You are on page 1of 14

Strat.

Change 24: 1–14 (2015)


Published online in Wiley Online Library
(wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/jsc.1994 RESEARCH ARTICLE

The Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation:


The Case of Rang De in Crowdfunding1
Arvind Ashta
Burgundy School of Business, Dijon, France
Djamchid Assadi
Burgundy School of Business, Dijon, France
Nadiya Marakkath
Tata Institute of Social Sciences, Mumbai, India

Crowdfunding sites in developing


countries need to work on A crowdfunding site in a developing country like India faces strategic challenges
due to both supply-side and demand barriers in the social lending market.
changing culture and social
structures to foster a ‘giving’
culture. Web 2.0 technology gave birth to a breakthrough social innovation in microfi-
nance. It considerably reduced the transaction costs of collecting and distributing
Crowdfunding sites must find an
funds to poor micro-entrepreneurs. At the same time, it introduced a planetary
appropriate legal status to be able
to conduct their business. dimension to microfinance where developed-country retail investors could now
participate. Though this innovative proposition seemed to be promising, particu-
Online lending platforms need to
make a decision on the
larly in countries with massive unsatisfied banking needs such as India, it did not
subsidization expected from unleash all the expected new driving forces within the sector owing to unprece-
lenders. dented strategic challenges for actors.
Online lending platforms need to
We explore the challenging strategic questions that an organization faces
be transparent on their interest through the evolution of an old sector (social group lending) to a high-technology-
rate and lending practices to the based stage (peer-to-peer (P2P) social lending on the Internet). This article also
microfinance institutions. explores the concept of social innovation, which enjoys increasing interest from
researchers, professionals, and the public (Beckett, 2012; Davies and Koza, 2001;
Descubes et al., 2013; Dunphy et al., 1995).
We first present the four challenging questions that actors in the solidarity
sector and, as an example in our study, in the business of lending money to the
poor, have to face. Secondly, we explain the model of online P2P social lending,
a particular type of crowdfunding, which exemplifies social innovation in the
sector of microfinance. We describe the emergence of the Web 2.0-based social
lending websites as a high-tech avatar of a sector that originally addressed the low
level of the pyramid. Finally, we consider the special Indian case of Rang De
(which means ‘adding color’ in Hindi) to consider all the above questions.

1
JEL classification codes: D14, G2, L22, L31, L86, O16, O31, O35.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


Strategic Change: Briefings in Entrepreneurial Finance DOI: 10.1002/jsc.1994
2 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

Challenges of financing a high-growth sector funds seems to have worked quite well in view of the
A large number of special-issue articles in this journal have stellar performance of the sector (Daher and Le Saout,
made the reader aware of many questions in microfinance 2013), and even if returns are low but the MFI is targeting
(Dowla, 2012; Hannam and Cheng, 2012; Milana and women (Mersland and Urgeghe, 2013). However, IPOs
Ashta, 2012). The sector is very profitable (Daher and Le have created societal debate (Ashta and Hudon, 2012;
Saout, 2013), although crises occur in some countries Rosenberg, 2007). This is because the public does not
from time to time (Constantinou and Ashta, 2011). realize that this double-bottom-line sector is extremely
Appendix 1 provides an idea of the magnitude of this profitable till it sees the initial public offerings (IPOs)
sector in India. Six of the largest microfinance institutions being priced at many times the book value and being
(MFIs) have more than a million clients each. oversubscribed. In India, the IPO of SKS led to a lot of
The amazing growth of this highly profitable sector soul-searching (Ashta and Hudon, 2012), attribution of
needs to be properly financed and managed if that growth blame to microfinance for borrower suicides (Ashta et al.,
is to be sustainable (Ashta, 2008; Higgins, 1977). Typi- 2011), and the Andhra Pradesh legislator passing an ordi-
cally, microfinance institutions may be financed by dona- nance which catalyzed a crisis in the sector (Mader, 2013).
tions, deposits, equity, or borrowing instruments. While much of the debate has been on the high profits of
Since donations are subject to fads, microfinance the MFIs, other practices such as high interest rates being
institutions search for other means to be sustainable. Most charged to customers and coercive loan-recovery practices
institutions have found that donor funds are limited and, are being brought to light.
in order to grow fast, they have tended to change their Finally, most investment funds and banks finance this
status from non-governmental organizations (NGOs) to sector through loans. This includes both soft loans from
for-profits. Appendix 2 shows that in India, eight out of public investment funds (and at times from private ones),
the top ten institutions are now non-banking financial as well as market or near-market loans from private invest-
institutions, of which five have changed to this legal status ment funds (CGAP, 2008; Goodman, 2006). This too
from a not-for-profit society status. The ethical challenge may create problems if MFIs get over-leveraged. However,
posed by this transformation is that the mission changes the industry has been more worried that there will not be
and donations, as well as volunteer work, are not rewarded. enough funds coming from the large public and private
Usually, only banks and cooperatives have access to investment funds, and therefore it is hoping that retail
deposits. Since banks were not initially lending to the investors will start taking an interest. Indeed, these retail
poor, only cooperatives were considered to be a relevant investors have started crowdfunding microfinance with
microfinance model. Collecting their own deposits allowed initiatives such as Kiva in the USA, Babyloan in France,
cooperatives to be self-financed and go into rural areas and Rang De in India.
(Périlleux, 2013). The cooperative model needs good gov- For this particular type of crowdfunding to be suc-
ernance if it is to succeed in microfinance (Allemand cessful in the long run, it will need to learn from and
et al., 2013). In India, the cooperative sector is quite small address the challenges that the microfinance sector has
and therefore most MFIs do not have access to deposits. faced. These challenges concern not only actors within the
Banks provide two-thirds of the microfinance to self-help microfinance sector but also in the entire solidarity sector.
groups. (1) Should MFIs be incorporated like any other conven-
A third possibility is equity, initially through one’s tional firm by appealing to profit-seeking investors? (2)
own profits, then through private placements and later Are poverty relief and profit belief compatible? That is, is
through public offerings. Financing from investment profit seeking, as an evident and necessary element of a

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 3

market economy, pertinent for a sector whose primary One stream of online lending models is commercial.
objective is to eradicate poverty? (3) Are MFIs responsible This includes Zopa, which started in 2005, Prosper and
for poor borrowers’ thorough understanding of all fees? Lending club, and a host of other newcomers. All these
(4) Are subsidies ethical, knowing their impacts on non- websites are domestic operators since they do not want to
subsidized private competitors? entertain problems of international law. When these web-
The first challenge is therefore to decide the appropri- sites expand to another country, they start a new company.
ate legal status and governance. The second challenge is So, you can have Zopa UK, Zopa Italy, Zopa Japan, for
to balance the double bottom line through appropriate example. The websites post a borrower’s profile on the
interest rates and social practices. The third challenge Internet, indicating why he or she requires the loan. This
relates to transparency. The fourth challenge is not to personalization of the money supply chain attracts a
crowd out the market. The discussion in our case study certain segment of lenders. The interest rates are set
will focus on each of these challenges. through auction mechanisms (Ashta & Assadi, 2011;
Johnson et al., 2010). Their initial promise was to lower
interest rates to borrowers and increase returns to lenders
Online lending models compared with what commercial banks were promising.
Business, as almost all other living actors, attaches to its However, often these rates could be higher than commer-
habits and does not like changes that imply revising cial lending rates because either the risk of the borrower
current practices. However, when a handful of early is not known (because he or she has no credit history) or
movers turn a breakthrough technology into a competi- it is too high and the banks are not willing to lend to them
tive advantage, the remaining competitors wake up and at any rate. All these companies are run on a for-profit
endeavor to catch up. This is what happened with the Web basis. They bring all small lenders and borrowers together,
2.0 tools on the Internet, which finally changed all the not necessarily poor borrowers.
business sectors without exception. These technologies As opposed to this commercial lending model, there
provide software and data directly, instead of needing to are other online lending sites specialized in lending to the
download them; in particular, they facilitate linkage by poor. The first of these, Kiva, also started in 2005. It was
connecting people through social networking. Social net- followed by Microplace and MyC4, who had distinctive
works are a powerful instrument for diffusing technologi- product offerings, and more recently by Rang De, DhanaX,
cal innovation (Davies and Koza, 2001). Businesses could Babyloan, and Wokai, who all follow the Kiva lines but
not ignore the considerable shift of power from suppliers with minor differences, as is explained below and can be
to clients and stakeholders. eBay and Skype were pioneers seen in Appendix 3.
and among the most famous companies to adopt the Web The basic Kiva intermediary model, illustrated in
2.0 technologies; they adapted their business models to Figure 1, is that small lenders lend to Kiva; Kiva lends to
this emerging reality. MFIs; and these MFIs then lend to poor people. Since
One of the most important strategic changes in the poor borrowers do not have computers and are often
microfinance sector took place with the introduction of illiterate, an additional intermediary is added, which is
the Web 2.0 technologies. This gave birth to online P2P usually the MFI. So, instead of poor borrowers posting
social lending. In recent years, since 2005, we have seen up their profiles, the MFIs do the posting for them. Thus,
the development of online lending models. The P2P social a certain category of social lenders, who want to help poor
lending websites are mainly characterized by their status people but not through donations, are attracted to send
(lucrative or not-for-profit) and intermediation mode. funds through these websites. The model also permits

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
4 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

Field Partner
Lenders Kiva Entrepreneur
MFI

The lender chooses who


The MFI distributes funds to
to lend to, but routes the
individual borrowers or to
funds through KIVA
groups of borrowers

Figure 1. KIVA: Movement of funds.

Microplace

Lenders
Security Field Partner Entrepreneur
Issuers MFI

The lender buys bonds of


The security issuers distribute
social funds but indicates
funds to identified MFIs
which MFI these should be
directed to

Figure 2. Microplace: Movement of funds.

MFIs to use Kiva as a financing agency. The Kiva model this in turn pays a substantial part of Kiva’s operating
thus provides a service to small lenders who want to par- expenses.
ticipate directly in the microfinance movement. In the The Microplace model, illustrated in Figure 2, is a bit
Kiva model, there is no interest given by Kiva to the lender different because Microplace is really a for-profit broker
and no interest charged by Kiva to the MFI. However, the of other security issuers of microfinance investment bonds.
MFI charges normal interest rates to the poor borrower These security issuers lend to MFIs, just as Kiva does.
vis-à-vis the MFI rates. By its legal structure, Kiva remains However, they use Microplace as an agent to get investors
a not-for-profit organization. to buy their bonds.
In any case, thanks to endorsements from figures such MyC4, a for-profit firm, has distinguished its product
as Bill Clinton and Oprah Winfrey, Kiva has become very offering from Kiva by indicating that it’s at the upper end
popular and a household name. Kiva and the online of the microfinance market and the lower end of the small
microfinance movement are accredited with democratiz- business financing market, mostly in Africa.
ing access to the microfinance movement for small savers. Babyloan is a Kiva clone, operating in France, and its
The immense brand equity of Kiva creates a virtuous basic language is French, thus offering it a protected niche
circle, attracting corporate sponsors who want to share in from Kiva. However, unlike Kiva, Babyloan is a for-profit
the ‘corporate social responsibility’ image building, and company.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 5

As can be seen from the brief descriptions above, the Rang De: Online micro-lending in India
online micro-lending marketplace is a mix of for-profit To analyze all the above strategic questions (legal status,
and not-for-profit models, depending on the ideology of balancing a double bottom line and transparency), we use
their founders. In addition to online lending, other online a case study approach. As a research method, case studies
microfinance players are entering the market. focus on particular points to help understand complex
Wokai, another not-for-profit, was also directed at a real-life aspects or add new insights to what is already
specific market of US residents aiming funds for microfi- familiar (Patton, 1987). Case studies, based on a qualita-
nance in China. However, it was funded by donors rather tive approach, are used to scrutinize a limited number of
than lenders. The donors got a one-time tax advantage situations or phenomena within their real-life context, to
and although Wokai could recirculate the money to other discover and explore foundations and relationships (Yin,
borrowers once the first borrowers pay back, the donors 1994).
did not get their money back. Thus, case study research generally poses questions
United Prosperity is a not-for-profit which takes funds which begin with ‘how’ or ‘why’ (Anderson, 1993) for
from residents in the developed world and then uses these exploratory, descriptive, and explanatory purposes (Yin,
to provide guarantees to banks for loans that the banks’ 1994). To answer these questions, the selection of exem-
correspondents in India give to poor borrowers. This plary and typical cases is crucial. Case data is generally
permits the Indian banks to multiply the total amount qualitative, but it may also be quantitative.
lent to borrowers. To investigate the case of social innovation as a
Many of these models use blogs and rich site summary response to the challenging questions within a sector, we
(RSS) feeds to personalize and lock in the users. Constant considered the case of Rang De within the P2P social
reports on the progress of the borrowers also add to the online lending model. P2P social lending websites, and in
humanization process. our case Rang De, are social innovations.
Besides the status, the intermediation mode, or more Social innovation is generally defined on supply and/
precisely the mode of supply chain management (SCM), or demand perspective sides (Mulgan et al., 2007; Trifilova
also plays a determining role in the P2P social lending et al., 2012). Innovation can be considered as social when
struggles. It is made up of the funds and information flows its impact is communal or it impacts clients’ work prac-
between suppliers (institutions, investors, individuals) and tices, such as open-source software (Beckett, 2012; Lead-
the P2P social lending website on the one side; and the beater, 2005). It can also be social when the demand for
latter along with its field partners and final micro- it is societal, like microcredit. Some authors associate a
entrepreneurs on the other side. A few sectors might be particular cause with social innovation on the demand side
able to showcase, as P2P social lending does, the solid for solving societal problems: sustainable development of
linkage which exists between the supply side and the local communities (Fink et al., 2010), education and
demand side. health, sustainable finance (Mumford, 2002), reducing
The strategic importance of SCM resides in the fact violence against women (Allen et al., 2013), or assisting
that it almost simultaneously creates information flows of homeless individuals. The capacity of a society to innovate
shifts in supply and demand. When a micro-entrepreneur is dependent on its culture and social structures (Dunphy
requests a loan in one continent and a lender or borrower et al., 1995).
in another considers it, the link becomes a breaking point Rang De showcases a societal supply because lenders
in the business of P2P social lending. Different models of are many, coming from different horizons. The demand
securing these SCM links are formed. is also societal and social. It is societal because many

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
6 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

borrowers — but also field MFIs — are involved in loan The challenge of legal status in the solidarity sector
processes. It is also social because the ultimate objective is To deal with the first strategic challenge, that of the legal
to eradicate poverty. status of an organization in the solidarity sector, the Rang
The case of Rang De is also peculiar and a reliable De founders, Smita and N.K. Ramakrishna, decided to
example of replication in the method of case studies stick with the not-for-profit route, mainly because, as they
because none of the P2P social lending models that we state, the mission of helping the poor and the message it
studied previously operated in India (since the Indian conveyed to society was more important for them.2 In
government did not allow foreigners to lend directly to addition, they believed that if they were to use market-
Indian borrowers, including MFIs). That is why we con- based incentives to finance the poor and include them in
sidered the special case of Rang De, which could adapt to the market, as advocated by C.K. Prahalad’s bottom-of-
the particular environment of India. the-pyramid model (Prahalad, 2006), perhaps they would
Smita Ramakrishna and N.K Ramakrishna (a wife need to wait many years.
and husband team) initiated Rang De in January 2008, For this first challenge, they decided to be a trust. The
in their early thirties, to knock out poverty and add color Rang De website is now an escrow agent. An escrow
to the lives of millions of Indians. The not-for-profit trust account is an account established by a broker for the
Rang De started the business of online micro-lending in purpose of holding funds on behalf of the broker’s prin-
Tamil Nadu (Chennai based), seeking to link small lenders cipal or some other person until the consummation or
with poor borrowers. termination of a transaction.
The founders of Rang De discovered, to their advan- Since Rand De is an escrow agent, legally speaking,
tage, a protected domestic market of over a billion people. it’s the social investor who lends the money to the bor-
At least 30 million of this market had access to the Inter- rower directly and neither Rang De nor the field partner
net and were potential lenders, since Internet access was is liable for non-repayment by the borrower.
strongly correlated with buying power and education.
Alternatively, we could say that seeing the government While Rang De follows the model of an Escrow agent,
blockage on the inflow of funds, Rang De decided to enter at the grassroots level, the money is being lent to
and help the poor. members of joint liability groups and self help groups.
Thus, from an operating model perspective, Rang De In both cases the group leaders sign as a co-applicant
is seen to have copied the basic Kiva lending model in on the application form thus forming a group
India, a country whose foreign exchange laws do not allow guarantee model. However, we do not guarantee the
Kiva to enter the market. However, Rang De has accom- money because there could be cases of natural calamity
plished specific changes to Kiva’s strategic model in order and disasters, in which case there is no recourse.3
to adapt to the requirements of the Indian market, such
The success of microfinance is based on repayment
as the obligation to attract funds only from Indian citi-
rates, which are at about 98% thanks to group lending
zens, living in India or abroad.
and other incentive-based contracts. However, this is not

2
Discussion of the Rang De case study The emails of N.K. Ram capture this in a footnote: ‘Let’s
The Rang De case study, and correspondence with the knock out poverty in India. Become a social investor today!
Log on to RangDe.Org.’
founders, provides pertinent insights on the previously 3
N.K. Ram, co-founder of Rang De, private correspondence
mentioned challenging questions. with us, quoted with permission.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 7

strictly comparable with the lower rates or reimbursement MFIs). But when the crisis hit the sector, there were alle-
of bank loans because banks take collateral, while MFIs gations of MFIs having hidden costs which added up to
usually do not. Therefore, if a bank is not paid back, it 50% and above.
can recover most of the balance outstanding. However, if As an intermediary, like any other P2P social lending
an MFI is not paid back, it loses the unpaid balance unless on the Internet, Rang De might decide between two types
the group pays for the defaulter. of interest rate at the two ends of its supply chain; one for
For the moment, there is no evidence of Rang De investors/lenders, the other for borrowers.
shifting its mission from NGO to for-profit, although In the basic Kiva model, there is no interest given to
they are preparing themselves for a switch from Trust to the lender. Even Babyloan, which is a French for-profit
Section 25 Company form. They feel, from a governance P2P social lending website, does not provide interest
and funding perspective, that this would be the best form income to lenders. However, both host countries of these
for them. two websites are near-zero-inflation countries. In India,
there has been persistent inflation and consequently Rang
The challenge of fixing interest rates for loans De needed to take this specificity into account instead of
addressed to the poor blindly following the Kiva model.
Answering the second strategic challenge, that of the level Therefore, Rang De offers some interest income to
of interest rates to be charged to the poor, requires a pre- its online social investors/lenders who want to get a
liminary comparison with the level of interest rates in the minimum return to keep up with inflation, but would
conventional economy. essentially like to help poor people in a responsible manner
Interest rates on deposits vary with the level of infla- by giving loans rather than donations. Rang De’s website
tion in India. They have been as high as 10–13% in the indicates the following information on its interest rate
1990s for long-term deposits of 5 years, but had come policy:
down to about 6% by 2005–6.4 In 2009, they were at
about 6–7.5% for deposits over 1 year and this moved up The borrower pays an interest rate of 8.5% flat p.a.
to 8–9% in early 2010 in keeping with higher inflation (16% APR). The breakup of the 8.5% flat p.a. (16%
rates of 8–10% in 2009, up from about 6% in the preced- APR) interest is as follows: 5% is for the field partner;
ing year. Even in 2013 rates continue in the same range. 2% (3.5% APR) is the financial return for the social
The bank rate in India is 8.75% as of 2013. Commercial investor; 1% is for Rang De to cover its operational
bank prime lending rates to bigger businesses are at around costs; and 0.5% goes to a contingency fund that is
14.45% as of 2013.5 maintained by Rang De to repay social investors in
Interest rates in microfinance in India have generally case a borrower dies or defaults on a loan.6
varied from 11% to 30%, depending on the social or
profit mission of the MFI (see Appendix 4 for the top 10
The challenge of transparency
The third strategic challenge is about the transparency of
4
RBI statistics till 2006, rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/ costs and fees of microfinance loans. Often, banks and
PDFs/69099.pdf lending organizations like to understate their loan terms
5
RBI, http://www.rbi.org.in/scripts/BS_NSDPDisplay.aspx, by using a flat rate on the initial amount lent and ignoring
consulted on February 7, 2010. See also http://
www.rbi.org.in/scripts/WSSViewDetail.aspx?TYPE=Basic&P
ARAM1=2/5/2010 and click on Cash Reserve Ratio and
6
Interest Rates. RangDe.org/faq.htm#50, consulted on October 28, 2009.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
8 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

repayments. What this means is that repayments do not On the supply side, about 5472 lenders have invested
lead to lower interest payments. Therefore, effectively the through Rang De, with total funds raised amounting to
borrower is paying a higher interest rate and governments about USD 3 million. However, these numbers are not
often impose a transparency regulation or ‘truth in yet very impressive when compared with Kiva’s 297,000
lending,’ which requires lenders to disclose the annual entrepreneurs financed since inception in 2005.
percentage rate or the effective annual rate. To some extent, Rang De has been able to achieve
Some lenders and intermediaries nevertheless manage visibility on its website. One way to look at website visibil-
to use other ways to raise interest rates such as asking for ity is in terms of Alexa ranking. Rang De ranks 12,012 in
a cash deposit of, say, 10% of the loan amount, so that India and 101,136 in the world (as of December 2013).
the loan disbursed is only 90% of the stated amount. Kiva remains the most visible leader in the microfinance
Appendix 4 indicates which of the top ten MFIs indicate sector with a global ranking of 10,820 and a US ranking
flat rates on their websites. They also indicate the equiva- of 4676, way ahead of Grameen and other large brick-
lent by a declining balance method. However, some of and-mortar initiatives.
them include a processing fee or a cash deposit and do
not account for these in the effective annual rate
calculation. Further recommendations
Rang De seems to be particularly vigilant on the It is evident that online lending firms must realize that
transparency question and prefers to indicate the annual their business model is leading to changes in practice of
percentage rate (APR). The APR is a method of finding donors and lenders. They may need to do field research
interest rates by using a simple interest rate. The effective on what an anonymous impersonal online loan means
annual rate (EAR) uses compounding to find the exact compared with giving a check to a human being.
interest rate. The methods should give the same result on Crowdfunding firms, in general, have to understand
a loan of exactly 1 year. Finance students would under- that Web 2.0 is about networking and that they need to
stand that EARs are more exact but rarely used in disclo- tap the networks of their lenders to get even more funding.
sures since not everybody understands them. They can do this by forming groups on sites such as Face-
Rang De is transparent also on its annual report and book and LinkedIn.
financial report being available online. Anyone can check In developing countries, people are used to fending
how it is doing. However, being an escrow agent, Rang for themselves and for their kinsmen, from whom they
De’s financial report does not seem to provide any idea of expect a like return. Crowdfunding firms wishing to create
the movement of funds. Nevertheless, information from a culture of donors and subsidized lenders will require
Rang De’s annual report for 2012–13 fills up this void work on the social structure of the country as a whole.
and indicates that in this period, about 25,000 entrepre- Kotter (1995) draws on the experience of different
neurs were funded USD 3 million of loans (Appendix 5). companies who have failed and then identifies the most
This means that the average loan size is about USD 120, common reasons for failure: (1) a dispossessed sense of
comparable with what we would expect from Indian urgency and too much complacency to drive people from
MFIs. The annual report also indicates that Rang De is their comfort zones; (2) absence of a powerful, guiding,
no longer operating in its home state but has expanded and sustainable coalition amongst all constituents; (3)
to 12 states, including north-east states, with 42 MFIs as lack of clear vision (or presenting a complicated and vague
field partners. 595 loans have been distributed through vision); (4) failing to communicate the vision effectively
the average MFI for about USD 71,000. to all constituents; (5) not removing obstacles from the

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 9

new vision and powerful resisting individuals; (6) defi- might provide different answers to the question of legal
ciency of planning for short-term wins and gains to status in the future.
produce more adherence of people; (7) declaring victory Rang De’s strategy is still limited to taking below-
too soon with the first performance and thus not achiev- market interest-rate loans from lenders and providing
ing the overall goals; (8) neglecting to anchor changes in below-market interest-rate loans to poor borrowers
the corporate culture and create new social norms and through its field partners. This strategy may appeal to a
values consistent with changes. certain section of lenders but that may not be enough.
There are evidently many different ways of making On the strategic question of pricing transparency too,
mistakes in change efforts. Even successful strategic Rang De has chosen to indicate its APR clearly. This may
changes witness confusion and surprises. However, any raise reticence from lenders on the need to provide cheap
organization attempting to change strategically might loans if the ultimate borrower is still paying fairly high
consider Kotter’s model in order to avoid committing rates.
‘common mistakes.’ For Rang De, scaling up needs a huge increase in both
infrastructure and operating costs. It is caught between
Concluding remarks constraints on the borrowing side and on the lending side.
Through this research, we have explored how a social On the borrowing side, they need to be able to quickly
innovation can respond to the strategic changes of a sector find and evaluate borrowers. On the lending side, the
which has evolved from its traditional phase to a high- concept of social lending has not yet caught on in India,
tech, supported one. We have also explored the strategic where people have always hankered for more, owing to a
challenges that organizations in the solidarity sector have legacy of poverty. Therefore, it will take some time for the
to deal with. common Joe to start giving, since he himself has not got
From this perspective, we have studied the field of enough. Further, family and friends come first, another
microcredit which has evolved not only from sporadic cultural legacy of social interdependence in poor coun-
regional practices to a worldwide movement, but also tries. These relationships do not need a website. Then,
from remote villages to the borderless cyberspace of the there is a strong need to leave something for future genera-
Internet. We have focused on the case of the P2P social tions of offspring and their descendants. The culture of
lending website Rang De, which targets India exclusively. not spoiling children by giving them too much has not
Through the research, we have obtained some insights. yet come in. Therefore, social lending is limited to the
Rang De has not been confronted with huge profits very upper middle classes or lower rich classes: usually
and the temptation to switch from a not-for-profit gover- highly educated individuals. This is not the case with Kiva
nance model to a for-profit status. Yet, it is operating in and Babyloan, who appeal to lower middle-class lenders
an environment where such strategic governance ques- in developed countries to lend directly and make a differ-
tions are perpetually being raised; consequently, Rang De ence in people’s lives.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
10 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

Appendix 1: Top 10 Indian MFIs in MIX database

Appendix 3: Early crowd-lending models within the microfinance industry around the time when Rang De was entering the market

http://www.unitedprosperity.org
as of September 30, 2013

http://www.microplace.com

http://www.DhanaX.com
http://www.RangDe.org

http://www.bayloan.org
MFI Average Gross loan Number

http://www.myc4.com

http://www.wokai.org
loan portfolio of active

http://www.kiva.org
balance borrowers
per
borrower

Website
Bandhan 148 711,345,571 4,804,053
Spandana 178 415,200,690 2,327,882
SKDRDP 149 409,725,046 2,741,814
SHARE 138 291,648,606 2,113,869

Intermediary to small business lending


Ujjivan 186 211,186,437 1,136,113
Equitas 128 207,869,793 1,622,794
Janalakshmi 228 191,464,193 841,509
Financial
Services
Pvt. Ltd
AML 171 164,322,314 962,552

Intermediary to MFI

Intermediary to MFI
Intermediary to MFI
Intermediary to MFI
Intermediary to MFI
SCNL 188 117,514,137 623,500

Guarantor to bank
Cashpor MC 143 86,793,416 605,209
Note: As we have used the quarterly data submitted to MIXMarket,

Investment
the figures may differ for the year end.
Model

Appendix 2: Legal status of some of the top


Indian MFIs
Non-profit

Non-profit

Non-profit
Non-profit
For profit
For profit

For profit
For profit
status
Legal

MFI Present status Former status

Bandhan NBFC since 2007 Society before


Spandana NBFC since 2005 Society before
Coverage

SKDRDP Trust since Trust since


Global
Global
Global

Global
China
India
India

India
inception inception
SHARE NBFC since 2000 Society before
Ujjivan NBFC since 2004 NBFC since 2004
Equitas NBFC since 2007 NBFC since 2007
which started

Janalakshmi NBFC for investors NBFC for investors


USA/China
Country in

USA/ India

Financial as a for-profit as a for-profit


Denmark

Services operating operating


France
India
India
USA
USA

Pvt. Ltd company and a company and a


Section 25 Section 25
not-for-profit not-for-profit
holding holding company
May 2007

May 2009
Nov 2005
Oct 2007

Feb 2008
Jan 2008

Jan 2009
Jul 2008

company for for social services


Launch

social services since 2003


date

since 2003
AML NBFC since 2002 NBFC since 2002
SCNL NBFC since 1990 NBFC since 1990
Prosperity

Cashpor Section 25 co. Section 25 co. since


Microplace

Babyloan
Rang De

MC since 1997 1997


DhanaX

United
MyC4

Wokai
Kiva

Source: Their websites.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 11

Appendix 4: Interest rates charged by different large MFIs in India (October 2009, prior to crisis)

Interest rate on Effective annual Source


flat basis rate/declining
balance

SKS 12.5–15% flat 25.6–30.2% http://www.sksindia.com/products.htm


Spandana Not disclosed
SHARE 23.6% http://www.sharemicrofin.com/resouces.html
Bandhan 12.50% flat + 1% 23.56% + + http://www.bandhanmf.com/faqs.html
processing + 10%
deposit
Asmitha 12.50–15.00% 23.60–28.13% http://www.asmithamicrofin.com/inside/product/ptable.html
SKDRDP 11–11.25% http://www.skdrdpindia.org/Systems.htm
BASIX 15%, 18%, 21%, 69.89.31.196/∼basixind/images/BasixAR2009Final.pdf
24% and a 10% p. 66
cash deposit
Grama Not disclosed
Vidiyal
BISWA 20% http://www.biswa.org/en/index.php?option=com_docman&
task=cat_view&gid=45&Itemid=65, Annual report
2008, p. 17
Equitas 27.5–28.5% equitas.in/ProFea_LoanProductsSummary.html
Note: As of 2013 they all are capped at 26% by the Malegam Committee Report appointed by the Reserve Bank of India as there were allega-
tions of hidden costs and high interest rates above 50%.

Appendix 5: Rang De’s partner profile and borrowers (as of November 2013)

Name Status Number Loans Loans Loans Defaults Delayed Repayment


of Disbursed Repaid Outstanding Repayments Rate
Borrowers USD USD USD

Andhra Pradesh
Hope IRDS Inactive 470 39 167 31 132 8 035 79.5%
Roshan Vikas Inactive 108 13 883 13 883 100.0%
Bihar
JJKK Active 913 101 150 66 640 34 510 587 99.1%
CDOT Active 182 18 500 14 957 3 543 100.0%
Gujarat
Prayas Inactive 372 31 000 31 000 100.0%
Jharkhand
Udyogini Active 75 11 383 10 383 1 000 100.0%
Support Inactive 75 6 250 5 417 833 833 86.7%
Gravico Inactive 1 028 89 367 60 879 28 404 83 26 807 69.4%
Karnataka
GMASS Inactive 20 1 667 1 667 100.0%
ICF Inactive 135 33 750 32 125 1 625 1 625 95.2%
Gramothan Inactive 10 833 833 100.0%
Foundation
Safe Hands Active 12 16 967 8 483 8 483 100.0%

Continued

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
12 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

Appendix 5: continued

Name Status Number Loans Loans Loans Defaults Delayed Repayment


of Disbursed Repaid Outstanding Repayments Rate
Borrowers USD USD USD
Magic Wand Active 11 3 667 3 667 468 —
SVYM Active 300 50 000 13 207 36 793 100.0%
Kerala
Hope Active 2 252 279 858 210 454 69 404 47 170 81.7%
Foundation
Madhya Pradesh
Sambhav Inactive 205 18 000 17 403 597 597 96.7%
Prayas Jhabua Inactive 763 94 550 84 277 10 273 100.0%
Shakti Mahil a Active 919 107 817 40 480 67 337 100.0%
Sangh
Maharashtra
CBMD Inactive 500 46 583 46 583 100.0%
Sagras Active 3 125 387 163 274 922 112 241 100.0%
PSW Active 573 65 802 24 921 40 880 100.0%
BNGVN Active 570 97 833 83 884 13 949 100.0%
Sakhi Active 77 21 000 10 458 10 542 100.0%
Samudaya
Kosh
Manipur
Freedom from Inactive 123 10 563 7 570 2 993 2 993 71.7%
Hungers
SEVA Active 844 108 900 53 966 54 934 2 489 95.6%
Orissa
Pragati Active 1 197 107 750 84 240 23 510 23 510 78.2%
Gram Utthan Inactive 1 580 107 158 107 158 100.0%
NSKS Active 1 406 159 443 116 541 42 782 121 99.9%
Ori da Inactive 221 18 283 15 151 3 132 3 132 82.9%
DSS Active 489 49 750 31 658 18 092 100.0%
SARC Active 351 43 017 26 357 16 642 18 99.9%
Tamil Nadu
New Li fe Inactive 57 8 883 8 883 100.0%
Sornammal Inactive 18 1 833 1 833 100.0%
Trust
Bl aze Trust Inactive 100 11 745 11 745 100.0%
Uttar Pradesh
BMSKSS Inactive 77 7 058 7 003 56 99.2%
West Bengal
SSVWSS Active 2 942 379 133 268 488 110 646 218 99.9%
DBIS Inactive 228 21 000 20 919 81 99.6%
VAM Inactive 50 4 167 4 167 100.0%
UTSS Inactive 196 18 533 4 632 13 901 13 901 25.0%
SEDP Inactive 256 26 867 26 432 435 483 98.2%
KSDF Active 424 40 583 15 200 25 383 100.0%
GBK Active 1 748 339 883 185 401 154 482 339 99.8%
Total 42 25 002 3 000 741 2 081 335 911 014 8 393 125 154 94.1%
Average 595 71 446 50 764 31 414 1 399 8 344

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
Strategic Challenges of a Social Innovation 13

Acknowledgments Dowla A. 2012. How to deal with a default tsunami in the


The authors gratefully thank Conseil Regional de Bour- microfinance industry: Lessons from Grameen Bank. Strategic
Change 21(7/8): 343–353.
gogne for co-financing this research.
Dunphy S, Herbig PA, Palumbo FA. 1995. Structure and inno-
References vation. Strategic Change 4(3): 137–154.
Allemand I, Brullebaut B, Raimbault S. 2013. Exploring the Fink M, Lang R, Harms R. 2010. Local responses to global
role of the board of directors in cooperatives: Lessons for technological change — contrasting restructuring practices in
microfinance. Strategic Change 22(1/2): 79–93. two rural communities in Austria. Technological Forecasting
and Social Change 80(2): 569–581.
Allen NE, Larsen S, Trotter J, Sullivan CM. 2013. Exploring
the core service delivery processes of an evidence-based com- Goodman P. 2006. Microfinance investment funds: Objectives,
munity advocacy program fpr women with abusive partners. players, potential. In Matthäus-Maier I, von Pischke JD (eds),
Journal of Community Psychology 41(1): 1–18. Microfinance Investment Funds: Leveraging Private Capital for
Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction. Springer: Berlin; pp.
Anderson G. 1993. Fundamentals of Educational Research.
11–46.
Falmer Press: London.
Hannam M, Cheng P. 2012. Financing sustainable micro-
Ashta A. 2008. Sustainable growth rates: Refining a measure.
lending in London. Strategic Change 21(7/8): 369–378.
Strategic Change 17(5/6): 207–214.
Higgins RC. 1977. How much growth can a firm afford? Finan-
Ashta A, Assadi D. 2011. The use of Web 2.0 technologies in
cial Management 6(3): 7–16.
online lending and impact on different components of interest
rates. In Advanced Technologies for Microfinance: Solutions and Johnson S, Ashta A, Assadi D. 2010. Online or offline? The rise
Challenges, Ashta A (ed). IGI Global: Hershey, PA. of “peer-to-peer” lending in microfinance. Journal of Electronic
Commerce in Organizations 8(3): 26–37.
Ashta A, Hudon M. 2012. The Compartamos microfinance
IPO: Mission conflicts in hybrid institutions with diverse Kotter JP. 1995. Leading change: Why transformation efforts
shareholding. Strategic Change 21(7/8): 331–341. fail! Harvard Business Review Mar/Apr: 59–67.
Ashta A, Khan S, Otto PE. 2011. Does microfinance cause or Leadbeater C. 2005. The era of open innovation. TEDGlobal,
reduce suicides? Policy recommendations for reducing bor- www.ted.com/talks/charles_leadbeater_on_innovation
rower stress. Available at: ssrn.com/abstract=1715442.
Mader P. 2013. Rise and fall of microfinance in India: The
Beckett A. 2012. Disrupting practices: New insights into inno- Andhra Pradesh crisis in perspective. Strategic Change 22(1/2):
vation. Strategic Change 21(5/6): 217–229. 47–66.
CGAP. 2008. Microfinance Investment Vehicles Survey. Con- Mersland R, Urgeghe L. 2013. International debt financing and
sultancy Group to Assist the Poor: Washington, D.C. performance of microfinance institutions. Strategic Change
22(1/2): 17–29.
Constantinou D, Ashta A. 2011. Financial crisis: Lessons from
microfinance. Strategic Change 20(5/6): 187–203. Milana C, Ashta A. 2012. Developing microfinance: A survey
of the literature. Strategic Change 21(7/8): 299–330.
Daher L, Le Saout E. 2013. Microfinance and financial perfor-
mance. Strategic Change 22(1/2): 31–45. Mulgan G, Tucker S, Ali R, Sander B. 2007. Social innovation:
What it is, why it matters and how it can be accelerated. Skoll
Davies PN, Koza MP. 2001. Eating soup with a fork: How
Centre for Social Entrepreneurship: Oxford.
informal social networks influence innovation in high-
technology firms. Strategic Change 10(2): 95–102. Mumford MD. 2002. Social innovation: Ten cases from Ben-
jamin Franklin. Creativity Research Journal 14(2): 253–266.
Descubes I, Timsit J-P, Truong Y. 2013. Social innovation in
emerging economies: A resource-based view perspective. Stra- Patton M. 1987. How to Use Qualitative Methods in Evaluation.
tegic Change 22(7/8): 503–510. Sage Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
14 Arvind Ashta, Djamchid Assadi, and Nadiya Marakkath

Périlleux A. 2013. Strategic governance lessons from history for nance Interest Rates and Profits. World Bank: Washington,
West African microfinance cooperatives. Strategic Change D.C.
22(1/2): 95–106.
Trifilova A, Oleynik-Garbuz J, Bessant J. 2012. Develop-
Prahalad CK. 2006. The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid: ing capabilities through social innovation: A case study of
Eradicating Poverty Through Profits. Wharton School Publish- student-led initiatives in Russia. Paper presented at EURAM
ing: Upper Saddle River, NJ. 2012.
Rosenberg R. 2007. CGAP Reflections on the Comparta- Yin R. 1994. Case Study Research: Design and methods. Sage
mos Initial Public Offering: A Case Study on Microfi- Publishing: Beverly Hills, CA.

BIOGRAPHICAL NOTES

Arvind Ashta holds the Banque Populaire Chair in Djamchid Assadi is a professor and a member of the
Microfinance at the Burgundy School of Business, research team of the Banque Populaire Chair in
Dijon, France. He offers courses in microfinance Microfinance at the Burgundy School of Business,
and researches institutional aspects of microfinance, Dijon, France. He is a specialist in (online) strategy
technology in microfinance, and CSR. He has and marketing. His research focuses on the impact
taught microfinance as visiting faculty in Brussels, of non-economic factors on buying behavior and
Barcelona, Chicago, Hertfordshire, and Pforzheim. strategic behavior, and ‘peer-to-peer’ relations
He guest edits special editions of various journals including ‘social lending.’ He teaches the course
devoted to microfinance. He is on the editorial Microfinance Strategy and Marketing. He has
review board of Cost Management and Strategic taught at several universities in France and the USA.
Change. He is a member of a micro-investors’ club He has written many books, several book chapters,
(CIGALES), research associations (CEREN, and articles and papers presented at numerous
CERMi), and professional associations (European conferences.
Microfinance Platform).

Correspondence to: Nadiya Marakkath is an assistant professor at the


Arvind Ashta Centre for Social Entrepreneurship, School of
Banque Populaire Chair in Microfinance at the Management and Labor Studies, Tata Institute of
Burgundy School of Business
Social Sciences (TISS), Mumbai, India. Apart from
ESC Dijon-Bourgogne
29 rue Sambin, 21000 Dijon, France
her teaching at the school, she is the coordinator of
e-mail: arvind.ashta@escdijon.eu the Incubation Center and Funding Support
Services offered to the nascent social entrepreneurs
at the Center for Social Entrepreneurship of TISS.
Her current research efforts span microfinance
sustainability management, inclusive financial
systems, legitimacy and sustainability challenges in
social entrepreneurship, and funding models for
social ventures.

Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc

You might also like