You are on page 1of 2

RESEARCH

B R I E F S
I N E C O N O M I C P O L I C Y

O c to b er 5, 2022 N u m b e r 305

Rent-Seeking through Collective


Bargaining
Teachers Unions and Education Production
B y J a s o n C o o k , U n i v e rs i t y o f U ta h ; S t é p h a n e L av e rt u , t h e O h i o S tat e U n i v e rs i t y ;
a n d C o r b i n M i ll e r , O f f i c e o f T ax A n a lys i s , U.S. D e pa rt m e n t o f t h e T r e a s u ry

T
here is a growing consensus that increasing laws are limited because student achievement data are
school district funding can lead to better educa- unavailable going that far back, whereas studies that esti-
tion outcomes, but how teachers’ unions affect mate the more recent impact of collective bargaining on
these returns to spending is unclear. Teachers student achievement generally lack plausibly exogenous
may be committed to imparting knowledge and skills, but they variation in union-district bargaining. Even studies that
also seek better salaries, benefits, and work conditions. Critics largely overcome these limitations cannot speak to the effi-
of teachers’ unions often cite such rent-seeking to argue that ciency of union-induced spending.
empowering teachers to bargain collectively for compensation Our study addresses these limitations by estimating the
undermines public education. Whether this argument holds contemporary impact of teacher collective bargaining on
depends on teachers’ and administrators’ relative understand- revenue allocation and student achievement, holding fixed
ing of education production and the extent to which they all other district differences (e.g., revenue levels). Specifically,
prioritize student achievement. If teachers are more inclined to using data on thousands of tax referendums held across Ohio
prioritize student learning or understand education produc- school districts from 1995 to 2019, we use a model designed to
tion better than administrators, then teachers’ influence estimate the impact of just passing a tax levy—as compared
through collective bargaining could increase efficiency. with just failing to pass a tax levy—on collective-bargaining
Unfortunately, we lack conclusive empirical evidence on agreements (CBAs), resource allocation, and student achieve-
whether teacher rent-seeking impacts education produc- ment. In particular, we compare the effect of obtaining this
tion. Studies that leverage the enactment of duty-to-bargain new tax revenue just before a CBA is set to expire—in the

Editor, JEFFREY MIRON, Harvard University and Cato Institute.


midst of collective bargaining—with the effect of obtaining teacher benefits to a greater extent (both in absolute terms
this tax revenue well before the next scheduled round of nego- and as a proportion of district revenues), experienced relative
tiations. Essentially, because districts largely commit revenue declines in their reserves, and were more likely to pass a new
to operational functions in the summer immediately follow- tax when the CBA expired.
ing a tax referendum, there are limited resources for unions Consistent with rent-seeking theory, additional revenue
to bargain over if collective bargaining is scheduled to take did not lead to student achievement gains among districts
place at a time other than the summer immediately following that allocated these new funds while in the midst of collective
the referendum. Importantly, we find that the precise timing bargaining, but it did among districts that committed new
of local tax levies (relative to scheduled collective-bargaining revenue one year prior to collective bargaining. For these dis-
negotiations) is plausibly random. Thus, comparing the tricts, relative spending increases of approximately $200 per
impact of tax elections held at different times relative to collec- pupil translated to an increase of annual achievement gains of
tive-bargaining negotiations should reflect the effect of union 0.02 of a student-level standard deviation, for total accumu-
pressure on resource allocation and student achievement. lated gains of around 0.06 student-level standard deviations
Our analysis of CBAs yields imprecise estimates but, as a over the following three years (the typical duration of a CBA).
whole, paints a coherent picture. Unions and districts agreed to Put differently, districts that allocated funds relatively free of
higher teacher salaries if collective bargaining occurred while collective-bargaining pressures were more efficient, realizing
a district decided how to allocate new revenue as opposed to an extra 0.002 standard deviations in student-level achieve-
well after a district allocated new revenue. Similarly, CBAs con- ment gains for every $1,000 in annual per pupil expenditures.
ferred more teacher benefits—such as dental coverage, extend- To our knowledge, this study provides the most direct test
ed mealtimes, and more sick and personal days—if districts of rent-seeking theory as it relates to collective bargaining over
secured and allocated new revenue in the midst of collective- teacher compensation and its impact on student achievement,
bargaining negotiations. On the other hand, tax passage was confirming more suggestive evidence from recent studies. The
more likely to lead to changes in CBA text dealing with work study also illustrates a mechanism through which collective
conditions among districts that committed new revenue one bargaining leads to greater educational spending, as districts
year prior to collective bargaining. These results are consistent subject to union pressure subsequently raised taxes further—
with research indicating that unions pursue higher salaries and ostensibly because they committed to unsustainable teacher
benefits in times of abundance but settle for perks with few or compensation levels. Finally, the study contributes to the
no immediate financial implications when budgets are tight. growing literature on school district collective bargaining with
Our analysis of school district spending and staffing cor- the analysis of decades of CBAs, providing evidence that in
roborates the results of the CBA analysis. Districts in which the absence of available funds, unions and districts negotiate
tax levies generated funds in the year leading up to sum- changes to work conditions instead of salaries and benefits.
mer CBA negotiations spent more on teacher compensation, This research brief only reflects the opinions of the authors and
spent down their reserves to a greater extent, and hired fewer not those of the U.S. Treasury Department.
teachers than districts that allocated new tax revenue well
before negotiating new CBAs. Specifically, although both sets
of districts increased overall spending on instructor salaries, NOTE
districts that allocated new revenue well before collective bar- This research brief is based on Jason Cook, Stéphane Lavertu,
gaining spent the money on 10–12 new teachers as opposed and Corbin Miller, “Rent-Seeking through Collective Bargain-
to salary increases. Moreover, districts subject to more union ing: Teachers Unions and Education Production,” Economics of
pressure in collective bargaining increased spending on Education Review 85 (December 2021).

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the Cato Institute, its trustees,
its Sponsors, or any other person or organization. Nothing in this paper should be construed as an attempt to aid or hinder
the passage of any bill before Congress. Copyright © 2022 Cato Institute. This work by the Cato Institute is licensed under a
Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License.

You might also like