You are on page 1of 7

Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling

The impact of pre-IPO performance pressure on research and development


investments of an IPO firm: Evidence from China☆
Mingshan Zhou a, Dacheng Xiao b, Kam C. Chan c, d, *, Hung-Gay Fung e
a
Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu, China
b
China Securities Co. Ltd, China
c
Fuzhou University of International Studies and Trade, Fuzhou, China
d
Gordon Ford College of Business, Western Kentucky University, Bowling Green, KY 42101, USA
e
College of Business Administration, University of Missouri-St. Louis, St. Louis, MO 63121, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL code: We derive a simple model to show that pre-IPO performance pressure has a negative impact on an IPO applicant's
G0 research and development investments. The findings from the Chinese IPOs in the growth enterprise market
Keywords: (GEM) are consistent with the model's predictions. Further analysis suggests that when the time to listing is
IPO shorter, the adverse impact of performance pressure on R&D investments is stronger. While the objective of the
Performance pressure GEM is to encourage innovative firms to raise new capital via IPOs to enhance their innovations in the future, the
Time to listing
cutting of R&D investments to enhance the probability of receiving IPO approval defeats the purpose. Our
Growth and enterprise market
findings suggest that it may be useful for a regulatory authority to consider multi-dimensional criteria in IPO
approvals for GEMs instead of heavily relying on the pre-IPO performance to sustain a healthy IPO market and
innovation activities of a country.

1. Introduction window-dress firms' performance and smooth their IPO applications. In


addition to earnings management, other potential manipulations by IPO
An initial public offering (IPO) is a desired goal and important firms in the pre-IPO process are underexplored in the literature.
milestone for a private firm to raise external capital for future expansions For young firms that aim to go public on the GEM, managing research
and operations. Capital formation by IPOs, particularly for firms on the and development (R&D) investments is even more convenient and crit-
growth enterprise market (GEM), which primarily promotes advanced ical than other items compared to listing in a main board. Firms on the
technology and innovations, would likely create more firm innovations GEM are generally smaller and younger and heavily rely on innovations
and spillovers, leading to higher economic growth of a country (Mas-Tur that are implicit in the policy objectives of the GEM than those on a main
et al., 2015; Ferreira et al., 2017; Bournakis et al., 2018). board. R&D investments play a crucial role in the future success of young
The quest for an IPO implies that a firm is under pressure to meet or firms post-IPOs (Guo and Zhou, 2016). Yet, few studies examine how the
exceed the listing requirements for regulatory approval, which may have performance pressure (i.e., pressure arising from the need to perform) in
unintended consequences as there are limited quotas imposed in the IPO pre-IPOs affects their R&D investments.
listing. Firms often take actions to fulfill the listing requirements by The objective of this paper is to examine the impact of the pre-IPO
managing their earnings to make the firms look good. Aharony et al. performance pressure on a firm's R&D investments. On one hand, an
(1993) document widespread earnings management among IPO firms in IPO firm, due to performance pressure, may choose to reduce its R&D
their pre-IPOs to meet specific earnings requirements. These authors investments to boost its short-term earnings in pre-IPO to increase its
attribute the findings to managers' opportunistic behaviors to chance to receive regulatory approval. However, a low R&D investment


We acknowledge the helpful comments from two anonymous reviewers and the editor (Professor Mallick). Zhou acknowledges the financial support from the
National Science Foundation of China (No. 71572151). The usual caveats apply.
* Corresponding author. Fuzhou University of International Studies and Trade, Fuzhou, China.
E-mail addresses: zhoumingshan@swufe.edu.cn (M. Zhou), xiaodacheng@csc.com.cn (D. Xiao), Johnny.chan@wku.edu (K.C. Chan), fungh@msx.umsl.edu
(H.-G. Fung).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.09.013
Received 25 April 2018; Received in revised form 1 August 2018; Accepted 9 September 2018
Available online 10 September 2018
0264-9993/© 2018 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

level threatens the firm's post-IPO performance or even survival in the 2. Background and literature review
long-term (Guo and Zhou, 2016). We expect the threats in the post-IPO
performance will be even stronger for firms on the GEM. Therefore, it is 2.1. Background
an interesting research question whether an IPO firm chooses to cut
R&D investments in pre-IPO or keeps the R&D investments intact for a Recognizing the need for innovation to enhance its economic devel-
better performance in post-IPO. We focus on the R&D investments of a opment, the Chinese government began to consider establishing a GEM in
firm because they are a critical inputs for innovation, which play a 1999. The objective of a GEM is to encourage young and innovative firms
critical role in the success of the firm post-IPO and to the economy to go public in raising new capital for further development. After 10 years
(Ferreira et al., 2017; Mas-Tur et al., 2015; Fleming and Sorenson, of evaluation, the Chinese GEM was officially launched in 2009 in the
2004). Shenzhen Stock Exchange, and it is officially called ChiNext.1 Initially,
We use a sample of Chinese IPOs on the GEM in our examination. there were 28 firms listed in the Chinese GEM in 2009, which rose to 602
China provides a good environment for our study. Since the launching of firms in the beginning of 2017. In terms of the funds raised, the funds rose
its stock markets in the early 1990s, China has had a large volume of from approximately RMB 155 billion in 2009 to approximately RMB 5.3
IPOs to enhance capital formation. In particular, China encourages trillion in early 2017. To maintain an orderly market, the China Securities
young and innovative firms to list on the GEM in recent years. These Regulatory Commission (CSRC), the watch dog of the securities market, is
young firms are acutely confronted with the decision of cutting their charged with the approval of IPO applications. While there are several
R&D investments due to the pre-IPO performance pressure or to listing criteria in the Chinese GEM market,2 CSRC primarily uses pre-IPO
continue their R&D investments for better post-IPO prospects. The firms' earnings as the most important criterion in making approval de-
analysis enables us to better understand how young and innovative firms cisions. According to the “the Measures on the Administration of Initial
make tough decisions on their R&D investments during the IPO appli- Public Offerings and Listings of Shares on the ChiNext” in 2015, an IPO
cation process. applicant needs to have the following: (1) a minimum of positive earnings
Using a simple theoretical model of IPOs on the GEM and empirical in the two most recent years with cumulative earnings of at least RMB10
testing of the model predictions with data from 2010 to 2016, we offer million or (2) RMB 50 million positive earnings in the most recent year.
three findings. First, our model suggests that IPO firms tend to cut R&D In reality, just meeting the minimum earnings requirement does not
investments to window dress their probability to receive IPO approval suffice for regulatory IPO approval. For instance, in 2016, among all of
instead of maintaining R&D investments for future success. We note that the new IPO firms approved on the GEM, the lowest earnings level was
our model does not have country-specific elements. Thus, the theoretical approximately RMB 46 million by Hangzhou Anysoft IT Co. Ltd (ticker
predictions apply to all markets, not only the Chinese market. no. 300571), which was four and a half times the minimum earnings
Second, after accounting for several control factors, we document requirement (RMB 10 million). Hence, it would not be a surprise that IPO
that, consistent with our model's prediction, the pre-IPO performance applicants manipulate their earnings to boost their chance of IPO
pressure (or moving the IPO listing requirement higher as an alternative approval, especially when the published minimum earnings requirement
way of raising the pre-IPO performance pressure) has an adverse impact is not indicative. Several studies, such as Aharony et al. (1993) and Teoh
on R&D investments. et al. (1998), confirm the widespread earnings manipulation phenome-
Third, we find that when the time to listing is shorter, the adverse non in pre-IPOs. Engaging in earnings management is not without limits
impact of the performance pressure on R&D investments is stronger. as excessive earnings management raises a red-flag that will hurt a firm's
Thus, while the objective of the GEM is to encourage innovative firms to chance of IPO approval. Thus, a reasonable approach for pre-IPO firms is
raise new capital via IPOs to enhance their innovations in the future, to cut their real expenses to boost earnings. Among all expenses, R&D
cutting of R&D investments to enhance the probability of receiving IPO investments, which are a discretionary item, can immediately reduce
approval defeats the purpose. earnings. Thus, IPO firms have a strong temptation to cut R&D in-
Our study contributes to the literature in two ways. First, we provide a vestments to boost current earnings.
theoretical model to predict the adverse impact of the pre-IPO perfor-
mance pressure on R&D investments. Our empirical results confirm the
model's prediction. Thus, our study enriches our understanding on how 2.2. Literature review
pre-IPO operations, such as R&D investments, are affected by the IPO
approval requirements. To the best of our knowledge, our study is the 2.2.1. IPO-earnings management
first to study how an IPO firm manipulates its operations (R&D in- To gain regulatory IPO approval, firms can use strategic assets to
vestments) pre-IPO beyond earnings management. We also show that avoid uncertainty and conflicts to exploit market imperfections to ach-
when an IPO firm has a shorter time to the listing date, the adverse ieve the desired results (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993). When firms go
impact of the performance pressure on R&D investments is magnified. public to raise external capital, they need to satisfy the listing re-
Second, we show that pre-IPO firms on the GEM choose to reduce quirements, which may vary across exchanges and countries. As a result,
R&D investments to window dress their performance. R&D investments these IPO firms will take certain actions that appear to fulfill the listing
are key to these high-tech firms succeeding in the long run. Cutting requirement of earnings by manipulating their accounting information.
R&D investments implies a loss in the competitiveness of these firms. Naturally, IPO firms will likely manipulate their earnings in the periods
Thus, the “do-anything” strategy to enhance IPO firms' probability to prior to taking their firms public. Earnings management is expected to be
receive approval may not help these young IPO firms in their post-IPO less severe if there is better monitoring (Aharony et al., 1993) and these
performance and long-term survival (Guo and Zhou, 2016). While our firms are concerned with a subsequent poor long-term earnings perfor-
study uses Chinese data, our theoretical model and empirical findings mance. Earnings management by IPO firms will also negatively affect the
are applicable to other markets, especially those with GEMs. As to the
policy implication, it may be useful for a regulatory authority to 1
consider multi-dimensional criteria in IPO approvals for GEMs instead For convenience and consistency with the literature, we continue to call it
GEM in this paper.
of heavily relying on the pre-IPO performance to sustain a healthy IPO 2
Some additional listing requirements include the following: (1) A minimum
market and innovation activities of a country. A multi-dimensional
of RMB 20 million in total assets; (2) after the IPO, the total share capital must
criteria approach for IPO regulatory approvals can mitigate the be at least RMB 30 million; and (3) a minimum of three years of operations.
opportunistic behaviors of cutting R&D investments in the IPO appli- There are also other criteria, such as operations, personnel, accounting, and
cations and provide for the healthy economic development of an company organization. For more details, see http://www.szse.cn/main/en/
economy. ListingatSZSE/ListingRequirements/ (accessed February 2018).

41
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

sentiment of institutional investors toward subscriptions of the IPO, their pressure on R&D investments. The model has five assumptions.
bid prices, and final offer prices; therefore, institutional investors keenly A1: The IPO firm's shareholders are homogenous in their utility
recognize earnings management by IPO issuing firms, thus resulting in a functions. Without the loss of generality, the initial shareholders have a
lower offer price (Gao et al., 2017). common quadratic utility function based on the inputs that are related to
the probability of receiving IPO approval (P) and the future performance
2.2.2. IPO R&D investments and their implications (F) of the firm. The utility functions from the probability of IPO approval
R&D investments are expensive and are not mandatory. Firms and future performance are additive. The utilities are positively corre-
manipulate R&D investments to achieve different goals. We would expect lated with the inputs related to the probability of receiving approval and
that CEOs would manage costly R&D investments to achieve a better future performance. That is,
short-term performance that can potentially improve their compensation,
which in turn, is linked to firm performance (Cheng, 2004; Dechow and U ¼ UðPÞ þ UðFÞ (1)
Sloan, 1991). Reductions in R&D investments clearly reflect cost-benefit
where U is the utility of the initial shareholders, U(P) ¼ -P2 þ βP;
tradeoffs to a CEO, who acts as an agent and demands better compen-
0 P < β/2, and U(f) ¼ -F2 þ βF; 0 F < β/2; and β > 0.
sation, and the shareholders of the firm, who want a higher market value
A2: The probability of receiving approval is positively correlated with
of the firm (Dechow and Sloan, 1991). If R&D investments can be
the difference between an IPO firm's after-taxed earnings (I) and the
manipulated to boost the short-term earnings performance, the impli-
regulatory authority's minimum IPO required earnings (M). That is, if
cation is whether IPO firms indeed boost earnings to satisfy the
(I  M) is high, the firm has a higher probability of receiving IPO
short-term earnings target requirement of the IPO application.
approval. To factor in the impact of R&D investments (R), we define EBR
It seems clear that R&D investments are an important input for
as the earnings after interest and taxes without R. We consider the fact
innovativeness that maintains a firm's market competitiveness (Greve,
that many countries, such as China, provide tax incentives to firms for
2003). Thus, it is expected that the noted changes in R&D investments
R&D investments. Without a loss of generality, we assume that R&D
have severe adverse consequences on the firm, in particular, and on the
investments are fully tax deductible.3 The after-tax earnings, I, can be
economy, in general. At the firm level, R&D investments will likely lead
expressed as follows:
to an improved operating performance, followed by improved stock
prices or returns in the long-run (Eberhart et al., 2004; Chan et al., 2001). I ¼ EBR  ð1  τÞ*R (2)
Particularly, Guo and Zhou (2016) demonstrate that the innovation
capability is critical to contemporaneous stock performance and future where τ is the corporate income tax rate. Upon simplification, we have
firm survival. The R&D investment intensity reduces IPO underpricing I ¼ EBR  R þ τ*R, where τ*R is the present value of the tax-shield on
and improves the long-term performance of IPO firms because in- R&D investments.
novations would reduce information asymmetry to investors (Heeley To simplify the model, we assume the inputs related to the probability
et al., 2007; Guo et al., 2006). Addessi et al. (2014) derive a model function of receiving IPO approval, P, is given as follows:
showing that R&D and innovation can enhance labor productivity.
Nemlioglu and Mallick (2017) document that better-managed firms P¼MI (3)
enhance the impact of innovation on firm performance.
That is, a large difference in (M  I) means a high performance
At the macroeconomic level, increases in R&D investments would
pressure for the firm to receive IPO approval, or vice versa.
likely provide greater innovations in a country and thus trigger higher
A3: The future performance (F) of the firm is a positive and linear
economic growth (Ferreira et al., 2017; Mas-Tur et al., 2015; Fleming and
function of R (research and development investments), thus implying
Sorenson, 2004) and improved total factor productivity (Bournakis and
that R provides long-term benefits to the firm in terms of profitability and
Mallick, 2018). Improved economic growth will certainly increase the
competitive advantages. That is,
employment opportunities and living standards of the working class.
The results of the R&D investment literature have particularly F ¼ q*R; q > 0: (4)
important implications for high-tech IPO firms that face performance
pressure. As R&D investments are costly, they will reduce current earn- A4: EBR is exogenous to the model.
ings performance. Therefore, imposing more stringent regulations, such A5: The IPO firm's initial shareholders maximize their utility.
as raising the IPO listing requirements, clearly affect firm behaviors and Based on five assumptions of the model, we obtain the following two
the market (Ma et al., 2010) and motivates firms to manage R&D in- propositions:
vestments during the IPO application process. However, there is limited Proposition 1. An IPO firm cuts R&D investments when facing perfor-
research on R&D investments for IPO firms. mance pressure pre-IPO, and
Jeon and Kim (2011) show that an IPO firm's R&D investments exert
positive effects on firm value, and in general, R&D investments and Proposition 2. An IPO firm cuts R&D investments when the regulatory
capitalizing R&D expenses positively affect firm values in the Korean authority raises the listing requirement with respect to performance.
stock market. Proof. See Appendix A.
Overall, our paper is the first to examine the impact of the IPO
application process on R&D investments. Our results shed light on the We can test the first proposition by examining the impact of perfor-
question of whether an IPO firm cuts R&D investments to boost earnings mance pressure in the pre-IPO period on the firm's R&D investments. In
listing requirements. The decision to cut R&D investments would illus- the second proposition, the CSRC has not officially raised the listing
trate an interesting tradeoff between successful IPO approval and losing performance requirement since the establishment of the GEM in 2009.
the firm's market value and competitiveness. Moreover, this action clearly Hence, it cannot be directly tested and can only be indirectly inferred. All
contradicts the intended goal of the government policy for the high-tech else being equal, raising the listing performance requirement is only an
firms listed on the GEM and is thus worthy of a closer examination. alternative way of raising the performance pressure on an IPO firm pre-
IPO. If Proposition 1 is empirically valid, Proposition 2 is also valid. Using
3. The model a general model without the restrictive assumptions of the quadratic

3.1. Base model


3
The Chinese government allows for 150% tax deductions of R&D in-
We propose a simple model to show the impact of performance vestments. Other countries may have similar arrangements.

42
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

utility function, we obtain the same two propositions, which can be when PP is small (i.e., a large negative number), it means that the EBR of
tested empirically. See Appendix B for the details. a firm is large. Thus, the IPO applicant will face a lower performance
pressure.
3.2. Extensions The control variables include the following: firm size (SIZE), return on
assets (ROA), financial leverage (LEV), operating cash flows to total
In addition to the performance pressure, we contend that the time to revenue (OCF), net profit margin (NPM), and overseas revenue to total
listing (TTL) moderates the performance pressure on R&D investments. revenue ratio (OB). The detail definitions of all of the variables are pre-
Proposition 1 in the model does not incorporate the impact of TTL. Based sented in Table 1.
on intuition, with all else being equal, when TTL is small, the IPO firm has
less time and room to maneuver its performance in preparation for its IPO 5. Results and discussions
application. Thus, the pressure to cut R&D investments is stronger when
TTL is shorter. We consider TTL in our additional analyses when exam- 5.1. Summary statistics
ining the validity of our model.
We present the summary statistics in Table 2. For R, the mean is
4. Data and methods 5.124, thus suggesting that a typical IPO firm has 5.124% of R&D in-
vestments relative to its total assets in all firm-years. In terms of perfor-
4.1. Data mance pressure, the average of PP is 2.321, thus suggesting that, on
average, an IPO firm is 232.1% above the implicit minimum listing
The GEM began trading in 2009. With the need to have pre-IPO data, requirement. To provide graphical evidence, we plot the IPO firms'
we focus on IPOs from 2010 to 2016. China suspended its IPO applica- average R and PP in t-4 to t-1 (where t is the IPO year) in Fig. 1. The
tions in November 2012 and reopened them in January 2014. Hence, average R monotonically decreases from 5.6% in t-4 to 4.78% in t-1. For
those listed in early 2014 were approved in 2012. Thus, we use the the average PP, it exhibits a U-shape with a drop from t-4 to t-3, but
official CSRC IPO approval date, not the actual listing date, as our gradually reverses back the same level in t-1. Despite that PP does not
reference date. The IPO application takes time, and thus, some IPO ap- show monotonic decreases, it is higher when the firm is closer to the IPO
plicants have more pre-IPO financial statements available than others. year. The graphical evidence provides preliminary evidence that a pre-
Therefore, we have an unbalanced panel of data. We have 453 IPOs in the IPO firm cuts R&D investments and that the performance pressure is
GEM. After deleting some firm-years with missing information in R&D higher when it is closer to the IPO year.
investments or control variables, our final sample has 1026 firm-years in
pre-IPOs. 5.2. Base results

4.2. Method We present the regression results for the base model of Eq. (5), as
shown in column (1) of Table 3. The coefficient of the PP is 0.099, and it
We use a multiple regression model to examine our two propositions. is significant at the 1% level, suggesting that when a firm faces a high
The base model is as follows: performance pressure, it cuts its R&D investments. The coefficient of the
PP is also economically significant. When PP increases by one standard
Ri;t ¼ β0 þ β1 *PPi;t þ Σβj CONTROLi;t þ εi;t (5) deviation (5.582), R will decrease by 0.145 standard deviation. The re-
sults are consistent with Proposition 1. The control variables, if signifi-
where R is the R&D investments, PP is the performance pressure, CON- cant, carry the expected signs. For instance, the coefficients of SIZE and
TROL is a set of control variables, and ε is a random error term. To ac- NPM are negative, thus indicating that when a firm is large or when the
count for firm size, we normalize R by total assets. We calculate PP as firm keeps its net profit margin high, its R&D investments are lower. By
follows: contrast, when a firm has a high profitability (a high ROA), it can afford
0  0 to bear more R&D investments.
PP ¼ M  EBR =M (6)

5.3. Additional results: impact of the time to the IPO listing date
EBR ¼ I þ ð1  1:5τÞ*R (7)
To examine the moderating role of the time to the IPO listing date
where M0 is the implicit minimum listing requirement and EBR is the
(TTL), we modify Eq. (5) to factor in these variables as follows:
after interest and taxes but before R&D investments earnings. Given that
all IPO firms' performances exceed the official minimum (M), it is not
useful to use the official M to calculate performance pressure. Hence, we Table 1
use M0 instead of M. While M0 is not directly observable, we proxy M0 as Variable definitions. Table 1 provides the definitions of the major variables.
the 10th percentile of the average of the previous three years earnings4
Variable Meaning Definitions
for all of the successfully listed firms on the GEM in the current and
previous years.5 For instance, in 2016, we consider all of the approved R R&D investments The ratio of R&D investments to total assets
R2 Alternative R&D The ratio of R&D investments to total sales
IPO firms in 2015 and 2016 and examine the average of their previous investments
three years of earnings. Then, we rank them from top to bottom and take PP Performance PP ¼ (M0  EBR)/M0 where EBR ¼ I þ (1-1.5τ)
the 10th percentile firm's average three-year earnings as M0 . It is expected pressure *R, M0 is the implicit minimum listing
that M0 is higher than the legal minimum listing requirement (M). requirement, τ is the corporate tax rate, and EBR
is the after tax earnings before R&D investments.
We modify Equations (2)–(7) to reflect the Chinese tax policy of
TTL Time to IPO listing Takes a value of 1 if the time is t-1 (t is the IPO
allowing firms to deduct 150% of R&D investments. With a given M0 , year) and zero otherwise
SIZE Firm size Natural logarithm of total assets
ROA Returns on assets Net earnings to total assets ratio
4
We use three years because the CSRC mandated IPO firms to disclose at least LEV Financial leverage Total liabilities to total assets ratio
three years of financial data in their pre-IPOs. OCF Operating cash flow Operating cash flow to total assets ratio
5 NPM Net profit margin Net earnings to total revenue ratio
The conclusions do not change if we use the lower 5th, 15th, or 20th
OB Overseas revenue Overseas revenue to total revenue ratio
percentiles.

43
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

Table 2 Table 3
Summary statistics. Table 2 presents the summary statistics of the major vari- The impact of performance pressure and time to listing on R&D in-
ables. The definitions are provided in Table 1. vestments. Table 3 presents the findings on the impacts of performance pressure
Unit N Mean Median Std dev.
(PP) and time to listing (TTL) on R&D investments (dependent variable). The
definitions are provided in Table 1. The t statistics are in parentheses. ***, **, and
R Percent 1026 5.124 4.044 3.802 * indicate 1%, 5%, and 10% significance, respectively.
R2 Percent 1026 6.227 4.916 4.216
PP Number 1026 2.321 1.456 5.582 (1) (2) (3)
TTL Indicator variable (1, 0) 1026 0.357 0.000 0.479 R R R
SIZE Natural logarithm of yuan 1026 19.625 19.584 0.649
ROA Percent 1026 18.315 15.842 10.501 PP 0.099*** 0.098*** 0.087***
LEV Percent 1026 38.572 37.768 15.765 (-2.710) (-2.660) (-2.838)
OCF Number 1026 0.125 0.114 0.108 SIZE 1.724*** 1.703*** 1.804***
NPM Number 1026 0.200 0.183 0.099 (-4.428) (-4.187) (-4.413)
OB Number 1026 0.133 0.007 0.225 ROA 0.145*** 0.145*** 0.140***
(5.645) (5.628) (5.490)
LEV 0.045*** 0.045*** 0.045***
(-4.711) (-4.659) (-4.646)
Ri; t ¼ δ0 þ δ1 *PPi;t þ δ2 *ðPPi;t *TTLi;t Þ þ δ3 *TTLi;t þ Σδj CONTROLi;t þ φi;t OCF 2.235 2.231 2.343
(8) (1.452) (1.452) (1.523)
NPM 13.409*** 13.422*** 13.273***
(-6.762) (-6.762) (-6.766)
where TTL is a (1, 0) indicator variable with a value of 1 if the IPO firm is
OB 0.093 0.088 0.084
within 1-year of the IPO approval date and zero otherwise. We expect δ1 (0.162) (0.154) (0.146)
to be negative and significant per Proposition 1. For δ2, we expect it to be TTL 0.077 0.301
negative and significant for PP*TTL. That is, conditional on the perfor- (-0.300) (-1.148)
mance pressure, when an IPO firm faces a tight time constraint, it cuts PP*TTL 0.095*
(-1.939)
more R&D investments. We expect that δ3 is either insignificant or Year Yes Yes Yes
negatively significant. Intercept 39.813*** 39.471*** 41.533***
For robustness, we run an additional Eq. (8) without PPi,t*TTLi,t. The (5.169) (4.951) (5.170)
results are presented in columns (2) and (3) of Table 3. As expected, the N 1026 1026 1026
R2 0.292 0.292 0.295
coefficients of PP in columns (2) and (3) are consistently positive and
significant at the 1% level, thus confirming the results in column (1).
More importantly, the coefficient of PP*TTL (the interaction term) is
negative and significant at the 10% level in column (3), thus suggesting investments.
that the marginal impact of having the pre-IPO firm in t-1 magnifies the
negative impact of PP in the pre-IPO on R&D investments. The co- 5.4. Robustness checks
efficients of TTL in columns (2) and (3) are not significant, thus indi-
cating that the adverse impact of TTL on the R&D investments is For the robustness of the base results and the moderating findings, we
conditional on PP. That is, an IPO firm only encountering a tight time use alternative measures of R&D investments and performance pressure.
window in its pre-IPO does not necessarily cut its R&D investments. If an Specifically, we use R2, which is a firm's R&D investments divided by its
IPO firm faces performance pressure and it is close to the approval time, total sales.
then the negative impact of TTL adds to the negative impact on R&D Table 4 presents the robustness checks results in columns (1) to (3).

Fig. 1. R&D investments (R) and performance pressure (PP) in the pre-IPO.

44
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

Table 4 1% level. In column (3), the coefficient of PP*TTL is significant at the 5%


Robustness checks: Alternative measures of research and development level with the expected sign. Thus, using alternative measures of R&D
expense. Table 4 presents the findings on the impacts of performance pressure investments does not qualitatively change our earlier findings presented
(PP) and time to listing (TTL) on R&D investment. The definitions are provided in in Table 3.
Table 1. The t statistics are in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate 1%, 5%, and
10% significance, respectively.
6. Summary
(1) (2) (3)

R2 R2 R2 IPOs are critical for firms, especially young and innovation ones, to
PP 0.117*** 0.117*** 0.103***
raise capital. The capital formation in IPOs contributes to the economic
(-2.808) (-2.784) (-3.023) development of an economy. The evolution of the stock market and ac-
SIZE 1.906*** 1.907*** 2.035*** celeration of the IPO market have propelled the fast economic growth of
(-4.455) (-4.296) (-4.563) China in recent years. To accommodate young and innovative firms,
ROA 0.057** 0.057** 0.064**
China introduced a GEM in 2009. Our study shows that, in theory and
(-2.209) (-2.198) (-2.381)
LEV 0.041*** 0.041*** 0.040*** evidence, the listing requirements lead to an unintended consequence of
(-3.558) (-3.517) (-3.504) lower R&D investments for IPO applicants in the Chinese GEM. The
OCF 1.506 1.506 1.647 adverse impact on R&D investments is magnified when the time to IPO
(0.931) (0.931) (1.014) application is shorter and conditional on the performance pressure. Our
NPM 10.458*** 10.459*** 10.647***
(4.241) (4.236) (4.302)
findings show that the cutting of R&D investments defeats the purpose of
OB 0.690 0.690 0.696 a GEM. Therefore, for government regulations (in the IPO approval) in
(-1.270) (-1.270) (-1.282) financial markets, while the policy intent is to protect investors and
TTL 0.004 0.279 promote economic development, it reduces the competitiveness of the
(0.012) (-0.866)
firms because they want to cut R&D to boost earnings to receive IPO
PP*TTL 0.121**
(-2.303) approval. The cutting of R&D investments hurt firms and the industry in
Year Yes Yes Yes the long run because it lowers the long-term profitability of the firms and
Intercept 43.504*** 43.521*** 46.131*** industry. These firms would not as competitive as they should be, thus
(5.152) (5.010) (5.268) leading to suboptimal resource allocations. Hence, for IPO approval, it
N 1026 1026 1026
would be useful for the regulatory authority to implement a multi-
R2 0.200 0.200 0.204
dimensional criteria approach, which can mitigate the situation of
being overly dependent on earnings and help to develop a healthy IPO
Using R2 as the dependent variable, the coefficient of PP is negative and market and the economic development of a country.
significant at the 1% level in column (1). In addition, in columns (2) to
(3), the coefficients of PP continue to be negative and significant at the

Appendix A. Proof for Propositions 1 and 2

Following assumptions A1 to A5, when we substitute Equations (2)–(4) into Equation (1), we have
 
U ¼  P2 þ βP þ  F 2 þ βF ¼ ½EBR  ðR  τ*RÞ  M2 þ β½EBR  ðR  τ*RÞ  M  ðq*RÞ2 þ βðq*RÞ (A1)

To maximize the utility in Eq. (5), the first order condition for optimum R&D investments (R*) is

2ð1  τÞðEBR  MÞ þ βq  βð1  τÞ


R* ¼ (A2)
2ð1  τÞ2 þ 2q2
To examine the pre-IPO performance pressure and regulatory minimum performance (the level of EBR and M), we obtain the first derivative of R*
with respect to EBR and M as follows:

∂R* ð1  τÞ
¼ >0 (A3)
∂EBR ð1  τÞ2 þ q2

and

∂ R* ð1  τÞ
¼  <0 (A4)
∂M ð1  τÞ2 þ q2
Since (1  τ) > 0 and [(1  τ) þ q2] > 0. Hence, according to Equation (A3), if an IPO firm faces performance pressure, i.e., EBR is dropping pre-IPO,
then the firm will cut its R&D investments, as suggested by Proposition 1. Similarly, according to Equation (8), if the regulatory authority raises the
listing performance (M is rising) pre-IPO, the firm will cut its R&D investments, as proposed by Proposition 2. It is easy to show that the second order
condition is met in Equation (A4). Q.E.D.

Appendix B. A Model with some general assumptions

Let us assume

UðPÞ ¼ f ðPÞ and UðFÞ ¼ gðFÞ (B1)

45
M. Zhou et al. Economic Modelling 78 (2019) 40–46

where P ¼ M  I þ tR, and t ¼ (1  τ); F ¼ qR.


Assumptions:

(1) The first derivatives of f and g with respect to R are positive, thus implying a positive return to R. That is, f0 and g0 > 0.
(2) The second derivative is negative, thus denoting diminishing return of these functions with respect to R. That is, f00 < 0, and g00 < 0.
(3) The first derivative of F with M is negative. It is a reasonable assumption because when a regulator's target earnings requirement is higher, it
reduces the entrepreneur's utility due to lowering the chance of IPO approval.
(4) First derivative of F with respect I is positive, thus implying that higher earnings of the firm generate higher utility for the entrepreneur.

The first order condition to obtain an equilibrium R is to differentiate Eq. (B1). Then, we obtain the equilibrium by setting the first order condition to
zero:
0 0
f tþgq¼0 (B2)
Differentiating Eq. (B2) with respect to I yields the following:

dI dR dR
f 00 ð  1 Þ þ f 00 t 2 þ q2 g00 ¼ 0
dI dI dI
Rearranging the equation yields the following:

dR  
¼ f 00 t 2 f 00 þ q2 g00 > 0 (B3)
dI
Eq. (B3) is positive because f 00 < 0 while f00 and g00 are negative in the denominator of the equation, which is Proposition 1.
To analyze the relationship between equilibrium R and M, we utilize Eq. (B2) again. Differentiating the first order condition with respect to M yields\
0
df dR dR
t þ f 00 t2 : q2 g00 ¼0
dM dM dM
Rearranging the terms yields the following:
 0 
dR df 
¼ t t2 f 00 þ q2 g00 < 0 (B4)
dM dM
As f00 and g00 are both negative while the first derivative of f0 with respect to M is negative as assumed earlier, Eq. (B4) is negative, thus confirming
Proposition 2. Q.E.D.

Appendix C. IPO approval rate in GEM

Appendix C presents the IPO approval rate in the Chinese GEM. China suspended IPOs from November 2012 to December 2013. Hence, we use the
2012 figures for 2013.

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

IPO applications 168 139 117 0 38 114


IPO approvals 143 113 91 0 33 103
IPO rejection rate 14.88% 18.71% 22.22% 22.22% 13.16% 9.65%

References Fleming, L., Sorenson, O., 2004. Science as a map in technological search. Strat. Manag. J.
25, 909–928.
Gao, S., Meng, Q., Chan, K.C., Wu, W., 2017. Earnings management before IPOs: are
Addessi, W., Saltari, E., Tilli, R., 2014. R&D, innovation activity, and the use of external
institutional investors misled? J. Empir. Finance 42, 90–108.
numerical flexibility. Econ. Modell. 36, 612–621.
Greve, H.R., 2003. A behavioral theory of R&D expenditures and innovations: evidence
Aharony, J., Lin, C.J., Loeb, M.T., 1993. Initial public offerings, accounting choices, and
from shipbuilding. Acad. Manag. J. 46, 685–702.
earnings management. Contemp. Account. Res. 10, 61–81.
Guo, R., Zhou, N., 2016. Innovation capability and post-IPO performance. Rev. Quant.
Amit, R., Schoemaker, P.J.H., 1993. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strat.
Finance Account. 46, 335–357.
Manag. J. 14, 33–46.
Guo, R.J., Lev, B., Shi, C., 2006. Explaining the short- and long-term IPO anomalies in the
Bournakis, I., Christopoulos, D., Mallick, S., 2018. Knowledge spillovers and output per
US by R&D. J. Bus. Finance Account. 33, 550–579.
worker: an industry-level analysis for OECD countries. Econ. Inq. 56, 1028–1046.
Heeley, M.B., Matusik, S.F., Jain, N., 2007. Innovation, appropriability, and the
Bournakis, I., Mallick, S., 2018. TFP estimation at firm level: the fiscal aspect of
underpricing of initial public offerings. Acad. Manag. J. 50, 209–225.
productivity convergence in the UK. Econ. Modell. 70, 579–590.
Jeon, S.I., Kim, J.E., 2011. The role of R&D on the valuation of IPO. J. Int. Bus. Res. 10,
Chan, L.K.C., Lakonishok, J., Sougiannis, T., 2001. The stock market valuation of research
39–57.
and development expenditures. J. Finance 56, 2431–2456.
Ma, J., Song, F., Yang, Z., 2010. The dual role of the government: securities market
Cheng, S., 2004. R&D expenditures and CEO compensation. Account. Rev. 79, 305–328.
regulation in China 1980-2007. J. Financ. Regul. Compl. 18, 158–177.
Dechow, P.M., Sloan, R.G., 1991. Executive incentives and the horizon problem: an
Mas-Tur, A., Pinazo, P., Tur-Porcar, A.M., Sanchez-Masferrer, M., 2015. What to avoid to
empirical investigation. J. Account. Econ. 14, 51–89.
succeed as an entrepreneur. J. Bus. Res. 68, 2279–2284.
Eberhart, A.C., Maxwell, W.F., Siddique, A.R., 2004. An examination of long-term
Nemlioglu, I., Mallick, S., 2017. Do managerial practices matter in innovation and firm
abnormal stock returns and operating performance following R&D increases.
performance relations? New evidence from the UK. Eur. Financ. Manag. 23,
J. Finance 59, 623–650.
1016–1061.
Ferreira, J.J., Fayolle, A., Fernandes, C., Raposo, M., 2017. Effects of Schempeterian and
Teoh, S.H., Wong, T.J., Rao, G., 1998. Are accruals during initial public offerings
Kirznerian entrepreneurship on economic growth: panel data evidence. Enterpren.
opportunistic? Rev. Account. Stud. 3, 175–208.
Reg. Dev. 29, 27–50.

46

You might also like