You are on page 1of 12

Multiobjective Stochastic Inoperability Decision

Tree for Infrastructure Preparedness


Hiba Baroud 1; Kash Barker, Ph.D. 2; and F. Hank Grant, Ph.D. 3

Abstract: Decision making for managing risks to critical infrastructure systems requires accounting for (1) the uncertain behavior of
disruptive events; and (2) the interdependent nature of such systems that lead to large-scale inoperability. This paper integrates a dynamic
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

risk-based interdependency model, the dynamic inoperability input-output model, with a multiobjective decision tree to analyze preparedness
decisions. The use of a dynamic model allows for resilience and recovery decisions to be incorporated in the decision-making framework,
and uncertainty is accounted for using probability distributions. The multiobjective inoperability decision tree is applied to the study of
transportation infrastructure disruptions, namely closures of an inland waterway and an inland waterway port. A data-driven multiregional
study of the Port of Catoosa in Oklahoma, along the Mississippi River Navigation System, is discussed and suggests careful consideration
when investing larger amounts toward port security. DOI: 10.1061/(ASCE)IS.1943-555X.0000171. © 2013 American Society of Civil
Engineers.
Author keywords: Decision tree; Disruptive event; Infrastructure preparedness; Multiobjective decision; Dynamic inoperability
input-output model (DIIM).

Introduction Government Accountability Office 2011). The highway and


railway networks in many cities near coastal ports are already
A number of infrastructure systems, both in the United States and experiencing bottlenecks. A viable alternative to these modes for
globally, have been identified as critical due to their ubiquitous freight transport is the inland waterway navigation system. Vital
influence on society’s way of life. Among these critical infrastruc- to commodity flows in the United States, almost 80 percent of all
tures are energy, health care, and transportation sectors (Dept. of U.S. international trade is transported through coastal ports, with 40
Homeland Security 2009). Their criticality is due to their intercon- percent of these shipments moving inside the United Sates through
nectedness with other infrastructure systems, as well as industries inland ports before reaching their final destination (Haveman
and workforces that rely upon them. A disruption to such a critical and Howard 2006). However, commodity flows through inland
infrastructure, whether the result of a terrorist attack, a natural dis- waterways are a distant third behind highway and rail traffic
aster, an accident, or common failure, could incur widespread (U.S. Army Corps of Engineers 2010), giving them an opportunity
losses of functionality that affect not only the infrastructure itself for expanded use.
but all the industries depending on it. Therefore, to effectively plan Understandably, research focusing on economic impact analy-
for the protection of these infrastructures from failure, and more ses of disruptions to transportation systems has primarily been de-
importantly the response to and recovery from such failures when voted to highway and railway transport systems (Sohn et al. 2004;
they inevitably occur, an important challenge exists in portraying Gordon et al. 2004; Ham et al. 2005a, b) and coastal ports (Rosoff
the widespread economic losses resulting from a disruptive event, and von Winterfeldt 2007; Park 2008; Jung et al. 2009). Little work
as well as measuring the efficacy of risk management to determine is done to understand the impacts of inland waterway port and
the appropriate investment to enable preparedness. network closures: Pant et al. (2011) provide a simulation model
Of interest here are transportation systems, specifically inland of inland port activities to parameterize a port disruption within
waterway navigation systems, though the methodology provided a multiregional interdependency model, while MacKenzie et al.
here has broader applicability to preparedness in other infrastruc- (2012a) focus on the multiregional impacts in functionality and
ture systems. As truck and pedestrian traffic continues to increase, in economic losses of decision making for shipping alternatives
congestion on highway networks will worsen and become a major following an inland port disruption.
issue for commodity flows (U.S. Dept. of Transportation 2009, This paper integrates a dynamic interdependency modeling
2011; National Cooperative Freight Research Program 2010; methodology with a stochastic decision analysis methodology to
assess investment strategies for infrastructure preparedness, guided
1 by prior work by Santos et al. (2008), who developed a static
Ph.D. Student, School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Univ. of
Oklahoma, Norman, OK 73019. formulation for the interdependent effects of biofuel subsidies
2
Assistant Professor, School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, and the widespread adoption of biofuels. The dynamic interdepend-
Univ. of Oklahoma, 202 W. Boyd St., Room 124, Norman, OK 73019 ency model and the stochastic decision tree have both been sepa-
(corresponding author). E-mail: kashbarker@ou.edu rately used in risk analysis and decision-making problems, as is
3
Dugan Professor, School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Univ.
highlighted in the next section. However, the integration of both
of Oklahoma, Norman, OK 73019.
Note. This manuscript was submitted on August 30, 2012; approved on
approaches with the addition of uncertainty analysis through prob-
May 22, 2013; published online on May 24, 2013. Discussion period abilistic measures is a novel idea constituting the main contribution
open until May 26, 2014; separate discussions must be submitted for of this paper. The sections of this paper, in order, provide the meth-
individual papers. This paper is part of the Journal of Infrastructure Sys- odological background of the dynamic multiobjective inoperability
tems, © ASCE, ISSN 1076-0342/04013012(12)/$25.00. decision tree; an extension of the multiobjective inoperability

© ASCE 04013012-1 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


decision tree to address stochastic decision tree problems; a case some decision makers might be interested in the mean of the dis-
study of a disruption of the Port of Catoosa, an inland waterway tribution while more risk-averse decision makers base their analysis
port on the Mississippi River Navigation System near Tulsa, on the 70th or higher percentile. The point estimate alone does not
Oklahoma; and concluding remarks. offer sufficient information in the selection of parameters represent-
ing the outcome function.
The outcome of a particular path of alternatives and states of
Methodological Background nature is quantified with function rð·Þ. Alternatives are compared
by the rollback method, which consists of computing the expected
This section provides a discussion of several of the components that value of each outcome resulting from a specific path followed in the
will make up the dynamic multiobjective decision tree deployed for tree. For a v-period tree, theP
expected value for the lth alternative at
infrastructure preparedness. the vth decision is E½avl  ¼ j∈Jv pðsvj Þrðavi ; svj Þ, and in prior peri-
l
ods, the expected
P value of the lth alternative at the kth decision is
Stochastic Decision Tree E½akl  ¼ j∈Jk pðskj ÞE½ak−1
j . If outcome rð·Þ represents an adverse
l

outcome (e.g., risk), the alternative that minimizes E½akl  would be


Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

A common tool for aiding the decision-making process through the


chosen at time k. Likewise, if rð·Þ represents a beneficial outcome
graphical depiction of a sequence of decisions and uncertain events
is the decision tree (Raiffa 1968). A simple one-period decision tree (e.g., profit), the alternative that maximizes E½akl  would be chosen.
is provided in Fig. 1, with notation from Santos et al. (2008) and Folding back stochastic decision trees is done using Monte Carlo
Barker and Wilson (2012). Decisions are made at decision nodes, simulation, as the point estimates pðskj Þ are replaced with distribu-
designated by squares in the decision tree, and branches extending tions (Dicdican and Haimes 2005), and consequently rð·Þ functions
from a decision node represent actions, options, or alternatives from follow a distribution function. The decision is then based on the
which the decision maker has to choose. The notation in Fig. 1 for probability distribution of the expected value.
the lth decision alternative for the kth time period in which that There are typically a finite number of alternatives and states of
decision is made is alternative akl . Chance nodes are designated nature. The drawback of using a decision tree is that the number of
with a circle, and branches emanating from a chance node represent branches emanating from the nodes must be small, otherwise com-
the states of nature, the occurrences that occur with some known putations can easily become cumbersome. In addition, it might not
probability. The jth state of nature in the kth time period in which be possible to sufficiently specify all the alternatives necessary to
the chance event may occur is represented by skj. The probability of represent the uncertainty of the event.
occurrence
P of a state of nature is represented by pðskj Þ, where Many real-world decisions often require the trade-off of multi-
k k
j∈J ki pðsj Þ ¼ 1 and set J l refers to the set of state of nature sub- ple objectives. Haimes et al. (1990) provide an approach for dealing
scripts that follow the lth alternative in period k and which them- with multiple objectives in sequential decision making with the
selves occur in period k. Stochastic decision trees, like that depicted multiobjective decision tree (MODT). The single outcome function
in Fig. 1, can better incorporate uncertainty by using probability rð·Þ corresponding to a sequential set of alternatives is replaced
distributions for the likelihood of the occurrence of states of nature with a vector-valued outcome function or a vector of m outcomes,
instead of probability point estimates (Hespos and Strassman [r1 ð·Þ; : : : ; rm ð·Þ]. The rollback procedure for MODTs is similar
1965). The use of probability distributions in stochastic decision to that for decision trees with a single objective. Each sequential
trees, as opposed to the point estimates in the traditional decision path of decisions and chances results in a vector-valued outcome
trees, provides a more comprehensive way to model uncertainty function at final period v, generally represented as ½r1 ðavi ; svj Þ; : : : ;
and a wider selection of decision key parameters. For example, rm ðavi ; svj Þ, noting again that the value of the vector-valued

Fig. 1. Depiction of a general stochastic decision tree

© ASCE 04013012-2 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


outcome function is found for a specific path of alternatives and aij ¼ aij ð^xj =^xi Þ ⇔ A ¼ ½diagðxÞ
^ −1 A½diagðxÞ
^ ð4Þ
states of nature from periods 1 to v. When each of the m outcomes
in [r1 ð·Þ; : : : ; rm ð·Þ] represents an adverse outcome, a minimum Such a matrix would translate the relationship between indus-
to the vector-valued function is sought at each decision node. tries and the impact caused to an industry by the disruption of an-
However, there may exist no single optimal alternative to roll back other industry sector. If, for example, a disruption affects petroleum
to the previous period but more likely a set of noninferior, or production, electric power and transportation industries would also
Pareto-optimal, solutions. A noninferior solution is defined as a be adversely impacted by the disruption. Note that industry sectors
solution to a multiobjective problem where any improvement in are impacted differently by the disruption of one particular industry,
one objective comes only at the expense of another objective and in some cases, in which the impact is infinitesimal or does not
(Chankong and Haimes 2008). Trade-offs among the m competing exist, the matrix entry would be null. Eq. (5) calculates c , a vector
objectives can be calculated between each string of alternatives. of normalized demand reduction, that drives inoperability in the
demand-reduction IIM (Santos 2006):
Interdependency Model ci ¼ ð^ci − c~ i Þ=^xi ⇔ c ¼ ½diagðxÞ
^ −1 ð^c − cÞ
~ ð5Þ
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

A widely accepted model for describing the interconnected rela-


The elements of c represent the difference in as-planned
tionships among infrastructure systems and industry sectors is
demand ĉi and perturbed demand c~ i divided by as-planned produc-
the Nobel Prize-winning economic input-output model (Leontief
tion, quantifying the reduced final demand for sector i as a propor-
1966), as shown in Eq. (1). For a set of n infrastructure and industry
tion of total as-planned output. The effects of inoperability across
sectors, n × 1 vector x quantifies production outputs in each sector,
multiple sectors can be expressed with total economic losses,
n × n matrix A represents the proportional interdependence among
Q ¼ xT q, or the amount of production made inoperable due to
sectors (that is, Ax represents intermediate demand resulting from
a disruption.
the production of x), and n × 1 vector c provides final exogenous
A dynamic version of this model, the dynamic inoperability
consumer demand. As such, Eq. (1) describes how changes in con-
input-output model, or DIIM, calculates the inoperability at any
sumer demand lead to widespread changes in sector production:
point in time using the recursive formula in Eq. (6), quantifying
the temporal nature of how inoperability propagates across sectors
x ¼ Ax þ c ⇒ x ¼ ½I − A−1 c ð1Þ
then dissipates with recovery (Lian and Haimes 2006). The inop-
erability vector, qðtÞ, as well as the vector of demand perturbation,
The extensive usage of input-output models is due, in part, to the c ðtÞ, change in time. An n × n resilience matrix, K, represents the
availability of economic interdependency data describing the inter- capability of a certain sector to recover from the disruptive event
connected nature of infrastructures and industries in a number of and reach a desired performance state:
countries (Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Develop-
ment 2011), including an extensive data collection effort by qðt þ 1Þ ¼ ðI − KÞqðtÞ þ K½A qðtÞ þ c ðtÞ ð6Þ
the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), which maintains
input-output tables at different levels of aggregations (BEA 2010). One way to estimate the entries in matrix K is in Eq. (7), a result
The input-output framework has also been used in modeling inter- of the dynamic version of Eq. (6) with no temporal demand per-
dependent systems that are not economic in nature [e.g., by Setola turbations (Lian and Haimes 2006). Value qi ð0Þ is the initial inop-
and De Porcellinis (2008)]. erability experienced in sector i following a disruptive event, qi ðT i Þ
The input-output model was extended to describe the propaga- is the desired inoperability state after recovery (assumed to be small
tion of inoperability, or the proportional extent to which sectors are but nonzero), which requires T i time periods to achieve, and aii is
not performing in an as-planned manner (e.g., reduced production the diagonal entry in the interdependency matrix:
capability), through several interdependent infrastructure and in- h i
dustry sectors (Santos and Haimes 2004b). This model, the inop- ln qqiiðT
ð0Þ

erability input-output model (IIM), is expressed in Eq. (2): ki ¼ ð7Þ
T i ð1 − aii Þ
q ¼ A q þ c ⇒ q ¼ ½I − A −1 c ð2Þ The IIM and its extensions have been used in a number of
risk-based applications, including inventory decision making
Vector q is a vector of infrastructure and industry inoperabilities, (MacKenzie et al. 2012c; Barker and Santos 2010a), workforce
proportional reductions in production, describing the extent to disruptions (Barker and Santos 2010b; Orsi and Santos 2010), and
which ideal functionality is not realized following a disruptive electric power outages (MacKenzie and Barker 2012; Anderson
event. Inoperability for sector i is defined in Eq. (3), where as- et al. 2007), among others.
planned total output is represented with x̂i and degraded total out-
put resulting from a disruption is represented with x~ i :
Distribution Assumptions
−1
qi ¼ ð^xi − x~ i Þ=^xi ⇔ q ¼ ½diagð^xÞ ðx^ − xÞ
~ ð3Þ Two sources of uncertainty enter the analysis of infrastructure pre-
paredness as described here: (1) the uncertainty associated with the
An inoperability of 0 suggests that an industry is operating at states of nature that may occur, as depicted in the decision tree, and
normal production levels, while an inoperability of 1 means that (2) the uncertainty associated with how sequences of decisions and
the industry is not producing at all. Normalized interdependency states of nature will impact demand perturbations in the inter-
matrix A is a modified version of the original A matrix describing dependency model (thereby driving the calculation of inoperability
the extent of economic interdependence among a set of infra- across sectors). These two representations of uncertainty are de-
structure and industry sectors. Shown in Eq. (4), A is an inter- scribed subsequently. Note that the two uncertainties considered
dependency matrix in which every entry represents how much here are not related to interconnectedness of the economy repre-
inoperability is contributed by the column industry to the corre- sented by the A matrix. Therefore, although the interdependent
sponding row industry: impact between industries involves uncertainties, this is not

© ASCE 04013012-3 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


analyzed in this paper. An integration of the suggested approach and sample variance, s2 , the parameters are estimated with
with models that consider not only the uncertainty of the inoper- Eqs. (12) and (13):
ability but also the uncertainty of the A matrix (Barker and  
Rocco 2011; Oliva et al. 2011) constitutes the subject of future X̄ð1 − X̄Þ
α̂ ¼ X̄ −1 ð12Þ
research. s

 
Distribution of Disruptive Events X̄ð1 − X̄Þ
β̂ ¼ ð1 − X̄Þ −1 ð13Þ
s
Discussed in more detail in the methodological development
section, the states of nature describe the magnitude of a disruptive
event at the inland port, where such an event may be rare in nature Dynamic Multiobjective Inoperability Decision Tree
with large impacts. Originally introduced through the idea of the
scale invariance (Richardson 1948), which is an inverse power scal- Extending a static version of the multiobjective inoperability deci-
ing between independent and dependent variables, the power-law sion tree (MOIDT) (Santos et al. 2008), this section describes a
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

distribution has been used to model different social, political, and dynamic and stochastic MOIDT to model the (1) investment in in-
financial patterns in history. frastructure preparedness, and (2) the interdependent benefits of
Studies aimed at determining the probability distribution of such investments (or adverse impacts of a lack of investment).
the severity of a terrorist attack agree that, according to empirical The use of the DIIM considers the cumulative effect of the
data on worldwide terrorist events from 1968 to 2008, the proba- total economic loss, a risk measure of interest to decision makers.
bility of a terrorist event claiming x deaths follows a power-law Also, the problem is solved here by taking into account the uncer-
distribution (Clauset and Youngal, unpublished data, 2005; tainty in the parameters of the DIIM as well as in the states of nature
Johnson et al. 2006; Clauset et al. 2007): in the decision tree. As a consequence, the parameters of the beta
distribution for each entry in the demand perturbation matrix, c ,
PðxÞ ¼ Cx−λ ð8Þ
depend on the state of nature as well as on the point estimates of
This model, which is provided in Eq. (8) for scale parameter λ each entry.
and normalizing constant C, has been extended to a more general
form to describe other covariates such as the size and experience of Infrastructure Preparedness Decision Problem
the terrorist organization and the type of weapons used in the attack
(Clauset and Gleditsch 2009; Clauset and Wiegel 2009). Power-law An influence diagram is a useful graphical tool that helps to visu-
relationships are also used to model the severity of natural disasters alize the decision problem in terms of the decision, uncertainties,
such as tornadoes (Malamud and Turcotte 2012), other severe objectives, and the influential relationship each has on the others.
weather conditions (Dessai and Walter 2000), and large earth- For the infrastructure preparedness decision problem in Fig. 2, the
quakes (Mega et al. 2003), among others. decision to make, represented by a rectangle, is a certain amount
Statistical methods such as the least square methods, the of dollars invested in preparedness activities. This decision will
maximum likelihood function, or an extended combination of these directly affect one of the objective functions, represented by a dia-
with other statistical tests are used to estimate the parameters of this mond shape, which is the cost. It will also indirectly affect the other
distribution (Clauset et al. 2009): λ, C, and minimum value of the objective function, which is the expected total economic loss as it
random variable xmin . will impact two uncertainties, represented by a circular shape:
(1) the probability of a disruptive event occurring (in case of a man-
made attack), and (2) the severity of the disruptive event. Hence, the
Distribution of Demand Perturbation problem presented is a multiobjective decision problem in which
The manner in which the disruptive event affects changes in the decision maker is interested in minimizing both the cost of pre-
demand is itself represented with a probability distribution. As in paredness and the expected total economic loss in case of a disrup-
Santos et al. (2008) and Santos (2008), the beta distribution is used tive event. Both objectives are competing (as increased investment
here to describe uncertainty in c . An advantage of using this in preparedness would expectedly lead to fewer losses). And while
distribution, whose probability density function is shown in both are measured in dollar terms, the objectives are noncommen-
Eq. (9), is that its support is on [0,1]. This is beneficial in describing surable in that investment budgets would likely come primarily
a parameter such as ci , the minimum and maximum are control-
lable, and the range of values of its parameters determine several
shapes for the probability distribution:
Γðα þ βÞ α−1
fðxÞ ¼ x ð1 − xÞβ−1 ð9Þ
ΓðαÞΓðβÞ

The mean and variance of the beta distribution are shown in


Eqs. (10) and (11), respectively:
α
μ¼ ð10Þ
αþβ

αβ
σ2 ¼ ð11Þ
ðα þ βÞ2 ðα þ β þ 1Þ
Fig. 2. Influence diagram describing the infrastructure preparedness
The parameters of this distribution are estimated using the
investment decision-making process
method of moments. Given the values of the sample mean, X̄,

© ASCE 04013012-4 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


from government sources, while losses would be experienced While multiple planning periods could be explored with this prob-
across a wide number of infrastructure and industry sectors. lem, only a one-period tree is addressed here.
From Fig. 2, the preparedness investment decision directly The outcome of each sequential decision and state of nature is a
affects the cost, and this investment has an effect on the likelihood (1) cost of investment and (2) total economic loss across all sectors
and severity of a disruptive event. The way in which the investment resulting from the disruptive event corresponding to the chance
affects these others quantities is through a factor of influence, θi , node. The relationships below describe how the investment deci-
linearly related to the investment amount, I, and the maximum sion, through the factor of influence, θI , from Eq. (14), alters
amount to be invested, I max , as shown in Eq. (14): the different parameters in the model.
First, the probability of a disruptive event occurring is decreased
I with increasing investment, as governed by Eq. (15). That is, de-
θI ¼ ð14Þ
I max pending on the nature of the investment, some amount of protection
is assumed in preventing the event (or reducing its likelihood of
The factor of influence is used as a translation of the amount occurrence). The probability of the occurrence of the event, p,
invested from dollars to fraction terms expressing how large is is reduced to pI :
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

the investment compared to other possible investments. In particu-


lar, the amount invested is compared to the maximum investment pI ¼ e−θI p ð15Þ
that can be made and is then expressed as a value between 0 and 1,
providing the factor of influence. The impact of the investment on
the likelihood and severity of the disruption can then be modeled Dynamic Recovery Model
using this factor. A simple linear relationship between the invest- It is assumed that a disruptive event befalling the infrastructure sys-
ment and the factor of influence is more than enough to express tem impacts demand for commodities whose flow or production
how large the investment is in proportion terms. A more sophisti- is enabled by the infrastructure (e.g., commodities that flow
cated relationship would make unnecessary complications to the through a port would be impacted by the port’s closure). Such a
overall model. Note that the impact of investment through that fac- demand perturbation for some commodities could be the result
tor of influence may not be as simple as a linear relationship and is of a supply reduction in other commodities. Given the magnitude
thoroughly discussed in the following section. of disruptive events in infrastructure systems and their large eco-
nomic impacts, industries and consumers overall tend to become
more conservative in demand activity due to the instability of
Decision Tree Construction and Parameters
the economy after the disruption. This does not mean that supply
A dynamic MOIDT is constructed in Fig. 3 to address the invest- or production is also impacted by the disruption. In fact, the inop-
ment in infrastructure preparedness, where the decision addresses erability vector in the DIIM is representative of the supply reduc-
the amount of investment in period k, I kj . Two chance nodes are tion following disruptive events. To account for the uncertainty in
assumed: the first concerns the occurrence of a disruptive event, the demand reduction, the values of the entries in the c vector are
and the second concerns the severity of the event if it occurs. drawn from the beta distribution whose parameters depend on the
The occurrence of the event is a deterministic chance node where severity of the disruptive event. The severity is generated from the
the likelihood of occurrence is known to be p. The second chance stochastic chance node in the decision tree following a power-law
node representing the severity has infinitely many states of nature distribution.
to represent the severity of attack (thus, a stochastic chance node), The severity of the event and the amount invested in prepared-
and consequently the demand perturbation and ultimate total eco- ness activities are two factors having opposite impacts on several
nomic losses across all sectors. The stochastic nature of the severity distributional parameters as well as other parameters in the model.
of the disruption is modeled with the power law distribution, and As noted earlier, the shape and scale parameters of the beta distri-
the demand perturbation is modeled with the beta distribution. bution for c are estimated using the method of moments according

Fig. 3. Multiobjective stochastic inoperability decision tree for infrastructure preparedness

© ASCE 04013012-5 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


to Eqs. (12) and (13). This method considers the sample mean and The idea is deemed useful in a manner that is not too simplistic,
variance to be known. The sample mean of the demand reduction, such as the case of a linear relationship, and not too complicated
X̄, is directly related to the maximum demand perturbation cmax , in a manner to make it problem-specific. Similar ideas have been
with the latter representing the worst-case scenario that could occur. implemented in other scenarios, such as resource allocation prob-
For example, this could describe a one-year closure of a transpor- lems (MacKenzie et al. 2012b).
tation facility (e.g., inland waterway port) or any type of prolonged Note the double effect on the input parameter from the severity
dysfunction of an infrastructure affecting the economy. Such sce- of an event leading to more perturbation and inoperability and less
narios are generally assessed by means of expert solicitation. resilience, while risk management helps in decreasing the initial
The sample mean of the demand perturbation is in fact a impact and increasing the recovery rate by decreasing the time
proportion of the maximum perturbation, and this proportion, γ, required to full recovery.
depends on the severity of the event. For example, if severity is It is also worth noting that the demand perturbation, which is
measured in terms of the number of months a certain facility is a function of time, starts to decrease as recovery commences
closed, and the worst-case scenario assumes a full year of closure, and is updated at discrete time points from t ¼ 1 to t ¼ T ¼
then γ ¼ 0.75 for a nine-month closure. Further, the sample mean maxðT 1 ; T 2 ; : : : ; T n Þ. Updating the demand reduction during
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

has a negative exponential relationship with the factor of influence, the recovery process depends on the case study and will be further
θI , computed in Eq. (14). This relationship ensures that as the developed in the illustration in case study section.
amount of investment is increased, the reduction in demand after The decision is then based on the aggregate economic loss
a disruptive event is exponentially decreased. These relationships computed at the time, T, when all industries are fully recovered,
are represented in vector form in Eq. (16), where X̄ increases as and since the decision tree is a one-period, more precisely one-year
the proportion of the maximum demand perturbation increases, de- decision tree, there is one investment to be made.
pending on the severity of the event, and it decreases exponentially
as the factor influence (or equivalently the amount invested) Simulation of the Decision Tree
increases:
Alluded to previously, stochastic decision trees require the use of
X̄ ¼ γe−θI cmax ð16Þ Monte Carlo simulation in the folding back process. For each alter-
native emanating from the first decision node, a fixed cost repre-
Likewise, standard deviation s is computed by assuming that the senting the amount invested is assumed, and θI for an investment of
maximum demand perturbation lies three standard deviations I can be computed. The following steps guide the simulation for a
above the mean, shown in vector form in Eq. (17). No further sufficiently large number of iterations:
restrictions or assumptions are applied to sample variance, which 1. Generate a random variable from the power law distribution
results in larger variations when the sample mean is smaller: within the bounds of the minimum and maximum severity,
guided by Eq. (8).
1
s ¼ ðcmax − X̄Þ ð17Þ 2. Given the severity, factor of influence, θI , and the elicited
3 values cmax and qmax ð0Þ, calculate the sample mean, X̄, and
Similar to the sample mean, the initial inoperability is a function standard deviation, s, of the demand perturbation from
of both the investment strategy, θI , and the severity of the event, γ, Eqs. (16) and (17), the parameters of the DIIM from Eqs. (18)
as shown in Eq. (18), where qmax ð0Þ represents the vector of initial and (19), and the probability, pI , of a disruptive event occur-
inoperability under the most extreme circumstances: ring from Eq. (15).
3. Using the method of moments, compute estimates for the para-
qð0Þ ¼ γe−θI qmax ð0Þ ð18Þ meters of the beta distribution from Eqs. (12) and (13) and
draw random variables from this distribution for each industry
The values of qmax ð0Þ could either be determined by experts or element in the demand perturbation vector. It is assumed that
estimated depending on the system considered in the application. the number n 0 of initially perturbed industries can represent a
Resilience is often defined from two aspects: (1) reducing the subset of all industries, n 0 ≤ n.
impact of a disruptive event, and (2) improving the speed with 4. Compute the inoperability vector at each point in time
which recovery occurs (Henry and Ramirez-Marquez 2012; Zobel from Eq. (3). P
2011). The effect of an investment in improving the first aspect is 5. Compute the total economic loss, QðTÞ ¼ xT τt¼1 qðtÞ.
found in Eq. (18), where the initial inoperability experienced after a 6. Compute the expected value of the total economic loss as the
disruptive event is lessened with an investment in infrastructure product of the loss and the probability p of a disruptive
preparedness. The second aspect is addressed in Eq. (19), where event, EQðTÞ ¼ QðTÞp.
preparedness investments can also decrease the time to full recov- Repeating the above steps for a number of iterations, N, for one
ery of industry i, T i . Like the previous relationships, recovery particular investment cost results in a distribution for EQ under this
time is reduced according to e−θI T i , an exponentially decreasing specific investment. The mean values of the EQ distributions for
function of the factor of influence, θI . As recovery commences, each investment could be compared to determine the appropriate
inoperability decreases over time, consequently impacting total investment level. Further, the conditional expected value (upper-
economic losses across all sectors over time, QðtÞ ¼ xðtÞT qðtÞ: tail value) provides an idea of how each investment performs in
h i extreme conditions (Asbeck and Haimes 1984).
ln q ðeqi−θð0ÞI T Þ
i
ki ¼ −θ i ð19Þ
ðe I T i Þð1 − aii Þ Illustrative Example: Inland Waterway Port
Investment
The amount invested in port security and system hardening, in
general having an exponential impact on the effect of a disruption, The methodology developed in this paper is illustrated with a
is a more realistic representation of the real life behavior of im- decision problem regarding inland waterway port security and resil-
provements in the risk management of infrastructure systems. ience. This data-driven case study involves the Port of Catoosa in

© ASCE 04013012-6 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


Tulsa, Oklahoma, the largest inland port in the United States in considering other values for the probabilities. The choice of this
terms of area. Located on McClellan-Kerr Arkansas River, the port value serves solely for illustration purposes, though it is motivated
is part of the Mississippi River Navigation System and roughly from previous work.
2 million tons of commodities flow annually through the port. Generally extreme events that are modeled with a power-
As such, preparing for disruptive events is crucial to the port itself law distribution result in an estimated scale parameter ranging
as well as to the economic system depending on the trading activity between 2 and 3 (refer to the previous discussion on the distribution
at the port. of disruptive events in the distribution assumptions). It is then
assumed that λ ¼ 2.5 and, for simplicity, C ¼ 1. In addition, it is
assumed that the severity of the disruptive event is bounded with a
Motivation minimum and a maximum number of days during which the port is
The Dept. of Homeland Security (DHS) announced a set of grant closed, between 15 and 60 days.
programs targeting different areas prone to willful attacks or natural The cost of investment, I, ranges from $0 to $1,000,000 and the
disasters (DHS 2012). The grants aim at providing resources proportion parameter of the severity of the event, γ, is the number
helpful in supporting the National Preparedness Goal (NPG) in suc- of days the port is closed divided by 365, meaning that the maxi-
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

ceeding in its mission of ensuring “a secure and resilient Nation mum perturbation and initial inoperability represent a one-year clo-
with the capabilities required across the whole community to pre- sure of the port. Since this case study is motivated by the amount of
vent, protect against, mitigate, respond to, and recover from the grant from PSGP allocated to the group of ports to which the Port of
threats and hazards that pose the greatest risk” (DHS 2011). Catoosa belongs, the maximum amount of investment is deter-
Among this set of grants is the Port Security Grant Program mined accordingly. It is also assumed that all the industries require
(PSGP), whose purpose is “ : : : to support increased port-wide risk the same time, T ¼ T i , to fully recover, where T depends on the
management; enhanced domain awareness; training and exercises; duration of the closure of the port. In this particular example we
expansion of port recovery and resiliency capabilities; and further consider κ ¼ 0.5, and assume that if the port was closed for D days,
capabilities to prevent, detect, respond to, and recover from the industries relying on the port as well as the interdependent in-
attacks : : : and : : : assist ports in obtaining the resources required dustries will all recover in T ¼ κD days. This assumes that while
to support the NPG’s associated mission areas and core the port was closed, the products that were supposed to be exported
capabilities.” were held at the port and those that were supposed to be imported
According to the grant program overview report (DHS 2012), were held at their original port, and after the port reopened, the port
the ports in the United States were categorized into three different needs T days to ship all the products held and hence the industries
groups, and DHS divided the grant of the PSGP among the three would be fully recovered. This would mostly affect the manner
groups. However, the ports within each category were to compete in which the demand perturbation is decreasing in the recovery
for the funding available in their group. According to that report, period, and instead of adding c ðtÞ, in Eq. (6), we are adding
the group in which the Tulsa Port of Catoosa is placed contains a the change in the demand perturbation, Δc , which considers that
total of 22 ports and received a grant of $4,875,000. The approach once the recovery starts, the commodity flows through the port at a
provided in this paper could provide a helpful means to determine rate of 1=κ; in this case the flow is twice as much as it usually is to
the appropriate investment amount allocated to each port based on make up for the loss and the time during which the commodity had
the port’s size, its mix of annual commodity flows, and its location, to wait at the port. During the recovery, the daily demand pertur-
among other factors impacting the probability of a disruptive event bation is subtracted from the initial demand perturbation and
occurring as well as its consequences in terms of economic losses. updated accordingly every day until Δc ðTÞ ¼ 0. Note that while
the port was closed for D days, the recovery process does not
start until the port reopens. This suggests that the port and associ-
Assumptions ated industries are not functioning for D days, after which the
The probability of a (rare) event causing a disruption of an extreme recovery process commences and spans T ¼ κD days before the
nature at the port is assumed to be similar to the probability of a port and industries are fully recovered. However, since the DIIM
terrorist attack since this type of event would incur large impacts models the recovery process, the model is implemented for T ¼ κD
and rarely occurs. This assumption is merely for illustration pur- days and not the full period of time required to fully recover,
poses; a sensitivity analysis will follow to address scenarios with D þ κD:
different probabilities. Bun (2006) developed a mathematical
1  1 
model to measure the probability of a nuclear terrorist attack, find- Δc ð1Þ ¼ c ð0Þ − c ð0Þ Δc ðtÞ ¼ Δc ðt − 1Þ − c ð0Þ
ing that, with a set of plausible parameters, the probability of a nu- T T
clear terrorist attack in the next 10 years is 0.29. Extending from ð20Þ
this result, the probability associated with a terrorist event occurring
in a one-year period is assumed to be 0.29=10 ¼ 0.029, which Finally, we assume that the demand perturbation comes from the
corresponds to one period of a decision tree. This computation loss in exports and is computed as the ratio of exports of industry i
assumes independence between probabilities of occurrence of a to the total production output of that industry at a specific time, t, as
terrorist attack over the years and generalizes the likelihood of a shown in Eq. (21):
nuclear terrorist attack to any broadly defined disruptive event.
Therefore, a baseline probability for a disruptive event occurring ei ðtÞ
ci ðtÞ ¼ ð21Þ
in one year is assumed to be 0.02 for this particular application. xi ðtÞ
Given that the result used is specific to a nuclear attack, it might
seem unrealistic to model any type of disruptive event occurring at Similarly, the inoperability is the result of imports not reaching
the Port of Catoosa. However, since determining the appropriate the port and causing a shortage in the material needed to produce in
estimate for the probability of a disruptive event lies beyond the the industries relying on such commodities. It is then the ratio of
scope of this research, a baseline probability is set to be slightly imports to the total production output of industry i, provided in
less than the given result and followed up by a sensitivity analysis Eq. (22) (MacKenzie et al. 2012a, Pant et al. 2011):

© ASCE 04013012-7 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


 
mi ðtÞ
q̂i ðtÞ ¼ ð22Þ
xi ðtÞ

If both the numerator and the denominator in Eqs. (21) and (22)
are yearly estimates, the above metrics can serve as the maximum
demand perturbation and the maximum inoperability because the
worst-case scenario is considered to be a full year of port closure
and they are used to compute the initial demand perturbation and
inoperability. The elements of the sample mean and initial inoper-
ability vectors in Eqs. (16) and (18) are then expressed in Eqs. (23)
and (24), where ei ðtÞ, mi ðtÞ, and xi ðtÞ, respectively, represent the
exports, imports, and total production output for industry i at time t
of one year:
 
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

−θI ei ðtÞ
X̄ i ¼ γe ð23Þ
xi ðtÞ
 
mi ðtÞ
qi ð0Þ ¼ γe−θI ð24Þ Fig. 4. Frequency distribution of the expected total economic losses
xi ðtÞ
across all regional industries
The input data described above rely on either (1) parameter
assumptions that could be altered depending on the application,
or (2) port-specific data. Several data sources from the Tulsa Port measured in dollars, they are not necessarily commensurate as
of Catoosa (2009), the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers (2010), and the preparedness investment would likely come from a port author-
the Bureau of Transportation Statistics (2009) were used by ity or DHS funding program while economic losses would be
MacKenzie et al. (2012a) to derive estimates of the dollar amount shared across multiple industries. The resulting Pareto-optimal
of commodities flowing through the Port of Catoosa. These frontier, plotting expected total economic loss, EQðTÞ, computed
estimates are inputs to Eqs. (21) and (22). The interdependencies once the industries are fully recovered, versus investment is shown
between the critical infrastructure and the rest of industries are in Fig. 5. Note that, as Fig. 4 suggests, there exists a probability
expressed by two matrices in the DIIM model: (1) the A matrix distribution for expected total economic loss for each realization
describes how inoperability propagates among industries when the of investment. Shown in Fig. 5 are the mean, M, of these distribu-
infrastructure is disrupted, and (2) the K matrix governs the recov- tions, as well as conditional means CM 0.01 and CM 0.05 . Although
ery of infrastructure and industry sectors. The entries in the A the Pareto-optimal frontiers in Fig. 5 are not completely smooth, it
matrix are computed using data from the Bureau of Economic is concluded that none of the investment strategies is dominant due
Analysis, and the formula for the entries of the K matrix is to the overall shape of the curve. Additional iterations would likely
discussed the DIIM background section. The idea of expressing result in smoother curves.
initial inoperability and demand perturbation as a fraction of the Here, the conditional expected total economic loss values are
worst-case scenario has been used in a different study on port upper-tail, or extreme, values associated with higher consequence,
disruptions (Pant et al. 2011). The length of closure of the port but lower probability, events (Asbeck and Haimes 1984). The
is chosen to be anywhere between two weeks and two months, conditional expected value is found with Eq. (25) and indicator
a reasonable assumption in the case of any disaster [e.g., see Pant function in Eq. (26):
et al. (2011)]. And the time to full recovery, controlled by κ, is ran-
domly chosen. These parameters can be altered according to each
case and largely depend on the decision makers and the type of risk
they seek to mitigate.

Decision Tree Solution


A simulation of 100,000 iterations was performed, and several
metrics related to inoperability and economic loss were computed
for each investment amount using the aggregate inoperability
throughout the recovery period.
The distribution of total economic loss without preparedness is
depicted in Fig. 4. The property of the power-law distribution can
be easily seen, as disruptive events with larger impacts have a
smaller chance of occurring, while less impactful events are more
common. An important feature of this distribution is that it does not
rule out extreme events as outliers but rather considers them as
events with an infinitesimal likelihood of occurrence, important
for a risk-averse decision maker who is interested in minimizing
extreme risks.
Recall that this MODT is constructed for two minimization
Fig. 5. Pareto frontier for expected total losses versus the amount
objectives: (1) expected total economic loss across all industries,
invested toward preparedness activities
and (2) investment amount. While both of these objectives are

© ASCE 04013012-8 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


PN
i¼1 δðiÞEQðiÞ
CM r ¼ EðEQjβ < EQ < ∞Þ ¼ PN ð25Þ
i¼1 δðiÞ


1 if EQðiÞ > β
δðiÞ ¼ ð26Þ
0 otherwise

The use of an upper-tail conditional expected economic loss


calculation is particularly telling for the power-law distribution,
which naturally has high consequence, low probability values in
its upper tail.
The indicator function is used to select the observations falling
under the upper-tail of the probability distribution and include them
in the computation of the conditional expectation, a means to
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

determine the extent to which the extremity of the event is consid-


ered. Depending on the decision maker, more or less extreme case
scenarios could be analyzed to determine the amount of prepared-
ness investment needed (e.g., risk-averse decision makers tend to
be prepared for more extreme events). Hence, using the indicator Fig. 6. Behavior of standard deviation of the expected total economic
function, it is possible to determine the degree of risk aversion of loss as investment increases
the decision maker (Santos and Haimes 2002a). The formula in
Eq. (27) calculates the significance level, which is the probability
corresponding to the upper-tail portion of the distribution of EQ:
different risk management strategies Si and Sj is computed in
1X N
Eq. (28):
r¼ δðiÞ ð27Þ
N i¼1
fnjSi − fnjSj
λðfm ;fn jSi Sj Þ ¼ − for i ≠ j ð28Þ
The larger the r, the less risk averse is the decision maker fmjSi − fmjSj
because the calculation is incorporating more points into the
expectation and the risk aversion is somehow moving toward a risk
neutral decision making using the mean. By examining Fig. 5, The trade-off analysis gives insights on the efficacy of additional
notice that all the metrics decrease as the investment cost increases, risk management investments. It is true that the more the decision
suggesting that the more the risk manager invests, the less impact- maker invests, the less the expected economic loss would be;
ful is the disruptive event in terms of economic losses. If the invest- however, how efficient is this additional investment? Consider
ment is higher than $800,000, both the mean and conditional means the numerical example in Eq. (29): investing $100,000 more would
provide very similar estimated values for the expected total eco- decrease the expected total economic loss by $5 million. A trade-
nomic loss. CM 0.01 and CM 0.05 are two conditional expectations off of 50 means that the total expected loss decreases by $50 for
for different levels of risk aversion. Risk-averse decision makers each $1 invested in preparedness:
would have to invest much more to get the same expected total
economic loss as a risk-neutral decision maker. For example, a 30 − 35
λ¼− ¼ 50 ð29Þ
risk-neutral decision maker investing $100,000 would see an ex- 0.2 − 0.1
pected total economic loss of about $10 million, while a risk-averse
decision maker aiming to reach the same level of expected eco- As long as the trade-off is positive, neither of the two strategies
nomic loss would need to invest $500,000 to $700,000 depending considered dominates the other. However, the value of that trade-off
on his or her extent of risk aversion. indicates how efficient the investment is. Note in Fig. 7 that the
Recall that no particular restriction was applied to the variance trade-off decreases as the amount invested increases while it re-
of the beta distribution except that cmax ¼ X̄ þ 3s. Fig. 6 plots the mains positive. This means that although the investment is helping
standard deviation of the total expected economic loss as the invest- to decrease the expected total economic loss, the efficiency of
ment changes. Note that the variation in the expected total eco- that risk management procedure is decreasing as the investment in-
nomic loss decreases as the investment increases, suggesting that creases. The same pattern is observed in Fig. 8, in which the trade-
no further restriction is required for the variance of the beta distri- off is based on the values of CM 0.01 from Fig. 5. Although it has a
bution as the model accounts for the behavior of the variance of the similar pattern of decreasing the efficiency of the investment as
expected total economic loss, ensuring that it decreases with larger more money is invested, the value of the trade-off is much larger
investments. Noted previously, additional iterations would result in than the one computed using the mean value of the expected total
smoother curves and hence the small jumps along the curve should economic loss. That is due to the decision maker being risk averse
be considered insignificant. and any additional investment would highly impact the risk func-
tion the decision maker is trying to minimize.
Trade-Off Analysis
Sensitivity Analysis
A trade-off analysis is necessary to study the additional effect on
the total economic loss of investing an extra dollar in port security. A number of input parameters needed to be estimated in this meth-
The trade-off analysis is done using the generalized trade-off func- odology; therefore, a sensitivity analysis is useful in determining
tion for discrete strategies used in Santos et al. (2008). The trade-off the impact of these parameters on the output of the model.
of a risk function f m with respect to another risk function fn for two One of the key parameters in this paper is the probability p of a

© ASCE 04013012-9 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

Fig. 9. Sensitivity analysis on the probability of a disruptive event


Fig. 7. Trade-off as a function of the cost of investment for a risk-neu-
tral decision maker

Conclusion

Preparedness decision making is an important issue critical infra-


structure systems have been dealing with for the past decade, given
their vulnerability to disruptive events and their interdependence
with other industries. Therefore, it is crucial to consider accurate
measures of the risk functions and use the appropriate methodol-
ogies to solve such decision problems. This paper provides a new
framework for analyzing such infrastructure preparedness prob-
lems, by integrating two well-known methodologies in risk analysis
and decision making, a stochastic decision tree and a dynamic inter-
dependency model, to capture the uncertain and widespread eco-
nomic impacts of disruptive events. With this framework, the
authors contribute a more comprehensive means to quantify risk
and measure the efficacy of risk management while accounting
for uncertainties in the parameters of the models used in this inte-
grated approach. Particular distributions, namely the power law and
beta distributions, are used here, though any appropriate distribu-
tions could describe the parameters of the decision problem.
The framework was applied to an inland port preparedness in-
vestment problem. Results suggest that while an increase in invest-
Fig. 8. Trade-off as a function of the cost of investment for a risk- ment provides better protection to the port in terms of the average
averse decision maker, r ¼ 0.01 and conditional expectation of the upper tail of the total economic
loss as well as the likelihood of a disruptive event occurring, the
decision maker should be aware of the value this increased invest-
disruptive event occurring, an important issue addressed in the ment is adding. Sometimes investing an additional dollar in port
probabilistic risk analysis applications. Determining the probability security might not greatly improve the port security, depending
of an accident, a willful attack, or a natural disaster occurring is on the risk preference of the decision maker.
challenging and has been a subject of research in the past decade. An extension to this research would be to consider multiperiod
A sensitivity analysis is performed to determine the effect of the decision trees and incorporate resource allocation in addition to
probability of a disruptive event on the expected economic loss as a preparedness decisions. Also, using a multiregional dynamic inter-
dependency model is useful in indicating the regional or even na-
function of different preparedness investment strategies. Fig. 9 de-
tional expected total economic losses.
picts the mean of the distribution of the expected total economic
loss, M, as a function of different preparedness strategies for several
possible probabilities of a disruptive event occurring ranging from Acknowledgments
0.01 to 0.05. Naturally, the higher the probability, the higher the
expected economic loss under any preparedness strategy. However, The authors wish to acknowledge the assistance of Dr. Cameron
the more the decision maker chooses to invest, the less the effect of MacKenzie, Assistant Professor with the Naval Postgraduate
the probability on the economic loss. More precisely, for prepar- School, and Dr. Raghav Pant, Infrastructure Network Analyst
edness investments of $600,000 or higher, the average expected with the University of Oxford. This work was supported in part
total economic loss is almost the same regardless of the estimated by the U.S. Federal Highway Administration, under awards
value used to express the probability of a disruptive event. SAFTEA-LU 1934 and SAFTEA-LU 1702, and the National

© ASCE 04013012-10 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


Science Foundation, Division of Civil, Mechanical, and Manufac- Ham, H., Kim, T. J., and Boyce, D. (2005a). “Assessment of economic
turing Innovation, under award 0927299. Further, the suggestions impacts from unexpected events with an interregional commodity
of the reviewers significantly improved this paper. flow and multimodal transportation network model.” Transp. Res.
Part A, 39(10), 849–860.
Ham, H., Kim, T. J., and Boyce, D. (2005b). “Implementation and estima-
tion of a combined model of interregional, multimodal commodity
References shipments and transportation network flows.” Transp. Res. Part B,
39(1), 65–79.
Anderson, C. W., Santos, J. R., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2007). “A risk-based
Haveman, J. D., and Howard, S. eds. (2006). Protecting the nation’s sea-
input-output methodology for measuring the effects of the August 2003
ports: Balancing security and cost, Public Policy Institute of California,
Northeast blackout.” Econ. Syst. Res., 19(2), 183–204.
San Francisco, CA.
Asbeck, E., and Haimes, Y. Y. (1984). “The partitioned multiobjective risk
Henry, D., and Ramirez-Marquez, J. E. (2012). “Generic metrics and
method.” Large Scale Syst., 6(1), 13–38.
quantitative approaches for system resilience as a function of time.”
Barker, K., and Rocco S., C. M. (2011). “Evaluating uncertainty in
Reliab. Eng. Syst. Saf., 99(1), 114–122.
risk-based interdependency modeling with interval arithmetic.” Econ.
Hespos, R. F., and Strassman, P. A. (1965). “Stochastic decision trees
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

Syst. Res., 23(2), 213–232.


for the analysis of investment decisions.” Manage. Sci., 11(10),
Barker, K., and Santos, J. R. (2010a). “Measuring the efficacy of inventory
244–259.
with a dynamic input-output model.” Int. J. Prod. Econ., 126(1),
Johnson, N. F., et al. (2006). “Universal patterns underlying ongoing wars
130–143.
and terrorism.” 〈arXiv: physics/06050305v.1〉 (Apr. 4, 2012).
Barker, K., and Santos, J. R. (2010b). “A risk-based approach for identify-
Jung, J., Santos, J. R., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2009). “International trade
ing key economic and infrastructure sectors.” Risk Anal., 30(6),
inoperability input–output model (IT-IIM).” Risk Anal., 29(1),
962–974.
137–154.
Barker, K., and Wilson, K. J. (2012). “Decision trees with single and
multiple interval-valued objectives.” Decis. Anal., 9(4), 348–358. Leontief, W. W. (1966). Input-output economics, Oxford University Press,
New York.
Bun, M. (2006). “A mathematical model of the risk of nuclear terrorism.”
Ann. Am. Acad. Polit. Soc. Sci., 607(1), 103–120. Lian, C., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2006). “Managing the risk of terrorism to
interdependent infrastructure systems through the dynamic inoperabil-
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). (2010). “Interactive access to input-
output accounts data.” 〈http://www.bea.gov.in〉 (Apr. 25, 2012). ity input-output model.” Syst. Eng., 9(3), 241–258.
Bureau of Transportation Statistics. (2009). “2007 commodity flow survey: MacKenzie, C., Barker, K., and Grant, F. H. (2012a). “Evaluating the
CF0700A10: Shipment characteristics by commodity by shipment consequences of an inland waterway port closure with a dynamic
weight by distance shipped for the U.S.” Research and Innovative Tech- multiregional interdependency model.” IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern.
nology Administration, 〈http://www.bts.gov/publications/commodity Part A, 42(2), 359–370.
flowsurvey/〉 (Apr. 25, 2012). MacKenzie, C. A., and Barker, K. (2012). “Empirical data and regression
Chankong, V., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2008). Multiobjective decision making: analysis for estimation of infrastructure resilience, with application to
Theory and methodology, Dover Publications, Mineola, NY. electric power outages.” J. Infrastruct. Syst., 10.1061/(ASCE)IS.1943-
Clauset, A., and Gleditsch, K. S. (2012). “The developmental dynamics of 555X.0000103, 25–35.
terrorist organizations.” PLOS ONE, 7(11), e48633. MacKenzie, C. A., Baroud, H., and Barker, K. (2012b). “Optimal resource
Clauset, A., Shalizi, C. R., and Newman, M. E. J. (2009). “Power-law allocation for recovery of interdependent systems: case study of the
distributions in empirical data.” SIAM Rev., 51(4), 661–703. deepwater horizon oil spill.” Proc., 2012 Industrial and Systems
Clauset, A., and Wiegel, F. W. (2009). “A generalized aggregation- Engineering Research Conf. (CD-ROM), G. Lim and J. W. Hermann,
disintegration model for the frequency of severe terrorist attacks.” eds.
J. Conflict Resolut., 54(1), 179–197. MacKenzie, C. A., Santos, J. R., and Barker, K. (2012c). “Measuring
Clauset, A., Young, M., and Gleditsch, K. S. (2007). “On the frequency of international production losses from a disruption: case study of the
severe terrorist events.” J. Conflict Resolut., 51(1), 58–87. Japanese earthquake and tsunami.” Int. J. Prod. Econ., 138(2),
Dept. of Homeland Security (DHS). (2009). National infrastructure pro- 293–302.
tection plan: Partnering to enhance protection and resiliency, U.S. Malamud, B. D., and Turcotte, D. L. (2012). “Statistics of severe tornadoes and
Dept. of Homeland Security, Washington, DC. severe tornado outbreaks.” Atmos. Chem. Phys. Discuss., 12, 6957–6988.
Dept. of Homeland Security (DHS). (2011). National preparedness goal, Mega, M. S., et al. (2003). “Power-law time distribution of large earth-
U.S. Dept. of Homeland Security, Washington, DC. quakes.” Phys. Rev. Lett., 90, 188501.
Dept. of Homeland Security (DHS). (2012). “FY 2012 preparedness grant National Cooperative Freight Research Program. (2010). “Research results
program overview.” U.S. Dept. of Homeland Security, Washington, DC. digest, subject areas: IV operations and safety, VII Rail, VIII freight
Dessai, S., and Walter, M. (2000). “Self-organized criticality and the atmos- transportation, IX marine transportation.” 〈http://onlinepubs.trb.org/
pheric sciences: Selected review, new findings and future direction.” onlinepubs/ncfrp/ncfrp_rrd_002.pdf〉 (Apr. 25, 2012).
Contributed to XE: Extreme Events: Developing a Research Agenda Oliva, G., Panzieri, S., and Setola, R. (2011). “Fuzzy dynamic input–
for the 21st Century 〈http://www.isse.ucar.edu/extremes/〉. output inoperability model.” Int. J. Crit. Infrastruct. Prot., 4(3–4),
Dicdican, R. Y., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2005). “Relating multiobjective 165–175.
decision trees to the multiobjective risk impact analysis method.” Syst. Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development. (2011).
Eng., 8(2), 95–108. “OECD. StatsExtrats.” 〈http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx〉 (Apr. 25,
Gordon, P., Moore, J. E., Richardson, H. W., Shinozuka, M., Donghwan, 2012).
A., and Cho, S. (2004). “Earthquake disaster mitigation for urban Orsi, M. J., and Santos, J. R. (2010). “Incorporating time-varying pertur-
transportation systems: An integrated methodology that builds on the bations into the dynamic inoperability input-output model.” IEEE
Kobe and Northridge experiences.” Modeling spatial and economic im- Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Part A, 40(1), 100–106.
pacts of disasters, Y. Okuyama and S. E. Chang, eds., Springer-Verlag, Pant, R., Barker, K., Grant, F. H., and Landers, T. L. (2011). “Interdepend-
Berlin, 205–232. ent impacts of inoperability at multi-modal transportation container
Government Accountability Office. (2011). “Surface freight transportation: terminals.” Transp. Res. E: Logist. Transp. Rev., 47(5), 722–737.
A comparison of the costs of road, rail, and waterways freight ship- Park, J. Y. (2008). “The economic impacts of dirty bomb attacks on the Los
ments that are not passed on to consumers.” GAO-11-134, U.S. Angeles and Long Beach ports: Applying the supply-driven NIEMO
Government Accountability Office, Washington, DC. (National Interstate Economic Model).” J. Homeland Security Emerg.
Haimes, Y. Y., Li, D., and Tulsiani, V. (1990). “Multiobjective decision tree Manage., 5(1).
method.” Risk Anal., 10(1), 111–129. Raiffa, H. (1968). Decision analysis, Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA.

© ASCE 04013012-11 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.


Richardson, L. F. (1948). “Variation of the frequency of fatal quarrels with Setola, R., and De Porcellinis, S. (2008). “A methodology to estimate input-
magnitude.” J. Am. Stat. Assoc., 43(244), 523–546. output inoperability model parameters.” Crit. Inf. Infrastruct. Secur.,
Rosoff, H., and von Winterfeldt, D. (2007). “A risk and economic analysis 5141, 149–160.
of dirty bomb attacks on the ports of Los Angeles and Long Beach.” Sohn, J., Hewings, G. J. D., Kim, T. J., Lee, J. S., and Jang, S. G . (2004).
Risk Anal., 27(3), 533–546. “Analysis of economic impacts of an earthquake on transportation
Santos, J. R. (2006). “Inoperability input-output modeling of disruptions to network.” Modeling spatial and economic impacts of disasters,
interdependent economic systems.” Syst. Eng., 9(1), 20–34. Y. Okuyama and S. E. Chang, eds., Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 233–256.
Santos, J. R. (2008). “Interdependency analysis with multiple probabilistic Tulsa Port of Catoosa. (2009). “Tonnage comparison: 2007–2008.” 〈http://
sector inputs.” J. Ind. Manage. Optim., 4(3), 489–510. www.tulsaport.com/aboutourwaterway.html〉 (May 21, 2010).
Santos, J. R., Barker, K., and Zelinke, P. J., IV.(2008). “Sequential decision- U.S. Army Corps of Engineers. (2010). Waterborne commerce of the
making in interdependent sectors with multiobjective inoperability United States: Calendar year 2009, U.S. Army Corps of Engineers
decision trees: Application to biofuel subsidy analysis.” Econ. Syst. Waterborne Commerce Statistics Center, New Orleans.
Res., 20(1), 29–56. U.S. Dept. of Transportation. (2009). Freight facts and figures 2009,
Santos, J. R., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2004a). “Applying the partitioned Federal Highway Administration, Office of Freight Management and
multiobjective risk method (PMRM) to portfolio selection.” Risk Anal., Operations, Washington, DC.
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by New York University on 05/12/15. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

24(3), 697–713. U.S. Dept. of Transportation. (2011). America’s marine highway, U.S. De-
Santos, J. R., and Haimes, Y. Y. (2004b). “Modeling the demand reduction partment of Transportation, Maritime Administration, Washington, DC.
input-output (I-O) inoperability due to terrorism of interconnected infra- Zobel, C. W. (2011). “Representing perceived tradeoffs in defining disaster
structures.” Risk Anal., 24(6), 1437–1451. resilience.” Decis. Support Syst., 50(2), 394–403.

© ASCE 04013012-12 J. Infrastruct. Syst.

J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2014.20.

You might also like