You are on page 1of 16

World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

Remittances, finance and growth: Does financial development foster


the impact of remittances on economic growth?
Izabela Sobiech
Sao Paulo School of Economics – FGV, Rua Itapeva 474, 01332-000 Sao Paulo, SP, Brazil

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: There is no consensus in the literature regarding the long-run impact of remittances on economic growth.
Accepted 25 August 2018 Previous studies have shown that it might be related to financial development in the transfer-receiving
country, but the direction of the link remained unclear. I contribute to this literature by using a newly
created index of overall financial development and two different estimation methods. I measure the
Jel classification: importance of remittances given financial development for economic growth in developing countries.
F24 As there is no widely accepted measure of financial sector development, I estimate an index of overall
O11
financial conditions. It is created by means of an unobserved components model and used to determine
O15
O16
the relevance of the financial sector as a transmission channel for remittances to affect economic growth.
I show that the more financially developed a country is, the smaller the impact of remittances on eco-
Keywords: nomic growth. Remittances can foster growth, but the effect is significant only at low levels of financial
Remittances development. This is in line with previous studies, which found remittances and financial development to
Economic growth be substitutes. However, the interaction between the two factors becomes weaker once size, depth and
Financial development efficiency of the financial sector are taken into account. My results suggest that, while attracting
Unobserved components model
migrants’ transfers can have important short-run poverty-alleviating advantages, in the long-run it might
Dynamic panel data analysis
be more beneficial for governments to foster financial sector development.
Ó 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction Development in Addis Ababa in July 2015.2 The importance of


remittances in supporting families in developing countries was rec-
Remittances are migrants’ transfers in money and kind sent to ognized and a well-functioning financial sector was considered nec-
their home countries.1 In the last 15 years these flows have been essary to boost migrants’ transfers through lower costs and better
increasing rapidly, exceeding official development assistance service availability.
(ODA), and more steadily than foreign direct investment flows Existing academic studies on short-run and long-run economic
(FDI) (cf. Fig. 1). Economists have become interested in these inter- effects of remittances have ambiguous conclusions. Rapoport and
national money flows, since they can be an important source of Docquier (2006) provide an extensive review of the literature
development financing. and the studies more closely related to this one are summarized
Migrants’ transfers were recently debated in the context of the in Section 2.
post-2015 Sustainable Development Agenda of the United Nations In this paper I consider a sample of 61 emerging and developing
Development Programme (UNDP, Agenda adopted in September countries over the time period 1970–2010. I evaluate the impact of
2015). There are 17 newly proposed Sustainable Development remittances on economic growth, taking into account financial sec-
Goals (SDG) and their achievement relies on public as well as pri- tor development measured with a newly constructed index. There
vate financing from industrial countries. Remittances have been are several challenges associated with answering this question. They
recognized as one of the potential sources of funding for the SDG are related in particular to capturing financial sector development in
during the UN Third International Conference on Financing for a comprehensive way, considering its size, depth and efficiency at
the same time. For many developing countries data on financial

2
Resolution adopted by the General Assembly on 27 July 2015, Sixty-ninth session,
E-mail address: izabela.sobiech@fgv.br Agenda item 18, available at http://www.un.org/esa/ffd/wp-content/uploads/2015/
1
In this paper I focus on remittances in money, transfers in kind are not included in 08/AAAA_Outcome.pdf, accessed on May 25, 2016.
international statistics.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.08.016
0305-750X/Ó 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 45

800 countries with very high efficiency but low size proxies is also
adjusted downwards. The first case accounts for loans which were
not given out for the most productive use, and the second case
accounts for the fact that even if procedures related to obtaining
600

a loan are simple, applicants may not be able to receive financial


Billions USD

support due to the lack of resources.


400

The main purpose of this paper is therefore to verify whether


size or efficiency matter more, or in other words – which of the
effects dominates? Does the ‘‘overall financial development”
200

strengthen the effect of remittances on economic growth in


transfer-receiving developing countries (positive coefficient on
the remittance-finance interaction term)? Or is it a substitute for
0

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015


year remittances, removing credit constraints, providing financial
resources for productive activities and allowing transfer recipients
FDI ODA
Remittances Pvt.debt&port.equity to spend remittances in a different, non-growth-enhancing way
(negative sign of the remittance-finance interaction term and
diminishing or even negative impact of transfer inflows on GDP
Fig. 1. Foreign financial flows to developing countries – Remittances, official aid
per capita growth)?
and private flows. Source: World Bank Migration and Development Brief from April
13, 2015. Notes: Remittances to developing countries exceeded 400 billion USD in Another issue pertaining to this research question, and to
2012 and are estimated to reach almost 480 billion by 2017. Up to 75% of all growth regressions in general, is the potential endogeneity of
remittance flows go to these countries, with only a slight majority coming from the financial development and remittance measures (and other poten-
‘‘North” (industrial countries). While still half as large as foreign direct investment, tial determinants of long-run economic growth). In this paper I rely
remittances prove to be more resilient to changing global economic conditions.
on the assumption of weak exogeneity of the variables of interest. I
Private debt and portfolio flows on average reach similar levels as migrants’
transfers but are also more volatile. Official development flows are even more stable account for it by lagging the regressors by one year with respect to
than remittance inflows, but they have a much lower rate of increase. the dependent variable when forming 5-year averages. Then I use
two estimation methods, consistent under this assumption. The
indicators3 are generally available only for short time periods or with quasi-maximum likelihood for dynamic panel data with fixed
gaps. There is also no consensus as for an adequate measure of finan- effects (QML-FE) is the first method. I discuss the results of it in
cial development – in a related study Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2009) more detail, as the preferred ones, given that system GMM, the
used four different proxies: deposit to GDP ratio, loan to GDP ratio, other method used, may suffer from weak instrument problems
credit to GDP ratio and M2 to GDP ratio to provide some insights about described by Roodman (2009) and Bazzi and Clemens (2013).
different aspects of financial sector development. All of them refer GMM methods are more popular in the literature and can also be
only to the size of the financial sector, for which reason Bettin and seen as a robustness check if my explanatory variables do not fulfill
Zazzaro (2012) also used a measure of bank inefficiency, but due to the exogeneity requirement. Moreover, to remove most common
data availability their sample is limited to the time period from sources of cross-sectional dependence, year fixed effects are
1991 to 2005, which may not be enough to pick up long-run trends. included in all regressions.
For these reasons it is worthwhile to create a measure of finan- The results of this paper show that the impact of remittances on
cial development which would capture more aspects of the finan- economic growth indeed depends on the level of financial develop-
cial sector at the same time. It would help to evaluate the impact of ment. For countries with the least advanced financial sector there
remittances on growth and the role of the financial intermediaries is evidence for positive partial correlation between remittances
in this process. In this paper I tackle this problem by using an and growth, but the effect turns negative with increasing financial
unobserved components model in which a financial development development and migrants’ transfers become irrelevant. A country
indicator is extracted from available information stemming from could even experience long-run output losses if it achieved very
existing measures describing the size, depth and efficiency of the high levels of financial development and at the same time experi-
financial sector, combined into one number. enced an increase in remittance inflows. The results do not change
The measure proposed in this paper can provide information significantly when the years 2007–2010 (global financial crisis and
about the overall impact of financial sector development on the following economic slowdown in industrial countries) are
remittance-growth relationship. This can be of interest for policy excluded from the sample, preserving the negative sign of the
makers in transfer-receiving developing countries, since it provides remittance-finance interaction term in my growth regressions.
the answer to the following question: once the financial sector is The structure of the paper is as follows. After a brief literature
well developed (large and efficient), what is the impact of remit- review in Section 2, Section 3 gives a detailed description of the
tance inflows on economic growth? Growth regressions including data used for the creation of the index and for estimation, Section 4
such measures as financial deposits or credit to GDP ratio answer includes an overview of the methodology applied, both for the
this question only partially, because they do not capture efficiency index formation and for growth regressions. In Section 5 I present
of the financial sector. the results concerning the financial development index and in Sec-
By combining elements of size and efficiency of the financial tion 6 I show the results of the growth model for a cross-section of
sector, it takes into account the fact that availability of credit in countries over the time period 1970–2010. Section 7 shows that no
the economy is determined both by bank efficiency (bureaucracy strong structural shifts took place during the financial crisis so that
related to the application and decision process) and by availability the role of the financial sector as a substitute for remittances has
of financial resources. The proposed measure assigns lower values remained unchanged. Section 8 concludes.
of financial development to countries who have high deposits or
credit to GDP ratio but have inefficient banks and non-banking
institutions. Similarly, in the opposite situation, the score of 2. Related literature

There is a vast literature on the importance of remittances for


3
For example in the Financial Development and Structure Dataset. development and poverty alleviation. Given their large values,
46 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

reaching 30% of GDP, sometimes bigger than the value of FDI or Bettin and Zazzaro (2012) explain that the negative sign of the
ODA, many researchers have examined the impact of these trans- interaction term between remittances and financial development
fers on economic growth in receiving countries. Although no con- need not necessarily indicate that they are substitutes and can be
sensus has been reached until now, remittances are generally considered alternative sources of financing productive investment
believed to enhance economic growth through indirect channels for economic growth. They explain, following Rioja and Valev
(mainly through investment and human capital formation). Yet, (2004b) and Barajas et al., 2009, that this coefficient may capture
studies focusing on their direct impact on GDP per capita growth a nonlinear effect of the size of financial sector on output growth.
suggest a negative or at best an insignificant relationship This is in line with an alternative interpretation of the interaction
(Barajas, Chami, Fullenkamp, Gapen, & Montiel, 2009; Chami, term between remittances and financial sector development,
Fullenkamp, & Jahjah, 2005; Rao & Hassan, 2011). focusing on the marginal effect of the latter factor. In this case,
Rao and Hassan (2012) and Senbeta (2013) show that the direct the negative sign of the interaction term coefficient can mean that
effect of remittances on economic growth may be nil but these growing remittances increase bank deposits and available credit,
transfers can still affect GDP per capita through different channels: but loans are not necessarily given in an efficient way. Therefore,
investment, financial development, output volatility, total factor this remittance-driven rise in the financial sector size does not con-
productivity (TFP) and the real exchange rate. However, on aggre- tribute to economic growth.
gate the effects can cancel out. Senbeta (2013) argues additionally For this reason, Bettin and Zazzaro (2012) construct a measure
that the negligible remittance impact on TFP justifies the lack of of financial development related to its (in) efficiency rather than its
significance of migrants’ transfers4 on long-run economic growth. size and provide evidence for remittances and financial sector’s
More recently, Clemens and McKenzie (2014); Rao and Hassan efficiency to act as complements for economic prosperity. The effi-
(2011) have shown that the rapid increase in remittances recorded ciency of the financial sector in a given country is measured as the
after the year 2000 is due to changes in the definition of the transfers weighted average of the ratio of banks’ operating expenses to their
rather than actual increases in transfers. In this context, they do not net interest revenues and other income.6 Higher outcomes are
expect remittance measures based on Balance of Payments data to related to less efficient financial intermediation. Bettin and Zazzaro
show significant growth-enhancing effects. (2012) show that the combined effect of remittances on GDP per
Some studies have found positive causal links between remit- capita is lower the larger the size of the financial sector (substitutes)
tances and growth (Catrinescu, Leon-Ledesma, Piracha, & Quillin, but it is higher the more efficient the financial sector is
2009; Giuliano & Ruiz-Arranz, 2009; Mundaca, 2009; World (complements).
Bank, 2006). Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2009) show that remit- This paper extends upon the results of Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz
tances can significantly improve economic growth, if the financial (2009) and Bettin and Zazzaro (2012) by constructing a measure of
sector development is taken into account, hence showing that the overall financial development, based not only on measures of size
financial sector can be a channel through which remittances affect of the financial sector but also of its depth and efficiency. In this
growth. They also argue that migrants’ transfers and the financial way it addresses the critique of Rioja and Valev (2004b) and
sector can be substitutes – their growth model includes an interac- Barajas et al. (2009). I provide a robust analysis of the impact of
tion term between the two variables and this term has a negative the financial sector as a whole on the remittance-economic growth
coefficient. They interpret this result as follows. If the financial sec- relationship and confirm the results of Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz
tor is well-developed, credit constraints are removed and remit- (2009), that remittances and financial development can be seen
tances received from relatives from abroad need not be used in a as substitutes even if efficiency of the financial sector is accounted
productive way. However, in countries with poorly developed for. However, the relationship is weaker than found in the previous
financial markets remittances can be an important source of studies.
financing growth-enhancing activities.
The substitutability found by Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2009) 3. Data issues
is confirmed by Barajas et al. (2009). However, Nyamongo,
Misati, Kipyegon, and Ndirangu (2012) provide evidence of the 3.1. Remittance data
opposite relationship between remittances and financial develop-
ment in African countries. In this region, the two factors seem to Personal remittances are the sum of three elements: personal
be complements with continuing financial deepening strengthen- current and capital transfers between resident and nonresident
ing the positive impact of remittances on growth, rather than mit- households and compensation of employees, less taxes and social
igating it. As remittances can be deposited in banks, they bring a contributions.7 These data are readily available in shares of current
larger share of the population in contact with the financial sector, GDP values in the World Development Indicators data set of the
expanding the availability of credit and savings products World Bank. As it is also the most complete compilation, I use it in
(Aggarwal, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Pería, 2011; International Monetary this paper.
Fund, 2005). Mundaca (2009) provides a theoretical framework Given the definition of remittances in the Balance of Payments, it
supporting this hypothesis5 and shows that also in Latin American is crucial to emphasize what kinds of transfers are reflected in offi-
and Caribbean countries the impact of remittances on economic cial statistics, as this can potentially translate into the direction of
growth becomes stronger and positive if a measure of financial their impact on economic growth. Migrants transfer parts of their
development is included in the regression. However, the empirical income back home for two main reasons: altruistic and selfish –
analysis does not include any interaction term of migrants’ transfers the ‘‘portfolio motive” (see for example Schiopu & Siegfried
and financial development. (2006), Bouhga-Hagbe, 2004). The former is related to supporting
family members who stayed in the home country, mainly in times
4
In this paper I use the term migrants’ transfers interchangeably with remittances or of bad economic conditions (countercyclical behavior), while the
remittance inflows. Until 2009, migrants’ transfers constituted one item in the Balance latter is motivated by portfolio diversification reasons (procyclical).
of Payments, and together with compensation of employees added up to remittances.
According to International Monetary Fund (2009) the former was changed into
6
personal transfers and therefore I treat migrants’ transfers and remittances as synonyms The data covers 53,820 banks in 66 developing countries over the time period
(including also compensation of employees, given the data series available from the 1991–2005.
7
World Development Indicators (WDI) database – Personal remittances). For a technical definition of remittances and their computation see International
5
In her model, remittances are deposited in banks as ‘‘illiquid investment”. Monetary Fund (2009).
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 47

Official remittance data should only reflect the altruistic motive, as This leads to the conclusion that there is no composite measure
the second kind of transfers should be booked in the financial which would gauge the ability of the financial sector to transform
account (however it is not always possible to recover the purpose savings into investments and cover many countries over a long
of the transfer). time period. However, such an indicator can be obtained by com-
This implies that migrants’ transfers could possibly lower eco- bining information from various existing measures:11
nomic growth through real exchange rate appreciation and
resource reallocation from tradable goods to non-tradable goods 1. overall size of the financial system:
production – similar to the Dutch disease, cf. Acosta, Lartey, and  financial system deposits to GDP ratio (%) – demand, time
Mandelman (2009). Transfer recipients can also lower their labor and saving deposits in deposit money banks and other finan-
supply, offsetting multiplier effects associated with increased con- cial institutions as a share of GDP.
sumption.8 However, as these monies can be spent on investment in  liquid liabilities to GDP ratio (%) – defined as M3 to GDP
education or health care, or in starting a business, it may also gener- ratio. It is broader than M2, and therefore reflects better
ate long-run growth. This paper tries to evaluate which motive dom- the ability of an economy to channel funds from savers to
inates by quantifying growth effects of remittances. borrowers.12
2. financial institution depth – provision of credit to the
economy:
3.2. Data on financial development and the composition of the index  private credit by deposit money banks and other financial
institutions to GDP ratio (%) – all loans offered by commer-
The main purpose of the financial sector can be summarized as cial banks and other financial institutions.
follows:  domestic credit to the private sector to GDP ratio (%) – only
domestic loans to the private sector.
 ‘‘The role of the financial system is to transform liquid, short- 3. institutional efficiency – ability of the financial sector to pro-
term savings into relatively illiquid, long-term investments, vide high-quality products and services at the lowest cost:
thus promoting capital accumulation.” (World Bank, 2005, p.  interest rate spread – difference between the lending and
22) the deposit interest rate (reflects the value of loan-loss pro-
 ‘‘Financial markets have an important role in channeling invest- visions and the risk premium associated with loans to high-
ment capital to its highest value use.” (Huang, 2011) risk borrowers).
 deposit interest rate (%) – reflects the ability to attract
There are a few data sets providing information about various savings.
aspects of the financial sector. The largest one is World Bank’s ‘‘A  overhead costs to total assets (%) – total costs of financial
Database on Financial Development and Structure”, also distributed intermediation, including operating costs, taxes, loan-loss
in an updated version as ‘‘The Global Financial Development provisions, net profits.
Database” (see Cihak, Demirguc-Kunt, Feyen, & Levine, 2012). It
includes data for 203 countries, with the maximum time span of The measure created based on information from these three cate-
1960–2011. The second comprehensive database is the Dataset on gories is able to combine both size and efficiency aspects of the
Financial Reforms (Abiad, Detragiache, & Tressel, 2010). It covers financial sector. Therefore it passes the critique raised by Barajas
91 countries over the time period 1973–2005. It includes variables et al. (2009) and Bettin and Zazzaro (2012) that most studies only
measuring financial sector policies related, among others, to credit focus on measures of size of the financial sector, ignoring its effi-
or interest rate controls, entry barriers, state ownership of banks, ciency. If this measure of overall financial development is used,
prudential regulation and policies related to the securities market. concerns related to the interaction term between finance and
Apart from these, in the years 2008–2012 the World Economic remittances reflecting the inefficient increase of the financial sec-
Forum was publishing a ranking of overall financial development tor due growing migrants’ transfers are limited. As a measure of
for 62 advanced and emerging economies (World Economic ‘‘overall financial conditions”, this index also accounts for the fact
Forum, 2012, p. 12).9 To the best of my knowledge this was the first that higher availability of financial resources (through transfer
attempt to create a composite index of financial development.10 inflows) may not be enough for improvements of bank efficiency.
This means that I estimate the impact of remittances on economic
8
Chami et al. (2005) claim that the consumption motive dominates over the growth given size, depth and efficiency of the financial sector at the
investment motive and that the decrease in labor supply is related to moral hazard same time.
problems between the money sender and receiver. They analyze first-stage regression There is one important aspect that is not included in the con-
results of previous empirical studies. As remittances are significantly correlated with
GDP differentials but not with interest rate differentials between the home country
structed index. This measure captures the ability of the financial
and the US (2SLS instrumenting remittances with the two aforementioned variables), sector to transform liquid deposits into illiquid investments, but
the altruistic motive for sending money to the home country seems to be more it does not capture advantages in terms of risk sharing, allowing
relevant. for consumption and output smoothing. This is a feature of all
9
Some measures of financial development are now included in the Global
proxies of financial development commonly used in the
Competitiveness Report of the World Economic Forum.
10
In the meantime the IMF has also started working on a new broad financial
remittance-growth relationship literature. Remittances can serve
development index, which also captures many aspects of the financial sector at the to buffer economic fluctuations, therefore substituting for this role
same time (cf. Svirydzenka, 2016). This data set includes information about the depth, of the financial sector. However, in this paper I focus on growth
access and efficiency of financial institutions and financial markets in 183 countries effects, rather than on business cycle smoothing, related to second
from 1980 to 2015. All indices take values between 0 and 1, with the extremes
moments, which constitutes a different research question.
referring to the lowest and highest country observation of a given index over the
entire time period. This formulation enables us to make easy interpretations of
country rankings and distances from the leader, but there are also some challenges
11
related to it. Firstly, assigning the value 1 to the overall leader (Switzerland in 2007 in Classification and definitions of the variables come from World Bank (2005). The
the latest version of the data set) may give the false impression that this country in data sources are the World Bank’s ‘‘A Database on Financial Development and
that particular year achieved the maximum possible level of financial development, Structure” (updated in November 2013) and the WDI.
12
which is not necessarily true. Secondly, the ranking is not time invariant. If at some High M2 or M3 to GDP ratio can reflect lack of other, more profitable forms of
point a new leader appears, the index values for all countries in all years will have to value storage than cash, see Khan and Senhadji (2000). This measure is only included
be rescaled. if financial system deposits to GDP ratio is not available.
48 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

The financial development index and some of the other proxies financial sector indicator (in what follows also referred to as over-
listed above enter my growth regressions, together with remit- all financial development or overall financial conditions index)
tance inflows to GDP ratio, an interaction term between the two, from them. I only include a given country in the sample if data
and other determinants of long-run economic development. from at least two out of the three categories are available for at
least 20 time periods (not necessarily consecutive). The model is
3.3. Other determinants of economic growth formalized following Stock and Watson (1991):

zit ¼ a þ biFinDevit þ wit ð1Þ


Other variables included in the estimation are standard in the
growth literature and come from the World Development Indica- FinDevit ¼ cFinDevi;t1 þ v it ð2Þ
tors (version 2014) database of the World Bank: gross fixed capital
with
formation to GDP ratio, government expenditure to GDP ratio, pop-
ulation size and trade openness (sum of exports and imports to Eðwit Þ ¼ 0 8i; t ð3Þ
GDP ratio). Human capital is measured by the average years of sec- 
R if t ¼ s
ondary schooling attained by the population aged 25 and over Eðwit w0is Þ ¼ ð4Þ
(from the Barro & Lee (2013) database, updated in June 2014). It 0 otherwise
is important to include this variable in estimations related to the Eðv it Þ ¼ 0; Eðv 2it Þ ¼ 1 8i; t ð5Þ
effects of remittances, as these money flows might reflect the
impact of brain drain on growth. I discuss this in more detail in where zit is a ki  1 vector consisting of measures of financial devel-
Online Appendix A.1. opment from the three categories described in Section 3.2 (ki ¼ 3 if
all three measures are available for a country i at time t, otherwise
ki 2 f0; 1; 2g); FinDevit is a scalar representing the unobserved
3.4. Estimation sample
financial sector development measure for country i at time period
t and wit is the idiosyncratic error. i is a vector of ones with the
The estimation sample consists of emerging markets and devel-
same dimension as the data in zit (ki  1). t in this setup refers to
oping countries based on the classification used by the IMF in the
a 1-year time period (in the latter growth regressions it will stand
World Economic Outlook.13 The maximum time period is 1970–
for 5-year time averages). a is a ki  1 vector of constants, and b
2010, non-overlapping 5-year time averages for each country are
is a ki  ki matrix with off-diagonal elements equal to zero. Only
used in the estimations. This means that up to 8 observations are
elements (1,1), (2,2) and (3,3) are estimated and referred to as
available per country.
bð1Þ; bð2Þ and bð3Þ.
It is common in empirical growth studies to follow Mankiw,
Eq. (1) is referred to as the ‘‘measurement equation” (or obser-
Romer, and Weil (1992) and exclude small countries and oil-
vation equation). For each country it is a system of ki equations
producers from the estimation sample. The authors argue that
relating the unobserved overall financial conditions index to exist-
the former have low availability of primary data and potentially
ing proxies of financial development (from the available cate-
high measurement error in aggregate variables, while in the latter
gories).15 Eq. (2) is the ‘‘state equation”, describing the data
a large part of GDP comes from exploitation of existing natural
generating process which the created index is assumed to follow.
resources rather than from value added. Given that remittance to
Both groups of equations (referring to measured and unobserved
GDP ratios are particularly high in smaller countries, I do not
variables) are estimated jointly for all countries (parameters are
exclude them from the sample, hence not following Mankiw
not country-specific) by maximum likelihood (MLE) and the Kalman
et al. (1992). I also keep oil-producers. This should not affect the
filter.16 This specification is based on the assumption that existing
results to a large extent, as I identify only five countries as small
measures of financial development are determined by the overall
(with average population below 1 million): Barbados, Belize,
state of the financial development which is unobserved and that
Cyprus, Fiji, Malta and Swaziland, and only two as oil-producing:
the relationship is the same in all countries. The unobserved variable
Gabon and Iran, in the set of 61 developing countries. In principle,
is estimated jointly with the vector of unknown parameters:
potential differences in the structure of these economies should be
h ¼ fa; b; c; vechðRÞg.
captured by the individual effects.14
FinDevit combines information about the size (category 1),
For former communist countries (Central and Eastern European
depth (category 2) and inefficiency17 (category 3) of the financial
countries, as well as former USSR republics) only data from 1990
sector. Higher values of the unobserved variable should translate
onward are considered (allowing for a maximum of 4 observations
into greater values of the first two measures, for which reason bð1Þ
per country, from 1995 to 2010). The list of countries and years for
and bð2Þ are expected to be positive. At the same time they should
which data is provided in Online Appendix A.2.
be related to lower levels of inefficiency of the financial sector, trans-
lating into a negative value of bð3Þ.
4. Methodology The assumption that the measurement Eq. (1) has the same
parameters for all countries might seem strong. However, it just
4.1. Dynamic factor model – construction of the financial development means that I am using a universal definition of financial develop-
index ment – in all countries financial development is reflected in the
same way in measures of size, depth and efficiency. This simplifies
The variables described in Section 3.2 have been grouped into international comparisons and identification of the effects of
three categories in order to extract the overall, unobserved
15
As mentioned above, although ki 2 f0; 1; 2; 3g, I only include countries with at
13
I use the list of emerging markets and developing countries from International least two measures available. This means that in my case ki 2 f2; 3g.
16
Monetary Fund (2011) (Table E. p. 170). I extend this list by adding a few countries, The Kalman filter is the best linear unbiased predictor of unobserved states even
which have become richer more recently and are not included on the list: Cyprus, if the normality assumption on errors from Eqs. (1) and (2) does not hold. If it holds,
Czech Republic, Estonia, Israel, Malta, Slovak Republic, Slovenia. and the initial states are also normally distributed, the Kalman filter gives the best
14
Mankiw et al. (1992) did not use panel data techniques, for which reason they prediction among all possible functional forms, not only among the linear ones
were not able to account for potential structural differences between oil-producers (Harvey, 1989; Ho, Shumway, & Ombao, 2006).
17
and other countries. Individual effects included in my fixed effects regressions do Higher values of deposit interest rates, interest rate spreads or overhead costs are
capture these particularities under the assumption that they are time invariant. signs of inefficiency.
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 49

finance on growth. In principle there is no reason to assume that yit ¼ a þ cyi;t1 þ d1 Remit þ d2 FinDevit þ d3 Remit FinDevit
overall financial development affects its measures of size/depth/ef- þ bX it þ li þ gt þ it ð6Þ
ficiency in a different way in the United States than in Brazil, or in
any other country.
where the left-hand side variable is the 5-year average of real GDP
Eq. (2) implies that the overall financial development index fol-
per capita, Remit denotes the share of remittance inflows to GDP of
lows the same stochastic process in all countries. This is a simpli-
the transfer-receiving country, FinDevit is a measure of financial
fying assumption, allowing for differences in c across countries
development (estimations are repeated for four different measures)
could be an interesting robustness check. However it might be
and the vector X it includes all other regressors from Section 3.3. gt
challenging to estimate such models precisely due to the loss of
refers to common unobserved shocks and is approximated by time
degrees of freedom.
dummy variables (referring to each 5-year period). In this way,
The methodology builds on the idea of Stock and Watson (1991)
potential cross-sectional correlation is limited. To ensure that no
(‘‘Single-Index” Model, for one country), Kaufmann, Kraay, and
such dependence among countries prevails in the model I perform
Mastruzzi (2008) (extended to panel data) and Binder,
the test developed by Sarafidis, Yamagata, and Robertson
Georgiadis, and Sharma (2009).18 In contrast to the previous litera-
(2009).20 The error term it contains all other unobserved time-
ture, the data generating process of the unobserved component (the
varying sources of variation in GDP per capita.
financial sector development index) is assumed to be autoregressive
The dependent variable is expressed as the natural logarithm of
(with one relevant lag). In this way, I allow for persistence in the
GDP per capita in constant 2005 US dollars, others are expressed in
development of the index. It accounts for two special cases: a ran-
percentages as shares in the country’s GDP, apart from years of
dom walk and a process with no memory. The latter was the speci-
schooling (not transformed), population growth (percentage
fication chosen in previous studies. The Kalman filter accommodates
changes) and financial development measures. I apply a log-
AR(1) processes (cf. for example Hamilton (1995)).
modulus transformation to the data related to the financial sector
Another advantage of this methodology is the fact that it
which were used for the index construction.21 The reason for using
accounts for missing values. Countries for which not all observa-
this transformation rather than taking the natural logarithm is that it
tions for each time period are available can be included in the sam-
preserves negative values in the original data. These can occur in the
ple, as the estimation-maximization (EM) algorithm applied
third category of financial sector development measures (for exam-
estimates the value of the unobserved component consistently
ple for the interest rate spread, but cannot be excluded in the case of
even in the presence of missing values (Durbin & Koopman,
the deposit interest rate either). Following Mankiw et al. (1992), I
2001). This is important, because the efficiency measures have a
add 5 percentage points to the population growth, to account for
lower availability and with this procedure I am able to compute
the capital depreciation rate and for the average technology growth
the financial development index value even if this information is
rate. Table 1 shows summary statistics for the transformed data
missing, based on information from other countries (using the
(after obtaining 5-year time averages) and Online Appendix A.4
assumption about parameter equality across countries in Eqs. (1)
provides information about pairwise correlation between the
and (2)). In Online Appendix A.3. I show that the backward
regressors.
smoothing applied after estimation of the financial development
Given the dynamic structure of the model and a ‘‘short T, large
index helps eliminate sudden jumps in the index value if one of
N” specification of the panel data, one of the methods which I use is
the measured variables is missing.
system GMM (Arellano & Bover, 1995; Blundell & Bond, 1998).22
Instead of using the index I could include measures of all three
The advantage of this approach is that it allows for weakly exoge-
aspects of financial development (and their interaction terms with
nous regressors and takes account of the endogeneity of the lagged
remittance inflows to GDP ratio) in the growth regressions, but this
dependent variable at the same time. Moreover, it models initial
would lead to a drop in the sample size and increase of the number
observations for the sake of including the first time period. To
of parameters to be estimated. By combining information from
include as many observations for unbalanced panels as possible,
these three measures I increase the sample size and lower the
forward orthogonalization can be used instead of first differences.
number of parameters, which translates into efficiency gains.19
There are disadvantages too, though. This method has been criticized
Measures of size and depth of the financial sector are highly corre-
for low robustness against the instrument choice, in particular in
lated with one another, and by using one index instead of them I also
large models weak instruments may cause the estimates to be
limit this potential efficiency loss. More details on the estimation
biased.23
procedure are provided in Online Appendix A.3.
For these reasons, the second method which I use in this paper
is the quasi maximum likelihood estimator for fixed effects
4.2. Dynamic panel data models for growth regressions dynamic panel data developed by Hsiao, Pesaran, and
Tahmiscioglu (2002) (denoted as QML-FE24), and I treat coefficients
The estimation equation looks as follows:
20
A simple way to perform this test was proposed by De Hoyos and Sarafidis (2006)
18 and consists of computing the difference in Sargan’s statistics for overidentifying
Stock and Watson (1991) have used a single-index model to estimate the overall
state of the American economy, Kaufmann et al. (2008) have estimated various restrictions from two GMM regressions – one with the full set of instruments and one
dimensions of governance in 212 countries over 1996–2007, while Binder et al. without instruments with respect to the lagged dependent variable. A large
(2009) used this kind of model to obtain a financial development index and a discrepancy between the two values indicates presence of cross-sectional correlation.
institutions development index for 60 countries in 1970–2006, but only a small Results available upon request.
21
subset of them are developing countries. Given that developing countries are the ones The transformation, denoted as lm(x), takes the following form: lm(x) = sign(x) ⁄
studied in this paper, existing measures of financial development cannot be used, due ln(abs(x) + 1). It preserves the sign of the original data (values below zero get a
to their low time or spatial coverage. negative sign, values above get a positive sign). This transformation facilitates the use
19 of the Kalman filter as it changes the distribution of the data into one that is closer to
A regression of real GDP per capita on the control variables from Section 3.3 but
including financial deposits to GDP ratio, private credit by banks and other fin. a normal distribution (variables from the first and second category can only take
institutions to GDP ratio and deposit interest rate (efficiency measure with highest nonnegative values in their original form).
22
availability), remittances and the three interaction terms decreases the sample size I use the xtabond2 Stata command developed by Roodman (2009).
23
from 332 to 261 and leads to insignificant results related to all coefficients of interest. For comprehensive critique of GMM estimators refer to Roodman (2009) and
If the estimated index and its interaction term with remittance inflows are used Bazzi and Clemens (2013).
24
instead, the results are significant even for the smaller sample. Estimation tables not For this estimation method I use the xtdpdqml command for Stata by Kripfganz
shown. (2016).
50 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

Table 1
Summary statistics of 5-year averaged data (1970–2010).

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. N


Real GDP per capita (log) 7.46 1.12 5.14 10.07 393
Remittance inflows/GDP (%) 3.01 4.08 0 22.89 393
Overal financial development (findev) 1.12 5.38 16.38 16.11 393
Financial systems deposits/GDP 3.32 0.65 1.43 5.28 388
Liquid liabilities (M3)/GDP 3.57 0.61 1.6 5.32 387
Private credit by deposit money banks and other fin.inst./GDP 3.2 0.77 0.99 5.43 387
Domestic credit to the private sector/GDP 3.27 0.74 1.07 5.48 392
Interest rate spread 1.95 0.72 1.97 5.42 289
Deposit interest rate 2.28 0.77 0.84 7.99 331
Overhead costs 1.58 0.44 0.09 2.73 174
Investment/GDP (%) 21.09 5.8 4.99 47.68 393
Population growth (%) 7.08 1.09 0.5 11.6 393
Years of secondary education 1.36 0.97 0.05 4.89 393
Government expenditure/GDP (%) 14.26 5.15 4.08 38.68 393
Trade Openness (Exports + Imports)/GDP (%) 70.82 35.43 8.42 187.15 393

Notes: Population growth includes also the depreciation and technology growth rates (assumed to be 5% in total). Variables referring to the financial sector from ‘‘findev” to
‘‘Overhead costs” are after log-modulus transformation: lm(x) = sign(x) ⁄ ln(abs(x) + 1) – smoothing the data and preserving the original sign.

obtained by this method as the main results. This method also takes well as imputing information for countries with missing values.
account of initial conditions to correct for short-T bias but does not Problems, however, are related to the additional uncertainty added
rely on instrument use. to the model if an estimated variable is included instead of its
Following the economic growth literature, lagged values of the observed value.
dependent variable and of the regressors which are assumed to be The problem was first pointed out by Pagan (1984) and then by
weakly exogenous are used as ‘‘GMM style” instruments. I use the Murphy and Topel (2002). They propose different two-step maxi-
second to fourth lags of investment, trade openness, government mum likelihood procedures in order to account for the bias in
expenditure and years of secondary education, second to fifth lags the standard errors of the coefficients. Alternatively, if analytical
of remittance inflows, financial development measure and their solutions are cumbersome to obtain, bootstrap can be used to cor-
interaction term.25 Exogenous variables (time dummies and popula- rect the standard errors, as was done by Ashraf and Galor (2013).
tion growth) serve as instruments for themselves (‘‘IV style”). I use They generate a variable measuring migratory distance from East
the ‘‘collapse” option to keep the overall number of instruments at Africa to destination country in order to predict ethnic diversity
a reasonable level (following the rule-of-thumb that the number of (a variable which was originally only available for 21 countries)
instruments should be lower than the number of panel data units).26 and use this diversity as a regressor to explain population density
Third to fifth lag of the dependent variable are also included as in year 1500 in 145 countries. This is analogous to me generating
‘‘GMM style” instruments. Estimation tables include Hansen’s test an index of overall financial conditions and then plugging it into
statistics for overidentifying restrictions which can help evaluate growth regressions. In this paper I follow their approach. More
the quality of the instruments. Also, I consider pooled OLS and fixed details about the bootstrap procedure can be found in Online
effects (FE) within estimation results, both for the estimation sample Appendix A.6.
as for the truncated sample for robustness check. According to
Roodman (2009), GMM results can be trusted if the coefficient on
the lagged dependent variable lies between the FE and pooled OLS 5. The financial development index – results
estimates. This is true in my case, estimation results can be found
in Tables A.8 and A.9 in Online Appendix A.5. The index of financial development was estimated for 151
Such a formulation of the model including an interaction term countries for the time period from 1970 to 2010 (or other longest
between remittances and financial development allows for a non- available time span). The resulting relationship between the
linear impact of remittances on economic growth, depending on underlying variables and the constructed index can be summarized
the level of financial development of the transfer-receiving coun- by the following equations (standard errors in brackets):
try. This means that remittances might be particularly important 0 0 1 1 0 1
only for a subgroup of countries, for example those with lowest z1it 3:46½0:057 0:11½0:005
B 2C B
levels of financial development, which is the main hypothesis of B z C ¼ @ 3:40½0:061 A þ @ 0:13½0:007 C
C B
A  FinDevit ð7Þ
@ it A
this paper. For countries with more developed financial markets I
z3it 1:97½0:048 0:04½0:006
expect the impact of remittances on economic growth to be
reduced. FinDevit ¼ 0:99½0:001  FinDevi;t1 ð8Þ
Eqs. (7) and (8) show the solutions to (1) and (2). In particular,
4.3. Generated regressor problem z1it ; z2it ; z3it refer to variables which were used to generate the index.
Each row of (7) represents one category discussed in Section 3.2.
The inclusion of the estimated overall financial conditions index This means that z1it is a measure of overall size of the financial sys-
in the regressions brings about advantages as well as challenges.
tem, z2it is financial institution depth and z3it a measure of efficiency.
The former have already been discussed and refer to measuring
All coefficients in Eqs. (7) and (8) are statistically significant at
better the different aspects of financial sector in one indicator, as
the 1% significance level. The first vector in Eq. (7) (a in Eq. (1))
refers to the estimated means of the variables from each of the
25
One lag of all variables was omitted when forming the instrument set as second
three categories used for extracting the overall financial conditions
order serial correlation in the differenced error terms was detected.
26
This option limits the number of moment conditions by writing all instruments
index, abstracting from the index values. The second vector (b in
related to a given observation of the dependent variable in one column, rather than Eq. (1)) reflects the strength of the dependence of the observable
having multiple columns for each time period, cf. Roodman (2009). measures on the unobserved overall financial conditions indicator.
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 51

The coefficients can be interpreted as follows – the higher financial effects implicitly allowed in Eqs. (1) and (2). As these are random
development in general, the higher financial deposits to GDP ratio effects, the additional assumption which is necessary is that this
(impact of bð1Þ on z1it ) and credit to GDP ratio (effect of bð2Þ on z2it ). tax-haven feature is not correlated with my understanding of overall
A higher level of financial development leads to higher institu- financial development, defined above and in more detail in Sec-
tional efficiency, represented by decreasing interest rate spreads tion 3.2. There is no reason for such potential correlation.
– hence the negative sign of bð3Þ. The inclusion of tax havens certainly affects the ranking of
Eq. (8) implies that the overall financial development index is highly financially developed countries. These do not enter the esti-
nearly a random walk. This is a reasonable and rather agnostic out- mation sample used in the growth regressions, as the sample is
come – financial development is likely to be a process with a long limited to developing countries with enough data available for
memory and it is safe to assume that changes to it are an outcome other variables.
of a white noise process, due to the lack of further knowledge For the sake of brevity I do not provide information about the
about it. estimation results of the financial development index for each par-
Online Appendix A.7 provides a ranking of financial develop- ticular country. Such data, including graphs of historical evolution
ment, based on the time mean of the estimated index for each and tables with mean values of the index and the underlying vari-
country. As expected, advanced economies take the highest posi- ables, is available upon request.
tions, with East Asian, European countries and the United States
forming the top ten. 6. Estimation results from growth regressions
The leaders in the group of developing countries are Hong Kong
(1), Cyprus (5), Macao (8), Malta (11), Malaysia (15), St. Kitts and In the tables and graphs in the remainder of this paper I present
Nevis (19), South Africa (21), Lebanon (22) and Thailand (23). As results of quasi-maximum likelihood and system GMM estima-
for European countries included in the ranking are: Cyprus, Malta, tions. For both methods, I repeat each estimation four times: first
Israel (34), Czech Republic (38) and Bulgaria (55). The leaders for for the generated index of financial conditions and then for three
developing Asia are Hong Kong, Macao, Malaysia, Thailand, Vanu- other measures which were used for its construction. The three
atu (27), China (28) and Fiji (63), while in Latin America and the other variables referring to financial sector development and used
Caribbean the best positions are taken by small states: St. Kitts in the estimations are following. First, financial system deposits to
and Nevis (19), St. Lucia (26), Antigua and Barbuda (30), Grenada GDP ratio which is, apart from M3 to GDP ratio, the broadest read-
(31) and Panama (32). As for larger and more important (in terms ily available measure of the financial sector. Second, as I am not
of economic power) countries from this region, Chile (50) is fol- only interested in domestic loan providers, I use private credit by
lowed by Brazil (59), Uruguay (73), Venezuela (78) and Colombia banks and other financial institutions to GDP ratio to account for
(87). South Africa, Lebanon, Jordan (29), Bahrain (41) and Tunisia all sources of credit offered to the private sector by financial insti-
(42) obtained highest results among countries from the Middle tutions. Thirdly, I use the interest rate spread to include a measure
East and Africa. covering the cost efficiency aspect of financial development.
What stands out when looking at the country list above and in Results based on the three other measures of financial develop-
the complete ranking, is the high representation of small coun- ment are included to verify the reliability of the constructed indi-
tries, often tax havens or countries with strict financial secrecy cator and for comparison with other studies.
rules, among the most financially developed economies. This is
due to their large financial deposits to GDP ratios (measure of size 6.1. Main regression results and marginal effects of remittances
of the financial sector). Some of these countries like Macao, St.
Kitts and Nevis or St. Lucia could be eliminated from the sample While Table 2 (QML-FE results) and Table 3 (system GMM
for example by excluding smallest sovereign states using a thresh- results) show the main estimation results from growth regressions,
old of average population of at least 1 million, popular in the the marginal effect of remittances cannot be learned directly from
growth literature. However, this would not affect the inclusion them. I present it in Table 4, Figs. 2 and 3, using the calculations
of Hong Kong, Switzerland or Singapore. These are, at least cur- discussed below. The last table and the figures are given more
rently, countries with the highest values of the Financial Secrecy attention in the text, Tables 2 and 3 are included to show the
Index published by the Tax Justice Network. This index reflects underlying parameters and to allow for an overall assessment of
the impact of financial secrecy in a given country on the world the results of the growth regressions.
economy.27 Small countries, which could be excluded based on pop- The coefficient on remittances inflows share in GDP (d1 in Eq.
ulation size, like St. Kitts and Nevis or St. Lucia receive much lower (6)) refers to its influence on GDP per capita growth for countries
scores. with financial development equal to 0 (which is possible given
For this reason I decided not to draw any arbitrary line to the log-modulus transformation applied to measures of financial
exclude countries in which the financial sector might play an addi- conditions, cf. Table 1 and Online Appendix A.8). 29 Yet, this value
tional role, apart from efficiently transforming savings into produc- does not contain all the information about the relationship between
tive investments. Nonetheless, through inclusion of measures of remittances, growth and finance. To fully assess it, also d3 from Eq.
depth and efficiency of the financial sector I do correct the high (6), the coefficient on the interaction term between remittance
positions of countries with large financial deposits to GDP ratios.28 inflows and measures of financial development, needs to be taken
For example Macao drops from rank 5 (size of financial sector) to 8 into account, as:
(overall financial development), St. Kitts and Nevis from 10 to 19.
@yit
Moreover, as the index is created in a panel data setup which allows ¼ d1 þ d3 FinDevit  dit ð9Þ
@Remit
for unobserved individual effects, time invariant special features of
countries considered as tax havens will be captured by the random

27 29
The index was launched in November 2015 and is only available for the year 2015 Actually, financial development exactly equal to zero is possible for the generated
at the moment. More details: www.financialsecrecyindex.com (accessed on Novem- index, but less likely for most of the variables which were used for its generation. The
ber 20, 2015). log-modulus transformation preserves zeros, implying nil financial deposits to GDP
28
Columns (1) to (3) in Online Appendix A.7 include financial development rank ratio, credit to GDP ratio or interest rate spread. However, a nil nominal deposit
positions based on measures from each category from which the index was extracted. interest rate is not that unlikely.
52 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

Table 2
Main QML-FE results (1970–2010).

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Overall fin. cond. Fin. syst. deposits/GDP Priv. credit/GDP Int. rate spread
b/se b/se b/se b/se
L.Real GDP per capita (log) 0.863⁄⁄⁄ 0.860⁄⁄⁄ 0.858⁄⁄⁄ 0.820⁄⁄⁄
(0.044) (0.048) (0.046) (0.054)
Remittance inflows/GDP 0.004 0.018 0.021⁄⁄ 0.006
(0.003) (0.013) (0.009) (0.013)
Financial development (findev) 0.001 0.006 0.000 0.010
(0.003) (0.030) (0.018) (0.026)
Remittance-findev interaction term 0.001⁄ 0.004 0.005⁄⁄ 0.004
(0.000) (0.003) (0.002) (0.006)
Investment/GDP 0.008⁄⁄⁄ 0.008⁄⁄⁄ 0.007⁄⁄⁄ 0.008⁄⁄⁄
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Population growth 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.009
(0.015) (0.017) (0.017) (0.015)
Years of secondary education 0.039 0.045⁄ 0.044⁄ 0.065⁄
(0.026) (0.026) (0.025) (0.034)
Government expenditure/GDP 0.005⁄ 0.004⁄ 0.004⁄ 0.006
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004)
Trade Openness 0.001 0.001⁄ 0.001⁄⁄ 0.001⁄⁄
(0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
Observations 332 325 322 217
Countries 61 60 59 48
Log-likelihood 338.544 330.705 326.452 223.101

Notes: The dependent variable in all columns is the natural logarithm of real GDP per capita. Each column shows results using different measures of financial development.
For the overall fin. conditions index the annual speed of convergence is k   lnð5cÞ  3% (c ¼ 0:863). All values of k in this table and in Table 3 are between 1:3% and 4%, which
are reasonable numbers, between the results of Mankiw et al. (1992) and Caselli et al. (1996). Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses, ⁄ p < 0:10, ⁄⁄ p < 0:05, ⁄⁄⁄ p < 0:01.
All regressions include country and time fixed effects and a constant. See also notes to Table 3.
The bold values refer to the coefficients which are needed to compute the marginal effect of remittances on economic growth given financial development.

Table 3
Main System GMM results (1970–2010).

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Overall fin. cond. Fin. syst. deposits/GDP Priv.credit/GDP Int. rate spread
b/se b/se b/se b/se
L.Real GDP per capita (log) 0.927⁄⁄⁄ 0.904⁄⁄⁄ 0.936⁄⁄⁄ 0.869⁄⁄⁄
(0.039) (0.053) (0.042) (0.044)
Remittance inflows/GDP 0.001 0.035⁄ 0.052⁄⁄ 0.015
(0.005) (0.018) (0.021) (0.039)
Financial development (findev) 0.006 0.015 0.020 0.015
(0.004) (0.036) (0.022) (0.048)
Remittance-findev interaction term 0.003⁄⁄⁄ 0.010⁄⁄ 0.016⁄⁄⁄ 0.006
(0.001) (0.005) (0.006) (0.018)
Investment/GDP 0.008⁄⁄ 0.009⁄⁄ 0.010⁄⁄⁄ 0.010⁄⁄
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005)
Population growth 0.013 0.012 0.006 0.010
(0.016) (0.015) (0.013) (0.014)
Years of secondary education 0.075⁄⁄ 0.077⁄ 0.058 0.101⁄⁄
(0.032) (0.045) (0.040) (0.048)
Government expenditure/GDP 0.002 0.003 0.001 0.002
(0.003) (0.005) (0.003) (0.005)
Trade Openness 0.002⁄⁄ 0.002 0.002 0.002⁄⁄
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Observations 332 332 332 246
Countries 61 61 61 50
Number of instruments 43 43 43 43
p-value for Hansen’s test 0.379 0.394 0.625 0.670
p-value for AR(1) in residuals test 0.013 0.027 0.012 0.162
p-value for AR(2) in residuals test 0.064 0.101 0.077 0.225
p-value for AR(3) in residuals test 0.177 0.148 0.165 0.247
p-value H0 : c ¼ 1 (one-sided) 0.032 0.038 0.067 0.002
@Y it
@lnðY it Þ
Notes: The interpretation of d2 (for FinDev, a log-modulus transformed variable) is similar to a regular elasticity: d2  @lmðx ¼ , where lnðY it Þ ¼ yit (the natural logarithm
Y it

it Þ
@xit
jxit jþ1

of real GDP per capita) and xit is the level of financial development underlying the log-modulus transformed values used in the above estimations. Standard errors in
parentheses, ⁄ p < 0:10, ⁄⁄ p < 0:05, ⁄⁄⁄ p < 0:01, bootstrapped in column (1), robust with Windmeijer’s correction in (2)–(4).
The bold values refer to the coefficients which are needed to compute the marginal effect of remittances on economic growth given financial development.

Varðdit Þ ¼ Varðd1 Þ þ Varðd3 ÞFinDevit þ 2FinDevit Cov ðd1 ; d3 Þ


2
ð10Þ to GDP ratio has been computed for all observed values of the four
considered measures of financial development and the standard
Eq. (9) captures the complete relationship between remittances and error of dit was obtained from Eq. (10). The graphs reinforce the
GDP per capita growth for different levels of financial development. inference based on estimation tables. There is a positive effect of
Estimates of dit and its 90% confidence interval is depicted in Figs. 2 remittances on economic growth in countries with lowest financial
and 3. The partial derivative of yit with respect to remittance inflows development, but it becomes insignificant with improvements of
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 53

Table 4
The estimated effects of remittance inflows on growth for different measures of financial development (QML-FE results).

Partial percentile effects for different measures of financial development:


(1) (2) (3) (4)
Effect at: overall fin. dev. fin. sys. deposits/GDP priv. cred. by banks interest rate spread
and fin. inst./GDP
mean 0.486 0.440 0.397 0.091
p-value 0.119 0.145 0.152 0.798
median 0.523 0.470 0.390 0.076
p-value 0.101 0.132 0.159 0.834
other percentiles:
10th 0.986 0.753 0.921 0.153
p-value 0.036 0.103 0.018 0.793
25th 0.785 0.618 0.646 0.045
p-value 0.045 0.105 0.040 0.921
75th 0.180 0.260 0.131 0.213
p-value 0.564 0.357 0.644 0.588
95th 0.260 0.020 0.272 0.520
p-value 0.559 0.959 0.471 0.507
average marginal effect 0.459 0.422 0.371 0.089
p-value 0.298 0.127 0.384 0.692

Notes: The values in the table can be directly interpreted as semi-elasticity. For example, for a country with overall fin. dev. at the sample mean, if remittances share in GDP
changes by 1 percentage point real GDP per capita will change by 0:486% over 5 years (significant at 12%, all effects are multiplied by 100).
The bold values refer to statistically significant partial effects.
.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0

−20 −10 0 10 20 1 2 3 4 5
Overal fin.dev. Financial systems deposits/GDP
.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0

1 2 3 4 5 −1 0 1 2 3 4
Private credit by deposit money banks and other fin.inst./GDP Interest rate spread

confidence bound (90%) marginal effect

Fig. 2. Marginal effects of remittances on economic growth for different levels of financial development – QML-FE results. Notes: These figures show the marginal effect of
remittances on ln(GDP per capita) depending on the level of financial development for each of the four measures that were used in the estimation equations. The dashed line is
dit defined in (9) (with parameter values from Table 2 and from Table 3 in Fig. 3) and and the 90% confidence bound is computed based on its standard deviation defined in (10).

financial conditions. The effect turns negative for moderate values i at time t increases by 1 percentage point, real GDP per capita will
of financial development and can become statistically significantly change by 100  dit %. Therefore, given the coefficient estimates for
negative for the most financially developed countries (when system different levels of financial development presented in Table 431 a
GMM results are considered). This indicates that remittances and change in remittance inflows would not have significant growth
financial development can be seen as substitutes on the way to effects in countries with mean, median or higher financial develop-
achieve economic prosperity, assuming that the impact of financial ment levels.
development on growth for low levels of remittances is also posi- While countries with well developed financial markets do not
tive.30 However, once one of these inputs becomes large, the other seem to benefit from remittance inflows, Table 4 also reveals that
one can become redundant. the impact of remittances on economic growth is positive and sta-
dit can be interpreted as follows: given the level of financial tistically significant for financial development up to the 25th per-
development, if the share of remittance inflows to GDP in country centile in the sample. This is true for the generated index as well

30 31
In order to call two factors substitutes to achieve economic growth, each of them Table A.11 in Online Appendix A.9 shows analogous marginal effects calculated
should be conducive to growth individually, when the level of the other one is low. based system GMM results presented in Table 3.
54 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

.1

.1
−.1 −.05 0 .05

−.1 −.05 0 .05


Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−20 −10 0 10 20 1 2 3 4 5
Overal fin.dev. Financial systems deposits/GDP
.1

.1
−.1 −.05 0 .05

−.1 −.05 0 .05


Marginal effect

Marginal effect
1 2 3 4 5 −2 0 2 4 6
Private credit by deposit money banks and other fin.inst./GDP Interest rate spread

confidence bound (90%) marginal effect

Fig. 3. Marginal effects of remittances on economic growth for different levels of financial development – system GMM results.

as for the variables from the second category (reflecting the depth are related (as substitutes or complements) to the impact of remit-
of the financial sector). Migrants’ transfers can be particularly tances on economic growth.
important in countries with lowest financial development (up to The third row of Tables 2 and 3 shows the impact of the finan-
the 10th percentile in the sample), where an increase of the remit- cial sector on the logarithm of GDP per capita, with each element
tance inflows to GDP ratio by 1 percentage point can lead to almost referring to the effect for different measures of financial develop-
a proportional gain GDP per capita (rising by roughly 1% over the ment. This coefficient, d2 in Eq. (6), reflects the direct impact of
next 5 years). the discussed variable, abstracting from remittance inflows. In
Results related to the interest rate spread are not statistically my model the remittance variable is defined as a share in GDP
significant for any of the percentiles considered. This is related to (in percent), which means that it cannot achieve negative values.32
the fact that this estimation sample includes only 217 observa- This means that d2 is the highest or lowest impact of financial devel-
tions, which means that information for one third of the main esti- opment on economic growth (depending on the sign of the interac-
mation sample is missing. tion term, negative or positive respectively).
The positive (even though not always statistically significant) While the literature tends towards a positive impact of financial
marginal effect of remittances on economic growth for countries development on economic growth,33 when considering the QML-FE
with low financial development can indicate that there are binding results, only the coefficients in column (1) and (4), where the gener-
liquidity constraints in these countries. As the financial sector is ated financial development index and interest rate spread are used
not well developed, the supply of loans for productive activities respectively, have the expected sign.34 The system GMM results pre-
can be insufficient. Transfers from family members abroad can sented in Table 3 all have the expected sign, but they depend on the
help overcome these constraints. On the other end of the financial instruments choice.35 This means that for the QML-FE estimations
development distribution there are countries with well- the generated index seems to reflect better the relevance of the
functioning markets – on levels similar to industrial countries financial sector for economic growth. If financial deposits to GDP
(e.g. in Malaysia, South Africa). In these places, moral hazard prob- ratio or private credit by banks (and other financial institutions)
lems can appear, as indicated by Chami et al. (2005). If remittances were considered instead of the generated index, one would draw
are spent on consumption and labor supply is lowered, there will the conclusion about financial development being detrimental for
be negative long-run effects on economic growth. This could be
one explanation of the negative impact of remittances on GDP
32
per capita for countries with highest financial development. Negative values would be possible if I included net remittances, but I consider
Another reason could be that, given that these monies are regis- only transfer inflows, which are the relevant monies for developing countries.
33
For a review of theoretical and empirical research concerning the finance-growth
tered as remittances, they are not invested in the financial market
nexus see Levine (2005). Beck, Levine, and Loayza (2000), Levine, Loayza, and Beck
by the sender but sent to their family, who spends them in a differ- (2000) (among others) find a positive impact of financial development measures on
ent way. This means that, again, they are not used in the most pro- economic growth, while Rioja and Valev (2004a) find no significant growth effects in
ductive way in order to contribute to economic prosperity. countries with lowest levels of Liquid Liabilities or Private Credit. Schiavo and Vaona
(2008) argue that the effects are not necessarily homogenous across countries, which
is confirmed by Barajas, Chami, and Yousefi (2013).
6.2. How does the generated index affect the results? 34
The sign of the findev coefficient in column (4) is negative, as a higher interest
rate spread reflects lower financial development.
35
A comparison of results between the first and the other columns Not shown here, all variables apart from financial development measures and
remittances inflows have the expected sign irrespective of the choice of number of
in Tables 2 and 3 shows that the inclusion of the generated overall lags included in the GMM-style instrument set (considering instruments which pass
financial conditions index improves the estimated outcomes and Sargan/Hansen tests of overidentifying restrictions). The remittance-finance interac-
provides information about which aspects of financial development tion term prevails with a negative sign (as for the overall financial conditions index).
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 55

economic growth (on average, but not necessarily statistically significance in the main estimation results. In this paper, I am not
significant). focused on inference about these variables.
Also when considering the remittance-findev interaction term The generated index is estimated efficiently if variables from all
d3 , the generated index provides additional information when three categories are available in a given time period. However,
compared to results obtained by using proxies of various aspects when a variable is missing (for example a measure of financial sec-
of financial development separately. The individual results in col- tor efficiency, as the deposit interest rate or interest rate spread),
umns (2) and (3) of Tables 2 and 3 show that the size and depth the precision of the Kalman filter worsens and the confidence
aspect of financial development can be substitutes to remittances bound around the estimated financial development index
(negative sign of interaction term). However, the alternative inter- increases. This is one of the reasons why I use 5-year averaged
pretation related to nonlinear effects of finance on growth, driven quinquennial data – annual changes of the index may not always
by remittances, discussed by Bettin and Zazzaro (2012), cannot be be statistically significant.37 Kaufmann et al. (2008), the authors of
excluded. Moreover, no clear inference can be made about the rela- the World Governance Indicators measures of institutional quality,
tionship between financial sector efficiency (measured by interest point out a similar drawback of their indices and even suggest ana-
rate spread) and migrants’ transfers – the interaction term sign is lyzing their evolution over decades. Fig. A.6 in Online Appendix A.10
positive (as expected) when QML-FE results are considered, but shows examples of countries for which the index was estimated
negative for system GMM estimation (both not statistically signif- with very high precision and countries with intervals of higher
icant, though). uncertainty.
While the remittance-findev interaction term is significantly
negative both for private credit to GDP ratio (column (3)) and for
the generated index (column (1)), the value of the parameter d3 7. Robustness
in the latter case is lower (both for QML-FE and system GMM
results). This means that overall financial development is a weaker 7.1. Did the financial crisis affect the role of the financial sector as a
transmission channel of the impact of remittances on economic transmission channel?
growth. In other words, the substitutability of the two factors is
less pronounced in that case. The global financial crisis (GFC) of 2007–200838 may have chan-
When comparing the overall impact of remittances on eco- ged the role of the financial sector as a transmission channel or sub-
nomic growth dit in Table 4, it can be seen that it is only statistically stitute for remittances. Less developed financial markets could have
significantly positive for low levels of financial development in col- to lower credit availability and increase the costs of financing in the
umns (1) and (3). The marginal effects presented in column (1), case of private capital reversals and of higher bond spreads. How-
related to the generated index of financial development, are cor- ever, only more financially integrated (emerging) economies should
rected upwards. This means that the impact of remittance inflows have been affected strongly by this phenomenon and therefore the
on economic growth is stronger when the overall financial devel- aggregate effect on all developing countries in the sample is not
opment index is included instead of measures of size or depth of clear.39
the financial sector. This is due to the fact that the index accounts The role of migrants’ transfers could also have changed. Fig. 1
also for efficiency, which cannot be analyzed separately given the shows that these flows remained relatively stable (with a decline
lower data availability. only in 2009, followed again by stable growth) after 2007, while
The differences between the main estimation results including other kinds of flows to developing countries experienced larger
the generated index of overall financial development and those drops. Even though they increased since then, they became more
which use standard measures of size, depth or efficiency can be volatile. Only development assistance experienced a steady
summarized as follows. The impact of remittance inflows on GDP increase during the entire time period considered, but these flows
per capita is higher for all levels of financial development (cf. are much lower in volume. The strong reversal in private capital
Table 4, columns (1) and (3)), but the substitutability between flows has made such countries as Bangladesh and the Philippines
remittances and financial development as contributors to growth even more dependent on remittance flows as their sovereign rat-
is weaker (lower value of d3 in column (1) than in column (3) of ings were based on these transfers (cf. Sirkeci, Cohen, & Ratha
Table 2). As the interaction term d3 remains negative, it can be said (2012, p. 6)).40 This dependence of sovereign ratings on remittance
that the substitutability effect of the size of the financial sector inflows and the drop of remittance inflows in 2009 are reasons
dominates over the potential complementarity effect of its why I chose to exclude the period of the global financial crisis of
efficiency. 2007–2008 and its aftermath from the estimation sample as a
As discussed in Section 4.3, the use of the generated index robustness check. No such strong decreases of migrants’ transfers
comes also with caveats. It introduces additional uncertainty into
the model, which can be seen when comparing the statistical sig- 37
In this case, the use of every fifth observation is additionally driven by the
nificance of the coefficients associated with control variables usu- inclusion of the human capital measure (years of secondary education), which for
ally considered in the economic growth literature, other that the older years was only available on quinquennial basis. 5-year averaging is usually
justified by smoothing out business cycle variations and obtaining a long-run
savings rate (investment to GDP ratio) in column (1) in Table 2
relationship, however there is no guarantee that the chosen time span for averaging
with those in the other three columns. Trade openness and years will cover the cycles exactly, from peak to through.
of secondary education (human capital measure) have a positive 38
I consider 2007 as the starting point of the crisis, even though it is one year before
impact of similar magnitude in all cases, but not statistically signif- the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. However trust into the financial sector in the US
icant if my generated measure of overall financial conditions is began to dissolve already in 2007, and the housing bubble burst even one year earlier
(cf. ‘‘The origins of the financial crisis: Crash course”, The Economist, September 7,
considered.36 These coefficients are significant before the bootstrap-
2013, available at http://www.economist.com/news/schoolsbrief/21584534-effects-
ping and for this reason I am not concerned with the lack of their financial-crisis-are-still-being-felt-five-years-article, accessed on September 15,
2015).
39
For an analysis of channels of impact of the global financial crisis on developing
economies see for example Griffith-Jones and Ocampo (2009) and The International
36
Years of education may not capture the effect of human capital on economic Bank for Reconstruction (2009).
40
growth equally well in all countries. A measure of cognitive skills might be more Putting remittance inflows as collateral was not uncommon even before the crisis,
relevant, but has lower availability across countries and years (cf. Hanushek & however this practice was used more by banks than countries (for example Banco do
Wößmann, 2010). Brasil in 2002).
56 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0
−20 −10 0 10 20 1 2 3 4 5
Overal fin.dev. Financial systems deposits/GDP
.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0
1 2 3 4 5 −1 0 1 2 3 4
Private credit by deposit money banks and other fin.inst./GDP Interest rate spread

confidence bound (90%) marginal effect

(a) QML-FE
.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0

−20 −10 0 10 20 1 2 3 4 5
Overal fin.dev. Financial systems deposits/GDP
.1

.1
.05

.05
Marginal effect

Marginal effect
−.1 −.05 0

−.1 −.05 0

1 2 3 4 5 −2 0 2 4 6
Private credit by deposit money banks and other fin.inst./GDP Interest rate spread

confidence bound (90%) marginal effect

(b) system GMM


Fig. 4. Marginal effects of remittances on economic growth for different levels of financial development – before the global financial crisis. Notes: These marginal effects were
computed based on parameter estimated presented in Table 5 and in Online Appendix A.11.

were observed in the 1990s, at the time of financial and currency To see whether the financial crisis has changed the role of
crises in emerging and developing economies. remittances and financial development for economic growth in
Sirkeci et al. (2012) list six reasons for remittances to remain developing countries, I have removed the years 2007–2010 from
resilient to the crisis. The most relevant for the current study is the estimation sample.41 Estimation results for this truncated sam-
the one related to unexpected exchange rate movements (cf. p. 5 ple are presented in Fig. 4, Table 5 and Tables A.12 and A.13 (Online
therein). Developing countries’ currencies have depreciated Appendix A.11).
against the dollar during the crisis and migrants’ purchasing power
increased. Investment-related remittances increased in South and 41
This means that the last observation for the explanatory variables is for the year
East Asia. This should translate into a stronger positive direct 2005 (not a 5-year average); and the dependent variable is the logarithm of real GDP
impact of remittances on long-run growth, as discussed before. per capita in 2006.
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 57

Table 5
Coefficient estimates for the whole sample and for the sample limited to 2006.

Coefficient: Remittance inflows/GDP Financial development Remittance-finance Av. marginal effect


interaction
Finance measure Full sample Before GFC Full sample Before GFC Full sample Before GFC Full sample Before GFC
QML-FE results
Overall fin. dev. 0.004 0.004 0.001 0.001 0.001⁄ 0.001⁄ 0.459 0.467
s.e. (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.000) (0.000) (0.441) (0.442)
Fin. syst. deposits/GDP 0.018 0.019 0.006 0.003 -0.004 0.004 0.422 0.430
s.e. (0.013) (0.012) (0.030) (0.029) (0.003) (0.003) (0.277) (0.286)
Priv. credit/GDP 0.021⁄⁄ 0.020⁄⁄ 0.000 0.001 0.005⁄⁄ 0.005⁄⁄ 0.371 0.383
s.e. (0.009) (0.010) (0.018) (0.018) (0.002) (0.003) (0.426) (0.391)
Interest rate spread 0.006 0.008 0.010 0.015 0.004 0.004 0.089 0.043
s.e. (0.013) (0.012) (0.026) (0.022) (0.006) (0.005) (0.226) (0.266)
System GMM results
Overall fin. dev. 0.001 -0.000 0.006 0.003 0.003⁄⁄⁄ 0.002⁄⁄⁄ 0.333 0.169
s.e. (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.001) (0.001) (1.443) (1.136)
Fin. syst. deposits/GDP 0.035⁄⁄ 0.007 0.015 0.027 0.010⁄⁄ 0.003 0.073 0.161
s.e. (0.018) (0.016) (0.036) (0.034) (0.005) (0.004) (0.68) (0.173)
Priv. credit/GDP 0.052⁄⁄ 0.037 0.020 0.007 0.016⁄⁄⁄ 0.012⁄ 0.026 0.16
s.e. (0.021) (0.023) (0.022) (0.026) (0.006) (0.006) (1.274) (0.942)
Interest rate spread 0.015 0.010 0.000  0.013 0.006 0.005 0.270 0.087
s.e. (0.039) (0.029) (0.048) (0.028) (0.018) (0.013) (0.419) (0.372)

Notes: The values in the table can be interpreted as semi-elasticity (need to be multiplied by 100): the average marginal effect of remittances given financial development
values observed in the sample is 0:005, hence if the remittances share in GDP changes by 1 percentage point real GDP per capita will change by 0:5% ¼ 0:005  100% over
5 years (not statistically significant).

The fastest way to compare the results is by checking the coef- 8. Concluding remarks
ficient of the interaction term between remittances and financial
development in Table 5. This parameter reflects the strength of The impact of remittances on economic growth is a relatively
dependence of marginal effects of remittances on economic growth new topic in the literature. It arose in the last two decades, as
on the level of financial development in the receiving country. The migrants’ transfers reached the highest levels in history and gov-
main results remain unchanged – the remittance-finance interac- ernments of developing countries and international organizations
tion term is of similar magnitude and significance for both estima- realized their importance. However, until now, there is no consen-
tion methods. sus in the literature coming from cross-country analysis.
Average marginal effects of remittances on economic growth Recently, researchers have started studying the role of the finan-
(see Table 5, last two columns of each panel) are slightly higher cial sector as a channel for remittances to affect growth, or, on the
when considering the truncated sample and QML-FE estimates, contrary, as a substitute for remittances (as means for overcoming
but lower for system GMM. The differences are not statistically credit constraints). Since not many composite measures of financial
significant. development exist, especially for developing countries over a long
These results indicate that inclusion of the time period of the time span, it is challenging to establish the direction of relationship
global financial crisis in the main estimation sample does not affect between migrants’ transfers and financial development.
the results to a large extent. The confidence into and role of the In this paper I use an unobserved components model to con-
financial sector to provide alternative sources of financing to struct an a priori unknown index of financial development from
migrants’ transfers were not perturbed in the developing countries observable measures (which are commonly used as proxies for
included in this study. financial development). This overall financial conditions index
reflects the size, depth and efficiency of the financial sector. It can
7.2. Exclusion of potential outliers be used for creating international comparisons of financial develop-
ment or for studying its historical evolution in a particular country.
I performed the statistical test for detecting outliers in multi- I provide a ranking comparing average overall financial conditions
variate data using the bacon procedure.42 Even though the test for a large group of advanced and developing economies.
did not point out any irregular observations, there are two countries The index can also be used to reconcile contradictory or
which have much higher remittance inflows to GDP ratios than the ambiguous results of studies which used proxies instead of one
others. These are Albania (which additionally recorded high GDP composite index. In this paper I include the newly generated index
per capita growth) and Jordan. I excluded these two countries from as a control variable in growth regressions measuring the impact of
the estimation sample to see if the main results (negative remittances on GDP per capita changes, with special focus on the
remittance-finance interaction term, positive but decreasing influ- financial sector as a possible catalyst or obstacle in this process.
ence of remittances on economic growth) prevail. While the direct My QML-FE and system GMM estimations show that, indepen-
impact of migrants’ transfers diminishes, the effect is still dependent dently of the measure of financial development used, there is sub-
on the level of financial development, as suggested by the main stitution between remittances and financial development as
results (cf. Table A.14 and Fig. A.7 in Online Appendix A.12). factors enhancing economic performance, measured by GDP per
capita. The negative sign of the interaction term between remit-
42
Blocked adaptive computationally efficient outlier nominators, see Weber (2010). tances and financial development indicates that if the financial sec-
This test chooses a subset m of observations from the multivariate data set and tor is sufficiently large, additional transfers from migrants are not
consecutively adds more observations based on their Mahalanobis distance from the used in the most efficient way in the domestic economy.
basic subset, if this distance is not larger than a chosen percentile of a v2 distribution
The model predicts that in economies with less advanced finan-
(usually 85th percentile). The procedure continues until the subset of nonoutliers
stops changing and the remaining observations are marked as outliers. cial markets there are positive effects of remittance inflows on
58 I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59

growth. The robustness check shows that the recent global finan- Caselli, F., Esquivel, G., & Lefort, F. (1996). Reopening the convergence debate: A
new look at cross-country growth empirics. Journal of Economic Growth, 1,
cial crisis did not affect this relationship to a large extent.
363–389. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00141044.
The results show that it is not enough for a government to attract Catrinescu, N., Leon-Ledesma, M., Piracha, M., & Quillin, B. (2009). Remittances,
more remittance inflows, but additional incentives are necessary in institutions, and economic growth. World Development, 37(1), 81–92. https://
order for these transfers to be spent in a productive way and con- doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.02.004.
Chami, R., Fullenkamp, C., & Jahjah, S. (2005). Are immigrant remittance flows a
tribute to economic growth. Maimbo and Ratha (2005) suggest that source of capital for development? IMF Staff Papers, 52, 55–81. https://doi.org/
one way to encourage migrants and remittance recipients to make 10.2307/30035948.
investments in their home countries is by introducing clear regula- Cihak, M., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Feyen, E., & Levine, R. (2012). Benchmarking financial
systems around the world Tech. Rep. 6175. The World Bank.
tions and by limiting corruption. Unfortunately my data set Clemens, M. A., & McKenzie, D. (2014). Why don’t remittances appear to affect
includes countries for which measures of such institutional quali- growth? Policy Research Working Paper 6856 Washington, DC: World Bank.
ties are not available for a long time horizon and conditioning the Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the
world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198. https://doi.
impact of remittances on economic growth on measures of political org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2012.10.001.
and institutional qualities is left for future research. De Hoyos, R., & Sarafidis, V. (2006). Testing for cross-sectional dependence in panel-
data models. Stata Journal, 6(4), 482–496.
Durbin, J., & Koopman, S. (2001). Time series analysis by state space methods. New
Conflicts of interest York, USA: Oxford University Press. Ch. 4. Filtering, smoothing and forecasting,
pp. 25–36.
Giuliano, P., & Ruiz-Arranz, M. (2009). Remittances, financial development, and
None.
growth. Journal of Development Economics, 90, 144–152. https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.10.005.
Acknowledgements Griffith-Jones, S., & Ocampo, J. A. (2009). The financial crisis and its impact on
developing countries. Poverty reduction discussion paper 1. United Nations
Development Programme.
I thank Michael Binder, Philipp, Harms, Mauro Rodrigues Jr., Hamilton, J. (1995). Time series analysis. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University
Volker Nitsch, Sylwia Białek and the participants of the GSEFM Press. Ch. 13. The Kalman Filter, pp. 372–408.
Hanushek, E. A., & Wößmann, L. (2010). International encyclopedia of education. Vol.
Summer Institute, XV Conference on International Economics,
2. Oxford: Elsevier. Ch. Education and Economic Growth, pp. 245–252.
Money and Macro Brown Bag Seminar at Goethe University and Harvey, A. C. (1989). Forecasting, structural time series models and the Kalman filter.
of the 21st International Panel Data Conference for their helpful Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. Ch. 3. State space
comments. This research did not receive any specific grant from models and the Kalman filter, pp. 100–167.
Ho, M.-H. R., Shumway, R., & Ombao, H. (2006). 7. The state-space approach to
funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit modeling dynamic processes. In T. A. Walls & J. L. Schafer (Eds.), Models for
sectors. intensive longitudinal data (pp. 148–175). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ch. 7.
Hsiao, C., Pesaran, H. M., & Tahmiscioglu, K. A. (2002). Maximum likelihood
estimation of fixed effects dynamic panel data models covering short time
Appendix A. Supplementary data periods. Journal of Econometrics, 109, 107–150. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-
4076(01), 00143-9.
Huang, Y. (2011). Private investment and financial development in a globalized
Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in world. Empirical Economics, 41, 43–56. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-010-
the online version, at https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.08. 0394-3.
016. International Monetary Fund (2005). World economic outlook. Globalization and
external imbalances. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Ch. 2. Two
Current Issues Facing Developing Countries, pp. 69–107.
References International Monetary Fund (2009). Balance of payments and international
investment position manual. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
Abiad, A., Detragiache, E., & Tressel, T. (2010). A new database of financial reforms. Ch. Appendix 5. Remittances, pp. 272–277, sixth edition.
IMF Staff Papers, 57, 281–302. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2009.23. International Monetary Fund. (2011). World economic outlook. Slowing growth, rising
Acosta, P., Lartey, E., & Mandelman, F. (2009). Remittances and the Dutch disease. risks. Washington.
Journal of International Economics, 79, 102–116. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2008). Governance matters VII: Aggregate
jinteco.2009.06.007. and individual governance indicators, 1996–2007. The World Bank. Policy
Aggarwal, R., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Pería, M. S. M. (2011). Do remittances promote Research Working Paper 4654.
financial development? Journal of Development Economics, 96, 255–264. https:// Khan, M. S., & Senhadji, A. S. (2000). Financial development and economic growth: An
doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.10.005. overview. International Monetary Fund. IMF Working Paper 209.
Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable Kripfganz, S. (2016). Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation of linear dynamic
estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–52. short-T panel-data models. Stata Journal, 16(4), 1013–1038.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D. Levine, R. (2005). Finance and growth: Theory and evidence. In P. Aghion & S.
Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2013). The ‘Out of Africa’ hypothesis, human genetic Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth. Vol. 1, Part A of handbook of
diversity, and comparative economic development. American Economic Review, economic growth (pp. 865–934). Elsevier. Ch. 12.
103, 1–46. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.1.1. Levine, R., Loayza, N., & Beck, T. (2000). Financial intermediation and growth:
Barajas, A., Chami, R., Fullenkamp, C., Gapen, M. T., & Montiel, P. (2009). Do workers’ Causality and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(1), 31–77. https://doi.
remittances promote economic growth? IMF Working Paper 153 International org/10.1016/S0304-3932(00)00017-9.
Monetary Fund. Maimbo, S. M., & Ratha, D. (2005). Remittances: Development impact and future
Barajas, A., Chami, R., & Yousefi, R. (2013). The finance and growth nexus re-examined; prospects. World Bank Publications. Ch. Remittances: An Overview, pp. 1–16.
do all countries benefit equally? IMF Working Paper 130 International Monetary Mankiw, N., Romer, D., & Weil, D. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of
Fund. economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 407–437. https://doi.
Bazzi, S., & Clemens, M. A. (2013). Blunt instruments: Avoiding common pitfalls in org/10.2307/2118477.
identifying the causes of economic growth. American Economic Journal: Mundaca, B. G. (2009). Remittances, financial market development, and economic
Macroeconomics, 5(2), 152–186. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.5.2.152. growth: The case of Latin America and the Caribbean. Review of Development
Beck, T., Levine, R., & Loayza, N. (2000). Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Economics, 13, 288–303. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2008.00487.x.
Financial Economics, 58(1), 261–300. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(00) Murphy, K. M., & Topel, R. H. (2002). Estimation and inference in two-step
00072-6. econometric models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 20, 88–97. https://
Bettin, G., & Zazzaro, A. (2012). Remittances and financial development: Substitutes doi.org/10.2307/1391724.
or complements in economic growth? Bulletin of Economic Research, 64, Nyamongo, E. M., Misati, R. N., Kipyegon, L., & Ndirangu, L. (2012). Remittances,
509–536. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8586.2011.00398.x. financial development and economic growth in Africa. Journal of Economics and
Binder, M., Georgiadis, G., & Sharma, S. (2009). Growth effects of financial Business, 64, 240–260. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2012.01.001.
globalization, unpublished manuscript. Pagan, A. (1984). Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in regressors. International Economic Review, 25, 221–247. https://doi.org/10.2307/
dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143. https://doi. 2648877.
org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8. Rao, B. B., & Hassan, G. M. (2011). A panel data analysis of the growth effects of
Bouhga-Hagbe, J. (2004). A theory of workers’ remittances with an application to remittances. Economic Modelling, 28, 701–709. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Morocco IMF Working Paper 194. International Monetary Fund. econmod.2010.05.011.
I. Sobiech / World Development 113 (2019) 44–59 59

Rao, B. B., & Hassan, G. M. (2012). Are the direct and indirect growth effects of Sirkeci, I., Cohen, J. H., & Ratha, D. (Eds.). (2012). Migration and remittances during the
remittances significant? The World Economy, 35, 351–372. https://doi.org/ global financial crisis and beyond. The World Bank.
10.1111/j.1467-9701.2011.01399.x. Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1991). A probability model of the coincident economic
Rapoport, H., & Docquier, F. (2006). The Economics of Migrants’ Remittances. Vol. 1 of indicators. In G. Moore & K. Lahiri (Eds.), The leading economic indicators: New
Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism. Elsevier. Ch. 17. approaches and forecasting records (pp. 63–90). Cambridge: Cambridge
Rioja, F., & Valev, N. (2004a). Does one size fit all?: A reexamination of the finance University Press. Ch. 4.
and growth relationship. Journal of Development Economics, 74(2), 429–447. Svirydzenka, K. (2016). Introducing a new broad-based index of financial development.
Rioja, F., & Valev, N. (2004b). Finance and the sources of growth at various stages of International Monetary Fund. IMF Working Paper 5.
economic development. Economic Inquiry, 42, 127–140. https://doi.org/10.1093/ The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and The World Bank.
ei/cbh049. (2009). Global monitoring report: A development emergency. Washington, D.C.,
Roodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and Ch. 1. The Global Financial Crisis and its Impact on Developing Countries, pp.
system GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9, 86–136. 23–50.
Sarafidis, V., Yamagata, T., & Robertson, D. (2009). A test of cross section Weber, S. (2010). bacon: An effective way to detect outliers in multivariate data
dependence for a linear dynamic panel model with regressors. Journal of using Stata (and Mata). Stata Journal, 10, 331–338.
Econometrics, 148, 149–161. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2008.10.006. World Bank (2005). Financial sector assessment: A handbook. Washington, D.C.:
Schiavo, S., & Vaona, A. (2008). Poolability and the finance-growth nexus: A World Bank Publications. Ch. 2. Indicators of Financial Structure, Development,
cautionary note. Economics Letters, 98(2), 144–147. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. and Soundness, pp. 15–33.
econlet.2007.04.015. World Bank. (2006). The development impact of workers remittances in Latin America.
Schiopu, I., & Siegfried, N. (2006). Determinants of workers’ remittances. Evidence Vol. 2: Detailed findings. Washington, D.C., Ch. 3. Remittances and Poverty
from the European neighbouring region. European Central Bank. ECB Working Reduction, pp. 62–89, report No. 37026.
Paper 688. World Economic Forum. (2012). The Financial Development Report 2012. Geneva,
Senbeta, A. (2013). Remittances and the sources of growth. Applied Economics Switzerland.
Letters, 20, 572–580. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2012.718057.

You might also like