You are on page 1of 15

Int. J.

Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Journal of Production Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ijpe

Single item periodic review inventory control with sales dependent


stochastic return flows
Esra Gökbayrak, Enis Kayış ∗
Department of Industrial Engineering, Ozyegin University, Nisantepe Mah., Orman Sok., Istanbul, 34794, Turkey

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: Retailers have to deal with increasing levels of product returns as the shares of e-commerce sales soars. With
Inventory management this increase, it is no longer feasible to dispatch returned products to outlets or landfills, hence retailers must
Stochastic product returns re-evaluate them both to maximize profit and to minimize their environmental impact. Our objective is to study
Dynamic programming
a retailer’s optimal inventory control policy under product returns to maximize expected profit which is the
sales revenue minus the procurement, backorder, holding, and salvage costs incurred in a finite horizon. We
model a period’s returns to be stochastically dependent on the previous period’s sales quantity. Using dynamic
programming formulation, we solve for the optimal periodic review inventory policy and provide structural
results on the optimal policy of the final period. Through numerical studies, we show that incorporating
detailed sales-dependent returns could increase a retailer’s expected profit by 23%. Ignoring this dependency
in determining the optimal inventory policy results with increased order frequency, higher levels of backorders
and more leftovers which could eventually end up in a landfill, but above all could lead to a significant
overestimation of the resulting profit.

1. Introduction a slowdown in the growth due to reopened states (AdobeAnalytics,


2020). According to the report, online shopping was preferred for
The retail industry is gigantic and was worth nearly $24 trillion cheaper prices before the pandemic but now it seems that this differ-
in 2019 (O’Connell, 2020). The industry is mostly run by large retail entiation is no longer valid and in fact, online sales are substituting
chains since they have the cost advantage of buying huge amounts off-line sales.
of inventory. Walmart, the largest retail chain in the world, is top- As retail e-commerce grows rapidly, product returns are also grow-
ranked among all industries in Fortune Global 500 list for years. As ing. Either for legislative or competitive reasons, many companies
the retail industry expands and evolves with digitalization, consumers accept returns without any reason declared, under the ‘‘No Questions
with dynamic purchasing behaviors are also pushing for higher levels Asked Return Policy’’ (Ülkü and Gürler, 2018), and this customer
of personalization and quality. To overcome this consumer hunger, experience increases sales. The National Retail Federation states that
retailers increase the number of products they offer. For example, $260 billion in merchandise has been returned in 2016 in the US,
Walmart offers more than 75 million stock keeping units for sale on which is a 66% increase from five years ago. The lack of power of
its online channel (Lore, 2018).
touch at online stores further increases the number of returns. Smith
A majority of the retail chains sell through both off-line and online
(2015) presents that a brick-and-mortar store faces returns as 10% of
stores, with an increasing focus on the latter, and allow customers to
the sales, whereas this ratio is 20% with e-commerce returns. Holiday
experience a smooth service from both channels. The Chinese company,
e-commerce returns increase to 30% of the sales and even to 50%
Alibaba Group, significantly increased its online retail sales with its 580
of the sales for expensive products. Increasing return rates are also
million active monthly users while European and US countries face the
attributable to strategic customers who are abusing the return policies
brick and mortar store closures (Devani and Coonan, 2018). During the
of retail companies and ordering more than they need to resolve fit
Covid-19 pandemic, the retail industry has even struggled with jumping
online sales due to ‘‘stay at home’’ obligations. Bhattarai (2020) states uncertainty and then simply returning the unfit fashion items (Ülkü
that Walmart’s online sales increased by 74%, lifting overall sales by and Gürler, 2018). Mostard and Teunter (2006) reports that for catalog
nearly 9% in two months. Adobe’s Digital Economy Index for July retailers return rates on fashion items are generally around 35–40% and
2020 reveals that US online sales increased 55% from last year, despite could increase to 75% of the sales for some products.

∗ Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: esra.gokbayrak@ozu.edu.tr (E. Gökbayrak), enis.kayis@ozyegin.edu.tr (E. Kayış).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2022.108699
Received 12 August 2021; Received in revised form 6 September 2022; Accepted 21 October 2022
Available online 28 October 2022
0925-5273/© 2022 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Product returns are often accepted for longer periods when there previous sales modeled in this paper is original and rich in detail
is a defect under the product warranty. This return process is often and thus operationally more relevant for the practitioners. (2) Using
protected by law. Companies also may accept returns of no-defect dynamic programming, we derive an optimal periodic review inventory
products for a shorter declared period even if it is not always obligatory, policy for our problem and demonstrate that an (𝑠, 𝑆) type inven-
which is the focus of this paper. Retailers can increase consumer tory policy may no longer be optimal. (3) We show some structural
satisfaction and loyalty and collect data regarding consumer behavior properties of the optimal profit and the optimal inventory policy in
or product performance by allowing returns of no-defect products the last period. (4) We compare the profits of a return-smart retailer
(Li et al., 2016, Narang and Shankar, 2019). Retailers also have the who manages its inventory by keeping separate records of sales and
advantage of using the funds obtained from the revenue of the returned returns and following our results and a return-naive retailer who does
products till the product is eventually returned and the customer is not track sales explicitly and simply uses the net demand approach
refunded, which could take a substantial amount of time (Winkler, (i.e., considers only the product demand less the product returns).
2021). However, handling product returns could be costly especially Using Monte Carlo simulation, we find that the return-smart retailer
when the returns are not resold. If the returns are not added back to the could enjoy on average 23% more profit than the return-naive retailer.
inventory during the selling season, they could stay in the warehouse We find that this profit improvement percentage is most sensitive to
generating holding costs until they are resold or salvaged, or could go the fixed order cost, backorder cost, and return rates. The return-smart
to a landfill generating obsolescence or environmental costs (Constable, retailer considers the possible incoming product returns and orders
2019). Hence retailers are in a position to carefully manage their less frequently (thus saves from the fixed order cost) compared to the
inventories to address these challenges in order to reap the benefits of return-naive retailer. The latter option leads to lower order-up-to levels
product returns. which increase backorders as the return rates increase. (5) Finally, we
Inventory management under product returns requires detailed provide an extension of our model with backorders to the case with lost
sales and returns data. Trivially, the number of product returns depends sales.
on the previous sales: as sales increase, returns in the following period The paper is organized further as follows. In Section 2, we review
are also likely to increase. When the return rates are low, the net the related literature. In Section 3, we describe the details of the model
demand approach (i.e., recording only the amount of demand less and our assumptions. Analytical results of the formulated problem are
the returns) is convenient (Fleischmann and Kuik, 2003). For high- discussed in Section 4. We exhibit the results of a numerical study along
return products, however, relevant data to measure the dependency with a sensitivity analysis in the next section. We present an extension
between sales and returns is needed. Şen (2008) shows the importance with the lost sales case in Section 6. Finally, we summarize the results
of tracking sales data, and exchanging electronic sales and related and conclusions and give an outlook for future research in Section 7.
information. Narang and Shankar (2019) argues that offering a mobile
application that tracks user purchases and returns could translate into 2. Literature review
higher profits via increased sales as well as returns. However, not
all companies keep a separate record of sales and return data due to Product returns have been studied in the literature along several
practical or economic reasons and instead keep track of net demand. lines of research such as inventory management with return flow (see,
In this paper, we will present an inventory control model in which for example, Reimann, 2016), the effects of return cost (see, for exam-
stochastic returns depend on previous sales. Retailers could leverage ple, Shulman et al., 2010), and pricing strategy under product returns
our model to quantify the benefits of keeping detailed sales and returns with money-back guarantee policy (see, for example, Chen et al., 2019).
data, and how to leverage this data in managing product inventories. We focus on the inventory management implications of product returns,
The results of this paper interest many retail companies but the assump- which have been studied in literature since the late seventies. In this
tions of our paper best suit fast fashion retailers that offer stylish clothes section, we review papers that use stochastic models and refer the
at affordable prices. This industry is characterized by short life-cycle readers to papers with deterministic models to Schrady (1967) as one of
products, dynamic assortments, high demand and supply uncertainties, the earlier works and Fleischmann et al. (1997) for various extensions.
and highly responsive supply chains (Caro and Martínez-de-Albéniz, We consider two streams of papers: The papers in the first stream
2015, Wen et al., 2019). In fast fashion retail, the seasons and the consider the return of used products that cannot be resold unless
related assortments change rapidly such as 4 − 5 different seasonal processed, i.e., remanufactured. All returns may not be directly added
assortments in a year. According to Şen (2008), 35% of the U.S. apparel back to inventory upon receipt: The amount of returns that are reman-
market contains fashion products that have only a 10-week product life. ufactured is a critical decision variable, especially if the new product
Fashion products are also known to have high return rates, as discussed price is sensitive to sales quantity. In the second stream, papers study
above. 80% of these returns can be resold as new, of which 50% need commercial returns that are directly added back to inventory. These
just new packaging (Reimann, 2016). Hence, retailers can either resell are mostly unused products that require negligible processing time and
them or send the returns back to the manufacturer for a refund of the cost to be resold. While our paper belongs to the second stream, we
wholesale price (Ferguson et al., 2006). review the papers in the first stream as well: The models used in this
In the literature, there are many papers on inventory management stream are quite similar to those in the second one when all returns are
that consider returns of used products that are repurposed via re- remanufactured under negligible lead time. Moreover, the modeling of
manufacturing or recycling (see, for example, Fleischmann and Kuik, dependence between returns and product sales/demand is common to
2003, Benedito and Corominas, 2013). Another stream of literature both streams which is at the core of this paper.
focuses on commercial returns: These items can be sold as new products The first stream includes papers focusing on hybrid manufacturing,
after minimal processing (see, for example, Kiesmüller and Van der remanufacturing, and disposal processes. Demand and return distribu-
Laan, 2001 and Zerhouni et al., 2013). We contribute to the latter tions are mostly assumed to be independent across periods and a net
stream of literature by incorporating the dependency of returns on demand approach is followed. Only a handful of these papers assume
previous sales. Specifically, we assume that product returns are stochas- that demand and returns are correlated albeit within the same period.
tically dependent on the previous period’s sales quantity. In our model, The papers in this stream could be further grouped based on the type
we maximize a retailer’s expected total revenue less the costs of fixed of inventory review.
order, procurement, backorder, holding, and salvage incurred during a The first group of papers studies continuous review policies. Hey-
finite horizon. man (1977) aims to determine the manufacturing quantity and Heyman
Our main contributions to the existing literature can be summarized (1978) studies an extension where excess returns are sent to a central
as follows: (1) The form of stochastic dependency of returns on the warehouse. In his model, a remanufacturing cycle is initiated when the

2
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Table 1
Detailed comparison of closely related papers.
Return Review Return Solution Unmet Horizon Fixed Lead Demand Return
type type dependency method demand cost time distribution distribution
Simpson (1978) U P DWP DP BO F Generic Generic
Kelle and Silver (1989) C P DAP S NA F * Normal Binomial
Inderfurth (1997) U P DWP DP BO F * Generic Generic
Yuan and Cheung (1998) C C DAP MC/H BO IF * Poisson Exponential
Buchanan and Abad (1998) C P DAP DP BO F Generic (Exp.) Generic (Uni.)
Kiesmüller and Van der Laan (2001) C P DAP MC BO F * Poisson Poisson
Fleischmann and Kuik (2003) U P DWP MC BO IF * * Generic (Poi.) Generic (Poi.)
DeCroix (2006) U P DWP DP BO F * Generic Generic
Mitra (2013) C P DWP S BO IF * Normal Normal
Benedito and Corominas (2013) U P DAP MC/H NA IF Generic Generic (Bin.)
Zerhouni et al. (2013) C C DAP MC/H LS IF Poisson Exponential
Calmon and Graves (2017) U P DWP S/H NA F * Generic Generic
Fu et al. (2019) U P SWP DP LS F Generic (Uni.) Generic (Uni.)
Our Paper C P SAP DP BO/LS F * Generic (Poi.) Binomial

inventory of returned items exceeds a certain value. Simpson (1978) authors compare different return forecasting methods based on the
and Inderfurth (1997) study settings where a customer needs a brand granularity of the return and demand data (e.g., only aggregate, past
new product upon return of an old product that reached its end of period(s) demand, past period(s) return) and find the reorder point
life. Muckstadt and Isaac (1981) extends further by adding positive given the return forecast. Buchanan and Abad (1998) employs dynamic
lead time and fixed order cost under both single and two-echelon programming to solve the similar model of the preceding work under
systems. Fleischmann et al. (2002) revises this work by allowing returns finite horizon. Yuan and Cheung (1998) studies a continuous review (s,
to be added back to inventory upon receipt and show the optimality of S) inventory system for rental products in which stochastic returns are
the conventional (s, Q) inventory policy. A multi-echelon version of the dependent on demand. In a finite period model, Kiesmüller and Van der
problem studied in this group of papers is studied in Mitra (2009). Laan (2001) studies a periodic review inventory system where product
The papers in the second group consider periodic review poli- returns are dependent on demand under positive processing lead time.
cies. Simpson (1978) finds the optimal solution to an 𝑛-period re- Zerhouni et al. (2013) uses Yuan and Cheung (1998)’s model and
pairable return inventory problem. Inderfurth (1997) incorporates pos- compares the demand-dependent return model with an independent
itive lead times to Simpson (1978)’s model. Kiesmüller and Scherer one using a queuing system formulation and investigates the optimality
(2003) suggests effective heuristics to solve the models presented in of base-stock policies.
the preceding two papers. Fleischmann and Kuik (2003) studies the Table 1 provides a taxonomy of the most relevant papers to this
average cost optimality of an (s, S) manufacturing policy with return work. First, we group papers based on the type of returns studied:
flow using net demand in an infinite horizon assuming dependence used product returns (U) and commercial returns (C). In the second
of stochastic demand and returns within the same period. DeCroix column, we group the papers based on the studied inventory control
(2006) extends the first two papers in this group to a serial multi- method e.g., periodic review (P) and continuous review (C). The next
echelon inventory system when remanufactured items flow into the column specifies the return dependency on demand under five clusters:
most upstream stage. Mitra (2013) extends this study with correlated demand dependent within the same period (DWP), demand dependent
demand and returns within the same period. Benedito and Corominas across periods (DAP), sales-dependent within the same period (SWP),
(2013) considers a setting where the amount of returns depends on the and sales-dependent across periods (SAP). In the fourth column, we
useful life of the products sold and the probability of returns. Calmon indicate the employed solution methodology: dynamic programming
and Graves (2017) incorporates positive lead times to Simpson (1978) (DP), Markov Chain modeling (MC), simulation (S), or heuristics (H).
but assumes that unmet demand is outsourced from an external source We also label the unmet demand assumption as backorder (BO), lost
instead of a backorder model. More recently, Fu et al. (2019) studies sales (LS) or an instantaneous outsource supply (NA) in column five.
a two-period model that assumes stochastic dependency of the returns The next one lists whether the model is created under a finite (F) or an
and sales within the same period. infinite horizon (IF). Columns seven and eight denote papers with fixed
Papers in the second stream study inventory control problems under ordering cost or positive processing lead times, respectively, with an
commercial returns. Prior to being sold as new items, the returns are asterisk. The last two columns specify the distributions used to model
added back to inventory either without further processing (e.g., mer- demand and return in the main model and the computational study in
chandise, containers, blood) or sometimes after minimal processing parenthesis.
but lead time or cost involved in such operations is generally ignored. Our most significant contribution to the existing literature is to
Few papers in this stream specifically focus on fashion retailers: Fisher present and study a model with stochastic return flows that depend on
et al. (2001) investigates optimal order quantities under a two-period the actual sales in the previous period. This is a critical extension, as the
newsvendor model assuming a fixed fraction of sales returns to be sold retailer’s ordering decisions now indirectly affect the return quantity
immediately to the consumers. In a single selling season, during when in the following periods. We also incorporate fixed ordering cost in a
a fixed fraction of sales returns, Reimann (2016) studies optimal pre- finite horizon setting, with a detailed terminal period cost structure.
season procurement quantity and evaluates the value of using returns All these modeling choices lead to a rich model setting which translates
to fulfill seasonal demand. into practically relevant conclusions about managing inventories under
Next, we discuss a subset of the papers in the second stream that do return flows.
not necessarily focus on fashion retailers, but those in which demand
and returns are assumed to be dependent across periods as in this 3. Model formulation
paper. Cohen et al. (1980) studies a periodic review inventory system
with recycling in which returns are deterministic and modeled to be We consider a fast-fashion retailer’s finite horizon periodic review
a fixed fraction of demand. The paper assumes lost sales in a finite inventory control problem where the product returns depend on the
horizon with no fixed order cost or lead time. Kelle and Silver (1989) previous period sales quantity. We assume that the retailer has a single
studies a similar model with stochastic returns. Using simulation, the store and focuses on a single item that is allowed to be returned

3
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Table 2 Any excess inventory at the end of a period incurs unit holding cost,
List of notations used in this paper.
ℎ. Similarly, any shortage at the end of a period incurs unit backorder
Parameters
cost, 𝑏.
𝑐 Unit procurement cost We formulate the retailer’s multi-period inventory control problem
𝐾 Fixed ordering cost
ℎ Holding cost per unit per period
using dynamic programming. The state variable at each period 𝑡 has
𝑏 Backorder cost per unit per period two components: the net inventory at the beginning of this period (𝐼𝑡 )
𝑟 Return credit and the sales quantity in the previous period (𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ). Our objective is
𝑠 Salvage value to find the optimal net inventory just after replenishment in each pe-
𝑝 Retail price
𝛼 Return probability
riod, 𝑆𝑡 ∶= 𝐼𝑡 + 𝑂𝑡 , to maximize the expected profit. Using the principle
𝑇 Number of periods in the selling season of optimality, one could write the backward recursive formulation for
Variables the expected total profit-to-go function 𝑃𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) as follows:
𝐼𝑡 Net inventory at the beginning of period 𝑡
𝑃𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) = max {𝑝E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [𝑆𝑄𝑡 ] − 𝑐(𝑆
̄ 𝑡 − 𝐼𝑡 ) − 𝑟E[𝑅𝑡 ] − 𝐽 (𝑆𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 )
𝑂𝑡 Replenishment order in period 𝑡 𝑆𝑡 ⩾𝐼𝑡
𝐷𝑡 Demand realized during period 𝑡
𝑆𝑄𝑡 Sales realized during period 𝑡
+E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [𝑃𝑡+1 (𝐼𝑡+1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡 )]}
𝑅𝑡 Returns received during period 𝑡
(2)
𝑆𝑡 Inventory level just after replenishment order but
before demand and returns in period 𝑡
where the first term is the expected revenue from sales, next two terms
are the ordering costs and return credits and the fourth term is the
current period’s total expected backorder and holding costs which could
within one period upon purchase without any restrictions. The returned be written as:
product is assumed to be in almost perfect condition and is directly put
𝐽 (𝑆𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) = ℎE𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [(𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 )+ ] + 𝑏E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [(𝐷𝑡 − 𝑆𝑡 − 𝑅𝑡 )+ ]. (3)
on the shelf for resale as a new product upon arrival to the store after
minor processing which is assumed to have negligible cost and takes In this paper, we use the notations 𝑥+ ∶= max{0, 𝑥} and 𝑥− ∶=
negligible time. max{0, −𝑥}. During the selling season, the net inventory cannot be
The retailer reviews its net inventory at the beginning of each
salvaged or destroyed. Hence the only constraint on the admissible
period 𝑡, 𝐼𝑡 and gives a replenishment order, 𝑂𝑡 , if necessary. For
inventory policies is that 𝑆𝑡 ≥ 𝐼𝑡 : the net inventory after replenishment
example, Caro and Gallien (2010) discusses that Zara, one of the
cannot be less than the beginning net inventory. Both parts of the state
biggest fast-fashion retailers, replenishes product inventories on a fixed
schedule (i.e., periodic-review inventory policy). We assume that the variable at period 𝑡 + 1, 𝐼𝑡+1 , and 𝑆𝑄𝑡 , depend on demand and return
order is received after a negligible replenishment lead time. On the of period 𝑡. Hence the expectation before the next period’s profit-to-go
manufacturing side, the production and distribution to warehouses function in Eq. (2) is over 𝐷𝑡 and 𝑅𝑡 . Finally, we assume that there is
have to be completed before the selling season. Since assortments are no discounting as the selling season is comparatively short for many
‘‘floor-ready’’ to deliver, with the proper labels, price tags, and hangers, retail products.
there is no production lead time and delivery lead time is negligible The transition of the state variable can be explained in two parts.
(Şen, 2008). Next, product returns, 𝑅𝑡 , are accepted and then demand Given the sequence of events, the net inventory at the beginning of
(𝐷𝑡 ) and resulting sales (𝑆𝑄𝑡 ) are realized. In this paper, we assume period 𝑡 + 1, 𝐼𝑡+1 , can be simply written as 𝐼𝑡+1 = 𝐼𝑡 + 𝑂𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 =
that any unsatisfied demand is backordered without a fulfillment time 𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 . Next, the sales quantity at time 𝑡 can be written as:
limit during the season. With the increasing use of e-commerce chan-
nels along with retail stores, unsatisfied orders are more conveniently 𝑆𝑄𝑡 = min{𝐼𝑡+ + 𝑂𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡− } = min{𝐼𝑡+ + 𝑆𝑡 − 𝐼𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡− }
(4)
backordered as these orders could be taken online and then delivered = min{𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 } + 𝐼𝑡− ,
to the customer (Mahar et al., 2014, Barry, 2019). At the end of the
period, holding or backorder costs are incurred. We assume that the where the first equality follows from the definition of 𝑂𝑡 and the
selling season for this product ends after 𝑇 periods. After the end of the second equality follows from the fact that 𝑥 = 𝑥+ − 𝑥− for any
selling season, either the final shortage is satisfied via final procurement 𝑥 ∈ R. Eq. (4) formulates that the sales quantity of period 𝑡 is the
or the remaining inventory is salvaged. A list of notations is provided minimum of the inventory on-hand plus the replenishment order plus
in Table 2. the returns received and current period’s demand plus the backordered
We assume that the demand across periods, 𝐷𝑡 , is independent, demand quantity from the previous period (i.e., the negative part of net
identically distributed and a discrete random variable with probability inventory).
mass function 𝑓 (𝑥) and mean 𝜇. Customers pay a stationary unit price At the end of the selling season, which is denoted by period 𝑇 + 1,
of 𝑝 to purchase the product. Each sold product in period 𝑡 is assumed any excess inventory is salvaged at a unit profit of 𝑠 and any shortage
to be returned in period 𝑡 + 1 with probability 𝛼. The return period for is purchased and delivered to the customers. During end-of-season
a backordered item starts with the fulfillment of this order. We assume operations, inventories of all product types are reviewed together, final
that return probability is independent of the sales period, but our model orders are placed for backordered items, and unsold merchandise is sent
can be extended to incorporate nonidentical return probabilities across
back to the warehouse. Thus a fixed ordering cost would be incurred
sales periods. Given the previous period sales 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 , one could deduce
independent of this particular product. We ignore this constant term in
that; 𝑅𝑡 , follows a binomial distribution with parameters 𝛼 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 .
our objective function (i.e., fixed cost for this last order is excluded).
Immediately upon the receipt of a return, the retailer is obliged to pay
the return credit, 𝑟, back to the customer. It is trivial to extend our This assumption is consistent with the vast literature on inventory
model to incorporate nonzero unit return processing cost by simply management (see, for example, Porteus 1971, Chen and Simchi-Levi
increasing the value of 𝑟 accordingly. 2003, Wagner et al., 1965, Chen et al., 2012, Canyakmaz et al., 2019).
The retailer begins the initial period with zero inventory. Then the We account for any returns of the satisfied backordered demand after
total cost of ordering in any period has two parts: unit procurement the end of the season by including the return credit and the salvage
cost, 𝑐, and fixed ordering cost, 𝐾. Thus, the total cost of ordering 𝑂𝑡 profit due to these returns. Thus the terminal expected profit could be
units is denoted by 𝑐̄ and can be stated as follows: written as follows:
{
𝐾 + 𝑐𝑂𝑡 if 𝑂𝑡 > 0, 𝑃𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) = 𝑝(𝐼𝑇 +1 )− + 𝑠E𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+ ]
̄ 𝑡) =
𝑐(𝑂 (1) (5)
0 otherwise. −𝑐E𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ] − 𝑟E[𝑅𝑇 +1 ] + 𝛼(𝑠 − 𝑟)(𝐼𝑇 +1 )−

4
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

In this equation, each term accounts for the following: profit from the Proposition 3. Let 𝐾 = 0 and 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠. Then the following statements hold:
backordered items, salvage from the leftover inventory, final procure-
ment cost to fulfill backordered demand, and the return credit. The last (i) 𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) is submodular on (𝐼𝑇 , −𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ).
term accounts for the products that are sold and then returned back at (ii) Let 𝑆𝑇∗ (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) be the set of optimal order-up-to levels. Then
the end of the selling season. 𝑆𝑇∗ (.) is nondecreasing in 𝐼𝑇 and nonincreasing in 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 .

Using Propositions 1 and 2, it is trivial to show that the following


4. Structure of the optimal profit and inventory policy corollary is true:

In this section, we present some analytical results based on the


Corollary 1. Let 𝐾 = 0 and 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠. Then the following statements hold:
formulated problem. First, we provide an alternative cost-centric for-
mulation and show that these two formulations are equivalent. Next, (i) 𝑃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) is supermodular on (𝐼𝑇 , −𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ).
we provide some monotonicity properties of the profit-to-go func- (ii) Let 𝑆𝑇∗ (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) be the set of optimal order-up-to levels in the
tion. Finally, the structure of the optimal inventory policy is analyzed profit-centric formulation. Then 𝑆𝑇∗ (.) is nondecreasing in 𝐼𝑇 and
utilizing the alternative formulation. nonincreasing in 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 .
We choose a profit-centric approach in this paper. Alternatively, one
could follow a more traditional cost-centric formulation and study the Corollary 1 shows that the optimal net inventory after replen-
optimal inventory policy of the retailer that minimizes total expected ishment is non-decreasing in the net beginning inventory and non-
cost. Specifically, one could use a dynamic programming formulation increasing in the sales quantity of the previous period. The former
using cost-to-go and terminal cost functions as stated below: result is expected given the zero fixed ordering cost assumption and
indestructibility of net inventory. The latter result also holds since a
𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) = min {𝑐(𝑆
̄ 𝑡 − 𝐼𝑡 ) + 𝑟E[𝑅𝑡 ] + 𝐽 (𝑆𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 )
𝑆𝑡 ⩾𝐼𝑡 higher level of sales quantity in the previous period implies a higher
(6)
+E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [𝐶𝑡+1 (𝐼𝑡+1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡 )]}, number of possible returns in the current period. This structural result
is quite substantial: One could utilize this result to find the optimal
𝐶𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) = 𝑐E𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ] − 𝑠E𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+ ] inventory decisions more quickly by narrowing down the search space
+𝑟E[𝑅𝑇 +1 ] + 𝛼(𝑟 − 𝑠)(𝐼𝑇 +1 )− using the optimal decisions for adjacent values of the state variables.
The structural results hold under two assumptions. Nonzero fixed
(7)
ordering cost could lead the cost-to-go function to be non-submodular.
Next, we show that these two formulations are basically equivalent. The assumption of 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠 is satisfied for cases worth studying: Otherwise,
it is optimal to procure a very large quantity in the last period and
Proposition 1. Given any state variable pairs 𝐼𝑡 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 the profit-to-go salvage them at the end of the selling season for profit. Unfortunately,
and cost-to-go functions of the two formulations stated in Eq. (6),(7) and we could not extend the results to other periods in the selling season,
(2),(5) have the following relationship: which requires convexity of the cost-to-go function which may not hold
for many cases. Hence we resort to numerical experiments to analyze
𝑃𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) = 𝑝 (𝜇 (𝑇 − 𝑡 + 1) + 𝐼𝑡− ) − 𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ), ∀1 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 . (8) the structure of the optimal policy for interim periods under nonzero
All the proofs are relegated to Appendix. Proposition 1 implies that fixed ordering cost.
for each period 𝑡, the profit-to-go function is equal to total revenue
from the expected demand during the remainder of the selling season 5. Computational results
and any backordered demand from previous periods less the cost-to-go
function for all values of the net inventory and previous period sales In this section, we present the results of an extensive numerical
quantity. Hence the optimal ordering decisions are exactly the same study to better understand and quantify the results of our proposed
under both formulations for any state variable pairs 𝐼𝑡 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 . In model. First, we study the structure of the optimal inventory control
particular, one can easily deduce that 𝑃1 (0, 0) = 𝑝 𝜇 𝑇 − 𝐶1 (0, 0). This policy using the model proposed in Section 3. Then, we discuss the
implies that, due to our assumption of backordered unmet demand, one value of incorporating detailed return flow into the retailer’s inventory
could easily find the optimal expected profit by subtracting the optimal control problem and how the problem parameters affect this value.
expected total cost from the revenue of expected total demand during We refer to the retailer that uses our proposed model in managing
the selling season. her inventory as the ‘‘return-smart’’ retailer who keeps detailed records
One can show that the optimal profit-to-go function is monotone in of sales and returns and considers item returns as dependent on the
the return probability. previous period sales. As a benchmark, we also consider an alternative
retailer who does not track previous period sales explicitly, ignores the
Proposition 2. Assume that 𝑟 ⩾ 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑟 ⩾ 𝑏. Given any state dependency of the return flow on sales and instead simply uses a net
variables 𝐼𝑡 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 , the profit-to-go function is decreasing in the return demand approach (i.e., considers only the product demand less the
probability. returns). For this ‘‘return-naive’’ retailer, it is known that the optimal
As expected, the profit is decreasing as customers have a higher like- inventory control policy is a traditional (𝑠, 𝑆) policy where an order is
lihood of returning products. Proposition 2 requires some parametric given to increase net inventory to 𝑆 only if the net inventory is less
assumptions, which simply eliminates trivial cases: The return credit than or equal to 𝑠 (see, for example, Porteus, 1971).
is more than the product cost, which in turn is larger than the salvage In this computational study, we assume that the demand for each
value. Similarly, the per unit and per period backorder cost is also lower period follows Poisson distribution with mean 𝜆𝐷 . The return-smart
than the return credit. Following the same logic in the proof, one can retailer considers that each sold item could be returned in the next
trivially show that the profit is also decreasing in all the cost parameters period with probability 𝛼. On the other hand, the return-naive retailer
(𝑐, 𝐾, ℎ, 𝑏) and increasing in the salvage value. simply uses the net demand in managing the inventory. In our case, one
We now present analytical results on the structural properties of the can show that the net demand follows Poisson distribution with mean
optimal inventory policy. In the rest of this section, we assume that (1 − 𝛼)𝜆𝐷 .
there is no fixed ordering cost and there are only two periods: one For the rest of this paper, we consider a particular parameter set,
selling period and one terminal period. called the base case scenario, to study the differences between the
The next proposition provides structural results on the optimal inventory control policies and profits of return-smart and return-naive
inventory policy for the last period: retailers. The parameters are set following Mitra (2009) which also

5
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

considers an inventory system with product returns. Since retail price higher fixed order cost due to increased order frequency to compensate
is not used in Mitra (2009), we set the value for this parameter as for the increased backorders. We also find similar observations for
twice the procurement cost, implying 50% unit profit margin which the order level in the first period: The return-smart retailer orders
is common for retailers. The mean of the Poisson distribution is taken 8 units whereas the return-naive retailer orders only 6 units. Later
as 𝜆𝐷 = 4 and 𝛼 = 0.50, hence the return-naive retailer uses the net on, whenever the inventory decreases below the re-order point, the
demand with mean (1 − 𝛼)𝜆𝐷 = 2. Since the support of the Poisson return-naive retailer always orders less compared to the return-smart
distribution is unbounded, we truncate the demand from a level such retailer.
that the cumulative probability exceeds 0.9972. We assume that each Given the effect of net inventory level on inventory decisions, next
period lasts a month and that there are 4 periods in a season (𝑇 = 4). we investigate the effect of previous period sales. By definition, the
Inventory holding cost rate is taken as 5% per unit per month, 𝑏 = $20 return-naive retailer does not use this information. For the return-smart
per unit per month, 𝐾 = $25 per order, 𝑐 = $40 per unit, and 𝑝 = $80 retailer, Fig. 2 shows the optimal inventory levels after ordering in
per unit. We also assume that there is no salvage value at the end of the period 2 as a function of the net inventory level before ordering and the
period (𝑠 = 0) and the customer is given full credit for returns and any previous period sales. Notice that the values in the first column of Fig. 2
related processing cost is ignored (𝑟 = 𝑝). In Section 5.3, we provide an are also presented in the left part of Fig. 1 with 𝑆𝑄1 = 0. Fig. 2 presents
analysis on the sensitivity of our results on this base case scenario. optimal order-up-to levels for all values of 𝑆𝑄1 . In the gray shaded
area (bottom right) no replenishment order is given. In the white area,
5.1. Analysis of the optimal inventory control policy the return-smart retailer places a positive replenishment order. For a
fixed net inventory level, the order quantity decreases monotonically in
We calculate the optimal inventory decisions for the return-smart the previous period sales. The amount of returns in the current period
retailer using our proposed model and also for the return-naive retailer increases stochastically in the previous sales quantity; thus the retailer
following Porteus (1971). The calculation for the return-smart retailer orders less expecting a larger number of returns.
follows a backwards solution approach: We solve for the optimal in-
ventory decision of the last period, keep the optimal values in a
5.2. Value of using sales-dependent returns
matrix, then solve for the previous period. Since the demand follows
Poisson distribution we evaluate only the integer valued decisions. This
In this section, we quantify the value of considering sales-dependent
procedure continues in a recursive fashion. For each period and each
returns in making inventory decisions. Specifically, we calculate the
state, we calculate the value of the objective function for each possible
improvement in the profit of the return-smart retailer versus the return-
inventory level after ordering (between the lower bound of current
naive one. Given the optimal inventory decisions of both retailers as
net inventory and the upper bound of remaining periods times the
discussed in the previous subsection, we evaluate the expected profit
maximum demand per period) and record the one that yields the best
of both retailers using the same Monte-Carlo simulation. The Monte-
value (i.e., exhaustive search).
Carlo simulation generates a random demand value for each period
For the base case scenario, the optimal inventory decisions in period
in the horizon and using each retailer’s inventory policy, evaluates
2 for both types of retailers are presented in Fig. 1 given that the
the resulting average total profit across simulation runs. Clearly, the
previous period sales are equal to zero. Let us first compare the form of
expected profit of the return-smart retailer is asymptomatically the
the optimal policies. As expected, the return-naive retailer follows an
same if one uses simulation instead of the dynamic programming model
(𝑠, 𝑆) policy where she places an order only if the net inventory is below
or equal to 1 (i.e., re-order point 𝑠 = 1) and increases the inventory to of Section 3. Our dynamic programming formulation could be used
4 (i.e., order-up-to level 𝑆 = 4). On the other hand, the return-smart for the return-naive retailer as well, however we specifically employ
retailer does not follow an (𝑠, 𝑆) type inventory policy. She places an simulation to be able to calculate the components of the total profit and
order only if the inventory level is below or equal to 4, however, the better understand the underlying factors for differences in the profits.
order-up-to level is not constant for all values of the net inventory. To minimize any variation due to the generated random numbers,
When the net inventory is below zero (i.e., there is positive backorder we use identical random demand values while running simulations.
from previous periods), the order-up-to level decreases as the number Finally, we compare the evaluated total profit of the return-smart
of backorders increases. This could be seen as counter-intuitive at first retailer for the whole season to that of the return-naive one, assuming
sight as the retailer could be expected to order more especially when zero initial inventory. In this subsection, we use the base case scenario
the backordered demand is high. However, the return-smart retailer parameters and conduct a one-way sensitivity analysis in the next
knows that each fulfilled backordered demand is going to turn into sales subsection.
in the current period which then could be returned with probability 𝛼 In our Monte Carlo simulation, we determine to use 100,000 sam-
in the next period. Thus she reduces the order size taking into account ples. After 10 replications, we find that the standard deviation of the
the higher number of possible returns from these fulfilled backordered return-smart retailer is $0.37(𝐶𝑉 = 0.0029), supporting our choice of the
demand. Using the same logic, the return-smart retailer keeps the order- number of samples. Even though both retailers face the same demand
up-to level constant when there is no backordered demand as each realization (i.e., same random numbers), they order according to their
product in the inventory has to be first sold and then returned, a lower separate inventory control policies. Thus they may have different sales
probability event, in order to be used in fulfilling demand in future and return quantities in each period and eventually different total
periods. profits from each other.
Comparing the inventory levels below which an inventory order For the base case scenario, Table 3 provides the total expected prof-
is given, we observe that the return-smart retailer places an order its of both retailers as well as their cost breakdowns. It has four sections:
whenever the net inventory is at or below 4 which is much smaller for The first section shows a breakdown of the total cost during the selling
the corresponding threshold with the return-naive retailer (i.e., 1). This season into procurement, ordering, holding, and backorder costs. The
is because the return-smart retailer expects a higher demand rate of 4 next section presents the costs incurred after the selling season ends
assuming no returns will arrive in period 2 as 𝑆𝑄1 = 0. However, the that include the final purchasing cost of remaining backorders, the
return-naive retailer ignores the sales-dependency of the returns and return credits for these fulfilled backorders, the salvage value of on-
expects a lower net demand rate of 0.5 ∗ 4 = 2. This phenomenon also hand inventory, if any; after the remaining backorders are fulfilled and
results in the return-naive retailer ordering less (4) than the return- the sales revenue of the fulfilled backorders. The third section displays
smart retailer (7) when she orders and there is no backorder. Thus the net revenue after the returns are credited from the total revenue
we expect the return-naive retailer to have higher backorder costs and during the selling season. Finally, in the last section, we deduct both

6
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Fig. 1. The optimal order-up-to levels of both retailers for the base case scenario at period 2 (𝑆𝑄1 = 0).

Fig. 2. The optimal order-up-to levels of the return-smart retailer for the base case scenario at period 2 as the previous period sales quantity varies.

Table 3
Total profit breakdowns for both retailer types using base case scenario.
Retailers Procurement Ordering Holding Backorder Total Season End-of-Season Season Return Season Net Total
cost cost cost cost cost cost revenue credit revenue profit
B1 B2 B3 B4 B=B1+B2+B3+B4 C A1 A2 A=A1-A2 A-B-C
Return-naive 398.69 50.39 12.77 50.69 512.54 113.14 1180.48 452.22 728.26 102.59
Return-smart 380.23 36.57 17.13 46.88 480.80 97.96 1161.86 456.58 705.28 126.52

total season and end-of-season costs from the net revenue to find the optimal inventory policy derived from this approach under stochastic
total profit of each retailer. sales-dependent returns results in a much lower expected profit of
Table 3 shows that the return-smart retailer has a significant 23% $102.45 which is 53.21% lower than the evaluated optimal profit.
increase in profit compared to the return-naive one. The latter retailer However, this discrepancy does not exist for the return-smart retailer
has higher costs in all categories except the holding cost. The under- since she considers returns in evaluating the optimal profit. This level
lying reason for this observation stems from the optimal inventory of overestimation would be problematic for many reasons including
decisions studied in the previous subsection: The return-naive retailer budget planning. Thus another advantage of our model is the correct
never considers the incoming returns and orders more frequently in evaluation of the actual profit resulting from a chosen inventory control
smaller quantities. The total order quantity during the season is also strategy.
slightly (5%) higher. However, the timing of these orders is not perfect:
The return-naive retailer faces more backorders leading to slightly a
5.3. Sensitivity analysis
lower product fill rate (87%) compared to the return-smart retailer
(89%) as expected. The return-smart retailer orders fewer units at the
right time since she considers the possible returns and treats them as For the base case scenario, we find that the value of incorporating
a secondary supply source. Moreover, the return-naive retailer has to sales-dependent returns in finding the optimal inventory policy is 23%.
satisfy a higher number of backorders at the end of the season and then In this section, we first present a one-way sensitivity analysis on this
has to pay for any return credits associated with these sales without value with respect to problem parameters. For each parameter, we
being able to resell. modify the number used in the base case scenario and report the change
On a final note, we observe that the return-naive retailer, which in the percentage difference in the retailers’ profits. Then, we show the
uses the net demand approach (i.e., considers only the product demand results of a full factorial experiment.
less the returns), evaluates her optimal profit as $218.95 using the as- Fig. 3 provides the results of sensitivity analysis with respect to
sociated dynamic programming formulation. However, simulating the the fixed order cost. As expected both retailers’ profits decrease as the

7
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Fig. 3. % profit improvement of incorporating sales-dependent returns as the fixed order cost varies.

fixed cost increases. However, the decrease in the return-naive retailer’s Table 4
% profit improvement in the retailer’s profit as procurement cost, holding cost, and
profit is steeper as this retailer orders more frequently as compared
salvage value parameters vary.
to the return-smart one. The value of incorporating sales-dependent
Parameter Instance set Min Med Max
returns increases to about 70% when the fixed cost increases to 50$.
Procurement unit cost [10,15, . . . ,45] 3% 9% 52%
The effect of the backorder cost on the value of incorporating sales-
Holding cost [1%,2%, . . . ,6%] 23% 27% 29%
dependent returns is shown in Fig. 4. There are two main observations: Salvage value [0,10, . . . ,40] 4% 15% 23%
(1) When the backorder cost is as low as the holding cost (i.e., ℎ = 𝑏 =
$2), the return-naive retailer places no order in the first period 𝑡o save
from the fixed order cost. As a result, she does not sell any products
in the first period and loses the opportunity of incoming returns in The resulting service levels could be a separate concern for the re-
the second period. On the other hand, the return-smart retailer places tailer. Table 5 shows the percentage difference in the cycle service level
(type I) and the product fill rate (type II) as the problem parameters
a positive initial order and uses the returns in the following periods
vary. The percentage differences in both service level measures are
as a second source of supply resulting in a 36% profit gap between
most sensitive to the backorder cost as expected from our earlier results.
the two retailers’ profits. (2) When the backorder cost is quite large,
Moreover, the return-naive retailer has better service levels (i.e., the
the return-naive retailer orders more frequently than necessary to
percentage difference is negative) when 𝛼 ≤ 0.2 at the expense of higher
save from backorder cost. Thus she incurs high fixed order cost and
costs, but both the service level and the profit are smaller for larger
the percentage profit improvement of incorporating sales-dependent
values of the return probability.
returns could be as high as 90%. For moderate values of the backorder
To assess the robustness of our one-way sensitivity results, we
cost, the percentage profit difference is lower.
design a full factorial experiment with 69.984 instances varying all
The significant effect of the return probability is evident from
parameters. However, some of the parameter value combinations result
Fig. 5 which shows the percentage change in the retailer’s profit as
in very small or even negative profits for the retailers. Thus, we
the return probability (𝛼) varies. The value of incorporating sales-
removed 4488 instances which results in an operating margin of less
dependent returns increases monotonically with 𝛼: With higher values
than 10%. Three statistics for each parameter are reported in Table 6,
of the return probability, the return-naive retailer chooses a lower which support our conclusions from the one-way sensitivity results:
initial order quantity expecting a lower net demand. However, the Return rate has the highest impact on the percentage improvement in
actual demand is much higher in the first period which leads to high retailer’s profit, while salvage value and the holding cost rate have very
backorder costs, low sales, and low returns in each period which ends little effect. The average improvement monotonically increases with the
with a loss at the end of the season. fixed ordering cost and the procurement cost. When the procurement
We conduct an additional one-way sensitivity analysis for the re- cost is very large (𝑐 = 45), however, the improvement slightly drops
maining cost parameters and the results are presented in Table 4. Three since the profit margin in these instances is the smallest. Finally, the
statistics (minimum, median, and maximum) for % improvement are average improvement is highest when the backorder cost is very small
presented for each parameter as the value of that parameter changes in or high.
the given interval while keeping the others at base values. As the pro-
curement cost increases, the percentage improvement in the retailer’s 6. Extension: Lost sales case
profit reaches 52%. As the profit margin decreases with the higher pro-
curement cost, the return-naive retailer has difficulty in controlling the Our main formulation introduced in Section 3 assumes that unmet
comparatively higher fixed order costs. Since the total holding cost is demand is backordered in line with most of the related literature in
the lowest cost category (see Table 3), the percentage improvement in this field. For online sales, this assumption is even more plausible
the retailer’s profit varies only slightly as the holding cost rate increases (see, for example, Mahar and Wright, 2009, Bretthauer et al., 2010,
from 0.5% to 4%. Finally, we find that the percentage improvement and Mahar et al., 2012). However, an alternative assumption would be
decreases with the salvage value. However, the return-smart retailer’s to assume that any unmet demand is lost (see references in Table 1).
profit is still 4% higher than the return-naive retailer even when the Hence in this section, we revisit our research question under the lost
salvage value is the same as the procurement cost. sales assumption.

8
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Fig. 4. % profit improvement of incorporating sales-dependent returns as the backorder cost varies.

Fig. 5. % profit improvement of incorporating sales-dependent returns as the return probability varies.

Table 5
The percentage difference in the service levels as the problem parameters vary.
Parameter Instance Type I Type II
Min Med Max Min Med Max
Procurement unit cost [10,15, . . . ,45] −3% −2% 9% 2% 3% 3%
Holding cost [1%,2%, . . . ,6%] −4% −2% 3% 2% 3% 4%
Backorder cost [8,14, . . . ,50] −7% −3% 8% 1% 3% 8%
Fixed order cost [10,15, . . . ,50] −8% 1% 2% 1% 4% 4%
Return probability [10%,20%, . . . ,60%] −6% −3% 5% 0% 2% 5%
Salvage value [0,10, . . . ,40] −5% −2% 8% 2% 3% 3%

Under the lost sales assumption, the transition of the state variable The profit-to-go functions of the dynamic programming formulation
comprising of the net inventory at the start of period 𝑡 + 1 and the also require some modifications. First, expected unmet demand should
previous sales quantity at period 𝑡 + 1 could be written as follows: be multiplied by the lost sales cost. For our base case scenario, we
assume that the lost sales cost is zero to focus on the effect of losing
𝐼𝑡+1 = (𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 )+ (9)
sales revenue. Moreover, the terminal profit function is also modified
such that it includes only the salvage value of the ending inventory and
𝑆𝑄𝑡 = min{𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 } (10) the credits issued for the returns of the products sold in the last period.

9
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Table 6
The statistics for the % profit improvement in the retailer’s profit in the full factorial experiment.
Backorder cost 2 8 14 20 26 32 38 44 50
10th Percentile 0.2% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%
Average 8.8% 5.3% 5.5% 5.9% 6.2% 6.4% 6.5% 6.6% 6.7%
90th Percentile 24.7% 14.9% 15.6% 16.5% 17.7% 18.3% 18.6% 18.7% 19.4%
Fixed order cost 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
10th Percentile 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%
Average 4.7% 5.0% 5.4% 5.9% 6.5% 6.9% 7.5% 7.9% 8.3%
90th Percentile 12.9% 13.9% 15.2% 16.4% 18.4% 19.8% 21.3% 22.9% 24.0%
Procurement unit cost 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
10th Percentile 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%
Average 2.5% 2.8% 4.3% 5.2% 7.7% 7.7% 8.4% 7.3%
90th Percentile 7.6% 7.9% 12.4% 14.3% 21.6% 22.0% 25.8% 21.3%
Return rate 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60
10th Percentile 0.0% 0.2% 0.5% 1.4% 3.2% 6.8%
Average 0.2% 0.8% 2.3% 5.7% 11.9% 22.8%
90th Percentile 0.4% 1.4% 4.4% 11.5% 25.9% 47.9%
Holding cost rate 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06
10th Percentile 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%
Average 6.2% 6.3% 6.3% 6.5% 6.6% 6.7%
90th Percentile 17.6% 17.7% 18.0% 18.6% 18.8% 18.7%
Salvage value 0 10 20 30 40
10th Percentile 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1%
Average 7.0% 6.2% 6.2% 6.1% 6.0%
90th Percentile 19.4% 17.4% 17.7% 17.8% 18.1%

Table 7
Total profit breakdowns for both retailer types using the base case scenario and the lost sales assumption.
Retailers Procurement Ordering Holding Total season End-of-season Season Return Season net Total
cost cost cost cost cost revenue credit revenue profit
B1 B2 B3 B=B1+B2+B3 C A1 A2 A=A1-A2 A-B-C
Return-naive 407.24 55.48 16.73 479.45 130.70 1,154.88 446.61 708.27 98.12
Return-smart 321.44 25.30 16.00 362.74 87.20 1,031.80 428.73 603.08 153.14

Under the base case scenario, our numerical results show that the Table 8
% improvement in the retailer’s profit as the problem parameters vary assuming unmet
return-smart retailer now follows an (s,S) inventory policy as well.
demand is lost.
The (𝑠, 𝑆) values of the return-smart retailer depend on the previous
Parameter Instance Min Med Max
sales quantity since she considers the return flow as a second source
Procurement unit cost [10,15, . . . ,45] 4% 14% 128%
of supply and decreases its orders as the previous period sales increase. Holding cost [1%,2%, . . . ,6%] 39% 48% 60%
During period 2, she follows a (3,6) inventory policy when 𝑆𝑄1 = 0 but Fixed order cost [10,15, . . . ,50] 23% 44% 71%
switches to using a (1,4) inventory policy when 𝑆𝑄1 ∈ {3, 4}. Similar Return probability [10%,20%, . . . ,60%] 0% 12% 126%
to our findings with the main model, we find that the return-naive Salvage value [0,10, . . . ,40] 3% 17% 56%

retailer orders fewer quantities compared to the return-smart retailer.


For example, she uses a (2,5) inventory policy in the second period.
Comparing with the main model, the return-naive retailer has higher in Section 5.3, there is a significant increase in the variation of the
(𝑠, 𝑆) values under lost sales setting, pointing towards a possible reason percentage improvement.
for lower profit. Finally, we investigate the effect of a positive lost sales cost on the
Under the lost sales assumption, the return-smart retailer’s profit is percentage profit improvement and present the results in Fig. 6. As the
56% higher using the base case scenario as shown in Table 7. Compared lost sales cost increases moderately from zero, the return-smart retailer
to the 23% profit improvement under the backordered demand setting, slightly increases her order frequency and orders in some periods in
we conclude that the value of incorporating sales-dependent returns is addition to the initial one. Thus the profit gap between the retailers
higher if unmet demand is lost. Notice that the return-naive retailer has decreases. When the lost sales cost is very high, however, the return-
a higher revenue, but the increase in costs more than offsets increase in naive retailer increases order frequency, even more, to not incur high
the revenue. On average the return-naive retailer orders twice, whereas lost sales cost. The return-smart retailer does not react drastically as
the return-smart retailer only orders in the initial period. In addition, she acknowledges possible returns in the subsequent periods. Thus the
the return-naive retailer also orders more units (10) than the return- percentage improvement increases again to more than 70% when the
smart retailer (8) on average. Since the salvage cost is zero, excess lost sales cost is $40.
inventory at the end of the selling season is worthless.
Table 8 shows the results of the one-way sensitivity analysis on the 7. Conclusions
retailer’s percentage improvement in profit as the problem parameters
vary from the base case scenario. The percentage improvement in- We investigate how a return-smart retailer could utilize the product
creases with the procurement unit cost, the holding cost rate, the fixed returns to maximize her total profit over a finite selling season. She
ordering cost, the return probability and decreases with the salvage could use the returns as a second source of supply and thus limit
value. Compared with the results for the backordered demand setting her order frequency and backorders. A comparison with the profit of

10
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Fig. 6. % profit improvement of incorporating sales-dependent returns as the lost sales cost varies.

a return-naive retailer which ignores the dependency of returns on First, return-smart retailers should reconsider their inventory re-
previous sales quantifies the value of incorporating detailed return plenishment decisions by incorporating return flows. For example,
information. Using a base case scenario, we find that the return-smart slightly increasing the initial order sizes, compared to a return-naive
retailer could obtain a 23% higher profit. Our sensitivity analysis shows setting, could be a smart strategy over the rest of the selling season,
that this value could be much higher especially when the fixed ordering especially if the return rate and fixed ordering cost are high. Inflated
cost is high, the backorder cost is very small or high, the return initial order sizes could also be used to identify products with high
probability is high or the procurement unit cost is high. return rates early in the season and react accordingly. Second, retailers
Our results complement the existing literature in the field of inven- could quantify the value of using detailed return information. Our
tory management under commercial returns along multiple directions. proposal requires firms to keep separate meticulous records of both
Most of the papers in this stream assume that returns are demand product sales and returns, which could be costly from IT and labor
dependent, which leads incoming returns to be independent of inven- points of view. Moreover, product return process flows should be
tory management decisions made in previous periods. The stochastic redesigned to collect this additional information. Our results highlight
dependency of returns on the previous sales as assumed in Buchanan when and if incurring these additional costs is worthwhile for the
and Abad (1998) and Benedito and Corominas (2013) translates into retailer.
The results of this paper could alleviate some of the environmental
a dependency of returns and demand, as any unmet demand can be
concerns prominent in the retail sector. After the selling season ends,
satisfied from an external supply source in these papers. In a two-
leftover inventory mostly does not have a salvage value due to rapid
period model for a perishable product, Fu et al. (2019) assumes that
trend changes or seasonal reasons. Hence they could be a costly burden
returns are dependent only on the current period’s sales. In our previous
for the firm even after markdown sales and could eventually end up
sales dependent return model, return quantity is indirectly affected by
in a landfill. According to Constable (2019), five billion pounds of
the retailer’s actions. This fundamental difference in our formulation
returned goods end up in the US landfills each year and this land-
brings forth new insights. For example, our results suggest that raising
fill waste from returns alone contributes 15 million metric tons of
the initial order amount a bit could save fixed ordering costs in the
carbon dioxide to the atmosphere. Our model results in less leftover
following periods due to returns from probabilistically higher amount
inventory (62% in the backorder setting and 87% in the lost sales
of sales in the initial period. The finite horizon model coupled with a
setting) compared to a model that ignores this dependency. Thus our
detailed terminal period cost structure, as compared to zero terminal model could indirectly lower the environmental impact of a retailer
cost assumption used in papers reviewed in Table 2, is another unique by limiting landfill waste. Faced with such a return-smart retailer that
feature of this paper. Under these distinct and realistic elements of treats returns as a second source of supply, the upstream firms are
our model, we quantify the value of incorporating returns in inventory expected to lower their respective orders accordingly which, in turn,
management as in Kelle and Silver (1989), Buchanan and Abad (1998), could decrease the leftover inventory at the rest of the supply chain
and Benedito and Corominas (2013), which is increasing in the return as well. As the retailer could absorb some of the demand variability
rate (Kiesmüller and Van der Laan, 2001; Zerhouni et al., 2013). using returns, the bullwhip effect would be reduced leading to positive
Customers increasingly opt to return products and with the higher impacts on the environmental performance of supply chains (Braz et al.,
share of e-commerce channel sales, the product return rates are rising 2018). Sharing detailed return information with the upstream parties
above 30−50% in some categories. Due to the Covid-19 pandemic, even could further reduce the bullwhip effect.
more, offline sales are substituted by online sales, thus subject to higher Future works to study product returns with detailed operational
return rates. Retailers, specifically those in the fast fashion industry models could expand our understanding of this pressing problem faced
which operates under the main assumptions used in our paper, could by retailers and our work could be extended along several lines. While
benefit from the results shared for two related issues. we focus on the sales-dependency of returns on the most recent period

11
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

sales, another alternative is to model the periods in a finer granu- Following similar steps, one could also expand the cost-to-go function
larity and allow for product return from sales of multiple previous for period 𝑇 as follows:
periods with possibly different return rates. Omnichannel extensions 𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
with different return probabilities and possibly correlated return flow
is another research direction. Since customers often buy multiple, pos- + ℎE𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
sibly substitute, products in each shopping cart, incorporating return + 𝑏𝐸𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝐷𝑇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑅𝑇 )+ ]
information from related products could further improve the inventory + 𝑐 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ] (A.3)
replenishment decisions of the retailers. Finally, non-stationary product +
− 𝑠 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 ) ]
prices could be investigated to deepen our grasp on this problem. All
these extensions, however, would require the design of novel method- + 𝑟𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]
ologies to solve the resulting models such as machine learning-based + 𝛼 (𝑟 − 𝑠)(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− }
approximate dynamic programming approaches.
Let us define
𝑓𝑇 (𝑆𝑇 , 𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) ∶=𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
Data availability + ℎE𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
+ 𝑏𝐸𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝐷𝑇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑅𝑇 )+ ]
No data was used for the research described in the article. + 𝑐 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ] (A.4)
− 𝑠 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+ ]
Acknowledgments + 𝑟𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]
+ 𝛼 (𝑟 − 𝑠)(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− .
This study has been partially supported by the Scientific and Tech- Notice that
nological Research Council of Turkey (TUBITAK) under grant number
(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− + min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } = − min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 , 0}
121M581.
+ min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } = 𝐷𝑇 .
(A.5)
Appendix
Hence Eq. (A.2) could be rewritten as:

Proof of Proposition 1. We will complete the proof in two steps. First, −𝑃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝑓𝑇 (𝑆𝑇 , 𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) − 𝑝E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝐷𝑇 + 𝐼𝑇− ]}
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
we will show that the claim of the proposition holds for 𝑡 = 𝑇 . Next, we
= min {𝑓𝑇 (𝑆𝑇 , 𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 )} − 𝑝(𝜇 + 𝐼𝑇− ) (A.6)
will show that the claim holds for 𝑡 − 1, assuming it holds for 𝑡. These 𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇

two steps ensure that the claim holds ∀1 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 . = 𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) − 𝑝(𝜇 + 𝐼𝑇− ),
Step 1: Using the transition of the state variables 𝐼𝑇 +1 and 𝑆𝑄𝑇 , we where the first equality follows from the fact that the second term
can rewrite the profit-to-go function for period 𝑇 multiplied by −1 as inside the minimization function does not depend on the decision
follows: variable 𝑆𝑇 and the second equality uses the expanded form for the
−𝑃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟E[𝑅𝑇 ] + 𝐽 (𝑆𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) cost-to-go function in Eq. (A.3). Thus completing the proof that the
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇 claim of the proposition holds for 𝑡 = 𝑇 .
− E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝑃𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 )] Step 2: Next we are going to show that the claim holds for period
− 𝑝E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝑆𝑄𝑇 ]} 𝑡 − 1 assuming it holds for period 𝑡. In other words assume that the
following is true for all 𝐼𝑡 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 :
= min {𝑐(𝑆
̄ 𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇 𝑃𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) = 𝑝 (𝜇 (𝑇 − 𝑡 + 1) + 𝐼𝑡− ) − 𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ).
(A.1)
+ ℎE𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
Using this assumption, one could write the profit-to-go function for
+ 𝑏𝐸𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝐷𝑇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑅𝑇 )+ ] period 𝑡 − 1 as:
− E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝑃𝑇 +1 (𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇
−𝑃𝑡−1 (𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) = min {𝑐(𝑆
̄ 𝑡−1 − 𝐼𝑡−1 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2
− 𝐷𝑇 , min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− )] 𝑆𝑡−1 ⩾𝐼𝑡−1

− 𝑝E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]} + ℎE𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [(𝑆𝑡−1 + 𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝐷𝑡−1 )+ ]


+ 𝑏E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [(𝐷𝑡−1 − 𝑆𝑡−1 − 𝑅𝑡−1 )+ ]
Replacing the terminal profit function with Eq. (5) and using
the expectation of the binomial distribution, one can further expand + E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 )]
𝑃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) as: − 𝑝E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [𝜇 (𝑇 − 𝑡 + 1) + 𝐼𝑡− ]

−𝑃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 − 𝑝E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [min{𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 } + 𝐼𝑡− ]}
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
(A.7)
+ ℎE𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
The cost-to-go function for period 𝑡 − 1 is:
+ 𝑏𝐸𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝐷𝑇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑅𝑇 )+ ]
+ 𝑐 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ] 𝐶𝑡−1 (𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) = min {𝑓𝑡−1 (𝑆𝑡−1 , 𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 )}, (A.8)
𝑆𝑡−1 ⩾𝐼𝑡−1
+
− 𝑠 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 ) ] (A.2) where
+ 𝑟𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ] 𝑓𝑡−1 (𝑆𝑡−1 , 𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) ∶=𝑐(𝑆
̄ 𝑡−1 − 𝐼𝑡−1 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2
− 𝛼(𝑠 − 𝑟)E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− ] + ℎE𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [(𝑆𝑡−1 + 𝑅𝑡−1 − 𝐷𝑡−1 )+ ]
(A.9)
− 𝑝E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− + 𝑏E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [(𝐷𝑡−1 − 𝑆𝑡−1 − 𝑅𝑡−1 )+ ]
+ min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]} + E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 )].

12
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Now, using the last two equalities and recalling that 𝐼𝑡 = 𝑆𝑡 +𝑅𝑡 −𝐷𝑡 , Clearly 𝑚𝑖𝑛(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ) ∈ Z and 𝑚𝑖𝑛(−𝑆𝑄1𝑡−1 , −𝑆𝑄2𝑡−1 ) ∈ Z+ .
Eq. (A.7) could be rewritten as: Moreover, we know that 𝑆𝑡1 ⩾ 𝐼𝑡1 and 𝑆𝑡2 ⩾ 𝐼𝑡2 .
Thus 𝑚𝑖𝑛(𝑆𝑡1 , 𝑆𝑡2 ) ⩾ 𝑚𝑖𝑛(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ), which implies that 𝑥1𝑡 ∧ 𝑥2𝑡 ∈ 𝑡 .
−𝑃𝑡−1 (𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) = min {𝑓𝑡−1 (𝑆𝑡−1 , 𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 )
𝑆𝑡−1 ⩾𝐼𝑡−1 Next, consider
− 𝑝(𝜇(𝑇 − 𝑡 + 1) + E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [(𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 )−
𝑥1𝑡 ∨ 𝑥2𝑡 ∶= (𝑚𝑎𝑥(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ), 𝑚𝑎𝑥(−𝑆𝑄1𝑡−1 , −𝑆𝑄2𝑡−1 ), 𝑚𝑎𝑥(𝑆𝑡1 , 𝑆𝑡2 )).
+ min{𝑆𝑡 + 𝑅𝑡 , 𝐷𝑡 } + 𝐼𝑡− ])}
Now, 𝑚𝑎𝑥(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ) ∈ Z and 𝑚𝑎𝑥(−𝑆𝑄1𝑡−1 , −𝑆𝑄2𝑡−1 ) ∈ Z+ .
= min {𝑓𝑡−1 (𝑆𝑡−1 , 𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) − 𝑝(𝜇(𝑇 − 𝑡 + 1)
𝑆𝑡−1 ⩾𝐼𝑡−1 Also, one can conclude that 𝑚𝑎𝑥(𝑆𝑡1 , 𝑆𝑡2 ) ⩾ 𝑚𝑎𝑥(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ), implying
+ E𝐷𝑡−1 ,𝑅𝑡−1 [𝐷𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡− ])} 𝑥1𝑡 ∨ 𝑥2𝑡 ∈ 𝑡 . Since both 𝑥1𝑡 ∧ 𝑥2𝑡 and 𝑥1𝑡 ∨ 𝑥2𝑡 are elements of 𝑡 , we
can conclude that 𝑡 is a lattice. □
= min {𝑓𝑡−1 (𝑆𝑡−1 , 𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 )}
𝑆𝑡−1 ⩾𝐼𝑡−1
Now, we are ready to prove Proposition 3:
− 𝑝(𝜇(𝑇 − 𝑡 + 2) + 𝐼𝑡− )
=𝐶𝑡−1 (𝐼𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−2 ) − 𝑝(𝜇(𝑇 − 𝑡 + 2) + 𝐼𝑡− ), Proof of Proposition 3.
We first rewrite the cost-to-go function using equations (3), (4), (6),
where the third to last equality follows using an equivalent version
and (7):
of Eq. (A.5) for period 𝑡, and the second to last equality follows as
the second part of the minimization function does not depend on the 𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
decision variable 𝑆𝑡−1 , and the last equality is by Eq. (A.8). Thus we
complete the proof that the claim of the proposition holds for period + ℎ E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
𝑡 − 1, assuming it holds for period 𝑡. □ + 𝑏 𝐸𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝐷𝑇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝑅𝑇 )+ ]
+ 𝑐 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )− ]
Proof of Proposition 2. The proof is by induction. Let 𝑡 = 𝑇 + 1.
Following Proposition 1 and the fact that 𝑥− = 𝑥+ − 𝑥, one can write − 𝑠 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+ ]
that + 𝑟𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]
𝑃𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) =𝑝𝐼𝑇−+1 − (𝑐 − 𝑠)E𝑅𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 ) +
− 𝛼(𝑠 − 𝑟)E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− ]}
+ 𝑐(𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) (A.10)
− 𝑟𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 − 𝛼(𝑟 − 𝑠)𝐼𝑇−+1 = min {𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) + 𝑟 𝛼 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
Taking the derivative with respect to 𝛼 yields:
+ (ℎ + 𝑏) E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
𝜕𝑃𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) 𝜕E𝑅𝑇 +1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+
= − (𝑐 − 𝑠) + 𝑏 (𝜇 − 𝑆𝑇 − 𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 )
𝜕𝛼 𝜕𝛼
+ (𝑐 − 𝑠) E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )+ ]
− (𝑟 − 𝑐)𝑆𝑄𝑇 − (𝑟 − 𝑠)𝐼𝑇−+1
− 𝑐 E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 )]
Consider two random variables 𝑅1𝑇 +1 ∼ 𝐵𝑖𝑛(𝛼1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ) and 𝑅2𝑇 +1 ∼
𝐵𝑖𝑛(𝛼2 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 ), where 𝛼1 < 𝛼2 . In this case, 𝑅2𝑇 +1 is first-order stochasti- + 𝑟𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ]
cally dominant over 𝑅1𝑇 +1 , which implies that − 𝛼(𝑠 − 𝑟)E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− ]}

E𝑅1 (𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅1𝑇 +1 )+ ⩽ E𝑅2 (𝐼𝑇 +1 + 𝑅2𝑇 +1 )+ where the last equality follows from using the equation (−𝑎)+ = 𝑎− =
𝑇 +1 𝑇 +1
𝑎+ − 𝑎 for any 𝑎 ∈ R. Now, we derive a set of useful equalities.
Since 𝑟 ⩾ 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠, we deduce that the terminal profit function is decreas-
ing in 𝛼. For the second part of the proof, assume that 𝑃𝑡+1 (𝐼𝑡+1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡 ) (i)
is decreasing in 𝛼 for all 𝐼𝑡+1 and 𝑆𝑄𝑡 , Now, using Proposition 1, E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− ] = 𝑆𝑇 + 𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1
equations (3) and (6) and utilizing the envelope function and dominated
− E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ] + 𝐼𝑇−
convergence theorems, one can show that:
𝜕𝑃𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) 𝜕𝐶𝑡 (𝐼𝑡 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ) (ii)
=−
𝜕𝛼 𝜕𝛼
E[𝑅𝑇 +1 ] =E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [E[𝑅𝑇 +1 |𝐷𝑇 , 𝑅𝑇 ]]
𝜕E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 (𝑆𝑡∗ + 𝑅𝑡 − 𝐷𝑡 )+
= −(𝑟 − 𝑏)𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 − (ℎ + 𝑏) =E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝛼(min{𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 , 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− )]
𝜕𝛼
𝜕𝐶𝑡+1 (𝐼𝑡+1 , 𝑆𝑄𝑡 ) =𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − (𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ + 𝐼𝑇− ]
− E𝐷𝑡 ,𝑅𝑡 [ ]
𝜕𝛼 =𝛼𝑆𝑇 + 𝛼 2 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 − 𝛼E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
The first term is negative as 𝑟 ⩾ 𝑏. Using similar arguments as in part
+ 𝛼𝐼𝑇−
one, it is easy to see that the second term is also negative. Finally, due
to the induction assumption, the last term is also negative. Thus we (iii)
deduce that the profit-to-go function is decreasing in 𝛼. □
E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )− ] = E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
Next, we present Lemma 1, along with its proof, which is used later
− 𝑆𝑇 − 𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 + 𝜇
in the proof of Proposition 3.
Using (i)-(iii) and rearranging terms gives us:
Lemma 1. Let 𝑡 denote the set of feasible states and actions:
𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) = min {𝜇(𝑏 + 𝑐 − 𝛼(𝑠 − 𝑟)) + 𝐼𝑇− 𝛼(𝑟 − 𝑐)
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇
+
𝑡 ∶= {(𝐼𝑡 , −𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 , 𝑆𝑡 ) ∣ 𝐼𝑡 ∈ Z, 𝑆𝑄𝑡−1 ∈ Z , 𝑆𝑡 ⩾ 𝐼𝑡 }.
+ 𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇 − 𝐼𝑇 ) − 𝑆𝑇 (𝑏 + (1 + 𝛼)𝑐 − 𝛼𝑠)
Then 𝑡 is a lattice. + 𝛼𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 (𝑟 − 𝑏 − 𝑐(1 + 𝛼) + 𝛼𝑠)
+ (ℎ + 𝑏 + 𝛼(𝑐 − 𝑠))E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]
Proof of Lemma 1. Let 𝑥1𝑡 , 𝑥2𝑡 be elements of 𝑡 .
Consider + (𝑐 − 𝑠)E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 [(𝑆𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 + 𝑅𝑇 +1 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]}

𝑥1𝑡 ∧ 𝑥2𝑡 ∶= (𝑚𝑖𝑛(𝐼𝑡1 , 𝐼𝑡2 ), 𝑚𝑖𝑛(−𝑆𝑄1𝑡−1 , −𝑆𝑄2𝑡−1 ), 𝑚𝑖𝑛(𝑆𝑡1 , 𝑆𝑡2 )). ∶= min {𝐶̃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 , 𝑆𝑇 )}
𝑆𝑇 ⩾𝐼𝑇

13
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Now, we would like to show that 𝐶̃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 , 𝑆𝑇 ) is submodular References
on 𝑇 . In order to show that, let 𝑥1𝑇 ∶= (𝐼𝑇1 , −𝑆𝑄1𝑇 −1 , 𝑆𝑇1 ) and 𝑥2𝑇 ∶=
AdobeAnalytics, 2020. Adobe digital economy index. URL https://www.adobe.com/
(𝐼𝑇2 , −𝑆𝑄2𝑇 −1 , 𝑆𝑇2 ) be elements of 𝑇 . We need to prove that:
content/dam/www/us/en/experience-cloud/digital-insights/pdfs/adobe_analytics-
digital-economy-index-2020.pdf.
𝐶̃𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) + 𝐶̃𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ) ⩾ 𝐶̃𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝐶̃𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ). (A.11) Barry, Brian, 2019. The true cost of ecommerce backorders. URL https://
multichannelmerchant.com/blog/true-cost-ecommerce-backorders/.
Define 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥𝑇 ) ∶= E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇 +𝑅𝑇 −𝐷𝑇 )+ ] and 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥𝑇 ) ∶= E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 Benedito, Ernest, Corominas, Albert, 2013. Optimal manufacturing policy in a reverse
[(𝑆𝑇 +𝑅𝑇 +𝑅𝑇 +1 −𝐷𝑇 )+ ] where 𝑥𝑇 ∈ 𝑇 and 𝑅𝑇 ∼ 𝐵𝑖𝑛(𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 , 𝛼). Using logistic system with dependent stochastic returns and limited capacities. Int. J.
Prod. Res. 51 (1), 189–201.
the definition of 𝐶̃𝑇 (.) and the fact that 𝑦 + 𝑧 = min(𝑦, 𝑧) + max(𝑦, 𝑧) Bhattarai, Abha, 2020. Sales soar at Walmart and Home Depot during the pandemic.
∀𝑦, 𝑧 ∈ R, rearranging the terms of inequality (.11) gives us: The Washington Post, URL https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/2020/05/
19/walmart-earnings-economy-coronavirus/.
𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇1 − 𝐼𝑇1 ) + 𝑐̄ (𝑆𝑇2 − 𝐼𝑇2 ) + (ℎ + 𝑏 + 𝛼𝑐 − 𝛼𝑠)(𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 )) Braz, Antonio Carlos, De Mello, Adriana Marotti, de Vasconcelos Gomes, Leonardo Au-
+ (𝑐 − 𝑠)(𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 )) ⩾ 𝑐(min(𝑆 1 2 1 2 gusto, de Souza Nascimento, Paulo Tromboni, 2018. The bullwhip effect in
̄ 𝑇 , 𝑆𝑇 ) − min(𝐼𝑇 , 𝐼𝑇 )) closed-loop supply chains: A systematic literature review. J. Clean. Prod. 202,
1 2 1 2
𝑐(max(𝑆
̄ 𝑇 , 𝑆𝑇 ) − max(𝐼𝑇 , 𝐼𝑇 ))
(A.12) 376–389.
Bretthauer, Kurt M., Mahar, Stephen, Venakataramanan, M.A., 2010. Inventory and
+ (ℎ + 𝑏 + 𝛼(𝑐 − 𝑠))(𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ))
distribution strategies for retail/e-tail organizations. Comput. Ind. Eng. 58 (1),
+ (𝑐 − 𝑠)(𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 )). 119–132.
Buchanan, D.J., Abad, P.L., 1998. Optimal policy for a periodic review returnable
Part 1: Without loss of generality, assume that 𝑆𝑇1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑇2 . If −𝑆𝑄1𝑇 −1 ⩽ inventory system. IIE Trans. 30 (11), 1049–1055.
Calmon, Andre P., Graves, Stephen C., 2017. Inventory management in a consumer
−𝑆𝑄2𝑇 −1 , then 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) = 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) and 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ) = 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ). Thus
electronics closed-loop supply chain. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 19 (4), 568–585.
𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ) ⩾ 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ). Canyakmaz, Caner, Özekici, Süleyman, Karaesmen, Fikri, 2019. An inventory model
Otherwise 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧𝑥2𝑇 ) = E𝐷 ,𝑅1 [(𝑆𝑇1 +𝑅2𝑇 −𝐷𝑇 )+ ] and 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨𝑥2𝑇 ) = where customer demand is dependent on a stochastic price process. Int. J. Prod.
𝑇 𝑇 Econ. 212, 139–152.
E𝐷 2 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑅1𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ] where 𝑅𝑖𝑇 ∼ 𝐵𝑖𝑛(𝑆𝑄𝑖𝑇 −1 , 𝛼). Using Klenke and
𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 Caro, Felipe, Gallien, Jérémie, 2010. Inventory management of a fast-fashion retail
Mattner (2010), since 𝑆𝑄1𝑇 −1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑄2𝑇 −1 , we conclude that 𝑅2𝑇 dominates network. Oper. Res. 58 (2), 257–273.
Caro, Felipe, Martínez-de-Albéniz, Victor, 2015. Fast fashion: Business model overview
𝑅1𝑇 under first-order stochastic dominance (FSD).
and research opportunities. In: Retail Supply Chain Management. Springer, pp.
Consider 𝑢𝑇 (𝑥) ∶= E𝐷𝑇 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑥 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ − (𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑥 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ]. Since 237–264.
𝑆𝑇1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑇2 , 𝑢𝑇 (𝑥) is a non-decreasing function. Thus, by Milne and Neave Chen, Youhua, Lu, Ye, Xu, Minghui, 2012. Optimal inventory control policy for
(1994), we can deduce that periodic-review inventory systems with inventory-level-dependent demand. Nav.
Res. Logist. 59 (6), 430–440.
E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅2 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑅2𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )1 − (𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑅2𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ] ⩾ E𝐷𝑇 ,𝑅1 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑅1𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )1 Chen, Xin, Simchi-Levi, David, 2003. Coordinating inventory control and pricing
𝑇 𝑇
strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag.
− (𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑅1𝑇 − 𝐷𝑇 )+ ] 5 (1), 59–62.
Chen, Jing, Venkatadri, Uday, Diallo, Claver, 2019. Optimal (re) manufacturing
which implies that 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) ⩾ 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑊𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ). strategies in the presence of spontaneous consumer returns. J. Clean. Prod. 237,
Part 2: Following similar steps of part 1, we now show that 117642.
Cohen, Morris A., Pierskalla, William P., Nahmias, Steven, 1980. A dynamic inventory
𝑌𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) ⩾ 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ). system with recycling. Nav. Res. Logist. Q. 27 (2), 289–296.
Constable, Harriet, 2019. Your brand new returns end up in landfill. BBC Earth,
Again, without loss of generality, assume that 𝑆𝑇1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑇2 . URL https://www.bbcearth.com/blog/%3Farticle%3Dyour-brand-new-returns-end-
up-in-landfill/.
The case with −𝑆𝑄1𝑇 −1 ⩽ −𝑆𝑄2𝑇 −1 is obvious. For 𝑆𝑄1𝑇 −1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑄2𝑇 −1 ,
DeCroix, Gregory A., 2006. Optimal policy for a multiechelon inventory system with
let 𝑅𝑖𝑇 +1 (𝑥) ∼ 𝐵𝑖𝑛({𝑆𝑇𝑖 + 𝑥, 𝐷𝑇 } + 𝐼𝑇− , 𝛼) for any 𝑥 ∈ Z+ . Define remanufacturing. Oper. Res. 54 (3), 532–543.
Devani, Dev, Coonan, Dan, 2018. Global retail trends. KPMG, URL https://assets.kpmg/
𝑉𝑇 (𝑥) ∶=E𝐷 2 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑥 + 𝑅2𝑇 +1 (𝑥) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑥] content/dam/kpmg/be/pdf/2018/03/Global_Retail_Trends_2018.pdf.
𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1
Ferguson, Mark, Guide Jr., V. Daniel R., Souza, Gilvan C., 2006. Supply chain
− E𝐷 1 [(𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑥 + 𝑅1𝑇 +1 (𝑥) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑥] coordination for false failure returns. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 8 (4), 376–393.
𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1
Fisher, Marshall, Rajaram, Kumar, Raman, Ananth, 2001. Optimizing inventory
Since 𝑆𝑇1 ⩽ 𝑆𝑇2 , 𝑅2𝑇 +1 (𝑥) dominates 𝑅1𝑇 +1 (𝑥) under FSD for any 𝑥 ∈ Z+ . replenishment of retail fashion products. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 3 (3), 230–241.
Fleischmann, Moritz, Bloemhof-Ruwaard, Jacqueline M., Dekker, Rommert, Van der
Thus it is trivial to see that 𝑉𝑇 (𝑥) is a non-decreasing function. Also
Laan, Erwin, Van Nunen, Jo A.E.E., Van Wassenhove, Luk N., 1997. Quantitative
recalling that 𝑅2𝑇 dominates 𝑅1𝑇 under FSD leads to E𝑅2 [𝑉𝑇 (𝑅2𝑇 )] ⩾ models for reverse logistics: A review. European J. Oper. Res. 103 (1), 1–17.
𝑇
E𝑅1 [𝑉𝑇 (𝑅1𝑇 )] which further implies that: Fleischmann, Moritz, Kuik, Roelof, 2003. On optimal inventory control with
𝑇 independent stochastic item returns. European J. Oper. Res. 151 (1), 25–37.
Fleischmann, Moritz, Kuik, Roelof, Dekker, Rommert, 2002. Controlling inventories
E𝑅2 [E𝐷 2 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑅2𝑇 + 𝑅2𝑇 +1 (𝑅2𝑇 ) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑅2𝑇 ]]
𝑇 𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 with stochastic item returns: A basic model. European J. Oper. Res. 138 (1), 63–75.
Fu, Ke, Gong, Xiting, Liang, Guitian, 2019. Managing perishable inventory systems with
− E𝑅2 [E𝐷 1 [(𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑅2𝑇 + 𝑅1𝑇 +1 (𝑅2𝑇 ) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑅2𝑇 ]]
𝑇 𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 product returns and remanufacturing. Prod. Oper. Manage. 28 (6), 1366–1386.
⩾ E𝑅1 [E𝐷 2 [(𝑆𝑇2 + 𝑅1𝑇 + 𝑅2𝑇 +1 (𝑅1𝑇 ) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑅1𝑇 ]] Heyman, Daniel P., 1977. Optimal disposal policies for a single-item inventory system
𝑇 𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 with returns. Nav. Res. Logist. Q. 24 (3), 385–405.
− E𝑅1 [E𝐷 1 [(𝑆𝑇1 + 𝑅1𝑇 + 𝑅1𝑇 +1 (𝑅1𝑇 ) − 𝐷𝑇 )+ |𝑅1𝑇 ]] Heyman, Daniel P., 1978. Return policies for an inventory system with positive and
𝑇 𝑇 ,𝑅𝑇 +1 negative demands. Nav. Res. Logist. Q. 25 (4), 581–596.
Inderfurth, Karl, 1997. Simple optimal replenishment and disposal policies for a product
thus showing that 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ) ⩾ 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∧ 𝑥2𝑇 ) + 𝑌𝑇 (𝑥1𝑇 ∨ 𝑥2𝑇 ). recovery system with leadtimes. Oper.-Res.-Spektrum 19 (2), 111–122.
Using the results obtained in parts 1 and 2, and recalling the Kelle, Peter, Silver, Edward A., 1989. Forecasting the returns of reusable containers. J.
assumptions that 𝐾 = 0 and 𝑐 ⩾ 𝑠, we can conclude that inequality Oper. Manage. 8 (1), 17–35.
(.12) holds completing the proof that 𝐶̃𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 , 𝑆𝑇 ) is submodular Kiesmüller, Gudrun P., Scherer, Carsten W., 2003. Computational issues in a stochastic
finite horizon one product recovery inventory model. European J. Oper. Res. 146
on 𝑇 . (3), 553–579.
Following Topkis (1998), we can thus deduce that the set of optimal Kiesmüller, Gudrun P., Van der Laan, Erwin A., 2001. An inventory model with
net inventory after replenishment decisions, 𝑆𝑇∗ (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ), is non- dependent product demands and returns. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 72 (1), 73–87.
decreasing in 𝐼𝑇 and non-increasing in 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 by definition of 𝑇 in Klenke, Achim, Mattner, Lutz, 2010. Stochastic ordering of classical discrete
distributions. Adv. Appl. Probab. 42 (2), 392–410.
Lemma 1. Moreover, preservation of submodularity under minimiza- Li, Y., Xu, F., Li, X., 2016. Intelligent systems for managing returns in apparel supply
tion (see, Topkis, 1978) implies that 𝐶𝑇 (𝐼𝑇 , 𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ) is also submodular chains. In: Information Systems for the Fashion and Apparel Industry. Elsevier, pp.
on (𝐼𝑇 , −𝑆𝑄𝑇 −1 ). □ 199–219.

14
E. Gökbayrak and E. Kayış International Journal of Production Economics 255 (2023) 108699

Lore, Marc E., 2018. Walmart Inc 2018 Q&A Session with the Investment Community. Schrady, David A., 1967. A deterministic inventory model for reparable items. Nav.
URL https://corporate.walmart.com/media-library/document/2018-shareholders- Res. Logist. Q. 14 (3), 391–398.
q-a-session-with-the-investment-community-transcript/_proxyDocument?id= Şen, Alper, 2008. The US fashion industry: A supply chain review. Int. J. Prod. Econ.
00000163-cb67-db80-a3ff-cb6fe66f0000. 114 (2), 571–593.
Mahar, Stephen, Salzarulo, Peter A., Wright, P. Daniel, 2012. Using online pickup site Shulman, Jeffrey D., Coughlan, Anne T., Savaskan, R. Canan, 2010. Optimal reverse
inclusion policies to manage demand in retail/E-tail organizations. Comput. Oper. channel structure for consumer product returns. Mark. Sci. 29 (6), 1071–1085.
Res. 39 (5), 991–999. Simpson, Vincent P., 1978. Optimum solution structure for a repairable inventory
Mahar, Stephen, Wright, P. Daniel, 2009. The value of postponing online fulfillment problem. Oper. Res. 26 (2), 270–281.
decisions in multi-channel retail/e-tail organizations. Comput. Oper. Res. 36 (11), Smith, Erin Geiger, 2015. How online retailers predict your perfect outfit. The Wall
3061–3072. Street Journal (Last seen 11.11.2019), URL https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-
Mahar, Stephen, Wright, P Daniel, Bretthauer, Kurt M, Hill, Ronald Paul, 2014. online-retailers-predict-your-perfect-outfit-1438794462.
Optimizing marketer costs and consumer benefits across ‘‘clicks’’ and ‘‘bricks’’. J. Topkis, Donald M., 1978. Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Oper. Res.
Acad. Marketing Sci. 42 (6), 619–641. 26 (2), 305–321.
Milne, Frank, Neave, Edwin H., 1994. Dominance relations among standardized Topkis, Donald M., 1998. Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton University
variables. Manage. Sci. 40 (10), 1343–1352. Press.
Mitra, Subrata, 2009. Analysis of a two-echelon inventory system with returns. Omega Ülkü, M. Ali, Gürler, Ülkü, 2018. The impact of abusing return policies: A newsvendor
37 (1), 106–115. model with opportunistic consumers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 203, 124–133.
Mitra, Subrata, 2013. Periodic review policy for a two-echelon closed-loop inventory Wagner, H.M., et al., 1965. Computing optimal (s, S) inventory policies. Manag. Sci.
system with correlations between demands and returns. Opsearch 50 (4), 604–615. 11, 525–552.
Mostard, Julien, Teunter, Ruud, 2006. The newsboy problem with resalable returns: A Wen, Xin, Choi, Tsan-Ming, Chung, Sai-Ho, 2019. Fashion retail supply chain
single period model and case study. European J. Oper. Res. 169 (1), 81–96. management: A review of operational models. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 207, 34–55.
Muckstadt, John A., Isaac, Michael H., 1981. An analysis of single item inventory Winkler, Nick, 2021. When you returned gifts after the holidays last year, when did
systems with returns. Nav. Res. Logist. Q. 28 (2), 237–254. you return the gifts?. https://www.shopify.com/, URL https://https://www.shopify.
Narang, Unnati, Shankar, Venkatesh, 2019. Mobile app introduction and online and com/enterprise/how-to-reduce-post-holiday-returns.
offline purchases and product returns. Mark. Sci. 38 (5), 756–772. Yuan, Xue-Ming, Cheung, Ki Ling, 1998. Modeling returns of merchandise in an
O’Connell, Liam, 2020. Retail market worldwide - Statistics and Facts. Statista, URL inventory system. Oper.-Res.-Spektrum 20 (3), 147–154.
https://www.statista.com/topics/5922/retail-market-worldwide/. Zerhouni, Hichem, Gayon, Jean-Philippe, Frein, Yannick, 2013. Influence of dependency
Porteus, Evan L., 1971. On the optimality of generalized (s, S) policies. Manage. Sci. between demands and returns in a reverse logistics system. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 143
17 (7), 411–426. (1), 62–71.
Reimann, Marc, 2016. Accurate response with refurbished consumer returns. Decis. Sci.
47 (1), 31–59.

15

You might also like