You are on page 1of 12

Australian Journal of Public Administration, vol. 72, no. 3, pp. 228–238 doi:10.1111/1467-8500.

12025

RESEARCH AND EVALUATION

Understanding Intergovernmental Relations:


Key Features and Trends

John Phillimore
Curtin University

This article discusses several features of intergovernmental relations (IGR), paying particular
attention to IGR in federations. A number of recent trends and challenges are identified, and
implications are drawn for the analysis of IGR. The article shows how IGR has traditionally
been dominated by informal processes and power relationships, but that formalisation and
institutionalisation have increased and can provide greater certainty and protection for
sub-national governments in dealing with central government.

Key words: Intergovernmental relations, centralisation and decentralisation, federalism, unitary sys-
tems, vertical and horizontal relations, path dependency

Intergovernmental relations (IGR) are an in- law’) that cannot be readily overturned (Fenna
tegral and pervasive part of modern political 2012: 750–1). National governments in unitary
systems, of growing importance as complexi- systems, by contrast, can (again, at least in prin-
ties of modern governance increase. They have ciple), abolish, restructure or neuter their con-
become a notable feature of federal political stituent units.
systems; however, they are an important com- This essential characteristic means that IGR
ponent of any political system with more than in federations have some distinctive features
one level of government. absent from IGR in non-federal countries. In
There is no necessary correlation between particular, the constitutional underpinning of
the system of government and the degree of constituent units with the full array of exec-
centralisation of IGR or the relative power be- utive, legislative and judicial institutions pro-
tween the various levels of government. Indeed, vide them with ‘hard’ protections and their own
a number of federations – such as Australia political constituency. Therefore, political mo-
and the USA – have steadily become more cen- tivations and considerations of policy auton-
tralised while many unitary countries have re- omy shape the conduct of IGR in a way that
cently decentralised. This is true both for devel- may not be so evident – or even possible – for
oped countries such as the UK and Spain, which sub-national levels of government in a unitary
have devolved substantial policy and political state. This is likely to be particularly true for
authority to regional governments, and for de- countries such as China and Vietnam where
veloping countries such as China, Vietnam and centralised political control through their re-
Indonesia, where regional governments have spective Communist Parties are likely to per-
increased their autonomous decision making meate and overshadow formal decentralisation
power and financial independence. measures taken in financial and administrative
However, federations are distinctive in that governance.
their constituent units (states, provinces, can- The existence of a presidential system can
tons, Länder), at least in principle, have their also have important effects on IGR, primarily
existence and minimal competencies protected by dispersing the channels of communications
by a foundational law (the constitution or ‘basic (Watts 2008: 119). However, there are examples


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Phillimore 229

of centralised and decentralised, effective and ative spillovers in areas like transport, water,
ineffective IGR institutions in both presidential the environment and business regulation meant
and parliamentary systems. that roles and responsibilities between levels of
This article describes the main dimensions, government were no longer clear cut and that
institutions and processes of IGR, looking pri- IGR of some sort were required to establish
marily at IGR in federations and Australia in policy positions and accountabilities as well as
particular. A number of trends and challenges administrative protocols between governments.
are identified, and implications are drawn for Crucially, with the rise in national income
the analysis of IGR. tax as a tool of macroeconomic policy and wel-
fare state redistribution, national governments
invariably raised more revenue than they could
What are intergovernmental relations and spend and fiscal transfers to sub-national units
why are they important? became much more important. This dictated
that IGR of some sort were necessary (Fenna
We can define intergovernmental relations 2012: 754).
(IGR) as the processes and institutions through As a result of these and other factors – in-
which governments within a political system cluding judicial decisions on matters of dispute
interact. All countries, whether unitary or fed- between the levels of government – the need
eral, have IGR of some sort, provided they have for regular IGR became more obvious. Coor-
more than one level of government. dinate federalism was increasingly replaced by
Analysis of IGR has traditionally focused on concurrent federalism, which required the dif-
the formal structures and institutions of IGR, ferent levels of government to deal with each
in particular those connected with the finan- other, even if only sporadically. This in turn
cial arrangements between the levels of gov- raised the need for cooperation as well as the
ernment (Painter 2012: 731). However, IGR potential for duplication, overlap, complexity,
also involves extensive informal processes of political opportunism, coercion and gaming.
exchange and interaction. A common response to these developments
The older Anglo federations of the USA, has been to seek a more ‘rational’ allocation of
Canada and Australia did not make significant roles and responsibilities (to rekindle the initial
provision for IGR in their constitutions, coordinate intent of the constitution), although
assuming instead that the two principal levels whether this should be achieved by a return of
of government (the central government and the powers to the states or additional powers for the
governments of the constituent units) would central government is contested.
operate virtually autonomously in the policy The alternative to re-drawing ‘bright lines’
spheres allocated to them by the roles and between governments is cooperative federal-
responsibilities designated in the constitution ism, which of necessity implies a more com-
(Fenna 2012: 753). plete and coherent set of IGR institutions and
However, over time, and sooner rather than processes to govern the inevitable concurrency
later, it became clear that this separation of ac- of government responsibilities (Wanna et al.
tivities through a coordinate form of govern- 2009). As noted, such concurrency implies at
ment was unrealistic and unlikely to last. As least a minimum level of consultation, cooper-
governments increased in size and scope dur- ation and coordination between governments,
ing the twentieth century, new issues arose that as well as conflict resolution mechanisms and
the original constitutions had not anticipated. a willingness to adapt to changing circum-
Policy areas that had formerly been seen as stances. The extent to which this can be done
local matters became matters of national so- effectively and efficiently is a crucial question,
cial, economic or environmental significance as is the issue of whether cooperative IGR may
or at least matters of political and policy inter- come at the expense of democratic accountabil-
est to national governments. Positive and neg- ity (Poirier and Saunders 2010: 8).


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
230 Understanding Intergovernmental Relations September 2013

Studying IGR Dimensions of IGR

Although inevitable and important, IGR can There are several different dimensions to IGR
pose difficulties for generalisation and theori- that provide the basis for subsequent analysis of
sation. This is partly because so much of IGR is IGR institutions and processes. These include
informal and reflective of each country’s par- vertical, horizontal and sectoral dimensions, as
ticular national characteristics. These charac- well as the degree of formality with which IGR
teristics can lead to strong path dependency. is carried out.
The informal nature of IGR also means that
politics, power and contingency tend to assume Vertical dimension
primacy over law, institutions and consistency,
in guiding the relations between the various lev- IGR occurs most importantly in the ‘vertical’
els of government. This again results in wide relationship between the central government
variations across countries and over time. As a and sub national governments. In unitary sys-
result, there has been a general dearth of com- tems, these are usually referred to as national
parative analysis or agreement on ‘principles’ and local governments, while in federations we
of IGR on which analysts and governments can normally refer to the central or federal govern-
draw. ment and the constituent units of the federa-
The view that IGR is best regarded as a tion (states in Australia and the US; provinces
‘game’ akin to diplomacy has also been com- in Canada; Länder in Germany; cantons in
mon (Simeon 1972; Sharman 1977; Painter Switzerland).
2001: 139; Harwood and Phillimore 2012: 88– However, many countries have more than two
89). Such an approach focuses on the motiva- levels of government. In China, for example,
tions and resources of the various ‘players’ in the constitution specifies four tiers (central,
the game (the levels of government, their per- province, county, township) while a fifth tier
sonnel and agencies), as well as the rules of the (prefecture-city) has effectively been added be-
game and its boundaries (IGR institutions, pro- tween the province and county levels. Vietnam,
cesses, laws, etc.). Rather than regarding IGR similarly, has four levels (central, provincial,
as a ‘team effort’ in which a country’s various district and commune). The central government
levels of government are striving to achieve a may deal with all the constituent units, a few
common policy purpose, this perspective ar- or just one, depending on the issue. Thus ver-
gues that we cannot assume that all the players tical IGR may be bilateral or multilateral. It
are even ‘on the same side’. is not always necessary or even advisable for
In particular, the constituent units often all constituent units to be treated equally by the
regard the promotion and protection of their central government on all issues. Asymmetry is
policy and administrative autonomy as more possible and common (Watts 2008: chapter 8).
important than promoting the ‘national in- In federations, three or more levels of gov-
terest’ or ensuring harmonisation of service ernment are common (e.g. central, state and
delivery across the country. However, while local government, as in Australia). But the cru-
all sub-national governments would agree on cial intergovernmental relationship in federa-
the desirability of autonomy, their substantive tions is generally between the constitutionally
policy goals may well differ from each other protected constituent units and the central gov-
depending on their economic, social and ernment (Fenna 2012: 751). Local government
cultural circumstances and interests. These is generally established under state government
differences may also affect how they conduct legislation and regarded as a state government
IGR. Quebec in Canada is an obvious example, creation, even though they are popularly elected
as are the resource-rich jurisdictions of Al- and have distinct (although quite limited) re-
berta or Western Australia, which have regular sponsibilities. Indeed, while they often resent
clashes with their central government and other federal government efforts to conduct IGR di-
jurisdictions. rectly with local governments, many states act


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Phillimore 231

just as overbearingly with ‘their’ local govern- and how trusted each level of government is
ments as they accuse federal governments of regarded within the community in relation to
doing with states. Given the lack of any con- the particular policy area in question.
stitutional obstacles to state interference with
local government, allegations of cost shifting Formal and informal dimensions
by states onto local government are frequently
made, and a number of states have amalga- IGR occur through both formal and informal
mated local governments or dismissed councils means. Formal mechanisms can be constitu-
without consultation. The situation is basically tional, statutory or by way of non-statutory in-
similar in the US and Canada. stitutions, agreements and processes. Informal
IGR are inevitably more difficult to observe
Horizontal but often as important as formal mechanisms,
if not more so. Informal interactions often hold
Horizontal IGR can take many forms and in- the system together. In addition, there may be
volve some or all of the constituent units. Typ- unspoken rules, conventions or principles that
ically, horizontal relations between constituent are important to the conduct and effectiveness
units arise to deal with geographic trans-border of IGR (Harwood and Phillimore 2012: 88).
issues such as rivers, transport, local taxation As noted, in the older federations (USA,
and service provision. In addition, national Canada, Australia), constitutions generally said
peak bodies of constituent unit government very little about IGR and established few if any
leaders have been formed to take joint actions institutions to deal with relations between their
not requiring the national government, to dis- constituent units and the federal government.
cuss common issues or to lobby the national This was because they assumed coordinate gov-
government on issues of joint importance. Re- ernment would prevail. Federations created in
gional groupings of constituent units are also more recent times, such as Germany and South
common in Canada and the US. In Australia, Africa, having witnessed the growth of con-
formal groupings are less common although currency in the older federations, have tended
alliances can develop, for example between to establish some structures and mechanisms
smaller states, or between resource-based to cater for the inevitability of IGR, prefer-
jurisdictions. ably in ways that promote better processes
and more productive outcomes (Poirier and
Sectoral Saunders 2010: 4).
Some countries have explicitly specified
A third dimension of IGR relates to the policy principles that should govern the conduct of
sector in question. In the US, so-called ‘picket IGR in order to indicate respect between the
fence federalism’ refers to the way in which two levels of government and to reduce con-
each policy sector tends to have its own flict, coercion and opportunism (Wanna et al
IGR networks and personnel (Radin 2012: 2009: 9, 11). The EU specifies ‘subsidiarity’,
735). In Australia, this is formalised through the German Federal Constitutional Court has
the establishment of ministerial councils officially recognised the ‘comity principle’ and
consisting of federal and state ministers and South Africa’s constitution has a section listing
their officials (COAG 2013; Phillimore 2010: ‘Principles of co-operative government and in-
14). The scope, frequency and intensity of tergovernmental relations’.
interaction can vary between policy sectors, as
can the level of cooperation or conflict. Much IGR Institutions and Processes
depends on the financial dependence of states
in each policy area, their constitutional powers, There is a wide range of IGR institutions
their administrative experience and technical and processes, most of which are extra-
knowledge and competence in the area, as constitutional. Most belong to the executive
well as the political importance of the issue branch of government.


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
232 Understanding Intergovernmental Relations September 2013

The legislature legedly undermining public accountability and


democratic control of government (Poirier and
Almost all federations have bicameral parlia- Saunders 2010: 8).
ments, and most have some form of regionally- Many countries have a peak intergovern-
influenced representation in their second cham- mental body at which heads of government
ber or upper house. However, the only chamber meet regularly to discuss common issues
that can really be depicted as an IGR institution and propose joint actions. In Australia, for
is the German Bundesrat whose members di- example, the peak IGR body is the Council of
rectly represent the Länder governments – who Australian Governments (COAG), comprising
therefore have a direct say in federal govern- all first ministers (the prime minister, premiers
ment policy and law making (Watts 2008: 154). of all six states, the chief ministers of the
Although they provide equal representation for two territories) and the head of the national
each state regardless of population in recogni- association of local governments. Yet COAG
tion of the federal principle, upper houses such has no formal status in the constitution, in leg-
as the US and Australian Senates have directly islation or even in a formal intergovernmental
elected members who primarily represent party agreement. It is in fundamental respects a
rather than state interests. meeting of government leaders, serviced by a
Countries use a range of legislative tech- Commonwealth secretariat (Phillimore 2010:
niques to facilitate IGR coordination or give 13–14). Reflecting the Commonwealth’s fi-
effect to national laws. In Australia, the con- nancial dominance, the prime minister calls the
stitution allows for states to refer powers to meetings, sets the agenda and prioritises policy
the Commonwealth, although this has been issues.
done only sparingly (Phillimore 2010: 13). Often connected to the peak IGR body are
More common has been the use of mirror meetings of ministers responsible for particular
or template legislation, which enables model policy areas, which are usually supported by
laws, agreed by all governments, to be repli- officials’ meetings. In Australia, for example,
cated by others to ensure uniformity or consis- ministerial councils, which long pre-date
tency across the nation. Such legislation often COAG’s establishment, now often deal with
arises from intergovernmental agreements (see matters delegated from COAG as well as with
below). Parliaments occasionally play a formal issues generated by their own ministers, upon
role in monitoring the executive in particular which action may be taken or endorsement
areas of IGR, such as foreign treaties which from COAG sought. However, these bodies
place obligations on the sub-national govern- have been subject to criticism as they generally
ments. But generally the legislature is a junior work on consensus principles, and therefore it
player compared to the executive. is quite possible for one or more governments
to ‘hold out’ and exercise effective veto
The executive powers. This can lead to inertia or lowest
common denominator solutions (Painter 2001:
In parliamentary systems in particular, ‘exec- 140).
utive federalism’ dominates, with most IGR In some countries, horizontal IGR bodies
taking place between the executives of the re- have been established to enable constituent
spective governments, including both politi- units to work with each other without the partic-
cal office bearers and public servants. Inter- ipation of the federal government. In Canada,
action generally involves a range of standing the provincial premiers formed the Council of
and ad hoc councils and committees, as well as the Federation in 2003 and Australia followed
ongoing discussions between officials. These suit with the Council for the Australian Feder-
executive mechanisms vary in their level of ation in 2007. The efficacy of these bodies as
formality, openness and effectiveness, and in- either lobbying or governing bodies is unclear,
deed have been the subject of criticism for al- however (Tiernan 2008).


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Phillimore 233

Intergovernmental agreements (IGA) Australian Energy Regulator). A common ef-


fect of establishing these executive bodies is to
An important method of coordinating IGR in depoliticise an issue after initial negotiations
all countries occurs through formal agreements and discussions have taken place and a resolu-
between governments. In some countries these tion reached.
are legislated, but in most they are concluded
through executive agreement alone – although Public service
they may form the basis subsequently for legis-
lation and the establishment of funding pro- The public service is crucial to the conduct of
grams or new agencies. Australia currently IGR in all countries. It is the ‘engine room’
has well over 100 existing agreements, and al- where detailed work is done, both through for-
though most are concluded between the Com- mal meetings of officials as well as through
monwealth and the states and territories, some personal relations and informal interactions.
are ‘horizontal’ agreements between states. Often, and in keeping with the diplomacy anal-
Major national agreements are normally mul- ogy concerning IGR, it is the job of the pub-
tilateral but some include bilateral agreements lic service to maintain relations and dialogue
so the Commonwealth and individual state gov- with other governments even during times of
ernments can sort out details or deal with issues political tensions and stand offs (Poirier and
relating to a particular jurisdiction. Saunders 2010: 6).
Agreements typically assign roles and However, it cannot be assumed that the pub-
responsibilities to the signatory governments; lic service of each jurisdiction is necessarily
detail any financial provisions; and establish re- unified. For many years in Australia, for ex-
porting requirements. Many arise from the dis- ample, ‘line agencies’ (responsible for most
tribution of Commonwealth funds to the states of the spending and service delivery functions
to deliver services. Such agreements can be and often reliant to an important degree on
more or less detailed in terms of the obligations funds from the Commonwealth government)
they place on the signatories. Their legal status differed markedly from central agencies (pre-
varies, and dispute resolution mechanisms are miers and treasury departments) in how they
usually not detailed to any great extent. approached IGR (Painter 2001: 140; Harwood
and Phillimore 2012). Line agencies tradition-
Independent and joint agencies ally had a more pragmatic and cooperative rela-
tionship with their Commonwealth government
A common IGR mechanism is to establish a counterparts, who were a key source of funds.
joint or independent agency to deal with a At the same time, the pace of change and reform
specific public policy issue (Poirier and Saun- in policy and administration was often quite
ders 2010: 6). These often arise from an IGA slow. Over the past 25 years, however, central
and may be further supported by legislation. In agencies have taken a more active role in IGR
Australia, such IGR bodies are sometimes es- and asserted political and policy control over
tablished and funded solely by the Common- line agencies to ensure that government prior-
wealth, but with the states having a role in ities are adhered to, including in IGR. This is
appointing or approving their members. Aus- often accompanied by an increase in resources,
tralia has numerous such bodies (see Phillimore including dedicated IGR units or sections co-
2010: 14) dealing with a range of issues includ- located with their cabinet or policy unit.
ing fiscal federalism (Commonwealth Grants Nor should it be assumed that all govern-
Commission), performance evaluation (COAG ments are equally capable or interested in IGR.
Reform Council), policy advice (Food Stan- While national governments normally have ac-
dards Australia and New Zealand, National cess to more financial and human resources,
Transport Commission), and regulation (Office even they can find it difficult to cover the
of the Gene Technology Regulator, Australian wide array of skills and competences involved
Competition and Consumer Commission, in IGR properly (Menzies 2011; Harwood and


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
234 Understanding Intergovernmental Relations September 2013

Phillimore 2012: 48–50). This is even more the Australia, for example, business groups and
case for constituent units, for whom IGR can trade unions used to be state-based but have
often be seen as a nuisance or intrusion into steadily become more national in organisa-
their regular activities and a burden on their tion, focus and policy prescriptions, as the fed-
administrative resources. eral government has taken on more respon-
Occasionally, particular jurisdictions take the sibility for economic, competition, regulation
lead on certain IGR issues. Victoria, for exam- and industry policy. Key professional bod-
ple, was the principal driver behind Australia’s ies (lawyers, doctors, other health professions)
National Reform Agenda in the mid-late 2000s. were traditionally subject to state legislation,
Less populous and financially weaker govern- and have been slower to agree to national reg-
ments often have to prioritise by focusing their ulation, with smaller jurisdictions (supported
limited human resources on the IGR issues and by their state governments) often holding out
institutions of most importance to them while against moves to ‘go national’.
keeping a watching brief or relying on other
constituent units to look after their interests on
other issues (Harwood and Phillimore 2012: Trends, Challenges and Improvements
66–73).

Political parties General

Political parties can have a large influence on Based on case studies of thirteen federations,
IGR. If parties are very centralised and hold Poirier and Saunders (2010: 7–8) noted sev-
power at both national and sub-national level, eral trends and challenges emerging from re-
then national leaders may overwhelm and dom- cent IGR experience.
inate regional or state governments despite The first trend has been a general increase
what the formal division of powers may say in the formalisation and institutionalisation of
(Watts 2008: 119–20). This characterises the IGR.
situation in South Africa and Malaysia, for ex- A second trend has been the development of
ample, and is likely to be the case in the transi- horizontal IGR. The examples of Canada and
tion economies of Asia. Australia have already been noted, and other
In Australia, the major parties are struc- countries such as Austria and Nigeria have also
tured federally and state branches and govern- established leaders’ forums at the sub-national
ments retain substantial importance and inde- level. These bodies aim primarily to influence
pendence, although ‘federal intervention’ by national policy.
the national party organisation into dysfunc- A third development has been the emergence
tional state branches does occur from time of new actors, in particular large municipalities
to time. Collectively agreed federalism reform (in Brazil and South Africa) as well as local
and policy initiatives have occurred more read- governments more generally. This development
ily on the relatively rare occasions when one is not confined to federations. China and Viet-
party holds power at the federal level and in nam have also provided more autonomy and
most jurisdictions – as it did in Australia in self-government for their largest cities. Other
the early 1990s and most recently in 2008–09 non-state actors include First Nations and in-
(Fenna and Anderson 2012). However, there are dustry organisations. In 2012 the Australian
also numerous examples of conflict between government established a Business Advisory
Commonwealth and state governments having Forum, which met with all COAG members the
political leaders from the same party. day before COAG meetings, to discuss business
regulation and competition reforms.
Interest groups Fourth, there has been ‘a general trend to-
wards greater centralisation despite some ‘ad-
Interest groups can both reflect and influ- ministrative’ devolution’ (Poirier and Saunders
ence the form of IGR in a country. In 2010: 8). Some argue that traditionally dualist

C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Phillimore 235

federations (where each level of government tralisation despite devolution is evident in the
is responsible for setting and implementing its shift to performance management and evalua-
own policies) are being turned into integrated tion associated with the COAG Reform Council
federations along German lines, where the fed- deliberations (O’Loughlin 2012), as well as the
eral government sets the major policy direc- new policy and funding arrangements for hos-
tions and provides the relevant funding, while pitals, schools and disabilities being promoted
the sub-national units implement these poli- by the Commonwealth.
cies as ‘agents’ of the centre (Fenna 2012: Executive federalism, led by COAG, contin-
757). However this is occurring without the ues to dominate and despite periodic bursts of
sub-national levels having the protected right to reform, disillusion has set in for many par-
participate in the national policy and law mak- ticipants, stakeholders and observers. COAG
ing process (as is provided by the Bundesrat in has gone from being seen as ‘the workhorse of
Germany), potentially reducing the status and the nation’ (Karvelas 2007) to being criticised
powers of the constituent unit government. as overloaded and ineffective (Editorial 2013).
Finally, an ongoing challenge is the tension At least two Premiers have revived calls for
between efficiency and accountability, between ‘competitive federalism’ to be restored in or-
flexibility and the rule of law, and between ef- der to increase accountability and performance
fectiveness and consultation (Poirier and Saun- (Ashton 2012; McKenna 2012).
ders 2010: 8). IGR is primarily a function of the Pragmatism and opportunism rather than
executive arm of government, and reflects its federal principles or legal positions tend to in-
strengths and weaknesses. Inevitably, executive fluence the behaviour of governments (Hollan-
federalism has a fairly poor record in terms of der and Patapan 2007), reflecting the status of
citizen participation, transparency and account- IGR as a ‘game’ in which the Commonwealth’s
ability. Its positive feature is that it may be more financial dominance always looms large. Nev-
effective in delivering outcomes for citizens, ertheless, the states possess their own political
especially those living in under-resourced sub- and legal resources as well as expertise and
national jurisdictions. But too much emphasis knowledge essential for effective implementa-
on consulting with sub-national governments tion of policy (Harwood and Phillimore 2012:
to obtain their consent can slow the pace of re- 88–89). As a result, they have been able to in-
form and lead to lowest common denominator fluence the course and outcome of IGR negotia-
policies (Painter 2001: 140). tions on some issues, such as hospitals funding.

Australia Improving IGR

Australian IGR demonstrates each of the trends Many discussions on IGR have a normative fo-
identified by Poirier and Saunders. cus, aimed at improving the conduct of IGR and
Despite the lack of constitutional provisions the federation more generally (Chattopadhyay
dealing with IGR, Australia has developed a and Nerenberg 2010: vii-viii). Of course, im-
comprehensive set of IGR institutions and pol- provement is in the eye of the beholder and may
icy networks over the past twenty years. How- well be seen differently by different govern-
ever, these institutions (in particular COAG) ments within the IGR system. Increased policy
stand on rather flimsy institutional ground and administrative autonomy rather than sub-
and therefore remain heavily dependent on the stantive policy outcomes may be the most im-
Commonwealth for their vibrancy and effec- portant direct objective for some sub-national
tiveness. governments.
The establishment of the Council for the Aus- But if we accept that there is value in achiev-
tralian Federation created a national horizontal ing productive and efficient policy outcomes
IGR body in Australia for the first time, al- that are generally accepted by the public and
though its efficacy is in question. Business has their relevant governments, without too much
been formally consulted prior to COAG. Cen- waste, overlap, delay, politicisation or conflict,


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
236 Understanding Intergovernmental Relations September 2013

then a combination of formal and informal IGR ing of the constitution will not provide a
appears to be highly desirable. In terms of for- full picture, and nor will a simple read-
mal design features, the following aspects ap- ing of COAG communiques or intergov-
pear most important: ernmental agreements. In countries such
as China and Vietnam, their respective
r Where possible, building in constitutional Communist Parties play a crucial role in
and statutory protections for sub-national their conduct of IGR.
governments and their policy and admin- (2) Power is at the centre of any system
istrative roles and responsibilities; of IGR – and is closely linked to the
r Formalising and institutionalising key relative fiscal capacity of the various
IGR institutions and mechanisms; governments.
r Annunciating explicit principles to guide (3) IGR are more like diplomatic relations
behaviour (the ‘comity’ principle in than contractual or legal relations.
Germany) and policy-making (the ‘sub- (4) Notwithstanding the previous points, the
sidiarity’ principle in the EU). ‘hard’ protections which federations pro-
vide for their constituent units do set a
These features provide more certainty and base, however flawed, from which states
importantly provide a level of protection for can undertake IGR. This may not be the
the weaker party to any IGR (normally the case in unitary countries.
sub-national government), thereby reducing (5) Path dependence is frequently observed
the temptation and opportunity for the na- and important. Whether a country is on an
tional level to engage in coercion, opportunism, integrative or devolutionary path makes
poor behaviour and capriciousness (Poirier and a difference in terms of determining what
Saunders 2010: 4). There is a balancing act re- might be regarded as the ‘natural’ or
quired in order to ‘avoid extensive, complex ‘common sense’ direction of IGR reform.
and rigid legal requirements that could become Australian federalism has been integrat-
a long-term straightjacket’ (Watts 1997: 38). ing and centralising for decades; several
But in general ‘hard’ protections such as those unitary countries have been doing the
inherent to federations enable negotiations be- opposite.
tween the levels of government to be more equal (6) The increase in the number and range
and less prone to simple coercion. of actors involved in IGR adds com-
Formal or ‘hard’ rules and institutions are plexity and hence, potentially, ineffi-
necessary but they are not sufficient. They need ciency to their operation. But it also
to be supported by informal or ‘soft’ conditions allows for asymmetry, bilateralism, com-
such as respect, trust, mutuality, tolerance of di- petition, collaboration, experimentation,
versity, a willingness to engage and cooperate, and opportunism, all of which can have
and recognition of the legitimacy of the other’s positive as well as negative effects.
position (Watts 1997: 38). They also require (7) For all sub-national governments, pre-
government capacity to engage in meaningful serving control over key policy and ad-
IGR. ministrative decisions affecting their ar-
eas of responsibility (both geographical
Conclusion and policy) are likely to be crucial – and
legitimate – goals. Central governments
From the above, we may draw the following need to remember this.
concluding observations. (8) Relatedly, not all governments possess
the financial and human resources, or
(1) It is necessary to go beyond the formal the political inclination, to conduct IGR
rules, regulations and institutions of IGR conscientiously or effectively. Most place
to understand their substance. Trying to a higher priority on policy and politics
understand IGR in Australia from a read- within their own jurisdiction.


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Phillimore 237

(9) While effective formal IGR institutions Hollander, R. and Patapan, H. 2007. ‘Pragmatic Fed-
are important, so too are ‘soft’ skills, eralism: Australian federalism from Hawke to
values and competencies. Trust and re- Howard.’ Australian Journal of Public Adminis-
spect between governments are particu- tration, 66(3): 280–297.
larly important. Kavelas, P. 2007. ‘Rudd harnesses COAG
‘workhorse.’ The Australian. 21 December.
(10) Investing in IGR capacity is crucial to
McKenna, M. 2012. ‘State against state: Campbell
achieving better outcomes, both for each
Newman’s federalism.’ The Australian. 12 April.
level of government and for the system Menzies, J. 2011. ‘Blowing hot and cold – Inter-
as a whole. governmental relations capacity in the Common-
wealth government.’ Australian Journal of Public
Administration, 70(4): 408–420.
In a globalising and interdependent world,
O’Loughlin, M. A. 2012. ‘Benchmarking and Ac-
IGR are increasingly important to politics, pol- countability: the role of the COAG Reform
icy and administration. Understanding the var- Council.’ In A. Fenna and F. Knüpling (eds.),
ious dimensions, institutions, processes and Benchmarking in Federal Systems. Melbourne:
challenges of IGR may not necessarily lead to Productivity Commission: 247–266.
harmonious relations, but further study of this Painter, M. 2001. ‘Multi-level governance and the
important aspect of public policy and adminis- emergence of collaborative federal institutions in
tration should highlight some possibilities for Australia.’ Policy & Politics, 29(2): 137–150.
reform and more effective outcomes for citi- Painter, M. 2012. ‘Intergovernmental Relations’.
zens and governments alike. In B. G. Peters and J. Pierre (eds.), The SAGE
Handbook of Public Administration. Los Ange-
les: SAGE: 730–734.
References Phillimore, J. 2010. ‘Intergovernmental Relations in
Australia: Increasing Engagement.’ In R. Chat-
Ashton, H. 2012. ‘O’Farrell bid to reduce tax burden topadhyay and K. Nerenberg (eds.), Dialogues on
for business.’ The Sydney Morning Herald. 25 Intergovernmental Relations in Federal Systems.
March. Booklet Series Volume 8. Ottawa: Forum of Fed-
Chattopadhyay, R. and Nerenberg, K. 2010. ‘Pref- erations and International Association of Centers
ace.’ In R. Chattopadhyay and K. Nerenberg for Federal Studies: 12–15.
(eds.), Dialogues on Intergovernmental Relations Poirier, J. and Saunders, C. 2010. ‘Comparative re-
in Federal Systems. Booklet Series Volume 8. Ot- flections on Intergovernmental Relations in Fed-
tawa: Forum of Federations and International As- eral Countries.’ In R. Chattopadhyay and K.
sociation of Centers for Federal Studies: vii-x. Nerenberg (eds.), Dialogues on Intergovernmen-
Council of Australian Governments. ‘COAG Coun- tal Relations in Federal Systems. Booklet Series
cils’, URL: <http://www.coag.gov.au/coag_ Volume 8. Ottawa: Forum of Federations and In-
councils Accessed 19 June 2013>. ternational Association of Centers for Federal
Editorial, 2013. ‘COAG broken, time to trade it in.’ Studies: 3–8.
The Australian Financial Review. 22 April. Radin, B. 2012. ‘The Instruments of Intergovern-
Fenna, A. 2012. ‘Federalism and Intergovernmental mental Management.’ In B. G. Peters and J. Pierre
Coordination.’ In B. G. Peters and J. Pierre (eds.), (eds.), The SAGE Handbook of Public Adminis-
The SAGE Handbook of Public Administration. tration. Los Angeles: SAGE: 735–749.
Los Angeles: SAGE: 750–763. Sharman, C. 1977. The Premiers’ Conference: An
Fenna, A. and Anderson, G. 2012. ‘The Rudd Re- essay in federal state interaction. Canberra: De-
forms and the Future of Australian Federalism.’ In partment of Political Science, RSSS, Australian
G. Appleby, N. Aroney and T. John (eds.), The Fu- National University.
ture of Australian Federalism: comparative and Simeon, R. 1972. Federal–Provincial Diplomacy:
interdisciplinary perspectives. Cambridge: Cam- the making of recent policy in Canada. Toronto:
bridge University Press: 393–413. University of Toronto Press.
Harwood, J. and Phillimore, J. 2012. The Effects Tiernan, A. 2008. ‘The Council for the Australian
of COAG’s National Reform Agenda on Central Federation: A new structure of Australian feder-
Agencies. Melbourne: Australia and New Zealand alism.’ Australian Journal of Public Administra-
School of Government. tion, 67(2): 122–134.


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
238 Understanding Intergovernmental Relations September 2013

Wanna, J., Phillimore, J., Fenna, A. and Harwood, J. opment and Provincial Affairs in collaboration
2009. Common Cause: Strengthening Australia’s with the National Democratic Institute for Inter-
Cooperative Federalism. Council for the Aus- national Affairs (South Africa).
tralian Federation. Watts, R. L. 2008. Comparing Federal Systems,
Watts, R. L. 1997. ‘Intergovernmental Relations: 3rd edn. Montreal: McGill–Queen’s University
A Report’. Department of Constitutional Devel- Press.


C 2013 National Council of the Institute of Public Administration Australia
Copyright of Australian Journal of Public Administration is the property of Wiley-Blackwell
and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without
the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or
email articles for individual use.

You might also like