You are on page 1of 19

Debates paper

Urban Studies
2019, Vol. 56(2) 452–470
Ó Urban Studies Journal Limited 2018
Why bright city lights dazzle and
illuminate: A cognitive science Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0042098018804762
approach to urban promises journals.sagepub.com/home/usj

Rodrigo Cardoso
Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Architecture and the Built Environment, The Netherlands

Evert Meijers
Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Architecture and the Built Environment, The Netherlands

Maarten van Ham


Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Architecture and the Built Environment, The Netherlands;
University of St. Andrews, School of Geography and Sustainable Development, UK

Martijn Burger
Erasmus University Rotterdam, The Netherlands

Duco de Vos
Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Architecture and the Built Environment, The Netherlands

Abstract
Despite the many uncertainties of life in cities, promises of economic prosperity, social mobility
and happiness have fuelled the imagination of generations of urban migrants in search of a better
life. Access to jobs, housing and amenities, and fewer restrictions of personal choices are some of
the perceived advantages of cities, characterised here as ‘urban promises’. But while discourses
celebrating the triumph of cities became increasingly common, urban rewards are not available
everywhere and for everyone. Alongside opportunity, cities offer inequality, conflict and poor liv-
ing conditions. Their narrative of promise has been persistent across different times and places,
but the outcomes and experiences of urban life compare poorly with the overoptimistic expecta-
tions of many newcomers. And yet, millions still come and stay regardless of odds, raising the
question why we have such positive and persistent expectations about cities. To examine this
question, this paper considers the process of urban migration from the perspective of decision-
making under uncertainty. It discusses how decisions and evaluations are based on imperfect
information and offers a novel contribution by examining how the cognitive biases and heuristics
which restrict human rationality shape our responses to urban promises. This approach may
allow a better understanding of how people make decisions regarding urban migration, how they
perceive their urban experiences and evaluate their life stories. We consider the prospects and
limitations of the behavioural approach and discuss how biases favouring narratives of bright
Cardoso et al. 453

urban futures can be exploited by ‘triumphalist’ accounts of cities which neglect their embedded
injustices.

Keywords
cognitive biases and heuristics, decision-making, social mobility, subjective wellbeing, urban migra-
tion, urban triumphalism

᪈㾱
ቭ㇑෾ᐲ⭏⍫ᆈ൘䈨ཊн⺞ᇊഐ㍐ˈն㓿⍾㑱㦓ǃ⽮Պ⍱ࣘᙗ઼ᒨ⾿Ⲵ᢯䈪◰ਁҶаԓ৸
аԓ෾ᐲ〫≁ራ≲ᴤྭ⭏⍫Ⲵᜣ䊑࣋DŽ㧧ᗇᐕ֌ǃտᡯ઼‫࡙ׯ‬䇮ᯭˈԕ৺߿ቁњӪ䘹ᤙᯩ
䶒Ⲵ䲀ࡦᱟ෾ᐲⲴаӋਟ㿱Ո࣯ˈ䘉䟼〠ѻѪ“෾ᐲ᢯䈪”DŽնᱟˈ㲭❦ᒶ⾍෾ᐲ㜌࡙Ⲵ䈍
䈝䎺ᶕ䎺Პ䙽ˈն෾ᐲⲴ⾿࡙ᒦнᱟ䲿༴ਟ㿱ˈҏнᱟ⇿њӪ䜭ਟԕ㧧ᗇDŽ䲔ҶᵪՊˈ෾
ᐲ䘈ᨀ‫׋‬нᒣㅹǃߢケ઼ᚦ࣓Ⲵ⭏⍫ᶑԦDŽԆԜ〫≁ሩ᢯䈪Ⲵਉ䘠൘н਼Ⲵᰦ䰤઼ൠ⛩ᤱ
㔝ᆈ൘ˈն෾ᐲ⭏⍫Ⲵ㔃઼᷌㓿傼о䇨ཊ෾ᐲᯠ〫≁䗷ҾҀ㿲Ⲵᵏᵋ⴨৫⭊䘌DŽ❦㘼ˈቭ
㇑ᴹ䘉а࠷ˈᮠԕⲮз䇑ⲴӪԜӽ❦ᶕࡠ෾ᐲᒦ⮉ҶлᶕDŽ䘉ᨀࠪҶањ䰞仈˖ѪӰѸᡁ
Ԝሩ෾ᐲᣡᴹྲ↔〟ᶱ઼ᤱѵⲴᵏᵋDŽѪҶ⹄ウ䘉њ䰞仈ˈᵜ᮷Ӿн⺞ᇊᙗлߣㆆⲴ䀂ᓖ
ᙍ㘳෾ᐲ䗱〫Ⲵ䗷〻DŽᵜ᮷䇘䇪Ҷߣㆆ઼䇴ՠྲօสҾнᆼழⲴؑ᚟ˈ਼ᰦˈ䙊䗷⹄ウ䲀
ࡦӪ㊫⨶ᙗⲴ䇔⸕‫ٿ‬㿱઼੟ਁᔿᙍ㔤ྲօກ䙐ҶᡁԜሩ෾ᐲ᢯䈪Ⲵ৽ᓄˈᵜ᮷֌ࠪҶᯠⲴ
⨶䇪䍑⥞DŽ䘉⿽ᯩ⌅ਟԕᴤྭൠ⨶䀓ӪԜྲօ‫ࠪڊ‬ᴹ‫ޣ‬෾ᐲ〫≁ⲴߣㆆˈԆԜྲօⴻᖵ෾
ᐲփ傼ᒦ䇴ՠԆԜⲴ⭏⍫᭵һDŽᡁԜᙍ㘳㹼Ѫᯩ⌅ⲴࡽᲟ઼ተ䲀ˈᒦ䇘䇪‫ੁٿ‬Ҿ෾ᐲ‫ݹ‬᰾
ᵚᶕ䇪䘠Ⲵ‫ٿ‬㿱ྲօ㻛෾ᐲ“㜌࡙ѫѹ”Ⲵ䇪䘠ᡰ࡙⭘DŽ䘉⿽“㜌࡙ѫѹ”Ⲵ䇪䘠ᘭ㿶Ҷ෾ᐲ
޵൘Ⲵн‫↓ޜ‬DŽ

‫ޣ‬䭞䇽
䇔⸕‫ٿ‬㿱઼੟ਁᔿᙍ㔤ǃߣㆆǃ⽮Պ⍱ࣘᙗǃѫ㿲ᒨ⾿ᝏǃ෾ᐲ䗱〫ǃ෾ᐲ㜌࡙ѫѹ

Received April 2018; accepted September 2018

‘. And by the way, the man who told Introduction


That London’s streets were paved with gold
Was telling dreadful porky-pies’. For centuries, people have been flocking to
(That’s cockney rhyming slang for lies.) cities in search of a better life. Despite their
The cat went on, ‘To me it seems changing fortunes over time, big cities have
These streets are paved with rotten dreams. always been perceived as the places to go
Come home, my boy, without more fuss.
to for jobs, amenities, socio-economic
This lousy town’s no place for us.’
(Roald Dahl, ‘Dick Whittington and His
mobility, freedom and happiness. Whatever
Cat’, 1989) their background, people could reinvent

Corresponding author:
Rodrigo Cardoso, Technische Universiteit Delft Faculteit Bouwkunde, OTB Research for the Built Environment, Julianalaan
134, Delft 2628 BL, The Netherlands.
Email: r.o.v.cardoso@tudelft.nl
454 Urban Studies 56(2)

themselves anew by moving to the city and migrants (Knight and Gunatilaka, 2010;
abandoning the social constraints of their Williams and Donald, 2011). Cities have
original milieu (Yamagishi et al., 2012). indeed shown a remarkable attractive force
There they would also enjoy the economic throughout history, which raises the ques-
externalities triggered by the urban environ- tion why so many people have such positive,
ment and step on the escalator of accelerated persistent and possibly overrated expecta-
upward mobility (Fielding, 1992; Glaeser, tions about them.
2011). Together, these perceived advantages
of cities build a set of expectations which we
characterise as ‘urban promises’. A cognitive science perspective
However, bright city lights can dazzle as A substantial amount of research has exam-
well as illuminate. There is ample evidence ined the cognitive mechanisms shaping the
showing that the urban escalator is not avail- spatial preferences of individuals and influ-
able everywhere and for everyone. While the encing their consequent location decisions,
potential aggregate economic benefits of perceptions and judgement of experiences
urban agglomeration are evident across dif- (Gould and White, 1986; Harvey, 1970;
ferent periods and places, the outcomes for Meester and Pellenbarg, 2006; Oishi, 2010;
individuals are extremely diversified. Some Pred, 1967). This literature has confronted
receive disproportionally high rewards from assumptions of urban migration as a rational
urban life, but cities turn out to be disap- choice, based on an objective assessment of
pointing for many hopeful migrants, causes costs and benefits and an informed anticipa-
ranging from illness, social collapse and pov- tion of the future. On the contrary, the con-
erty in the industrial cities of the past, to struction of our spatial preferences –
congestion, un(der)employment, pollution, including those attracting us to cities and
loneliness, socio-ethnic conflict and inequal- nudging us to stay in cities – can be inter-
ity in today’s advanced capitalist cities preted as the product of decision-making
(Davis, 2006; Florida, 2017; UN-Habitat, under uncertainty, based on imperfect infor-
2016). mation, shaped by individual perceptions,
Such evidence has substantiated the values and desires, and relying on many con-
notion that cities are places of inequality tingent, non-economic factors. Research
and that their aggregate positive impacts on integrating these ideas develops concepts
human life have their fair share of winners such as bounded rationality or satisficing
and losers. And yet, even if reality does not behaviours, as derived from Herbert Simon’s
hold up to expectations, the overwhelming work (1955, 1957, 1959).
belief by newcomers that cities will bring The behavioural approach has influenced
them a better future persists. Millions still many disciplines, most prominently econom-
come to cities facing unknown odds and stay ics. However, its application to urban migra-
despite negative experiences, from migration tion studies is challenging. Behavioural
streams from developing countries looking analyses of spatial dynamics are too indivi-
for economic opportunity to young, edu- dualised to make useful predictions and dis-
cated migrants hoping for career advance- regard wider social forces which constrain
ment and self-realisation (King et al., 2018). individuals regardless of their cognitive pro-
However, both the objective socioeconomic cesses (Hayter and Watts, 1983; Meester and
outcomes and the subjective experiences of Pellenbarg, 2006; Sayer, 1982). As a result,
urban life tend to compare poorly with the ‘behavioural urban geography’ is no longer
overoptimistic expectations of many urban prominent among scholars and explanations
Cardoso et al. 455

for urban attractiveness have shifted to types of decision-making. Examples of such


rational choice models based on the eco- biases are our lack of statistical intuition to
nomic opportunity paradigm, leaving the evaluate risk, generalisation of exceptional
alternative perspective ‘dead and forgotten’ cases, overconfidence about ourselves and
(Meester and Pellenbarg, 2006: 365). This our ability to control our environment, illu-
has reduced our ability to support research sory cause–effect attributions and rationali-
with realistic models of human behaviour, sations of failures. Psychological literature
departing from normative economic assump- shows that these restrict our capacity to
tions (Harvey, 1970) and building on the make judgements about the future, the self
success of the behavioural approach in other and the world, as well as to fairly evaluate
fields. ongoing and past trajectories (Kahneman,
Reinstating that perspective is timely and 2003, 2011; Kahneman and Tversky, 1979;
relevant for two reasons. First, because the Tversky and Kahneman, 1971).
shift to rationality in research comes hand in Bringing ideas from cognitive science
hand with recent scholarly and popular texts into urban studies is not new, and such
celebrating the potential of ‘humanity’s studies are common in environmental psy-
greatest invention’ and the ‘triumph’ of the chology and urban design journals.
city, a trend aptly named ‘urban triumphal- However, since the heyday of behavioural
ism’, among a variety of similar designa- decision-making models in the 1970s and
tions. This work stresses the apparent ability early 1980s, these ideas have mostly been
of urban environments to offer a ‘richer, used to understand perception rather than
smarter, greener, healthier and happier’ life cognition – for instance, perceptions of dif-
(Glaeser, 2011), providing opportunity for ferent areas of the city, responses to the
all. But the narrative of urban triumphalism built environment, cultural familiarity
is contested because of its focus on economic enabling socio-ethnic clusters in cities, etc.
factors to measure quality of life and explain Departing from that tradition, this paper
choices, modelling of individuals as empow- offers new insights by directly interrogating
ered rational agents pursuing opportunities, the field of cognitive biases and heuristics
and consequent use by policymakers to jus- and its potential to explain the mechanisms
tify the reduction of public intervention in of anticipation, decision-making and jud-
cities and the neglect of urban injustices gement involving urban migration and the
(Amin, 2013; Gleeson, 2012; Nicholls, 2011; urban experience.
Okulicz-Kozaryn, 2015; Peck, 2016).
Second, because cognitive scientists have Research potential
been working on models of decision-making The behavioural perspective claims that
based on a number of cognitive biases and depending on the tractability of the problem
heuristics, which explain the way individuals and the imponderability of the future,
anticipate the future, make decisions, per- humans are neither capable of optimal
ceive their experiences and judge their out- decision-making nor of unbiased assess-
comes. The novel contribution of this paper ments of the future, their environment and
is exploring this framework to understand themselves. Precisely because it is so com-
the expectations, decisions, perceptions and plex and unpredictable, urban life illustrates
judgements of the urban experience, under that kind of problem. Exploring how the
the hypothesis that the mechanisms shaping enduring attractiveness of cities as well as
these processes are strongly influenced by the penetration of positive messages about
the same cognitive biases that affect other cities are supported by cognitive biases
456 Urban Studies 56(2)

provides another way to interpret the human individuals. Then we examine the cognitive
response to cities, including their ability to biases embedded in decision-making under
retain even those people whose hopes and uncertainty and connect them to the ratio-
dreams have not been fulfilled. This helps nale under which cities are conceived as sites
shed light on several relevant issues for pol- of promise and prosperity. The arguments
icy and research: apply to contexts where people have reason-
able options available, rather than to
 The reasons for the consistent attractive- extreme situations across the globe where
ness of large cities throughout history, cities are an escape from hunger, war or per-
despite their varying socioeconomic secution, where other decision-making
prospects and living conditions. mechanisms related to survival certainly pre-
 How a risky and uncertain enterprise vail. We conclude by discussing how the
such as moving to the city makes people incorporation of this perspective can be pro-
overcome their preferred state of staying ductive for research and assess the implica-
in a familiar place (Morrison and Clark, tions of either exploiting our cognitive biases
2016), even if basing their decisions on to fuel narratives about urban triumphs or
contingent information. acknowledging them to enable more critical
 Whether people continually realign the participants in urban life.
reference point used to evaluate their life
trajectory and therefore risk accommo-
dating to disappointing living conditions Examining urban promises
mitigated by permanently deferred
Cities are places of inequality. Even a self-
expectations.
 proclaimed ‘urban optimist’ such as Richard
Whether, in response, urban policies act
Florida (2017) now concedes that the pro-
on hopes and dreams rather than actual
mises of cities have failed too many people
contexts and opportunities, considering
and that their ‘winner-take-all’ measure of
that people are more willing to accept
success plants the seeds of more inequality
inequalities if they believe in their own
and segregation. Moreover, ‘the larger, den-
chances of success (Davidai and
ser and more knowledge-intensive and tech-
Gilovich, 2015).
 based a city or metro is, the more unequal it
How one-sided, overoptimistic messages
tends to be’ (Florida, 2017: 82). In developed
in ‘urban triumphalist’ discourses can
countries, this is partly explained by the
exploit our cognitive predispositions, to
combination of the availability of high-end
better spread their powerful narratives
jobs for the most skilled workers and the
and obscure how fairly cities are deliver-
high levels of competition between them,
ing to citizens.
increasing the risk of failure (Behrens and
Robert-Nicoud, 2014). In much of the devel-
While this perspective is valid for any
oping world, this is aggravated by poor
kind of migration, we focus on migration to
urban governance, derelict infrastructure
large cities, first, because of its global magni-
and lack of legal and social protection for
tude and potential social and environmental
citizens, especially migrants (IOM, 2015).
implications. Second, owing to the salience
Overall, cities provide high rewards for the
of the ‘urban triumph’ story in recent years
most able workers and privileged groups,
and its association with the largest cities.
but may be a source of disappointment for
We proceed by reviewing evidence about
the less talented or less privileged.
the impacts of urban life on groups and
Cardoso et al. 457

While cities have historically been mag- force (Ross, 2013). The emerging picture is
nets for people, a scalar shift happened after one of contrast between the economic oppor-
the industrial age. In previous economic tunity offered by cities to some and the nega-
regimes, most people were bounded to spe- tive social and health impacts that made the
cific places (by feudalist relations, agricul- urban experience troublesome for many.
ture, or lack of connective infrastructure).
Industrialisation marked the end of place-
boundedness, and its uneven geographic dis- Escalators up . and down (and with
tribution caused massive migration. Rural– limited capacity)
urban migration in Britain following early The upward mobility effect of moving to cit-
industrialisation has been studied in detail ies is known as the ‘escalator effect’, and
by Long (2005). He found that the move to ‘escalator regions’ (Fielding, 1992) are those
urban areas was generally not triggered by that propel the careers of migrants upward,
famine or poverty, but by an expectation of with the associated benefit of higher wages
opportunities for socioeconomic improve- leading to a higher socioeconomic status.
ment, thereby escaping an inherited inter- There is a beneficial impact on wages of
generational trajectory with little promise in moving into cities, although partially offset
the countryside. This migration was selec- by higher living costs (Glaeser and Maré,
tive, in the sense that urban migrants were 2001). This premium also relates to the fact
the most skilled and entrepreneurial of the that people with higher skills tend to sort
rural labour pool. As a result, those who into big cities, a cohort that would have
migrated to cities fared better: ‘On average, experienced a rapid increase in income or
people from all socio-economic strata who occupational attainment in the first years
moved to the city were substantially more anyway (van Ham, 2001; van Ham et al.,
successful in improving their socio-economic 2012).
status than they would have been had they Talented migrants may indeed advance
remained in rural areas’ (Long, 2005: 29). faster in an urban environment that lets
And yet, Long’s statistics are limited to them develop their human and social capital,
those who managed to survive the 30-year by having access to learning opportunities,
period between the 1851 and 1881 censuses, acquiring tacit knowledge and frequently
which he used for comparison. In reality, changing jobs, enabling even more and more
urban mortality rates were up to 50% higher diversified tacit knowledge. Nevertheless,
than in rural areas, and urban life expec- Gordon (2015) emphasises that this is not an
tancy was about 10 years lower, and even ‘effortless ride up’: ambition and learning
worse in the largest cities, which kept grow- skills are key intermediating variables deter-
ing only because of massive inward migra- mining whether one exploits the potential
tion (Haines, 2001). This state of affairs gains of an escalator region. Moreover, the
persisted until the 1930s. The costs of living link between long-term economic status and
in cities were high, as famously illustrated by urbanisation has been contested in some
Friedrich Engels, describing Manchester’s cases: in a spatial analysis of the odds of
squalor as ‘hell upon earth’. But while social intergenerational economic mobility in the
scientists and activists worked to mitigate USA, Chetty et al. write that ‘urban areas
the problems of urban living, stressing the tend to exhibit lower levels of intergenera-
economic opportunity argument was in the tional mobility than rural areas’ (Chetty
interest of an urban elite who fuelled the nar- et al., 2014: 1593). Finally, a large part of
rative of promise to attract more labour urban migration comes from abroad, in
458 Urban Studies 56(2)

which case other hurdles exist, even for the All these risks are poorly anticipated
young and educated: language and barriers when making a residential location decision,
to employment lead to initial jobs below and may offset the benefits of moving to
their skill level and allow a relatively slow and living in cities. Interestingly, the data set
progression (Parutis, 2011). It follows that by Chetty et al. (2014) mentioned earlier also
the urban escalator has limited capacity and shows no positive correlation between
is often inaccessible. Furthermore, it cannot greater odds of intergenerational mobility
be found everywhere: only a select class of and recent population changes (based on US
metropolitan area functions as an escalator Census 2000–2010 data), meaning that peo-
region (Champion et al., 2014). ple are not necessarily migrating ‘rationally’
The quality of life in cities has improved to the places where economic opportunities
considerably over the past decades, certainly (at least for their children) are better.
in developed countries. But other problems Motives for migration vary, and economic
persist: residents of large cities compared factors are filtered by individual perceptions
with small towns and rural areas experience and intertwined with non-economic issues,
more traffic congestion (Broersma and Van such as family, amenities, lifestyle and hous-
Dijk, 2008) and pollution (Burgalassi and ing needs (Clark and Maas, 2015). It follows
Luzzati, 2015), are more exposed to infec- that transitory interests, errors of judgement
tious diseases (Alirol et al., 2011), suffer and irrational decisions play a role in spatial
greater social isolation (Scharf and DeJong location outcomes, and this is where cogni-
Gierveld, 2008), and, especially in Western tive biases may give the urban narrative its
Europe and North America, report lower competitive advantage. Indeed, any histori-
levels of subjective wellbeing, despite greater cal overview of the rapid growth of the larg-
material wealth (Berry and Okulicz- est cities suggests that they were experienced
Kozaryn, 2011; Lenzi and Perucca, 2018). as dirty, crowded and poor, but also
Foreign-born urban migrants may addi- expected to be rich in opportunity (Williams
tionally experience exclusion and social vul- and Donald, 2011). In this gap between the
nerability. The World Migration Report expected and the experienced lies the
states that ‘migrants, and in particular recent strength of urban promises, but also their
migrants, [.] tend to be disproportionately pitfalls, as the downsides of urban life are
represented among the poor and vulnerable neglected. This paper offers a new interpre-
of urban populations in both developed and tation of this asymmetry by examining what
developing countries’ (IOM, 2015: 79). This psychological mechanisms individuals
is not limited to fast-growing cities in low- deploy to anticipate the future, choose
or middle-income countries: Eurostat statis- between scenarios, perceive ongoing experi-
tics (2017) show that foreign urban migrants ences and report on past trajectories.
in the EU are more likely than natives to live
in overcrowded lodgings and be overbur- Understanding the psychology
dened by housing costs. OECD (2016) data
for Sweden show that employment rates of
of urban promises
foreign-born migrants are lower than those As Okulicz-Kozaryn and Valente (2018)
of natives at all skill levels, partly because write, ‘[A]lthough in many ways the city pro-
the largest cities with more work opportuni- vides many freedoms to urbanites, it also
ties also face housing shortages and afford- entraps them in city dreams and illusions’
ability crises, which affect migrants to a (2018: 1). The powerful attractive force of
greater degree. cities and their associated rhetoric is based
Cardoso et al. 459

not only on what cities can actually offer but environment, and (2) rationalisations of fail-
also on what people believe they can offer. ure. We will refer to the biases emerging
As many psychological studies have shown, from these categories, illustrate them from
most decisions in life are actually made the perspective of urban experiences, and
according to the latter (Kahneman, 2011). In then go over the ways in which they can be
complex environments, the fact that out- advertently or inadvertently induced.
comes do not mirror initial expectations is Figure 1 presents a scheme of the relevant
unremarkable, and in many situations of cognitive mechanisms. It differentiates
daily life such discrepancies go unnoticed. between, first, the basic cognitive biases we
What turns the case of urban promises into experience, and then the heuristics, or men-
more than a trivial matter is that it seems to tal shortcuts, that primarily enable them.
be an especially strong manifestation of this We include some arrows in the scheme to
phenomenon, in its persistence over time, highlight this interaction.
geographical scope and impact on human
life. Indeed, Mulchany and Kollamparambil Unrealistic perceptions of risk, environment and
(2016) write that the significant decrease of the self. Unrealistic expectations and poor
subjective wellbeing among many rural– perception of risk often conflate to influ-
urban migrants may be a result of overopti- ence decisions in a variety of areas. For
mistic expectations which failed to realise. instance, Simon et al. (2000) have demon-
Morrison and Clark (2016) use psychologi- strated that what drives so many individu-
cal theories on loss aversion and risk assess- als to start business ventures with little
ment to argue that the preferred state in chances of success (the so-called ‘entrepre-
humans is staying in familiar settings, not neurs’) is not their propensity to accept
moving. The incentive to alter that state high risks but their lack of perception of
must be more than trivial and involve the risk. At the initial stages, they base their
expectation of substantial relative advan- decisions on the ‘law of small numbers’
tages, otherwise migration would be less (Kahneman, 2003; Taylor and Brown,
common. 1988; Tversky and Kahneman, 1971), a
tendency to fallaciously generalise from
Cognitive biases and the attractiveness of sparse data and to be insensitive to sample
size – we tend to find patterns and stories,
the uncertain especially those that confirm our values
To understand the mental processes through and desires, in very small samples, neglect-
which urban promises are perceived and ing randomness and representativeness.
acted upon by individuals, we build on the- If migration to cities is similarly seen as a
ories about decision-making under uncer- life-changing venture of uncertain outcome,
tainty, pioneered by Herbert Simon, Amos the adherence to that endeavour is also
Tversky, Daniel Kahneman, and others. likely to be explained by a law of small num-
These authors expand the notion of bounded bers. Despite positive aggregate effects, the
rationality to investigate how individuals fact that urban migration is risky for indi-
interact with the social world around them. viduals has been extensively documented.
The nature of their assessments and deci- However, anecdotal evidence about a distant
sions is shaped by several consistent biases, acquaintance who achieved success after
which, for the purposes of our argument, we moving to the city may be enough to send
organise in two categories: (1) unrealistic others down the same path, in an expanded
perceptions of risk, the self and the version of chain migration not restricted to
460 Urban Studies 56(2)

Figure 1. Unrealistic perceptions of risk, environment and the self.

family and close friends. Taleb (2005) points et al. (2000) also argue that individuals ven-
out our ‘survivorship bias’, the tendency to turing into business assume they have much
select the stories of winners to inspire our greater control over their environment than
actions but disregard the vast number of they actually do, neglecting the role of
losers. Narratives about urban opportunity chance and the impact of unexpected events
cherry-pick examples of success with ‘no (Taleb, 2007; Taylor and Brown, 1988). The
particular care for audit by numbers, or illusion of control adds causality to random
more accurately, behind the statistics of events and retrospectively explains outcomes
absolute and relative poverty, it finds by reconstructing the actions which appar-
context-specific place biographies and com- ently led to them, overestimating the instru-
plex ethnographies of being and becoming’ mental role of agents (Miller and Ross,
(Amin, 2013: 480). Cities with a substantial 1975) or fetishising a specific event which
density of such stories associated with them people believe to have controlled for their
can benefit from an ‘attractiveness bonus’, benefit. According to McGee (2005), this is
even if they are the most saturated and com- the strategy of self-help books: readers who
petitive places where the chances for individ- achieved a desired outcome reconstruct the
ual success may actually be lower. choices they made in such a way that they
The poor measurement of risk coming can attribute their success to their actions in
from weak statistical intuition coexists with response to the book, thus justifying their
a tendency for overconfidence, which relies investment.
on two further biases: the illusion of control Similarly, in an environment saturated
and overly positive self-assessments. Simon with positive messages about urban
Cardoso et al. 461

opportunity and individual empowerment this smoke detector principle applies there:
(which often remind us of the rhetoric of is the cost of failure low in comparison with
self-help books) it is easy to reconstruct past the potential opportunity? How much does
or ongoing life stories to reflect the illusion the sheer increase of competitive actors and
of control over external events, and recog- the unevenness of the playing field affect the
nise causalities that confirm the ‘natural level of opportunity? How much is the emo-
powers’ of cities to improve our lives – tional and social cost of migration compen-
another form of (spatial) fetishism. Forces sated for by economic benefits?
emanating from the spatial opportunity The interesting point is that, later, the jud-
structure of cities (Galster and Killen, 1995) gement of outcomes may indeed confirm the
are thus overweighed, assuming our ability initial expectations: Engelhardt and Wagener
to control them in our favour, while the (2014) have studied the gaps between actual
uneven distribution of personal skills and and perceived upward economic mobility in
social safety nets, or simple luck, are 26 OECD countries, in terms of job status
neglected. These deterministic assumptions and material wellbeing, to find that the per-
often appear in the urban triumphalism nar- ceived mobility of individuals is higher than
rative (Gleeson, 2012), suggesting that reality in every case. Surveys by Hagerty
enabling the illusion of control may partly (2003) stress this positive bias: most people
support its attractiveness and penetration. believe their lives have improved over time,
The overly optimistic self-assessment bias but think that the life of the average person
plays a role in this imbalance. Surveys show has not. Overoptimistic self-assessments may
that most people believe they have better embolden us and lead to positive outcomes
qualities and future prospects than most but they also introduce great unreliability in
other people, a tendency known as the self-reported life situations. As to the poten-
‘better-than-average’ effect (Alicke and tial benefits of urban migration, this means
Govorun, 2005). Despite the logical incon- that the urban escalator may be only avail-
sistency of these assessments, they are seen able for some, but everyone tends to believe
as adaptive strategies that improve mental it will include or has included them. And yet,
health, strengthening motivation and pro- despite the popularisation of optimistic
tecting us from pessimism (Taylor and views, this discussion is far from settled. In
Brown, 1988). For psychologists, the overes- many cases, urban migration replaces one set
timation of the likelihood of success in spite of risks with another. People are right about
of contrary signals follows the ‘smoke detec- the unmatched opportunity of cities, but
tor’ principle, which posits that the cost of poor perception of risk, overconfidence and
responding to a false alarm is low compared the illusion of control might make them dis-
with not acting on a real threat. Haselton regard the unrelenting competition and injus-
and Nettle (2006) explain that if the cost of tice embedded in it.
failure is low compared with the cost of
missing a real opportunity of gain, people Rationalisations of failure. Cognitive biases
taking decisions under uncertainty will strongly influence the expectations and deci-
embark on potentially promising endeavours sions of individuals considering urban
even if the chances of success are low. migration. But why do people stay even in
If the attractiveness of urban migration the face of negative experiences and failed
can be framed partly as an outcome of expectations? The costs of failure are diffi-
overly optimistic self-assessments, then we cult to measure because they are often ratio-
should consider whether something akin to nalised in a self-illusory way, to protect self-
462 Urban Studies 56(2)

esteem and motivate us to try again (Polivy Haartsen and Thissen (2014: 89) write
and Herman, 2002). This cognitive bias is that the alternative, return migration, is
known as sunk-cost fallacy, or escalation of often perceived as failure, and ‘because they
commitment. Several competing theories failed in the destination, failure returnees are
explain it (see a review in Brockner, 1992; thought to have inferior human and social
also Kahneman, 2011), but the basic idea is capital and will therefore not be able to have
that people are unwilling to change a failing any (positive) impact on the development of
course of action if they have already invested the region of origin’. Many returns are
substantial resources in it (financial, emo- planned and socially well-regarded
tional, timewise), either because of the need (Newbold and Bell, 2001), and intended
of self-justification or because of the antici- ‘successful’ return justifies keeping close ties
pation of substantial losses. The rationalisa- with the location of origin (Stark, 1991).
tion of failure, shifting responsibility to However, there is evidence for a negative
external events, serves as a motivation to selection bias in return migration, namely
keep the commitment. when purely economic factors are considered
The paradox is that overly ambitious pur- (Niedomysl and Amcoff, 2011). In those
poses demand overly ambitious investments, cases, those who do not step up the escalator
becoming simultaneously more difficult to but stay and insist, even if objectively worse
attain and less likely to be abandoned. off, keep their condition hidden from social
Similarly, the great promises of cities, as disdain and can hope for their own lucky
shaped collectively by generations of moment.
migrants, make them seem more attractive
than an unbiased account of urban life. But
(Self-)inducing cognitive biases
the greater the magnitude of these promises,
the more unattainable they become for Psychologists and behavioural economists
most; and rather than giving up, this actu- see the biases of poor perception of risk, illu-
ally makes people more likely to rationalise sions of control, overly optimistic self-
failure and try again. assessments, and rationalisation of failure as
Can this mechanism be behind the visible design features of human cognition rather
capacity of cities not only to attract people, than flaws that can be corrected (Haselton
but also to retain those who were left at the and Nettle, 2006). However, Kahneman
lower steps of the urban escalator? There are (2011) argues that we can mitigate the nega-
numerous examples of resilient communities tive consequences of these cognitive limita-
staying and persevering in decaying city tions by becoming more aware of the ways
economies, such as in Detroit. Probable in which they can be induced and exploited.
explanations for this involve the natural ten- We will refer to three main ‘cognitive short-
dency to remain in familiar contexts and loy- cuts’ used as heuristics to support decision-
alty to place (King, 2004). However, the making: framing, the way that gains and
cognitive biases perspective offers another losses are presented; accessibility, the ease
interpretation. It suggests that successive with which thoughts are recalled; and focus-
failures are prone to escalate commitment ing illusions, the errors in judging the weight
and retain people in cycles of motivation and of especially visible distinctions (see Figure 1
frustration as they keep trying, rather than for their connection with cognitive biases).
to make them abandon their investment. All these enablers of biases can be recog-
The implication is that people may decide nised, explicitly or implicitly, in current
against their own economic best interest. understandings of cities.
Cardoso et al. 463

Framing. Framing effects (Tversky and Accessibility. Urban imaginaries often rely on
Kahneman, 1981) violate the rationalist very rich descriptions, visually striking
assumption that the addition of irrelevant images and memorable concepts. From the
features or outcome differences does not first suburbs and Garden Cities to present
affect decision-making. In fact, logically urban regeneration projects, developers
equivalent assertions result in very different advertise their new ventures with detailed
perceptions depending on how they are pre- imagery and descriptions to trigger strong
sented (a treatment presented as having a reactions and easily recallable memories.
10% mortality rate is likely to be less The reason why they do this illustrates the
favoured than one with 90% survival rate; phenomenon of accessibility: when con-
see Kahneman, 2003). This not only lets fronted with a question about which we do
individuals reinvent their own narratives not have sufficient information – such as
about urban promises to better confirm their what will life in the city be like? – we tend to
desires and beliefs, but also allows city replace it with a secondary question to
authorities and opinion-makers to frame which we can respond easily – such as do I
information in different ways according to feel attracted to this promise? In decision-
the effect they wish to create. For instance, making, the ease of recollection and salience
investment agencies highlight the numbers of the data are more important than their
that show the positives of their cities, but statistical representativeness (Kahneman,
not those that may reveal negative features; 2011; recall the law of small numbers).
municipalities frame gentrification as ‘regen- The capacities to surprise, alter moods
eration’ to create a positive response in visi- and evoke familiar stereotypes are attributes
tors and investors. that enhance accessibility (Higgins, 1996;
Cities have used framing techniques to Kahneman, 2003). Therefore, rhetorically
position themselves under a positive light for effective discourses about the promises of
centuries, a common trend known as urban cities, rich in imagery and resorting to spe-
boosterism. But framing can have a more cific anecdotes, are likely to override other,
pervasive use, namely to make claims about eventually more balanced, sources of infor-
urban life in general rather than particular mation. Urban promises have been present
cities. Leaving aside the discussion about in films, popular music and other forms of
supporting evidence, see how Glaeser (2011) art and media, and this is likely to have
reframes the problem of concentrated urban helped the accumulation of simplified, sali-
poverty by implying that cities are ‘good ent and biased messages which are part of
places to be poor’ and thus attract more our cognitive associations with the idea of
poor people (Peck, 2016). Amin adds that the city: in some sense, successive replica-
popular urban imaginaries reframe slums as tions and modernisations of the Stadtluft
‘another kind of creative/resilient macht frei motto turn it into a ‘meme’, a
Schumpeterian space’ (Amin, 2013: 479), full carrier of cultural ideas which transmits
of opportunity and empowerment, while across generations (Dawkins, 1976). And
implicitly endorsing the neglect of public yet, to be fair, the reliance on accessibility
intervention in the city. This use of framing works both ways, as the literature about the
helps create generalisable stories, regardless negative side of urban life, which occupied
of context. Later they become accessible part of the 20th century, resorted perhaps
simplifications, which we value more than even more to highly recallable and strong
evidence for decision-making. That is how imagery about dystopia and conflict to make
the next heuristic, accessibility, works. its points.
464 Urban Studies 56(2)

Focusing illusions. A well-known illustration between very distinct environments (say,


of the final bias, the focusing illusion, London and a village in southern Italy),
involves precisely the perceived distinction than those opting between two more similar
between two spatial locations, which relates places.
nicely to the argument about how people The point that what counts is not the
judge the promises of urban life. Schkade actual factor of satisfaction but the change it
and Kahneman (1998) compared how peo- implies in comparison with current condi-
ple living in the Midwest (USA) judged their tions suggests that cognitive biases can pro-
own life satisfaction and that of people liv- duce similar discrepancies between
ing in California, and vice versa. While the expectations and outcomes across all types
average satisfaction was similar in both of social groups. There is a whole spectrum
places, Midwesterners assumed that life of urban migrants, from underprivileged
satisfaction in California was higher, based populations going to cities in search of a bet-
on the better weather as a highly salient dis- ter life to skilled professionals looking for
tinction, which they overweighed relative to the next career move. But, excluding situa-
the rest. The authors write that the correla- tions of absolute need to migrate, whatever
tion between subjective wellbeing factors the odds, the differences in the mental pro-
and objective life circumstances is very low, cesses used by these groups to perceive and
but ‘judgements of life satisfaction in a dif- act upon urban promises may be in degree
ferent location are susceptible to a focusing rather than nature. Kahneman and Tversky
illusion: easily observed and distinctive dif- (1979) developed prospect theory around the
ferences between locations are given more notion that the actual carriers of utility are
weight in such judgements than they will not expected states of wealth but the poten-
have in reality’ (Schkade and Kahneman, tial gains and losses in relation to a point of
1998: 340). Under this perception, people reference. This reference dependence sug-
might indeed move to California ‘in the mis- gests that people in all kinds of initial states
taken belief that this would make them hap- may fall for the same type of judgement
pier’ (Schkade and Kahneman, 1998: 345). errors and similarly overrate urban pro-
While the weather is a secondary factor, mises. All will require the anticipation of a
what counts is how much it sets a difference significant amount of relative change to cur-
from the present situation of the observer. rent conditions to overcome loss aversion
Messages highlighting salient distinctions and engage in the risky enterprise of urban
between alternative places can exploit the migration (Morrison and Clark, 2016).
focusing illusion to induce life-changing Nevertheless, qualified professionals are
decisions. Urban promises thrive on such likely to have more measurable expectations,
illusions: visible differences between large such as education or a new job. For under-
cities and the original settings of migrants – privileged people, on the other hand, not
whether they focus on access to amenities only will the lower reference point facilitate
and jobs, finding potential love partners, or the illusion of greater relative changes, but
enjoying the cultural milieu – will be greatly the move to the city may also be more
overweighed as to their potential for change clouded with uncertainty about the future,
and role in future life satisfaction. The adding difficulty to their decisions and
greater the difference, the greater the error exacerbating the potentially negative impacts
of judgement, meaning that the focusing illu- of wrong choices.
sion is more likely to affect people choosing
Cardoso et al. 465

Summary and discussion for the ability of cities to retain even those to
whom urban life was not yet generous.
Urban promises have fuelled the imagina-
All these biases feature prominently in
tion of generations of hopeful migrants, who
how we anticipate and perceive life in cities.
have often exaggerated the potential benefits
They can be strengthened by a variety of
and neglected the drawbacks of cities. The
heuristics, or cognitive shortcuts. Framing
way this tendency has endured throughout
and accessibility are common strategies to
history, in many different contexts, makes
convey positive messages about urban life
an explanation deeply embedded in the
and dispel its downsides. Focusing illusions
human psyche quite likely. This paper used
overweigh the importance of future changes
insights from cognitive science to better
but always relate to a point of reference,
understand why people tend to have strong
meaning that the tendency to overrate such
and positive expectations about cities, even
changes to one’s current situation may affect
in the face of uncertain odds, contradicting
all kinds of socioeconomic groups.
facts and negative experiences. It discussed
urban migration as a form of decision-
making under uncertainty and provided a Policy implications: The city as a self-help
novel contribution by using the framework book? Several implications of how cognitive
of cognitive biases and heuristics, popu- biases affect individuals are relevant for policy.
larised by Daniel Kahneman and others in Recent literature has even proposed that
various fields of sociology and economics, to public policies should be formulated in a way
explore the psychological mechanisms affect- that builds on those biases to improve our
ing how we understand and act upon urban ‘choice architecture’ and nudge us towards
promises. In parallel, the paper aimed to elu- healthier, more responsible and more sensible
cidate some of the reasons for the attractive- behaviours (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008).
ness of the ‘urban triumphalism’ discourse However, acknowledging cognitive biases is
and provide further directions for its cri- also important to mitigate their negative
tique. More broadly, it argued the impor- impacts, namely in the case of urban migration
tance of a behavioural approach to urban and urban life in general. For instance, while
studies to diversify current debates around ICT and social media can help support
migration and urban agglomeration. migration decisions by providing better
Cognitive biases provide, indeed, clues to information about the destination (Cooke and
explore relevant urban research concerns: (1) Shuttleworth, 2018), thus reducing the risk of
the poor perception of risk (law of small failure, it is also true that digital connectivity
numbers) explaining the exaggerated value often amounts to personal information
given to previous individual urban migration bubbles which restrict access to balanced
stories; (2) the illusion of control providing information. Considering that the levels of risk
fertile ground for the rhetoric of urban tri- coming from acting on inaccurate information
umphalism and the belief in the ‘natural and the potential impact of wrong decisions
powers’ of cities; (3) overoptimistic self- vary significantly between more and less
assessments inducing individual trust in the privileged socioeconomic groups, this implies
urban escalator, the neglect of playing fields more attention to how cognitive features can
tilted by embedded injustice and competi- be purposefully exploited by techniques of
tion, and making us misevaluate success; and manipulation of information and affect the
(4) the escalation of commitment as a factor most vulnerable.
466 Urban Studies 56(2)

Indeed, when it comes to the promised distort not only future expectations but also
triumph of the urban, there is much self-help the perceived outcomes of urban life.
book-styled rhetoric promised by city mar- Misguided perceptions even apply to ‘hard’
keting gurus. But the logic behind self-help factors such as economic mobility
books is often dangerous – they fetishise (Engelhardt and Wagener, 2014), stressing
single actions, provide immoderate hopes, that ‘factual’ realities are also contingent
neglect that choice sets are severely limited, and are apprehended through filters of emo-
and spread the idea that being poor, unsuc- tion, affect, personality, age, relative change,
cessful, unattractive or depressed is one’s among others. It is not just that our cogni-
own responsibility and can be changed by tive abilities are limited when we are antici-
one’s own reinvention (McGee, 2005). In a pating and deciding, but also that our (non-
curious analogy, much contemporary urban cognitive) experience of reality is not objec-
policy frames the withdrawal of public inter- tive but interpretative (Oishi, 2010).
vention and the neglect of collective respon- And yet, these imperfect tools are all we
sibility for spatial and social justice as a have to decide, perceive and judge life. When
‘bottom-up’ empowerment of free-choosing it comes to assessing expectations, experi-
citizens (Amin, 2013), similarly seen as well- ences and perceptions about urban life, they
informed, resourceful and free from social make individuals more likely to constantly
or choice constraints. Research in the USA realign their reference points (Kahneman,
shows that especially the poorest individuals 2011). This makes them likely to accommo-
are indeed willing to accept vast amounts date to disappointing but misperceived life
of inequality, as long as they believe in conditions, mitigated by constantly deferred
the opportunity to succeed, overestimating expectations, especially in large urban areas
the likelihood of upward mobility against where opportunities are diffuse and possibili-
the risk of downward mobility (Davidai and ties abundant.
Gilovich, 2015). This presents a problem for research
The exploitation of these tendencies is interested in applying behavioural methods
patent in the futurology of some urban tri- to urban studies. With no objectively
umphalists, announcing the natural powers reported outcomes to test our hopes and
of cities to make us all happier, wealthier dreams against, we end up comparing two
and healthier. Highlighting the biases levels of subjectivity. The complex wash of
through which we perceive the world may filters affecting the perception of experiences
help to tone down some of these celebratory, introduces unreliability in typical methods
but paralysing narratives that have spread to of assessment such as individual surveys or
policymaking and media. life story interviews. Better approaches are
probably long-term longitudinal studies
Theoretical implications and limitations. We illu- comparing large data sets, which could
strated the discrepancy between the expected dilute the impact of individual unreliability,
and the experienced life in cities through and studies testing for differences (age,
notions of bounded rationality when antici- skills, nationality, socioeconomic back-
pating the future. However, alongside that ground, etc.) where the issue is not how peo-
gap, we must consider another one between ple report on their experiences but how
the experienced and the perceived: even in much subjective reports by different groups
the presence of results, we tend to misrepre- vary on average.
sent and overrate our successes, meaning Anyway, behavioural urban geography
that individual idiosyncrasies and values would not be a positivist discipline able to
Cardoso et al. 467

generate postulates, as Harvey wondered seems likely: the features of human cognition
decades ago (1970). Its strengths are in illu- process information asymmetrically and pro-
minating differences between individuals, vide a comparative advantage to the urban
times and contexts and adopting a critical narrative. The question then is to make peo-
realism approach. In other words, taking the ple more aware of these features so that they
individuality and fragmentation of explana- are able to critically judge the benefits and
tions as an assumption, the behavioural costs of urban life, avoid one-sided or biased
approach operates through a retroductive discourses, and make more informed deci-
method, which, unlike other approaches, sions about their future. When it comes to
explores not the logical or the general conclu- developing policies that improve urban life
sion of the analysis but the realistically ade- for a majority of people, the belief in better
quate explanation, ever provisional, mainly urban futures should not be appropriated as
asking what qualities should exist for some- a pretext to perpetuate spatial and socio-
thing to be possible (Danermark et al., 2002; economic injustices.
Meyer and Lunnay, 2013).
The positive aspects of cities should not be Declaration of conflicting interests
downplayed. Cities are engines of socio- The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of
economic mobility, freedom, innovation and interest with respect to the research, authorship,
quality of life. Agglomeration benefits are evi- and/or publication of this article.
dent and people looking for greater life
opportunities are right to consider moving to Funding
larger cities. Advertising their positive sides,
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following
believing in unlikely promises and following financial support for the research, authorship,
uncertain paths may have productive effects, and/or publication of this article: Cardoso,
reinforcing motivation and helping overcome Meijers and De Vos acknowledge the financial
reluctance to change (Berliant, 2010). support of a VIDI grant (Grant No. 45214-004)
However, the question of how the ‘compara- offered by the Netherlands Organisation for
tive advantage’ of cities emerges can be asked Scientific Research (NWO).
by future research. We consider two possibili-
ties: first, there are actors with an incentive to ORCID iD
frame cities as more attractive than they actu-
Rodrigo Cardoso https://orcid.org/0000-0001-
ally are. Second, there is a systematic infor- 8989-9160
mation asymmetry, related to the scale of
cities and the density of stories and events
that take place there, which develops into a References
commonly accepted form of spatial fetishism Alicke MD and Govorun O (2005) The better-than-
– things are not just in the city, they become average effect. In: Alicke MD, Dunning DA and
of the city (Saunders, 1986). This process Krueger JI (eds) The Self in Social Judgment.
shifts the focus from purposeful framing to New York: Psychology Press, pp. 85–106.
Alirol E, Getaz L, Stoll B, et al. (2011) Urbanisa-
the accessibility and focusing illusion heuris-
tion and infectious diseases in a globalised
tics which unfold in our minds regardless of
world. The Lancet Infectious Diseases 11(2):
intentions (e.g. positive stories will have 131–141.
greater salience, despite representativeness; Amin A (2013) Telescopic urbanism and the poor.
potential changes are excessively valued). City 17(4): 476–492.
Considering the historical persistency of Behrens K and Robert-Nicoud F (2014) Survival
‘urban promises’, the second possibility of the fittest in cities: Urbanisation and
468 Urban Studies 56(2)

inequality. The Economic Journal 124(581): CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4838. Avail-
1371–1400. able at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2463129.
Berliant M (2010) Misbehavioral urban econom- Eurostat (2017) Migrant Integration Statistics –
ics. Journal of Regional Science 50(1): 93–101. Housing. Luxembourg: Eurostat.
Berry BJ and Okulicz-Kozaryn A (2011) An Fielding AJ (1992) Migration and social mobility:
urban–rural happiness gradient. Urban Geo- South East England as an escalator region.
graphy 32(6): 871–883. Regional Studies 26(1): 1–15.
Brockner J (1992) The escalation of commitment Florida R (2017) The New Urban Crisis: How Our
to a failing course of action: Toward theoreti- Cities Are Increasing Inequality, Deepening
cal progress. Academy of Management Review Segregation, and Failing the Middle Class –
17(1): 39–61. And What We Can Do About It. New York:
Broersma L and Van Dijk J (2008) The effect of Basic Books.
congestion and agglomeration on multi-factor Galster GC and Killen SP (1995) The geography
productivity growth in Dutch regions. Journal of metropolitan opportunity: A reconnais-
of Economic Geography 8(2): 181–209. sance and conceptual framework. Housing
Burgalassi D and Luzzati T (2015) Urban spatial Policy Debate 6(1): 7–43.
structure and environmental emissions: A sur- Glaeser EL (2011) Triumph of the City: How Our
vey of the literature and some empirical evi- Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter,
dence for Italian NUTS 3 regions. Cities 49: Greener, Healthier, and Happier. New York:
134–148. Penguin Press.
Champion T, Coombes M and Gordon I (2014) Glaeser EL and Maré D (2001) Cities and skills.
How far do England’s second-order cities emu- Journal of Labor Economics 19(2): 316–342.
late London as human-capital ‘escalators’? Gleeson B (2012) Critical commentary. The urban
Population, Space and Place 20(5): 421–433. age: Paradox and prospect. Urban Studies
Chetty R, Hendren N, Kline P, et al. (2014) 49(5): 931–943.
Where is the land of opportunity? The geogra- Gordon I (2015) Ambition, human capital acqui-
phy of intergenerational mobility in the United sition and the metropolitan escalator. Regional
States. The Quarterly Journal of Economics Studies 49(6): 1042–1055.
129(4): 1553–1623. Gould P and White R (1986) Mental Maps. Sec-
Clark W and Maas R (2015) Interpreting migra- ond edition. London: Routledge.
tion through the prism of reasons for moves. Haartsen T and Thissen F (2014) The success–
Population, Space and Place 21(1): 54–67. failure dichotomy revisited: Young adults’
Cooke TJ and Shuttleworth I (2018) The effects motives to return to their rural home region.
of information and communication technolo- Children’s Geographies 12(1): 87–101.
gies on residential mobility and migration. Hagerty MR (2003) Was life better in the ‘good
Population, Space and Place 24(3): e2111. old days’? Intertemporal judgements of life
Dahl R (1989) Rhyme Stew. London: Jonathan satisfaction. Journal of Happiness Studies 4(2):
Cape. 115–139.
Danermark B, Ekstrom M, Jakobsen L, et al. Haines MR (2001) The urban mortality transition
(2002) Explaining Society. Critical Realism in in the United States, 1800–1940. Annales de
the Social Sciences. Abingdon: Routledge. de´mographie historique 2001(1): 33–64.
Davidai S and Gilovich T (2015) Building a more Harvey D (1970) Behavioural postulates and the
mobile America – One income quintile at a construction of theory in human geography. In:
time. Perspectives on Psychological Science Osborne R and Wrobel A (eds) Geographica
10(1): 60–71. Polonica 18. Studies in Geographical Methods.
Davis M (2006) Planet of Slums. London: Verso. Warsaw: Polish Scientific Publishers, pp. 27–46.
Dawkins R (1976) The Selfish Gene. Oxford: Haselton MG and Nettle D (2006) The paranoid
Oxford University Press. optimist: An integrative evolutionary model of
Engelhardt C and Wagener A (2014) Biased per- cognitive biases. Personality and Social Psy-
ceptions of income inequality and redistribution. chology Review 10(1): 47–66.
Cardoso et al. 469

Hayter R and Watts HD (1983) The geography of Miller DT and Ross M (1975) Self-serving biases
enterprise: A reappraisal. Progress in Human in attribution of causality: Fact or fiction? Psy-
Geography 7: 157–181. chological Bulletin 82(2): 213–225.
Higgins ET (1996) Knowledge activation: Acces- Morrison PS and Clark W (2016) Loss aversion
sibility, applicability, and salience. In: Higgins and duration of residence. Demographic
ET and Kruglanski A (eds) Social Psychology: Research 35: 1079–1100.
Handbook of Basic Principles. New York: Mulchany K and Kollamparambil U (2016) The
Guilford Press, pp. 133–168. impact of rural–urban migration on subjective
International Organization for Migration (IOM) well-being in South Africa. The Journal of
(2015) World Migration Report. Migrants and Cit- Development Studies 52(9): 1357–1371.
ies: New Partnerships to Manage Mobility. Gen- Newbold KB and Bell M (2001) Return and
eva: International Organization for Migration. onwards migration in Canada and Australia:
Kahneman D (2003) A perspective on judgment Evidence from fixed interval data. Interna-
and choice. Mapping bounded rationality. tional Migration Review 35(4): 1157–1184.
American Psychologist 58(9): 697–720. Nicholls W (2011) Book review: Welcome to the
Kahneman D (2011) Thinking, Fast and Slow. Urban Revolution: How Cities are Changing
New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. the World. Dialogues in Human Geography
Kahneman D and Tversky A (1979) Prospect the- 1(2): 265–268.
ory: An analysis of decisions under risk. Econ- Niedomysl T and Amcoff J (2011) Why return
ometrica 47(2): 263–291. migrants return: Survey evidence on motives
King LA (2004) Democratic hopes in the poly- for internal return migration in Sweden. Popu-
centric city. Journal of Politics 66(1): 203–223. lation, Space and Place 17(5): 656–673.
King R, Lulle A, Parutis V, et al. (2018) From OECD (2016) Promoting Well-being and Inclu-
peripheral region to escalator region in Europe: siveness in Sweden. Better Policies Series. Paris:
Young Baltic graduates in London. European OECD.
Urban and Regional Studies 25(3): 284–299. Oishi S (2010) The psychology of residential
Knight J and Gunatilaka R (2010) Great expecta- mobility: Implications for the self, social rela-
tions? The subjective well-being of rural–urban tionships and well-being. Perspectives on Psy-
migrants in China. World Development 38(1): chological Science 5(1): 5–21.
113–124. Okulicz-Kozaryn A (2015) Happiness and Place:
Lenzi C and Perucca G (2018) Are urbanized Why Life is Better Outside of the City. New
areas source of life satisfaction? Evidence York: Palgrave Macmillan.
from EU regions. Papers in Regional Science Okulicz-Kozaryn A and Valente RR (2018) City
97(S1): 105–122. life: Glorification, desire, and the unconscious
Long J (2005) Rural–urban migration and socio- size fetish. In: Kapoor I (ed.) Psychoanalysis
economic mobility in Victorian Britain. The and the Global. Lincoln, NE: University of
Journal of Economic History 65(1): 1–35. Nebraska Press, pp. 209–232.
McGee M (2005) Self Help, Inc. Makeover Cul- Parutis V (2011) ‘Economic migrants’ or ‘mid-
ture in American Life. New York: Oxford Uni- dling transnationals’? East European migrants’
versity Press. experiences of work in the UK. International
Meester WJ and Pellenbarg PH (2006) The spa- Migration 52(1): 36–55.
tial preference map of Dutch entrepreneurs: Peck J (2016) Economic rationality meets celeb-
Subjective rating of locations, 1983, 1993 and rity urbanology: Exploring Edward Glaeser’s
2003. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale city. International Journal of Urban and
Geografie 97(4): 364–376. Regional Research 40(10): 1–30.
Meyer SB and Lunnay B (2013) The application Polivy J and Herman CP (2002) If at first you
of abductive and retroductive inference for the don’t succeed. False hopes of self-change.
design and analysis of theory-driven sociologi- American Psychologist 57(9): 677–689.
cal research. Sociological Research Online Pred A (1967) Behavior and Location: Founda-
18(1): 1–11. tions for a Geographic and Dynamic Location
470 Urban Studies 56(2)

Theory, Part I. Lund, Sweden: Department of Taleb NN (2007) The Black Swan. The Impact of
Geography, University of Lund. the Highly Improbable. New York: Random
Ross A (2013) ‘Nothing gained by overcrowding’: House.
The history and politics of urban population Taylor SE and Brown JD (1988) Illusion and
control. In: Bridge G and Watson S (eds) The well-being: A social psychological perspective
New Blackwell Companion to the City. Oxford: on mental health. Psychological Bulletin
Blackwell Publishing, pp. 169–178. 103(2): 193–210.
Saunders P (1986) Social Theory and the Urban Thaler RH and Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: Improv-
Question. London: Routledge. ing Decisions About Health, Wealth and Happi-
Sayer A (1982) Explanation in economic geogra- ness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
phy: Abstraction versus Generalization. Prog- Tversky A and Kahneman D (1971) Belief in the
ress in Human Geography 6: 68–89. law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin
Scharf T and DeJong Gierveld J (2008) Loneli- 76(2): 105–110.
ness in urban neighbourhoods: An Anglo- Tversky A and Kahneman D (1981) The framing
Dutch comparison. European Journal of Age- of decisions and the psychology of choice. Sci-
ing 5(2): 103–115. ence 211(4481): 453–458.
Schkade DA and Kahneman D (1998) Does living UN-Habitat (2016) Urbanization and Develop-
in California make people happy? A focusing ment: Emerging Futures. World Cities Report
illusion in judgments of life satisfaction. Psy- 2016. Nairobi: United Nations Human Settle-
chological Science 9(5): 340–346. ments Programme.
Simon H (1955) A behavioral model of rational van Ham M (2001) Workplace mobility and occu-
choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics pational achievement. International Journal of
69(1): 99–118. Population Geography 7: 295–306.
Simon H (1957) Models of Man. New York: Wiley. van Ham M, Findlay A, Manley D, et al. (2012)
Simon H (1959) Theories of decision-making in Migration, occupational mobility, and
economics and behavioral science. The Ameri- regional escalators in Scotland. Urban Studies
can Economic Review 49(3): 253–283. Research 2012: 1–15.
Simon M, Houghton SM and Aquino K (2000) Williams A and Donald A (2011) The Lure of the
Cognitive biases, risk perception, and venture City. From Slums to Suburbs. London: Pluto
formation: How individuals decide to start Press.
companies. Journal of Business Venturing Yamagishi T, Hashimoto H, Li Y, et al. (2012)
15(2): 113–134. Stadtluft macht frei (City air brings freedom).
Stark O (1991) The Migration of Labor. Cam- Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology 43(1):
bridge: Blackwell. 38–45.
Taleb NN (2005) Fooled by Randomness. The Hid-
den Role of Chance in Life and in the Markets.
New York: Random House.

You might also like