You are on page 1of 14

Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in


International Accounting
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/adiac

Mandatory audit partner rotation, audit market concentration, and audit


quality: Evidence from China☆
Sati P. Bandyopadhyay a,1, Changling Chen a,⁎, Yingmin Yu b,2
a
School of Accounting and Finance, University of Waterloo, 200 University Avenue West, Waterloo, Ontario N2L 3G1, Canada
b
School of Accountancy, Central University of Finance and Economics, 39 College South Road, Haidian District, Beijing 100081, China

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Available online 29 December 2013 This research examines the audit quality consequences of China's mandatory audit partner rotation (MPR) reg-
ulation, which became effective in 2004. The rule requires firms to rotate signing audit partners of audit reports
JEL classification: every five years. We find that audit quality improves in the three years immediately following a client firm's MPR
M41 during the 2004–2011 period for a sample of 273 Chinese publicly listed firms. Specifically, we find that the im-
M42 provement is most pronounced in those Chinese provinces with both low levels of audit market concentration
and low levels of legal development. However, MPR does not improve audit quality in jurisdictions where
Keywords:
Mandatory audit partner rotation legal conventions are more developed and/or where audit markets are highly concentrated with a handful of
Audit market concentration large audit firms dominating the market.
Audit quality © 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction reviewing partner in order to improve audit independence and thus


audit quality. For example, the Sarbanes–Oxley Act (henceforth SOX,
In this study we examine the effects of mandatory audit partner ro- 2002) mandates US audit partners to rotate their audit clients every
tation (MPR) on audit quality. Specifically, we look at the effects of MPR five years, and the European Union requires audit firms to replace
under varying audit market concentration (AMC) conditions in the Chi- audit partners in charge of their clients that are Public Interest Entities
nese audit market, where, starting in 2004, regulators required client every seven years. Similar MPR requirements are also in vogue in
firms to rotate audit partners every five years. We find that MPR im- Australia, China, Taiwan, and many other jurisdictions.3 The conse-
proves audit quality in provinces with low levels of AMC but not in quence of mandatory auditor rotation (at firm or partner level) on
provinces with high levels of AMC. Our results suggest that the effec- audit quality depends on the tradeoff of improvement in audit indepen-
tiveness of MPR policy on audit quality depends on the structure of dence versus loss in client-specific audit experience (Kinney &
the audit market. Our research contributes to audit literature by relating McDaniel, 1996; Knapp, 1991; Mautz & Sharaf, 1961).4 On the one
two long-standing issues, namely, the consequence of MPR on audit hand, a fresh look into the audit engagement by the rotated-in audit
quality, and the impact of AMC on audit quality. Both these issues partner improves audit independence and thus the quality of the
have recently re-entered the public debate in the USA (Public audit. On the other hand, the rotated-in partner does not possess the
Company Accounting Oversight Board, 2011a) and the European client-specific expertise of the rotated-out partner, and this lack of ex-
Commission (EU) (2011). perience could reduce audit quality. The final effect of MPR on audit
In the post-Enron era, several countries have mandated periodic ro- quality is an empirical issue determined by the tradeoff. Empirical evi-
tation of the lead audit engagement partner and the concurring dence on the relation between MPR and audit quality is mixed. Studies
based on the Taiwanese audit market indicate either no effect or a neg-
☆ We thank the editor Philip Reckers and two anonymous referees for their insightful ative effect of MPR on audit quality (Chen, Lin, & Lin, 2008; Chi & Huang,
comments. We also thank Xi Wu, Junsheng Zhang, and other workshop participants at
the Central University of Finance and Economics. This study is supported by the research
3
grants from the “Project 211” Fund of the Central University of Finance and Economics, Other countries adopting MPR include Singapore, Japan, United Kingdom, France,
China and grants from the “2011 Synergetic Innovation” Key Project on “Development of Spain, the Netherlands, and Germany (General Accounting Office 2003, Appendix V; Chi
Public Accounting Profession” of the Central University of Finance and Economics, China. et al., 2009).
4
We also gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Research Fellowship These authors use the generic “auditor” term in their papers and do not specify wheth-
Program at the School of Accounting and Finance of the University of Waterloo. er their arguments apply to audit firm or audit partner level. These arguments apply equal-
⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 519 888 4567x35731; fax: +1 519 888 7562. ly well to both firm and partner level (Chen et al., 2008). DeAngelo (1981) defines audit
E-mail addresses: bandy@uwaterloo.ca (S.P. Bandyopadhyay), clchen@uwaterloo.ca quality as the joint probability that an auditor detects a breach of accounting standards
(C. Chen), yuym168@gmail.com (Y. Yu). and the probability that the auditor reports the breach. MPR will likely decrease the prob-
1
Tel.: +1 519 888 4567x32533; fax: +1 519 888 7562. ability of detecting a breach because of lost audit knowledge but increase the probability of
2
Tel.: +86 10 62156441; fax: +86 10 62288114. reporting the breach.

0882-6110/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.adiac.2013.12.001
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 19

2005; Chi, Huang, Liao, & Hong, 2009). In contrast, research based on the by the same audit firm that audits its competitors (European Commission
Australian audit market (Carey & Simnett, 2006) provides some evi- (EU), 2011).
dence that MPR tends to enhance audit quality. Experimental evidence Regardless of such comments, which reflect serious policy concerns
(Dopuch, King, & Schwartz, 2001; Tan, 1995) also suggests that MPR im- about the consequences of heightened AMC, recent research often finds
proves audit quality. Note that while the identity of audit partners is a positive relation between AMC and audit quality (Francis, Michas, &
public information in Taiwan and Australia, and thus the effect of MPR Seavey, 2013; Kallapur, Sandaraguruswamy, & Zang, 2010). In our
on audit quality can be evaluated directly, this is not the case in many paper we examine whether MPR can improve audit quality in low
jurisdictions, including the USA. AMC jurisdictions where extant research tends to report lower audit
Recently, the European Commission (EU) (2011) has expressed the quality than that in high AMC jurisdictions. It might be noted that, to
view that the practice of MPR does not improve audit independence date, audit research has either examined the relation between audit
(and hence audit quality). The argument is that MPR does not remove quality and MPR without controlling for AMC (e.g. Carey & Simnett,
the familiarity threat that might cloud audit judgment and reduce pro- 2006; Chi et al., 2009) or the relation between AMC and audit quality
fessional audit skepticism of a new (rotated-in) audit partner, who without controlling for MPR (Kallapur et al., 2010). The unequal pace
would not have incentives to take decisions that might cause the audit of audit market development across Chinese provinces makes it an
firm to lose a long-standing client firm. Hence, new (replaced) audit ideal setting for our analysis. For example, our Chinese MPR sample ex-
partners “likely feel obliged to live with the decisions and agreements hibits a wide range of variation in AMC at the provincial level. During
made by the former (rotated-out audit) partner; he/she may have little the 2004 to 2011 sample period, the provincial Herfindahl index
flexibility to reopen them” (European Commission (EU), 2011, page 17). based on audit fees and client locations varies between a minimum of
On the basis of these arguments, European Commission (EU) (2011) 0.071 and a maximum of 0.982, with the first quartile of 0.125, a median
proposes mandatory audit firm rotation (MFR) to replace MPR. Consis- of 0.155, and the third quartile of 0.217.5
tent with the view of the European Commission (EU) (2011), the US We identify 273 unique Chinese publicly listed client companies
Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (henceforth PCAOB) is- countrywide that are subject to the MPR rule and compare their audit
sued a concept release in August 2011 (PCAOB, 2011a) that also sug- quality both pre- and post-MPR.6 We require our sample companies ro-
gests MFR for US firms. tate out their signing audit partners when they have met the maximum
The accounting community, however, has generally opposed the five-year tenure requirement. We also impose the condition that audit
proposal to replace MPR with MFR. For example, a summary of re- partner rotation not be accompanied by audit firm rotation in the
sponses to the MFR study by the General Accounting Office (GAO, periods before and after MPR to avoid a potentially confounding
2004, Question 73) shows that about two-thirds of the respondents ap- effect of audit firm rotation on audit quality. Following prior research
pear to believe that relative to potentially more costly MFR, MPR suffi- (e.g. Chen et al., 2008; Francis et al., 2013), we use abnormal (discretion-
ciently achieves the intended benefits of taking a fresh look at the ary) accruals as our measure of audit quality.
audit engagement by the rotated-in partner. In their response letter to We find that on average MPR has a positive effect on audit quality in
the PCAOB (PCAOB, 2011b), the International Federation of Accountants the post-rotation years, especially in the second and third years after
(henceforth IFAC) argues that “these changes [MPR] are still relatively MPR. When we partition our sample by the provincial AMC levels, we
new, and have not been in place sufficiently long enough to objectively find that the incremental benefit of MPR on audit quality is observed
assess their impact.” This IFAC response implies the need for further ex- only in low, but not high, AMC provinces in China. We then extend
amination of the consequences of MPR. Firth, Rui, and Wu (2012a) to examine whether the interaction of the
In summary, while many in the professional accounting and audit level of legal development with AMC has an effect on how MPR en-
community believe that MPR enhances audit quality, international reg- hances audit quality. Firth, Rui, and Wu (2012a) show that MPR has a
ulators do not seem to share that view. Moreover, as discussed above, positive effect on audit quality in China only in regions with low levels
academic research provides mixed evidence on the impact of MPR on of legal development. We find that the beneficial effect of MPR is ob-
audit quality. served in those provinces that not only have low levels of legal develop-
Responding to the call of IFAC for further research on the effects of ment but also low levels of AMC. Our results are robust to alternative
MPR, we examine the relation between MPR and audit quality in the audit quality measures such as the discretionary working capital ac-
Chinese audit market to provide some insight into this contentious de- cruals (Carey & Simnett, 2006), different AMC measures, and various
bate. Also, in contrast to extant research, we consider the impact of re- pre-MPR periods (one year before MPR and a three-year period before
gional variation in AMC, whose role has recently been highlighted in MPR), after controlling for audit firm tenure, client company size, cash
the foregoing MPR versus MFR deliberations. For example, the Center flows, industry growth, age, state ownership, and leverage.
for Audit Quality (henceforth CAQ) argues in its written statement Our paper contributes to the literature by bringing together two dif-
(PCAOB, 2011c) to PCAOB's (2011a) concept release that many small ferent streams of extant audit research. One stream examines the effects
audit firms will find the costs of periodic tendering, documentation of MPR on audit quality, but the results are indeterminate. The other
and staffing associated with MFR too onerous and will be forced to stream of literature examines the effect of AMC on audit quality in papers
“abandon their public practice and focus instead on private company such as Kallapur et al. (2010) and Francis et al. (2013). We contribute to
audits” (PCAOB, 2011c, page 12). This suggests that abandonment of the literature by investigating the effects of MPR on audit quality under
MPR for MFR could lead to a higher level of concentration of the Big 4 different AMC conditions and different levels of legal development. We
audit firms in many public audit markets that are already considered show that MPR is able to enhance audit quality in Chinese provinces
highly concentrated by policymakers. where both of these features are relatively underdeveloped. However,
For example, European Commission (EU) (2011) has expressed con-
cerns that a potential demise of any of the existing Big 4 audit firms in
highly concentrated audit markets might de-stabilize the financial sys- 5
Kallapur et al. (2010) report US MSA (metropolitan statistical area) Herfindahl index-
tem. There is also concern that “concentration among a few firms en- es of 0.230, 0.252, and 0.293 respectively for the first quartile, median, and the third quar-
abled the largest accounting firms to exercise greater influence over tile distributions in the 2000–2006 period. However, these authors study the relation
the audit standard setting process and regulatory requirements.” between AMC and audit quality but not in the MPR setting.
6
(GAO, 2003) Audit quality could also be compromised through moral Relative to a cross-sectional comparison between MPR client firms and a control sam-
ple (e.g. voluntary audit partner rotation or no-rotation sample, as in Chi et al., 2009) our
hazard issues if large audit firms believe they are “too few to fail” pre- versus post-MPR comparison for MPR firms has the advantage of highlighting the
(GAO, 2003). The lack of choice in audit markets dominated by Big 4 consequence of MPR by eliminating the potentially confounding effects of covariates relat-
audit firms is another concern. Client firms might not want to be audited ed to client firms' characteristics.
20 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

the improvement in audit quality does not seem to be large enough to and a reviewing partner who must be at least a deputy executive of
catch up with the high levels of audit quality enjoyed by client firms in the audit firm.9 These two signing auditors are required to assume the
provinces with high AMC and a high level of legal development. Our find- same legal liability unless proved to the contrary (Firth et al., 2012a).10
ings suggest that the effect of MPR on audit quality needs to be examined To be consistent with prior literature, we refer to signing auditors as
on a case-by-case basis and cannot be subject to generalized conclusions audit partners.
for different audit market structures. For example, the contradictory MPR The usefulness of mandatory auditor rotation (at the firm or partner
results in Taiwan versus Australia might arise from not considering inter- level) has been a matter of debate both in the financial press and in the
nal variations in audit market conditions in these countries. academic auditing literature for a number of years. Apart from a few
Our results have some potential policy implications. As previously jurisdictions, like Italy and Brazil, that have mandatory audit firm
mentioned, while regulators are concerned about the potential adverse rotation, individual audit partner rotation has become a require-
effects of high AMC, audit quality is also demonstrated to be high in ment in several jurisdictions including Australia (Carey & Simnett,
these jurisdictions. Our study shows that MPR is a policy tool that 2006), Taiwan (Chi et al., 2009), China (Firth et al., 2012a), USA
could potentially improve audit quality in low AMC areas and thus (SOX, 2002), Singapore, United Kingdom, France, Spain, Netherlands,
avoid the attendant policy problems of high AMC. However, given that Japan, and Germany (GAO, 2003, Appendix V). It is also currently
our sample firms (273) constitute less than 20% of Chinese publicly being considered in Canada. The adoption of MPR rules in these audit
listed companies, the generalizability of our results needs to be treated markets reflects regulators' concerns that lengthy audit partner ten-
with caution. ure reduces audit quality on account of its adverse effect on audit
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, independence.
we describe the institutional background and summarize the litera- Researchers have argued both in favor of and against mandatory ro-
ture. We develop our hypotheses in Section 3. In Section 4, we dis- tation at the audit firm level.11 Some of these arguments apply to man-
cuss the sample selection procedure, variable measurement, and datory rotation at the audit partner level as well, because individual
research methods. Section 5 summarizes our results. Section 6 partners have incentives to maintain their relationships with a client
concludes. in order to retain the client (Chen et al., 2008, page 420). The argument
in favor of mandatory rotation is that a long association with an audit
client clouds the auditor's judgment and leads to impairment of audit
2. Institutional background and literature review independence (Mautz & Sharaf, 1961). A new audit partner who rotates
in to periodically replace an incumbent audit partner is expected to take
Since the 1990s, Chinese accounting and auditing regulators, in- a “fresh look” into different aspects of the engagement and improve
cluding the Chinese Institute of Certified Public Accountants audit quality. Healey and Kim (2003) argue that mandatory rotation
(CICPA), the Ministry of Finance (MOF), and the China Securities will restore “badly shaken investor confidence in the financial account-
Regulatory Commission (henceforth CSRC), have undertaken a num- ing system.” In an experimental study, Dopuch et al. (2001) provide ev-
ber of steps to enhance audit independence. In 1996, these national idence that MPR increases auditor independence. In another
regulators required all Chinese audit firms that had previously had experimental study, Tan (1995, page 115) concludes that “staff rotation
government affiliations to break off their government ties (Gul, and review awareness can improve the quality of the audit decision pro-
Fung, & Jaggi, 2009). Regulators also adopted a new set of auditing cess.” Raghunathan, Lewis, and Evans (1994) provide some evidence
standards in 1995, which ultimately resulted in their convergence consistent with greater frequency of US Security Exchange Committee
with the International Standards on Auditing (ISA) promulgated by (SEC) actions against longer tenure audit firms, suggesting a potential
the IFAC (Firth et al., 2012a; Lin & Chan, 2000; Xiao, Zhang, & Xie, beneficial role of MPR practice.
2000). An important argument against mandatory rotation is that it will de-
Moreover, in the wake of a series of accounting scandals that took prive the client of the firm-specific knowledge acquired by the incum-
place in the late 1990s and early 2000s, which resulted in the bankrupt- bent auditor through a steep learning curve over a period of time
cy of Yinguangxia Company and other listed companies, the auditing li- (Knapp, 1991). This knowledge is not available to the replaced (rotat-
cense of the then largest audit firm in China, Zhongtianqin ed-in) auditor. This view is largely supported in the extant US-based
(Yinguangxia's auditors),7 was suspended. The Chinese government studies which, with few exceptions (e.g. Davis, Soo, & Trompeter,
then implemented a series of measures to restore public confidence in 2009; Deis & Giroux, 1992) find that audit quality is poor in the early
the financial reporting process (Chen, Sun, & Wu, 2010). In October
2003, the CSRC and MOF jointly issued a mandatory audit partner rota-
tion rule (Chinese Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC Regulation)
& China Ministry of Finance (MOF), 2003 No. 13) to improve audit inde- 9
In the review process, a review partner examines audit plan, audit risk (inherent risk
pendence and thus audit quality. Under this rule, which became effec- and control risk), audit evidence (e.g. audit sampling), auditing adjustments, and audit re-
port draft. This is consistent with ISA regulations, under which engagement control review
tive January 1, 2004, all Chinese-listed companies are required to
partners are required to review the risk of material misstatement (inherent risk and con-
rotate out their audit partners who have signed the company's audit re- trol risk) and audit sampling among others. In our sample, we are unable to identify which
ports for five consecutive years.8 As in Taiwan, Chinese audit reports of the two signing auditors is the lead or reviewing partner. The authors' interviews with
have two signatories: a lead audit partner responsible for fieldwork practitioners in China reveal that the order of two signatures is random for many auditing
firms. We find that our results are not sensitive to whether we center our MPR analyses on
audit tenure of the first versus the second signing auditor. In our sample, 108 of the 273
client companies of our sample rotated out their first signing audit partners, 83 rotated
7
Chen et al. (2010), Appendix 1) provides a list of scandals in the Chinese stock market out the second signing audit partners, and 82 rotated out both partners.
10
in the early 2000s. Chinese Independent Auditing Standards, adopted in 1995, are highly convergent
8
Chen et al. (2008) raise the concern that MPR may be superficial if a partner rotates with the ISA of the IFAC (Firth et al., 2012a; Lin & Chan, 2000; Xiao et al., 2000). According
back to the client after a very short “cooling-off” period. They find that more than half of to the Chinese auditing standards, reviewing partners must hold the position of at least
the partners in their Taiwanese sample, who rotated off in 2003 or 2004, rotated back after deputy executive in an audit firm. In the review process, a review partner shall examine
one year. Note that there is no minimum cooling-off period for a rotation-off audit partner the audit plan, audit risk (inherent risk and control risk), audit evidence (from audit sam-
in Taiwan. In contrast, Chinese regulations require a minimum two-year “cooling-off” pe- pling), auditing adjustments, and audit report draft. By ISA, the engagement control re-
riod. In our sample, 53 client companies are found to have re-appointed the same audit view partner shall also review the risk of material misstatement (inherent risk and
partners to their prior audit clients in Year 8, the year right after the required two-year control risk) and audit sampling among others. The Chinese review audit partners' tasks,
cooling-off period. We conduct sensitivity tests by eliminating these client companies hence, share similarities with ISA's engagement quality control on audit review.
11
and our results hold. Firth, Rui, and Wu (2012b) findings are consistent with reduced audit In our paper, mandatory rotation refers to mandatory audit partner rotation, unless in-
quality associated with “rotated back” partners. dicated otherwise.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 21

years of an audit firm's tenure with a specific client.12 This is consistent Public Accountants (CICPA), 2007 Bulletin No. 15), averaging at less
with the notion that audit quality improves as an audit partner acquires than 25 clients per audit firm. The dominance of Big 4 audit firms is
client-specific knowledge over time. As a corollary, it could be argued much less evident in China (auditing 17% of all listed Chinese companies
that the loss of client-specific expertise when an incumbent audit part- during 1999–2007 period) relative to many other jurisdictions (Francis
ner is rotated out under MPR could hurt audit quality. However, none of et al., 2013) including the USA (61%), Australia (71%), and Taiwan (74%).
the foregoing US-based papers provide direct evidence on the conse- Chinese regulators are wary of its audit markets being dominated by Big
quences of MPR on measures of audit quality because they mostly 4 audit firms and is keen to encourage the growth of domestic firms to
study audit firm tenure but not individual audit partner tenure. compete with large international audit firms that were allowed to oper-
Direct empirical tests of the consequences of MPR on audit quality ate directly in China after the country's accession to the World Trade Or-
are mostly based on the audit and financial data obtained from ganization (henceforth WTO) in the post-2001 period (Chan & Wu,
Taiwan and Australia where13, unlike in the US, identities of the audit 2011).14 Variations in AMC across different Chinese provinces provide
partners who perform the audit are disclosed. In China, as in these coun- us with the opportunity to examine whether the beneficial effects of
tries, the names of the two audit partners engaged in auditing a client MPR on audit quality, if any, vary with AMC levels.
are public information. Finally, we examine if the relation between MPR and audit quality is
Carey and Simnett (2006) examine the association between audit affected by the level of legal development of the province in which the
quality and long audit partner tenure using data from Australia for a pe- audit client is located, especially when viewed in conjunction with the
riod when audit partner rotation was not mandatory. They find that AMC level of the province. Chinese provinces do not have a uniform
audit quality declines with audit partner tenure when audit quality is level of legal development, and they exhibit large differences in this re-
measured as (1) the propensity to issue a going concern opinion for dis- spect. Fan, Wang, and Zhu (2004) measure the provincial level of legal
tressed firms, or (2) the probability of exceeding earnings benchmarks. development in terms of the number of lawyers as a percentage of the
Also using Australian data, Hamilton, Ruddock, Stokes, and Taylor population, the efficiency of the local courts, and the protection of prop-
(2005) find less income-increasing discretionary accruals following erty rights. Wang, Wong, and Xia (2008) show that there are great geo-
MPR. In contrast, using Taiwanese audit partner data, Chen et al. graphical disparities in legal development in China in terms of
(2008) find that audit quality increases with audit partner tenure and protection of property rights and efficiency of law courts among other
audit firm tenure, thus concluding that MPR (and also MFR) is likely legal elements. Firth et al. (2012a) examine the audit quality conse-
to impair audit quality. Similarly, Chi et al. (2009) conclude that MPR quence of MPR in China in strong versus weak legal environments
does not help audit quality in Taiwan. These authors find that the level using the Wang et al. (2008) criteria. These authors find that client com-
of discretionary accruals of client companies in the year of MPR is no panies subject to MPR exhibit better audit quality than non-MPR com-
lower than the pre-rotation year level. panies in 2004, the first year that MPR was adopted in China.
The above mentioned mixed results show that the effect of MPR on However, this positive audit quality effect is restricted to client compa-
audit quality in Taiwan versus Australia is different, probably due to the nies located in Chinese provinces suffering from low levels of legal de-
specific audit market in which the relationship is examined. In our velopment; the positive audit quality effect of MPR does not apply to
study, we first examine the average effect of MPR on audit quality more legally developed provinces.
using Chinese audit data over all Chinese provinces. This analysis pro- However, Firth et al. (2012a) do not examine, as we do, the change
vides fresh insights into the benefits or otherwise of MPR in a different in audit quality pre- and post-MPR for both the mandatory rotation
audit market. We then analyze how this relation changes with the pro- year and up to two years subsequently. More importantly, they do not
vincial variation in AMC, which is an audit market characteristic not examine the audit quality effect of MPR conditional on varying provin-
studied in previous Australian/Taiwanese research. It is important to cial AMC levels. In contrast, in our paper we examine how MPR affects
note that AMC has an independent effect on audit quality (e.g. Francis audit quality for different provinces that exhibit different levels of
et al., 2013; Kallapur et al., 2010) and might confound empirical tests legal development and AMC.
of the relation between MPR and audit quality if its effect not controlled
for. Furthermore, international regulators are concerned about the ad-
3. Hypotheses development
verse effects on audit quality of dominance of a handful of audit firms
in international audit markets.
As stated earlier, the effect of MPR on audit quality is the result of
China exhibits wide variation in provincial AMC. For example, the
a tradeoff between having an independent and fresh look at the en-
Herfindahl index based on audit fees and client locations is around
gagement by a new (rotated-in) audit partner versus losing the
0.07 in the populous Guangdong province through our sample period,
audit expertise of the departing (rotated-out) auditor. Note that
whereas the figure is around 0.55 for the equally populous Zhejiang
audit independence is defined in the literature as the joint probability
province over the same period. In the entire country, 64 audit firms
that a given auditor will both (a) “discover a breach in the client's
audited 1570 listed clients in China (Chinese Institute of Certified
accounting system, and (b) report the breach” (DeAngelo, 1981). The
rotated-in partner will probably have less hesitation in reporting a breach,
12
if a breach is discovered, than the outgoing partner, because he or she
Gul, Jaggi, and Krishnan (2007) demonstrate greater earnings management in the ear-
ly years of an audit firm's tenure. Arel, Brody, and Pany (2005) show that audit failures are
would not have had enough time to build up a relationship with the
common in the initial years of an audit firm's audit engagement. Geiger and Raghunandan client. This is likely to enhance audit independence and thus audit quality.
(2002) measure audit failure as the inability of the auditor to issue a modified audit opin- However, the effects of MPR on the probability of discovering a
ion before its client goes bankrupt and find more instances of audit failures in the early breach is not very clear. On the one hand, the new partner, by taking a
years of the audit firm's tenure. Carcello and Nagy (2004) come to similar conclusions
“fresh look” (Mautz & Sharaf, 1961), might find it easier to uncover a
about the timing of financial statement frauds. Stanley and DeZoort (2007) also find that
audit failures tend to take place in the early years of an audit firm's tenure. Several studies
14
find a positive relation between financial reporting quality and audit firm tenure (e.g. The motivation for Chinese regulators to encourage the growth of domestic audit
Johnson et al., 2002; Mansi, Maxwell, & Miller, 2004; Myers et al., 2003). This suggests that firms is to improve the supply of quality audit services to meet the increased demand
financial statement quality improves with audit firm tenure, which is in contrast to the resulting from the transformation of state-owned enterprises (SOE) into public-listed
non-linear relation between earnings management and audit firm tenure demonstrated companies (Chan & Wu, 2011). Note that before SOEs were privatized, they were audited
by Davis et al. (2009), who find that audit quality of firms with short (two to three years) by the National Audit Office of the People's Republic of China, not independent audit firms.
or very long (13–15 years or more) tenure tends to be low. Ghosh and Moon (2005) find a In addition, the demand for large domestic audit firms arose from sovereignty consider-
positive relation between earnings response coefficients and audit firm tenure. ations, rather than audit market considerations, especially after the Chinese accession to
13
Recently, PCAOB has proposed that US audit firms disclose the name of the audit part- WTO. In other words, the Chinese government felt it was more desirable to have large local
ner in charge of a client's audit (Rapoport, 2013). audit firms dominate the Chinese audit market than large foreign Big 4 audit firms.
22 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

breach, compared to the outgoing partner. On the other hand, the new evidence tends to show that audit quality is better in high AMC US city
partner probably will not possess the firm-specific expertise enjoyed markets (Kallapur et al., 2010) and international country-level markets
by the outgoing partner, thereby making it harder for him or her to de- (Francis et al., 2013). Despite this, some influential commentators hold a
tect a breach, if one exists. The outcome of the tradeoff of the “fresh different view. For example, Honorable Richard Breeden (see PCAOB,
look” versus reduction of client-specific expertise on the probability of 2012, page 5), an ex-chairman of the SEC, has stated that the present
discovering a breach is an empirical issue.15 Thus, because it is deter- value of future revenues from a few large audit engagements of any
mined by the joint probability of discovering a breach and disclosing a Big N audit firm, assuming “continued incumbency,” could exceed sev-
breach, overall improvement of audit quality due to MPR is hard to eral billion dollars, which “helps to explain why the issue of auditors try-
predict. ing to please the largest clients continues to arise.” This view is
Extant evidence on the effect of MPR on audit quality, which relies consistent with audit quality being low in highly concentrated markets,
on empirical research using Australian (Carey & Simnett, 2006; where MPR might have a beneficial effect.
Hamilton et al., 2005) and Taiwanese (Chen et al., 2008; Chi et al., Since the relation between MPR and audit quality under different
2009) audit data, is mixed. Experimental studies, on the other hand, audit market conditions is ambiguous, our second hypothesis, also
show positive effects of MPR on audit independence (Dopuch et al., non-directional, is as follows:
2001) and audit quality (Tan, 1995). Given the theoretical and empirical
evidence, our first hypothesis about average audit quality in Chinese H2. The improvement in audit quality after mandatory audit
audit markets across all provinces is non-directional. partner rotation in provinces with low audit market concentration
is not different from that in provinces with high audit market
H1. Average audit quality across Chinese provinces does not change concentration.
after mandatory audit partner rotation as compared to the pre-
rotation period. Finally, we examine the effect of market concentration in interaction
with legal development on the change in post-MPR audit quality. As
As stated earlier, AMC varies greatly across different provinces in stated earlier, Firth et al. (2012a) find that the level of legal develop-
China. In this paper we also examine the effect of MPR on audit quality ment in Chinese provinces affects the relation between MPR and audit
under varying AMC conditions at the provincial level. To the best of our quality using the provincial legal environment index of Wang et al.
knowledge, there has not been any theoretical analysis of this issue. (2008).17 Arguably, market discipline and more effective monitoring
However, the literature does provide a number of conflicting predic- in the high AMC and high legal development provinces allow audit
tions about the potential effects of AMC on audit quality. For example, firms to maintain a high level of audit quality regardless of MPR. The
in a theoretical paper, Chaney, Jeter, and Shaw (2003) argue that the code of auditor ethics and legal environment likely provide an effective
cost of losing a single client when an auditor tells the truth about a monitoring mechanism for maintaining audit independence in jurisdic-
breach is quite small under high competition (low AMC) because of tions with high levels of AMC and a strong legal enforcement frame-
the low profit margins in these markets and a large client pool. work. Thus, incremental benefits from MPR, if any, might be less
These authors state that the low cost of “telling the truth” would en- significant in provinces with high AMC and a strong legal environment
courage disclosure of a breach and improve audit quality in high relative to provinces of low AMC and low legal development. However,
competition audit markets. It is unclear, however, how MPR will we do not have a directional hypothesis on this interaction effect be-
change this cost of telling the truth in highly competitive (low cause it is also possible that audit quality in low AMC and low legal de-
AMC) audit markets. velopment provinces does not improve after MPR due to potentially
In contrast, DeAngelo (1981) argues that large audit firms with a weak market discipline and government regulation. Our third hypothe-
large client base have strong incentives to remain independent because sis also has no directional predictions:
of large quasi rents they earn from their clients. Large quasi rents exist
because the potential reputation cost arising from an audit failure is H3. The improvement in audit quality after MPR in provinces with low
likely to be high for large audit firms. This implies that audit markets audit market concentration and low legal development is not different
that are dominated by a small number of large audit firms (or high from that in provinces with high audit market concentration and high
AMC) will exhibit a high level of audit independence and therefore legal development.
high audit quality. If this argument is true, MPR will likely not affect
audit quality in high AMC markets incrementally either, given that
4. Sample selection and research design
audit quality is probably high to begin with.16
In addition, Watts and Zimmerman (1981) argue that larger audit
4.1. Sample selection
firms, which dominate concentrated audit markets, are better at moni-
toring their auditors in comparison with small audit firms. Since the cost
We obtain our audit and financial data from a database compiled by
of audit failure is high for large audit firms, resulting in costly decline in
Sinofin Technology Limited Co. and China Center for Economic Research
reputation and probable shareholder lawsuits, these audit firms moni-
(CCER) of Beijing University. The names of the signing auditors and
tor their audit partners very closely. Therefore, the incremental effect
audit firm data of Chinese publicly listed companies are available in
of MPR, with its fresh look into the engagement by a rotated-in partner,
the CCER database starting from 2000. We manually collect 1999 audit
is likely to be minimal. This implies that any enhancement to audit qual-
data from publicly available CICPA archives to compile data over a
ity from MPR is more likely to be significant in less concentrated (highly
five-year period from 1999 to 2003, as illustrated in Appendix 1, for
competitive) audit markets where audit firm, on average, are likely to
identifying clients firms' MPR in 2004, the first year of adoption of the
be smaller, and the level of monitoring of audit partners by the audit
MPR rule.18
firm is probably less intense.
Our sample covers the 1999–2011 period. We require signing audi-
The forgoing discussions indicate that the predicted effects of MPR
tors' identity data for consecutive six-year rolling windows starting
on audit quality under differing AMC conditions are uncertain. Empirical
from 1999 in order to identify mandatory audit partner changes starting
in 2004, the first year of MPR. Any effect of MPR on audit quality
15
In any case, we control for audit expertise effects by including incoming partner's in-
17
dustry experience in our empirical tests. We provide details on the legal environment index measure in Section 5.
16 18
“Theory suggests that auditor independence and audit quality are inextricably linked, Our sample does not include those companies that adopted the MPR rule early in
with auditor independence being an integral component of audit quality.” (GAO, 2003). 2003. All Chinese-listed companies are required to have a fiscal year end of December 31.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 23

could take longer than one year because rotated-in audit partners companies that change audit firms during the Year 1 to Year 6 peri-
might require some time to familiarize themselves with the new od.19 We then exclude 7 companies which rotated only one audit
client's business. Therefore, we compare client firms' audit quality partner when both partners should have been replaced after the
in the pre-MPR period versus the MPR year, and two subsequent mandated maximum five-year tenure, as well as 6 companies with
years as well, in order to examine longer-term effects of MPR, if missing accrual data during Years 5–6. We are left with 273 remain-
any. Our last MPR year is 2009 because 2011 is the last year of our ing unique client companies (or 1092 firm–year observations) after
sample period. completing these data screening procedures.
Appendix 1 describes the method we follow to classify an audit part- As described above, our sample selection procedure requires client
ner change as mandatory rotation. We refer to the first year that we companies to have the same audit firms in the five-year period (Years
start counting audit partner tenure as Year 1, the last year prior to 1 to 5) preceding the identified mandatory rotation year (Year 6). In ad-
MPR as Year 5, the MPR year with new rotated-in audit partner as dition, in the two-year period subsequent to the MPR year, if there is an
Year 6, and the two subsequent years as Years 7 and 8, respectively. audit firm change in Year 7, we eliminate the corresponding Year 7 and
We classify an audit partner change as a mandatory rotation if the pre- Year 8 observations. Alternatively, if there is no audit firm change in
vious incumbent audit partner “A” had audited a client from Years 1 to 5 Year 7 but there is one change in Year 8, we keep the Year 7 observation
but was replaced by audit partner “B” in Year 6. In our main tests, we and eliminate only the Year 8 observation. In this way, we attempt to re-
compare audit quality of Year 5 versus Years 6, 7, and 8. For example, move any confounding effect of audit firm change in our empirical anal-
for client companies subject to MPR in 2004 (Year 6), we use 2003 yses; we also try to restrict loss of power of tests arising from small
data to evaluate Year 5 audit quality, and 2006 and 2007 data to evalu- sample size by not requiring the inclusion of all three post-MPR years
ate Years 7 and 8, respectively. (Years 6, 7, and 8) in the sample selection procedure.20 Our final sample
As shown in Table 1, we begin with the CCER sample of 13,287 has 887 firm–year observations, including 273 respectively for each of
firm–year observations for the 2004–2011 period. After eliminating Year 5 and Year 6, 197 for Year 7, and 144 for Year 8 (see Panel B of
observations with missing audit partner names in Year 6 and the Table 1).
five preceding years, we obtain 7094 firm–year observations, Note that we identify Year 6 as the first year of a client company's
representing an average of 887 client companies per year. Out of first-time mandatory audit partner rotation after the adoption of the
this sample, we select 455 unique client companies who rotate MPR rule. As in Australia and Taiwan, Chinese audit reports have two
their audit partners after they finish their five-year tenure for signing audit partners, namely, a lead engagement partner and a
the first time during 2004–2009. We remove another 169 client reviewing partner. The rule allows a one-year postponement for one
of the two signing auditors if both signing auditors reach their five-
year tenure at the same time (Chinese Securities Regulatory
Commission (CSRC Regulation) & China Ministry of Finance (MOF),
2003 No. 13). For example, consider a client with two signing audit part-
Table 1
ners, one of them having audited the client for five years, but the other
Sample selection and composition.
for only four years. According to the mandatory rotation rule, the first
Panel A: Sample selection auditor is required to rotate out in Year 6, but the second auditor is
China Center for Economic Research (CCER) Database No. of Obs. allowed to audit the client for one more year. Therefore, for this case,
Total number of firm–year observations during 2004–2011 13,287 the second mandatory rotation happens in Year 7. We identify the
Less: Number of firm–year observations that had missing (6193) first year of the client firm's MPR as Year 6; we treat the second MPR
signing audit partners' names in the current year
year as Year 7. It is also possible that audit partner changes in Years 7
(2004–2011) and the five preceding years (1999 audit partner
and audit firm data were hand-collected) and 8 that take place before the expiry of the MPR imposed maximum
Preliminary sample: five-year tenure are voluntary. In order to address any confounding ef-
Number of firm–year observations (2004–2011) 7094 fects arising from multiple audit partner rotations in post-MPR years,
Average number of client firms per year 887
we eliminate those observations that are associated with audit partner
Mandatory partner rotation sample selection:
Number of companies that had auditor rotations after a five-year 455 changes (71 voluntary and 47 mandatory) in Years 7 and 8 in our sensi-
tenure for the first time at Year 6 (2004–2009) tivity checks. Our results hold.
Less: Number of companies with audit firm change in Year 6 or (169)
the five preceding years 4.2. Audit quality measures
Less: Number of companies that should rotate both partners but (7)
only rotate one after mandated tenure (one-year extension
allowed when both audit partners' tenure reached five years Following the literature, we use an earnings quality measure, name-
in the same year) ly, discretionary (abnormal) accruals, as a proxy of audit quality. Prior
Less: Number of companies that have missing abnormal accruals (6) research shows a positive relation between measures of high quality
in Year 6 and Year 5
audit (such as audit firm size or industry expertise) and high quality fi-
Remaining number of companies: 273
Number of firm–year observations in the period 2004–2011 1092
nancial reporting (Balsam, Krishnan, & Yang, 2003; Ghosh & Moon,
(279 times 4 years, namely, Year 5, Year 6, Year 7, and Year 8) 2005; Johnson, Khurana, & Reynolds, 2002; Krishnan, 2003; Myers,
Less: Observations with audit firm change in Years 7 or 8 (202) Myers, & Omer, 2003). The underlying argument is that high quality au-
Less: Observations with missing abnormal accrual values in (2) ditors are capable of detecting questionable accounting practices and
Years 7 or 8
misrepresentations as reflected in discretionary accruals. If managers
Less: Observations with missing values in control variables (1)
Remaining number of firm–year observations (273 for Year 5, 887 are unwilling to address the auditor's concerns about their discretion
273 for Year 6, 197 for Year 7, and 144 for Year 8): in financial reporting, high quality auditors are more likely than other
Panel B: Distribution of mandatory rotation years:

2004 54 19
We eliminate client companies with audit firm changes to isolate the effect of manda-
2005 72
tory audit partner rotation. Companies can change their audit firms for many reasons. For
2006 63
example, Johnson and Lys (1990) show that audit firm changes are related to client char-
2007 39
acteristics and audit firm cost structures. Schwartz and Menon (1985) report that client
2008 33
firms with poor performance may switch their audit firms on account of disputes regard-
2009 12
ing audit opinions, reporting issues, management changes, and audit fees.
Total 273 20
We thank our anonymous reviewer for this suggestion.
24 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

auditors to issue qualified audit reports (see DeAngelo, 1981). Myers 4.3. Research models
et al. (2003), page 783) argue that “high quality audits mitigate
more extreme management reporting decisions, and suggest that We estimate the following equation to compare the audit quality of
accruals can be used to identify these extreme reporting decisions.” Year 5, the last year prior to MPR, versus the three post-mandatory rota-
Empirical studies with Chinese data provide evidence that discre- tion Years: 6, 7, and 8.
tionary accruals measures are capable of capturing earnings manip-
ulation behavior in China (Ting, Yen, & Huang, 2009; Yu, Du, & Sun, DA ¼ α0 þ α1 POST þ β1 IBIG4 þ β2 CIBIG10 þ β3 FT þ β4 SIZE þ β5 CFO
2006). þβ6 GROW þ β7 AGE þ β8 SOE þ β9 LEV þ β10 TTYPE þ β11 EXP
Consistent with prior research on MPR and audit quality (Chen et al.,
þβ12 CLIENTP þ δ Year þ γIndustry þ ε ð2Þ
2008; Chi et al., 2009), we measure discretionary accruals using the
modified Jones model (Dechow, Sloan, & Sweeney, 1995) matched by
performance (Kothari, Leone, & Wasley, 2005). For simplicity, firm sub- where DA is discretionary accruals. POST is an indicator variable that
script is omitted in Eq. (1) and later equations. equals one for Years 6, 7, and 8 and zero for Year 5.
The constant term (α0) represents audit quality of Year 5, after con-
trolling for covariates. A negative coefficient (α1) on the POST variable is
TotalAccuralst =Assetst−1 ¼ α0 þ α1 ð1=Assetst−1 Þ þ β1 ðΔSt−ΔARt Þ=Assetst−1 consistent with audit quality improvement in the post-rotation period
β2 ðPPEt−1 =Assetst−1 Þ þ β3 ROAt−1 þ εt ð1Þ relative to the benchmark last pre-rotation year (Year 5), after control-
ling for covariates. A positive coefficient of POST indicates lower audit
quality after MPR.
where total accruals (TotalAccruals) equal net income before extraordi- Following prior research (Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen et al., 2008;
nary items minus operating cash flows, ΔS is change in sales, ΔAR is Chi et al., 2009; DeFond, Raghunandan, & Subramanyam, 2002), we in-
change in account receivables, PPE is net property, plant and equipment, clude several control variables in Eq. (2). Audit firm size variables
ROA is return on assets, and t is the year subscript. All variables are IBIG4 and CBIG10 equal one respectively for Big 4 international audit
scaled by lagged assets (Assetst − 1). firms and Top 10 Chinese audit firms22 and zero otherwise. FT is audit
We estimate Eq. (1) using the full CCER sample with non-missing firm tenure measured as the number of years that a client firm is audited
values of the regression variables by industry–year. We require at by the same audit firm.23 SIZE is client company size computed as the
least 15 valid observations for each industry–year regression. natural logarithm of total assets. Audit firm size and audit firm tenure
The industry category follows the 13-industry codes announced control for the audit quality effects of audits by large audit firms and
by CSRC. The mean coefficients of industry–year regressions are by audit firms with a long tenure with its incumbent client. We include
used to estimate the fitted values of non-discretionary accruals. cash flow variable CFO (operating cash flows scaled by lagged assets) be-
Discretionary accrual (DA) is computed as the total accruals minus cause prior research shows that it is negatively associated with accruals
the fitted values. Following Carey and Simnett (2006), we also use (Chi et al., 2009). GROW is growth in sales, measured as the total sales of
discretionary working capital accruals (DWCA) in our sensitivity the current year scaled by the industry total sales of the last year. AGE is
test. the number of years that the client firm is listed in a Chinese stock ex-
Extant literature uses a number of different measures of audit qual- change, which controls for the propensity of relatively younger compa-
ity, for example, absolute values (unsigned) of discretionary accruals, nies in high-growth industries to recognize extreme accruals.
signed values, or positive/negative values of discretionary accruals. In In addition, we include the SOE variable, which equals one, for state-
this paper, we focus on the signed value of discretionary accruals for owned enterprises, and zero otherwise. Chen, Chen, Lobo, and Wang
two reasons. The first reason follows from the results of Hribar and (2011) argue that SOE companies have less incentive to manage earn-
Nichols (2007) indicating that firm characteristics such as operating ings relative to non-SOE companies because the differences in the na-
volatility are related to the error variance in discretionary accruals. ture of the ownership, agency relations, and bankruptcy risks.
These authors argue that this correlation could weaken the statistical However, we do not predict the sign of the SOE variable. Aharony, Lee,
power of detecting low quality earnings using the unsigned (or abso- and Wong (2000) argue that while SOE managers do not have the
lute values of) discretionary accruals measure. Besides Hribar and same incentives as US managers to manage earnings since they do not
Nichols (2007), Carey and Simnett (2006) and Francis et al. (2013) own any shares of the firm, they might still earn high prestige and
also focus on the signed discretionary accruals in their analysis other non-pecuniary benefits from reporting higher earnings by under-
of audit quality. The second reason is regulatory; Chinese-listed taking earnings management activities. We also include a leverage var-
companies have disincentives to recognizing extreme income- iable (LEV) to capture the effects of risk associated with high levels of
decreasing accruals arising from CSRC-imposed regulations for eligi- debt (Carey & Simnett, 2006). LEV equals total liability scaled by total
bility for rights offerings. The most rigid regulation is the minimum assets. TTYPE is an indicator variable for special treatment stocks to cap-
ROE requirement.21 This regulation is widely applicable because al- ture earnings incentives arising from potential delisting risks.24 We do
most all listed firms tend to seek permission to undertake rights of-
ferings (Chen & Yuan, 2004). 22
The top 10 Chinese audit firms are selected based on the ranking prepared by CICPA in
2009. Chen, Chen, Lobo, and Wang (2011) use Top 8 to categorize big audit firms in their
study.
23
Audit data in CCER become available in 2000. Therefore, we count the number of years
that an audit firm serves a client (audit firm tenure) starting in 2000. For observations with
MPR year in 2004, we manually check 1999 audit firm data to ensure that audit firms are
21
The requirement for rights offerings was changed a number of times, reflecting the the same in 1999.
24
CSRC's efforts to protect shareholders against management expropriation. For example, ST/PT/ ∗ ST firms are firms that report consecutive losses and face substantial delisting
rights offerings required two consecutive years of profits after December 1993, and a risk. According to the rules introduced by the CSRC in 1999, a firm is designated as a special
three-year average ROE not below 10% after September 1994. The rules changed in Janu- treatment (ST) firm if it incurs losses for two consecutive years and a particular treatment
ary 1996, which required that for each of previous three years prior to a rights offering, the (PT) firm if it continues to report a loss for another year. A PT firm is delisted if it fails to
incumbent firms' three-year average ROE must not fall below 10%. This rule was changed become profitable in the following year. PT stocks cannot be traded except on Fridays
again in March 1999, which required the maintenance of a minimum ROE level of not be- and are limited to a maximum 5% price increase over the last Friday's close (no downside
low 6% for each of previous three years before rights offerings. After May 2006, these firms limit). The PT designation has been discontinued by the CSRC in 2002. Since 2003, the
needed to maintain a minimum three-year weighted average ROE of 6%. For regulations CSRC introduced a new designation called “*ST”, which is similar to ST, to further advise
on rights offerings, see the CSRC's regulation released on May 8, 2006, available on the of- the market of the risk that a company will be delisted if its loss continues the following
ficial webpage http://www.csrc.gov.cn. year. If a firm incurs losses for three consecutive years, it is de-listed.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 25

Table 2
Variable distributions and correlation matrix.

Panel A: variable distributions

Variable Mean Std. dev. Min. 25% Median 75% Max.

DA 0.001 0.091 −0.387 −0.043 0.006 0.042 0.706


DWCA −0.140 5.594 −0.584 −0.063 0.004 0.075 0.679
IBIG4 0.054 0.226 0 0 0 0 1
CBIG10 0.157 0.364 0 0 0 0 1
HERF 0.202 0.152 0.071 0.125 0.155 0.217 0.982
LEGAL 5.951 1.230 2.620 5.050 5.630 6.980 7.970
FT 6.515 1.387 4 5 6 8 9
SIZE 21.515 0.990 17.967 20.831 21.472 22.147 25.585
CFO 0.059 0.099 −0.645 0.014 0.054 0.105 0.601
GROW 1.266 0.205 0.787 1.161 1.212 1.357 3.284
AGE 9.079 3.036 0 7 9 11 18
SOE 0.661 0.474 0 0 1 1 1
LEV 0.540 0.366 0.021 0.389 0.544 0.657 7.788
TTYPE 0.159 0.366 0 0 0 0 1
EXP 0.020 0.037 0 0.002 0.006 0.018 0.297
CLIENTP 0.045 0.066 0 0.009 0.022 0.056 0.598

Panel B: Pearson correlation matrix

Variable DA DWCA HERF LEGAL FT SIZE CFO GROW AGE LEV EXP

DWCA 0.164
HERF −0.010 0.014
LEGAL −0.065 0.020 0.194
FT −0.041 0.020 0.129 0.026
SIZE 0.087 −0.011 0.053 0.175 0.197
CFO −0.639 −0.017 −0.042 −0.073 0.020 0.096
GROW −0.007 0.021 −0.004 0.015 −0.071 0.081 −0.008
AGE −0.027 0.013 −0.007 0.171 0.397 −0.003 0.003 −0.033
LEV −0.160 −0.097 0.049 −0.053 0.043 −0.032 −0.076 −0.066 0.082
EXP −0.002 0.007 0.121 0.134 −0.103 0.000 −0.045 −0.085 −0.071 0.145
CLIENTP 0.021 0.059 −0.120 −0.105 −0.156 −0.008 0.049 −0.034 −0.067 0.026 −0.033

See Appendix 2 for variable definitions. Bold numbers in Panel B are correlations significant with p b 0.05 (including b0.01). EXP (CLIENTP) variable values in Panel B are the residuals from
the first-stage regression EXP (CLIENTP) on SIZE (see Section 4.3 for the details of the two-stage method).

not have predictions for LEV and TTYPE. While financially distressed three indicator variables Y6, Y7, and Y8, that equals one, respectively,
firms with high debt and delisting risk may be aggressive in accruals for Years 6, 7, and 8, and zero for pre-rotation period (Year 5).
recognition, these firms may have to reduce instances of earnings man-
agement because of potentially restrictive debt covenants for high le-
verage firms and/or the tight levels of regulations on TTYPE companies. DA ¼ α0 þ α1 Y6 þ α2 Y7 þ α3 Y8 þ β1 IBIG4 þ β2 CBIG10 þ β3 FT
The EXP variable measures the two incumbent audit partners' com- þβ4 SIZE þ β5 CFO þ β6 GROW þ β7 AGE þ β8 SOE þ β9 LEV ð3Þ
bined experience in auditing clients in the incumbent client's industry. þβ10 TTYPE þ β11 EXP þ β12 CLIENT þ δ YEAR þ γIndustry þ ε
An audit partner's industry experience is measured as the percentage
of his/her audited client companies' assets in the same industry. Note 5. Data descriptive statistics and research findings
that the EXP score associated with the rotated-in partner(s) compen-
sates partially for the audit expertise that is lost with the departing part- 5.1. Data descriptive statistics
ner(s). As mentioned earlier, the effects of MPR on audit quality reflect a
tradeoff of enhanced audit independence versus loss of client-specific Table 2 Panel A reports the descriptive statistics of the selected sam-
audit expertise. After controlling for EXP (and effects of covariates), ple. The means of different indicator variables show that 5.4% of the
the indicator variable POST captures the change in post-MPR audit qual- sample observations are audited by Big 4 international audit firms
ity arising from potentially improved audit independence. (IBIG4), and 15.7% by the Top 10 largest Chinese audit firms (CBIG10);
The CLIENTP variable measures client power, which equals the per- 66.1% reflect state ownership (SOE) of client firms; and finally, 15.9%
centage of a client's total assets as a percentage of its audit firm's total were listed as special treatment stocks or particular transfer stocks
audited assets countrywide. This variable and EXP are both highly corre- (TTYPE) at some point by the CSRC in Year 5 and/or Year 6. The average
lated with the SIZE variable, with correlation coefficients of around 0.50 firm tenure (FT) is approximately 6.5 years. The average leverage ratio
(un-tabulated). In an attempt to reduce the potential effects of (LEV) is 54.0%, with a median of 54.4%. The minimum and maximum
multicollinearity, we use a two-stage approach. We first run two regres- values of discretionary accruals (DA), discretionary working capital ac-
sions, namely EXP on SIZE, and CLIENTP on SIZE. We derive the residuals cruals (DWCA), and other variables do not exhibit obvious outliers.25
of each regression by taking the actual EXP (CLIENTP) value minus its Table 2 Panel B reports the Pearson correlation matrix of our variables.
fitted value. Then we use the residual values, which are orthogonal to
SIZE values, to estimate Eq. (2). We control for Industry (Industry)
and year (Year) fixed effects in all regressions. Appendix 2 provides de- 25
To address the effects of potentially influential observations, we winsorize variable
tails on the measurement of all variables. values at the levels of 1% and 99%. We also use r-student screening (Belsley, Kuh, & Welsch,
To assess the effect of MPR on audit quality in each of the individual 1980) in all our regressions by eliminating observations with r-student absolute values
post-MPR years, we revise Eq. (2) by replacing the POST variable with greater than 4 in the regressions.
26 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

Table 3
Audit Quality Pre versus Post-MPR.

Pred. sign DA DA (DA N 0) DA (DA b 0) DA

Coef. (t-value) Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat)

POST +/− −0.012*** (−2.54) −0.059** (−1.97) −0.001 (−0.12)


Y6 +/− −0.008 (−0.99)
Y7 +/− −0.014*** (−2.66)
Y8 +/− −0.017*** (−2.63)
IBIG4 − −0.016* (−1.77) −0.093** (−2.37) 0.001 (0.08) −0.016* (−1.78)
CBIG10 − −0.006 (−1.04) −0.041 (−1.43) −0.001 (−0.06) −0.006 (−0.99)
FT − −0.001 (−0.20) 0.007 (0.53) −0.001 (−0.20) −0.001 (−0.31)
SIZE + 0.014*** (5.80) 0.039*** (2.98) 0.002 (0.34) 0.014*** (5.52)
CFO − −0.637*** (−18.85) −0.898*** (−6.96) −0.582*** (−13.22) −0.607*** (−18.05)
GROW + 0.001 (0.06) −0.114 (−1.33) 0.029 (0.83) −0.005 (−0.26)
AGE − 0.001 (1.52) 0.005 (1.12) 0.001 (0.37) 0.011* (1.64)
SOE +/− 0.009*** (2.15) 0.041* (1.78) 0.000 (−0.03) 0.008* (1.75)
LEV ? −0.080*** (−6.09) −0.384*** (−5.24) −0.015 (−0.73) −0.080*** (−6.00)
TTYPE ? 0.014** (2.04) 0.041 (1.35) 0.030*** (2.62) 0.014** (1.97)
EXP − −0.035 (−0.44) 0.102 (0.28) −0.151 (−0.92) −0.073 (−0.89)
CLIENTP + 0.063 (1.56) −0.091 (−0.41) 0.109 (1.58) 0.058 (1.42)
Constant ? −0.240*** (−4.24) −0.435 (−1.48) −0.033 (−0.31) −0.237*** (−3.99)
Obs. no. 879 479 408 881
Adj. R2 (%) 54.01 39.87 46.87 53.29

See Appendix 2 for variable definitions. All regressions control for industry and year fixed effects. Truncated regressions were used in the positive and negative abnormal accrual
regressions. *, **, *** significant respectively at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels with two-tailed tests.

DA and DWCA are positively correlated. DA is negatively correlated with and Francis et al. (2013). Our positive coefficient on SOE is consistent
HERF, LEGAL, CFO, and LEV. with SOE companies having incentives to use income-increasing ac-
cruals to boost bottom line net incomes (Aharony et al., 2000). We
5.2. Results of H1 find some evidence of high audit quality associated with Big 4 interna-
tional firms' audits. We also find that high leverage clients report
Table 3 reports the regression results of estimating Eqs. 2 and 3. Note more income-decreasing accruals and that there is some evidence that
that all our tests are two-tailed t-tests because our hypotheses are non- TTYPE clients are more aggressive in recognizing income-increasing
directional. Standard errors are clustered at individual client firm level accruals.
since discretionary accruals are firm-specific.26 Using signed discretion-
ary accruals (DA) as the dependent variable in Eq. (2), we find
5.3. Results of H2 and H3
that the indicator variable, POST, has a negative coefficient of −0.012
(t-stat = −2.54) significant at less than 5% level. This result is consis-
Hypothesis H2 examines whether the MPR's effect on audit qual-
tent with the notion that audit quality in the post-MPR years is superior
ity in provinces with less concentrated audit markets is different
to that in the last year prior to the start of MPR.
from that in other provinces. To test H2, we compute the Herfindahl
We also estimate truncated regressions respectively for positive
index for each client-province as the sum of squared audit firm fee
DA and negative DA observations. We find that a positive DA subsample
shares of all audit firms in a province. We estimate Eq. 2 for two sub-
has less income-increasing abnormal accruals in the POST period
samples grouped by the observations that reflect clients located in
(α3 = −0.059, t-stat = −1.97, p b .10), but a negative DA subsample
provinces with higher than the median provincial Herfindahl index
exhibits no significant change in audit quality in the post-MPR period.
versus those with lower than the median provincial Herfindahl
This is consistent with sample firms not undertaking “big baths” (poten-
index.28
tial reasons for firms recognizing negative accruals) in the post-MPR pe-
Table 4 summarizes the regression estimates of Eq. (2) for clients lo-
riod. For Eq. 3, while the coefficient on the first rotation year (Y6)
cated in provinces that exhibit Herfindahl indices less than the median
is insignificant, both Year 7 (Y7) and Year 8 (Y8) coefficients are
level (low AMC) versus more than the median level (high AMC). The re-
negative and significant (α2 = −0.014, t-stat = −2.66; α3 = −0.017,
sults show that the POST variable is insignificant for the high AMC group
t-stat = −2.63) at less than the 1% level. Collectively, these results indi-
but significant at less than the 5% level for the low AMC group using
cate that client companies report less extreme income-increasing abnor-
two-tailed tests (coefficient = − 0.017, t-stat = − 2.30). The control
mal accruals after MPR.27
variables have similar coefficients across the two regressions. SIZE and
The control variables in Table 3 are generally consistent with our
LEV are both significant at less than 1% level.
predictions. Specifically, our findings of positive coefficients on SIZE
We also examine the stand-alone effect of legal environment on the
and negative coefficient on CFO are consistent with Chi et al. (2009)
relation between MPR and audit quality (Firth et al., 2012a). The provin-
cial legal environment index scores are taken from Wang et al. (2008),
Table A1). These authors report the levels of legal development index
26
We use the SAS programming codes provided by Noah Stoffman, Kelley School of
Business, Indiana University (http://kelley.iu.edu/nstoffma/fe.html) to run regressions
with clustered standard errors and fixed effects models. While the degree of freedom is
28
much less after controlling for (client) firm effects in the fixed effects model, our results We also estimate Eq. (3) using the same sample decompositions by median of the me-
(un-tabulated) hold. dian of provincial Herfindahl index, and the median of legal development index. Consis-
27
The truncated regressions do not report the adjusted R-Squared. When using OLS re- tent with Eq. (2) results reported in Table 4, our results (un-tabulated) suggest audit
gressions, the adjusted R-Squared is respectively 39.87% and 46.87% for the income- quality improvement in the post-MPR period, especially in Years 7 and 8, for the low
increasing and income-decreasing accrual regressions. Herfindahl index and low legal development index groups, respectively.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 27

Table 4
Audit quality pre versus post-MPR: conditioning on AMC or legal environment.

Pred. DA DA DA DA

Sign Low AMC High AMC Low Legal High Legal

Coef. (t-value) Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat)

POST +/− −0.017** (−2.30) −0.009 (−1.46) −0.017*** (−2.47) −0.002 (−0.25)
IBIG4 − −0.040** (−2.23) 0.004 (0.46) −0.019 (−1.49) −0.021 (−1.50)
CBIG10 − −0.017 (−1.23) 0.002 (0.38) −0.008 (−0.87) −0.003 (−0.36)
FT − 0.002 (0.47) −0.002 (−0.66) 0.002 (0.53) −0.007* (−1.69)
SIZE + 0.014*** (4.17) 0.013*** (3.61) 0.015*** (4.46) 0.014*** (3.92)
CFO − −0.584*** (−9.75) −0.652*** (−18.83) −0.600*** (−13.33) −0.730*** (−12.93)
GROW + −0.042 (−1.24) 0.055** (2.06) 0.024 (0.69) −0.012 (−0.45)
AGE − 0.001 (0.98) 0.001 (0.83) 0.001 (0.85) 0.001 (1.50)
SOE +/− 0.013** (2.14) 0.005 (0.78) 0.012* (1.83) 0.003 (0.49)
LEV ? −0.080*** (−4.34) −0.080*** (−4.06) −0.098*** (−4.97) −0.074*** (−4.21)
TTYPE ? 0.025*** (2.60) 0.003 (0.37) 0.013 (1.31) 0.028** (2.37)
EXP − −0.117 (−1.12) −0.005 (−0.04) −0.044 (−0.27) 0.112 (1.06)
CLIENTP + 0.160*** (2.99) 0.005 (0.08) −0.001 (−0.02) 0.169*** (2.81)
Constant ? −0.214*** (−2.65) −0.265*** (−3.25) −0.273*** (−3.26) −0.223*** (−2.69)
Obs. no. 448 433 454 426
Adj. R2 (%) 49.05 59.73 45.22 67.03

See Appendix 2 for variable definitions. Low and high AMC regressions are respectively for the two subsamples of below or above median audit market concentration levels measured by
Herfindahl index (HERF). Low and high legal regressions are respectively for the two subsamples of below or above median legal environment index (LEGAL). All regressions control for
industry and year fixed effects. *, **, *** significant respectively at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels with two-tailed tests.

of 30 Chinese provinces' comprising of the following sub-indices, name- The results from the high–high group show insignificant change in
ly, (1) the number of lawyers as a percentage of the provincial popula- audit quality in the post-MPR period. The results (un-tabulated) are
tion, (2) the efficiency of local courts (percentage of lawsuits also insignificant for the two middle groups, namely, the low AMC and
pursued by the courts), and (3) protection of property rights.29 As high legal development and the high AMC and low legal development
Table 4 summarizes, POST is significantly negative (coefficient = provinces.
− 0.017, t-stat = − 2.47) only for the low legal development We also estimate a single regression with the full sample where
provinces (i.e., those with legal indices less than median index POST interacts respectively with the AMC variable (LHERF) and the
for the country) but not for the high legal development group. The re- legal environment variable (LLEGAL). The regression includes a
sults, consistent with Firth et al. (2012a), suggest that MPR is less like- two-way interaction of LHERF ∗ LLEGAL, and a three-way interaction
ly to improve audit quality in high AMC or high levels of legal of POST ∗ LHERF ∗ LLEGAL. In order to simplify the interpretation of
development audit markets, but is more effective in provinces low the coefficient signs, we reverse decile rank both the provincial
levels of AMC or low levels of legal environment. Herfindahl indices and the provincial legal development indices.
In the foregoing regressions, we use the median split to estimate For example, the variable LHERF is set to one for provincial
separate regressions for high versus low AMC subsamples and also Herfindahl indices that are included in the lowest decile of observa-
high versus low legal development subsamples. The reason for estimat- tions. Conversely, LHERF is set to zero for Herfindahl indices falling in
ing separate regressions is that the relation between audit quality and the highest decile rank. LHERF takes values between zero and one for
control variables (e.g. IBIG4) likely varies with high versus low AMC the intervening Herfindahl indices.30 We repeat this procedure for
and legal development. For example, in Table 4, the coefficients of the legal development index variable, LLEGAL. Decile ranking pro-
IBIG4 and CLIENTP are significant in the low AMC group but not in the vides more information in the variable measures relative to binary
high AMC group. Consequently, estimating one single regression indicator measures.
would force equality of coefficients on the control variables in this re- Consistent with our decile ranking approach, in the following dis-
gression that could potentially bias the coefficient of POST, the post- cussions, LL provinces are those that have the lowest AMC decile
MPR year indicator variable. rank and the lowest legal development index decile rank as well.
To test hypothesis H3, we estimate the effect of MPR on audit quality For these provinces, both LHERF and LLEGAL take the value of one.
with provincial AMC in interaction with the provincial legal develop- Similarly, the HH provinces reflect the highest AMC decile and
ment in empirical tests. Table 5 presents the regression results of the highest legal development index decile, with LHERF and LLEGAL
two groups with low AMC and low legal development (low–low) versus both taking the value of zero.31
those with high AMC and high legal development (high–high) based on Table 5 shows that audit quality improves in the LL (LHERF = 1 and
medians of these variables. To save space, we only report the results of LLEGAL = 1) provinces in the post-MPR period, but not in the HH
Eq. (3) with the POST variable to capture the overall change in audit provinces (LHERF = 0 and LLEGAL = 0). Note that the change in the
quality after MPR. The regression results are similar when we substitute (pre- versus post-MPR) audit quality in LL provinces, after controlling
Y6, Y7 and Y8 indicator variables for POST in regression models (results for covariates, equals the sum of coefficients of POST + POST ∗ LHERF +
un-tabulated). For the low–low group, the POST variable is significantly POST ∗ LLEGAL + POST ∗ LHERF ∗ LLEGAL. Since the coefficient on POST
negative at less than 1% level (coefficient = −0.027, t-stat = −2.74). is insignificantly different from zero, and all the other foregoing

29 30
The index is obtained from the National Economic Research Institute (NERI) Index of Setting the lowest value to zero and the highest value to one is convenient for the in-
Marketization of China's provinces in 2000 to measure the quality of market-supporting terpretation of coefficients. The intervening eight values are set to 1/9, 2/9, …, up to 8/9
institutions at the provincial level. The NERI Index project was sponsored by the National consistent with the Proc Rank procedure under SAS.
31
Economic Research Institute and the China Reform Foundation and conducted by Fan, Note that in Table 4, we use median-based ranks to define low–low/high–high groups;
Wang, and Zhu (2004). in Table 5, we used decile-based ranks to define LL/HH groups.
28 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

Table 5
Audit quality pre versus post-MPR: conditioning on AMC/legal environment.

D.V. = DA Pred. Sign Low–Low High–High Full Sample

Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat)

POST +/− −0.027*** (−2.74) 0.003 (0.32) 0.000 (0.03)


POST ∗ LHERF +/− −0.022* (−1.80)
POST∗ LLEGAL − −0.014** (−2.31)
POST∗ LHERF∗ LLEGAL +/− −0.011*** (−2.60)
LLEGAL + 0.016** (2.37)
LHERF + 0.021*** (2.91)
LHERF∗ LLEGAL + 0.019*** (2.51)
IBIG4 − −0.051** (−2.16) −0.037** (−2.34) −0.018* (−1.86)
CBIG10 − −0.019 (−1.41) 0.002 (0.26) −0.002 (−0.41)
FT − 0.003 (0.54) −0.008 (−1.47) 0.000 (−0.05)
SIZE + 0.021*** (3.06) 0.018*** (3.82) 0.015*** (6.40)
CFO − −0.623*** (−8.96) −0.810*** (−17.34) −0.665*** (−22.80)
GROW + −0.086* (−1.83) 0.041* (1.74) 0.001 (0.03)
AGE − 0.002 (1.36) 0.002* (1.72) 0.001* (1.67)
SOE +/− 0.021* (1.90) 0.003 (0.36) 0.009** (2.13)
LEV ? −0.127*** (−4.45) −0.087*** (−3.44) −0.084*** (−6.49)
TTYPE ? 0.034** (2.45) 0.028 (1.52) 0.012* (1.80)
EXP − 0.266 (0.72) 0.192 (1.13) −0.018 (−0.23)
CLIENTP + 0.035 (0.33) 0.042 (0.53) 0.053 (1.31)
Constant ? −0.303* (−1.79) −0.451*** (−4.08) −0.292*** (−5.08)
Obs. no. 232 211 876
Adj. R2 (%) 47.68 79.2 56.32
Chi-Square
POST + POST∗ LHERF + POST∗ LLEGAL + POST∗ LHERF∗ LLEGAL −0.047*** 7.69
LHERF + LLEGAL + LHERF∗ LLEGAL 0.056* 2.85
POST + POST∗ LHERF + POST∗ LLEGAL + POST∗ LHERF∗ LLEGAL 0.009** 3.58
+LHERF + LLEGAL + LHERF∗ LLEGAL

See Appendix 2 for variable definitions. Low–Low and High–High regressions are respectively for the two subsamples with both audit market concentration (HERF) and legal environment
index (LEGAL) levels below or above their median values. Variable LHERF is reversely ranked HERF deciles scaled between zero and one, with zero as the highest decile and one as the
lowest decile HERF values. Similarly, LLEGAL is reversely ranked LEGAL values scaled between zero and one, with zero as the highest decile and one as the lowest decile LEGAL values.
All regressions control for industry and year fixed effects. *, **, *** significant respectively at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels with two-tailed tests.

coefficients are negative and significant, these results are consistent with Moreover, Table 5 also shows that the audit quality in HH
smaller income-increasing discretionary accruals (or improved accrual provinces is superior to that in LL provinces, both before and after
quality) for the LL provinces after MPR. The sum of these coefficients is MPR is introduced. Specifically, the sum of the coefficients of
− 0.047 and significantly different from zero (Chi-Square = 7.69, LLEGAL + LHERF + LHERF ∗ LLEGAL reflects the difference in the
p b 0.001). The difference in (pre- versus post-MPR) audit quality audit quality (DA) of LL provinces relative to that of the HH prov-
in HH provinces is reflected by the coefficient on the POST variable, inces in Year 5 (the last year prior to MPR), after controlling for co-
which is insignificantly different from zero, indicating no change in variates. All these coefficients are positive and significant,
the audit quality of these provinces in the post-MPR period, after and their sum is 0.056 and significantly different from zero (Chi-
controlling for covariates. Square = 2.85, p b 0.10). This indicates that LL provinces exhibit lower

Table 6
Audit quality pre versus post-MPR: sensitivity tests.

Low–Low High–High

Coef. (t-stat) Coef. (t-stat)

Alternative audit quality measure


D.V. = DWCA −0.060* (−1.84) −0.273 (−0.90)
Obs. no. 230 203

Alternative sample
Add Years 3 and 4 data −0.025*** (−2.92) 0.009 (1.12)
Obs. No. 387 309
Remove Years 7 and 8 audit partner change obs. −0.029*** (−2.96) 0.002 (0.30)
Obs. no. 205 176

Alternative Herfindahl indices


Client sales revenue by province–year −0.016* (−1.72) −0.002 (−0.22)
Obs. no. 202 193
Audit fees within Big 4 international accounting firms by province–year −0.020** (−2.40) 0.005 (0.44)
Obs. no. 213 195
Audit fees within Big 10 domestic accounting firms by province–year −0.036*** (−4.30) 0.002 (0.25)
Obs. no. 211 179

See Appendix 2 for variable definitions. Low–Low and High–High regressions are respectively for the two subsamples with both audit market concentration (HERF) and legal environment
index (LEGAL) levels below or above their median values. To save space, Table 6 summarizes the coefficients of only POST variables in alternative sensitivity check regressions. All regres-
sions control for industry and year fixed effects. *, **, *** significant respectively at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels with two-tailed tests.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 29

audit quality (greater income-increasing DA values) relative to HH prov- 6. Conclusions


inces in Year 5. In the post-MPR period, the difference in audit quality
between LL versus HH provinces, after controlling for covariates, Our research examines audit quality in China in the years immedi-
is the sum of coefficients of LLEGAL + LHERF + POST ∗ LHERF + ately following mandatory audit partner rotations. Using a sample of
POST ∗ LLEGAL + LLEGAL ∗ LHERF + POST ∗ LLEGAL ∗ LHERF. The sum 273 Chinese firms that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotations,
of these coefficients is 0.009 and significantly different from zero (Chi- we provide evidence of the consequences of mandatory audit partner
Square = 3.58, p b 0.001). This indicates that MPR helps narrow, but rotation on discretionary accruals, a proxy of earnings (audit) quality.
does not eliminate, the difference in audit quality between the LL and We find that while audit quality in the first post-rotation year (Year 6)
HH provinces. Note that while the difference in DA values between the is not significantly different from that in the final pre-rotation year
LL and HH provinces decreases from 0.056 in Year 5 to 0.009 after MPR, (Year 5), audit quality does improve significantly in the two subsequent
the audit quality of LL provinces is still lower. years (Years 7 and 8). This is a new result because prior research on
In summary, Table 5 results suggest that in the post-MPR period, audit partner rotation focuses on changes to audit quality only in the
audit quality improves the most for client firms in low AMC and low first year after mandatory rotation and largely finds no evidence of im-
legal development provinces. Firth et al. (2012a) document the effective- provement in audit quality. We extend the focus of our study to three
ness of MPR in low legal development provinces in China. In contrast, we years post-rotation, on the ground that new rotated-in audit partners
show that AMC and legal development both incrementally moderate the likely face a learning curve in a new audit engagement after taking
effect of MPR on audit quality. Our results imply that the positive effect of over clients from incumbent audit partners. We document an improve-
MPR on audit quality occurs to clients in legally less developed provinces ment in audit quality following mandatory audit partner rotation, par-
that have low AMC, where audit quality is low to begin with. ticularly in Years 7 and 8.
We condition our tests on two factors that exhibit significant varia-
tion across different Chinese provinces. We find that audit quality in
5.4. Sensitivity analyses the post-rotation period improves in provinces that exhibit not only
low audit concentration (high audit competition) but also low levels
We check the robustness of our results with an alternative earnings of legal development. In contrast, mandatory audit partner rotation
quality measure used by Carey and Simnett (2006), namely, discretionary does not have any significant effect on clients located in provinces that
working capital accruals (DWCA). The value of DWAC in year t equals cur- exhibit high audit market concentration levels and high legal develop-
rent realized working capital (WCt) minus the expected level of working ment levels, where audit quality is higher even in the pre-rotation peri-
capital needed to support the current level of sales (WCt − 1/St − 1) ∗ St). od. Mandatory audit partner rotation helps narrow the difference in
We estimate Eq. (3) after replacing the dependent variable DA with audit quality of low concentration/low legal development provinces
DWAC. As Table 6 summarizes, the POST variable is significantly nega- versus high concentration/high legal development provinces, but it
tive (coefficient = − 0.060, t-stat = − 1.84) for the low–low prov- does not eliminate the difference completely.
inces, but insignificant for the high–high provinces grouped by the Our results are robust to our alternative audit quality measure and
median values of AMC and legal development. Therefore, our results alternative samples. The overall positive audit quality effect of mandato-
hold when we use DWAC as a measure for audit quality. ry audit partner rotation in the less legally developed provinces with
In the foregoing tables, we compare the pre-MPR Year 5 earnings' low levels of audit market concentration suggests that the rule is likely
quality with post-MPR Years 6, 7, and 8. In our sensitivity analysis, we to enhance audit quality in jurisdictions that have low audit quality to
compare the pre-MPR Years 3, 4, and 5 to post-MPR Years 6, 7, and 8 begin with and thus need it the most. Our results also indicate that the
with symmetric three-year periods both before and after MPR. This effects of MPR on audit quality cannot be generalized and must be eval-
approach addresses potential unknown bias in the last pre-MPR year uated on a case-by-case basis in different audit markets.
precisely because it is the last year for the audit partner who is
rotated off.31 Table 6 shows that our results continue to hold with a Appendix 1. Categorization of mandatory partner rotation
significantly negative coefficient on POST at less than 1% level
(coefficient = −0.025, t-stat = −2.92).
As we mentioned before, some client firms in our sample change audit
Mandatory audit partner rotation year
partners in Years 7 or 8. In our sensitivity checks, we eliminate these Years
7 and 8 observations that are associated with audit partner changes. The 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
two post-MPR years' partner rotations could be mandatory (the second 1999 A (Year 1)
audit partner also finishes five-year tenure after Year 6; 47 observations) 2000 A (Year 2) A (Year 1)
or voluntary (before finishing the five-year tenure; 71 observations). Our 2001 A (Year 3) A (Year 2) A (Year 1)
2002 A (Year 4) A (Year 3) A (Year 2) A (Year 1)
results do not change after removing these 118 observations. Table 6 2003 A (Year 5) A (Year 4) A (Year 3) A (Year 2) A (Year 1)
shows that the coefficient of the POST variable is significantly negative, 2004 B (Year 6) A (Year 5) A (Year 4) A (Year 3) A (Year 2) A (Year 1)
with p b 0.01 (coefficient = −0.029, t-stat = −2.96) for the low–low 2005 B (Year 7) B (Year 6) A (Year 5) A (Year 4) A (Year 3) A (Year 2)
provinces, but insignificant for the high–high provinces. 2006 Year 8 Year 7 B (Year 6) A (Year 5) A (Year 4) A (Year 3)
2007 Year 8 Year 7 B (Year 6) A (Year 5) A (Year 4)
Table 6 also reports the regression results using alternative AMC
2008 Year 8 Year 7 B (Year 6) A (Year 5)
Herfindahl indices. Our results hold for all three alternative 2009 Year 8 Year 7 B (Year 6)
Herfindahl index measures at the province–year level calculated 2010 Year 8 Year 7
by (1) client companies' sales revenues for all audit firms, 2011 Year 8
(2) audit fees within Big 4 international audit firms, and (3) audit
fees within the top 10 Chinese audit firms. 32 The coefficients of
POST are all significantly negative for the low–low provinces but Appendix 1 describes the method to classify an audit partner change
not the high–high. as mandatory audit partner rotation. For example, if an audit partner “A”
had audited a client in the past five consecutive years from 1999 to
31
We thank our anonymous reviewer for this suggestion. 2003, and was replaced by audit partner “B” in the sixth year (2004),
32
We also do a robustness check using the Herfindahl index computed by client compa-
nies' assets. The results (un-tabulated) hold. We derive these alternative AMC measures
we categorize this audit partner change as mandatory audit partner ro-
based on prior research, such as Wolk, Michelson, and Wootton (2001) and Francis et al. tation. The first MPR year is 2004; the last MPR year is 2009. Our post-
(2013). MPR period includes Year 6, Year 7, and Year 8.
30 S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31

Appendix 2. Variable definitions

Variable Definitions

DA Discretionary accruals derived from modified Jones model (Dechow et al., 1995) matched by performance (Kothari et al., 2005), estimated with the entire CCER
TotalAccrualst =Assetst−1 ¼ α0 þ α1 ð1=Assetst−1 Þ þ β1 ðΔSt −ΔARt Þ=Assetst−1
database sample from the corresponding industry–year regression:
þβ2 ðPPEt−1 =Assetst−1 Þ þ β3 ROAt−1 þ εt
where Total Accruals equals net income before extraordinary items minus operating cash flows. DA equals the deviation of total accruals from the model predicted
values. The industry category follows the 13-industry codes announced by CSRC. Each industry–year regression requires a minimum of 15 observations.
DWCA Discretionary working capital accruals. It equals current realized working capital (WCt) minus the expected level of working capital needed to support the current
level of sales (WCt − 1/St − 1)*St.
Y6; Y7; Y8 Y6 is an indicator variable that equals one for the first post-mandatory rotation year (Year 6) and zero otherwise; Y7 equals one for Year 7 and zero otherwise; Y8
equals one for Year 8 and zero otherwise.
POST Post-mandatory rotation period indicator variable; equals one for the first three years subsequent to the mandatory rotation (Years 6, 7, and 8), and zero otherwise.
HERF Audit market concentration measured by Herfindahl index of audit firms' audit fee income at the province level. It equals the sum of squared audit fee shares of all
audit firms in a province.
LHERF Reversed decile rank in the provincial Herfindahl index (HERF). We scale the reversed rank between zero and one. LHERF equals one for provincial Herfindhal indices
that are included in the lowest decile of observations; zero for the highest decile rank.
LEGAL Legal environment index at the province level, from Table A1 of Wang et al. (2008).
LLEGAL Reversed decile rank in the provincial legal environment index (LEGAL). We scale the reversed rank between zero and one. LLEGAL equals one for provincial legal
environment indices that are included in the lowest decile of observations; zero for the highest decile rank.
SOE An indicator variable that equals one if a company is a state-owned enterprise and 0 otherwise.
IBIG4 An indicator variable of big audit firms that equals one for big 4 international audit firms and zero otherwise.
CBIG10 An indicator variable of big audit firms that equals one for top 10 Chinese audit firms and zero otherwise.
SIZE Client company size variable, which equals the natural log of total assets.
CFO Client cash flows from operation (scaled by lagged assets).
GROW The growth in sales, measured as the industry total sales of the auditor rotation year t scaled by the industry total sales of year t − 1.
FT Audit firm tenure counting from 2004, the first year that the audit firm data became available in CCER database.
AGE No. of years since a client company was first listed in Chinese stock exchanges.
TTYPE And indicator variable that equals one if a client company was listed as ST/*ST company by the Chinese Stock Regulatory Committee in the period of Year 1 to Year 6,
and zero otherwise.
LEV Leverage ratio that equals total liability scaled by total assets.
EXP Two incumbent audit partners' experience in auditing clients in the same industry as their current client, measured as the sum of each audit partner's percentage of
their audited same-industry assets out of the total industry assets. The industry category follows the 13-industry codes announced by China Securities Regulatory
Commission (CSRC).
CLIENTP Client power measured as the percentage of a client's total assets out of an audit firm's total audited assets.

References accounts and consolidated accounts and a proposal for a regulation of the European
Parliament and of the Council on specific requirements regarding statutory audit of
Aharony, J., Lee, C. J., & Wong, T. J. (2000). Financial packaging of IPO firms in China. public-interest entities. Commission Staff Working Paper. Impact assessment accompa-
Journal of Accounting Research, 38(1), 103–126. nying the document. Brussels, 30.11.2011.
Arel, B., Brody, R., & Pany, K. (2005). Audit firm rotation and audit quality. CPA Journal, Davis, L., Soo, B., & Trompeter, G. (2009). Auditor tenure and the ability to meet or beat
36–39 (January). earnings forecasts. Contemporary Accounting Research, 26(2), 517–548.
Balsam, S., Krishnan, J., & Yang, J. S. (2003). Auditor industry specialization and earnings DeAngelo, L. (1981). Auditor size and audit quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics,
quality. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 22(2), 71–97. 3(3), 183–199.
Belsley, D. A., Kuh, E., & Welsch, R. E. (1980). Regression diagnostics: Identifying influential Dechow, P.M., Sloan, R. G., & Sweeney, A. P. (1995). Detecting earnings management. The
data and sources of collinearity. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Accounting Review, 70(2), 193–225.
Carcello, J. V., & Nagy, A. L. (2004). Audit firm tenure and fraudulent financial reporting. DeFond, M. L., Raghunandan, K., & Subramanyam, K. R. (2002). Do nonaudit service fees
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 23(2), 55–69. impair auditor independence? Evidence from going-concern audit opinions. Journal
Carey, P., & Simnett, R. (2006). Audit partner tenure and audit quality. The Accounting of Accounting Research, 40(4), 1247–1274.
Review, 81(3), 653–676. Deis, D. R., & Giroux, G. A. (1992). Determinants of audit quality in the public sector. The
Chan, K. H., & Wu, D. (2011). Aggregate quasi rents and auditor independence: Evidence Accounting Review, 67(3), 462–479.
from audit firm mergers in China. Contemporary Accounting Research, 28(1), 175–213. Dopuch, N., King, R. R., & Schwartz, R. (2001). An experimental investigation of re-
Chaney, P., Jeter, D., & Shaw, P. (2003). The impact on the market for audit services of aggres- tention and rotation requirements. Journal of Accounting Research, 39(1),
sive competition by auditors. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 22(6), 487–516. 93–117.
Chen, H., Chen, J. Z., Lobo, G. J., & Wang, Y. (2011). Effects of audit quality on earnings Fan, G., Wang, X., & Zhu, H. (2004). The report on the relative process of marketization of
management and cost of equity capital: Evidence from China. Contemporary each region in China. The Economic Science Press, Beijing, Chapter 1 (in Chinese).
Accounting Research, 28(3), 892–925. Firth, M., Rui, O. M., & Wu, X. (2012a). How do various forms of auditor rotation affect
Chen, C., Lin, C., & Lin, Y. (2008). Audit partner tenure, audit firm tenure, and discretionary audit quality? Evidence from China. The International Journal of Accounting, 47,
accruals: Does long auditor tenure impair earnings quality? Contemporary Accounting 109–138.
Research, 25(2), 415–445. Firth, M., Rui, O. M., & Wu, X. (2012b). Rotate back or not after mandatory audit partner
Chen, S., Sun, S. Y. J., & Wu, D. (2010). Client importance, institutional improvements, and rotation? Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 31(4), 356–373.
audit quality in China: An office and individual auditor level analysis. The Accounting Francis, J. R., Michas, P. N., & Seavey, S. E. (2013). Does audit market concentration harm
Review, 85(1), 127-15. the quality of audited earnings? Evidence from Audit Markets in 42 Countries.
Chen, K. C. W., & Yuan, H. (2004). Earnings management and capital resource allocation: Contemporary Accounting Research, 30(1), 325–355.
Evidence from China's accounting-based regulation of rights issues. The Accounting GAO (2003). Public accounting firms: Required study on the potential effects of mandato-
Review, 74(3), 645–665. ry audit firm rotation. United States General Accounting Office. Report to the Senate
Chi, W., & Huang, H. (2005). Discretionary accruals, audit–firm tenure and auditor tenure: Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs and the House Committee on Finan-
An empirical case in Taiwan. Journal of Contemporary Accounting & Economics, 1(1), cial Services: November 2003.
65–92. GAO (2004). Mandatory audit firm rotation study: Study questionnaires, responses and
Chi, W., Huang, H., Liao, Y., & Hong, X. (2009). Mandatory audit partner rotation, audit summary of respondents' comments. United States General Accounting Office. Report
quality, and market perception: Evidence from Taiwan. Contemporary Accounting to the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs and the House Commit-
Research, 26(2), 359–391. tee on Financial Services: February 2004.
Chinese Institute of Certified Public Accountants (CICPA) (2007). The No.15 bulletin on Geiger, M., & Raghunandan, K. (2002). Auditor tenure and auditor reporting failures.
2007 annual financial reports auditing updates. (www.cicpa.org.cn (in Chinese)) Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 21(1), 67–78.
Chinese Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC Regulation), & China Ministry of Finance Ghosh, A., & Moon, D. (2005). Auditor tenure and perceptions of audit quality. The
(MOF) (2003). The regulation regarding the mandatory rotation of auditors issuing Accounting Review, 80(2), 585–612.
auditing reports for companies issuing and trading stocks and options No.13. (in Chinese). Gul, F. A., Fung, S. Y. K., & Jaggi, B. (2009). Earnings quality: Some evidence on the role of
European Commission (EU) (2011). Proposal for a directive of the European Parliament auditor tenure and auditors' industry expertise. Journal of Accounting and Economics,
and the Council amending directive 2006/43/EC on statutory audits of annual 47(3), 265–287.
S.P. Bandyopadhyay et al. / Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting 30 (2014) 18–31 31

Gul, F., Jaggi, B., & Krishnan, G. V. (2007). Auditor independence: Evidence on the joint ef- Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) (2011c). Comments by Center for
fects of auditor tenure and non-audit fees. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, Audit Quality. (http://pcaobus.org/Rules/Rulemaking/Docket037/519_CAQ.pdf De-
26(2), 117–142. cember 14, 2011. PCAOB 2011.)
Hamilton, J. M., Ruddock, C. M. S., Stokes, D. J., & Taylor, S. L. (2005). Audit partner rota- Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) (2012). Statement of Hon. Richard
tion, earnings quality and earnings conservatism. Working Paper. La Trobe University, C. Breeden, Former Chairman, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission and Chairman,
University of New South Wales, Monash University. Breeden Capital Management, to the Public Company Oversight Board regarding auditor
Healey, T., & Kim, Y. (2003). The benefits of mandatory auditor rotation. Regulation, 26(3), independence and audit firm rotation. (http://pcaobus.org/Rules/Rulemaking/
10–11. Docket037/ps_Breeden.pdf. March 21, 2012. PCAOB 2012.)
Hribar, P., & Nichols, D. R. (2007). The use of unsigned earnings quality measures in tests Raghunathan, B., Lewis, B.L., & Evans, J. H., III (1994). An empirical investigation of prob-
of earnings management. Journal of Accounting Research, 45(5), 1017–1053. lem audits. Research in Accounting Regulation, 8, 33–58.
Johnson, V., Khurana, I., & Reynolds, J. (2002). Audit–firm tenure and the quality of finan- Rapoport, M. (2013, Dec 04). PCAOB proposes rule to identify partners in charge of audits;
cial reports. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19(4), 637–660. audit regulator proposes accounting firms identify partner in charge of each client's
Johnson, W. B., & Lys, T. (1990). The market for audit services: Evidence from voluntary audit. Wall Street Journal (Online). (Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com.
auditor changes. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 12(1–3), 281–309. proxy.lib.uwaterloo.ca/docview/1464719554?accountid=14906)
Kallapur, S., Sandaraguruswamy, S., & Zang, Y. (2010). Audit market concentration and Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002 (2002). An Act to protect investors by improving the accura-
audit quality. Working paper. Indian School of Business, National University of cy and reliability of corporate disclosures made pursuant to the securities laws and
Singapore, and Singapore Management University. for other purposes. Public Law (July 30, 2002. 107th. Congress.).
Kinney, W., & McDaniel, L. (1996). How to improve the effectiveness of substantive ana- Schwartz, K. B., & Menon, K. (1985). Auditor switches by failing firms. The Accounting
lytical procedures. CPA Journal, 66(4), 52–54. Review, 60(2), 248–262.
Knapp, M. (1991). Factors that audit committees use as surrogates for audit quality. Stanley, J., & DeZoort, T. (2007). Audit firm tenure and financial restatements: An analysis
Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 10(1), 35–52. of industry specialization and fee effects. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 26(2),
Kothari, S. P., Leone, A. J., & Wasley, C. E. (2005). Performance matched discretionary ac- 131–159.
crual measures. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(1), 163–197. Tan, H. -T. (1995). Effects of expectations, prior involvement, and review awareness on
Krishnan, G. V. (2003). Does big 6 auditor industry expertise constrain earnings manage- memory for audit evidence and judgment. Journal of Accounting Research, 33(1),
ment? Accounting Horizons, 17, 1–16. 113–135.
Lin, K. Z., & Chan, K. H. (2000). Auditing standards in China: A comparative analysis Ting, W., Yen, S., & Huang, S. (2009). Top management compensation, earnings manage-
with relevant international standards and guidelines. The International Journal of ment and default risk: Insights from the Chinese stock market (2009). The
Accounting, 35(4), 559–577. International Journal of Business and Finance Research, 3(1), 31–46.
Mansi, S. A., Maxwell, W. F., & Miller, D. P. (2004). Does auditor quality and tenure matter to Wang, Q., Wong, T. J., & Xia, L. (2008). State ownership, the institutional environment, and
investors? Evidence from the bond market. Journal of Accounting Research, 42(4), 755–793. auditor choice: Evidence from China. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 46(1),
Mautz, R. K., & Sharaf, H. A. (1961). The philosophy of auditing. Monograph, 6. Sarasota, FL: 112–134.
American Accounting Association. Watts, R., & Zimmerman, J. (1981). The markets for independence and independent
Myers, J. N., Myers, L. A., & Omer, T. C. (2003). Exploring the term of the auditor–client re- auditors. Graduate School of Management, University of Rochester unpublished
lationship and the quality of earnings: A case for mandatory auditor rotation? The manuscript (Series No. GPB 80-10.).
Accounting Review, 78(3), 779–799. Wolk, C. M., Michelson, S. E., & Wootton, C. W. (2001). Auditor concentration and market
Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) (2011a). Concept release on auditor shares in the US: 1988–1999. A descriptive note. The British Accounting Review, 33(2),
independence and audit firm rotation: Notice of roundtable. PCAOB release No. 2011–006 157–174.
August 16, 2011. PCAOB rulemaking docket No. 37. PCAOB 2011. Xiao, J. Z., Zhang, Y., & Xie, Z. (2000). The making of independent auditing standards in
Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB) (2011b). Comments by Internation- China. Accounting Horizons, 14(1), 69–89.
al Federation of Accountants (IFAC). (http://pcaobus.org/Rules/Rulemaking/ Yu, Q., Du, B., & Sun, Q. (2006). Earnings management at rights issues thresholds—
Docket037/367_IFAC.pdf December 14, 2011. PCAOB 2011.) Evidence from China. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30, 3453–3468.

You might also like