You are on page 1of 74

Microeconomics

Eighth Edition, Global Edition

Chapter 4
Consumer Choice

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Topics
4.1 Preferences
4.2 Utility
4.3 Budget constraint
4.4 Constrained consumer choice
4.5 Behavioural economics and consumer choice.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Premises of consumer behaviour
• Individual tastes or preferences determine the
amount of pleasure people derive from the goods and
services they consume.
• Consumers face constraints or limits on their
choices.
• Consumers maximise their well-being or pleasure
from consumption, subject to the constraints they
face.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Properties of consumer preferences
(1 of 3)

• Completeness - when facing a choice between any


two bundles of goods, a consumer can always rank
them.
• That is, one and only one of the following relationships
is true:
▪ The consumer prefers the first bundle to the
second,
▪ prefers the second to the first, or
▪ is indifferent between them.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Properties of consumer preferences
(2 of 3)

• Transitivity - a consumer’s preferences over bundles


is consistent, in the sense that, if the consumer
weakly prefers Bundle a to Bundle b (likes a at least
as much as b) and weakly prefers Bundle b to Bundle
c, then the consumer also weakly prefers Bundle a to
Bundle c.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Properties of consumer preferences
(3 of 3)

• Non-satiation (‘more is better’) - all else being


the same, more of a commodity is better than less
of it.
– Good - a commodity for which more is preferred to
less, at least at some levels of consumption.
– Bad - something for which less is preferred to more,
such as pollution.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Preference maps
• Indifference curve - the set of all bundles of goods
that a consumer views as being equally desirable.
• Indifference map - a complete set of indifference
curves that summarize a consumer’s tastes or
preferences.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Just by the way - what is a burrito?

A burrito is a type of
Mexican and Tex-Mex
food, consisting of a
tortilla, wrapped or
folded into a cylindrical
shape to completely
enclose the filling.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.1 Bundles of Pizzas and
Burritos Lisa might consume (1 of 2)
(a) (b)
Lisa prefers any bundle
Which of these in area A over e
two bundles would

B , Burritos per semester


B , Burritos per semester

c A c
25 be preferred by 25
Lisa?
f
20 20
Lisa prefers bundle fe
over bundle e,
d, since fe e
15 15
e has more of both
a a
d goods: Pizza and
10 10 I1
Burritos
5
B

15 25 30 15 25 30
Z , Pizzas per semester Z , Pizzas per semester

If Lisa
Lisa prefers
is indifferent
bundle ebetween
to we can draw an indifference
any bundle
bundles e, a,inand …..
areac B curve over those three points

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.1 Bundles of Pizzas and
Burritos Lisa might consume (2 of 2)
(a) (c)

c A c
B , Burritos per semester

B , Burritos per semester


25 25

f f
20 20

e I2
15 15
e
a a
d d
10 10 I1

5
B I0

15 25 30 15 25 30
Z , Pizzas per semester Z , Pizzas per semester

If Lisa is indifferent between we can draw an indifference


bundles e, a, and c ….. curve over those three points
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Properties of indifference curves
1. Bundles on indifference curves farther from the
origin are preferred to those on indifference curves
closer to the origin.
2. An indifference curve goes through every possible
bundle.
3. Indifference curves cannot cross.
4. Indifference curves slope downward.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.2 Impossible indifference curves

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.2 Impossible indifference curves (a)
• Lisa is indifferent between e
B , Burritos per semester

and a, and also between e


and b…
– so by transitivity she should
also be indifferent between a
and b…
e – but this is impossible, since b
b must be preferred to a given it
a I1 has more of both goods.
I0

Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.2 Impossible indifference curves (b)
• Lisa is indifferent between

B , Burritos per semester


b and a since both points
are on the same
b
indifference curve…
– But this contradicts the
“more is better”
assumption. Can you tell a
why?
I
– Yes, b has more of both
and hence it should be
preferred over a.

Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.2 Impossible indifference curves (c)
• Consumer is indifferent
B , Burritos per semester

between b and a since


both points are in the
same indifference
curve…
b
– But this contradicts the
a “more is better”
assumption since b has
I more of both and hence
it should be preferred
over a.
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


MCQ blitz
The principle that “more is better” results in indifference
curves:
A. sloping down.
B. not intersecting.
C. reflecting bundles that are preferred the further
they are from the origin.
D. All of the above.
E. None of the above.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Willingness to substitute between goods
• Marginal rate of substitution (MRS) - the
maximum amount of one good a consumer will
sacrifice to obtain one more unit of another good.
• Lisa’s marginal rate of substitution of burritos for
pizza is

B
MRS =
Z
MRS is the slope of the indifference curve.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.3(a) Marginal Rate of Substitution
Indifference Curve Convex to the Origin
B , Burritos per semester

a From bundle a to bundle b, Lisa is willing


8 to give up 3 Burritos in exchange for 1
more Pizza…
–3
b From bundle b to bundle c, Lisa is willing to give up 2
5
1 Burritos in exchange for 1 more Pizza…
-2
c From bundle c to bundle d, Lisa is willing to give up 1
3
1
-1 d Burrito in exchange for 1 more Pizza…
2
1
I

0 3 4 5 6
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Curvature of indifference curves
• Casual observation suggests that most people’s
indifference curves are convex to the origin.
• Diminishing marginal rate of substitution: The
marginal rate of substitution approaches zero as we
move down and to the right along an indifference
curve.
• Why?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


MCQ blitz
Convexity of indifference curves implies that consumers
are willing to:
A. give up more “y” to get an extra unit of “x” the more
“x” already they have.
B. give up more “y” to get an extra unit of “x” the less “x”
they have.
C. settle for less of both “x” and “y”.
D. acquire more “x” only if they do not have to give up
any “y”.
E. None of the above.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Consumers with different preferences
(from Frank, R.H. Microeconomics and behaviour, 8th ed.)

Relatively speaking, Tex is a potato-lover and Mohan a rice-lover. Can


you see this difference in preferences from their IC curves? For any
given bundle, Tex’s MRS of potatoes for rice is smaller than Mohan’s.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
• The marginal rate of substitution approaches zero
as we move down and to the right along an
indifference curve.

• Discussion: Could you imagine a pair of goods


that does not exhibit this property?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.3(b) Marginal Rate of Substitution
Indifference curve concave to the origin (rare)

(b) Indifference Curve Concave to the Origin • From bundle a to


bundle b, Lisa is willing
B , Burritos per semester

to give up 2 Pizzas for


1 Burrito.
a
7
–2 – Nevertheless, from b to
b c she is willing to give
5
1 up 3 Pizzas for 1
Burrito.
–3
c
2 – This is very unlikely
1
(Could you think why?)
I
0 3 4 5 6
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Curvature of indifference curves (cont.)
• Casual observation suggests that most people’s
indifference curves are convex to the origin.
• Special cases:
– Perfect substitutes - goods that a consumer
is completely indifferent as to which to
consume.
– Perfect complements - goods that a
consumer is interested in consuming only in
fixed proportions (i.e. together).

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.4(a) Perfect Substitutes
• Bill views Coke and Pepsi as
perfect substitutes: what do
Coke, Cans per week

4 you think his indifference


curves would look like?
3
– Straight, parallel lines
with an MRS (slope) of
2
−1.
1 – Bill is willing to exchange
I1 I2 I3 I4
one can of Coke for one
can of Pepsi.
0 1 2 3 4
Pepsi, Cans per week

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.4(b) Perfect Complements
▪ If Maureen has only one
piece of pie, she gets as
Ice cream, Scoops perweek

much pleasure from that


piece and one scoop of
e c
3 I3 ice cream, a,
b  as from that piece and
d
2 I2 two scoops, d,
a  or from that piece and
1 I1 three scoops, e.

0 1 2 3
Pie, Slices per week

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.4(c) Imperfect Substitutes
• The standard-shaped,
convex indifference curve
B , Burritos per semester

in the panel lies between


these two extreme
examples.
• Convex indifference
curves show that a
consumer views two
I goods as imperfect
substitutes.
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Application: Indifference curves between
food and clothing

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Problems: Constructing indifference curves
1. Don is altruistic. Show the possible shape of his
indifference curves between charity and all other
goods.
2. Miguel considers tickets to the opera and to
football games to be perfect substitutes. He’s
always willing to exchange one opera ticket for
one football game ticket. Show his preference
map.
3. If Joe views two candy bars and one piece of
cake as perfect substitutes, what is his marginal
rate of substitution between candy bars and
cake?
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Problems: Constructing indifference curves

Football
All Don’s IC map game Miguel’s IC map
Other tickets
2
goods

1 2 Opera tickets
Charity
4
Joe’s IC map

Candy
bars
2 Candybars 2
MRS = = − = −2
Cake 1

1 2 Pieces of cake
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Utility
• Utility - a set of numerical values that reflect the
relative rankings of various bundles of goods.
• Utility function - the relationship between utility
measures and every possible bundle of goods:
– For our pizza & burrito example, U(Z, B)
– E.g. Lisa’s U might be: U ( Z , B ) = BZ

– So we could work out a numerical value for U if


we know how much Z & B she has

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Example with Lisa’s utility (cont.)

So if Lisa had to choose between these two bundles:


Deal 1: [9B & 16Z]
OR
Deal 2: [13B & 13Z] ??
We could say which she’d prefer:
U ( Z , B ) = BZ
so for Deal 1: U = √9x16 = 12
& for Deal 2: U = √13x13 = 13
So Lisa would get more utility from Deal 2 ☺
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Ordinal Preferences
• If we only know a consumer’s relative ranking of
bundles, the measure of pleasure is ordinal.
– Tells us the relative ranking of two things, but not ‘by
how much’ one is better than another.
• A cardinal measure is one by which absolute
comparisons between ranks may be made. Money is
an example of a cardinal measure.
• Here, we use utility (utils) as a cardinal measure.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Utility and indifference curves
• An indifference curve consists of all those bundles
that correspond to a particular level of utility.
• If Lisa’s utility function is U(Z, B), then an
indifference curve is given by

U = U ( Z, B )

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.5(a) The relationship between the
utility function and indifference curves

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.5(b) The relationship between the
utility function and indifference curves

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Marginal Utility
• Marginal utility - the extra utility that a consumer
gets from consuming the last unit of a good.
– the slope of the utility function as we hold the
quantity of the other good constant.
• Marginal utility of good Z is:

U
MUZ =
Z

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.6 Utility and Marginal Utility
• As Lisa consumes more pizza,
holding her consumption of
burritos constant at 10, her
total utility, U, increases…
– and her marginal utility of
pizza, MUZ, decreases
(though it remains
positive).
• Marginal utility is the slope of
the utility function as we hold
the quantity of the other good
constant.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Utility and Marginal Rate of Substitution
• The MRS is the negative of the ratio of the marginal
utility of another pizza to the marginal utility of
another burrito.
• Formally, B MU Z
MRS = =−
Z MU B
• Since utility is constant along a given IC,
MU Z Z = MU B B
• i.e. moving down a given IC, utility lost from having
fewer burritos is compensated exactly by utility
gained from having extra pizzas.
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
To see why MRS is the negative of the ratio of
the marginal utilities:
Moving from a to b, Lisa is
giving up 3 burritos and
B , Burritos per semester

getting 1 more pizza.


8
a Her total utility from
eating B & Z stays the
–3
same from a to b.
(Why?)
b
So the ‘lost’ U from
5
1 - ∆B.MUB = ∆Z.MUZ
fewer burritos must
exactly equal the
3
‘gained’ U from Rearrange:
2 more pizza ∆B / ∆Z = - MUZ / MUB
I

0 3 4 5 6
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Budget Constraint (1 of 5)
• Budget line (or budget constraint) - the bundles
of goods that can be bought if the entire budget is
spent on those goods at given prices.
• Opportunity set - all the bundles a consumer can
buy, including all the bundles inside the budget
constraint and on the budget constraint.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Budget Constraint (2 of 5)
• If Lisa spends all her budget, Y, on pizza and
burritos, then
pBB + pZ Z = Y
– where pB B is the amount she spends on burritos and
pZ Z is the amount she spends on pizzas.

• This equation is her budget constraint.


– It shows that her expenditures on burritos and pizza
use up her entire budget.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Budget Constraint (3 of 5)
• How many burritos can Lisa buy?
– To answer, solve budget constraint for B (quantity of
burritos):

PB B + PZ Z = Y
PB B = Y − PZ Z
Y PZ
B= − Z
PB PB

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Budget Constraint (4 of 5)
From previous slide we have: Y PZ
B= − Z
PB PB
Lisa can buy more burritos with a higher income, a lower
price of burritos or pizza, or if she buys fewer pizzas.

If pZ = $1, pB = $2, and Y = $50, then:


$50 $1 1
B= - Z = 25 - Z
$2 $2 2
Some bundles Lisa can afford:

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Figure 4.7 Budget Constraint
Amount of Burritos  From previous slide we have
consumed if all income that if:
B , Burritos per semester

is allocated for Burritos. pZ = $1, pB = $2, and Y = $50,


a then the budget constraint, L1,
25 = Y /pB
is:
b
20 $50 − ($1 Z )
B= = 25 − 0.5Z
L1 $2

c Amount of Pizza
10 consumed if all income
Opportunity set is allocated for Pizza.

d
0 10 30 50 = Y / pZ
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Slope of the Budget Constraint
• We have seen that the budget constraint for Lisa
is given by the following equation:
Y PZ
B= - Z
PB PB

Slope =  B/ Z = MRT


– The slope of the budget line is also called the
marginal rate of transformation (MRT).

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Solved Problem 4.2
• Suppose that a government rations water by
setting a quota on how much a consumer can
purchase.
• If a consumer can afford to buy 12 thousand litres
a month but the government restricts purchases to
no more than 10 thousand litres a month, how
does the consumer’s opportunity set change?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Solved Problem 4.2: Answer

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.8(a) Changes in the budget constraint:
price of pizza doubles
Slope = -$1/$2 = -0.5
B= Y - PZ = $1
$2
Z
B , Burritos per semester

PB PB
25 If the price of pizza
doubles, (increases from
L 1 (p Z = $1) $1 to $2) the slope of the
budget line increases

Loss
L2 (pZ = $2) This area represents
the bundles she can no
longer afford
0 25 50
Z , Pizzas per semester
Slope = -$2/$2 = -1

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.8(b) Changes in the budget constraint:
income doubles
PZ
B = $100
$50 - Z
PB PB
B, Burritos per semester

If Lisa’s income increases


50 by $50 the budget line
L 3 (Y = $100)
shifts to the right (with the
same slope!)

25
This area represents the
Gain
new consumption
L 1 (Y = $50) bundles she can now
afford!!!
0 50 100
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Solved Problem 4.3
Is Lisa better off if her income doubles or if the prices of
both the goods she buys fall by half?
Answer: Her budget line and her opportunity set are
the same with either change.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Problems for class discussion
Thando consumes cans of anchovies (A) and boxes
of biscuits (B). Her indifference curves show
diminishing MRS. Where A = 10 and B = 7, her
MRS between cans of anchovies and boxes of
biscuits is –2 (= MUB / MUA).
If offered a bundle with 6 cans of anchovies and 9
boxes of biscuits, would she find it more, less or
equally as desirable as her current bundle? Why?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Problems for class discussion
Ayanda consumes choc bars and oranges. He is
given 2 choc bars and 10 oranges. He can buy or
sell choc bars for R5 each, or oranges for R2 each.
If he has no other source of income, draw his
budget constraint and write the equation. What is
the most he can spend on these goods?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Constrained Consumer Choice
• Given information on Lisa’s preferences and how
much she can spend, we can determine her optimal
bundle.
• Her optimal bundle is the bundle out of all the bundles
that she can afford that gives her the most pleasure.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.9 Consumer maximization, interior
solution (1 of 2) • Would Lisa be able to consume any bundle along
▪I▪(i.e.
3 Would
Bundle Lisa
bundle f)? e isbe called
ableato
B , Burritos per semester

consumer’s
–consume
No! Lisa does any optimum.
bundle
not have along
enough income
3
to
1 afford any bundle along I
I ? If Lisa is consuming this
 Yes; she could
bundle, she afford
has no bundles
d, c, and a.
25
incentive to change
 Nevertheless, there are other
her
20
c f behaviour
affordable by substituting
bundles that should
beone good for
preferred andanother.
affordable.
B e  For instance bundle e
10
I3
d I2
A a
I1
0 10 30 50
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.9 Consumer maximization, interior
solution (2 of 2)
▪ The budget constraint and the indifference curve
have the same slope at point e where they touch.
B , Burritos per semester

Therefore, at point e:

MUZ PZ
MRS = − =− = MRT
25 MUB PB
Slope of I2
e Slope of BL
I2

0 50
Z , Pizzas per semester

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Consumer maximization, interior solution
cont.

i.e. rate at which consumer will trade off one good


for the other = rate at which the two are traded in
the market

Rearrange:
MUZ = MUB
pZ pB

In equilibrium / at optimal bundle / to max U,


consume goods such that the last $ spent on
each brings as much U.
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Additional Problem 4.?
• Nate’s utility function over jelly and peanut butter is U
= JN. Nate’s marginal utility from jelly is MUJ = N,
and his marginal utility from peanut butter is MUN = J.
• The price of a jar of jelly is $5. The price of a jar of
peanut butter is $10. Nate has a budget of $100 to
allocate to these two items.
• If Nate maximizes his utility, how much of each good
does he consume?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Problem 4.?: Answer guideline
1. Derive Nate’s budget line by setting his expenditure
equal to his budget.
2. Find the relationship between N and J.
3. Substitute this utility-maximizing condition into the
budget equation to determine J and N.
4. Substitute the solution for J into the budget line to
solve for N.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.10 Consumer maximization, corner
solution For another student, Rethabile:
• at all bundles, Rethabile’s MRS is lower than
the MRT,
• that is, her ICs are flatter than the BL.
B, Burritos per semester

• Rethabile does best to consume only burritos


and no pizzas
• Her optimal bundle is e (0 pizzas, 25 burritos).
• Her optimal bundle is a corner solution.
• Why is bundle y not optimal?
e
25

I3
x
I2
y
Budget line
I1

50
Z , Pizzas per semester
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Solved Problem 4.4
• The concentration of the active ingredient, sodium
hypochlorite, in Clorox is twice that of the generic
brand.
• Consequently, Chris views one cup of Clorox to be
a perfect substitute for two cups of the generic.
• If Clorox costs $3 gallon, the generic costs $1, and
Chris allocates Y = $6 per year, what bundle does
Chris buy? If the price of Clorox falls to $2, how
does Chris’s behaviour change?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Solved Problem 4.4

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Food Stamps (1 of 2)
• The U.S. Food Stamp Plan started in 1939.
• Renamed to Supplemental Nutrition Assistance
Program (SNAP) in 2008.
• 44 million people receive food stamps at a cost of
$67 billion in early 2016.
• The average benefits were $125 per person per
month or $4.12 per day (U.S. Department of
Agriculture).

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Food Stamps (2 of 2)
• Would a switch to a comparable cash subsidy
instead of food stamps increase the well-being of
people who receive food assistance?
• Would recipients spend less on food and more on
other goods?

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Social grants in SA
• Grants paid in cash,
unlike USA food
stamps

• 45.5% of SA
households received
at least one form of
social grant in 2015

http://www.statssa.gov.za

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Some findings re SA social grant
• Aguero, Carter & Woolard (2006): The impact of
unconditional cash transfers on nutrition: The South African
Child Support Grant
• Unconditional, targeted transfers have significantly
improved child nutrition (height-for-age) – so grants are
being spent on food.
• Not the case in other countries. (Most SA recipients are
women / mothers…?)
• ‘Human capital’? Studies link wages to adult height – the
present value of increased future earnings may be 60% -
130% more than the cost of early life CSG support!

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.12 Food Stamps Versus Cash

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Fig 4.12 adapted: Impacts of cash grant in SA?

All other goods per month Budget line with cash


Y + 100

C
Y

A Original
budget line

0 Y Y + 100
Food per month
Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved
Behavioural Economics
• Economists try to better predict economic decision
making by adding insights from psychology and
empirical research on human cognition and
emotional biases to the rational economic model.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Test of Transitivity
• Adults tend to make transitive choices.
• Children are less likely to make transitive choices.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Endowment Effect
• People place a higher value on a good if they own it
than they do if they are considering buying it.
• Consumer choice theory assumes a consumer’s
endowment does not affect the indifference curve
map.
• Research has shown that experience significantly
reduces the endowment effect.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Salience and Bounded Rationality (1 of 2)
• People are more likely to consider information if it
is presented in a way that grabs their attention or
if it takes relatively little thought or calculation to
understand.
– for example, tax salience is awareness of a tax.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Salience and Bounded Rationality (2 of 2)
• When a store’s posted prices exclude the sales
tax, consumers are much less likely to react to a
change in the price.
• Tax is not salient and some consumers ignore
taxes.
• Bounded rationality - people have a limited
capacity to anticipate, solve complex problems, or
enumerate all options.

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved


Why Americans buy more ebooks than
Germans

Copyright © 2018 Pearson Education, Ltd. All Rights Reserved

You might also like