evolution of state power in
various model specifications, international war has very little effect on a given case over time, and the material that follows is presented in that
army size - there is no effect for current war, nor for years of war in the manner. Cross-case comparison reveals variation in the power of the four
previous decade, and this holds when dummy variables for individual states at any given moment.
countries are included. Civil war, under either specification (and specified
as total years of civil war since independence) has no effect on army size 2

(see Table 6.1). War, then, did not even lead to increased army size in the Chile
region.3 Figure 6.1 shows the size of the Chilean army from 1827 (shortly after
independence) through 1912. A first glance at the figure highlights the
THE CAPACITY TO MOBILIZE fact that the army was usually very small. Over time, the army grew from
levels below 3,000 for the l84os (notably, this is after the first War of
Moving beyond army size to more nuanced assessments of state capacity the Pacific) to levels around 7,000 by l9ro, arate of growth that did not
involves reconsidering the relationship between war and the state. A mea- even keep pace with population. More important, however, as an indica-
sure of the state's capacity to mobilize is the ability to move from a peace- tor of the state's capacity to mobilize its population when necessary are
time equilibrium of relatively little force to a wartime state of intense the severa! huge spikes in Figure 6.r. The two largest spikes respond to
mobilization when necessary. The increase in army size at moments when the War of the Pacific and the 1891 Civil War, but the Chilean army also
war looms reflects the state's ability to penetrate society and effectively increased rapidly in size in response to a series of threats to the state, both
implement policy. To score the cases on this dimension of state capacity, interna! and externa!: the war against the Peru-Bolivian Confederation
I examine the military conflicts in which each was embroiled during the (1836-1839), the 1859 Revolution (but not the l8SI Revolution), the
long nineteenth century, and consider how the capacity to mobilize and war with Spain in 1865-1866, the War of the Pacific that began in 1879,
deploy forces changed over time. Where mobilization took place quickly the 1891 Civil War, and border tensions with Argentina in the late l89os.
and systematically, this indicates that the state was powerful. Where As the nineteenth century wore on, and the state's power increased, it
became increasingly effective at mobilizing military power when it saw fit.
' Data come from Centeno (2002). Army size data is in Table 5.1; data on wars is in
Table 2.I. I focus only on the army, leaving out the navy, both because the army was the
In the 1836-1839 war with Bolivia and Peru, ittook Chile ninemonths
largest branch of the military and dueto data availability. National Guard units and other to dispatch its first force of 2,200 officers and roen to the battlefront.4
"men in arms" are discussed later. After this force was defeated, it took eight months to organize the sec-
, The only specification of war that does ha vean effect on army size is the cumulative num-
ond force of 5,400. Not long therafter, by the time of the l 8 5 l and l 859
ber of years of intemational war since independence, which has a statistically significant
but negative effect on the proportion of the population enrolled in the army. For every Civil Wars, the state's capacity had already increased: it could mobilize an
year of war since independence, the current size of the army is reduced by nearly 0.06% equivalent number of troops much more quickly.
of the population.This result is statistically significant at the 99% confidence leve! in a By the time of the War of the Pacific, the mobilizational capacity of the
linear regression model (n=n3 country-decades). This is a sizable effect, since most data
points for the army size fall between o and 1 % of the population. Since severa! countries Chilean state had grown dramatically. Officially, Chile began the war in
in the sample had nearly thirty years of war in the period, this suggests that the size of the April 1879 with 3,500 officers and men under arms, although the fiscal
army in these countries was cut by more than 50% dueto a history of war. Certainly this
pattern is in tension with the claim that war makes states. • These assessments of mobilization are largely based on the descriptions of military cam-
J Nor did externa! rivalry, as Thies (2005) suggests. Rivalry was ubiquitous in ali four
paigns in various volumes of the Historia del Ejército Chileno (HEC). Although this source
cases, and yet most are not marked by the slow accretion of state power that Thies finds is an official military history, and therefore potentially subject to bias, its descriptions are
for the twentieth century. For a case-based reevaluation of the relation Thies claims to echoed by independent investigations of particular conllicts, such as Sater (2007), and it
find between intemational rivalry and state building, see Saylor and Soifer (2008). is commonly cited by historians.
208 State Building in Latin America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 209

50000 With the end of each of these threats, the army was decreased in size
¡;¡ OFFICIAL ARMY SIZE quite rapidly, as seen most dramatically in the demobilization of thousands
45000 11 ACTUAL ARMY SIZE
of troops within two months after the occupation of Lima in January 1881
(HEC 6, 226-227), and the reduction in unit size and dissolution of multi-
40000
ple infantry units (HEC 4, 167) in the immediate aftermath of the departure
35000 of the Spanish navy from the Chilean coast in 1867. Even at the turn of the
twentieth century, tensions with Argentina highlight the same pattern: sig-
30000 nificant forces were mobilized rapidly in the late l89os as tensions rose, but
Sater and Herwig (1999, 72) claim that army size was cut in half almost
25000
immediately after a treaty resolved the dispute in October 1904.
The Chilean state also mobilized the country's National Guard when
20000
it needed to respond to both interna! and externa! challenges, making
15000 its coercive capacity even more impressive. The first war with Peru and
Bolivia saw National Guard units mobilized to a limited extent as reserve
10000 units used far domestic policing (Hernandez Ponce 1984, 95ff). Guard
units were also mobilized to respond to military revolts in 1850-1851
(HEC 4, 7off) and to a greater extent in the more protracted fighting of
the 1851 Civil War, where Guard units were mobilized in both the south-
ern and central campaigns (HEC vol. 4, pp. 88, 94, 96, 98). The 1859
Civil War saw a similar pattern of National Guard mobilizations (HEC 4,
FIGURE 6.r. Chilean army size, r827-r9r2. 145-149). More significant mobilization of the National Guard occurred
Sources: Data from various volumes of the HEC, and various Memorias of the War Ministry, during the War of the Pacific: more than 200 guard units were mobi-
and Heroandez Ponce (1984). Official figures represent the size of the army as set by the lized, reorganized, or activated in 1879 and 1880 (HEC ro, Appendix
executive branch, while actual figures represent actual force sizes.
l). In mid-1883, more than 13,000 guard members were serving active
duty in the war against Peru and on the southern frontier when the army
crisis of the late l87os likely reduced the number below this level. By units were mobilized against Peru (HEC 6, 438). Thus, the Chilean state's
October 1879, nearly lo,ooo men were under arms: the size of the army increasing capacity to summon forces far its defense grew even larger
had tripled in six months. It doubled again by the middle of 1880, and when we consider the National Guard alongside the Army.
doubled again to reach nearly 42,000 by the end of that year when the
campaign of Lima was launched. In other words, during the War of the
Peru
Pacific, the army ranks grew tenfold; more than 3 6,ooo officers and men
were mobilized and dispatched to the battlefield. Data is too fragmentary to compile a time series of army size far Peru
This notable increase in the capacity of the state to mobilize forces to like the one shown far Chile earlier. But it does permit the examination of
defend itself can also be seen in the 1891 Civil War. Faced with a battle mobilization in response to the six6 international wars that Peru fought
against the forces supporting the Congress, President Balmaceda raised the between independence and 1870, as well as the subsequent War of the
size of the army from about 5,ooo to more than 3 6,ooo in six months. In Pacific. The six wars listed in Table 6.2 involved significant army cam-
addition, the Congressional forces (not included in Figure 6.1) numbered paigns, and Peru won three of them, defeating Bolivian forces in 1828,
nearly 10,000 officers and men (HEC 7, l32ff). Thus, the Chilean state,
by century's end, was able to mobilize tens of thousands of men far combat s Both civil wars of the 185os also saw sorne National Guard units join rebel forces.
within a matter of months, a vast improvement over its ability in the l83os. 6
I exclude the war with Spain 1865-1866, since it was conducted entirely as a naval battle.
210 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 211

TABLE 6.2. Peruvian nineteenth-century wars and army mobilization for our purposes is this level of mobilization compared to those in the
Years Opponent Maximum peruvian earlier conflicts described earlier: Peru was barely able to mobilize more
mobilization troops in the 188os than in the early post-independence decades. In this
sense, there was no increase in coercive capacity.
1827-1828 Bolivia 5,000
1828-1829 Gran Colombia 7,500* Coercive capacity did improve in one sense: the army carne fumly under
1835-1836 Bolivia lO,ooo** the aegis of the national government by mid-century. In the 182os and
1836-1839 Chile 6,ooo*** 183os various military caudillos each had their own armies, and chose to
1841 Bolivia 5,377 cooperate or to withhold their forces from unified combat against ene-
1859-1860 Ecuador 8,ooo mies for their own purposes. Gamarra, a military caudillo from Cuzco,
1866 Spain Army not significantly
mobilized was notorious for this practice throughout the fust two decades after
1879-1883 Chile 7,246**** independence. 8 Castilla was a ble to put an end to this practice, and cre-
19,000 ate the Peruvian national army. Yet the army failed to become a unified
national force; as late as the War of the Pacific, Peruvian forces were
* This figure <loes not include the 4,500 troops that Gamarra and La Fuente mobi-
often divided into "troops" and "indios" (Méndez 2005). Thus, the size
lized in the southem highlands that never reached the battlefront, ar the Peruvian
reserve army of 8,ooo. of the Peruvian forces in these campaigns overstates the number of troops
** This figure represents Gamarra's army of" 4,000 troops and 6,ooo indios" in this that were trained and organized as part of the Peruvian national army.
conflict. (Citation from Dellepiane 1943, 333). Even with that overestimate, we can see that the Peruvian state saw much
*** This figure represents the size of the army of the Peru-Bolivian Confederation,
and not exclusively Peruvian forces. smaller gains in coercive capacity over the state-building period than did
**** The first figure derives from HEC 5, w8, and reflects the mobilization of its Chilean counterpart.
Peruvian forces in October 1879: six months after war was declared and when
the first confrontations of the war began. The second figure represents the size of
the force mobilized to defend Lima from Chilean attack in early l88r. Colombia
Source: Dellepiane (1943) vol. I.
Even in comparison to Peru, the coercive capacity of the Colombian state
was quite limited. The strikingly anti-statist attitudes of mid-century
Gran Colombian forces in present-day Ecuador in 1829, and Ecuadorian Colombian liberals, highlighted in the previous chapters on taxation and
forces in 1860. Yet in each case, fewer than 10,000 troops were mobilized education, can be seen in the military realm as well. The army remained
for combat.7 This low level of mobilization is consonant with Centeno's vestigial at best, and the national government went so far as to grant
argument about limited war in Latin America, and casts doubt on the legal status to other armed forces even as they challenged the central
notion that war made the Peruvian state. state. This was a state that had no particular commitment to developing
The 1879-1883 War of the Pacific revealed Peru's limited coercive any coercive capacity, and no concern about retaining a monopoly of
capacity, especially in comparison to Chile's. Six months after war was legitimate force.
declared, Peru could mobilize only 7,246 officers and men on the battle- The army numbered about 3,000 during the 183os in the aftermath
front; the smallest army at this time of the three combatants. After the of the conf!icts that tore apart the Gran Colombian confederation, and
defeat of this force, Peru struggled to organize an army to defend Lima did not grow much from that level for the remainder of the century (see
from Chilean attack (Kurtz 2009, 496). Edicts ordered the mobilization Figure 6.2). Liberals, who took power in 1849, strongly considered elim-
of all males aged sixteen to sixty, and yet Lima was defended by a "poorly inating the standing army altogether (Bushnell 1993, 112). Its size was
equipped and led 19,000 man improvised militia" substantially smaller slashed, falling as low as 400 men for much of the 185os, and to 109
than the attacking Chilean force (Klarén 2000, 189 ). The key implication
8
Dellepiane (1943, vol. l, 299-344) makes this practice clear. See also Walker (1999,
7 Data about military mobilization in this section is based largely on Dellepiane (1943). chapter 5).
212 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 213

(officers and troops) in 1856. Scheina (2003, I, 496) cites an average size 9000
of l,200 between I855 and 1874. When Nuñez took power in 1880, l m Army Size 1
8000
he made sorne efforts to increase the role of the army in the service of
national stability and unity (Park 1985, 210). Only in the r88os did the 7000
size of the standing army return to the levels of the r83os and surpass
3,000. After this point, the army ranks consistently numbered more than 6000
5,000, and often more than 6,ooo. But between 1890 and r92I, while
5000
the country's population rose by more than 50 percent, the army did not
increase in size. Colombia, in other words, saw little or no growth of 4000
coercive capacity by this crude measure.
Yet a better measure of coercive capacity than the size of the standing 3000

army is the ability of the state to mobilize troops for war when needed. 2000
Since Colombia was not embroiled in any international war between
I830 and I930, we must look to mobilization for internal security.
Exarnining the Colombian state's response to internal threats reveals that
it remained strikingly lacking in its ability to mobilize in response to a
threat. The severity of interna! threat can be approximated with data
from McGreevey (r97r, 88) on deaths in combat per decade and months FIGURE 6.2. Colombian army size, 1830-1930.
of conflict per decade. Neither of these measures of severity of internal Source: Cardona (2008, 93 ).
threat is systematically associated with army size,9 Only in the r89os,
which was marked by the most severe civil war since independence, do
we see significant mobilization. 1 º Otherwise, domestic conflict appears severa! armed movements in seizing the state during the nineteenth cen-
not to have spurred significant rnilitary development. tury reveals its limited coercive capacity most clearly.
A second manifestation of the state's weakness is the ability of chal- Figure 6.2 shows that the army grew sharply under Nuñez in the
lengers to mobilize forces equal to or larger than those of the national gov- ~88os. But this increase overstates the gains in coercive capacity. The
ernment (Cardona 2008, 94). Valencia Tovar (I993, Vol. 2) cites severa! lrmits of Nuñez's efforts to ensure a domestic monopoly of force can
examples of opponents to national authority mobilizing forces equivalent clearly be seen in several aspects of his policies. First, his public order
to those of the national army. And even when single opposition arrnies law of I88o restricted the rights of the national government to intervene
did not match those of the national government in size, Bogotá was still in state-level politics without the invitation of the relevant individual
vulnerable to defeat: the modal pattern for civil wars in Colombia was s~a~~ governments. National leaders, in other words, accepted the pos-
multiple concurrent uprisings by regional leaders, which the central state s1b1hty of overthrow of state governments and ceded the right to inter-
was unable to address simultaneously (Earle 2000). Indeed the success of vene to prevent such instability. Even more dramatically, Nuñez-era law
allowed state governments to import weapons for their own purposes·
affirming in an r88r law that "under the federal constitution the state~
ha ve the right to huy, import, and possess arms and war materials" (Park
9 The overall correlation between rnonths of conflict per decade and rnaxirnurn arrny size
I985, 2_09). The federal government, in other words, enjoyed nothing
per decade is actually negative. While the causal relationship here cannot be identified,
we can conclude that protracted interna! conflict was not associated with increased rnil- resemblmg a monopoly of force in Colombia, and was willing to toler-
itary rnobilization. ate this situation. Nuñez was no different from his predecessors in this
'º The correlation between combar deaths and arrny size is 0.77; rernoving the decade of sense: national leaders had since I863 been regularly notified about state
the l9oos reduces it to 0.19. This suggests that there was little relationship between the
severity of conflict and arrny size before 1900. imports of weapons and never acted to block these actions.
2I4 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capaáty 2I5

The War of l,ooo Days was a unique instance of mass military mobi- It also parallels the discussions of the other countries by comparing the
lization. The war began with fairly small armies, akin to those mobilized state's military response to threat over time during the Porfiriato.
for earlier interna! conflicts, but mobilization escalated in preparation for War against the United States (1845-1848) and resistance to the
the May l 900 battle of Palonegro, which was the largest military engage- French Intervention (1862-1867), along with conflict between Liberals
ment on Colombian soil to date, pitting more than lo,ooo troops on each and Conserva ti ves in the mid-18 5os, had resulted in the mobiliza-
side (Bergquist 1986, 149). After the Liberal defeat, the war devolved into tion of thousands of armed men (Santoni 1996). These forces, com-
guerrilla violence, which spurred further recruitment of forces on both manded by local and regional strongmen, served as the foundation for
sides; McGreevey (1971, 88) estimates the maximum army size at 29,000. the massive decentralization of political power in mid-century Mexico.
Although the size of force mobilized was great, a closer examination of Cross-national statistical comparisons, which show that Mexico had
this episode reveals the limited coercive capacity of the state. Military about as many men in arms as did other Latin American countries, con-
commanders had massive difficulties compelling troops to do anything ceal the vast fragmentation of coercive capacity in Mexico. Instead of
more than defend "their own homes" (Bergquist 1986, 164-165). The a national army, the country had dozens of forces, each drawn from a
national army of the War of l,ooo Days was, in other words, more like particular region and with a particular set of loyalties and allegiances,
a series of local militias pressed into service that "refused to pursue guer- that carne together only against foreign foe and fragmented when con-
rillas outside their own districts" (ibid., 165 ). And although the state was flict ended. This can be seen, for example, in the fact that the early
able to increase the size of the army, it was unable to command com- Porfirian national army numbered between 24,000 and 30,000, while
pliance even over officers who regularly "neglected their duties" (165) various "irregular and auxiliary state forces" numbered about 70,000
and betrayed the government cause, or to prevent massive desertion by (Hernández Chávez 1989, 262).
soldiers. In terms of pure numbers, the historical record shows a decline in
For this and other reasons, the government found itself strikingly troop sizes over the Liberal and Porfirian eras. Upon taking power with
unable to combat the Liberal guerrillas effectively. As guerrilla violence the defeat of the French in l 8 67, one of the first orders of business for the
dragged on for more than two years, elites of all political stripes began to Liberals was an effort, driven by both fiscal constraints and fear of armed
feel threatened, leading them to "minimize their long-standing differences opponents, to demobilize as many troops as possible. Hernández Chávez
and [act] to bring the conflict to a close" (ibid., I57). Additionally, the (1989, 267) estimates a reduction from about 80,000 to about 20,000;
specter of United States meddling in Panama and the loss of that province Fuentes (1983, 59) estirnates an immediate 60 percent reduction from
motivated peace efforts. This led to the settlement of the conflict. With 70,000. Reduction in army size continued under Porfirio Díaz: Table 6.3
peace, the standing army was cut sharply, falling back to 5,300 by l9ro. shows a steady but slow decline in the number of troops, and a more
The army would remain at this small size until the l93os. rapid cashiering of officers. Given the absence of externa! threat through-
out this period, this trend is not terribly surprising. n
But the declining raw figures of the number of troops conceal the
Mexico
sizable gains that state leaders achieved in two aspects of coercive capac-
The challenge of military development in Mexico was different than in the ity. First, even as the army shrank, it carne more firmly under the con-
other cases. Rather than difficulties in mobilizing troops to meet threats to trol of state leaders. Multiple armed forces with limited loyalty to the
the state, the state confronted tens of thousands of men in arms who were national government were eliminated and replaced with a professional
neither unified nor loyal to the national government. Gains in the state's military, loyal to national leaders, rather than to local and regional elites.
coercive capacity in Mexico, then, are reflected not only in the number of
troops that could be summoned, but also in the increased centralization " While the United States continued to loom to the north, there was a broad consen-
sus among policymakers that military development would not suffice to respond to an
of military force. To capture this process, this section largely explores the American invasion; thus scholars agree the development of Mexican coercive capacity
complex evolution of the rnilitary over time that increased central control. did not respond to international threat (Hernández Chávez r989).
216 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 217

TABLE 6.3. Army size in Mexico, selected years, I884-I9IO of decommissioning thousands of officers and soldiers (Neufeld 2009, 17
and 46). He also began to use the army rather than the National Guard,
Year Officers Troops
at least in sorne cases, to put clown revolts. But this represented only
1884 3,684 30,366 lirnited progress in rnilitary development, leaving the same challenge to
1896 3,288 confront Díaz when he took power in 1876.
1899 3,501 26,13 l
Like the Liberals, Díaz rode localized military force to national
1905 3,396 24,758
1907 2,855 24,841 power, leading a successful revolt in 1876 that was heavily supported by
1910 2,365 22,980 National Guard units (Neufeld 2009, 17). Upon taking power, he found
other localized forces with similar ambitions. Like his Liberal predeces-
Source: Hernández Chávez r989, 286.
sors, he would find it politically difficult to centralize rnilitary force, and
even harder to disband localized forces. Yet significant progress was made
Second, the ability of the state to respond to security threats increased, during the Porfiriato. Two policies were the cornerstones of his efforts to
even as the brute size of the army declined. build effective centralized coercion.
Both Liberals and Porfirians sought to boost rnilitary centralization One was the 1888 elirnination of the National Guard, which did not
and effectiveness. But they were hampered by the fact that they had come fit into plans for a centralized military in Mexico. Recognizing the dan-
to power with the support of local forces (chiefly National Guard units) ger posed by units that had fundamentally local loyalties, especially after
seeking greater autonomy. Both by design and because of the centrifuga! units joined local uprisings in several cases in the l88os, Díaz sought to
nature of the fighting that brought the Liberals to power in l 8 57, the demobilize the National Guard entirely (Thomson with LaFrance 1999,
National Guard could not be a reliable arm of the central state because it 250). This process faced resistance, at times violent, both from soldiers
represented fundamentally local and state-level Liberal interests (Hamnett concerned about losing salary and from regional commanders concerned
1996, 666). Even when the new constitution placed the National Guard about losing armed loyalists (ibid., 260). But Díaz pushed through
under the control of Congress, the centralization Mexico City sought was with elirninating the Guard, and replaced its internal security role with
hampered by a law that held that Congress could only order units outside army units.
their local community with the consent of local officials. And because Second, Díaz made fundamental changes to the army. Most cen-
Congress itself feared many of the Liberal centralizing measures, which trally, he divided it between permanent and auxiliary forces, relying
were associated with the empowering of the presidency at Congress's on the former and keeping the second in reserve in their home regions
expense, it proved reluctant to change this legal obstacle to centralization for deployment as needed. Graduates of the reorganized officer train-
(Hamnett 1996, 680-681). ing schools (opened in 1869 and 1879) populated the permanent army;
Liberals made fairly little progress on this front. Deep distrust of the the old guard were relegated to the auxiliary forces. While they thus
army left them reluctant to rebuild it, and therefore they were reliant on remained a burden on the state's coffers, Díaz was able to layer a new
the National Guard. Local Guard units could neither be molded into a professional officer corps over the old regional caudillos (Hernández
national force nor disbanded (which would cost thousands of jobs) as Chávez 1989, 264). Boundaries between the two forces were hard to
Liberals sought to centralize and increase coercive power. The balancing cross; the new permanent force developed a professional officer corps
act of "the subordination of regionalism to nationalism without destroy- without directly challenging the auxiliary forces that were threatened by
ing federalism with centralism" was a very difficult one (Perry 1978, 5). the Díaz reforms.
Rather than addressing this issue head on, Liberals opted for incremental At first, Díaz relied on auxiliary units of the army to replace the
measures to weaken their reliance on the Guard. Juárez created a series National Guard in its policing capacity. This was both cheaper and
of rnilitary colonies to garrison hostile and remote areas, and increased less overtly centralist than deploying the permanent units without
the size of the military reserve as a way to avoid the political challenges local ties into a state. But a series of local uprisings in the early l 89os
218 State Building in Latin America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 219

revealed the problems with this strategy, as auxiliary units refused to TABLE 6.4. Troops stationed by state, Mexico, 1895-19ro
fight against their fellow residents' (Hernández Chávez 1989, 277).
2

1895 1900 1910


This confirmed the distrust Díaz had of the auxiliary corps, and the
1896 military reforms involved massive cuts of the auxiliary forces. TOTAL 33,226 38,588 36,720
Díaz retired six of seven generals, more than three-quarters of colo- Aguascalientes 233 265 377
Baja 289 244 377
nels, and similarly high proportions of high-ranking officers (ibid., Campeche 1,530 214 45
Table 2). Chiapas 232 223
358
Over the course of the Porfiriato, the territorial reach of the state's coer- Chihuahua 622 1,241 1,268
cive power spread quite widely and centralized coercive power increased. Coahuila 656 392 1,211
Table 6.4 shows that troops in significant numbers were present in every Colima 272 84 102
Distrito Federal 6,753 8,543 9,175
one of Mexico's states after l 89 5. Díaz divided the country into eleven
Durango 571 680 292
military zones, whose boundaries did not overlap with state borders. Guanajuato l,936 l,686 1,230
Regular rotation of officers and units also contributed to increased central Guerrero 946 900 470
government control over the army (Lieuwen 1968, 2). Detachments were Hidalgo 607 827 689
deployed far and wide, reaching far beyond state capitals and economic Jalisco 1,729 3,488 951
centers to "communities, towns, neighborhoods, and countryside often México 498 931 1,558
Michoacán 331 1,404 1,323
to places that had scarcely seen the federal presence previously" (Neufeld Morelos 1,818 197 549
2009, 178). The entry of small corps of troops to small towns in remate Nuevo León 1,773 1,614 976
areas, as Neufeld describes, served a dual role of enhancing security and Oaxaca 2,219 2,421 1,760
undermining localism. Combined with the extension of railroad and tele- Puebla l,189 2,591 1,855
graph networks that could surnmon and deliver reinforcements, small Querétaro 416 413 669
Quintana Roo o o l,239
detachments could more effectively respond to threats.
San Luís Potosí 529 416 l,143
The relatively high level of coercive capacity can also be seen in the Sinaloa 634 646 234
state's responses to two prominent outbreaks of regional unrest (the Sonora 1,029 4,638 2,918
Yaqui rebellions and the aftermath of the Yucatán Caste War), and even Tabasco 152 170 66
in the performance of the Porfirian army in the 19 IO revolution. The state Tamaulipas 1,405 l,008 808
responded to rebellion by entering the Sonaran heartland of the Yaqui, Tepic 385 625 1,387
Tlaxcala 347 346 390
an indigenous community, with a massive military intervention (along Veracruz l,845 1,260 1,694
with sorne development initiatives) (Hu-DeHart 1988, 161). Yaqui insur- Yucatán 1,619 236 876
gents were "crushed" in 1887 by the "larger and better equipped federal Za catecas 661 750 865
army" (ibid., 162), and the federal government took charge of develop-
Source: Estadísticas Económicas del Porfiriato: Fuerza de Trabajo y Actividad Económica
ing a long-term pacification program to prevent further irruption of vio- por Sectores (Mexico: El Colegio de México) 1960, p. 56.
lence. With the failure of initial efforts, and further uprising, the Díaz
government turned to the wholesale deportation of the Yaqui. Beginning
in 1902, thousands were shipped to the south of Mexico, in a policy of support, and brought an end to the conflict (Hu-DeHart 1988, 166).
"genocide through deportation" (Neufeld 2009, 184). Others were forc- Once the region was depopulated, the Yaqui River valley was resettled
ibly conscripted into military units sent to the Yucatán. This brutal pol- under military control, with modernization projects and infrastructural
icy extirpated the Yaqui guerrillas by draining their sea of community development undertaken to draw investors. This "taming" of the Yaqui
regions reflected the coercive capacity of the Porfirian state, as well as its
11
On earlier similar incidents, see Reina (1980, 30-3 l). modernizing ambitions.
220 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 22I

Increasingly effective coercive intervention also brought an end to developed a well-oiled rnobilizational apparatus for rnilitary deployment;
longstanding conflict in the Yucatán that persisted for decades after the and Mexico was also relatively capable of effective military mobilization
Caste War, festering largely because insurgent Mayan forces could arrn by the late Porfiriato and had gone a long way toward unifying the armed
thernselves and evade the rnilitary by crossing the international bor- forces in the country under the control of the national governrnent. By
der into British Honduras. '3 A holistic strategy, devised in the l89os, contrast, Peru saw no such gains in coercive capacity. To explain var-
atternpted nothing less than the full incorporation of the region. This iation arnong these three cases, 1 turn once again to the forro of local
included rnilitary intervention, the settlernent of colonists frorn elsewhere adrninistration, and argue that deployed rule (as in Chile and Mexico)
in the country, and infrastructure developrnent. Federal efforts were facilitated state development while delegated rule (as in Peru) tended to
explicitly designed to exclude local elites, both because their cooperation undermine it.
was in question, and due to fear that the Maya would not accept rule The logic linking the incentives of local officials to rnilitary mobiliza-
by the Yucatecan elites they had been fighting for decades. The rnilitary tion feeds through conscription. The ability of the central state to mobi-
cornponent of the intervention included thousands of troops, with par- lize troops depended on its ability to generate cornpliance from its local
ticularly high nurnbers in the final offensive of the conflict in early l90I. agents. But conscription was costly for local officials: as Deas (2002,
Both of these initiatives involved extensive carnpaigns and thousands of 86) writes, "Like taxation, it was rarely popular. Public order being often
troops, a reflection of the state's ability to rnobilize overwhelrning force precarious, governrnents were reluctant to spread alarrn and perturba-
and irnpose regional stability. tion. Resistance to recruiting and conscription through riot, bochinche,
The rapid fall of the Porfirian state at the start of the Mexican was comrnonplace." Where local officials regularly cornplied with con-
Revolution seerns to call into question the scoring of the Mexican state scription edicts, it became systematized and routine, and populations
as relatively strong, since theorists beginning with Skocpol (1979) have accepted the burden of rnilitary participation to a greater extent. The
ernphasized state weakness as crucial in revolutions. Yet an exarnination result was less desertion and an easier time mobilizing rnen in arms when
of the rnilitary's performance in the war demonstrates its coercive capac- necessary. Conscription by civilian officials also contributed to the emer-
ity: as Vanderwood (1976, 579) puts it, the Porfirian counterinsurgency gence of a national rnilitary identity, since it tended to result in units that
was "unsuccessful, but not necessarily inept." The state fell for reasons mixed recruits frorn various regions. Thus deployed bureaucrats contrib-
largely independent of its coercive capacity. Harnpered by problems of uted to the development of coercive capacity, as shown in the cases of
personalisrn that disrupted rnilitary coordination, by difficulties with sup- Chile and Mexico that follow.
ply chains and cornrnunication, and (rnost of all) by the ability of rebels But under delegated rule, local state agents were less likely to comply
to seek sanctuary north of the U.S. border, Díaz found himself unable with conscription edicts. Mobilization took place in an ad hoc rnanner,
to defeat the Maderista insurgency centered in Chihuahua. As the guer- carried out as necessary by the rnilitary and often by force. The result was
rilla war dragged on, perceptions of the regime's stability shifted sharply, that conscription rernained conflictual. Recruitrnent in Peru was never
and this triggered cascading defections by elites frorn the Díaz coalition. rnarked by the quasi-voluntary cornpliance that routinization brought,
Although the state faced an uphill battle it would eventually lose, the and desertion was higher. Because rnilitary units conscripted en rnasse,
arrny rernained well organized; defeat carne in spite of, and not because the composition was more regionally hornogeneous, and the arrny never
of, its performance. served as a "school for the nation." Delegated rule was key in underrnining
the implementation of rnobilization policies in Peru. The evidence shows
LOCAL OFFICIALS AND MILITARY RECRUITMENT
that in these three cases, local adrninistrative institutions shaped coercive
practices, and thus the coercive facet of state capacity.
The earlier discussion dernonstrates that a gulf in mobilizational capac- Understanding the Colornbian state's lack of coercive capacity requires
ity emerged over the nineteenth century arnong our four cases. Chile us to turn to the ideational cornponent of rny argurnent: I show that state
weakness can result frorn the failure of national officials to ever develop
'' This paragraph draws heavily on Macías Richard (1999). systematic policy. In the coercive realm, this left local officials and military
222 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 223

units to their own devices in the area of conscription even during war- region." Third, lacking local ties, troops could effectively complement
tirne. The result was that conscription remained ad hoc and conflictual, police forces in maintaining social order. Thus the capacity to compel
frustrating mobilization efforts when the state needed them most. Once Chileans to enlist in the army also contributed to the capacity to main-
again, we see that state weakness in Colombia and Peru derives from tain an internal monopoly of force. Because they knew that the army
distinct causal pathways; I address this issue in detail in the Conclusion. served as a guarantor of regional security, and because of the ability
of the central state to sanction them, local authorities were willing to
designate young (predominantly poor) roen for service, and the army
Deployed Rule, Legal-Formal Conscription, and Chilean
no longer had to fill its ranks by forcible conscription.
Military Effectiveness
The only sizable deviation from this model of systematic conscription
By the I84os, military ranks in Chile were filled with a combination was undertaken by President Balmaceda during the I89I civil war. With
of volunteers and those sentenced to rnilitary service by local judicial much of the rnilitary siding with his congressional opponents, Balmaceda
officials (Resende Santos 2007, I35). Volunteers were often motivated built a new fighting force largely through press-gangs. By contrast to the
by enlistment bonuses, which were particularly high for those with pre- motivated and disciplined forces built by his opponents, this practice of
vious army experience who were willing to reenlist (Sater and Herwig Balmaceda produced a force of "hesitant if not indifferent soldiers" that
I999, 67). Because local state agents were responsible for conscription in refused to fight and deserted en masse, leading directly to his defeat (Sater
Chile, and because forcible enlistment was largely eliminated, conscrip- and Herwig I999, 47). By contrast, his opponents engaged in more sys-
tion took place with a veneer of legality that legitirnized and routinized tematic recruitment to fill rnilitary ranks, prornising civilian back pay to
rnilitary service. This quasi-voluntary, rather than coerced, compliance enlistees and spreading recruitment widely to limit its effects on the local
with rnilitary service both reflected the greater ability of the Chilean state economy (ibid., 49 ). This army, which looked more like Chilean arrnies
to penetrate local society and irnproved its rnilitary effectiveness. Both of of previous decades, triumphed easily, reinforcing the link between con-
the mechanisms linking deployed rule to increased state capacity were scription practices and coercive capacity.
at work in this context. Although conscription was not popular, and Conscription became more systematized when Chile undertook
the court sentences of rnilitary service engendered significant resistance, a massive rnilitary modernization project at century's end (Resende
the central state could and did sanction local officials who did not meet Santos 2007). Driven both by response to foreign threats (largely from
recruitment quotas. Beyond the threat of sanctions, local agents were also Argentina) and by the vision of Prussian advisers, systematic conscription
willing to bear the costs of enforcing conscription because they lacked underwent a series of reforms between I893 and I900 (Sater and Herwig
private sources of coercion and therefore needed an effective rnilitary to I999, 8I-83). A draft lottery held in each municipality included all males
help maintain order in their jurisdictions (HEC vol. 4, I6). aged twenty to forty-five, although exemptions tended to favor the upper
The effects of compliance with conscription policies on coercive classes and the politically connected (ibid., rn2-rn3). Sater and Herwig
capacity were manifold. First, the greater cohesion of the Chilean term conscription a "failure" (9 5) based on its unequal incidence. But a
rnilitary can be seen in the low levels of desertion from its army. For glance elsewhere in the region calls that judgement into question: as they
example, during the second War of the Pacific, a force of nearly 4,000 themselves demonstrate, the Chilean state was able by I898 to activate
soldiers involved in a year-long campaign in the Peruvian highlands 60,000 reserve troops when war with Argentina loomed. The focus on
suffered only rn3 desertions (HEC vol. 6, pp. 295-296). Second, sys- the limitations of this mobilization - equipment, training, and leader-
tematic conscription mixed troops from across the country within each ship - makes too little of the degree of coercive capacity demonstrated in
unit rather than leading to individual units recruiting exclusively from mobilizing so many Chileans to military bases in preparation for combat.
the zones in which they were stationed. This helped to create a: sense of After the I900 conscription reform, the state's capacity to mobilize esca-
an army fighting for the Chilean nation. Beginning in I862, the army lated even further: one rnilitary attaché cited in Sater and Herwig (I999,
began the practice of rotating units through the country, which sev- rn9) estirnated that 200,000 reservists (out of a population of 3. I rnil-
ered any remaining connection between a particular unit anda "home lion) could be mobilized within six months.
224 State Building in Latin America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 225

Chile's elites were not well disposed to the military. 1 4 Sater and Herwig As both sides competed to mobilize troops in the I857 civil war,
(I999, 97) highlight the interventions of landed elites to limit military use conditions of recruitment notably improved, shifting from legal
of railroads during harvest time, and refer to the "hatred" of employers enforcement to inducements. Liberals recruited on the grounds of
and wealthy farmers for conscription (rn5). But elite interference with ideological sympathy, by highlighting the tax exemptions awarded to
conscription was absent not because they approved of it, but because guardsmen, and by promising that Guard units would serve close to
they were excluded from local administration by the deployment of home and remain under local, and often indigenous, control. The result
bureaucrats. Where they were able to interfere with military policies was that voluntary enrollment dominated. As Thomson writes in his
costly to them, such as the use of railroads during harvest time, elites study of communities in Puebla, "People chose to join the Guard. Even
did so. Conscription, however, like taxation and education development, if driven to serve by poverty or landlessness, few were forced to serve
was out of their control because it was administered by bureaucrats against their will" (ibid., 37). A crucial shift in I858 instituted a tax,
deployed to the localities where they implemented policies emanating the contribución de rebajadas, imposed on ali who chose not to serve
from state-builders in Santiago. The form of administration was crucial in the National Guard. Payment of the tax, or Guard service, was a
in the successful development of coercive capacity, as it was for the other guarantee against military recruitment (Thomson I990, 38). This gen-
elements of Chilean state strength. erated a consistent pattern of voluntary enrollment in the National
Guard; Thomson (I990, '{2) even highlights sorne communities that
Mexico: Voluntary Enlistment and Legalistic Recruitment had an "enthusiastic response" to mobilization. This tax thus created
a legal framework of eligibility for conscription into both the military
The leva or forced enlistment is commonly cited in accounts of the condi- and the National Guard.
tions of the nineteenth-century Mexican army. Neufeld (2009), for exam- With the escalation of conflict during the French Intervention, recruit-
ple, refers to conscripts as "cannon meat" (43) and claims that conscripts ment became more routinized. Thomson (I993, 2I3ff) describes three
were taken "from their communities by force of arms and law" (39). models of recruitment by the various forces in addition to the model
Yet forcible impressment was in fact fairly rare in Mexico by regional described previously of voluntary recruitment based on ideological
standards. Most conscription in late nineteenth-century Mexico seems appeals and tax exemptions. First and most commonly, local officials
to have operated in a much more legal and formal manner, as suggested were charged with sentencing deserters, vagrants, and other "undesir-
by Neufeld's own use of the term "force of law" in the citation just men- ables" to military service. This option, in somewhat modified terms,
tioned. The Mexican armed forces could fill their ranks in this manner would dominate recruitment until the revolution. A second model, oper-
thanks to their reliance on deployed rule. And the legal nature of most ative only when local states of emergency were declared, placed the
military recruitment facilitated mobilization both in the regionally con- recruitment and equipment of troops under the control of local com-
trolled National Guard and, over time, in the centralizing Porfirian army. manders, who could impose these burdens on the communities where
The first glimmers of systematic conscription emerged during the war they were stationed and require a certain number of "volunteers" for
with the United States. Obligatory universal service was considered for service. This practice was common in the early stages of the war of the
the first time by Mexican politicians, who were driven to "ignore the spec- French Intervention (I86I-I862). Forcible impressment by military units
tre of an armed and angry pueblo" and mobilize the masses (Thomson was the third option; in this model a unit occupied a town on a Sunday or
I990, 3 5 ). Wartime governments created the National Guard, for which market day, and rounded up victims to escort them to the battlefield. This
registration was obligatory and nearly universal; no purchasing of substi- option, both "ineffective and politically counterproductive," was only
tutes was allowed. This compulsory registration stayed on the books for used in times of desperation during the French intervention and thereafter
more than a decade. (Thomson I993, 2I9). The most common model of conscription during
the Liberal era, assignment by legal sentence, thus placed the responsi-
>< Kurtz (2009, 507) disagrees, claiming that Chilean elites were willing to tolerare it, but bility for filling military ranks in the hands of local officials. The active
offers no explicit evidence far this claim. participation of local officials with this mode of military mobilization
226 State Building in Latin America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 227

allowed the Mexican state to mobilize troops largely by means other than provision, jefes also stood to benefit from military development for pro-
forcible impressment. tection against local contention. These two factors, consistent with the
Under Porfirio Díaz, military recruitment continued to operate largely broader argument about deployed rule, explain why they complied with
via legal sentencing. These practices, although somewhat coercive, were orders to send conscripts to military training.
more routinized than the forcible impressment by army units described The compliance of local officials with recruitment edicts allowed them
later in Peru and Colombia. National officials (the Secretary of War and to take place through legal means. Legal conscription contributed to mili-
the Jefes de Reemplazo he appointed for each state) and state governors tary effectiveness in severa! ways. First, desertion rates, although signifi-
set quotas for each jefe político to meet, and these officials "delegated it cant, appear to have been lower than the rates seen in Peru or Colombia.
to municipal officials or personally worked to gather the needed men" Second, army units (although not the National Guard) mixed residents
(Neufeld 2009, sr). The jefe político was free to fill his assigned quota of many regions. For example, troublesome conscripts and desert-
as he chose, with the restriction that recruitment could not take place ers from various parts of the country were often sent far from home
by force - indeed the jefe himself was charged with preventing forcible to the Yucatán, where units mingled soldiers from nationwide (Macías
recruitment by other actors, a power that apparently sought to prevent Richard 1999). Combined with significant military education and the
military units from filling their ranks extralegally. fact that many units served in the Yaqui and Yucatán campaigns, the
The practice of military recruitment was incredibly unpopu- Mexican army did ·become a school for inculcating nationalism among
lar: Neufeld, for example, claims that it was "one of the most despised the Mexican population.
institutions of the Porfirian era" (ibid., 50-51). Recruitment generated At the end of the Porfiriato, conscription had become largely formal,
resistance, especially from peasants and the urban poor, whether overt relying primarily on local authorities such as jefes políticos and local
protest or evasion. Military law banned forcible recruitment, requiring judges, rather than taking the form of coercive impressment by military
that ali soldiers be volunteers or selected by lottery. This formed the basis units. These practices survived even during the early years of the revo-
for legal challenges to recruitment, which were successful enough to lution: as the Madero revolt grew, and recruitment became both more
cause concern among high ranking military officers (Neufeld 2009, 63ff). difficult (dueto the defections of local officials) and more urgent, forc-
The legalistic veneer of conscription practices increased their legitimacy ible impressment still remained on the margins of state practice. Instead,
in the eyes of the population, even if legality did not necessarily make monetary bonuses were used to increase the appeal of military service.
them popular. Yet jefes seemingly complied quite regularly with the order The result was a loyal army rank and file through the early phases of
to impose military quotas on their populations. Indeed, Neufeld (52) conflict, which only fell apart with the more fractal post-1913 phase of
claims that they often went above and beyond the call of duty in sending the Revolution. Systematic legal conscription practices eroded as multi-
recruits. We must acknowledge that in part this was because the power ple armed actors turned to force to fill their ranks; desertion, which had
to assign local male residents to military service strengthened the hold become relatively rare in the Porfiriato, rose sharply in Huerta's army
of local officials over the communities where they ruled; it also provided (Vanderwood 1976, 5 5 5 ). Yet this sharp decline should not conceal the
opportunities for profit and the removal of enemies. And jefes políticos serious increase in the coercive capacity of the Mexican state in the five
could force prisoners, the poor, and local "troublemakers" to bear the decades befare the Revolution.
costs of service, allowing them to conscript without affecting the locally
prominent and powerful.
Delegated Rule and Peruvian Military Weakness
But the central factor in explaining the compliance of local agents was
the incentives of deployed rule. As Neufeld (2009, 51) writes, local offi- For most of the nineteenth century, conscription in Peru was the respon-
cials faced "pressure from above" to fill army ranks, and were induced to sibility of subprefects, who were overwhelmingly selected from among
comply. Given that they carne from outside the communities they ruled, local elites. Local notables had little interest in conscription because it
were more loyal to Porfirio Díaz than to local interests, and had no ties created a national army that threatened their established local power, and
to local National Guard units or alternative options for local security because it removed Indian laborers who were economically vital to their
228 State Building in Latín America Conscription and Coercive Capacity 229

estates (Kurtz 20I3}. Since they were able to draw on their connections Peruvian state to rnobilize a sizable, unified, reliable army caused its
and local power to raise prívate security forces, local officials in Peru did defeat by Chile in the second War of the Pacific.
not rely exclusively on the national army to protect them against threats Just as in education and taxation, the Aristocratic Republic saw
to their power. Additionally, conscription was unpopular and therefore a prograrn of military development that sought to increase the state's
generated the risk of reprisals. In one instance, "following the recruit- reach. Rather than addressing the problems of conscription, however, the
ment of nearly ten soldiers in Cuzco, an anonymous group raided and reforms mostly focused on professionalizing the military and preparing
laid waste to the house of the subprefect responsible for the measure" it for more success in international warfare - a priority for the govern-
(Muecke 2004, I?5). ment, given smoldering tensions with Chile and tense relations with its
As a result of these incentives characteristic of delegated rule, local offi- other neighbors. Particular attention was paid to officer training corps
cials in Peru often shirked and avoided the conscription duties assigned and tactics, which were acquired from the French military training mis-
to them by presidential arder, and ignored regulations governing mili- sion that arrived in I896. Yet little changed below the officer corps; con-
tary recruitment. Far example, although the I872 military service law scription still centered on coerced irnpressment, and the ranks remained
set population-based recruitment quotas for each province, not a single far from a unified, disciplined, national army. This highlights the uneven
province saw full compliance. nature of state building during the Aristocratic Republic, as Peru saw
Because local officials were so reluctant to participate in con- much less progress in coercive capacity than in the realm of education.
scription, military units had to fill their own ranks frorn the popula- Indeed, González-Cueva (2000) cites evidence of forcible conscription as
tions of the regions in which they were located (MGUERRA I845, recently as the I99 5 conflict with Ecuador.
4). Conscription by rnilitary units operated by force and extralegally,
and thus it lacked any legitirnacy. It also led to a concentration of
recruiting in the heavily indigenous southern highlands region of Peru, The Absence of Systematic Recruitment Efforts in Colombia
where "the arrny scoured the countryside of the altiplano from one Just as in the realms of taxation and education, the development of con-
end to another" when troops were needed (Jacobsen I993, I32-I33). scription shows that Colombia's state leaders made very limited efforts
Dueto their recruitrnent by force and by "notoriously cruel methods," to increase the state's power. Indeed, no effort was made to systematize
Peruvian conscripts were not loyal to their army (Méndez 2005, 243). conscription at all and no national policy governing military recruitment
Desertion by these irnpressed soldiers was consistently high, even dur- was ever enacted. This left the task of conscription in the hands of indi-
ing the transport of troops to the front in I879 (Contreras and Cueto vidual military unit commanders, who had to fill their ranks when needed
I999, I37). Officers were occupied just as rnuch with policing new by any means available. Whereas the Peruvian army filled its ranks in a
recruits for desertion as with battlefield training. similar manner because local officials did not cooperate with edicts from
The failure of local officials to collaborate with conscription also had Lima, no such edicts were even issued in Colombia. l5 The absence of sys-
an effect on the arrny's role in nation building. Unlike the regional hetero- tematic conscription procedures hampered the performance of the army
geneity of Chilean and Mexican arrny units, the Peruvian arrny was not a in ways similar to those seen earlier in the Peruvian case, weakening it in
place where recruits carne into contact with a cross section of the nation. the face of domestic challengers. Indeed, because conscription was often
Instead they encountered their fellow poor from the province where the carried out by violent means, recruitment drives contributed to opposi-
unit was rnost recently based. Far exarnple, the Dos de Mayo regirnent in tion support (Deas 2002).
I878 recruited 343 soldiers frorn the departrnent of Ayacucho, where it Systematic historical study of Colombian conscription is lirnited. 16
was deployed to put clown a revolt, in a single rnonth (MGOB I878, 77). Accounts of mid-nineteenth-century civil wars show that both Liberals
Irnpressed troops were more likely to desert, more poorly trained, and
15
less nationally representative. The Peruvian arrny was much further frorn Delpar (1981, 87) cites a requirernent that each state (during the l88os) contribute to the
arrny in proportion to its population, but this contained no edicts on the fonn of recruit-
the ideal of a "nation under arrns," had rnany more discipline problerns, rnent, and was never irnplernented.
and was less effective on the battlefield. The inability of the guano-era 16
Deas (2002) sketches the terrain to be explored and the lirnits of previous scholarship.
State Building in Latin America Conscription and Coercive Capacity

and Conservatives relied on "both volunteers and unwilling recruits" four cases. Instead, war (whether international or internal) posed chal-
(Sanders 2010, 29 ). Military units appealed for volunteers, but filled much lenges to state leaders that revealed the extent of their ability to mobilize
of their ranks by conscription, including forcible impressment. The army compliance. War, in other words, did not make states; it tested them.
filled its ranks through "time-tested methods of forced recruitment of Over the nineteenth century, state leaders in Chile developed increasingly
lower-class men" (Bergquist l 9 86, l 3 3). The army vastly over-represented effective means of mobilizing an army, and security from both domes-
"lndians from Boyacá and Cundinamarca" rather than from the country tic and international threats increased as a result. This derived from the
as a whole (Delpar 1981, 87). Soldiers were recruited as needed by mili- role of deployed bureaucrats in the task of conscription. These officials
tary units in or near the locations where fighters were needed, and often systematized it and made recruitment routine and relatively consensual
marched straight into battle. The result was an untrained army full of and efficient; the army that resulted saw more homogenization and less
soldiers with questionable loyalty and quality, which was strikingly inef- desertion. In Mexico, too, jefes políticos complied with conscription
fective on the battlefield. edicts, leading to the development of a national army for the first time
This pattern is not dissimilar from that seen in the other cases in the during the Porfiriato. Progress here was slower, largely because state
first decades after independence, but military recruitment policies in those leaders had to tread carefully to avoid conflict with the multiple armed
countries emerged as part of state-building efforts. What sets Colombia groups that existed when state building began. But particularly during
apart from the other cases is the absence of efforts to change this policy the Porfiriato, significant steps were taken toward the emergence of a
and systematize military recruitment in any manner. As late as the War powerful national army.
of l,ooo Days, most recruitment continued to take place by ad hoc forc- By contrast, Peruvian and Colombian state leaders continued to strug-
ible recruitment. Bergquist (1986, 135-136) describes conscription by gle to fill military ranks. In Peru, this derived from a continued reliance
"groups of armed men" targeting poor people without. any legal proce- on local elites for recruitment; delegation to these disinterested officials
dure. The result was that desertion and military discipline were a major made the policies ineffective. In Colombia, no efforts were made to sys-
problem for unit commanders, and resistance to conscription was wide- tematize the military's recruitment. In both cases, the absence of sys-
spread, and at times violent. tematic conscription and the reliance on forcible recruitment hampered
The violence of impressment by all sides in the War of l,ooo Days, military mobilization, poisoned state-society relations, and weakened the
and the resulting failures of the army, did place the issue of recruit- homogenizing effect of a national army. By examining conscription, then,
ment squarely at the center of the postwar Reyes reform efforts. Yet his we see how delegated rule (in Peru) and the absence of a state-building
response failed to address the core issue. Although forced recruitment project (in Colombia) each led to a striking absence of coercive capacity.
was formally abolished in 1907, no system of filling army ranks was put
in place. The only new legislation governed the terms of volunteer enroll-
ment; no other means of recruitment was enacted. The disinclination of
political elites to increase state capacity thus continued to account for the
weakness of the Colombian state. 7 1

CONCLUSION

This chapter began by showing that differential participation in con-


flict does not explain the variation in state coercive power across the

" The fact that Colombia did not develop systernatic conscription until well into the twen-
tieth century rnay indeed be one factor underlying the pattem of elite conflict spiraling
into generalized violence at various points in Colombian history.
Conclusion 233

development, while at other times they do not. In a context where


war and other threats to the survival of the state were not present,
factors identified by existing scholarship under-determine variation
in state capacity. This is because the política! decision to pursue state
Conclusion building has not been theorized, and state building has been reduced
to a reaction to structural conditions rather than a política! choice.
In developing an explanation far why state-building efforts emerge,
I have facused on a combination of ideational and material factors,
and argued that state-building initiatives were more likely to be
undertaken in countries characterized by a unified political economy
with a central capital city at its core. Under these circumstances, lead-
ers tended to share a more developmentalist liberal vision and to
believe that the promotion of "arder" and "progress" entailed the
development of state institutional capacity and its extension across
This book has explored the origins of state strength and weakness in the national territory. Where leaders instead confronted a polycen-
Latin America. Unlike most extant scholarship on state development, tric network of urban centers with fragmented regional political
1 have sought to explain two distinct types of variation in state building. economies, they did not see state building as a viable means far pur-
The framework 1 have developed seeks to account far the decision to suing development;, and were more likely to endorse a laissez-faire
build the state, and far the fate of state-building efforts. Thus it explains stance toward the national state and to pursue economic and politi-
why state-building efforts succeed, faunder, or fail to emerge. Although cal development at the regional leve!. The farmer pattern, of a single
it increases the number of "moving pieces" involved, the construction of national center, a developmentalist version of liberalism, and con-
a unified framework to account far the ful! range of state capacity tra- certed state-building effarts, described Mexico in the Liberal and
jectories has sorne important payoffs. Mter pulling together the account Porfirian eras, Chile, and Peru. The latter pattern of multiple salient
developed in the preceding chapters in the first section of the Conclusion, and self-sufficient regions, conflict over the role of the national state,
1 address the extent to which it can be applied more generally across and the absence of a state-building projects accounted far Colombia's
South America. I then turn to highlighting sorne of the implications of the strikingly weak state.
argument developed in this book and the analytical choices that underpin Unlike most scholarship on state building, my account also investi-
it. 1 discuss the importance of long-term historical processes in account- gates why, once state-building projects are undertaken, they tend to
ing far contemporary state weakness in the region, the place of ideas in succeed or fail. This question is simply neglected by the existing scholar-
accounts of state building the central role of equifinality in explanations shi p, which overlooks the fact that state-building efforts do not always
of state development, and the relative importance of the two causal fac- succeed and thus risks falling into the fallacy of assuming that where a
tors - ideational and administrative - far the outcomes observed across weak state is faund, a state-building effort must not have been pursued.
the regían. I clase with sorne implications of my argument far contempo- A more persuasive approach to variation in state capacity is to develop a
rary nation-building projects in post-conflict settings. theoretical account of state-building failure. I argue that the institutional
choices made by leaders in populating the bureaucracy shape the fate of
state-building effarts. In particular, I facus on the differential effects of
THE EMERGENCE AND OUTCOMES OF
deployed and delegated rule. Where leaders relied on deployed rule, send-
STATE-BUILDING EFFORTS
ing outsiders into communities to serve as administrators and implement-
1 have argued that it is crucial to understand why sometimes politi- ers of state policies, state-building effarts were more successful, but under
cal elites unite around state building as an important means to delegated rule, where local elites were appointed to bureaucratic posts,

232
234 Conclusion Conclusion 2 35

state-building efforts foundered. 1 Two mechanisms underlie this diver- capacity, confronted two more altemative explanations. There, I showed
gence: first, deployed bureaucrats could more easily be held accountable that resource dependence can only be a partial explanation for varia-
by the central state, since a larger share of their income depended on tion in state capacity, since it is overly focused on the political costs of
their position. Second, because deployed bureaucrats possessed less local taxation. Resource dependence can account for why governments choose
authority independent of the presence of the central state, they had an not to tax; it cannot account for variation in the capacity to tax where
independent interest in increasing its presence in the communities where commodity booms are absent. Comparing Peru and Chile after the end
they serve. It was this factor, and not the failure of a state-building project of their commodity booms, and tracing the different difficulties which
to emerge, that accounted for state weakness in guano-era Peru. the two states faced in recovering lost revenues, Chapter 5 made the lim-
its of the resource dependence explanation clear. Nor does federalism
Alternative Explanations account for variation in extractive capacity; the comparison of Mexico
and Colombia showed that the distinct obstacles this set of institutions
In developing this account, I have also considered and shown the limits placed on the extractive capacity of the central state were overcome in
of a range of altemative explanations. Chapter l showed that geography the former case but not in the latter. Finally, Chapter 6 addressed the role
did not shape state-building outcomes by affecting the cost-benefit calcu- of war in the development of the state's coercive capacity and showed
lations of state leaders. Indeed, mountainous or rugged terrain, size, and that the nature of war in Latin Arnerica is better seen as a crucible that
other geographicfactors are weakly associated with state development out- tests the state rather than as a forge that makes the state. Against argu-
comes. Chapter 3 addressed the possibility that other historical moments ments about the "bellic" roots of state development, I found that in Latín
rnight hold the key to the divergence among cases: there I showed that Arnerica the capacity to mobilize, train, and deploy troops was not asso-
neither differences in colonial rule, nor the nature of the independence ciated with the onset of war, its duration, or its severity.
period and its irnmediate aftermath, deterrnined state-building trajecto-
ries in the four cases. Chapter 4 showed that ethnic diversity, commonly
A BROADER PERSPECTIVE ON LATIN AMERICAN STATE
said to account for variation in public good provision more generally
BUILDING
and education in particular, cannot account for variation in efforts by
national state leaders to promote education development. The significant This book has made two claims about the causes of state capacity draw-
gains in education development in Peru during the Aristocratic Republic ing on the detailed study of four country cases. One of these can be easily
(1895-1919) highlight the limits of this argument most clearly, since evaluated in a broader set of cases; the other requires more intensive data
the change from eadier periods in Peruvian history was not that social collection and remains to be verified in future research. I first explore the
inequality declined (in fact, most scholars see this as a period where elite relationship between urban primacy and the emergence of a state-building
dominance increased) but that a shift to increase reliance on deployed consensus, generalizing the framework developed in Chapter l to the ten
rule prevented elite preferences about education from affecting its imple- majar countries of Spanish Arnerica. The claim that the delegation of
mentation. Chapter 5, which explored the development of extractive adrninistrative posts to local elites underrnined state-building efforts is
more difficult to test due to data limitations; I provide sorne evidence
1
Chapter 3 provides an account of the choice of delegated or deployed rule in the cases from Argentina to supplement the detailed discussion of this issue in
of Chile, Peru, and Mexico, showing that it was not a result of preexisting variation in Chapter 2.
state capacity but instead the product of a cornplex, historically specific set of factors.
There I show that only where state leaders faced a perceived threat of subaltern revolt to
systernic stability, where they did not see traditional local elites as an obstacle to devel-
oprnent, and where the currency of patronage by which alliances between central and
Urban Primacy and the Origins of State-Building Projects
local elites were cernented was political rather than administrative were the ranks of state
adrninistration populated with local elites. It was the cornbination of these three factors
I argued in Chapter l that the absence of salient regionalism was neces-
that distinguished guano-era Peru frorn the other state-building rnornents under study, sary for state-building efforts to emerge because it would lead to fairly
produced delegated rule, and thus underpinned failed state building in that case. muted regionalist conflicts over public good provision, and a fairly unified
236 Conclusion Conclusion 2 37

TABLE 7.r. Urban primacy and the emergence of state building around state capacity as a means to development, and to pursue state
Predicted
building during the Liberal era. Cases that score below 0.5 on urban pri-
Country Primacy State-building Actual
project state-building correctly? macy are ones where multiple large cities exist, and where regional ten-
seore
predicted? project? sions and self-sufficient regions are likely to undermine the emergence of
a developmentalist vision in which state building is central to economic
Uruguay 0.84 YES YES YES
YES development and political stability.
Argentina o.66 YES YES
o.6 YES YES YES Based on this, the second column of Table 7.I codes whether a
Peru
Mexico o.55 YES YES YES state-building project should be expected to emerge in a given coun-
Chile 0.53 YES YES YES try during the Liberal era, given the score for urban primacy. The third
Ecuador 0.47 NO NO YES column surnmarizes the brief case studies that follow, showing whether
Bolivia 0.46 NO NO YES
developmentalist or laissez-faire liberalism took hold, and whether a
Colombia 0.44 NO NO YES
PARTIAL NO state-building project emerges. The rightmost column simply shows
Paraguay 0.39 NO
(international whether the prediction of the urban primacy-state building argument
threat) holds in each case. As the table prefaces, and the discussions that follow
Venezuela 0.39 NO PARTIAL NO (primacy confum, ali but two cases are predicted correctly. For the two cases that
changes)
are mis-predicted, a brief discussion of Paraguay helps to shed light on
The urban primacy score used for Mexico here is from 1867 and is higher than the 1856 the limits of the argument I have developed, and suggests the lirnits of
score used in Chapter l; as discussed there, this later score more accurately captures the using urban primacy as a measure of the absence of salient regionalism.
dominance of Mexico City during the state-building era. Ali other seores come from The case of Venezuela shows that change over time in urban primacy is
Table r.r. associated with the tirning of state building.

national economy. This facilitares the emergence of an elite consensus High Primacy, Concerted State-Building Efforts Emerge
around the idea that increased state authority was central to develop- ARGENTINA. The dominance of Buenos Aires reflected in the high
ment rather than a more laissez-faire vision of how development rnight urban primacy score for Buenos Aires actually understates the power
'
be pursued. I showed in the three empirical chapters that this difference of the capital. Many of the other large cities listed in the I869 census
in ideas about development accounted for Colombia's distinct trajectory, were located in the littoral provinces near the capital, and deeply tied
in which no salient and sustained state-building project emerged. into its economic orbit. Indeed, Buenos Aires held sway over the entire
But to what e:xtent does this variation in regionalism and ideas about country, since it was the only majar point of export for agricultura! pro-
development account for variation across a broader set of cases? In duction from the interior. Although the early decades after independence
exploring this set of issues, I focus on the ten countries of Spanish South saw massive center-periphery conflict in Argentina, the country never had
America, excluding Brazil because its nineteenth-century history was so the self-contained regional economies that marked cases like Colombia.
distinct in the extent of adrninistrative and political continuity from colo- This lack of salient regionalism, as discussed later, underpinned a robust
nialism to independence. The leftmost column of Table 7.I shows the developmentalist liberal consensus. Buenos Aires and the provinces had a
urban primacy score for each country, using the same data and methods shared econornic interest in export promotion, and a shared commitment
used in Chapter r. Urbanists generally consideran urban primacy score to developing links between zones of export production and the port of
of more than 0.5 - meaning that the largest city in a country has the Buenos Aires (Richmond I989, I).
same population as the next three cities combined to be characterized Underneath the struggle between Buenos Aires and the provinces was
by a primate urban distribution. Based on this, I describe the cases that a consensus on the model of state-led export-based development. By the
fit this pattern as "high primacy" cases and expect them to be dominated I85os, the provinces "now openly espoused ideas earlier identified with
by a single national center, to have a relatively consistent elite consensus the Unitarists" (Rock I987, 120). The weakening of regionalist divisions
Conclusion Conclusion 2 39

accelerated with economic development. In part, this was driven by the investment and immigration seen as the "keys to progress." Throughout
rapid demographic and economic growth of Buenos Aires, which became the second half of the nineteenth century, then, the developmentalist
ever more dominant relative to the rest of the country. But economic consensus in Argentina, which at times was explicitly positivist, under-
development in the interior also underpinned the robustness of the con- pinned a sustained state-building effort (Richmond 1989, 20).
sensus around national unification. URUGUAY. Uruguay was torn by civil war for the first fifty years after
Although it had precursors under Rosas, the first true manifestation its independence, leaving it with a strikingly weak state as of about 1870
of the statist developmental project in Argentina can be seen in the (López-Alves 2000, chapter 2). But this conflict had no salient regional
l 8 5 3 constitution, which called for a state project of education, immi- cleavage. Instead, Blancos and Colorados differed on how the country
gration and colonization, railroad development, and the promotio\n of should respond to political tensions in Brazil and Argentina (Kurtz 20 l 3,
domestic production (Rock 1987, 124). Alberdi and other mid-cell¡tury 126). In short, reflecting its strikingly high urban primacy score (and
liberals "regarded economic growth as the potential consequence, likely its small size), Uruguay had no salient regionalism, or any sense
rather than the cause of state building" and believed that what they of self-contained regional economies. Liberals had "aspirations" of state
called "national organization" would promote rapid economic growth building as a way to enrich Montevideo and attract foreign investment
(Rock 2000, 179 ). An elite consensus "inherited a positive view of (Rock 2000, 182). Here, too, the Liberal project that emerged placed
state power" rather than a laissez-faire view (Rock 2002, 4). After an the extension of state authority at the center of the agenda for develop-
imposed settlement between Buenos Aires and the provinces, the Mitre ment, and this effort was sustained for the last quarter of the nineteenth
government that carne to power in 1862 sought to put these ideals century.
into practice. His administration created a bureaucratic apparatus, a LaTorre, who carne to power in the l87os, sought to extend the state's
tax system, and a national postal system, seeking explicitly to extend reach into the interior as a way to stimulate economic development
the reach of the state into the national interior. Importantly, all this through policing, communication and transport infrastructure, a judicial
institutional development was undertaken befare the 1865-1870 war system, education, and bureaucratic development (López-Alves 2000,
with Paraguay. Sarmiento, returning to power in 1868, expanded the
2 92). The core element of this effort, as Kurtz (2013, n7) points out, was
ambit of the central state by undertaking a majar education devel- the creation and enforcerp.ent of property rights the state's intervention
opment project (Rock 1987, 130). "Deliberate government programs" in the rural economy, in other words, was seen as a central element of
also sought to promote immigration, and the development of small development. In short, the Uruguayan consensus held that the extension
and medium-scale agricultura! production (Rock 1987, 141). A further of state authority into the interior was central to achieving economic
agreement to protect flour, sugar, and wine production underpinned a development and political stability, and helping the country to overcome
consensus around the extension of infrastructure development - rail- the dark decades of poverty and conflict it had endured after its indepen-
roads - to Mendoza and Tucumán. Succeeding governments contin- dence. The same era also saw a massive expansion of public schooling
ued these efforts, which included the l 8 8os "Conquest of the Desert" with the 1877 Law of Common Education.
extermination campaign aimed at the indigenous population as part State building was a central element of the Liberal project of the late
of its project of national "civilization" as well as more benign initia- nineteenth century, culminating with the massive initiatives of the two
tives of railroad building and education development. Rock (1987, Batlle administrations after 1903.As Kurtz (2013, 2n) writes, a "politi-
184) describes the Roca government as Porfirian (not surprising given cal consensus about the expansion and strengthening of state institu-
its slogan of "Peace and Administration"), undertaking a positivist tions" emerged during this time. The Batlle reforms were nothing less
project of peace and administration that was designed to attract the than a radical transformation of the Uruguayan state, expanding both
its strength and its scope in arenas such as economic management, social
programs, labor regulation, and taxation, especially of the agricultura!
-~-The war did allow the central state to "strike new blows against caudillismo in the
interior" resulting in "a much stronger central authority in the north and west" (Rock
sector. This was the last step in the emergence of the region's most effec-
1987, 128). tive state during the initial state-building era.
Conclusion Conclusion

Low Primacy, No State-Building Efforts Emerge trade in the south collapsed, and the balkanization of Bolivia deepened
BOLIVIA. With an urban primacy score of 0.46, Bolivia fell toward (Paredes 2013, ll6-rr7).
the more fragmented end of the continuum of Latin American states. And Elites, centered in the country's various regions, looked to the state
as expected, the country saw high regional tensions, conflicts between increasingly as its coffer-s swelled with tin export revenue. But each region's
regions over public good provision, and an elite consensus that, when politicians brought distinct visions of development to the table. The city
it did emerge, made little effort to extend state authority through the of Santa Cruz, for example, "clamored" for a railroad line connecting it
national territory. As in Uruguay, political stability emerged late, coming to the capital, with the slogan of Ferrocarril o nada (Paredes 2013, 261).
only after Bolivia's 1880 defeat in the War of the Pacific, in which the As Paredes describes, "the increasing wealth of the state, the conviction
country suffered fairly little in military terms but lost its coastal ~rov­ of [President] Montes that railways were the true carriers of progress,
inces, which contained not only access to the sea but the massive ni~rate and the increasing and sometimes conflicting demands of the regional
producing regions that would lay the foundation for Chile's economic landed elites led the government to initiate a big railway crusade....
boom described in Chapter 5. The war defeat firmly convinced elites that The program consisted of eleven lines, all to be started at the same time"
stable government was sorely needed. And the rise of sil ver mining, which (ibid., 262). This was the climax of the Bolivian state's attempt to satisfy
had begun in the l86os and l87os, provided a fiscal foundation for its the distinct preferences of elites in the country's many salient regions. It
emergence (Klein 1969, 13-15). "Classic l9th century civilian rule" - a did so with an immense foreign borrowing program, leading to debt. And
broadly liberal, civilian government, emerged in 1880 (Klein 2003, 143 ). when the railroad efforts failed, this log-rolling model was replaced with
But while this elite consensus would hold for the next fifty years, lit- an explicit decision not to centralize political authority. Lacking a single
tle in the way of a state-building project emerged. Elites agreed on an national center, or any national market, Bolivia was an archipelago of
export-based economic model, but they agreed on little else (Klein 2003, fragmented economic regions only loosely connected to the tin mining
143 ). There was no broad support for national unification or the centrali- boom that filled government coffers. Under these conditions, even polit-
zation of political authority. Mine owners' interests in the state essentially ical stability brought no concerted state-building project; Bolivia closely
began and ended with transportation development, and their preferences resembled Colombia not only in its level of urban primacy but in the tra-
here (for a railroad linking the mines to the coast) diverged from those of jectory of absent state development it followed.
other regional and sectoral actors. Conflict between the mining territory ECUADOR. Ecuador was a particularly striking instance in which
of Potosí and Sucre and the growing city of La Paz erupted in full-fledged regionalist tensions undermined any potential unified state-building proj-
civil war in 1899, which was resolved by making La Paz the center of ect. The result was a state so weak that the country did not even conduct
government,3 a full national census until 1950, more than a century after indepen-
The rise of tin mining after 1900 shifted elite dynamics once again. dence. The country's political economy was polarized between Quito, the
The remainder of the domestic economy "remained rural, commercially capital located in the highlands, and the coastal seaport of Guayaquil,
disconnected, and primarily oriented to local and fragile markets" (ibid., which was at least as powerful in political and economic terms. Because
249 ). Because traditional agriculture (with the exception of production of the power of Guayaquil, state building could not unfold as the exten-
in the Cochabamba region) largely and increasingly served local markets, sion of Quito's influence over the national territory. This was not a case
rural elites had no interest in forging the political consensus needed to of self-sufficient regional economies as in Colombia or Bolivia. Instead,
extend state authority. Nor did tin mining elites, who were famously unin- the more important mechanism undermining state building was tensions
terested in national politics; they funded a railroad linking their mines to between regions with distinct public good preferences. These manifested
the (now) Chilean port of Antofagasta with privare funds, choosing not in disputes over tariffs, education, water management, public works,
to seek state support. With the construction of the railroad, intra-regional sanitation, and transportation, and were especially intense around the
construction of railroads linking Quito to the coast. Coastal planters
i Many historians see a broader trend of regionalist tensions that endured long thereafter had no need for this majar undertaking, and did their best to thwart
(Paredes 2013, 245-246; Vergara 2012). it (Henderson 1997, 172). Because there was little money economy
Conclusion Conclusion

elsewhere in the country, the flow of trade through Guayaquil "provided state-building (Pastare 1994, 322). Although explaining the fust differ-
the state with opportunities to impose a variety of direct and indirect ence is beyond the scope of my argument - for my purposes ali that mat-
taxes," which were seen as unjust and fed regionalist rhetoric and conflict ters is that Paraguay saw a concerted state-building effort in the 18 5os
(Rodríguez l 9 8 5, 5 3). This led to pressures for the decentralization of tax and l86os the second difference reveals an important scope condition
revenue, which the national government was forced to grant. Regionalist of the theoretical framework developed in this book. The geopolitical
tensions drove five major domestic conflicts in the nineteenth century, position of Paraguay, as a buffer between Argentina and Brazil, meant
and "intermittent civil war" from 1895 to 1916 (ibid., 37). As the)price that state leaders saw military defense as a crucial aspect of export pro-
for domestic peace, regionalist leaders "insisted that ali areas simultane- motion - productive regions had to be defended from the "competition
ously receive a share of public projects" (ibid., 92). Congress, desperate of predatory neighboring states" (Pastore 1994, 297). State building as
to maintain political stability, simply approved every public works proj- a means to economic development in pre-1870 Paraguay centered less
ect proposed by any of its members; this obviated any sort of national on making markets, citizens, and political stability, and more on interna-
decision making and concerted development effort. Regionalism directly tional defense.
underpinned the absence of state building in Ecuador during the fust This unique geo-political position led Paraguay into a uniquely disas-
century after independence; despite ample revenues from cacao exports, a trous war with Brazil, Argentina, and Uruguay from 1865 to 1870.
state-building project never emerged due to tensions between Quito and Conflict killed a large share of the population, and also brought increased
Guayaquil over development priorities. foreign domination of the economy, and of Paraguayan politics. The
result, Abente (1989, 83) argues, was that from 1870 through the l92os
Mis-Predicted Cases the Paraguayan state, re-born "weak by design" after the war, took a
PARAGUAY. Paraguay also scored very low on urban primacy, mean- strikingly laissez-faire approach to development. The state's behavior
ing that we should expect to find no state-building project in that case. during this period cannot be easily linked to the economic regionalism
But despite the fact that the population was spread across various towns argument I have developed, or at least none of the historiography makes
(Paraguay remained a highly rural country long after urbanization began the connection - one should note, however, the increased regional eco-
in most of Latin America) it had no salient economic regions. With a nomic diversification in this period with the rise of cattle, tirriber, and
small domestic market, economic activity centered on export agricul- cotton exports in distinct parts of the country. Abente traces the con-
ture (Abente 1989, 77). Ali of the country's production traveled down- tent of Paraguayan liberalism largely to the influence of foreign economic
river to the Atlantic, as did ali imports. This meant that despite the low actors, and to defeat in war. These factors, both resulting from Paraguay's
urban primacy, Paraguay had neither the self-sufficient regions nor the unique position between Argentina and Brazil, make its trajectory in the
divergent public good preferences that I have argued tended to prevent Liberal era (1870-1936) an outlier in terms of my predictions. In the ear-
the emergence of state-building projects. Indeed, Pastore (1994) argues lier period, Paraguay had a unified economy and state building despite a
that the l85os and l86os saw state building, as the national govern- low score for urban primacy - its experience matched the predictions of
ment sought to intervene in the economy to promote export production. my theory but the case was coded wrong on regionalism by the urban pri-
This state-building project shared a similar emphasis on the development macy indicator. In the later period, it had no state building, but because
of transportation and communications infrastructure - railroads and this unfolded for reasons other than those I theorized, I cannot claim that
telegraphs. But in two fundamental ways, it took a very different forro my argument explains the Liberal era.
than was seen in the other cases. First, it centered on land expropriation VENEZUELA. Despite its low urban primacy score, as reported
and labor coercion, as an 1846 decree made yerba mate (the country's in Table 7 .1, Venezuela did see sorne state building beginning in the
main export) a state monopoly. Plantations were either harvested by the l89os. Yet as discussed later, it is no coincidence that this initia-
army directly or by "state-sponsored slavery" (López-Alves 2000, 208). tive began only after the massive growth of Caracas and its rise as a
Second, there was an overwhelming emphasis on the military, which national center. Thus, the over-time shift in Venezuela explains why
(given fiscal constraints) crowded out spending on any other aspects of the prediction of disinclination toward state building turns out not
244 Conclusion Conclusion 245

to hold in that case, and provides further evidence in support of the responsibility for economic development" and a slow shift away from
regionalism argument 1 ha ve developed. "classical laissez-faire" (ibid., 29). The fust two decades of the twentieth
More than any other country except Colombia, Venezuela's division century saw the creation of arder, the nationalization and professional-
into multiple salient economic regions was reflected in its political devel- ization of the army, massive road-building, and an end to tax farming,
opment. This division was reinforced by fragmentation during th~ inde- which sharply increased national government revenue. In short, the rise
pendence conflict, which led to the emergence of local militias rath~r than of Caracas after 1870 prefigured the state building that unfolded between
a single national army (López-Alves 2000, 201). But regionalism was also 1900 and 1920. Shortly thereafter, of course, massive oil revenues began
shaped by the form of the political economy - each of the ports along the to flow into state coffers, transforming the state in fundamental ways
Atlantic, for example, had "clase links to its own hinterland," _creating that set Venezuela apart from other countries in the region (Tinker Salas
salient regional economies (Ewell 1984, 14). 2009). But both the absence of a state-building project in the nineteenth
Regionalism directly prevented the emergence of state building. century, and the emergence of a limited effort after 1900 match the pro-
Maracaibo and the Guayana regían "openly challenged the authority posed link between regionalism and the content of liberalism.
of Caracas on several occasions" and actively resisted the extension of CENTRAL AMERICA. The claim that the absence of regionalism was
central political authority (Tarvear and Frederick 2006, 69 ). The 1864 associated with the emergence of state-building efforts also finds support
Constitution, coming in the aftermath of the Federal Wars (1858-1863) in the political development of Central America during the nineteenth
empowered local political actors and fundamentally weakened the de jure century, where all five of the independent countries also saw significant
powers of the national state. Like the l 849 Constitution in Colombia dis- state-building efforts. 4 This, too, is consistent with the prediction that the
cussed in Chapter l, this was a direct reflection of the salience of regional- absence of salient regionalism would be associated with statist visions
ism. The subsequent attempt to reverse this devolution, the centralization of liberal development. The absence of salient regionalism in Central
project of the Guzmanato (1870-1888), reveals the absence of state America, and the orientation of politics around single national centers
building in post-independence Venezuela: although it was an attempt to in each country, was to sorne extent determined by the small size of the
bring political arder, it was limited to "empowering caudillos, who in national territory. But where it did exist in the early decades after inde-
turn refrained from waging war on the central state" (López-Alves 2000, pendence, its erosion set the stage for subsequent state-building efforts. In
198). There was no attempt to extend central authority or the institu- Nicaragua, the l85os establishment of Managua as a compromise capital
tions of the central state through the national territory, and the vision between the dominant cities of León and Granada resolved the regional
of development through immigration and transportation development cleavage and allowed a state-building consensus to emerge and endure dur-
was expected to unfold through prívate initiative (Ewell 1984, 21). Yet ing the "Thirty Years" and the Zelaya administration, which made signifi-
even this effort met sizable resistance, especially from the gold-producing cant gains befare being cut off with U.S. intervention after 1909 (Mahoney
region of Guayana, which saw little to be gained from immigration or 2001, roo-ro1). And despite the fact that its urban population was dis-
railroad development. tributed across several large towns in the central and western highlands,
If the account so far suggests that Venezuela's absence of state build- Guatemala was unified in economic terms around coffee production, lacking
ing is well predicted by regionalism, Venezuela's over-time trajectory both challengers to the center and sizable, politically powerful self-sufficient
reinforces the power of the regionalist argument. After l 870, the coun- regions.
try saw a slow concentration of population and power in Caracas and State building efforts in Guatemala, El Salvador, and Costa Rica were
the north coast, with a concomitant decline in the salience of regional associated with the rise of the coffee economy and a clear vision of the
divisions, and a rise in economic ties between the capital and many for- state's role in pursuing development via coffee exports. The emergence of
merly self-sufficient regions (Ewell 1984, 9). Not coincidentally, by the the banana trade after 1900 in certain parts of the territories of Guatemala
end of the l89os, a slow shift toward a more developmentalist liber-
alism began to emerge; the country saw, under Cipriano Castro (presi- 4
Panarna only gained independence frorn Colombia in r904, and Belize rernained a British
dent 1899-1908) the "timid beginnings of the state commitrnent to a colony until the late twentieth century.
Conclusion Conclusion 2 47

and Costa Rica did not create regionalist tensions over public good provi- evidence suggests this was the case. The early state-building era in
sion, since private companies-controlled those fairly unpopulated regions Argentina saw the defeat of the caudillos that had rnilitarily dorninated
and provided the infrastructure necessary for export rather thar¡. placing the country in early years, and the "consolidation of the national state
demands on the state. State-building efforts were most lirnited in Hpnduras; in the provinces" (Rock 2002, 56-57). Over the course of the I86os and
it is no coincidence that this country, among those in Central /America, I87os, the federal government established control. lt did so largely by
most closely resembled cases like Colombia in the lack of econornic con- building alliances with governors, who were allowed to use provincial
neccions among its regions, as it was divided into what one historian (cited administration as a means of building "their own networks of authority"
in Mahoney 200I, Io4} described as multiple "herrnit societies." This lack through appointments (Rock 2002, 7I}. A consensus not only among
of a nacional market that generated an imperacive for nacional unification scholars but among contemporary observers was that patronage was a
led Honduran state-building efforts to emerge relatively late and to be rela- central element of the logic of Argentinean adrninistration, beginning in
tively muted in character; Mahoney shows that the liberal reform agenda in the I86os and continuing long thereafter (Salvatore 20I3).
Honduras was born weak and then undermined by international econornic Alongside this increasingly tightly woven patronage network, we see
intervention. Thus the overall pattern of concerted state-building efforts by sorne hints that this was not a case of delegacion to local elites. As my
Liberals, as well as temporal variation in its emergence in Nicaragua and argument predicts we should find in a case that saw significant state
the partial exception of Honduras are all consonant with the argument building, offices in the rank and file of the Argentinean adrninistration
1 have advanced about regionalism and the origins of state-building efforts. tended not to be held by local elites. Governors were an exception: they
did tend to be local elites, especially in the early state-building era when
these positions still were used to co-opt regional caudillos. At this time,
Forms of Rule and the Outcomes of State-Building Efforts
we can still talk about certain states, like Tucumán, being controlled by
Chapter 2 developed an account of the success and failure of state-building single farnilies (Richmond I989, 3 I). But the central government began
efforts. The daim that the success of state building depended on adrnin- under Mitre in I862 to slowly oust provincial governors, replacing them
istracion through deployed rule should only be tested in cases where (in at least sorne cases) with outsiders, such as the governor of San Juan
state-buildingprojects emerged; thus, Colombia, Ecuador, Bolivia, pre-I 899 installed in I859 (Rock 2002, I7.) Military commanders, appointed
Venezuela, and Paraguay after I870 can be set aside. 5 The universe of and rotated by the central government, also brought the central state's
cases, beyond those discussed in Chapter 2, includes Argentina, Uruguay, authority in and weakened local power monopolies. By the time Roca
Venezuela I899-I92os, and Paraguay I852-I870. Unfortunately, evi- carne to power in I88o, a local observer described governors nationwide
dence on the use of deployed or delegated rule in the adrninistrations of as "accessible to the suasion of the Chief of the Executive" (quoted in
additional cases is scarce. The lirnited available evidence, however, sup- Rock 2002, Io7).
ports the claim that deployed rule fed increased state capacity. 1 draw here Below the rank of governor, the Argentinean administration diverged
on secondary source accounts of Argentine political development, and from delegation to local elites in two key ways. One important differ-
find that (consistent with the prediction of my argument) deployed rule ence, although it still indicates the presence of sorne degree of delegation
characterized the adrninistration in this case of successful state building. to locals in Argentinean adrninistration, was that when positions went

Argentina z862-z9z6
state capaciry, since I have claimed rhat these factors only underlie rhe success of those
If my argument holds, as a case of successful state building, Argentina state-building efforts that emerge. In those countries where state-building efforts never
should be characterized by significant reliance on deployed rule. Sorne emerge, my theory makes no prediction ar al! about rheir effects on levels of state capac-
iry. Instead, the onser of state-building efforts acts as a scope condition on rhese proposed
s The analytical distinction between emergence and success has irnplications for theory test- relationships. The explicir definirion of these scope conditions will prevent scholars from
ing. Explanations for rhe success of state-building projects should not be tested in cases inappropriately testing explanations for successful and failed state building outside rhem.
where state building did not occur. Ir would be incorrect, in other words, to test my theory On the issue of scope condirions on theoretical claims in mulri-causal argurnenrs, see
by examining rhe correlarion berween parteros of adminisrrarion or polirical srabiliry and Soifer (2012a).
Conclusion Conclusion 249

to locals, they tended not to be the most powerful members of the local
THE END OF THE LIBERAL ERA
community. Instead, as Rock (2002, 79) notes for the province o( Buenos
Aires, there was an "absence of strong links between the justicek [of the The relative political calm of the Liberal era that has been the context
peace] and the rural gentry." While this shows that at least a share of of this book carne to an end early in the twentieth century as the viabil-
Argentinean administrative appointments cut out lower power holders, ity of that economic model began to be called into question. With the
these appointments did go to locals. emergence of new social actors, political instability reappeared at levels
More supportive of my account is that "expert bureaucracies" played not seen since the early post-independence decades. A majar economic
a central role in the extension of state authority during this period crisis, which was closely associated with (although not entirely reducible
(Salvatore 20I3). These experts, who were not governors or justices of to) the Great Depression, also played a crucial role in destabilizing the
the peace (territorial officials) but school directors, teachers, and other Liberal-era dominance of elites. The collapse of the Liberal coalitions
functional administrators, "acquired an important degree of power and of the long nineteenth century and the emergence of new social actors
respect in local communities" (ibid., 226). An "army of teachers'' spread into the political arena beginning in the early twentieth century drove an
through the country, trained in normal schools, to bring education to upsurge in political instability across the region.
fruition, and a corps of professional school inspectors emerged to replace This instability can be seen in ali four of the cases under study in
local councils of parents in overseeing education programming, in a pat- the preceding chapters. In Colombia, debates over how to respond to
tern that closely mirrored the institutionalization of Chilean education. the "social question" split the Liberal Party beginning in the I93os and
A similar development and deployment of a professional bureaucracy fueled the decade-long horror of La Violencia that began after the I948
characterized the field of public health (ibid., 227). Salvatore's crucial assassination of Liberal Party leader and presidential candidate Jorge
claim is that this spread of technical expertise could coexist, although not Eliecer Gaitán. In Mexico, of course, the Revolution that began in I9IO
without sorne tension, with a patronage-based system of appointment. !asted for a decade, and was followed by another majar conflict in the
Argentina appears to ha ve seen a more gradual version of what unfolded late I92os, the Cristero War. In Chile, the I925 overthrow of Alessandri
in Mexico during the Porfiriato: the establishment of parallel networks capped a period of coalitional instability and set off seven years of fre-
of administration that excluded local elites alongside the longstanding quent regime change, and in Peru majar unrest in the southern highlands
means of patronage used to bind center to locality and incorporate local in the I92os presaged conflict between APRA and other political actors
caudillos into the ruling coalition. Over time, the increasing reliance on that erupted after I930. Instability was not unique to these four cases; it
outsider experts seems to have allowed state building to succeed. erupted in the form of majar strikes, coups, and civil wars across South
This cursory examination of other cases in the region provides evi- America. This instability marked the end of the elite-dominated political
dence that largely supports the two key arguments advanced in this coalitions that oversaw the divergent state-building trajectories discussed
book. First, urban primacy and the absence of salient regionalism in this book. These elites were driven out of their dominance of the politi-
shaped the nature of political projects pursued by mid-century polit- cal arena, as politics and public policy were transformed in lasting ways
ical elites, influencing whether these took the form of state building, after about I920 across Latin America. As a result, the elite coalitions
or of more laissez-faire strategies of development. Second, reliance on and ideational consensus behind Liberal development projects collapsed.
deployed rule was necessary for the success of these efforts not only in State building, of course, continued into the twentieth century. The
Mexico, Chile, and post-I895 Peru (as shown in the preceding. chap- emergence of new actors, and a shift in the challenges to development per-
ters) but also in Argentina. Ideas and local administration combined to ceived by state elites, prompted a renewed emphasis on state building. The
shape the emergence and outcomes of state-development efforts during Depression, and the broader collapse of export-led growth asan economic
the Liberal era, and thus underlie the variation that emerged in state model, drove state leaders to pursue heavier state intervention in the econ-
capacity across Latin American countries during the first century after omy and a shift away from the promotion of primary product exports.
independence. New social actors placed pressures on the state that led to efforts at labor
Conclusion
• 1 Conclusion
!

market regulation and a degree of welfare provision. In many ways, then, TABLE 7.2. Beyond national averages in literacy, four cases
state building was a central feature of political projects that emerged in
Chile Colombia Mexico Peru
the Depression and its aftermath. This especially characterized those pop-
ulist projects that built a multi-class coalition centered on organized labor Year of census 2002 2005 2005 2007
Unir (N) Province (sr) Dept (33) State (32) Department (25)
movements (Collier and Collier 1991). State building was also a focus of
National avg 87.53% 85.88% 89.05% 87.73%
the rniddle-class reforrnist coalitions that emerged later in the century in St dev 2.58% 5.83% 4.54% 5.09%
places like Chile, Peru, and Brazil (Belaúnde 1965; Davis 2004). % of pop in o r.51% o o
But even as state building unfolded during the post-Liberal era, the units with
differences in state capacity that were inherited from the Liberal era - <70% lit
especially in the territorial reach of the state's capacity to perform basic Units with o I (La Guajira) o o
<70% lit
functions - remained visible. The cross-national differences in state
%ofpopin o 7.90% ro.44% 13.12%
strength in 1920 were not superseded by the later expansion of state units with
welfare and social service bureaucracies. Instead, these initial differences <80% lit
in the state's territorial reach persisted, as weak states continued to lag Units with o 6 (Sucre, 3 (Chiapas, 5 (Cajamarca,
in their ability to extend basic services to the entire population and were <80% lit Cordoba, Guerrero, Ayacucho,
even, at times, lirnited in their ability to monopolize force. Throughout Guaiana, Oaxaca) Huanuco,
Choco, Huancavelica,
the subsequent decades, and even as state-building efforts proceeded,
Vichada, La Apurimac)
those states that lacked an effective reach into the national periphery by Guajira)
1920 continued to lag in extension into those outlying regions, and in
their ability to carry out basic state functions across the national territory.
This can be seen most clearly in terms of the provision of basic ser- The persistence over time of divergent trajectories of state capac-
vices, one of the core dimensions of state capacity considered in the pre- ity strongly implies that the roots of contemporary state strength and
vious chapters. Primary school enrollment, for example, grew steadily weakness are deeply historical. Given that most explanations of state
across all countries in the region, especially after 19 50. But those states development, including the one advanced in this book, take the forro of
with lower illiteracy rates in l92os remain at the top of regional rankings historical causation, this is not surprising. But state capacity is, of course,
seventy years later. The key difference between high and low perforrning not simply a historical curiosity: contemporary stateness is at the center
countries is revealed in their ability to extend their reach throughout the of social science scholarship and policy discourse about Latín America. 6
nacional territory, in the state's ability to penetrate populations not only That rankings on state capacity today are, as the Introduction showed, so
in important regions and sectors, but nationwide. As Table 7.2 shows, well predicted by those a century in the past has important implications
national average data make literacy rates in our four cases seem indistin- for considering contemporary stateness.
guishable - all four countries had national literacy rates of bet:Ween 86 Given the deep continuities demonstrated in this book, and the fact
and 89 percent. But wide differences appear at the subnational level: for that the contemporary divergence between strong and weak states in
example, in Colombia, ten departments containing nearly l 3 percent of Latin America is so well explained by the divergence a century ago,
the population had literacy rates below 80 percent in 2005, while none understanding state strength and weakness in the region requires tak-
of Chile's regio ns had a literacy rate below 8 l percent according to the ing the weight of history seriously. First, it suggests a need to rethink the
2002 census. Similar patterns can also be seen in the provision of other state crises of the l98os and l99os in places like Colombia and Peru, and
basic services, like vaccination, and in the adrninistration of the national to see their deep historical roots rather than leaping to the conclusion
census and other sorts of core government functions; in all of these areas,
the reach of the state in Mexico and Chile continues to outpace that of 6
See, for exarnple, the special issue of Revista de Ciencia Política (2012) for a broad range
Peru or Colombia. of perspectives on the irnportance of stateness in Latin Arnerica.
Conclusion Conclusion 253

that contemporary factors account for state weakness. To fail to con- The independent force of ideational factors can be found in both parts
sider the weight of history in studying state weakness, in other words, of the argument developed in this book. First, and most prominently, the
risks misidentifying its causes. Second, taking a presentist perspective broader ideological vision of state leaders affected whether they pursued
risks over-predicting the possibility of change: failing to recognize the "order and progress" through a state-building project or through a coher-
long-term historical continuities of stateness in Latin America can lead ent set of laissez-faire policies. It was the distinctly anti-statist ideological
to an overestimation of the prospects for gains in state capacity under vision of Colombian leaders that underpinned the absence of state build-
single administrations or as the result 'of temporally truncated initiatives. ing in that case, and set that country on its distinct trajectory. 1 argued in
Third, ignoring the weight of history leads to overstated claims of "state Chapter I that the anti-statist vision resonated with Colombia's uniquely
crisis" or "state collapse" in places like contemporary Mexico that ignore polycentric political and econornic geography, but this does not imply
the long history of effective stateness as countries confront challenges that they were reducible to geography. Indeed, I argued against most
to political order. Ignoring historical continuity grants too much causal existing geographic explanations for state building that connect the two
weight to short-term causes, and neglects the importance of the full set of through a cost mechanism, and emphasized that ideas explain how geog-
conditions that this book has shown must be present for state~building raphy influences the decision of state leaders whether or not to increase
efforts to emerge in a sustained way, and to succeed. the capacity of the national state in pursuit of development.
Second, ideas played an important role in the choice of delegated and
deployed rule. Where there was a substantial threat of indigenous or
THEORIZING STATE BUILDING subaltern revolt, the willingness of state leaders to risk upsetting local
The argument and findings of the preceding chapters also have impor- hierarchy and damaging their relations with local elites by establishing
tant theoretical implications. This book breaks new theoretical ground in deployed rule depended in large part on their ideological vision for state
the study of state building in two related but analytically distinct ways. development. Where they had come to believe that traditional elites were
First, it integrates ideational factors into the account of state building, an obstacle to development - as in Liberal Mexico and post-189 5 Peru -
and second, it develops an account for both the emergence and the suc- state leaders were willing to underrnine the power of traditional elites
cess or failure of state-building efforts. Both of these analytical moves through deployed rule even at the risk of revolt. But where they did not
have implications for the broader state-building literature. believe that development required the elirnination of tradition, they were
willing to respond to the threat of revolt by cementing ties to local elites.
Here too, then, the choices made by state leaders cannot be explained by
Bringing Ideas into State Development incentives alone. We must also understand the ideas they had in mind as
By contrast to the existing scholarship on state development, I highlight they pursued development.
that ideational factors play a part in accounting for the divergent trajec- In both of these components of the argument, we can see that a focus
tories traced by my cases. Rather than directly connecting charaCteristics on purely material factors cannot account for the variation we observe in
of the political or econornic environment to incentives for state building, outcomes. Had we only focused on material factors in accounting for the
1 argue that the relationship between structure and choice is mediated onset of state-building efforts, the common challenges to política! stabil-
by leaders' perceptions and beliefs. In particular, I focus on the ways ity, econornic development, and social peace would make the choice of dif-
in which ideas shape how rational incentives are perceived, and deter- ferent means of pursuing those goals quite surprising. And had we only
mine which strategies resonate with political leaders as an appropri- focused on material factors in accounting for the choice between delegated
ate response to their objective material situation. Rather than taking a and deployed rule, we would not understand the choices of state leaders to
deductive approach in deciding how state leaders should have responded opt for deployed rule despite the threat of indigenous revolt during Peru's
to the incentives they faced, I investigate the content of their ideas, and Aristocratic Republic, or during the Liberal era in Mexico. Material factors,
account for how they actually did respond. in other words, underpredict the variation we observe. State leaders respond
254 Conclusion Conclusion 255

in different ways to the incentives created by very similar material incen- The way in which ideas are given causal power in my argument is more
tives. This does not mean, of course, that they are not strategic. But it does subtle than in either of these two existing positions. Unlike Herbst, Bates,
imply that the effects of rational incentives are mediated by broader politi- and Slater, I see state leaders as more than profit maxirnizers (for the for-
cal ideologies that unite a spectrum of political interests and affect which of mer two) or Slater's threat rninirnizers. Instead I argue that the strategies
the set of plausible responses to a particular situation "resonate" or "fit." In chosen in response to opportunities and threats - their choice of how to
my account, then, ideas play a role very clase to Weber's famous "switch- try to seize opportunities or whether and how to rninirnize threats - are
men" that "deterrnined the tracks along which action has been pushed by shaped by their ideological visions. But unlike Scott, I find a range of
the dynarnic of interest.'' Weber claims that "from what and for what one ideological visions among state leaders. Not all state leaders are in the
wished to be redeemed and, let us not forget, could be redeemed, depended grip of what he described in Seeing Like a State as a "high modernist"
upon one's image of the world" (Weber I958, 280). In my account, state vision that calls for the reordering of society, but neither are all state lead-
leaders arrived at very different diagnoses of the means by which they ers best seen as motivated only by revenue-based considerations. 8 Against
should respond to very similar crises; these different diagnoses depended on Herbst, then, I argue that state inaction can be seen as motivated by ide-
their broader ideological visions - their images of the world. ology and not just by the sorts of cost-benefit calculations he emphasizes.
lntegrating the ideas of state leaders into accounts of state develop- And against Scott, I allow for the possibility that state leaders choose not
ment beyond Latin America would allow scholars to ask similar questions to pursue state building; laissez-faire models of development can, once
about where and why state-building efforts emerged, and why they took again, be grounded in ideology. Rather than assuming that all state lead-
particular forms. Ideas have been understudied in the historical European ers are pursuing the same goal, or that when they are they will choose the
cases in part because considerations of survival narrowed the options same means under the same set of material incentives, we should instead
available to state leaders. Yet rather than assurning that state leaders had consider the possibility that state leaders' decision making about how to
such a lirnited set of choices as they responded to international threats, pursue development is shaped by their ideological visions.
an exarnination of the range of responses is in arder. Uncovering the his-
tory of the losers in early modern Europe what Davies (20II) calls its
Separating Emergence and Success
"vanished kingdoms" rnight reveal distinct ideational visions underlying
their erasure from the map.1 In a second departure from the status quo in the state-building litera-
Ideas have been understudied as a causal factor in contemporary state ture, I separately theorize the emergence of state-building efforts and
building as well. Those scholars of post-colonial cases who downplay the their success. I have argued in this book that analytically distinct sets
role of ideas tend to either see leaders' actions as determined directly by of factors explain the emergence of state-building efforts, and the suc-
the threats they face (Slater 20Io) or, more commonly, by calculations of cess of only sorne of those efforts. The causal factors I have emphasized,
the costs incurred and revenues to be gained from state expansion (Herbst a developmentalist (as opposed to laissez-faire) elite consensus and
2000; Bates 2008). On the other hand, James Scott (I998, 2009) places deployed (as opposed to delegated) rule, are not analytically equivalent
ideas front and center, arguing that state leaders motivated by a "high mod- independent variables. Instead, the fust is a necessary and sufficient con-
ernist" vision seek to reshape society in fundamental ways through making dition for state-building efforts to emerge, while the latter is necessary for
it legible, standardized, and homogeneous. These two views of the contem- those efforts that do emerge to succeed. Making explicit this distinction
porary state are in striking contrast to one another, and scholars on both
sides of the debate point to the experiences of particular cases in support of 8
In Scott's more recent work (2009) the pursuit of legibility has come to be seen as a
their overarching claim about the nature of state motivations. constant ideological vision underpinning state actions across a wide range of cases. My
position falls closer to his earlier (r998) view that acknowledged that not ali state leaders
held a high modemist vision and pursued wholesale social transformation. For a fuller
elaboration of the argument that state leaders face a range of options for ruling in any
1 This issue is taken up later from a different angle when I explore what the scholarship on given situation, which includes both Scott's forcible legibilization and much less intrusive
European state building has to say about the emergence of state-building efforts. possibilities, see Slater and Kim (forthcoming).
Conclusion Conclusion 2 57

between explanations of the emergence and success of state-building administration constructed and thus long-term trajectories of state capac-
efforts highlights the place of equifinality in accounts of state weakness. ity. But he, too, fails to consider cases in which state-building efforts did
The discussion in the previous chapters traces two distinct logical not emerge at all. For Ertman and most other scholars of European state
paths leading to state weakness. A first is the absence of a state-building building, the decision to undertake state building is not a choice: there
project; among our core cases, this was the path traced by Colombia, is no other alternative. Even Tilly (1992), in distinguishing between
and severa! of the shadow cases discussed earlier also followed this path. coercion-centered and capital-centered paths to European state develop-
A second is marked by the failure of concerted state building; this was ment, focuses on the range of ways in which states respond to the threat
the case in Peru befo re l 89 5. A complete account of the causes of state of war, and fails to problematize the emergence of state-building projects.
capacity must explore both pathways, by asking both what prompts The most irnportant exception to this failure to explain the emer-
state-building efforts, and what conditions are necessary for those efforts gence of state-building efforts is Downing's (1992) study of the survival
to succeed, but few studies do so. Thus they fall short of being l~gically of medieval constitutionalism. He argues that where military competi-
complete accounts of variation in state capacity. tion was financed through intensified domestic taxation, constitutional-
Scholars of European cases have generally failed to problematize the ist institutions were dismantled in favor of absolutism - this explains
origins of state-building efforts, since most see military competition as a the paths traced by France and Prussia. But where other conditions pre-
constant and powerful pressure forcing states to respond or get wiped off vailed, constitutionalism could survive. States that could, as Sweden did,
the map.9 Because scholars only study the survivors of European wars, rely on foreign resource mobilization avoided absolutism. So did the
we simply do not know why those cases that were wiped off the map did Dutch Republic, which drew on allies for defense, on capital markets as
not survive. Io There are severa! logical possibilities. First, but least theo- an alternative to taxation, and on geography as a substitute for military
retically interesting for scholars of state building, is the possibility that modernization. In both of these cases, despite war, major state-building
the losers built effective states but were defeated nevertheless because of efforts were avoided. But Downing also argues that England befare 1688
size, wealth, geographic location, or other factors that determined their avoided absolutism because it was not embroiled in majar conflict. He
military fate. Two alternatives are the absence of state-building efforts, thus avoids both of the standard truisms in the European state-building
and the failure of state-building efforts. We simply do not know which literature: the first sees war as an omnipresent threat, and the second
of what Tilly estimates as 500 political units in early modern Europe fol- assumes that the onset of war automatically triggers state building.
lowed each of these paths, and therefore we lack a complete theory of The English case debunks the first truism; the Dutch and Swedish cases
Euro pean state development. u debunk the second. With these two analytical moves, Downing explains
In the face of this dilemma, most scholars simply assume that the why state-building efforts emerged in sorne cases but not others in early
onset of military competition created a constant state-building impera- modern Europe rather than just assuming either (to quote Tilly 1975)
tive across Europe at sorne point in the early modern era. This lets them that war made states or that states made war.
set aside explanations for the choice to increase state capacity to focus If most scholarship on European cases takes the emergence of
on the success and failure of state-building efforts. Ertman (1997) is a state-building efforts for granted, most scholarship on the developing
partial exception; he argues that the timing of military competition var- world elides the explanation of the success and failure of those efforts.
ied over cases, explaining (in his study of a set of survivors) the forms of When we move away from early modern Europe to a context where
interstate competition is less intense, the weak are not erased from the
map. This is particularly true, as Jackson and Rosberg (1982) and Herbst
9 A few scholars, such as Deborah Boucoyannis (n.d.) and Spruyt (1994), argue that war
<lid not drive state building in early rnodem Europe, but the consensus sees geopolitical (2000) show, for post-1945 states, for whom international norms of
cornpetition as crucial to forrning European states. territorial integrity and nonintervention have been particularly strong.
'º This, of course, is a cornrnonly noted problern in the literature; Tilly (1975, 14-15) But in Latin America, too, over a longer time span, state weakness has
describes the tradeoffs-between prospective and retrospective studies of state forrnation.
11
Davies (2011) provides a series of case studies of these "vanished kingdorns" but fails to not led to the elimination of countries from the map: although signifi-
develop a systernatic theoty of state weakness in Europe. cant territory has changed hands (usually in the aftermath of warfare)
Conclusion Conclusion 259

and early post-independence confederations in Central America and the


Causal lmportance
northern Andes fell apart, there ha ve been no instances in which a coun-
try was wholly incorporated into another. If in Europe, historical accu- When confronted with a causally complex account like the one devel-
racy demands that we more carefully theorize the (non)emergence of oped in this book, a natural question relates to the relative importance
state-building efforts, scholarship of the developing world needs to more of each of its components. In particular, we can ask how to evaluate the
carefully account far state-building failure. relative importance of state-building absence and state-building failure
To fail to account far the conditions that determine the success and in explaining state weakness. Given the equifinality of negative outcomes
failure of state-building efforts is to risk what Slater (2010, l)) calls 1 have theorized and demonstrated, which of the two steps in the causal
"crude and discredited modes of functionalist reasoning." Yet even Slater chain to state strength trips up more Latín American cases? Table 7.3
himself <loes not fully theorize the success and failure of elite responses provides sorne evidence we can use to answer this question. It shows the
to systemic threats; he limits himself to arguing what he calls "inverted presence or absence of state building in each case arrayed on the vertical
functionalism": "if no threat, no response" (ibid., 13). Other schol- axis, and the level of urban primacy and salient regionalism, based on
ars do no better. Herbst (2000), far example, simply ignores the pos- data from Table I.l and discussions earlier in this chapter, on the hori-
sibility that state-building efforts might emerge and fail in colonial or zontal axis. Where necessary, 1 have placed a single country in multiple
post-independence Africa. Instead, he argues that state leaders choose cells to reflect periods that marked qualitative shifts in the trajectory of
the optimal level of state capacity based on the costs of administrative state capacity.
extension and the benefits of tax revenue. The result is that many states What can we conclude from this table? First, because there are only
in sub-Saharan Africa were born, and remain, strikingly weak. An alter- two cases in violation of this logical relationship, we can conclude that
native, of course, is that state leaders tried and failed to build states, but urban primacy is, as predicted, probabilistically necessary far state
Herbst fails to discuss this logically possible path to state weakness. capacity. As described earlier, one of these cases, Paraguay 1852-1870,
We can only develop, far example, a full theory of the effects of war is mis-predicted because of the anomalous geopolitical threats it faced,
on state capacity if we specify factors that determine success and fail- which were unique in regional perspective. The second, Venezuela, is
ure of state-building efforts once war had spurred them. Barnett (1992) likely mis-coded, since it saw (as discussed previously) a shift toward
makes such an argurnent, claiming that the outcome of an increase or increased urban primacy precisely during the period indicated.
decrease in state power is shaped by the strategy chosen by the govern- Second, and more relevant, we can conclude that many cases fall along
ment in response to the threat. When adopted in the context that spurs with Colombia in the "salient regionalism, no state building" cell. This
state building, they produce variation in the outcome of interest. It is the suggests that rather than defining a scope condition that is rarely vio-
strategy chosen in response to an external threat, not the threat itself, lated, explaining the non-emergence of state building in Latín America
that shapes the state power outcomes caused by war. This theoretical accounts far a lot of the variation in state capacity. In formal terms,
insight points the way to sharper analyses of the relationship between urban primacy and the ideological visions with which it is associated are
war and the state by pointing our attention to variation in response to of high causal relevance, since only one case where it exists did not see
international threat as our focus of interest. State power may grow, and state building. To understand state weakness in Latín America, this sug-
state-society relations may be altered, by war. But whereas Tilly's famous gests, we must understand why political elites did not see state building
"states made war and war made states" only identified a relationship, as a means to development. By contrast, the path of state-building failure,
Barnett develops a set of predictions about when this relationship will traced only by the case of Peru, seems to be a regional outlier, the only
and will not hold. This set of predictions depends on the causal mech- country with a high score on urban primacy but no state-building suc-
anism he has elaborated (strategy of resource mobilization), which can cess. In explaining the initial variation in state strength and weakness in
only be identified by distinguishing between the conditions that drive Latín America, the ideational and geographic factors that prompted the
emergence and success, and seeing the international threat of war as the emergence of state-building efforts appear to be more important than
former rather than the latter. those determining why sorne succeeded while others failed.
260 Conclusion Conclusion 261

TABLE 7.3. Urban primacy and state building the lessons of cases where state-building efforts fail must be examined
Urban primacy so that we can generate systematic knowledge about where, when, and
why state-building efforts have failed to produce significant gains in state
Successful state building Low High capacity.ª
No Bolivia In that sense, this book's examination of historical cases of
Colombia state-building failure in places like guano-era Peru has important impli-
Ecuador
cations. The finding that reliance on local elites as administrators in the
Paraguay (1870-:1936)
Venezuela (1864-1899) national periphery fundamentally undermined state-building efforts in
guano-era Peru suggests that delegating power to local strongmen, while
Yes Paraguay (1852-1870) Argentina possibly generating stability by cementing their alliances with the central
Venezuela {1899-192os) Chile______ _
Mexico
government, will cripple state-building efforts. There may, of course, be
Peru (1895-1919) reasons to cement these sorts of alliances anyway; state capacity is not
Uruguay a goal pursued in a vacuum, but in relation to other desiderata such as
political stability oran end to violence. Hutchcroft (2000), for example,
shows how state building and the promotion of civil society institutions
HISTORICAL STATE BUILDING AND CONTEMPORARY
were in tension during American colonial rule in the Philippines. But the
"NATION BUILDING"
clear and consistent relationship between reliance on local elites and the
failure of state building in Peru points to the importance of taking the
The recent upsurge of concern about state weakness in many contexts design of local administrative institutions seriously.
of political instability has prompted a call for lessons from historical In many contexts, local elites are not only a potential ally for the state
cases for contemporary efforts. The findings of this book about the com- but a potential challenger (Luna and Feldmann 2012). State-builders con-
parative experiences of Liberal-era Latin America generate several such front elites that possess not only power at the local and regional level
implications. A fust such insight relates, once again, to the important dis- but the potential to spoil state-building efforts. The constructiori of alli-
tinction between the factors underlying the emergence of state-building ances with these actors is often necessary for state building to even be
projects, and the factors underlying their success. State-building proj- pursued in a consistent and coherent manner. Here, the argument of this
ects have, in recent years, emerged in many places, introduced not by book generates another important policy implication about how these
a domestic political coalition but by the international community. Yet alliances are constructed. 13 Chapter 3 argued that in terms of effects on
few of these efforts at nation-building have succeeded. This suggests that state capacity, the type of patronage used in creating coalitions with these
policy recommendations must focus attention on why these efforts have local strongmen can have an important effect. Alliances built through
not borne fruit: if the roots of state weakness in Latin America are largely political patronage - access to elected office - may be less damaging than
found in the absence of state-building efforts in many countries, the prob- those built on access to appointments in the administration of local com-
lem of state-building failure looms large in many contemporary cases. munities. Peruvian state building during the guano era failed because
Yet as Brownlee (2007, 3 r 5) shows, the policy literature on contempo- state leaders built coalitions with local elites, and because they did so
rary state building has tended to take a "volitional" approach to state through administrative appointments rather than via an electoral coali-
building, in which commitment, duration, and resources are seen as the tion. Should designers of a state-building project face this sort of choice,
keys to the construction of an effective state. The belief is that devoting
enough resources to the effort over a sufficient period of time will suffice. " As Brownlee (2007) traces, policymakers have drawn nearly ali of their conclusions
But resources, even when spent over several decades, are not sufficient, about how to state-build from the rare {and overdetermined) success stories of postwar
Germany and Ja pan.
as we saw in the case of guano-era Peru, to ensure the increased ability '
3
For another account that explores the range of strategies available to state leaders in
of the state to effectively penetrate society and implement policy. Here, confronting challengers to their rule, see Slater and Kim {forthcoming).
Conclusion

the findings of this book suggest that they should consider building those
alliances through elected positions rather than through administrative
appointments. Only by distinguishing failed state building in guano-era
Peru from the absent state building in Colombia could we iden~ify these Works Cited
possible institutional prescriptions. Historical cases of state-building suc-
cess and failure, in short, are not only of interest to scholars of history.
Instead, understanding the paths traced by the countries exainined in this
book, and by historical cases more generally, is necessary to help identify
policy recommendations for successful state building.

Abbott,Jared A, Matthias vom Hau, and Hillel David Soifer (2013) 'Transforming
the Nation? The B"olivarian Education Reform in Context' (Paper presented
at LASA 2013, Washington, DC).
Abente, Diego (1989) 'Foreign Capital, Economic Elites, and the State in Paraguay
during the Liberal Republic (1870-1936)' ]ournal of LatinAmerican Studies
vol. 21 #1 (February) pp. 61-88.
Aboites Aguilar, Luis (2003) Excepciones y Privilegios: Modernización Tributaria
y Centralización Política en México, I922-1972 (El Colegio de México).
Aboites Aguilar, Luis, and Luis Jáuregui, eds. (2005) Penuria sin Fin: Historia de
los Impuestos en México Siglos XVIII-XX (Mexico, DF: Instituto Mora).
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2001) 'Colonial
Origins of Comparative Development' American Economic Review vol. 9 l
PP· l369-14or.
(2002) 'Reversa! of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the
Modern World Income Distribution' Quarterly ]ournal of Economics vol.
II8 pp. 1231-1294.
Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2012) Why Nations Fail: The Origins
of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (Crown Books).
Adelman, Jeremy (2006) Sovereignty and Revolution in the Iberian Atlantic
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
Acles, Alberto F. and Edward L. Glaeser (1995) 'Trade and Circuses: Explaining
Urban Giants' The Quarterly ]ournal of Economics vol. l ro #1 pp. l 9 5-228.
Albertus,Michael, and Oliver Ka plan (2013) 'Land Reformas a Counterinsurgency
Policy: Evidence from Colombia' ]ournal of Conflict Resolution vol. 57 #2
pp. 198-23 I.
Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (2005) The Size of Nations (Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press).
Alexander, Robert J. (2007) A History of Organized Labor in Peru and Ecuador
(Westport, CT: Praeger).
Works Cited Works Cited

Allina-Pisano, Jessica (2004) 'Sub Rosa Resistance and the Politics of Economic Bensel, Richard (1984) Sectionalism and American Political Development,
Reform: Land Redistribution in Post-Soviet Ukraine' World Politics vol. 56 1880-1980 (Madison: University ofWisconsin Press).
Uuly) pp. 554-58r. (1990) Yankee Leviathan (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Anderson, Benedict (1983) Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin Bergman, Marcelo (2009) Tax Evasion and the Rule of Law in Latin America
and Spread of Nationalism (London: Verso). (University Park: Penn State University Press).
Anderson, Perry (1974) Lineages of the Absolutist State (New York: New Left Bergquist, Charles W. (1986) Coffee and Conflict in Colombia 1886-1910
Books). (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Angell, Alan (1972) Politics and the Labor Movement in Chile (Oxford: Oxford Bergquist, Charles W., Ricardo Peñaranda, and Gonzalo Sánchez C., eds. (2001)
University Press). Violence in Colombia 1990-2000: Waging War and Negotiating Peace
Ansell, Ben W. (2010) From the Ballot to the Blackboard: The Redistributive (Wilmington, DE: Scholarly Resources).
Political Economy of Education (New York: Cambridge University Press). Berman, Sheri (1998) The Social Democratic Moment: Ideas and Politics in the
Auyero, Javier (2007) Routine Politics and Violence in Argentina: The Gray Zone Making of Interwar Europe (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
of State Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (2001) 'Ideas, Norms, and Culture in Political Analysis' Comparative Politics
Báez Osorio, Miryam (2006) La Educación en los Orígenes Republicanos de vol. 33 #2 Uanuary) pp. 231-250.
Colombia (Tunja: Universidad Pedagógica y Tecnológica de Colombia). (2006) The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making of Europe's
Baland,Jean-Marie, andJamesA. Robinson (2008) 'Land and Power: Theory and Twentieth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Evidence from Chile' American Economic Review vol. 98 # 5 pp. 173 7-176 5. Bethell, Leslie, ed. (1993) Chile Since Independence (New York: Cambridge
Barbier, Jacques A. (1980) Reform and Politics in Bourbon Chile 1755-1796 University Press).
(Ottawa: University of Ottawa Press). Blanchard,Peter (1982) The Origins of the PeruvianLabor Movement 1883-1919
Barnett, Michael (1992) Confronting the Costs of War (Princeton, NJ: Princeton (Pittsburgh; PA: University of Pittsburgh Press).
University Press). Blyth, Mark M. (1997) 'Any More Bright Ideas? The Ideational Turn of
Barrantes, Emilio (1989) Historia de la Educación en el Perú (Lima: Mosca Azul). Comparative Political Economy' Comparative Politics vol. 29 #2 Uanuary)
Barzel, Yoram (2002) A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal Rights, and pp. 229-250.
the Scope of the State (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Bobrow-Strain, Aaron (2007) Intimate Enemies: Landowners, Power, and
Bates, Robert H. (2008) When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Violence in Chiapas (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Africa (New York: Cambridge University Press). Bonilla, Heraclio (1989) Estado y Tributo Campesino: La Experiencia de
Bauer, Arnold (1975) Chilean Rural Society from the Spanish Conquest to 193º Ayacucho (Lima: IEP) Documento de Trabajo #3.
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (2001) Metáfora y Realidad de la Independencia en el Perú (Lima: IEP).
Bazant, Jean (1991) 'From Independence to the Liberal Republic 1821-1867' Bonilla, Heraclio, and Karen Spalding (1981) 'La Independencia en el Perú: Las
in Leslie Bethell, ed. Mexico since Independence (Cambridge: Cambridge Palabras y los Hechos' in Heraclio Bonilla et al., La Independencia en el Perú
University Press) pp. 1-48. (Lima: IEP).
Bazant, Mílada (1993) Historia de la Educación durante el Porfiriato (México Boone, Catherine (2003) Political Topographies of the African State
DF: El Colegio de México). (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Bazant, Mílada (1998) 'Los Inspectores y los Vecinos de los Pueblos Determinan Bowman, J ohn, and Micha el Wallerstein ( l 9 8 2) 'The Fall of Balmaceda and Public
la Suerte de los Maestros Mexiquenses: 1874-1910' in Pilar Gonzalbo Finance in Chile: New Data for an Old Debate' ]ournal of InterAmerican
Aizpurú, ed. Historia de la Educación y la Enseñanza de la Historia (Mexico, Studies and World Affairs 24 no. 4 pp. 421-460.
DF: El Colegio de México) pp. 63-88. Bowman, Kirk S. (2002) Militarization, Democracy, and Development: The Perils
Beatty, Edward (2001) Institutions and Investment: The Political Basis of of Praetorianism in Latin America (University Park: Penn State University
Industrialization in Mexico befare 19II (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).
Press). Brewer, John (1990) The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State,
Belaúnde, Fernando ( 196 5) Peru's Own Conquest (Lima: Latin American Studies 1688-1783 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
Press). Brinks, Daniel (2008) The Judicial Response to Police Killings in Latín
Bello, Andrés (1997) Selected Writings, edited and translated by Iván Jaksic America: Inequality and the Rule of Law (Cambridge: Cambridge University
(Oxford: Oxford University Press). Press).
Bengoa,José (1985) Historia del Pueblo Mapuche (Santiago: Ediciones Sur). Britton, John A., ed. (1994) Molding the Hearts and Minds: Education,
Bengoa, José (1999) Historia de un Conflicto: el Estado y los Mapuches en el Communications, and Social Change in Latin America. (Wilmington, DE: SR
Siglo XX (Santiago: Planeta). Books).
266 Works Cited Works Cited

Brooks, Sarah (2009) Social Protection and the Market in Latin America eds., States and Development: Historical Antecedents of Stagnation and
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Advance (Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan), pp. 69-9 r.
Brownlee,JasonA. (2007) 'Can America Nation Build?' World Politics vol. 59 #2 Chaudhry, KirenAziz (1999) The Price ofWealth (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
(January) pp. 314-340. Press).
Burr, Robert N. (1965) By Reason or Force: Chile and the Balancing of Power in Cheibub, José Antonio (1998) 'Political Regimes and the Extractive Capacity of
South America, I830-I905 (Berkeley: University of California Press). Governments: Taxation in Democracies and Dictatorships' World Politics 50
Bushnell, David (1954) The Santander Regime in Gran Colombia no. 3, pp. 349-376.
(Newark: University of Delaware Press). Chowning, Margaret (l 999) Wealth and Power in Provincial Mexico: Michoacán
(1993) The Making of Modern Colombia: A Nation in Spite of Itself from the Late Colony to the Revolution (Stanford, CA: Stanford University
(Berkeley: University of California Press). Press).
Bushnell, David, and Neill Macaulay (1994) The Emergence of Latin America in Christie, Keith H. (1979) 'Gamonalismo in Colombia: an Historical Overview'
the Nineteenth Century, 2nd ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press). North-South: Canadian ]ournal of Latin American Studies vol. 4 pp. 42-59.
Callaghy, Thomas M. (1984) The State-Society Struggle: Zaire in Comparative CIESIN (Center for-International Earth Science Information Network), Columbia
Perspective (New York: Columbia University Press). University (2007) National Aggregates of Geospatial Data: Population,
Cammett, Melani, and Lauren Morris MacLean (20 l l) 'Introduction: The Political Landscape, and Climate Estimates, v.2 (PLACE II) (Palisades, NY: CIESIN,
Consequences of Non-state Social Welfare in the Global South' Studies in Columbia University) Available at: sedac.ciesin.columbia.edu/place/
Comparative International Development vol. 46 #1 (Spring) pp. l-2!. Coatsworth, John H. (1978) 'Obstacles to Econornic Growth in Nineteenth
Camp, Roderic Ai (1991) Mexican Political Biographies, I884-I934 Century Mexico' The American Historical Review vol. 83 #1 (February) pp.
(Austin: University of Texas Press). 80-100.
(1995) Political Recruitment across Two Centuries: Mexico, l884-I99I (1981) Growth against Development: The Economic Impact of Railroads in
(Austin: University of Texas Press). Porfirian Mexico (DeKalb: Northern Illinois University Press).
Campbell, John L. (1993) 'The State and Fiscal Sociology' Annual Review of ( l 9 8 8) 'Patterns of Rural Rebellion in Latin America: Mexico in Compara ti ve
Sociology 19, pp. 163-185. Perspective' in Friedrich Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion, and Revolution: Rural
Campbell, Margaret V. (1959) 'Education in Chile, 1810-1842' ]ournal of Social Conflict in Mexico (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press)
Inter-American Studies vol. l #3 pp. 3 53-3 7 5. pp. 21-62.
Campos Harriet, Fernando (1960) Desarrollo Educacional, I8IO-I960 (1998) 'Econornic and Institucional Trajectories in Nineteenth-Century Latin
(Santiago: Editorial Andres Bello). America' in Coatsworth, John, and Alan M. Taylor, eds. Latín America and
Cardona, Christopher M. (2008) 'Politicians, Soldiers, and Cops: Colombia's La the World Economy since I8oo (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press)
Violencia in Comparative Perspective' (PhD Dissertation, Departrnent of pp. 23-54.
Political Science, University of California Berkeley). (2008) 'Inequality, Institutions, and Econornic Growth in Latin America'
Carmagnani, Marcello (1989) 'El Liberalismo, los Impuestos Internos y el ]ournal of Latín American Studies vol. 40 #3 pp. 545-569.
Estado Federal Mexicano, 1857-1911' Historia Mexicana vol. 38 #3 pp. Collier, David (1976) Squatters and Oligarchs (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
471-496. University Press).
(1994) Mercado y Estado, Historia de la Hacienda Publica en Mexico, Collier, David, and Ruth Berins Collier (1991) Shaping the Political Arena
I857-I910 (Mexico, DF: El Colegio de México). (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
Carpenter, Daniel P. (2001) The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy (Princeton, Collier, Simon (2003) Chile: The Making of a Republic, I830-I865
NJ: Princeton University Press). (New York: Cambridge University Press).
Castañeda Zavala, Jorge (2001) 'El Contingente Fiscal en la nueva nación mexi- Collier, Simon and William F. Sater (1996) A History of Chile I808-I994
cana, 1824-1861' in Marichal, Carlos and Daniela Marino, eds., De Colonia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
a Nación: Impuestos y política en México, I750-I860 (Mexico, DF: El Compendio Estadístico del Perú (2001) (Lima: Instituto Nacional de Estadística
Colegio de México) pp. 135-187. e Informática).
Centeno, Miguel Ángel (1994) Democracy within Reason: Technocratic Contreras, Carlos (1996) Maestros, Mistis y Campesinos en el Perú Rural del
Revolution in Mexico (University Park: Penn State University Press). Siglo XX (Lima: IEP) Documento de Trabajo #80.
(2002) Blood and Debt: War and the Nation State in Latin America (University (2001) Ideales Democráticos, Realidades Autoritarias: Autoridades políticas
Park: Penn State University Press). locales y descentralización en el Perú a finales del siglo XIX (Lima: IEP)
(2007) Warfare in Latin America (2 volumes) (Hampshire: Ashgate). Documento de Trabajo #n3.
Chancla, Areendam, and Louis Putterman (2005) 'State Effectiveness, Econornic (2004) El Aprendizaje del Capitalismo: Estudios de Historia Económica y
Growth, and the Age of Sta tes' in Lange, Matthew, and Dietrich Rueschemeyer, Social del Perú Republicano (Lima: IEP).
Works Cited Works Cited

(2005) 'The Tax Man Cometh: Local Authorities and the Barde over Taxes in Meisel Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana
Peru, 1885-1906' in Jacobsen, Nils, and Cristóbal Aljovín de Losada, eds. del Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de Cultura Económica) pp. 674-705.
Política/ Cultures in the Andes, 1750-1950 (Durham, NC: Duke University DeHart, Evelyn Hu (1984) 'Sonora: Indians and Immigrants on a
Press) pp. II6-135. Developing Frontier' in Benajamin, Thomas, and William McNellie,
Contreras, Carlos, and Marcos Cuero (1999) Historia del Perú Contemporaneo eds. Other Mexicos: Essays on Regional Mexican History, I876-19n
(Lima: IEP). (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press) pp. l77-2II.
Coronil, Fernando (1997) The Magical State: Nature, Money, and Modernity in Dellepiane, Carlos (1943) Historia Militar del Perú 2 vols. (Lima: Imprenta del
Venezuela (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Ministerio de Guerra).
Cosio Villegas, Daniel (19 56) Historia Moderna de México (México DF: Editorial Delpar, Helen (1981) Red against Blue: The Liberal Party in Colombian Politics,
Hermes). 1863-1899 (Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press).
Covarrubias,José Díaz (1993) La Instrucción Pública en México (originally pub- Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística (1985) 50 Años de
lished in 1875 by Imprenta del Gobierno) (México: Colección Tlahuicole). Estadísticas Educativas (Bogotá: DANE).
Crabtree, John (2008) 'Introduction: A Story of Unresolved Tensions' in Crabtree, de Ramón, Armando (1999) Biografías de Chilenos: Miembros de los Poderes
John, and Laurence Whitehead, eds. Unresolved Tensions: Bolivia Past and Ejecutivo, Legislativo y Judicial (Santiago Editores Universidad Católica de
Present (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press) pp. l-7. Chile) 4 volumes.
Cruz, Nicolás (2002) El Surgimiento de la Educación Secundaria Pública en Desch, Michael C. (1996) 'War and Strong States, Peace and Weak States?'
Chile, 1843-1876 (El Plan de Estudios Humanista) (Santiago: DIBAM). International Organization vol. 50 #2 (Spring) pp. 237-268.
Cruz Santos, Abel (l 966) 'Economía y Hacienda Pública de le República Unitaria DeShazo, Peter (1979) 'The Valparaíso Maritime Strike of 1903 and the
a la Economía del Medio Siglo' in Historia Extensa de Colombia vol. l 5, part Development of a Revolutionary Labor Movement in Chile' ]ournal of Latín
II (Bogotá: Ediciones Lerner). American Studies vol. 2 #1 (May) pp. 145-168.
Cuadro Sinóptico Histórico (19ro) (Mexico City: Secretaría de Fomento, de Soto, Hernando (1989) The Other Path (New York: Harper and Row).
Colonización e Industria). Díaz Zermeño, Héctor (1979) 'La Escuela Nacional Primaria en la Ciudad de
Cuadro Sinóptico y Estadístico de la República Mexicana (1900) (Mexico México' Historia Mexicana vol. 29 pp. 59-90.
City: Dirección General de Estadística). Dix, Robert (1987) The Politics of Colombia (London: Praeger).
Dargent, Eduardo (201 l) 'Agents or Actors? Assessing the Autonomy of Economic Domínguez, Jorge I. (1980) Insurrection or Loyalty: The Breakdown of the
Technocrats in Colombia and Peru' Comparative Politics vol. 43 #3 (April) Spanish American Empire (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).
pp. 313-332. Downing, Brian (1992) The Military Revolution and Política/ Change (Princeton,
(2015) Technocracy and Democracy in Latín America: Experts Running the NJ: Princeton University Press).
Government (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Drinot, Paulo (20II) The Allure of Labor: Workers, Race, and the Making of the
Davies, Norman (2005) God's Playground: A History of Poland Vol. I: The Peruvian State (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Origins to 1795 (New York: Columbia University Press). Dunning, Thad (2008) Crude Democracy: Natural Resource Wealth and Political
(20II) Vanished Kingdoms: The Rise and Fall of States and Nations Regimes (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
(New York: Viking Press). Earle, Rebecca (2000) 'The War of the Supremes: Border Conflict, Religious
Davies, Thomas (l 970) Indian Integration in Peru: A Half Century of Experience, Crusade, or Simply Politics by Other Means?' in Rebecca Earle, ed. Rumours
1900-1948 (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press). ofWars: Civil Confiict in Nineteenth Century Latín America (London: ILAS)
Davis, Diane E. (2004) Discipline and Development: Middle Classes and Prosperity pp. 119-134.
in East Asia and Latín America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Eaton, Kent (2004) Politics beyond the Capital: The Design of Subnational
Deas, Malcolm (1982) 'The Fiscal Problems of Nineteenth Century Colombia' Institutions in Latín America (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).
]ournal of Latín American Studies vol. 14 #2 (November) pp. 287-328. Echeverry S., Alberto (1989) Santander y la Instrucción Pública (Bogotá: Foro
(1993) Del Poder y la Gramática y Otros Ensayos sobre Historia, Política y Nacional por Colombia).
Literatura Colombianas (Bogotá: Tercer Mundo Editores). Edwards, Sebastian (20ro) Left Behind: Latín America and the False Promise of
(2002) 'The Man on Foot: Conscription and the Nation-State in Nineteenth Populism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Century Latin America' in James Dunkerly, ed. Studies in the Formation of Egaña Baraona, Maria Loreto (2000) La Educación Primaria Popular en el Siglo
the Nation-State in Latín America (London: ILAS) pp. 77-93. XIX en Chile: Una Práctica de Política Estatal (Santiago: DIBAM).
(2oro) 'Inseguridad y Desarrollo Económico en Colombia en el Primer Siglo Elliott, John H. (2006) Empires of the Altlantic World: Britain and Spain in
de Vida Republicana Independiente: Unas Consideraciones Preliminares' in America, 1492-1830 (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).
Works Cited Works Cited 271

Encina, Francisco A. (1982) Resumen de la Historia de Chile, edited and summa- Gade, Daniel W. (1994) 'Regional Isolation in the High Provinces of Cusco
rized by Leopoldo Castedo (Santiago: Zig Zag) volumes II, III, rv. and Apurímac' in Deborah Poole, ed. Unruly Order: Violence, Power,
Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (1997) 'Factor Endowments, and Cultural Identity in the High Provinces of Southern Peru (Boulder,
Institutions, and Differential Patterns of Growth among New World CO: Westview Press) pp. 31-62.
Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States' in, Gallo, Carmenza (1991) Taxes and State Power: Political Instability in Bolivia,
Stephen Haber, ed. How Latín America Fell Behind (Stanford, CA: Stanford 1900-1950 (Philadelphia: Temple University Press).
University Press) pp. 260-304. Gallup, John Luke, Alejandro Gaviria, and Eduardo Lora (2003) Is Geography
(2002) 'Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths ofDevelopment among New Destiny? Lessons from Latín America (New York: Inter-American
World Economies.' Working paper No. 9259, Nacional Bureau of Economic Development Bank).
Research. Galván de Terrazas, Luz Elena (1985) Los Maestros y la Educación Pública
Ertman, Thomas (1997) Birth of the Leviathan (Cambridge: Cambridge en México (Hidalgo y Matamoros, Tlalpan: Centro de Investigaciones y
University Press). Estudios Superiores en Antropología Social).
Estadísticas Históricas (1975) (Bogotá: DANE). García Alcaraz, María Guadalupe, and Armando Martínez Moya (2006) 'Poder,
Estadísticas Sociales del Porfiriato (1956) (Mexico City: Secretaría de Economía, Educación y Region: Un Ejercicio de Reflecxión para el Estudio de las
Dirección General de Estadística). Escuelas Primarias de Guadalajara en la Segunda Mitad del Siglo XIX' in
Estado Mayor General del Ejército (various years) Historia del Ejército de Chile Martínez Moctezuma, Lucía, and Antonio Padilla Arroyo, eds. Miradas a la
(ro volumes) (Santiago: Colección Biblioteca Militar). Historia Regionalde la Educación (Mexico, DF: Universidad Autónoma del
Estefane Jaramillo, Andrés (2004) 'Un Alto en el Camino para Saber Cuántos Estado de Morelos).
Somos: Los Censos de Población y la Construcción de Lealtades Nacionales, García Villegas, Mauricio, et al. (2on) Los Estados del País: Instituciones
Chile Siglo XIX' Historia (Santiago) vol. 37 #1 Oune) pp. 33-59. Municipales y Realidades Locales (Bogotá: Colección DeJusticia).
Evans, Peter (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation George, Alexander L., and Andrew A. Bennett (2005) Case Studies and Theory
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Development in the Social Sciences (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).
Ewell, Judith (1984) Venezuela: A Century of Change (Stanford, CA: Stanford Gerschenkron, Alexander (1962) Economic Backwardness in Historical
University Press). Perspective (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press).
Falcon, Ramona (1988) 'Charisma, Tradition, and Caciquismo: Revolution in San Gilbert, Dennis L. (1977) The Oligarchy and the Old Regime in Peru (Ithaca,
Luís Potosí' in Friedrich Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion, and Revolution: Rural Social NY: Cornell University Press).
Conflict in Mexico (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press) pp. 417-447. Gill, Anthony (l 99 8) Rendering unto Caesar (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
Falleti, Tulia G. (2010) Decentralization and Subnational Politics in Latín America Gingerich, Daniel W. (2013) 'Governance Indicators and the Level of Analysis
(New York: Cambridge University Press). Problem: Empirical Findings from South America' British ]ournal of Political
Fearon, James, and David Laitin (2003) 'Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War' Science vol. 2 pp. 1-3 8.
American Political Science Review vol. 97 #1 pp. 7 5-90. Glave, Luís Miguel (1999) 'The Republic oflndians in Revolt' in Salomon, Frank,
Fisher, John (1998) 'Commerce and Imperial Decline: Spanish Trade with the and Stuart B. Schwartz, eds. The Cambridge History of the Native Peoples of
Americas, 1797-1820' ]ournal of Latín American Studies vol. 30 #3 the Americas vol.ID, Part 2, pp. 502-587.
(October) pp. 459-479. Goldstein, Judith, and Robert Keohane, eds. (1993) Ideas and Foreign
Flórez, Carmen Elisa, and Oiga Lucía Romero (2010) 'La Demografía de Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Política/ Change (Ithaca, NY: Cornell
Colombia en el Siglo XIX' in Meisel Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa University Press).
Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana del Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de Gonzales, Michael J. (1985) Plantation Agriculture and Social Control in
Cultura Económica) pp. 375-418. Northern Peru, 1875-1933 (Austin: University ofTexas Press).
Fowler, Will (2000) 'Civil Conflict in Independent Mexico, l 821-5 7: An Overview' González-Cueva, Eduardo (2000) 'Conscription and Violence in Peru' Latin
in Rebecca Earle, ed. Rumours ofWars: Civil Conflict in Nineteenth Century American Perspectives vol. 27 #3 (May) pp. 88-102.
Latín America (London: ILAS) pp. 49-86. Gootenberg, Paul (1988) 'Beleaguered Liberals: The Failed First Generation of
Frazier, Leslie Jo (2007) Salt in the Sand: Memory, Violence, and the Nation-State Free Traders in Peru' in Love, Joseph L., and Nils Jacobsen, eds. Guiding
in Chile, 1890 to the Present (Durham, NC: Duke University Press). the Invisible Hand: Economic Liberalism and the State in Latin American
Fukuyama, Francis (2004) State Building: Governance and World Order in the History (New York: Praeger) pp. 63-97.
21st Century (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press). (1989) Between Si/ver and Guano: Commercial Policy and the State in
(2013) 'What Is Governance?' Governance vol. 26 #3 pp. 347-368. Post-Independence Peru (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
Works Cited Works Cited 273

(1990) 'Carneros y Chuño: Price Levels in Nineteenth Century Peru' Hispanic (1996) 'Liberalism Divided: Regional Politics and the National Project during
American Historical Review vol. 70 #1 pp. l-56. the Mexican Restored Republic, 1867-1876' Hispanic American Historical
(1993) Imagining Development: Economicldeas in Peru's 'Fictitious Prosperity' Review vol. 76 #4 pp. 659-689.
of Guano, 1840-1880 (Berkeley: University of California Press). Hanson, E. Mark (1986) Educational Reform and Administrative
(1995) Población y Etnicidad en el Perú Republicano (Siglo XIX): Algunas Development: The Cases of Colombia and Venezuela (Stanford, CA: Hoover
Revisiones (IEP Documento de Trabajo No. 71, Lima). Institution Press, Stanford University).
Gorski, Philip S. (2003) The Disciplinary Revolution: Calvinism and the Rise of Hanson,Jonathan and Rache! Sigman (2orr) Measuring State Capacity: Assessing
the State in Early Modern Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). and Testing the Options (paper presented at the annual meetings of the
Gose, Peter (1994) 'Embodied Violence: Racial Identity and the Semiotics of American Political Science Association).
Property in Huaquirca, Antabamba (Apurímac)' in Deborah Poole, ed. Hanson, Stephen E. (2003) 'From Culture to Ideology in Comparative Politics'
Unruly Order: Violence, Power, and Cultural Identity in the High Provinces Comparative Politics vol. 3 5 #3 (April) pp. 3 5 5-3 76.
of Southern Peru (Boulder, CO: Westview Press) pp. 165-198. Hardoy, Jorge (1968) Urban Planning in Pre-Columbian America
Goyer, Doreen, and Elaine Domschke (1983) The Handbook of National (New York: Braziller).
Population Censuses: Latín America and the Caribbean, North America, and Hart, John M. (1988) 'The Southwestern Mexico Peasants' War: Conflict
Oceanía (Wesport, CT: Greenwood Press). in a Transitional Society' in Friedrich Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion, and
Grez Toso, Sergio (1997) De La 'Regeneración del Pueblo' a la Huelga Revolution: Rural Social Conflict in Mexico (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
General: Génesis y Evolución Histórica del Movimiento Popular en Chile University Press) pp. 249-268.
{18ro-1890) (Santiago: DIBAM). Hartlyn, Jonathan (1988) The Politics of Coalition Rule in Colombia
Grindle, Merilee S. (2003) '1952 and Ali That: The Bolivian Revolution in (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Comparative Perspective' in Grindle, Merilee S. and Pilar Domingo, eds. Hazen, Dan C. (1978) 'The Politics of Schooling in the Nonliterate Third
Proclaiming Revolution: Bolivia in Comparative Perspective (DRCLAS, World: The Case of Highland Peru' History of Education Quarterly vol.18
Harvard University and ILAS, University of London) pp l-2I. #4 (Winter) pp. 419-443.
Haber, Stephen (1989) Industry and Underdevelopment: The Industrialization of Hechter, Michael (2000) Containing Nationalism (Oxford: Oxford University
Mexico, 1890-1940 (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Press).
Haber, Stephen, Noel Maurer, and Armando Raza (2003) The Politics of Property Heise González, Julio (1974) Historia de Chile: El Período Parlamentario
Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (Santiago: Editorial Andrés Bello).
Haggard, Stephan, and Robert R. Kaufman (2008) Development, Democracy, Helg, Aline (1987) La Educación en Colombia, 1918-1957 (Bogotá: Editorial
and Welfare States: Latín America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe (Princeton, CEREC).
NJ: Princeton University Press). Henderson, Paul (1997) 'Cocoa, Finance, and the State in Ecuador, 1885-1925'
Hale, Charles A. (1968). Mexican Liberalism in the Age of Mora, 1821-1853 Bulletin of Latín American Research vol.16 #2 pp. 169-186.
(New Haven, CT: Yale University Press). Heraclio, Bonilla and Karen Spalding (2001) La Independencia del Perú, las pal-
(1989) The Transformation of Liberalism in Late Nineteenth Century Mexico abras y los hechos (Lima: IEP) (Inicial publication 1972).
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Herbst, Jeffrey (2000) States and Power in Africa (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Hall, Peter A. (1993) 'Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case University Press).
of Economic Policymaking in Britain' Comparative Politics vol.25 #3 (April) Hernández Chavez,Alicia (1989) 'Orígen y ocaso del ejército porfiriano' Historia
pp. 275-296. Mexicana vol. 39 #1 pp. 257-296.
Halperín Donghi, Tulio (1973) The Aftermath of Revolution in Latín America (2006) Mexico: A Brief History (Berkeley: University of California Press).
(New York: Harper Torchbooks). Hernández Ponce, Roberto (1984) 'La Guardia Nacional de Chile: Apuntes sobre
(1988) 'Argentina: Liberalism in a Country Born Liberal' in Love, Joseph L. su Orígen y Organización, 1808-1848' Historia vol. 19 pp. 53-114.
and Nils Jacobsen, eds. Guiding the Invisible Hand: Economic Liberalism Herr, Pilar M. (2001) 'Indians, Bandits, and the State: Chile's Path toward
and the State in Latín American History (New York: Praeger) pp. 99-116. National Identity, 1819-1833' (PhD Dissertation, Department of History,
Hamilton, Nora (1975) 'Mexico: The Limits of State Autonomy' Latín American Indiana University).
Perspectives vol. 2 #2 pp. 75-ro8. Herrera, Martha Cecilia (1999) Modernización y Escuela Nueva en Colombia
Hamnett, Brian R. (1977) 'Process and Pattern: A Re-examination of the (Bogotá: Plaza y Janés Editores).
Ibero-American Independence Movements, 1808-1826' ]ournal of Latín Hirschman, Albert (1970) Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
American Studies vol. 29 pp. 279-328. University Press).
274 Works Cited Works Cited 275

Rolden, Robert H. (1994) Mexico and the Survey of Public Lands: the Junguito, Roberto, and Hernán Rincón (2007) 'La Política Fiscal en el Siglo
Management of Modernization (DeKalb: Northern lllinois University Press). XX en Colombia' in Robinson, James, and Miguel Urrutia, eds. Economía
Hu-DeHart, Evelyn (1988) 'Peasant Rebellion in the Northwest: The Yaqui Colombiana del Siglo XX: un Análisis Cuantitativo (Bogotá: Fondo de
Indians of Sonora, 1740-1976' in Friedrich Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion, and Cultura Económica) pp. 239-312.
Revolution: Rural Social Confiict in Mexico (Princeton, NJ: Princeton Karl, Terry Lynn (1997) The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States
University Press) pp. 141-175. (Berkeley: University of California Press).
Humphreys, Macartan, Jeffrey D. Sachs, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, eds. (2007) Katz, Friedrich (1988a) 'Introduction: Rural Revolts in Mexico' in Friedrich
Escaping the Resource Curse (New York: Columbia University Press). Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion, and Revolution: Rural Social Confiict in Mexico
Hünefeldt, Christine (1989) 'Poder y Contribuciones: Puno 1825-1845' Revista (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press) pp. 3-17.
Andina 7 no. 2, 367-407. (1988b) 'Rural Rebellions after l8ro' in Friedrich Katz, ed. Riot, Rebellion,
Hunt, Shane J. (1973) 'Growth and Guano in Nineteenth Century Peru' Discussion and Revolution: Rural Social Confiict in Mexico (Princeton, NJ: University
Paper 34, RPED (Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton). Press) pp. 521-560.
(1985) 'Growth and Guano in Nineteenth Century Peru' in Conde, Roberto (1991) 'The Liberal Republic and the Porfiriato, l867-19ro' in Leslie Bethell,
Cortés, and Shane J. Hunt, eds. The Latin American Economies: Growth and ed., Mexico Since Independence (New York: Cambridge University Press)
the Export Sector, 1880-1930 (New York: Holmes and Meier) pp. 255-319. pp. 49-124.
Hutchcroft, Paul D. (2000) 'Colonial Masters, National Politicos, and Provincial Kaufman, Herbert (1967) The Forest Ranger: A Study in Administrative Behavior
Lords: Central Authority and Local Autonomy in the American Philippines, (Washington, DC: Resources for the Future).
1900-1913' The ]ournal of Asian Studies vol. 59 #2 (May) pp. 277-306. Kaufman, Robert, and Joan Nelson, eds. (2004) Crucial Needs, Weak Incentives
Jackson, Robert H., and Carl G. Rosberg (l 9 82) 'Why Africa 's Weak States Persist: the (Princeton, NJ: Woodrow Wilson Center Press).
Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood' World Politics 35 no. l, pp. 1-24. Klarén,Peter (2000) Peru: Society and Nationhood in theAndes (New York: Oxford
Jacobsen, Nils (1988) 'Free Trade, Regional Elites, and the Interna! Market in University Press).
Southern Peru, 1895-1932' in Love, Joseph L., and Nils Jacobsen, eds. Klein, Herbert S. (1969) Parties and Política[ Change in Bolivia, 1880-1952
Guiding the Invisible Hand: Economic Liberalism and the State in Latin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
American History (New York: Praeger) pp. 145-176. (1991) Bolivia: The Evolution of a Multi-Ethnic Society (Oxford: Oxford
(1993) Mirages of Transition: The Peruvian Altiplano, 1780-1940 University Press) Second Edition.
(Berkeley: University of California Press). (2003) A Concise History of Bolivia (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Jaramillo Uribe, Jaime (1964) El Pensamiento Colombiano en el Siglo XIX Press).
(Bogotá: Editorial Temis). Knight, Alan (1986) The Mexican Revolution (2 volumes) (Lincoln: University
Jáuregui, Luis (2005) 'Los Orígenes de un Malestar Crónico: Los Ingresos y los of Nebraska Press).
Gastos Públicos de México, 1821-1855' in Aguilar, Aboites Luis, and Luis (1990) 'Mexico c.1930-46' in Leslie Bethell, ed. The Cambridge History of
Jáuregui, eds. (2005) Penuria sin Fin: Historia de los Impuestos en México Latin America, vol. 7: Latin America since 1930, Mexico, Central America,
Siglos XVIII-XX (Mexico, DF: Instituto Mora), pp. 79-n4. and the Caribbean (New York: Cambridge University Press) pp. 3-82.
Jimeno, Camilo García, and James A. Robinson (2oro) 'Élites, Prosperidad y (1992) 'The Peculiarities of Mexican History: Mexico Compared to
Desigualdad: Los Determinantes de la Detentación de Cargos Públicos en Latín Arnerica, 1821-1992' fournal of Latin American Studies vol. 24
Antioquia durante el Siglo XIX' in Meisel Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa (Quincentenary Supplement) pp. 99-144.
Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana del Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de (2002) Mexico: The Colonial Era (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Cultura Económica) pp. 617-673. (2013) 'The Mexican State, Porfirian and Revolutionary, 1876-1930' in
Jones, Kristine L. (1999) 'Warfare, Reorganization, and Readaptation at the Centeno, Miguel, and Agustín Ferraro, eds. State and Nation Making in
Margins of Spanish Rule: The Southern Margin (1573-1882)' in Salomon, Latín America and Spain: Republics of the Possible (Cambridge: Cambridge
Frank, and Stuart B. Schwartz, eds. The Cambridge History of the Native University Press) pp. n6-138.
Peoples of the Americas vol.III, Part 2, pp. 13 8-187. Kohli, Atul (1994) 'Where Do High Growth Political Economies Come From?
Joseph, Gilbert, and Daniel Nugent (1994) Everyday Forms of State The Japanese Lineage of Korea's Developmental State' World Development
Formation: Revolution and the Negotiation of Rule in Modern Mexico vol. 22 #9 pp. 1269-1293.
(Durham, NC: Duke University Press). (2004) State Directed Development: Political Power and lndustrialization in
Junguito, Roberto (2oro) 'Las Finanzas Públicas en el Siglo XIX' in Meisel Roca, the Global Periphery (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Adolfo, and María Teresa Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana del Siglo Kristal, Efraín (1987) The Andes Viewed from the City: Literary and Política/
XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de Cultura Económica) pp. 41-137. Discourse on the lndian in Peru, 1848-1930 (New York: Peter Lang).
Works Cited Works Cited

Kurtz, Marcus J. (2009) 'The Social Foundations of Institutional Lipset, Seymour M., and Stein Rokkan (r967) 'Cleavage Structures, Party
Order: Reconsidering War and the Resource Curse in Third World State Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction' in Lipset and Rokkan,
Building' Politics and Society vol. 37 #4 pp. 479-520. eds. Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives
(2or3) Latín American State Building in Comparative Perspective: The Social (New York: Free Press).
Origins of Institutional Order (New York: Cambridge University Press). Lipsky, Michael (r980) Street-Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in
Kurtz, Marcus J. and Andrew Schrank (2007) 'Growth and Governance: Models, Public Services (New York: Russell Sage Foundation).
Measures, and Mechanisms' ]ournal of Politics vol. 69 #2 (May) pp. 53 8-5 54. Llinás Álvarez, Édgar (r978) Revolución, Educación, y Mexicanidad (México,
La Porta, Rafael, Florencia López de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. DF:UNAM).
Vishny (r998) 'Law and Finance' ]ournal of Política/ Economy v.ro6 #6 pp. López-Alves, Fernando (2000) State Formation and Democracy in Latín America,
rrr3-rr55. I8Io-r900 (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Lange, Matthew (2004) 'British Colonial Legacies and Political Development' Lave, Joseph L. (r988) 'Structural Change and Conceptual Response in Latin
World Development vol. 32 #6 pp. 905-922. America and Romania, r860-r950' in Love, Joseph L., and Nils Jacobsen,
(2009) Lineages of Despotism and Development: British Colonialism and State eds. Guiding the Invisible Hand: Economic Liberalism and the State in Latín
Power (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). American History (New York: Praeger) pp. r-33.
Lange, Matthew, and Hrag Balian (2008) 'Containing Conflict or Instigating Loveman, Brian (r993) The Constitution of Tyranny: Regimes of Exception in
Unrest? A Test of the Effects of State Infrastructural Power on Civil Spanish America (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press).
Violence' Studies in Comparative International Development vol. 43 #3-4 (20or) Chile: The Legacy of Hispanic Capitalism 3rd ed. (New York: Oxford
pp. 314-333. University Press).
Larson, Brooke (r999) 'Andean Highland Peasants and the Trials of Loveman, Mara (2005) 'The Modern State and the Primitive Accumulation of
Nation-Making during the Nineteenth Century' in Saloman, Frank, and Symbolic Power' American ]ourna/ of Sociology vol. r ro #6 (May) pp.
Stuart B. Schwartz, eds. The Cambridge History of the Native Peoples of the r651-r683.
Americas vol. ID, Part 2, pp. 5 58-703. Loy,Jane Meyer (r97r) 'Primary Education during the Colombian Federation: The
(2004) Trials of Nation-Making: Liberalism, Race, and Ethnicity in the Andes, School Reform of r870' Hispanic American Historica/ Review vol. 5r #2
r8ro-r9ro (New York: Cambridge University Press). (May) pp. 275-294.
Leal Buitrago, Francisco, Ladrón de Guevara, and Andrés Dávila (r990) Ludlow, Leonor, ed. (2002) Los Secretarios de Hacienda y Sus Proyectos (Mexico,
Clientelismo: El Sistema Político y Su Expresión Regional (Bogotá: Tercer DF: UNAM) 2 volumes.
Mundo Editores). Luna, Juan Pablo, and Andreas Feldmann (2or2) 'States and
Lebot, Ivon (r978) Elementos para la Historia de la Educación en Colombia en Challengers: A Conceptual Typology' (unpublished paper, Pontificia
el Siglo XX (Bogotá: DANE). Universidad Católica de Chile).
LeGrand, Catherine (r986) Frontier Expansion and Peasant Protest in Colombia, Lustick, Ian S. (r993) Unsettled States, Disputed Lands (lthaca, NY: Cornell
r830-r936 (Albuquerque: University ofNew Mexico Press) University Press).
Levi, Margaret (r988) Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Lynch, John (r986) The Spanish American Revolutions, r808-r826
Press). (New York: Norton).
(r997) Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism (New York: Cambridge University Macías Richard, Carlos (r999) 'El Territorio de Quintana Roo: Tentativas de
Press). Colonización y Control Militar en la Selva Maya, r888-r902' Historia
Levitsky, Steven and Maria Murillo (2009) 'Variation in Institutional Strength' Mexicana vol. 49 #r (July-September) pp. 5-54.
Annual Review of Po/itical Science vol. r2 pp. rr5-r33. Mahoney, James (2000) 'Path Dependence in Historical Sociology' Theory and
Levitsky, Steven, and LucanA; Way (20ro) Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Society vol. 29 #r pp. 507-548.
Regimes after the Cold War (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (2oor) The Legacies of Liberalism: Path Dependence and Po/itical Regimes in
Lieberman, Evan S. (2002) 'Taxation Data as Indicators of State-Society Central America (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press).
Relations: Possibilities and Pitfalls in Cross-National Research' Studies in (20ro) Colonia/ism and Post-Colonial Development: Spanish America in
Comparative Internationa/ Development 36 no. 4, (Winter) pp. 89-rr5. Comparative Perspective (New York: Cambridge University Press).
(2003) Race and Regionalism in the Politics of Taxation in Brazil and South Mahoney, James, and Matthias vom Hau (2005) 'Colonial States and Econornic
Africa (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Development in Spanish America' in Lange, Matthew, and Dietrich
Lieuwen, Edwin (r968) Mexican Mi/itarism: The Política/ Rise and Fa// of the Rueschemeyer, eds. States and Development: Historica/ Antecedents of
Revolutionary Army (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press). Stagnation and Advance (New York: Palgrave Macmillan) pp. 92-rr6.
Works Cited Works Cited 279

Mainwaring, Scott, and Timothy R. Scully, eds. (2oro) Democratic Governance Meyer,Jean (1986) 'Mexico: Revolution and Reconstruction in the l92os' in Leslie
in Latín America (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Bethell, ed. The Cambridge History of Latín America, Vol. V, c.1870-1930
Mallon, Florencia E. (1983) The Defense of Community in Peru's Central (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) pp. 15 5-194.
Highlands (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Meyer, Michael C., and William L. Sherman (1995) The Course of Mexican
(1995) Peasant and Nation: the Making of Post-Colonial Mexico and Peru History, 5th ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
(Berkeley: University of California Press). Middlebrook, Kevin (1995) The Paradox of Revolution: Labor, the State, and
(2005) Courage Tastes of Blood: The Mapuche Community of Nicolás Ailío Authoritarianism in Mexico (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press).
and the Chilean State (Durham, NC: Duke University Press). Migdal, Joel S. (1988) Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations
Mamalakis, Markos J. (1976) The Growth and Structure of the Chilean and State Capabilities in the Third World (New York: Cambridge University
Economy: From Independence to Allende (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).
Press). (2001) State in Society: Studying How States and Societies Transform and
Mamdani, Mahmood (1996) Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Constitute One Another (New York: Cambridge University Press).
Legacy of Colonialism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Milla Barres, Carlos, ed. (1994) Enciclopedia Biográfica e Histórica del Perú
Mann, Michael (1984) 'The Autonomous Power of the State: Its Origins, Siglos XIX-XX (ten volumes) (Lima: Editorial Milla Barres).
Mechanisms, and Results' European ]ournal of Sociology vol. 25 #2 pp. Molina, Iván, and Steven Palmer (2004) 'Popular Literacy in a Tropical
185-213. Democracy: Costa Rica, 1850-1950.' Past and Present 184: 169-208.
Mariscal, Elisa and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (2000) 'Schooling, Suffrage, and the Monteón, Michael (1982) Chile in the Nitrate Era: The Evolution of Economic
Persistence of Inequality in the Americas, 1800-1945' in Stephen Haber, Dependence, 1880-1930 (Madison: University ofWisconsin Press).
ed. Political Institutions and Economic Growth in Latín America (Stanford (1998) Chile and the Great Depression: The Politics of Underdevelopment,
CA: Hoover Institution Press) pp. 159-218. 1927-1948 (Tempe: Arizona State University Press).
Márquez, Graciela (2005) 'Aranceles a la Importación y Finanzas Públicas: Del Montero, Cármen, ed. (1990) La Escuela Rural: Variaciones sobre un Tema
Porfiriato a la Crisis de 1929' in Aguilar, Aboites Luis, and Luis Jáuregui, (Lima: FAO).
eds. (2005) Penuria sin Fin: Historia de los Impuestos en México Siglos Monteverde, Alessandro (1999) 'La Delincuencia enAconcagua entre l 8 50 y 1900
XVIII-XX (Mexico, DF: Instituto Mora) pp. 141-160. a través de Documentos y Periódicos' Revista de Estudios Histórico-Jurídicos
Martínez Jiménez, Alejandro (1973) 'La Educación Elemental en el Porfiriato' #21, pp. 159-169.
Historia Mexicana v. 32#4 (April-June) pp. 514-552. Muecke, Ulrich (2004) Política! Culture in Nineteenth Century Peru: The Rise of
Mata, Javier F. and Sebastian Ziata (2009) User's Cuide on Measuring Fragility the Partido Civil (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press).
(Bonn and Oslo: German Development Institute and United Nations Needell, Jeff (2013) 'The State and Development under the Brazilian Monarchy'
Development Prograrnme ). in Centeno, Miguel Ángel, and Agustín Ferraro, eds. State and Nation
McCaleb, Walter (1921) The Public Finances of Mexico (New York: Harper and Making in Latín America: Republics of the Possible (Cambridge: Cambridge
Brothers). University Press) pp. 79-99.
McEvoy, Carmen (1994) Un Proyecto Nacional en el Siglo XIX: Manuel Pardo y Neufeld, Stephen (2009) 'Servants of the Nation: The Military in the Making
Su Visión del Perú (Lima: PUCP). of Modern Mexico, l876-19n' (PhD Dissertation, History Department,
McFarlane, Anthony (1984) 'Civil Disorders and Popular Protests in Late University of Arizona).
Colonial New Granada' Hispanic American Historical Review vol. 64 #1 Newland, Carlos (1994) 'The Estado Docente and Its Expansion: Spanish
(February) pp. 17-54. American Elementary Education, 1900-1950' ]ournal of Latín American
(1993) Colombia befare Independence: Economy, Society, and Politics under Studies 26 no.2 pp. 449-467.
Bourbon Rule (New York: Cambridge University Press). North, Douglass C. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History
McGreevey, William P. (1971) An Economic History of Colombia, 1845-1930 (New York: Norton).
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance
Meisel Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa Ramírez, eds. (2010) Economía (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Colombiana del Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de Cultura Económica). Nugent, David (1997) Modernity at the Edge of Empire: State, Individual, and
Meltzer, Allan H., and F. Scott Richard (1981) 'A Racional Theory of the Size of Nation in the Northern PeruvianAndes, 1885-1935 (Stanford, CA: Stanford
Government' ]ournal of Political Economy 89: pp. 914-927. University Press).
Méndez, Cecilia (2005) The Plebeian Republic: The Huanta Rebellion and the Nuñez, Javier (2005) 'Signed with an X: Methodology and Data Sources for
Making of the Peruvian State, 1820-1850 (Durham, NC: Duke University Analyzing the Evolution of Literacy in Latin America and the Caribbean,
Press). 1900-1950' Latín American Research Review 40 no.2, pp. n7-135.
280 Works Cited Works Cited

Nunn, Frederick (1970) Chilean Politics 1920-1931: The Honorable Mission of Perry, Laurens Ballard (1978) ]uárez and Díaz: Machine Politics in Mexico
the Armed Forces (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press). (DeKalb: Northern Illinois University Press).
Nunn, Nathan, and Diego Puga (2012) 'Ruggedness: The Blessing of Bad Pierson, Paul (1994) Dismantling the Welfare State: Reagan, Thatcher, and the
Geography in Africa' Review of Economics and Statistics vol. 94 #1 Politics of Retrenchment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
(February) pp. 20-3 6. (20ooa) 'Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics'
Obregón, Javier Sáenz, Óscar Saldarriaga, and Armando Espina (1999) Mirar American Política! Science Review vol. 94 #2 pp. 251-268.
la Infancia: Pedagogía, Moral, y Moderndidad en Colombia, 1903-1946 (2ooob) 'The Limits of Design: Explaining Institutional Origins and Change'
(Bogotá: Ediciones Foro Nacional por Colombia) 2 volumes. Governance vol. 13 #4 (October) pp. 475-499.
O'Donnell, Guillermo (1973) Modernization and Bureaucratic Authoritarianism (2004) Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Política! Analysis (Princeton,
(Berkeley: University of California Press). NJ: Princeton University Press).
(1993) 'On the State, Democratization and Sorne Conceptual Problems: A Latín Pike, Frederick B. (1967) The Modern History of Peru (Westport, CT: Praeger
American View with sorne Glances at Post-Communist Countries' World Press).
Development 21 no. 8, pp. 1355-1369. Pinto Rodríguez, Jorge (2003) La Formación del Estado y la Nación, y el Pueblo
Olson, Mancur (1993) 'Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development' American Mapuche: de la Inclusión a la Exclusión (Santiago: DIBAM).
Política! Science Review vol.87 #3 pp. 567-576. Pittman, Dewitt Kenneth (1989) Hacendados, campesinos y políticos: las clases
Orlove, Benjamín (1994) 'The Dead Policemen Speak: Power, Fear, and Narrative agrarias y la instalación del Estado oligárquico en México, 1869-1876
in the 193 l Molloccahua Killings (Cusco)' in Deborah Poole, ed. Unruly (Mexico, DF: Fondo De Cultura Economica USA).
Order: Violence, Power, and Cultural Identity in the High Provinces of Poole, Deborah (1994a) 'Introduction: Anthropological Perspectives on Violence
Southern Peru (Boulder, CO: Westview Press) pp. 63-96. and Culture - a View from the Peruvian High Provinces' in Deborah Poole,
Ortega, Luis (1984) 'Nitrares, Chilean Entrepreneurs, and the Origins of the War ed. Unruly Order: Violence, Power, and Cultural Identity in the High
of the Pacific' Journal of Latín American Studies vol. l 6 pp. 3 37-3 80. Provinces of Southern Peru (Boulder, CO: Westview Press) pp. l-30.
Padgen, Anthony (1987) 'Identity Formation in Spanish America' in Canny, (1994b) 'Performance, Domination, and Identity in the Tierras Bravas
Nicholas, and Anthony Padgen, eds. Colonial Identity in the Atlantic World, of Chumbivilcas (Cusco)' pp. 97-132 in Deborah Poole, ed. Unruly
1500-1800 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press) pp. 51-94. Order: Violence, Power, and Cultural Identity in the High Provinces of
Palacios, Marco (1980) Coffee in Colombia: An Economic, Social, and Política! Southern Peru (Boulder, CO: Westview Press).
History (New York: Cambridge University Press). Posada-Carbó, Eduardo (1996) The Colombian Caribbean: A Regional History,
(2006) Between Legitimacy and Violence: A History of Colombia, 1875-2002 1870-1950 (Oxford: Clarendon Press).
(Durham, NC: Duke University Press). Powell, Walter W., and Paul J. Dimaggio, eds. (1991) The New Institutionalism in
Palmer, David Scott (1977) 'The Politics of Authoritarianism in Spanish America' Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).
in James M. Malloy, ed. Authoritarianism and Corporatism in Latín America Przeworski, Adam, and Fernando Limongi (1997) 'Modernization: Theories and
(Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press) pp. 377-412. Facts' World Politics vol. 49 #2 (January) pp. 155-183.
Papponet-Cantat, Christiane (1994) 'Gamonalismo after the Challenge of Putnam, Robert (1993) Making Democracy Work (Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Agrarian Reform: The Case of Capacmarca, Chumbivilcas (Cusco)' in University Press).
Deborah Poole, ed. Unruly Order: Violence, Power, and Cultural Identity Quiroz, Alfonso W (1988) 'Financia! Leadership and the Formation of Peruvian
in the High Provinces of Southern Peru (Boulder, CO: Westview Press) pp. Elite Groups, 1884-1930' Journal of Latín American Studies vol. 20 #1
199-222. (May) pp. 49-8r.
Paredes, Maritza (2013) 'Shaping State Capacity: A Comparative Historical Rámirez, María Teresa, and Irene Salazar (2010) 'El Surgimiento de la Educación
Analysis of Mining Dependence in the Andes, l84os-192os' (PhD en Colombia: En qué Fallamos?' in Meisel Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa
Dissertation, Department of International Development, Oxford University). Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana del Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de
Park, James William (1985) Rafael Nuñez and the Politics of Colombian Cultura Económica) pp. 419-482.
Regionalism, 1863-1886 (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press). Ramírez, María Teresa, and Juana Patricia Téllez (2007) 'La Educación Primaria
Pastare, Mario (1994) 'State-Led Industrialization: The Evidence on Paraguay, y Secundaria en Colombia en el Siglo XX' in Robinson, James, and Miguel
1852-1870' Journal of Latín American Studies vol. 26 #2 (May) pp. Urrutia, eds. Economía Colombiana del Siglo XX: Un Análisis Cuantitativo
295-324. (Bogotá: Fondo de Cultura Económica) pp. 459-517.
Peloso, Vincent (1999) Peasants on Plantations: Subaltern Strategies of Labor and Rausch, Jane M. (1993) The Llanos Frontier in Colombian History, 1830-1930
Resistance in the Pisco Valley, Peru (Durham, NC: Duke University Press). (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press).
Works Cited Works Cited

(l 999) Colombia: Territorial Rule and the Llanos Frontier( Gainesvile: University Ruiz-Esquide, Andrea (2000) 'Migration, Colonization, and Land Policy in the
Press of Florida). Former Mapuche Frontier: Malleco, 1850-1900' (Dissertation presented to
Reed, Nelson (1964) The Gaste War of Yucatan (Stanford, CA: Stanford the Department of History, Columbia University).
University Press). Safford, Frank (1976) The Ideal of the Practica[: Colombia's Struggle to Forma
Reina, Leticia (1980) Las Rebeliones Campesinas en México, 1819-1906 Technical Elite (Austin: University ofTexas Press).
(Mexico, DF: Siglo XXI). (1988) 'The Emergence of Economic Liberalism in Colombia' in Love,
Remmer, Karen L. (1984) Party Competition in Argentina and Chile: Political Joseph, and Nils Jacobsen, eds. Guiding the Invisible Hand: Economic
Recruitment and Public Policy, l 890-193 o (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Liberalism and the State in Latin American History (New York: Praeger)
Press). pp. 35-62.
Rénique, José Luis (1994) 'Political Violence, the State, and the Peasant Struggle (1991) 'Race, Integration, and Progress: Elite Attitudes and the Indian in
for Land (Puno)' in Deborah Poole, ed. Unruly Order: Violence, Power, Colombia, 1750-1870' Hispanic American Historical Review vol. 71 #1
and Cultural Identity in the High Provinces of Southern Peru (Boulder, pp. 1-33.
CO: Westview Press) pp. 223-246. (2010) 'El Problema de Los Transportes en Colombia en el Siglo XIX' in Meisel
(2004) La Batalla por Puno: Conflicto Agrario y Nacion en los Andes Peruanos Roca, Adolfo, and María Teresa Ramírez, eds. Economía Colombiana del
(Lima: IEP). Siglo XIX (Bogotá: Fondo de Cultura Económica) pp. 523-574.
República de Colombia, Departamento de Contraloría Anuario de Estadística Safford, Frank, and Marco Palacios (2002) Colombia: Fragmented Land, Divided
General (Bogotá: Imprenta Nacional) (Various years). Society (New York: Oxford University Press).
Resende Santos, Joao (2007) Neorealism, States, and the Modern Mass Army Salvatore, Ricardo D. (2013) 'Between Empleomanía and the Common
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Good: Expert Bureaucracies in Argentina, 1870-1930' in Centeno, Miguel,
Richmond, Douglas W. (1989) Carlos Pellegrini and the Crisis of the Argentine and Agustín Ferraro, eds. State and Nation Making in Latin America and
Elites, 1880-1916 (Westport, CT: Praeger Press). Spain: Republics of the Possible (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
Riedl, Rache! Beatty (2009) 'Institutions in New Democracies: Variation in pp. 225-246).
African Party Systems' (PhD Dissertation, Department of Politics, Princeton Sanders, James E. (2010) 'Subaltern Strategies of Citizenship and Soldiering in
University). Colombia's Civil Wars: Afro- and Indigenous Colombians' Experiences in
Rock, David (1987) Argentina 1JI6-1987: From Spanish Colonization to the Cauca, 18 51-1877' in Foote, Nicola, and René D. Harder Horst, eds.
Alfonsín (Berkeley: University of California Press). Military Struggle and Identity Formation in Latin America: Race, Nation,
(2000) 'State-Building and Political Systems in Nineteenth Century Argentina and Community during the Liberal Period (Gainesville: University ot Florida
and Uruguay' Past and Present #167 pp. 176-202. Press) pp. 25-4r.
(2002) State Building and Political Movements in Argentina, 1860-1916 Santos Granero, Fernando, and Frederica Barclay (2002) La Frontera
(Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Domesticada: Historia Económica y Social de Loreto, 1850-2000
Rodden, Jonathan, and Erik Wibbels (2002) 'Beyond the Fiction of (Lima: PUCP).
Federalism: Macroeconomic Management in Multitiered Systems' World Sater, William F. (1973) 'Chile during the First Months of the War of the Pacific'
Politics vol. 54 Uuly) pp. 494-53 r. ]ournal of Latín American Studies vol. 5 #1 (May) pp. 133-158.
Rodríguez, Linda A. (1985) The Search for Public Policy: Regional Politics and (1976) 'Economic Nationalism and Tax Reform in Late Nineteenth-Century
Government Finances in Ecuador, 1830-1940 (Berkeley: University of Chile' The Americas pp. 3l1-3 3 5.
California Press). (2007) Andean Tragedy: Fighting the War of the Pacific, 1879-1884
Rojas, Cristina (2002) Civilization and Violence: Regimes of Representation in (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press).
Nineteenth Century Colombia (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press). Sater, William F., and Holder H. Herwig (1999) The Grand Illusion: The
Romero, Marías (l 89 8) Geographical and Statistical Notes on Mexico (New York: Prussianization of the Chilean Army (Lincoln: University of Nebraska
Knickerbocker Press). Press).
Rosenthal,Joshua M. (2001) 'La Salina de Chita: Fiscal Policy and Local Power in Sausi Garavito, María José Rhi (2001) 'El Deber Fiscal durante la Regencia
Provincial Colombia' (PhD Dissertation, Department of History, Columbia y el Segundo Imperio: Contribuciones y Contribuyentes de la Ciudad de
University). México' in Marichal, Carlos, and Daniela Marino, eds. De Colonia a
(2012) Salt and the Colombian State: Local Society and Regional Monopoly in Nación: Impuestos y Política en México, 1750-1860 (Mexico City: El
Boyacá, 1821-1900 (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press) Colegio de México) pp. 247-275.
Ross, Michael L. (2001) Timber Booms and Institutional Breakdown in Southeast (2005) '¿Cómo Aventurarse a Perder lo Que Existe? Una Reflexión sobre
Asia (New York: Cambridge University Press). el Voluntarismo Fiscal Mexicano del Siglo XIX' in Aguilar, Aboites Luis,
Works Cited Works Cited

and Luis Jáuregui, eds. (2005) Penuria sin Fin: Historia de los Impuestos (2010) Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in
en México Siglos XVIII-XX (Mexico, DF: Instituto Mora), pp. n5-140. Southeast Asia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Saylor, Ryan R. (2008) 'Commodity Booms, Political Coalitions, and State Slater,Dan, and Sofia Fenner (201 l ). State Power and StayingPower: Infrastructural
Building in Latin America and Africa' (PhD Dissertation, Department of Mechanisms and Authoritarian Durability f ournal of International Affairs
Politics, University ofVirginia). vol. 65 #1 pp. 15-29.
(2012) 'Sources of State Capacity in Latin America: Commodity Booms and Slater, Dan, and Diana Kim (2015) 'Standoffish States: Nonliterate Leviathans in
State Building Motives in Chile' Theory and Society vol. 41 #3 pp. 301-324. Southeast Asia' TRaNS vol. 3 #r.
(2014) State Building in Boom Times: Commodities and Coalitions in Latin Slater, Dan, and Erica Simmons (2010) 'Informative Regress: Critical Antecedents
America and Africa (Oxford: Oxford University Press). in Comparative Politics' Comparative Political Studies vol. 43 #7 (July) pp.
Saylor, Ryan R., and Hillel David Soifer (2008) 'Rivalry and State Building in 886-917.
Latin America: Tracing and Adjudicating Competing Causal Mechanisms' Slater, Dan, and Daniel Ziblatt (20 l 3) 'The Enduring Indispensability of the
(unpublished paper, University ofTulsa and Temple University). Controlled Comparison' Comparative Política/ Studies vol. 46 #ro (October)
Scarritt, Arthur (2005) 'The Battle of Burnt Bread: Indigenous Mobilization pp. 1301-1327.
and Land Loss in the Peruvian Highlands, 1982-2003' (Ph.D. Dissertation, Srnith, Gavin (l 9 89) Livelihood and Resistance: Peasants and the Politics of Land
Department of Sociology, University of Wisconsin). in Peru (Berkeley: University of California Press).
Scheina, Robert L. (2003) Latín America's Wars (two volumes) (Washington, Snyder, Richard (2001) Politics after Neoliberalism: Reregulation in Mexico
DC: Brassey's). (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Scott, James C. (1976) The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and (2001b) 'Scaling Down: The Subnational Comparative Method' Studies in
Subsistence in Southeast Asia (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press). Comparative International Development vol. 36 #1 pp. 93-no.
(1998) Seeing Like a State: How Various Schemes to Improve the Human Snyder, Richard, and Angelica Durán-Martínez (2009) 'Does Illegality Breed
Condition Have Failed (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press). Violence? Drug Trafficking and State-Sponsored Protection Rackets' Crime,
(2009) The Art of Not Being Governed (New Haven, CT: Yale University Law, and Social Change vol. 52 pp. 253-273.
Press). Soifer, Hillel David (2008) 'State Infrastructural Power: Conceptualization and
Scully, Timothy (1992) Rethinking the Center: Party Politics in Nineteenth and Measurement in Empirical Analysis' Studies in Comparative International
Twentieth Century Chile (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Development vol. 43 #3-4 (November) pp. 231-251.
Serrano, Sol (1995-1996) 'De Escuelas Indígenas sin Pueblos a Pueblos sin (2009) 'The Sources of Infrastructural Power: Evidence from Nineteenth
Escuelas Indígenas: la Educación en la Araucanía en el Siglo XIX' Historia Century Chilean Education' Latín American Research Review vol. 44 #2
29, pp. 423-474. pp. 158-180.
Shafer, D. Michael (1994) Winners and Losers: How Sectors Shape the (2012a) 'The Causal Logic of Critical Junctures' Comparative Política/ Studies
Developmental Prospects of States (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press). vol. 45 #12 (December), pp. 1572-1597.
Sikkink, Kathryn (1991) Ideas and Institutions: Developmentalism in Brazil and (2012b) 'Measuring State Capacity in Contemporary Latin America' Revista
Argentina (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press). de Ciencia Política, special issue on 'States and Challengers in Contemporary
Siller, Javier Pérez (2004) Los Ingresos Federales del Porfirismo (Puebla, Latin America' vol. 32 #3 (November-December) pp. 58 5-598.
Mexico: Universidad Autónoma de Puebla). (2013a) 'State Power and the Redistributive Threat' Studies in Comparative
Silva, Patricio (2008) In the Name of Reason: Technocrats and Politics in Chile International Development vol. 48 #1 (March) pp. 1-22.
(University Park: Penn State University Press). (2013b) 'Elite Preferences, Administrative Institutions, and Educational
Silva Olarte, Renán (1989) 'La Educación en Colombia, 1880-1930' in Alvaro Development during Peru's Aristocratic Republic (1895-1919)' Chapter in
Tirado Mejía, ed. Nueva Historia de Colombia (Bogotá: Editorial Planeta) Centeno and Ferrara, eds. Paper Leviathans (Gainesville: University Press of
vol. IV, pp. 61-86. Florida).
Sinkin, Richard (1979) The Mexican Reform, 1855-1876: A Study in Liberal Soifer, Hillel David and Matthias vom Hau (2008) 'Unpacking the "Strength" of
Nation-Building (Austin: University ofTexas Press). the State: The Utility of State Infrastructural Power' Studies in Comparative
Skuban, William E. (2007) Lines in the Sand: Nationalism and Identity on the International Development vol. 43 #3-4 (November) pp. 219-230.
Peruvian-Chilean Frontier (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press). Spruyt, Hendrik (1994) The Sovereign State and Its Competitors (Princeton,
Slater, Dan (2008) 'Can Leviathan Be Democratic? Competitive Elections, Robust NJ: Princeton University Press).
Mass Politics, and State Infrastructural Power' Studies in Comparative Staples, Anne (1979) 'Alfabeto y Catecismo: Salvación del Nuevo País' Historia
International Development vol. 4 3 #3-4 pp. 2 52-272. Mexicana vol. 29 #1 (July-September) pp. 35-58.
286 Works Cited Works Cited

(r992) 'Alfabeto y Catecismo, Salvación del Nuevo País' in Josefina Zoraida (2006) 'Public Violence and State Building in Central America' Comparative
Vásquez, ed. La Educación en la Historia de México (México, DF: El Colegio Política! Studies vol. 39 #ro pp. I263-I282.
de México) pp. 69-92. (2007) 'The Political Economy of State Building in Sub-Saharan Africa' The
(r998) 'Los Poderes Locales y las Primeras Letras' in Pilar Gonzalbo Aizpurú, ]ournal of Politics vol. 69 #3 pp. 7r 6-73 r.
ed. Historia de la Educación y la Enseñanza de la Historia (Mexico, DF: El Thomson, Guy P. C. (r990) 'Bulwarks of Patriotic Liberalism: The National
Colegio de México) pp. 47-62. Guard, Philharmonic Corps, and Patriotic Juntas in Mexico, r847-r888'
Stasavage, David (20rr) States of Credit: Size, Power, and the Development of ]ournal of Latín American Studies vol. 22 #r pp. 3 r-68.
European Polities (Princeton: Princeton University Press). (r993) 'Los Indios y el Servicio Militar en el México Decimonónico. Leva o
Stein, Stanley (r98r) 'Bureaucracy and Business in the Spanish Empire, Cuidadanía?' in Antonio Escobar Ohmsted, ed. Indio, Nación, y Comunidad
r759-r804: Failure of a Bourbon Reform in Mexico and Peru' Hispanic en el México del Siglo XIX (Mexico, DF: Centro de Estudios Mexicanos y
American Historical Review vol. 6r #r (February) pp. 2-28. Centroamericanos) pp. 207-2p.
Steinmo, Sven (r993) Taxation and Democracy (New Haven, CT: Yale University with David G. LaFrance (r999) Patriotism, Politics and Popular Liberalism in
Press). r9th Century Mexico (Wilmington, DE: Scholarly Resources).
Stevens, Donald F. (r99r) Origins of Instability in Early Republican Mexico Thomson, Jan and Dietrich Angerstein (2000) Historia del Ferrocarril en Chile
(Durham, NC: Duke University Press). (Santiago: DIBAM).
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. ( r 968) Constructing Social Theories (Chicago: University Thorp, Rosemary, and Geoffrey Bertram (r978) Peru r890-r977: Growth and
of Chicago Press). Policy in an Open Economy (New York: Columbia University Press).
Subercaseaux, Benjamin (r944) Chile, o una Loca Geografía (Santiago: Ediciones Thurner, Mark (r997) From Two Republics to One Divided: Contradictions of
Ercilla). Postcolonial Nationmaking in Andean Peru (Durham, NC: Duke University
Szuchman, Mark D. (r990) 'Childhood Education and Politics in r9th Century Press).
Argentina: The Case of Buenos Aires' Hispanic American Historical Review Tilly, Charles (r975) 'Reflections on the History of European State-Making'
vol. 70 #r pp. ro9-r38. in Charles Tilly, ed. The Formation of National States in Western Europe
Tanck de Estrada, Dorothy (r973) 'Las Escuelas Lancasterianas en la Ciudad de (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press) pp. 3-83.
México r822-42' Historia Mexicana vol. 22 #4 (April-June) pp. 494-p3. (r985) 'State Making as Organized Crime' in Evans, Peter, Dietrich
(r977) La Educación Ilustrada I786-r836: Educación Primaria en la Ciudad Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol, eds. Bringing the State Back In
de México (Mexico, DF: El Colegio de México). (New York: Cambridge University Press) pp. r69-r9r.
Tantaleán Arbulú, Javier (r983) Política Económico-Financiera y la Formación (r992) Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-r992 (Cambridge,
del Estado: Siglo XIX (Lima: CEDEP). MA: Blackwell).
Tarrow, Sid (r998) Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Tinker Salas, Miguel (2009) The Enduring Legacy: Oil, Culture, and Society in
Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press). Venezuela (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Tarvear, H. Michael, and Julia C. Frederick (2006) The History of Venezuela Topik, Steven (r988) 'The Economic Role of the State in Liberal Regimes: Brazil
(London: Palgrave). and Mexico Compared, r888-r9ro' in Love, Joseph L., and Nils Jacobsen,
Taylor, Lewis (2006) $hining Path: Guerrilla War in Peru's Northern Highlands, eds. Guiding the Invisible Hand: Economic Liberalism and the State in Latín
r980-r997 (Liverpool: Liverpool University Press). American History (New York: Praeger) pp. rr7-r44.
Tenenbaum, Barbara (r986) The Politics of Penury: Debts and Taxes in Mexico, Tutino, John (r986) From Insurrection to Revolution in Mexico: Social Bases of
I82I-r856 (Albuquerque: University ofNew Mexico Press). Agrarian Violence, r750-r940 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
'The Growing Power of the Republic of Chile' (r884) Atlantic Monthly Uuly) Uhthoff López, Luz María (2004) 'La Dificil Concurrencia Fiscal y la Contribución
pp. IIO-II7. Federal, r86r-r924: Notas Preliminares' Historia Mexicana vol. 54 #r pp.
Thelen, Kathleen, and Sven Steinmo (r992) 'Historical Institutionalism in r29-r78.
Comparative Politics' in Steinmo, Sven, Kathleen Thelen, and Frank (2005) 'La Fiscalidad y la Revolución Constitucionalista' in Aguilar, Aboites
Longstreth, eds. Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Luis, and Luis Jáuregui, eds. (2005) Penuria sin Fin: Historia de los
Comparative Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) pp. r-33. Impuestos en México Siglos XVIII-XX (Mexico, DF: Instituto Mora), pp.
Thies, Cameron G. (2004) 'State Building, Interstate and Intrastate r6r-r88.
Rivalry: A Study of Post Colonial Developing Country Extractive Efforts, (2003) 'Hacía la Institucionalización de la Hacienda Pública: la Participación
r975-2000' International Studies Quarterly vol. 48 #r pp. 53-72. de Guillermo Prieto' in Brian F. Connaughton, ed. Poder y Legitimidad en
(2005) 'War, Rivalry, and State-Building in Latin America' American ]ournal of México en el Siglo XIX: Instituciones y Cultura Política (Mexico: UNAM)
Política! Science vol. 49 #3 (July) pp. 4p-465. pp. 431-450.
288 Works Cited Works Cited

UNDP (2009) Por una densidad del estado al servicio de la gente. (2009) 'Unpacking the School: Textbooks, Teachers, and the Construction
Urzúa Valenzuela, German (1970) Evolución de la Adminstración Pública of Nationhood in Mexico, Argentina, and Peru' Latin American Research
Chilena, r8r8-r968 (Santiago: Editorial Jurídica de Chile). Review 44: l27-r54.
Valencia Tovar, Alvaro (1993) Historia de las Fuerzas Militares de Colombia Voss, Stuart F. (1982) On the Periphery of Nineteenth Century Mexico: Sonora
(Bogotá: Planeta). and Sinaloa, r8ro-r877 (Tucson: University of Arizona Press).
Valenzuela, Arturo (n.d.) 'Political Elites in the Chilean Parliamentary Republic' Vu, Tuong (20rn) 'Studying the State through State Formation' World Politics
(unpublished manuscript). vol. 62 #r pp. 148-r75.
(1977) Political Brokers in Chile: Local Government in a Centralized Polity Wagner, Gert, José Jofré, and Rolf Lüders (2000) 'Economía Chilena
(Durham, NC: Duke University Press). r810-1995: Cuentas Fiscales' Documento de Trabajo #188, Instituto de
Vanderwood, Paul J. (r970) 'Genesis of the Rurales: Mexico's Early Struggle Economía, Universidad Católica (Santiago, Chile).
for Public Security' Hispanic American Historical Review vol. 50 #2, pp. Waldner, David (l 999) State Building and Late Development (Ithaca, NY: Cornell
323-344. University Press).
(r976) 'Response to Revolt: The Counter-Guerrilla Strategy of Porfirio Díaz' Walker, Charles F. (1999) Smoldering Ashes: Cuzco and the Creation of
HispanicAmerican Historical Review pp. 551-579. Republican Peru, I780-r840 (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
(1990) 'Explaining the Mexican Revolution' in Jaime Rodríguez O., ed. The Weber, Eugen (1976) Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural
Revolutionary Process in Mexico (UCLA Latin American Studies Volume France, r870-r9r4 (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).
72) pp. 97-r I4· Weber, Max (1958) 'Politics as a Vocation' in Gerth, H. H. and C. Wright Milis,
(r998) The Power of God against the Guns of Government: Religious Upheaval eds. From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (New York: Oxford University
in Mexico at the Turn of the Nineteenth Century (Stanford, CA: Stanford Press) pp. 77-128.
University Press). Winters;Jeffrey A. (20u) Oligarchy (New York: Cambridge University Press).
(r992) Disorder and Progress: Bandits, Police, and Mexican Development Woll, Afien A. (1975) 'For God or Country: Historical Textbooks and the
(Wilmington, DE: SR Books). Secularization of Chilean Society, 1840-1890' ]ournal of Latin American
Vaughan, Mary Kay (r982) The State, Education, and Social Class in Mexico, Studies 7 pp. 23-43.
r880-r928 (DeKalb: Northern Illinois University Press). Womack, John Jr. (1986) 'The Mexican Revolution, 1910-1920' in Leslie
(r987) 'Primary Schooling in the City of Puebla, l82r-r860' The Hispanic Bethell, ed. The Cambridge History of Latin America, Vol. V, c.r870-r930
American Historical Review vol. 67 #r (February) pp. 39-62. (New York: Cambridge University Press) pp. 79-154.
(r997) Cultural Politics in Revolution: Teachers, Peasants, and Schools in Woods, Ngaire (1995) 'Economic Ideas and International Relations: Beyond
Mexico, r930-r940 (Tempe: University of Arizona Press). Rational Neglect' International Studies Quarterly vol. 39 #2 Uune) pp.
Vázquez,Josefina Zoraida (1967) 'La República Restaurada y la Educación: Un 161-180.
Intento de Victoria Definitiva' Historia Mexicana vol. 17 #2 Wright, Thomas C. (1973) 'Origins of the Politics oflnflation in Chile, 1888-1918'
(October-December) pp. 200-21r. The Hispanic American Historical Review vol. 53 #2 (May) pp. 239-259.
Vázquez de Knauth, Josefina ed. (1970) Nacionalismo y Educación en México Yashar, Deborah (2005) Contesting Citizenship in Latin America: The Rise
(México, DF: El Colegio de México). of Indigenous Movements and the Post-Liberal Challenge (Princeton,
Veliz, Claudia (r980) The Centralist Tradition in Latin America (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
NJ: Princeton University Press). Yeager, Gertrude M. (1983) 'Women's Roles in Nineteenth Century Chile: Public
Ventresca, Marc (199 5) 'When States Count: Institutional and Política! Dynamics Education Records, 1843-1883' Latin American Research Review vol. 18
in Modern Census Establishment, 1800-1993' (PhD Dissertation, Stanford #3 pp. 149-156.
University). (2005) 'Religion, Gender Ideology, and the Training of Female Public
Vera, Robustiano (1886) Lei de Régimen Interior de la República de Chile Elementary School Teachers in l9th Century Chile.' The Americas vol. 62
(Valparaíso, Chile: Imprenta y Librería Americana). #2 pp. 209-243.
Vergara, Alberto (2or2) 'Conflicto regional, estado central, y sociedad periférica Young, Crawford (1994) The African Colonial State in Comparative Perspective
en Bolivia y Perú: un análisis histórico comparado' (Ph.D. Dissertation, (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).
Université de Montréal Política! Science Department). Zeitlin, Maurice (1984) The Civil Wars in Chile (Or the Bourgeois Revolutions
vom Hau, Matthias (2008) 'State Infrastructural Power and That Never Were) (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
Nationalism: Comparative Lessons from Mexico and Argentina' Studies in Ziblatt, Daniel (2006) Structuring the State: The Formation of Italy and Germany
Comparative International Development vol. 43 #3-4 pp. 334-354. and the Puzzle of Federalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).
Works Cited

Zipf, George K. (1941) National Unity and Disunity (Bloomington, IN: Principia
Press).
Zuleta, María Cecilia (2003) 'De Viejos y Nuevos Impuestos: El Estado Y Los
Contribuyentes Frente a la Abolición de las Alcábalas en México a Finales del
Siglo XIX' in Brian F. Connaughton, ed. Poder y Legitimidad en México en el Index
Siglo XIX: Instituciones y Cultura Política (Mexico: UNAM) pp. 451-496.
Zuleta, María Cecilia (2004) 'Hacienda Pública y Exportación Henequenera en
Yucatán, 1880-r9ro' Historia Mexicana vol. 54 #r pp. 179-247.

Abente, Diego, 243 Amazon,30,3r-2,32n7


accommodationist ideology, in guano American Civil War, 33
era, 118-19 Ancash, Peru, 183
Adelman, Jeremy, 9 5n8 Antioquia, Colombia, 44
adrninistration, 82-6, 180, r8onr9, anti-statist consensus, 52-5, 253
r8r. See also delegated rule; anti-statist vision of development.
deployed rule; tax adrninistration; See laissez-faire vision of
territorial administration development
adrninistrative appointments. anti-traditional ideology,
See appointments rr6-r8, rr9-20
adrninistrative institutions, Antofagasta, Chile, 240-r
61-82,62-5 Anuarios Estadísticos, 48
administrative patronage. See patronage appointment decrees, 66-70,
administrative reforms, of 66n8,77-8
timbre, 197 appointments, 60-r. See also deployed
adrninistrative slippage, 64n6 appointments
adrninistrators, 154-5, 184-5 central government controlling, 74
Africa, 85, 258 in Chile, 7rnro, 7rnr3,
African states, 7, 21 74-5, ro9-13
agents, 6rn2, 62. See also state agents decree analysis, 66-70, 66n8
agiotistas (loan providers), ro2 as delegated, 7rnr2
agricultural properties, rolls inMexico, 7rnro, n3-r4
of, r88n29 national projects
agriculture, of Chile, rn-12 influencing, I I 6-20
Alberdi, Juan Bautista, 23 8 of outsiders, 8 r
Albertus, Michael, 27n2 overview of, 107-23
alcábala (excise tax), roo, roon9, ror, patronage influencing, 120-3
r99-200,r99n38 perceived threats influencing,
Alesina,Alberto, 33n9 107,108-16
Alessandri, Jorge, 249 in Peru, 7rnro, 7rnr3, 114-16
Index Index 293

appointments (cont.) Battle of Lircay, 103 capital city, 33n9 bureaucratic networks in, 8 3-4
in political biographies, 71-4 Bauer, Arnold, 39, 74, l13n24 Caracas, Venezuela, 243, 244-5 bureaucrats in, 141, 189,
practices, 107-23 Bazant, Mílada, l 3 2 career politicians, 78-9 190-1,222
qualitative evidence shedding light Belize, 24 5ll4 Carmagnani, Marcello, 199-200 Catholic Church in, l 3 6
on,74-82 bellic approach, 27, 204-6 Cartagena, Colombia, 42 census in, 9 8
refusals of, 76-7 Bengoa, José, 109 Casanare, Colombia, 98, 177-8 civil war in, lll, 111n21, llln22,
traditional authority Bergquist, Charles W., 230 case studies, 15-17 208-9,223
influencing, n6-20 Berman, Sheri, 56 Caste War, 105 clearly deployed appointments in,
Araucana,48-9 Bertram, Geoffrey, 76nr6 Castilla, Ramón, sr, 211 68, 69, 70
Araucanía,48-9,111 Blancos, Uruguay, 239 Castro, Cipriano, 244-5 commodity booms
El Araucano, 66, 66n8 Bobrow-Strain,Aaron, 81-2, l95n33 catastro (real estate true), 100 influencing, l 5 8-9
Arequipa, Peru, 40, 78 Bogotá, Colombia, 41, 43, 91 Catholic Church, 130.-1, 13 5-6 commodity busts influencing, l 5 8-9
Argentina,37,110,209,223, Bolívar, Simón, 9 5 cattle slaughter tax. See degüello conscription in, 203, 222-4
237-9,246-8 Bolivia, l, 2, 71n13, 145, 240-r. (cattle slaughter) tax constitution of, 98
central state authority in, 238n2 See a/so War of the Pacific Cauca, 42, 43, 53 curriculum in, 132
Aristocratic Republic (Peru), 3n5, 17, capital city of, 33n9 caudillismo, 238n2 decentralization in, 187-8, l87n24
52,79-80, 144-7 Chile's war with, 207, 209 caudillos, II7-18, 21 l deployed bureaucrats in, 124-5
deployed rule in, 68, 86 Boucoyannis, Deborah, 256n9 Caupolicán,Chile,141 deployed rule in, 73-4, 73n14,
military in, 229 Bourbon Reforms, 82, 89-94, 89n2 causal mechanisms, 62-5 77-8, 86, II3, 186-92,
schools in, 130 Boyacá, Colombia, 42 censuses, l-2, 13-14, l4n16, 80, 148. 195,222-4
armies. See a/so mobilization capacity; Brazil, 239 See a/so education census of 1902, education in, 98, 124-5,
recruitment British Empire, 85, 88 in Peru 138-40, 156-7
of Chile, n1, 112, 222-3 British Honduras, 220 in Chile, 98 elites in, 75, 103-4, 110, 112-13,
of Colombia, 2 II-14 Britton, J ohn A., 14onr 5 of Peru, 40, 14 5-6 224,224n14
independence, 9 5 Brownlee, Jason A., 260, 261n12 of schools, 9 8 extractive capacity of, 15 8,
of Mexico, 227 Buenaventura, Colombia, 42 Centeno, Miguel, 6-7, 18, 204, 163-4, 188-9
of Peru, 106, 227-9 Buenos Aires, Argentina, 37, 206,206n1 governors in, 189, 190, 191
war influencing size of, 206, 237-8, 248 Central Ameriq, 24 5-6 guerrilla warfare in, 96, 103,
206n1,206n2 Búlnes, Chile, 191 central state 109-10, lll-13
assimilation, 48-9, 51, llln20 bureaucracies, 61n2, 80-2, 83, 248 authority, 25, 238n2 independence of, 94-5
Atlantic coast, 42 bureaucratic appointments. oversight capacity of, 63n3 inequality in, 14on14
Atsuparia uprising, 183, 183n20 See appointments Chachapoyas, Peru, 76n16 infrastructure development of, 3 l
authority, 64-5. See also traditional bureaucratic networks, 83-4 Chaudhry, Kiren Aziz, l79nr6 insurrection in, l II
authority bureaucratic professionalism, 2fi4 Chiapas, Mexico, 81-2, l95n33 intendants in, 84
Ayacucho,Peru,228 bureaucratic quality, 60 Chihuahua, Mexico, 220 internal trucation in, 165, 191-2
bureaucrats, 60-1, 141, 196. See a/so Chile. See also Mapuche; National literacy in, 250-1
Baja California, Mexico, 130 appointments; authority; Guard; nitrates; War of the Pacific military of, 222-4
Balmaceda (president), 208, 223 deployed bureaucrats; officials; agriculture of, 1n-12 mobilization capacity of,
banditry, in Chile, 103, state agents appointment decrees, 66-70, 207-9,220-1
109-10, llln2l Bushnell, David, 53, 55 66n8,77-8 monopoly of force in, 103-4, 223
Barnett, Michael, 2 5 8 appointments in, 71n10, 71n13, municipal taxation in,
Barranquilla, Colombia, 42 cacao, 42n16 74-5, 109-13 173-4, 187-8
Basadre,Jorge,99 Cáceres, Andrés Avelino, 144 army of, 111, 112, 222-3 nitrares influencing, 164-5,
Bates, Robert H., 2 5 5 Cáceres government, Peru, 78, assimilation in, l l 1n20 172-3,191-2
Batlle administrations, Uruguay, 239 119-20,182 banditry in, 103, 109-10, lIIn21 perceived threats to, 109-13
Battle of Ayacucho, 9 5 Callao, Peru, 35, 37, 40, 106 Bolivia's war with, 207, 209 Peru invaded by, 181-2
Battle of Boyacá, 9 5 Camp, Roderic Ai, 71-2, 7rn9 Bourbon Reforms influencing, 90-1 Peru's war with, 207, 209
294 Index Index 295

Chile (cont.) Coatsworth, John, 50, recruitment in, 229-30, 229nr5 Constitutional Congress, rr7
political biographies of, 72-3 ro5nr4, r38nr2 regions of, 42-5, 42nr4 Constitutional Convention, 41
in post-independence crisis, 98, coercive capacity, 202-4, 2r4-20, revenue reforms in, r94-5, r94n32 consumption taxes, r84-5
roo, 103-4 2r 5nrr, 221-2, 230-r. See a/so revolts in, 9 r Contreras, Carlos, 75, 79nr9, 83,
primary schools in, 127, 128-9 conscription; mobilization school inspection in, r 3 3 83nio, r46n20
school inspection in, r 3 3, 140-3 capacity school materials in, r 3 2 contribución de rebajadas
school materials in, r 3 r-2 coffee, 42nr6, 44 schools in, 98, r27-30 (conscription exemption
schools in, r24-5, r29fi4, r29n5 Colombia. See a/so liberal reforms; self-sufficient regions in, 44-5 tax), 225
state leaders in, 6, r24-5, 139-40 War of rooo Days state leaders in, 124 contribución federal, r7r-2
state strength of, r r rn20 anti-statist consensus of, 52-5, 253 state weakness of, r24, 22r-2 contribución indígena (head tax),
systemic stability in, ro9-13 army of, 2rr-r4 tax burden in, 177-8 85n2r,roo,ror,ro2-3,
tax burden in, r72-4 Bourbon Reforms influencing, 9r-2 tax state development in, ro3nr3, r6,s
tax state development in, r8r, r95 Catholic Church in, r30-r, 135-6 r59-60,r93 collections, r 83n22
tax types in, r63-5 civil war in, 43, 53-4, 94-5, 212-13 tax types in, r68-70 failure of, r82-4
taxation in, roo, r8o, r86-92 civilization in, 52-5 taxationin,roo-r,r8onr7, r93-5 Copiapó, Chile, 3 8
teachers in, 130, r4r coercive capacity of, 22r-2 teachers in, 130-r Coquimbo,Chile,r88n30
terrain of, 3 r coffee in, 44 textbooks in, r 3 2 Córdoba, Colombia, 2
territorial administration in, commodity booms in, 44-5 threat defense of, 203, 2r2 cost structure, state leaders
63n5,84 conflict in, ro4 transpon in, 5 5 influenced by, 2r
textbooks in, r3r, r3rn7 conscription in, 203-4 uprisings in, 2r2-r3 Costa Rica, 24 5-6
threat defense of, 203 Conservatives in, 52-3, 5 5 urban primacy in, 4r-6, 4rnr2 costs of state building, 25-7, 254, 255
uprising in, r I I constitution of, 53-5 war in, 52-3, 55 Cristero War, Mexico, 249
urban primacy in, 3 8-9 currículum in, r 3 2 weapons in, 2r3 Cundinamarca, Colombia, 41, 42
violence in, ro9-r3 development in, 44-5, 52-5, 137 colonial impact, mechanisms of, 88-9 currency of patronage, ro7-8, 120-3
war and, r8, 52 direct taxes in, 194 colonial legacies, 88-94. See a/so currículum, r32, r46
Chiloé,Chile,98,r4r divergent preferences in, 42-4 Bourbon Reforms customary law, 60, 8 5-6, 8 5n22
Chowning, Margaret, I I 8, education in, 98, r24, 134-7, colonial política! institutions, 9rn3 customs duties, ro2, r70-2
r53n23, r55 r56, r56n25 colonial rule, 65n7, 89-94, 26r. Cuzco, Peru, rr5, 228
Christie, Keith H., 41 elites in, 52-3, 104, r37, 229-30 See a/so Japanese colonial rule
Chuquisaca, Bolivia, 2 extractive capacity of, r 5 8 Colorados, Uruguay, 239 Dargent, Eduardo, 2fi4
church-state relations, 47, 48 federalism in, r93 commodity booms, 44-5, 158-9, Davies, Thomas, 254, 256nrr
Cisneros, Pedro, r46n20 guerrilla warfare in, 96, 214 r79nr 5. See a/so nitrates de Ramón, Armando, 7rn9, 72-3
civil service reform, 84 independence of, 94-5 commodity busts, r 5 8-9 Deas, Malcolm, 4rnr2, r69, r77,
civil wars, 33, 38, 74. See a/so laissez-faire in, 53-5, r3 5nro, Compañia Lancasteriana, 99 r94n32,r95,22r,229nr6
mobilization capacity r8onr7, r93-5 Compañia Nacional de Recaudación decentralization, r87-8, r87n24,
in Chile, rrr, rrrn2r, rrrn22, Liberals in, 52-3, 55, 2rr-r2 (CNR),79-80,185-6, r85n23 189, r90-r
208-9,223 literacy in, 250-r Comunero Rebellion, Colombia, 9r decentralization law, r7 4nr 3
in Colombia, 43, 53-4, mandatory schooling in, r34-7 Concepción, Chile, 38, 7rnr2 degüello (cattle slaughter) tax, r69
94-5, 2I2-I3 mobilization capacity of, 2rr-14, Concordato, r 3 6 DeHart, Evelyn Hu, r53n23, 154
in Uruguay, 239 2r2n9,2r2nro conscription, rr, 79, 203-4, delegated appointments, 7rnr2
Civilista era,Peru, 52, rr6, rr9 monopoly of force in, ro4 22r, 222-4, 227-9. See also delegated rule, 62-82, ro7-8,
Civilista governments, Peru, 146-7 national government of, 53-5 mobilization I2I,22I
Civilistas, Peru, 78-80, rr9-20, in post-independence crisis, 98, conscription exemption tax. See adrninistrative slippage under, 64n6
r2on29,r22-3, r67-8 roo-r,ro4 contribución de rebajadas deployed rule compared
civilization, 46-8, p-5 public works in, 43-4 (conscription exemption tax) with, 62-82
CNR. See Compañia Nacional de railroads in, 43-4, 45 conservatives, 49, 52-3, 55, rr4 in Peru, rr6, 227-9
Recaudación (CNR) rebellion in, 53-4 constitution, 53-5, 98, 99, rr7, 244 state leaders choosing, 87-8, ro8
Index Index 2 97

Dellepiane, Carlos, 21on7, 2rrn8 domestic threats, r 8 administrators' conflict with, r 54-5 France, 257
Delpar, Helen, 229n1 5 Domínguez, Jorge I., 93 appointments influenced by, 7 5 French Intervention, 49, 225
department heads. See jefes de Domschke, Elaine, 13-14 in Argentina, 24 7-8 Fukuyama, Francis, lonro
departamento (department heads) Downing, Brian, 7, 21, 257 in Aristocratic Republic, 144-5 functionalism, 21, 258
deployed appointments, 67-70, 78 Dunning, Thad, 179-80 in Bolivia, 240-1
deployed bureaucrats, 22, 63-4, 124-5 Dutch Republic, 21-2, 257 in Chile, 75, 103-4, rro, rr2-13, Gaitán, Jorge Eliecer, 249
deployed rule, 107-8, lo7n17 224,224n14 geography, 4-5, 17, 20, 25-45.
administrative slippage under, 64n6 Eastern Cordillera, Colombia, 42 in Colombia, 52-3, ro4, See also urban primacy
in Argentina, 246-8 Eaton, Kent, 187 137,229-30 Germany, 261n12
in Aristocratic Republic (Peru), 68, Ecuador, l, 33, 229, 241-2 in guano era, rr8-19 Gingerich, Daniel W., 2fi4
79-80,86, 144-7 education, ro, 71n12. See also ideas influencing, 24-5 Goldstein, J udith, 4 6nr 8
in Chile, 73-4, 73nr4, 77-8, 86, primary schooling; primary in Mexico, 49-50, 81, rr4, 116-18, González-Cueva, Eduardo, 229
113,186-92,195,222-4 schools; public primary 153-6, l95n33 Gootenberg, Paul, 40, 51n21, 102n12,
definition of, 62 schooling; schools; textbooks in Peru, 51-2, 75-80, 76n16, 115n26, rr9
delegated rule compared inChile,98,124-5,138-40, 156-7 78-80,119-20,122-3,146-7, Gorski, Philip S., 7
with, 62-82 in Colombia, 98, 124, 134-7, l83n21, 227-8 Government Effectiveness, 13n15
educacional development influenced 156, l56n25 state leaders' coalitions with, 261-2 governors
by, 155 in Mexico, 99, 124, 125-6, 138-40, state leaders excluding, 22 in Argentina, 24 7
extractive capacity and, 188-9 147-56, 157 tax administration in hands in Chile, 189, 190, 191
in Liberal Mexico, 120 in Peru, 99, 124, 125, of, 195n33 decentralization criticized by, 190
in Mexico, 73-4, 73nr4, 80-2, 86, 138-40, 143-7 Encina, Francisco A., 98 in Mexico, 80-2, 121-2, 154,
115-16,118,195-200,226-7 education census of 1902, in Engerman, Stanley, l38n12, l4on15 155, 156
in Peru, 73-4, 73n14, 75-80, 86, Peru, 145-6 England, 21-2, 257 in Peru, 75, 83-4
116, 120, 125 education development. See also enlistment, 22:4-7 Goyer, Doreen, 13-14
in Porfirian Mexico, 120, 121-2 school inspection Ertman, Thomas, 7, 2 56-7 Granada, Nicaragua, 24 5
state agents influenced by, 142 in Chile, r 5 6-7 Europe,6-7,18,34n10,48,254,258 Great Depression, 249-50
state leaders choosing, 87-8, in Colombia, 156, 156n25 excise tax. See a/cábala (excise tax) Guanajuato, Mexico, 93
108-9 deployed rule influencing, r 55 expert bureaucracies, 248 guano,5,78,86,115n26,
state-development efforts influenced dimensions, r 26-7 extractive capacity of states, 158, 158-9, l8onr8
by, 124-5 indicators, r 26-7 163-4, 188-9 Peru influenced by, 165-7
deputy governor, in Peru, 83-4 inequality and, r 3 8-40 taxation after boom of, 181-6
Desaguadero, Peru, 14 5 in Mexico, 147-56, 157 Falleti, Tulia G., 187n24 guano era, 51n21, 116, 118-19, 120,
desertions, 222, 22 7 overview of, r 5 6-7 Fearon, James, 27n2 121,174-5
Deustua, Alejandro, 144-5 in Peru, 157 Federal District, Mexico, 13 l, 134, 147 Guatemala, 24 5-6
development, in Colombia, 44-5, during post-independence federal government, of Mexico, Guayana, Venezuela, 244
52-5, 137 crisis, 97-103 199-200, l99n38 Guayaquil, Ecuador, 33, 241-2
Diario Oficial, 66n8 social conditions influencing, 125-6 federal taxation, Mexico, r 9 5-200 Guerra a Muerte (War to the Death),
Díaz, Porfirio, 81, 118, 121, state agents and, 142-3 Federal Wars, 244 96, ro9
204,217-18 Education Ministry, 140-I, 143 federalism, 159, 193 guerrilla warfare, 96, 103, 109-10,
Díaz regime, 154, 218-19. See also Egaña Baraona, Maria Loreto, finance, 96, 102 lir-13, 214, 218-20. See also
Porfiriato 13on6, 142 flour exports, 39 Sendero Luminoso
diezmo (tithe), roo El Salvador, 24 5 forced enlistment. See leva (forced
direct rule, in British Empire, 88 elected offices, 121 enlistment) Haber, Stephen, rr 8
direct taxes, 167-8, l67n7, 194 elite preferences, in Mexico, r 51 forced loans, 102nrr haciendas, rr6-17
domestic manufactured goods tax. elites, 4-5, 65n7, 232-3, 234nr. forcible impressment, 225-6 Hale, Charles A., r 17
See renta interior (domestic See also landowners, in Mexico; foundational wars, 94-6 Hall, Peter A., 46nr8
manufactured goods tax) patronage Fowler, Will, 104-5 Hamnett, Brian R., 9 5n8
Index Index 2 99

Hanson, Jonathan, lon9 indirect rule, 85-6, 85n21, 183n21 Knight,Alan,93,118, 122 López-Alves, Fernando, 7
head tax. See contribución indígena inequality, l 3 8-40, 140nr4, l 5 l Kohli, Atul, 88-9 Los Angeles, Chile, rr r
(head tax) infrastructural power, of states, Kurtz, Marcus J., 7, 8, 8n7, 9, 13n15, Lustick, Ian, 21n19
health, 77 204-6. See also Mann, Michael; 19,224n14,239
HEC. See Historia del Ejército state capacity; state power; state Macaulay, Neill, 53
Chileno (HEC) strength La Guajira, Colombia, 2 Macías Richard, Carlos, 22onr 3
Hechter, Michael, 62 inspection. See school inspection La Paz, Bolivia, 240 Madero revolt, 220, 227
Helg,Aline, 130, 133, 135 inspectors (inspectores), 83-4, 141-3, laissez-faire, in Colombia, 53-5, Magdalena River, 42, 43, 43nr7, 45
Herbst,Jeffrey, 7, 21, 27, 32n6, 32n8, 145, 196 135n10,18on17, 193-5 Mahoney,James, 8n7, 15, 88, 246
85, 255, 257, 258 institutional capacity, 2fi4 laissez-faire vision of development, 26 Mainwaring, Scott, 11n12
Hernández Chávez, Alicia, 215 institutional change, in Peru, 143-7 Laitin, David, 27n2 Malinowski, Ernest, 5 r
Herr, Pilar M., lIOnr8 insurgency, 30, 218-20 landowners, in Mexico, 81-2, rr6-17 Malloa, Chile, 188n29
Herwig, Holder H., 209, 223-4 insurrection, in Chile, l l l Lange, Matthew, 8 5, 8 8 Mallon, Florencia, 92fi4, 92n5, 114-15
Hidalgo revolt, Mexico, 94 insurrectionary leaders, 74 Larson, Brooke, 51 Mamalakis, Markos J., roon9,
high modernist vision, 254-5 intendancy, 90 LaTorre, Lorenzo, 239 163fi4, 174n12
highlands, 43nr7 intendants, 84 laws, 174n13, 213. See also Managua, Nicaragua, 24 5
Hilario López, José, l 3 5, l 9 3-4 internal taxation, 165, 170-2, 191-2 customary law mandatory schooling, in
Historia del Ejército Chileno International Road Federation World legal sentence, conscription by, 22 5-6 Colombia, 134-7
(HEC), 207fi4 Road Statistics, l ln14 legitimacy, 64-;5 Mann, Michael, 9, 9n8, ro, 183
Holden, Robert H., 198n37 international threats, l 8 León, Nicaragua, 24 5 Mapuche, 109, rro-13. See also War
homicide rate, 2 intra-regional variation, 6-9 Letelier, Valentin, 84 to the Death
Honda, Colombia, 4 3 Iquitos, Peru, 3 l leva (forced enlistment), 224 Maracaibo, Venezuela, 42n16, 244
Honduras, 246 Iturbide, Agustín, 9 5-6 Levi, Margaret, 203 Mariscal, Elisa, 138n12, 139, 14on14,
Huancané revolt, Peru, 5 l Ley de Caminos, 43 l40n15, 151n22
Huanta, Peru, 96, 106, rr4n25 Jackson, Robert H., 257 Ley de Comuna Autónoma Martínez Moya, Armando, l 53n24
Huaraz, Peru, 183, 183n22 Jacobsen, Nils, 92fi4 (Municipal Autonomy Law), 187 McEvoy, Carmen, 51n22, 119n28
Huaylas region, Peru, 7 5n15 Jalisco, Mexico, 153n24 Ley de Régimen Interior, 84 McGreevey, William P., 212, 214
Huerta, Victoriano, 227 Japan, 261n12 Liberal era, end of, 249-52 medical officials. See médicos titulares
Hünefeldt, Christine, 103nr 3 Japanese colonial rule, 88-9 Liberal Mexico, rr6-r8, 120, 253 (medical officials)
Hutchcroft, Paul D., 261 Jauja, Peru, 40 liberal reforms, 46n19, 49-50, 168 médicos titulares (medical
jefes de departamento (department liberalism, 46-8 officials), 77
lea, Peru, 76-7 heads), 78-9 liberals, 52-3, 55, rr9n27, 131, Meltzer-Richard model, I 3 8nr 3
ideas, 19-20, 24-5, 46-55, 46nr8, jefes de provincia (provincial 2rr-12. See also Liberal Mexico Méndez, Cecilia, ro6nr 6
56-8, 252-5 chiefs), 78-9 Liberals, 85n21, 114, 147, 214 Mexican Porfiriato. See Porfiriato
ideology, in Porfirian Mexico, rr8. jefes políticos (political leaders), 81, liberum veto, Poland, 21 Mexican Revolution, 220
See also accommodationist 204,226 Lieberman, Evan S., 160, 162n2 Mexican-American War, 105
ideology, in guano era; Jesuits, 89n2 Lima, Peru, 31, 35, 37, 40-1, 76, 80, Mexico. See also Liberal Mexico;
anti-traditional ideology Juárez, Benito, 121, 216-17 129,131,181-2,210-11 National Guard; Porfiriato;
illiteracy, l jungles, 27n2, 30, 31, 32n7 literacy, 2, 11n13, 148, 151, 250-1 Restored Republic
immunizations, 2n3 Junguito, Roberto, 194n32 Llanos, Colombia, 95, 177 administrators in, 154-5
impuesto de haberes, 188-9, 191 loan providers. See agiotistas (loan appointments in, 71n10, 113-14
impuesto de mercados, 188 Kaplan, Oliver, 27n2 providers) army of, 227
independence, 94-6, 105. See also Karl, Terry Lynn, 18on19 loans, 102, 102n1 r Bourbon Reforms influencing, 92-4
post-independence crisis Kaufman, Herbert, 61n2 local officials, military recruitment bureaucracy of, 80-2, 83
indigenous authorities, 85 Keohane, Robert, 46n18 and,220-30 bureaucrats in, 196
indigenous population, 51, 114-15, Kim, Diana, 25 5n8, 261n13 logrolling, 4 3 coercive capacity of,
l l 5n26, 144-5. See also Araucana Klarén, Peter, 102n12 López Pumarejo, Alfonso, 194 214-20,215n11
300 Index Index 301

Mexico (cont.) revolts in, 49, 93, 94, 94n7, 105, Molina,Iván, l4on1 Palacios, Marco, 41
conflict in, l 17 105n15,113-14,227 monopolies Palmer, David Scott, 88
conscription in, 204 revolution in, 130, 220, 249 salt, l 69, l 84 Palmer, Steven, 14on1
Conservatives in, 49 school enrollment in, 148, tobacco,90,93n6,100,101, 168 Palonegro battle, 214
constitution of, n7 151, 151n22 monopoly of force, 103-7, 223 Panama,41,53,214,245fi4
cross-state variation in, 147-56 school inspection in, 133-4 Morelos, Mexico, 122 Pando, Bolivia, 2
customs duties in, 170-2 schools in, 99, 127, 128-9 mountainous terrain, 27n2, 30-1 Paragua~238,238n2,242-3,259
deployed rule in, 73-4, 73n14, spending of, l 5 ln22 Muecke, Ulrich, 76, 119, 122 Pardo, Manuel, 51, 51n22, 119, 146
80-2,86,115-16,118, state leaders in, 6, 113, 139, 140 Municipal Autonomy Law. See Ley de Pardo administration, Peru, l 3 2
195-200,226-7 states of, 199-200 Comuna Autónoma (Municipal Paredes, Maritza, 7-8, 18on18, 241
education in, 99, 124, 125-6, structural inequality in, 151 Autonomy Law) Park, James William, 42m3, 168n9
138-40,147-56,157 systemic stability in, n3-14 municipal taxation, in Chile, Paseo, Peru, 76-7
elite preferences in, l 51 tax burden in, 17 8-9 173-4,187-8 passports, l l 5
elites in, 49-50, 81, n4, n6-18, tax collectors in, l 9 5 Pasto, Colombia, 96
153-6,195n33 tax state development in, Napoleonic Wars, 9 5 Pastare, Mario, 242
enlistment in, 224-7 159-60,193 nation building, 260-2 Patria Boba, Colombia, 95-6
extractive capacity of, 158 tax types in, 170-2 national council of nobles. See sejm, patrimonialism, in
federal government of, taxation in, 100, 101-2, 193, Poland (national council of nobles) administration, 82-3
199-200,199n38 195-200 National Guard, '.?º9' 209n5, patronage,107-8,120-3
federalism in, l 9 3 teachers in, l 3 l 216-17,224-5 peasants, 105, lo5n15, 113-14
governorsin,80-2,121-2, 154, textbooks in, 132-3 national projects, n6-20, n9n28 perceived threats, 107, 108-16
155, 156 urban primacy in, 3 8, 39-40, 41 nationalism, 9 5n8 Perry, Laurens Ballard, 121
guerrilla warfare in, 218-20 urbanization in, l 51 naval vessels, 96 Peru. See also Aristocratic Republic
independence achieved U.S.'s war with, 215nn, 224 negotiation, 59-60 (Peru); Civilista era, Peru;
in, 95-6 wars of, 101, 105, 215n1 l, Neufeld, Stephen, 218, 224, 226 Civilistas Peru; Civilistas; guano;
intendancy in, 90 224,249 New Granada. See Colombia guano era; head tax; War of the
interna! taxation in, 170-2 México, Mexico, l 34 New Spain. See Mexico Pacific
landowners in, 81-2, n6-17 Mexico City, Mexico, 39-40, Newland, Carlos, 128-9 anti-traditional ideology in, n9-20
liberal reforms in, 49-50 50, 81, 99 Nicaragua, 245, 246 appointments in, 71n10,
Liberals in, 131, 147 Michoacán, Mexico, 148, nitrares, 158-9, 164-5, 172-3, 71n13, II4-16
literacy in, 148, l 51 l 53-4, l 5 5-6 186-92,191-2 army of, 106, 227-9
loans of, 102 mid-century liberalism, 46-8 Nugent, David, 76m6, 76n17, 84, Bourbon Reforms influencing, 92
mobilization capacity of, Migdal, Joel, 60, 66 122, 184, 18 5 bureaucratic networks in, 83-4
214-20,221 military, 222-4, 227-9, 242-3. Núñez, Rafael, 54, 55, 212, 213 Catholic Church in, l 3 6
monopoly of force in, 104-5 See also armies; coercive Nunn, Nathan, 27n2 census of, 40, 14 5-6
national government of, 8 l capacity; conscription; Chile invading, 181-2
order in, 49-50 enlistment; mobilization capacity; O'Donnell, Guillermo, 9 Chile's war with, 207, 209
patronagein, 121-2 recruitment officials, 6 5, 7 5m 5. See also clearly deployed appointments in,
peasants in, 105, 113-14 military mobilization. See appointments; bureaucrats; 68-70,78
perceived threats to, n3-14 mobilization delegated rule; deployed commodity booms
political biographies of, 71-2 military recruitment, 220-30, 221 rule; local officials, military influencing, l 5 8-9
Porfirian regime in, 50 Milla Batres, Carlos, 71n9, 72 recruitment and; medica! officials; commodity busts influencing, l 5 8-9
in post-independence crisis, 99, mining, 240-1 state agents conscription in, 203, 227-9
101-2,104-5, 106-7 Mitre, Bartolomé, 238 O'Higgins, Bernardo, IIO-II constitution of, 99
progress in, 49-50 mobilization, nn12 oil boom, 32 consumption taxes in, 184-5
railroads in, 50 mobilization capacity, 206-21, 212n9, opportunities as motive for state curriculum in, l 3 2, 146
recruitment in, 224-7 212n10,230-1 building, l 8-20 customs duties used by, 102
302 Index Index 303

Peru (cont.) state agents in, r8r-6 press-gangs, 223 resource rents, r79-80
decree analysis, 66-70, 66n8 state in, sr-2 primary schools, r27, I28-9, r45-6 Restored Republic, rr6-r8, 121, 154
decrees in, 77-8 state leaders in, 6, r39, r40 progress, 46-50, 5r-2, rr9n27, r37 revenue, in Aristocratic
delegated rule in, rr6, 227-9 state weakness of, r82, 222 protector de escuela (school Republic, 79-80
deployed rule in, 73-4, 73n14, systemic stability in, r14-r6 overseer), r4l revenue reforms, in Colombia,
75-80,86,rr6,r20, r25 tax burden in, r74-7 provincial chiefs. See jefes de 194-5, l94n32
deputy governor in, 83-4 tax reform in, r85-6 provincia (provincial chiefs) revolts, ro5n14
direct taxes in, r67-8, r67n7 tax state development in, r8r-6 Prussia, 257 in Colombia, 9 l
education development in, r 57 tax types in, r65-7, r67-8 public adrninistration. See consumption taxes prompting, r84
education in, 99, r24, r25, taxation in, roo, ro2-3, r8o administration in Mexico, 49, 93, 94, 94n7, ro5,
l38-40,r43-7 teachers in, r 3 r public goods, provision of, 3 3-4 ro5nr5,rr3-r4,227
elites in, sr-2, 75-80, 76nr6, territorial administration in, public primary schooling, r26-34, of peasants, ro5, lo5nr5, rr3-14
78-80,rr9-20,r22-3,r46-7, 63n5, 84 r37, rsr, 250 in Peru, 5r, 9r, 92, 92fl4, 94,
r83n2r,227-8 textbooks in, r32, I46 public works, in Colombia, 43-4 r14-15, 184-5
extractive capacity of, r58 uprising in, r83, r83n20 Puebla, Mexico, 99 taxation and, 183-4, r83n20
finance used by, ro2 urban primacy in, 3 8, 40-r Puga, Diego, 27n2 Reyes, Rafael, 230
governors in, 75, 83-4 war and, r8, 52, 209-rr Puno,Peru,76n18,92 rivalry (interstate), 206n3
guano influencing, r65-7 E/Peruano,66,66n8,75,76nr8,77,78 roads,11n14,43nr7
independence of, 96 Petorca, Chile, r90 quasi-voluntary compliance, 203 Roca government, 23 8-9
indigenous population of, r14-r5, Philippines, 65n7 Quito, Ecuador, 33, 24r Rock, David, 23 8, 248
r15n26, r44-5 Piérola, Nicolás de, I20, r44, Rodríguez, Linda A., 3 3
indirect rule in, r83n2r 145-6, r84 railroads, 39, 4_3-4, 43n17, 45, 50, rol de avaluos, r88n29
institucional change in, r43-7 Pincheira brothers, ro3, ro9 5r,240-1 Rosas, Juan Manuel de, 238
intendancy in, 90 Pittman, Dewitt Kenneth, r22 Ramírez, María Teresa, r34 Rosberg, Car! G., 257
liberals in, rr9n27 Poland, 2r-2 real estate tax. See catastro (real Rosenthal,Joshua M., l68n8
military of, 22 7-9 policy instruments, ideas as, 46nr8 estate tax) rubber boom, 3 2
military recruitment in, 22r political biographies, 7r-4 rebellion, 53-4, 96, ro6 ruggedness, 30-1
mobilization capacity of, political costs, r79-80, r8r-2 recruitment, 224-7, 229-30, 229nr5 Ruiz-Esquide, Andrea, rrr-r2
209-rr,22r political leaders. See jefes políticos Reform War, Mexico, 49 Rule of Law, r3llI5
monopoly of force in, ro5-7 (political leaders) reforms, 46n19, 78-80. See also
patronagein, r22-3 political patronage. See patronage administrative reforms, of salt, r69, I?8, r84
perceived threats to, r14-r6 polycephalic population timbre; Bourbon Reforms; civil Salvatore, Ricardo D., 248
política! biographies of, 72 distribution, 35, 37 service reform; liberal reforms; Samper, Miguel, 54
in post-independence crisis, 99, population, 34-7, 34nrr. See a/so revenue reforms, in Colombia; San Martín, José de, 9 5
ro2-3, ro5-7 censuses tax reform, in Peru Santa Anna, Antonio López de,
primary schools in, r4 5-6 Porfirian Mexico, rr8, r2o, refusals, 76-7 49, ro5
progress in, 5r-2, rr9n27 r2r-2,220 Regeneration, 54, r94 Santa Anna government, 99
railroads in, 5 r Porfirian regime, 50 regional salience, 3 2-4 5 Santa Cruz, Bolivia, 24r
rebellion in, 96, ro6 Porfirians, 8r-2 regionalism, 32n8, 33-7 Santa Marta, Colombia, 42
reforms in, 78-80 Porfiriato, Sr, rr6, r32-3, r54 regions, 5, 25, 31-2, 32n6, 40-1, 42-5, Santander, Colombia, 42, 42nr6, 44
refusals in, 76-7 Portales, Diego, ro4 42nr4. See a/so urban primacy Santander regime, lor
regions in, 40-r Posada-Carbó, Eduardo, 42nr4, ro4 renta interior (domestic manufactured Santiago,Chile,3r,38-9,74,98, r10
revolts in, 5r, 9r, 92, 92fl4, 94, positional authority, 64-5 goods tax), r72, r99-200 Sarmiento, Domingo Faustino, 238
rr4-r5, r84-5 post-independence crisis, 96-ro7 resource abundance, r79n15, 180 Sater, William F., 207fi4, 209, 223-4
school inspection in, r33, r45 Potosí, Bolivia, 240 resource booms, r79nr6. See also Saylor, Ryan R., 7, 8n7, r9,
schools in, 99, r27-9, r3o power, 64-5, r2o. See a/so state power commodity booms; guano; nitrares r79nr6, 206n3
Spain's war with, 209n6 prefectoralism, 62 resource dependence, r79nr5, 180 Scheina, Robert L., 2r 2
Index Index

school director, 76m8 Spanish South America, 236-46 ideas influencing, 19-20 tariff warfare, 43-4
school enrollment, in Mexico, q8, Spolaore, Enrico, 3 3n9 in Mexico, 6, 113, 139, 140 tax administration, 19 5n3 3, 196
151, 15rn22 Spruyt, Hendrik, 34n10, 256n9 in Peru, 6, 139, 140 tax burden, 162, 172-9
school inspection, 133-4, 140-3, 145 Staples, Anne, 99 state power, 89-94, 126-7 tax capacity, variation in, 179-200
school materials, 131-2. See a/so state agents, 142-3, r8r-6, 189, state strength, ro7n17, 111n20, tax collectors, in Mexico, l 9 5
textbooks 190-r, 222. See a/so bureaucrats; 142, 251-2 tax ratio, lrn1r
school overseer. See protector de delegated rule; deployed rule; state weakness, 22-3, 221-2, tax reform, in Peru, l 8 5-6
escuela (school overseer) officials 251-2, 257-8. See a/so tax relief, adrninistrators
schooling, 79. See a/so mandatory state building, 8, 82-6, 204-6, 232, post-independence crisis granting, 184-5
schooling, in Colombia 235-48, 252-62 causal irnportance, 259 tax state, Civilista, 167-8
schools, 98-9, 124-5, 127-30, r29n4, state capacity, 123. See a/so education; of Colombia, 124, 221-2 tax state development, 158-62,
129n5, 145. See a/so currículum; extractive capacity of states; overview of, 87 181-6,193,195,200-r
enrollment; primary schooling; mobilization; mobilization of Peru, 182, 222 tax types, 160-2, 163-5, 165-7,
primary schools; public primary capacity; state development; regionalism's relationship with, 33-7 167-8,168-70, 170-2
schooling; school materials state power; state strength; state state-building efforts taxation, 10-11, 21-2. See a/so
Schrank, Andrew, 9, 13n15 weakness; taxation alternative explanations, 234-5 Bourbon Reforms; federal
Scott,James, 60, 254, 255, 255n8 definition, 9-II failure of, 3, 20-3, 2rn20, 45, taxation; interna! taxation;
Scully, Timothy R., 1rn12 historical trends, n-15 59-86,233-4 municipal taxation, in Chile
secession, 3 3 measures, 9-11 ideational foundations of, 46-5 5 administration influencing,
seignorage, 101 resource booms influencing, 179n16 outcomes of, 61-82, 232-5, 246-8 180, r8onr9
sejm, Poland (national council of variation in, 1-9, 17-23, 87, as proactive, 4n6 in Aristocratic Republic, 79-80
nobles), 21 203, 251 success of, 3, 5-6, 59-86, 233-4, in Chile, roo, 180, 186-92
self-sufficient regions, 44-5 state capture, reforms as, 46n19 246n5,255-8 in Colombia, roo-r, 18onr7, 193-5
Sendero Luminoso, 106nr6 state collapse, 2 5 2 urban primacy influencing, comparative development of, 162-72
short-term finance, 102, 102n12 state development, 2-3 20, 235-46 decision on, 179-80
Sierra, Justo, II 8 in Argentina, 237-9 state-building efforts emergence, 3-5, after guano boom, 181-6
Sigman, Rache!, 10n9 commodity booms r7-20,232-5,246n5,255-8 during guano era, 174-5
Siller, Pérez, 196, 199n3 8 influencing, 179Ill 5 overview of, 24-58 irnplementing, l 8 r
Sinkin, Richard, II7 deployed rule influencing, 124-5 urban primacy influencing, 25, in Mexico, roo, 101-2, 193,
sisal, 39 geography and, 27-45 32-45, 235-46 195-200
situado (subsidy), 90, 187n25 ideas brought into, 252-5 state-indigenous relations, 85, 8 5n21 after nitrate boom, 186-92
Skocpol, Theda, 220 size facilitating, 29 state-level variation of education, of in Peru, 100, 102-3, 180
Skuban, William E., 2rn19 in Uruguay, 239 Mexico, 147-56 during post-independence
Slater, Dan, 7, 17, 18, 11onr9, 255, state extractive capacity. See extractive stationary bandits, 4n6 crisis, 100-3
255n8,258,26rnr3 capacity of states statist vision of development, 26 revolts and, 183-4, 183n20
Snyder, Richard, 3 w6 state failure, 21n20 status-based authority, 64-5 state agents increasing, 191
social conditions, educational state leaders, 234nr, 252-5, subdelegate, 83-4 taxes, 160-2, 161, 169. See a/so
development influenced by, 125-6 255n8,261m3 subsidy. See situado (subsidy) Bourbon Reforms; direct taxes;
Sokoloff, Kenneth, 138n12, 139, in Chile, 6, 124-5, 139-40 Sucre, Bolivia, 240 excise tax; head tax; real estate tax
14on14,r4on15,151,15rn22, in Colombia, 124 surveying of vacant land, Taylor, Lewis, 76m7
156, 156n25 cost structure influencing, 21 197-9, 198n37 teachers, 130-1, 14I
Sonora,Mexico,148,153-5, 156 delegated rule chosen by, 87-8, ro8 Sweden, 21-2, 257 technical expertise, 84-6
South Korea, 88-9 deployed rule chosen by, switchmen, ideas as, 2 54 Tenenbaum, Barbara, 101
Southeast Asia, 27 87-8, 108-9 terrain, 30-2
Spain, 85n22, 95, 96, 109, 209n6 elites' coalitions with, 261-2 Talca, Chile, r ro territorial administration, 63n5, 84
Spanish America, 82-3, 88. See a/so elites excluded by, 22 Tamaulipas, Mexico, 130 Texas, independence declared by, 105
Bourbon Reforms geography influencing, 25-7 Tanck Estrada, Dorothy, 99 Texas war, ror, 105
306 Index Index

textbooks, 131, 131n7, 132-3, 146 in Peru, 38, 40-1 coercive capacity influenced by, 202 World Development Indicators, 1rnr3
textiles, 44 regional economies in Colombia, 52-3, 5 5 World War I, 191-2
Thies, Cameron G., 18, 206n3 accompanying, 34 as foundational, 94-6 Wright, Thomas C., 188n29
Thomson, Ian, 22 5 state-building efforts emergence against French, 114
Thorp, Rosemary, nn13, 76n16 influenced by, 20, 25, forindependence,94-6 Yaqui, 154-5, 218-19
threats, 18, 203, 212, 215n11, 254, 32-45, 235-46 ofMexico,101,105,249 Yeager, Gertrude M., 14on15
255. See also Bourbon Reforms; in Uruguay, 239 Peru and, 18, 52, 209-11 Young, Crawford, 89
perceived threat ofVenezuela, 243-4 state and, 204-6, 257-8 Yucatán, 39, 105, 105n15, 220
Thurner, Mark, 75n15, n4-15, urbanization, in Mexico, 151 weapons, in Colombia, 213 Yucatán Caste War, 49
183n20, 183n22 Uruguay, 1-2, 239 Weber, Eugen, 19n18
Tilly, Charles, ro, 1on9, 19n18, Weber, Max, 254 Zeitlin, Maurice, 74
59-60,256,256n10,257,258 vacant land, surveying, 197-9 World Bank Governance Indicators, Ziblatt, Daniel, 10n9
timbre, 171-2, 197 vaccinations, 1, 2, 2n3, 11n13 9, 13nr5 Zipaquirá, Colombia, 178
tin mining, 240-1 Valencia Tovar, Alvaro, 212
tithe. See diezmo (tithe) Valparaíso, Chile, 3 I, 3 8, 39
tobacco,45,90,93n6,100,101, 168 Vanderwood, Paul, 220
trade,34n10,42n15 Vatican, I 3 6
traditional authority, n6-20 Vaughan, Mary Kay, 99, 130
transport, in Colombia, 55 Veliz, Claudia, 63fi4
Transport Law, 43 Venezuela, 2, 42n16, 243-4, 259
tribute, 8 5n21 Veracruz, Mexico, 39, 50, 101
tribute collectors, 7 5n15 violence, in Chile, 109-13
troops, of Spain, 96 La Violencia, Colombia, 249
Tupac Amarú revolt, 91, 92, visitadores, 196
92n4, 114 voluntary enlistment, 224-7
Tutino,John, 105n15 volunteers, 225
vom Hau, Matthias, 9n8, 59n1
Uchuraccay, Peru, 106, 106n16 Voss, Stuart F., 153n23, 154
Uhthoff, Luz María, 171-2, 200 Vu, Tuong, 7
United States (U.S.), 33, 39, 49, 50, 138
colonial rule of, 65n7, 261 Wagner, Gert, 163fi4
Mexico's war with, 215n11, 224 Walker, Charles F., 92, 21rn8
Panama and, 214 war, states and, 204-6, 257-8
unpopulated regions, 3 2n6 War of 1000 Days, 55, 214, 230
uprisings, nr, 183, 183n20, 212-13 War of the Pacific, 71n13, n2,
urban primacy, 33n9, 56-7 141-2, 144, 203, 228-9. See also
in Argentina, 237-9 mobilization capacity
in Bolivia, 240-1 Bolivia's defeat in, 240
in Central America, 24 5-6 desertions in, 222
in Chile, 3 8-9 War of the Supremes, 52-3
in Colombia, 41-6, 4rn12 War to the Death. See Guerra a
definition of, 20, 25, 34 Muerte (War to the Death)
in Ecuador, 241-2 wars, 21-2. See also civil wars;
elites influenced by, 26 mobilization capacity
measurement of, 34-7 army size influenced by, 206,
in Mexico, 38, 39-40, 41 206n1,206n2
in Paraguay, 242-3 Chile and, 18, 52

You might also like