You are on page 1of 9

PERSONALITY AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY BULLETIN

Parks, Rumble / RECIPROCITY AND SOCIAL VALUES

Elements of Reciprocity and Social Value Orientation

Craig D. Parks
Ann C. Rumble
Washington State University

This study assessed the impact of social value orientation on the have focused on the use of strategic choice rules
ability of a reciprocal choice strategy to induce high rates of coop- designed to induce high rates of cooperation in others.
erative behavior in a prisoner’s dilemma. Prosocials, competi- In particular, researchers have been interested in the
tors, and individualists played against reciprocal strategies for ability of reciprocal strategies to induce cooperation. In
which delay of reciprocation of both cooperation and its most basic sense, reciprocation involves behaving so
noncooperation were orthogonally manipulated. As predicted, as to return to an exchange partner an outcome of the
individualists cooperated most frequently against Tit-for-tat, same valence as was provided by the partner’s earlier
competitors when retaliation for noncooperation was delayed, behavior (Parks & Komorita, 1998). A specific form of
and prosocials when their cooperative choice was immediately reciprocation that has received much attention, at least
reciprocated. In addition, it was found that prosocials began within the prisoner’s dilemma format, is Tit-for-tat. Tit-
“behavioral assimilation” as early as the second of four five-trial for-tat involves cooperating on the initial encounter and
blocks and that changes in competitors’ rate of cooperation over thereafter simply performing on trial t + 1 the behavior
time were determined by immediacy of reciprocating cooperation. that one’s partner performed on trial t. Although
research on Tit-for-tat has been conducted for many
years (see Patchen, 1987, for a summary of this early
Research on choice behavior in mixed-motive situa- work), recent research has been spurred by Axelrod’s
computer simulations of behavioral choice strategies in
tions has long been a popular topic of study for psycholo-
gists. One particular type of mixed-motive situation that prisoner’s dilemmas (summarized in Axelrod, 1984).
commands attention is the social dilemma, a situation in Axelrod pitted Tit-for-tat against a large number of alter-
which there is a conflict between maximization of per- native strategies and showed that Tit-for-tat returned a
sonal and collective outcomes (Komorita & Parks, 1995). greater mean pay-off than any other strategy. Axelrod
Regardless of how one’s fellow group members behave, (1984) theorized that Tit-for-tat’s success was attribut-
it is always personally most beneficial (in terms of out- able to (a) its niceness (one always begins with a cooper-
comes) to act selfishly rather than for the collective ative choice), (b) clarity (it is a simple strategy to perceive
good. However, this is also true for all other group mem- and understand), (c) provocability (one immediately
bers, and if everyone succumbs to this selfish temptation, responds to a noncooperative choice with noncoopera-
all persons are worse off than if all had acted for the col- tion), (d) forgiveness (one always responds to a coopera-
lective good. An excellent example of a social dilemma is tive choice with cooperation, regardless of the prior
public television. Public television is available to all view- actions of the opponent), and (e) lack of envy (no refer-
ers regardless of whether a viewer has made a contribu- ence is made to one’s accumulated outcomes relative to
tion to the station. Thus, it is personally profitable to those of the opponent).
keep one’s money and watch the station’s programs
rather than give one’s money and watch the programs.
However, if all viewers act in this way, the station will Authors’ Note: We would like to thank Shawn Scamahorn for his assis-
receive no money, will be forced to cease broadcasting, tance with data collection and Sam Komorita for his input on the de-
sign. Address correspondence to Craig D. Parks, Department of
and all viewers are worse off than if all had contributed to Psychology, Washington State University, P.O. Box 644820, Pullman,
the station. WA 99164; e-mail: parkscd@mail.wsu.edu.
Although social dilemma researchers are interested PSPB, Vol. 27 No. 10, October 2001 1301-1309
in many aspects of choice behavior, some investigators © 2001 by the Society for Personality and Social Psychology, Inc.

1301
1302 PERSONALITY AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY BULLETIN

Empirical tests of some of these propositions by


Komorita, Parks, and colleagues (Komorita, Chan, &
A B
Parks, 1993; Komorita, Hilty, & Parks, 1991; Komorita,
Parks, & Hulbert, 1992; Parks, Henager, & Scamahorn,
A 3, 3 1, 4
1996; Parks & Vu, 1994) have shown that (a) immediate
reciprocation of cooperative choice is crucial; (b) response
B 4, 1 2, 2
to noncooperation can be delayed but should still be
responded to; (c) clarity does positively influence rate of
cooperation, although opponent use of Tit-for-tat is not Figure 1 A prisoner’s dilemma pay-off matrix.
as easily perceived as it seems; and (d) the effects of nice- NOTE: Values to the left of the comma are payoffs for the Row player,
ness are not clear. To date, the effects of envy have not and values to the right are payoffs for the Column player.
been studied. Additional theoretical work has shown
that a modified version of Tit-for-tat can be successfully
employed in very large groups (Parks & Komorita, 1997; (1999) demonstrated that, through frequent repetition
but see de Hues, 2000). of mixed-motive problems, competitors can be taught
Researchers, then, have made some progress toward the long-term benefits of Tit-for-tat.
understanding the dynamics of reciprocation. However, These studies are important because they demon-
an important factor that may qualify many of these find- strate that people with different value orientations can
ings is the social value orientation of group members. A respond to the same behavioral strategy in different
social value orientation is a tendency to prefer particular ways, a factor not accounted for in the Axelrod (1984)
patterns of outcomes for self and others (Messick & simulations but that would be present in almost any
McClintock, 1968). Although many different outcome mixed-motive setting. Furthermore, these data show that
patterns have been identified, the most commonly the nature of responding is not straightforward. Thus,
occurring orientations are prosocial—a desire to maxi- for example, a competitor will not automatically respond
mize joint gain; competition—a desire to maximize rela- to a cooperative action with an attempt at exploitation.
tive gain for self; and individualism—a preference to Rather, there seem to be some situational factors that
maximize personal gain, irrespective of others’ pay-offs influence response. Accordingly, the purpose of this
(van Lange, Otten, de Bruin, & Joireman, 1997). A con- study was to assess the relationship between social value
siderable amount of research has been, and continues to orientation and a situational factor that is known to
be, conducted on social value orientations. This affect response to a Tit-for-tat strategy; namely, delay in
research has focused on their development (e.g., van reciprocating cooperative and/or noncooperative
Lange et al., 1997); their influence across a variety of choice. We orthogonally manipulated these delays to see
interpersonal situations (e.g., Parks, 1994; van Lange, if particular patterns of delay were more or less influen-
van Vugt, Meertens, & Rutter, 1998); their relationship tial on the choice behavior of prosocials, competitors,
to other individual difference constructs, such as trust and individualists.
(e.g., Joireman, van Lange, Kuhlman, van Vugt, & Shel- Reciprocity and Social Values
ley, 1997; Parks, 1994) and willingness to sacrifice (e.g.,
van Lange, Agnew, Harinck, & Steemers, 1997); and Consider the basic prisoner’s dilemma matrix shown
their interaction with personal characteristics of other in Figure 1. In this matrix, ”A” is described as the cooper-
group members (e.g., van Lange & Kuhlman, 1994; van ative choice because the “AA” choice combination pro-
Lange & Semin-Goossens, 1998). Relatively little duces the greatest joint pay-offs in the long run, and “B”
research has examined how people of different social is the noncooperative choice because it will lead to
value orientations respond to strategic behavior of oth- either consistent exploitation (if the opponent continu-
ers, and this research has been somewhat inconsistent. ally chooses “A”) or long-term suboptimal outcomes (if
For example, van Lange and Visser (1999) showed that opponent also keeps choosing “B”). A primary goal of
prosocials and individualists respond to Tit-for-tat with dilemma researchers is to discover techniques for
high levels of cooperation but that competitors do not. encouraging and maintaining mutual “A” choices and
Similarly, de Dreu and van Lange (1995) found that, in a discouraging exploitative choices. Indeed, one of the
negotiation setting, prosocials respond to opponent primary benefits of a Tit-for-tat strategy is that the user
concessions with concessions of greater magnitude than cannot be regularly exploited—if the opponent chooses
those offered by individualists or competitors. However, “B” when Tit-for-tat chooses “A,” Tit-for-tat will switch to
de Dreu and van Lange (1995) also found that competi- “B” on the next trial. Our focus in this study was to assess
tors and individualists are as willing to make concessions the extent to which specific components of Tit-for-tat
on low-priority issues as were prosocials, and Sheldon interact with various social value orientations to affect
Parks, Rumble / RECIPROCITY AND SOCIAL VALUES 1303

the induction and maintenance of cooperation. The fol- ence to the Komorita et al. (1991) paradigm, being slow
lowing predictions were tested regarding these to anger means delaying response to a noncooperative
interactions. choice—instead of responding to noncooperation on
the next trial, one responds at some point in the future.
Competitors Thus, if the slow-to-anger argument is accurate, it should
Probably the greatest amount of theorizing involves be the case that a delay in responding to a competitor’s
the induction of cooperation in competitors. There are noncooperative choice should induce greater rates of
two schools of thought regarding how to accomplish this. cooperation than an immediate response. Komorita and
The first argues that one should be tough with competi- colleagues found that delaying a retaliation for as little as
tors and immediately retaliate against noncooperation. one trial (i.e., a noncooperative choice on trial t was
In this way, competitors will come to learn the futility of reciprocated on trial t + 2 rather than t + 1) nonetheless
chronic noncooperation and will become cooperative induced greater rates of cooperation in participants
(Braver & Barnett, 1976; Kraines & Kraines, 1993). The than did an immediate retaliation. Hence, we
second school of thought suggests that one should be operationalized “delay” in our study as a one-trial lag in
somewhat lenient and tolerate occasional exploitations. responding.
The theoretical basis for this argument stems largely Individualists
from Camerer and Ho’s (1998, 1999) experience-
weighted attraction-learning model of cooperative Individualists are motivated to maximize their own
choice. This model suggests that people select an initial gain, irrespective of the outcomes for others. As a result,
choice strategy at the outset of the game and then adopt the individualist will tailor his or her choices to fit the
new strategies as a function of outcomes, estimations of environment. In a hostile environment where others are
the outcomes that other strategies would have pro- not cooperative, the individualist is faced with the choice
duced, and changing expectations about how oppo- of either being exploited (i.e., choosing “A” while others
nents will act in the future. Strategy selection is assumed choose “B”) or entering into a series of mutual “B”
to follow the principle of “better responding,” which, in choices. The latter option is more attractive than the
a manner akin to satisficing, implies that people will first; thus, it follows that an individualist will be
favor strategies that produce high, but not necessarily noncooperative when playing against similarly
the best, outcomes. Competitors enter into a mixed- noncooperative others. Less straightforward is how an
motive situation with the expectation that others will be individualist will behave in a cooperative setting. If the
similarly competitive (Kelley & Stahelski, 1970). Accord- other is uniformly cooperative (i.e., always chooses “A”),
ing to Camerer and Ho, tolerating some exploitation then it becomes possible for the individualist to consis-
would lead competitors to alter their expectations about tently exploit the other by being noncooperative (i.e.,
one’s future behavior, and this alteration, coupled with always choosing “B”), and it follows that the individualist
mental simulation of alternative courses of action, should have a low rate of cooperation. By contrast, if the
should provoke competitors into changing their choice other is employing a reciprocal strategy, then consistent
strategies and becoming more cooperative. That choices exploitation of the other becomes impossible. In this sit-
are driven by “better responding” can explain why the uation, the individualist will gain the largest pay-off by
competitor would move away from an action that has the being cooperative. Because of this, Tit-for-tat should be
potential to return the single best outcome (through very effective at inducing cooperation in individualists, a
exploitation). Also, experience-weighted attraction prediction supported by van Lange and Visser (1999).
learning implies that being tough will be ineffective, However, it also should be the case that any deviation
because toughness will simply confirm the competitor’s from strict reciprocity will lead to decreased rates of
initial beliefs and will not produce any alteration of cooperation by individualists. A delay in retaliation for a
expectations. noncooperative choice should create a perception that
We have, then, two contrasting viewpoints on how to the other is exploitable, and a delay in responding to
induce more frequent cooperation in competitors. cooperative choice should suggest that the environment
Regarding toughness, van Lange and Visser (1999) is hostile. Because individualists enter an interaction
found competitors to have low rates of cooperation focusing only on how to maximize long-term selfish
when playing against Tit-for-tat. Because Tit-for-tat interests (van Lange, 1999), a perception that the envi-
always immediately retaliates against noncooperation, ronment is either hostile or exploitable should make the
its ineffectiveness at inducing competitors to be more noncooperative choice more attractive as a long-run
cooperative is evidence against the “be tough” argu- strategy, and it follows that the individualist should
ment. However, the second argument, which we shall respond with a decrease in the frequency of cooperative
call a “slow to anger” approach, is still viable. In refer- choice. Note that we expect delay of retaliation for
1304 PERSONALITY AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY BULLETIN

noncooperation to have different effects on competitors Design


versus individualists. For competitors, a delay should
There were three independent variables: niceness
produce a violation of expectations, which promotes
(yes or no), Lag-A (one or two trials), and Lag-B (one or
strategy switching, but for individualists, a delay should
two trials). There was also one classification variable,
make noncooperation more salient as a means of maxi-
value orientation, with three levels (prosocial, competi-
mizing long-term personal gain.
tor, individualist). These were combined in a 2 ´ 2 ´ 2 ´ 3
Prosocials completely crossed design. Niceness reflected whether
the programmed opponent’s Trial-1 choice was “A” or
On the surface, it seems that we should be unconcerned
“B.” It was included as a factor because Komorita et al.
with induction and maintenance of cooperation in
(1991) had found some evidence for its influence on
prosocials because these individuals are oriented toward
cooperative choice and we wanted to investigate whether
maximization of joint gain. However, although it may be
similar effects would show up in our data. There were 10
true that concerns over how to induce cooperation in
participants per cell.
prosocials are unwarranted, maintenance of sustained
cooperation is in fact an issue. Kelley and Stahelski Procedure
(1970) argued that prosocials will eventually tailor their
In the first phase, 1,100 students enrolled in introduc-
choices to fit the situation; thus, if prosocials are behav-
tory psychology courses were given a social values ques-
ing within a hostile environment, they will initially
tionnaire as part of a mass testing session that counted
attempt to convince others to cooperate by themselves
toward the course’s experiment participation require-
engaging in repeated cooperation, but if their overtures
ment. Students were told that people with particular
are not reciprocated, prosocials will eventually become
scores on the questionnaire would be contacted and
noncooperative. Kelley and Stahelski termed this
invited to participate in a second phase of the study for
“behavioral assimilation.” Behavioral assimilation sug-
additional credit. All questionnaires were scored and 80
gests that, with prosocials, immediate reciprocation of
prosocials, 80 competitors, and 80 individualists,
cooperation will become more important as time goes
selected at random from the master list of students, were
on: At the start, the prosocial is oriented toward frequent
called and invited to the second phase, which was the
cooperation, but he or she will eventually lose patience
experiment proper. Students who declined the invita-
with an uncooperative other. We thus expect that a delay
tion, or who did not show up for a scheduled session,
in reciprocation of cooperation will lead to lower rates of
were replaced by randomly selected others from the mas-
cooperation than immediate reciprocation but only in
ter list.
the latter stages of the dilemma.
The social values assessment instrument used was the
Summary of Hypotheses shortened Decomposed Game (DG) measure devised by
van Lange and Kuhlman (1994) and based on a longer
We expect to observe the following patterns of
form created by Messick and McClintock (1968). This
choices:
measure requires participants to imagine that they and a
Hypothesis 1: Competitors will cooperate more frequently randomly selected, anonymous other person will be allo-
when retaliation for a noncooperative (“B”) response is cating points to themselves and each other. Participants
delayed rather than immediate. are presented with sets of three choice options (an exam-
Hypothesis 2: Individualists will cooperate most frequently
ple of which is shown in Figure 2), with each option pre-
when reciprocation of both cooperation and senting one particular allocation of points to self and
noncooperation is immediate. A delay in either or both other, and are instructed to select which of the three
will lead to decreased rates of cooperative choice. options they most prefer. One of the options represents
Hypothesis 3: Prosocials initially will be unaffected by any de- the “maximize joint gain” motive (in Figure 2, this is
lays in reciprocation, but in the later stages of the di- Option B), a second the “maximize personal gain”
lemma they will cooperate more frequently when motive (Option C), and the third the “maximize relative
reciprocation of a cooperative choice is immediate gain” motive (Option A). Nine such sets are presented.
rather than delayed. The questionnaire is scored by tallying how many times
each motive is selected, and a value orientation is
METHOD assigned if the respondent selects the same motive at
least six times. Thus, a prosocial is someone who chose
Participants
the joint-gain option at least six times, an individualist
The participants were 240 undergraduates enrolled will have chosen the personal-gain option at least six
in introductory psychology courses. Participation was in times, and a competitor will have chosen the relative-
partial fulfillment of a course requirement. gain option at least six times. The DG measure was
Parks, Rumble / RECIPROCITY AND SOCIAL VALUES 1305

announce when they were to make their choices and


when they were to return their switches to the “OFF”
A B C
position.
The game then began, and the experimental manipu-
You get 500 500 550
lations were implemented at this point. Although partic-
ipants were led to believe that their opponent would be
Other gets 100 500 300
another participant, in truth all participants competed
against one of the eight programmed strategies that
Figure 2 Sample social value orientation questionnaire item. resulted from the combination of the independent vari-
ables. The lags were implemented following the proce-
dure used by Komorita et al. (1991). If Lag-A was equal
selected because it seems to be an effective technique for to 1, a participant’s A-choice was reciprocated on the
measuring value orientation. Liebrand and Van Run next trial, and if it was equal to 2, the participant’s A-
(1985) administered four different DG forms and choice was reciprocated two trials later. The same rules
obtained a mean Spearman-Brown reliability of .93. applied to the Lag-B variable and a participant’s B-
Parks (1994) found it to be unrelated to a measure of choice. Particular choice patterns by participants could
interpersonal trust. Finally, Eisenberger, Kuhlman, and produce conflict between the lags. To address this possi-
Cotterell (1992) found the DG to be predictive of behav- bility, we established the following priorities: (a) The
ior that was observed up to 6 weeks after administration programmed opponent chose “A” on the second trial in
of the questionnaire. all conditions except (Lag–A = 1, Lag–B = 1), which is the
Participants were scheduled in groups of 4 After Tit-for-tat condition; (b) a repeated choice was always
entering the lab, each person was seated in a cubicle that immediately reciprocated; and (c) when there was a con-
contained the pay-off matrix shown in Figure 1 and a flict between a one-trial lag and a two-trial lag, the one-
tripole switchbox labeled “A,” “B,” and “OFF.” After all trial lag was followed. Each of these priorities follows
participants were seated, the nature of the game was those used by Komorita et al. (1991).
explained. Participants were told that they and an After the 20th trial, the experimenter announced that
unidentified other participant, with whom they would the game was over. A short questionnaire, assessing indi-
have no contact, would be working together to earn vidual perceptions of the game, was distributed. After a
points for themselves. Each person would choose either participant had finished the questionnaire, he or she was
“A” (the cooperative choice, although it was not given a debriefing sheet, which included a thorough dis-
described as such to participants) or “B” (the competi- cussion of the deception, and was dismissed. The master
tive choice) on each of a series of trials (20, although the list from the mass testing session was used to contact lot-
actual number was left unspecified). The combination tery winners and was then destroyed.
of the participant’s choice and other’s choice would
determine how many points each person received. Sev- RESULTS
eral examples of how to read the matrix were given at Choices were divided into four blocks of five trials
this point. Participants were told that at the end of every each. Within each block, rate of cooperation (propor-
trial, each person would receive a slip of paper identify- tion of cooperative choices) was calculated for each par-
ing the participant’s choice, the choice of the other per- ticipant by dividing the total number of cooperative
son, and the participant’s pay-off. Every 10 points accu- (“A”) choices within that block by five total trials. These
mulated by a participant earned one ticket in a $50 cash block rates served as the dependent variable.1 The data
lottery to be conducted at the end of the experiment. were analyzed with a 2 (niceness)´ 2 (Lag-A) ´ 2 (Lag-B)
Next, it was explained that choices would be made by ´ 3 (social value) ´ 4 (block) ANOVA, with repeated
using the switchboxes. Moving the switch either up (to measures on the last factor.2 The Type I error rate was set
make an “A” choice) or down (“B” choice) would illumi- at a = .05. No effects of niceness were found; neither the
nate a light on a central control panel seen only by the main effect nor any interactions involving niceness was
experimenter. Moving the switch to the center “OFF” significant. To simplify the analyses, we collapsed across
position turned off all lights. To demonstrate, partici- niceness and reanalyzed the data with a 2 ´ 2 ´ 3 ´ 4
pants were asked to move the switch to one position or repeated-measures ANOVA.
the other, and the experimenter gave them written feed- We obtained significant main effects for Lag-A, value
back indicating which choice they had made. Partici- orientation, and block. Also, 2 three-way interactions
pants were told that, at the end of every trial, their were significant: Orientation ´ Lag-A ´ Block and Orien-
switches needed to be moved to the “OFF” position to tation ´ Lag-A ´ Lag-B. Tukey’s honestly significant dif-
clear the control panel. The experimenter would ference (HSD) post hoc analyses were conducted on the
1306 PERSONALITY AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY BULLETIN

TABLE 1: F Ratios and Effect Sizes for All Significant Effects TABLE 2: Mean Rates of Cooperation and Standard Deviations for
2
Lag-A by Lag-B Across Different Types of Value Orientation
Effect df F p<
Lag-B
Lag-A 1,227 44.94 .01 .17 One Trial Two Trials
Orientation 2,227 60.89 .01 .35
Block 3,681 27.88 .01 .13 Value Lag-A M (SD) M (SD) Grand M
Orientation ´ Lag-A ´ Lag-B 2,227 3.77 .05 .03
Orientation ´ Lag-A ´ Block 6,681 3.58 .05 .05 Prosocial One trial .62a (.15) .62a (.22) .62 (.18)
Two trials .47b (.12) .44b (.17) .46 (.15)
NOTE: a = .05. Mean .55 (.15) .53 (.21) .54 (.18)
Competitor One trial .25b (.08) .44a (.12) .35 (.14)
Two trials .09c (.07) .34a,b (.13) .22 (.17)
Mean .17 (.11) .39 (.14) .28 (.17)
means associated with all of the significant effects;3 the Individualist One trial .61a (.15) .28b (.19) .45 (.24)
between-participants MSE was .022, and the within- Two trials .41b (.16) .31b (.14) .36 (.16)
participants MSE was .068. The F ratios and effect sizes Mean .51 (.18) .29 (.16) .40 (.21)
are in Table 1. We shall discuss the main effects first. The
NOTE: Within each level of value, means with differing subscripts are
block main effect shows that cooperation declined over significantly different from one another. For each grand mean, each
time (M = .48, .37, .39, and .38; SD = .24, .25, .25, and .26, value is significantly different from the other value(s).
respectively), a relatively common pattern in prisoner’s
dilemma research (cf. Komorita & Parks, 1996). The
cooperation was delayed (Lag 2), all three value orienta-
decline is significant only between the first and second
tions showed declines in cooperation, with individualists
blocks, after which rate of cooperation stabilizes. The
declining at a slower rate than the other two. The
Lag-A main effect shows that cooperation was more fre-
response patterns for prosocials support our third
quent when it was reciprocated on the next trial (M = .47,
hypothesis.
SD = .22) rather than two trials later (M = .34, SD = .19).
This replicates the finding of Komorita et al. (1991). The
value orientation main effect shows that prosocials were DISCUSSION
more cooperative (M = .54, SD = .18) than individualists The goal of this study was to demonstrate that differ-
(M = .40, SD = .21), who in turn were more cooperative ent aspects of the Tit-for-tat strategy have differential
than competitors (M = .28, SD = .17). This is as expected. effects on rate of cooperation, depending on the target’s
Note that the failure to obtain a main effect for Lag-B is social value orientation. As predicted, we found that
consistent with Komorita et al. (1991). They found delay (a) cooperation is best induced in competitors by delay-
of retaliation to have some effect on the rate of repeti- ing retaliation for a noncooperative choice, (b) individu-
tion of competitive choice, but it had no overall effect on alists are most cooperative when both cooperative and
rate of cooperation. noncooperative choices are immediately reciprocated,
The Orientation ´ Lag-A ´ Lag-B interaction speaks and (c) prosocials eventually respond to delayed recip-
directly to our second hypothesis. Cell means are shown rocation of cooperation by decreasing their own rates of
in Table 2, where differing subscripts identify means that cooperative choice. Thus, the results extend the previ-
differ significantly. We predicted that individualists ous work of Komorita and colleagues on the basic prop-
would cooperate most frequently when both cooperative erties of Tit-for-tat, as well as recent work by van Lange
and noncooperative choices were immediately recipro- and Visser (1999) on how individuals with different
cated and that competitors would cooperate most fre- value orientations respond to Tit-for-tat.
quently when response to “B” was delayed by two trials In addition to the support for our hypotheses, we
rather than one. Both predictions are supported by our observed some other, unanticipated results. First,
data. In addition, these means reveal that prosocials prosocials had higher rates of cooperation when recipro-
cooperated more frequently when reciprocation of an cation of a cooperative choice was immediate rather
“A” choice was immediate rather than delayed; this was than delayed. This effect can largely be attributed to the
an unexpected pattern. fact that by the second block of trials, behavioral assimi-
The cell means for the Orientation ´ Lag-A ´ Block lation was already occurring. This is an important find-
effect are plotted in Figure 3. It can be seen that when ing, because it indicates that prosocials will not long tol-
cooperative choice was immediately reciprocated (Lag 1), erate exploitation. Komorita and Parks (1999) argued
prosocials maintained a constant rate of cooperation that knowing to what extent exploitation is tolerated can
over time, competitors increased their frequency of help shed light on the limitations of reciprocity as a strat-
cooperation, and individualists demonstrated a slow, egy for inducing cooperation, especially in larger
irregular decline; in addition, when reciprocation of groups. Our data indicate that even among those most
Parks, Rumble / RECIPROCITY AND SOCIAL VALUES 1307

Lag 1 need to be handled very carefully if one is trying to


0.8 induce them to cooperate. Basically, one needs to imme-
diately reciprocate their cooperative overtures and be
0.7 somewhat tolerant of noncooperative choice. This rec-
ommendation is sensible from the perspective of trying
Frequency of cooperation

0.6
to demonstrate to the competitor that one is trustworthy
and truly interested in cooperation. If one followed this
0.5
modified version of Tit-for-tat, one would begin with a
Prosocial cooperative choice; immediately respond to cooperative
0.4 Competitor
Individualist
choice with cooperation; retaliate only after the other
0.3
person had made a series of noncooperative choices;
and never unilaterally switch from cooperation to
0.2
noncooperation. This would create a friendly environ-
ment that should encourage competitively oriented oth-
0.1 ers to be more cooperative. This is consistent with Parks
and Komorita’s (1998) argument that a delay in retalia-
0
1 2 3 4
tion for a noncooperative choice—at least in a situation
Block in which all group members realize equal pay-offs—gives
the impression that one wants to be cooperative.
Finally, individualists showed slow declines in rate of
cooperation, regardless of whether reciprocation of
Lag 2
0.7
cooperation was immediate or delayed, although the
decline under immediate reciprocation was irregular.
This irregularity can perhaps be explained as the individ-
0.6
ualist’s “testing the waters” to determine to what extent
exploitation is possible. During the first block of trials,
0.5
both the individualist and the reciprocal other were fre-
Frequency of cooperation

quently cooperative. The individualist then significantly


0.4
decreased cooperation during the second block, possi-
Prosocial
Competitor
Individualist
bly to see if the cooperative other could be exploited.
0.3 When he or she saw that consistent exploitation was not
possible, the individualist began moving back toward
0.2 mutual cooperation. Presumably, if we had collected
data beyond 20 trials, the individualist’s rate of coopera-
0.1 tion might have returned to that of the first block and
perhaps even exceeded that rate. The fact that a one-trial
0
delay in responding to cooperative choice produced a
1 2 3 4
consistent rate of cooperation in individualists is inter-
Block
esting, although perhaps illusory. Participants in this
Figure 3 Mean rates of cooperation for Lag-A by orientation, across condition had decreased their rates of cooperation by
four trial blocks.
10% from the first to fourth blocks, and more trials may
have eventually produced a significant decline.
inclined to be cooperative, willingness to be exploited
for eventual, greater gain is limited. This suggests that GENERAL DISCUSSION
even when working with prosocials, one must quickly In addition to extending our understanding of how
establish a reputation for being cooperative and Tit-for-tat works, our data also suggest an explanation for
nonexploitative. inconsistencies between the findings of Komorita et al.
Next, we found that competitors are sensitive to a (1991) and Bixenstine and Gaebelein (1971), as well as
delay in response to cooperation. Rate of cooperation inconsistencies within the Komorita et al. (1991) article.
generally increased over time when reciprocation was Bixenstine and Gaebelein found rate of cooperation to
immediate and declined over time when it was delayed. be greatest when reciprocation of both cooperation and
Combined with our finding that retaliation for noncooperation were delayed (.71), but Komorita et al.
noncooperation should be delayed when interacting (1991) found a delay-delay combination to inhibit coop-
with competitors, the data indicate that competitors eration (.28). It is possible that this discrepancy is attrib-
1308 PERSONALITY AND SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY BULLETIN

utable to different distributions of value orientations known that reciprocation in general becomes less effec-
within the two participant samples. For example, tive as group size increases (Komorita et al., 1992), and
Komorita et al. (1991) may have had an inordinate num- the inclusion of value orientation adds complexity,
ber of individualists within their sample, who would have because the larger group will contain a range of value
reacted to a global delay in reciprocation by being unco- orientations. We have earlier demonstrated that, in the-
operative. Note that our overall rate of cooperation in ory, a basic Tit-for-tat strategy can be modified to be
the delay-delay condition (.36) is more similar to applicable to large groups (Parks & Komorita, 1997), but
Komorita et al. (1991) than to Bixenstine and our model does not address delay of reciprocation.
Gaebelein, suggesting that the latter’s reported rate may Extension of this article’s results to large-scale groups
have been unusually high. first requires an investigation of how delays in reciproca-
We noted earlier that the data suggest a very particu- tion of choices affect widespread cooperation in such
lar way in which to interact with competitors if one is try- groups. Regarding dilemma type, with occasional excep-
ing to induce cooperation. In effect, one is trying to in- tions (Komorita et al., 1991; Kramer, McClintock, &
directly communicate the value of cooperation as well as Messick, 1986; Parks, 1994), researchers have not investi-
one’s willingness to be cooperative. This is consistent gated how either value orientation or reciprocity influ-
with goal/expectation theory (Pruitt & Kimmel, 1977), ences choice in more general social dilemmas such as
which states that prosocials possess the goal of mutual resource dilemmas and public goods. Given the preva-
cooperation and the expectation that others will be simi- lence of these types of dilemmas in society, and given the
larly cooperative. If others act noncooperatively, the evidence for both social values and reciprocity as influ-
prosocial will eventually retreat into a “defensive” mode ences on behavior, this lack of research is surprising. The
and become noncooperative. Thus, the prosocial has study of reciprocity in other types of dilemmas would be
faith in others but also needs evidence that this faith is intertwined with the group size issue, because public
warranted. Competitors have neither the goal of cooper- goods and resource dilemmas almost always involve
ation nor the belief that others will cooperate and need more than two people, but the role of value orientation
to develop both to become cooperative. Our data sug- could be addressed in a straightforward manner. Both
gest that this information can be transmitted through a Kramer et al. (1986) and Parks (1994) found value orien-
specific set of actions. However, it is also possible to com- tation to be predictive of harvesting behavior, and Parks
municate this information through the sharing of state- (1994) also showed that it was unrelated to public good
ments of intended behavior, which are known to influ- contribution. However, these two studies raised many
ence the choices of others (Chen, 1996; Parks et al., additional questions that have yet to be answered. In
1996). Both goal/expectation theory and our data imply conclusion, our data extend our understanding of how
that people with different value orientations will react to reciprocity works, as well as the limits of a reciprocal
different types of information in such statements. Spe- approach. We have seen that simply applying a Tit-for-tat
cifically, it should be the case that prosocials need only to strategy in any interdependent situation, irrespective of
be told that others intend to be cooperative to induce the distribution of value orientations within the group,
them to cooperate, whereas competitors need this infor- may or may not lead to long-term mutual cooperation.
mation and need to be taught why mutual cooperation is Instead, one needs to ascertain the orientations within
beneficial. the group and then tailor one’s choice strategy
Our hypotheses were derived from the experience- accordingly.
weighted attraction-learning model (Camerer & Ho,
1998, 1999), which offers an explanation for why a per- NOTES
son might alter his or her choice strategy over time.
1. Proportional data are susceptible to variance deflation problems
Although our data were consistent with the predictions resulting from the squaring of decimal data, producing an inflated
of that model, we cannot say for certain that expecta- Type I error rate. To check for this, arcsine transformations of the data
tions were violated or that participants were engaging in were also analyzed. The results were the same as those obtained from
the raw data, indicating that none of the significant findings were
mental simulations of alternate courses of action. For- attributable to variance deflation. For ease of explanation, we report
mal tests of these propositions would help us better the original raw results.
understand the processes by which choices are made in 2. During data entry, it was discovered that a programmed strategy
had been incorrectly applied to one participant, an individualist in the
multitrial, mixed-motive interactions, an understanding (not nice, 2-trial Lag-A, 2-trial Lag-B) condition. This person was dis-
that is currently very limited (Messick & Liebrand, carded from the data set.
1995). 3. A test for homogeneity of variance indicates consistency of vari-
ance across cells of the design, making Tukey’s honestly significant dif-
Finally, it should be noted that our conclusions apply ference (HSD) an appropriate post hoc test. Because we had to discard
only to dyadic, prisoner’s dilemma–type situations. It is one participant, producing unequal cell counts, the general form of
Parks, Rumble / RECIPROCITY AND SOCIAL VALUES 1309

the Tukey procedure was used, which can accommodate unequal ns. Kramer, R. M., McClintock, C. G., & Messick, D. M. (1986). Social val-
This involves calculating the value ues and cooperative response to a simulated resource crisis. Jour-
2 nal of Personality, 54, 576-591.
n g n h Yg Yh Liebrand, W.B.G., & Van Run, G. J. (1985). The effects of social
F (1), motives on behavior in social dilemmas in two cultures. Journal of
ng n h MSE Experimental Social Psychology, 21, 86-102.
Maxwell, S. E., & Delaney, H. D. (1990). Designing experiments and ana-
for each pair of means and then comparing F against the critical value lyzing data. Pacific Grove, CA: Brooks/Cole.
2
q /2. Any pair of means for which F exceeds the critical value are sig- Messick, D. M., & Liebrand, W.B.G. (1995). Individual heuristics and
nificantly different from one another (see Maxwell & Delaney, 1990, the dynamics of cooperation in large groups. Psychological Review,
pp. 184-185, for more information). 102, 131-145.
Messick, D. M., & McClintock, C. G. (1968). Motivational basis of
choice in experimental games. Journal of Experimental Social Psy-
REFERENCES chology, 4, 1-25.
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books. Parks, C. D. (1994). The predictive ability of social values in resource
Bixenstine, V. E., & Gaebelein, J. W. (1971). Strategies of “real” oppo- dilemmas and public goods games. Personality and Social Psychology
nents in eliciting cooperative choice in a prisoner’s dilemma Bulletin, 20, 431-438.
game. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 15, 157-166. Parks, C. D., Henager, R. F., & Scamahorn, S. D. (1996). Trust and
Braver, S. L., & Barnett, B. (1976). Effects of modeling on coopera- reactions to messages of intent in social dilemmas. Journal of Con-
tion in a prisoner’s dilemma game. Journal of Personality and Social flict Resolution, 40, 134-151.
Psychology, 33, 161-169. Parks, C. D., & Komorita, S. S. (1997). Reciprocal strategies for large
Camerer, C., & Ho, T. H. (1998). Experience-weighted attraction groups. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 1, 314-322.
learning in coordination games: Probability rules, heterogeneity, Parks, C. D., & Komorita, S. S. (1998). Reciprocity research and its
and time-variation. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42, 305-326. implications for the negotiation process. International Negotiation,
Camerer, C., & Ho, T. H. (1999). Experience-weighted attraction learn- 3, 151-169.
ing in games: Estimates from weak-link games. In D. V. Budescu, Parks, C. D., & Vu, A. D. (1994). Social dilemma behavior of individu-
I. Erev, & R. Zwick (Eds.), Games and human behavior (pp. 31-51). als from highly individualist and collectivist cultures. Journal of
Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum. Conflict Resolution, 38, 708-718.
Chen, X. P. (1996). The group-based binding pledge as a solution to Patchen, M. (1987). Strategies for eliciting cooperation from an
public goods problems. Organizational Behavior and Human Deci- adversary: Laboratory and internation findings. Journal of Conflict
sion Processes, 66, 192-202.P Resolution, 31, 164-185.
de Dreu, C.K.W., & van Lange, P.A.M. (1995). The impact of social Pruitt, D. G., & Kimmel, M. M. (1977). Twenty years of experimental
value orientations on negotiator cognition and behavior. Personal- gaming: Critique, synthesis, and suggestions for the future.
ity and Social Psychology Bulletin, 21, 1178-1188. Annual Review of Psychology, 28, 363-392.
de Hues, P. (2000). Do reciprocal strategies work in social dilemmas? Sheldon, K. M. (1999). Learning the lessons of Tit-for-tat: Even com-
Personality and Social Psychology Review, 4, 278-288. petitors can get the message. Journal of Personality and Social Psychol-
Eisenberger, R., Kuhlman, D. M., & Cotterell, N. (1992). Effects of ogy, 77, 1245-1253.
social values, effort training, and goal structure on task persis- van Lange, P.A.M. (1999). The pursuit of joint outcomes and equality
tence. Journal of Research in Personality, 26, 258-272. in outcomes: An integrative model of social value orientation.
Joireman, J. A., van Lange, P.A.M., Kuhlman, D. M., van Vugt, M., & Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77, 337-349.
Shelley, G. P. (1997). An interdependence analysis of commuting van Lange, P.A.M., Agnew, C. R., Harinck, F., & Steemers, G.E.M.
decisions. European Journal of Social Psychology, 27, 441-463. (1997). From game theory to real life: How social value orienta-
Kelley, H. H., & Stahelski, A. J. (1970). Social interaction basis of tion affects willingness to sacrifice in ongoing close relationships.
prosocials’ and competitors’ beliefs about others. Journal of Person- Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 73, 1330-1344.
ality and Social Psychology, 16, 66-91. van Lange, P.A.M., & Kuhlman, D. M. (1994). Social value orientation
Komorita, S. S., Chan, D.K.S., & Parks, C. D. (1993). The effects of and impressions of partner’s honesty and intelligence: A test of
reward structure and reciprocity in social dilemmas. Journal of the might versus morality effect. Journal of Personality and Social Psy-
Experimental Social Psychology, 29, 252-267. chology, 67, 126-141.
Komorita, S. S., Hilty, J. A., & Parks, C. D. (1991). Reciprocity and van Lange, P.A.M., Otten, W., de Bruin, E.M.N., & Joireman, J. A.
cooperation in social dilemmas. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 35, (1997). Development of prosocial, individualistic, and competi-
494-518. tive orientations: Theory and preliminary evidence. Journal of Per-
Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1995). Interpersonal relations: Mixed- sonality and Social Psychology, 73, 733-746.
motive interaction. Annual Review of Psychology, 46, 183-207. van Lange, P.A.M., & Semin-Goossens, A. (1998). The boundaries of
Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1996). Social dilemmas. Boulder, CO: reciprocal cooperation. European Journal of Social Psychology, 28,
Westview. 847-854.
Komorita, S. S., & Parks, C. D. (1999). Reciprocity and cooperation in van Lange, P.A.M., van Vugt, M., Meertens, R. M., & Rutter, R.A.C.
social dilemmas: Review and future directions. In D. V. Budescu, (1998). A social dilemma analysis of commuting preferences: The
I. Erev, & R. Zwick (Eds.), Games and human behavior (pp. 315-330). roles of social value orientation and trust. Journal of Applied Social
Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum. Psychology, 28, 796-820.
Komorita, S. S., Parks, C. D., & Hulbert, L. G. (1992). Reciprocity and van Lange, P.A.M., & Visser, K. (1999). Locomotion in social dilem-
the induction of cooperation in social dilemmas. Journal of Person- mas: How we adapt to cooperative, Tit-for-tat, and noncooperative
ality and Social Psychology, 62, 607-617. partners. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77, 762-773.
Kraines, D., & Kraines, V. (1993). Learning to cope with Pavlov: An
adaptive strategy for the prisoner’s dilemma with noise. Theory and Received January 3, 2000
Decision, 35, 107-150. Revision accepted October 11, 2000

You might also like