You are on page 1of 16

48(11) 2339–2354, August 2011

Information and Communication


Technologies and the Geographical
Concentration of Manufacturing
Industries: Evidence from China
Junjie Hong and Shihe Fu
[Paper first received, December 2009; in final form, August 2010]

Abstract
Using the 2004 China economic census database, this paper examines the impact of
information and communication technologies (ICT) on the geographical concentration
of manufacturing industries, controlling for a broad set of other determinants of
industrial agglomeration. Contrary to the argument that ICT leads to more dispersion,
it is found that ICT promotes geographical concentration of industries. The results
are robust to different measures of ICT, at different geographical levels and to the
consideration of endogeneity.

1. Introduction
Economists have long recognised that of agglomeration economies is geographical
agglomeration—of both population and proximity. To be more specific, the demand
firms—in cities, yields economic benefits. for geographical proximity stems from the
In Marshall’s view (Marshall, 1920), firms demand for face-to-face communications,
of the same industry concentrate in a city to especially in an innovative business environ-
incorporate specialised labour pooling and ment where tacit, uncodifiable and rapidly
the availability of intermediate inputs, as well changing information is crucial to decision-
as information and knowledge spillovers. In making (Storper and Venables, 2004).
Jacobs’ opinion (Jacobs, 1961), firms of dif- Many recent studies have confirmed the
ferent industries concentrating in a city can existence and significance of agglomera-
facilitate cross-fertilisation of new ideas. In tion economies among firms and among
both arguments, the underlining determinant workers in cities. Further, economists have

Junjie Hong is in the School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business
and Economics, Beijing, 100029, China. E-mail: hongjunjie@alumni.nus.edu.sg.
Shihe Fu is in the Research Institute of Economics and Management, Southwestern University of
Finance and Economics, Chengdu, China. E-mail: fush@swufe.edu.cn.

0042-0980 Print/1360-063X  Online


© 2010 Urban Studies Journal Limited
DOI: 10.1177/0042098010388956
Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015
2340  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

tried to disentangle the foundations of firm that agglomeration economies are localised
agglomeration. For example, Rosenthal and and decay with geographical distances. For
Strange (2001) examined the impact of example, Jaffe et al. (1993) found that pat-
knowledge spillovers, labour market pool- ent citations decrease when distance from
ing, input-sharing and natural advantage the company holding the patent increases.
on industrial agglomeration. Audretsch and Previous studies also found that business
Feldman (1996) found that industries that agglomeration economies (Rosenthal and
emphasise research and development (R&D) Strange, 2003) and labour market agglom-
are more likely to concentrate in an area. eration economies (Fu, 2007; Rosenthal and
Lovely et al. (2005) investigated whether the Strange, 2008) attenuate rapidly with distance.
need to acquire information contributes to Although these studies did not explicitly pre-
spatial concentration, while Nakamura (2005) dict the impact of ICT on agglomeration, the
focused on the forward and backward linkage implication is that a decrease in the cost of
externalities.1 communication and transport over distance
Along with the rapid progress and wide will attenuate agglomeration and lead to more
application of information and communica- dispersion.
tion technologies (ICTs) during the past few The second strand of literature predicts
decades, an interesting research question has that ICT will attenuate the demand for face-
been debated: if people can communicate over to-face communications and thus will result
a long distance at decreasing cost via phones, in greater dispersion of economic activities.
fax machines, the Internet and e-mails, is Ota and Fujita (1993) constructed a general
it still necessary for people and firms to be equilibrium model of multiunit firms’ loca-
located close to each other? Or, put in another tion and showed that the development of
way, will the improvement of ICT attenuate, information technology will lead to a greater
or even eliminate the geographical concen- concentration of front-units in the city cen-
tration of economic activities, or even cities? tre and to a dispersion of back-units in the
There is no consensus, either theoretically or far suburbs. Sivitanidou (1997) found that
empirically. between 1989 and 1994 the office-commercial
Theoretically speaking, while ICTs have land value gradients within polycentric Los
led to the de-agglomeration or dispersion Angeles flattened. His interpretation was
of some routine activities, ICTs have also that the recent information revolution had
created a knowledge-based economy result- weakened the attractiveness of large business
ing in more new complex opportunities centres to office-commercial activities, result-
that continue to require face-to-face contact ing in the increasingly dispersed patterns of
(Storper and Venables, 2004). In addition, business locations. Ioannides et al. (2007)
it is argued that information is inevitably developed a formal model showing that the
embedded in social relations since learn- improvement of ICT will increase the disper-
ing (transforming information to people’s sion of economic activities across cities, sug-
knowledge) relies on complex social interac- gesting that city sizes would be more uniform.
tions (Brown and Duguid, 2002). Therefore, They also used cross-country city size data
whether ICT promotes agglomeration or not and found supportive evidence.2
is an empirical question. The third strand, however, has an opposite
Existing empirical studies on the relation- viewpoint. Gaspar and Glaeser (1998) devel-
ship between ICT and the geographical con- oped a theoretical model and demonstrated
centration of industries can be grouped into that ICT and face-to-face interactions could be
roughly three strands. The first strand found complementary, rather than substitute goods.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2341

The reason is that, while some face-to-face out separately, at these three geographical
contacts will be replaced and conducted elec- levels. The empirical results show a positive
tronically, the improved ICT may result in more and strong association between the adoption
face-to-face interactions. If the second force is of ICT and the geographical concentration
dominant, then ICT may strengthen agglomer- of industries. These results are quite robust
ation. They also provided some suggestive evi- to different measures of ICT as well as at
dence, such as the negative correlation between different geographical levels. To deal with
geographical distance and number of phone the concerns on omitted variables and endo-
calls, the complementary relationship between geneity issues, we add two-digit industry
business travel and telecommunications, and dummies and control for government policy
the increase in co-authorship in economics. that might have affected both ICT usage and
Panayides and Kern (2005) extended Gaspar geographical concentration. We also use an
and Glaeser’s model and found that improve- instrumental variable approach based on a
ments in ICT may increase or decrease the predetermined value of ICT. The estimation
demand for face-to-face interactions, depend- results provide further support to the argu-
ing on the cross-price elasticity. If the cross- ment that the adoption of ICT promotes the
elasticity is negative, then city size may increase geographical concentration of industries.
with electronic communications. Kolko (2000) The next section describes the measurement
found that commercial Internet domain density of variables, the econometric model specifica-
(the ratio of commercial Internet domains to tions and identification issues and strategies.
commercial establishments) is higher in larger Section 3 introduces the data and provides
cities, controlling for a broad range of other summary statistics. Section 4 presents the
factors. He interpreted this as evidence that estimation results and section 5 concludes.
face-to-face contact is a complement to elec-
tronic communication.3
2. Variable Definitions and
This study contributes to the literature by
Econometric Model Specification
providing new evidence for unravelling the
dispute between the competing hypotheses This section begins by discussing the mea-
regarding the relationship between ICT and surement of geographical concentration.
the geographical concentration of manufac- The variables that proxy for ICT, and other
turing industries. Specifically, we examine determinants of industrial agglomeration,
the impact of ICT on the spatial concentra- are then defined, followed by the specification
tion of manufacturing industries in China, of econometric models and identification
controlling for other main determinants of strategies.
geographical concentration. The data used in
this research are drawn from the 2004 China 2.1 Measuring Geographical
economic census database, which is believed Concentration
to be the most comprehensive micro-level The two widely used indexes of geographical
database in China thus far. It contains detailed concentration are the Gini coefficient, pro-
information on the entire universe of manu- posed by Krugman (1991), and the Ellison–
facturing firms in China. For each four-digit Glaeser index (Ellison and Glaeser, 1997). The
manufacturing industry, we compute the difficulty with the Gini coefficient is that an
Ellison–Glaeser index (Ellison and Glaeser, industry will be regarded as highly localised if
1997) to measure the level of geographical there are several very large firms concentrat-
concentration at the county, city and province ing in a limited number of locations. The EG
levels. The econometric analyses are carried index, however, can control for differences

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2342  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

in firm size. This paper uses the EG index, own websites where relevant information is
calculated according to the following formula posted, including descriptions of companies
and products, company and industrial news,
G − (1 − ∑ mi2 )H career information and after-sale services.
γ=
i (1) Some company sites also support business
(1 − ∑ mi )(1 − H )
2
transactions and electronic commerce. With
i
the popularity of the Internet, a company’s
where, γ is the EG index (also called the website has become increasingly important.
Gamma index), for a particular industry; One can expect that the companies that have
G = ∑ i (si − mi )2; and s is the ratio of location
i their own website may have more advanced
i’s employment in a particular industry to the information technology. Thus, we use share of
national employment in that industry; mi is companies that have a website in an industry,
the ratio of location i’s total employment to as a proxy of ICT.
the national employment; and H = ∑ j z j
2
E-mails and fax machines have also been
denotes the (employment) Herfindahl index widely used in business and generate new
of the J plants in the industry, with z j repre- options for communication. Some rela-
senting the employment share of the jth plant. tionships that previously would have been
The Gamma index has been widely conducted face-to-face have been replaced
employed in recent studies on industrial by telecommunications. For instance, a com-
agglomeration (for example, Lovely et al., pany manager now can send an e-mail to the
2005; Rosenthal and Strange, 2001). Values clients instead of meeting them in person.
of the Gamma index usually range between Business partners can fax or e-mail draft
-1 and 1. γ takes on a value of zero when contracts to each other instead of delivering
an industry is as concentrated as one would them by hand. However, as noted by Gaspar
expect if the plants in the industry choose and Glaeser (1998), there is an opposing
locations by throwing darts at a map. A posi- effect when telecommunication improves:
tive value of γ indicates excess concentration, advanced ICT makes communication easier
while a negative value of γ implies an excess and hence increases the number of relation-
diffusion of employment. ships. For example, with improved ICT, a
company manager can contact more clients
2.2 Measuring Information and and run more projects, which implies that the
Communication Technologies manager needs more face-to-face contacts.
Geographical distance is a hindrance to face- Since the requirement of face-to-face contacts
to-face contacts and the communication of contributes to agglomeration, the net effect of
ideas. With the improvement of ICT, some telecommunication improvement on indus-
face-to-face contacts are replaced electroni- trial agglomeration is unknown. Therefore,
cally and the costs of communicating ideas we use the share of firms that have a fax number
over distance are reduced, implying that or an e-mail address in an industry, as a proxy
advanced ICT may affect agglomeration for ICT. Since firms that have more computers
forces. The focus of this paper is to test the per worker are believed to have better ICT,
impact of ICT on industrial agglomeration. we also try share of firms with above-average
The rapid development of ICT has been computer share, as an additional proxy.5
characterised by the ever-increasing use of
phones, fax machines, personal comput- 2.3 Controls for Other Variables
ers, the Internet and e-mails, over the past Our model includes a set of control variables
few decades.4 Many companies have their that may affect industrial agglomeration. The

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2343

first set of control variables concern labour officials and help to maintain social stability
market pooling. We use share of workers with and serve other social purposes (Bai et al., 2004;
a master’s or college degree6 in an industry Lu and Tao, 2009). Therefore, share of employ-
respectively, as proxies for labour pooling. ment in state-owned enterprises in an industry
We also define average labour intensity in an is used to measure local protectionism.
industry as proportion of number of employ- Our model also considers the impact of
ees over total asset to examine the impact of firm age. Rosenthal and Strange (2001) found
labour markets. The basic idea is that the that, compared with the agglomeration of all
need for human capital and labour intensity establishments, agglomeration of new estab-
may have an impact on a firm’s motivation lishments is not as strongly related to agglom-
to concentrate. erative spillovers and natural advantages. We
The second set of variables controls for include share of young firms in an industry in
natural advantages and knowledge spillovers. the model, where young firms are defined as
Industries concentrate partially due to natural those that are five years old or younger.
advantages, as discussed in Ellison and Glaeser
(1999). We use share of firms in the industry 2.4 Econometric Model Specification
that are located in coastal provinces as a proxy and Identification
for natural advantage, because coastal regions We are interested in how the Gamma index is
in China tend to have flatter terrain, a bet- affected by ICT, controlling for other determi-
ter climate and easier access to seaports and nants of industrial agglomeration, as defined
international markets. Knowledge spillover earlier. The econometric model is specified
is also an important factor in determining as follows
industrial concentration. Because knowledge γ ij = δ X j + eij
(2)
spillover is found to be more significant in
R&D intensive industries, industries that are where, γ ij is the Gamma index for industry j
highly innovative are expected to have higher (four-digit code) at geographical level i; X j is
levels of agglomeration (Lovely et al., 2005). a vector of industry characteristics, including
Similar to previous studies (for example, variables that proxy for ICT, labour pooling,
Lovely et al., 2005), we use number of innova- knowledge spillovers and natural advantages;
tions per worker in an industry, as a proxy for δ is the coefficient vector to be estimated; and
knowledge spillover.7 eij is the error term, assumed to be indepen-
Previous studies have shown that local dently and identically distributed.
protectionism is an important and special The benchmark model is estimated at the
determinant of geographical concentra- county level. To test the robustness of our
tion in China (Bai et al., 2004; Lu and Tao, specification, we also estimate the model at
2009). Local governments have motivation the city and province levels. In China, a city
to protect local firms and industries due to is larger than a county, in terms of land area.
fiscal decentralisation after China’s economic A city normally contains a number of coun-
reform. There was a rise of local protection- ties. There are 31 provinces, 345 cities and
ism in China during the reform era (Young, 2831 counties in mainland China.
2000), creating barriers to trade and imped- The key identification assumption is that,
ing the process of industrial agglomeration. after including the control variables in the
Local governments give more protection to model, the ICT variables are uncorrelated
industries with higher shares of state owner- with the error term. This assumption may
ship, because state-owned enterprises can cre- be violated if there are important omitted
ate much more benefit for local government variables or if firms in highly concentrated

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2344  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

industries have a stronger preference to between ICT adoption in an industry and


adopt ICT, generating omitted variable bias geographical concentration. However, the
and an endogeneity problem. To address the causality direction can run both ways.10 It is
omitted variable bias problem, we add to possible that ICT causes more concentration
the benchmark model two sets of variables by facilitating more face-to-face interactions
that may affect ICT adoption as well as geo- or through other channels; it is also possible
graphical concentration. Since unobservable that concentration causes firms to adopt more
industrial characteristics may affect both ICT because of the harsh competition among
ICT and geographical concentration, we firms in the same geographical cluster. To deal
add 29 two-digit industry dummies to the with the causality problem, we use instrumen-
model. Another important omitted variable tal variable estimation. A valid instrument
that we can think of is government policy. should be correlated with ICT variables, but
In China, government zoning policies have orthogonal to the error term. Following previ-
played an important role in both business ous studies (for example, Henderson, 2003),
location and ICT adoption. Local govern- we use a predetermined value of ICT as an
ments have established high-tech industrial instrument. We use another dataset—the
parks to promote high-tech industrial clus- 2003 State Statistical Bureau enterprises sur-
tering, and some other special zones (such vey dataset, which covers all manufacturing
as export-processing zones and free trade enterprises that are state-owned or are above
zones) to promote export. Within high-tech a designated size.11 The database contains
industrial parks, some preferential policies information on firms’ e-mail addresses, but
(such as tax holidays, preferential account- does not provide information on website,
ing treatment) are implemented to promote fax and computer usage. Therefore, we use
adoption of new technologies like ICT. Within the share of firms in each industry that had
export-processing zones and free trade zones, e-mail addresses in 2003 as an instrument.
export-oriented firms tend to locate close
to each other. Because these firms are more
3. Data and Summary Statistics
exposed to international trading practices
and standards, they are more likely to adopt The data used for this research are drawn
ICT as well.8 Therefore, the government from the first economic census in China,
zoning policies could have driven up both conducted by the Chinese government from
geographical concentration and ICT usage. 2004 to 2005. It is believed to be the most
To deal with this concern, two proxy variables comprehensive micro-level database on
are added to the model. The first is a dummy Chinese industries thus far. We obtained
for high-tech industries, used to capture the the manufacturing industry data from the
effect of government policy towards high-tech State Statistical Bureau of China. The dataset
industries. The classification of high-tech contains detailed information on all manufac-
industries is based on the standard used by turing firms (over 1.3 million) at the end of
the State Statistical Bureau of China. There 2004, including firm location, year of entry,
are 59 high-tech manufacturing industries at ownership, employees and the like.
the four-digit level. The second variable is to Two characteristics of this database make
measure the export orientation of an industry, it distinct from those used in previous stud-
which equals one if an industry has an above- ies. First, the dataset contains information
average export share and zero otherwise.9 on the entire universe of manufacturing
The estimation results based on equation firms in China, while many recent studies
(2) provide evidence on the correlation (for example, Lovely et al., 2005; Maurel and

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2345

Sedillot, 1999; Rosenthal and Strange, 2001) be very high, but the EG index at the county
used only a proportion of manufacturing level may not be so high. These results are
firms in a country.12 Secondly, all data used also consistent with those of previous studies
in this research are from the same census (for example, Rosenthal and Strange, 2001),
database, therefore the consistency of data suggesting that spillovers go beyond a small
is guaranteed. However, the census database area (Ellison and Glaeser, 1997).
available for research is only at the firm level Table 2 indicates that there are large varia-
and not at the establishment or plant level. tions in spatial concentration across two-
One concern is that, if a firm has several plants digit industries. At the county level, the most
located in different places, and all employees localised industries are cultural, educational
are assigned to the headquarter, a measure- and sports goods, and smelting and pressing
ment error arises when we calculate industrial of non-ferrous metals. At the city and prov-
agglomeration. Fortunately, only a very small ince levels, the most concentrated industries
proportion (about 1.778 per cent) of firms are smelting and pressing of non-ferrous met-
have multiple plants. In addition, according als, and electronics and telecommunication.
to the rule of the State Statistical Bureau of We note that some high-tech industries are
China, all employees of a multiplant firm are highly concentrated (for example, electronics
allocated to the address where the main pro- and telecommunication), while other high-
duction takes place. Thus, we believe that this tech industries are much less concentrated
issue does not lead to serious bias, especially, (for example, medical and pharmaceutical
at the higher geographical levels. products). The pattern of traditional indus-
The data cover 482 four-digit manufac- tries is also mixed. For instance, cultural, edu-
turing industries. Based on the firm-level cational and sports goods are very localised,
data, we calculate the Gamma index at the while the tobacco processing industry is quite
county, city and province levels, for each dispersed.
four-digit industry. Table 1 shows that there An industry is as concentrated as a ran-
is substantially more concentration at the dom allocation when the EG index equals
higher geographical levels: the mean value zero and is excessively concentrated when
of the Gamma index at the province level the index is positive. Using manufacturing
is 0.0657, while at the county level it is only census data for the US, Ellison and Glaeser
0.0155. These results are as expected, since (1997) defined not very localised (state level
provinces are larger than cities and counties. 0 < γ < 0.02), intermediate, and very localised
If employment in an industry is spread over a (state level γ > 0.05) ranges. When we apply
number of counties within one province, the the same classification criteria of Ellison and
Gamma index at the provincial level would Glaeser (1997) to Chinese manufacturing

Table 1.   Summary of the EG Gamma index at the four-digit industry level

Correlation with γ at
the level of

γ Mean SD Minimum Maximum City Province

County 0.0155 0.0231 –0.0188 0.1931 0.8482 0.6531


City 0.0287 0.0370 –0.0186 0.2919 0.7373
Province 0.0657 0.0718 –0.0812 0.5195

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2346  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

Table 2.   Mean value of the Gamma index in two-digit industries

Industry code and name County γ City γ Province γ

13 Food production 0.0118 0.0261 0.0829


14 Food manufacturing 0.0089 0.0176 0.0473
15 Beverage production 0.0052 0.0167 0.0465
16 Tobacco processing 0.0030 0.0034 0.0663
17 Textile industry 0.0219 0.0330 0.0703
18 Garments and other fibre products 0.0112 0.0173 0.0334
19 Leather, furs, down and related products 0.0264 0.0471 0.0866
20 Timber processing, bamboo products 0.0136 0.0260 0.0519
21 Furniture manufacturing 0.0153 0.0195 0.0640
22 Paper making and paper products 0.0111 0.0142 0.0319
23 Printing and medium reproduction 0.0053 0.0126 0.0250
24 Cultural, educational and sports goods 0.0375 0.0506 0.0947
25 Petroleum refining and coking 0.0049 0.0087 0.0665
26 Raw chemical materials and chemical products 0.0098 0.0182 0.0493
27 Medical and pharmaceutical products 0.0037 0.0099 0.0270
28 Chemical products 0.0083 0.0124 0.0296
29 Rubber products 0.0063 0.0123 0.0281
30 Plastic products 0.0176 0.0257 0.0646
31 Non-metal mineral products 0.0207 0.0323 0.0593
32 Smelting and pressing of ferrous metals 0.0045 0.0189 0.0814
33 Smelting and pressing of non-ferrous metals 0.0317 0.0583 0.1516
34 Metal products 0.0161 0.0283 0.0479
35 Ordinary machinery 0.0091 0.0170 0.0436
36 Special-purpose equipment 0.0098 0.0209 0.0528
37 Transport equipment 0.0154 0.0445 0.0726
39 Electrical machinery and equipment 0.0182 0.0266 0.0768
40 Electronics and telecommunication 0.0206 0.0538 0.1119
41 Instruments and meters 0.0156 0.0308 0.0721
42 Artwork and others 0.0269 0.0460 0.0988
43 Recycling and disposal of waste 0.0109 0.0119 0.0138

Table 3.   Distribution of the Gamma index at the four-digit industry level

Number of four-digit industries

Gamma γ at the county level γ at the city level γ at the province level
γ≤0 286 144  45
0 < γ ≤ 0.02 135 197 107
0.02 < γ ≤ 0.05  44  92 147
0.05 < γ ≤ 0.10   9  33 113
0.10 < γ ≤ 0.20   8   9  47
γ > 0.20   0   7  23

industries, 107 out of 482 four-digit industries Compared with the spatial concentration
are not very localised at the province level, of US manufacturing industries (for example,
while 183 of them are very localised, as shown Rosenthal and Strange, 2001), Chinese indus-
in Table 3. tries are more concentrated on average. For

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2347

example, the average EG index equals 0.0657 websites, e-mail addresses and fax numbers
at the province level in China, while that for are, on average, 6.58 per cent, 8.16 per cent
the US is 0.0485 at the state level (Rosenthal and 42.04 per cent respectively. There are 33.4
and Strange, 2001). However, we need to be per cent of firms with a computer share above
cautious when making such comparisons, the average level. The correlation coefficients
since the Chinese provinces are normally among these ICT-related variables are quite
larger than American states in terms of land high. To avoid multicollinearity, we will not
area. In addition, the official classification of include them in the same equation.
industries is different. Table 4 also reports descriptive statistics for
Table 4 reports descriptive statistics of other control variables. The variable of num-
the explanatory variables. In the census, all ber of innovations per worker is at the three-
firms were required to report their websites, digit industry level and is drawn from the
fax numbers, e-mail addresses and number China Economic Census Yearbook 2004 (State
of computers, if any. There was an auditor, Statistical Bureau, 2006). All other variables
who has been trained formally by the State are computed directly from the census data-
Statistical Bureau, to recheck the data and base and are at the four-digit industry level.
information reported after a firm filled in
the census form, which guarantees the qual- 4. Estimation Results
ity of the database. The value takes one if a
firm has a website, fax or e-mail, and zero 4.1 Benchmark model results
otherwise, based on which we compute ICT- Table 5 presents the estimation results for
related variables at the four-digit industry the benchmark model, with the EG index
level. The shares of firms that have their own at the county level as the explained variable.

Table 4.  Descriptive statistics of explanatory variables

Variable Definition Mean S.D.

Master’s degree Share of workers with master’s degree 0.0044 0.0094


College degree Share of workers with college degree 0.0910 0.0443
Average labour intensity Number of employees/total asset 0.0385 0.1038
Innovations per worker Number of innovations per worker in an industry 0.0006 0.0006
Natural advantage Share of firms in the industry that are located in 0.6973 0.1691
coastal provinces
Local protectionism Share of employment in state-owned enterprises 0.1025 0.1472
in an industry
Young firms Share of young firms (5 years old or younger) 0.5166 0.0800
Website Share of firms that have website 0.0658 0.05197
Fax Share of firms that have fax 0.4204 0.1534
E-mail Share of firms that have e-mail 0.0816 0.0580
Computer Share of firms with above-average computer 0.3340 0.0982
share
High-tech dummy A dummy variable, which equals to 1 for 0.1224 0.3281
high-tech industries, and 0 otherwise
Export orientation The ratio of export sales over total sales 0.3838 0.4868
Notes: The variable of innovations per worker is at the three-digit industry level, drawn from the
China Economic Census Yearbook (State Statistical Bureau, 2006). All other variables are at the four-
digit industry level, computed by the authors, based on the census database.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2348  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

Huber–White’s robust standard error is used effect on the geographical concentration of


to control for heterogeneity. The adjusted Chinese industries at the county level.
R2 ranges from 0.097 to 0.113. The labour Table 5 consistently shows that coefficient
market pooling effect is represented by three estimates for local protectionism are posi-
variables: share of workers with master’s degree, tive and insignificant. This is in contrast to
share of workers with college degree, and aver- the findings of Bai et al. (2004), who found
age labour intensity. The results in Table 5 that stronger local government protection
consistently show that share of workers with decreases the degree of geographical concen-
college degree has negative and significant tration during the period of 1985–97. One
impact. The coefficient estimates range from possible interpretation is that our sample
–0.159 to –0.191. The variable share of workers includes all manufacturing firms, but Bai
with master’s degree is negative and significant et al. (2004) considered only firms that are
in one out of the four models. These results above designated size and state-owned.
show that labour quality, in terms of educa- Another possible interpretation is the differ-
tion, is negatively associated with geographi- ent periods studied. Lu and Tao (2009) found
cal concentration of manufacturers. These that the impacts of local protectionism may
results are consistent with some of the previous have become weaker over time. The variable
studies (for example, Shaver and Flyer, 2000; share of young firms, the percentage of firms
Hong, 2009), which find that firms with that are five years old or younger, in an indus-
better human capital are less likely to locate try, is worth noting. The coefficient is positive
close to other firms in an industry. One pos- and significant in most models, suggesting
sible reason is that such firms gain little from that industries with more young firms are
access to competitors’ human capital, while associated with a higher degree of geographi-
firms with weaker human capital greatly cal concentration. Since young firms are easily
benefit from proximity to competitors. This exposed to ICT, this may suggest that ICTs
asymmetry in returns to agglomeration may have not weakened the incentives of new firms
motivate firms with better human capital to concentrate.
not to cluster geographically (Shaver and The key interest of this paper is to inves-
Flyer, 2000). The coefficient of average labour tigate the impact of ICT on geographical
intensity is positive and significant in two of concentration. Four variables are used to
the four models. Taken together, these results measure the adoption of ICT in an industry:
provide supportive evidence that labour share of firms that have websites, share of firms
market pooling has a significant effect on that have fax numbers, share of firms that have
industrial agglomeration. e-mail addresses and share of firms with above-
We also examine the impact of natural average computer share. Table 5 indicates that
advantages and knowledge spillovers. Share of the coefficients for website, fax, e-mail and
firms in the industry that are located in coastal computer share are 0.088, 0.037, 0.095 and
provinces is used as a proxy for natural advan- 0.031 respectively. All coefficient estimates are
tages and its impact is insignificant, consistent significant at the 5 per cent level. Contrary to
with Rosenthal and Strange (2001). The the argument that ICT leads to more disper-
impact of number of innovations per worker, sion, these results provide strong evidence
a proxy for knowledge spillovers, is positive that the adoption of ICT is associated with a
and marginally significant in two of the four higher degree of geographical concentration
models. These results suggest that natural of manufacturers. This evidence is consistent
advantage has an insignificant impact, while with the view that improved ICT may result
knowledge spillover has a moderate and positive in more face-to-face relationships (Gaspar

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2349

Table 5.   Benchmark model: regression results at the county level (N = 482)

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)

Master’s degree -0.129 -0.092 -0.163* -0.094


(-1.46) (-1.35) (-1.80) (-1.48)
College degree -0.181*** -0.191*** -0.185*** -0.159***
(-4.31) (-5.12) (-4.50) (-4.81)
Average labour intensity 0.008** 0.006 0.008** 0.006
(2.20) (1.42) (2.32) (1.38)
Innovations per worker 4.270* 4.056 3.961 5.016*
(1.72) (1.46) (1.58) (1.80)
Natural advantage 0.003 -0.009 -0.001 0.004
(0.33) (-0.78) (-0.11) (0.49)
Local protectionism 0.024 0.016 0.023 0.029
(1.03) (0.72) (1.03) (1.42)
Young firms 0.034** 0.032* 0.034** 0.034**
(2.17) (1.95) (2.11) (2.01)
Website 0.088**
(2.52)
Fax 0.037***
(3.53)
E-mail 0.095***
(3.55)
Computer 0.031***
(2.83)
Adjusted R2 0.105 0.109 0.113 0.097
Notes: Dependent variable is g at the county level. Constants are not reported in order to conserve
space. T-values are given in parentheses. Huber–White’s robust standard error is used to control
for heterogeneity. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10 per cent, 5 per cent and 1 per cent level
respectively.

and Glaeser, 1998; Panayides and Kern, levels. One interesting finding is that the
2005), which motivates firms to agglomerate magnitude of all four ICT variables increases
geographically. at higher geographical levels. For instance,
the coefficient for website is 0.088 at the
4.2 Robustness Tests county level; it increases to 0.113 at the city
In the benchmark model, we regress the level and to 0.280 at the province level. We
Gamma index on possible determinants also note that model fitness is improved sig-
at the county level. Readers might wonder nificantly at higher geographical levels. This
whether our results are sensitive to different pattern is consistent with that in Rosenthal
levels of geography. To address this concern, and Strange (2001).
we estimate the model at the city and prov- Another concern is that our results may be
ince levels. The results are reported in Table 6, subject to outlier bias. Compared with other
where each estimate is taken from a separate industries, the electronics and telecommu-
regression. It shows that all ICT variables are nication industry has a significantly higher
significant at both the city and the province Gamma index, as well as ICT adoption.
levels. This provides supportive evidence that A natural concern is that the estimation
our results are robust at different geographical results may be biased by the inclusion of

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2350  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

Table 6.   Robustness test: regression results Table 7.   Estimation results: inclusion of
at the city and province levels two-digit industry dummies and policy effects

Variables City level γ Province level γ County City Province


level γ level γ level γ
Website 0.113* 0.280***
(1.94) (2.74) Website 0.062 0.033 0.011
Fax 0.067*** 0.210*** (1.26) (0.39) (0.08)
(3.94) (4.45) Fax 0.019* 0.038** 0.132***
E-mail 0.147*** 0.427*** (1.68) (1.98) (2.95)
(3.54) (4.54) E-mail 0.071* 0.078 0.229*
Computer 0.054*** 0.148*** (1.71) (1.13) (1.84)
(2.69) (3.11) Computer 0.009 0.017 0.036
(0.64) (0.72) (0.65)
Notes: Each estimate is taken from a separate
regression. All other variables in Table 5 are Notes: Each estimate is taken from a separate
included, but the coefficients are not reported regression with 29 two-digit industry dummies
here. T-values are given in parentheses. Huber– and policy effects (high-tech dummy and
White’s robust standard error is used to control export orientation) included. High-tech
for heterogeneity. *, ** and *** denotes the industries are at the four-digit level and cross
significance at the 10 per cent, 5 per cent and 1 nine two-digit industries. The coefficient
per cent level respectively. estimates for the high-tech dummy range
between -0.009 and 0.013, and are insignificant
in all regressions. The estimated coefficients
this outlier industry. We experiment to drop
of export orientation range between 0.006
this industry and re-run the regressions. The and 0.029, and are significant at the 1 per cent
results show that dropping the electronics and level in all regressions. All other variables in
telecommunication industry does not change Table 5 are included, but the coefficients are
the coefficient estimates substantially.13 Most not reported here. T-values are given in the
ICT variables are still significantly and posi- parentheses. Huber–White’s robust standard
tively associated with geographical concen- error is used to control for heterogeneity.
tration. This provides an additional piece of *, ** and *** denote the significance at the 10 per
evidence that our regression results are robust. cent, 5 per cent and 1 per cent level respectively.

4.3 Endogeneity Issues other control variables are quite consistent


To deal with possible endogeneity issues, we with those in Table 5, in terms of both signifi-
try two experiments. The first experiment cance and magnitude (to save space, the results
concerns possible omitted variable bias. We for other variables are not reported here).
add to the benchmark model two sets of The other experiment involves instrumen-
variables that may affect ICT adoption as well tation. A valid instrument should be cor-
as geographical concentration, including 29 related with ICT variables but orthogonal
two-digit industry dummies and two proxies to the error term. We use the share of state-
for government policies (a high-tech dummy owned or above-designated-size firms in an
and the export-orientation of an industry). industry that had e-mail addresses in 2003
The results are reported in Table 7. The results as an instrument (lagged e-mail thereafter).
are still robust: all coefficient estimates for The correlation coefficients between ICT
ICT variables are positive. The variable fax variables and lagged e-mail range from 0.408
is significant at all three geographical levels, to 0.606 (column 1 of Table 8). We regress
while e-mail is significant at both county and each ICT variable on lagged e-mail, and find
province levels. The coefficient estimates of that all coefficients are positive and significant

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2351

Table 8.   Correlation between ICT variables instrument. With regard to the exclusion
and the instrumental variable restriction (i.e. the instrumental variable does
not affect geographical concentration through
Correlation
between ICT with channels other than the ICT variables), we
instrumental believe that the causality of lagged e-mail is
variablea Coefficientb irreversible: new firm location can respond
to past industry ICT adoption, but not vice
Website 0.557 0.507*** versa. We do a test related to the exclusion
(5.58)
Fax 0.536 1.388*** restriction by regressing the residuals from
(6.39) the second-stage estimations on the instru-
E-mail 0.606 0.593*** mental variable. If the instrumental variable
(6.42) affects the industrial agglomeration through
Computer 0.408 0.678***
(5.19) other channels, the residuals from the second-
stage estimations should be correlated with
a
The instrumental variable is the share of the instrumental variable (Lu and Tao, 2009).
state-owned or above-designated-size firms that
The regression results consistently show that the
have e-mail in an industry in 2003.
b
Coefficient is on the instrumental variable correlation between the two is close to zero in
(lagged e-mail) in a regression of ICT variables magnitude and is statistically insignificant.14
(website, fax, e-mail, computer respectively) on In summary, these tests show that lagged
lagged e-mail. e-mail is a good instrument.
Note: *** indicates the significance at the Table 9 shows that all ICT coefficient esti-
1 per cent level. mates are positive and significant, although
the coefficient estimates lose some signifi-
at the 1 per cent level (column 2 of Table 8), cance compared with the benchmark models.
which indicates the instrument strength. The As in previous studies (for example, Alfaro
IV regression results are reported in Table 9. et al., 2004), the coefficients increase consid-
F-values greater than 10 in the first-stage erably in values compared with the earlier
regressions confirm again the validity of the OLS results in Tables 5 and 6. One possible

Table 9.   IV estimation results

First-stage partial
County level γ City level γ Province level γ R2 and F-value

Website 0.381* 0.649** 0.809** [0.167, 14.749]


(1.77) (2.09) (2.29)
Fax 0.126* 0.215** 0.267** [0.147, 22.518]
(1.87) (2.29) (2.54)
E-mail 0.301** 0.513** 0.640** [0.207, 22.150]
(1.97) (2.32) (2.54)
Computer 0.300* 0.510** 0.636** [0.059, 13.083]
(1.83) (2.07) (2.22)
Notes: Each estimate is taken from a separate regression. All control variables in Table 5 are included
in the model. The ICT variables are instrumented by the share of state-owned or above-designated-
size firms that have e-mail in an industry in 2003. T-values are shown in parentheses. Huber–White’s
robust standard error is used to control for heterogeneity. *, ** and *** denotes significance at the 10
per cent, 5 per cent and 1 per cent levels respectively. Partial R2 and F-value based on the first-stage
regression are shown in brackets.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2352  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

interpretation is that instrumental variable exact mechanisms through which ICT affects
estimation here corrects for measurement industrial agglomeration are left for future
error, which biases the OLS coefficients to research agenda.
zero. Taken together, the results in this sec-
tion lend additional support to the view that
modern information and communication Notes
technologies have resulted in a higher degree   1. For more related studies, see the literature
of industrial agglomeration. review by Duranton and Puga (2004) and
Rosenthal and Strange (2004).
  2. There are a few futurists predicting the
5. Conclusions disappearance of cities, see Toffler (1980) and
It has long been speculated that adoption of Naisbitt (1995).
ICT may decrease industrial agglomeration   3. Using individual on-line and off-line
shopping behaviour data, Sinai and Waldfogel
because developments in telecommunications
(2004) found that the Internet can be both
have generated new options for communica- a complement to cities and a substitute for
tions and have replaced face-to-face contacts. cities.
Some people even predict that industrial   4. We do not test the impact of phone lines,
clusters will decline or disappear because because almost all firms use telephones.
firms have no need to locate close to each   5. We do not use average computer share of an
other with improvements in telecommuni- industry as a proxy, because a small proportion
cations technologies. However, others argue of companies have a very large number of
that face-to-face communication and tele- computers. We use share of firms with above-
communication can be complements, since average computer share to avoid outlier bias.
  6. The variable share of workers with bachelor’s
face-to-face contact is necessary for learning
degree is not included, since it is highly
and creative activities, and adoption of ICT correlated with other variables. In China,
can increase the number of business relation- college-degree holders normally receive a
ships. Our research examines the impact of three-year education, while bachelor-degree
advanced information and communication holders require a four-year education.
technologies on the geographical concentra-   7. Following Rosenthal and Strange (2001), we
tion of manufacturing industries in China. have also tried to use energy consumption per
We use the 2004 China economic census worker and technological funds per worker
data and compute the Ellison–Glaeser index to measure natural advantage and knowledge
to measure the geographical concentration spillover respectively, and find quite consistent
estimation results.
of four-digit industries. After controlling for
  8. Lovely et al. (2005) found that exporter
the main industrial characteristics that may headquarters are more agglomerated when
influence geographical concentration, such foreign market information is difficult to
as labour pooling and natural advantage, we obtain.
find that adoption of ICT actually increases   9. We do not use average export share of an
geographical concentration. These results industry as a proxy, because a small proportion
are quite robust to various measures of ICT, of companies have a very high export share.
at different geographical levels, the inclusion In order to avoid outlier bias, we use share of
of other determinants of agglomeration and firms with above-average export share instead.
10. The causality direction between some
consideration of endogeneity. Our findings
industrial characteristics (such as labour
suggest that knowledge spillovers through quality) and agglomeration can run both
face-to-face contact might still be important ways. For these variables, the coefficients may
for manufacturing industries. However, the reflect the equilibrium relationship rather than

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


ICT AND MANUFACTURING IN CHINA   2353

causal effects. Since our focus is the impact of Vol. IV, pp. 2063–2117. Amsterdam: Elsevier
ICT, we will conduct causality analysis only North-Holland.
on ICT effects. Ellison, G. and Glaeser, E. (1997) Geographic
11. Firms that are above designated size are defined concentration in U.S. manufacturing indus-
as those with annual sales of over 5 million tries: a dartboard approach, Journal of Political
Chinese yuan. We did not use predetermined Economy, 105, pp. 879–927.
values of ICT in earlier years as instruments, Ellison, G. and Glaeser, E. (1999) The geographic
because the industry category and code by concentration of an industry: does natural
State Statistical Bureau changed significantly advantage explain agglomeration?, American
in 2003. Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 89,
12. An exception is a recent paper by Lu (2010) pp. 311–316.
that used the first and second Chinese national Fu, S. (2007) Smart café cities: testing human
establishment censuses in 1996 and 2001, capital externalities in the Boston metropolitan
which cover all manufacturing establishments area, Journal of Urban Economics, 61, pp. 86–111.
in China. Gaspar, J. and Glaeser, E. (1998) Information
13. To save space, the estimation results are not technology and the future of cities, Journal of
reported here, but are available from the Urban Economics, 43, pp. 136–156.
authors upon request. Henderson, J. (2003) Marshall’s scale economies,
14. To save space, the estimation results are not Journal of Urban Economics, 53, pp. 1–28.
reported here, but are available from the Hong, J. (2009) Firm heterogeneity and location
authors upon request. choices: evidence from foreign manufacturing
investments in China, Urban Studies, 46(10),
pp. 2143–2157.
Acknowledgement Ioannides, Y., Overman, H., Rossi-Hansberg, E.
and Schmidheiny, K. (2007) The effect of
Shihe Fu gratefully acknowledges financial support
information and communication technologies
from Project 211 (Phase III) of the Southwestern
on urban structure. Discussion Paper No. 812,
University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu,
Centre for Economic Performance, London
China.
School of Economics.
Jacobs, J. (1961) The Death and Life of Great
References American Cities. New York: Vintage Books.
Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R.
Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and (1993) Geographic localization of knowl-
Sayek, S. (2004) FDI and economic growth: edge spillovers as evidenced by patent cita-
the role of local financial markets, Journal of tions, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108,
International Economics, 64, pp. 89–112. pp. 577–598.
Audretsch, D. B. and Feldman, M. (1996) R&D Kolko, J. (2000) The death of cities? The death
spillovers and the geography of innovation of distance? Evidence from the geography of
and production, American Economic Review, commercial internet usage, in: I. Vogelsang and
86, pp. 630–640. B. Compaine (Eds) The Internet Upheaval: Raising
Bai, C., Du, Y., Tao, Z. and Tong, S. (2004) Local Questions, Seeking Answers in Communications
protectionism and regional specialization: Policy, pp. 73–97. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
evidence from China’s industries, Journal of Krugman, P. (1991) Geography and Trade.
International Economics, 63, pp. 397–417. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Brown, J. S. and Duguid, P. (2002) The Social Lovely, M., Rosenthal, S. and Sharma, S. (2005)
Life of Information. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Information, agglomeration, and the head-
Business School Press. quarters of U.S. exporters, Regional Science and
D u r a n t o n , G . a n d P u g a , D. ( 2 0 0 4 ) Urban Economics, 35, pp. 167–191.
Microfoundations of urban agglomeration Lu, J. (2010) Agglomeration of economic activi-
economies, in: V. Henderson and J. Thisse (Eds) ties in China: evidence from establishment
Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, censuses, Regional Studies, 44(3), pp. 281–297.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015


2354  JUNJIE HONG AND SHIHE FU

Lu, J. and Tao, Z. (2009) Trends and determinants Rosenthal, S. and Strange, W. (2004) Evidence on the
of China’s industrial agglomeration, Journal of nature and sources of agglomeration economies,
Urban Economics, 65(2), pp. 167–180. in: V. Henderson and J. Thisse (Eds) Handbook
Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics. of Regional and Urban Economics, Vol. IV,
London: Macmillan. pp. 2119–2171. Amsterdam: Elsevier North-
Maurel, F. and Sedillot, B. (1999) A measure of the Holland.
geographic concentration in French manufac- Rosenthal, S. and Strange, W. (2008) The attenu-
turing industries, Regional Science and Urban ation of human capital spillovers, Journal of
Economics, 29, pp. 575–604. Urban Economics, 64(2), pp. 373–389.
Naisbitt, J. (1995) The Global Paradox. New York: Shaver, J. and Flyer, E. (2000) Agglomeration
Avon Books. economies, firm heterogeneity, and foreign
Nakamura, R. (2005) Agglomeration economies direct investment in the United States, Strategic
and linkage externalities in urban manufacturing Management Journal, 21, pp. 1175–1193.
industries: a case study of Japanese cities. Paper Sinai, T. and Waldfogel, J. (2004) Geography
presented at the 45th Congress of the European and the Internet: is the Internet a substitute
Regional Science Association, Amsterdam, or a complement for cities?, Journal of Urban
August. Economics, 56, pp. 1–24.
Ota, M. and Fujita, M. (1993) Communication Sivitanidou, R. (1997) Are center access advantages
technologies and spatial organization of multi- weakening? The case of office-commercial mar-
unit plants in metropolitan areas, Regional kets, Journal of Urban Economics, 42, pp. 79–97.
Science and Urban Economics, 23, pp. 695–729. State Statistical Bureau (2006) China Economic Census
Panayides, A. and Kern, C. (2005) Information Yearbook 2004. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
technology and the future of cities: an alterna- Storper, M. and Venables, A. J. (2004) Buzz: face-
tive analysis, Urban Studies, 42, pp. 263–267. to-face contact and the urban economy, Journal
Rosenthal, S. and Strange, W. (2001) The deter- of Economic Geography, 4, pp. 351–370.
minants of agglomeration, Journal of Urban Toffler, A. (1980) The Third Wave. New York:
Economics, 50, pp. 191–229. Bantam Books.
Rosenthal, S. and Strange, W. (2003) Geography, Young, A. (2000) The razor’s edge: distortions and
industrial organization, and agglomera- incremental reform in the People’s Republic of
tion, Review of Economics and Statistics, 85, China, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4),
pp. 377–393. pp. 1091–1135.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at MEMORIAL UNIV OF NEWFOUNDLAND on April 4, 2015

You might also like