You are on page 1of 14

Regional Studies

ISSN: 0034-3404 (Print) 1360-0591 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cres20

The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and


Regional Urban Systems

John B. Parr

To cite this article: John B. Parr (2014) The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional
Urban Systems, Regional Studies, 48:12, 1926-1938, DOI: 10.1080/00343404.2013.799759

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2013.799759

Published online: 18 Jun 2013.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 1314

View Crossmark data

Citing articles: 21 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cres20
Regional Studies, 2014
Vol. 48, No. 12, 1926–1938, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2013.799759

The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and


Regional Urban Systems
JOHN B. PARR
School of Social and Political Sciences (Urban Studies), University of Glasgow, Glasgow G12 8QQ, UK.
Email: John.Parr@glasgow.ac.uk

(Received July 2011: in revised form March 2013)

PARR J. B. The regional economy, spatial structure and regional urban systems, Regional Studies. In approaching the concept of the
regional urban system, attention is initially drawn to the better-known types of economic region. The distinctive nature of the
regional economy is next examined, and it is argued that its spatial structure represents an important dimension. Spatial structure
can be characterized in a variety of ways, the most comprehensive of which employs the perspective of an urban system. This is
examined firstly in terms of particular models from location theory, which provide important points of reference, and then within
the setting of the present-day city-region.

Regions Regional economy Spatial structure Regional urban systems

PARR J. B. 区域经济、空间结构与区域城市系统,区域研究。本文在着手处理区域城市系统的概念时,首先将关注较
为人所熟知的经济区域类型,接着将检视区域经济的特殊性,并主张其空间结构表现出一个重要的面向。空间结构
的特徵可依各种不同的方式描绘之,其中最为广泛的方式便是运用城市系统的视角。此将首先以区位理论中的特定
模型检视之,该理论提供了重要的参照依据,再者将置放在当今城市—区域的脉络中检视之。

区域 区域经济 空间结构 区域城市系统

PARR J. B. L’économie régionale, la structure spatiale, et les systèmes urbano-régionaux, Regional Studies. Pour aborder la notion de
système urbano-régional, on porte une attention particulière dans un premier temps aux typologies de région plus connues. Il
s’ensuit un examen des particularités de l’économie régionale, et on affirme que sa structure spatiale constitue un facteur
important. On peut caractériser la structure spatiale de différentes manières, dont la plus exhaustive est du point de vue d’un
système urbain. On l’examine primo à partir des modèles particuliers puisés dans la théorie de la localisation, qui fournissent
d’importants points de repère, et secundo dans le cadre de la cité-région d’aujourd’hui.

Régions Économie régionale Ossature spatiale Systèmes urbano-régionaux

PARR J. B. Regionalwirtschaft, Raumstruktur und regionale Stadtsysteme, Regional Studies. In dieser Untersuchung des Konzepts
des regionalen Stadtsystems richtet sich der Augenmerk zunächst auf die bekannteren Typen der Wirtschaftsregion. Anschließend
werden die charakteristischen Merkmale der Regionalwirtschaft untersucht, und es wird die These aufgestellt, dass es sich bei ihrer
Raumstruktur um eine wichtige Dimension handelt. Die Raumstruktur lässt sich auf vielfältige Weise charakterisieren; bei der
umfassendsten dieser Methoden kommt die Perspektive eines Stadtsystems zum Einsatz. Diese wird zunächst mit Hilfe
bestimmter Modelle der Standorttheorie untersucht, die wichtige Anhaltspunkte bieten, und anschließend innerhalb der
Umgebung der heutigen Stadtregion.

Regionen Regionalwirtschaft Raumstruktur Regionale Stadtsysteme

PARR J. B. Economía regional, estructura espacial y sistemas urbanos regionales, Regional Studies. Al analizar el concepto del sistema
urbano regional, prestamos atención a los tipos más conocidos de la región económica. A continuación se examina la naturaleza
distintiva de la economía regional y se postula que su estructura espacial representa una dimensión importante. La estructura espacial
puede caracterizarse de varias formas, y la más completa de ellas emplea la perspectiva de un sistema urbano. Esto se analiza en
términos de modelos específicos de la teoría de la ubicación que ofrecen puntos de referencia importantes y luego en el
entorno de la región metropolitana de hoy día.

Regiones Economía regional Estructura espacial Sistemas urbanos regionales

JEL classifications: R, R1, R12

© 2013 Regional Studies Association


http://www.regionalstudies.org
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1927
INTRODUCTION however; the disciplinary tradition dies hard! In order
to simplify the argument, the major concern will be
The intention of the following discussion is to consider
with conditions in nations of the economically devel-
some of the more important aspects of the urban system
oped world, and the weaknesses of such a restriction
within the context of a regional economy. There can be
are acknowledged. The discussion proceeds as follows.
no question that the regional urban system occupies a
After briefly surveying several forms of economic
prominent position within market economies, in
region, attention is drawn to the regional economy
much the same manner that the metropolitan area
and the importance of spatial structure in its operation
came to play a comparable role during the course of
and development. The nature of the urban system is
the nineteenth century. The comments to follow are
next examined, with the initial focus on particular
based on four interrelated propositions, which collec-
location-theory frameworks. These provide a platform
tively form the background motivation for this examin-
for examining conditions within the city-region, a
ation of regional urban systems.
major feature of the contemporary economic landscape.
First, despite the upsurge of interest in the region
within the social sciences over recent decades
(STORPER , 1995), the concept of the region remains
THE ECONOMIC REGION
shrouded in uncertainty, with opinion sharply divided.
Some view the concept of the region as an inherently The notion of the economic region is a relatively new
vague one that defies precise definition (WREN , one. It came to be used during the 1920s in the
2009). Others (probably representing the majority United States within the fields of agricultural economics
view) embrace the concept as a flexible and therefore and economic geography, where agricultural regions,
convenient spatial scale that lends itself to a wide crop cultivation regions and manufacturing regions rep-
variety of interpretations and applications, not recogniz- resented early examples. More refined definitions sub-
ing perhaps that this very flexibility may be a source of sequently appeared.
imprecision. Second, the regional economy represents
a particular scale of economic organization. It is not to
A preliminary classification
be seen simply as an element of a disaggregated national
economy: the region contains an internal spatial struc- A useful starting point in any discussion of modern-day
ture of varying complexity, which is influenced by the economic regions is the tripartite classification proposed
course of economic and social change, but which may by MEYER (1963). He argued that for the purpose of
also exert an influence over such change. The nature economic analysis the following typology was useful:
of the regional economy can only be fully appreciated homogeneous (or uniform) regions; nodal regions; and
if there is adequate scrutiny of its spatial dimension. programming (that is, policy-related) regions. The
Third, in understanding the significance of regional homogeneous region probably comes closest to the
spatial structure, the urban system is an especially appro- popular view of an economic region as a space through-
priate perspective, since it is able to incorporate a out which there is a similarity of economic character-
number of different approaches. In this connection istics, and which by implication is distinguishable from
much is to be gained from visiting or revisiting those other regions. The regions proposed by OHLIN (1933)
branches of location theory concerned with urban and by NORTH (1955) fall into this category (PARR ,
systems. To a large extent such frameworks tend to be 2008).
overlooked, probably because these are thought to The nodal region, by contrast, is based on the internal
have little relevance in a world that has undergone structure of its economy. Reduced to its essentials, the
rapid economic and technological change during the nodal region is composed of two components: the
last sixty years. Fourth, the urban-system view of core or node and the hinterland. The core may rep-
spatial structure takes on a particular significance in the resent a service centre or point of supply for the hinter-
case of the city-region, an increasingly important land, which would comprise its market area.
feature of the national space economy. Although city- Alternatively and/or additionally, the core can be seen
regions display a diversity of forms, both within the indi- as a point of demand on the part of households or
vidual nation and among nations, striking commonal- firms for goods and services produced in the hinterland
ities are revealed when city-regions are seen through which would function as its supply area. In both cases,
the prism of the urban system. however, the core and the hinterland may contain
In the following discussion the perspective adopted economic activities that are primarily related to areas
will be largely of an economic character. As a conse- beyond the region. A general characteristic of the
quence, important aspects of a political, sociological nodal region is the pronounced interdependence
and institutional nature are not emphasized. Each is suf- (direct and indirect) between the core and the hinter-
ficiently substantial as to merit separate treatment, and land (HOOVER and FISHER , 1949), not simply with
under ideal circumstances these various strands would respect to trade, but also in terms of income levels,
be drawn together. Such a synthesis has yet to emerge, capital movements, migration, commuting, etc.1
1928 John B. Parr
MEYER ’s (1963) third type of region – the policy forms of integration are not specific to the PUR, and
region – represents a space over which an official body may be applied to other types of economic region.
exercises a jurisdiction in the implementation of a par-
ticular policy. While this could represent an existing
Variation in scale and hierarchical structure
political or administrative unit, it might also be a
special-purpose region such as the area of operation of It will be apparent that each of the regional types dis-
the Appalachia Regional Commission in the United cussed above may display a considerable variation in ter-
States. This tripartite classification of regions is a ritorial extent or relative scale, so that a given regional
common one, and most academic discussions of the type may be seen as occupying a particular position
region are concerned with one of the three types. along a continuum. To emphasize this point, consider
There is a degree of overlap between the three types the case of the nodal region. Toward the lower end of
of region, as Meyer clearly recognized. For example, the continuum there exists the ‘functional urban
the policy region could be based on a homogeneous region’ (FUR) (KARLSSON and OLSSEN , 2006),
region or a nodal region. which is often used in labour-market analysis. As with
all nodal regions, the FUR has a core–hinterland struc-
ture. The core is regarded as a centre of employment,
Other regional types
and is taken to be either the central municipality of an
The Meyer classification is incomplete, however, urban area or the entire urban area, while the hinterland
and mention is made of two other regional types. One consists of a series of directly or indirectly adjacent
is the region based on a watershed or river basin municipalities. Various methods have been used to
(KRUTILLA and ECKSTEIN , 1958). There is a case for define this type of FUR. One method is to include
regarding this as a homogeneous region, to the extent each municipality in the hinterland if it has a
that there may be a dominant pattern of agricultural minimum number of jobs per hectare, and if there are
land uses. On the other hand, the river has been more commuters travelling to the relevant core than
regarded as a barrier to interaction, often forming the to any other (CHESHIRE and HAY , 1989, p. 15). A less
basis for a political or administrative boundary. sophisticated method is to include a hinterland munici-
However, because of such trends as rail and road pality, if at least a certain percentage of its workforce is
communications replacing waterways, and resource employed in the core, this percentage being as low as
development declining in relative importance, regions 10% in a study of European FURs (BRUNEL , 2002).
based on river basins have tended to lose much of Toward the other end of the continuum of nodal
their significance in the organization of space. regions is the major city-region, a sub-national unit
Another regional type not fitting comfortably within comparable with those based on urban concentrations
the Meyer classification is the ‘polycentric urban region’ (and not simply their political cities) such as Barcelona,
(PUR) (DAVOUDI , 2003; MEIJERS et al., 2003). This has Birmingham, Bordeaux, Milan and Munich in
also been referred to as the ‘dispersed city’ (BURTON , Western Europe, and Boston, Denver, Kansas City,
1963) and ‘network city’ (BATTEN , 1994). Examples Seattle and Vancouver in North America. Here the
include the Ruhr District of Germany, Randstad in the core is represented by a larger city or metropolitan
Netherlands, and the Research Triangle (Raleigh, area that acts as an important centre of ownership,
Durham, Chapel Hill) of North Carolina in the United decision-making and communications, as well a provi-
States. As originally proposed, the PUR represented an der of goods and services to the hinterland, sometimes
area containing a cluster of urban centres, none of of considerable extent. Simultaneously, the hinterland,
which had a pronounced dominance over the others, which contains an urban as well as a rural population,
and each of which had one or more specializations, supplies the node with agricultural goods, raw materials,
usually giving rise to a well-developed pattern of inter- and semi-manufactured or finished goods as inputs to
action among the centres.2 Relevant here was the production, and is increasingly associated with the pro-
concept of ‘borrowed size’, by which smaller urban vision of services involving recreation, amenity and
centres would be able to benefit from their proximity retirement. Under no circumstances, however, should
to a larger centre (ALONSO , 1973). Note that the pres- the city-region be viewed as a closed system or self-
ence of clustered urban centres is a necessary, though sufficient entity, particularly since it invariably has
not a sufficient, condition for the existence of a PUR. extensive interregional as well as international linkages.
Again, there is a case for regarding the PUR as a homo- The term ‘city-region’ appears to have been first used
geneous region, largely on the grounds of its over- by DICKINSON (1947), and the concept was also exam-
whelming urban character, but this characterization ined in considerable depth by BOGUE (1950). Bogue
would fail to capture certain key facets of such a referred to it as the ‘metropolitan community’, and
region. An important aspect of the PUR is the extent somewhat later DUNCAN et al. (1960) used the
to which it is integrated, both morphologically and func- expression ‘metropolitan region’. Whereas Dickinson
tionally, a question recently explored in the case of and Duncan et al. tended to regard the hinterland in
Randstad by BURGER and MEIJERS (2012). These two general terms as an area dominated by the core,
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1929
Bogue examined the structure of the hinterland in more the national economy, social accounts provide impor-
detail, with attention given to the size-frequency struc- tant information on the regional economy. In output
ture of urban centres. From time to time it is argued that terms the gross domestic product of a region (corre-
what is deemed to be a PUR might be better viewed as a sponding to the gross domestic product of the nation)
series of city-regions, each based on a major centre of is the value of all goods and services produced within
the supposed PUR. The work of MUSTERD and VAN a region. By contrast, the gross regional product (corre-
ZELM (2001) and VAN OORT et al. (2010) may be sponding to the gross national product) is equal to the
cited as examples. It can be expected that the greater sum of gross domestic product and net external pay-
the territorial extent of the PUR, the more likely will ments, that is, the dividends, rents, wages received by
be the validity of this alternative interpretation. The residents and firms of the region from outside the
penultimate section of this paper will return to the region and transfers from the central government,
concept of the city-region. minus comparable payments made by residents and
This differentiation of a given type of region may also firms to outside the region, and payments made to the
be viewed in hierarchical terms. Continuing with the central government.
example of a nodal region, the FUR may represent a sec- Against these similarities between regional and
ondary city-region, situated within some primary city- national economies need to be set the equally important
region (of a scale similar to that indicated above). In differences. For example, the divergence between gross
view of the obvious advantage in having a political or domestic product of the region and gross regional
governmental region coincide with an economic product is usually more pronounced than the diver-
region, this hierarchical arrangement of economic gence at the national level. In addition, the economic
regions could form the basis of a two-tier system of performance of the region in terms of the growth rate
administration. Under actual conditions, however, it is of income or employment is likely to be above or
not unusual for a secondary city-region to straddle the below that of the nation, depending inter alia on the sec-
boundary between two (sometimes three) primary city- toral composition of its economy and the performance
regions. While this would not constitute a problem in of its individual sectors. Similarly, the temporal fluctu-
the supply of goods and services by the private sector ations of the regional economy (with respect to the
(nor, more generally, an obstacle to the efficient func- length and amplitude of the trade cycle) can be expected
tioning of the relevant regional economies), it would to differ from those of the national economy.
pose a problem for the spatial structure of administration. As an economic unit the region typically represents a
In particular, the secondary city-region could not form small, open economy. The relative openness of the
the basis of a secondary administrative region, since this regional economy is reflected by the fact that exports
would be run counter to a fundamental tenet of political (visible and invisible) from the region usually account
organization, which requires that a secondary unit must for a greater proportion of its gross domestic product
be wholly contained within a primary unit (PARR , 2007). than is the case for the nation in which the region is
Having considered the principal forms of economic located. Associated with this relative openness of the
region, the obvious question arises as to which is the regional economy is the high level of interregional
most appropriate type. Unsurprisingly, this will depend factor movement, particularly in the case of capital and
on a number of factors, including the scale of the area skilled labour. Such a characteristic, together with the
being studied, the kinds of research issues being investi- existence of economies of scale in production, causes
gated, the nature of the problems being addressed, etc. trade among regions to take place on the basis of absol-
Nevertheless, some variant of the nodal region appears ute advantage, a tendency that partially explains the
to have become the most useful and the most commonly presence of problem regions. These are unable to capi-
employed. To a greater extent than is possible with other talize on their comparative advantage, and are vulner-
types of region, the nodal region (in its various forms) is able to competition from successful regions.
able to provide insights into the operation of its economy Perhaps the most fundamental difference between
over space and into the spatial interrelations of the various the regional economy and the national economy lies
elements of this economy. These particular strengths do within the area of economic sovereignty. Here the pos-
not, of course, amount to a rejection of other types of ition of the region is greatly constrained. Even if the
region in all circumstances. In the balance of the paper, region has a government or administration (and this is
however, the emphasis will be on the nodal region, the exception rather than the rule), it is unable to
with the scale specified as appropriate. pursue a meaningful macro-economic policy. Thus,
there can be no monetary policy, simply because the
region lacks the ability to issue currency, and as a
result the region cannot follow an external economic
THE REGIONAL ECONOMY AND ITS
policy, involving exchange-rate adjustment. While
SPATIAL STRUCTURE
under certain conditions it is possible for a region to
The economic region (whatever its type) has a number pursue a fiscal policy, the prerogative of taxation and
of similarities with the economy of the nation. As with expenditure has been increasingly surrendered to (or
1930 John B. Parr
usurped by) a higher authority, usually the central or particular cities within a region or nation (GLAESER ,
federal government (in the UK the recent public- 2008). There is, in addition, a more general factor in
finance proposals for Scotland and Northern Ireland operation. This concerns the fact that the spatial struc-
are something of an exception to this trend). The limit- ture at a given point in time will be determined to a sub-
ing effects of this lack of economic sovereignty are miti- stantial degree by the spatial structure that existed during
gated to some extent by the existence of interregional the preceding era of economic development. It is
financial transfers from the relatively prosperous seldom the case that an existing spatial structure of a
regions to the relatively poor regions. These transfers region has emerged tabula rasa.
are orchestrated by the central government (sometimes The relationship between economic activity and
according to strict formulae), and have the effect of par- spatial structure may operate in the opposite direction,
tially offsetting the lack of competitiveness of the so that spatial structure exerts an influence on the level
problem regions and the absence of adequate interregio- of economic activity. For example, if for technological
nal mobility of parts of the workforce. and/or transport-cost reasons the locational require-
ments of the economic activities forming part of the
regional export base were to undergo a substantial
The question of spatial organization
change, continued operation of these activities might
By the same token that the regional economy displays a require an identifiably different spatial structure. The
variation over time (in terms of economic development problem here is that the spatial structure may not be
and trade-cycle fluctuation, for example), it also exhibits able to respond adequately to these changed conditions,
a variation across space. Lösch (LÖSCH /WOGLOM and thus inhibiting the continued existence of the dominant
STOLPER , 1944/1954) regarded this latter type of vari- economic-activity set, and possibly preventing the
ation as anything but random, and referred to it as räum- emergence of replacement economic activity that
liche Ordnung (spatial order or spatial ordering), that is, might be viably located within the region. Although
the spatial structure of the regional economy. In adequate supplies of labour and elements of infrastruc-
addition to the locational pattern of economic activity ture are available within the region, these may exist at
and infrastructure endowment (including communi- inappropriate locations and/or in insufficient quantities
cations and other elements of economic and social over- to be attractive to domestic or external sources of
head capital), spatial structure is concerned with the capital that would otherwise be invested within the
organization and functioning of markets for goods and region.
factors of production, an aspect considered in the fol- The influence of a pre-existing spatial structure on
lowing section. Spatial structure highlights the fact that regional economic performance need not be adverse,
the regional economy does not operate at a single however. It is sometimes neutral, and on occasions
point and is not evenly distributed over space, the may be positive, as will be argued in a later section.
actual spatial structure of a region representing a con- The spatial structure of a region may thus be conducive
figuration intermediate between these two extremes. to improved productivity, innovation and creativity, as
The spatial structure of a region may be seen as well as its ability to adjust to external shocks. Consider-
reflecting the locational characteristics of economic able debate has taken place on the net advantages of
activities located there. For example, a region with an different spatial structures, although no consensus has
economy based on extensive commercial agriculture been reached. Successful economic performance
will have a different spatial structure from that of a appears to be associated with a range of significantly
region with an economy dependent on extractive different spatial structures. It becomes evident that
industries and the processing of raw materials, which while the spatial structure may be seen as a reflection
in turn will differ from the spatial structure of a regional of regional economic activity, it can also act as an impor-
economy reliant on engineering and other fabricative tant influence on the nature and the level of such
manufacturing. The contrasting spatial structures are activity, an influence that may be positive or negative.
likely to be influenced by a number of factors. These
include the orientation of economic activity (to
Characterizing spatial structure
markets, raw materials, energy sources, etc.) and the
strength of agglomeration economies, both internal After considering the significance of spatial structure
and external to the firm, based on the advantages of within the regional economy, the various ways in
scale, scope and complexity (OHLIN , 1933; PARR , which spatial structure can be specified are now briefly
2002a). A useful distinction is sometimes made reviewed. One fairly obvious approach is to view
between static and dynamic agglomeration economies: spatial structure as a series of areal distributions. These
static agglomeration economies are generally concerned would involve such major aggregates of the regional
with the efficient locations of firms under a given set of economy as population, workforce, employment,
economic conditions, while dynamic agglomeration unemployment, etc. In certain cases the areal distri-
economies draw attention to their influence on inno- bution of fixed investment, raw materials, energy
vation and productivity, leading to the growth of sources, and the land available for industrial or
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1931
commercial development may also be included. This can be generated. The construction of a model of the
approach would not simply be concerned with inven- urban system requires many variables to be held con-
tories of the various elements; certain of the inter- stant, often involving the imposition of strong (even
relations among these various elements could be heroic) assumptions. Inevitably, therefore, urban-
analyzed with the aid of geographical information system models contain a simplicity or starkness, which
systems (GIS) and the application of spatial statistics. not all researchers in the area find acceptable. With
It is also possible to view the spatial structure of the these considerations in mind, attention is now focused
region as a set of flows among specified locations on several models of the urban system, starting with
within the region, making use of the extensive literature the Christaller framework (CHRISTALLER /BASKIN ,
on network analysis, an early example being the work of 1933/1966). This is considered in some detail since it
GARRISON (1960). An important category of intra- will be the standard against which other models are
regional flows involves those that can be expressed in compared.
economic terms such as trade flows (transactions
among firms as well as those between firms and house-
The Christaller urban system
holds), capital movements, wages and salaries paid by
firms to commuters, and (where relevant) transfers of The Christaller contribution model was based on an
funds to and from the regional government. Unfortu- empirical study of the central places of Southern
nately, the lack of reliable data on these flows often Germany in the 1920s. The primary focus was on
makes it necessary to rely on surrogate flows such as three regions (the L-systems centred on Munich, Nur-
those relating to shopping trips, freight traffic, commu- emberg and Stuttgart, each being a Landstadt or regional
ter flows, telephone connections, etc. city).3 Although not without a number of precursors,
Additional methods of characterizing regional spatial the Christaller framework was an early attempt at
structure are worthy of mention. One of these involves viewing the urban system as a set of hierarchically differ-
city-size distributions in terms of population and entiated service centres, each of these ‘central places’
employment (LASUEN et al., 1967; MALECKI , 1980). having one or more exclusive market areas to which
Another approach treats spatial structure as a surface the various goods and services were supplied.
(HAGGETT , 1968; KRUMBEIN , 1959), an important The Christaller urban system is concerned exclusively
perspective if the concern is with dynamic spatial struc- with ‘central goods’ which are supplied to a dispersed
ture. A particular type of surface is the density function. market, and which are provided by the public sector
Though usually employed at the scale of a metropolitan as well as the private sector.4 In terms of household
area, the density function may also be applied at the scale demand the central goods involve retail goods, consu-
of the region, centred on the regional core (BOGUE , mer services, the output of certain types of manufactur-
1950; VINING , 1955). Undoubtedly, the most compre- ing such as job printing, newspaper production, and
hensive characterization of spatial structure makes use of various kinds of food processing. In the case of inter-
an urban-system perspective. Such a view of spatial mediate demand (that is, the demand exerted by
structure is concerned with the hierarchical differen- firms), central goods include wholesaling, transport
tiation of centres in terms of their size, spacing, fre- and communications, storage, business and financial ser-
quency and functional composition, and also includes vices, as well as numerous repair, maintenance and
other approaches already mentioned, notably the econ- engineering services. The various goods and services
omic flows among centres and their size distributions. can be grouped to form N sets, each of which may be
This urban-system perspective on the spatial structure regarded as a composite good of level m where m = 1,
will be explored in the next two sections. 2, …, N. This grouping is based on the frequency of
points required for the viable supply, whether private
or public. Although not undertaken by Christaller, it
is possible to introduce a level 0 set of goods, which
REGIONAL URBAN SYSTEMS:
includes agricultural commodities, foodstuffs, minerals
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND
and other raw materials, etc., and which is supplied
In considering the internal structure of a region in terms only from level 0 of the hierarchy, that is, rural areas.
of an urban system, attention is first given to several
important models developed in location theory. As
Structure of the Christaller urban system
with models in general, a model of the urban system is
an abstraction, which is not intended to replicate Four major influences underlie the form of the Christal-
reality. It seeks to explore the processes by which par- ler urban system. First, the demand for all central goods
ticular variables are related or interrelated, and attempts is dispersed, and in varying degrees is sensitive to dis-
to formulate a structure which reflects this. Models of tance from the point of supply. Second, the supply of
the urban system can thus be employed not only as these goods is closely related to this demand, and takes
benchmarks in the examination of actual conditions, place at points centrally located within their respective
but also as the means by which working hypotheses market areas. The frequency of these points (and thus
1932 John B. Parr
market areas) depends on transport costs borne by the spaced on a triangular or some alternative lattice (strictly
consumer and on economies of scale in the production speaking, the even spacing of level m centres refers to all
of the good in question. A third influence reflects the centres of levels m to N, a consequence of the succes-
propensity of consumers to minimize travel costs, by sively inclusive hierarchy). This even spacing stems
engaging in multipurpose trips, both with respect to from the underlying assumption of a uniform density
goods within a given set, but also in the case of goods of rural population. Such an assumption is easily dis-
belonging to different sets. The fourth influence is the pensed with, as demonstrated by RUSHTON (1972),
tendency of suppliers of a given good to be drawn to and the resulting pattern of variable centre spacing is
the location of suppliers of other goods, whether in obviously more in keeping with actual conditions.
the same set or different sets. To some extent this is
determined by the previous influence, but it also
Limitations of the system
permits suppliers to benefit from agglomeration econ-
omies of the urbanization type such as access to infra- While the Christaller structure is able to reflect several
structure and public utilities. This advantage tends to important facets of actual urban systems, it nevertheless
increase with hierarchical level, although it is likely to contains a number of serious weaknesses. Perhaps the
be partially offset by increasing location rents. most serious of these is the fact that attention is confined
These four influences give rise to an urban system in to goods and services of a market-orientated nature,
which there is a correspondence between spatial where centrality with respect to the consuming
demand and spatial supply, although this correspon- market (whether comprising households or firms) is of
dence is not of the same strength for all sets of paramount importance. Consideration of goods with
goods.5 A prominent feature of the Christaller urban other orientations is excluded. Another weakness of
system is the successively inclusive hierarchy. It is the model is that it wholly neglects the input structure
assumed that there are N levels of centre, N levels of of production: it is as if all inputs to production are ubi-
market area and N sets of goods (as defined above). quitous, that is, available everywhere at approximately
The successively inclusive hierarchy is such that a equal cost.
centre of level m supplies a characteristic set m, together A further deficiency is concerned with the direc-
with sets 1 to (that is, up to and including) m – 1. More tional pattern of trade. Thus, a centre of a given level
specifically, the centre of level m supplies sets 1 to m to does not export to (that is, supply) a centre of a
itself and to its market areas of levels 1 to m, respect- higher level, and does not import from (that is, is not
ively, where its level m market area represents the supplied by) a centre of a lower level. The reasons
‘characteristic market area’. For a level 1 centre the for this pattern may be explained as follows. A centre
characteristic market area is wholly rural (part of level of level m < N, for example, is exporting goods of
0), while the characteristic market area of a centre of levels 1 to m, but these same goods are also exported
level m > 1 consists of a rural component (part of from centres of level m + 1 to N. Since these higher-
level 0) plus particular centres (of decreasing frequency) level centres can assumed to be self-sufficient in such
belonging to levels 1 to level m – 1. The existence of goods, there is no basis for exports from the centre of
this successively inclusive hierarchy places a limitation level m to centres of higher levels. At the same time
on the number and the sizes of the various market this centre of level m < N is self sufficient in goods of
areas.6 It also implies a distinctive pattern of trade levels 1 to m – 1, so that there is no basis for imports
among centres. Thus, a centre of level 1 < m < N to this centre from centres of levels 1 to m – 1. By
exports to centres of levels 1 to m – 1, and imports similar reasoning there is no basis for trade among
from centres of levels m + 1 to N. A balance-of-pay- different centres of level m. As will be argued, these
ments problem does not arise, if it is assumed, reason- restrictions on the pattern of trade (though logical in
ably enough, that centres of particular levels are being terms of the assumptions of the model) represent an
supplied with the level 0 goods from level 0 (rural inadequacy of the Christaller structure in the context
areas). Under actual conditions, the balance-of-pay- of the modern conditions.
ments problem is also avoided by the existence of Finally, the Christaller model places an excessive
non-trade flows such as capital movements, govern- premium on proximity. Thus, when a centre (or a
ment expenditures, and the wages and salaries associ- location in a rural area) is supplied with a good of a
ated with commuting. given level m, this is always from the nearest centre of
The overall structure of the Christaller system may be level m or higher.7 Such a requirement results from
summarized with respect to centres belonging to any the assumption that demand for goods and services is
given level: the higher the level of a centre, the extremely sensitive to distance. No allowance is made
greater the number of sets of goods supplied from it; for a person travelling to a centre other than the
the greater its population; the greater the size of its nearest relevant one, in order to buy a particular style
characteristic market area; and (because of this) the of clothing or brand of consumer good, nor for a firm
lower the frequency of such centres and the wider failing to select the closest relevant centre, in order to
their spacing. In addition, centres of level m are evenly obtain an input to production.
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1933
The economic region of Lösch The Tinbergen contribution
It fell to Lösch (LÖSCH /WOGLOM and STOLPER , 1944/ The work of TINBERGEN (1961, 1968) stands in con-
1954) to provide the micro-economic underpinnings of trast to the Christaller–Lösch tradition. TINBERGEN
the Christaller model. The objective of the Lösch analy- (1968, p. 65), who was apparently unimpressed with
sis was to construct from first principles a regional land- previous attempts at modelling the urban system,
scape of production points, giving rise to an urban offered an alternative structure. This considers N
system. In several important respects the Lösch approach goods (or N sets of goods), N levels of centre, as well
was similar to the Christaller model: attention was con- as N levels of market area (where m = 1, 2, …, N).
fined to central goods (though there is more concern Also included is a level 0 good, which is supplied from
with manufactured goods); no consideration was given the rural area (level 0) to the rest of the system. Tinber-
to the location of inputs; the supply of a good to a par- gen introduced a successively inclusive hierarchy that
ticular location was always from the nearest relevant resembled the Christaller structure, but only to the
centre. extent that a centre of level m supplies goods of levels
The approach involved the analysis of demand over 1 to m to itself. As far as exports are concerned, the
space with freight-on-board (FOB) pricing, increasing centre of level m only supplies the level m good to its
returns to scale in production, and spatial competition single market area (its level m market area), comprising
among suppliers under conditions of free entry. In part of level 0 (the rural area) and centres of levels 1 to
the case of a single good the spatial equilibrium is speci- m – 1. This assumption results in an arrangement of
fied for each identical firm in terms of price, output centres and market areas different from that in the Chris-
and market-area radius. This outcome for a single taller system, and also a distinctive pattern of trade
good is broadly equivalent to that in the Christaller (MULLIGAN , 1982). To appreciate this, we may con-
structure. The analysis was then extended to examine sider a household or firm within a rural area in the
the outcome for all goods. However, instead of impos- immediate vicinity of a centre of level m. By the assump-
ing the successively inclusive hierarchy in the manner tions of the model this rural location would be supplied
of Christaller, Lösch allowed a wider variation in with a level m – 1 good from the nearest centre of level
market-area size. In this multi-good setting the m – 1, and not from the closer centre of level m, despite
primary concern was with minimizing the overall the fact that this centre would be supplying the level m –
number of production points. What emerged was a 1 good to itself.
continuous economic landscape in which an economic Such a pattern indicates a relaxation, but not the
region could be identified. Interestingly, Lösch abandonment, of the requirement of centrality,
(LÖSCH /WOGLOM and STOLPER , 1944/1954, although it is not at all obvious how such a pattern
pp. 130–131) was aware of the Christaller urban could be sustained in a market economy. What the Tin-
system, and regarded this as a special case of his own bergen model does illustrate, however, is that centres of
more complex system, a case in which the number of level m of the hierarchy have a particular export special-
market-area sizes is limited by the number of levels ization, namely, the level m good. This is consistent with
of political or administrative organization. the observed tendency for certain industries to be
The economic region derived by Lösch contains located at particular size classes of centre. It is also con-
three major features not present in the Christaller struc- sistent with the presence of agglomeration economies of
ture. First, the centres have a wider diversity of func- the localization type (ISARD , 1956). These factors
tional complexity and therefore a greater range of suggest that the model is best suited to explaining the
population sizes (STOLPER , 1955). Second, a relatively location of intermediate goods that have a particular
small centre (one supplying few goods) can export to input supply, that is, where the input is supplied from
a large centre (one supplying relatively many). Third, level 0 or from a higher-level centre. As with the Chris-
the regional economic landscape is dominated by a taller model any centre of a level m < N only exports to
single metropolitan centre, from which all goods are lower levels and only imports from higher levels. No
supplied, and from which extend six centre-rich balance-of-payments problem arises, however, since it
sectors and six centre-poor sectors. The centre-rich is specifically assumed that there exists a rural area
sectors of adjacent regions form the bases for transport (level 0), which exports the level 0 good to one or
axes between pairs of neighbouring metropolitan more of the urban levels of the hierarchy.
centres. This explanation for the common phenomenon Before moving to the next section, a general
of inter-metropolitan corridors is imaginative, although comment is included, regarding a particular aspect of
the analysis contains too many inconsistencies and con- the models outlined above. It will be observed that
tradictions for such a result to be accepted. Moreover, each model treats the urban system as existing within
within an actual regional urban system it is debateable an unchanging equilibrium. The principal reason for
whether centre-rich sectors gave rise to transport corri- this is that in the development of these models it was
dors or whether the causation was in the reverse convenient for time to be held constant, so that atten-
direction. tion could be focused on spatial structure. Obviously,
1934 John B. Parr
urban systems can be expected to become modified over levels of centre, only three of these had centre popu-
time, and none of the models discussed can be con- lations that could be considered urban in any practical
sidered inherently stationary. Moreover, the apparent sense, that is, in excess of 10 000 people (ULLMAN ,
static bias of the models is largely overcome, if these 1941). With some exceptions, the present-day hierarchy
are reworked in dynamic terms or as multi-static of urban centres typically consists of three or four levels.
models. The various attempts along these lines are dis- The successively inclusive hierarchy continues to be
cussed elsewhere (PARR , 2002b). present, but it is less clearly defined, being partially
obscured by the supply of non-central goods.
It will be recalled that in the urban system of Chris-
REGIONAL URBAN SYSTEMS: THE taller the location of all non-rural economic activity is
CONTEMPORARY CITY-REGION governed exclusively by the principle of centrality
with respect to the location of demand. As a conse-
In the light of these theoretical approaches to the urban quence a given level of urban centre only supplies
system, not all of which were originally presented by central goods, with the number of sets of goods supplied
their authors in an explicit manner, it is now possible corresponding to the number of market areas being
to explore the extent to which the models are able to served. For the modern city-region this pattern tends
cast light on the modern-day city-region. Although to hold for centres of lower levels. Centres of
the major concern has been with the internal factors medium-to-high levels, however, commonly supply
influencing the organization of a regional urban particular non-central or specialized goods (to national
system, it is important to consider some of the changing and international markets), in addition to central
external forces that have continued to shape it. Over vir- goods (largely to regional markets). It will be argued
tually any period of economic history during the last shortly that the structure of the hierarchy is not immu-
two to three hundred years, urban systems have been table, and may thus be subject to change.
undergoing transformations, affected in part by external Non-central or specialized goods comprise a highly
conditions. This is as true in the present era as it was in diverse and evolving group of activities, which includes
the nineteenth century, for example, which saw the mineral exploitation, a wide array of manufacturing
continuation of the Industrial Revolution, the rise of industry, a range of business and commercial services,
steam power and the expansion of overseas trade. as well as numerous specialized consumer services. In
The decades following the Second World War the case of non-central goods the locational orientation
experienced considerable economic expansion, inno- of production or supply is not primarily to the market
vation and modernization. Associated with these devel- but variously to sources of raw materials and manufac-
opments were fundamental changes in the technologies tured inputs, to major ports and international airports,
of production and communications, overall improve- to supplies of skilled or semi-skilled labour, etc. (BECK-
ments in living standards, shifts in consumer preferences, MANN , 1968). However, the predominant location of
vastly different patterns of international trade (not only these kinds of economic activities is in urban centres.
in terms of volume, but also with respect to the location This is largely a reflection of the co-location of firms,
of markets and sources of supply), substantial increases in in order to gain agglomeration economies, not simply
the international movement of capital, changed patterns of the urbanization type but also of the activity-
of corporate ownership and control both nationally and complex type (PARR , 2002a). In addition, there is a ten-
internationally, etc. These various changes exerted an dency (consistent with the Tinbergen analysis) for
influence (direct as well as indirect) on regional econ- certain activities to be associated with particular levels
omies. But despite such a dramatic modification of the of the urban system, suggesting that the relevant firms
general economic environment the regional urban benefit from agglomeration economies of the localiz-
system endured, though inevitably in a modified form, ation type (BERRY and HORTON , 1970; EVANS ,
and this cannot be emphasized strongly enough. The 1972; ISARD , 1956). This tendency is not present in
remainder of this section will be concerned with the all city-regions, however.
urban system of the major city-region, as discussed
above.
Economic flows within the city-region
Since the nature of economic activity and its overall
The location of economic activity within the city-region
locational pattern in the modern city-region are more
The urban system of the major city-region typically complex than in the Christaller structure, it is not sur-
possesses certain features of the L-system of Christaller, prising that more intricate patterns of interaction are
particularly in terms of the hierarchical structure of present. Consumer accessibility continues to be impor-
urban centres.8 One such feature is the size, spacing tant for many goods, but its influence is no longer as
and frequency of centres, which distinguishes the city- decisive as in the past. Improved mobility and the exten-
region from other types of region, for example, the sion of product differentiation have meant that supply
PUR. Although Christaller identified seven hierarchical from the nearest relevant centre is no longer a
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1935
requirement. And in the case of trade among firms, adjustments of this kind are possible, particularly since
reductions in the cost of transport have reduced the commuting may be a temporary or even a permanent
importance of centrality in gaining access to markets substitute for migration (TERMOTE , 1978). In addition,
and inputs to production. Under these conditions it is the joint-location problem of dual-income households
certainly possible for a low-level centre to export to a (VAN OMMEREN et al., 1999) becomes a less pressing
high-level centre (and therefore for a high-level centre one. In this way the spatial structure of the city-region
to import from a low-level centre), a feature of the permits or even facilitates economic adjustment. It
Lösch system. It is also possible for centres of approxi- must be stressed, however, that this spatial-structure
mately the same level to trade with each other, regard- advantage in the process of adjustment would be less
less of their respective locations with the city-region. prominent and perhaps even non-existent in city-
In recent decades, information flows have rightly regions that are more extensive, with low overall popu-
been accorded an importance among many researchers. lation densities.
Unfortunately, flows of this kind are difficult to acquire,
hard to measure and not readily interpreted (HALL ,
Spatial-structure change in the city-region
1991; HALL and PAIN , 2006). Of particular interest
here is the extent to which information flows are sensi- It will be apparent that the urban system of the modern
tive to distance, and the evidence on this is not clear. It city-region is to be seen as something other than a static
should not be forgotten that the city-region exists structure, although there may be intervals when the
within the wider territory, be this the nation, a trading pace of change is relatively slow. As already mentioned,
bloc or the world economy, and in discussions of the the urban system of a city-region is subject to the effects
city-region external linkages sometimes go unrecog- of external as well as internal change, these taking the
nized or underemphasized. Of relevance at the national form of shocks. Obviously, there can be no question
level is the location of a city-region in relation to other of the urban system being rebuilt de novo. Instead,
city-regions. One aspect of this, which was considered there is a process of self-adjustment on the part of the
by Lösch, is the development of inter-metropolitan system, which takes place over the short-to-medium
axes or corridors between the dominant metropolitan run. For example, as the result of a given shock, an indi-
cores of adjacent city-regions, and the accompanying vidual good may now need to be supplied from fewer
interaction based on trade flows, the movement of centres or from more centres. Under these conditions
people and information, as well as the diffusion of there is a hierarchical redefinition of the relevant sets
innovations. of goods, but the hierarchy remains unchanged in
Another category of flows in the urban system of a terms of its number of levels and the number of
city-region (though one not present in the models dis- centres of each level. However, the shock may be suffi-
cussed above) concerns the daily movement of labour ciently great that the hierarchy, itself, is transformed.
from centres of one level to centres of a higher, a One case involves the formation of a new level. In
lower or the same level. For each of these flows of another case the level continues to exist but becomes
labour there is a reverse flow of wages and salaries, less extensive (with fewer centres) or more intensive
which may be an important part of the economic base (with a greater number of centres), while in a further
for many urban centres in the city-region. Daily flows case there is complete disappearance of a level, this
of labour to (and also from) the dominant metropolitan former level being combined with the next higher or
core continue to be important, but there is an increase in next lower level. It follows that these different adjust-
flows among centres within the hinterland, which are ments all involve changes in the structure of trade
unrelated to the core. There is, of course, some upper flows. The effect of such shocks is to modify the size dis-
limit on the daily distance travelled between centres tribution of centres within the regional urban system.
(whether between levels or within a level), but this Within most city-regions of the developed world the
has exhibited a steady increase over recent decades due spatial structure continued to undergo a process of con-
to the expansion of car ownership, reduced travel centration well into the first quarter of the twentieth
costs and shorter travel times. century, up to which time the metropolitan core grew
Commuting represents an important lubricant for at a faster rate than its hinterland in terms of population,
both labour-market flexibility and residential adjust- employment and income. In more recent times,
ment. It not only allows the separation between resi- however, the trend has been toward deconcentration,
dence and workplace, but also permits changes in the with the growth rate of the hinterland (most of this
location of the workplace, with the location of residence growth being in urban centres) exceeding that of the
remaining unaffected, as well as changes in the location core. In part, this has resulted from households and
of residence with the location of the workplace unaf- firms relocating from the metropolitan core to locations
fected. In the typical city-region of Northwest Europe beyond it, often as part of a mutually reinforcing shift of
and the Eastern Seaboard of North America, where population and employment. Such shifts include reloca-
population density is relatively high and the accompa- tions among levels of the urban hierarchy, which increas-
nying spacing of urban centres is correspondingly low, ingly take place from the highest level (the metropolitan
1936 John B. Parr
core) to lower levels, and also from the highest level to For the developed world, and to an increasing extent
urban centres located within a particular distance range. the developing world, the city-region has emerged as a
There seems to be every indication that the nature of dominant spatial form, and it is common for a national
economic and technological change will continue to space economy to comprise a set of city-regions,
favour the broad trend toward deconcentration. usually hierarchically differentiated. Over recent
decades the city-region has become the arena in
which the processes of economic development and
economic change are being played out, the implications
of which are likely to be considerable. As a consequence
CONCLUSIONS
the spatial structure of the city-region (particularly when
Attention may now be drawn to some of the main issues viewed as a regional urban system) will assume an
that have emerged from this discussion, beginning with obvious importance in public as well as private
the notion of the region. This represents an important decision-taking. With regard to the future structure of
scale of analysis (intermediate between the locality or the city-region, the outcome is anything but certain.
urban centre and the nation), although its significance HALL (2009, pp. 808–811), while warning of the
and utility have been called into question. Unfortu- dangers of prediction, has offered a thoughtful account
nately, the region as a unit of analysis is not always of the more important tendencies (what he terms
well defined and can thus become a source of confusion. changes in the ‘basic parameters’) that are likely to influ-
At the very least, it would seem desirable that whenever ence the form of the city-region in coming decades.
the term ‘region’ is being used, some working definition These range from environmental modification and
should be provided. More generally, it would be helpful demographic evolution to the impacts of economic
if urban and regional analysis had at its disposal a and technological change, along with greatly altered
language (or simply a grammar) by which this confusion patterns of consumption. While there is an obvious
could be avoided. Various fields of the medical and bio- need for information about future trends (in order to
logical sciences, for example, have availed themselves of assist the policy-maker, the planner and the analyst), it
such a facility for centuries, and to good effect. would probably be imprudent (and also very difficult)
It has long been maintained that for economic (and to pursue matters concerning the future beyond this
other kinds of) analysis the nation is too unwieldy a point.
unit, which should be disaggregated into regions, in
order to understand more adequately the spatial and sec- Acknowledgements – The author wishes to thank
toral variability of economic performance. By exten- D. Batten, C. Wren and two anonymous referees for their
sion, it may be claimed that the region is too crude a comments on earlier versions of this paper. Thanks are also
focus, and that its economy should be considered at a due to the Guest Editors of this special issue of Regional
sub-regional scale or preferably in spatial-structure Studies, and to the Deputy Editor-in-Chief of the journal.
terms, so as to gain insight into its internal operation
and evolution over the long run. As was argued,
spatial structure represents a partial determinant of NOTES
regional economic change as well as a reflection of it,
the latter emphasis being the more conventional view. 1. As an economic unit, the origins of the nodal region can be
Consideration of spatial structure thus goes some way traced back to the work of von Thünen (VON THÜNEN /
WARTENBURG , 1842/1966). In Part I of this study his
to understanding the nature of the regional economy
Isolated State consisted of a single urban core and a hinter-
and its ability to adjust to external influences. land, the core representing the single market for agricul-
In the analysis of spatial structure the contributions of tural commodities produced in the hinterland, to which
location theory are substantial, although there has been a it supplied goods and services.
tendency for these to be underestimated. While particu- 2. Currently, the term ‘polycentric’ tends to be employed
lar aspects of location theory have assisted our under- indiscriminately. Naturally, all regions can be regarded as
standing of urban systems, the formulation of a general polycentric, in the narrow sense that each contains a
theory has nevertheless proven elusive. Further progress number of (sometimes many) urban centres, and to this
can be expected, and the continued development of the extent the term is redundant. On occasions the term ‘poly-
‘New Economic Geography’ (NEG), stimulated by the centric’ is used as a shorthand means of describing a region
work of KRUGMAN (1995, 2009) and FUJITA et al. that is not ‘monocentric’, that is, not excessively domi-
nated by a particular centre.
(1999), is of potential importance in this connection.
3. Two further L-systems were included: those based on
It must be added, however, that while NEG models Frankfurt and Strasbourg. Since these extended beyond
are able to provide powerful insights into the operation the boundary of the area of the case study (Southern
of an economy over space, the treatment of the region Germany), only part of the L-system was included in
requires further elaboration and specification, not least each case.
in terms of its spatial structure (GARRETSEN and 4. Christaller was certainly aware that goods and services
MARTIN , 2010; OVERMAN and IOANNIDES , 2001). were produced in Southern Germany which were not
The Regional Economy, Spatial Structure and Regional Urban Systems 1937
central goods, and that many goods were manufactured 6. In Christaller’s theoretical model of the urban system, the
there (particularly in the regional capitals) for national size of the characteristic market area increases from one
and international markets. Given the paucity of prior level to the next by a constant factor, usually denoted as
work on urban systems, Christaller appears to have K. This is consistent with, though not required by, the exist-
excluded non-central goods in order to isolate the influ- ence of a successively inclusive hierarchy (PARR , 2002b).
ence of centrality in the process of urbanization and in 7. This argument does not apply in the case of certain kinds of
the formation of the urban system. multipurpose trips, for example, when a consumer travels to a
5. This correspondence is particularly strong when demand level m centre to purchase a level m good, but uses this oppor-
for a set of goods is influenced by high transport costs, tunity to buy a level m – 1 good, which could have been pur-
and supply is subject to minimal economies of scale, so chased at a centre of m – 1 located closer to the consumer.
that the frequency of centres is high, and each of their 8. For this reason the city-region is sometimes likened to a
market areas is relatively small. By contrast, the corre- ‘central place model’ of the Christaller type (CAMAGNI
spondence is far less strong (though still present) when and CAPELLO , 2004), while BATTEN (2011) has referred
the demand for a set of goods is only mildly affected to it as a ‘central place region’. Such characterizations of
by transport costs, and economies of scale are substantial, the city-region may create the wrong impression,
in which case the frequency of centres is low, and each however. As will be demonstrated, the urban system of
of their market areas is large. Not all goods tend to the modern city-region departs from the Christaller
one or other extreme, and this is a basis for a hierarchy central place structure in several fundamental respects,
of more than two levels, which will be considered while also displaying most of the attributes of the
shortly. Camagni–Capello ‘urban network model’.

REFERENCES
ALONSO W. (1973) Urban zero population growth, Daedalus 109, 191–206.
BATTEN D. F. (1994) Network cities: creative urban agglomeration of the 21st century, Urban Studies 32, 313–327.
BATTEN D. F. (2011) On creative network cities, in ANDERSSON Å. E., ANDERSSON D. E. and MELLANDER C. (Eds) Handbook of
Creative Cities, pp. 284–306. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
BECKMANN M. J. (1968) Location Theory. Random House, New York, NY.
BERRY B. L. J. and HORTON F. (1970) Geographic Perspectives on Urban Systems. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
BOGUE D. (1950) The Structure of the Metropolitan Community. Horace H. Rackham School of Graduate Studies, University of
Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI.
BRUNEL D. (Ed.) (2002) Cahiers de l’Institut d’Aménagement et d’Urbanisme de la Région Île-de-France (IAURIF) Number 135,
Economic Performance of the European Regions. IAURIF, Paris.
BURGER M. and MEIJERS E. (2012) Form follows function? Linking morphological and functional polycentricity, Urban Studies 49,
1127–1149.
BURTON I. (1963) A restatement of the dispersed city hypothesis, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 63, 285–289.
CAMAGNI R. and CAPELLO R. (2004) The city network paradigm: theory and empirical evidence, in CAPELLO R. and NIJKAMP P.
(Eds) Urban Dynamics and Growth, pp. 495–529. Elsevier, Amsterdam.
CHESHIRE P. C. and HAY D. G. (1989) Urban Problems in Western Europe: An Economic Analysis. Unwin Hyman, London.
CHRISTALLER W. (1933/1966) Die zentralen Orte in Süddeutschland [1933]. Gustav Fischer, Jena; trans. BASKIN C. (1966) as Central
Places in Southern Germany. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
DAVOUDI S. (2003) Polycentricity in European spatial planning: from an analytical tool to a normative agenda, European Planning
Studies 11, 980–999.
DICKINSON R. E. (1947) City, Region and Regionalism. Routledge & Kegan Paul, London.
DUNCAN O. D., SCOTT W. R., LIEBERSON S., DUNCAN B. and WINSBOROUGH H. H. (1960) Metropolis and Region. Johns Hopkins
Press, Baltimore, MD.
EVANS A. (1972) The pure theory of city size in an industrial economy, Urban Studies 9, 49–77.
FUJITA M., KRUGMAN P. R. and VENABLES A. J. (1999) The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions and International Trade. MIT Press,
Cambridge, MA.
GARRETSEN H. and MARTIN R. (2010) Rethinking (new) economic geography: taking geography and history seriously, Spatial
Economic Analysis 5, 27–60.
GARRISON W. L. (1960) Connectivity of the interstate highway system, Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association 6,
121–137.
GLAESER E. L. (2008) Cities, Agglomeration, and Spatial Equilibrium. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
HAGGETT P. (1968) Trend surface analysis in the interregional comparison of intra-regional structures, Papers of the Regional Science
Association 20, 19–28.
HALL P. (1991) Moving information: a tale of four technologies, in BROTCHIE J., BATTY M., HALL P. and NEWTON P. (Eds) Cities of
the 21st Century: New Technologies and Spatial Systems, pp. 1–21. Longman, Melbourne, VIC.
HALL P. (2009) Looking backward, looking forward: the city-region of the mid-21st century, Regional Studies 43, 803–817.
HALL P. and PAIN K. (Eds) (2006) The Polycentric Metropolis: Learning from Mega-City Regions in Europe. Earthscan, London.
HOOVER E. M. and FISHER J. L. (1949) Research in regional economic growth, in Problems in the Study of Economic Growth, pp. 173–
250. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), New York, NY.
ISARD W. (1956) Location and Space-Economy. Technology Press of MIT and Wiley, New York, NY.
1938 John B. Parr
KARLSSON C. and OLSSON M. (2006) The identification of functional regions: theory, methods and applications, Annals of Regional
Science 40, 1–18.
KRUGMAN P. R. (1995) Development, Geography and Economic Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
KRUGMAN P. R. (2009) The increasing returns revolution in trade and geography, American Economic Review 99, 561–571.
KRUMBEIN W. C. (1959) Trend surface analysis of contour-type maps with irregular control-point spacing, Journal of Geophysical
Research 64, 823–834.
KRUTILLA J. V. and ECKSTEIN O. (1958) Multiple Purpose River Development. Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore, MD.
LASUEN J. R., LORCA A. and ORIA J. (1967) City size distribution and economic growth, Ekistics 24, 221–226.
LÖSCH A. (1944/1954) Die raumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft, 2nd Edn [1944]. Gustav Fischer, Jena; trans. WOGLOM W. H. and
STOLPER W. F. (1954) The Economics of Location. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.
MALECKI E. J. (1980) Growth and change in the analysis of rank-size distributions: empirical findings, Environment and Planning A
12, 41–52.
MEIJERS E. J., ROMEIN A. and HOPPENBROUWER E. C. (Eds) (2003) Planning Polycentric Regions in North West Europe: Value. Feasi-
bility and Design. Delft University Press, Delft.
MEYER J. R. (1963) Regional economics: a survey, American Economic Review 53, 1–54.
MULLIGAN G. F. (1982) Tinbergen-type central place systems, International Regional Science Review 7, 83–91.
MUSTERD S. and VAN ZELM Z. (2001) Polycentricity, households and the identity of places, Urban Studies 38, 769–796.
NORTH D. (1955) Location theory and regional economic growth, Journal of Political Economy 63, 243–258.
OHLIN B. (1933) Interregional and International Trade. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
OVERMAN H. G. and IOANNIDES Y. M. (2001) Cross sectional evolution of the US city size distribution, Journal of Urban Economics
49, 543–566.
PARR J. B. (2002a) Missing elements in the analysis of agglomeration economies, International Regional Science Review 25, 151–168.
PARR J. B. (2002b) The location of economic activity: central place theory and wider urban system, in MCCANN P. (Ed.) Industrial
Location Economics, pp. 32–82. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
PARR J. B. (2007) On the spatial structure of administration, Environment and Planning A 39, 1255–1268.
PARR J. B. (2008) Cities and regions: problems and potentials, Environment and Planning A 40, 3009–3026.
RUSHTON G. (1972) Map transformation of point patterns: central place patterns in areas of variable population density, Papers of the
Regional Science Association 28, 111–129.
STOPLER W. F. (1955) Spatial order and the economic growth of cities: a comment on Eric Lampard’s paper, Economic Development
and Cultural Change 3, 137–146.
STORPER M. (1995) The resurgence of regional economies, ten years later: the region as a nexus of untraded interdependencies,
European Urban and Regional Studies 2, 191–221.
TERMOTE M. (1978) Migration and commuting in Lösch’s central place system, in FUNCK R. and PARR J. B. (Eds) The Analysis of
Spatial Structure: Essays in Honour of August Lösch. Karlsruhe Papers in Regional Science, Vol. 2, pp. 83–90. Pion, London.
TINBERGEN J. (1961) The spatial dispersion of production: a hypothesis, Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik 97,
412–419.
TINBERGEN J. (1968) The hierarchy model of the size distribution of centres, Papers of the Regional Science Association 20, 65–68.
ULLMAN E. L. (1941) A theory of location for cities, American Journal of Sociology 46, 835–864.
VAN OMMEREN J., RIETVELD P. and NIJKAMP P. (1999) Job moving, residential moving, and commuting: a search perspective,
Journal of Urban Economics 46, 230–253.
VAN OORT F., BURGER M. and RASPE O. (2010) On the economic foundation of the urban network paradigm: spatial integration,
functional integration and economic complementarities within the Dutch Randstad, Urban Studies 47, 725–778.
VINING R. (1955) A description of certain spatial aspects of an urban system, Economic Development and Cultural Change 3, 147–195.
VON THÜNEN J. H. (1842/1966) Der isolirte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirthschaft und Nationalökonomie, 2nd Edn [original spelling,
1842]. Leopold, Rostock; trans. WARTENBURG C. M. (1966) Von Thünen’s Isolated State, Intro. by P. HALL . Pergamon,
Oxford.
WREN C. (2009) Onward the spatial: an essay on the nature and relevance of regional economics, Spatial Economic Analysis 4,
447–465.

You might also like