You are on page 1of 18

City

analysis of urban trends, culture, theory, policy, action

ISSN: 1360-4813 (Print) 1470-3629 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/ccit20

Participatory budgeting, austerity and institutions


of democracy

Mark Davidson

To cite this article: Mark Davidson (2018) Participatory budgeting, austerity and institutions of
democracy, City, 22:4, 551-567, DOI: 10.1080/13604813.2018.1507107

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/13604813.2018.1507107

Published online: 20 Sep 2018.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 33

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ccit20
CITY, 2018
VOL. 22, NO. 4, 551 –567, https://doi.org/10.1080/13604813.2018.1507107

Participatory budgeting,
austerity and institutions of
democracy
The case of Vallejo, California

Mark Davidson

Participatory budgeting operates in approximately 1500 cities across the globe. Often these
projects are used in attempts to make city government more democratic. The growing popu-
larity of participatory budgeting also reflects scholarly concerns about elite interests domi-
nating policy-making to the extent that democratic institutions principally serve
legitimation purposes. This paper examines the implementation and evolution of participa-
tory budgeting in the City of Vallejo, California, following its 2008 chapter 9 bankruptcy.
The City of Vallejo introduced participatory budgeting as part of a broader collection of
reforms implemented to restructure the city budget and re-legitimate Vallejo’s city govern-
ment. Participatory budgeting introduced new decision-making processes to the city and
directed expenditures into new programs. An evaluation of the reforms and outcomes of
Vallejo’s participatory budgeting reveals a picture of mixed success. Although participatory
budgeting opened an important part of the city’s budget to democratic deliberation, the
process became aligned with entrenched institutional interests. In conclusion the paper
reflects on how the institutional structures of urban politics might limit the democratic
potential of participatory budgeting.

Key words: austerity, urban politics, participatory budgeting, urban governance, California

Introduction (re)embrace of democracy, Pateman


observes that ‘we seem to be in a favorable

I
n Pateman’s (2012) revisiting of her time for participatory democracy.’ (ibid.) In
1970 Participation and Democratic contrast to the prior popularity of political
Theory she summarizes the recent tra- theorists (e.g. Dahl [1974] 2005) who fol-
jectory of democratic thought: ‘Over the lowed Schumpeter’s ([1950] 2008) Platonic
past two decades we have heard an histori- position on minority-led democracies,
cally unprecedented volume of talk about democratic theorists now tend to stress
and praise of democracy, and many gov- the importance of widespread citizen par-
ernmental, non-governmental, and inter- ticipation throughout the political process
national organizations have been engaged (e.g. Fung and Wright 2001). The reasons
in democracy promotion.’ (7) Within this behind this embrace of participatory

# 2018 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group


552 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

democracy are varied (Sintomer, Herzberg, and adapted because they work within the
and Rocke 2008). For those on the left, par- competitive urban system, not because they
ticipation offers a route to empowerment reflect the wants and desires of citizens
and egalitarian social reform (Polletta (Davidson and Iveson 2015). City govern-
2013). On the right, participatory reforms ments now commonly respond to a lack of
are often seen to create more efficient gov- democratic engagement with limited
ernment (Toubeau and Wagner 2015). attempts to incorporate citizens within
Despite the broad support for participa- policy-making processes (e.g. Radzik-Marus-
tory democracy, recent commentaries on zak and Bátorová 2015). A further example is
actually-existing democracies have tended to post-recession state retrenchment and its
diagnose outright democratic decline. This associated devolving of responsibility onto
critique extends beyond Dahl’s ([1974] local government (Peck 2014). Such impo-
2005) observation that city government sitions are viewed as democratically con-
tends to be the concern of a professional pol- straining, reducing urban governance to an
itical minority, to condemnations of oli- austere exercise in necessity (Hackworth
garchic failure (Fraser 2015). The implosion 2015). Recent urban politics scholarship
of financial markets in 2008 seemed to therefore questions what extent to which
confirm a critique already circulating within urban politics remain democratic and if parti-
critical theory debates about the end of cipatory governance is compatible with exist-
democratic politics (Mouffe 2006; Rancière ing governance structures.
2004). In the US, system-saving financial This paper examines a recent attempt to
and economic interventions are seen by remedy democratic deficits using citizen par-
many to have imposed technocratic reforms ticipation in the context of urban austerity
and circumvented democratic processes (Peck 2014; also see Holdo (2016) on partici-
(Tahoun 2017). Theorists such as Fraser patory governance and austerity). In 2008,
(2015) have subsequently argued that post- the City of Vallejo, California, filed for
recession governance remains overtly techno- chapter 9 bankruptcy. Dramatic declines in
cratic because the State has continued to the City of Vallejo’s housing market-related
struggle with systemic crises. An inability to and sales tax revenues meant that in 2008
resolve concurrent crises using technocratic the City could not afford to pay its employ-
means is, Fraser (2015) argues, related to ees (Davidson and Kutz 2015). After the
growing doubts about the legitimacy of the bankruptcy ended in 2011, the City of
State (see Habermas 1975). Necessity (e.g. Vallejo undertook a host of reforms designed
economic stimulus and stabilization) is seen to produce a stable, structurally-sound city
to justify technocratic governance, but with budget. These fiscal and budgetary reforms
the implication that democratic deliberation included the introduction of participatory
has little role to play (see Rancière (2004) budgeting (PB), making Vallejo the first to
on post-politics). operate PB on a city-wide basis. The Vallejo
This tension between technocratic govern- case therefore represents a notable combi-
ance and a (re)embrace of participatory nation of post-recession technocratic govern-
modes of democracy is increasingly reflected ance (i.e. bankruptcy reform; see Bomey
in the urban politics literatures. For example, 2016; Peck 2014) and an attempt to remedy
technocratic urban government is now com- related problems using participatory
monly associated with policy mobility reforms (Holdo 2016).
(McCann and Ward 2011). As certain urban The paper proceeds with a review of the
policies become globally popular, their relevant PB literature and its relationship to
mutated application (Peck 2012) is often the literature on post-recession urban poli-
observed to be technocratic and lacking in tics. Following this, the paper draws on
democratic oversight. Policies are adopted research that examined Vallejo’s bankruptcy
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 553

and the city government’s subsequent allocation, and (iii) reform the administrative
attempts to implement fiscal and budgetary apparatus.’ (2)
reform. The focus of the paper is upon the
institutional changes associated with the The first part of this description helps explain
introduction of PB into the City of Vallejo. why PB has become a critical tool for partici-
First the paper explains how PC funds were patory democracy advocates (Bherer,
generated in Vallejo, before examining how Dufour, and Montambeault 2017). The ‘par-
the PB process has evolved through the first ticipatory turn’ (Pateman 2012) within demo-
four funding cycles. The conclusion reflects cratic theory can be understood as a
on how longstanding institutional political collection of critical reactions to liberal and
relationships (Dahl [1974] 2005) in Vallejo representative democracies (ibid.; also see
impacted the evolution of the city’s PB Mouffe 2006). Advocates of the participatory
democratization experiment. turn have been critical of the ways in which
democracy processes have been controlled
by political and economic elites who tend to
Participatory budgeting, austerity and role operate without broad citizen involvement
of urban politics and/or oversight (Abensour 2011). Increasing
participation consequently serves to return
The development of PB projects in over 1500 and/or bring the influence of citizens into
cities across the globe (Baiocchi and Ganuza political and bureaucratic processes (Fung
2014) has inevitability generated a variety of and Wright 2001). PB is therefore one
contextually-influenced PB processes. This reform among others, including citizen coun-
geographical variance has led some to ques- cils, public consultations, neighborhood
tion to the extent to which PB now represents councils and participatory planning (Bherer,
a coherent political reform (Baiocchi and Dufour, and Montambeault 2017, 225), that
Ganuza 2014; Bassoli 2012; Wampler 2010). seek to make government more participatory
It is therefore worth returning to the basic through the engagement and empowerment
premises of PB. Wampler (2000) described of citizens.
PB programs in the following way (also see The meaningful participation of citizens
Bassoli 2012; Sintomer, Herzberg, and within the democratic process is thought,
Rocke 2008): by some, to prospectively bring with it
emancipatory transformation: ‘the idea was
‘Participatory Budgeting (PB) programs are
indeed that participation could transform
innovative policymaking processes. Citizens
are directly involved in making policy the inegalitarian relationships between the
decisions. Forums are held throughout the state and society and that is could help to
year so that citizens have the opportunity to emancipate and empower citizens in every
allocate resources, prioritize broad social sphere of their daily lives’ (Bherer, Dufour,
policies, and monitor public spending. and Montambeault 2017, 226). In the
These programs are designed incorporate second part of Wampler’s description, this
citizens into the policymaking process, connection between PB and social reform is
spur administrative reform, and distribute explicit. PB is described as a social justice
public resources to low-income tool, with increased citizen participation
neighborhoods. Social and political exclusion
spurring redistribution and reducing levels
is challenged as low income and traditionally
of social exclusion. Although some (Baiocchi
excluded political actors are given the
opportunity to make policy decisions. and Ganuza 2014; Holdo 2016) now ques-
Governments and citizens initiate these tion the extent to which PB brings with it
programs to (i) promote public learning and progressive redistributive social reforms,
active citizenship, (ii) achieve social justice this connection remains central for many
through improved policies and resources proponents of PB.
554 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

This perceived connection between citizen neighborhood councils, and improved gov-
participation and egalitarian politics is ernment efficiency (Wampler 2010). The
demonstrated by the Real Utopias project. meaningful involvement of citizens in Porto
The Real Utopias project, much of it coordi- Alegre’s policy-making and governance pro-
nated around the thought of E.O. Wright cesses is commonly associated with redistri-
(2010), has attempted to bridge the gap butive budgeting and social welfare budget
between radical political theory and practice. priorities (Abers 1998).
Writing about the failures of actually-existing Porto Alegre’s PB project offers an
democratic institutions, Fung and Wright example of how progressive political goals
(2001) have argued that participatory modes can be achieved through local institutional
of democracy provide the mechanisms reforms. However, Porto Alegre’s PB
through which to achieve meaningful politi- program has not produced a set of policy pre-
cal change: ‘As the tasks of the state have scriptions that can be simply transferred from
become more complex and the size of polities one place to the next. Porto Alegre’s PB
larger and more heterogeneous, the insti- project has its origins within the city’s own
tutional forms of liberal democracy devel- history and context. As de Sousa Santos
oped in the nineteenth century— (1998) argued with respect to the overall
representative democracy plus technobureau- objective of the Workers’ Party’s participa-
cratic administration—seem increasingly ill tory initiative:
suited to the novel problems we face in the
twenty-first century’ (5). In response to the ‘The participatory budget promoted by the
failures of actually-existing democratic insti- Prefeitura of Porto Alegre is a form of public
tutions, Fung and Wright (2001) envisage government that tries to break away from the
authoritarian and patrimonialist tradition of
the Real Utopias project helping to bring
public policies, resorting to the direct
about a reactivated and reengaged citizenry, participation of the population in the different
a citizenry who are at the heart of policy- phases of budget preparation and
making and implementation, and whose implementation, with special concern for the
deliberative governance itself generates definition of priorities for the distribution of
more egalitarian social structures. investment resources’ (467)
PB has become a best practice example for
the institutional reforms promoted by this It was within Brazil’s broader attempt to re-
project (Wright 2017). The popularity of PB install democratic institutions that Porto
within participatory democracy movements Alegre’s PB project came into being.
is often linked to the successes of PB in the Although the PB reforms of the Workers’
groundbreaking Porto Alegre PB project Party had progressive intentions, PB
(Baiocchi 2001). Instigated by a coalition of reforms were also reacting to Brazil’s recent
social activists and the Workers’ Party political history and the need to create a
(Partido de Trabalhadoes) in 1989, and fully legitimately democratic government (see
active between 1991 and 2004, PB in Porto Abers 2000). Porto Alegre’s PB program
Alegre is widely acknowledged to be the therefore opened-up policymaking and bud-
most successful and influential PB project. geting, increased government oversight,
PB helped to transform a bankrupt and inef- made more transparent government spending
ficient city government into a governance and reduced corruption (see Abers 1998;
model now disseminated around the world Baiocchi and Ganuza 2014) in response to
(Baiocchi and Ganuza 2014). The success of its recent history. Although reform advocates
PB in Porto Alegre was demonstrated by such as the Real Utopias Project have empha-
the widespread participation of residents in sized the redistributive outcomes of the Porto
government from across different social Alegre experience, the project’s governmen-
divides, city-wide policymaking via tal reforms have also made PB attractive to
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 555

those on the political right. PB advocates now Theodore 2003), Baiocchi and Ganuza
include organizations such as the World (2014) now caution against the association
Bank, with PB seen as a mechanism with of PB with particular political positions and
which governments can be made more social outcomes.
accountable, transparent and less corrupt Detached from the Porto Alegre context,
(Shah 2007). PB can therefore be viewed as a set of insti-
This distinguishing between PB as having tutional reforms (Goldfrank 2007) that most
progressive and efficiency elements is consistently attempt to make government
reflected in Baiocchi and Ganuza’s (2014) more accountable and transparent for con-
recent division of PB into communicative stituents (Sintomer, Herzberg, and Rocke
and empowerment dimensions (also see Sin- 2008). Writing from this perspective, Baioc-
tomer, Herzberg, and Rocke 2008). They chi and Ganuza (2014, 29) identify three fea-
claim: tures of PB reform that remain central across
most cases: open meetings, yearly funding
‘As it [PB] traveled internationally, it became cycles, and a combination of deliberation
completely dissociated from progressive and representation. This combination unites
parties altogether. By the time it arrived in the a host of PB initiatives that otherwise con-
United States, some of its implementers still
trast in political intent and outcomes (also
invoked social justice, but it was delinked
from progressive institutional projects and
see Bassoli 2012). Consequently, there is a
instead became part of the loose toolkit of growing need to examine PB initiatives
ideas for innovative good governance, part of within the contexts they emerge and identify
the ‘fast policy transfer’ that Jamie Peck has how certain contexts produce different types
described as characteristic of our era.’ (31) of PB projects (Rast 2012).
In the US, there are a growing number of
Baiocchi and Ganuza’s (2014) argue that as cities developing PB projects. This is a
PB became a mobile policy (see McCann recent innovation in US urban governance,
and Ward 2011), the linkage between partici- with the first PB project beginning in
pation and redistribution decoupled. In most Chicago in 2009. There are now approxi-
cases of PB, they now see city governments mately 250 PB projects across the US. Many
emphasizing the communicative component; of these projects have been advised by the
open-meetings, regular citizen consultation US-based non-for-profit consultancy, the
and communication. The empowerment of Participatory Budgeting Project. Founded in
citizens within the budget process—some- 2009 by Josh Lerner and Gianpaolo Baiocchi,
thing that was critical to the redistributive the Participatory Budgeting Project draws on
outcomes of Porto Alegre’s PB program the PB model developed in Porto Alegre and
(Abers 1998)—has often not accompanied advises various governmental organizations
PB on its travels (Holdo 2016). This splinter- on how to organize budgeting on a participa-
ing of PB, they argue, was critical to making it tory basis. The most notable examples of PB
compatible with neoliberal governance: ‘As in the US are found in Chicago, New York
part of a new rationality of government that City and Vallejo, California. In Chicago, PB
calls forward an entrepreneurial citizen, par- has been used at the ward level to create
ticipation emphasizes some of the most good governance and legitimacy (Hatcher
important characteristics of that citizen: 2016). Chicago’s 49th Ward now has the
self-regulation, responsibility for one’s own longest running PB project in the US, allocat-
problems, and a nonconflictive partnerships ing at least $1 m of capital funding each year
with the state.’ (ibid., 40). Whereas Porto since 2009. Amid the Great Recession, and
Alegre’s PB represented a model of urban with declining political support, Alderman
government that stood in contrast to neolib- Joe Moore introduced PB to the 49th Ward
eral urban governance (see Brenner and to re-engage the local community and
556 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

rebuild his electoral support (Pin 2017). In (2017) has used Baiocchi and Ganuza (2014)
collaboration with the Participatory Budget- distinction between the communicative and
ing Project, Alderman Moore installed a empowerment dimensions of PB to evaluate
yearly process of allocating infrastructure the 49th Ward’s experiment. Pin’s (2017)
investments via participatory methods. Since concluding comments about the 49th Ward
2009, six other Chicago wards have intro- reconfirm Baiocchi and Ganuza’s (2014)
duced PB programs, with over $6 m being claim about empowerment being absent
allocated via PB each year. In 2011, four from many PB programs: ‘the municipal bud-
New York City Council Members followed geting process, where many crucial decisions
Chicago’s lead and introduced PB into their are made regarding social programming, con-
districts. In 2017, New York City’s PB tinues to be elite driven and insulated from
project had extended to 27 districts, with resident influence’ (Pin 2017, 135). Although
over $30 m of capital spending being distrib- PB may be introducing more participatory
uted using PB. In New York City PB is expli- modes of government across the US, Pin’s
citly premised on increasing (i) inclusion, (ii) (2017) reiteration of existing criticisms
equality and (iii) empowerment. New York suggest that the decision-making structures
City Council explains its PB process in the of the urban political orthodoxy (Brenner
following way: and Theodore 2003) remain largely
unchallenged.
‘Participatory Budgeting is a democratic This paper examines the installation and
process in which community members evolution of PB in the only case of city-
directly decide how to spend part of a public wide PB in the U.S., the City of Vallejo, Cali-
budget. It’s grassroots democracy at its best. fornia. The paper conceptualizes PB as a chal-
It helps make budget decisions clear and
lenge to existing political norms and an
accessible. It gives real power to people who
have never before been involved in the
alternative conception of democratic practice
political process. And it results in better (see Dahl [1974] 2005, 319– 320). Conse-
budget decisions—because who better knows quently, understanding PB reform needs to
the needs of our community than the people involve an examination of how existing insti-
who live there?’ (https://council.nyc.gov/pb/) tutional interests respond and/or adapt to PB
practices. Within this framing, the paper
This description encapsulates the idea that makes two contributions. First, it builds on
more participation from citizens leads to the small number of studies of PB projects
better government, while the project’s goals in the U.S. (see Baiocchi and Lerner 2007;
are explicitly progressive. Pin 2017) by describing how PB emerged in
In an era where trust in the Federal govern- Vallejo from a context of national-wide
ment is at historic lows,1 it is perhaps unsur- fiscal crisis and austerity (see Peck 2014).
prising that local politicians are responding Second, the paper examines how PB devel-
using reforms such as PB to (re)build oped and evolved as part of Vallejo’s post-
relationships with constituents. However, bankruptcy fiscal reforms. PB emerged in
we know little about how PB is variously Vallejo as a pragmatic response to severe pol-
implemented within the U.S.’s distinctive itical and fiscal problems and lacked explicit
system of urban governance. For example, it redistributive intent. However, the project
is unclear if more participatory democracy did create progressive opportunities for Val-
practices are instituting changes within estab- lejo’s citizens by them being able to debate
lished urban political communities (see Dahl and allocate significant amounts of discre-
[1974] 2005; Bassoli 2012) or creating new tionary taxation revenue. Through an exam-
challenges to growth-oriented policies ination of how (i) PB introduced
(Logan and Molotch 1987). In one of the institutional change, (ii) evolved through its
few studies of Chicago’s PB program, Pin first four funding cycles, and (iii) experienced
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 557

shifting patterns of project funding, the paper obligations made in collective bargaining
explains how PB has not been able to insulate agreements. Bankruptcy proceedings contin-
itself from the city’s longstanding insti- ued until late 2011, when a Federal judge
tutional politics. approved a Plan of Readjustment. The read-
justment plan capped retiree healthcare
costs and reduced some of the City’s long-
Case study and research methods term employment obligations. Vallejo’s
bankruptcy restructuring avoided the politi-
The City of Vallejo, California, is located on cally difficult choice of radically reforming
the northern edge of San Francisco Bay and at salary, pension and bond obligations.
the southern end of Napa Valley. It has an However, the City’s limited budgetary
ethnically and racially diverse population of restructuring in bankruptcy court left some
120,000 residents. For much of the twentieth predicting a second bankruptcy for Vallejo
century the city’s economy was dominated (Hicken 2014).
by its largest employer, the US Navy. The Dramatic fiscal decline, an unprecedented
Mare Island Navy Shipyard covered over bankruptcy, and post-bankruptcy budgetary
5000 acres of Vallejo’s Mare Island peninsula struggles have done little to inspire confidence
when it was decommissioned in 1996. The in the city’s government. When the city
closure of the shipyard transitioned the emerged from bankruptcy, changes within
city’s economy and began a period of pro- the city bureaucracy and City Council
longed economic struggles. Vallejo has there- brought with them new fiscal strategies and
fore experienced economic renewal a desire on the City Council to restore trust.
challenges like those in deindustrialized It was from this context that the city’s PB
cities across the United States (Wilson and program emerged. The paper draws upon
Wouters 2003). The city’s major employers research undertaken between 2010 and 2017
are now state and local government, health that followed Vallejo’s bankruptcy and
care services and a Six Flags amusement park. related restructuring. The research involved
Since the drawdown of the Navy’s pres- the collection and analysis of city budget
ence in the early 1990s, the City of Vallejo documents, bankruptcy filings, and secondary
has experienced structural fiscal problems. literature appertaining to the City’s bank-
However, throughout the 1990s and early ruptcy. Three field visits to Vallejo (2011,
2000s, the City managed to balance its 2013 and 2017) were also undertaken to inter-
General Fund budget. Although the City view 35 key-informants (e.g. City Councilors,
continued to experience significant growth administrators, civic society actors, commu-
in employment and related benefit expenses, nity organizers) and 11 politically-engaged
a healthy housing market helped to grow residents on issues relating to the City’s bank-
the City’s revenues. When the 2007 – 08 ruptcy and restructuring. Interviews were
Great Recession hit, this arrangement col- semi-structured and lasted between 45 and
lapsed. Despite significant staffing and 90 minutes. Most interviews were conducted
service cuts, in 2008 the City’s General in person, although eight telephone/Skype
Fund could not afford to pay its employees. interviews were used where interviewees
Negotiations between the City and its four could not be visited in person.
public employee unions failed to produce an
agreement that would balance the budget.
Consequently, on May 6th 2008 the City Introducing participatory budgeting to
Council voted to file for chapter 9 bank- Vallejo: revenues and institutional reform
ruptcy. The City of Vallejo’s chapter 9
filing was the first to claim bankruptcy pro- Vallejo’s PB program emerged from within
tections due to an inability to fulfill the broader attempt to restructure the city
558 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

budget and restore services after the 2008 effort to ensure Measure B funds were used
bankruptcy. Bankruptcy restructuring had for the city’s betterment. Vallejo’s PB
stabilized the City’s financial situation but project, unlike many others (Holdo 2016),
not created the revenues necessary to did not therefore emerge from a grassroots
rebuild city services (City of Vallejo 2013). social movement. As a City Councilor,
The need to generate new revenues is a diffi- Brown was particularly concerned that
cult problem in California’s restrictive taxa- Measure B revenues might not be used to
tion environment. Article XIIIC of the improve the city’s budget and infrastructure.
California Constitution, commonly known Her fear was that the same institutional
as Proposition 218, requires that a city gain context that pushed Vallejo into bankruptcy
a two-third majority voter approval for any would lead to an appropriation of new reven-
new local tax. This requirement of a two- ues without budgetary reform:
third majority vote has ensured that local
taxation rates have grown slowly in Califor- ‘When the 1% sales tax passes, you have a
nia. When Vallejo’s City Council was flood of money into the city. I knew there
looking to generate new revenues in 2011, it would be instant pressure to hire more police
eventually opted to pursue a 1% increase in . . . Some wanted to whisk it [Measure B
revenue] away for policing. But we had ripped
the City’s sales tax rate. This extension of an
away so many services. I wanted to give
already-existing sales tax would only require something back. For that we need more
approval by a simple majority of voters. people participating, a common and collective
In November 2011, 50.43% (9,295) of voice. People were leaving, so we need to give
Vallejo voters approved a 1% sales tax something back’ (Interview 3A 2017)
increase on the purchase of goods and ser-
vices for ten years. This moved the effective When Measure B passed, Brown was already
sales tax in Vallejo from 7.375% to 8.375%, engaged with PB. Before running for City
now the highest sales tax rate in Solano Council in 2009, she had independently con-
County. The City estimated that the tax ducted research on city budgeting and in the
increase would raise an addition $9.8 m in process discovered PB (Interview, 2017).
revenue during the first year. In 2010– 11, After reaching out to Josh Lerner at the Par-
the City’s General Fund revenues totaled ticipatory Budgeting Project, and visiting Joe
just over $65 m. With $48 m of this total Moore in Chicago’s 49th Ward, Brown was
being allocated to police and fire salaries convinced that ‘participatory budgeting
and benefits, the addition of $9.8 m in new would not solve all the [city’s] problems,
sales tax revenue represented a significant but that it would generate transparency and
increase in discretionary revenue. In the public engagement’ (Interview 3A 2017).
context of the City’s recent fiscal problems, Before the new City Council was sworn in,
the generation of this new revenue also Brown had agreed with the new majority
created the problem of how to best distribute that PB should be instituted to distribute
the funds. Part of the solution to this problem some of the new Measure B revenues.
was to be PB. Initially Brown proposed that 50% of
City elections in 2011 resulted in a change Measure B revenues would be allocated
in the composition of the City Council. The using PB. At the request of the newly-
seven-member City Council now found appointed City Manager, this number was
itself with a new majority, composed of reduced to 30% (Interview 3B 2017). Based
four members who variously agreed that on the City’s estimates, this would create
reform of the City’s budgetary process was $3.2 m of PB funding and around $300,000
required. Out of the new majority, one City to staff the PB project.
Councilmember, Marti Brown, would With PB installed by the City Council, the
become an advocate of PB as part of her City hired the Participatory Budgeting
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 559

Project (PBP) to help operate the first cycle structure have been influenced by the
of funding. Two PBP staff members worked demands of the City Council and the evol-
within the city to create the community- ution of PB in Vallejo.
based budgeting process needed to spend Vallejo’s PB rulebook establishes project
the $3.2 m of allocated funds. One member eligibility, timelines, participation rules, and
of the PBP staff described the rationale of PB roles and responsibilities. The rulebook
the Vallejo PB project in the following way: originally set out three PB goals, and later
expanded this to four (see Figure 1). It was
‘The rationale was about bring legitimacy only with the addition of the fourth goal for
back to the city. Showing the City had an the third funding cycle that Vallejo recognized
ability to govern [after the bankruptcy]. In PB has having a redistributive function. The
order to bring it back, they had to give more
emphasis of most of the PB project has been
power to citizens. They also had to figure out
how to go about decision-making . . . We had
upon problem-solving, civic engagement and
to establish what the limitations on the money the generation of political participation. Inter-
would be, establish guidelines.’ (Interview 9C viewees of all types repeatedly commented
2017) that these priorities reflect the ways in which
Vallejo’s bankruptcy impacted governmental
With the help of PBP staff, the City created a priorities at the time of PB initiation (Inter-
rulebook for the PB project and agreed upon views 2B 2013, 7A 2017). In particular, the
a funding cycle structure. Both borrowed maintenance and improvement of basic infra-
heavily from the Porto Alegre model, structure, particularly roads, had become a
although the final PB rulebook and funding significant issue after years of disinvestment.

Figure 1 The four main goals of Vallejo’s PB project (Source: City of Vallejo 2012, 2015).
560 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

The rulebook requires that PB projects operation of PB in Vallejo. The City


must be of public benefit and one-time Council and City Council-appointed Steer-
expenditures. The Vallejo PB timeline (see ing Committee therefore serve as authorita-
Figure 2) reflects the general approach to tive PB actors charged with oversight and
yearly funding cycles developed by PBP direction responsibilities.
(Interview 9C 2017). First, budget assemblies
serve to communicate with participants and
generate project ideas. Then delegate meet-
The participatory budgeting in Vallejo
ings use PB volunteers to develop project
ideas into full proposals that can be displayed
(a) Participation: Figure 3 shows partici-
and voted on in city-wide ballots. The City of
pation data for the first four cycles of PB
Vallejo’s PB Rulebook limits voting on
funding in Vallejo. General involvement in
project proposals to Vallejo residents who
the PB project is indicated by how many
are at least 16 years old, although partici-
people participated in Budget Assemblies,
pation in budget assemblies is extended to
how many people volunteered to coordinate
stakeholders (e.g. non-residents who work
meetings as Budget Delegates, and overall
in Vallejo) and 14– 15 year old youth. The
levels of PB voting. Since 2012 – 13, partici-
rulebook notably instituted two key govern-
pation in Budget Assemblies has fluctuated.2
ance mechanisms into the PB process. First,
In 2015, 449 people met to brainstorm
the rulebook gave the City Council final
project ideas and listen to PB staff reports.
approval on all projects selected by public
This represents a city-wide participation
voting. Second, the rulebook established a
rate of less than 0.5%. A member of the
20-member Steering Committee. The Steer-
City of Vallejo’s PB staff commented on
ing Committee is composed of representa-
this participation rate:
tives from civic, business, cultural,
education and community organizations in ‘If you walk out onto the street and ask
Vallejo and Solano County. The Steering someone about PB, they are not going to
Committee is responsible for designing and know anything about it . . . For the public at
revising the PB rulebook and overseeing the large, they just want the streets to be fixed and

Figure 2 Timeline for the first PB funding cycle, 2012– 13 (Source: City of Vallejo 2012).
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 561

Figure 3 Indicators of PB participation and spending in the City of Vallejo, 2012 –17. (Source: Participatory Budgeting
in Vallejo Summaries, Cycles 1 –4. Available at: http://www.ci.vallejo.ca.us).

more cops. Some would certainly see PB as an ‘In the first year we had a lot of ideas
expense, and an expensive way of doing things proposed and some were pretty interesting.
like that [fixing roads]. We need to explain the One resident had proposed some kind of
projects better.’ (Interview 9D 2017) community investment bank, something that
could support small business projects in
For staff, the installation of PB within the Vallejo. A lot of people liked the idea but we
city’s different communities was still an ran into some legal problems. The City could
ongoing effort. That stated, staff did not finance private activities . . . So I think
acknowledge that PB had enlarged the base part of the declining participation probably
relates to the fact that residents realize the
of politically active residents, moving it
projects are pretty limited in scope.’
away from what they described as ‘the usual (Interview 5A 2017)
suspects who turn up to most events, the pro-
fessional residents’ (Interview 9D 2017). One The second explanation was offered by resi-
the other hand, Vallejo’s PB project has seen a dents, who claimed that the funding priorities
decline in people volunteering to be budget of most voters had been made clear and
delegates. One interviewee acknowledged would remain largely the same: ‘It is
that the time commitment required for obvious at this point where the money we
budget delegation was ‘probably not worth have needs to be spent, which is basically on
it since PB has not really delivered huge inno- roads. I mean, they are crumbling, and every-
vations’ (Interview 9C 2017). one is dealing with that’ (Interview 11A
Critical commentaries about what PB was 2017). This concern about the state of the
delivering were often made with reference city’s roads and the need to direct spending
to the ideas and projects that are being gener- towards infrastructure repair and mainten-
ated by the process. In 2012– 13, PB gener- ance was repeated by residents, elected offi-
ated 60 potential projects for vetting by cials and bureaucrats throughout the
City staff. By 2016– 17, this number has research.
shrunk to 19. Two explanations were (b) Funding: Figure 3 shows that total
offered for this decline. The first was men- amounts of PB funds declined by over $2 m
tioned by two different organizers of the PB between 2012 – 13 and 2016– 17. This fall of
project. They both claimed that the PB PB expenditures is less accentuated when
project has become more constrained by actual expenditure is accounted for (see
legal necessity. For example, one interviewee Figure 3). The discrepancies between
who was involved in organizing the 2012 – 13 amounts allocated and funds used relates to
PB cycle explained: the inability of some projects to start and
562 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

underspending in others. For example, a of city staff, the City Council voted to
2013 – 14 homelessness project was never make Measure B an indefinite tax. This has
active and therefore unable to use its allocated folded Measure B revenues into general bud-
funds (Interview, 2017). Due to this geting and made all staff hired on a tempor-
occasional inability of a project to utilize ary basis—including PB administrators—
PB funds, the City has transferred $2.45 m permanent City employees. Given the city
(2013 – 14) and $2.44 m (2014 – 15) of PB had already hired police and fire personnel
project funding back into General Fund on permanent contracts, converting
budget reserves. This has contributed to Measure B into a permanent tax increase
administrative costs becoming a larger share saved the City a future budget crisis.
of PB expenditures. In 2017, the City of It is therefore despite a healthy growth in
Vallejo employed three administrative staff Measure B revenues that Vallejo’s PB
to operate the $1 m PB program at an project has seen funding decline. The City
annual cost of $420,929. now commits $1 m per year to PB, down
Since Vallejo’s PB project emerged as an from the previous 30% of Measure B reven-
attempt to ensure new tax revenue ues ($4.29 m in 2016– 17). For those in the
(Measure B) would be distributed democrati- city government, this decline is concerned
cally, it is illustrative to place the PB funding with the higher priority of other expendi-
trajectory in the context of overall Measure B tures, particularly increasing the number
revenues. In 2012 – 13, Measure B exceeded police officers (Interviews 3B, 9C 2017). For
projections and raised $11.7 m in additional some residents, the decline in PB funding
revenue for the City. By 2016 – 17, Measure and reallocation of Measure B funds to
B was projected to raise $14.3 m in extra police and fire personnel is an inevitable
revenue. As a proportion of Measure B rev- outcome of the city’s politics:
enues, Vallejo’s PB project has therefore
declined from a 28% to 7% share. This ‘You knew it was going to happen that way.
reflects a broader reorientation of Measure Nothing has changed since the bankruptcy, in
B spending. At inception, Measure B was fact it is even worse. All those monies
[Measure B revenues] have been seized by the
voted on as a ten-year sales tax increase
police and fire unions . . . PB was a nice idea,
that would be used to rectify under-invest- but until we fix the political problem this
ment in services and infrastructure. PB fit situation will not change and we continue to
into this program as a democratic process head to another bankruptcy’ (Interview 11B
that could identify need and develop reme- 2017)
dial projects. By 2016 – 17, Measure B reven-
ues have become mainly orientated towards For this resident/activist, the shrinkage in PB
personnel costs, with $10.5 m of Measure B funding reflected the broader political
revenues being allocated to city payroll. dynamics in the City. In this case, the inter-
These personnel costs are associated with viewee was arguing that the City of Vallejo’s
new positions in the police and fire depart- 2008 bankruptcy was due to the City not
ments, although PB staffing is also provided being able to afford the collective bargaining
by Measure B revenue. The largest declines agreements it had made with labor unions.
in Measure B budget items have been in The proportion of General Fund revenues
‘Public Safety Preservation/Enhancement’ being expended on labor costs and pensions
(e.g. emergency call center improvement) had been highlighted in 1993 by a citizen
and ‘Infrastructure Enhancement’ (e.g. committee created by the City to examine
street maintenance). With an increasing fiscal and budgetary issues (City of Vallejo
amount of city personnel employed on 1993). Subsequently this issue has defined
Measure B revenues with a 10-year sunset much of the city’s budgetary politics, as one
provision, in 2017, on the recommendation City Councilor commented:
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 563

‘The short story about Vallejo is the of Vallejo has classified projects into either
relationship between the unions and the City ‘People’ or ‘Infrastructure’ projects. These
Council. They have always been bound up . . . categories have been further broken down
It has always been that way. It is not always here according to the content of project
about disagreements, more that the City
descriptions. ‘Infrastructure’ is sub-divided
Council, for one reason or another, tends to
into ‘Improvement’ and ‘Maintenance’ pro-
be directed by the police and fire guys.
Having more police is always popular jects. ‘People’ projects are sub-divided into
politically and the police help with raising ‘Animal Control’, ‘Education’, ‘Emergency
money for campaigns. It is a powerful Services’ and ‘Social Services’. Figure 4
combination . . . It is no surprise then that shows a general decline in PB funding and a
Measure B and participatory [budgeting] shifting allocation of funding. Maintenance
projects would get dragged into it.’ (Interview and infrastructure projects have been consist-
4A 2017) ently funded. The most popular project
throughout the first four cycles has been
As Measure B revenues have become pro- street and pothole repair. Education projects,
gressively allocated to police and fire person- such as college scholarship schemes, and
nel, some City Councilors and residents social services were not funded in Cycle
therefore see history repeating itself. The 4. Two interconnected explanations were
impact on PB is acknowledged by city offered for this shift.
administrators as a lowering of the project’s The first explanation was offered by a PB
funding priority. administrator:
(c) Spending: Since 2012 – 13, each year a
smaller number of PB projects have been ‘We have certainly seen projects that favor a
funded (see Figure 4). There has also been a particular place or group of people declining
shift in the types of projects funded. Figure in popularity. It is now really hard for those
4 shows the types of projects that have been projects to get funding. The projects that get
funded over the first four cycles. The City funded are general city-wide projects . . . That

Figure 4 Types of projects funded over four participatory budgeting cycles (Source: City of Vallejo’s Participatory Bud-
geting Annual Reports, 2012 –13 thru 2016– 17).
564 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

is why the street projects receive the most should be doing anyway’ (Interview 11A
votes. The roads impact almost everyone . . . 2017). One resident described this at length:
Some projects have just become hard to work
within the yearly timetable. The homelessness ‘It is hard to really engage with the [PB]
project was like that. Even with an [funding] process since most of the things you are asked
extension it never got going. That makes it to vote on are basic city services. Look, I
hard to pursue through the funding cycle and don’t really think that we should be voting to
hard to promote to residents.’ (Interview 5A repair our roads. That stuff should just get
2017) done since it is a basic service. You can say the
same about the neutering programs. That is a
Shifts in project funding can therefore be basic service . . . Where PB would be effective
understood as reflections of public prefer- is monies beyond the basic stuff, which, of
ences in the context of shrinking funding course, we don’t have. But no, I don’t think
and emerging understandings of project via- that PB is working as it should. Frankly, it is a
bility. In Cycle 4, the four projects that very expensive way of running city services’
received funding could all be described as (Interview 11A 2017)
general city services. The projects were
‘Street and Pothole Repair’, ‘911 Emergency Such criticisms were linked by politically-
Call Center Equipment’, ‘Local Parks active residents and administrators to the
Improvement’ and ‘Fixing Pets and Feral broader changes to Measure B spending and
Cats for Better Health’. The other related the associated directing of new tax revenues
explanation concerns changes made to the to police and fire services. One resident/acti-
PB rulebook for the 2015 third cycle of vist explained:
funding. This rule change altered the classifi-
‘As much as it would be nice for participatory
cation of projects and eligibility criteria. The
budgeting to be another story, it is not. It is
City now stipulates two types of projects: the same story it has been for decades. Unless
Services and Durables. Services are eligible the City can find a way to reform its pension
for $150,000 of funding ($20,000 minimum/ and [collective] bargaining agreements, the is
$50,000 maximum) and need to benefit low- no way out . . . The participatory stuff has
to-moderate income residents. Durables (i.e. been taken over by the demands of police and
infrastructure) are eligible for $850,000 of fire, just like the [Measure B] sales tax. I saw
funding ($30,000 minimum/$400,000 they [police department] had a call room
maximum) and should benefit all Vallejoans. funded [via PB], which says it all’ (Interview
This change has had the effect of creating 8A 2017)
two PB processes, one deciding redistributive
Administrators of the PB project agreed that
PB funding for services and the other for
the original ringfencing intentions of PB were
infrastructure priorities. The introduction of
disappearing as the City Council redefined its
a redistribution requirement for the third
priorities (Interview 9C 2017). They ident-
funding cycle came at the recommendation
ified the changing level of PB funding and
of city staff (Interview 9C 2017). It also
rulebook revisions as the key examples how
meant that social service projects with costs
PB was evolving to reflect the City Council’s
over $50,000 are no longer eligible for PB
changing priorities.
funding. In the context of city-wide projects
receiving the most votes in PB ballots, these
funding limitations on service projects Conclusion
restrict their ability to be city-wide and there-
fore popular with voters (Interview 2B 2017). ‘. . . to gain legitimacy for their actions
The directing of PB funding into general city leaders frequently surround their covert
services (i.e. durables) has attracted criticism behavior with democratic rituals’ (Dahl
from residents for being ‘things the city [1974] 2005, 89)
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 565

As an act of democratizing reform, Vallejo’s with control over new taxation revenues and
PB project has struggled to change the city’s direct any new tax dollars away from public
institutional politics. This outcome reflects sector pay. In the first cycle of funding, PB
Baiocchi and Ganuza’s (2014) critique that began as a not insignificant $3.5 m spending
city governments often prefer the communi- commitment. Subsequent changes on the
cative element of PB over the more difficult City Council and the successful demands of
empowerment dimension. It also confirms police and fire services to restore staff levels
Holdo’s (2016) realist perspective that PB to pre-recession levels without significant
projects will always tend to be coopted by labor agreement reform has meant a $3.5 m
government actors. Vallejo’s PB project is a PB commitment is no longer possible. In
product of, and has evolved within, its addition to reducing PB funding, the City
context (see Rast 2012). This conclusion Council has also reformed the PB project so
reflects Dahl’s ([1974] 2005) realpolitik view that most funds are now directed into ‘dur-
that in pluralistic democracies, members of ables’ and the ability of residents to decide
the political stratum tend to resist alternative funding priorities has been significantly
conceptions of democratic practice. In his curbed. PB has therefore become a less
study of New Haven’s political evolution, impactful part of the city’s government.
Dahl observed that alternative interpretations The first five years of Vallejo’s PB project
of democratic practice often become the therefore questions the extent to which this
source of political conflict. In these situ- democratization reform can transform actu-
ations, existing political elites tend to ally-existing urban democracies within the
mobilize to avoid any restructuring of U.S. urban system (Davidson and Kutz
power relations: 2015). In Dahl’s ([1974] 2005) study of U.S.
urban politics in New Haven, CT, he argued
‘The professionals, of course, have access to that the acceptance of American political
extensive political resources which they norms—i.e. the democratic creed—is perva-
employ at a high rate with superior efficiency.
sive in the U.S. However, democratic beliefs
Consequently, a challenge to the existing
norms is bound to be costly to the challenger,
are seen to be ‘ . . . influenced by a recurring
for legitimist professionals can quickly shift process of interchange among political pro-
their skills and resources into the urgent task fessionals, the political stratum, and the great
of doing in the dissenter’ (320) bulk of the population’ (316). The result of
this interchange is that the rules and norms
Vallejo’s urban politics have been long been of governance are incomplete and tend to
bound up with the relationship between the evolve. Furthermore, the practical concerns
City and public labor unions (see Rast of political actors often override any moral
(2006) on regimeless cities). As one City or ideological commitment to improving
Councilor described, ‘getting onto the City democratic life (ibid., 6). The introduction of
Council either means getting their [police PB in Vallejo, and the U.S. generally, therefore
and fire unions] support or getting elected differs from the Porto Alegre architype in that
despite not having their support’ (Interview, it is not a process of democratization onto a
2017). In the two decades leading up to the previous undemocratic context. Rather the
2008 bankruptcy, the city had failed to introduction of PB into U.S. urban politics
rework this relationship to produce a viable represents the introduction of an alternative
fiscal future (City of Vallejo 1993). After conception of democracy into an already-
the 2008 bankruptcy, changes within the democratic institutional context.
City Council meant that PB could emerge The challenges of instituting PB within this
as a response to this situation. context are two-fold. First, as Baiocchi and
PB was viewed by the new City Council Ganuza (2014) argue, the installation of PB
majority as a tool that could provide citizens almost inevitably involves a challenge to
566 CITY VOL. 22, NO. 4

existing political institutions. Just as with any Notes


new entrant into a democratic community,
such a challenge will conflict with existing 1 Source: http://www.people-press.org/2017/05/
institutional arrangements and experience 03/public-trust-in-government-1958-2017/.
2 The City of Vallejo did not release participation
push-back from incumbent power holders
figures for 2016–2017.
(Dahl [1974] 2005). Most notably, citizen-
directed expenditure (i.e. empowered PB)
threatens the automatic prioritization of
growth related spending (Davidson and
References
Ward 2014) and existing expenditure priori-
ties. Second, in the U.S. context, PB will
Abensour, Miguel. 2011. Democracy Against the State:
likely often involve a battle over the idea of Marx and the Machiavellian Movement. Cambridge,
democracy. In Vallejo, proponents of PB MA: Polity.
see it as deepening democracy, with citizen Abers, Rebecca. 1998. “From Clientelism to Cooperation:
participation and decision-making ensuring Local Government, Participatory Policy, and Civic
Organizing in Porto Alegre, Brazil.” Politics & Society
the public good is pursued by the city gov-
26: 511– 537.
ernment. There is no debate over the merits Abers, Rebecca. 2000. Inventing Local Democracy.
of democratic governance in Vallejo (see Grassroots Politics in Brazil. Boulder: Lynne Rienner
Dahl [1974] 2005), or even over the merits Publishers.
of participatory methods. Indeed, as Vallejo’s Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2001. “Participation, Activism, and
Politics: The Porto Alegre Experiment and Deliberative
City Council has rolled back PB spending, it
Democratic Theory.” Politics & Society 29: 43 –72.
has continued to celebrate the national Baiocchi, Gianpaolo, and Ernesto Ganuza. 2014. “Parti-
acclaim it has received for its PB program. cipatory Budgeting as if Emancipation Mattered.”
The challenge for participatory democracy Politics & Society 42: 29 –50.
advocates is therefore how to ensure pro- Baiocchi, Gianpaolo, and Josh Lerner. 2007. “Could
Participatory Budgeting Work in the United States?”
grams such as Vallejo’s PB program do not
The Good Society 16: 8 –13.
become legitimation devices—particularly Bassoli, Matteo. 2012. “Participatory Budgeting in Italy:
during a period of support for participatory An Analysis of (Almost Democratic) Participatory
ideals—with little ability to change the insti- Governance Arrangements.” International Journal of
tutions of governance. This will likely require Urban and Regional Research 36 (6): 1183– 1203.
Bherer, Lawrence, Pascal Dufour, and Francoise Montam-
a more concerted effort to demonstrate the
beault, eds. 2017. The Participatory Democracy Turn.
practical benefits and political necessity of London: Routledge.
participation within governance. As historian Bomey, Nathan. 2016. Detroit Resurrected: To Bankruptcy
Wood (2012, 14– 21) has described, such and Back. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
debates over what constitutes democratic Brenner, Neil, and Nick Theodore, eds. 2003. Spaces of
Neoliberalism: Urban Restructuring in North America
governance and citizenship characterized
and Western Europe. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.
the beginnings of the American republic. City of Vallejo. 1993. Report of the Citizens Budget Advi-
With questions about the legitimacy of the sory Committee. City of Vallejo, May 11.
state reappearing (Fraser 2015), PB advocates City of Vallejo. 2012. Participatory Budgeting in Vallejo
will likely benefit from a consideration of Cycle 1 Rulebook. http://www.ci.vallejo.ca.us/.
City of Vallejo. 2013. City of Vallejo Adopted Budget
how the process helps realize the republican
2013– 2014. http://www.ci.vallejo.ca.us/.
aspirations of American democracy. Moving City of Vallejo. 2015. Participatory Budgeting in Vallejo
forward might well mean first looking back. Cycle 3 Rulebook. http://www.ci.vallejo.ca.us/.
Dahl, Robert. [1974] 2005. Who Governs?: Democracy
and Power in an American City. 2nd ed. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press.
Disclosure statement Davidson, Mark, and Kevin Ward. 2014. “‘Picking up the
Pieces’: Austerity Urbanism, California, and Fiscal
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the Crisis.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and
author. Society 7 (1): 81 –97.
DAVIDSON: PARTICIPATORY BUDGETING, AUSTERITY AND INSTITUTIONS OF DEMOCRACY 567

Davidson, Mark, and Kurt Iveson. 2015. “Recovering the Polletta, Francesca. 2013. “Participatory Democracy in
Politics of the City: From the ‘Post-Political City’ to a Social Movements.” In The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclo-
‘Method of Equality’ for Critical Urban Geography.” pedia of Social and Political Movements, edited by
Progress in Human Geography 39: 543– 559. David Snow, Dontella della Porta, Bert Klandermans,
Davidson, Mark, and William Kutz. 2015. “Grassroots and Doug McAdam, 1– 4. New York: Blackwell.
Austerity: Municipal Bankruptcy from Below in Val- Radzik-Maruszak, Katarzyna, and Michaela Bátorová.
lejo, California.” Environment and Planning A: 2015. “Citizen Participation and Engagement in
Economy and Space 47: 1440–1459. Urban Governance: Perception of Finnish and Polish
de Sousa Santos, Boaventura. 1998. “Participatory Bud- Local Officials.” NISPAcee Journal of Public Admin-
geting in Porto Alegre: Toward a Redistributive istration and Policy 8: 85– 110.
Democracy.” Politics & Society 26: 461– 510. Rancière, Jacques. 2004. Disagreement: Politics and
Fraser, Nancy. 2015. “Legitimation Crisis? On the Political Philosophy. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Contradictions of Financialized Capitalism.” Critical Press.
Historical Studies 2: 157–189. Rast, Joel. 2006. “Governing the Regimeless City: The
Fung, Archon, and Erik Olin Wright. 2001. “Deepening Frank Zeidler Administration in Milwaukee, 1948–
Democracy: Innovations in Empowered Participatory 1960.” Urban Affairs Review 42: 81– 112.
Governance.” Politics & Society 29: 5 –41. Rast, Joel. 2012. “Why History (Still) Matters: Time and
Goldfrank, Benjamin. 2007. “Lessons from Latin American Temporality in Urban Political Analysis.” Urban
Experience in Participatory Budgeting.” In Participa- Affairs Review 48: 3 –36.
tory Budgeting, edited by Anwar Shah, 91–126. Schumpeter, Joseph. 2008. Capitalism, Socialism, and
Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. Democracy. New York: Harper.
Habermas, Jurgen. 1975. Legitimation Crisis. Boston, MA: Shah, Anwar, ed. 2007. Participatory Budgeting.
Beacon Press. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.
Hackworth, Jason. 2015. “Rightsizing as Spatial Austerity Sintomer, Yves, Carsten Herzberg, and Anja Rocke. 2008.
in the American Rust Belt.” Environment and Planning “Participatory Budgeting in Europe: Potentials and
A 47: 766– 782. Challenges.” International Journal of Urban and
Hatcher, Desiree. 2016. “Participatory Budgeting: Regional Research 32 (1): 164– 178.
Enhancing Community Reinvestment Through Public Tahoun, Ahmed. 2017. “The Best Democracy Money Can
Engagement.” ProfitWise News and Views 3: 25 –28. Buy?” London Business School Review 28: 32 –35.
Hicken, Melanie. 2014. “Once Bankrupt, Vallejo Still Can’t Toubeau, Simon, and Markus Wagner. 2015. “Explaining
Afford Its Pricey Pensions.” CNN Money, March 10. Party Positions on Decentralization.” British Journal of
Holdo, Markus. 2016. “Reasons of Power: Explaining Political Science 45: 97– 119.
Non-Cooptation in Participatory Budgeting.” Inter- Wampler, Brian. 2000. A Guide to Participatory Budget-
national Journal of Urban and Regional Research 40 ing. https://www.internationalbudget.org/wp-
(2): 1 –17. content/uploads/A-Guide-to-Participatory-
Logan, John, and Harvey Molotch. [1987] 2007. Urban Budgeting.pdf.
Fortunes: The Political Economy of Place. 20th Anni- Wampler, Brian. 2010. Participatory Budgeting in Brazil:
versary ed. Berkeley, CA: University of California Contestation, Cooperation, and Accountability. Uni-
Press. versity Park, PA: Penn State University Press.
McCann, Eugene, and Kevin Ward. 2011. Mobile Wilson, David, and Jared Wouters. 2003. “Spatiality and
Urbanism: Cities and Policymaking in the Global Age. Growth Discourse: The Restructuring of America’s
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Rust Belt Cities.” Journal of Urban Affairs 25: 123–
Mouffe, Chantel. 2006. The Return of the Political. London: 138.
Verso. Wood, Gordon. 2012. The Idea of America: Reflections on
Pateman, Carole. 2012. “Participatory Democracy the Birth of the United States. London: Penguin Books.
Revisited.” Perspectives on Politics 10: 7 –19. Wright, Erik Olin. 2010. Envisioning Real Utopias.
Peck, Jamie. 2012. “Austerity Urbanism.” City 16: London: Verso.
626– 655. Wright, Erik Olin. 2017. “Real Utopias.” In Performing
Peck, Jamie. 2014. “Pushing Austerity: State Failure, Utopias in the Contemporary Americas, edited by
Municipal Bankruptcy and the Crises of Fiscal Feder- Kim Beauchesne and Alessandra Santos, 151– 160.
alism in the USA.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Economy and Society 7: 17– 44.
Pin, Laura. 2017. “Does Participatory Budgeting Lead to
Local Empowerment? The Case of Chicago, IL.” Mark Davidson is Associate Professor at the
Alternate Routes: A Journal of Critical Social Graduate School of Geography, Clark Uni-
Research 28: 114– 140. versity. Email: mdavidson@clarku.edu

You might also like