You are on page 1of 13

Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Land Use Policy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/landusepol

Managing urban land markets in Africa: Valuation, performance and


policy implication
Alebel B. Weldesilassie a, *, Genanew B.Worku b, *
a
Ethiopian Policy Studies Institute, Blue Bldg, Near Addis Ababa Stadium, P.O.Box: 2479, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia
b
Department of Economic, Dubai Business School, University of Dubai, P.O.Box: 14143, Dubai, United Arab Emirates

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL Classification: Land management system is an underlying factor for rapid urbanization. The urban land lease policy of Ethiopia
Q24 is considered the most influential policy, where leasing is through auction or negotiation. This study examines its
Q15 implementation using land auction data in Addis Ababa, one of the fastest growing city in Sub Saharan African
R15
Countries. The result suggests a high divergence between land-auction guide and sale prices. The study found
and R52
that the urban land market is not just driven by economic rationale, it is also determined by non-economic
Keywords:
factors. The findings imply that the land market is not only exposed to speculations but also its urban land
Urban land lease policy
Ethiopia (Africa)
acquisition is majorly a secondary market, with no policy-ground.
Urban land policy
Land auction
Land premium
Least-squares estimation

1. Introduction private entities. The constitution allows the state to continue owning
land (as means of production), creating a tradable claim on land - the
Because land holds a unique and pivotal position in the process of ’use right’. Following the ratification of the constitution in 1995, various
economic growth and poverty reduction, the nature of its property right policies and policy instruments were formulated to promote investment
is very crucial. More importantly, the debate on urban land policy and urban development. The urban development policy/strategy(Min­
fundamentally originates whether or not it should be based on the istry of Urban Development and Construction, 2013) and the urban land
principle of private or public ownership. Evidence revealed that urban development and management policy and strategy (Ministry of Urban
land policy is a complex undertaking and not only varies by country but Development and Construction, 2011) are the two key policies that
also that such a policy must involve a large number of policy in­ guide the management of land for investment and urban development in
struments, carefully designed to be mutually supportive (Deininger and Ethiopia. Among the policy instruments, Proclamation 455/2005,
Jin, 2006). This notion has an empirical foundation from the experi­ Proclamation No. 721/2011, and Proclamation No. 818/2014 are the
ences of the countries that adopt private or public ownership of land key institutional arrangements that have direct implications for the use
(Hong and Bourassa, 2003; Deininger, 2003; Deininger and Chamorro, of land for socioeconomic development and promoting private sector
2002). Though there is still the historical debate on whether private or investment in the country. While the former proclamation guides the
public ownership should be the basic principle that guides the land expropriation of land holdings for public purposes and payment of
tenure system in Ethiopia (Benayew, 2015; Desalegn Rahmeto, 2006; compensation, Proclamation No. 721/2011 directs the implementation
Taffese, 2006; Pankhurs, 2006), the 1995 - Ethiopian constitution is a of the provision of lease holding of urban lands, and the later establishes
foundational law for the land tenure system since 1995 (Federal Dem­ the foundation for urban landholding registration. These reforms issue
ocratic Republic of Ethiopia, 1995). Land in Ethiopia is constitutionally the authority to sell land and determine the terms of redevelopment in
state-owned, and the right to use land is separated from its ownership, the nine federal states and two city administrations of the country. The
with ‘use rights’ given to individuals, groups (communal holdings), and land lease regulation stipulates that land is transferred through

* Corresponding authors.
E-mail addresses: alebel.bw@gmail.com (A.B. Weldesilassie), gbekele@ud.ac.ae (G. B.Worku).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2021.105906
Received 22 August 2020; Received in revised form 22 May 2021; Accepted 29 November 2021
0264-8377/© 2021 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

negotiation for industrial investment and auction to other developers. distortions in the land rental market and a price hike.
This regulation was intended to address the lack of transparency and The findings and conclusions from these previous studies are based
improvement in land market competitiveness. on qualitative data, and hence are open to debate as their interpretations
Whether the reforms can help the country to capitalize the oppor­ are often subject to individual judgments. These studies, however, are
tunity from or face the challenges of urbanization1 has been an open vital as they pose essential policy questions that need to be addressed
policy question and a subject of discussion among policymakers, quantitatively. The only exception is the study made by Alebel and
development partners, scholars and the private sector (World Bank, Genanew (2007b), who quantitatively analyzed the land market. How­
2016; Zelalem, 2014; Belachew, 2010; Bacry, 2009; Alebel and Gena­ ever, their study was undertaken before the formulation of the land lease
new, 2007a, 2007b). The effect of such reforms is still a subject of in­ reforms. Besides, all prior studies did not consider the demand side of
terest. On the one hand, there have been substantial improvements in land for investment, which determines the land value. The demand side
big cities of Ethiopia, such as Addis Ababa.2 A decayed ago, Addis Ababa of urban land management is an essential element in promoting in­
was characterized by dilapidated structures, congestion, vestment and enhancing the contribution of cities for economic growth
environmental-related problems, poor urban image, and shortage of (Collier and Venables, 2013). The absence of such consideration is
quality infrastructure and basic services. The City is now in better con­ explicitly reflected in urban areas of the country, as discussed above.
dition than ten years ago. Its development has started to be guided by The implication is that the land lease policy still requires a re-
well-prepared plans and in a well-coordinated manner. Such positive examination of its constraints and opportunities to devise appropriate
changes are due to two important phenomena of the reforms. First, the measures and strategies for action. To this end, unlike previously made
lease policy influences the efficient management of land through its studies, this study analyzed both the supply and demand side of the
effect on the value of the land. As a result, land price has been contin­ urban land lease policy in Ethiopia. Concerning the supply side of land
uously rising in urban areas.3 Second, revenue from land lease has for investment, the paper critically reviews the land lease policy, its
become a significant source of financing for local development in urban institutional arrangement as well as its governance system. Concerning
areas of Ethiopia.4 Peterson (2006) finds that land leasing has become the demand side, the land pricing policy is the primary component for
the single largest source of municipal revenue in the country, ranging understanding the demand side of investment and the determination of
from 21% to 45% of the total revenue and 77–145% of the total capital land price, which is the key component of an appropriate incentive for
spending of the country. balanced and coordinated investment. Consequently, this study quan­
On the other side of the argument, there has been a debate on the titatively analyzes the fundamental importance of the value that in­
shortcomings of the reforms. Peterson (2006) argues that even if reve­ vestors place on land characteristics.
nue from land is becoming an essential source of financing infrastructure The auction method for selling properties has been studied exten­
in developing countries, such a source can introduce a new set of risks sively in the literature (c.f. Allen and Swisher, 2000; Dotzour et al.,
that can profoundly affect fiscal management. The author indicates that 1998; Mayer, 1998; and Lust, 1996).5 However, most of these studies
cities are unable to obtain revenue growth from other sources, which focus on property markets such as housing rather than land markets.
risks their future recurrent budgets from other sources. Besides, relying Thus, our study adds value to the limited literature on urban land market
municipal revenue primarily on land leasing may introduce an unprec­ particularly in urban areas of Sub Saharan African countries. Even if
edented degree of volatility in its own-source of revenues. On a related Gwin et al. (2005) investigated the effect of auction market mechanism
study made by the World Bank, the revenue from land is less than its true on the value of land, they use experimental method. Their study is
value in urban Ethiopia. Moreover, the lease regulation not only restricts different from ours, which uses actual data based on land market price.
the right to transfer use right but also it is not linked with the urban Moreover, despite high rate of urbanization, there is little empirical
development strategy of the country (World Bank, 2016). As a result, the evidence on the land auction market in urban areas of Sub Saharan
reforms give little concern for sustainable expansion possibilities and African (SSA) Countries. As far as our domain is concerned, it is Abdul
only add inefficiencies in land utilization. Firstly, there is a marked gap and Alirat (2009) who examined the determinants of auction premium
between the demand for basic services and the supply of those amenities using data from a first-price sealed bid auction in Nigeria. However,
by the city administration to keep pace with the expectations emanating unlike their study, which focuses on comparison of revenues from
from the scale of change that the City undergone. Secondly, urban land various auction types in Nigeria, this paper focuses on evaluating the
for domestic investment has emerged as a key bottleneck in Ethiopia. As determinants of auction success in Ethiopia. Besides, the studies made
of June 2016, about 6000 local investors are in a waiting list only in the by Amidu et al. (2008) and Aluko (2007) focuses on residential prop­
capital city, requesting land for investment purposes. This does not only erties and auction sale valuations accuracy. Thus, our study not only
discourage private investments (and thereby employment opportu­ adds value to the little empirical evidence on the land auction market in
nities) but also, coupled with the limited supply of land, created urban areas of SSA but also it is an original study in a case where land is
constitutionally state-owned and land developers have only ‘use rights’.
The reminder of the paper is organized as follow. The following
1 section briefly reviews the literature related to this study, focusing on
Though Ethiopia is among the least urbanized country in the world, the
country is one of the most rapidly urbanizing countries in Sub Saharan Africa.
the land lease system in urban Ethiopia. The methodological framework
About 19% of its people (more than 102 million in 2016, World Bank, http: adopted in this study is presented in section three. Section four describes
//www.worldbank.org) currently live in the country’s urban areas, with the data used and presents the empirical results. The final section con­
annual growth rate (1984 –2013) of 4.54% and expected to triple by 2040 (UN, cludes the study.
2012).
2
Addis Ababa is the capital of the Ethiopia and seat of many international
organizations such as AU and UNECA.
3
In Addis Ababa city, for example, this study confirms that real price of land
per M2 increased by 151% between 2013 and 2016.
4
Sale of land or land rights has the advantage of producing revenue quickly
5
and being easier to administer than betterment taxes, land re-adjustment Mayer (1998) compared the returns to auctions and those to negotiated
schemes, or universal property taxation. For example, the study by the World sales using U.S. real estate transaction data. The performance of auction market
Bank revealed that many cities in China have financed half or more of their very for residential real estate in Christchurch, New Zealand has been studied by
high urban infrastructure investment levels directly from land leasing, while Dotzour et al. (1998). Lust (1996) studied the auction market for houses in the
borrowing against the value of land on their balance sheets to finance much of Melbourne (Australia) housing market to test the impact of auction on house
the remainder (Peterson, 2006). prices.

2
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

2. Urban land lease system in Ethiopia auction transfers the land to a third person through a bilateral agree­
ment. Such secondary markets do not have a policy (or regulation). The
2.1. Review of the urban land lease system land acquired through the secondary market is too expensive and un­
regulated, and it is a concern in many ways. Rental cost constitutes a
Ethiopia formulated various proclamations related to urban land use: large part of the firms’ costs, which renders them uncompetitive. Leas­
Proclamation No. 80/1993, which is the first proclamation associated ing from private providers often creates uncertainty as the landlords
with the urban land lease enacted since the 1991 reform, followed by the frequently increase the rental price or unexpectedly break the tenancy
enactment of Proclamation 271/2002 and 721/2011.6 These procla­ agreement. There is also uncertainty about the legality of the lease/rent.
mations have social and economic goals to be achieved through their Price setting is at the discretion of the landlord. Landlords often force the
effective implementation. In these proclamations, appropriate land tenants to pay a down payment for an extended period, which reduces
administration needs to be seen in the lens of sustainable rapid economic the working capital of the tenant/investor. There appears no efficient
growth. In this respect, efficiency and responsiveness to the growing contractual arrangement that binds both the supplier and the customer.
demand for land are key issues in the land market. However, the More importantly, private rental is not an option for many
emphasis is also given to consider equity as a prime motive in the land manufacturing activities that require large tracts of land.
administration. The proclamations aim to realize a robust free-market This study also reveals that the size of the land that is available for
economy and build a transparent and accountable land administration each tender is very small in comparison to the demand. The limited land
system that ensures the rights and obligations of the lessor and the supply, coupled with the discretionary power of government officials to
lessee.7 restrict, tighten or widen access to land, creates a hike in the rental price;
Accordingly, the lease policy states that the right to use urban land thus, it attracts more speculators into the bidding process. The admin­
(through lease) is permitted to realize the common interest and devel­ istration is not able to differentiate the speculators (“flippers”) from the
opment of the people. In this regard, the lease policy is expected to genuine investors (“real land demanders”) with a genuine interest in
address the development challenges8 in urban Ethiopia (Alebel and leasing a land, as opposed to “flippers”. Speculators largely dominate the
Berihu, 2017). According to the World Bank, the fundamental causes of bid process. They tend to increase the bid price, which crowds out the
development problems in urban Ethiopia are land management, gover­ genuine investors. The speculators retain the land for some time and
nance, and municipal finance (World Bank, 2016). The practical resell their use right at even higher prices. This has proven to be
implementation of the regulations is directly related to their key fea­ discouraging to the genuine investors and the productive sectors. Ac­
tures. These features explicitly define (among others) the scope of cording to the World Bank (2016), land allocation is the second most
application, property rights related to transfer, ways of acquiring new area of corruption in Ethiopia following customs services. The most
development land, grace period, lease fee payment modalities, and corrupt activity in the land sector occurs at the implementation stage,
duration of lease period. suggesting that the level of corruption is influenced by how policies and
A critical examination9 of the policy and the institutional arrange­ legislations are formulated, implemented, and enforced. Overall, the
ment of the land acquisition system for investment (Proclamation No above discussions show that corruption, non-transparency, and unfair­
721/2011; Regulation No.14/2004; Regulation No.4/1994; and Regu­ ness have reigned in the system and created a means of exploiting the
lation No.3/1994) reveals that there are at least three main modes are system by a few urban speculators and brokers. The next subsection
practiced to access land for business purposes in urban Ethiopia. These presents the implementation mechanism of the land auction system.
include rent from private sources, leaseholds, and public allotments.
Each of these modes has its advantages and shortcomings. For instance, 2.2. Land auction implementation in urban Ethiopia
the land rental market is characterized by very high rental prices and
uncertain contracts. On the other hand, the main problem with land In Ethiopia, each federal state has the authority to establish an
leasehold arrangement is that the land supplied for bidding is limited; appropriate body that has the power to administer, develop urban land,
hence it is quite competitive and expensive for investors. There are also and advertise lease tender.11 Regional states or City administrations
implementation problems in transferring land to leases. Though public release public land for private developers through allotment or auction
allotment has the advantage of being quite cheap, cities have a limited of land leases. In Addis Ababa city administration, the Land Banking and
amount of land that they can allot. Moreover, the allotment decision Transfer Office is mandated to transfer land through tender or allotment.
often takes a long time (usually up to 2 years) and thus uncertain. The office is responsible for auctioning land for different development
The urban land lease regulation stipulates that the acquisition of activities. It prepares a land lease-bid-offer form,12 which a bidder
urban land is only possible through the land lease market system or should buy, then fill it out and submit it to the office during the tender
negotiation.10 In practice, however, these are not the only land acqui­ period. Plots are released for auction openly at the benchmark (or floor)
sition mechanisms in urban Ethiopia. Land is also acquired through a price set by the government; then, the bidders submit their offer price for
secondary market in which individuals who obtain/lessee land through the particular plot in a closed envelope. There are no restrictions on the

6 11
These proclamations can be cited as the Urban Lands Lease Holding Proc­ Ethiopia is a federal state consisting of nine regional states and two city
lamation No. 80/1993, 271/2002; and 721/2011. They are applicable to all administrations. Each regional state and city has constitutional mandate to
urban centers in Ethiopia with a minor difference for Addis Ababa. administer and prepare regulations for the implementation of the land lease
7
These objectives are expected to be realized through the role of the proc­ policy within their jurisdiction.
12
lamations in enhancing investment (economic growth), improvement in hous­ The form contains four sections in addition to its heading and bid round
ing and infrastructure (equity) through revenue collection (capital number. In the first section, bidders are expected to fill their personal infor­
mobilization), regulated expansion and/or restrict the informal expansion of mation including their full name, residence and nationality. In the second
cities (social objective). section, basic information of the plot is described including area code, location
8
Evidences revealed that the key challenges in urban Ethiopia include, of the plot, area size in square meter, type of plot use, minimum building
among others, lack of affordable and decent houses, unemployment, infra­ requirement, and benchmark price per M2 in Ethiopian Birr, lease payment
structure such as water supply and sanitation, and poor waste management. completion period and lease period. The third section of the form is left for
9
Noted in Alebel and Berihu (2017). bidders to fill (in figure and words) their offer value including price per M2,
10
Given the skyrocketed land prices in the land lease auction market, Ethiopia initial down payment in percent and total lease price of the plot. In the last
uses land as a key instrument and incentive to attract investments by providing section, bidders should indicate whether or not they have attached bid bond
free or subsidized land access. and any other documents such as official delegation.

3
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

eligibility of bidders, and the auctions are open to all interested de­ is 90 years for social, 70 years for the industry, and 60 years for com­
velopers. Each auction site has specific land use parameters to be made merce and other uses. Even if the city administration sets the minimum
public through media and to be posted on the City’s bi-weekly news­ amount of the down payment and includes in the bid announcement,
paper ‘Addis Lisan’. The location (sub-city), type of development, floor bidders should also state the amount of the down payment as this is one
price, lease period, lease payment period, lease grace period, etc. for of the key criteria for the selection of the winner. The regulation states
each auction site are accessible to the bidders. The auction winner will that the amount of the down payment may not be less than 10% of the
be decided based on the highest price (per M2) offered and the per­ total lease amount of the plot. The lease period may be renewed upon
centage of the down payment, where the former accounts 80% of the expiry on the bases of the prevailing benchmark lease price and other
total score, and the latter accounts for 20% of the overall rating. requirements. Once the bidder wins, [s]he is expected to pay a down
Once the winner is announced, the office concludes the lease con­ payment not less than 5% of the total amount, the remaining balance to
tract with the winner, hands over the land, and collects the lease pay­ be paid during the lease payment period, which takes into consideration
ment based on the lease contract. Developers’ valuations of lands in the the payback period of the investment. The balance is to be paid in equal
City, therefore, are based on the same land-use parameters and under­ annual installments during the payment term with the prevailing in­
lying market conditions. terest on loan offered by the commercial bank of Ethiopia with penalty
Ideally, many factors contribute to the value of a plot of land. fee against defaulting to pay the annual payment. From the period 2013/
Physical attributes of the plot are one of the key factors. These attributes 14 to 2016/17, the city administration supplied 3038 plots in 18 rounds
include location, plot size, topography, access to basic social services/ of land auctions over the ten sub-cities of the City. Of these, 67% of the
infrastructures, and environmental features such as the absence of bad plots are sold at the time they were tendered, and the rest could not be
smells, noise, etc. The regulation that governs land management and leased out at the time when they are first tendered.14
administration, such as the type and amount of taxation, zoning and
building laws, and planning and restrictions, is also a key determinant of 3. Methodological framework
land value. The social factors include population growth/decline,
changes in family sizes, age, attitudes toward law and order, and pres­ 3.1. Data source and type
tige and education levels. The economic forces include value and income
levels, growth and new construction, and vacancy or availability of land. The data set used in this study consists of land transactions made
It is the influences of these forces, expressed independently and in through auctions in Addis Ababa city over the period 2013/14–2016/
relationship to one another that contributes to the valuation of land. 17. In this period, the city administration supplied more than 3000 plots
Given this as a general framework, the city administration sets floor of land in 18 bid-rounds (bid-round five to twenty-four, with no data
prices based on the development condition of the specific site. This available for bid-round nine and ten) of land auctions.15 While the city
condition gives weights to the topography of the site, its existing and administration provides basic information about the plots available for
planned engineering and economic infrastructures, its access to social auction, bidders are required to reveal their personal information,
and administrative infrastructures, housing condition, and urban plan of including their full name, residence, and nationality. The auction tender
the City.13 Moreover, the floor-price of a specific plot depends on contains basic information about the plot being auctioned including its
whether the plot is located in Central Business District (CBD, areas with area code, location (both sub-city and ‘Woreda’),16 size (in M2), use
access to transport and communication that attract more people and type, minimum building requirement, benchmark price (per M2), lease
socioeconomic activities), Suburban and Urban-Rural Fringes (SUR, payment completion period, and lease period. For the plot they bid,
areas that are good for residence), or in Zone of Transition (TRZ, areas in bidders offer price (per M2), initial down payment (in percent), and total
between the CBD and SUR). lease price. For each land lease transaction, the Land Bank and Transfer
According to the leasehold regulation, the tender should contain the Office of the city administration made available the plot area code and
benchmark/floor-price of the plot as well as information on at least the its basic information during the tender announcement. This is to be
plot size, plot use type, grace period, and minimum capital requirement. followed by the announcement of the winning price. This announcement
These are determined by the city administration. As stated in procla­ includes the names of the first and second winners and their respective
mation 721/2014, the grace period is determined based on the type of offer prices.
development on the plot, the conclusion of the lease contract, and the The ‘area code’ was used to link the information available for each
construction completion period. The construction completion period is plot before and after the tendering process. Accordingly, it was possible
from 1 to 2 years, depending on the size of the construction. This can be to compile the data on base-price, winning-price for first and second
extended up to 2 years for small and 5 years for large construction rank bidders and their name, plot size (in M2), plot location, plot grade,
projects. The lessee has the right to transfer or pledge the leasehold and land use type, the capital requirement for construction, minimum down
can use its right as collateral or capital contributions to the extent of the payment, grace period, and lease period for each plot auctioned. In
lease amount already paid. The lessee also has the right to transfer prior addition to the land transaction data, this study used relevant official
to the commencement or at half-completion of the construction. policy and land lease holding and other regulation documents from the
Moreover, the land lease period varies depending on the level, sector, city municipality and federal offices.
and type of development on the plot. It is 99 years for residential, science
and technology, and research purposes; 15 years for a business like
urban agriculture use. In Addis Ababa city, in particular, the lease period 14
There could be various reason for the cancellation of a tender. Perhaps, it
could be that the number of bidders per plot is less than three, in which case the
tender should be canceled or lack of information. According to the urban land
leasehold policy, a bid should be canceled if less than three bidders participated
13
This condition gives weights to the topography of the site (slope, soil type in the round of tender. Lack of information which could be due to affordability,
and texture/morphology, bearing capacity, hydrology, etc.), its existing/plan­ residents’ perception on the high competitiveness of the land auction market in
ned engineering and economic infrastructures (e.g. road, drainage, sewerage, city or speculation on the land price by the so called ‘middle men’.
15
electricity, transportation and communication, water, business area, etc.), its The Land Bank and Transfer Office of the Addis Ababa city administration
access to social and administrative infrastructures (e.g. health, education, po­ made available information on completed land lease transactions and new land
lice stations, fire-extinguishing, stations, sport and recreation, worship place, lease listings to the public through its website on a regular basis.
16
green areas, etc.), housing condition (e.g. function, typology and condition, etc. Addis Ababa, the capital city of Ethiopia and sit of many international or­
of the house), and urban plan of the city (e.g. land use and function, and ganization including AU and UNECA, is divided into ten sub-cities. Each sub-
building blocks). city is further divided into districts (‘weredas,)

4
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Moreover, other relevant data are extracted from the recent land 3.3. The econometric model and hypotheses
lease implementation and land market report of the city administration.
This enables us to conduct detail quantitative analyses using descriptive The initial econometric model used in this study follow that of Abdul
and econometric analyses to understand the key features of the land and Alirat (2009), Stevenson and Young (2004), Matysiak and Wang
market and the key determinants of the price of land in the City. The (1995) and Brown (1985) whose primary focus, unlike to our land
richness of the data allows us to assess the relative strengths of the plot valuation study, was to assess the relationship between guide/reserve
characteristic variables on the bidder’s land valuation decision. In and auction prices for residential properties. To examine the difference
particular, it will enable us to examine the variation in the land sale in land sale price relative to its guide price, we used two alternative
price relative to its floor-price17and to assess the determinants of the models (equation-1 and equation-2)20:
variation, if any.
ln(FPRICEi ) = α0 + α1 ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵi (1)

3.2. Theoretical framework ln(WPRICEi ) = β0 + β1 ln(FPRICEi ) + εi (2)


The dependent variable (FPRICE) in Eq. 1 is the floor (or guide) price
Auction theory is the theoretical foundation of our analysis. While an
per M2 to be achieved for the land to be sold at the auction, and the
auction is usually a process of buying and selling goods or services, the
independent variable (WPRICE) is the winning price per M2. Equation-2
theory largely relies on identifying the driving forces in bids of the
reverses equations-1 to use WPRICE as a dependent variable and FPRICE
bidders. Milgrom and Weber (1982) develop a general auction model for
as an independent variable. α and β are parameters of the models, and ϵ
risk-neutral bidders which includes, as special cases, the independent
and ε are prediction errors. These models are used to test whether the
private values model and the common value model, as well as a range of
floor-price acted as a proxy for the final sale price.
intermediate models. Consider an auction in which n bidders compete
The two equations above are estimated, assuming that the floor-price
for the possession of a single object. Each bidder possesses some infor­
is determined independently. However, the city administration uses
mation concerning the object up for sale; let X = (XI., Xn) be a vector, the
specific parameters to determine the floor-price of a plot. A key
components of which are the real-valued informational variables (or
parameter that the administration uses is plot grade. The administration
value estimates, or signals) observed by the individual bidders. Let S =
ranks21 plots based on their location, access to infrastructure, and the
(SI,., Sm) be a vector of additional real- valued variables which influence
number of stories to be built on the plot, development cost of the area,
the value of the object to the bidders. Some of the components of S might
and the plot-use type. It is, therefore, essential to analyze whether or not
be observed by the seller. The actual value of the object to bidder
developers (bidders) consider plot grade when they value a plot. Be­
i-which may, of course, depend on variables not observed by him at the
sides, the plot-use type is also an important variable for developers
time of the auction-will be denoted by Vi = ui(S, X). The theory predicts
(bidders). The land could be purchased with the intent of using it for
that the most common auction forms lead to the same expected price18
commercial, residential, or mixed; each may provide the developers
as well as, despite its generality, the model yields several testable
with a different expected return of investment within the lease-
predictions.19
agreement period. Accordingly, separate regressions are specified for
It has been shown that a number of factors can affect the predicted
the major plot grade types: Grade III4, Grade III3, and Grade III2. Simi­
auction price. The seller setting a reserve price or charging an entry fee is
larly, separate regressions are specified for the major plot use types:
a predictor of the price that bidders offer to a particular auction market.
mixed, residential, and commercial purposes. Thus, the following pairs
Such devices are commonly used in auctions and are believed to raise
of equations are specified for each plot use type (Eqs. 3.1 to 3.6) and
the seller’s revenue (Milgrom and Weber, 1982). One important factor
each plot grade types (Eqs. 4.1 to 4.6):
that determine predicted auction price is characteristics of the object
such as its location, plot size, etc. The purpose of the object for which the ln(FPRICEim ) = α0m + α1m ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵim ; for Mixed use plots
bidder is biding can also potentially predicts the price premium. Bid­ (3.1)
ders’ characteristics also affects the optimal bidding strategy to the
extent that different types of buyers have varying bid–rents curves that ln(WPRICEim ) = β0m + β1m ln(FPRICEi ) + εim ; for Mixed use plots
lie either above or below that of competing buyer types. Bidders’ income (3.2)
is also a key determinant of the price premium. Risk behavior of Bidders
may also affect the optimal outcome of an auction market. The demand ln(FPRICEic ) = α0c + α1c ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵic ; for Commercial use plots
curve for a risk averse bidder is different from those of risk lovers or risk (3.3)
neutral. We apply the general theoretical framework briefly discussed
here to our empirical model. Based on this framework, we have also ln(WPRICEic ) = β0c + β1c ln(FPRICEi ) + εic ; for Commercial use plots
specified our hypothesis. Both discussed below. (3.4)

ln(FPRICEir ) = α0r + α1r ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵir ; for Residential use plots


17
In this paper, base price, guide price, bench mark price or reserve price are (3.5)
alternative names for floor price.
18
In practice, auctions can take different forms depending on timing of de­
cision and the amount that winner is required to pay. Most common forms of
20
auctions are ‘English auctions’, ‘Sealed bid auctions’ and ‘Dutch auctions’. In The two equations are specified not to identify causality in the relationship
English auctions, bidders bid openly against each other and the bids continue to between two variables. Rather, the focus is to test whether the floor-price
increase. Ultimately, the object is sold to the highest bidder. In sealed–bid (FPRICE) acted as a proxy for the final sale price or the winning price
auctions, bidders simultaneously submit written bids. It can take two forms: (WPRICE). This can be addressed using either equation − 1 (as in Matysiak and
first – price sealed and second – price sealed. ‘First-price’ means the highest Wang, 1995) or equation-2 (as in Brown, 1985). We used one as an alternative
bidder is selected and pays the bid amount. In a ‘second-price’ auction, the specification to the other (as in Stevenson, 2004), either of them aiming at
highest bidder is selected, but pays the second highest bid. In a Dutch auction, testing whether the floor-price acted as a proxy for the final sale price. A simple
however, the price on an item is lowered until it gets a bid. The item is sold to t-test is used to validate this (Note: In a simple linear regression for assessment
the first bidder to accept that price, assuming that the price is above the reserve of X as proxy measure for Y as Y= β0 + β1X + error; one needs to formally test
price. the null hypothesis that H0: β0 = 0 ∩ β1 = 1).
19 21
Readers can get the general model and its assumptions in Milgrom and Based on the lease policy, the guide (or bench) price is updated at least
Weber (1982). every two years to reflect current condition.

5
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

ln(WPRICEir ) = β0r + β1r ln(FPRICEi ) + εir ; for Residential use plots premium, defined as the percentage difference between the highest bid
price and the reserve price, divided by the reserve price, will be deter­
(3.6)
mined by land use type, amount of down payment, plot grade and plot
ln(FPRICEiG4 ) = α0G4 + α1G4 ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵiG4 ; for Grade IV plots size. Our data allows us to disaggregate land use type into residential,
mixed use, business use and others. We expect that bidders for resi­
(4.1)
dential use will have higher auction premium compared to bidders for
ln(WPRICEiG4 ) = β0G4 + β1G4 ln(FPRICEi ) + εig4 ; for Grade IV plots mixed use and business use. This is due to the fact that since there is
(4.2) housing price hikes in the city, plots for residential purpose have higher
demand compared to plots for mixed and business purpose. Amount of
ln(FPRICEiG3 ) = α0G3 + α1G3 ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵiG3 ; for Grade III plots down payment is expected to negatively affect auction premium. This is
(4.3) due to that the bidder is expected to pay a down payment not less than
5% of the total amount if [s]he wins, which will be a financial burden to
ln(WPRICEiG3 ) = β0G3 + β1G3 ln(FPRICEi ) + εiG3 ; for Grade III plots bidder. Hence, higher down payment amount is expected to deter bid­
(4.4) ders’ premium price. Location of the plot land will also have a statisti­
cally significant influence on auction premium. In this regard, we expect
ln(FPRICEiG2 ) = α0G2 + α1G2 ln(WPRICEi ) + ϵiG2 ; for Grade II plots that bidders for plots in central part of the city, Kirkos sub city, will have
(4.5) greater interest and pays higher premium due to the location advantage
compared to for plots in other parts of the city. Controlling for plot
ln(WPRICEiG2 ) = β0G2 + β1G2 ln(FPRICEi ) + εiG2 ; for Grade II plots location, Plot grade is expected to have positive effect on auction pre­
(4.6) mium since bidders may have greater preference for higher grade plots.
The variable Plot size is expected to have negative influence on bidders’
Both floor and winning price data are transformed into price per M2
premium price since bidders may also take their budget constraint as
to adjust for differences in plot sizes (c.f. European Union et al., 2013).
they have to pay higher amount as a down payment if they win for
The data is then logarithmically transformed to normalize the frequency
higher plot size or due to their expected budget constraint. A detailed
distribution of the price per M2. This helps to overcome the likelihood of
investigation of the performance of the land auction market and the
positive skewness of the resulting data distribution if the sample con­
estimation results of the models are presented in the next two sections.
tains plots with high per M2 values. Moreover, these transformations are
required for correct interpretations of the statistics of the regression
4. Empirical analysis and results
analysis (c.f. Brown, 1992).
The econometric model specified in equation-5 is used to examine
4.1. Performance of the land lease system
the determinants of the size of bidder’s willingness to pay over the land
floor-price:
The implementation mechanism of the urban land lease regulation is
∑J
PREMIUM i = αi + β Sij + εi (5) described in section two. Here, we empirically investigate its actual
j=1 i
performance both from the supply and demand sides. From the supply
Where the dependent variable, land auction premium (PREMIUM), is side, the study analyzes the trends in the supply of land auctions for
defined as the percentage difference between the winning price (per M2) different land-use types, plot grade types, and locations of the City. This
for plot i and its floor-price (per M2), divided by the floor-price (per M2) helps to understand whether or not there is a systematic trend in the
of the plot (as in equation-6) (c.f. Weidong and Xiaolong, 2012; Abdul supply of land, and, if so, what are the key considerations taken by the
and Alirat, 2009; Ong et al., 2005): administration? This is followed by the critical investigation of the de­
mand side where we analyze land price development and the gap (as
PREMIUM i =
WPRICEi − FPRICEi
× 100% (6) well as the relationship) between the winning price and floor price.
FPRICEi Lastly, the result from the econometric analysis of the determinants of
This variable, PREMIUM shows bidders’ (developers) willingness to the observed gap will be presented.
pay for the auctioned plot relative to the floor-price.α and β are pa­
rameters of the model, Sij is a set of j auction plot characteristic or 4.1.1. Supply side of the land market: land auction trends in Addis Ababa
explanatory variables. Table A (see Appendix) presents the definition More than 3000 plots were tendered by the city administration
and summary statistics of variables used in the regressions. ε is predic­ during December 2013/14 - October 2016/17. Of these, 2621 plots
tion errors. (approximately 1,070,528 M2) were transferred to bidders (developers)
We also specified equation-7 as an alternative to equation-5. In through 18 rounds of auctions. The largest number of plots (242 plots)
equation-7 (following Alebel and Genanew, 2007b and Yuming and was supplied in round 7, followed by 238 and 230 plots in round 13 and
Stephen, 2001), the ordinary least squares (OLS) specification is used; 20, respectively. Only a few plots (less than 100 plots) were auctioned in
where the dependent variable, land mark-up price, is expressed as the round 12, 16, and 18.22 Looking into the distribution of the transferred
difference between the winning price (per M2) for plot i and its plots by their use type, about 50%, 41%, 8%, and 1% of the transferred
floor-price (per M2). This variable, unlike PREMIUM, is the absolute plots were allocated for mixed, residential, business and social or
difference between the winning price and floor price, and is referred to apartment uses through auctions, respectively. While the overall
as the mark-up price (MUP). It is considered in this study as an alter­ average plot size auctioned was about 408 M2 per plot, there has been a
native definition for the bidder’s willingness to pay for the auction plot. noticeable variation across the various plot use types. The average size
The parameters α∗ and β∗ , the set of plot characteristics (Sij ) and ε∗i are as per plot auctioned was the largest for social use (1147 M2), followed by
defined in equation-5 but specific to the mark-up price.

J
22
MUPi = α∗i + β∗ij Sij + ε∗i (7) Location wise, the largest number of plots (988 plots) was auctioned in Bole
j=1 sub city, followed by those supplied in Akaki Kaliti sub city (809 plots). Of the
total number of plots supplied for auction during the study period, only less
Model 5 presents the determinants of the premium that auction than 2% were auctioned in Addis Ketema, Gulele, Lideta, Arada and Kirkos sub
bidders paid above reserve prices. Given the land tenure system and the cities combined. A similar trend is observed in the total size of land auctioned in
nature of our data, we expect that the dependent variable, land auction these sub cities.

6
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

plots used for business purposes (746 M2), mixed-use (477 M2), and with a median price ETB 9012.25 per M2. Similarly, the median price in
residential use (246 M2). Bole sub-city, from where about 43% of the plots made available for
Over the study period (Fig. 1), there has been a decline in the supply auction during the period from 2013/14–2016/17, is Birr 11,318 (per
of land (both in plot size and number of plots), with a noticeable fluc­ M2) of land.
tuation in land size being supplied for auction. Whether this is due to the While location and the number of plots available for auction can
lack of capacity of the City’s administration to provide sufficient- have a crucial role in land price determination, plot use type can also
serviced land or due to a decline in land stock is an essential issue. affect its price. In nominal terms, the average price (per M2) of plots for
This is because such a land market scenario may induce informal business is ETB 25,977, while it is ETB 13,749 and ETB 12,693 for res­
development due to high-unmet demands. It is worth noting that not all idential and mixed-use plots, respectively. However, there has been a
land supplied by the City are leased, which is a more worrying perfor­ substantial fluctuation in the land price, and it varies by land use type
mance of the land auction market in particular in round 7 and 12. Only and plot grade. During the study period, the lowest price increase was
about 37% and 39% were sold in round 7 and 13, respectively. observed for business use plots, followed by residential use, with the
In a related topic, a study by Alebel and Genanew (2007b) assessed highest increment for mixed-use plots. The real median price (per M2) of
the performance of the land auction market in the City for the period plots for mixed-use has increased by 73% in round 24 compared to
1994/95–2002/03. The study found that only 15% of the available plots round 5 (see Fig. B in Appendix). Similarly, the real median price of plots
were sold each year. Though the land auction market seems to perform for business use increased by 34%, while the increase for residential use
better in terms of market-clearing over the last decade compared to the plots was by about 69%. Such an increasing trend of the real median
market during the period 1994/95–2002/03, such performance entails price could show the rising demand for a plot of land in the City. The
more detailed investigations for two reasons. First, there is a high de­ fluctuation in the prices is more frequent for plots used for commercial
mand for land, particularly for domestic investment. Second, previous or business than plots for mixed-use, with a steeper price increase for the
studies show that not just the number of plots supplied for auction later. A similar fluctuating pattern is observed in the real median price
matters but also that the type of land use crucially determines the de­ (per M2) of plots of Grade III4, Grade III3, and Grade III2 types. The real
mand for land (Alebel and Genanew, 2007b). median price (per M2) of plots of Grade III2 types, in particular, has
A closer look into the land supplied for auction by land-use type shown a drastic increase. It has increased by about 159% in round 24
revealed that in round 7, about 55% of the total land auctioned were for compared to round 5. Noticeably, more plots of mixed-use are sold, and
mixed-use. This figure was 77% in round 13. From the trends portrayed the number of Grade III4 plots is the highest during the study period. In
in Fig. 1, therefore, it is hardly possible to conclude the insufficiency of the overall, land sale price offered by bidders is far higher than the base
supplying land. The other possible reason for lack of market clearing price set by the city administration. While the average plot sale price
transaction could be that the number of bidders for a particular plot of (per M2) is ETB 14052 (with a median value of ETB 11838), the average
land matters most for such insufficiency. In this regard, Alebel and base price for a plot is only ETB 221 (with a median value of ETB 191).
Genanew (2007b) revealed that the average number of bidders was 14 Remarkably, plots used for commercial or business purposes are sold at a
per plot with an increasing trend over 1999/00–2002/03, during which higher price (on average) compared to plots used for mixed, residential,
only 15% of the supplied land is transacted. A recent study by the World or other purposes. Similarly, ‘other grade’ plots are sold at a higher price
Bank also shows that the number of bidders for a plot of land ranges from (on average) compared to Grade III4 , Grade III3 or Grade III2 plots.
10 to 12 (World Bank, 2016). Thus, other demand-side factors may While such price development trends provide a general overview of
explain the non-existence of the market-clearing land auction, which is the value of plots, it does not help to understand the revealed value for a
to be discussed next. plot of land offered by developers (or bidders). The next subsection fills
this gap. It presents an analysis of the base, winning, premium, and
4.1.2. Demand side of the land market: land price development mark-up prices of plots by their use types and grade types.
In the economic sense, assessing the trends in the price development
of land auction is an important indicator of the level of efficiency of the 4.1.3. Land premium and markup price
land management system. In this regard, the mean winning price and In this study, two alternative definitions are used to gauge the gap
base price (per M2) of a plot of land is ETB 13,40923 and ETB 218, between the floor-price (set by the government) and the winning price
respectively. Over the study period, the real auctioned price (per M2) of (offered by the bidder): premium price and mark-up price. The former is
land has shown an increasing trend. In real terms, the median land price defined as the percentage difference between winning price (per M2)
has increased by about 46% between 2013/14 (bid round 5) and 2016/ and floor-price (per M2), divided by the floor-price. The winning-price
17 (bid round 24). (Fig. 2). On the other hand, the median real base price and floor-price are as defined in equation-6 in Section 3. On the other
(per M2) has shown a modest decline of about 11% over the study hand, the mark-up price is the absolute difference between the winning
period. price (per M2) and floor-price (per M2) of the plot. In the economic
Location wise, plots located in ‘Addis Ketema’ sub-city, the center sense, these indicators are the revealed value for a plot of land offered by
and most developed part of the City, are expensive compared to plots developers. They measure the bidder’s (developer’s) willingness to pay
situated elsewhere. The median price of a plot in Addis Ketema sub-city for a specific auctioned-plot relative to the floor-price set by the gov­
is ETB 150,500 (per M2), which is way above the median price (ETB ernment. Table 1 provides the summary statistics for land premium and
63,600) of a plot in the second most expensive location of Lideta (see mark-up prices by land use purpose and grade type.
Fig. A in Appendix), which is also most developed and oldest part of the Irrespective of plot use type and plot grade type, plots were sold at an
City. Such a high price is expected given both sub-cities are developed average premium of more than 6000% over the base (floor) price. An
and are located in the central part of the City. It could also be due to a important issue that can be observed in Table 1 is that the premium is
small number of plots available for auction in these two sub-cities: only 6 higher for plots used for commercial purposes. Based on the median
and 13 plots were made available for auction in Lideta and Addis Ketema values, Grade III4 plots received the highest premium. The range be­
sub-cities during the study period, respectively. These two factors seem tween the maximum and minimum premium is the highest for com­
more plausible given the price of a plot of land in the outskirt parts of the mercial plots and Grade III4 plots. This should be viewed in light of the
City and in part of the City where more number of plots are available for small number of plots of ‘other grade’ types. Moreover, the median sale
auction. Plots located in Akakai Kaliti sub-city are valued the lowest, price is lower than the mean price, and the variations in median prices
across the different plot-use types and plot-grade types are less
compared to the differences in mean prices. This would indicate the
23
USD $1 = ETB (Ethiopian Birr) 34.88 as of 27 July, 2020. positive skewness of sale prices in that high valued plots are biasing the

7
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Fig. 1. Trends in lands size (in M2) available for auction and leased:dec 2013 to oct 2016.

Fig. 2. Trends in median auction land price:dec.2013 to oct 2016.

Table 1
Summary statistics for Premium and Markup prices by land use purpose and grade type.
Entire Plot use (or investment) types Plot grade types
Sample
Mixed Commercial/ Residential Other Grade III4 Grade III3 Grade III2 Others
Business

Number of observations 2034 1017 136 873 8 1392 401 214 27


Mean floor/base/ price 221 212 289 219 386 195.18 222.91 300.05 899.22
Mean Sale/winning/ price 14052 12693 25976.60 13749 17253 11830.47 14106.57 18444.88 92967.74
Median floor/base/ price 191 191 191 217 191 191.00 217.00 299.00 935.00
Median Sale/winning/ price 11838 11619 11185.50 12155 6635 11105.00 12345.67 6231.00 51050.00
Premium (Average Mean 6107% 5955% 6551% 6227% 4785% 6018.03% 6317.50% 6051.13% 7990.88%
absolute % Median 5522% 5660% 5717% 5453% 3269% 5659.16% 5522.12% 5292.14% 5359.89%
difference) Minimum 173% 173% 590% 1235% 1104% 172.77% 1994.93% 1104.01% 2491.55%
Maximum 23060% 20636% 23060% 22151% 17544% 22151.31% 18870.97% 20635.79% 23059.61%
0 – 5% 102 (5%) 85 (8%) 9 (7%) 6 (1%) 1 (13%) 88 (6.32%) 2 (0.50%) 11 (5.14%) 0 (0%)
5 – 10% 102 (5%) 70 (7%) 10 (7%) 19 (2%) 3 (38%) 64 (4.60% 23 (5.74%) 12 (5.61%) 3 (11.11%)
10 – 25% 303 (15) 134 18 (13%) 150 1 (13%) 175 88 (21.95%) 33 7 (25.93%)
(13%) (17%) (12.57%) (15.42%)
25 – 50% 512 (26%) 208 27 (20%) 275 2 (25%) 357 90 (22.44%) 61(28.50%) 4 (14.81%)
(21%) (32%) (25.65%)
50 – 75% 506 (25%) 262 33 (24%) 211 0 (0%) 351 90 (22.44%) 61(28.50%) 4 (14.81%)
(26%) (24%) (25.22%)
75% + 510 (25%) 258 39 (29%) 212 1 (13%) 357 108 36 9 (33.33%)
(25%) (24%) (25.65%) (26.93%) (16.82%)
Mark-up Mean 13831 12481 25688 13530 16867 11635 13884 18145 920689
Median 11607 11428 10995 11948 6444 10910 2128.67 15932 50115
Standard 16432 8071 56123 6164 21636 5589 6806 10811 104901
deviation
Minimum 330 330 1126 2359 3301 330 4329 3301 8845
markup
Maximum 353965 100691 353965 48626 64465 42309 40950 61701 353965
markup

mean sale price. This is also confirmed by the distribution of the pre­ similar in terms of plot grades, with 25% of the plots received a premium
mium. In terms of plot use purpose, about 50% of the plots received a higher than 7754, 7965, 6929, 10228% above the base price set for
premium higher than 5522% (1st quartile premium value), while the Grade III4 , Grade III3 , Grade III2 , and ‘Others type’ plots respectively.
3rd quartile premium value is 7695% above the base price. The result is During the study period, the median premium plot price increased from

8
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

5000% to 7927% above the base price while land mark-up price (per bidders offer for a particular plot is specific to the individual bidder and
M2) increased from ETB 10,203 to ETB 19,182. Such price variation is is affected by observed and unobserved characteristics of the plot. Our
observed across the different land-use types and plot-grade types. Fig. 3 analysis begins by examining the difference in sale-price relative to the
illustrates the variation in median premium values by plot-use types floor-price using two alternative ways, stated in the methodology sec­
over the study period. Also, Figure C (see Appendix) shows the trends in tion (as equation-1 and equation-2, and Eqs. 3.1 through 4.6). This will
mark-up price by land-use types across bid rounds over the study period, be followed by an analysis of the determinants of the size of the premium
and Figure D (see Appendix) shows the trend in the overall median (and mark-up) prices that land auction bidders are willing to pay over
premium and mark-up price over the bid rounds). the land floor price. For the latter, this study used two regression esti­
The overall mean mark-up price of a plot (per M2) is ETB 13,831, mations (stated in the methodology section as equation-5 and equation-
with a standard deviation of ETB 16,432 and a significant difference 7) to examine the determinants. Such multivariate analysis provides
between the minimum (ETB 330) and maximum (ETB 353,965) offers. better information and more insights into the factors that affect bidders’
These figures vary by type of land use and plot grade (Table 1). Mixed- willingness to offer for auction plot. The empirical results from these
use plots have a median mark-up price of ETB 11,418. In contrast, models are presented in the following subsections. Firstly, the rela­
residential-use and commercial-use plots have median mark-up prices of tionship between the floor-price and winning-price will be examined.
ETB 11,948 and ETB 10,995, respectively, with a high variation (stan­ This will be followed by a presentation of the empirical results on the
dard deviation of ETB 56123) for commercial-use plots compared to determinants.
mixed-use and residential-use plots. Such variation appears to suggest
that there is high competition for mixed and residential use plots 4.2.1. Relationship between Floor-price and Winning Price
compared to plots for business use. The mark-up price offers also differ As explained in Section 3 of this paper, plot grade is a key parameter
among the various plot grades. On average, Grade III2 plots are highly used by the City’s administration to determine the floor-price of a plot.
valued, with a median mark-up price (per M2) of ETB 15,932 and a high On the other hand, land use type is an important variable for the bidder
standard deviation value of ETB 10812. Such a high variation in the (investor) who leases the land with the intent to use for commercial,
mark-up price of Grade III2 plots suggests the presence of high compe­ residential, or mixed purposes; each may provide the bidder with a
tition for Grade III3 and Grade III4 plots with a relatively lower standard different expected return of investment within the lease-agreement
deviation of ETB 6806 and ETB 5589, respectively (Table 1). period. Consequently, separate regressions are specified for the major
In order to understand whether or not there is variation in land plot use types: commercial, residential, and mixed purposes. The same is
valuation across the different locations of the City, this study also ex­ done for the major plot grade types: Grade III4 , Grade III3 , and Grade
amines the premium and mark-up price offers in each sub-city. A III2 .
detailed investigation of the premium price by sub-city reveals that the Table 2 presents the econometric results for equation-1 and
highest median premium is offered for plots in Nifas-silk sub-city, fol­ equation-2, and Eqs. 3.1 through 4.6 (as shown in Section 3). The results
lowed by plots in Bole sub-city with a median premium of 8160 and from these estimations are reasonably similar, except for Grade III2 and
16598% respectively. Similarly, the highest mark-up price (per M2) is Grade III4 plots with coefficients significantly different from unity at 1%
offered for plots in Nifas-silk sub-city, but in this case, followed by plots level. These results suggest the presence of divergence between the floor
in Kolfe sub-city with mark-up price (per M2) of ETB 16,598 and ETB and sale prices. This confirms the finding reported in the description
16,362 respectively. The lowest premium and mark-up price is observed section of this paper in that the government-set prices have not acted as
in Akaki–kaliti sub-city where a plot of land received a premium of a good proxy for the land sale price over the study period. The literature
4278% (with a standard deviation of 1691%) above the base price and attributes such divergence between the guide and sale prices to differ­
valued at a median mark-up price of ETB 8805, with a standard devia­ ences in the timing of the valuation and sale of the plot (c.f. Brown,
tion of ETB 3480. In Nifas-silk, the premium ranges from 1104% to 1985) or a fast increase of price in the land market and a speculative
20636% while the mark-up price ranges from ETB 3301 to ETB 61,701 nature of the market (c.f. Stevenson and Young, 2004). In the context of
whereas in Bole ranges from 173% to 18376% above the base price and this study, the divergence may not necessarily be due to time differ­
the mark-up price in Kolfe ranges from ETB 3301 to ETB 48,626 (per ences, but rather due to the fast pace of land price and speculations in
M2). Notably, the ranges in the premium and mark-up price offers for the land market in the City. Moreover, it can also be because the gov­
plots in Addis Ketema, Kirkose, and Arada sub-cities are exceptional. ernment may have deliberately underpriced land to encourage de­
Overall, the results suggest several key facts. The plot sale price is velopers to lease land for investment purposes. Alternatively, the
way higher than the base price set by the government. The difference divergence between the guide and sale prices can be due to inefficiency
between the base and sale prices (expressed in both premium and in continuously updating the land floor-price to reflect the current land
makeup prices) varies across the plot-use type, plot-grade types, and plot market scenario. Indeed, between bid round-5 and bid round-24, the
locations. Such a jump in sale prices over the base prices is rational, mean plot real sale-price (per M2) increased by 151% while the mean
given the fast economic development in the City over the study period floor real price increased by only 8.62%. Such a price variation is
and the accompanying land demand for sustained infrastructure need. observed across the different land-use types. An exception in the
The result also suggests that the base price set by the City’s adminis­ econometric results is that of for Grade III2 and Grade III4 plots where
tration seems not to proxy the sale price of land in the City. Though not the coefficients are not significantly different from unity.
steady, the land premium and mark-up price has shown an increasing
trend for each land use type over the study period. In sum, the results in 4.2.2. Determinants of the Size of Auction Premium (and Markup Price)
this section revealed that the land premium and mark-up price not only The descriptive statistics of variables included in the regressions are
vary by plot-use types and plot-grade types but also by location. They shown in Table A (see Appendix). While about 60% of bid winners are
also vary across the auction periods. Besides, the results show that there required to deposit 20% of the bid amount as a down payment, 40% are
is a marked difference between the minimum and maximum premium required to deposit only 10% of the bid amount. Whereas the majority of
and mark-up price offers. Thus, it is worth conducting a detailed bid winners (about 59%) are required to complete the total amount of
investigation of such characteristics of price variations and their de­ the lease payment in 30 years, 41% are required to complete the total
terminants, which is a point discussed in the next section. amount in 40 years with a grace period of 4 years. While the lease period
for the majority (about 60%) of the auctioned plots is 90 or 99 years, the
4.2. Regression Results lease period for 40% of the auctioned plots is 60 or 70 years. The mean
minimum capital amount bidders are required to have as their invest­
The competitiveness of bidding in land auctions and, hence, the price ment capacity is about ETB 466,002, with a minimum amount of ETB

9
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Fig. 3. TRENDS IN MEDIAN PREMIUM PRICE BY PLOT USE TYPE,BY ROUND.

Table 2
Regression result of the relationship between Floor (base) price (FPRICE) and Wining (sale) price (WPRICE).
Log of WPRICE regressed on log of FPRICE Log of FPRICE regressed on log of WPRICE

Constant Sale price Constant Floor price

Full sample Coefficient 3.805 0.166 3.979 1.00


Standard Error 0.077 0.008 0.267 0.050
T-statistics 49.32 * ** 20.15 * ** 14.880 * ** 20.150 * **
Plot use types Mixed Coefficient 4.582 0.080 5.547 .701061
Standard Error 0.096 0.010 0.480 0.090
T-statistics 47.680 * ** 7.790 * ** 11.56 * ** 7.790 * **
Business Coefficient 1.077 0.460 1.792 1.412
Standard Error 0.277 0.029 0.489 0.099
T-statistics 3.880 * ** 15.770 * ** 3.670 * ** 15.770 * **
Residential Coefficient 4.290 0.115 5.131 0.801
Standard Error 0.116 0.0122 0.458 0.085
T-statistics 37.120 * ** 9.400 * ** 11.200 * ** 9.400 * **
Plot grade types Grade III4 Coefficient 5.224 0.005 8.425 0.158
Standard Error 0.043 0.005 0.817 0.155
T-statistics 121.560 * ** 1.020 10.310 * ** 1.020
Grade III3 Coefficient 5.016 0.040 6.750 0.500
Standard Error 0.132 0.014 0.947 0.176
T-statistics 37.890 * ** 2.850 * ** 7.130 * ** 2.850 * **
Grade III2 Coefficient 5.692 0.001 6.272 0598
Standard Error 0.029 0.003 8.855 1.553
T-statistics 193.340 * ** 0.390 0.710 0.390

12,377 and a maximum of ETB 1820,000. (Table 3) has auction premium as a dependent variable, the depen­
Before we run the regression, we first investigated the data if there is dent variable for equation-7 (see Table B in Appendix)24 is plot mark-up
heteroscedasticity problem in our dataset. We used graph (residual vs price. Both results present the determinants of the divergence between
fitted plot) as well as statistical approaches (Breusch - Pagan / Cook­ floor-price and sale prices of plots auctioned in the City, each estimated
–Weisberg test test) to investigate the homoscedasticity of the model, in in two specifications. In the first specification (Specification-1), we run
its three specifications. The residual vs fitted plots (please see Figure E in the model by including dummies for plot grade and location. In the
Appendix), in general, are equally distributed along the line though few second specification (Specification-2), we run the model by excluding
residuals slightly divert from the middle line. Nevertheless, the p-value location. Our aim is to examine the level of influence of plot grade on
obtained from Breusch-Pagen test for the models are less than 0.001. land value without controlling for location effect.
Thus, we re-estimated the models with robust standard errors, which A comparison of the results from estimations of the two specifica­
helped us to remove a potential heteroscedasticity problem. This spec­ tions in equation-5 (Table 3) and Eq. 7 (see Table B in Appendix) shows
ification makes our inferences valid in spite of the problem. Table 3 (and the model that best fits the data is specification-1. This is evidenced by
Table B in Appendix) present the estimation results, which is discussed comparing the goodness-of-fit measures where the specification-1 pro­
below. vides a better fit compared to its alternative, as it generates the lowest
Moreover, skewness is checked for all the continuous variables. AIC and BIC. Moreover, the choice of this specification is intuitive, given
Accordingly, the logarithm transformations of auction premium price, that its estimated coefficients provide more economic meaning in values
mark-up price, benchmark price, winning price, plot size, and capital are and signs compared to the alternative specification. On the other hand, it
used in the empirical analysis. we also checked for collinearity. We is worth noting that the results in equation-5 (Table 3) and equation-7
observed perfect collinearity between the variables ‘lease period’ and (see Table B in Appendix) are similar; hence only the estimation re­
‘payment period’. We, thus, run the regressions by including the later sults in specification-1 of Table 3 are discussed below.
variable in our model specifications.
The empirical analysis of the determinants of auction premium and
mark-up price uses two alternative estimations: equation-5 and 24
The estimation result for the determinants of Land markup price are present
equation-7. These two estimations differ only in the way their dependent
but suppressed in this paper. They are submitted as a separate appendix as
variables are defined. While the estimation result for equation-5 Table-B.

10
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Table 3
Ordinary Least Square regression estimation of Determinant of logarithm of land auction premium in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia (Robust standard error estimation).
Dependent variable: Logarithm of Premium Price (Eq. 5)

Variables Specification 1 Specification 2

Coef. Robust Std. Err. Coef. Robust Std. Err.

Logarithm of floor/bench mark price -0.680 * ** 0.221 -0.110 0.132


Logarithm of plot size -0.127 * ** 0.036 -0.164 * ** 0.042
Logarithm of capital -0.007 0.018 0.027 0.021
Down Payment -0.348 * ** 0.366 -0.195 * ** 0.032
Payment period -0.425 0.262 -0.533 * * 0.236
Land use type Dummy for Mixed -0.540 * * 0.258 -0.667 * ** 0.235
Dummy for Business -0.250 0.262 -0.612 * 0.238
Plot gradea Dummy for Grade III4 plot -0.591 * ** 0.197 -0.247 0.206
Dummy for Grade III3 plot -0.608 * ** 0.190 -0.384 * * 0.194
Dummy for Grade III2 plot -0.527 * ** 0.185 -0.241 0.173
Plot Locationb Dummy for Akaki sub-city -1.521 * ** 0.350
Dummy for Yeka sub-city -0.867 * * 0.355
Dummy for Nifas Silk lafto -0.688 * * 0.342
Dummy for Addis Ketema -0.239 0.318
Dummy for Kolfe Keraniyo -1.047 * ** 0.333
Dummy for Bole sub-city -0.971 * ** 0.361
Dummy for Gulele -1.109 * ** 0.355
Dummy for Lideta sub-city -0.862 * ** 0.249
Dummy for Arada -1.009 * ** 0.208
Bid round 0.039 * ** 0.006 0.036 * ** 0.006
Number of floors on plot 0.003 0.015 -0.020 0.018
Year Year Dummy 2013/14 -0.265 * * 0.115 -0.199 0.122
Dummy Year Dummy 2014/15 -0.100 0.078 -0.344 * ** 0.081
Year Dummy 2015/16 0.078 0.057 -0.022 0.060
Constant 14.847 * ** 1.607 10.39 * ** 0.901
Number of observations 2015 2015
R2 0.5139 0.3106
F( 24, 1990) 87.67 * ** F(22, 1986)= 95.22 * **
Likelihood -885.315 -885.647
AIC; BIC 1818.631; 1953.232 2504.883; 2589.008

*CPI, obtained from Central Statistical Agency, is used to calculate the real price.

The estimated coefficient of determination indicates that about 51% mixed or commercial use plots.
of the variations in the bidder’s premium price is explained by the The estimated coefficient for the amount of down payment is nega­
model, and the joint F-statistic is significant at the 1% level. This yields tive and highly significant (at least at the 1% level) in affecting auction
evidence regarding the strength of the estimation for the overall data. premium. Once the bidder wins, [s]he is expected to pay a down pay­
The constant term is positive and statistically significant at least at 1%, ment not less than 5% of the total amount, which will be a financial
suggesting that plots in the City have high value regardless of its char­ burden to bidder. Hence, higher down payment amount is expected to
acteristic features, assuming all factors being constant. The results show deter bidders’ premium price. To control for the transaction year effect,
that auction premium price is significantly explained by factors we define year-dummies for the year 2013/14 to year 2016/2017, using
including plot size, plot use type (residential versus mixed-use), plot- 2016/17 as the reference category. The result shows that only the
grade types, amount of down payment, plots location, bid round, and dummy for the year 2013/14 is statistically significant (at the 5% level)
time of the auction (bid round). On the other hand, the variable bidder’s and negative, suggesting that the auction premium in 2013/14 is
loan capacity (capital), which is believed to be theoretically important significantly less than the auction premium in 2016/17. That is, a sig­
in land valuation decisions is found to be insignificant. The in­ nificant transaction year effect is observed in the City in a span of three
terpretations of the econometric findings with respect to the signs of the years. This result is complemented by the result that bid round variable
estimated coefficients are discussed below chronologically in terms of is statistically significant (at the 1% level) and positive.
their quantitative importance. Though the government-set floor price has not acted as a good proxy
The estimated coefficient for the mixed-use type is found to have a for the land sale price in the City (as discussed earlier in this paper), it is
negative and statistically significant (at the 5% level) on auction pre­ found to have a significant (at the 1% level) and negative effect on
mium. Though the coefficients for the business-use type is negative, it is auction premium. This indicates that a higher floor-price decreases the
statistically insignificant. Given that the reference category (dummy bidder’s premium offer. This result reveals the importance of floor-price
variable) for plot use type is residential, the result shows that plots for in guiding the sale price of a plot, suggesting that the determination of
residential use command a higher premium than plots for mixed or the floor-price should be given due consideration as it affects the auction
commercial uses. This result may be attributed to the demanding nature premium. In terms of plot size, the estimated coefficient is negative and
of plots for residential purposes and the accompanying housing price highly significant (at least at the 1% level) in affecting auction premium.
hikes in the City. If one believes that higher auction premiums in the City Such a negative effect of plot size may be due to that larger-sized plots
are due to the result of competition among land developers, then this entail land buyers to own higher capital and, hence, a lower number of
finding suggests that developers are more interested in residential de­
velopments. Indeed, the residential land market, compared to the mixed
or commercial land markets, is highly demanding and developed in
Addis Ababa. This suggests the theoretical expectation that higher per
plot turnouts for residential use plots are associated with an increase in
auction price and higher auction premiums in these plots compared to

11
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

competitive bidders, which results in a lower premium.25 fluctuations in the size of land being supplied over the period. On the
The coefficient for plot grade is found to be negative and statistically other hand, the descriptive result revealed that there had been a sub­
significant, at least at the 5% level.26 This result is in line with prior stantial fluctuation in the price of land, and it varies by land use type and
expectations given the plot grade in specification 127 (Table 3) is defined plot grade. Over the study period, the lowest price increase was
as a categorical variable with category-1 being for plots with better observed on plots for business-use, followed by residential-use, with the
development condition and category-6 being for plots with the least highest increment for mixed-use plots. Such an increasing trend of real
developed states. The result demonstrates that bidders tend to offer a median price could show the rising demand for land in the City. An in-
higher premium for plots with better facilities, controlling for location depth analysis of the price development of the land market revealed that
effect. Estimating plot grade without controlling for location effect (see the median premium plot price increased from 5000% to 7927% above
result from specification 2 in Table 3) shows that plot grade has little or the base price while land mark-up price (per M2) increased from ETB
no effect on land value. This is in line with our expectation that plot 10,203 to ETB 19,182. Such price variation is observed across the
grade has relatively higher effect on and value if one controls the effect different land-use types and plot grades. This difference is expressed in
of location. The result is also in line with prior studies (c.f. Weidong and premium and mark-up prices and varies across the plot use, plot grade
Xiaolong, 2012) in that the higher the plot grade, the easier and quicker types, and plot location. Such a jump in sale prices over the base prices is
for land developers to develop the land into real estate, business, or rational, given the fast economic development in the City over the study
mixed-use development projects. period and the accompanying land demand for sustained infrastructure
Interestingly, the coefficients for plots located in all sub cities, except needs. The result also suggests that the base price set by the city
in Addis Ketema, are negative and statistically significant at conven­ administration does not seem to proxy the sale price of land.
tional probability levels. Bidders tend to offer lower auction premiums The results from the descriptive statistics are also confirmed by the
to plots in these areas than the reference Kirkos sub city, which is located econometric results, which show a mix of factors explains the price
in the central part of the city. There is no significant difference between development in urban land market. Auction premium price is signifi­
plots in Addis Ketema and Kirkos sub cities. These two sub cities are cantly explained by factors including floor price, plot size, amount of
located in central part of the city. The fact that location has a strong down payment, plot use type, plot grade, plots location, bid-round, and
influence on bidders’ premium is consistent with the literature (c.f. time of the auction. The auction premium in 2013/14 is found signifi­
DeBoer et al., 1992), where location advantages can be translated into cantly less than the auction premium in 2016/17, suggesting a trans­
high bidding prices and hence higher premiums. The result also shows action year effect in a span of three years. Based on the leasehold
that the coefficient for bid-round is positive and significant at least at the regulation, a benchmark price is supposed to be updated at least every
1% level, suggesting an increasing trend of land auction premium over two years to reflect the current condition. The result shows that there is a
time. The results from the descriptive statistics (see Section 4.1) also significant difference in land premium and mark-up price from round to
shows a similar result. round. Given that more than one rounds of bid are tendered in one year,
there is little justification to update the mark-up price at least once in
5. Conclusion two years. On the other hand, though the government-set benchmark
price does not act as a good proxy for the land sale price in the City, it is
The paper critically reviews and empirically investigates the land found to have a significant and positive effect on auction premium and
lease policy in urban areas of Ethiopia, one of the fastest urbanizing mark-up prices. This suggests that the determination of the benchmark
countries in SSA. From the supply side, the paper critically reviews the price should be given due consideration as it affects the land auction
land lease policy and its implementation mechanism. From the demand premium and mark-up price. These two results suggest that the munic­
side, the paper quantitatively analyzed the fundamental factors that ipality is not earning the expected revenue from land whose value is
drive developers’ land premium and mark-up price using the land auc­ determined based on the market.
tion data obtained from the city administration for the period 2013/ The results on plot use type imply that even if domestic investors are
14–2016/17. willing to provide high value for land, they are investing less in the
The study shows a general decline in the supply of land (both in plot productive sectors (that generates more employment). In this regard,
size and number) supplied for auction over the study period, with our finding suggests that investors are more interested in residential
developments (real estate), which creates less employment, at least in
the long run. Besides, the finding on the effect of plot use type on land
value implies the need to give due consideration in discriminating prices
25
Inclusion of the ‘square of plot size’ would have been enlightening in terms across the different plot use types. Given the hot land market in the City,
of knowing the U or Inverted-U shape effect of plot size on auction premium. a valuable lesson from the finding of the effect of plot grade is that the
However, this variable is excluded in the regression as it is highly collinear with competition for high-grade plots can be strengthened through a unique
‘plot size’. However, a separate regression using ‘square of plot size’ an inde­
auction mechanism in allocating high-grade plots that are subject to
pendent variable instead of ‘plot size’ shows the former has negative and sig­
fierce competition, and such grading should also consider the location of
nificant effect on auction premium.
26
We used two variables to measure plot grade which are included in two
the plot within the city. A more interesting finding of the econometric
separate model estimations. In the first estimation, we create land grade cate­ analyses is that factors that are believed to be theoretically important in
gorical variable that characterize the land grade into 6 categories as per the the bidder’s land valuation decision are found to be insignificant. These
classification of the city administration. In the second estimation, we create include bidder’s loan capacity (capital), payment period, and the num­
four dummy variables by re-categorizing the six categories of the city admin­ ber of floors allowed to be built on plot. The findings imply that land
istration into four grade. The bench mark land price map of A.A City labeled value in urban Ethiopia is driven by a mix of economic and non-
plots in the city in to five grades where Grade 1 plot is with batter development economic factors. Perhaps, the non – economic factors may be associ­
condition, and so on. Thus, access to basic services here is specified as: 1 if plots ated with the speculative nature of the land market, which makes the
is Grade 1, 2 if Grade 2; 3 if Grade 3; 4 if Grade 4; and 5 if Grad 5. We further land price not to increase systematically, though it is surging. It could
narrow down these groupings into four categories: 1 =Grade4,
also be associated with the unnecessary delay in transferring of the
2 =Grade4,3 =Grade2, 4 =Others. Only few observations (about 1.15%) are in
lessee land to winners. Accordingly, these features may trigger in­
category 4. Therefore, we introduced three dummies: DummyGrade4, Dum­
myGrade3, DummyGrade2, and hence Other Grade types (only about 35 ob­ efficiency in the land market, particularly in the implementation of the
viations, 1.15%) are reference category. leasehold system in urban areas of the country, and thus, need to be
27
A similar result is found in specification 3 (See table-3) where plot-grade corrected.
variable is defined as a set of dummy variables.

12
A.B. Weldesilassie and G. B.Worku Land Use Policy 114 (2022) 105906

Acknowledgments DeBoer, L., Conrad, J., McNamara, K., 1992. Property Tax Auction Sales. Land Econ. 68,
72–82.
Deininger, K., 2003. “Land policies for growth and poverty reduction”, World Bank
The authors would like to acknowledge the Addis Ababa city Policy Research Report series. World Bank; Oxford and New York: Oxford University
administration for making the land transaction data available for this Press,, Washington D.C.
study. The Critical Assessment of Urban Land Leasehold System in Deininger, K., Chamorro, C., 2002. Investment and Income Effects of Land: The Case of
Nicaragua. World Bank Policy Res. Work. Pap.
Ethiopia by Alebel and Birhanu (2017) greatly helped to shape the re­ Deininger, K., Jin, S., 2006. Tenure Security and Land-Related Investment: Evidence
view section of this study, and the authors are indebted to this work. The from Ethiopia. Eur. Econ. Rev. 50 (5), 1245–1277.
release time support from the University of Dubai (UD) to one of the Desalegn Rahmeto, (2006), From Heterogeneity to Homogeneity Agrarian Class
Structure in Ethiopia since the 1950s. in Desalegn and Taye(ed) Land and the
author to work on this paper is greatly appreciated. challenges of sustainable Developmnet in Ethiopia, conference proceeding (Forum
for Social Studies).
Appendix A. Supporting information Dotzour, M., Moorhead, E., Winkler, D., 1998. The Impact of Auctions on Residential
Sales Prices in New Zealand. J. Real. Estate Res. 16 (1), 57–70.
Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia, 1995. Proclamation of the Constitution of the
Supplementary data associated with this article can be found in the Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia, proclamation No. 1/1995. Addis Ababa
online version at doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2021.105906. Berhan ena Selam Printing press,.
Gwin, C., Ong, S., Spieler, A., 2005. Auctions and Land Values: An Experimental
Analysis. Urban Stud. 42 (12), 2245–2259.
References Hong, Y., Bourassa, S., 2003. Why Public leasehold? Issues and concepts. Hong., Yu-
Hung. /Bourassa, Steven (Ed. ). Leas. Public Land – Policy Debates Int. Exp. 3–38.
Abdul, R.A., Alirat, O.A., 2009. Empirical Evidence of the Influences on First-Price Bid Lust, K.A., 1996. Comparison of Price Brought by English Auctions and Private
Auction Premiums. Int. Real. Estate Rev. Vol. 12 (No. 2), 157–170. Negotiations. Real. Estate Econ. 24 (4), 517–530.
Alebel, B. and Berihu, A. (2017), “A Critical Assessment of Urban Land Leasehold System Mayer, C.J., 1998. Assessing the Performance of Real Estate Auctions. Real. Estate Econ.
in Ethiopia”, Paper prepared for presentation at the “2017 World bank conference on 26 (1), 41–66.
land and poverty”, The World Bank - Washington DC, March 20–24, 2017. Matysiak, G., Wang, P., 1995. Commercial Property Market Prices and Valuations:
Alebel, B. and Genanew, B. (2007a), “Households’ Willingness to Resettle and Preference Analyzing the Correspondence. J. Prop. Res. 12, 181–202.
to Forms of Compensation for Improving Slum Areas in Addis Ababa City”, Ministry of Urban Development and Construction, 2011. The urban land development
Conference proceedings of the Fourth International Conference on Ethiopian and management policy and strategy.
Development Studies (4th ICEDS) on the challenges and opportunities for peace & Ministry of Urban Development and Construction, 2013. ‘Urban Dev. Policy’ Amharic
development in Ethiopia & the horn of Africa, August 2–4, 2007, 2000 Schneider Version.
Hall, Haworth College of Business, Western Michigan University, Kalamazoo, USA. Ong, S.E., Lusht, L., Mak, C.Y., 2005. Factors Influencing Auction Outcomes: Bidder
Alebel, B. and Genanew, B. (2007b), “Investors willingness to pay for urban land in Addis Turnout, Auction Houses and Market Conditions. J. Real. Estate Res. 27 (2),
Ababa”. Conference proceedings of the Fourth International Conference on 177–191.
Ethiopian Development Studies (4th ICEDS) on the challenges and opportunities for Pankhurs, R., 2006. State and Land in Ethiopian History, the Institute of Law of
peace & development in Ethiopia & the horn of Africa, August 2–4, 2007, 2000 Hailesilassie I University in Association with Oxford University. Addis Ababa.
Schneider Hall, Haworth College of Business, Western Michigan University, Milgrom, Paul R., Weber, Robert J., 1982. “A THEORY OF AUCTIONS AND
Kalamazoo, USA. COMPETITIVE BIDDING”. Econometrica Vol 50 (No. 5). September 1982.
Allen, M., Swisher, J., 2000. An Analysis of the Price Formation Process at a HUD Peterson, G. E., 2006. Land Leasing and Land Sale as an Infrastructure- Financing Option.
Auction. J. Real. Estate Res. 20 (3), 279–298. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4043, November 2006 (Retrived from
Aluko, B.T., 2007. Accuracy of Auction Sale Valuations in Distressed Banking Lending https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/9020).
Decisions in Nigeria. J. Bus. Econ. Manag., VIII 3, 225–233. Stevenson, S., Young, J., 2004. Valuation Accuracy: A Comparison of Residential Guide
Amidu, A., Aluko, B.T., Oyedele, J.B., 2008. Price Formation in Residential Property Prices and Auction Results. Prop. Manag. 22 (1), 45–54.
Market: Evidence from FGLP Auction in Nigeria. Prop. Manag., Forthcom. 26, 4. Taffese O., 2006; Ethiopia: Politics of Land Tenure under Three regimes: A Carrot and
Bacry, Y., Sileshi, T., Admit, Z., 2009. Land lease policy in Addis Ababa. Prod. Distrib. Stick Ruling Strategy. In Alexander, Kassahun and Yonas(ed) Ethiopia: Politics,
Addis Ababa Chamb. Commer. Sect. Assoc. Financ. Support Swed. Agency Int. Dev. Policy Making and Rural Development.
Coop., Sida. Weidong, Q., Xiaolong, L., 2012. Assessing the Performance of Chinese Land Lease
Belachew, Y., 2010. Urban Land Lease Policy of Ethiopia: Case Study on Addis Ababa and Auctions: Evidence from Beijing. J. Real. Estate Res. Vol. 34 (Issue 3), 291–310.
Lease Towns of Amhara National Regional State. FIG Congr. 2010 Facing Chall. – World Bank (2016), “Ethiopia Urbanization Review: Urban Institutions for a Middle –
Build. Capacit., Syd., Aust. 11-16 April 2010. Income Ethiopia” World Bank Group 100238.
Benayew, T.G., 2015. Historiographical Review of the Current Debate on Ethiopian Land Yuming, F., Stephen, C., 2001. Examining Competition in Land Market: An Application of
Tenure System. Afr. J. Hist. Cult. Vol 7 (2), 44–51. February 2015. Event Study to Land Auctions in Hong Kong. Department of Real Estate and Urban
Brown, G., 1985. Property Investment and Performance: A Reply. J. Valuat. 16, 755–769. Land Economics. University of Wisconsin,.
Brown, G., 1992. Valuation Accuracy: Developing The Economic Issues. J. Prop. Res. 9, Zelalem, Y.A., 2014. Critical Analysis of Ethiopian Urban Land Lease Policy Reform Since
199–207. Early 1990s. FIG Congr. 2014 Engag. Chall. – Enhancing Relev., Kuala Lumpur,
Collier, Paul, Venables, Anthony J., 2013C. Housing and Urbanization in Africa: Malays. 16-21 June 2014.
unleashing a formal market process. CSAE Working Paper Series 2013-01, Centre for
the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford, WP84253.

13

You might also like