You are on page 1of 19

HSC TOPIC 2: Australia’s place in the Global Economy

Australia’s trade and financial flows


Value, composition and direction of Australia’s trade and financial flows

Trends in Australia’s trade pattern


Composition of Aus trade flows Direction of Aus trade flows

Primary industry has been the main focus of Aus X due to comparative advantage Change in key export markets in recent decades: previously it used to be Japan,
in commodities because of vast natural resources. (agriculture + minerals) UK and Europe → South Korea, China, ASEAN.
Reason:
Change in composition of Aus exports (1990 → 2020) (% of total exports) - EU trading bloc → barrier to Europe market for X
- Minerals/metals: 39 → 66 - Japan = high eco growth + D: largest X market for Aus before 1990s
- Rural: 23 → 10 - China = high eco growth + global dominance + demand for
- Services: 20 → 13 commodities: dominant X market for Aus in 21st century.
- Manufacturing: 13 → 8 - Asian economies: expected to dominate world trade in 2020s
Reasons for decline in agriculture exports as % of Aus trade: Change in direction of merchandise trade(1990 → 2020)
- Large fluctuations in world price + trade protection policies → Annual exports (% of total)
influenced export revenue. - China: 5.8 → 38.5
- Agricultural commodity items have little extra value added from - Japan: 26.5 → 10.7
processing compared to other areas eg. transformed manufactures - ASEAN: 12.6 → 11.2
- More extreme weather patterns → reducing output and productivity. - EU: 16.9 → 5.5
Manufacturing decline due to ↑competition from Asian low-cost economies - USA: 13.1 → 6.3
Annual imports (% of total)
Aus imports are relatively unchanged from the 1980s with intermediate goods - China: 4.4 → 23.9
dropping 10% of total and consumer goods ↑ by 15% due to shift away from - Japan: 15.6 → 5.5
domestic manufacturing and the reduction of tariffs + local content rules. - ASEAN: 7.0 → 14.5
- EU: 26.1 → 19.4
- USA: 23.4 → 12.6

Value of Aus trade


- Exports: $457 billion
- Imports: $368 billion
- Average tariff: 1.8% in 2021, was 25% in 1983
- Net foreign debt servicing: $14 billion
- Net returns to foreign investors: $25 billion
- Foreign investment in Aus: $4 trillion
- Aus investment overseas: $3.1 trillion
- Net foreign debt: $1.2 trillion

Trends in financial flows - debt and equity


Investment composition
Foreign investment in Aus
- 1990-91: Direct = 107B, Portfolio = 145 B | Total = 309B
- 2020-21: Direct = 1.1 trillion, Portfolio = 2.1 trillion | Total = 4 trillion
Aus investment abroad
- 1990-91: Direct = 45B, Portfolio = 23B | Total = 115B
- 2020-21: Direct = 874B, portfolio = 1.5 trillion | Total = 3.1 trillion
Reasons for trend
International financial flows began growing rapidly in the 1980s after the deregulation of the financial
sector, floating of the AUD + no foreign ownership rules.
Aus has always been a net capital importer, meaning that FDI levels are way higher than Aus investment
levels abroad.
● This is due to Aus historically low level of domestic savings → relying on overseas financial flows
to make up for the shortfall between S and I in Australia.
● Aus also has significant overseas assets: due to overseas capital markets becoming more open to
foreigners and Australia’s super funds pursuing investment opportunities o/s.
○ Superannuation assets valued at $3.3 trillion at June 2021

Australia’s balance of payments

Structure (Current Account, Capital and Financial Account)


Balance of payments (BOP) → the record of the transactions between Australia and the rest of the world
during a given time period (usually one year)

The Current Account (CA) The Capital and Financial Account (KFA)

External transactions that are not reversible External transactions that are reversible (can be repaid/resold)

a) Net Goods - goods X minus goods M | 76 $bn a) Capital Account - comprises of capital transfers | -0.7 $bn
b) Net Services - services X minus services M | 13.1 $bn ● Transferring of ownership (conditional grants, aid to a foreign
country that is tied to a capital project, assets
a) + b) = Balance of Goods and Services (BOGS) | 89 $bn ● Transactions involving intangible assets: patents, copyrights,
trademarks, franchises
c) Net Primary Income (NPY) - refers to income earnings from FOPs flowing
in and out of Australia | -18.8 $bn b) Financial Account - Australia’s transactions in foreign financial assets
and liabilities | -57.1 $bn
d) Net Secondary Income - refers to current non-market transfers when ● Direct investment → establishment of new company or 10%
flows of money occur without a specific g/s in return. | -2.3 $bn ownership of existing company 10.1 $bn
- Eg: payouts on insurance claims, workers working o/s, pensions ● Portfolio investment → loans, other forms of securities,
provided by foreign gov, general unconditional aid given to speculative shares -57.1 $bn
another country. ● Financial Derivatives → complex financial assets derived off the
performance of other instruments (IRs, XRs, assets) -19.2 $bn
a) + b) + c) + d) totals the balance on the CA. | 68 $bn ● Reserve Assets → monetary gold, SDRs, foreign exchange held by
RBA. -4. $bn
● Other investment → residual category which captures
transactions that don’t belong elsewhere eg: loans, trade credits.
Net errors and omissions - refers to statistical discrepancies to ensure that 13.2 $bn
the BOP = 0 as it does under a floating exchange rate system. Included in
the KFA. -10.2 $bn a) + b) totals the balance on the KFA | -57.8 $bn

Current Account

Debits (outflow) Credits (inflow)

Imports of g/s Exports of g/s


Factor incomes: Factor incomes:
● Interest paid to foreign firms ● Interest received by Australian firms from o/s
● Profits of foriegn firms operating in Aus ● Profits of Australian firms earned offshore
● Payments to offshore employees by Aus firms ● Payments to offshore employees working in Aus
Non-market transfers out of Australia Non-market transfers into Australia

Capital and Financial Account

Debits (outflow) Credits (inflow)

Capital transfer out of Aus Capital transfer into Aus


Direct or portfolio I o/s Direct or portfolio I into Aus
Loans made to foreigners Loans made to Australians by foreigners
Deposits in foreign banks Deposits into Australian banks
RBA selling A$, buying foreign currency. ↑ in reserve assets RBA buying A$, selling foreign currency. ↓ in reserve assets.

Links between key Balance of Payments categories


Equilibrium of exchange rate

M + Y debits + K outflow = X + Y credits + K inflow


M-X + Y debits - Y credits = K inflow - K outflow
CAD = Surplus on KFA (vice versa)

Link between CA and KFA


Strongest link between accounts can be seen through the NPY and KFA.
Every K inflow must earn an income return for the owner. This return is recorded as an NPY debit.
The NPY is the structural cause of a CAD.
K inflow affects NPY in 2 ways:
● International borrowing → debt servicing costs are recorded as NPY debits. So when Australians
borrow money from o/s, this causes a greater NPY deficit as there are more NPY debits as K
inflows increase.
● Foreign investment → require returns on the equity investment in the form of interest, rent,
dividends or profits which is recorded as an NPY debit.
Another link: Australia’s low savings level relative to investment demand has made it necessary to
attract a large inflow on the KFA. Large K inflow = more NPY debits due to debt servicing costs.

Trends in the size and composition of Australia’s Balance of Payments


CA trends
CAD averaged (% of GDP) - 70s = 1.1, 80s = 4, 90s = 4.1, 2000s = 4.9, 2010s = 2.5%
CAS achieved in 2019-20 and 2020-21 due to strong commodity prices, low global IRs, larger contraction
in M than X during the Covid-19 recession.
Treasury forecast of a CAD of 2.25% of GDP in 2022-23 due to the short-term nature of above factors.

BOGS - cyclical factors


1) Terms of Trade → the relative movements in the price of an economy’s imports and exports over a
period of time. (Export price index / import price index ) x 100
- An improvement in the Tot (unless ↓ X volumes) = improvement in BOGS.
- Global commodities boom in 2000s led to significant improvement in BOGS X
- ToT peaked in 2011 (85% above average level of 20th century)
- ToT low point in March 2016 (89)
- ToT increased rapidly in 2019 - ↑iron ore price due to supply shortage in Brazil
- ToT in Dec 2019 fell to 99 - Covid, global output/trade ↓, imposition of tariffs on Aus
agricultural products by China (beef, barley)
- ToT in Nov 2020 back to 101.3 as China rebuilds economy after Covid
- ToT reached all time high of 128 in 3rd quarter of 2021
2) Exchange rate of the A$ → sustained appreciation during mining boom, depreciation in early 2016 to
less than US$0.70, averaging US$0.77 in 17-18, US$0.67 in 19-20
- Low of US$0.48 in April 2001, high of US$1.1 in July 2011
- Recent depreciation in March 2020 (US$0.55) due to:
- ↑in risk aversion and ↓ in investor confidence globally due to Covid. ↑financial market
volatility.
- ↓ in Aus IR differential with other major advanced economies
- Falling commodity prices w/ exception of iron ore → reduced ToT + D for $A
- Effect of depreciation on BOGS:
- ↑BOGS credits from non-mining sectors such as service X (education/tourism) and
↓BOGS debits from ↓imports as they are more expensive
3) International BC → impacts upon the demand for our X, especially from China, India, Asian region
- Prior to Covid, China’s economy was slowing from 10% to 6-7% which led to slower growth in
demand for commodities → fall in commodity prices + worsening of ToT and BOGS.
- Increased demand for X due to greater trade links with faster growing economies such as India
- Growing protectionism and trade tensions since Covid has reduced demand for our X.
4) Domestic eco growth → ↑eco growth = ↑Y, ↑C, ↑X and M.
- Increase in investment in the mining sector has led to ↑M of mining capital goods, worsening
the BOGS during mining investment phases
- Prior to Covid, M were subdued due to weaker household consumption (low wage growth)
- Covid led to Aus recession - ↓ in demand for M, fall in BOGS debits, contributed to BOGS
surplus
- During 2020 higher levels of domestic savings , slower wage growth and soft eco growth in
Australia resulted in ↓growth for M.
- Recently due to Covid, the household saving ratio climbed to an all time high of 22.1.
Restrictions on service M contributing to BOGS surplus.
BOGS - structural factors
1) Australia’s narrow export base
- ⅔ of our X revenue comes from low value added primary goods (mining/agri)
- Aus imports high value added consumer/capital goods (Aus lack IC in these areas)
- Global commodity prices are more volatile resulting in large fluctuations in the BOGS every year
- Economists encourage diversification of our X base away from carbon-intensive exports and
towards ETMs and service exports (recent FTAs should support this)
2) Capacity constraints
- Infrastructure bottlenecks (rail, road, port) were key issues during mining investment phase
- Skill shortages (especially pre GFC as UE rate was at 4% and below NAIRU)
- Supply issues in mining - an inability to increase BOGS credits to potential during mining booms
- Recent years - greater investment in infrastructure have reduced capacity constraints and X
volumes have grown.
3) Global supply chains -
- Rise in the number of TNCs and taking advantage of abundant low wage labour in developing
economies has decreased the price of M → improvement in BOGS.
NPY - cyclical factors
1) XRs (valuation effect) - affects foreign debt valued in foreign currencies
- An appreciation of A$ leads to a ↓ in $A value of our debt, resulting in ↓ NPY debits
- A depreciation of A$ causes an ↑ in value of our debt, leading to an ↑ in NPY debits
- However since most of our foriegn debt is valued in A$ or hedged (65-70%), the valuation effect
has a limited impact on NPY.
2) Global/domestic IRs - changes in IRs can change the level of our debt servicing requirements
- Decline in IRs globally and in Australia has reduced debt servicing costs. Net debt servicing = 14
$bn in 2020-21
- Increase in the share of foreign liabilities owned by the government which pays a lower IR
- Results in narrowing of the NPY deficit recently.
3) Profits + investment returns
- Domestic BC directly influences equity servicing costs. Strong growth results in a rise in profits
distributed as dividends.
- An improvement in the ToT increased X revenue for mining companies. As 80% of mining shares
are owned o/s, this resulted in an ↑ in equity servicing costs to foreigners.
- Strong performance of Aus super funds resulting in high Australian ownership of foreign equity
should offset debt servicing costs in the NPY.
NPY - structural factors
1) Savings-investment gap
- Australia has historically a low level of national savings. Household savings ratio averaged at
1.7% between 2000 and 2008. Following GFC, it ↑ to 10.7% and has fallen back to 2.1%
recently.
- Australians have to borrow from o/s to meet our investment needs as domestic savings are too
low. ↑ debt/equity servicing costs (NPY debits)
- Federal government budget deficits → NPY deficit
- In 2018, 55-60% of Commonwealth Government Securities (CGS) were owned by
foreigners.
KFA trends
Net foreign debt (NFD) = value of what Australia owes to the rest of the world - value of what foreigners
owe to Australia → 59.6% of GDP (June 2021)
Net foreign equity (NFE) = value of o/s assets owned by Australia minus value of domestic assets owned
by foreigners. → -15.1% of GDP (June 2021)
Net foreign liabilities (NFL) = NFD + NFE → 44.5% of GDP (June 2021)

Effects of these trends on Australia’s Balance of Payments


Risks of high CAD
● Growth of foreign liabilities - a CAD involves financial inflow through borrowing from o/s or
selling equity. Results in lenders becoming more reluctant to lend to or invest in Australia.
● ↑ servicing costs - High levels of foreign debt can result in foreign lenders demanding a “risk
premium” on loans, forcing up IRs.
● ↑ volatility for XRs - high CAD can undermine the confidence of o/s investors in the Australian
economy. Can reduce demand for AUD → depreciation of A$
● Constraint on future eco growth - high levels of eco growth involve an ↑ in imports which
deteriorates CAD. Therefore eco growth may have to be limited to make CAD sustainable. (BOP
constraint)
● More contractionary economic policy - governments may want to reduce a high CAD, using
tighter FP/MP
● Sudden loss in international investor confidence - countries with high CADs are more vulnerable
to shifts in investor sentiment. Loss of investor confidence due to unsustainable debt.
The IMF considers a CAD to be too high if it averages over 4% in the medium to long term or over 6% in
the short term.

Exchange rates

Measurement of relative exchange rates


A currency can be measured through:
● Bilateral XRs - measures the value of a unit of domestic currency relative to another currency.
● Trade Weighted Index (TWI) - measures the movements in the AUD against a basket of
currencies of Australia’s major trading partners (weighted according to Aus trade importance)
○ Includes 18 currencies, a more accurate measure of currency value.

Factors affecting the demand for and supply of Australian dollars


Demand for A$ - people who want to buy A$
● Size of financial flows into Australia from foreign investors who want to invest in Aus affected
by:
○ Level of Aus IRs relative to o/s IRs. Higher domestic IR is more attractive to foreigners.
○ Availability of investment opportunities in Australia. Need A$ to invest in Aus
● Expectations of future movements of the A$ - speculators may expect an appreciation leading to
an increase in demand currently which brings about an appreciation.
● The demand for Australian exports affected by:
○ Changes in commodity prices / ToT - can increase/decrease X value
○ IC of domestic exporters and Aus inflation rate relative to o/s countries -
○ Changes in global economic conditions - influences demand for X
○ Tastes/preferences of o/s consumers affects X demand.
Demand for currency is a derived demand - derived from the demand for Australian g/s and assets by
foreigners.
Supply for A$ - people who want to sell A$
● Level of financial flows out of Aus by Australian investors who want to invest o/s affected by:
○ Level of Aus IRs relative to o/s IRs. Higher o/s IR is more attractive for Aus investors
○ Availability of investment opportunities o/s. Sell A$ for other currency to invest o/s.
● Speculators - eg: may anticipate a depreciation and sell A$ thus increasing supply.
● Domestic demand for imports affected by:
○ Level of domestic income, more income = more demand for M, more supply of A$
○ Domestic inflation rate, IC of import-competing domestic firms. Eg: high domestic
inflation, low IC can make imports more attractive, thus increasing demand for M
○ Taste/preferences of domestic consumers + preference for g/s from o/s
Supply of currency is derived from the domestic demand for foreign g/s and assets.

Changes in exchange rates - appreciation/depreciation


Factors causing an appreciation/depreciation
Determination of exchange rates incl. fixed, flexible and managed rates
Fixed
In a fixed XR system, a country’s XR is fixed by the central bank (usually on a daily basis) to another
currency (eg: reserve currency like the $US).
China, Hong Kong SAR fixed their currency to the US$ until 2005.
Government intervention to fix exchange rate
● A devaluation of a currency occurs when there is deliberate action taken by a government to
decrease the value in the forex market.
● A revaluation of a currency occurs when there is deliberate action taken by a government to
increase the value in the forex market.
Advantages:
● Certainty - trade and investment less risky
● Absence of speculation - no speculation as investors know what the rate would be beforehand
● Constraint on gov policy - gov is unable to pursue extreme or irresponsible macroeconomic
policies as it would be unsustainable in the medium term and put pressure on forex reserves.
Disadvantages:
● Economy may be unable to respond to shocks - no mechanism for gov to act during BOP crises
● Problems with reserves - requires large foreign reserves, international liquidity problems
● Speculation - forex market believe there would be a change, run of speculation could occur.
● Deflation - countries with BOP deficits deflate their economies to correct deficits, this will
reduce the surpluses of other countries as well as deflating their own economies to restore the
surplus (creates deflationary bias)
Flexible/floating
Supply and demand determine XR.
The Australian government floated the AUD in 1983
Advantages:
● Protection from external shocks - free XRs can change in response to external shocks due to
demand and supply mechanisms (shock-absorber)
● Lack of policy constraints - government are free to pursue policies appropriate for the domestic
economy without worrying about XR policy
● Correction of BOP deficits - floating XR can depreciate to compensate for a BOP deficit. Restores
IC of exports (J-Curve theory)
● Government could pursue more independent and effective MP as BOP outcomes would not
impact on the money supply and cause MP to be less effective in controlling inflation.
Disadvantages:
● Instability - prone to large fluctuations in value. Investment/trade may be adversely affected.
Known as 'overshooting' where the currency changes in value by more than anticipated.
Derivatives, hedging options prevent this.
● No constraints on domestic policy - governments can pursue inappropriate domestic policies.
● Speculation - existence of speculation can lead to exchange rate changes which are unrelated to
trade patterns.
Managed
Similar to fixed as the currency is pegged/adjusted daily to variations in major trading partners currency.
Australia’s XR was pegged to the UK pound in the 1950s (most of Aus trade was with the UK back then).
In the 1960s, it was pegged to the $US as it was the international reserve currency,
Between 1978 and 1983, a 'crawling peg' was used with the XR pegged to the TWI.
In this system, the central bank would set the XR daily, keeping it within a 'target band'. It would buy
and sell currency to ensure that the currency remained in the target area.

The influence of the RBA on exchange rates


Currency trader in the forex market
The RBA has reserves of foreign currencies and gold so it can affect the XR directly by intervening in the
forex market as a buyer or seller. (Dirtying the float)
Two main strategies:
● Targeting → when the RBA aims for a precise currency value, it would then buy/sell currencies
to achieve this target. This undermines the flexible XR system.
○ Problems: RBA’s currency reserves are very small and can only affect XRs for less than a
day. Prolonged selling of A$ can create inflationary pressures by increasing the money
supply.
● Smoothing and testing → the RBA 'smooths out' large fluctuations in the currency’s value.
○ XR is still largely determined by D/S but only has a small effect to ensure that the
economy does not destabilise.
Interest rates
RBA indirectly influences the XR through its MP activity
MP affects domestic IRs. If Australia’s IR is higher than the rest of the world we attract more foreign
investment. More K inflow = increased demand for A$ = appreciation.
RBA uses MP for inflation controlling purposes rather than for external stability.
Jawboning
Practice where officials try to affect the forex market outcomes through public statements.
Eg: officials can cause an appreciation by ‘talking up’ the economy. Predictions of strong eco growth can
encourage foreign investment in Australia, resulting in an appreciation.
Speculators in particular try to seize on hints/clues given by officials to act quickly in forex markets.

The effects of fluctuations in exchange rates on the Australian economy

Appreciation Depreciation

X X becomes relatively more expensive o/s X becomes relatively cheaper o/s


X volumes + revenue may ↓ X volumes/revenue ↑

M M becomes relatively more cheaper in Australia M becomes relatively more expensive in Australia
More spending on M + domestic firms may stop Less spending on M + more domestic firm production
producing goods that have import substitutes. + greater domestic market share.
KFA O/s asset price is reduced, easier for Australian O/s asset price becomes more expensive for
investors to purchase = ↑ in KFA outflow Australian investors to purchase = ↓ in KFA outflow
Less debt, more equity More debt, less equity
Becomes more expensive for foreign investors to Becomes cheaper for foreign investors to invest in
invest in Australia = ↓ KFA inflow Australia = ↑ KFA inflow

Foreign debt Reduce the A$ value of foreign debt borrowed in Increases the A$ value of foreign debt borrowed in
foreign currency (valuation effect) foreign currency.

NPY account ↓ the interest servicing cost on foreign debt (due ↑ the interest servicing costs on foreign debt (due to
to ↓ in NFL) ↑ in NFL) Increases outflow on the NPY account
Reduces outflow on the NPY account

CAD ↓X, ↑M = ↓BOGS ↑X, ↓M = ↑BOGS


↑NPY ↓NPY
CAD likely to worsen but offsetted by CAD is likely to improve but would be slowed by
improvement in NPY worsening of NPY.

Domestic investment May reduce domestic investment as capital Can encourage an ↑ in domestic investment through
equipment is not in high demand due to lower purchasing capital equipment for X-competing firms
production output from domestic firms. to boost production (eg. mining)

Eco growth AD = C + I + G + (X-M) AD = C + I + G + (X-M)


↓I, ↓X, ↑M = reduced eco growth rate ↑I, ↑X, ↓M = increased eco growth

Inflation Demand pull inflation: ↓ Demand pull inflation: ↑


↓ net X can slow AD causing supply surpluses. ↑ net X can cause excessive demand and supply
Widespread price discounting = low inflation shortages = ↑ demand pull inflation

Cost-push inflation: ↓ Cost push inflation: ↑


Costs of inputs for local producers become Costs of inputs for local producers become expensive
cheaper thus easing cost push inflation. (from o/s) thus adding to cost push inflation

Government policy Less spending on repaying public sector debt, More spending on repaying public sector debt due to
more funds available for other policy initiatives. valuation effects → less funds available for other
policies.
MP is not as necessary for lowering Inflation.
More inflation → gov policy needs to be more
focussed on this

J CURVE

The J curve suggests that a depreciation in currency will


lead to the trade deficit to worsen before having positive
effects on trade. J shape.
Free trade and protection
Australia’s policies regarding free trade + protection
Government’s main aims in reducing protection:
● Force domestic industries to become internationally competitive by exposing them to overseas
competition.
● Reallocating resources to industries which have a comparative advantage.
● Giving consumers/firms access to global g/s at lowest possible price through global integration.
● Promote structural change with a long term aim of encouraging efficient industries producing
goods for the global economy.
Government initiatives to reduce protection
● Gradual decline in average tariff level: 1969 = 36%, 2018 = 0.9%
● Historically, some manufacturing industries such as PMV or TCF were protected by high tariff
levels but these have been phased out by 2015.
● Australia is one of the least protectionist economies in the world + provides less subsidies
compared to North America, EU, East Asia.
● Instead of subsidies, the government provides export assistance through the Export Market
Development Grants (EMDG) scheme which reimburses export costs
○ The EMDG scheme was effective (2015 review). Each dollar had an economic benefit of
$1.50 to $7.
● Few ways where policy changes could liberalise trade (as per WTO, 2020):
○ Abolish tax on luxury cars (hurts exports from some countries)
○ Abolish certain foreign investment restrictions.
○ Less prolific use of anti-dumping measures.
Trade examples/policy
● 2016 - DCNS Group 25 year, $50 billion contract to build 12 submarines. Reason: its promise to
do the bulk of the manufacturing work in SA. Expected to add 30-40% to the total cost but
deepens domestic skill base for vessel maintenance.
● 2018 - Aus gov announced a telecommunications industry policy that banned Chinese telecom
giants, Huawei + ZTE from involvement in 5G mobile telecommunications network rollout.
Makes the rollout more expensive + lower quality.
● 2020 - Chinese government imposed tariffs on >80% on Aus exports on barley. Reason: anti-
dumping + anti-subsidy penalties (no evidence however), retaliation for Aus advocacy into China
inquiry of Covid-19 origins.

Australia’s multilateral + bilateral free trade agreements


List of FTAs for Australia
Bilateral: (12)
● ANZCERTA → NZ est 1983
● SAFTA → Singapore, est 2003
● TAFTA → Thailand, est 2005
● AUSFTA → USA, est 2005
● ACI-FTA → Chile, est 2009
● MAFTA → Malaysia, est 2013
● KAFTA → Korea, est 2014
● ChAFTA → China, est 2015
● JAEPA → Japan, est 2015
● IA-CEPA → Indonesia, est 2019
● A-HKFTA → Hong Kong, est 2020
● PAFTA → Peru, est 2020
Multilateral (3)
● APEC forum, est 1989
● AANZFTA → ASEAN + NZ, est 2010
● CPTPP → Aus + 19 other countries, est 2018

Agreements overview

Bilateral Agreement JAEPA ChAFTA

Agreement date July 8th 2014, implemented in Jan 2015 Nov 17th 2014, implemented Dec 2015

Economic importance to Aus: Trade Trade


- Trade • Japan is 3rd largest economy in the world • China is Aus largest trading partner
- investment • Aus 2nd largest trading partner due to large • important for Aus to establish trade agreement to
amounts of exports. maximise agricultural exports as China demand
• Rapid eco growth in Asian economies, essential increases.
for Aus continued prosperity.
Investment
Investment • China is Aus 8th largest source of investment
• Japan was the 4th largest source of investment
stock in Australia (ÅUD 241B in 2019)
• Japan is Aus 4th largest investment destination
(AUD 139B in 2019)

Main exports/imports Top 5 exports to Japan Top 5 exports to China


1. Natural Gas 1. Iron ores/concentrates
2. Coal 2. Natural gas
3. Iron ore + concentrates 3. Coal
4. Beef 4. Education-related travel
5. Copper ore + concentrates 5. Beef
Aus is 3rd largest source of Japan’s M Aus is 5th largest source of China’s M
Top 5 imports from Japan Top 5 imports from China
1. PMV 1. Telecom equipment + parts
2. Refined petroleum 2. Computers
3. Goods vehicles 3. Furniture, mattresses + cushions
4. Gold 4. Refined petroleum
5. Rubber tyres/treads/tubes 5. Toys, games, sporting goods.
China is 13th largest source of Aus’s M

Trade position (19-20 figures) Total X to Japan = 53 Billion AUD Total X to China = 151 Billion AUD
Total M from Japan = 19 billion AUD Total M from China = 81 Billion AUD

Investment activity with country • Aus investment in Japan = AUD 139 Billion Aus investment in China = AUD 85 billion
(2019 figures) • Japan investment in Aus = AUD 241 Billion China investment in Aus = AUD 78 billion

Main benefits of agreement Agriculture Agriculture


● Beef (comp adv for Aus) ● Dairy (2019 ones done)
JAPAN - Frozen beef tariff facing Aus = 38.5% to 30.5% (in Tariff eliminations:
Agriculture 2015) - phases down to 19.5% over 18yrs. - 15% tariff on infant formula (by 2019)
- beef, ↓ tariffs
- 10-19% tariff on ice cream, lactose, casein (by 2019)
- dairy ↓ tariffs, ↑ quotas
- horticulture, tariff elimination - Fresh beef tariff facing Aus = 38.5% to 32.5% (in - 15% tariff on liquid milk (by 2024)
Provides comp adv for Aus exporters 2015) - phases down to 23.5% over 15yrs. - 10-15% tariff on cheese, butter and yoghurt (2024)
over major competitors such as USA - 10% tariff on milk powders (by 2026)
- Aus can never be subjected to an auto 50% global
Resources, energy, manufacturing snapback tariff Aus faces discretionary safeguard on whole milk
Immediate tariff elimination ● Dairy powders ONLY.
Phased tariff elimination (5-10yrs) - Immediate Aus-only duty free quotas for
Duty free exports
Natural cheese for processing (4000T → 20 ● Hides, skin, leather (2019 ones done)
thousand T over 20yrs) Tariff eliminations:
Shredding cheese (1000 → 5000 T ovr 10yrs) - 7% tariff on sheepskins (by 2019)
- Immediate elimination of tariffs upto 8.5% on - 5-8.4% tariff on cow hides/skins (by 2022)
casein, lactose, albumin & milk protein - 9% tariff on kangaroo hides/skins, 14% kangaroo
concentrates. leather (by 2019)
- 5-15% tariff on a range of leather products (done)
- Preferential Aus-only quotas for ice cream, ● Wine/spirits by 2019
yoghurt, grated cheese. - Tariffs of 14-20% on Aus wine M eliminated
- Tariffs upto 65% on alcoholic beverages eliminated
- Preferential access for blue veined cheese with no
volume restrictions. Resources, energy, manufacturing
● Horticulture Elimination of a wide-range of tariffs on mining
- Immediate elimination of tariffs on fresh veg, eg: products by 2019 or immediately:
asparagus, carrots, potatoes, truffles. - Tariff of 3% on coking coal ($8B market - 2017)
- Tariff of 6% on thermal coal ($3.8B - 2017)
- Immediate elimination of tariffs upto 6% on - Tariff of 3% on unwrought zinc ($661M - 2017)
macadamia nuts, almonds, pecans, hazelnuts +
phased elimination of 10% tariff on walnuts (5yrs) Elimination of a wide-range of tariffs on manufactured
and chestnuts (10yrs) goods by 2019 or immediately:
- 3-10% tariffs on pharmaceutical products
- Immediate elimination of tariffs on fresh mangoes, - Tariff of 20% on car parts, engines
dried grapes + range of berries. - Tariff of 6.5-14% on plastic products

Resources, energy, manufacturing Closer collaboration between regulators, authorities,


- Almost all resource, energy, manufacturing relevant professional bodies on both sides to facilitate
exports entered Japan duty free (all by 2034) traditional Chinese meds + complementary meds.
- Immediate elimination of tariffs on coke (+ semi)
of coal, non-crude petroleum oils, aluminium Services
hydroxide & titanium dioxide Australian service providers gain significant access into
- Phased elimination of tariffs for unwrought nickel Chinese markets eg:
and ferro-manganese Aus firms can conduct construction projects in China,
- Immediate elimination of tariffs on paints, key Aus tourism companies operate hotels in China,
plastic products and pearl jewelry. Aus subsidiaries can contract Chinese manufacturing
- provides boost to Aus exporters (greater market services to lower production costs.
share in Jap)
Investment
Intellectual property + electronic commerce Under ChAFTA, the Gov will continue to screen Chinese
- no custom duties on electronic transmissions investments at lower thresholds for agriculture, media,
- cooperation on regulating spam, cyber-security, telecommunications, and defence.
telemarketing
- Aus innovators will enjoy protection for their China granted Aus a Renminbi quota of RMB 50B to
intellectual property in Japan. invest in Chinese securities to allow Aus institutions to
invest offshore Chinese currency in Chinese financial
Services products.

Investor State DIspute Settlement (ISDS)


A mechanism which prompts investor confidence and
resolves disputes between China and Aus.
Aus investors in China can use the ISDS mechanism to
protect their investments from discriminatory
treatment compared with Chinese domestic investors

Labour market
Higher skilled workforce for Aus greater geographical
mobility between Aus and China with more reasons for
access for Chinese citizens.
More workers are coming to Aus to fill occupations
related specifically to China such as martial arts,
traditional Chinese medicine practitioner, Mandarin
language tutors.

Main criticisms of agreement

Multilateral Agreements ASEAN-Aus-NZ FTA (AANZFTA) Regional Comprehensive Economic


Partnership (RCEP)

When + who Signed 2009, in force since 2010 15 countries including Australia, China, Japan, NZ and
Updated in 2015 to streamline certification ASEAN countries + Indo-Pacific Region.
processes for the movement of goods through
AANZFTA countries. Signed November 2020 after 8 years of negotiation.

Australia, NZ, ASEAN (10 countries): Brunei,


Darussalam, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia,
Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand,
Vietnam

Importance to Australia GDP: US$3.9 trillion (2015) World’s largest trade deal, covers 30% of global GDP 30
GDP per capita: US$5,948 (2015) % of world's exports.
Population: 658.2 million (2015)
Trade with Aus: $120 bn (2015) Bigger than CP-TPP and inclusive of almost all Asian
2019 estimated GDP of all ASEAN: 9.34 trillion USD regions (except India)

Main benefits Aus total 2-way g/s trade with ASEAN has increased
by 16.4% since 2010. 2019 total trade = $122 bn
ASEAN accounts for 13.8% of Aus 2-way g/s trade
(2016)

Aus direct investment in ASEAN in 2019 accounted


for 5.5% of Aus total FDI abroad. (AUD 45 bn)

Trends in shifts to emerging sectors - clean energy,


financial services, professional services, health
Reflects shifts in ASEAN region with a 600m
population which is young + growing middle class
demand high quality services from Aus.

Issues/challenges Implementing rules of origin requirements


Delays in conducting mandated interviews
stipulated for non-tariff measures.
Limited use of the FTA as a regional agreement to
offer opportunities additional to bilateral FTAs.
Micro, Small + Medium Enterprises account for 98%
of business in Asia, and need to be incorporated in
the FTA framework to allow greater access in supply
chains.

The implications of Australia’s policies for individuals, firms and governments


Summary Table (reduced protection):
Individuals Firms Governments

Short Structural UE ↑ as inefficient firms close Import-competing industries go out of business Cutting tariffs will reduce gov revenue
Run (non-transferrable skills → LT UE)
↓tariffs provide ↓input costs for firms ↓protection → adverse political consequences
Consumers gain ↑access to ↑variety of
g/s at ↓prices, higher living standards ↑gov spending on structural adjustment programs
(long run as well)

Long run ↑job opportunities in internationally Efficient firms restructure operations to compete Sustainable eco growth → ↑revenue
competitive sectors on global stage

Example Low-skilled, production-line jobs in Individual firms in marginal import-competing Reduction in gov revenue - $1.5B collected by gov (19-20_
s manufacturing sector → ↓ occupational industries will shrink unless they improve However, it's less than 1% of total revenue.
mobility competitiveness.
Assist with structural adjustment programs through
Detail
Clothing tariff cuts: 17.5% to 10% in 2010 Eg: Manufacturing of consumer electronics increased expenditure + UE benefits, retraining programs.
Created unemployment of over 1500 jobs ceased in Australia in 2017 → cannot compete
Lower prices for consumers. with low wage costs of China/Viet Eg: $155 mil Growth Fund to support transition away
from PMV industry when domestic car production ended
2021 Aus was the largest LNG exporter in Restructuring operations to stay in business or in 2017.
the world raise profits. Eg; Consolidate process to one
plant, eliminate unprofitable product lines, more Political consequences because the costs of ↓protection
New job opportunities in export exports, new tech, less staff etc. are easily visible: structural UE, factory closure, damage
industries such as LNG. to regional Aus.
Productivity Commission 2020: abolishing tariffs
(liquefied natural gas)

Between 1985 and 2011: ↓54% in real


on production inputs → ↓$2B per year in input
costs. ↓
Makes it unpopular with communities
price for manufactures e.g., footwear, Winner/loser firms → changes composition of X
electronics, furniture, motor vehicles. 1990 - 2021 (Aus exports)
Minerals/metals: 33% → 58%
Improved customer service due to Rural: 23% → 10%
increased competition. Services: 20% → 14%

Implications for Australia of protectionist policies of other countries and trading blocs
Agriculture
- EU trading bloc → CAP heavily subsidies farmers
- The USA, Japan, Korea, Switzerland all give subsidies to farmers.
- ChAFTA → Aus wine X to China worth $1.1 bn in 2019-20. However, tariffs in 2020 have caused
major damage.
- Reducing agricultural protection in recent years has slowed down (reflecting protectionism
trend) due to taking advantage of WTO loopholes
Manufacturing/mining
- Mining and resources sector face very few barriers to trade due to high global demand.
Countries importing Aus energy do not have their own resources to produce alternatives
- Most industrialised economies have low manufacturing tariffs. Some Aussie exporters face non-
tariff barriers such as technical restrictions and licensing rules
Services
- Many natural barriers to services trade due to geography, transport costs, language, cultural,
local preferences rather than protectionism.
- 70% of Aus economy but only ¼ of our X.
- Government regulations restrict services, eg. banking licences, monopoly government providers,

Future of Aus Industry in the Global Economy


- Mining will likely remain Australia’s most important industry. 2020-21: mining/resources
earnings exceeded $200 billion
- Expansion of LNG exports, 36 $bn in 2020
- Agriculture faces a mixed outlook: wilder weather (climate change, disasters etc) + subsidy
effect o/s.
- Digital g/s. 4th largest X at $5 bn in 2018 (Export Council of Australia.)
- Environmental services: annual global investment in clean energy is now over US$280 billion,
taking total investment since 2004 over $3 trillion. (Global Trends in Renewable Energy
Investment Report 2020)

TOPIC 3: ECO OBJECTIVES CONFLICTS (TEST)


Economic Objectives

Objective Measured By? Why is this an objective Recent Issues/2022 goals

Economic Growth GDP per annum An ↑in EG helps keep UE low = Economic Recovery
Real GDP = Nom GDP x 100/CPI ↑ in Y and ↑material living standards Most severe economic downturn since 1930s
↑ G finances + capacity to provide services LT EG rate = 2.75%
Growth rate = (Cur GDP - Prev GDP) x + welfare ST high rebound EG rate (2022) - budget forecast: 21-22
Prev GDP ↑ non-material living standards → reduced → 4.5%, 22-23 → 2.5%
crime, mental health ↑ Largest fiscal stimulus in history (-8% of GDP)
↑X, more consumer variety through M Lowest ever cash rate - 0.1%
Encourages I for future growth Industry specific measures to support affected industries
(aviation, tourism, art etc)
Issues =
Covid variants
Global downturn - trade tensions, geopolitical risk, oil
prices (Rus-ukr)
Supply chain constraints (transport costs)
USA rising inflation
Domestic conditions - recent floods. (-0.2% impact on
march quarter)

↑ productivity and sustainable LT EG rate


Need measures to improve productivity and workforce
participation to address capacity constraints.
Need reforms in edu + training, competition, national
regulation, infrastructure.

Full Employment UE rate = (UE / labour force) x 100 ↑ in human resources = ↑ in productive Reducing UE
Labour force = UE + FT + PT capacity Prevent labour market scarring (LT UE)
Occurs at the Participation rate = (working age Closer to full production (PPF curve) Stimulus - JobKeeper
natural rate of UE popln / labour force) x 100 ↑ in Y = ↑ in living standards. UE to fall to 4.25% by end of 2022
(NAIRU) Job recovery thru tax cuts for L&MIT earners and
Elimination of business, I in new projects, labour market initiatives,
cyclical UE. JobTrainer, childcare support
Issues = migration restrictions,

Price Stability Inflation rate = (Cur Infl - Prev Infl) / Inflation results in a reduction in the Maintain low + stable inflation
Prev Infl x 100 purchasing power of money = ↓ SOL Inflation target of 2-3% - currently at 3.5% (March 22)
Low inflation within Underlying inflation removes one-off Results in distortion of resource allocation Priority in recovery for higher EG + lower UE ahead of
target band (3-4%) events. Producers put up higher prices or reduce inflation.
labour costs = ↑UE Issues =
“Internal stability” Y redistribution from fixed Y and wage Underlying inflation has picked up to 3.25% (mid-22) →
earners to those receiving profits/dividends 2.75% in 2023 as microeconomic problems are resolved
↓ in real savings and real I and consumption patterns normalise. Will spike due to:
Loss of IC as X prices ↑ - Higher oil prices
- Fanned by labour shortages
- Demand in construction / durables
- Supply constraints - flood / transport costs
- Imported inflation from the US

External Stability As a % of GDP: Lowers external balances which results in Two phase approach to FP
- CAD less vulnerability to adverse developments Budget deficit used to support EG and job creation
- NFL in global financial markets Fiscal discipline once UE back to pre-crisis level + reduce
- NFD debt as %GDP (↓ crowding-out)
- TOT LT effects on EG, inflation, internal stability Government debt to GDP ratio → improve stability of
- XR public finances and investor confidence.
- IC Issues =
Rising commodity prices and favourable ToT
Budget deficits projected until 2061 due to ageing
popln, lower participation rate

Fair Income Lorenz curve: outward shift = Reducing the gap → ↑ in C and ↑ in utility Improving distribution of income/wealth
Distribution ↑inequality Reduces G spending on welfare in LT LT objective:
Gini coefficient: Decreases tax burden on households + G Policy response - education funding reforms, ↑ in age
Area A / (Area A + Area B) fiscal position pensions, NDIS
Where GC approaches 1, inequality Address economic costs of poverty + LT ST-policy - to minimise effects on vulnerable groups due
↑ social negatives (alienation, poverty trap) to Covid thru JobKeeper, double UE benefit, access to
Super funds.
21-22 budget ($bn) - 3.4 for women’s safety, 18 for aged
care
Issue = access to super → depletes savings of lower Y
earners - ↑ inequality.

Environmental Various measurements eg: Need to minimise environmental costs of Promoting environmental sustainability
Sustainability. - Gas emissions EG in LT LT EG dependent on overcoming environmental
- Loss of biodiversity challenges (climate change, water shortages, diversity)
- Loss of habitat Minimise negative externalities, climate ST trade-off with EG and inflation
- Deterioration of common change economic impacts . Committed to net-0 emissions by 2030 - using tech not
access goods taxes.
- Deforestation Environmental damage leads to loss of life + Issues =
potentially reducing production output with Phase down, not out approach for coal/methane at
fewer resources. COP26
Removal of Biodiversity Conservation Act
Weakens G finances (↓T, ↑G on repairs, Covid recovery stimulus → no environmental focus
infrastructure, assistance etc) Plans for $600m gas fired power station for carbon
capture.

Economic Conflicts

Conflicting Objectives Explanation of the Conflict

1. UE and inflation
Full employment + price stability The Phillips Curve - governments face a trade off b/w lower UE and
inflation in the short to medium term.

Stronger AD caused job growth and reduces UE but puts upward


pressure on prices (higher labour costs + shift in demand)

Weaker AD forces firms to restrain price rises but that can lead to an
increase in UE (as firms need less labour)

A 2015 RBA research paper concluded that inflation targeting had


resulted in a “flatter” Phillips Curve → less trade-off b/w UE and
inflation.

Since 1993, Australia has had an explicit inflation target of 2-3% → priority over low UE.

2. EG and external balance Strong EG often results in a deterioration in the CA of the BOP. Higher EG is usually associated with increases in C
and I which will cause the M volume to rise. This is known as the BOP constraint → the limitation on the growth
rate because of the impact of high growth on the CAD.

3. EG and environmental Pursuit of EG can come at the cost of environmental damage. Eg. a government approves mining projects to
sustainability boost I and X but disregards their environmental effects → could have faster EG but can damage air quality,
cause lung cancer or water pollution and affect industries such as tourism.
A government that attempts to reduce Australia’s carbon emissions may impose costs on households and firms
that slow down EG (through lower C from lower purchasing power)

4. EG and income inequality Economic reforms can have negative social effects. G spending on infrastructure can lead to a reliance on toll
roads or user-pay charges for public services which can disadvantage low-income earners as it becomes a higher
proportion of their income compared to high-Y earners.

You might also like