You are on page 1of 13

767 Moneylending 768

Painting: 1600–1800 (New Haven, Conn./London 1995). miner-turned-oilman on a ruthless quest for wealth
■ Tumay, M., “Jews, Money, Myth: Debunking the Illusion,”
during the California oil rush at the turn of the last
Impakter (August 12, 2019; https://impakter.com). century. Daniel’s efforts to acquire drilling rights
Tijana Zakula and Yannis Johanides on property are initially thwarted by a local
preacher, Eli Sunday, who demands a large cash do-
IX. Film nation for his church. Daniel’s efforts are further
Money has served as a major theme in film, with complicated by an orphan whom he passes off as his
infamous characters like Gordon Gekko (Wall Street; son, and a stranger who presents himself as a “long-
dir. Oliver Stone, 1987, US) dominating popular lost brother,” both of whom become opportunities
consciousness as the archpriest of modern capital- to advance as well as obstacles to be overcome. Dan-
ism; Gekko’s infamous baptism of vice is: “Greed, iel’s murderous pursuit of wealth and status leaves
for lack of a better word, is good.” The American him a “ruin unto himself” (Prov 11:17) even as he
superhero film Constantine (dir. Francis Lawrence, acquires enormous wealth. The film’s murderous
2005, US/DE) makes use of Milton’s personification conclusion leaves Eli dead and Daniel declaring that
of Mammon as a fallen angel in his classic, Paradise he is “finished.”
Lost. Two films, however, stand out as exemplary
Bibliography: ■ Blake, R. A., “After Sunset,” America 198.8
in offering more biblically informed and complex
(March 10, 2008) 18–20. ■ Diken, B., “Money, Religion,
accounts of money, of its impact on personal charac- and Symbolic Exchange in ‘Winter Sleep,’” Religion and Soci-
ter, and of its place in the social order: Winter Sleep ety 8 (2017) 94–108.
and There Will Be Blood. Christopher McMahon
Anton Chekhov’s The Wife (along with several
other of Chekhov’s short stories) provides the inspi- See also / Alms; / Cleansing of the Temple;
ration for Nuri Bilge Ceylan’s 2014 film Kış Uykusu / Coins; / Debt, Debts; / Inclinations (Good
(TR/FR/DE, Winter Sleep). Although the film’s impact and Evil); / Judas; / Mammon; / Moneylend-
within Western circles may be limited, critics hon- ing; / Poor, Poverty; / Prosperity Gospel;
ored the film with the Palme d’Or at Cannes. The / Salvation; / Seven Deadly Sins; / Shekel,
story, set in the mountains of Anatolia, examines the Half-Shekel; / Silver; / Taxes and Taxation;
significant divide between rich and poor as well as / Temptation; / Trade and Commerce;
the powerful and the powerless in contemporary / Usury; / Wealth and Riches
Turkey. In the film, Aydın (Haluk Bilginer) sees him-
self as the local benevolent Don, intervening in the
business of the local townspeople below the moun- Moneylending
tain and pontificating on perceived social ills
I. Ancient Near East and Hebrew Bible/Old
through his newspaper column as he sits atop his Testament
cave-like office in his mountain inn. The truth, how- II. Greco-Roman Antiquity
ever, is that Aydın is almost universally despised and III. New Testament
resented. In particular, his wife, Nihal (Melisa IV. Judaism
Sözen), stands as a foil, challenging Aydın’s imperi- V. Christianity
ousness and casual indifference to the suffering of VI. Islam
those beneath him in the social order. As Aydın be- VII. Literature
VIII. Visual Arts
comes preoccupied with writing a history of Turkish
IX. Film
theater, Nihal dedicates her efforts to fundraising for
developing schools, a cause not shared by Aydın.
When Nihal organizes a fundraiser in their home, Ay- I. Ancient Near East and Hebrew Bible/
dın belittles her for her inexperience and lack of fi- Old Testament
nancial skill. But, in a characteristically transparent 1. Semantics and Word Usage. Two roots are
act of self-aggrandizement, Aydın makes a large used to evoke in-kind or moneylending (money
anonymous cash donation to the fundraiser, one that could be grains, weighted metal or coins, see
will eventually be thrown into a fire when Nihal of- “Money”) in the HB: l–w–h (LXX, δανείζω; qal, “to
fers it to their tenants, a local imam, and his extended borrow”; hiphil, “to lend”) and n–š–h (qal, “to
family, who are in danger of being evicted. The bibli- lend,” “be a creditor” [with bet]; hiphil, also, “to
cal and qurānic admonitions concerning wealth, lend”; “make a loan”). The former is positively con-
power, and the care of the poor and vulnerable echo noted as helping a person in financial difficulty by
throughout the film (see, e.g., S 2:177; Prov 22:16). granting a loan, while the latter has a negative con-
Upton Sinclair’s novel Oil! (1926–27) provides notation. In the legal and wisdom traditions, the
the basic structure of Paul Thomas Anderson’s There “righteous” and the “wicked” are opposed in re-
Will Be Blood (2007, US), a ruthless unmasking of the gards to lending money; the righteous lends
so-called Protestant work ethic and the American (MT lwh) out of pity or gives to the one in need
dream of entrepreneurial integrity and triumph. while the wicked practices usury by applying a high
Daniel Day-Lewis plays Daniel Plainview, a silver interest rate (MT nāšak, LXX τόκος; Exod 22:24; Lev

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
769 Moneylending 770
25:36–37; Deut 23:20; Ps 15:5; 37:21, 26; 112:5; sometimes seen as a reason for inflation and local
Prov 19:17; Ezek 18:8, 13, 17; see also the more de- economic crisis due to a weak local money supply
veloped passage Sir 29 which reflects economic (Neh 5). Nevertheless, the monetization appears late
problems in the Hellenistic period). Several passages and most of the taxation was levied in kind as evi-
condemn usury or interest-bearing lending among denced by the lyhd seals found in the administrative
Israelites but allow it for foreigners, probably mer- center of Ramat Rachel.
chants (Exod 22:24; Lev 25:36–37; Deut 23:20). This
Bibliography: ■ Altmann, P., Economics in Persian-Period Bibli-
ideology distinguishes subsistence lending from cal Texts (FAT 109; Tübingen 2016). ■ Chirichigno,
economic lending (see Sir 8:12 which advises G. C., Debt-Slavery in Israel and the Ancient Near East (JSOTSup
against lending to the rich). Being a lender is a sign 141; Sheffield 1993). ■ Hossfeld, F.-L./E. Reuter,
of prosperity, while being a debtor is a sign of de- “nāšâ,” TDOT 10 (Grand Rapids, Mich. 1999) 55–59.
■ Hudson M./M. Van de Mieroop (eds.), Debt and Economic
pendence and vulnerability (Deut 28:12, 44). This
vulnerability can be a source of conflict and social Renewal in the Ancient Near East (International Scholars Con-
tension (Jer 15:10; Neh 5). ference on Ancient Near Eastern Economies 3; Be-
thesda, Md. 2002). ■ Kapelrud, A. S., “nāšak,” TDOT 10
2. Function and History. The loan is made in (Grand Rapids, Mich. 1999) 61–65. ■ Kellermann, D., “II
front of witnesses and stipulates a pledge, a dead- lāwâ,” TDOT 7 (Grand Rapids, Mich. 1995) 477–78.
line, and an “interest” (nešek; tarbit; marbit; Lev Axel Bühler
25:36–37) which is expressed as an absolute amount
and not a percentage. Indeed, the term nešek, well II. Greco-Roman Antiquity
known from other Semitic languages, comes from a
root meaning “to bite” and refers to a loan where Moneylending is the act of loaning money by one
only a part of an amount is given but the full party to another – with or without interest
amount is due (e.g., 80 shekels are given but 100 (τόκος, fenus) – with the expectation of repayment.
shekels must be returned; 20 shekels are “bitten”). In Greco-Roman antiquity, the loan may or may not
The words tarbit and marbit, attested in many Ara- have involved a security deposit (ἀρραβών, pignus).
maic documents from the Persian period, come References to lending abound in the sources: papyri,
from the root “to multiply” and refer to an amount literature, inscriptions, etc. In the 6th-century BCE,
due each month until the debt is repaid. Solon abolished all debt in Athens (Plutarch, Solon
In case of non-payment, the pledge can be re- 15.3). Livy (7.27.3–4) documents fluctuating inter-
tained and frequently the debtor becomes a slave to est rates at Rome in the 4th-century BCE. Lending
repay the debt (see Chirichigno). According to the could involve considerable sums (e.g., Cicero’s bor-
Covenant Code and the Deuteronomic Law the slave rowing 3,500,000 sesterces [Letters to His Friends
had to work for six years before being freed (Exod 5.6.2; cf. Andreau 2020]). Temples and bankers
21:1–6; Deut 15:12–18). In comparison to the Laws (τραπεζίται, mensarii) served as lenders (e.g., the ta-
of Hammurabi (see Altmann: 42) this a quite severe bles of the Sulpicii, a family of bankers from Puteoli
stipulation, since the Law of Hammurabi releases in the 1st century CE; cf. Jones). Interest rates varied
the debtor after three years. The interest rate varies considerably. Thus, a 2nd-century CE inscription
greatly depending on the time, place, and circum- from Dacia: “Julius Alexander required a promise
stances, but also on whether it is a monetary loan in good faith that the interest on this principal …
or an in-kind loan (the former benefits from a more would be one percent per thirty days” (CIL 3.934–
advantageous rate). Nevertheless, lending is rarely 35). Also, “Earring left with Faustilla as collateral.
an economic activity in itself. It must be considered For a loan of two denarii [= thirty-two asses] she
as an ancillary activity of traders or a charitable ne- took as interest one bronze as from the sum of 30
cessity; interest, pledge or slavery are guarantees of [thirty-two?] [asses] (CIL 4.8203).” The potential pit-
the loan rather than a return. The temple in Jerusa- falls of borrowing as well as the questionable ethics
lem, like other temples in the ancient Near East, of lenders were well-known (e.g., Plutarch, That We
probably played an important role in monetary Ought Not to Borrow [Mor. 827D–832A]; cf. Maloney).
loans. Charity loans (i.e., interest-free loans) and Bibliography: ■ Andreau, J., Banking and Business in the Ro-
consumption loans in times of hardship may have man World (KTAH; Cambridge 1999). ■ Andreau, J., “Bank-
been granted. However, people asking for help may ing, Money-Lending, and Elite Financial Life in Rome,” in
have dedicated their children to the temple in ex- Roman Law and Economics, vol. 2: Exchange, Ownership, and Dis-
change. Unfortunately, the Bible does not provide putes (ed. G. Dari-Mattiacci/D. P. Kehoe; Cambridge 2020).
■ Jones, D., The Bankers of Puteoli: Finance, Trade and Industry
information on this subject. From the 6th century
in the Roman World (Stroud 2006). ■ Maloney, R. P., “Usury
BCE onwards (the Persian period), the economy un-
in Greek, Roman, and Rabbinic Thought,” Traditio 27 (1971)
derwent a privatization, as can be seen from the nu- 79–109. ■ Scheidel, W., “Money and Finance,” in The Cam-
merous economic archives of individuals (archives bridge Companion to the Roman Economy (ed. W. Scheidel; Cam-
of Bēl-rēmanni, Murašu, Zenon, Zū-Bala, etc.). The bridge 2013) 266–82. ■ Temin, P., The Roman Market Econ-
appearance of coins in the 4th century BCE and the omy (Princeton, N.J. 2013).
demand for the payment of taxes in this form is Trevor W. Thompson

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
771 Moneylending 772
III. New Testament even to enemies, characterizes the children of God
The HB/OT refers to the giving and taking of loans who will reward them.
on several occasions. Its main concern is not with The lack of other direct references to actual
the fact of such lending (which is not questioned as moneylending is surprising, as moneylending was
part of the realities of life), but with the conditions common on all levels of society and also served as
under which such lending occurs. While they may a means of creating social obligations and bonds.
do so from non-Israelites (Deut 23:19–20), Israelites Exhortatory texts regarding the proper use of mate-
are not to charge interest from their fellow Israelites rial means call Christians to give to each other and
(Exod 22:25; Lev 25:36–38; see also Ezek 18:8–17; to other people freely as they themselves received
Ps 15:5). The taking of pledges is strictly limited freely from God (Matt 10:8). As far as we know, Paul
(Deut 22:26). Lenders may not enter a house and accepted gifts but never borrowed from or lent to
seize pledges but are to accept what is offered to others nor did the communities which he founded.
them. If a cloak is given as a pledge, it is to be re- Rather than lending the money, they were to make
turned before night sets in so that the needy may a concentrated effort to gather the funds on a regu-
sleep in it. The blessing of the poor of those who lar basis (1 Cor 16:1–2).
lend to them fairly will be to the lender’s credit be- In the NT, the language of lending and debt also
fore God (Deut 24:6–17; Prov 19:17). There is to be occurs in a figurative sense (sin, forgiveness, expres-
remission of debt at regular intervals (Deut 15:1– sion of gratitude). For example, according to Paul,
15). When such stipulations are not followed and the gentile Christians owe a debt to the Jewish
injustice is rife, firm intervention is necessary to re- Christians of Jerusalem (Rom 15:27; see “Debt,
store justice (Neh 5; Amos 2:6–8). The HB/OT also Debts II. Hebrew Bible/Old Testament and III.
mentions the risks involved for the lenders (“The New Testament”).
wicked borrow and do not pay back,” Ps 37:21) and Bibliography: ■ Chilton, B., “Debts,” ABD 2 (1992) 114–16.
those who have to borrow money and are unable to ■ Crüsemann, M./W. Schottroff (eds.), Schuld und Schulden

pay back as agreed (2 Kgs 4:1). “The borrower is the (Munich 1992). ■ Ernst, M. et al., “Gewinn,” Sozialgeschicht-
slave of the lender” (Prov 22:7; with consequences liches Wörterbuch zur Bibel (ed. F. Crüsemann et al.; Gütersloh
up to losing one’s freedom). Therefore, both lend- 2009) 215–18. ■ Hays, C. M., Luke’s Wealth Ethics (WUNT.2
275; Tübingen 2010). ■ Schäfer-Lichtenberger, C.,
ing and borrowing may result in being cursed by
“Schulden,” Sozialgeschichtliches Wörterbuch zur Bibel (ed. F.
those affected (Jer 15:10). Giving and lending to Crüsemann et al., Gütersloh 2009) 509–15. ■ Schottroff, W.,
others generously characterizes a righteous person Gerechtigkeit lernen (ed. F. Crüsemann/R. Kessler; Gütersloh
(Pss 37:21, 26; 112:5). The ability to lend to many 1999).
nations (rather than having to borrow from them) Christoph Stenschke
is an indication of divine blessing (Deut 28:12, but
also v. 44). IV. Judaism
The potentially dire consequences of money- ■ Second Temple and Hellenistic Judaism ■ Rabbinic Ju-
lending also appear in the NT (Matt 5:25–26; daism ■ Medieval Judaism ■ Modern Judaism
18:23–35; Luke 7:41–42). Some parables of Jesus
mention moneylending. As an illustration of the A. Second Temple and Hellenistic Judaism
implications of divine forgiveness, Jesus speaks of a During the Second Temple period, moneylending
debtor whose tremendous financial debt is cancelled became much more common, as Judea and its envi-
and generously forgiven by the lender, but who fails rons transitioned to a more currency-based econ-
to cancel the small debt which others owe to him. omy, and elite and mercantile interests saw height-
In return, the cancellation is recalled and the entire ened opportunities for profit. The life of most
debt has to be paid (Matt 18:21–35). A shrewd man- Judeans revolved around a patrilocal (“house of the
ager reduces the debt in material goods which sev- father”) system in an agrarian context, and precari-
eral debtors owe to his master in order to endear ous circumstances were the norm. Only a small per-
himself to them (Luke 16:1–9). Jesus praises him for centage of the population enjoyed the benefits of
taking action in order to secure his future. The slave wealth, and the extant sources indicate a frequent
who in Jesus’ parable doubled the five talents en- willingness among lenders to capitalize on the gap
trusted to him while his master was away (Matt between rich and poor.
25:14–30; Luke 19:11–27), likely did so by lending In some of the sources, especially the wisdom lit-
the money out at extortionate interest rates rather erature, lending is encouraged as a means of helping
than by putting the money into the bank. a neighbor as required by the Torah. For example,
Following the stipulations of the Law regarding “The merciful lend to their neighbors; by holding out
the lending of money or goods, Jesus emphasizes a helping hand they keep the commandments” (Sir
the duty of supporting the needy with loans though 29:1). Even with such advice, problems might arise
nothing can be expected in return. There is no di- for borrowers, especially in light of the usurious
vine reward in lending to people where the return terms of most loans. Moreover, the mere charging of
is guaranteed (Luke 6:34–35). Generous lending, interest went against the stipulations of earlier legal

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
773 Moneylending 774
traditions, which prohibited usury among members 4–6) catalog contracts and institutions concerning
of the covenant community (e.g., Deut 23:19–20). Yet transactions known from the Roman world, and
creditors could and did change the terms of loans and mark each one as permitted or prohibited. They are
raise interest rates during the Second Temple period, thus useful for consumers and scribes, who give le-
a practice known as antichresis. Such penal lending gal language for economic transactions. In the Aqi-
could lead to loss of land and even debt slavery, as ex- van tannaitic corpus (Mishnah, Tosefta, Sifra, Sifrei,
emplified in Neh 5, where wealthy lenders force des- Mekhilta de-Rabbi Shimon), the prohibition on usury
perate borrowers into servitude during a famine pe- is decoupled from the duty to care for the poor. This
riod. decoupling continues in the Talmuds and classical
Contractual evidence from this period also midrash. Tannaitic literature (Mishnah and Tosefta)
points to interest charges as a regular feature of the employs the usury prohibition to envision an urban
regional economy, and the increase of written docu- society of equal citizens. Gentiles, dependent family
ments allowed for better adherence to the terms of members, and close friends are all excluded from
a loan. Yet the warnings in the Torah against loans the usury prohibition in different ways. This decou-
at interest continued to guide certain communities, pling ends only in later works such as the piyyutim
such as the sectarians responsible for the Dead Sea of Yannai and the Tanhuma midrashim, which re-
Scrolls (e.g., 4Q267 iv:9–10). Moreover, Philo pro- connect the usury prohibition to a concern about
hibits lending at interest among fellow believers poverty. Some (Gamoran) have read rabbinic usury
(Virt. 82) based on his reading of Mosaic traditions, legislation as “flexible,” changing according to the
and Josephus follows the same logic (Ant. 4.266). needs of the people and increasing the supply of
In addition to charging interest, it was common loans or allowing for the charging of certain mark-
in the Second Temple period to serve as guarantor ups on loans in order to increase the supply of
for a neighbor or associate. This practice, known as credit. Others (Neusner: ch. 5; Lapin: ch. 5; Gva-
surety, was condemned by the sages responsible for ryahu) have opposed this reading, pointing to the
Proverbs (e.g., Prov 6:1–5) and receives a mixed re- fact that there is scant evidence that Jews in the first
sponse in the Second Temple sources. Ben Sira en- centuries CE avoided usury. These scholars empha-
dorses vouching for the loan of another individual size the institutional and communal aspect of the
as a generous act that coheres with the benevolent usury laws rather than their more abstract macro-
spirit of Israel’s sapiential and legal traditions: “A economic impact. Central to the claim that rabbinic
good person will be surety for his neighbor, but the usury laws are flexible is the fact that a late stratum
one who has lost all sense of shame will fail him” of the Babylonian Talmud marked most of the
(Sir 29:14). In contrast to this advice, 4QInstruction, usury laws in the Mishnah as belonging to a lesser
from the Dead Sea Scrolls corpus, warns against prohibition, termed “dust of usury.” This is how-
standing surety for another person because of the ever grounded in the hermeneutic motives of the
inherent financial risks. A person might fall into Babylonian Talmud (Gvaryahu: ch. 3), not in the
penury by vouching for the loan of another (e.g., tannaitic or even early amoraic materials.
4Q418 88:3). The contrast between these two texts Individuals who lend at interest are disqualified
probably can be traced to different social locations: from testimony in court (mSan 3:3). This is a civic
Ben Sira had a more elite audience, while 4QIn- sanction, which deprives the moneylenders of their
struction circulated among those in more precarious standing as equals in their communities. This status
circumstances. What all of these sources share is the highlights the fact that lending at interest is an of-
difficulty in balancing the prohibitions against in- fence against the city, rather than against the poor
terest in earlier legal traditions with the reality of (Gvaryahu: ch. 5; Malka). Unlike the usury laws,
widespread lending in the Second Temple period. which the rabbis expanded and developed, they all
Bibliography: ■ Adams, S. L., Social and Economic Life in Sec- but abolished the sabbatical debt remission in sev-
ond Temple Judea (Louisville, Ky. 2014). ■ Murphy, eral ways, the most far-reaching of which is the pros-
C. M., Wealth in the Dead Sea Scrolls and in the Qumran Commu- bul, understood as a declaration stating that the len-
nity (STDJ 40; Leiden 2002). der can collect his loan any time he pleases (see
Samuel L. Adams mShevi 10; Llewelyn; Ancselovits).
B. Rabbinic Judaism Bibliography: ■ Ancselovits, E., “The Prosbul – A Legal Fic-
In rabbinic literature, moneylending is governed by tion?,” JLA 19 (2011) 1–16. ■ Gamoran, H., Jewish Law in
three discrete sets of laws: pledges (Deut 15:8, Transition: How Economic Forces Overcame the Prohibition against
24:10), usury (Exod 22:24; Deut 23:20–21), and she- Lending on Interest (Cincinnati, Ohio 2008). ■ Gvaryahu, A.,
mitøtøah, the once-in-seven year forgiving of debt “Lending at Interest in Rabbinic Literature: Law, Homilet-
ics, and Cultural Contacts” (PhD diss., The Hebrew Univer-
(Deut 15:1–3). The laws of pledges (mBM 9:13) are
sity of Jerusalem, 2019). [Heb.] ■ Lapin, H., Early Rabbinic
short, and largely unchanged in scope between the Civil Law and the Social History of Roman Galilee: A Study of
Bible and rabbinic literature. Rabbinic laws on Mishnah Tractate Baba Mesøia (Atlanta, Ga. 1995). ■ Llewelyn,
usury are broader and more complex than those in S. R., “The Procedure of the Execution and the Prosbolē,”
the HB/OT. Mishnah and Tosefta (mBM 5 and tBM in NDIEC, vol. 7: A Review of the Greek Inscriptions and Papyri

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
775 Moneylending 776
Published in 1982–83 (North Ryde, NSW 1994) 197–232. is received as a loan, and half as a deposit. The agent
■ Malka, O., “Disqualified Witnesses between Tannaitic Hal-
makes profit on the first, and the investor on the
akha and Roman Law: The Archeology of a Legal Institu- latter. (Jews did not limit themselves to rabbinic
tion,” Law and History Review (2019) 1–34. ■ Neusner, J., The
contracts, but also used among themselves contracts
Economics of the Mishnah (CSJH; Chicago, Ill. 1990).
from the majority Christian or Islamic culture.) The
Amit Gvaryahu
heter isqa (ca. 1600) allowed for greater flexibility in
C. Medieval Judaism the terms of the contract and greater security for
1. Moneylending in Medieval Jewish Sources. the investor.
Moneylending is addressed primarily in five types The interpretive issue which shifts most signifi-
of medieval Jewish texts: biblical commentary, tal- cantly between the classical rabbinic period and the
mudic commentary, rabbinic codes, responsa medieval regards taking “usury” from non-Jews.
(sheelot u-teshuvot), and polemical literature. Biblical Whereas talmudic commentators express a broad
commentary concentrates on the passages in the To- range of opinions, medieval rabbinic commentators
rah concerning loans, pledges, and “usury” (Exod in Christian Europe almost uniformly define Chris-
22:24–26; Lev 25:36–37; Deut 23:20–21; 24:10–13), tians as strangers (nokhrim), from whom one may
as well as the moral exhortations against “usury” in take usury (Deut 23:21). Medieval Christian com-
the Writings and Prophets (Ps 15:5; Prov 28:8; Ezek mentators, in polemics and disputations of the
18; 2 Kgs 4:1–2; Hab 2:6; Neh 5:1–11). Foremost 12th–14th centuries, contested this interpretation
medieval Jewish biblical exegetes include Rashi as well as others. Jewish polemics refuted Christian
(northern France, 1040–1105), Rashbam (northern challenges and defended Jewish biblical interpreta-
France, 1080–1158), Abraham Ibn Ezra (Spain, tion in texts such as: Sefer ha-Berit (The Book of the
1089–1167), Radaq (David Qimh i; Provence, 1160– Covenant) by Joseph Qimh i (ca. 1105–1170), the
1235), Nah manides (Moses ben Nah man; Spain, anonymous Sefer Nitsahø on Yashan (The old Book of
1194–1274), and Gersonides (Levi ben Gershom; Polemics), and Milhø emet Mitswah (Obligatory War)
Provence, 1288–1344). The commentators harmo- by Menahem ben Solomon Meiri (1249–after 1314).
nize the interpretation of biblical texts with rab- 2. The Myth of the Medieval Jewish Money-
binic law on loans, pledges, and interest or profit. lender. The most significant medieval develop-
They also explicate difficult biblical language ment for Judaism and Jewish communities was the
through literary, linguistic, and historical interpre- emergence in Western Europe of the image of the
tation (peshat) and through traditional exegetical Jew as usurer. This negative stereotype is errone-
methods of midrash. The central interpretive ques- ously assumed today to describe a social and eco-
tions revolve around clarifying: when one is obli- nomic fact – that moneylending was a Jewish occu-
gated to give a loan, the meaning of neshekh and pation. The persistence of this myth is due in part
tarbit (terms usually translated as “usury”; see, e.g., to modern antisemitic politics and in part to a poor
Lev 25:36; Ezek 18:8), from whom one may or may understanding of medieval economic history and
not take neshekh or tarbit (a poor or rich Jew; a thought.
brother [ahø ], resident alien [ger, toshav], or foreigner “Usury” is often incorrectly read as a pejorative,
[nokhri]), whether a borrower also sins by paying nes- premodern term for “interest.” But usury, then as
hekh or tarbit, and how lenders should preserve the today, referred to exploitative and illegal profit as
dignity of borrowers and extend mercy to them, defined by custom, culture, and religious law. In
particularly in regard to seizure of pledges. probing the ethical and legal limits of just profit,
Medieval rabbinic authorities also codified and medieval religious authorities – Jewish, Christian,
elaborated the halakhah on moneylending, which and Muslim – all developed sophisticated economic
had been developed in the Mishnah and Talmud on thought on markets and prices, contracts, loans, in-
the basis of the biblical passages. Great care was terest, currency exchange, and commercial invest-
taken to define gray areas where illicit interest ment. Ethical concerns did not obstruct economic
might knowingly or unknowingly change hands: growth. Rather, they simultaneously produced
loans of produce, purchase on credit, advance pay- more precise definitions of usury and more expan-
ment for goods, mortgages, and investments. The sive permissions on profit. Both were driven by the
responsa literature extends the legal thinking on religious aim to fulfill divine law, particularly the
lending and shows that rabbinic laws were widely biblical precepts on usury. Two examples warrant
practiced in medieval Jewish communities. Observa- mention: the term “interest” was created by medie-
tion of rabbinic prohibitions did not mean the end val Christian theologians and canon lawyers to de-
of intra-Jewish credit, nor widespread deployment fine permissible profit on a loan due to loss, dam-
of fictitious workarounds. For example, commercial age, or injury. Investment loans were permitted by
investments generating profit could take place be- Jewish, Muslim, and Christian law when the inves-
tween Jews through a contract known as an isqa in tor shared risks as well as profits with the agent,
which the investor splits the profit with the agent. as in the contracts known as isqa, mudø āraba, and
No usury takes place, because half of the investment commenda, respectively.

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
777 Moneylending 778
It is often assumed that medieval Christians Economic-theological concepts put forward by
were not allowed to lend on interest, and Jews the friars contributed to the growth of anti-Juda-
therefore became Europe’s moneylenders. Both as- ism. The friars, embracing voluntary poverty as the
sumptions are incorrect. Jews did lend money, but fullest expression of the apostolic life, expanded the
the majority of professional moneylenders, money early Christian theological language infused with
changers, bankers, and merchants were Christian. economic concepts. Economic trust was fused with
Some Jews were wealthy moneylenders and mer- religious faith, and mistrust with infidelity. The NT
chants. But most Jews, like most Christians, were figure Judas, who had misvalued the incommensu-
too poor to have been either. Second, the limits on rate worth of the savior at thirty talents of silver,
lending for Christians, whether interest rates set by became a prototype for the contemporary Jew and
secular rulers or canonical decrees against usury, his obstinate unbelief, his economic misvaluation,
were extended to Jews as well. and hostility to Christ(ians). The Jew became the
The stereotype of the Jewish usurer emerged prototype for the false Christian whose usury in-
over the 12th to 15th centuries out of a campaign jured the Christian commune. From the late 13th–
against lay Christian usury. The campaign was put 15th centuries, entire Jewish communities were
in motion by a reforming papacy driven by concerns characterized as usurers, and mass expulsions in
over protecting the property of the church and her Western Europe were justified on this basis.
crusaders, strengthening papal authority, and re- From the early modern period to today, the
forming lay and clerical Christian practices. When
myth of the medieval Jewish moneylender has con-
the usury campaign became involved with religious
tributed to anti-Judaism and antisemitism. Yet, the
movements avowing abject, voluntary poverty
myth has also been sustained by Jewish leaders and
(Waldensians, Franciscans, etc.), the repression of
philosemitic scholars who have embraced the image
“heresies,” and the new theological and legal stud-
of Jewish moneymaking as a contribution to the so-
ies at universities, the church’s ancient theological-
economic language of salvation swelled into an ac- ciety. By revaluing the act of moneylending as a
rid anti-Jewish rhetoric. credit instrument necessary for economic develop-
In the new climate of orthodoxy and heresy, re- ment, they recast the greedy, Jewish usurer as a ben-
jection of Christian “truth” was manifest evidence eficial, modernizing agent: Jews furnished Europe
of irrationality, if not willful disbelief. Jewish unbe- with credit, but suffered an antisemitic backlash for
lief was consequently akin to heresy. In the milieu doing so. Both the antisemitic portrait of the Jewish
of crusading, Jews were imagined as a dangerous, usurer and the philosemitic view of “Jewish eco-
internal enemy with a psychotic hatred of Christ nomic function” misunderstand the dynamics of
and Christians. The image of the hostile Jew was medieval economic history and thought in relation
projected into the vicious and bizarre accounts fab- to biblical directives on usury.
ricated about ritual murder, blood libel, and host Bibliography: ■ Baldwin, J., Masters, Princes, and Merchants:
desecration by Jews. In this context, moneylending The Social Views of Peter the Chanter and his Circle (Princeton,
was seen as a way that Jews could gain abusive N.J. 1970). ■ Cohn, H. H./B. Z. Eliash, “Usury,” EncJud 20
power over Christians. (Detroit, Mich. 22007) 437–43. ■ Dorin, R., “Banishing

The reforming papacy used canon law widely to Usury: The Expulsion of Foreign Moneylenders in Medieval
reform Christendom, and specifically to suppress Europe, 1200–1450” (PhD diss.; Harvard University, 2015).
■ Gamoran, H., Jewish Law in Transition: How Economic Forces
Jews’ authority over Christians and separate them
socially and economically. Canonical decrees were Overcame the Prohibition against Lending on Interest (Cincinnati,
Ohio 2008). ■ Karp, J., The Politics of Jewish Commerce: Eco-
issued against Jews holding public office, employ-
nomic Thought and Emancipation in Europe, 1638–1848 (Cam-
ing Christian servants, comingling in taverns, bath- bridge 2008). ■ Kellenbenz, H. et al., “Banking and Bank-
houses, or parties, selling food to, or having sexual ers,” EncJud 3 (Detroit, Mich. 22007) 111–19.
liaisons with Christians. Jews were to be distin- ■ McLaughlin, T. P., “The Teaching of the Canonists on

guished by badges or distinctive clothing. Jewish Usury,” Mediaeval Studies 1 (1939) 81–147; and 2 (1940) 1–
“blasphemy” and “magic” were condemned, and 22. ■ Mell, J., The Myth of the Medieval Jewish Moneylender, 2
many copies of the Talmud burned. Usury too be- vols. (New York 2017–18). ■ Mundill, R., England’s Jewish
came part of this anti-Judaic legislation, as the Solution: Experiment and Expulsion, 1262–90 (Cambridge 1998).
■ Penslar, D., Shylock’s Children: Economics and Jewish Identity in
Christian anti-usury campaign widened. But the pa-
pacy first turned to secular rulers to curtail Jewish Modern Europe (Berkeley, Calif. 2001). ■ Satlow, M. (ed.), Ju-
usury. Rulers implemented royal registries for Jew- daism and the Economy: A Sourcebook (London 2019). ■ Shatz-
miller, J., Shylock Reconsidered (Berkeley, Calif. 1990). ■ So-
ish-Christian loans, conducted inquests into usury
loveitchik, H., “Usury and Moneylending,” in id., Collected
(Christian and Jewish), set interest rates, and ex- Essays, vol. 1 (Oxford/Portland, Oreg. 2013) 41–168.
pelled foreign Christian and Jewish usurers. What ■ Stein, S., “Moneylending,” EncJud 14 (Detroit, Mich. 22007)
had begun as a church campaign to protect her 436–43. ■ Toch, M., The Economic History of European Jews:
property and her crusaders ballooned into a cam- Late Antiquity and Early Middle Ages (Leiden/Boston, Mass.
paign protecting all Christians and their property 2013). ■ Toch, M./E. Müller-Luckner (eds.), Wirtschaftsge-
against “false Christians” and “infidels.” schichte der mittelalterlichen Juden: Fragen und Einschätzungen

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
779 Moneylending 780
(Munich 2008). ■ Todeschini, G., Franciscan Wealth (St. Bon- Together, these developments have made con-
aventure, N.Y. 2009). tracts between Jews no different than from those
Julie Mell between gentiles, and they eventually allowed Jews
D. Modern Judaism to become consumers in the emergent retail-bank-
ing industry. The prohibition against usury has
The “Jewish” profession of moneylending did not thus become almost a dead letter in the otherwise
spur significant innovation in the modern Jewish observant Jewish community.
treatment of moneylending, whether legal or homi-
letical. However, three other critical developments Bibliography: ■ Bleich, J. D., “Survey of Recent Halakhic
Periodical Literature: The Hetter Iska and American
in modern Jewish history have made the prohibi-
Courts,” Trad. 42.3 (2009) 49–79. ■ Feinstein, M., Iggerot
tion on usury nearly inoperative in most contexts in Mosheh, vol. 8 (OH 5; YD 4; New York 1996). [Heb.] ■ Ga-
the present. moran, H., Jewish Law in Transition: How Economic Forces Over-
The first development is the creation of the legal came the Prohibition against Lending on Interest (Cincinnati,
instrument known as heter isqa, “the permission of Ohio 2008). ■ Gvaryahu, A., “A Bill to Allow Banking

partnership.” This instrument was pioneered by (Heter Isqa),” in Judaism and the Economy: A Sourcebook (ed. M.
Isaiah Menahem ben Isaac Avigdors of Krakow Satlow; London/New York 2019) 198–201. ■ Halperin, I./I.
Bartal (eds.), The Records of the Council of the Four Lands, vol. 1
(d. 1599), and it is in use to this day and known
(Jerusalem 21990). [Heb.] ■ Rosin, J., Tsofnat Paneahø (War-
eponymously as Heter MaHaRaM (The permission of saw 1938).
Rabbi Menahem; Gamoran: 159–63; Bleich); it Amit Gvaryahu
builds on earlier work casting loans as investments.
Other instruments were sanctioned by the Polish V. Christianity
halakhist Joshua Falk Cohen (1555–1614), Avig- ■ Patristics and Orthodox Churches ■ Medieval Times

dors’ sucessor as rabbi in Lodomeria, in his Qun- and Reformation Era ■ Modern Europe and
tresal dinei ribbit (Treatise on the laws of interest), America ■ New Christian Churches and Move-
and commissioned by the Council of the Four Lands ments ■ Africa and Southeast Asia
of Poland and Lithuania (1607). R. Joshua Falk of- A. Patristics and Orthodox Churches
fered laypeople instructions about how to avoid the Almost without exception, patristic theologians
prohibition and admonished them to do so, while condemned moneylending at any rate of interest.
supplying rabbis with “permissions” (heterim) in a Three biblical passages are often referenced in sup-
second, more specialized segment of his treatise port of this position toward moneylending: most
(Halperin/Bartal: 1:18–25; Gamoran: 162). There frequently, Ps 15:5; less frequently, Jesus’ parable
was a similar development in Ottoman Egypt about the talents (cf. Matt 25:14–30); least fre-
(ibid.: 164–66). In contemporary times, most Israeli quently, reference to moneylending in expositions
banks have a generic “permission” bill on hand that of Ps 37:21. There are occasional references in expo-
covers all of their transactions (ibid.: 172–75; Gva- sitions of these biblical passages to Levitical injunc-
ryahu). The bill today is used not only for commer- tions against moneylending, which seem to influ-
cial loans but for consumer loans as well. ence Jesus’ – and later patristic theologians’ – views
The Sanhedrin of Paris (articles 8 and 9), decreed towards individuals in need. These references
in 1812 that Jews were forbidden from taking stressed the attitude of loving-kindness from the
usury usure from anyone, Jew or gentile, whereas moneylender towards the one in financial distress,
legal intérêt charged on loans for “enterprise and especially when this distress involved family; re-
speculation of commerce” was permitted to be garding those in difficulty: “You shall not lend
taken from all – Jew or gentile. This ruling was ex- them money at interest taken in advance or provide
plicitly rooted in the exegesis of the Biblical Hebrew them with food at a profit” (Lev 25:35–37).
terms neshekh and tarbit (Lev 25:36–37), “correcting” We may divide comments made about money-
widespread “misunderstanding” about them, and lending in patristic homilies into three different
offering a new rationale for them. categories: The first is offhand remarks against
The Orthodox halakhic decisor R. Moshe Fein- moneylending. For example, in his exposition of Ps
stein, writing in the 1960s, approved of the wide- 14, Athanasius stated little more than the passage
spread practice of religiously observant Jews in the itself, that followers of Christ may not lend money
US of availing themselves of retail banking for cur- at interest (Athanasius, Expositiones in Psalmos, Ps.
rent accounts, despite the fact that this could be 14). The second category is digressions from errors
construed as lending at interest (Feinstein: YD, of lending money to spiritual meanings of economic
4:62–64; Gamoran: 174–75). Feinstein suggested terminology. Cassiodorus, for instance, taught that
that the bank’s status as a limited liability corpora- moneylending is an ambivalent word. Bad money-
tion meant that it was an entity separate from its lending is money lent at interest that ought to have
shareholders, and not liable to the laws of interest; otherwise gone to the poor, while good moneylend-
he did not allow retail borrowing from banks (cf. ing is preaching and teaching the Gospel (Cassiodo-
Rosin: 182). rus: 155–60). The third is lengthy expositions

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
781 Moneylending 782
against the practice of moneylending. We find such usury was a much more loosely used word that
expositions in texts by Basil the Great, Gregory of sometimes could have a positive meaning, while
Nyssa, and Ambrose of Milan, who composed ser- those wishing to disguise dubious transactions
mons specifically devoted to refuting the practice naturally tried to redefine their activities in terms
(Basil, Homilia in psalmum 14; Ambrose, Tob.; Greg- of a verum interesse. One response to this ambiguity
ory of Nyssa, Contra usurarios). Drawing heavily on was to develop guidelines for regulating interest
Deuteronomy, Ps 15, and Greek and Roman phi- rates. The purpose of this effort was not to accept
losophy, they addressed ethical, social, and theo- any interest rate as legitimate, but to define accept-
logical implications of the practice. Common able interest rates and condemn usurious practices
themes include usury as theft, lies of the lender, that took advantage of the vulnerable.
anxiety of borrower and lender, enslavement to ava- Regarding the recipients of moneylending, Mar-
rice, and heavenly usury. tin Luther wrote that a Christian “should be willing
Later Christian theologians inherited these to lend and give to everyone who asks him. Yet if
negative patristic stances and continued the con- he knows that this is a scoundrel, he is not obliged
demnation of moneylending. Until the High Mid- to give it to him” (LW 21:117). Other reformers like
dle Ages, the church stood firmly against any lend- John Calvin and Martin Bucer, following the usage
ing with interest. Taking their cue from laws, the of the Roman civil law, distinguished between legit-
HB, free lending encouraged by Jesus and recogni- imate usury (which included uncontested practices
tion by philosophers that usury is unethical and un- as the lending of land to farm) and illegitimate
social, early Christian bishops wrote in explicit usury, which caused confusion over whether the re-
terms against moneylending. formers allowed usury in the narrowly defined or
Bibliography: ■ Cassiodorus, Explanation of the Psalms (ACW broader popular sense (Kerridge: 30). Anabaptists
51; Mahwah, N.J. 1990). ■ Percival, H. R., The Seven Ecumen- denounced all interest-taking and expected mem-
ical Councils of the Undivided Church: Their Canons and Dogmatic bers to abandon any usurious enterprise before join-
Decrees, Together with the Canons of All the Local Synods which ing the brotherhood (Klassen: 97).
have received Ecumenical Acceptance (Peabody, Mass. 1999).
Bibliography: ■ Kerridge, E., Usury, Interest and the Reforma-
Brenda Llewellyn Ihssen tion (Aldershot 2002). ■ Klassen, P. J., The Economics of Ana-
B. Medieval Times and Reformation Era baptism 1525–1560 (The Hague 1964). ■ Lier, S./C. Schwei-
ger (eds.), Between Creativity and Norm-Making: Tensions in the
During the medieval and Reformation eras, Chris-
Early Modern Era (Leiden 2013). ■ Rex, R., The Making of
tian teaching about moneylending depended on Martin Luther (Princeton, N.J. 2017). ■ Torvend, S., Luther and
whether it was considered usury or interest. Confu- the Hungry Poor (Philadelphia, Pa. 2008).
sion over these terms and the tendency not to dis- Esther Chung-Kim
tinguish clearly between them contributed to the
misconception that Christianity imposed a univer- C. Modern Europe and America
sal ban on all forms of interest. Yet “there was a Christian teachings about lending money in early
world of difference between usury and interest” modernity were first based upon received medieval
(Kerridge: 5). Theologians distinguished between and reformation patterns wherein usury, i.e., lend-
sinful usury and legitimate interest, and this dis- ing money at excessive interest, was absolutely pro-
tinction was crucial in determining the ethics of hibited, although lending in hopes of a profit if the
moneylending. Medieval writers delineated four principal was at risk was allowed. In England in
grounds of entitlement to interest. The first three 1611, the chaplain to the Lord High Chancellor,
related to an agreed penalty or loss of opportunity Roger Fenton produced a treatise decrying contem-
if repayment was delayed beyond the stipulated porary, actual uses of credit practiced in London
date. The fourth came from the risk shared between trade, high and low. Fenton employed a full range
lender and borrower, for example in a trading voy- of biblical references – Exod 22, Lev 25, Deut 23, Ps
age. During the South German Interest Rate Con- 15, Ezek 18, and more – to argue for the elimina-
troversy in 1514–15, Johannes Eck espoused a mod- tion of all forms of lending money at interest. His
erate interest of up to five percent as acceptable views were influential in Anglican and Puritan cir-
(Rex: 109; Lier/Schweiger: 200). cles alike. Yet but a few short decades later, Protes-
Moneylending, which received compensation tant clergy in Holland, England, and America had
due to an individual’s interest in a business (verum come around to the morality of lending. The reason
interesse), was acceptable up to an extent, while for the change was to be found in the era of explora-
usury was unjust interest that took above and be- tion and increased international trade, beginning
yond the principal solely in return for a secured around 1650.
loan. Several biblical examples recognized this dis- The Catholic nations of France and Spain carried
tinction between usury and interest. Psalm 15 con- on their economies in hard currency enlarged by Pe-
demned the usurer, but Jesus Christ in the parable ruvian silver and Mexican gold and were thus able
of the talents (Matt 25:14–30) emphatically recom- to continue to observe the taboo on lending money
mended depositing accounts with interest. Yet at interest. The Protestant nations of England and

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
783 Moneylending 784
the Netherlands came, by contrast, to depend on economic systems should not underprivilege the
new forms of paper money to expand their econo- poor. In the same year, Justin Welby, Archbishop
mies – bills of exchange, notes, and bonds – that of Canterbury, vigorously opposed “pay day loans,”
as conceptual money led to innovations in thinking which are made to poverty-stricken individuals with
about valuing and discounting particular instru- insufficient funds to meet their financial needs un-
ments in relation to time, distance, and risk of re- til they are paid by their employers. Such loans
payment. Conceptually, the religious meaning of could incur interest equivalent to as much as 4,000
lending in these lands and in early America shifted percent per annum.
to what rates of interest were just and unjust under In his Interest and Usury, B. W. Dempsey distin-
particular circumstances. A lively Protestant clerical guishes between two types of loan – one to buy fin-
literature on each side of the Atlantic sought to deal ished goods in order to reduce the waiting time for
with the traditional biblical teachings in a changed their acquisition, and another to buy unfinished
context, not unlike centuries of rabbinical thought goods with a view to improving them and selling
that had likewise squared trade with justice. them in a completed state. Most Christians would
In the late 18th century views shifted again find no objection to the latter, and most would only
when Jeremy Bentham argued against Adam Smith refuse to charge interest to members of their own
in favor of lifting any caps on rates of interest, community, in line with the ancient Jewish practice
Smith having argued that high rates invited moral of only seeking usury from foreigners (Deut 23:20).
imprudence and unproductive projects for lenders Jesus’ parable of the talents (Luke 19:11–27) is
and creditors alike. Half a century later Papal policy often taken to recommend investing one’s money
at last relaxed the practical prohibition against for interest; however, Protestant writer Paul Mills
Catholics lending money at interest, so long as it points out that the master describes himself as a
was just. Usury was finally omitted from doctrine “hard man,” “reaping what I did not sow” (Luke
in the 1983 Code of Canon Law. Still, the morality of 19:22), thus implying that attracting interest for
money lending survives in the culturally Christian lent money is unjustifiable unearned income. He
secular West in the form of hotly debated laws set- contends, however, that lending money to an indi-
ting maximum interest rates well into the 21st cen- vidual usually differs from lending money for busi-
tury on grounds that the prophet Amos (8:5–6) ar- ness ventures, which involves risk-taking and profit
gued, namely that credit too easily allows the rich sharing, although ethical considerations must be
and powerful to exploit the poor. taken into account, for example if one were to in-
Bibliography: ■ Bentham, J., Defense of Usury: Shewing the Im- vest in alcohol, tobacco, armaments, or pornogra-
policy of the Present Legal Restraints on the Terms of Pecuniary phy.
Bargains (London 31816). ■ Fenton, R., A Treatise of Usurie Bibliography: ■ Dempsey, B. W., Interest and Usury (London
(London 1611). ■ Valeri, M., “The Christianization of
1948). ■ Mills, P., “Investing as a Christian: reaping where
Usury in Early Modern Europe,” Interpretation 65.2 (April you have not sown?,” Cambridge Papers 5.2 (June 1996;
2011; https://journals.sagepub.com). www.jubilee-centre.org). ■ Pope Francis, Evangelii Gaudium
James Hudnut-Beumler (Vatican 2013). ■ Pope Pius XI, Quadragesimo Anni (Vatican
D. New Christian Churches and Movements 1933). ■ Tomielli, A./G. Galeazzi (eds), This Economy Kills:
Pope Francis on Capitalism and Social Justice (Collegeville,
Most present-day Christian organizations accept Minn. 2015).
that moneylending is a necessity in contemporary George D. Chryssides
economic conditions. The Claretians are a rare ex-
ception: founded in 1849 as of the Congregation of E. Africa and Southeast Asia
the Missionary Sons of the Immaculate Heart of Moneylending among majority world Christians is
Mary, its members hold that accruing interest on common among ministers, kinsfolk, and close
lent money is sinful (Exod 22:25). In the main, friends. Calls to give or lend are seen in 1 John
Christian commentators argue that prohibitions on 3:17–18 (“But whoever has the world’s material
“usury” belong to the Old Covenant, and are not possessions and observes his brother in need and
binding on Christians. Christian objections to exact- shuts his heart against him, how does the love of
ing interest arise where a loan is exploitative, or the God reside in him?”). Pietistic Christians see Luke
interest excessive. In 1931, during the Great De- 6:34 as calls to lend generously, but without any
pression, Pope Pius XI issued the encyclical Quadra- kinship, tribal or ethnic ties, seldom does one lend
gesimo Anno, in which he deplored the way in which to an enemy (Luke 6:35) or to unbelievers. This is es-
“an immense power and despotic economic dicta- pecially true in India, Sri Lanka, Thailand, and
torship is consolidated in the hands of a few,” with many Muslim majority nations to avoid charges of
the result that those who manage investments con- financially-induced conversions.
trol the lending process. In his 2013 Evangelii Gau- In patron-client cultures, interpersonal concerns
dium Pope Francis condemned the progressive accu- include moneylending as meeting another person’s
mulation of debt in poor countries, for which need. For example, African Christians place money-
interest was required, and he urged that the world’s lending into relationships of care between powerful

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
785 Moneylending 786
patrons and those working their land or businesses. almsgiving fruitful.” Also, S 3:130 says: “O you who
Thus, while the needy understand Phil 4:19 as God believe! Do not devour [ribā], doubling and quadru-
meeting their financial needs, they are not averse to pling (the sum lent).” The Qurān describes the
borrowing. These sustain a culture of moneylend- practice of ribā as “devouring people’s wealth by
ing, but, outside these relationships, Christians gen- false pretenses” (S 4:161).
erally shun such practices. Moreover, African and The Qurān also makes a distinction between
Asian Christians understand that lending cannot be trading and ribā: “God permits trading and forbids
exploitative, since the love of money is the root of [ribā]” (S 2:275). Money generated by trading is legal
all evil (1 Tim 6:10). Lending in the majority world because the increase of money is generated by the
is virtuous when it meets the needs of poor kinsfolk exchange of goods and commodities while ribā is
and is offered without interest (so that lenders avoid the increase of money without any exchange of
shame and charges of exploitation). They may or goods (al-T ūsı̄: 360). Also, with trading, there is the
may not be familiar with biblical injunctions not prospect of earning profit and there is the risk of
to charge interest (in Lev 25:35–38) or to hold collat- incurring loss. Ribā, however, is the earning of
eral from the borrower (Deut 24:10–13), but money regardless of the outcomes. Hence, “there
their moneylending practices nevertheless parallel can be no doubt that the payment of something def-
those prescribed in the Bible. inite in return for something uncertain inflicts a
Most moneylending involves small and moder- harm” (Chapra: 10). The Qurān chastises those who
ate amounts, but larger sums require greater discre- equate ribā with trading because ribā is in conflict
tion. If loans are requested too often, they strain with the socio-economic justice of the Qurān.
relationships. In Malaysia and Singapore, there is Moreover, to equate trading with ribā is an outright
an unspoken understanding that borrowers should disbelief (kufr) in the Qurān and whoever profits
repay (Luke 12:48; Prov 22:7; Rom 13:7–8). Even from ribā is an unbeliever (kāfir) (al-T ūsı̄: 362). The
so, lenders downplay this to avoid conveying that prophet Muh ammad also spoke against ribā in the
their relationship is reduced to settling balances or strongest terms and condemned not only those who
to an ungenerous spirit. However, if requests are benefit from ribā but also those who give it as well
made too often, they strain relationships. If borrow- as those who record the transaction or act as wit-
ers cannot repay, the loan is often written off as a nesses to it (Sø ahø ı̄hø al-Bukhārı̄, vol. 7, bk. 72,
gift. In such cases, 2 Cor 9:6–8 (“God loves the no. 829; Sø ahø ı̄hø Muslim, bk. 10, Hadith 3854). Muh -
cheerful giver”) and Luke 6:38 (“give … for with the ammad even went further to equate ribā with as-
measure you use it will be measured back to you”) signing partners to God (shirk), killing an innocent
are sometimes applied to moneylending. soul, consuming the property of an orphan, and
Community-wise, when majority world nations slandering chaste women (Abū Dāwud bk. 11, Ha-
modernized, the lack of charitable institutions dith 2868). In the Sharia (Islamic law), ribā is de-
stirred local Christian giving practices to follow the fined as the premium that must be paid by the bor-
examples of missionaries who gave (but did not rower “as a condition for the loan or for an
lend) to the poor. This later stimulated other non- extension in its maturity … In this sense, ribā has
Christian faiths to establish charitable institutions the same meaning and import as interest,” accord-
that gave, not lent, money. ing to all the schools of law (Chapra: 4–5; al-Ja-
zı̄rı̄: 304). The Qurān’s condemnation of ribā was a
Bibliography: ■ Bonk, J. J., Missions and Money, revised and reaction to the injustices that occurred in pre-Is-
expanded (Maryknoll, N.Y. 2006). ■ De Neui, P. H. (ed.), lamic Arabia from the widespread practices of
Complexities of Money and Missions in Asia (Pasadena, Calif.
charging interest at the time. The Qurān wanted to
2012). ■ Maranz, D., African Friends and Money Matters (Dal-
las, Tex. 2001). guarantee a healthy financial system that is free
John Cheong from exploitation and fair for both moneylenders
and borrowers.
VI. Islam Bibliography: ■ Chapra, M. U., “The Nature of Riba in Is-
lam,” Hambard Islamicus 7.1 (1984) 3–24. ■ McAuliffe, J.
The Qurān not only provides legal injunctions in (ed.), The Qurān (New York/London 2017). ■ al-Jazı̄rı̄, A. R.,
regard to dealing with money and with the methods Kitab al-Fiqh, vol. 2 (Beirut 22003). ■ al-Tūsı̄, Abū Jafar

by which money is gained, but also sets strict guide- Muh ammad b. al-H  asan, Al-Tibyān fı̄ Tafsı̄r al-Qurān, vol. 2
lines on profit generated through moneylending. (Beirut n.d.). [Available at www.hadithcollection.com]
Receiving interest or any monetary profit through Hussam Timani
moneylending is prohibited outright in Islam (cf.
Exod 22:25; Lev 25:36–37; Deut 23:19–20; Neh 5:7). VII. Literature
Charging interest on borrowed money is referred to As other entries have shown, biblical injunctions re-
in the Qurān as ribā or usury, which means an in- lating to moneylending tend to accept it as an eco-
crease or growth in capital (al-T ūsı̄: 359). S 2:275– nomic necessity while urging restraint and generos-
76 illustrate the strict prohibition of ribā: “God … ity in the lender. The term “usury” in English
forbids [ribā]. God has blighted [ribā] and made connotes unscrupulous moneylending and there is

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
787 Moneylending 788
a fine distinction between the two. The rise of mer- (1870) were influenced by the anonymous Lazarillo
cantilism in Europe brought the tensions between de Tormes (1554), in Spanish literature a founda-
“acceptable” and “unacceptable” practice to the tional treatment of the theme of Dives and Lazarus
fore, with (for example) the trope of Christ driving (Alfieri: 723–25).
the moneychangers/-lenders from the temple part Moneylending as a symptom of unwelcome for-
of the anti-usury discourse. For Hyam Maccoby, the eign practices in evident in Gogol’s Dead Souls
Fourth Gospel’s treatment of Judas as the treasurer (1842), in Pushkin’s drama, The Miserly Knight
among the disciples of Jesus (John 12:3–6) “was a (1830) – made into an opera by Rachmaninov – and
most fateful development for the history of an- the short story “The Queen of Spades” (1834) –
tisemitism” (Maccoby: 63). made into an opera by Tchaikovsky – as well as in
While discussion of moneylending in literature Dostoevsky’s novel, The Gambler (1866) – made into
often tends to be tilted towards the issue of the anti- an opera by Prokofiev. In all these cases moneylend-
Semitism inherent in the medieval relegation of ing is associated with modernity rather than having
Jews to the role of userers through a dark form of anti-Semitic overtones.
Christian moral expediency, it is also true that early Arnold Wesker’s play The Merchant (1975) revis-
modern societies struggled more generally with the its the situation of Shylock, placing him in the Jew-
topic. In particular, in Russia moneylending at- ish ghetto in Venice in 1563, with its vibrant cul-
tracted the opprobrium associated with foreign in- tural life despite the limitations of the ghetto in
terference in Slavic culture. Usury in this context is which the main protagonist, confined to money-
vilified because it represents modernity. Similarly, lending as an occupation, is “bled dry by the Vene-
in England the intense debate about usury during tian tax-collector and compelled to purchase civic
the 16th and 17th centuries often revolved around rights by a contract whose renewal is uncertain”
the threat which usury presented to the status quo. (Sicher: 60).
In a paraphrase of Thomas Lodge’s An Alarum An interview with the author Gregor von Rez-
Against Userers (1584), “Usury is a means by which zori published in 1983 revealed disturbingly that
the low-born can get the land and money of the the medieval view of the relationship between Jews
high-born and invert the social order” (Berek: 147). and moneylending had not entirely died out (Hoff-
Dante in Inferno 11:109–11 contrasted the atti- man: 238–39). Tom Wolf’s novel The Bonfire of Vani-
tudes of userers with the vision set out in Gen 1. ties (1987) more broadly used a quasi-biblical trope
These were people who placed their hopes not in to highlight the excesses of Wall Street bond-trad-
God’s promise of abundance within Creation: ing using borrowed money.
They place their hopes in other things, and thus
Make mock of Nature’s self and her close kin. Bibliography. Primary: ■ Dante, A., Inferno (trans. R. Kirk-
(Dante: 97) patrick; London 2006).
Secondary: ■ Alfieri, J. J., “The Double Language of Avarice
For this these Florentines are consigned to the sev- in Galdós’ Novels,” Hisp. 46 (1963) 722–29. ■ Berek, P.,
enth circle of Hell. “The Jew as Renaissance Man,” RenQ 51.1 (1998) 128–62.
John Donne’s poem, “Love’s Usury” (ca. 1590) ■ Hoffman, N. Y., “The Temptations of Betrayal,” Southwest

daringly treats the raptures of love-making as a Review 68.3 (1983) 234–49. ■ Maccoby, H., Judas Iscariot and
form of borrowing from the future in a reversal of the Myth of Jewish Evil (New York 1992). ■ Rosenshield, G.,
the usual biblical connotations of the term and this “Gambling and Passion: Pushkin’s ‘The Queen of Spades’
and Doestoevsky’s ‘The Gambler,’” The Slavic and East Euro-
from an author deeply imbued with biblical no- pean Journal 55.2 (2011) 205–28. ■ Sicher, E., “The Jewing
tions. of Shylock: Wesker’s ‘The Merchant,’” Modern Language Stud-
William Shakespeare’s The Merchant of Venice ies 21.2 (1991) 57–69. ■ Smith, E., “Was Shylock Jewish?,”
(1605) clearly is a crucial text for understanding the Shakespeare Quarterly 64.2 (2013) 188–219.
moral ambiguities surrounding moneylending dur- Anthony Swindell
ing the Renaissance. Emma Smith points out that
the term “Jew” had become less of a racial signifier VIII. Visual Arts
than one specifically related to the occupation of Moneylenders were common in Christian religious
moneylending and equally that English anti-Semi- and secular art of the Middle Ages. Though not all
tism could be read as a cipher for other forms of medieval moneylenders were Jewish (in fact a rela-
racial prejudice, such as anti-Hispanic sentiment tively small number of Jews held lucrative positions
(Smith: 217). Previously Robert Wilson’s play The in the field), artists created a strong visual connec-
Three Ladies of London (1581) had presented the Jew- tion between this occupation and Judaism. This
ish moneylender Gerontus as a generous and car- connection, which Christians rooted in the HB/OT
ing man. (e.g., Lev 25:35–37; Deut 23:19–20; Ps 112:4–9;
The novels of Benito Pérez Galdós are much Matt 5:40–42) instigated and aggravated medieval
concerned with avarice. Gloria (1877) treats the char- antisemitism. The material culture of medieval
acter Juan Amarillo as a miser and userer, cast in moneylending largely depended on documents
the image of the figure of Dives in Luke 16:19–31. loosely categorized as tax records or receipts rolls.
Both this novel and the earlier La Fontana del Oro In addition to noting the minutiae of financial

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
789 Moneylending 790
17; Mark 11:15–19; Luke 19:45–48; John 2:13–16).
Artists tend to focus on Jesus’ physical actions of
driving the moneylenders out of the temple, push-
ing them from the space and intentionally overturn-
ing tables heavy with coins. The laden table in vari-
ous states of being overturned is usually a visual
center point – coins slide from the table alerting the
viewer to an implied loud noise of reckoning. In
Rembrandt’s 1625 etching of the scene, the coins
slide from the central table as if to pour right out
the picture plane. Jesus’ whip is about to descend
on a lender tightly clutching his bags of money.
Similar imagery appears in El Greco’s painting of
the Cleansing of the Temple (before 1570, National
Gallery of Art, Washington, D.C.), where Jesus’
strong dynamic movement confidently casts the
chaos out from the temple. In Quentin Matsys’ alle-
gorical painting of the Money Changer and his Wife
(1514, Louvre, Paris) the laden table is the most di-
rect indication of the male’s profession. Moneybags
and piles of coins tend to identify the moneylender
in Christian art. When appearing in isolation, im-
ages of moneylenders depend on the symbolism of
the trade (coins, moneybags, etc.) but when visual-
ized in larger narratives based on these scenes from
Fig. 16 “Hell with Satan and the infernal punishments the NT, the moneylenders tend to be pushed to the
for deadly sins” (ca. 1120/30) outskirts of the plane, while Jesus dominates the
center.
transactions, these records often contain visual in- Carlee Bradbury
formation. For example, the margins of English Ex-
chequer rolls are often punctuated with visual find- IX. Film
ing aids (the pointing hand or coin being the most Moneylending appears on screen primarily in two
common). In records pertaining to Jews, the hands ways. The first has only tangential relation to the
and coins are supplemented with drawings of Bible. The second relies on a form of antisemitism
badges (two tablets of the law) and human heads in that frequently bases itself in the Bible.
profile. In addition, drawings of known moneylend- The first category of films portrays moneylend-
ers from the Jewish community can appear in the ing as a neutral activity that can be either beneficial
rolls. Christian scribes portrayed historical figures or destructive. For example, in Frank Capra’s It’s a
such as Isaac of Norwich (12th–13th cent.) as ab- Wonderful Life (1946, US), the genial president of Bai-
stracted and grotesque figures, ignoring real hu- ley Building and Loan speaks movingly about how
manity in favor of derogatory caricature. Visualiza- his business enables people to build decent homes
tions of moneylenders in religious contexts for themselves. Meanwhile, the miserly bank owner
(especially illuminated manuscripts) tend to depend in the film cares only about profit and forecloses
on more subtle visual cues that identify the charac- ruthlessly on anyone who can’t pay him back. Simi-
ters as Jews. Despite these distinguishing cues, such larly, D. W. Griffith’s silent short The Usurer (1910,
as costume, Jewish moneylenders were humanized US) opens with an intertitle that alerts viewers to
rather than grotesquely rendered as in the secular “wine distilled from the blood of unfortunates – vi-
material or even passion imagery. The main visual ands paid for with the tears of the needy.” However,
identifier of the moneylender is a bag of coins that again, it is the exploitation of the poor by the
seems to weigh down even the most robust of char- wealthy that is condemned rather than lending it-
acters. In a tympanum sculpture on the façade of self. Neither of these films explicitly invokes the Bi-
the Romanesque Abbey Church of Sainte-Foy in ble, though biblical teachings about how the rich
Conques, a damned figure representing avaricious ought to treat the poor seem to lie in the back-
greed is visualized as a moneylender with a bag of ground.
coins tied round his neck as he hangs from the gal- A second category of films about moneylending
lows (see fig. 16). is complicated by negative stereotypes about Jews
The clearest narrative imagery connecting bibli- that are often biblically-derived. In her examination
cal moneylenders to Jews comes from the NT epi- of Jewish moneylending in medieval France, Julie
sode of the cleansing of the temple (Matt 21:12– Mell argues, “Jews became the symbolic referent for

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021
791 Mongolian Bible Translations 792
‘usurer’ not because they were the most important broker (dir. Wallace McCutcheon, written by D. W.
moneylenders, but because ‘infidel’ became identi- Griffith, 1908, US). In this short film, a Jewish mon-
fied with economic sin, and Jews were the most pre- eylender pays off the debts of a sick woman and her
scient symbol of the infidel as the historic agents child. The studio was so aware of the anomalous
who were offered the Messiah, yet rejected and depiction that it advertised the movie as overcom-
‘killed’ Christ” (2018: 184). Mell concludes that “the ing “the malignant calumnies launched at the He-
concept of Jewish enmity with the intent to injure braic race” (Erens: 31).
by economic means remains a staple of antisemi- The image of the nefarious Jewish moneylender
tism to this day” (ibid.: 81). Thus the stereotype of is found throughout cinema. There are over a dozen
the greedy Jewish moneylender may rely on bibli- different movie presentations of Shakespeare’s Mer-
cally-derived ideas about Jews as Christ-killers even chant of Venice in which the Jew Shylock demands a
when there is no explicit invocation of biblical lan- pound of flesh should his Christian borrower re-
guage. nege. These include a silent short from Italy di-
The most notorious anti-Semitic portrayal of rected by Gerolamo Lo Savio (Il mercante di Venezia,
moneylenders is Veit Harlan’s Jud Süss (1940, DE). 1911), a version from 1983 (dir. John Sichel, UK),
The film was produced as part of Joseph Goebbels’ and a 2004 version (dir. Michael Radford, US/IT/
Nazi propaganda campaign (Tegel: 151). A costume- LU/UK).
drama set in 18th-century Germany, the story was One final film of note is The Pawnbroker (dir. Sid-
based on the life of Joseph Süss Oppenheimer (who ney Lumet, 1964, US), which tells the story of a Jew-
was financial advisor to the Duke of Württemberg), ish Holocaust survivor who owns a pawnshop. The
but the facts of Süss’ life are twisted to promote a owner’s assistant is named Jesús, and in the end, he
Nazi agenda. In Harlan’s depiction, Süss is a malev- dies for the Jewish owner. Judith Doneson observes
olent schemer who uses his role as moneylender to that this plot sets up a troubling dynamic: “Juda-
insinuate his way into high society, uses his influ- ism, it is intimated, lacks that essential ingredient
ence to open the city gates to Jews, and rapes a vir- of ‘love thy neighbor’ found in Christianity”
ginal non-Jewish woman (who then commits sui- (22002: 112). Once again, though the Bible may not
cide). As happened in real life, the cinematic Süss is be explicitly referenced, ideas derived from the Bi-
executed. To justify the death sentence, the dead ble about Jews and Judaism may shape films’ narra-
woman’s father reflects, “An eye for an eye, a tooth tives.
for a tooth. That is not our custom. Our legal code Bibliography: ■ Doneson, J., The Holocaust in American Film
states, for all eternity: ‘Whenever a Jew mingles his (Syracuse, N.Y. 22002). ■ Erens, P., The Jew in American Cin-
flesh with a Christian woman – he should be ema (Bloomington, Ind. 1984). ■ Lam, B./G. B. White, “The
hanged at the gallows as well-deserved punishment Morality of Banking in It’s a Wonderful Life,” The Atlantic (De-
and a warning to all.” After Süss has been executed, cember 23, 2016; www.theatlantic.com). ■ Lipton, S., Im-
the local magistrate reads a declaration expelling all ages of Intolerance (Berkeley, Calif. 1999). ■ Mell, J., The Myth
Jews from Württemberg and adds, “May our de- of the Medieval Jewish Moneylender, 2 vols. (New York 2017;
Cham 2018). ■ Ray, J., The Sephardic Frontier (Ithaca, N.Y.
scendants adhere to this decree and thereby be
2006). [Esp. ch. 3] ■ Tegel, S., Jew Süss (London 2011).
spared suffering for their own wellbeing, and for
Theresa Sanders
the sake of their children’s blood, and that of their
children’s children.” See also / Anti-Judaism and Anti-Semitism;
Jud Süss was designed to warn Nazi society about / Cleansing of the Temple; / Debt, Debts;
the supposed threat of Jewish influence. At the / Economics and the Bible; / Money; / Poor,
same time that it rejects the lex talionis (Exod 21:24), Poverty; / Taxes and Taxation; / Usury
it alludes to Matt 27:25 (“His blood be on us and on
our children!”) as justification for executing Süss.
Notably, an earlier film had portrayed Süss as a Mongolian Bible Translations
hero. The English Jew Süss (dir. Lothar Mendes,
/ Versions and Translations of the Bible
1934, aka Power) opened with a description of the
film’s setting: “It was a time of brutality and univer-
sal intolerance and the Jews above all suffered op-
pression and boycott. At last there rose up a man
Moniuszko, Stanisław
who … resolved … to break down, once and for all, Stanisław Moniuszko (1819–1872) was a Polish Ro-
the barriers of the Ghetto.” In this version of the mantic composer, conductor, pedagogue, organist,
story, Süss was a fighter against the subjugation of and widely regarded as the father of Polish na-
his people. At one point in the film he declares, “I tional opera.
want to sit down to table with Dukes and Princes. Moniuszko came from a Polish, patriotic, Catho-
Not for my sake only, but for the sake of all of us” lic landowner (noble) family living under Russian
(Tegel: 128). rule during the partition of Poland (1795–1918), oc-
Another early movie that defied the stereotype cupied by Prussia, Austria, and Russia. His father
of the greedy moneylender was Old Isaacs, the Pawn- participated in Napoleon’s campaign against Russia

Encyclopedia of the Bible and Its Reception vol. 19


© Walter de Gruyter, Berlin/Boston, 2021

You might also like