You are on page 1of 535

“In a period in which American public life in the United States is a complex

and often bewildering subject, Nicholas Henry brings diamond-like clarity,


thorough scholarship, fascinating examples, current data, and entertaining
illustrations to the subject. The reader and the nation are better off for it.”
– James D. Carroll, former Program Director,
The Brookings Institution, USA

“This latest edition of a classic textbook retains the principles and practical
guidance needed by today’s students and administrators, and adds the latest
trends and insights required to confront effectively and efficiently the chal-
lenges of our rapidly changing social and political environment.”
– Naomi B. Lynn, University of Illinois at Springfield, USA
Public Administration and
Public Affairs

Public Administration and Public Affairs demonstrates how to govern effi-


ciently, effectively, and responsibly in an age of political corruption and
crises in public finance. Providing a comprehensive, accessible, and humor-
ous introduction to the field of Public Administration, this text is designed
specifically for those with little to no background in the field. Now in its 13th
edition, this beloved book includes:
■ Engaging, timely new sections designed to make students think, such as
“Why Are So Many Leaders Losers?” and “Even Terrorists Like Good
Government”
■ Comparisons throughout of the challenges and opportunities found
in the nonprofit sector vs. the public sector (sections such as “The
Dissatisfied Bureaucrat, the Satisfied Nonprofit Professional?”)
■ Extensive new material on e-governance, performance management,
HRM, intersectoral and intergovernmental administration, government
contracting, public budgeting, and ethics.
The 13th edition is complete with an Instructor’s Manual, Testbank, and
PowerPoint slides for instructors, as well as Learning Objectives and Self-test
Questions for students, making it the ideal primer for public administration/
management, public affairs, and nonprofit management courses.

Nicholas Henry is Professor Emeritus of Public Administration and President


Emeritus at Georgia Southern University, USA.
Public Administration and
Public Affairs
Thirteenth Edition

NICHOLAS HENRY
Georgia Southern University
Thirteenth edition published 2018
by Routledge
711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017

and by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN

Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business

© 2018 Taylor & Francis

The right of Nicholas Henry to be identified as author of this work has been asserted by him in
accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.

All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form
or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including
photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without
permission in writing from the publishers.

Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks,


and are used only for identification and explanation without intent to infringe.

First edition published by Prentice-Hall 1975


Twelfth edition published by Routledge 2016

Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data


Names: Henry, Nicholas, 1943– author.
Title: Public administration and public affairs / by Nicholas Henry.
Description: Thirteenth edition. | New York : Routledge, 2017. | Includes bibliographical
references and index.
Identifiers: LCCN 2017014970| ISBN 9781138693500 (hardback : alk. paper) |
ISBN 9781138693524 (pbk. : alk. paper) | ISBN 9781315530536 (ebook)
Subjects: LCSH: Public administration.
Classification: LCC JF1351 .H45 2017 | DDC 351.73--dc23
LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2017014970

ISBN: 978-1-138-69350-0 (hbk)


ISBN: 978-1-138-69352-4 (pbk)
ISBN: 978-1-315-53053-6 (ebk)

Typeset in Sabon and Bell


by Servis Filmsetting Ltd, Stockport, Cheshire

Visit the eResource: www.routledge.com/9781138693524


CONTENTS

Preface to the Thirteenth Edition xviii


Acknowledgments xx

Part I In Defense of Governing Well 1

Chapter 1 Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 10


Chapter 2 Paradigms of Public Administration 35

Part II Public and Nonprofit Organizations 55

Chapter 3 The Threads of Organizations: Theories 56


Chapter 4 The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 78
Chapter 5 The Fibers of Organizations: People 113

Part III Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 143

Chapter 6 Clarifying Complexity: The Public’s Information Resource 156


Chapter 7 The Constant Quest: Efficient and Effective Governance 192
Chapter 8 The Public Trough: Financing and Budgeting Governments 232
Chapter 9 Managing Human Capital in the Public and Nonprofit Sectors 294

Part IV Implementing Public Policy 379

Chapter 10 Understanding and Improving Public Policy 381


Chapter 11 Intersectoral Administration 397
Chapter 12 Intergovernmental Administration 460
Chapter 13 Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 500

Index 512
D E TA I L E D TA B L E O F C O N T E N T S

Preface to the Thirteenth Edition xviii The Consequences of Constraint 13


Hobbled Elected Chief Executives 13
Acknowledgments xx
Hobbled Governments 16
Hobbled Governmental Growth 16
PART I In Defense of Governing
The Bureaucrat: Brained, Blamed, and Bouncing
Well 1 Back 17
Do We Need Government? 1 Bashing Bureaucrats 17
The Wrecking-Crew View 1 Are Bureaucrats to Blame? 18
Wrecking Government and Wrecking The Bureaucrat: Government’s Savior? 19
America 1 A Paradoxical Power: The Gray Eminence of the
Is Graft Good? 3 Public Administrator 19
Fighting for Fraud: Corruption Improves Staying Power 19
Public Services 4 Discretionary Power 20
Fighting for Fraud: Corruption Brings Policymaking Power 20
Prosperity 4
Stopping Power 22
Fighting Fraud: The Many Reasons to Do So 4
The Contest for Control 23
A Globally Fading Philosophy 5 Presidents versus Bureaucrats: Mobilizing
What Is Good Government? 6 the Bureaucracy 23
Good Government Is Uncorrupted 6 Governors versus Legislators: The Battle for
Good Government Is Democratic 6 the Bureaucracy 24
Good Government Is Able 6 Managers and the Control of Local
Government 25
The Place of Public Administration 6
Knowledge: The Base of Bureaucratic Power 25
Notes 7
Knowledge Is Power 25
Knowledge, Power, and the Public
CHAPTER 1 Interest 26
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 10 Notes 26
An Unpromising Precis 10
The Indians and the English 10
Administration by Ambassadors: CHAPTER 2
The Articles of Confederation 10
Paradigms of Public Administration 35
Administration by Legislators:
The First State Constitutions 11 The Beginning 35
Administration by Enfeebled Executives: Think Tanks for Public Service 35
Jefferson Prevails 11 Public Administration and the Intellectuals:
A Culture of Constraint 12 The Fortuitous Year of 1914 35
Americans and Their Governments 12 Paradigm 1: The Politics/Administration Dichotomy,
Governing in a Distrusting Culture 12 1900–1926 36
DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS ix

The Uses of the Dichotomy 36 Does Governance Work? 47


The Dilemma of the Dichotomy 36 Public Administration, Happy at Last 48
Paradigm 2: Principles of Public Administration, Notes 48
1927–1937 37
A Reputational Zenith 37
The Meaning of Principles 37 PART II Public and Nonprofit
What the Pioneers of Public Administration Got Organizations 55
Right 38
Professional Public Administration Improves CHAPTER 3
Governing 38
The City or County Manager Improves The Threads of Organizations: Theories 56
Governing 38
The Closed Model of Organizations 56
The Council-Manager Form of Government
Improves Governing 38 Characteristics of the Closed Model
of Organizations 56
The Challenge, 1938–1950 39 Bureaucratic Theory 57
Deflating the Dichotomy 39 Scientific Management 57
Puncturing the Principles 40 Administrative Management 58
The Wreckage and Its Reactions 40 The Open Model of Organizations 59
Paradigm 3: Public Administration as Political Characteristics of the Open Model
Science, 1950–1970 41 of Organizations 59
Consternation and Contempt 41 Human Relations 60
The Impact of Political Science: Bureaucracy Organization Development 65
in the Service of Democracy 41 The Organization as a Unit in Its
Paradigm 4: Public Administration as Environment 66
Management, 1950–1970 42 The Closed and Open Models: The Essential
The “Groundswell” of Management 42 Differences 67
“Fundamentally Alike in All Unimportant Assumptions about the Organization’s
Respects” 42 Environment 67
The Impact of Management: Understanding Assumptions about the Human Condition 68
the “Public” in Public Administration 43 Assumptions about the Role and Legitimacy
Evaporation Averted, 1965–1975 44 of Organizational Power 68
The Forces of Separatism 44 Assumptions about Manipulating Members
of Organizations 69
Saving a Field 44
Assumptions about the Moral Significance
Paradigm 5: Public Administration as Public of Organizations in Society 70
Administration, 1990–Present 44
Conjoining Opposites: The Drive to Reduce
NASPAA’s Nascency 45 Uncertainty 71
The Statistics of Secession and Success 45 Uncertainty Reduction: Reconciling the Open
From Politics/Administration Dichotomy to and the Closed 71
Political–Administrative Continuum 45 Responding to Organizational Uncertainty 71
Logics: Politics and Administration 46
Are Public and Nonprofit Organizations
Paradigm 6: Governance, 1990–Present 47 Different? 72
“Making a Mesh of Things”: The Rise of Notes 73
Governance 47
x DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS

CHAPTER 4 The Cesspool Syndrome: How Independent


Organizations Die 100
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 78
Defying Death in the Independent Sector 101
Organizational Knowledge 78 Notes 101
Information and Hierarchy 78
Organizational Knowledge and Strategic
Decision Making 79 CHAPTER 5
Strategic Decision Making in Organizations 80 The Fibers of Organizations: People 113
The Bounds of Individual Rationality 80 Why Work for the People? 113
The Bounds of Organizational Rationality 82 The Draw of the Public Sector 113
Bounded Rationality and the Implementation The Draw of the Independent Sector 114
of Strategic Decisions 84
The Behavioral Bureaucrat 115
Decision Making in Public Organizations:
A Different Dynamic 85 “Administrative Man” 115
Decision Making in Nonprofit Organizations: “The Bureaucratic Personality” and “The
More Talk, Fights, Risk 88 Unbureaucratic Personality” 115
A Monumental Map Mess in Georgia 88 The Energetic, Committed Bureaucrat 115
Administration in Organizations 89 The Dissatisfied Bureaucrat, the Satisfied
Nonprofit Professional? 116
The Power of Subordinates 89
A Management Challenge 117
The Powers of Administrators 90
Growing into the Organization 117
The Mechanisms of Administrative
Control 90 Born to Conserve or Born to Rebel? 117
Administration in Public Organizations: Life’s Turning Points 118
A Different Dynamic 90 Turning Points and the Organization 118
Limited Change: The Impact of Technology and National Culture and the Organization 119
People on the Public Organization 91 Dimensions of National Culture 119
The Likely Limited Role of Technology 91 Patterns of Geography and Language 120
People Changing Their Public National Culture and Organizational
Organization 92 Behavior 120
Unlimited Change: The Impact of the Environment Getting Ahead 120
on the Public Organization 93 Organizational Politics 121
Change in Public Organizations: Politics, Institutionalists: Loyal and Lethargic 121
Pressures, and Prohibitions 93
Specialists: Professional and
Ordering Agency Openness 93 Maladjusted 121
The Osmotic Impact of the Agency’s Institutionalists, Specialists, and
Environment 95 Organizational Innovation 122
La Bureaucratie 95 Hybrids: Political and Unpredictable 122
Hierarchy and Government 96 What Is Leadership? 122
Red Tape and Government 97 The Leadership Literature 122
You Can Lead a Bureaucracy to Slaughter, but Leadership or Administration? 123
You Can’t Make It Shrink 99
Are Leaders Needed? 123
Administrative Autonomy and the Performance
of Public Organizations 100 Learning Leadership: The Evolution of a
The Impact of the Environment on the Independent Theory 125
Organization 100 The Leader: Alone and Glorious, 1900–
1930 125
DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS xi

The Leader in the Grip of the Group, Prosecuting Corruption: The Crucial Federal
1930–1970 125 Role 150
Culture and Charisma: The Leader and the Big Graft: Deep, Systemic, and Legal 150
Organization, 1970–Present 126
From Anticorruption to Efficiency: The Morphing
Leading Public and Nonprofit Organizations 128 of Public Management 151
Leadership at the Top 128 Notes 152
Sector and Successful Leadership 129
Why Are So Many Leaders Losers? 130
CHAPTER 6
Mostly Male 131
Clarifying Complexity: The Public’s
“The Psycho-Path to Disaster” 131
Information Resource 156
Race and the Unconscious 131
Hey, Good Lookin’! Whatcha Got Cookin’? Data for Public Administrators 156
Money and Bias, of Course 131 The Data Deluge 156
Swoon Song 132 Focusing and Narrowing Decision
The Public Perspective 132 Options 157
Notes 132 Knowledge Management: Managing the Public’s
Information Resource 158
Uniquely Governmental: Complexity and
PART III Public and Nonprofit Immensity 158
Management: Curbing Corruption, Managing the Nation’s Knowledge 160
Enhancing Efficiency 143 Subnational Knowledge Management 164
Corruption’s Causes and Continuance: The Larger Best Practices for Knowledge
Management 166
Picture 143
Corruption’s Causes 143 Privacy versus Policy: The Particular Problem of
the Public Computer 166
Corruption’s Continuance 144
Stealing You: Identity Theft 166
Comprehending Corruption in America 144
Protecting Privacy: Federal Efforts 167
Tradition! Good Old Graft 144
Protecting Privacy at the Grass Roots 168
Corruption as Conquest: Janitorial Joys 145
Cybercrime 168
Corruption as Culture: Murder and
Mortification 145 Hacking: Harrowing and Humiliating 169
Fraud in the Independent Sector 146 Cyberspying: Sinister and Slippery 170
The Evolution of American Graft 147 Cybersecurity 171
Graft Parties On, 1900–1940 147 Federal Cyber In-Security 171
Graft as a Nuisance, 1940–1970 147 Cybersecurity in the States 173
Our New and Messy Meaning of Corruption, Additional Actions Needed for Attacking
1970–Present 147 Hacking 173
Confronting Corruption in America 148 E-Gov: Lean, Seen, and Clean Government 174
Perceptions of American Corruption 148 Federal.gov 174
The Extent of Fraud 148 State.gov 174
Inhibiting American Graft: Cultural, Political, Local.gov 175
and Structural Factors 149 In Love with E-Gov 175
Curbing Corruption: The Case for Balance E-Gov and Graft: A Double-Edged
and Will 149 Sword 176
xii DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS

The Information Resource and the Future of Pruning the Plethora of Performance
Governing 177 Measures 208
Open Data and Effective Governance 178 Two Measured Notes of Measurement
Hope 210
Blue Skies? 178
From Bureaucrat to Infocrat? 179 Lessons Learned: Minimizing the Pitfalls of
Performance Measurement 210
Notes 179
Lessons Learned about Measures 210
Lessons Learned about Process 210
CHAPTER 7
Lessons Learned about People 211
The Constant Quest: Efficient and Effective
Evaluating Public and Nonprofit Programs 211
Governance 192
Public and Nonprofit Program Evaluation:
Why Can’t Government Be More Effective Purposes and Paranoia 211
and Efficient? 193 Permutations of Public and Nonprofit Program
Three Fundamental Reasons 193 Evaluation 212
Eight Political Reasons 193 Evaluating Federal Programs 213
Why Can’t Government—and the Nonprofit Evaluating State and Local Programs 213
Sector—Be More Efficient and Effective? 196 Uniquely Governmental: The Inspector
General 214
Process Change Equals Glacial
Change 197 Evaluating Nonprofit, Public-Serving
Programs 215
Technology, Productivity, and Service
Quality 197 Public and Nonprofit Program Evaluation in
Understanding Public Productivity 197 Practice 215
Productive Definitions 197 Selecting Evaluators: Inside or Outside
Jobs? 215
Ghettos in the Vastness 197
What Is Your Problem? 216
The Evolution of Public Efficiency
and Effectiveness 198 Designing the Evaluation 216
Implementing Evaluations 217
Measuring Public and Nonprofit
Performance 201 Using Public and Nonprofit Program Evaluations 218
Some Benefits of Performance Passive or Active Evaluation? 218
Measurement 201 Does Program Evaluation Matter? 219
Some Limitations of Performance Notes 219
Measurement 202
Measuring Federal Performance 202
Measuring State Performance 203 CHAPTER 8
Measuring Local Performance 204 The Public Trough: Financing and Budgeting
Measuring Nonprofit Performance 204 Governments 232
Permutations and Practices of Performance Defining Public Finance 232
Measurement 205 Financing the Federal Government 232
Measures: The Fundamental Five 205 Federal General Revenue 232
The Measurement Mire 205 Social Insurance and Retirement
Benchmarking Performance: From Receipts 233
Measurement to Comparison 206 Federal Expenditures 233
Accounting for Public Performance 207
Grass-Roots’ Revenues 234
Reporting Performance 208
General Revenue 234
DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS xiii

Own Source Revenue 234 Line-Item Budgeting, 1921–1949 259


Financing State Governments 235 Reform! Introducing the Public Budget 259
State General Revenue 235 What Is Line-Item Budgeting? 259
State Other Than General Revenue 236 The Legacies of Line-Item Budgeting 260
State Expenditures 236 Program/Performance Budgeting,
State Tax and Expenditure Limitations 237 1950–1964 260
Financing Local Governments 237 The New Deal and the Need for a New
Budget 260
Local General Revenue 237
Clarifying Programs and Performance 260
Local Other Than General Revenue 239
What Is Program/Performance
Local Expenditures 239 Budgeting? 261
Local Tax and Expenditure Limitations 239 The Legacies of Program/Performance
Taxing Times: Determining Tolerable Taxes 240 Budgeting 261
The Five Fundamental Features of Tolerable Planning-Programming-Budgeting System,
Taxes 240 1965–1971 261
Understanding the Income Tax 241 An Emerging New Standard for Budgetary
Understanding the Sales Tax 242 Theory 261
Understanding the Property Tax 243 What Is Planning-Programming-Budgeting
The Future of Taxes 244 System? 262
The Widening Wealth Gap and Its Crushing The Legacies of Planning-Programming-
Consequences 244 Budgeting System 262
Rethinking Federal Taxes 244 Budgeting-by-Objectives, 1972–1977 263
Rethinking State and Local Taxes 245 What Is Budgeting-by-Objectives? 263
Of Deficits and Debt: Washington’s Gifts 246 The Legacies of Budgeting and Managing by
Objectives 263
Understanding Federal Deficits 246
Zero-Base Budgeting, 1977–1980 263
Congress’s Quixotic Quest: Decreasing Deficits,
1985–2001 246 What Is Zero-Base Budgeting? 264
Federal Fiscal Follies 2001–2012 247 The Legacies of Zero-Base Budgeting 264
A Remarkable Reversal, 2013–Present 249 Target Base Budgeting, 1981–Present 264
Understanding Federal Debt 250 What Is Target Base Budgeting? 264
Subnational Sorrows 250 Cutback Management: TBB’s Administrative
Adjunct 265
Linked 251
The Legacies of Target Base Budgeting 267
Healthcare: The Ultimate Linkage 251
Pensions and Public Penury 252 Performance-Based Budgeting, 1993–
State and Local Debt 254 Present 267
Grass-Roots Borrowing: The Mysterious What Is Performance-Based Budgeting? 267
Municipal Bond 254 Budgeting for Federal Performance 268
The Blessing of Bankruptcy? 255 Budgeting for State Performance 268
From Fiscal Falter to Flinty Fate 256 Budgeting for Local Performance 269
Is Revenue Running Out? 257 The Possible Legacy of Performance-Based
A Dismal Science: Deficits, Debt, and Budgeting 269
Democracy 258 Two Useful, but Rarely Used, Budgetary Tools 269
A Muted Note of Hope 258 The Biennial Budget 269
Public Budgeting: Spending for Public Policy 258 The Budget Rollover 270
xiv DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS

Acquiring Budgets: Administrators and Securing Bureaucrats’ Jobs 309


Arguments 270 Keeping Competent Bureaucrats 309
Standing Strategies for Securing The Slippage of the Civil Service System 309
Budgets 270
A Faltering Federal Civil Service 309
Opportunistic Tactics for Securing
Budgets 271 Civil Service Slippage at the Grass
Roots 311
The Budget-Minimizing Bureaucrat 271
The Impact of Civil Service Reform 312
Legislating Budgets: Politicians and Power 271 A Modest Proposal 312
Legislating Federal Budgets 271
The Collective System: Blue-Collar
Legislating State Budgets 273 Bureaucrats 312
Legislating Local Budgets 275 The Scope of Organized Labor 312
“Budgeteers”: Humble Nevermore 275 A Unique Value 313
Notes 276 Want to Fire Your Boss? 313
Bargaining with Governments 314
Pay and Public Unions 315
CHAPTER 9
Striking Government 315
Managing Human Capital in the Public and Days of Glory . . . Gone 316
Nonprofit Sectors 294 A Threatening Court? 316
Who Wants to Work for the Public or Nonprofit Are Public Unions Good or Bad for the Public?
Sectors? And Who Doesn’t? 294 A Summing Up 317
The Evolution of Public Human Capital The Political Executive System: Policymaking and
Management 295 Politics in Public Administration 317
Government by Gentlemen, 1789–1827 295 Political Executives in Washington 318
Government by Spoilers, 1828–1880 295 Political Executives at the Grass Roots 321
Government by the Good, 1881–1905 296 Experience and Sector: Our New
Understanding of Public Executive
Government by Scientific Managers, Quality 322
1906–1936 297
Government by Policymaking Administrators, Specialized Public Professional Systems: The
1937–1954 297 Person over the Position 322
Government by Professionals, The Scope of Specialized Public Professional
1955–Present 297 Systems 323
The Civil Service System: The Meaning The Public Implications of Specialized Public
Professionalism 323
of Merit 298
The Meaning of Merit 298 The Professional Public Administration System:
Embracing the Professions of Politics and
The Profession of Public Human Capital
Management 298 Management 323
Recruiting Bureaucrats 299 The Roots of the Professional Public
Administration System 323
Hiring Bureaucrats 300
Reforming Classification 324
Classifying Bureaucrats 302
Managing Public and Nonprofit Employees’
Rating Bureaucrats 303 Performance 325
Paying Bureaucrats 303 Performance Management Challenge 1:
Training Bureaucrats 304 Appraising Employees’ Performance 326
Bolstering Bureaucrats’ Bravery 305 Performance Management Challenge 2:
Coping with Incompetents 327
DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS xv

Performance Management Challenge 3: The Neo-Institutionalist Model 383


Performance and Pay 331 The Organized Anarchy Model 384
The Prospects of Performance The Rationalist Paradigm of Public
Management 334
Policymaking 386
Defying Discrimination: The Extension of Civil The Rational Choice Model 387
Rights and the Entry of Affirmative Action 335
The Public Goods and Services Model 388
Civil Rights for Protected Classes 335
Paradigmatic Problems 389
Civil Rights for Sexual Minorities 335
Arguments over Incrementalism 389
Affirmative Action for Protected Classes 336
Incremental Policymaking? Not So
Federal Enforcement of Affirmative Much 389
Action 337
A Pair of Pouting Paradigms 390
Affirmative Action and the Grass-Roots
Governments 337 A Third Approach: The Strategic Planning
“Reverse Discrimination” and the Quota Paradigm of Public and Nonprofit
Question 338 Policymaking 390
Tests: The Validation Vexation 339 Public Strategic Planning 391
Women’s Work? 340 Nonprofit Strategic Planning 392
What a Strange Trip It’s Been: The Unique Successful Strategic Planning: Executives,
Experiences of Minority and Women Public Planners, Continuity, and Budgets 393
Administrators 342
Notes 393
Backlash! 344
Is Affirmative Action a Defensible
Policy? 345 CHAPTER 11
The Effects of the Efforts 346 Intersectoral Administration 397
A Demographic Solution? 349
Why Privatize? 397
Notes 350
Federal Privatization 399
Federal Fire Sales 400
PART IV Implementing Public The Enormity of Acquisitions 400
Policy 379 Federal Philosophies of Purchasing 400
Notes 380 Washington’s Buying Bureaucracy 402
The Case Against Federal Contracting 403
CHAPTER 10 The Shadow Government: Contractors,
Consultants, and Lobbyists 403
Understanding and Improving Public
Policy 381 A Crisis of Competence 407
A Crisis of Corruption 413
Public Policy Analysis: A Brief History 381 Is Business Better? 415
Public Policy and the Policymakers 381 Success! The Reforms of 2009 and
Public Policy and the Professoriate 381 Beyond 415
The Incrementalist Paradigm of Public Outsourcing’s Unabashed Outcome: Wealthier
Policymaking 382 Washingtonians 416
The Elite/Mass Model 382 Privatizing in the States 417
The Group Model 383 The States Resistant 417
The Systems Model 383 Motives, Money, and Management 417
The Institutionalist Model 383 The States’ Slower Revolving Doors 418
xvi DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS

Privatizing by Local Governments 418 CHAPTER 12


Selling Assets, Buying Goods, and Privatizing Intergovernmental Administration 460
Facilities 418
Privatizing Local Services 418 Some Systemic Findings about Federalism 460
Outsourcing in Extremis 419 Federal Systems versus Unitary Systems 460
Why Local Governments Privatize Findings from the States and Communities:
Services 419 Trust and Innovation 461
Why Local Governments Do Not Privatize Governments, the Constitution, and
Services 420 the Courts 461
Managing Privatized Local Services 421 America’s Proliferating Governments 461
The Firmly Shut Revolving Door 422 The Constitution: The Functions of
Which Sector Delivers Public Services Federalism 462
Best? 422 The Courts: Necessary and Proper Implied
Federal Powers 462
Does Government Partnering with the Private
and Nonprofit Sectors Deliver Services More The Evolution of Intergovernmental
Effectively and Efficiently? 422 Administration 462
Does Government Partnering with the Private The Layer Cake: Dual Federalism,
and Nonprofit Sectors Deliver Services More 1789–1932 462
Equitably? 423 The Marble Cake: Cooperative Federalism,
Privatizing Public Service Delivery: Lessons 1933–1958 463
Learned 423 The Pound Cake: Co-Optative Federalism,
The Businesses of Governments 424 1959–1978 463
Enterprising Washington 424 The Crumble Cake: Competitive Federalism,
1979–2008 464
State and Local Enterprises and the Public
Authority 426 The Angel Food Cake: Manna-from-Heaven
Federalism, 2009–Present 465
Creating, Governing, and Administering Public
Authorities 427 Fiscal Federalism 466
The Relatively Unconstrained Power of A World Turned Upside Down: A Century of
Governments at the Fringe: Have They Used Fiscal Change 466
It Well? 428 The Grant-in-Aid: Foundation of Fiscal
The Independent Sector: Big, Growing, and Federalism 466
Influential 429 Getting Theirs: Governments Lobbying
Governments 467
Serving Themselves or Serving
Others 429 Federal Grants: Distortions at the Grass
Roots 467
The Good that the Third Sector Does 430
Those Rascally Recipients! 469
A Remarkably Respected Sector 430
Fiscal Federalism in the States 469
Governments and the Independent
Sector 430 Regulatory Federalism 469
A Case of Independent Governance: Ruling Robustly 469
Neighborhoods Renascent 435 The Mandates Maw 470
Implementation by Individuals: Volunteers The Wreckage of Regulatory Federalism 471
and Vouchers 436 Deregulating Regulatory Federalism? 472
Volunteering for Government 436 Money, Mandates, and Washington: Now
Vouching for Citizen Service 437 What? 472
Notes 438 Washington’s Intergovernmental Role: One
Fine Mess after Another 472
DETAILED TABLE OF CONTENTS xvii

The Capable States 475 CHAPTER 13


Sorting Out Federalism: Who Should Do Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 500
What? 475
A Federal Reset? 476 Codes and Commissions: The Rise of Public Sector
Ethics 500
Federalism among Equals: The States 476
Ethics for the Public Professions 500
Interstate Cooperation 476
Ethics for Governments 500
Interstate Conflict 477
Practicing Ethical Public and Nonprofit
Intergovernmental Administration in the
Administration 501
States 477
Ethical Environments 501
Creatures of the States 477
Committing to Ethics 502
The Insidious Introduction of Home Rule 477
A Steadier Helping Hand 478 Do Morals Matter? 502
A Slow Centralization of State Power 478 Bureaucracy’s Bane: Determining the Public
Intergovernmental Administration among Local Interest 503
Governments 478 Bureaucratic Accountability: Skirting the
Question 503
Local Collaboration and Service
Delivery 478 Organizational Humanism: Addressing the
Question, but Irrelevantly So 503
Motivations to Collaborate 479
The Context of Collaboration 479 Can Normative Theory Help? Four Philosophies of
the Public Interest 504
Concerns over Collaboration: Community
Counts 480 Institutionalism: Morally Muddling
Through 504
Recurring Regionalism 480
Perfectionism: Promoting Perfect
Consolidating and Centralizing Local People 504
Services 481
Utilitarianism: The Most Benefits for the Most
Place, People, and Power: The Puzzle of People 505
Metropolitan Governance 481 Fairness: A Theory of Justice 505
The City: In Sickness and in Health 481 Does Philosophy Matter? 506
The Metropolis: Lots of Little, Layered Local
Governments 482 What Is to Be Done? Implementing Ethical Public
Administration 506
Ultralocalism: The Quest for Metropolitan
Efficiency 482 The Passion of Public Administration 507
Gargantua: The Quest for Metropolitan Big Democracy, Big Decisions 509
Efficiency—and Equity 484 Notes 509
The Efficiency Question 484
Mincing Toward Metro 485 Index 512
Notes 486
P R E FA C E T O T H E T H I R T E E N T H E D I T I O N

P
ublic Administration and Public Affairs is, at root, about the public interest.
It explains both the means used to fulfill the public interest, and the human
panoply that is the public interest.
Public Administration and Public Affairs, despite its orientation toward U.S.
readers, has been translated and published in Chinese, Japanese, Romanian, and
portions of it in Spanish. There is also an Indian edition and other national edi-
tions in English. We relate this polyglot publishing history to demonstrate that, with
accelerating appreciation, public administration is seen around the globe as central
to “good government,” and good government, as we explain in the introduction to
Part I, is seen by the world’s people as central to a good life.

WHAT’S NEW?
The thirteenth edition of Public Administration and Public Affairs has been signifi-
cantly revised, expanded, and updated. Most notably, we have concentrated on three
developments of singular consequence. They are:
■ Public administration’s reinvigorated concern with curbing corruption.
■ The rise of the nonprofit sector in governing and administering the state.
■ And the current, and likely long-term, crises in public finance.
There is a great deal of brand new information in this edition. A few highlights
follow.
■ Why are so many leaders losers? Because they too often are men, white,
handsome, tall, and sociopathic.
■ Bridgegate: The George Washington Bridge “repairs” as illustrative of the
damaging impact of the environment on public organizations.
■ The Supreme Court and the legalization of corruption. Campaign
contributions, the uniquely complex and huge federal tax code, and the
facilitation of corruption. E-government reduces official corruption, but
opens new opportunities for fraudsters. The growing problem of healthcare
fraud.
■ The emergence of big data analytics, enterprise risk management,
PerformanceStat, open data, and chief data officers as paladins of more efficient
governance.
■ Gone: the hack of the U.S. Office of Personnel Management and the theft of
22.5 million federal personnel records.
■ The Supreme Court and its undermining of whistleblowers and public unions.
■ The crushing costs of healthcare, pensions and public penury, costly budget
“cuts,” and two rarely used but useful budgetary tools, the budget rollover and
the biennial budget.
xviii
PREFACE TO THE THIRTEENTH EDITION xix

■ The obsessive focus of emergency financial managers and the fate of Flint, Michigan.
■ The return to government of cognitive ability tests for hiring and promotion.
■ Snowed: Edward Snowden and federal incompetence in contracting.
■ The case against federal contracting: lobbying, incompetence, corruption, and a growing body of
proof that government is better than business in delivering public programs.
■ Outsourcing’s unabashed outcome: wealthier Washingtonians.
■ The 115 “entities” that constitute the federal fringe government.
■ Governments’ support of the third sector and nonprofits’ little-known support of government.
■ Fractured federalism, deceptive federalism, and governments lobbying governments.

WHAT’S OLD?
What’s old? This book. It is now nearing its sixth decade.
Writing textbooks is unique. Paul Krugman, Nobel laureate and a columnist for the New York Times,
and Robin Wells, also a distinguished economist, wrote a textbook that consumed “five years of intense
work.” Wells described writing it as “excruciatingly hard” because, as Krugman explained, a textbook
“has to be impeccable. If you’re writing an academic paper, if you have some stuff that’s blurrily written,
that won’t do much harm. If you write a newspaper article, and a third of your readers don’t get it, that’s
a success. But a textbook has to be perfect.”1
As one who also has written academic papers, newspaper articles, and textbooks (alas, the Nobel has
stubbornly eluded us), we concur that a textbook should be perfect. A textbook has a far longer reach, a
far larger audience, and a far deeper impact than virtually any other intellectual medium.
We doubt, frankly, that Public Administration and Public Affairs is perfect. But we keep trying.

NOTE
1. Larissa MacFarquhar, “The Deflationist,” The New Yorker (March 1, 2010), pp. 38–49. The quotations are on
p. 47.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I
owe an unpayable intellectual debt to at least three of my teachers, Lynton Keith
Caldwell, Jack T. Johnson, and York Y. Wilbern. Later, Frank J. Sackton intro-
duced me to the classroom of the practical world. All, regrettably, are deceased,
but their beneficent influence lives on.
I am indebted to my editors at Routledge for their good cheer, hard work, and
solid advice in producing what you are reading.
I also am indebted to my colleagues, students, and the book’s reviewers who
have had such a constructive influence on the continuing evolution of Public
Administration and Public Affairs.
As always, my wife, Muriel, and my children, Adrienne and Miles, and their
spouses, Kevin and Anna, provided the deepest level of support. The book is for them,
and, much to my gratification, my grandchildren, Callum, Margaret, and Charlotte.

Nicholas Henry
Savannah, Georgia

xx
PART

In Defense of Governing Well

Bureaucracy is in our bones. Prehistoric evidence Americans do not subscribe to the wrecking-
unearthed at archeological digs suggests that the crew view. Out of thirteen major issues,
rudiments of a bureaucratic social order were in majorities state that the federal government
place 19,000 years ago.1 should play a major role  in twelve (the excep-
tion is space exploration).  Most Republicans
and  Democrats agree  that Washington should
DO WE NEED GOVERNMENT? play a  prominent role  in  controlling terrorism,
Not everyone agrees that bureaucracy and govern- responding  to  natural  disasters,  and managing
ment are basic to society. Some contend, in a distorted food, medicine  safety,  infrastructure,  and  even
extension of Thomas Paine’s dictum “that govern- immigration.5
ment is best which governs least,” that the very best Perhaps the clearest and most critical example
government is no government at all. As a prominent of the wrecking-crew mentality is that of regulation,
conservative explains, “What holds together the con- an area often touted by these advocates as a burden
servative movement” is that conservatives “want the from which Americans demand relief. Yet, when
government to go away.”2 queried about regulating specific industries, three
times more citizens, on average, want more regula-
tion than those who want less.6
The Wrecking-Crew View Underlying the wreckers’ ideology is their belief
It has been argued that, when those who want the that more governmental regulation equals fewer
government to go away are in power, they delib- jobs, and vice versa. Research, however, consistently
erately delegitimize government in the eyes of shows that there is no evidence supporting this view.
the public. Restrained by only what is politically In the aggregate, the jobs lost to regulation (for
infeasible, these “no-government conservatives”3 example, the jobs lost in a factory that produced
act as a “wrecking crew” that sabotages govern- lead additives for gasoline because of air pollution
mental competence; tolerates, even encourages, regulations) are replaced elsewhere in the economy
corruption; and  privatizes or sheds altogether (e.g., in a factory that makes catalytic converters,
core public  responsibilities.4 It is this perspective which control automobile emissions). It is, in short,
that has encouraged the founding of roughly a thou- a wash.7
sand extreme anti-government groups (the number
varies widely from year to year), such as those
that  influenced the bombers of a federal building Wrecking Government and Wrecking
in  1995, that killed 168 adults and children, and America
the  armed takeover and trashing of federal facili- That the public could benefit from more responsi-
ties in Oregon, in 2015,  resulting in one death by ble regulation of some industries seems plausible.
shooting. Consider some evidence.
2 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

Wrecking the Environment On April 20, 2010, tiny Texas subcontractor,” submitted by the four
BP’s (formerly British Petroleum) thirty-story-tall other major offshore drillers, all but one of which
Deepwater Horizon oilrig in the Gulf of Mexico also referenced those walruses in the Gulf.11 All
exploded, listed, and sank. Eleven crewmen’s lives five of the major companies’ spill response plans
ended, and the most disastrous oil spill in American amounted to the longest works of maritime fiction
history began. Ultimately, nearly 5 million barrels since Moby-Dick.
of crude polluted the Gulf. The company could not MMS was also riddled with corruption.
have been drilling in the Gulf had it not received a According to a federal report, the agency had a
federal permit to do so. “culture of ethical failure.” Not surprising in light of
Which BP had indeed received, despite its spec- the fact that three out of every four of the more than
tacularly tawdry safety record. Over the three years 600 lobbyists who lobby for the oil and gas industry
preceding the spill, the Occupational Health and are former federal employees, including two former
Safety Administration cited BP for 760 “egregious directors of MMS. “Nowhere has government and
willful” safety violations. These are the agency’s industry coziness been on display more clearly than
most severe violations out of five types, and apply at MMS.”12
only to violations of those rules that are “designed Besides being incompetent and corrupt, MMS’s
to prevent catastrophic events.” How many cita- administrators were just plain dumb. During the
tions for egregious willful violations had all other week following the president’s declaration of a mor-
oil companies combined accumulated over the same atorium on offshore drilling and the issuance of
period? One.8 waivers, with oil still gushing into the Gulf, MMS
The regulatory agency that had licensed BP granted seven permits and five waivers.13
to drill in the Gulf was the Minerals Management In 2011, the Government Accountability Office
Service (MMS), a little-known bureau of 1,700 belatedly declared the management of oil and gas
employees created by the interior secretary in 1982. resources to be a “high-risk area” that required extra
It is charged with issuing permits to, and collecting federal attention to prevent waste, fraud, and abuse;
royalties from, companies that drill offshore. it still remains one.
MMS’s regulatory record was at least as tawdry In the midst of the spill, MMS was hastily
as BP’s safety record. The agency, which collects renamed the Bureau of Ocean Energy Management,
more non-tax revenue—$9 billion per year—than Regulation and Enforcement, an exhaustingly long
any other, had for decades failed to collect bil- moniker that should discourage future journalistic
lions in royalties due it.9 MMS’s administrators coverage of the agency.
“routinely overruled staff scientists whose findings
highlight the environmental risks of drilling,” and Wrecking the Economy Three decades after the
scientists “repeatedly had their scientific findings steady deregulation of the financial sector that
changed to indicate no environmental impact.” It began in the early 1980s, America’s foremost busi-
would slander boilerplate to apply that term to BP’s ness magazine stated that, “It is chillingly clear that
582-page “oil spill response plan” that it submit- U.S. financial institutions have for a good while been
ted to MMS to establish the Deepwater Horizon. regulated no more stringently than, say, demolition
Besides stating that “no significant adverse impacts derby drivers.”14
are expected” from a spill, it notes that walruses Demolition is a fitting word. In the late 2000s,
(which have not wallowed in the Gulf since the Ice the United States narrowly escaped economic
Age) would be protected; provides an address for collapse. Near, or perhaps at, the heart of that
the “rapid deployment of spill response resources” barely-missed meltdown were over-the-counter
that turned out to be that of a Japanese home shop- derivatives, which are highly leveraged financial
ping network; and “never once discusses how to exotica, such as mortgage-backed securities, that
stop a deepwater blowout . . .. Nobody” at MMS many analysts think caused the crisis. In 2003, the
“read it.”10 legendary investor, Warren Buffet, dubbed these
Nor, apparently, had anyone read any of the derivatives “weapons of mass financial destruction,”
nearly identical plans, “all written by the same and warned that they involved “huge-scale fraud.”15
PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well 3

Derivatives were introduced in the 1980s and have raised significant red flags” and two articles that
flourished in a secretive, “completely dark market” “appeared in reputable publications,” that financier
about which regulators were also in the dark.16 Bernard Madoff was swindling his wealthy inves-
When the derivatives market peaked in June 2008, tors, including several charities. Yet, “a thorough and
its face (or “notional”) value was an absurd and competent investigation . . . was never performed.”22
inconceivable $683 trillion,17 and almost all of it Not that one was really needed; a whistleblower
was owned by America’s biggest banks. tried in vain to convince SEC that Madoff was a
When the head of a small regulatory agency crook, showing its inept staff that, if Madoff were
attempted, in the late 1990s, to persuade Washington a baseball player, he would have a batting average
to regulate derivatives, she ran into rock-hard resist- of 960 each and every year, and hit only doubles, a
ance. She was stunned when the chair of the Federal pair of statistical impossibilities.23 Madoff’s machi-
Reserve, Alan Greenspan, informed her that he nations eventually were ratted out by his own sons,
did not “believe that fraud . . . was something that and, by the time he was sentenced to 150 years in
regulators should worry about [because] the free prison, Madoff had “made off” with an estimated
market self-corrects and takes care of fraudulent $65 billion, marking it the biggest Ponzi scheme in
actors.”18 the history of the Milky Way Galaxy—well, at least
In 2000, at the urging of Greenspan, the treas- of Planet Earth.
ury secretary, and the financial industry (which Here is an example of the latter: the federal
has five lobbyists on its payroll for every member Wage and Hour Division, which is charged with
of Congress19), Congress passed the Commodity assuring that employers do not steal their employ-
Futures Modernization Act, which declared illegal ees’ wages, is “an ineffective system” that “dis-
any federal or state regulation of over-the-counter courages wage theft complaints”; is beset with
derivatives. “sluggish response times [of] months to years”; is
In less than a year and a half after the resultant characterized by a refusal to “compel employers to
“Great Recession” struck in 2007–2009, the stock pay” their employees what they owe them; and is
market had lost an astounding 56 percent of its rife with “inadequately investigated” cases in which
value, more than had been lost over the same period some investigators “lied about investigative work
during the Great Depression. Two years after its performed and did not investigate.” The Division
start, 8.7 million jobs were gone, four times more “instructed many offices” to alter their databases to
than in the severe, double-dip recession of 1980– hide the fact that they had made “low wage workers
1982.20 Five years after the Great Recession ended, vulnerable to wage theft.”24
the percentage of children living in poverty had risen All the quotations and findings in the foregoing
from 18 percent to 22 percent, an increase of more examples (with the exception of the whistleblower’s
than a fifth.21 baseball calculations) appeared not in lurid press
In 2015, Standard & Poor’s, the world’s largest accounts, but in official government reports. These
credit ratings firm, was fined almost $1.4 billion reports draw short of charging the agencies with
over its risky rating of mortgage-backed securities corruption, but whether they are corrupt or merely
that had led to the Great Recession, and, in 2017, incompetent (if staggeringly so), is either condition
Moody’s was fined nearly $864 million for the same good for society? Some scholars think so.
reason. No executives were prosecuted.

Equal Opportunity Wreckage The wrecking-crew IS GRAFT GOOD?


mentality is an equal-opportunity ideology. It hurts Graft, or corruption, is the conduct of dishonest
rich and poor alike. practices. This is the nicest definition; standard dic-
Here is an example of the former: the chief tionaries also offer such nouns as “putrefaction,”
business regulator, the Securities and Exchange “perversion,” “depravity,” and “debasement” in
Commission (SEC), received, over the course of their several definitions. Corruption’s etymological
sixteen years, “more than ample information,” roots reflect these descriptions; the Latin corrumpere
including “six substantive complaints that should can mean bribe—or it can mean destruction.
4 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

Defying even the basic definition of corruption blocking bureaucracy, thereby accelerating eco-
is the contention that graft-ridden government can nomic development.30
be good. It has two components: the political and Unfortunately for this perspective, it is increas-
the economic. Both positions have been touted, ingly clear that “efficient grease” actually retards
often enthusiastically, by political scientists,25 who prosperity. Not one of the nineteen impoverished
sometimes seem to act as cheerleaders for political nations that have been granted debt service relief
corruption. through the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries
Initiative is rated as having anything better than
“serious to severe” governmental corruption.31 The
Fighting for Fraud: Corruption Improves rate of investment in countries with high and unpre-
Public Services dictable rates of corruption is almost half of that in
The political argument for corruption is an old low-corruption countries.32 An analysis of more than
chestnut originated by a distinguished political sci- a hundred countries found that, when corruption
entist (the American Political Science Association’s increases by about two points on a ten-point scale,
Prize for Excellence is named in his honor), who investment decreases by 4 percent, and gross domes-
studied corruption in Chicago. Although, ironically, tic product falls by half a percent.33 Corruption
he was personally an ardent reformer, his work still inflates the prices of goods by as much as a fifth,34
is cited, approvingly, in mainstream texts.26 and severely curtails personal income growth for just
Graft’s political justification is that corrupt about everyone, but especially for the poor, thereby
political machines “work,” and perform “many intensifying income inequality. Graft even decreases
important social functions.” In exchange for votes the years that children spend in school.35
and the public’s tolerance for politicians and their The World Bank estimates that, globally, some
toadies who plunder the public till, ward heelers fix $1 trillion dollars in bribes are paid to government
their constituents’ traffic tickets, get them jobs, lower officials each year.36 So obviously some people—the
their tax bills, waive zoning and building codes, and corruptors—are making a ton of money, right?
attend their funerals, among a slew of other services, Well, no. Bribery costs even the bribers. Three
some more licit than others. (To be fair, up until the surveys of 2,400 businesses in fifty-eight nations
1940s or so, these practices often saved immigrants’ found that “firms that pay more bribes are also
livelihoods, but no longer.) When an “upper-class likely to spend more, not less, management time with
elite [of] reformers and do-gooders,” this argument bureaucrats negotiating regulations, and face higher,
implicitly continues, replaces responsive political not lower, costs of capital.”37 When firms increase
machines with lumbering, lethargic, legalistic public their bribes to bureaucrats by 1 percent, their annual
bureaucracies, the needs of the poor, and even of growth rate declines by an average of 3.3 percent.38
better-off taxpayers, are seldom met.27 The evidence, in sum, is overwhelming that cor-
This romanticized defense of corruption has ruption brings not prosperity, but poverty.
scant evidentiary support. Corruption slashes gov-
ernments’ legitimate revenue by as much as half,
and, with it, public services, and adds from 3 to 10 FIGHTING FRAUD: THE MANY
percent to the cost of legitimate services because citi-
zens must bribe officials to acquire them.28 REASONS TO DO SO
The fact that graft reduces public services, increases
their costs, and impoverishes the citizenry is reason
Fighting for Fraud: Corruption Brings enough to fight fraud. But there are many more
Prosperity reasons.
The other argument for corruption, though origi- When people perceive that their government is
nated by a sociologist,29 is economic; it holds that corrupt, particularly when that perception occurs
graft munificently paves the way for longer-term rather suddenly (as the function, for example, of an
prosperity. “Grease money” amounts to “speed abnormally improving economy), popular dissatis-
money,” in that bribes are used to circumvent a faction with democracy grows, trust in institutions
PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well 5

declines, government’s legitimacy erodes, and to fade as early as 1974, when the Portuguese
“rule-breaking behavior” expands.39 At its worst, overthrew their corrupt Fascist rulers. In so doing,
corruption can be so deeply offensive that it can Portugal ignited an international wildfire that con-
leave some citizens with a raging thirst for violent tinues to incinerate many national Gordian knots
vengeance. When captured prisoners were ques- that intertwine corruption and repression. (The
tioned in Afghanistan, the leading reason that they two are inextricably tangled largely because each
gave for joining the Taliban was not a commitment flourishes where there is no meaningful law.) In the
to Islam or anti-Americanism, but the corruption of 1980s, mass demonstrations erupted against graft
the Afghan government.40 and dictators in China and countries in Central Asia
When countries curb corruption, good things and Eastern Europe. As a result, communist China
happen: poverty and child mortality rates decline, converted to capitalism; the Soviet Union collapsed;
and per capita income and literacy rates rise, among and all its satellite states and many of its provinces
other benefits.41 were liberated.
The United States is not immune to corruption. The wildfire rages on, and is directed against
Long-term state government corruption, in tandem corruption at least as much as repression. In the
with high state unemployment rates, produces greater 2000s, Xi Jinping, now China’s president, intro-
income inequality among citizens and reduces real duced masters of public administration curricula
personal incomes, education levels, and unionization in dozens of top universities across the country in
rates, all to statistically significant degrees.42 the hope of curbing corruption, and, as president,
Corruption also causes state spending to be arti- initiated China’s toughest anti-graft campaign since
ficially elevated. In the ten most corrupt American the country embraced capitalism. In Russia, “reform
states, as measured by the number of graft convic- [is] not only about human rights. It’s about getting
tions per 10,000 public employees over thirty-two people [in power] to stop stealing.”46
years, total annual spending would have been Today, anti-corruption forces have gone global.
reduced by 5.2 percent of the mean state expend- The World Bank now recognizes that “corruption is
iture per capita (or $1,308 per capita) over eleven one of the most serious obstacles to development.”47
years if their corruption had merely matched the The United Nations Development Programme, the
average level of corruption in all the states. In world’s largest aid agency, has made “good govern-
addition, corruption distorts spending by favoring ment” its “top priority in poverty fighting” on the
“bribe-generating” expenditures, notably for con- grounds that “without good government, reliance on
struction, highways, and borrowing, among others, trickle-down economic development and a host of
and at the expense of education, welfare, health, and other strategies will not work.”48
hospitals.43 There is much additional global good news.
The United Nations Convention against Corruption
of 2003 has some 140 member nations. Relatively
A GLOBALLY FADING honest governments have passed laws that penal-
ize graft beyond their borders, such as the United
PHILOSOPHY States’ Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (which has
According to the World Bank, corruption was proven effective in reducing American invest-
“treated as a taboo subject” by the development ments in corrupt countries49) and Magnitsky Act
community for decades.44 In fact, one study found and Britain’s Bribery Act. Business interests have
that corrupt countries were more likely to attract formed anti-corruption cooperatives, such as the
European foreign aid (with the exception of International Corporate Governance Network and
Scandinavian aid) than relatively honest ones.45 the Financial Action Network, among others. The
This regrettable philosophy may have been a Open Government Network, with nearly sixty
consequence of corrupt countries contending that national governments as members, is dedicated to
what the West labeled as corruption was really a securing “concrete commitments” from its members
“cultural” trait, and to think otherwise amounted to battle graft. Transparency International, which
to racism. The dubious philosophy probably began annually ranks the globe’s nations by how corrupt
6 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

they are perceived to be, has mushroomed in influ- democracy are virtually universally accepted around
ence. National anti-corruption movements are the world,” regardless of culture, and that these ideas
popping up throughout Africa and Asia, and there is are “viewed as the only game in town,” even by the
now an International Anti-Corruption Day. residents of dictatorships.52
Bureaucrats are crucial to popular support of
democracy. A study of thirty-five democratic coun-
WHAT IS GOOD GOVERNMENT tries concluded that “citizens’ evaluation of public
A few years ago, captured correspondence revealed administration is related more strongly to their
that various jihadist groups yearned to be the stew- satisfaction with democracy than other explana-
ards of good governance in those areas that they tions—such as political trust, electoral fairness, and
occasionally conquered, and inevitably lost because political efficacy.” Public administrators play “the
they formed such horrific and incompetent “gov- central role  . . . in sustaining citizen support for
ernments” that the governed rebelled or held out democracy.”53
for rescue. The most prominent such group, the
Islamic State (IS), learned from its mistakes; after it
took a vast stretch of Iraq and Syria, in 2014, its Good Government Is Able
leader called on Muslim public administrators from
The central role that bureaucrats play in sustaining
around the world to help it manage its newly cap-
democracy leads to our third component of good
tured provinces. Although IS continues to lop off
government: competence.
hands and heads in territories that it conquers, for
As with uncorrupted and democratic govern-
a period of time it also hired accountants, restored
ment, well-managed government enhances the daily
electricity, and paid long-unpaid bureaucrats (ini-
lives of people. An analysis of twenty-nine nations
tially, some citizens from IS-occupied territories said
found that “the efficient delivery of public services
that IS was “actually less corrupt and provided more
can directly affect welfare, and good governance has
efficient services . . . than previous Syrian and Iraqi
been shown to be associated with higher rates of
governments”);50 IS still issues annual reports, and
. . . growth in incomes.”54 A study of the American
even has an equivalent of the U.S. Food and Drug
states found that a high level of “state management
Administration. Eventually, however, basic services,
capacity” to govern efficiently “clearly . . . contrib-
such as water supplies, essentially vanished and
utes directly to improving the overall quality of life
“taxes” rocketed, as IS and similar jihadists faced
for state citizens.”55
increasingly effective military opponents.
Governments’ often-heroic response to the
As this episode reveals, even terrorists like good
terrorist attacks of 2001 brought a doubling in
government. But what is it?
popular trust in government.56 Conversely, the price
Good government is uncorrupted, democratic,
of weak, brittle, and clumsy government can be
and competent.
steep. Governments’ bungled response to Hurricane
Katrina, in 2005, resulted in a ten-point plummet
Good Government Is Uncorrupted in Americans’ faith in their governments’ ability to
protect them.57
Aside from a few intellectuals who mud-wrestle on
President Barack Obama, in his first inaugural
the slippery slopes of “corruption that ‘works’” and
address, phrased the matter well: “The question we
“efficient grease,” everyone knows that honest gov-
ask today is not whether government is too big or
ernance is good government. Globally, the leading
too small, but whether it works.”58
“very big problem” in surveys is corrupt political
That is precisely what this book is about.
leaders.51

Good Government Is Democratic The Place of Public Administration


Democracy is good government. A massive and Good government, then, rests on three pillars:
ongoing study finds that “the basic ideas of honesty, democracy, and competency. Public
PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well 7

administrators, as we shall see throughout this book, (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press,
are essential to each. 2014).
Public administration is a broad-ranging and 8. Jim Morris and M.B. Pell, Renegade Refiner:
amorphous combination of theory and practice that OSHA Says BP Has “Systemic Safety Problem”
is meant to promote a superior understanding of (Washington, DC: Center for Public Integrity,
government and its relationship with the society it 2010), pp. 3, 1. Figures are for June 2007–February
governs, as well as to encourage public policies more 2010.
responsive to social needs and to institute managerial 9. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Mineral
practices attuned to effectiveness, efficiency, and the Revenues: Data Management Problems and
Reliance on Self-Reported Data for Compliance
deeper human requisites of the citizenry. Admittedly,
Efforts Put MMS Royalty Collections at Risk,
the preceding sentence is itself rather broad ranging
GAO-08-893R Mineral Revenues (Washington,
and amorphous (although one reviewer of this book
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008).
described our definition as “a classic”59), but for our
10. Tim Dickinson, “The Spill, The Scandal and the
purposes it will suffice. President,” Rollingstone.com (June 8, 2010).
In Chapter 1, we review the longstanding and 11. Steven Mufson and Juliet Eilperin, “Lawmakers
everlasting tension between bureaucracy and democ- Attack Plans Oil Companies Had in Place to Deal
racy in the United States. In Chapter 2, we review with a Spill,” Washington Post (June 15, 2010).
the intellectual evolution of public administration. 12. Ibid. Figures are for 2009.
How public administrators see themselves and their 13. Ian Urbina, “Despite Moratorium, Drilling Projects
proper field of action in a democracy deeply affects Move Ahead,” New York Times (May 23, 2010).
the health of democracy itself. 14. Carol J. Loomis, “Derivatives: The Risk That
So welcome to Public Administration and Public Still Won’t Go Away,” Fortune (July 6, 2009),
Affairs, and welcome to one of the most exciting and pp. 55–60. The quotation is on p. 55.
rewarding career possibilities on earth. 15. Warren Buffett, quoted in “Buffett Warns on
Investment ‘Time Bomb,’” BBC News (March 4,
2003).
NOTES 16. Public Broadcasting System, “The Warning,”
1. Scott Van Nystrom and Luella C. Nystrom, Frontline (October 20, 2009).
“Bureaucracy in Prehistory: Case Evidence from 17. Stephen Feglewski, Roy C. Smith, and Ingo Walter,
Mammoth Bone Dwellers on the Russian Steppes,” “Geithner’s Plan for Derivatives,” Forbes (May 18,
International Journal of Public Administration 21 2009).
(Winter 1998), pp. 7–23. 18. Public Broadcasting System, “The Warning.”
2. Newt Gingrich, former Republican Speaker 19. Ibid.
of the House, as quoted in John Cassidy, “The 20. Don Lee, “U.S. Unemployment Rate Falls
Ringleader,” The New Yorker (August 1, 2005), Unexpectedly, but Job Losses Continue,” Los
pp. 42–53. The quotation is on p. 46. Angeles Times (February 6, 2010).
3. Jon Favreau, “Jon Favreau on the Destructive Rise 21. Annie E. Casey Foundation, Kids Count: 2015
of No-Government Conservatives,” The Daily Data Book (Baltimore, MD: Author, 2015).
Beast (July 30, 2013). 22. Office of the Inspector General, U.S. Securities and
4. Thomas Frank, The Wrecking Crew: How Exchange Commission, Report of Investigation,
Conservatives Rule (New York: Macmillan, 2008). Case No. OIG-509, Investigation of Failure of the
5. Pew Research Center, “Beyond Distrust: How SEC to Uncover Bernard Madoff’s Ponzi Scheme,
Americans View Their Government,” People-press. Executive Summary (Washington, DC: Author,
org (November 23, 2015). 2009), p. 1.
6. As derived from data in Meg Bostrom, By, or for, 23. Henry Markopolis, appearing on Morning Joe,
the People? A Meta-analysis of Public Opinion MSNBC (August 24, 2011).
of Government (New York: Demos, 2006), p. 33. 24. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Figures are for 2003. Department of Labor: Wage and Hour Division’s
7. Cary Coglianese, Adam M. Finkel, and Christopher Complaint Intake and Investigative Processes
Carrigan, eds., Does Regulation Kill Jobs? Leave Low Wage Workers Vulnerable to Wage
8 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

Theft, GAO-09-458T (Washington, DC: U.S. 40. Sarah Chayes, Thieves of the State: Why Corruption
Government Printing Office, 2009), Highlights Threatens Global Security (New York: Norton,
page. 2015).
25. See, for example, James Q. Wilson, “Corruption 41. Stapenhurst and Kpundeh, Curbing Corruption.
Is Not Always Scandalous,” New York Times 42. Nicholas Apergis, Oguzhan Dincer, and James
Magazine (April 28, 1968), pp. 54–62, and Samuel Payne, “The Relationship between Corruption
P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing and Income Inequality in U.S. States: Evidence
Societies (New York: Norton, 1968). from a Panel Cointegration and Error Correction
26. Harold F. Gosnell, Machine Politics: Chicago Model Model,” Public Choice 145 (October 2010),
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1937). pp. 125–135.
27. Thomas R. Dye, Politics in States and Communities, 43. Cheol Liu and John L. Mikesell, “The Impact
9th ed. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, of Public Officials’ Corruption on the Size
1997), pp. 292, 299. and Allocation of U.S. State Spending,” Public
28. Rick Stapenhurst and Sahr Kpundeh, eds., Administration Review 74 (May/June 2014),
Curbing Corruption: Toward a Model for Building pp.  346–358. State corruption rankings are for
National Integrity (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1976–2008. Spending figures are for 1997–2008.
1999). 44. Stapenhurst and Kpundeh, Curbing Corruption.
29. Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social 45. Alberto Alesina and Beatrice Weder, Do Corrupt
Structures (New York: Free Press, 1957). Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?
30. Daniel Kaufmann and Shang-Jin Wei, Does “Grease (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Money” Speed Up the Wheels of Commerce? Research, 1999).
(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic 46. Anne Applebaum, “The Anti-Corruption Move-
Research, 1999). ment: Human Rights’ Natural Partner,” Washington
31. World Bank Institute, as cited in Transparency Post (December 12, 2012).
International, Perceived Corruption Index, 2005 47. James Anderson, Joel Hellman, Geraint Jones,
(Berlin: Author, 2005). et al., Anticorruption in Transition: A Contribution
32. World Bank, World Development Report, 1997 to the Policy Debate (Washington, DC: World
(Washington, DC: Oxford University Press, 1997), Bank, 2000), p. xiv.
pp. 102–104. 48. Barbara Crosette, “U.N. Says Bad Government Is
33. Paolo Mauro, Why Worry About Corruption? Often Cause of Poverty,” New York Times (April 5,
(Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 2000).
1997), pp. 9–10. Figures are for 1982–1995. 49. James R. Hines, Jr., Forbidden Payment: Foreign
34. Stapenhurst and Kpundeh, Curbing Corruption. Bribery and American Business after 1977
35. Sanjeev Gupta, Hamid Davoodi, and Rosa Alonso- (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Terme, Does Corruption Affect Income Inequality Research, 1995).
and Poverty? (Washington, DC: International 50. Kevin Sullivan, “Spoils for the Rulers, Terror for
Monetary Fund, 1998). the Ruled,” Washington Post (October 1, 2015).
36. Leslie Wayne, “Hits, and Misses, in a War on 51. Pew Global Attitudes Project, Global Opinion
Bribery,” New York Times (March 10, 2012). Trends, 2002–2007 (Washington, DC: Author,
Figure is for 2001–2002. 2008), p. 34. Figures are for 2007.
37. Kaufmann and Wei, Does “Grease Money” Speed 52. Pippa Norris, as quoted in Richard Morin, “Islam
Up the Wheels of Commerce? Abstract page. and Democracy,” Washington Post (April 28,
38. Jakob Fisman and Raymond J. Svensson, “Are 2002).
Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to 53. Gal Ariely, Emile Kolthoff, Michael Macaulay, and
Growth? Firm Level Evidence,” Journal of Deve- Frank Anechiarico, “Public Administration and
lopment Economics 83 (May 2007), pp. 63–75. Citizen Satisfaction with Democracy: Cross-
39. Manuel Villoria, Greg G. Van Ryzen, and Cecelia National Evidence,” International Review of
F. Lavena, “Social and Political Consequences Administrative Sciences 79 (December 2013),
of Corruption: A Study of Public Perceptions in pp.  747–766. The quotations are on p. 747.
Spain,” Public Administration Review 73 (January/ Emphasis added.
February 2013), pp. 85–96. 54. Stephen Knack, Social Capital and the Quality
PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well 9

of Government: Evidence from the U.S. States Confidence in Government after September 11
(Washington, DC: World Bank Development (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2002), p. 3.
Research Group, 2000), p. 24. Emphasis added. 57. Kathy Frankovic, “Polls Show Skepticism of
55. Jerrell D. Coggburn and Saundra K. Schneider, Katrina Recovery,” CBS News (August 29, 2007).
“The Relationship between State Government 58. Barack Obama, Inaugural Address (Washington,
Performance and State Quality of Life,” Inter- DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, January 20,
national Journal of Public Administration 26 2009).
(December 2003), pp. 1337–1358. The quotation 59. William H. Harader, “Whither Public Administra-
is on p. 1337. Emphasis added. tion?” Public Administration Review 37 (January/
56. G. Calvin McKenzie and Judith M. Labiner, February 1977), pp. 97–102. The quotation is on
Opportunity Lost: The Rise and Fall of Trust and p. 98.
CHAPTER

Big Democracy, Big


Bureaucracy

T
“ he true test of a good government is its apti-
tude and tendency to produce a good admin-
istration.” So wrote a famous founder of the United
rule on their own sceptered isle. No less an authority
than Woodrow Wilson, the acknowledged academic
founder of American public administration, observed
States, Alexander Hamilton, in “No. 68” of The that, “The English race long and successfully studied
Federalist Papers, the superb essays about govern- the art of curbing executive power to the constant
ance that preceded the Constitution. (So convinced neglect of the art of perfecting executive methods.”3
was Hamilton of this that he repeated the sentence, The Indians and the English set a governing
verbatim, in “No. 76.”) tone that, in the eighteenth century, expressed itself
Were he alive today, Hamilton might be dis- in three formats that outlined Americans’ enduring
appointed in a public bureaucracy that appears, at social contract, or that unwritten agreement between
least, to be atrophied when compared with its coun- the governed and their governments, often more
terparts in most other developed democracies. This understood than expressed, that defines and limits
seeming bureaucratic flaccidity is a consequence of the responsibilities of each.
an entrenched national culture and careful political
design.
Administration by Ambassadors:
The Articles of Confederation
AN UNPROMISING PRECIS One such format was the woefully misnamed Articles
The roots of Americans’ profound suspicion of exec- of Confederation and Perpetual Union, which, from
utive authority are deeply sunk, and are apparent in 1781 to 1789, provided the first framework for the
the nation’s earliest influences and origins. new nation and exemplified Americans’ contempt
for princely prerogatives.
There was no chief executive. In fact, the first
The Indians and the English draft of the Articles, written in 1776, was rejected
One such influence was the Native Americans, who by the Second Continental Congress on the specific
surrounded the early European settlers. Hence, the grounds that it had proposed an executive, and this
“framers of the Constitution . . . were pervaded bias against executive authority extended to every
by Indian images of liberty.”1 The vast Iroquois national officeholder; under the Articles, every con-
Confederation was emblematic of executive con- tinental official had a one-year term, and each one
straint: “Their whole civil policy was averse to the was subject to term limits.4
concentration of power in any single individual.”2 The states reigned supreme under the Articles.
Another influence was the English, who governed Congress was less a legislature and more a conven-
their colonists with a firm hand but resisted royal tion of powerless state ambassadors, chosen by state
10
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 11

assemblies, which could recall them at will. National (he was its first treasury secretary), but likely its first
administrators reported directly to congressional scholar of public administration, too. Hamilton was
committees. contemplating a “full investigation of the history and
When Daniel Shays launched, in 1786, his rebel- science of civil government and . . . practical results
lion against the government of Massachusetts—a of various modifications of it upon the freedom and
rebellion that had to be put down solely by the com- happiness of mankind.”7 In other words, Hamilton
monwealth’s militia—it became clear that the Articles was about to write the world’s first textbook in
were a failed vehicle for national governance. public administration, a project terminated by his
death in a duel.
Hamilton extolled a strong chief executive,
Administration by Legislators: The First equating a strong executive with the “energy” needed
State Constitutions to make a government function: “A feeble executive
At about the same time that the Articles of [by contrast] implies a feeble execution of govern-
Confederation were being written, eleven states ment. A feeble execution is but another phrase for
were busily drafting their own constitutions and a bad execution; and a government ill executed . . .
they reflected the Articles’ anti-executive paranoia. must be, in practice, a bad government.”8 Things, in
In ten states, governors were appointed by legis- sum, had to get done.
latures or the courts and were granted terms of a Even more than a strong chief executive,
single year. Nine states aggressively limited, or even Hamilton advocated a very strong bureaucracy. He
denied, their chief executives the veto and appoint- urged that department heads be paid exceptionally
ment power. All executive power, and most judicial well, that they possess substantial powers, and that
power, resided in the state legislatures or in “privy their tenure in office should extend beyond that of
councils” composed mostly of elected officials who the chief executive who appointed them.
usually were appointed by legislators.
At least one petulant English observer foresaw Jeffersonian Constraint In stark contrast to
the impossibility of his former colonies to ever found Hamilton, Jefferson held a “profound distrust of
a government worthy of the name, and he attributed bureaucracy,” and “was no friend . . . to profession-
this failure to Americans’ fixation on a weak exec- alism in public administration.”9
utive: “As to the future grandeur of America, and As we explain in the introduction to Part III
its being a rising empire under one head, whether and Chapter 7, the founders were concerned about
Republican or Monarchial, it is one of the idlest and governmental efficiency and honesty, two values that
most visionary notions that was ever conceived even gave birth to American public administration. But
by writers of romance.”5 it was Jefferson’s argument against an active public
administration that prevailed.
Jefferson’s victory is indicated by the fact that
Administration by Enfeebled Executives: the word, “administration” (or its cognates), appears
Jefferson Prevails in The Federalist Papers a remarkable 124 times—
Layering and striating all of this early American activ- more frequently than “Congress,” “President,” and
ity in drafting confederations and constitutions was “Supreme Court.”10 Yet, the word is nowhere to
our third expression of the emerging social contract: be found in the Constitution that James Madison,
the massive brilliance of America’s founders, but par- Jefferson’s disciple, largely framed.
ticularly that of Hamilton and Thomas Jefferson. “So Ironically, the more experience that Jefferson
baked into our civic DNA is this that today, more gained as a public official, the more that he forsook
than two centuries after our founding, our language this position, ultimately reversing his views, and
and behavior still are shaped and influenced by the advocating far greater powers for public execu-
alternatives represented by the two men.”6 tives. In his retirement, Jefferson even argued that
the “laws of necessity . . . are of higher obligation
Hamiltonian Energy Hamilton was not only, like [than] a scrupulous adherence to written law,”11 an
Jefferson, one of America’s first public administrators opinion as disquieting as Richard Nixon’s, uttered
12 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

167 years later: “If the president does it, that means relationship with the state. The American social con-
it’s not illegal.”12 tract, forged in revolution, leashes government with
a taut tether. Those who govern are, in every sense,
the citizenry’s “servants,” and, consequently, the
A CULTURE OF CONSTRAINT American social contract may be reduced to a word.
These eighteenth-century expressions of govern- That word is: constraint.
ment’s role reflected an already-formed American Such phrases as “the hollow government,”
political culture that continues unabated today. “government by gridlock,” and “demosclerosis” all
suggest a governance jammed by malfunctioning
political mechanisms. In reality, however, turbid gov-
Americans and Their Governments ernance is a consequence of an American culture that
Americans’ perspective on the proper place of places a high premium on constraining what govern-
government differs radically from that of Europeans. ments do. So ingrained is this culture of constraint
Fifty-eight percent of Americans think that the that serious scholars of American public adminis-
“freedom to pursue life’s goals without state interfer- tration have been known to argue against activist
ence” is more important than that the “state guar- administrative reforms precisely because they could
antees nobody is in need,” which just 35 percent displace constrained, “prudential judgment” by “dis-
believe  to be more important. Among Britons, creet ‘mandarins.’”15
Germans, French, and Spaniards, these percentages An American culture of administrative con-
range from 30 to 38 percent and from 55 to 67 percent, straint is unique to the public sector, and is quite
respectively. Similarly, 36 percent of Americans agree the opposite from that of the private sector, with its
that “success in life is determined by forces outside rapacious, robber-baron roots. Consider the assess-
our control,” but 62 percent disagree with the state- ment by Ted Turner, the spectacularly innovative and
ment. From 41 to 72 percent of the respondents in candid entrepreneur who founded CNN and other
the four European countries agree, and from 27 to 55 cable networks: “You play to win. And you know
percent disagree.13 Large majorities of Americans of you’ve won when the government stops you.”16
all races believe that “poor people have become too
dependent on government assistance programs.”14
Not for nothing has Europe been called America’s Governing in a Distrusting Culture
biggest blue state. Constrained governance is inextricably enmeshed
More broadly, the greatest governmental gap in Americans’ distrust of government. As Figure 1-1
between Americans and the rest of the world is their shows, only 22 percent of Americans trust government.

70

60

50

40

30

20
19 8
19 0
19 2
19 4
19 6
68

19 0
19 2
19 4
19 6
19 8
19 0
19 2
19 4
19 6
19 8
19 0
19 2
19 4
19 6
20 8
20 0
02
04

12
5
6
6
6
6

7
7
7
7
7
8
8
8
8
8
9
9
9
9
9
0
19

19

20

20

FIGURE 1-1
Trust in Government Index 1958–2012
Source: The National Election Studies, University of Michigan. The NES Guide to public Opinion and Behavior (Ann Arbor, MI: Author, 2005).
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 13

Distrust of Government Americans’ distrust less “negative” popular evaluations of the perfor-
focuses on government’s size, direction, performance, mance of the entire political system;29 and even with
and power.17 They reserve their deepest distrust for lower rates of street crime.30
those parts of government that house elected offi- In the United States, high levels of trust in gov-
cials, and display their highest trust for agencies with ernment not only associate with lower levels of cor-
public safety or military missions, findings that “are ruption31 and street crime,32 but also with energetic
consistent to a large extent with findings in other and widespread public policy innovation.33 In the
Western countries.”18 view of local officials, there is a very robust connec-
Over thirteen years, the number of Americans tion between high trust and deeper engagement by
who thought that the federal, state, and local gov- citizens in local policymaking.34
ernments have a “negative impact” on their day-to-
day lives grew, on average, by more than three-fifths, High Trust Equals High Performance Of greatest
a startling increase, and those who felt that govern- importance, public trust and esteem are “positively
ments’ impact was positive plummeted by a fourth.19 related” with high performance by public agencies
Not even half, a declining proportion of Americans, and greater citizen satisfaction with public services,
think that government is “really run for the benefit a “strong correlation” that is “not unusual and is
of all the people.”20 The decline in trust of govern- acknowledged in the literature.”35 This strong corre-
ment is not limited to the United States, and appears lation appears to be universal in democracies,36 and
to be global.21 it exists because trust “helps determine how much
Public administrators’ opinions track those power citizens grant” to their governments, which,
of the general public. Top federal, state, and local in turn, “is what allows citizens to grant the flexibil-
executives believe that “there is a deeply systemic ity required for bureaucrats to effectively govern.”37
problem with our governance system,” which “is not Indeed, trust trumps public participation in agency
performing the way it should.”22 decision making, accessibility of services, and even
Ominously, the public’s distrust of govern- equality of treatment as a correlate with higher
ment may be morphing from a political distrust public performance.38
(e.g., a gridlocked, unacceptably partisan Congress) Certainly, these patterns are found in the
to an institutional distrust, a leeriness caused by United  States. There is a clear correlation, for
strings of institutional failures, such as the pathetic example, between plentiful social capital (an index
roll-out of HealthCare.gov, the General Services composed of “generalized trust and strong civic
Administration’s high-rolling “conferences” in Las norms”) and high-performing state governments.39
Vegas and other resorts, and the deadly corruption Similarly, as state budgets improve, popular trust in
that afflicts the Veterans Health Administration, state governments rises.40 A study of the thirty-five
to name a few. In this light, it is worrisome that a largest American cities found that a 5 percent
survey of likely voters found that an astonishing 64 increase in popular trust in their government
percent thought that “things in the U.S. feel like they resulted in a 1 percent hike in that government’s
are out of control right now.”23 performance.41

Why Trust Matters Public trust in government is


critically important to good governance. THE CONSEQUENCES
Some Diverse and Unexpected Correlations High OF CONSTRAINT
levels of trust in government correlate, positively Constraint. What are its consequences in the context
and internationally, with: less political corruption24 of American governments?
(public esteem, a corollary of trust, for government
also associates with lower corruption25); better “gov-
ernment performance on the economy”;26 greater Hobbled Elected Chief Executives
economic growth and opportunity;27 superior “per- A notable consequence is the hobbling of elected
ceived outcomes” by networks of governments;28 chief executives at every level of government.
14 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

The Domesticated Presidency Largely as a con- agency policymaking, and this has been consistently
sequence of a largesse of Lilliputian leashes that the case for more than a quarter century; “legislators
Congress has imposed on executive action, there is exert major influence on agency rules.”45
a historic “presidential tendency” to be “reactive” in
domestic politics, where power must be shared with An Insipid Appointment Power Out of six “institu-
Congress and often is reined in by the courts, but to tional powers” available to the governors, the power
be “proactive . . . powerful, costly . . . energetic,” and to appoint ranks as the weakest.46 More than half
interventionist in foreign affairs.42 This reality has of key state administrators are not appointed by
endured for the life of the nation. the governor. Of the almost 2,000 major adminis-
Consider, first, Thomas Jefferson. In domes- trative officers in the fifty states, 750 are appointed
tic matters, Jefferson is one of only seven presi- by someone or some body other than the governor,
dents, and the sole two-term president, who never and nearly 300 are elected directly by the people.47
vetoed an act of Congress. Yet, in foreign affairs, he When we add in those state administrators who are
acted with stunning boldness. A case-in-point is the less than major, the total number who are elected
Louisiana Purchase. With no consultation whatso- separately surpasses 500, or more than ten per state,
ever with Congress, Jefferson assigned two of his on average, a number that has “changed little” since
public administrators to “merely inquire” about 1955.48
buying from France “The Floridas”—which were When agency heads are “outside the orbit of
Spain’s, but who knew?—and New Orleans. When control by the governor via appointment,” not-
France unexpectedly offered the entire Louisiana so-good things happen. Compared with those
Territory, Jefferson’s administrators snapped it up— appointed by the governor, these state executives not
without, in turn, consulting Jefferson. This unilat- only are somewhat more attuned to legislators than
eral act doubled the size of the nation – hardly a to their governors, they also attribute a significantly
dilettantish dabbling in diplomacy. So controversial “higher level of influence” to special interests when
was “this extraordinary example of administrative making policy, and lobbyists’ access to their agencies
discretion” that a band of respected political leaders is “definitely greater.”49
tried to organize a secession of Northern states!43
Consider, second, Bill Clinton. In 1998, a surreal Lieutenant Governors, Term Limits, and Recalls
spectacle of this schizoid duality unfolded when the There are additional constraints on executive power
House of Representatives voted to impeach him (for in the states.
only the second time in history) on charges pertaining One is the fact that, in twenty-four of the
entirely to domestic affairs, while President Clinton forty-three states with lieutenant governors (we are
simultaneously launched a major and sustained air not counting Tennessee and West Virginia, which
war against Iraq because it refused to cooperate with accord that title to the senate president), the gov-
weapons inspectors from the United Nations. ernor and lieutenant governor are elected inde-
In the administration of the nation, Jeffersonian pendently,50 and, presumably, have political agendas
constraint prevails—but only in domestic affairs. In that differ. (In 1804, Americans relieved the federal
foreign ones, Katy bar the door; Hamiltonian energy government of this potentially destabilizing conflict,
is rampant. as it applied to the president and vice president, by
ratifying the Twelfth Amendment.)
Constraining Governors Governors gradually Another is term limits—or the lack of them.
have gained executive power over the last three Most elected state administrators —from more
centuries—since 1960, state constitutional revisions than half to all, depending on the office51—and
have lengthened their terms of office and strength- legislators in thirty-five states,52 may be re-elected
ened their powers of appointment, budgeting, and the without limit, a potentially huge political advantage.
veto44—but they still remain tightly constrained. For By contrast, governors in only fourteen states have
example, state agency heads accord their governors unlimited terms.53
and legislators essentially identical levels of influence In 1908, Oregon introduced the state recall,
in agency “rulemaking,” which is a pseudonym for or a specially called election, initiated by voters
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 15

signing petitions, that determines whether or not an (86 percent of whom are part-timers), a mayor and
elected officeholder may complete his or her term. a council president, and in just 11 percent (a declin-
Most often, the recall petition must be signed by 25 ing number) of these jurisdictions does the mayor or
percent of all registered voters or by 25 percent of president have the exclusive authority to make and
voters who voted in the last election, “the highest recommend a budget.65 In those cities where depart-
signature threshold for any type of petition.”54 ment heads are appointed, only 17 percent (and
Thirty-six states have laws allowing for the recall of shrinking) of mayors or council presidents have the
some elected state or local officials.55 Three states sole power of appointment.66
permit the recall of any official, elected or not, and Puny powers indeed.
seven specifically include federal officials as subject
to recalls.56 The Rising Recall The local recall was invented
Nineteen states and the District of Columbia in 1903 by Los Angeles, and today twenty-nine
permit the recall of elected state (or district) offi- states permit voters in at least some of their local
cials and, although it has been used only three times jurisdictions to recall their elected chief executives,
against sitting governors (twice successfully),57 it is as well as  city council members and other city
a growing constraint. Of the thirty-two successful officials,  county commissioners and other county
recalls of state legislators conducted over 102 years, officials, sheriffs, school and special district board
a third have taken place since 2011.58 members, or state legislators.67 Even though many
mayors, council presidents, county commission
Constraining Local Elected Chief Executives Local chairs, and board members of special districts are
elected chief executives typically have powers barely not elected by voters, they still may be recalled
worthy of the noun. by them.
Voters in 56 percent of cities and towns (recall
Puny Political Powers Almost three-quarters of petitions are filed in about 5 percent of them annu-
county commission chairs,59 roughly half of the ally),68 and in 55 percent of counties69 may recall
mayors of towns and townships,60 and nearly a local officials. An estimated three-fourths of all
fourth of city mayors,61 are not elected to office local recall elections are at the city council or school
by popular vote. Instead, they are selected by their board level.70 From 14 to 19 percent of the officials
fellow council members or even by mindless rota- facing these elections are recalled, with the board
tion, thereby denying them their own electoral members of special districts being the leading losers,
power bases. at 80 percent.71
By contrast, legions of more specialized local Only about two-fifths of the total “recall
executives, such as sheriffs, treasurers, tax collec- efforts” aimed at all local officials ultimately make
tors, coroners, and clerks, are, as required by state it to the ballot. From a fourth to a third of these
constitutions, voted into office. On average, county efforts are targeted at mayors and council presi-
voters elect an astounding fourteen “row officers” dents,72 and typically are initiated because of service
(so named for the rows and rows of these positions cuts or tax hikes. There are, of course, some idiosyn-
that appear on the ballot), and township voters elect cratic reasons as well, such as the Ogden, Kansas,
five. City voters elect an average of only two, but, mayor who was recalled because he had fired two
in 14 percent of cities, residents elect some or all lifeguards. About a fourth of recall elections result in
department heads, and, in 25 percent, these admin- mayors resigning or being voted out of office.73 City
istrators are appointed not by the mayor, but by the council members comprise about half of all local
city council.62 recall efforts.74
Fifty-four percent of mayors and other local chief Historically, local recall efforts were rare. From
elected officers have terms of fewer than four years, 1911 through 2001, recall efforts were attempted in
and 33 percent (the next highest) have terms of just just ten of those years; beginning in 2002, however,
two years;63 95 percent have no veto power.64 recall efforts have occurred in every year without
Thirty-one percent of cities and towns split exception. Moreover, from 1911 through 2007,
their powers between two elected chief executives local recall efforts never exceeded three per year. In
16 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

2007, in keeping with tradition, there were three, with lower levels of corruption; an analysis of
but, in 2008, there were a record eight. Then, in fifty-seven democratic nations found that the more
2009, out of nowhere, 100 local recall efforts were that direct democracy was present, the smaller the
made, challenging not only a single elected official, shadow economy.78
but often entire councils, commissions, and boards.
Recall efforts continued to climb steadily, and, by Constraining State Governments Perhaps the least
2014, there were 189, targeting 387 local officials.75 direct device of direct democracy is the referendum,
The surge in recall efforts likely will continue, or a legislatively authorized popular vote to approve
and is attributable, in part, to the rise of informa- or disapprove proposed policy. Invented by South
tion technology, which has produced more reliable Dakota, in 1898, it has since spread to twenty-three
voter registration lists; relatedly, social media have states, and voters typically approve from three-
made petition signing much easier (if you want to quarters to four-fifths of them.79
recall a public official, there is an app for that). The South Dakota, also in 1898, gave us the initia-
nationalization of recall elections also is an impor- tive, or initiative petition, which places an issue on
tant factor. An example: of the nearly $64 million the ballot by gathering a stipulated percentage of
spent (unsuccessfully) in 2012 to recall Wisconsin’s registered voters’ signatures on a petition. Two dozen
governor because of his anti-union policies, more states now have it.80 The states’ use of the initiative
than half was contributed by unions and conserva- has nearly quadrupled since the 1960s, when fewer
tive groups external to the state.76 than a hundred were on state ballots, to a record 377
in the 1990s and 374 in the 2000s, a number second
only to the nineties.81 Slightly more than two-fifths
Hobbled Governments of all 2,421 state initiatives, beginning with the first
The constraints that Americans have imposed on one, in 1904, have been approved by voters.82
their elected chief executives extend to the institu- State initiatives can be costly and often are pro-
tion of government itself. moted by special interests. In the eleven states with
long histories of initiatives, corporations and bil-
Constraining the Federal Government The lionaires spent more than $1 billion over eighteen
American founders created a Constitution that months either for or against initiatives that involved
divides power between the national and state govern- taxes, casinos, and political fundraising by unions,
ments, and checks and balances federal power among among other policies.83
its executive, legislative, and adjudicative branches.
More contemporaneously, as we elaborate in Chapter Constraining Local Governments Local govern-
11, the federal government has ceded significant ments use most of the devices of direct democracy
power to private and nonprofit organizations. In the even more liberally than do states. Seventy percent
2010s, a sharply divided Congress has proven to be of cities have the referendum, and 92 percent have
the least productive in history (details follow). the initiative.84 More than seven out of ten counties
allow the referendum and the initiative.85
Constraining the Grass Roots The people have
imposed on their state and local governments the
devices of direct democracy, or the use of specially Hobbled Governmental Growth
called elections to approve or disapprove policy A culture of constraint restrains governmental
proposals or to retain or remove elected officials. growth.
“Every state has some form of legislative process American governments do grow. By the close
which allows the government to place issues on the of the 1800s, federal, state, and local government
ballot.”77 workers accounted for not even 2 percent of the
Though direct democracy clearly constrains population, and government revenues at all levels
governments, it also associates with some good amounted to about 8 percent of the economy.86 The
things: it likely renders governments more respon- proportion of all government workers since has more
sive to the electorate, and it correlates positively than tripled, accounting for more than 7  percent
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 17

of the population,87 and revenues collected by all 1950s, “before the advent of the most expensive
governments, at more than 19 percent of the gross transfer programs,” such as Medicare.92 One result:
domestic product (GDP), have more than doubled today, only 1 percent of Americans rank the tax
their share of the economy.88 system as the country’s top problem.93
The heart of our matter, however, is this: Do American governments are substantially smaller
American governments grow as fast and as big as than are governments in other developed democra-
governments elsewhere? cies. Whereas the revenue collected by all American
No, they do not. Constrained governmen- governments amounts to 26 percent of GDP, those
tal growth has been particularly evident since collected by the governments of thirty-four devel-
1978, when California’s notorious initiative, oped democracies, including the United States,
Proposition  13, was voted in by a two-to-one amount to an unweighted average of over 34 percent
popular margin. Proposition 13 slashed, and effec- of their respective GDPs–– a fourth higher take than
tively capped, all local property taxes, and made in the United States, which ranks thirty-first lowest
California the only state that requires a two-thirds (only Chile, Mexico, and South Korea are lower).94
vote in the legislature both to adopt a budget and Not only does the United States have a lower overall
to raise any tax. tax rate than almost all comparable countries, but,
Proposition 13 not only had a devastating remarkably, each type of American tax—income,
impact on California’s education, infrastructure, sales, property, and payroll tax—is lower than its
and finances, but, despite its status as the enduring counterpart tax in these nations.95
and iconic symbol of the revolt against governmen- Perhaps more than any other measures, the
tal growth, flatly failed to stanch that growth. The relatively slow rate of America’s long-term govern-
lost property tax revenue was replaced by sales and mental growth and the comparatively small size
income tax revenue. California has the highest sales of American governments, stand as testaments to
tax and personal income tax in the country for top America’s culture of governmental constraint.
earners, and one of the highest corporate income
tax rates (which may, in part, explain why it has the
third worst business climate of the states). In 1978, THE BUREAUCRAT: BRAINED,
the state had the highest overall tax burden, and
thirty-five years later, it still had the highest overall BLAMED, AND BOUNCING BACK
tax burden.89 America’s culture of constrained governance has
Between 1946 (the year following the end of unique effects on its public administrators.
World War II) and 1978 (the year of Proposition
13, which most observers peg as the year of the
tax revolt’s first shot heard around the nation), the Bashing Bureaucrats
revenue collected by the federal government as a per- A major effect is bureaucrat bashing. Wide swaths
centage of personal income grew by about one-half of American institutions single out the bureaucrat as
of 1 percent per year (17 percent over thirty-two the craven cause of governmental failure.
years), and the revenues of state and local govern-
ments as a percentage of personal income grew by Politicians’ Pandering Politicians routinely run
4 percent per year, nearly doubling over the same against the bureaucracy in their ceaseless grubbing
period. But after 1978, federal revenue as a percent- for votes. The campaign mantra of bureaucratic
age of personal income essentially held flat, and after “waste, fraud, and abuse” has been a self-serving
2001, as a consequence of unprecedented federal tax rhetorical standard of office seekers for more than
cuts, it actually declined.90 Similarly, after 1978, the a generation.96
growth of state and local revenues as a percentage of Once elected to office, politicians are radically
personal income was slashed by three-fourths to a more contemptuous of public administrators than
growth rate of about 1 percent per year.91 Today, all are the voters whose support they sought. The pro-
taxes imposed by all governments are at their lowest portions of elected officials who characterize public
levels as a percentage of personal income since the administrators as “dull” or who “make red tape” are
18 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

twice those of the general public, and the percentage


of politicians who describe them as “bureaucratic” Are Bureaucrats to Blame?
is three times that of the citizenry.97 When speak- Do Americans really believe that their public admin-
ing on the floor of the U.S. House, Representatives istrators are against them?
call public administrators “bureaucrats” 70 percent
of the time, and 84 percent of these references are The Public Likes Public Administrators Evidently
clearly pejorative.98 not. Overall, “the American public does not appear
as disdainful of bureaucrats as the projected media
Academia’s Undercutting Intellectuals foster an image would indicate.”105 More than seven out of
image of bureaucracy that ranges from its being every ten Americans have stated that they have a
merely unresponsive to dangerously undemocratic. favorable opinion of government workers.106 Only
This anti-public-administration propaganda begins 6 percent of Americans blame government employ-
at an early age. American children’s literature ees for “what is wrong with government,” com-
portrays public servants as measurably less benev- pared with four times that number, 24 percent,
olent and competent than does British children’s who say elected officeholders are responsible for
literature.99 government’s failures.107 Seventy-three percent of
Over three-fourths of introductory college Americans have “a lot of” (22 percent) or “some”
textbooks on American government portray public (51 percent) confidence in federal civilian workers;
administrators as “government employees who stay “Americans like federal workers a lot more than
on forever,” and two-thirds demonize governmental their bosses.”108
bureaucracy as “all powerful and out of control.”100 Why do Americans like public administrators
“The most deeply rooted and persistent misconcep- in spite of their deepening distrust of elected leaders
tion” of these texts is that public administrators “are and government, and the unremitting bombardment
not accountable.”101 fired by politicians, professors, reporters, and enter-
tainers blasting bureaucrats?
Media’s Mordancy Judging by what evidence
we have, the news media’s coverage of the public Encountering Bureaucrats Because bureaucrats
bureaucracy is not good. Over the course of two deliver. Polls prove it.
decades, 80 percent of the televised news stories About two-thirds of Americans who have asked
about the federal government, and 70 percent of federal, state, or local bureaucrats to do some-
the printed ones, focused on the executive branch, thing unusual for them—that is, their request was
and only a third—or, more commonly, depending not a routine matter—found their civil servants to
on the medium, less—of those that focused on the be helpful,109 a striking proportion that belies the
executive branch’s “job performance” were positive stereotype of inflexible, impersonal bureaucrats.
in tone.102 Nearly three-quarters of Americans report that “the
Media’s mordancy is not confined to the news. people at the [government] office” are very efficient
Thirty percent of television’s prime-time enter- (43 percent) or fairly efficient (31 percent) in handling
tainment episodes present civil servants in a posi- their problems, and more than three-fourths feel that
tive light  and 22 percent in a negative one—“as they are treated fairly; indeed, only 12 percent think
robotic paper shufflers or abrasive malcontents that they are treated unfairly.110
who were too  lazy, apathetic or self-absorbed to American bureaucrats give generally good
serve the public” (the remaining 48 percent portray service, too. At least one survey found “no system-
them in  neutral, “unmemorable roles”); these atic difference in attitudes” among citizens about the
figures that  have remained fairly constant since quality of selected private services and comparable
the mid-twentieth century.103 Perhaps we should federal, state, and local ones.111
not be surprised that young adults’ “favorite TV In annual surveys that have been conducted for
public servant” is the casually corrupt, and defini- well over a decade, selected federal agencies have
tively dumb, animated Mayor Joe Quimby of The received “customer experience” scores from the
Simpsons.104 public that range from sixty-four to seventy-two out
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 19

of 100 possible points. These are lower scores than institution of government persists.122 This phenom-
what businesses typically receive, which generally enon has been labeled “bureauphobia,” and it may
are accorded scores in the mid-seventies,112 and they affect as much as a fifth of those who deal with agen-
have been declining since 2012,113 perhaps because cies.123
of “cutbacks in agency budgets and staffs, which The high regard that Americans have for agen-
have made it difficult to provide quality service.”114 cies with which they have dealt is significant because
The federal government, probably like most govern- “the impact of a negative experience with a public
ments, usually receives the lowest scores for accessi- agency is much more pronounced than the effect
bility, timeliness, and efficiency of services,115 not a of a positive one . . .. Decreasing the number of
surprising finding in light of the fact that citizens, as disappointed clients will have a stronger effect on
opposed to customers, have little choice in selecting increasing trust in . . . government than increasing
public service providers. the number of already well-pleased clients.”124
Even though 59 percent of registered voters
are “frustrated” with the federal government, and
22 percent are “angry” with it,116 a surprising 58 A PARADOXICAL POWER:
percent of the citizenry view federal agencies favora- THE GRAY EMINENCE OF THE
bly. When asked whether they had positive or neg-
ative opinions about eight agencies, seven received PUBLIC ADMINISTRATOR
positive responses, ranging from 51 to 70 percent. So what does all this mean for the American public
Only the Internal Revenue Service was ranked unfa- administrator? It means that the United States has
vorably by most respondents (no surprise, that), but, produced a paradoxical public administration char-
at 48 percent, not by much.117 acterized by cultural, institutional, and legal limits
From three-fifths to over four-fifths of the public on executive action, and by a nonetheless powerful
report that they are satisfied or highly satisfied with public administrative class. “The fragmented mana-
state governmental services,118 and local services gerial climate of government” actually grants public
garner “generally favorable assessments” from more administrators more opportunities for acquiring
than 200,000 citizens in forty states.119 power than are available to their corporate coun-
terparts.125

The Bureaucrat: Government’s Savior?


Ironically, those battered and bruised bureaucrats Staying Power
may be leading the way in restoring Americans’ trust Of considerable, but often underappreciated, impor-
in government. tance is the staying power of bureaucracies and the
Seventy percent of Americans have low expec- bureaucrats in them, a power that permits them to
tations about obtaining good governmental services, wait out elected officeholders and the policies that
but more Americans, 77 percent, who actually expe- they push.
rience public services feel that they receive services Of 175 federal agencies, only 15 percent dis-
of high quality.120 appeared over a half century, a “death rate” that
The consequences of these positive experiences was far below that of business failures during the
with governments are varied. Overall, Americans same period, leading to the conclusion that, by
who have had good experiences with an agency (32 and large, government organizations are “immor-
percent, versus 18 percent who have not) are “three tal.”126 Examples include the Commission for the
times more likely to give a positive performance Standardization of Screw Threads, formed in 1918
rating” to “government in general” (41 percent with a sixty-day life span, and the Federal Helium
versus 14 percent).121 Those citizens who have had Reserve, created by Congress in 1925 to assure the
positive personal dealings with an agency, but who Army Air Corps a continuing supply of fuel for its
hold a deeply negative view about government in cutting-edge (at the time) aeronautical technology—
general, express highly positive opinions about that blimps. These and others, if differently titled, remain
particular agency but their negative view of the with us today.
20 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

Just as bureaucracies stay on, so do bureau- Supreme Court declared the practice to be unconsti-
crats. As we detail in Chapter 9, the median job tutional.133
tenure for workers in all governments is more than In 2017, Congress remembered its Congressional
twice as long as that for employees in the private Review Act of 1996, which allows Congress to review
sector, and, depending on the level of government, how agencies fill in the blanks in a law (which, as just
top public careerists average from seventeen to noted, happens more often than not), but only when
twenty-six years on public payrolls. Forty-three Congress specifically grants such an authority to the
percent of federal civilian workers, 38 percent of agencies in that law. The objective is to assure that
state government employees, and 37 percent of the agencies hew closely to the spirit of the law. Congress
local workforce are fifty years old or older; for the has at least sixty days to conduct this review, and, if
private sector, this figure is just 29 percent of all majorities in both chambers pass a “joint resolution
employees.127 of disapproval” and the president signs it, then the
Bureaucracies and bureaucrats endure. agencies’ fill-in (in reality a rule) is terminated.
The act has been successfully implemented
only once, when the president signed a resolution in
Discretionary Power 2001, but the president vetoed five resolutions since.
Discretionary power refers to a public administra- With the election, in 2016, of a president and major-
tor’s authority to make and administer regulatory ities in the House and Senate, all of the same party,
and bureaucratic policies, and to interpret and the Congressional Review Act is receiving renewed
implement legislative policies. attention. But the difference between a legislative
Discretion counts. In the American states, for veto and a congressional veto of how agencies have
example, “greater managerial discretion,” in tandem filled in legislative blanks strikes us as dim; given the
with deregulation, “drove reforms” in the critical judiciary’s negative position on the legislative veto, it
areas of budgeting, procurement, and personnel, would not be surprising if it took a similar position
and, in all three areas, these reforms left “a deep and on the Congressional Review Act.
long legacy.”128
Legislatures frequently enable bureaucratic
discretion. For instance, Congress, in 1988, effec- Policymaking Power
tively granted the Federal Emergency Management Aside from the actual decision to select a public
Agency total authority to determine not only how policy (a decision that, as we detail in Chapter 10, is
much  assistance is needed in a disaster, but even uniquely idiosyncratic for each policy process), pol-
how much aid is desirable.129 icymaking is composed of three main steps: setting
Often, however, administrators exercise discre- the policy agenda, or discovering and expressing
tion sans specific legislative instructions. Federal social problems that need addressing; developing
administrators “fill out” 71 percent of new laws by options about how to resolve those problems; and
appending proscriptions and procedures that have implementing the policy.134 Bureaucrats play signif-
the force of law.130 The Army Corps of Engineers, for icant roles—sometimes decisive roles—in all three
instance, has elected to interpret “navigable waters” policymaking steps.
to mean “wetlands” in a law that does not mention
“wetlands,” which, of course, are neither navigable Rulemaking as Policymaking Rulemaking embod-
nor waters.131 ies the grayest of gray bureaucratic eminences. All
For fifty years, Congress battled bureaucratic bureaucracies make rules, and rulemaking has been
discretion by imposing on agencies the legislative described as “the single most important function
veto, or the repeal by the legislature of an execu- performed by agencies of government.”135 Why?
tive action, such as new rules; from 1932 to 1980, Because rules can be a euphemism for policies,
Congress inserted legislative vetoes into 555 provi- sometimes very big policies. The various estimates of
sions in 355 acts, expanding its use over time (by the annual impact of federal regulations on society
the 1970s, the final full decade of its use, legislative range from more than $260 billion to over $2 tril-
vetoes had exploded by 507 percent).132 In 1983, the lion.136 Since 2003, federal agencies have churned
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 21

out an average of eighty-one “major regulations” 21,000 personal and committee staffers (up from
(as defined by the Congressional Budget Office) per fewer than 2,500 in 1948),144 and the employees of
year, and each one may “have an annual effect on the the Government Accountability Office, Library of
economy of $100 million or more.”137 Congress, and Congressional Budget Office. These
Policymaking via rules, rather than legislation, professionals, but particularly staffers, wield signifi-
accelerates when legislatures stymie. In recent years, cant power in the policymaking process.145
Congress has exemplified this dilemma. The 112th
Congress of 2011–2013 enacted into law 152 public Policymaking by State Administrators Public
bills (or bills that apply to everyone, in contrast to administrators play comparable policymaking roles
private bills, which apply to groups or individu- in the states. A five-decades-long study of state
als, such as naming a post office), and the 113th of agency heads finds that these executives consistently
2013–2014 passed 142, the fewest in history— allocate half their time to “policy development”
by contrast, Harry Truman’s “do-nothing” 80th and “building political support”; the other half is
Congress of 1947–1948 enacted 906 public bills. spent on “internal management.”146 In state exec-
Americans were well aware of Congress’s utive offices, administrative professionalism itself
stalemate. From 56 to 58 percent of Democrats, ranks “as an important influence” in state policy
Republicans, and independents believe that the formation, equaling “other more commonly studied
“political system can work fine, members of state  characteristics,” including the most powerful
Congress are the problem.”138 Just 26 percent of political forces, such as special interests and ideol-
Americans think that “more progress” is being ogies.147
made at “the national level” in dealing with “major The nation’s more than 7,300 state legislators
challenges facing the country,” compared with 64 employ 28,000 full-time legislative staffers and
percent who believe that the “state and local level” another 5,000 when the legislatures are in session.148
is making more progress.139 Just three legislatures fail to provide their standing
Confronted with these realities, President Barack committees with professional staffs;149 none did so
Obama, beginning in the fall of 2011, became “one in 1960.150
of the most prolific authors of major regulations in As with Congress, the role of these staffs is a
presidential history,” issuing hundreds of “rules” powerful one. As a former state legislative staffer
that affected, just as profoundly as any laws, the put it, “The most remarkable discovery that I made
minimum wage, civil rights, the environment, and during my tenure as a staff member was the amount
dozens of other vital areas.140 of power I had over bills on which I worked.”151

Policymaking by Federal Administrators Although Policymaking by Local Administrators Most of


“no one set of actors dominates the process” of the research on policymaking power in local gov-
federal agenda setting, “elected politicians and their ernments focuses on city and town managers, or
appointees come closer than any other.” Top pres- nonpartisan chief appointed executives who manage
idential appointees rank higher than the president 85 percent of all municipalities, a growing number,
and members of Congress in setting the agenda, and and 100 percent of the biggest cities—those with 1
are followed closely by staffers in the White House million people or more.152 Their “policy role con-
and Congress.141 sumes approximately one-third” of their time,153 a
Career civil servants in the executive branch are share that has held steady since the mid-1980s.154 In
less involved in agenda setting, but they are extremely 1973, when the first national survey of city manag-
significant—more so than political appointees—in ers on the topic was conducted, 64 percent reported
structuring alternative policies. Careerists have “yet that they initiated, set, or shaped policy in their
more” impact on the final policy process, that of cities; four decades later, 90 percent said this,155 with
implementing policy.142 a stunning 100 percent of city and county managers
There are about 29,000 unelected employ- playing “a significant role” in initiating policy pro-
ees in the institutional center of national policy- posals (48 percent do so frequently, and 40 percent
making, Congress,143 a number that includes some always).156
22 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

The rise of the local manager as a policymaker representatives of the people. “This finding repre-
is not without its tensions: As the managers’ “exter- sents a significant departure” from previous research,
nal” policymaking leadership deepens, their “inter- and marks a new nadir for local democracy.165
nal” administrative authority lessens.157 A remarkable 70 percent of city managers spend
“more than half their time . . . on self-selected tasks
Lethargic Local Legislators The expanding policy- [rather] than on tasks imposed by others,” such as
making power of local administrators has occurred council members, leaving them free “to work on
in part because local elected officials have ceded tasks that they find most appealing.” What these
their responsibilities to them. managers find most appealing is: taking “a more
Most city council members “are ambivalent active political role” in their communities; exhibiting
about making policy decisions,” are uninvolved “a strong preference” to communicate directly with
in policymaking and mission development, and citizens (another analysis found that city managers
approve of their managers’ taking over these respon- “have not taken advantage of the Internet to bring
sibilities that, legally, are theirs.158 The longer that citizens closer to their governments because these
a city council member has served on the council, officials strongly prefer traditional citizen participa-
the greater the deference that he or she has for city tion”166); and to “more directly and visibly influence
administrators.159 the development of public policy by working more
Other local councils demonstrate a compara- closely with citizens and assuming the mantle of
ble lack of interest in policymaking. Virtually all community leadership.”167
researchers who have addressed this issue in county Ninety-four percent of city and county manag-
governments find that county commissioners also ers “go out into the community and engage directly
“are relatively uninvolved in policy formation,” a with the public on policy issues” (54 percent do so
vacuum that is typically filled by county adminis- frequently or always). Once these issues become
trators,160 who are the equivalents of city managers. policy, 95 percent of them “exercise significant lati-
These appointed officials administer 56 percent, an tude and discretion in the interpretation and admin-
expanding number, of all counties.161 istration of governing board policy” (three-quarters
In school districts, the school superintendent do so frequently or always).168
is the major formulator of educational policy, and Is there any remaining rationale to elect local
school boards adopt the policies recommended by legislators to office?
their superintendents an astonishing 99 percent of
the time. “The superintendent—far more than the
board—is identified publicly as the ‘governor’ of Stopping Power
education.”162 Bureaucrats, in brief, have the power to do things.
The executive directors of special districts typ- They also possess the power to not do things.
ically report to boards of directors who often have Consider the case of John R. Bolton as arms-
scant interest in district business, and almost always control chief in the State Department. During
are accorded a wide policymaking berth.163 President George W. Bush’s first term, Bolton alleg-
Is this accretion by bureaucrats of local policy- edly stymied for two years the disposal of sixty-eight
making power a good thing? It likely is. An extensive tons of Russian plutonium capable of fueling 8,000
investigation found that local “democratic account- nuclear bombs (a task that he was charged with facil-
ability” is greatly enhanced by city managers who itating, not undermining); withheld American support
actively involve themselves in local policymaking, from Europe for a joint approach regarding Iran’s
and this is particularly true in light of “the dimin- nuclear plans; and blocked a new initiative concerning
ishing role of elected officials in providing political the sharing of civilian nuclear technology with India.
guidance.”164 In 2005, the president appointed a new secre-
tary of state and Bolton as ambassador to the United
The Demise of Democracy? Local managers are Nations, moves that effectively cut Bolton out from
not merely making public policy. They are replac- these policymaking loops. Almost immediately,
ing local legislators as the effective political the logjams on these and other issues broke. As a
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 23

former official at Foggy Bottom put it, “through- Intelligence Agency’s headquarters, which, in his
out his career . . . he was always playing the stopper view, should not be advertised. President Kennedy
role . . .. Even when there was an obvious interest by ordered an aide to have the sign removed; the aide,
the president to move things forward, Bolton often in turn, directed the Interior Department to remove
found ways of stopping things by tying the intera- it. Nothing happened. A few days later, the presi-
gency process in knots.”169 Or, as a federal adminis- dent repeated his order. Again, nothing happened.
trator phrased it when addressing another incident Aggravated by both the bureaucracy and his brother’s
of bureaucratic stopping power, “policy is not what badgering, the president personally called the official
the president says in speeches. Policy is what emerges in charge of signs: “This is Jack Kennedy. It’s eleven
from interagency meetings.”170 o’clock in the morning. I want that sign down by the
time the attorney general goes home tonight, and I’m
holding you personally responsible.” The sign was
THE CONTEST FOR CONTROL removed and the president had learned a lesson: “I
In light of the impressive quantum of power that now understand that for a president to get something
bureaucrats have accrued in both the executive and done in this country, he’s got to say it three times.”175
legislative branches of governments, how do elected Such an understanding of supposed bureau-
chief executives control “their” bureaucracies? cratic inertia is held by most presidents. But quite
the opposite can occur. President Carter’s daughter,
Amy, was having difficulty one Friday afternoon
Presidents versus Bureaucrats: Mobilizing on a homework problem about the industrial rev-
the Bureaucracy olution. Amy asked her mother for help, who asked
Nowhere is this challenge more daunting than in an aide if she knew the answer. The aide called the
that biggest bureaucracy of all, the federal service. Labor Department for assistance. Labor was pleased
to oblige. On Sunday, a truck pulled up to the White
Presidential Frustration Consider the following House with Amy’s answer: a massive computer
comments made by presidents about “their” bureau- printout, costing an estimated $300,000 and requir-
cracy. ing a special team of analysts to work overtime. The
Department thought it was responding to an order
■ Harry Truman: “I thought I was the president,
from the president. Amy received a “C” for her
but when it comes to these bureaucrats, I can’t
homework assignment.176
do a damn thing.”171
■ John F. Kennedy told a caller, “I agree with you,
Bringing Bureaucracy to Heel? As these incidents
but I don’t know if the government will.”172
reveal, gaining presidential control over a colossal
■ Richard Nixon: “We have no discipline in
bureaucracy involves clarity and communication,
this bureaucracy! We never fire anybody! We
skill and will. Some presidents have no clear vision
never reprimand anybody! We never demote
of what they want to do (George H. W. Bush,177 Bill
anybody!”173
Clinton178). Others do not comprehend the criticality
■ Jimmy Carter, in the final year of his
of the bureaucracy in securing their place in history
presidency: “Before I became president, I
(Nixon, at least in his first term,179 and Clinton,180
realized and was warned that dealing with the
who imprudently kept his naïve and rash campaign
federal bureaucracy would be one of worst
promise to cut the White House staff by a fourth,
problems I would have to face. It has been
filled the resultant vacuum with unpaid interns, one
worse than I had anticipated.”174
of whom he had an affair with, leading to his dis-
Why do presidents feel this way? We offer a couple barment and impeachment). Hence, not much gets
of small but revealing examples. done. Still others do have strategic goals, and appre-
Some years ago, President Kennedy was pestered ciate the civil service’s importance in attaining them,
by his brother, Attorney General Robert Kennedy, but lack the skills needed to master the bureaucracy.
over the fact that, during his daily commute, he Lyndon Johnson,181 Nixon in his second term,182
could see a large sign directing drivers to the Central and Carter183 are exemplary.
24 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

We offer two opposing and extreme examples the federal service are unique presidential challenges,
of presidents’ attitudes and actions in bringing their but an irony in presidents’ exertions to bring their
bureaucracies to heel. bureaucracy to heel is that the problem often resides
not with the bureaucrats, but with them. As we
Executive Expertise The president who was have noted, some presidents do not have a concrete
most skilled in mobilizing his bureaucracy behind mission in mind, and, without one, coherent policy
his vision was Ronald Reagan. So devoted were directives, other than a demand for loyalty, are often
Reagan’s appointees that they served, on average, absent.
about 50 percent longer than those appointed by When the president’s program is clear, top
Clinton and the two Presidents Bush.184 federal careerists are extraordinarily responsive,
Of greater importance, “few if any presidential even by White House standards. For more than forty
administrations come to Washington with as clear a years, from almost four-fifths to more than nine-
game plan as the Reagan administration had,” and tenths, depending on the administration, of all
this clarity was critical to its relative bureaucratic presidential appointees have fulsomely praised the
success. Reagan centralized personnel selection in competence and responsiveness of career public
the White House; appointed loyal fellow ideologues administrators.188 The “evidence is overwhelming
not only as Cabinet secretaries, but even to opera- that experienced political appointees, regardless of
tional positions deep in the bureaucracy (often, long administration, party, or ideology, believe that career
before he appointed the secretaries to whom they executives are both competent and responsive.”189
ultimately reported), and then decentralized power The central question is less one of presidential
to them.185 dominance of their bureaucracies versus the bureau-
Crucially, Reagan did not eschew competence in crats’ drive for autonomy, and more of a recognition
his appointments. “Ronald Reagan pursued manag- that “democratic control and bureaucratic auton-
ers,” and he “shrewdly coupled loyalty to the Reagan omy are not incompatible.” When elected executives
agenda with federal management experience.”186 and public administrators respect each other and
work together, the governed benefit.190
Presidential Indifference President George W.
Bush seems to have had neither a program, other A Bureaucracy Newly Girded Bureaucratic sab-
than cutting taxes and invading Afghanistan and otage of presidential policies, while not utterly
Iraq, nor an ability to manage the bureaucracy—or absent,191 is so rare as to be almost nonexistent.
even an interest in doing so. Former insiders portray Federal administrators, however, do resist the politi-
him not as the self-declared “decider,” but rather cization of their agencies, and they are getting better
as a dissociated ditherer on most important issues, at it. Over time, “the capacity of the bureaucracy
allowing them to fester among his executives. When to fight back” presidential attempts to undermine
a policy eventually was chosen, he typically failed to its professionalism “has improved substantially—
marshal his bureaucracy behind it. because of shifting cultural attitudes about the legiti-
Here is how Bush’s National Security Adviser, macy of bureaucratic dissent, better legal protections
in an “extraordinary remark,” put it: Bush “will talk for whistle-blowers . . . technological changes that
with great authority and assertiveness . . .. ‘This is have made it easier to broadcast leaks . . . [and] a
what we are going to do.’ And he won’t mean it. lucrative market for insider accounts of the adminis-
Because he will not have gone through the consid- tration’s decision making.” These add up “to a signif-
ered process where he finally is prepared to say, ‘I’ve icant new check on presidential authority.”192
decided.’” Historians will conclude from the written
record that, “‘Well, he decided on this day to do such
and such.’ It’s not true. It’s not history. It’s a fact, but Governors versus Legislators: The Battle for
it’s a misleading fact.”187 the Bureaucracy
“The struggle to control state bureaucracy is one of
Control and Autonomy There can be little doubt the long-standing conflicts of state politics,”193 and
that the immensity, complexity, and publicness of it pits governors against legislators.
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 25

In 1964, only 32 percent of state agency heads budget, and, in 22 percent, they may both form the
reported that their governors had greater control budget and hire and fire department heads.201
over their agencies than the legislature, and 44 As the “governors” of education, school super-
percent said that the legislature had more control. intendents are their districts’ chief administrators,202
Today, these figures have reversed to 45 percent and and the executive directors of special districts
32 percent, respectively.194 enjoy  managerial and policymaking “opportunities
On the other hand, empirical research finds that enviable to their counterparts in government and
governors and legislatures are essentially dead even industry.”203
in their control of executive agencies. The gover-
nors’ influence over their agencies in four vital areas
dealing with policy development is statistically the KNOWLEDGE: THE BASE OF
same as that of the legislatures’ influence over the
agencies.195 Similarly, the proportion of state budget BUREAUCRATIC POWER
chiefs who report that their governors’ power to Question: How has the bureaucracy grown so in
shape budgets has slipped by almost two-fifths over political importance and independence?
twelve years, and only about a third of them think
that their governors are their states’ principal budget
maker.196 Knowledge Is Power
Over time, governors have gained some power Answer: Because the old saw, “knowledge is power,”
over their bureaucracies, but it is indisputable that has never been more salient than it is today.
their authority remains severely constrained. A Public administrators work in bureaucracies,
half-century-long study of some 1,000 state agencies and bureaucracies are more likely to be found in big,
concludes that “the degree of executive control in complicated systems and societies, where knowl-
the American states is modest at best.”197 edge is critical to success and often to survival. The
more economically and socially complex states, for
instance, also have the more advanced, informed,
Managers and the Control of Local and well-developed legislative bureaucracies.204 The
Government larger the city, the likelier the city manager will be
Until the 1950s, approximately, local elected offi- intensely involved in municipal policymaking.205
cials often served as their jurisdictions’ main man- School superintendents have far more power relative
agers. No more. to their school boards in big cities, substantially less
In 65 percent of all municipalities, the city or power in the suburbs, and even less power in small
town manager has the exclusive responsibility for towns.206
developing the budget, and in another 8 percent Max Weber, the famous theorist on bureau-
the manager and the mayor develop the budget cracy, noted a century ago: “In facing a parliament,
together; in 10 percent, the budget is developed a bureaucracy, out of a sure power instinct, fights
solely by another bureaucrat, the chief financial every attempt of the parliament to gain knowl-
officer.198 edge by means of its own experts or from interest
In 37 percent, the manager has sole authority groups.”207 Consider, for example, city managers,
to appoint department heads, and in 11 percent most of whom strongly oppose a staff for the mayor
the manager shares this power with the mayor.199 and 60 percent of whom resist a full-time, paid city
In council-manager cities, which account for 59 council: “this item evoked the strongest expression
percent of all cities and half of all cities with popula- of opinion in the entire series of questions.”208
tions of 1 million or more, the city manager has the When forces external to the executive branch do
exclusive authority to appoint department heads in gain knowledge, they also gain power at its expense.
59 percent, and, in an additional 17 percent, jointly When governors, legislators, or lobbyists “have
with the mayor or council.200 informational advantages over estimated program
In 56 percent of all counties, county adminis- costs” relative to state agency heads, they “signifi-
trators have the exclusive authority to develop the cantly affect agency budget requests.”209 The more
26 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

highly professionalized the state legislature, and the Defense Department’s own inspector general,
larger its staff, the lower the influence of the execu- manufactured a case for an Iraq–Al Qaeda
tive agencies in their own policy areas.210 relationship that was never vetted by the
As a matter of course, bureaucracy and knowl- intelligence community and not supported by
edge reside most frequently in the executive branch. intelligence. A “Senior Intelligence Analyst . . .
Potentially, however, any branch of government, and countered, point-by-point, each instance of an
any special interest, can create its own bureaucratic alleged tie between Iraq and al-Qaida” pushed
knowledge base, and when it does, power follows. by the under secretary.217
■ And, in a sad reprise of an earlier presidency,
the Bureau of Labor Statistics, in 2005, was
Knowledge, Power, and the Public Interest ordered to stop reporting mass layoffs.218
As we all know, power can be misused, and, because Fortunately, these incidents are the exception, not
knowledge is power, knowledge sometimes is delib- the rule. “Politics as usual? Not really. Hard as it
erately distorted to serve the powerful. Consider may be to believe . . . the executive branch has tradi-
some examples: tionally succeeded at hewing to the ideals of objec-
■ President Nixon ordered his Bureau of Labor tivity and nonpartisanship.” Government agencies
Statistics to stop holding news conferences “have produced reliable numbers, even when those
in which politically-embarrassing monthly numbers have made sitting Presidents look worse. . ..
unemployment figure were released and The people who have made this possible are among
interpreted.211 the most heavily scorned figures in American life—
■ Vice President Al Gore “drove some George Wallace’s ‘pointy-headed bureaucrats.’” Yet,
environmental researchers out of government these bureaucrats are “the only professionals in
positions because their views on global warming government—the only ones to say what they think
and ozone depletion clashed with his own.”212 instead of what they believe their bosses and voters
■ Toward the close of President George W. Bush’s want them to. Would we trust the unemployment
second term, the Associated Press noted “a numbers if, every time a new President came along,
pattern by the Bush administration not to seek he replaced the entire Bureau of Labor Statistics
input from its scientists” concerning science- with a new crop of cronies and campaign aides?”219
based policy, relying instead on lawyers and Therein lies the power—and the honor—of the
ideologues.213 Sixty percent of nearly 1,600 public administrator.
scientists in the Environmental Protection
Agency214 and 58 percent of more than 1,600 NOTES
climate scientists in seven federal agencies,215
1. Charles C. Mann, “The Founding Sachems,” New
reported that they had experienced “political
York Times (July 4, 2005).
interference” with their work over the past five
2. Ethnographer Lewis Henry Morgan, as quoted in
years.
ibid.
■ A parallel pattern of ignoring or
3. Woodrow Wilson, “The Study of Administration,”
misrepresenting informed sources was evident Political Science Quarterly 2 (June/July 1887),
regarding 9/11 and the subsequent decision pp. 197–222. The quotation is on p. 206.
to invade Iraq. The White House scotched the 4. Garry Wills, A Necessary Evil: A History of
9/11 Commission’s conclusion that officials American Distrust of Government (New York:
of the Federal Aviation Administration Simon & Schuster, 1999), p. 66.
had ignored numerous advanced warnings 5. Josiah Tucker, as quoted in Page Smith, The
concerning possible airline hijackings and Constitution: A Documentary and Narrative
suicide missions by Al Qaeda terrorists.216 History (New York: Morrow Quill, 1980), p. 82.
In an apparent effort to drum up support 6. James Keene, “American Governance’s Funda-
for the invasion of Iraq, the under secretary mental Tension,” Governing.com (September 29,
of defense for policy, according to the 2016).
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 27

7. William Kent, Memoirs and Letters of James Kent 22. National Academy of Public Administration, Key
(Boston: Little, Brown, 1898), pp. 327–328. Kent Issues of Governance, Public Management, and
was a contemporary of Hamilton’s. Public Administration (Washington, DC: Author,
8. Alexander Hamilton, The Federalist No. 70. 1999), p. 6.
9. Lynton K. Caldwell, “The Administrative 23. Politico, Likely Voters in Competitive U.S. House
Republic: The Contrasting Legacies of Hamilton and Senate Races (Washington, DC: Author,
and Jefferson,” Public Administration Quarterly 2014), Q. 23.
13 (Winter 1990), pp. 470–494. The quotation is 24. Richard Wike and Kathleen Holzwart, Where
on p. 482. Trust Is High, Crime and Corruption Are Low
10. Linda J. Bilmes, “Federalist Nos. 67–77: How (Washington, DC: Pew Global Attitudes Project,
Would Publius Envision the Civil Service Today?” 2008). Data are for 2007.
Public Administration Review Supplement to 25. Geoffrey Brennan and Philip Pettit, The Economy
Volume 71 (December 2011), pp. S98–S104. of Esteem (New York: Oxford University Press,
11. Quoted in Wills, A Necessary Evil, p. 53. 2004).
12. Interview of April 6, 1977, with David Frost, in 26. Akira Nakamura and Soonhee Kim, “Public Trust
http://www.historycommons.org. in Government in Japan and South Korea: Does
13. Pew Global Attitudes Project, The American- the Rise of Critical Citizens Matter?” Public
Western European Values Gap (Washington, DC: Administration Review 70 (September/October
Pew Research Center, 2011), p. 1. Figures are for 2010), pp. 801–810. The quotation is on p. 801.
2011. 27. Vadim Radaev, “Coping with Distrust in Emerging
14. Pew Research Center for the People & the Press, Russian Markets,” Distrust, Russell Hardin, ed.
Independents Take Center Stage in Obama Era (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2004), pp.
(May 21, 2009), Section 2. 233–245.
15. John Kane and Haig Patapan, “In Search of 28. Erik-Hans Klijn, Jurian Edelenbos, and Bram
Prudence: The Hidden Problem of Managerial Steijn, “Trust in Governance Networks: Its
Reform,” Public Administration Review 66 Impact on Outcomes,” Administration & Society
(September/October 2006), pp. 711–724. The 42 (April 2010), pp. 193–221. The quotation is on
quotation is on p. 711. p. 193.
16. Quoted (p. 154) in Ken Auletta, “The Lost 29. Christopher J. Anderson and Yuliya V. Tverdova,
Tycoon,” The New Yorker (April 23 & 30, 2001), “Corruption, Political Allegiances, and Attitudes
pp. 138–163. Toward Government in Contemporary
17. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press, Democracies,” American Journal of Politics 47
Deconstructing Distrust: How Americans View (January 2003), pp. 91–109. Data are for 1996.
Government (Washington, DC: Author, 1998), 30. Wike and Holzwart, Where Trust Is High, Crime
p. 2. and Corruption Are Low.
18. Shlomo Mizrahi, Eran Vigoda-Gadot, and 31. Ibid.
Gregg Van Ryzin, “Public Sector Management, 32. Gary LaFree, Losing Legitimacy: Street Crime
Trust, Performance, and Participation,” Public and the Decline of Social Institutions in America
Performance & Management Review 32 (Boulder, CO: Westview, 1998).
(December 2010), pp. 268–312. The quotation is 33. Marc J. Heatherington, Why Trust Matters:
on p. 268. Declining Political Trust and the Demise of
19. As derived from data in Pew Research Center Liberalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
for the People & the Press, Distrust, Discontent, Press, 2004).
Anger and Partisan Rancor, Section 3. Figures are 34. William Barnes and Bonnie Mann, Making Local
for 1997–2010. Democracy Work: Municipal Officials’ Views
20. Pew Research Center for the People & the Press, about Public Engagement (Washington, DC:
Independents Take Center Stage in Obama Era, National League of Cities, 2010), p. 18. Data are
Section 2. Figure, 49 percent, is for 2010. In 1987, for 2009.
57 percent thought this. 35. Shlomo Mizrahi, Eran Vigoda-Gadot, and Nissim
21. Uri Friedman, “Trust in Government Is Collapsing Cohen, “Trust, Participation, and Performance in
Around the World,” Govexec.com (July 5, 2016). Public Administration: An Empirical Examination
28 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

of Health Services in Israel,” Public Performance 48. Beyle, “Enhancing Executive Leadership in the
& Management Review 33 (September 2009), States,” pp. 20–21. Figures are for 1955–1994.
pp. 7–33. The quotations are on pp. 7, 27. 49. Miller and Wright, “Who’s Minding Which Store?”
36. Brennan and Pettit, The Economy of Esteem. p. 410.
37. Christopher A. Cooper, H. Gibbs Knotts, and 50. Marsha Mercer, “In Many States, Lieutenant
Kathleen M. Brennan, “The Importance of Trust Governors Take on Larger Role,” Stateline (April
in Government for Public Administration: The 7, 2015). Figure is for 2015; South Carolina will
Case of Zoning,” Public Administration Review switch to team elections in 2018.
68 (May/June 2008), pp. 459–467. The quota- 51. As derived from data in Council of State
tions are on pp. 459, 464. Governments, Book of the States, 2015 (Lexington,
38. Mizrahi, Vigoda-Gadot, and Cohen, “Trust, KY: Author, 2015), Table 4.10.
Participation, and Performance in Public 52. National Conference of State Legislatures, Legis-
Administration.” lative Term Limits: An Overview (Washington,
39. Stephen Knack, Social Capital and the Quality DC: Author, 2010). Figure is for 2010.
of Government: Evidence from the U.S. States, 53. As derived from data in Council of State
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 2000). Governments, Book of the States, 2015, Table 4.9.
40. Gallup’s 2012 annual governance survey as 54. Ballotpedia, Recall (Madison, WI: Author, 2015).
cited in Jim Malewitz, “Survey: As State Budgets 55. Ballotpedia, Laws Governing Recall (Madison,
Improve, So Does Trust in Government,” Stateline WI: Author, 2015).
(September 27, 2012). 56. Ballotpedia, Recall.
41. Johnny Goldfinger and Margaret R. Ferguson, 57. National Council of State Legislators, Recall of
“Social Capital and Governmental Performance State Officials (Washington, DC: Author, 2013).
in Large American Cities,” State and Local Figures are for 2013.
Government Review 41 (Winter 2009), pp. 25–36. 58. Reid Wilson, “The Era of the Recall,” Washington
The data are on p. 32. Post (September 3, 2013). Figures are for
42. Caldwell, “The Administrative Republic,” 1911–2013 and 2011–2013.
pp. 483–484. 59. Tanis J. Salant, “Trends in County Government
43. Stephanie P. Newbold, “Statesmanship and Ethics: Structures,” Municipal Year Book, 2004
The Case of Thomas Jefferson’s Dirty Hands,” (Washington, DC: International City/County
Public Administration Review 65 (November/ Management Association, 2004), pp. 35–41.
December 2005), pp. 669–677. The quotations Figure (p. 39) is for 2002.
are on p. 671. 60. U.S. Bureau of Census, Census of Governments,
44. Thad Beyle, “The Governors,” Politics in the 1992, Vol. 1, No. 2 (Washington, DC: U.S.
American States: A Comparative Analysis, 6th Government Printing Office, 1995), pp. 9–19.
ed., Virginia Gray and Herbert Jacob, eds. Figure is for 1992, and includes council presidents.
(Washington, DC: CQ Press, 1996), pp. 207–252. 61. Evelina R. Moulder, “Municipal Form of
45. Cheryl M. Miller and Deil S. Wright, “Who’s Government: Trends in Structure, Responsibility,
Minding Which Store? Institutional and Other and Composition,” Municipal Year Book, 2008
Actors’ Influence on Administrative Rulemaking in (Washington, DC: International City/County
State Agencies, 1978–2004,” Public Administration Management Association, 2008), pp. 35–41.
Quarterly 33 (Fall 2009), pp. 397–428. The quo- Figure (p. 38) is for 2006, and includes council
tation is on p. 403. presidents.
46. Thad L. Beyle, “Enhancing Executive Leadership 62. U.S. Bureau of Census, Census of Governments,
in the States,” State and Local Government 1992, pp. 9–19.
Review 27 (Winter 1995), pp. 18–35. 63. James H. Svara and Jennifer Claire Auer, “Per-
47. National Commission on the State and Local spectives on Changes in City Government Structure,”
Public Service, Hard Truths/Tough Choices: An Municipal Year Book, 2013 (Washington, DC:
Agenda for State and Local Government Reform, City/County Management Association, 2013),
First Report (Albany, NY: Nelson A. Rockefeller pp. 17–34. Figures (p. 24) are for 2011.
Institute of Government, State University of New 64. Salant, “Trends in County Government Struc-
York, 1993), pp. 16–17. tures,” p. 39. Figure is for 2002.
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 29

65. Moulder, “Municipal Form of Government,” Author, 2011), p. 1. Figure excludes initiatives
pp. 38–40. seeking to repeal laws and refers only to those
66. Susan A. MacManus and Charles S. Bullock, seeking to enact new laws or constitutional
III, “The Form, Structure, and Composition of amendments.
America’s Municipalities in the New Millennium,” 83. Reid Wilson, “Initiative Spending Booms Past
Municipal Year Book, 2003 (Washington, DC: $1 Billion as Corporations Sponsor Their Own
International City/County Management Asso- Proposals,” Washington Post (November 8,
ciation, 2003), pp. 3–18. Figure (p. 12) is for 2001. 2013). Figure is for 2012–2013.
67. National Council of State Legislators, Recall of 84. Svara and Auer, “Perspectives on Changes in City
State Officials. Figure is for 2013. Government Structure,” p. 31. Figures are for 2011;
68. Svara and Auer, “Perspectives on Changes in City figure for initiatives includes popular referenda.
Government Structure,” p. 31. Figure is for 2011. 85. Ramirez de la Cruz, “County Form of Govern-
69. Edgar E. Ramirez de la Cruz, “County Form  of ment,” p. 26. Figures, 71 and 72 percent, respec-
Government: Trends in Structure and Com- tively, are for 2007. Figure for initiatives includes
position,” Municipal Year Book, 2009 (Washington, popular referenda.
DC: International City/County Management 86. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Association, 2009), pp. 21–27. Figure is for 2007. Relations, The Federal Role in the Federal System:
70. National Council of State Legislators, Recall of The Dynamics of Growth, A Crisis of Confidence
State Officials. and Competence, A-77 (Washington, DC: U.S.
71. Ballotpedia, Ballotpedia’s 2013 Recall Analysis Government Printing Office, 1980), pp. 131, 111.
and Ballotpedia’s 2014 Recall Analysis (Madison, 87. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
WI: Author, 2013, 2014). Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016, 4th
72. Ballotpedia, Political Recall Efforts (Madison, WI: ed. (Bethesda, MD: Author, 2016), Tables 2, 484.
Author, 2011–2014). Figures are for 2011–2014. Figure is for 2013.
73. Ryan Holeywell, “Recall Fever,” Governing (April 88. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, “Historical
2011), pp. 44–48. Tables,” The President’s Budget for Fiscal Year
74. Ballotpedia, Political Recall Efforts. Figures are 2017 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
for 2011–2014. Publishing Office, 2016), Table 2.3. Figure is for
75. Ballotpedia, Political Recall Efforts, 1911–2014, 2017.
and Ballotpedia’s 2014 Political Recall Analysis. 89. Noah Glyn and Scott Drenkard, Prop 13 in
We have subtracted from Ballotpedia’s 2014 California, 35 Years Later (Washington, DC: Tax
totals a recall effort aimed at “one state official.” Foundation, 2014). Figures are for 1978–2013.
76. Wilson, “The Era of the Recall.” 90. As derived from data in American Council on
77. Initiative and Referendum Institute, “State I & Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features
R,” Ballotwatch (Los Angeles: Author, 2015). of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2 (Washington,
78. Desiree Teobaldelli and Friedrich Schneider, “The DC: Author, 1998), p. 54, for 1978–1994 growth
Influence of Direct Democracy on the Shadow rates, and David Osborne and Peter Hutchinson,
Economy,” Public Choice 157 (December 2013), The Price of Government: Getting the Results We
pp. 543–567. Need in an Age of Permanent Fiscal Crisis (New
79. Initiative and Referendum Institute, Ballotwatch York: Basic Books, 2004), pp. 44–47, for subse-
(Los Angeles: Author, 2014). quent growth rates.
80. National Conference of State Legislatures, 91. As derived from data in American Council on
Initiative, Referendum and Recall (Washington, Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features
DC: Author, 2013). Figure is for 2013. of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 54. Current
81. Initiative and Referendum Institute, Overview of growth rates are for 1978–1994. State and local
Initiative Use, 1904–2009 (Los Angeles: Author, revenue growth refers to revenue derived from
2013), p. 1. Figures exclude initiatives seeking these governments’ own revenue sources and does
to repeal laws and refer only to those seeking to not include intergovernmental revenue trans-
enact new laws or constitutional amendments. ferred to them by other governments.
82. As derived from data in ibid. and Initiative and 92. John E. Petersen, “Debtor’s Dilemma,” Governing
Referendum Institute, Ballotwatch (Los Angeles, (May 2004), p. 78.
30 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

93. Gallup Poll, as cited in Robert J. Samuelson, “The Who. . . What. . . and How? (Washington, DC:
Tax Revolt, RIP?” Washington Post (April 13, Authors, 2008), p. 6.
2015). 105. Charles T. Goodsell, The Case for Bureaucracy: A
94. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Public Administration Polemic, 2nd ed. (Chatham,
Development, “Revenue Statistics 2015—United NJ: Chatham House, 1985), p. 106.
States,” OECD Revenue Statistics 2015 (Paris: 106. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press,
Author, 2016). Deconstructing Distrust, p. 2.
95. Sven Steinmo, “Why Is Government So Small in 107. Council for Excellence in Government and Hart-
America?” Governance 8 (July 1995), pp. 303–334. Teeter Poll, America Unplugged: Citizens and
96. Annenberg Campaign Data Base, as cited in Their Government (Washington, DC: Authors,
Paul C. Light, The True Size of Government 1999), p. 4. Figures are for 1999.
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 1999), p. 88. 108. George Washington University Battleground Poll,
97. Subcommittee on Intergovernmental Relations, Faith in Federal Employees Remains High Despite
Committee on Government Operations, U.S. Washington’s Image (Washington, DC: Author,
Senate, Confidence and Concern: Citizens View 2014). Figures are for 2014.
American Government, A Survey of Public 109. Subcommittee on Intergovernmental Relations,
Attitudes, Part 2, 93rd Congress, 1st Session Committee on Government Operations, U.S.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Senate, Confidence and Concern, Part 1, pp. 173–
Office, 1973), p. 310. Data are for 1973. 175, and Part 2, pp. 301, 303, 305, 311, 313, 315,
98. Thad E. Hall, “Live Bureaucrats and Dead 319, 321. Data are for 1973.
Public Servants: How People in Government Are 110. Daniel Katz, Barbara A. Gutek, Robert L. Kahn,
Discussed on the Floor of the House,” Public and Eugenia Barton, Bureaucratic Encounters
Administration Review 62 (March 2002), pp. (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan, 1975),
242–251. pp. 64, 68, 69, 221. Data are for 1973.
99. Marc Schwerdt, “Stories of Service: Public Service 111. Theodore H. Poister and Gary T. Henry, “Citizen
in the Children’s Literature of United States and Ratings of Public and Private Service Quality: A
Great Britain,” Politics and Policy 31 (June 2003), Comparative Perspective,” Public Administration
pp. 195–214. Review 54 (March/April 1994), pp. 155–160. The
100. Beverly A. Cigler and Heidi L. Neiswender, quotation is on p. 155.
“Bureaucracy in the Introductory American 112. American Customer Satisfaction Index, Special
Government Textbook,” Public Administration Report on Government Services and ACSI Federal
Review 51 (September/October 1991), pp. 442– Government Report 2014 (Ann Arbor, MI:
450. The quotation is on p. 444. Author, 2011 and 2015), p. 1 and p. 1. Figures are
101. David J. Lorenzo, “Countering Popular Mis- averages, 1999–2014.
conceptions of Federal Bureaucracies in American 113. American Customer Satisfaction Index, ACSI
Government Classes,” Political Science and Federal Government Report 2014.
Politics 32 (December 1999), pp. 743–747. The 114. “Declining Satisfaction with Government in 5
quotation is on p. 744. Charts,” GovExec.com (March 15, 2015).
102. Council for Excellence in Government and Center 115. Claes Fornell, ACSI Commentary: Federal
for Media and Public Affairs, Government: In Government (Ann Arbor, MI: American Customer
and Out of the News (Washington, DC: Authors, Satisfaction Index, 2011), p. 2.
2003), pp. 6, 5, 36, 125, 75. Figures are the com- 116. Pew Research Center, Views of the Primaries,
bined averages for 1981, 1993, 2001. Press Coverage of Candidates, Attitudes about
103. S. Robert Lichter, Linda S. Lichter, and Dan Government and the Country (Washington, DC:
Amundson, Changing Images of Government Author, 2016). Figures are for 2016.
in TV Entertainment (Washington, DC: Center 117. Pew Research Center, Most View the CDC
for Media and Public Affairs and Council for Favorably; VA’s Image Slips (Washington, DC:
Excellence in Government, 2002), pp. 8, 12. Author, 2015). Figures are for 2015.
Figures are for 1999–2001. 118. As derived from data in Subcommittee on
104. Council for Excellence in Government, Gallup, Intergovernmental Relations, Committee on
and Accenture, The Appeal of Public Service: Government Operations, U.S. Senate, Confidence
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 31

and Concern, Part 1, pp. 173–175, and Part 2, 128. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Brendan Burke, Chung-Lae
pp. 301, 303, 305, 311, 313, 315, 319, 321; and Cho, and Deil S. Wright, “No ‘One Best Way’
Stuart M. Schmidt, “Client-Oriented Evaluation to Manage Change: Developing and Describing
of Public Agency Effectiveness,” Administration Distinct Administrative Reform Dimensions Across
& Society 8 (February 1977), pp. 403–422. the Fifty American States, Public Administration
119. Thomas I. Miller and Michelle A. Miller,“Standards Quarterly 33 (Summer 2009), pp. 197–222. The
of Excellence: U.S. Residents’ Evaluations of Local quotations are on p. 206.
Government Services,” Public Administration 129. The legislation is the Robert T. Stafford Disaster
Review 51 (November/December 1991), pp. 503– Relief and Emergency Assistance Act of 1988.
514. The quotation is on p. 503. 130. Kenneth J. Meier and Laurence J. O’Toole, Jr.,
120. Claes Fornell, ACSI Commentary: Federal Bureaucracy in a Democratic State: A Governance
Government Scores (Ann Arbor, MI: American Perspective (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins
Customer Satisfaction Index, December 14, University Press, 2006), p. 60.
2006). Figures pertain to federal services, and are 131. The legislation is the 1972 amendments to the
for 2006. Federal Water Pollution Control Act of 1956.
121. Partnership for Public Service and Gallup 132. As derived from data in Cornelius M. Kerwin and
Consulting, In the Public We Trust: Renewing Scott R. Furlong, Rulemaking: How Government
the Connection between the Federal Government Agencies Write Law and Make Policy, 4th ed.
and the Public (Washington, DC, and New York: (Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2011), p. 230.
Authors, 2008), p. 3. Figures are for 2008. 133. The case is U.S. Immigration and Naturalization
122. As derived from data in Pew Research Center Service v. Chadha.
for the People and the Press, Performance and 134. John W. Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and
Purpose: Constituents Rate Government Agencies Public Policies (Boston: Little, Brown, 1984).
(Washington, DC: Author, 2000). Data are for 135. Cornelius M. Kerwin and Scott R. Furlong,
federal agencies in 2000. Rulemaking: How Government Agencies Write
123. Eloisa del Pino, Ines Calzada, and Jose M. Diaz- Law and Make Policy, 4th ed. (Washington, DC:
Pulido, “Conceptualizing and Explaining Bureau- CQ Press, 2011), p. xi.
phobia: Contours, Scope, and Determinants,” 136. Maeve P. Curry, Methods of Estimating the Total
Public Administration Review 76 (September/ Cost of Federal Regulations (Washington, DC:
October 2016), pp. 725–736. Congressional Research Service, 2016), p. 2.
124. Jarl K. Kampen, Steven Van de Walle, and Geert 137. As derived from data in U.S. Government Account-
Bouckaert, “Assessing the Relation Between ability Office, Federal Rulemaking: Agencies
Satisfaction with Public Service Delivery and Trust Could Take Additional Steps to Respond to Public
in Government: The Impact of the Predisposition Comments, GAO-13-21 (Washington, DC: U.S.
of Citizens Toward Government on Evaluation Government Printing Office, 2013), Highlights page.
of Its Performance,” Public Performance & Data are for 2003–2010, when 568 major regula-
Management Review 29 (June 2006), pp. 387– tions were finalized. The 2009–2015 period (when
404. The quotation is on pp. 399–400. 560 major regulations were issued) also averaged
125. Richard A. Loverd, “Gaining the Power to Lead,” eighty-one major regulations annually. See Benyamin
Leadership for the Public Service: Power and Applebaum and Michael D. Shear, “Once Skeptical
Policy in Action, Richard A. Loverd, ed. (Upper of Executive Power, Obama Has Come to Embrace
Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1997), pp. 1–16. It,” New York Times (August 13, 2016).
The quotation is on p. 7. 138. Pew Research Center for the People & the Press,
126. Herbert Kaufman, Are Government Organizations Majority Says the Government Threatens Their
Immortal? (Washington, DC: Brookings, 1976). Personal Rights (Washington, DC: Author, 2013),
The years covered were 1923–1973. p. 2.
127. As derived from data in Partnership for Public 139. Allstate and National Journal, Heartland Monitor
Service and Booz Allen Hamilton, Unrealized XXII (Washington, DC: FTI Consulting, 2015),
Vision: Reimagining the Senior Executive Service Q. 18. Figures are for 2015.
(Washington, DC, and Herndon, VA: Authors, 140. Applebaum and Shear, “Once Skeptical of Executive
2009), p. 7. Data are for 2008. Power, Obama Has Come to Embrace It.”
32 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

141. Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and Public 155. Kimberly L. Nelson and James H. Svara, “The
Policies, p. 7. Emphasis added. Roles of Local Government Managers in Theory
142. Ibid., pp. 46, 34. and Practice: A Centennial Perspective,” Public
143. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of Administration Review 75 (January/February
the United States, 2016, Table 515. Figure is for 2015), pp. 49–61. Current figure (p. 52) is for
2014. 2012.
144. Mike Causey, “Hill Staff, Then and Now,” 156. International City/County Management Asso-
Washington Post (September 30, 1991), and ciation, ICMA State of the Profession 2012
“Washington Pots and Kettles,” Baltimore Sun Survey Results (Washington, DC: Author, 2013),
(October 27, 1991). Q. 21d.
145. Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and Public 157. Yahong Zhang and Richard C. Feiock, “City
Policies, p. 34. Managers’ Policy Leadership in Council-Manager
146. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil Cities,” Journal of Public Administration Research
S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public and Theory 20 (April 2010), pp. 461–476.
Administration Across the 50 States: Linking 158. James H. Svara, “The Shifting Boundaries between
Practice, Theory, and Research through the Elected Officials in Large Council-Manager
American State Administrators Project, 1964– Cities,” Public Administration Review 59 (January/
2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental February 1999), pp. 44–53. The quotation is on
Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 6. Figures p. 50.
are for 1964–2008. 159. John Nalbandian, “Politics and Administration
147. Jerrell D. Coggburn and Saundra K. Schneider, in Council-Manager Government: Differences
“The Quality of Management and Government between Newly Elected and Senior Council
Performance: An Empirical Analysis of the Members,” Public Administration Review 64
American States,” Public Administration Review (March/April 2004), pp. 200–209.
63 (March/April 2003), pp. 206–213. The quota- 160. James H. Svara, “Leadership and Profession-
tions are on p. 206. alism  in County Government,” The American
148. Karl Kurtz and Brian Weberg, “The State of Staff,” County: Frontiers of Knowledge, Donald C.
State Legislatures (July/August 2009), pp. 42–45. Menzel, ed. (Tuscaloosa, AL: University of
Figures are for 2009. Alabama Press, 1996), pp. 109–127. The quota-
149. As derived from data in Council of State tion is on p. 118.
Governments, Book of the States, 2015, 161. Edgar E. Ramirez de la Cruz, “County Form
Table 3.22. of Government: Trends in Structure and
150. Herbert L. Wiltsee, “Legislative Service Agencies,” Composition,” Municipal Year Book, 2009
Book of the States, 1961–62 (Lexington, KY: (Washington, DC: International City/County
Council of State Governments, 1962), p. 67. Management Association, 2009), pp. 21–27.
151. Michael J. BeVier, Politics Backstage: Inside the Figure (p. 24) is for 2007.
California Legislature (Philadelphia: Temple 162. Harvey J. Tucker and L. Harmon Ziegler,
University Press, 1979), p. 229. Professionals versus the Public: Attitudes,
152. Svara and Auer, “Perspectives on Changes in City Communication, and Response in School Districts
Government Structure,” p. 22. Figures are for 2011. (New York: Longman, 1980), p. 143.
153. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity 163. Jerry Mitchell, The American Experiment with
and Change in the Role of City Managers,” Government Corporations (Armonk, NY: M. E.
Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington, Sharpe, 1998), p. 95.
DC: International City/County Management 164. Tansu Demir and Ronald C. Nyhan, “The
Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. The quotation is Politics-Administration Dichotomy: An Empirical
on p. 16. Figure is for 2010. Search for Correspondence between Theory
154. Charldean Newell and David M. Ammons, “Role and Practice,” Public Administration Review 68
Emphases of City Managers and Other Municipal (January/February 2008), pp. 81–96. The quota-
Executives,” Public Administration Review 47 tion is on p. 92.
(May/June 1987), pp. 246–253. Datum (p. 249) is 165. Killian and Choudhury, “Continuity and Change
for 1985. in the Role of City Managers,” pp. 16–17.
Big Democracy, Big Bureaucracy 33

166. Stephen Kwamena Aikens and Dale Krane, “Are and Theory 18 (July 2008), pp. 375–396. The
Public Officials Obstacles to Citizen-Centered figure and quotation are on p. 392.
E-Government? An Examination of Municipal 185. Aberbach and Rockman, In the Web of Politics,
Administrators’ Motivations and Actions,” State pp. 35–37. The quotation is on p. 35.
and Local Government Review 42 (Spring 2010), 186. Shirley Anne Warshaw, “White House Control
pp. 87–103. The quotation is on p. 87. of Domestic Policy Making: The Reagan Years,”
167. Killian and Choudhury, “Continuity and Change Public Administration Review 55 (May/June
in the Role of City Managers,” pp. 15–18. 1995), pp. 247–253. The quotation is on p. 250.
168. International City/County Management Asso- 187. Bob Woodward, “10 Take Aways From the
ciation, ICMA State of the Profession 2012 Bush Years,” Washington Post (January 18,
Survey Results, Q. 21i, Q. 21g. 2009). Woodward is quoting Stephen J. Hadley’s
169. Peter Baker and Dafnia Linzer, “Policy Shifts “extraordinary remark” of March 8, 2008.
Felt after Bolton’s Departure from State Dept.,” 188. Paul C. Light and Virginia L. Thomas, The Merit
Washington Post (June 20, 2005). and Reputation of an Administration: Presidential
170. Peter Baker, “As Democracy Push Falters, Bush Appointees on the Appointments Process
Feels Like a ‘Dissident,’” Washington Post (August (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2000), pp. 9, 31, 32.
20, 2007). 189. Pfiffner, “Political Appointees and Career
171. Quoted in Clinton Rossiter, The American Executives,” p. 61.
Presidency (New York: New American Library, 190. Doo-Rae Kim, “Political Control and Bureaucratic
1956), p. 42. Autonomy Revisited: A Multi-Institutional Anal-
172. Quoted in Richard P. Nathan, The  Adminis- ysis of OSHA Enforcement,” Journal of Public
trative Presidency (New York: Macmillan, 1983), Administration Research and Theory 18 (January
p. 1. 2008), pp. 33–55. The quotation is on p. 33.
173. Quoted in Richard P. Nathan, The Plot That 191. Marissa Martino Golden, What Motivates
Failed: Nixon and the Administrative Presidency Bureaucrats? Politics and Administration during
(New York: Wiley, 1975), p. 69. the Reagan Years (New York: Columbia Univer-
174. Quoted in Haynes Johnson, “Tests,” Washington sity Press, 2000). The Environmental Protection
Post (April 30, 1978). Agency and the Civil Rights Division of the
175. Quoted in Peter Goldman, et al., “The Presidency: Justice Department resisted Reagan administra-
Can Anyone Do the Job?” Newsweek (January tion efforts to pull back their initiatives.
26, 1981), p. 41. 192. Alasdair Roberts, as quoted in Donald Moynihan,
176. United Press International, “Amy’s Homework “A Crisis of Authority? A Conversation with
Aid Likely Costs Thousands,” Arizona Republic Alasdair Roberts about the Bush Years,” Public
(February 9, 1981). Administration Review 68 (May/June 2008), pp.
177. David Mervin, George Bush and the Guardianship 516–522. The quotation is on p. 517.
Presidency (New York: Macmillan, 1996). 193. Thad Beyle and Margaret Ferguson, “Governors
178. Joel D. Aberbach and Bert A. Rockman, In the and the Executive Branch,” Politics in the
Web of Politics: Three Decades of the U.S. Federal American States: A Comparative Analysis, 9th ed.
Executive (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2000), (Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2008), pp. 192–228.
pp. 39–40. The quotation is on p. 217.
179. Nathan, The Plot That Failed. 194. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
180. Aberbach and Rockman, In the Web of Politics, Change in Public Administration Across the 50
pp. 39–40. States, p. 17. Current figures are for 2008.
181. Randall B. Woods, LBJ: Architect of American 195. F. Ted Hebert, “Governors as Chief Administrators
Ambition (New York: Free Press, 2006). and Managers,” Handbook of State Government
182. Nathan, The Plot That Failed. Administration, John J. Gargan, ed. (New York:
183. Aberbach and Rockman, In the Web of Politics, Marcel Dekker, 2000), pp. 107–126.
pp. 32–35. 196. Figures are for 1982–1994. Sources and details
184. B. Dan Wood and Miner P. Marchbanks, III, are in Chapter 8.
“What Determines How Long Political Appointees 197. Yoo-Sung Choi, Chung-Lee Cho, and Deil S.
Serve?” Journal of Public Administration Research Wright, “Administrative Autonomy among
34 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

American State Agencies: An Empirical Analysis of 209. Jay Eungha Ryu, Cynthia J. Bowling, Chung-
Fragmentation and Functionalism,” International Lae Cho, and Deil S. Wright, “Effects of
Journal of Public Administration 27 (January Administrators’ Aspirations, Political Principals’
2004), pp. 373–398. The quotation is on p. 394. Priorities, and Interest Groups’ Influence on State
198. Moulder, “Municipal Form of Government,” p. 7. Agency Budget Requests,” Public Budgeting &
Figures are for 2006. Finance 27 (Summer 2007), pp. 22–49. The quo-
199. MacManus and Bullock, “The Form, Structure, tations are on pp. 41, 43. Figures are for 1998.
and Composition of America’s Municipalities in 210. Matthew Potoski and Neal Woods, “Designing
the New Millennium,” p. 12. Figures are for 2001. State Clean Air Agencies: Administrative
200. Svara and Auer, “Perspectives on Changes in City Procedures and Bureaucratic Autonomy,” Journal
Government Structure,” pp. 20, 28. Figures are of Public Administration Research and Theory 11
for 2011. (April 2001), pp. 203–221.
201. Salant, “Trends in County Government Structure.” 211. David E. Rosenbaum, “Politics as Usual, and Then
Figures are for 2002. Some,” New York Times (September 20, 2005).
202. Tucker and Ziegler, Professionals versus the 212. Ibid.
Public, p. 143. 213. Dina Cappiello, Associated Press, “Bush
203. Jerry Mitchell, “Policy Functions and Issues Administration to Relax Protected-Species Rule,”
for Public Authorities,” Public Authorities and Savannah Morning News (August 12, 2008).
Public Policy: The Business of Government, Jerry 214. Union of Concerned Scientists, Interference at the
Mitchell, ed. (Westport, CN: Praeger, 1992), EPA: Science and Politics at the Environmental
pp. 1–14. The quotation is on p. 6. Protection Agency (Cambridge, MA: USC
204. Stephanie Owings and Rainald Borck, “Legislative Publications, 2008), p. 2. Figure is for 2007.
Professionalism and Government Spending: Do 215. Union of Concerned Scientists, Atmosphere of
Citizen Legislators Really Spend Less?” Public Pressure: Political Interference in Federal Climate
Finance Review 20 (May 2000), pp. 210–225. Science (Cambridge, MA: USC Publications,
205. Robert J. Huntley and Robert J. McDonald, 2007), p. 2. Figure is for 2006.
“Urban Managers: Managerial Style and Social 216. Eric Lichtblau, “9/11 Report Cites Many
Roles,” Municipal Year Book, 1975 (Washington, Warnings about Hijackings,” New York Times
DC: International City Management Association, (February 10, 2005).
1975), pp. 149–159. The datum is on p. 153. 217. Deputy Inspector General for Intelligence, Review
206. Ziegler and Jennings, Governing American of the Pre-Iraqi War Activities of the Office of the
Schools, pp. 177–178. Under Secretary of Defense for Policy (Washington,
207. Max Weber, From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, DC: Office of the Inspector General, U.S.
H. H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills, eds. (New York: Department of Defense, February 9, 2007), p. 8.
Oxford University Press, 1946), p. 233. 218. James Surowiecki, “Hail to the Geek,” The New
208. Huntley and McDonald, “Urban Managers,” Yorker (April 19 and 26, 2004), p. 70.
p. 150. 219. Ibid.
CHAPTER

Paradigms of Public
Administration

P ublic administration has developed as an intellec-


tual and professional field through a succession
of six paradigms—that is, how the field has “seen
Tammany Hall, the corrupt political machine
that ran the city, felt directly threatened by the
bureau, referring to it as “The Bureau of Municipal
itself” in the past and present. Besmirch,” and initiated a smear campaign designed
to emasculate it. The campaign backfired, and
encouraged reformers in other cities to emulate the
THE BEGINNING Bureau’s success.2 By 1928, seventy-four cities had
That uniquely academic president, Woodrow research bureaus.3
Wilson, is commonly thought to be the founder
of public administration in the United States. In
1887,  Wilson introduced Americans to the field Public Administration and the Intellectuals:
with an essay titled, “The Study of Administration.”1 The Fortuitous Year of 1914
In it, the future president observed that it “is At the turn of the last century, academia was openly
getting  harder to  run a constitution than to disdainful of public administration.
frame  one,” and called  for  the  bringing of more
intellectual resources to bear in the management of Public Administration: “No Career for a
the state. Gentleman” Perhaps because professional public
administration was being practiced solely in
sordid city streets, the occupants of ivory towers
Think Tanks for Public Service had no interest in stooping to its level. During the
Aside from Wilson’s formative essay, public admin- first decade of the twentieth century, Ms. E. H.
istration’s intellectual roots were planted in practical Harriman offered $250,000 to the presidents of
ground—even in the streets. The reformist “public Harvard, Yale, and Columbia to start a school of
service movement” that was sweeping the American public administration. She found them to be “polite
political landscape in the early twentieth century but amused” by her proposal, advising her that they
was a factor in John D. Rockefeller’s decision, in had no intention of sending their “graduates into
1906, to found, and fund, the New York Bureau a blind alley” that led to “no career for a gentle-
of Municipal  Research. The Bureau was a proto- man.” Rejected by the Ivy League, Harriman gave
type of what we now know as “think tanks,” and, her money to the New York Bureau of Municipal
although its focus was limited to New York City, it Research, stipulating that it create, in 1911, its
was extraordinarily creative in laying the intellectual Training School for Public Service, which produced
and practical groundwork of what public adminis- the nation’s first corps of trained public adminis-
tration should be. trators. (Ultimately, Mary Harriman prevailed. In
35
36 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

1924, the bureau gave its Training School, lock, with policies or expressions of the state will,” while
stock, and students, to  Syracuse University, where administration “has to do with the execution of
it became the Maxwell School of Citizenship and these policies.”8 Goodnow’s point—that elected pol-
Public Affairs.)4 iticians and appointed public administrators do dif-
ferent things—eventually was labeled by academics
Turning Sharply: Academia’s Reconsideration as the politics/administration dichotomy.
Eventually, universities reconsidered. In 1912, an
influential scholarly journal devoted an entire issue
to municipal research bureaus,5 and, in 1914, aca- The Uses of the Dichotomy
demia’s attitudes evidenced a sharp turnabout. In As a practical matter, the politics/administration
that year, the American Political Science Association’s dichotomy offered some protection for a fledgling
(APSA) Committee on Practical Training for Public profession, particularly when the Great Depression
Service, which had been founded only two years struck in 1929. The dichotomy held that public
earlier, persuaded the reformist mayor of New administrators merely brought efficiency to the exe-
York to welcome the nation’s first “Conference on cution of policies made by elected politicians, and
Universities as Related to Public Service.” The con- thus, in their bland, bloodless, apolitical, and clerical
ference recommended, with unusual foresight, that way, more than paid for themselves.
“professional schools,” and possibly new degrees, This is not to say that the dichotomy amounted
be established to educate public administrators,6 to nothing more than a cynical defense of a nascent
and its attendees founded the freestanding Society and threatened profession. It also was a deeply
for the Promotion of Training for the Public Service. believed rationale for a profession of public admin-
Although the Society ceased its activities in 1917 istration, one that still has some salience to this day.
(it was effectively a casualty of World War I), it Even though city managers, for instance, assume a
nonetheless served as an inspirational model in the highly activist leadership and policymaking role in
founding, a generation later, of the field’s principal their governments (recall Chapter 1), many, if not
professional association, the American Society for most, are still uncomfortable with this role because,
Public Administration. as research indicates,9 it is a passionate “article of
Also in 1914, the APSA announced that one of faith among city managers that they are merely
political science’s four core missions was to educate administrators and do not involve themselves in
“experts and to prepare specialists for governmental politics.”10
positions.”7 And it was in 1914 that the first gradu-
ate degree in public (actually, municipal) administra-
tion was introduced—by the University of Michigan, The Dilemma of the Dichotomy
which placed the program in its political science Because those who ardently believed in the politics/
department, thereby establishing a precedent that administration dichotomy would not accept the
soon waxed into a national template. Public admin- reality that public administrators often make policy,
istration would stand for decades as a prominent it plagued the field for decades, ultimately displacing
pillar of political science. the founders’ idea that, while politicians and admin-
istrators did different things, they nonetheless must
work together for the greater good.
PARADIGM 1: THE POLITICS/ Regrettably, such subtleties were overlooked
ADMINISTRATION DICHOTOMY, as public administration sought its identity during
this period. Leonard D. White’s Introduction to the
1900–1926 Study of Public Administration of 1926, the first
In his groundbreaking book, Politics and Admini- textbook devoted to the field, expressed the pro-
stration, published in 1900, Frank J. Goodnow gressive value of public administration at the time:
contended that there were “two distinct functions politics must be cleaved from administration so that
of government,” which he identified with the title the field can develop as a pure science which will
of his tome. “Politics,” wrote Goodnow, “has to do assure the attainment of governmental efficiency.
Paradigms of Public Administration 37

This perspective provided the intellectual base for An Academic Backtrack By the late 1920s, there
public administration’s next paradigm. may have been thirty to forty universities with
public administration programs, and “many were so
subordinated to political science departments that
PARADIGM 2: PRINCIPLES their survival was in doubt.”13 This bleak condition
OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION, soon changed. Between 1927 and 1936, the number
of universities that offered public administration
1927–1937 courses quadrupled.14
In 1927, W. F. Willoughby’s book, Principles of So rapid was public administration’s rise that
Public Administration, appeared as the second the academic community grew worried over tradi-
fully-fledged text in the field. Its title alone indi- tional turfs. In 1935, Princeton University hosted a
cated  the new thrust of public administration: national conference that produced a report which
That public administrators would be effective if differed radically from the one issued in 1914.
they learned  and applied scientific principles of Rather than advocating separate schools and degrees
administration. for budding bureaucrats, the 1935 conference found
Willoughby’s textbook reflected intellectual itself “unable to find any single formula which
trends that suffused the whole of management warrants the establishment of an isolated college
theory, and public administration was no exception. or university program which alone will emphasize
In this regard, the field’s infatuation with prin- preparation exclusively for the public service.” Only
ciples of administration stood in stark contrast a “university-wide approach” would suffice.15
with its ongoing embrace of the politics/admin- If public administration were to be denied a
istration dichotomy, which was unique to public place on university organization charts, then it also
administration. would be denied a place in universities.

A Reputational Zenith The Meaning of Principles


The status of public administration soared during the By the very fact that the principles of administra-
principles-of-administration period. “Professional tion were indeed principles—that is, by definition,
associations for government employees had grown they “worked” in any administrative setting without
with ‘unexampled rapidity’ . . . and governments exception—it therefore followed that they could be
were calling on the public administration commu- applied successfully anywhere.
nity to provide advice on administrative problems In 1937, the community of public administra-
more and more frequently.”11 tion expressed this perspective in a singular volume
that has come to be called the field’s “high-noon
Money and Power Its rising stature can be attrib- of orthodoxy”:16 Luther H. Gulick and Lyndall
uted, at least in part, to the Rockefeller family, Urwick’s Papers on the Science of Administration.
whose interest in the field remained undiminished Principles were important to Gulick and Urwick,
following its success with the New York Bureau but where those principles were applied was not.
of Municipal Research. Rockefeller philanthro- “It is the general thesis of this paper that there are
pies poured millions of dollars into the profession, principles which . . . should govern arrangements for
leaving “no important part of the public administra- human association of any kind. . .. irrespective of the
tion community . . . untouched. . .. A person could purpose of the enterprise, the personnel comprising
not have spoken about the field of public adminis- it, or any constitutional, political, or social theory
tration in 1925 and had confidence that the audi- underlying its creation.”17
ence knew what was meant. In 1937, the situation Gulick and Urwick (though perhaps more so
was quite different. . .. and governments were calling in Gulick’s case) understood that their “principles”
on the public administration community to provide were not immutable facts of nature, but were simply
advice on administrative problems more and more helpful touch points in conveying an understand-
frequently.”12 ing of “What is the work of the chief executive?”18
38 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

(Their answer was “POSDCORB,” an influen-


tial acronym that stood for Planning, Organizing, The City or County Manager Improves
Staffing, Directing, CO-ordinating, Reporting, and Governing
Budgeting.) The primary professional devised by the public
Nevertheless, Gulick and Urwick also were administration pioneers was the local government’s
aware that their still-spindly profession needed chief appointed executive (the first such manager
nourishment if it were to survive, and realized that was appointed in 1908), and these professionals
a “science of administration,” based on scientific clearly have fulfilled the pioneers’ hopes.
“principles,” was a publicly-appealing image— When making decisions, city managers are much
indeed, “science” amounted to an “unassailable more responsive to citizens than are mayors of cities
principle” in its own right.19 Whatever the merits without city managers.24 “The most consistent pre-
might have been of promoting an unassailable dictor” that a city council will agree to proposals for
public administration, however, casting the field as more efficient and effective governance is the pres-
a pure science saddled it with an ultimately unten- ence of a city manager who has long been in office.25
able paradigm. The presence of appointed top managers also
enhances teamwork. There is greater political-
administrative teamwork in cities that have a city
WHAT THE PIONEERS OF PUBLIC manager than there is in these cities that lack one.26
Studies of American county governments similarly
ADMINISTRATION GOT RIGHT find that “county managers are adept at people skills
Although the faith that the pioneering public admin- and consensus building, perhaps even more so than
istration scholars had in the dichotomy and admin- city managers.”27
istrative principles was, as we review shortly, largely Teamwork is important because it has a direct
misplaced, research confirms that those pioneers impact on a local government’s fortunes. A densely
were pretty much right about what public adminis- careful study of local governments in fourteen
tration could and should be. Most of their thinking Western countries, including the United States, found
focused on local government, where, at the time, the that mayors and city managers “are not engaged in
vast bulk of public spending, employees, and corrup- a zero-sum contest for control,” but instead have
tion were found. “interdependency and reciprocal influence.”28 When
these managers “always” promote team building, 74
percent of city councils and county commissions are
Professional Public Administration rated “highly effective” as decision-making bodies,
Improves Governing but just 53 percent are so rated when top admin-
Perhaps the central insight of these early scholars istrators “never or occasionally” promote team
is that professionalism improves governing. Career building.29
federal executives are measurably and significantly
more productive public administrators than are
those who are political appointees.20 Mayors who The Council-Manager Form of Government
are greatly involved administratively, and who have Improves Governing
high levels of education and deep job-related expe- The pioneers also strongly advocated the adoption
rience, put more pupils in schools,21 collect more of another of their inventions, the council-manager
property taxes, and spend more on social programs plan, or council-manager form of government, in
than less educated and experienced mayors.22 The which the local government’s elected council votes
professionalizing reforms of local government that to hire and fire the government’s top appointed exec-
were advocated by the first public administration utive and approve budgets and policies, but essen-
professors—home rule, few governmental jurisdic- tially forbids council members from mucking about
tions, and short ballots, among others—all corre- in day-to-day administration. The first council-
late positively with more efficient and responsive manager plan was adopted by a local government
government.23 in 1912.
Paradigms of Public Administration 39

Just as the field’s first thinkers thought it would,


the council-manager plan has curtailed corrup- THE CHALLENGE, 1938–1950
tion. It “allows administrators and elected officers Dissent from mainstream public administration
to more  easily resist opportunistic behavior” accelerated in the 1940s in two mutually reinforc-
(i.e., corrupt behavior) relative to mayor-council ing directions. One objection was that politics and
communities.30 administration could never be separated in any
The council-manager plan also has rendered remotely sensible fashion. The other was that the
local services far more efficient, effective, and principles of administration were something less
responsive than in any other governmental form. than the final expression of managerial rationality.
For starters, council-manager governments are
unusually curious about whether they are, in fact,
efficient and effective. More than three-fourths Deflating the Dichotomy
of council-manager municipalities systematically Two subtle intellectual shifts were causing the poli-
inquire about their citizens’ satisfaction with spe- tics/administration dichotomy to be questioned.
cific services; no other governmental form (e.g.,
mayor-council, commission, town meeting) comes The Demise of the Dichotomy One such shift was
even remotely close.31 positive in tone. Public administration scholars were
When a city most exemplifies the values of shyly noting as early as the 1930s that making public
council-manager government, its citizens “are policy remained, certainly, “a question for statesmen,
more likely to rate the quality of city services in the but officials can effect in some manner the turning of
top category” than are citizens who are governed the scales.”38 In other words, public administrators,
by any other type of local government.32 In fact, like politicians, could mold public policy, too.
council-manager cities so satisfy their citizens that The second shift was negative. Over the years,
voting turnout in these “administrative cities” is a peculiar perversion had warped what likely was
much lower than in “political cities.” “Voter turnout the original meaning of the politics/administration
is dependent on the form of government” used by a dichotomy. “Politics” initially had meant only par-
community.33 tisan (and often corrupt) politics. By the 1930s,
In a reflection of the presence of top appointed however, “politics” had been expanded in its schol-
managers, the council-manager plan also promotes arly meaning to include public policymaking, and
teamwork in governing. In council-manager govern- public administrators, in accordance with the
ments, “elected officials and administrators . . . have dichotomy, should not enter this forbidden “politi-
extensive interactions,”34 and there is a growing cal” zone.
“complementarity” between them.35 Enhanced In 1946, a book of readings written by fourteen
teamwork also reduces conflict, and here again scholars, most of whom had extensive experience
the council-manager plan leads all other forms. as public administrators, forcefully questioned the
Indeed,  “form of government is the only statis- assumption that politics and administration could
tically significant factor”—not population size, be cleanly and clearly sundered.39 Were not what
urban  or  suburban location, finances, socioeco- appeared to be neutral “administrative” decisions
nomic conditions, or types of council elections—“to often heavily laden with policy preferences? The
account for levels of conflict and cooperation in the short answer was, “Yes.”
decision-making process.”36 The council-manager The abandonment of the politics/administra-
form extends the council’s reduced conflict to the tion dichotomy culminated in 1950 when a leading
larger community: just 5 percent of the “political scholar wrote in the field’s leading journal that, “A
discourse” in council-manager cities is “very polar- theory of public administration means in our time a
ized and strident, often rude,” the lowest percent- theory of politics also.”40 With this declaration, the
age out of five municipal governmental forms.37 dichotomy died.
Less conflict and more cooperation in governing, of
course, directly increase public productivity. People A Dead Dichotomy, a Diminished Field As a con-
benefit. sequence, the nature of the field was fundamentally
40 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

altered, and also, sadly, diminished. The field’s subordinates  if orders were to be communicated
founders had harbored no qualms about the wisdom effectively. Such an organization inevitably would
of differentiating public administration from the hoi have a “tall” hierarchy.
polloi of politics because they firmly believed that Span of control makes sense up to a point. Yet,
only a knowledgeable, noble elite (that is, public the administrative literature argued with equal vigor
administrators) could pull the people from their for another principle that was vital for clear com-
pestilent cistern of civic suffering, and into the light munication: minimal message handling. The fewer
of prosperity and progress. Consider what Wilson people who passed a message up or down the hierar-
wrote in this regard: “the many, the people. . . . are chy, the clearer and less distorted the message would
selfish, ignorant, timid, stubborn. . . . they are not be. This, too, makes sense up to a point. The hierar-
the children of reason.” Hence, “bureaucracy can chy required to bring the bureaucracy in accord with
exist only where” it is entirely “removed from the this principle, however, would be “flat.”
common political lives of the people.”41 Obviously to Simon and now to us, the two
Wow. We forget, perhaps mercifully, just how “principles” are mutually contradictory, and there-
arrogant the field’s first thinkers could be. But it fore, by definition, cannot be principles. This
was an arrogance that, whatever its drawbacks, dilemma drenched the whole of the management lit-
did imbue the public-administration pioneers with erature, including public administration, but it was
a sense of mission, leadership, superiority, and élan never more than suspected of being so stark a case
that was largely lost when public administration until Simon published his book.
became as “common” as politics. With time, the
revisionist ideology that politics and administration
were inseparable—indeed, indistinguishable—took THE WRECKAGE AND ITS
root and rigidified.
REACTIONS
By mid-century, the wreckage had been wrought. The
Puncturing the Principles two defining pillars of public administration—the
A simultaneous, and even more elemental, challenge politics/administration dichotomy and the principles
was the contention that there could be no such thing of public administration—had been abandoned by
as a “principle” of administration. creative intellects in the field, leaving it bereft of a
In 1947, Herbert Simon published Administrative distinct intellectual identity.
Behavior, his revolutionary and devastating critique Simon himself was rather mellow about the
of management theory. Although Simon was not future, writing that, “Can anything be salvaged  in
alone in his questioning of managerial principles, the construction of an administrative theory? As a
or what he dubbed dismissively as “the proverbs of matter of fact, almost everything can be salvaged.”44
administration,”42 his volume had such intellectual When it came to public administration, however, a
force that it led to Simon’s receiving the Nobel Prize revolutionary approach was once again in order.
in 1978. Simon proposed that there be two kinds of
Simon wrote that “a fatal defect of the current “public administrationists”45 (that is, the pro-
principles of administration” is that for “almost fessors, in contrast to the public administrators)
every principle one can find an equally plausible and working in harmony: Those scholars concerned
acceptable contradictory principle,” thus rendering with developing “a pure science of administration”
the whole idea of principles moot.43 based on “a thorough grounding in social psychol-
For example, the traditional administrative ogy,” and those concerned with “prescribing for
literature held that clear internal communica- public policy,” an enterprise that “cannot stop when
tion was  essential to effective managerial control, it has swallowed up the whole of political science;
but it promoted at least two contrary princi- it must attempt to absorb economics and sociology
ples for achieving clarity of communication. One as well.”46
principle was  narrow span of control—that is, a Political science, which was the first field that
manager could manage only a limited number of Simon fingered for public administration to swallow
Paradigms of Public Administration 41

up whole, had its own reasons for keeping public and loftier realm, but the price of admission was
administration under its thumb. A distinguished steep: public administration would shrivel to an
political scientist of this period wrote that politi- “emphasis,” an “area of interest,” even a “synonym”
cal science, “with the exception of public adminis- of political science.52 Observers commented that,
tration,” its most prestigious subfield, was “almost “public administration stands in danger of . . .
generally stigmatized as the least advanced” social senescence,”53 and “that lusty young giant of a
science by government and academia alike.47 decade ago, may now ‘evaporate’ as a field.”54
And political scientists had reason to fear that And evaporation during this perilous period
they might lose public administration: The found- was not improbable. Over ten years, a meager 4
ing, in 1939, of the American Society for Public percent of all the articles published in the five major
Administration was “above all an attempt to loosen political science journals dealt with public admin-
Public Administration from the restraints of political istration,55 and political scientists who identified
science.”48 public administration as their “primary field of
Political scientists were not about to ignore interest” shrank by a shattering two-thirds, from
their looming dismemberment, or, perhaps more 35 percent to just 12 percent.56 During the 1960s,
accurately, their eclipse; by the early 1950s, nearly the American Political Science Association moved
two-thirds (65 percent) of the 105 universities offer- “officially or formally” to rid itself of public admin-
ing public administration courses housed them in istration,57 and, even as late as 1977, the APSA’s
political science departments.49 In 1952, an article president dismissed it as an “intellectual waste-
appeared in political science’s preeminent journal land.”58 A leading public administrationist wrote
that put the matter plainly, calling for the continued during this period that political scientists’ opinions
“dominion of political science over public adminis- of his field often dripped with “undisguised con-
tration,” its “strange and unnatural child.”50 tempt or hostility. We are now hardly welcome in
the house of our youth.”59

PARADIGM 3: PUBLIC
The Impact of Political Science:
ADMINISTRATION AS POLITICAL Bureaucracy in the Service of
SCIENCE, 1950–1970 Democracy
As a result of these and related concerns, public Despite the disdain with which “the mother disci-
administrationists wormed their way back into the pline” often treated public administration, political
warm and welcoming womb (or so they thought) science likely was a salutary former of the field in
of the mother discipline, political science. Some laying some of its normative foundations, such as
political scientists, however, tried to smother their pluralism and equality under law, among other dem-
“strange and unnatural” progeny in it. ocratic values.
Beyond providing these values, however, politi-
cal science seems to have less utility in the education
Consternation and Contempt of public administrators. Asks a scholar: “What can
Paradigm 3 began as an exercise in reestablishing the political science contribute to the improvement of
linkages between public administration and political practitioner skill? An overview of the major intel-
science. But there were issues. lectual approaches within political science suggests
The public administrationists were no longer the answer is ‘not much.’”60 Or, to put the matter
really sure what they should be doing, groping for plainly, political science educates for (to quote
answers to the point that “the study of public admin- one particularly lucid synopsis) “intellectualized
istration in the United States” during this period was understanding” of public administration, whereas
“characterized by the absence of any fully compre- public administration educates for “knowledge-
hensive intellectual framework.”51 able action,”61 and these epistemologies—academic
For their part, political scientists were willing versus professional—are fundamentally different
to absorb public administration into their larger Zeitgeists.
42 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

that “management” was “a groundswell develop-


PARADIGM 4: PUBLIC ment that tends to pervade all others.”63 Suddenly
ADMINISTRATION AS it seemed that a number of public administration-
ists were rediscovering the line in Wilson’s seminal
MANAGEMENT, 1950–1970 essay of 1887: “the field of administration is a field
Partly because of their second-class citizenship in of business. It is removed from the hurry and strife
a number of political science departments, a few of politics.”64
public administrationists began searching for an
alternative. They found it in management, some-
times called administrative science or generic man- “Fundamentally Alike in All Unimportant
agement, which holds that sector, culture, institution, Respects”
mission, whatever, are of little consequence to effi- Is public administration a subfield of management?
cient and effective administration, and that “a body Does public administration, at root, amount to little
of knowledge”—statistics, economics, accounting, more than an understanding of civil service regula-
operations research, and organization theory are tions, while the core administrative functions remain
often cited—“exists that is common to the fields of essentially the same, whether they are practiced in
administration.”62 businesses, nonprofit organizations, or governments?
Paradigm 4 occurred roughly concurrently in
time with Paradigm 3, although it never received The Erratic Impact of the Intellectuals In light
the broadly-based favor that political science once of the management scholars’ contention that a
garnered from public administrationists. But in both singular body of knowledge exists that unites all
the Political Science and Management paradigms, administrative “fields,” it is noteworthy that there
the essential thrust was one of public administra- is a “substantial amount of disagreement about
tion losing its identity within the confines of some the commonality of administrative tools and tech-
“larger” concept. niques” among generic management schools, and no
Cornell University’s Graduate School of fewer than thirty different courses in these schools
Management, founded in 1948, is generally thought comprise the “basic requirements” for a master’s
to be the first academic unit that embraced the idea degree!65 If, indeed, management is management is
of generic management. Public administrationists who management, then why is there no reasonably con-
toiled in these schools (which, as a practical matter, sistent curriculum among the nation’s management
were rarely “management” schools but “business” schools?
schools), while not as actively reviled as those in some Given the national incoherence of generic man-
political science departments, were treated, at best, agement curricula, it is reasonable to conclude that
with indifference, shivering in the drafty attic of an something is missing.
absent-minded aunt who often forgot to serve meals.
What Is Missing? Actually, quite a lot is missing.
Specifically, function, institution, and sector are
The “Groundswell” of Management absent.
During the 1950s and 1960s, a spate of scholars Experiential data support the contention that
writing in a variety of journals accelerated the drum- public administration is unique. Those successful
beat of generic management as the logical succes- businesspeople who have become public executives
sor to more “parochial” paradigms, such as public are among the first to deny that there are significant
administration and business administration. In similarities between the public and private sectors.66
1956, the important journal, Administrative Science Public administrators who enter the corporate world
Quarterly, was founded on the premise that public, experience comparable difficulties of transition.67
private, and other institutional distinctions of man- Even entering the nonprofit sector represents, for
agement were false. both successful elected officials and businesspeople,
By the early sixties, a national survey of grad- “a journey to Mars” or to a long-lost primitive past
uate programs in public administration concluded in which “we’re bartering chickens for tools!”68
Paradigms of Public Administration 43

Empirical evidence similarly suggests that the the field. Seven out of ten books about public organ-
single most important key to managerial effective- ization theory take an “agency” perspective, as
ness in government is not wide-ranging experiences opposed to an “interest” or “access” view.73
as executives in other sectors, but the depth of one’s Regrettably, the real world renders this approach
experience as a public administrator.69 On a per- problematic. Privatization, the third sector, and
sonal level, it appears that a substantial background similar phenomena blur institutional distinctions,
in business may handicap a subsequent career in and conspire to make an institutionally-defined
government. Although there is usually an immediate public administration an elusive entity.
promotion involved for businesspeople who switch
to government, the longer the time spent working The Interest, or Philosophic, Definition of
in the private sector before entering public service, “Public” Interest is concerned with who benefits.
the lesser the likelihood that public administrators It is in the (public) interest of government to benefit
will be promoted and supervise large numbers of everyone it governs; it is in the (private) interest of
employees.70 the for-profit firm to benefit only its owners.
As we shall see in Part II, a burgeoning trove During the 1970s, public administrationists
of research that empirically compares public, non- moved toward a meaning of “public” that focused
profit, and private organizations casts grave doubt less on agencies and more on whose interest was
that management can be fruitfully approached as a affected. Thus, rather than concentrating on the
seamless entity, except in the broadest strokes con- Department of Defense, for instance, and leaving,
ceivable. The emerging consensus of both practi- say, Boeing Corporation to business scholars, public
tioners and scholars increasingly appears to be that administrationists explored the Pentagon’s contrac-
public and private management are, to cite Wallace tual relationships with Boeing because they involved
Sayre’s old saw, “fundamentally alike in all unimpor- the public interest.
tant respects.”71
The Access, or Organizational, Definition of
“Public” Our final dimension of “publicness”
The Impact of Management: Understanding and “privateness” is that of access, which addresses
the “Public” in Public Administration the degree of openness to the public found in an
The unambiguously clear impact of the management organization’s activities, space, information, and
paradigm is that it pushed public administration resources.
scholars into rethinking what the “public” in public As we explain in Part II, compared with private
administration really meant. and nonprofit organizations, public agencies are
Defining the “public” in public administration outrageously accessible. In fact, an astounding 94
has long been a knotty problem for academics, in percent of cities and counties (up from 84 percent
part because Western culture has never completely just three years earlier) invite such access, and proac-
sorted out the “complex-structured concept” of tively “provide citizens with the resources necessary
“publicness” and “privateness.”72 Publicness and to solve problems and implement decisions.” Some
privateness in society are composed of three dimen- four-fifths of these governments grant outsiders
sions: agency, interest, and access. access to their staffers, data, and reports, and nearly
two-fifths give them budgets.74
The Agency, or Institutional, Definition of
“Public” Agency refers to the distinction between Three Interlocked Understandings of “Public”
an institution that acts on behalf everyone (that is, it Our  three definitions of public administration—
acts publicly), and an institution that acts only in its institutional, interest, and organizational—are in no
own behalf (it acts privately). way mutually exclusive. Rather, they are mutually
Traditionally, public administrationists have reinforcing. Of equal importance, these definitions
thought that the “public” in public administration clarify not only the “public” in public administra-
refers to the institution of government and its agen- tion, but also demonstrate that “publicness,” and
cies, and this definition still dominates thinking in hence public administration, is unique.
44 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

“I was particularly shocked by a meeting I


EVAPORATION AVERTED, attended [in 1972] at Dulles Airport in Washington,
DC,” reminisced the founding dean of a then-new
1965–1975 school of public affairs, “between the assistant
Today, the raw peril confronting the field of public secretaries of personnel for all of the major U.S.
administration as a consequence of its being buried government agencies, and ten or so [nationally dis-
alive (even if it was barely alive) in political science or tinguished] public administration/affairs school
management is not fully appreciated. By the 1960s, deans.
the field’s “evaporation” was arguably imminent. “The secretaries warned us they were fed up
with the unpredictable quality and backgrounds of
our MPA [master of public administration] students,
The Forces of Separatism and their inability to have useful management skills
Even at its nadir during the period of Paradigms 3 that were of direct use when they joined the gov-
and 4, however, public administration was sowing, if ernment. The agencies said if we did not improve
unconsciously, the seeds of its own renaissance. this situation, they would no longer . . . recruit new
In the corridors of power, practitioners’ pride employees from our schools.
was emerging, as witnessed by the founding, in 1967, “The other deans and I took this as a direct
of the National Academy of Public Administration. challenge to the credibility and existence of our pro-
Its founders purposely created an association of the grams. . ..”75
nation’s most distinguished public administrators The situation was much the same at the state
and academics that could serve as a resource in the and local levels. When this writer became the first
solution of public problems—much like the National director of a newly-freestanding public administra-
Academy of Sciences (founded in 1863) serves as the tion program, in 1975, he was similarly shocked to
nation’s single most authoritative adviser to govern- find that subnational agencies consistently failed to
ment on scientific matters. Both academies are the mention in their recruitment materials the MPA as
only ones chartered by Congress. a qualification for public administrative positions;
In the halls of academe, it was becoming increas- they did cite, frequently, the master of business
ingly clear to public adminstrationists that neither administration as an earnestly sought-after qualifi-
political science nor management addressed their cation! Ample anecdotal evidence indicated that this
interests, nor could they. Political science’s intellec- situation was much the same nationally.
tual focus is pluralist, specialized, and communal, The forces of the 1960s that promoted the inde-
whereas public administration’s is elitist, synthesiz- pendence of public administration likely would have
ing, and hierarchical. Management’s focus is exclu- withered had not skillful educational leaders mar-
sively technical, whereas public administration’s is shaled those forces in the 1970s. Had those leaders
both technical and normative. These realizations not prevailed, the field might well be, at best, an eva-
crystallized when, in 1970, public administrationists nescent academic sycophant, gasping for life, or, at
organized their own, independent academic associa- worst, dead.
tion (details follow).
In sum, both the practitioner and academic
communities of public administration were moving PARADIGM 5: PUBLIC
toward an enhanced self-awareness. ADMINISTRATON AS PUBLIC
ADMINISTRATION, 1970–PRESENT
Saving a Field “Public administration as public administration”
The forces of scholastic separatism were strength- refers to public administration’s successful break
ened and accelerated by the professoriate’s growing with both political science and management, and
and worrying realization that their field was of its emergence as an autonomous field of study and
rapidly declining utility to practitioners of public practice, free at last from snide asides by political
administration. scientists about public administration’s predilection
Paradigms of Public Administration 45

for “nuts and bolts” and absent condescending com- science departments, and 14 percent are in business
ments by business faculties about the “sinecures” of schools.77
gutless government bureaucrats. The move toward an autonomous academic
field has been good for public administration. The
most effective MPA programs are those that are
NASPAA’s Nascency administered by freestanding schools and depart-
Academic programs in public administration ments78 (all of the top ten programs, as consistently
first banded together in 1958, when the long- ranked by U.S. News & World Report, are inde-
extinct Council on Graduate Education for Public pendent schools), and these units are experiencing
Administration was founded in a depressing attempt the fastest rates of student growth of all organiza-
to shield the field from being starved by political tional types.79
science and management. But it was only in 1970, Over the course of five decades, the number
when the National Association of Schools of Public of MPA and related programs and the students
Affairs and Administration (NASPAA) was birthed, enrolled in them nearly tripled.80 Of those 28,000
that public administration definitively declared its students (a significant undercount, as 31 percent
epistemological independence. of programs failed to respond to the survey), 57
NASPAA is composed of 285 of America’s percent are women and 31 percent are “persons of
master of public administration and related (e.g., diversity.”81
public affairs, public policy) master’s degree pro-
grams—essentially all such programs in the United
States. In 1983, NASPAA’s members voted to become From Politics/Administration Dichotomy to
the nation’s professional accrediting agency for these Political–Administrative Continuum
degrees. Central, perhaps, to Paradigm 5 is the resurrection of
One hundred eighty-four MPA and related the politics/administration dichotomy that defined
degree programs are accredited by NASPAA, and its public administration’s origins a century ago. But
accreditation associates with greater prestige, more the dichotomy has re-emerged in a significantly new
effective programs, an enhanced ability to recruit form—as a political–administrative continuum,
higher quality faculty and students, and, in contrast rather than as a politics/administration division—
to the chaotic core curricula found in schools of that furnishes the field with an intellectual gravitas
management, NASPAA-accredited programs offer a that is sensible, understandable, and workable.
consistent core curriculum nationally.76 Public administration rejects Paradigm 1’s
In 2013, NASPAA changed its name to the notion that public administration crouches, or ought
Network of Schools of Public Policy, Affairs, and to crouch, behind a dichotomizing firewall that pro-
Administration, but still refers to itself as NASPAA. tects it from politics. Nor does public administra-
Don’t ask. tion accept the puckering premise of Paradigms 3
and 4—that public administration is nonexistent,
amounting to nothing more than an unformed,
The Statistics of Secession and Success indistinguishable blob, sliming the awesome archi-
Public administration’s secession and resultant tectures of politics and management.
success are real. In Paradigm 5, politics and public administra-
A fourth of all 285 MPA programs are in free- tion do co-exist on the same social continuum, but
standing schools or colleges of public administration as separate and distinct formations of logic, whose
(and similar titles) that report directly to the central activities sometimes overlap. At the far ends of that
administration. Nineteen percent are in independ- continuum, political acts (such as appointing to gov-
ent departments. Twelve percent are institutes or ernment jobs unqualified nephews) can be distin-
centers that may or may not be freestanding. In sum, guished from administrative acts (such as appointing
from 44 to 56 percent of public administration and to government jobs the most qualified applicants
related programs are free of other fields. Twenty- drawn from a competitive pool), and easily so. This
six percent of all programs remain in political is not rocket science. True, it may be less easy to
46 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

LOGICS: POLITICS AND ADMINISTRATION

Shirley Sherrod is the daughter of an African- been friends with Sherrod, in part because, “She
American farmer. In 1965, when she was seventeen, helped us save our farm by getting in there and doing
her father was fatally shot in the back by a white everything she could do.”
farmer. An all-white grand jury in Baker County, The White House and the Department apologized
Georgia, filed no charges, so no one could be tried for to Sherrod. The secretary of agriculture offered to
his murder. Her mother and she remained in reinstate her. Sherrod declined.
southwest Georgia and became dedicated civil rights
activists. This episode epitomizes the logic of politics. It differs
Forty-five years later, in 2010, when Sherrod starkly from the logic of administration.
was the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s director The logic of politics demands that, for reasons
of rural development for Georgia, a conservative of personal professional survival, politicians rid
blogger released a portion of a videotape, broadcast themselves of harmful controversies (and all
by Fox News, of Sherrod addressing a banquet hosted controversies are harmful politically) as quickly and as
by the National Association for the Advancement of expeditiously as possible. Hence, Sherrod’s (allegedly)
Colored People (NAACP). In her address, Sherrod forced resignation was instant; she was the harmful
recounted an incident in which she said that, two controversy.
dozen years earlier, she had not given a white farmer By contrast, the logic of administration demands
facing the loss of his farm “the full force of what that, for reasons of personal professional survival,
I could do.” The NAACP’s national president and among others, executives learn the relevant facts
a heaving host of others denounced her remark as before acting. Had an impartial fact-finding inquiry
racist and, according to Sherrod, officials in her been mounted, which would have quickly exposed the
Department and the White House intensely pressured blogger’s malicious misdirection, Sherrod would not
her to resign. have been pressured to resign.
Sherrod resigned. No more than ten hours and The trick in public administration is to reconcile
twenty-two minutes had elapsed from the blogger’s political and administrative reasoning, a reconciliation
initial release of the edited videotape to Sherrod’s that often is difficult but is far from impossible.
resignation.* (In the foregoing fiasco, simply viewing the entire
As Sherrod had tried in vain to explain, her videotape, an undertaking that would have consumed
comment had been ripped out of context. The entire less than an hour, would have aborted vast political
tape of her speech revealed that Sherrod had gone embarrassment.) This is why public administration
on to state that she had rejected her first, admittedly is uniquely complex and deeply fascinating. Public
prejudiced, instinct, recognizing that “there is no administration blends politics and management,
difference between us,” and had in fact accorded and, as an intellectual and professional enterprise,
the farmer her full force in successfully saving his supersedes both.
farm. The farmer in question said that Sherrod had
exhibited “no racist attitude. Heck no. . .. I was never Sources: Will Bunch, “The Story behind the 1965 Killing
treated nicer.” His wife added that they have long of Sherrod’s Dad,” Huffington Post (July 21, 2010); Karen
Tumulty and Ed O’Keefe, “Fired USDA Official Receives
_________ Apologies from White House, Vilsak,” Washington Post
* The blogger released the videotape at 11:18 on the morning (July 22, 2010); and Media Matters for America, Timeline
of July 19, 2010, and “Fox News Alert” reported at 9:04 that of Breitbart’s Sherrod Smear, http://mediamatters.org/
evening that Sherrod “resigned just a short time ago.” research/201007220004.
Paradigms of Public Administration 47

separate the political from the administrative in the be a key issue.”85 The Government Performance and
middle reaches of that continuum, but we nonethe- Results Act Modernization Act of 2010 recognizes
less understand that politics’ values relate more to this, and requires interagency collaboration (the
power, community, pluralism, personality, loyalty, current federal buzzwords are “enterprise man-
emotion, and ideology, whereas public adminis- agement” and “enterprise government”), ranging
tration’s values relate more to fairness, hierarchy, from sharing information to effectively implement-
elitism, impersonality, professionalism, analysis, and ing policy across several agencies. The act man-
neutrality. dates, significantly, that the Office of Management
and Budget and certain congressional committees
develop a handful of long-range, “cross-agency,”
PARADIGM 6: GOVERNANCE, government-wide priority goals every two years, an
especially vexing challenge. Although most agency
1990–PRESENT officials state that that the act has improved col-
The roles of the profit, nonprofit, and public sectors laboration,86 two years after the first fourteen of
are metamorphosing in heretofore almost unimagi- Washington’s “interim” cross-agency goals had
nable ways. Most particularly, these sectoral changes been set, progress could not be reported for six (or
profoundly alter how we govern. more than two-fifths) because they “lacked either a
Globalization, the Internet, and social media, quantitative target or the data needed to track pro-
among other forces, are pressuring American gov- gress.”87 (As we explain in Chapter 7, quantifying
ernments to relinquish, by design or default, their some public goals is not always possible.)
traditional responsibilities to citizens, other govern- An astounding 97 percent of city and county
ments, and other sectors. managers report that they “use collaboration as a
As a scholarly wit winsomely asked, “Wither management strategy.” Collaboration is employed
the state?”82 most heavily in the areas of infrastructure, followed
by “fire/emergency management” and economic
development.88 Local administrators with economic
“Making a Mesh of Things”: The Rise development responsibilities spend one full working
of Governance day out of five on “handling the interdependencies
We are, in sum, moving away from government, or between their organizations and others,” and city
the control over citizens and the delivery of public governments link their activities with an average of
benefits by institutions of the state, and we are sixty other public, private, and nonprofit organiza-
moving toward governance (also known as govern- tions.89 Public administrators spend less time alone
ing by network, horizontal governing, and governing in their offices than corporate managers, and, when
by partnering), or configurations of laws, policies, they are by themselves, are on the telephone almost
and organizations that control citizens and deliver twice as long.90
public benefits. Government is institutional; govern- In a similar vein, nonprofit organizations collab-
ance is institutional and networked. orating with other nonprofits is a growing trend, and
Some seven decades ago, a distinguished scholar includes establishing collaborative grant-making
foretold of governing by network, defining public processes and the consolidation of several nonprof-
administration as “making a mesh of things,”83 a its’ financial management, and then outsourcing it.91
mesh that is amply documented. A unique analysis
of more than 800 empirical studies, covering a range
of disciplines, found a general shifting away from Does Governance Work?
“hierarchical government” and a distinct movement A “meta-analytical study [of] 137 cases of collabo-
toward “horizontal governing,” involving “a gradual rative governance across a range of policy sectors”
addition of new administrative forms.”84 concluded that making a mesh of things seems to
In Washington, “getting the government to work reasonably well.92 Governing by partnering
operate as a single entity instead of as a set of sep- correlates, significantly and positively, with agencies
arate, disconnected agencies and programs—should that perform better than agencies that work alone.93
48 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

We offer four examples: understanding of processes, people, and goals. When


it comes to governance, “small wins” matter a lot.102
■ The leading “positive results of collaboration,”
Governance also works well in the independ-
cited by more than four-fifths of city and
ent sector. Among its benefits are greater efficiency
county managers, are introducing greater
and organizational stability, and fewer overlapping
economic benefits and “better public service.”94
programs.103 “Political networking increases [non-
■ There is a positive correlation between intense
profits’] advocacy effectiveness and community net-
collaboration among public organizations and
working increases organizational effectiveness.”104
a high level of satisfaction held by clients.95
■ “At a minimum, managerial networking boosts
educational performance” in school districts.96
■ Focused deterrence is a network-based method PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION,
designed to reduce gang-related violence HAPPY AT LAST
by coordinating police, prosecutors, social
workers, clergy, outreach workers, victims, Public administration now straddles two paradigms.
former gang members, social-network analysts, One asserts its independence as a stand-alone, self-
and public and private employers, among aware field of study and practice. The other asserts
others. Used in about sixty diverse cities, its paramount purpose—creating and implementing
the approach has often been spectacularly social change for social good.
successful, with homicides in several cities Both paradigms are complementary and mutu-
cut by half or more in just two years. In High ally reinforcing. Without independence, public
Point, North Carolina, focused deterrence administration would be a sorry, surly suppli-
eliminated in a single day an open-air drug cant, shorn of the capacity to chart its own course.
market that had endured for decades, despite Without purpose, independence would be irrelevant.
unremitting “cuff-and-stuff” attempts to close This joyful, codependent, paradigmatic merger
it, and it had yet to return five years later.97 has been a long time coming, but it has come. And
it has arrived in style. Just as public administration
Governance is not a panacea. No paradigm is, and was a prestigious model for managers in all sectors
other paradigms, depending on “the nature of the during the 1930s, so it is today: As a major business
task” at hand, may be more useful, as “unexpected journal argued, “Public governance . . . offers a dis-
mismatches” of approach and task inevitably fail.98 tinct set of ideas for how corporate governance can
Nearly four-fifths of local managers say that collab- be improved in practice,” especially in the areas of
oration’s most significant challenge is “turf wars,” “manager compensation, division of power within
and almost two-thirds find it to be time-consum- firms, rules of succession to top positions, and insti-
ing.99 In fact, it appears that “networking overall, as tutionalized competition in core areas of the cor-
an aggregate concept, has no impact on [governmen- poration. . .. To an even larger extent,” these ideas
tal] performance.” Rather, specific parts of networks “could be applied to not-for-profit firms.”105
interacting with each other is what boosts perfor- Public administration, happy at last.
mance.100
A large-scale analysis found that certain “crit-
ical variables” must be present for governance to NOTES
succeed. They are: trust; commitment; solid leader- 1. Woodrow Wilson, “The Study of Administration,”
ship (well-educated, younger public chief executives Political Science Quarterly 2 (June/July 1887),
who exhibit a “concern with self-development” are pp. 197–222.
more effective organizational collaborators than are 2. Daniel W. Williams, “Evolution of Performance
their less-educated, older counterparts who have Measurement until 1930,” Administration &
little interest in self-improvement101); a history of co- Society 36 (May 2004), pp. 131–165.
operation; incentives to collaborate; balanced power 3. As derived from data in Institute of Public
and resources among the participants; face-to-face Administration, http://www.theipa.org/aboutipa/
conversation among the collaborators; and a shared history.html.
Paradigms of Public Administration 49

4. Luther Gulick, “George Maxwell Had a Dream: A 17. L. Urwick, “Organization as a Technical Problem,”
Historical Note with a Comment on the Future,” Papers on the Science of Administration, Luther
American Public Administration: Past, Present, Gulick and L. Urwick, eds. (New York: Institute
Future, Frederick C. Mosher, ed. (University, AL: of Public Administration, 1937), pp. 47–88. The
University of Alabama Press, 1975), pp. 253–267. quotation is on p. 49.
The quotation is on p. 257. 18. Luther H. Gulick, “Notes on the  Theory  of
5. “Efficiency in City Government,” Annals of the Organization,” Papers on the Science of Adminis-
American Academy of Political and Social Science tration, pp. 1–46. The quotation is on p. 9.
XLI (May 12, 1912). 19. Alasdair Roberts, “The Unassailable Principle:
6. Committee on Practical Training for Public Why Luther Gulick Searched for a Science of
Service, American Political Science Association, Administration,” International Journal of Public
Proposed Plan for Training Schools for Public Administration 21 (June 1998), pp. 235–274.
Service (Madison, WI: American Political Science 20. Lewis, Political Appointments, Bureau Chiefs,
Association, 1914), p. 3. and Federal Management Performance. Details
7. American Political Science Association, are in Chapter 9.
Proceedings of the American Political Science 21. Claudia N. Avellaneda, “Municipal Performance:
Association, 1913–1914 (Washington, DC: Does Mayoral Quality Matter?” Journal of Public
Author, 1915), p. 264. Administration Research and Theory 19 (April
8. Frank J. Goodnow, Politics and Administration 2009), pp. 285–312.
(New York: Macmillan, 1900), pp. 10–11. 22. Claudia N. Avellaneda, “Mayoral Quality and
9. Robert T. Golembiewski and Gerald T. Gabris, Local Public Finance,” Public Administration
“Today’s City Managers: A Legacy of Success- Review 69 (May/June 2009), pp. 469–486.
Becoming-Failure,” Public Administration Review 23. Alejandro Rodriguez, “Reformed County
54 (November/December 1994), pp. 525–530. Government and Service Delivery Performance:
10. Alan Ehrenhalt, “The Mayor-Manager Merger,” An Integrated Study of Florida Counties,”
Governing (October 2006), pp. 9–10. The quota- International Journal of Public Administration 30
tion is on p. 9. (10, 2007), pp. 973–994.
11. Alasdair Roberts, “Demonstrating Neutrality: 24. David H. Folz and P. Edward French, Managing
The Rockefeller Philanthropies and the Evo- America’s Small Communities: People, Politics,
lution of Public Administration, 1927–1936,” and Performance (Lanham, MD: Rowman and
Public  Administration Review 54 (May/June Littlefield, 2005).
1994), pp. 221–228. The quotation is on p. 222. 25. Timothy B. Krebs and John P. Peliserro, “What
The quotation concerning “unexampled rapidity” Influences City Council Adoption and Support
is by Leonard D. White, Trends in Public Admini- for Reinventing Government? Environmental
stration (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1933). or Institutional Factors?” Public Administration
12. Ibid., p. 222. Review 70 (March/April 2010), pp. 258–267. The
13. Alice B. Stone and Donald C. Stone, “Early Deve- quotation is on p. 263.
lopment of Education in Public  Administration,” 26. Karl Nollenberger, “Cooperation and Conflict in
in American Public  Administration, pp. 11–48. Governmental Decision Making in Mid-Sized U.S.
The quotation is on p. 30. Cities,” Municipal Year Book, 2008 (Washington,
14. Roberts, “Demonstrating Neutrality,” p. 222. DC: International City/County Management
15. Morris B. Lambie, ed., Training for the Public Association, 2008), pp. 9–15.
Service: The Report and Recommendations 27. James H. Svara, “Leadership and Profession-
of a Conference Sponsored by the Public alism  in County Government,” The American
Administration Clearing House (Chicago: Public County: Frontiers of Knowledge, Donald C.
Administration Clearing House, 1935). Menzel, ed. (Tuscaloosa, AL: University of
16. The famous phrase was first written by Wallace Alabama Press, 1996), pp. 109–127. The quota-
Sayre in “Premises of Public Administration: Past tion is on p. 124.
and Emerging,” Public Administration Review 18 28. Poul Erik Mouritzen and James H. Svara,
(March/April 1958), pp. 102–105. The quotation Leadership at the Apex: Politicians and
is on p. 104. Administrators in Western Local Governments
50 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

(Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 39. Fritz Morstein Marx, ed., Elements of Public
2002), p. 258. Administration (New York: Prentice-Hall, 1946).
29. Kimberly L. Nelson and James H. Svara, 40. John Merriman Gaus, “Trends in the Theory of
“Upholding and Expanding the Roles of Local Public Administration,” Public Administration
Government Managers: State of the Profession Review 10 (Summer 1950), pp. 161–168. The
2012,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 (Washington, quotation is on p. 168.
DC: International City/County Management 41. Wilson, “The Study of the Administration,”
Association, 2014), pp. 3–20. The figures are on pp. 501, 504.
p. 13, and include the 29 percent of the top city 42. Herbert A. Simon, “The Proverbs of
administrators who were not in mayor-council Administration,” Public Administration Review 6
cities and the 24 percent of top county adminis- (Winter 1946), pp. 53–67.
trators who were elected. Counties comprised 12 43. Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior:
percent of the governments surveyed (p. 6). A Study of Decision-Making Processes in
30. Richard C. Feiock and Jaehoon Kim, “Credible Administrative Organization, 3rd ed. (New York:
Commitment and Council-Manager Government: Free Press, 1976), p. 20.
Implications for Policy Instrument Choices,” 44. Ibid., p. 38.
Public Administration Review 63 (September/ 45. The term, public administrationist, apparently
October 2003), pp. 616–625. The quotation is on was coined by Dwight Waldo in his “Public
p. 616. Administration,” Political Science: Advance of the
31. Evelina R. Moulder, “Citizen Engagement: An Discipline, Marian D. Irish, ed. (Englewood Cliffs,
Evolving Process,” Municipal Year Book, 2010 NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1968), pp. 153–189. The phrase
(Washington, DC: International City/County appears on p. 154. Waldo wrote that he could not
Management Association, 2010), pp. 28–32. think of a better title, and hence was forced to use
Figures, 76 and 58 percent (p. 31), respectively, “an awkward expression in lack of an adroit one.”
are for 2009. 46. Herbert A. Simon, “A Comment on ‘The Science
32. Curtis Wood and Yongmao Fan, “The Performance of Public Administration,’” Public Administration
of the Adapted City from the Perspective of Review 7 (Summer 1947), pp. 200–203. The quo-
Citizens,” Public Performance & Management tation is on p. 202.
Review 31 (March 2008), pp. 407–430. The quo- 47. David Easton, The Political System (New York:
tation is on p. 407. Knopf, 1953), pp. 38, 40.
33. Curtis Wood, “Voter Turnout in City Elections,” 48. Dwight Waldo, “Introduction: Trends and Issues in
Urban Affairs Review 38 (November 2002), pp. Education for Public Administration,” Education
209–231. The quotations are on p. 209. Emphasis for Public Service, 1979, Guthrie S. Birkhead and
added. James D. Carroll, eds. (Syracuse, NY: Maxwell
34. James H. Svara, “The Search for Meaning in School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse
Political-Administrative Relations in Local University, 1979), pp. 13–26. The quotation is on
Government,” International Journal of Public p. 15.
Administration 29 (12, 2006), pp. 1065–1090. 49. Patricia W. Ingraham and Alfred Zuck, “Public
The quotation is on p. 1065. Affairs and Administration Education: An
35. Tansu Demir, “The Complementarity View: Overview and Look Ahead from the NASPAA
Exploring a Continuum in Political-Administrative Perspective,” Journal of Public Administration
Relations,” Public Administration Review 69 Education 2 (October 1996), pp. 161–174.
(September/October 2009), pp. 876–888. 50. Roscoe Martin, “Political Science and Public
36. Nollenberger, “Cooperation and Conflict in Administration – A Note on the State of the
Governmental Decision Making in Mid-Sized Union,” American Political Science Review 46
U.S. Cities,” p. 9. Emphasis added. (September 1952), pp. 660–676. The quotations
37. Nelson and Svara, “Upholding and Expanding the are on pp. 665, 661.
Roles of Local Government Managers,” p. 14. 51. William J. Siffin, “The New Public Administration:
38. E. Pendleton Herring, Public Administration and Its Study in the United States,” Public
the Public Interest (New York: McGraw-Hill, Administration 24 (Winter 1956), pp. 365–376.
1936), p. vii. The quotation is on p. 367.
Paradigms of Public Administration 51

52. Martin Landau, “The Concept of Decision- 66. See, for example, James M. Kouzes, “Why
Making in the ‘Field’ of Public Administration,” Businessmen Fail in Government,” New York
Concepts and Issues in Administrative Behavior, Times (March 8, 1987).
Sidney Mailick and Edward H. Van Ness, eds. 67. Donald Rumsfeld, “A Politician-Turned-Executive
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1962), Surveys Both Worlds,” Fortune (September 10,
pp. 1–29. 1979), pp. 50–54.
53. Frederick C. Mosher, “Research in Public Admini- 68. Clara Miller, “The Looking-Glass World of Non-
stration: Some Notes and Suggestions,” Public profit Money: Managing in For-Profits’ Shadow
Administration Review 16 (Summer 1956), Universe,” Nonprofitquarterly.org (December 21,
pp. 169–178. The quotation is on p. 171. 2005).
54. Landau, “The Concept of Decision-Making in the 69. David E. Lewis, Political Appointments, Bureau
‘Field’ of Public Administration,” p. 2. Chiefs, and Federal Management Performance
55. Jack L. Walker, “Brother, Can You Paradigm?” PS 5 (Princeton, NJ: Woodrow Wilson School of Public
(Fall 1972), pp. 419–422. Figure is for 1960– and International Affairs, Princeton University,
1970. 2005). Details are in Chapter 9.
56. Albert Somit and Joseph Tanenhaus, American 70. Barry Bozeman and Branco Ponomariov, “Sector
Political Science: A Profile of a Discipline (New Switching from a Business to a Government Job:
York: Atherton, 1964), pp. 52, 54. Figures are for Fast-Track Career or Fast-Track to Nowhere?”
1953–1963. Public Administration Review 69 (January/
57. Waldo, “Public Administration,” p. 154. February 2009), pp. 77–91.
58. Heinz Eulau (1977), as quoted in Krishna 71. The original expression of Sayre’s mythic and
K. Tummala, “Comparative Study and the Section enduring pronunciemento is unclear. Graham
on International and Comparative Administration T. Allison, Jr. reports that, after being a formative
(SICA),” Public Administration Review 58 figure in the planning of the nation’s first generic
(January/February 1998), p. 21. school of management, at Cornell University,
59. Dwight Waldo, “Scope of the Theory of Public Sayre departed for Columbia University and,
Administration,” Theory and Practice of Public evidently as a parting shot, issued his famous
Administration: Scope, Objectives, and Methods, aphorism. See Allison’s “Public and Private
Monograph 8, James C. Charlesworth, ed. (Phila- Management: Are They Fundamentally Alike in
delphia: American Academy of Political and Social All Unimportant Respects?” Public Management,
Sciences, 1968), pp. 1–26. The quotation is on p. 8. Public and Private Perspectives, James L. Perry
60. David L. Weiner, “Political Science, Practitioner and Kenneth L. Kraemer, eds. (Palo Alto, CA:
Skill, and Public Management,” Public Admini- Mayfield, 1983), pp. 72–92.
stration Review 52 (May/June 1992), pp.  240– 72. Stanley I. Benn and Gerald F. Gaus, “The Public
245. The quotation is on p. 241. and the Private: Concepts and Action,” Public and
61. Caldwell, “Public Administration and the Private Social Life, S. I. Benn and G. F. Gaus, eds.
Universities,” p. 57. (New York: St. Martin’s, 1983), pp. 3–27. The
62. Kenneth L. Kraemer and James L. Perry, “Camelot quotation is on p. 5. The following discussion is
Revisited: Public Administration Education in a based on this book.
Generic School,” Education for Public Service, 73. James L. Perry, Hal G. Rainey, and Barry
1980, Guthrie S. Birkhead and James D. Carroll, Bozeman, “The Public-Private Distinction in
eds. (Syracuse, NY: Maxwell School of Citizenship Organization  Theory: A Critique and Research
and Public Affairs, Syracuse University, 1980), Strategy,” Paper presented by the 1985 Annual
pp. 87–102. The quotation is on p. 91. Meeting of the American Political Science
63. Ward Stewart, Graduate Study in Public Admini- Association (New Orleans, August 29–September
stration: A Guide to Graduate Programs, Report 1, 1985), Table 1.
to the U.S. Department of Health, Education, 74. Evelina R. Moulder, “Citizen Engagement: An
and Welfare (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Evolving Process,” Municipal Year Book, 2010
Printing Office, 1961), p. 39. (Washington, DC: International City/County
64. Wilson, “The Study of Administration,” p. 209. Management Association, 2010), pp. 28–32.
65. Kraemer and Perry, “Camelot Revisited,” p. 92. Emphasis added. Data (p. 30) are for 2009.
52 PA R T I In Defense of Governing Well

75. Charles F. Bonser, “Institutionalizing a Discipline: Effects of Data-Driven Reviews on Performance


The Evolution of Public Administration but Some Should Strengthen Practices, GAO-15-
Education in the United States,” Paper prepared 579 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
for 2015 TPC Conference, National University Office, 2015), Highlights page.
of Public Service, Budapest, Hungary, May 2015, 87. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Managing
pp. 10–11. Emphasis added. for Results: OMB Should Strengthen Reviews of
76. Mark R. Daniels, “Public Administration as an Cross-Agency Goals, GAO-14-526 (Washington,
Emergent Profession: A Survey of Attitudes about DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2014),
the Review and Accreditation of Programs,” Highlights page.
Paper presented at the National Conference 88. Rosemary O’Leary and Catherine M. Gerard.
of  the  American Society for Public Admini- “Collaborative Governance and Leadership: A
stration, New York, April, 1993, and J. Norman 2012 Survey of Local Government Collaboration,”
Baldwin, “Comparison of Perceived Effectiveness Municipal Year Book, 2013 (Washington, DC
of MPA Programs Administered Under Different International City/County Management Asso-
Institutional Arrangements,” Public Admini- ciation, 2013), pp. 57–70. The quotations are on
stration Review 48 (September/October 1988), pp. 57, 59, 61
pp. 876–884. 89. Robert Agranoff and Michael McGuire,
77. Bonser, “Institutionalizing a Discipline,” p. 12. “American Federalism and the Search for Models
Data are for 2014. of Management,” Public Administration Review
78. Baldwin, “Comparison of Perceived Effectiveness 61 (November/December 2001), pp. 671–681.
of MPA Programs Administered Under Different The quotation is on p. 677.
Institutional Arrangements,” p. 876. 90. Lyman W. Porter and John Van Maanen, “Task
79. Robert A. Cleary, “Masters Programs in PA Accomplishment and the Management of Time,”
Continue to Expand,” PA Times, 19 (December 1, Managing for Accomplishment, Bernard Bass,
1996), pp. 2, 14. ed. (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1970),
80. NASPAA Data Center, 2013–2014 Annual pp. 180–192.
Program Survey Results (Washington, DC: 91. Erin Lamb, “Collaboration: The Nonprofit Trend,”
Author, 2015), and National Association of Nonprofitquarterly.org (February 2, 2015).
Schools of Public Affairs and Administration, 92. Chris Ansell and Alison Gash, “Collaborative
1986 Directory: Programs in Public Affairs and Governance in Theory and Practice,” Journal of
Administration (Washington, DC: Author, 1986), Public Administration Research and Theory 18
p. xix. Data are for 1973–2014. (October 2008), pp. 543–571.
81. NASPAA Data Center, 2013–2014 Annual 93. Rhys Andrews and Tom Entwistle, “Does Cross-
Program Survey Results. Sectoral Partnership Deliver? An Empirical Explo-
82. Ira Sharkansky, Wither the State? Politics and ration of Public Service Effectiveness, Efficiency,
Public Enterprise in Three Countries (Chatham, and Equity,” Journal of Public Administration
NJ: Chatham House, 1979). Research and Theory 20 (July 2010), pp. 679–701.
83. Paul H. Appleby, Policy and Administration Details are in Chapters 11 and 12.
(Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press, 94. O’Leary and Gerard, “Collaborative Governance
1949), p. 15. and Leadership,” p. 64.
84. Carolyn J. Hill, “Is Hierarchical Government in 95. Keith G. Provan and H. Brinton Milward, “A
Decline? Evidence from Empirical Research,” Preliminary Theory of Interorganizational Effect-
Journal of Public Administration Research and iveness: A Comparative Study of Four Community
Theory 15 (Spring 2005), pp. 173–196. The quo- Mental Health Systems,” Administrative Science
tations are on p. 173. Quarterly 40 (Spring 1995), pp. 1–33.
85. Jane E. Fountain, Building an Enterprise 96. Laurence J. O’Toole, Jr. and Kenneth J. Meier,
Government (Washington, DC: Partnership for “Desperately Seeking Selznick: Cooptation and
Public Service and IBM Center for The Business the Dark Side of Public Management in Net-
of Government, 2016), p. 5. works,” Public Administration Review 64
86. U.S. Government Accountability Office, (November/ December 2004), pp. 681–693. The
Managing for Results: Agencies Report Positive quotation is on p. 690.
Paradigms of Public Administration 53

97. John Seabrook, “Don’t Shoot,” The New Yorker the Public Sector: Do Chief Executives Make a
(June 22, 2009), pp. 32–41. Difference?” Journal of Public Administration
98. Jorgen Svensson, Willem Trommel, and Research & Theory 23 (October 2013), pp. 927–
Tineke Lantink, “Reemployment Services in 952.
the Netherlands: A Comparative Study of 102. Ansell and Gash, “Collaborative Governance in
Bureaucratic, Market, and Network Forms of Theory and Practice,” p. 543.
Organization,” Public Administration Review 68 103. Lamb, “Collaboration.”
(May/June 2008), pp. 505–515. The quotations 104. Morgan Johansen and Kelley LaRoux,
are on p. 514. “Managerial Networking in Nonprofit Orga-
99. O’Leary and Gerard, “Collaborative Governance nizations: The Impact of Networking on Orga-
and Leadership,” pp. 66, 65. nizational and Advocacy Effectiveness,” Public
100. Richard M. Walker, Rhys Andrews, George A. Administration Review 73 (March/April 2013),
Boyne, et al., “Wakeup Call: Strategic Manage- pp. 355–363. The quotation is on p. 355.
ment, Network Alarms, and Performance,” Public 105. Matthias Benz and Bruno S. Frey, “Corporate
Administration Review 70 (September/October Governance: What Can We Learn from Public
2010) pp. 731–741. The quotation is on p. 738. Governance?” Academy of Management Review
101. Marc Esteve, George Boyne, Vicenta Sierra, and 32 (January 2007), pp. 92–104. The quotations
Tamyko Ysa, “Organizational Collaboration in are on pp. 101, 92.
PART

II

Public and Nonprofit


Organizations

In the following chapters, we explain organiza- behavioral differences among organizations by


tions—their threads of theory, fabric of forces, and sector. The public sector is composed of govern-
fibers of people. ments, government agencies, and government cor-
We focus, of course, on public and public- porations. The private sector includes profit-seeking
serving nonprofit organizations, which are collectivi- companies. The nonprofit sector, also known as the
ties of people whose mission emphasizes the delivery independent, voluntary, emerging, hybrid, or third
of goods and services that benefit people outside, sector, is made up of privately-owned organizations
rather than people inside, the organization. It is a that do not seek profits. Technically, the nonprofit
realistic definition because it implicitly recognizes sector is a part of the private sector, but we treat it as
that these organizations are not necessarily peopled a stand-alone sector (one of its titles, after all, is the
by would-be saints; hence, the purpose of public and “third sector”). At the risk of getting ahead of our-
nonprofit organizations only “emphasizes” benefit- selves, we refer the reader to Figure 11-1, in Chapter
ing others, a nuance which accepts that these organ- 11, for a breakdown of the characteristics of each of
izations, like private ones, can legitimately benefit the three sectors.
their own employees, too. Still, the emphasis on Part II may be that portion of this book that will
serving others is real, and it associates with some have the most lasting value for you as you function in
very real differences. the world of organizations. It discusses why bureau-
All organizations, whether public, private, or crats behave in the ways they do, and attempts to
nonprofit, have some basic similarities, and we shall help you gain a bit of insight when working in the
review these, but our real interest lies in revealing public or nonprofit sector.
CHAPTER

The Threads of
Organization: Theories

B ecause organizations are different creatures to


different people, organizations are “defined”
according to the contexts and perspectives peculiar
THE CLOSED MODEL OF
ORGANIZATIONS
to the person doing the defining. Nevertheless, we Our first yarn is the closed model of organizations,
can, at least, posit certain characteristics that are which goes by many names. Bureaucratic, hierar-
common to all organizations. chical, formal, rational, and mechanistic are some
Organizations: of them.
■ are purposeful, complex human collectivities;
■ are characterized by secondary (or impersonal) Characteristics of the Closed Model
relationships; of Organizations
■ have specialized and limited goals;
We rely on a classic analysis in listing the principal
■ are characterized by sustained cooperative
features of the closed model of organizations:1
activity;
■ are integrated within a larger social system; ■ Routine tasks occur in stable conditions.
■ provide services or products to their ■ Task specialization (i.e., a division of labor) is
environment; and central.
■ are dependent upon exchanges with their ■ Means (or the proper way to do a job) are
environment. emphasized.
■ Conflict within the organization is adjudicated
Organization theorists, using essentially this list of
from the top.
characteristics but stressing different items in it, have
■ “Responsibility” (or what one is supposed
produced a vast body of literature on the nature of
to do, one’s formal job description) is
organizations. This literature can be viewed as a
emphasized.
long lanyard plaited of two yarns, each with its own
■ One’s primary sense of responsibility and
threads. Each of those threads of theory has contrib-
loyalty is to the bureaucratic subunit to
uted something of lasting value to our understand-
which one is assigned (such as the accounting
ing of organizations and their administration, but,
department).
as we shall see, each thread is tattered and torn in its
■ The organization is perceived as a hierarchic
own unique way.
structure (that is, the structure “looks” like a
pyramid).
■ Knowledge is inclusive only at the top of
the hierarchy (in other words, only the chief
executive knows everything).
56
The Threads of Organization: Theories 57

■ Interaction between people in the organization To Weber, an impersonal, rule-abiding, efficient,


tends to be vertical (that is, one takes orders merit-based career service provided the surest way of
from above and transmits orders below), but fulfilling the public interest in the face of a politi-
not horizontal. cally fragmented Germany and an arrogant,  pow-
■ The style of interaction is directed toward erful, yet somewhat silly aristocracy. Weber, in a
obedience, command, and clear superior/ large sense, was not anti-humanist in his thinking, as
subordinate relationships. has been alleged, but the effects of the bureaucracy
■ Loyalty and obedience to one’s superior and that he so loudly touted could be, both to the citizens
the organization generally are emphasized, who were governed by the bureaucrats, and to the
sometimes at the expense of performance. bureaucrats themselves.
■ Prestige is “internalized,” that is, personal Weber’s rigidly rational theory was warmly
status in the organization is determined largely welcomed by the first American public administra-
by one’s formal office and rank. tionists, who embraced it as an erudite justification
of their values, all of which shared an abhorrence
So runs our closed model of organizations. And it is with messy politics. Woodrow Wilson’s closest
just that—a model. No organization meets all twelve adviser, Colonel Edward House, anonymously
of its features in practice. Among organizations that wrote a novel that memorably expresses this revul-
are widely known, the Department of Defense likely sion. In it, the president is replaced by an omnip-
comes closest to accomplishing the requisites of the otent “Administrator of the Republic” who resides
closed model, but the Pentagon’s exceptions to the in a monastic barracks, spurning the distractive
model are obvious, such as highly unstable condi- fripperies of the White House, and who ends the
tions during wartime. odious political “rule of the bosses.” Congress is dis-
There are at least three theoretical threads that banded in favor creating numerous “boards,” each
have thrived within the closed model’s framework. composed of five neutral experts who are charged
with reforming the courts, taxes, railroads, “the
unsanitary custom of burial in cemeteries,” and
anything else that could benefit from a dose of the
Bureaucratic Theory Administrator’s common sense—in other words,
The earliest school of the closed model is that of just about everything.2 (This perspective remains
bureaucratic theory, or the study of the impersonal remarkably persistent; nearly a third of Americans
organization, and the execution, and enforcement of think that policymaking should be shorn from
legal rules in organizations. Its best-known represent- elected officials and turned over to “non-elected
ative is Max Weber, a remarkable German sociologist experts,” and nearly another third prefer that it go
who wrote around the turn of the twentieth century. to businesspeople.3)
Although “bureaucracy” is common in all sectors,
Weber cast his theory of bureaucracy squarely in the
public one. Scientific Management
In what is perhaps a too-succinct summary, the
Another rivulet of research in the closed model is
features of bureaucracy are:
scientific management (more popularly known as
“time-motion” studies), which is the analysis of
■ hierarchy;
workflow processes as the means of raising organ-
■ promotion based on professional merit
izational productivity.
and skill;
■ the development of a career service;
■ reliance on and use of rules and regulations; Workers as “Gear Wheels” Scientific manage-
and ment’s overriding concern is to increase production,
■ impersonality of relationships among and it does this by making human beings as effi-
career-professionals in the bureaucracy cient as, and more like, machines. To quote one of
and with their clientele. the school’s founders, “it is absolutely necessary for
58 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

every man in an organization to become one of a account of life in a scientifically-managed house-


train of gear wheels.”4 hold.
Key representatives of the scientific manage-
ment school include Frederick Taylor (who gave this The Lasting Impact of a Fraud? A deeper criti-
school its name with his 1911 volume, Principles cism of scientific management is that “there was
of Scientific Management), and Frank and Lillian almost no science to it.”10 Taylor’s Schmidt was
Gilbreth. The person-as-machine perspective, replete likely fictional,11 his methodologies were idiosyn-
with all its discomfiting overtones, is on clear display cratic at best, and he never published the actual data
in Taylor’s writings. A notorious example is Taylor’s on which his theory was based.12 Whether “Speedy
story of Schmidt, a pig-iron hauler, whom Taylor Taylor,” as he was called, was “a shameless fraud is
declared to be “stupid . . . phlegmatic . . . [and] more a matter of some debate, but not, it must be said,
nearly resembles in his mental make-up the ox than much.”13 Taylor’s sometimes brutal applications of
any other type.” After Taylor analyzed Schmidt’s his theory (the Gilbreths were much more humane)
physical movements, he ordered him to change how brought about strikes by exhausted workers (recall-
he moved his body and, as a result of these “scien- ing the old saw, “the flogging will stop when morale
tific” alterations, Schmidt’s production went up from improves”) and a hostile congressional investiga-
twelve and a half tons of pig-iron hauled per day to tion. (Perhaps it should give us pause that Taylor
forty-seven tons.5 thought public administration to be “on the whole
Similarly, the Gilbreths developed the concept of good.”14)
the “therblig,” each one of which represented a cat- Nevertheless, the impact of scientific manage-
egory of eighteen basic human motions—all physi- ment was stunning, and in every sector. Herbert
cal activity fell into a therblig class of one type or Hoover, as commerce secretary (1921–1928) and
another.6 (The scientific management crowd rarely later as president, took Taylor’s writings to heart,
was constrained by modesty, false or otherwise; try declaring a “war on waste” in both government
reading therblig backwards.) and business. Taylor was central in organizing
The person-as-machine perspective has a dis- America’s first graduate school to offer a degree in
tasteful aura. But rendering workers more physi- business (at Harvard, in 1908). His theories under-
cally efficient could benefit the workers (who, in the lay the Soviet Union’s first five-year economic plan.
early twentieth century, were commonly paid on a They were given their “fullest application by Henry
piecework basis), as well as their bosses, and even Ford, who,” following Speedy Taylor’s example,
clients. Frank Gilbreth, for example, applied his “measured his workers’ movements on the assem-
therbligs to surgery techniques in hospitals, and the bly line with a stopwatch.”15 “The world of man-
sharply-ordered “Scalpel! Sponge!” slapped into a agement”—including public management, where
surgeon’s palm by a hyper-efficient nurse is a direct “Taylor’s ghost” may “still haunt the halls of gov-
result of Gilbreth’s operating-room studies.7 Prior to ernment”16—“remains deeply Taylorist in its foun-
Gilbreth’s analysis, surgeons rustled around for their dations.”17
own instruments with one hand, evidently holding
open the incision with the other.
Frank Gilbreth’s wife, Lillian, held a professor- Administrative Management
ship at Purdue University that was split between Our final literature of the closed model is admin-
its schools of Management and Home Economics, istrative management, also called generic man-
and gave us kitchen islands, rolling kitchen carts, agement, which is the discovery and application
and cookery’s “work triangle.”8 As “the mother” of universal, scientific, administrative principles
of scientific management9 (Taylor is the “Father of that can improve any organization’s efficiency
Scientific Management”—it says so on his tomb- and effectiveness. (Administrative management’s
stone), she was featured on a U.S. postage stamp, oddly redundant title reflected its adherents’ desire
advised six presidents of the United States, and bore to distinguish it from the more physical scientific
Frank, at his request, six boys and six girls, two of management.) Unfortunately for this school, as
whom wrote Cheaper by the Dozen, a rollicking we explained in Chapter 2, there are no universal,
The Threads of Organization: Theories 59

scientific, administrative principles, but, as we noted It was not much of an inkling, but it is inti-
earlier, every school, including this one, has made mated, if perversely, in Mooney and Reiley’s con-
some contributions of consequence. tention that the “indoctrination” of workers is vital
The scholars of administrative management to well-managed organizations; they thought that
devoted their energies to the discovery of mana- the Catholic church had done a simply swell job
gerial principles that worked in any and all insti- of indoctrination over the preceding 2,000 years.21
tutional settings—from corporations and clubs, The idea that workers could think is much more
to governments and gulags—and in any and all apparent in Follett’s writing, who was suggesting
cultural contexts—from Boston and Botswana, to power sharing, stakeholder theory, and team build-
Paris and Patagonia. Writers in this stream usually ing in 1924!22
offered up very specific principles of administration: As Follett exemplifies, the administrative man-
The public administration scholars, Luther Gulick agement writers were among the first to express a
and Lyndall Urwick listed seven “principles” (recall dawning recognition that subordinates were people
POSDCORB, in Chapter 2); James D. Mooney and (like managers) and could think (almost like manag-
Alan C. Reiley, in their aptly-titled and influential ers). This breakthrough provided a basis for organi-
work, The Principles of Organization, found four; zation theory’s next paradigm, the open model.
another, Henri Fayol, unearthed fourteen.18 Among
the premier scholars in this tradition, Mary Parker
Follett was one of the few who fudged when it came THE OPEN MODEL
to enumerating principles of administration, but
then she was unusually ahead of her time, perhaps OF ORGANIZATIONS
because her intellectual roots were deeply planted in As with the closed model, the open model goes by
public administration.19 many names. Collegial, competitive, free market,
Follett’s ideas (as channeled through W. Edwards informal, natural, and organic are some of them.
Deming, of total-quality-management fame) were The origins of the open model actually precede
implemented by Japanese automakers, who applied those of the closed model by more than a century and
them with enormous success, at least up to a point. a half, and can be traced to Count Louis de Rouvroy
Japan’s Toyota, after faithfully following Follett’s Saint-Simon, the brilliant French social thinker, and
philosophy for more than fifty years, abandoned it to his protégée Auguste Comte, the “father of soci-
in favor of overtaking General Motors as the globe’s ology.” Both speculated on administration of the
biggest automaker (which it did) by embracing future: technology would spawn new professions;
“disastrous policies adopted after 2000, when top administrators would be appointed on the basis of
management’s thinking changed sharply in a direc- skill rather than heredity; and organizations would
tion that, while consistent with that of most other be created spontaneously, evolve “naturally,” and be
Western companies, would never have been toler- a liberating force for humanity.23
ated at Toyota in the past.”20 One result: Toyota’s
global rolling recalls in 2010 and 2011 to correct
safety issues in more than fourteen million vehicles, Characteristics of the Open Model
its largest number ever. Worse, Toyota executives of Organizations
lied to federal investigators, lies that resulted in a The principal features of the open model of organi-
$1.2 billion fine in 2014. zation are:24
With the emergence of administrative manage-
ment, a hint surfaced that presaged a revolution ■ Nonroutine tasks occur in unstable
in organization theory, one that ultimately would conditions.
bluntly question a foundation of its two theoreti- ■ Specialized knowledge contributes to common
cal predecessors, bureaucratic theory and scientific tasks (thus differing from the closed model’s
management. That hint was: underlings and toilers specialized task notion in that the specialized
in organizations conceivably might have minds of knowledge possessed by any one member of
their own. the organization may be applied profitably to
60 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

a variety of tasks undertaken by various other As with the closed model, three threads com-
members of the organization). prise the open model of organizations.
■ Ends (or getting the job done), rather than
means, are emphasized.
■ Conflict within the organization is adjusted by Human Relations
interaction with peers, rather than adjudicated The first of our three threads, human relations, is
from the top. the study of people’s problems, opportunities, and
■ “Shedding of responsibility” is emphasized interactions in organizations. It focuses on organiza-
(in other words, formal job descriptions tional variables, such as personal motivations, never
are discarded in favor of all organizational considered in the closed model.
members contributing to all organizational
problems). The Hawthorne Experiments In 1924, Elton Mayo
■ One’s sense of responsibility and loyalty is to and Fritz J. Roethlisberger began a series of studies
the organization as a whole. (later known as “the Hawthorne experiments,” for
■ The organization is perceived as a fluidic the location of the plant) of working conditions
network structure (that is, the organization and worker behavior at a Western Electric factory.
“looks” like an amoeba). Ultimately, the research involved six massive, and
■ Knowledge can be located anywhere in the hugely influential, studies conducted over eight
organization (in other words, everybody knows years.
something relevant about the organization, but Ironically, their experiment was predicated on
no one, including the chief executive, knows the then-plausible Taylorian hypothesis that workers
everything). would respond like “gear wheels” to changes in
■ Interaction between people in the organization working conditions. To test it, they altered the inten-
tends to be horizontal (that is, peers interact sity of light available to a group of selected workers,
with peers), as well as vertical. expecting that the dimmer the light the lower their
■ The style of interaction is directed toward productivity. The lights were turned down and pro-
accomplishment, “advice” (rather than duction went up. Mayo and Roethlisberger were dis-
commands), and is characterized by a concerted. They dimmed the lights to near darkness,
“myth of peerage,” which envelops even the and production kept climbing.
most obvious superordinate/subordinate Among the explanations of this phenomenon
relationships. that later came forth were: human workers probably
■ Task achievement and excellence of are not entirely like machines; the Western Electric
performance in accomplishing a task are workers were responding to some motivating varia-
emphasized, sometimes at the expense of ble other than the lighting, or despite the lack of it;
obedience to one’s superiors. and that the likely variable in question was that they
■ Prestige is “externalized” (i.e., personal status had been told that they were being watched25—a
in the organization is determined largely by condition that became known as the “Hawthorne
one’s professional ability and reputation, rather effect.”
than by office and rank). The Hawthorne experiments have grown
increasingly controversial over time. Some re-
So runs our open model of organizations, which, examinations of the data conclude that factors
like the closed model, does not exist in actual- other than human relations drove greater produc-
ity, although a major university might come close tivity, such as the observed workers’ fear of being
(which is why the open model occasionally is called laid off and that, unlike other workers, they were
the “collegial” model). But exceptions are apparent; given rest periods and group pay incentives;26 others
for instance, in universities one is likely to find a counter that the original findings remain valid.27
higher degree of loyalty to the subunit (such as the (For what it is worth, we tend to agree with the
academic department) than to the organization as former assessment.) Nevertheless, the experiments
a whole. rooted the idea deep into management theory that
The Threads of Organization: Theories 61

unquantifiable relationships (or “human relations”) Motivators relate, by and large, with the upper
between workers and managers, and among workers reaches of Maslow’s pyramid—belongingness and
themselves, are significant determinants of workers’ self-esteem, but not necessarily with self-actual-
productivity. ization. Belongingness and self-esteem result in
employees who are satisfied with their jobs, whereas
A Hierarchy of Human Needs: From Job self-actualization refers to one’s job becoming part
Satisfaction to Self-Actualization The Hawthorne of one’s definition of self, which is beyond mere job
experiments inspired much research on job satisfac- satisfaction; self-actualization verges on obsession.
tion—that is, what factors contribute to, or detract
from, employees’ acceptance of, and even happiness Hygienic or Motivator Factors: What Matters to
with, their employment. An early and important Public and Nonprofit Employees? What matters
contribution to this research is the “hierarchy of more to public and nonprofit employees, hygienic
human needs” developed by A. H. Maslow. Maslow factors, such as pay and perks, or motivators, such
perceived job-related human desires to be based, as praise and producing?
first, on physiological needs (such as eating), which Hygienic factors do not count for much among
provided the foundation for a person’s next great- these workers. Consider, for example, salary, perhaps
est need, economic security, then love or belong- the most definitively hygienic factor of all. As we
ingness, followed by self-esteem, and ultimately elaborate in Chapter 5, large-scale studies find that
self-actualization. government workers are “significantly less moti-
Self-actualization refers to a person growing, vated by salary” than are private-sector workers.30
maturing, and achieving a deep inner sense of Without question, motivator factors dominate.
self-worth as he or she relates to his or her job. And they appear to be more important to govern-
Maslow wrote that these “highly evolved” self- ment and nonprofit workers than they are to other
actualized people assimilated “their work into the and larger working populations. Motivator factors
identity, into the self, i.e., work actually becomes have an even greater impact among top public
part of the self, part of the individual’s definition of administrators than among lower-level ones.31
himself.”28 For over three decades, roughly nine out of
every ten federal employees have stated that “the
Hygienic Factors and Motivator Factors Frederick work I do is meaningful” or “important”32 com-
Herzberg extended Maslow’s hierarchy of human pared with about half of all Americans who state,
needs to his “motivation-hygiene theory,” which in a similar vein, that “a feeling of accomplishment”
holds that there are two classes of phenomena that is the “most important” single aspect of their jobs.33
make people feel good or bad about their jobs. Federal managers are much more likely than their
One class relates to the context of the job, and counterparts in business to “come to work” because
includes such factors as working conditions, organ- of the “nature of their jobs.”34
izational policies, and salary. Herzberg called these State government workers “are more motivated
“extrinsic” dimensions hygienic factors, so named to perform their work when they have clearly under-
because they are needed to avoid worker dissatis- stood and challenging tasks that they feel are impor-
faction, but fail, in and of themselves, to provide tant and achievable.”35
satisfaction and engagement. Hygienic factors cor- More than two-thirds of nonprofit employ-
respond, more or less, with the base of Maslow’s ees report that they are given the chance to do the
pyramid of human needs, where physiological and things that they do best and that their colleagues
security needs are found, are willing to help other employees learn new skills,
Herzberg’s second category relates to the content compared with about half of federal and corporate
of the job, and includes such factors as professional employees.36
and personal challenge, appreciation of a job well
done by supervisors and peers, and a sense of being Hygienic or Motivator Factors: What Matters
responsible for important matters. Herzberg called to Organizations? It may be comforting, in a
these “intrinsic” aspects motivator factors.29 bleeding-heart sort of way, to know that motivators
62 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

matter most to employees, but do they, or hygienic The Power of Public Employee Engagement
factors, matter more in advancing the interests of the “Multiple research studies have demonstrated the
organization? positive relationship between high levels of employee
Hygienic factors count, but not much. There is engagement and desired organizational outcomes,”41
simply no discernible relationship between generous perhaps because managers with high talent levels are
hygienic policies (e.g., lengthy vacations, etc.)—or twice as likely to be engaged than those with low
stingy ones—and more profitable companies.37 talent.42 Like all organizations, governments benefit
Hygienic factors “are like tickets to the ballpark— from engaged employees.
they can get you into the game, but they can’t help Federal employees who are engaged with their
you win.”38 jobs are up to three times less likely to perceive mis-
Motivator factors are more complicated. In and conduct than are their disengaged (and presumably
of themselves, they add more to employees’ job satis- more critical) colleagues,43 although, when engaged
faction than do hygienic factors, and job satisfaction workers do notice misconduct, they are more likely
can be, but not necessarily is, a positive component to report it;44 both behaviors reduce risk for the
in organizational productivity. But job satisfaction is organization.
merely that; one can be satisfied with one’s job, but Those federal agencies with the highest pro-
contribute to one’s organization so minimally that it portions of engaged employees, have: much higher
suffices only to avoid dismissal. performance and accountability scores; far less like-
lihood that employees will leave the agency; much
Enter Employee Engagement The multitude of lower injury and sick leave rates; and far fewer dis-
acolytes spawned by Maslow and Herzberg eventu- crimination complaints. These differences are not
ally began concentrating on what can help organi- merely statistically significant; those agencies with
zations win. Their answer is: employee engagement. many engaged employees frequently boast measures
Employee engagement holds that workers of agency quality that are two or three times greater
have a rational commitment (that is, employees’ than those of agencies with few.45 Disengaged federal
logical understanding that their employment ben- employees, by contrast, cost their government from
efits them financially and professionally—basically, an estimated $18 billion46 to $65 billion47 annually
an extension of Herzberg’s hygienic factors) and in lost productivity. The evidence is sufficiently com-
an emotional commitment (i.e., the visceral pride pelling that the feds, in 2014, set goals for greater
and enjoyment that employees derive from their employee engagement, took surveys of engagement,
work and organization—arguably an extension of and broke down the results for more than 20,000
Herzberg’s motivator factors) to their organization federal offices.
that inspire them to exert their very best effort on An analysis of state workers amplifies our
their organization’s behalf.39 Employee engage- understanding of those conditions that associate
ment expands the employee’s psychic bonding with more productive government workers. Public
with his or  her job (that is, Maslow’s self-actual- employee performance heightens when: the worker’s
ization,  should it be realized) to the whole of the job role is clear (“role ambiguity negatively affects
organization. job performance”); the employee directly contrib-
A variety of large-scale analyses show that utes to the fulfillment of the agency’s mission; and
“employee engagement surpasses satisfaction as an when the worker perceives that the agency not only
indicator of [individual and organizational] pro- is adequately funded, but that the agency also spends
ductivity.”40 And an individual’s job satisfaction those funds efficiently.48
per se was about all that Maslow and Herzberg Regrettably for governments, their disengaged,
were  really concerned with, but it is insufficient and relatively unproductive, workers are less likely
as a prod of  productivity. Wally, the bespectacled, to voluntarily leave their employers than are their
coffee-addicted slacker nonpareil in the comic disengaged colleagues in the private sector, in part
strip Dilbert,  exemplifies the satisfied, even happy, because they are “less likely to enjoy the pension
employee who also is spectacularly disengaged and and  health-care benefits that most government
unproductive. workers get.”49
The Threads of Organization: Theories 63

Engaging Government and Nonprofit Workers feedback are thirty times more likely to be engaged,
Although specific figures vary (sometimes widely), and even negative feedback increases engagement by
most employees fail to engage. The United States is a factor of twenty times61). Companies that fulfill
a global leader in its proportion of engaged employ- these conditions score markedly higher on the four
ees,50 but just 30 percent of America’s some 100 critical measures of corporate strength: productivity,
million full-time workers are engaged with their profit, employee retention, and customer satisfac-
jobs; half “are just kind of present,” and a fifth “are tion.62
actively disengaged.”51
America’s public employees handily surpass Rude, Crude, and Lewd: What Disengages Workers?
these overall figures. Two-thirds of federal workers “Toxic workers,” or employees who are thieves,
are engaged in their work.52 “Less than half of fraudsters, sexual harassers, or similar sociopaths
state and local employees are fully engaged in their can infect colleagues with their toxicity and result
jobs”53—still substantially higher than the national in massive employee disengagement from their jobs
employee proportion of three out of ten workers and organizations. Hence, neutralizing toxic workers
who are engaged at all. Engagement, however, is “enhances performance to a much greater extent
strikingly strong at the upper echelons of state and than replacing an average worker with a superstar
local governments, at least as measured by time worker.” In fact, hiring or retaining an employee who
spent. State department heads typically work over is “both highly productive and toxic” results in a cor-
fifty hours per week.54 City managers 55 and assistant porate profit that is “still net negative” and retention
city managers56 also work, on average, more than “no longer makes sense.”63
fifty hours per week, and 69 percent of “executives Two types of toxic workers are, unfortunately,
and senior managers in cities, counties and special common: uncivil boors and unconstrained bullies.
districts. . .. regularly work more than 40 hours [per
week] with no additional compensation”57—figures Uncivil Actions Organizational incivility is “the
that have held steady for decades. exchange of seemingly inconsequential inconsider-
Workers in the independent sector appear to be ate words and deeds that violate conventional norms
even more engaged. “The mean level of nonprofit of workplace conduct.”64
managers’ job involvement is significantly greater An astonishing 98 percent of American cor-
than for public managers.”58 Nonprofit “managers” porate workers and executives report that they
work 14 percent longer hours per week than state have been direct targets of uncivil behavior, and
“managers.”59 those who are “treated rudely” at least once a
week doubled over fourteen years, from a fourth
What Engages Workers? Six conditions of to half.65 To be fair, there are those grasping, nar-
employee engagement are the factors most clearly cissistic employees who believe themselves to be
associated with organizational productivity. They “entitled,” and are more prone than other workers
are: when employees feel that they know what is “to feel that they are victims of abuse and to react
expected of them at work; have what they need to do in undesirable ways.”66 We do not know just how
their jobs right; have the opportunity “to do what I many self-described “victims” of rudeness are actu-
do best every day”; receive recognition for work well ally self-centered egoists, but it is perhaps pertinent
done over the last seven days; believe that someone that nearly 11 percent of American workers over-
at work cares about them as a person (regrettably, estimate how productive they are relative to other
there is “total unawareness . . . across all levels of Americans, the highest proportion by far among
management. . .. [of employee] conditions that thirteen other developed countries (Canada ranks
foster positive emotions, strong emotions, strong next highest, at over 7 percent).67
motivation and favourable perceptions of the work Incivility’s presence may veil deeper pathologies,
itself”60); and think that there is someone at work such as racism and sexism;68 once started, rudeness
who encourages their development (98 percent of spreads quickly, “like catching a cold”;69 and it can
employees who receive little or no feedback are dis- morph into an “incivility spiral” of “increasingly
engaged from their jobs; those who receive positive intense aggressive behaviors.”70
64 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

Incivility’s organizational costs are considerable. are actually quitting their boss”81); 57 percent of
Eighty percent of workers and executives who think those bullied are women; and, when women are
that they were victims of uncivil acts report that they bullied, 71 percent of their bullies are women.82
lose work time “worrying about the incident”; 78 Bullying bosses focus on minorities, employees with
percent state that their commitment to their company little job security, and even highly-paid employees in
declined, and 66 percent say that their performance high-pressure organizations or during downsizing.83
declined (in a startling study, when medical teams Unsurprisingly, bullying by bosses occurs most fre-
received minor insults before conducting simulated quently at workplaces in all sectors that are char-
surgeries on babies, more babies “died” than when acterized by poor procedures, inadequate planning,
insults had not been received71); 63 percent lose time and incompetent managers.84
“avoiding the offender”; 48 percent intentionally The organizational costs of bullying are far
decrease their “work effort,” and 38 percent inten- higher than those of incivility. An impressive four-
tionally decrease their “work quality”;72 30 percent fifths of the victims of bullying voluntarily depart
were less creative and produced a fourth fewer new for other organizations (40 percent), are “termi-
ideas; and 12 percent voluntarily left the organiza- nated, driven out” (24 percent), or transfer to
tion because of incivility. Incivility also associates other departments (16 percent).85 These departures
with less teamwork.73 By contrast, civility and com- tote up when we realize that turnover costs range
pliments from colleagues lead to the recipient acti- from a third to two-and-a-half times the salary of
vating the “best self” in himself or herself, which can each  employee who leaves.86 Talented employees
result in improved job performance.74 are  the first to depart; 32 percent of employers
What happens to the perpetrators of incivil- report that  their “top performers left their organ-
ity? On the surface, not much. Only 1 percent to ization” in a single year.87 In those organizations
6 percent of employees who experience incivility where bullying is chronic, strong unions are often
report it.75 Dig a bit deeper, however, and the uncivil a consequence.88
suffer. Three-fifths of perceived incivility is inflicted As with uncivil employees, not much official
by supervisors on their subordinates, and their sub- action is taken against bullies. Sixty-eight percent of
ordinates sneakily subvert them; a fifth of those corporate executives state that their company took
miffed workers stall in responding to their super- action when bullying was discovered, but 88 percent
visors’ requests,76 and a third spread unflattering of the victims report that no action was taken, “a
rumors about them.77 Whether civil or uncivil, man- major disconnect.”89
agers and executives in Fortune 1000 firms report
that they spend 13 percent of their work time (or Incivility, Bullying, and Government Governments
seven weeks per year) dealing with the turbulent may be leading the way down these rude roads
wake of incivility.78 and  bullying byways. A fourth of government
employees have observed “abusive or intimidating
Bully Pulpits Bullying is incivility on steroids, and behavior” by co-workers over the past year (23
refers to overbearing and intimidating behavior. percent of federal workers and 26 percent each
Bullies are not nice, nor even competent, of state and local employees), compared with 21
employees. Supervisors who bully often perceive percent of businesspeople and 19 percent of non-
their victims as threats, or just enjoy bullying.79 profit employees.90
Arrogance, often a component of bullying (its Bullying in government reflects the same pat-
behavioral characteristics include anger and a desire terns, noted earlier, that occur elsewhere, with the
to dominate), clearly correlates with low self-esteem, added feature that more bullying occurs in those
low verbal and numerical abilities, and low perfor- public workplaces which are less representative of
mance ratings.80 the populations that they serve.91
Thirty-seven percent of employees in all sectors In the public sector, the costs of incivility and
report that they have been bullied at work. Seventy- bullying can be quite a bit higher than in the other
two percent of bullies are supervisors (three-quarters two, particularly when executives fail to actively
of all employees who voluntarily “leave their jobs squelch such behavior. When President George
The Threads of Organization: Theories 65

W. Bush and others were being briefed, in 2002, OD: The Public Experience Perhaps as many as
about the Iraq war plan, Defense Secretary Donald half of all organization development interventions
Rumsfeld snatched a copy of the Pentagon’s brief- occur in governments, and more than four-fifths
ing slides from the hands of National Security of government workers who participated in them
Adviser Condoleezza Rice, saying, “You won’t be report positive and intended effects on their agen-
needing that.” Bush responded with, “I’ll let you cies; less than a tenth report negative effects.95 These
two work it out,” and left. “Instead of a team of rates were quite comparable to the private sector’s
rivals, Bush wound up with a team of back-stabbers experience with OD.96 OD interventions in public
with long-running, poisonous disagreements about agencies “seem to be equally effective” as corporate
foreign policy fundamentals.”92 interventions when it comes to “enhancing both
individual development and organizational perfor-
mance,” but less so in affecting structures, goals,
Organization Development procedures, and rewards97—not surprising, as legis-
Another important subfield of the open model is latures and civil service commissions, not agencies,
organization development (OD), which is a planned, usually control these factors.
organization-wide attempt directed from the top Interestingly, it is the public sector (specifically, a
that is designed to increase organizational effective- metropolitan county’s sheriff’s department) that has
ness and viability through calculated interventions hosted “the longest longitudinal study” ever (over
in the active workings of the organization, using thirty years and counting) of OD’s long-term effects.
knowledge from the behavioral sciences.93 These include: lower turnover; more resources;
fewer jailbreaks and citizen complaints; and meas-
OD: Mission and Methods The mission of organ- urably improved leadership and organizational
ization development is to: improve the individual effectiveness.98
member’s ability to get along with other members;
legitimize human emotions in the organization; OD: Crises and Caveats Despite its successes,
increase mutual understanding among members; however, “a number of senior practitioners . . .
reduce tensions; enhance “team management” believe that the profession has lost its way.”99 OD
and intergroup cooperation; develop more effec- was “faddish” during the 1960s, “under attack” in
tive methods of conflict resolution using non- the 1970s, and morphed into so “many forms during
authoritarian and interactive methods; and evolve the 1980s and 1990s” that it is now “hardly recog-
less structured and more “organic” organizations. nizable” and may end up as “a historical artifact.”100
“The basic value underlying all organization- Which may have occurred: “Most . . . [OD] policies
development theory and practice is that of choice. are remnants of the 20th century.”101
Through . . . the collection and feedback of relevant Organization development’s disarray may stem
data to relevant people, more choices become avail- from its basics.
able and hence better decisions are made.”94 One such basic is the field’s premise that more
Organization development owes its origins to open and less tense employees are more satisfied
the social psychologist, Kurt Lewin, and his ground- (even happier) employees, and, hence, more produc-
breaking “Harwood studies” (named after Harwood tive employees. But, as we reviewed earlier, merely
Manufacturing, a textile plant) of 1939–1947. Over satisfied workers are not necessarily productive
time, techniques (e.g., sensitivity training, employee workers. Employee engagement, not necessarily
surveys) were developed that encouraged interper- more open and relaxed employees, is the key to
sonal candor and the creation of an interwoven heightened organizational productivity.
“managerial grid” that facilitated coordination More fundamental is the field’s founding notion
within the organization. Outside consultants who that the more choices available to employees, the
specialize in OD (what the field calls “third party more productive they and their organization will be;
change agents”) usually oversee all these group-and- recall that “choice [is] the basic value underlying all
feedback activities, and they call their consultations organization-development theory and practice.”102
“interventions.” Researchers have found that when people have
66 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

more, rather than fewer, options they believe that a whole as its analytical unit (in contrast to the
their choices will result in better performance, a other schools’ preference for the small group),
belief heartily endorsed by the OD scholars. In fact, and its focus on pressures emanating from the
the reverse is true, both organizationally and per- environment.  Organization theorists often refer
sonally. “The costs of choice freedom outweigh its to this  literary stream as adaptive systems or con-
benefits. . .. As a result, those who have the option tingency  theory, which holds that organizations
to choose exercise it, yet end up performing worse are  themselves, and function in, dynamic net-
and feeling worse than those who do not have that works in which forces act and react to one another,
option.”103 So basic is this reality that, one year after and are able to cohere and stabilize only when their
paraplegics have been completely paralyzed (thereby competition and collaboration achieve a rough
drastically decreasing their previously available balance.
choices), and one year after lottery winners have In this construct, the organization’s environ-
won large lotteries (vastly increasing their choices), ment is almost overwhelming, an “ever-changing
their happiness levels are virtually identical.104 screen,” through which the organization, by con-
tinually assuming “different shapes and sizes,” must
The Executive’s Dilemma OD’s prime value seems pass or be “swept away.”107 Hence, these research-
to be less one of organizational productivity and ers have found that more flexible organizations are
more one of employee happiness. In fact, some of more likely to endure in rapidly-changing environ-
the field’s adherents worry that the very idea of using ments,108 and that higher-performing organizations
OD to boost organizational performance is a sell- match the complexity of their environments.109
out of the field’s mission of improving individual Theorists differ over precisely how organiza-
lives in the workplace. The bottom line and “the tions adapt to their environments.110
mind-set of management” have perverted organi-
zation development; as a consequence, employees Adapting Biologically One school, known as pop-
trapped in “the grubby realities of worklife soon ulation ecology or organizational ecology, holds that
figure out whose side [these] breezy, self-assured, organizational adaptation is a biological, evolution-
and excessively articulate” OD consultants are truly ary process; organizations that cannot adapt die.
on.105 They are, contemptibly (in this perspective), The blind spots in this view are several. In the
on management’s side. biological world, survival is defined in terms of col-
All this is, of course, fine. It is admirable that lectivities (i.e., whole species); adaptation occurs at
organization development exists as a profession to the cellular level and is determined by genetic sport;
help people lead happier organizational lives. And, and an organism’s adaptation matches perfectly
as we have reviewed, there are correlations between with its environment. In the organizational world,
OD interventions and greater organizational pro- however, survival is defined in terms of individual
ductivity. Executives who hire OD consultants to units (i.e., an organization); adaptation occurs at the
enhance their organizations’ performance, however, societal level and is determined, at least in part, by
should be aware that their priority may not be rational action; and an organization’s adaptation
shared by those “third party change agents” whom matches imperfectly with its environment.
they hire.
Adapting Rationally Other theorists hold that
organizational survival and success are entirely
The Organization as a Unit in Its attributable to human rationality, a perspective
Environment that flourishes in business schools and in the lead-
Our third school of the open model can be traced at ership literature. The problem here (and one that
least as far back as the 1930s,106 and this theoretical it shares with the organizational ecologists) is that,
thread is undergoing a significant revitalization. although the rationalists understand that organ-
izations dwell in environments characterized by
Adapting to the Environment This research is competition and conflict, they fail to appreciate
characterized by its use of the organization as that organizations themselves are competitive and
The Threads of Organization: Theories 67

conflicted. Organizations are not happy families, affects every aspect of the public organization: pro-
but rather pastiches of passive and aggressive, cesses, structure, decision making, effectiveness—
astute and dumb, and ethical and unethical people, everything.
groups, and divisions, each with its own goals and
methods.
THE CLOSED AND OPEN MODELS:
Adapting Politically Luckily, there is a school that
reconciles the biological and rational metaphors. It THE ESSENTIAL DIFFERENCES
does so by focusing on political interactions. We have reviewed two, eminently disparate,
The political approach to organizational models of organizations, but they do share a pair
adaptation is realistic in that, first, it recognizes of basic  assumptions: Both models assume that
that organizations are highly diverse, with mul- organizations are not suicidal, and that they will
tiple divisions of labor and vastly different goals try not only to survive, but to thrive. Beyond these
held by  their members, and, second, with few commonalities, however, the models split over five,
exceptions  (e.g., prisons), their members are free deeply different, assumptions about how the world
to leave.  This combination of many internal dif- works.
ferences and few  sanctions allows organizations
to adapt both biologically,  in that environmental
forces affect discrete organizational elements (e.g., Assumptions about the Organization’s
individuals, divisions) differently (and not just the Environment
“whole” organization), and rationally, in that each One such difference is the models’ assumptions
of these elements is dealing with those forces in about their respective external environments. Each
logical ways that protect its own interests. In the works in the environment posited for it, but not in
political model, organizational adaptation com- the other.
bines heart and head—about as apt a description as A closed-model organization, with its tall,
we can imagine. many-layered hierarchy, inflexible bureaucracy, and
rigid routines, is superbly suited for its posited envi-
The Environment of the Public Organization ronment—one that is stable and devoid of surprises.
Perhaps the classic analysis of organizational Should its environment be shattered, however, and a
adaptation in the public sector is Philip Selznick’s chaotic environment, replete with swirling and con-
study of the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA). In fusing forces, smashes in, then our closed organiza-
it, Selznick introduced the notion of co-optation, tion would (if it were unable to loosen up and adapt)
which occurred when TVA’s directors won over perish from its own rigidities.
hostile local interests by cajolery, veiled bribery, By contrast, the open-model organization—with
and token representation in policymaking.111 Some its flat hierarchy, flexible responses, and minimal, if
forty years later, however, those local interests that any, routines—is supremely suited for its posited
ostensibly had been co-opted had waxed consid- environment—one that is tumultuous and replete
erably more powerful, and, in fact, could “foster with surprises. The open organization’s inherent
new operative goals for TVA” and “prevent TVA ability to nimbly respond to fast-paced, one-of-a-
initiated modifications of those goals.”112 Who had kind changes in its turbulent environment assures
co-opted whom? its survival. Should it find itself, however, in a new
As the studies of TVA imply, the task envi- environment that is characterized by stability, slow-
ronment has an unusually heavy and distorting ness, repetition, predictability, and boredom, then
impact on the public organization. If the litera- our open organization would die from its inability
ture on the differences between public, nonprofit, to tighten up, bureaucratize, and routinize in ways
and private organizations agrees on anything, it is that efficiently correspond to its new environmental
that public organizations must deal with far more realities. “Inventing the wheel” for each and every
environmental constraints and pressures than non- external challenge not only would no longer work;
profit and private organizations. This reality deeply it would kill the organization.
68 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

Happily, in most agencies, public administrators’


Assumptions about the Human Condition “self-interests do not necessarily run counter to the
The second difference between the closed and open organization’s overall interests, in that they reflect a
models parallels the first, in that their respective desire to make a useful contribution to the perfor-
models of human beings differ but are appropriate mance of their organization. . .. The assumption of
for each. an inherent conflict between self- and collective inter-
ests is not always valid, particularly in a public sector
Theory X and Theory Y Douglas McGregor context.”114 Given the extraordinarily high level of
famously named these models “Theory X” and nonprofit employees’ engagement, noted earlier, it
“Theory Y.”113 Theory X assumes that motivation to seems reasonable to conclude that much the same
work is an individual matter, and that most people could be said of the independent sector.
do not like work, prefer close supervision, cannot
contribute creatively to the solution of organiza-
tional problems, and are motivated by the threat of Assumptions about the Role and Legitimacy
punishment. It is apparent that organizations exem- of Organizational Power
plifying the closed model not only would fit, but pos- Power, in an organizational context, simply means
sibly might be appealing, to Theory X people. getting people to do what you want them to do. The
Theory Y, by contrast, assumes that motiva- models divide not only on how to exercise organ-
tion to work is a group matter, and, given the right izational power, but also on whether it should be
conditions, most people can enjoy work as much exercised at all.
as play, exercise self-control and prefer doing
jobs in their own way, solve organizational prob- Power in the Closed Model The closed model has
lems creatively,  and often are motivated by social no qualms about employing power. Its theorists
and ego rewards. It is apparent that organizations believe in orders and obedience, rules and regula-
predicated on the open model likely would attract tions, punctuality and punctiliousness. The callous
Theory Y people. use of authoritarian coercion is seen as entirely
legitimate.
The Riddle of Rational Interest A related facet
of human nature posited by the two models is the Power in the Open Model In complete contrast
problem of rational interest, or how people define to the closed model, the open model views coer-
their self-interest and the rationale that they use to cion as reprehensible, and, indeed, the open model
fulfill it. occasionally appears to argue against the presence
In the closed model, rational interest means that of organizational power altogether. Relying on it is
everyone in the organization has the same goal (that condemned as dehumanizing, “dematurizing,” and
is, the organization’s official mission) and agrees on not at all nice.115
how to achieve that goal in an optimal fashion. Regrettably, the open modelists’ distaste for
In the open model, however, rational interest power leads to a contradiction in their theory of
means that each person in the organization has organizational behavior. On the one hand, they
his or her own unique goals (e.g., getting ahead, argue that the exercise of authoritarian power makes
enjoying work), and has his or her own personal people miserable, and misery undermines the attain-
way to achieve those goals. Each person’s real ment of organizational goals; ergo, terminate the use
goals are not only disparate, but often in conflict of power and unhappy-unproductive workers will
with the goals of other members and possibly with blossom into “happy-productive workers” who will
the mission of their own organization. The way in fulfill those goals.116
which each person chooses to fulfill his or her goals On the other hand, these same scholars also
also is unique; executives vying for a promotion, agree that even happy workers remain uniquely
for instance, may employ entirely different means individual beings who still harbor their own per-
to win it, ranging from badgering their bosses to sonal objectives that may or may not coincide with
brown-nosing them. organizational missions. But which one prevails, the
The Threads of Organization: Theories 69

worker or the organization? “Either the individual


is autonomous or the organization is dominant, for Assumptions about Manipulating Members
the very notion of individualism wars against even of Organizations
benevolent organization”; reconciling the two may Manipulation is the techniques employed to exer-
be a “hopeless task.”117 cise organizational power. As with power itself, the
two models part company on its use.
The Quirk in Collective Action The open model-
ists’ contradictory and hopeless task suggests that Manipulation in the Closed Model A manipulative
large organizations, such as governments, face severe technique occasionally used by public administra-
challenges in motivating their employees to work for tors in the Third Reich, about as closed-model an
the benefit of the whole organization—that is, for organization as one is likely to find, was leveling a
the common collective good. Luger at a subordinate’s neck to persuade him or her
On the face of it, this is weird. If, for example, to execute an order.
International Widget’s employees all worked In closed-model organizations, manipulation is
together and succeeded in fulfilling their company’s obvious, coercive, and legitimate. The human and
mission of becoming the world’s most profitable cor- organizational dysfunctions of authoritarian manip-
poration, then they would, at least potentially, profit, ulation are clear: fear, rigidity, secrecy, narrowness,
too. So why do employees stubbornly and divi- alienation, falsification, and stultification number
sively persist in viewing their organization’s official among them. But there are also human advantages
mission not as an end, but merely as one of several to the crudities of the closed model’s manipulations:
means to an end—their end? Why do they not join in people in closed-model organizations “know where
the organizational equivalent of singing “Kumbaya” they stand.” The coerciveness of the closed model
and get with the program? is for people who like things straightforward and
Because, as Mancur Olson has enlightened us, clear-cut.
doing so makes little sense. Even though all organi-
zational members would benefit from attaining the Manipulation in the Open Model Manipulation in
collective good (that is, by fulfilling their organiza- the open model is far paler in hue than the red-meat
tion’s mission), it is nonetheless irrational for any one methods of the closed model, and its exercise is dis-
member to voluntarily sacrifice to achieve that col- creet, disguised, and obfuscated.
lective good. Why, for example, would an employee Recall our twelve characteristics of the open
voluntarily work without compensation? Better to model; “advice,” “adjustment,” “myths of peerage,”
let other employees work for free so that the non- and supportive relationships number prominently
volunteer can freeload. And, unless the organization among them. These and similarly insinuating subtle-
is composed of “altruistic” or “irrational” employees, ties comprise the manipulative methods of the open
no one else in the organization will volunteer, either.118 model. A distinguished scholar of organization devel-
opment, for example, has written that one’s “good
The Inescapability of Organizational Power If mornings” must be “appropriately” tailored in tone
organizations depended on each member’s unique to each of their recipients if one wishes to smooth
rational interest to attain their common goals, as the way for attaining organizational goals.119
advocated in the open model, then organizations The advantages of the open model’s social-
would be pushed toward actions that are collec- psychological manipulation are clear: openness,
tively ruinous. Hence, coercion is mandatory in any communication, teamwork, and innovation are
organization whose members are rational and self- some of them. But there are also liabilities. The open
interested if the common good—the organization’s model’s nuanced manipulative methods are “just a
stated purpose—is to be realized. more subtle form of bureaucratic control. . .. to get
Power is fundamental to the very idea of organ- each worker to participate in an ever more refined
ization. Most open-model theorists seem to accept, form of [his or her] enslavement.”120 Because they
if poutingly, the immutable reality of organizational camouflage the unavoidable exercise of power in
power. But some seem not to. organizations, as they are meant to do, people in
70 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

open organizations, unlike those in closed organiza- replete with its own internal injustices, dehuman-
tions, may never be sure “where they stand.” izing rules, and monocratic arbitrariness, was vital,
Of greater significance, if members think that in its very rigidity and rationalism, in mitigating
they do know where they stand, their knowledge the unorganized societal lunacy that surrounded it.
may be the end-product of a manipulation of their If Weber’s notion of the bureaucracy’s stand-alone
psyches so profound as to render them analogous to station in society could be illustrated, it would look
the “conditioned” human shell of the protagonist in something like Figure 3-1.
George Orwell’s 1984, who uncontrollably shrieked Weber was not unsympathetic to the plight
“Long Live Big Brother!” even as he despised him. of the individual bureaucrat. In fact, he deplored
Eric Fromm expresses this idea with his concept of what bureaucratic settings could do to the human
willing submissiveness; that is, even though organ- spirit, sighing that the passion for bureaucracy
izational subordinates may appear to have “team among his German students “is enough to drive
spirit” (and actually may have been so successfully one to despair.”123 But, when all was said and done,
manipulated as to believe they have it), the psy- Weber could accept the dehumanization of society’s
chological techniques used to create their willing public servants, who were somehow apart from the
submissiveness induces, in reality, a subliminal and other citizens, on the grounds that bureaucracy was
deep resentment toward their superiors bordering essential to social progress and the elimination of
on hatred.121 There is, in fact, empirical research injustice.
suggesting that this is precisely what happens in
organizations that use the open model’s manipula- The Moral View of the Open Model In marked
tive techniques.122 contrast, the open-model theorists hold that every
citizen, bureaucrat and non-bureaucrat alike, is
encased in some sort of bureaucratic organization.
Assumptions about the Moral Significance Society is a series of overlapping and interacting
of Organizations in Society organizations, and there is no unorganized, irra-
Our final distinction between the closed and open tional society “out there,” roiling beyond organiza-
models is particularly germane to the study of public tional boundaries. The open model’s concept that
and nonprofit administration, and centers on how society is bureaucracy looks like Figure 3-2.
their respective theorists have viewed the organiza- In this school, bureaucracy’s domination of
tion and its moral relationship with the larger society. society is not a good thing. “Bureaucracy gives birth
to a new species of inhuman beings. . .. incapable
The Moral View of the Closed Model The Ur closed of emotion and devoid of will,”124 as exemplified,
modelist, Max Weber, believed that bureaucracy, perhaps, by the Finnish public administrator who, in

“Rational”
Bureaucracy
“nonrational” society

FIGURE 3-1 FIGURE 3-2


The Closed Model’s View: The Open Model’s View:
Organizations and Society Organizations as Society
The Threads of Organization: Theories 71

2004, died at his office desk and was not recognized bureaucrats are different from citizens, and bureau-
as dead by his some 100 co-workers on the same cracies are the saviors of society. The open model
floor, including thirty in his own department, for two assumes that people love work, organizations are
days; his demise was discovered only when a friend irrational, their environments are unstable, coer-
arrived to join him for lunch.125 cion is unacceptable, bureaucrats and citizens are
Thus, for the public bureaucracy to dehuman- one and the same, and bureaucracies are the bane
ize its own bureaucrats in order to advance social of society. These are basic differences. Can they be
justice is self-defeating because the bureaucrat and reconciled?
the citizen are one and the same. Indeed, to treat a
member of an organization, particularly a subordi-
nate, badly is immoral because there is no higher Uncertainty Reduction: Reconciling
morality to excuse such treatment, as there is in the the Open and the Closed
closed model. In the open model, what is good for Yes, they can. Reconciling the open and closed
the person is good for the people. models begins with the open model’s world view—
that is, organizations are spontaneous collectivities
Who Must Be Sacrificed? These differing views of people with their own goals and drives, who are
about bureaucracy and society lead to starkly differ- operating uncertainly in an unstable environment.
ent ethical conclusions about just who must pay the This is not a bad set of assumptions about any organ-
price of advancing society. ization that is just getting started. But no organiza-
Those who advocate the closed model state tion can last long in a state of near nature. Nature is
that the organization’s clerks and laborers must be unpredictable and uncertain, and all organizations
sacrificed for the larger good of creating a fairer, are extraordinarily averse to uncertainty. So organ-
more honest, more equitable, and more transparent izations are possessed by an overpowering need to
society. Because only bureaucracy can achieve these reduce uncertainty—that is, to routinize and ration-
ends, and the bureaucracy’s executives are its engine, alize the organization’s internal workings and its
their chief tool—the human spirit of the bureaucra- relations with its environment whenever and wher-
cy’s clerks and laborers—can be legitimately sacri- ever possible. This organizational need to reduce
ficed for the good of the larger cause. uncertainty reflects the deeply human need to do the
Those who advocate the open model state that same: psychologists tell us that the more certain we
the creation of a more just society (which is cast in are, the happier we are.126
precisely the same terms as in the closed model) is In sum, we now understand that: organizations
not facilitated by bureaucracy, as the closed model and their environments constantly change; organi-
contends, but is blocked by them; hence, the organ- zations and the people in them try to survive and
ization itself must be sacrificed. If destroying the thrive; and organizations and the people in them
organization is impractical (as it likely is), then at learn from their mistakes, failures, and successes.
least indoctrinating, transforming, and, if necessary,
replacing (ideally with nonhierarchical teams of
clerks and laborers) those “inhuman beings” who Responding to Organizational Uncertainty
comprise its leadership, will suffice. Organizational uncertainty may spring from sources
inside and outside the organization, and whether the
source is internal or external can shape organiza-
CONJOINING OPPOSITES: THE tional strategies in addressing uncertainty.

DRIVE TO REDUCE UNCERTAINTY Responses to Internal Sources of Uncertainty If


Students of organizations may be initially puzzled the sources of organizational uncertainty are inter-
by the two fundamentally different paradigms of nal, then the organization will strive to reduce
organization theory. The closed model assumes uncertainty by centralizing. Centralizing techniques
that people hate work, organizations are rational, include: indoctrinating all members of the organiza-
their environments are stable, coercion is basic, tion “to respond only to commands from the central
72 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

leadership and from no other source”; controlling and exploratory “strategic stance” relative to their
all communication involving “vexing suborganiza- external environments.129
tions” in an effort to nip “nonconforming thought” When these public administrators worry about
and “deviant behavior”; intensifying surveillance of environmental uncertainty, the public can benefit.
troublesome subunits; “detaching key operations,” Public agencies “that perceive high levels of uncer-
such as the control of funds, from deviating depart- tainty in their external political environment perform
ments, “thus reducing their self-containment and better than those that perceive that environment to
increasing their vulnerability to central direction”; be certain,” and this linkage is “positive and statis-
and, finally, expelling offending units, a radical act tically significant. . .. even when controlling for past
that amounts to “a contraction of boundaries con- performance, service expenditure, and external con-
stituting a withdrawal from internal sources of straints.” This correlation pertains, however, only
uncertainty.”127 to the public organization’s political environment;
“perceptions of the relative level of uncertainty in
Responses to External Sources of Uncertainty If, the social and economic circumstances are unrelated
however, the sources of organizational uncertainty to their service achievements.”130
are external—that is, they are in the organization’s
task environment—then the organization will seek
to reduce that uncertainty by absorbing the outside ARE PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT
sources of uncertainty into the organization itself. It
does this by expanding its boundaries—by growing. ORGANIZATIONS DIFFERENT?
Co-optation, described earlier, is one form that this Historically, organization theorists have minimized,
incorporation of external uncertainties might take; ignored, or denied that organizations can be usefully
the effort by an organization to control some facet of classified along behavioral and sectoral lines (the
the natural environment (for example, to engage in profoundly influential sociologist, Talcott Parsons,
flood control) is another form; to merge or ally with likely set the standard in this regard), contending
competitive organizations is yet another. Ironically, instead that organizations are organizations are
decentralization often is required if an organization organizations. “Virtually all the major contribu-
is to expand, and decentralization can result in new, tions to the field were conceived to apply broadly
internal sources of uncertainty. across all types of organizations. . .. The distinction
If the expansion of an organization’s boundaries between public and private organizations received
is blocked, then the organization will seek to reduce short shrift.”131 As a consequence, there was, for at
its exchanges with its environment—“withdrawal least three-quarters of the twentieth century, “not a
from the source of uncertainty, as it were.”128 A firm single general work on organization theory that pays
uncertain about its future supplies might decide to systematic attention to the distinctive features of the
stockpile or produce its own manufacturing com- public bureaucracy.”132
ponents. Entire nations, particularly in Asia, have Researchers are now focusing more on the
been known to reduce their external uncertainties unique properties of public—and nonprofit—
by radically reducing exchanges with other nations organizations than they have in the not-so-distant
and launching self-sufficiency policies; the invariable past. This new focus is still coming in fits and
consequence, however, is an elevation of costs and a starts—what is arguably organization theory’s most
lowering of living standards. prestigious academic journal, Administrative Science
Quarterly, has slashed its articles that deal with
The Public Organization and Environmental public and nonprofit organizations by more than
Uncertainty In the public sector, those administra- 70 percent over two decades133—but it is coming,
tors who perceive high levels of political, social, and and it has produced a respectable literature. As we
economic uncertainty in their organizations’ envi- shall learn in the following two chapters, govern-
ronments also harbor concerns about their organi- mental, independent, and private organizations do
zations’ “inertia”; consult with citizens a lot; and, of indeed differ from one another, and in highly impor-
greatest importance, maintain a responsive, curious, tant ways.
The Threads of Organization: Theories 73

So, yes, public and nonprofit organizations are 15. Boyer, “The Road Ahead,” p. 44.
different. 16. Hindy Lauer Schachter, “Does Frederick Taylor’s
Ghost Still Haunt the Halls of Government? A
Look at the Concept of Governmental Efficiency
NOTES in Our Time,” Public Administration Review 67
1. Tom Burns and G. M. Stalker, The Management (September/October 2007), pp. 800–810.
of Innovation (London: Tavistock, 1961). 17. Stewart, “The Management Myth,” p. 82.
2. Edward Mandell House (anonymous), Philip Dru: 18. Henri Fayol, General and Industrial Management
Administrator: A Story of Tomorrow, 1920–1935 (London: Pittman, 1930).
(New York: B. W. Huebsch, 1912), pp. 262, 249. 19. M. P. Follett’s (her nom de plume) total scholarly
3. John R. Hibbing and Elizabeth Theiss-Morse, output consisted of two books that were exclu-
“Americans’ Desire for Stealth Democracy: How sively about government, and one book and a
Declining Trust Boosts Political Participation,” book chapter that were broadly relevant to organ-
Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the izations in all sectors.
Midwest Political Science Association (Chicago, 20. H. Thomas Johnson, an expert on Toyota, as
April 2001), Table 1. quoted in Cal Thomas, “Principles Come before
4. Frederick W. Taylor, quoted in Peter J. Boyer, “The Profits,” Savannah Morning News (March 3,
Road Ahead,” The New Yorker (April 27, 2009), 2010).
pp. 44–57. The quotation is on p. 49. 21. James D. Mooney and Alan C. Reiley, The
5. Frederick W. Taylor, Principles of Scientific Principles of Organization (New York: Harper &
Management (New York: Harper & Row, 1911), Row, 1939).
p. 59. 22. M. P. Follett, Creative Experience (New York:
6. Frank B. Gilbreth and Lillian M. Gilbreth, Longmans, Green, 1924).
Applied Motion Study: A Collection of Papers on 23. Alvin W. Gouldner, “Organizational Analysis,”
the Efficient Method of Industrial Preparedness Sociology Today, Robert K. Merton, Leonard
(New York: Sturgis & Walton, 1917). Broom, and Leonard S. Cottrell, Jr., eds. (New
7. Frank B. Gilbreth, “Scientific Management in the York: Basic Books, 1959), pp. 400–428.
Hospital,” The Modern Hospital 3 (November 24. Burns and Stalker, The Management of
1914), pp. 321–324. Innovation.
8. Jill Lepore, “Not So Fast,” The New Yorker 25. Fritz J. Roethlisberger and William J. Dickson,
(October 12, 2009), pp. 114–122. Management and the Worker (Cambridge:
9. Susan Reverby, “The Search for the Hospital Harvard University Press, 1939).
Yardstick: Nursing and the Rationalization of 26. One example is Richard Herbert Franke and James
Hospital Work,” Health Care in America: Essays D. Kaul, “The Hawthorne Experiments: First
in Social History, Susan Reverby and David Statistical Interpretation,” American Sociological
Rosner, eds. (Philadelphia: Temple University Review 43 (October, 1978), pp. 623–643.
Press, 1979), pp. 206–225. The quotation is on 27. One example is Stephen R.G. Jones, “Worker
p. 218. Interdependence and Output: The Hawthorne
10. Matthew Stewart, “The Management Myth,” The Studies Reevaluated,” American Sociological
Atlantic (June 2006), pp. 80–87. The quotation is Review (April, 1990), pp. 176–190.
on p. 81. 28. Abraham Maslow, Eupsychian Management: A
11. Charles D. Wrege and Amedeo G. Perroni, Journal (Homewood, IL: Dorsey, 1965), p. 1.
“Taylor’s Pig-Tale: A Historical Analysis of 29. Frederick Herzberg, with Bernard Mausner and
Frederick W. Taylor’s Pig-Iron Experiment,” Barbara B. Snyderman, The Motivation to Work
Academy of Management Journal 17 (March (New York: Wiley, 1959).
1974), pp. 6–27. 30. Marc Buelens and Herman Van den Broek, “An
12. Stewart, “The Management Myth,” p. 82. Analysis of Work Motivation between Public
13. Lepore, “Not So Fast,” p. 114. and Private Sector Organizations,” Public
14. Frederick Taylor, “Government Efficiency,” Administration Review 67 (January/February
Bulletin of the Taylor Society 2 (December 1916), 2007), pp. 65–72. The quotation is on p. 67.
pp. 7–13. The quotation is on p. 7. 31. Ibid.
74 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

32. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal 43. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems
Government: A Model Employer or a Work Protection Board, Prohibited Personnel Practices:
in Progress? Perspectives from 25 Years of the Employee Perceptions (Washington, DC: U.S.
Merit Principles Survey (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011), p. 37. Figure
Government Printing Office, 2008), p. 20, and U.S. is for 2010.
Office of Personnel Management, 2010, 2011 and 44. Ethics Resource Center and Hay Group, Ethics
2015 Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results and Employee Engagement (Washington, DC:
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing/ Authors, 2010), p. 4. This is a study of private
Publishing Office, 2010, 2011, 2015, 2016), companies.
Q. 13. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, 2009 45. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Power
Employee Survey Results (Washington, DC: U.S. of Federal Employee Engagement, pp. 27–36.
Government Printing Office, 2010), p. 3, Q. 5. Data are for 2005.
Figure is for eight MSPB surveys, 1986–2009, and 46. Gallup, as cited in GovExec Staff, “Disengaged
six OPM surveys, 2010–2016. Employees, Lackluster Pay and More,” Govexec.
33. Karlyn Bowman, Attitudes About Work and com (December 17, 2014).
Leisure in America (Washington, DC: American 47. Deloitte, as cited in Clement Christensen, “4
Leadership Institute, 2001), Table W-9. Data are Reasons Why Investing in Employee Engagement
for 1973–1994. Matters,” Government Executive (March 26,
34. Princeton Survey Research Associates and the 2013).
Brookings Institution, Health of the Public Service 48. James Gerard Caillier, “Factors Affecting
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2001). Data are for Job Performance in Public Agencies,” Public
2001. Performance & Management Review 34
35. Bradley E. Wright, “Public Service and Motivation: (December 2010), pp. 139–165. The quotation is
Does Mission Matter?” Public Administration on p. 139.
Review 67 (January/February 2007), pp. 54–64. 49. Pricewaterhouse Coopers as cited in Katherine
The quotation is on p. 60. Barrett and Richard Greene, “What Employee
36. Brookings Institution, Winning the Talent War: Surveys Reveal about Working in Government,”
Brookings Survey Finds the Nonprofit Sector Has Governing.com (June 9, 2016).
the Most Dedicated Workforce (Washington, DC: 50. As derived from data in The Marcus Buckingham
Author, 2002), p. 2. Company, StandOut Global Engagement Index
37. Nick Bloom, Tobias Kretschmer, and John (New York: Author, 2015).
Van Reenen, Work-Life Balance, Management 51. David Hassell, “Unlocking Potential with
Practices and Productivity (London: Centre for Employee Engagement,” TalentCulture (March
Economic Performance, 2006). 10, 2014), p. 2. Emphasis is original.
38. Marcus Buckingham and Curt Coffman, First, 52. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2011 and
Break All the Rules: What the World’s Greatest 2016 Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results,
Managers Do Differently (New York: Simon and pp. 20, 8.
Schuster, 1999), p. 29. 53. International Public Management Association for
39. Robert J. Vance, Employee Engagement and Human Resources, as cited in Barrett and Greene,
Commitment: A Guide to Understanding, “What Employee Surveys Reveal about Working
Measuring and Increasing Engagement in Your in Government.”
Organization (Alexandria, VA: Society for Human 54. Jeffrey L. Brudney and Deil S. Wright, “The
Resource Management, 2006). ‘Revolt in Dullsville’ Revisited: Lessons for
40. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Power Theory, Practice, and Research from the American
of Federal Employee Engagement (Washington, State Administrators Project, 1964–2008,” Public
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008), p. 3. Administration Review 70 (January/February
41. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Managing 2010), pp. 26–37. The data are on p. 29.
for Engagement, p. 2. 55. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity
42. Jim Harter, “Managers with High Talent Twice and Change in the Role of City Managers,”
as Likely to Be Engaged,” (Princeton, NJ: Gallup, Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington,
April 2, 2015). DC: International City/County Management
The Threads of Organization: Theories 75

Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. Data (p. 15) are Academy of Management Review 33 (January
for 2010. 2008), pp. 55–75.
56. Charldean Newell and David M. Ammons, “Role 69. Trevor Foulk, Andrew Woolum, and Amir Erez,
Emphases of City Managers and Other Municipal “Catching Rudeness Is Like Catching a Cold:
Executives,” Public Administration Review 47 The Contagion Effects of Low-Intensity Negative
(May/June 1987), pp. 246–253. Data (pp. 247– Behaviors,” Journal of Applied Psychology 101
248) are for 1985. (January 2016), pp. 50–67.
57. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Is a 70. Lynne M. Andersson and Christine M. Pearson,
40-Hour Workweek Enough in Government?” “Tit for Tat? The Spiraling Effect of Incivility in the
Governing.com (July 21, 2016). Workplace,” Academy of Management Review 24
58. Jessica Word and Sung Min Park, “Working (4, 1999), pp. 452–471. The quotation is on p. 452.
across the Divide: Job Involvement in the Public 71. Arieh Riskin, Amir Erez, Trevor A. Foulk, et  al.,
and  Nonprofit Sectors,” Review of Public “The Impact of Rudeness on Medical Team
Personnel Administration 29 (June 2009), Performance: A Randomized Trial,” Pediatrics
pp.  103–133. The quotation is on p. 103; the 136 (September 2015), pp. 487–495.
datum is on p. 108. 72. Porath and Pearson, “The Price of Incivility,”
59. Mary K. Feeney and Barry Bozeman, “Staying pp. 115–116.
Late: Comparing Work Hours in Public and 73. Porath and Pearson, “The Cost of Bad Behavior,”
Nonprofit Sectors,” American Review of pp. 64–66.
Public  Administration 39 (September 2009), 74. Daniel Cable, Jooa Julia Lee, Francesca Gino,
pp. 459–477. and Bradley R. Staats, How Best-Self Activation
60. Teresa Amabile and Steven Kramer, “The Progress Influences Emotions, Physiology and Employment
Principle: Optimizing Inner Work Life to Create Relationships, Harvard Business School NOM
Value,” Rotman Magazine (Winter 2012), Unit Working Paper No. 16-029 (September 17,
pp. 28–33. The quotations are on pp. 28, 31. 2015).
61. Hassell, “Unlocking Potential with Employee 75. Lilia M. Cortina and Vicki J. Magley, “Patterns
Engagement,” p. 3. and Profiles of Responses to Incivility in the
62. Buckingham and Coffman, First, Break All the Workplace,” Journal of Occupational Health
Rules, pp. 21–49. This purports to be “the largest Psychology 14 (July 2009), pp. 272–288.
study of its kind ever undertaken.” 76. Porath and Pearson, “The Cost of Bad Behavior,”
63. Michael Housman and Dylan Minor, Toxic pp. 64–65.
Workers, Working Paper 16-057 (Cambridge, 77. Christine M. Pearson and Christine L. Porath,
MA: Harvard Business School, 2015), pp. 1, 23. “On the Nature, Consequences and Remedies of
64. Christine L. Porath and Christine M. Pearson, Workplace Incivility: No Time for ‘Nice’? Think
“The Cost of Bad Behavior,” Organizational Again,” Academy of Management Executive 19
Dynamics 39 (January–March 2010), pp. 63–71. (February 2005), pp. 7–18. The data are on p. 11.
The quotation is on p. 64. 78. Porath and Pearson, “The Price of Incivility.”
65. Christine Porath and Christine Pearson, “The 79. Vincent J. Roscigno, Steven H. Lopez, and
Price of Incivility,” Harvard Business Review Randy Hodson, “Supervisory Bullying, Status
(January–February 2013), pp. 114–121. Figures Inequalities and Organizational Context,” Social
are for 1998–2011. Forces 87 (March 2009), pp. 1561–1589.
66. Paul Harvey, Kenneth J. Harris, William E. Gillis, 80. Russell E. Johnson, Stanley B. Silverman, Aarti
and Mark J. Martinko, “Abusive Supervision and Shyamsunder, et al., “Acting Superior but
the Entitled Employee,” The Leadership Quarterly Actually Inferior? Correlates and Consequences
(April 2014), pp. 204–217. The quotation is on of Workplace Arrogance,” Human Performance
p. 204. 23 (November/December 2010), pp. 403–427.
67. Joon Ian Wong, Americans Think They Work 81. Maren Hogan, “Defining Qualities of the Worst
Harder than Everyone Else—They Don’t (New Managers,” SmartBlog on Leadership (May 20,
York: Quartz, 2016). 2014).
68. Lilia M. Cortina, “Unseen Injustice: Incivility 82. Workplace Bullying Institute and Zogby
as Modern Discrimination in Organizations,” International, U.S. Workplace Bullying Survey
76 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

(Bellingham, WA, and Washington, DC: Authors, 96. Jerry Porras, “The Comparative Impact of
2008), p. 1. Different OD Techniques and Intervention
83. Roscigno, Lopez, and Hodson, “Supervisory Intensities,” Journal of Applied Behavioral Science
Bullying, Status Inequalities and Organizational 15 (April, 1979), pp. 156–178.
Context.” 97. Peter J. Robertson and Sonal J. Seneviratne,
84. Roscigno, Lopez, and Hodson, “Supervisory “Outcomes of Planned Organizational Change in
Bullying, Status Inequalities and Organizational the Public Sector: A Meta-Analytic Comparison to
Context.” the Private Sector,” Public Administration Review
85. Workplace Bullying Institute and Zogby Inter- 55 (November/December 1995), pp. 547–558.
national, U.S. Workplace Bullying Survey, p.  16. The quotation is on p. 554.
Figures are for 2007. 98. R. Wayne Boss, Benjamin B. Dunford, Alan D.
86. U.S. Department of Labor study, as cited in Scott Boss, and Mark L. McConkie, “Sustainable
Shortenhaus, Strategies for Working with Busi- Change in the Public Sector: The Longitudinal
nesses and High Growth Industries (Washington, Benefits of Organization Development,” Journal
DC: U.S. Department of Health and Human of Applied Behavioral Science 46 (December
Services, 2006). 2010), pp. 436–472.
87. Hassell, “Unlocking Potential with Employee 99. W. Warner Burke, “The New Agenda for Organi-
Engagement,” p. 2. Figure is for 2012. zation Development,” Organizational Dynamics
88. Roscigno, Lopez, and Hodson, “Supervisory 25 (June 1997), pp. 6–20. The quotation is on
Bullying, Status Inequalities and Organizational p. 8.
Context.” 100. Larry E. Greiner and Thomas G. Cummings,
89. Workplace Bullying Institute and Zogby, 2013 “Wanted: OD More Alive Than Dead!” Journal
WBI-Zogby Workplace Bullying from the of Applied Behavioral Science 40 (Winter 2004),
Perspective of U.S. Business Leaders (Bellingham, pp. 374–391. The quotation is on p. 374.
WA, and Washington, DC: Authors, 2013). The 101. Greg Young, Women, Naturally Better Leaders
quotation is on p. 5. for the 21st Century (New York: Routledge,
90. Ethics Resource Center, National Govern- 2016), p. 11.
ment Ethics Survey: An Inside View of Public Sector 102. Bennis, Organizational Development, p. 17.
Ethics, pp. 2, 20, 25, 31; National Nonprofit Ethics 103. Simona Botti and Christopher K. Hsee, “Dazed
Survey: An Inside View of Nonprofit Sector Ethics), and Confused by Choice: How the Temporal
p. 15; and National Business Ethics Survey: An Costs of Choice Freedom Lead to Undesirable
Inside View of Private Sector Ethics (Arlington, Outcomes,” Organizational Behavior and Human
VA: Author, 2008), p. 14. Figures are for 2007. Decision Processes 112 (July 2010), pp. 161–171.
91. Rhys Andrews and Rachel Ashworth, “Represent- The quotations are on p. 161.
ation and Inclusion in Public Organizations: 104. Dan Gilbert, “The Surprising Science of
Evidence from the U.K. Civil Service,” Public Happiness,” Ted.com (February 2004).
Administration Review 75 (March/April 2015), 105. Thomas H. Fitzgerald, “The O.D. Practitioner
pp. 279–288. in the Business World: Theory vs. Reality,”
92. Bob Woodward, “10 Take Aways From the Bush Organizational Dynamics 16 (Summer 1987), pp.
Years,” Washington Post (January 18, 2009). 20–34. The quotations are on pp. 25, 27.
93. Richard Beckhard, Organizational Development: 106. Chester I. Barnard, The Functions of the Executive
Strategies and Models (Reading, MA: Addison- (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
Wesley, 1969), pp. 20–24. 1938).
94. Warren G. Bennis, Organizational Development: 107. Herbert Kaufman, Time, Chance, and
Its Nature, Origins, and Prospects (Reading, MA: Organizations: Natural Selection in a Perilous
Addison-Wesley, 1969), p. 17. Environment (Chatham, NJ: Chatham House,
95. Robert T. Golembiewski, Carl W. Proehl, Jr., and 1985), p. 67.
David Sink, “Success of OD Applications in the 108. Paul R. Lawrence and Jay W. Lorsch, Organization
Public Sector: Toting Up the Score for a Decade, and Environment: Managing Differentiation and
More or Less,” Public Administration Review 41 Integration (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
(November/December 1981), pp. 679–682. Press, 1967).
The Threads of Organization: Theories 77

109. Peter M. Blau and R. A. Schoenherr, The Structure 120. Stewart, “The Management Myth,” p. 85.
of Organization (New York: Basic Books, 1971). 121. Eric Fromm, The Art of Loving (New York:
110. Much of the thinking in this and the following Harper & Row, 1956).
five paragraphs is drawn from Donald Chisholm, 122. See, for just one example of this research, Catherine
“Organizational Response to Environmental Casey, “‘Come, Join Our Family’: Discipline
Change,” Paper presented at the Annual and Integration in Corporate Organizational
Meeting  of the American Political Science Culture,” Human Relations 52 (February 1999),
Association (New Orleans, August 29–September pp. 155–178.
1, 1985). 123. Max Weber, quoted in Elizabeth Kolbert, “Why
111. Philip Selznick, TVA and the Grass Roots Work? A Hundred Years of the Protestant Work
(Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, Ethic,” The New Yorker (November 29, 2004),
1949). pp. 157, 160.
112. Richard A. Cuoto, “TVA’s Old and New Grass 124. Ralph P. Hummel, The Bureaucratic Experience:
Roots: A Reexamination of Cooptation,” A Critique of Life in the Modern Organization,
Administration & Society 19 (February 1988), 4th ed. (New York: St. Martin’s, 1994), p. 3.
pp. 443–455. 125. Roland Paulsen, “The Art of Not Working at
113. Douglas McGregor, The Theory of Human Work,” Theatlantic.com (November 3, 2014).
Enterprise (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960). 126. Daniel Gilbert, Stumbling on Happiness (London:
114. Peter J. Robertson, Feng Wang, and Supamas Vintage, 2007).
Trivisvavet, “Self- and Collective Interest in Public 127. Kaufman, Time, Chance, and Organizations,
Organizations: An Empirical Investigation,” p. 44.
Public Performance & Management Review 31 128. Ibid., p. 43.
(September 2007), pp. 54–84. The quotation is on 129. Rhys Andrews, “Perceived Environmental
p. 54. Uncertainty in Public Organizations: An Empirical
115. Chris Argyris, Organization and Innovation Exploration,” Public Performance & Management
(Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, 1965). Review 32 (September 2008), pp.  25–50. The
116. T. A. Wright and B. M. Staw, “Affect and quotations are on p. 41.
Favorable Work Outcomes: Two Longitudinal 130. Ibid., p. 41.
Tests of the Happy-Productive Worker Thesis,” 131. Hal G. Rainey, Understanding and Managing
Journal of Organizational Behavior 20 (January Public Organizations, 2nd ed. (San Francisco,
1999), pp. 1–23. Jossey-Bass, 1997), p. 55.
117. Allen Schick, “The Trauma of Politics: Public 132. Donald P. Warwick, in collaboration with
Administration in the Sixties,” American Public Marvin Meade and Theodore Reed, A Theory
Administration: Past, Present, Future, Frederick of Public Bureaucracy: Politics, Personality,
C. Mosher, ed. (Tuscaloosa, AL: University of and Organization in the State Department
Alabama Press, 1975), pp. 142–180. The quota- (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
tion is on p. 170. 1975), p. 190.
118. Mancur Olson, Jr., The Logic of Collective 133. As derived from data in Jeffrey Pfeffer, “Like Ships
Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups Passing in the Night: The Separate Literatures of
(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, Organization Theory and Public Management,”
1965). International Public Management Journal 43 (4,
119. Robert T. Golembiewski, Behavior and 2006), pp. 457–465. Decline from 44 percent of
Organizations (Chicago: Rand-McNally, 1962). all articles to 13 percent is for 1985–2005.
CHAPTER

The Fabric of
Organizations: Forces

H ow do organizations adapt to the fury of


forces that roil in them and in the society sur-
rounding them? To answer this question, research-
certain and “hard” as it is sent up through the
decision-making hierarchy.3
Consider, for example, the Central Intelligence
ers  weave  the threads of theory into a fabric. Agency’s (CIA) efforts to detect Iraq’s weapons of
Sometimes they weave a tapestry, other times a mass destruction. The agency had had no spies in
drop cloth. Iraq for five years before the invasion of 2003, and
its “assessments were increasingly based on very
limited information.” Although the CIA’s analysts
ORGANIZATIONAL KNOWLEDGE expressed their reservations, those passages “tended
Knowledge and information have been defined as to drop off as the reports would go up the food
“what changes us,”1 or data (i.e., facts that have chain. . .. As a result, virtually everyone in the United
no coherent meaning to the person who is aware States intelligence community . . . thought Iraq still
of them) that become meaningful. Organizational had the illicit weapons. . .. And the government
knowledge, or organizational intelligence, is not only became a victim of its own certainty.”4
the process of collecting yet one more datum to com-
plete a puzzle, but, of greater importance, it is also a Centralization and the Fate of Intelligence In
process of interpreting data to solve mysteries. Data closed, centralized organizations, information dis-
organizations have—usually in spades. Knowledge tortion often is intertwined with personal power.
is more elusive. There is no indication, for example, For a full year prior to the invasion of Iraq, the
that, despite many times more data, Americans are research director of Iraq’s intelligence agency wrote
any more knowledgeable about public affairs than “three assessments saying that the Americans would
they were in 1950.2 attack Iraq and that we had no chance to resist
them.” The director provided these reports to one
General Abed, Iraqi President Saddam Hussein’s
Information and Hierarchy most trusted aide (he was allowed, uniquely, to pack
If knowledge changes us, then it is disconcerting to a pistol in Saddam’s presence), but Abed “refused
know that organizations change knowledge. to give these [assessments] to the President. . .. Like
everyone else, he was afraid to tell him the truth.”5
Absorbing Uncertainty One of the more intrigu-
ing ways in which organizations distort knowledge Decentralization and the Fate of Intelligence Even
is called uncertainty absorption, whereby informa- when people trust each other and are working as a
tion that initially is regarded as uncertain and “soft” team, both of which are emblematic of the open,
by the people who collect it becomes increasingly decentralized organization, information still may fail
78
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 79

to reach the people who need it and can act on it. In information will be delayed and distorted, and the
these organizations, the pathology appears to be less less likely that it will reach someone who can intel-
one of fear (although even presidents must “beg for ligently act on it.9
the bad news” because subordinates “will not give It is striking that, following 9/11, federal poli-
it to you naturally”6) and more one of fumbling. cymakers determinedly ignored this fact of informa-
Perhaps the iconic instance of how bureaucracies in tional life. Washington’s response to that attack—a
democracies can falter in informing those who need rapid and enormous expansion of the intelligence
to know is the shambolic failure, in 1941, of anyone community—produced: bureaucratic overlap (for
to definitively alert the American troops at Pearl instance, fifty-one agencies charged with the narrow
Harbor that they expected the Japanese to attack. responsibility of tracking money flows among ter-
rorists); inefficiency (analysts publish about 50,000
Turf and Bureaucratic Jealousies An informational intelligence reports per year, “a volume so large
pathology that seems to be particularly present in that many are routinely ignored”); disarray (1,271
public organizations, whether centralized or decen- federal organizations and 1,931 companies charged
tralized, concerns “turf,” or agency rivalries that with terrorism duties, toiling in 10,000 locations
revolve around the control of areas of responsibility. across America); and blurred lines of authority (an
Here is an example of this pathology in a cen- estimated 854,000 professionals had top secret
tralized organizational context: The notorious World clearances nine years following the attacks). These
War II spy, “Cicero,” who was the valet of the British dysfunctions have, apparently, weakened the intel-
ambassador at Ankara, sold astonishingly accurate ligence agencies’ capacity to “connect the dots” and
and detailed intelligence concerning the planned disrupt future terrorist acts.10
D-Day invasion of Europe to one Ludwig Moyzisch,
who then sent it to the Nazi foreign minister, Joachim
von Ribbentrop. The foreign minister was involved Organizational Knowledge and Strategic
in a bitter power struggle with the Reich Security Decision Making
Office, and he loathed Franz von Papen, the German All of us are inundated by data (Chapter 6 has the
ambassador to Turkey; Moyzich, as it happened, scary details), and we often are unable to salvage
not only reported to the Reich Security Office, but from this flood the knowledge that we need to
also was an attaché on Papen’s staff. So Ribbentrop make good decisions. The economist Friedrich
found it expedient to bury Cicero’s information, and Hayek famously extended this idea to organizations,
with it, perhaps, the Third Reich.7 arguing that no one person could ever have enough
And here is an instance of the pathology in a information to make rational strategic decisions.
decentralized government: Even though fifty to sixty (Unless noted otherwise, strategic decisions—that
professionals in the CIA knew by March 2000 that is, the creation of important policies with significant
two of the Al Qaeda hijackers involved in the ter- consequences—are the sole focus of our discussions
rorist attacks of September 11, 2001, were in the of decision making.) Hayek held that market and
United States, no one informed the Federal Bureau other environmental forces provided the best infor-
of Investigation, which is charged with internal secu- mation for decision making.11
rity, of their presence.8
Know-Nothing Decision Making Perhaps we
Hierarchy, Handling, and Information Organi- should not be too surprised, therefore, that decision
zational structure, in short, is no panacea for curing makers “ask for reports and do not read them. They
pathologies of organizational information. We do act first and receive requested information later, and
know, however, that there is a model of hierarchi- do not seem to be concerned about the order.”12 As
cal distortion: the more hierarchical layers there are, much as four-fifths of organizational information
the more organizational subunits that are charged may be requested, filed away, and never used.13
with similar responsibilities, and the more that infor- Worse, the costs of collecting this unused infor-
mation is “handled” as it is passed up, down, and mation are horrendously high. Seventy-one percent
around the bureaucracy, the more likely it is that the of workers say that their main job is “tracking down
80 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

information,”14 and 44 percent of managers who


must search for information believe that its cost The Bounds of Individual Rationality
exceeds its value.15 Because the people who gather Every decision maker is boxed in by mental and
knowledge and the decision makers who purport- social bounds.
edly use it dwell in different organizational worlds,
the expense of collecting information is largely The Decision Premise All human beings make
hidden and, as a result, organizations over-invest in decisions on the basis of their decision premises,
information.16 or the unique values and viewpoints held by each
One explanation for this behavior is that organi- organizational member, and on which he or she
zations are not too bright. There is, however, another bases every decision he or she makes regarding the
possibility: organizational sophistication. organization.21
Sector plays a part in forming individual deci-
Information as Symbol “The acts of seeking and sion premises. “The values of profitability, compet-
using information in decisions have important sym- itiveness, and customer orientation,” for example,
bolic value” because they cloak their actors with “have a greater influence on business decisions; in
legitimacy, “a necessary property of effective deci- public organizations, values such as legitimacy, law-
sions.” Hence, the “conspicuous consumption of fulness, accountability, and impartiality play a larger
information,” whether done consciously or not, “is a role.”22
sensible strategy for decision makers” because their The organization also has a role. It can render
decisions not only are more readily implemented, but its members’ decision premises more reflective of the
organizations with elaborate information systems organization’s values, and, when it does, it produces
also house more effective decision makers than those happier employees who stay longer with the organ-
without them.17 ization.23 Still, regardless of how much sector and
The symbolism syndrome seems to be particu- organization may mold individual decision premises,
larly present in public administration; the consump- people do not make more rational decisions.
tion of information is “more conspicuous in policy
making than in engineering, more conspicuous in the Bounded Rationality and Dysrationalia This
public sector than in the private, more conspicuous is because the human species is beset by bounded
at the top of an organization than at the bottom.”18 rationality; that is, the reasoning powers of the
A study of defense contracts, for example, found human mind are bound to a small and simple plot
“no empirical evidence” that gathering information compared with the vastness and complexity of the
controlled costs or enhanced quality, but that there territory spanned by the problems that human minds
nonetheless was “substantial evidence” supporting are expected (expected, at least, by traditional theo-
the “symbolic hypothesis” of information’s organi- rists in economics and management) to comprehend
zational role.19 It is worth noting in this regard that and solve.24
55 percent of federal chief information officers ques- Research buttresses the reality of the bounded
tion the reliability of their own agencies’ data.20 brain. The human mind can distinguish a maximum
In sum, research on how information is used in of just seven categories of phenomena at a time, but
decision making implies that the process is less than beyond that number loses track.25
rational. And, to an extraordinary extent, it is not Emotion colors decision making. A decision is
rational. first made as an emotional response to one’s envi-
ronment,26 and this is especially the case when there
have been recent and dramatic events in it; conse-
STRATEGIC DECISION MAKING quently, decision makers often misstate the problem
to be solved.27 If anger is among the decision maker’s
IN ORGANIZATIONS emotional responses, the likelihood of unethical
The principal reason underlying this darker side of decisions increases, but if fear or little emotion are
decision making is that the people who make deci- present, then ethical decisions become more possi-
sions, like all people, are often less than logical. ble.28 Although this emotional phase is sometimes
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 81

criticized as an impediment to rational decision displaces critical thinking, and “is likely to result in
making, emotion is central to decision making; irrational and dehumanizing actions directed against
people who cannot process emotions also struggle out-groups.”37
to make decisions.29 Instances of groupthink include the American
Later, more rational responses to environmen- decision to invade Iraq. The basis of that decision
tal events overlay the initial emotional ones.30 When was the “erroneous National Intelligence Estimate
this phase is reached, decision makers usually are of October 2002,”38 which was “the Intelligence
overcautious, favoring stability over change,31 and Community’s most authoritative and comprehensive
tend to prefer information that protects them against judgment.”39
anticipated losses over information that they can use How this happened, as recorded in official
to make gains.32 reports, is a primer on groupthink: “At some point,
Decision makers typically use heuristic thinking [the intelligence community’s] premises stopped
(or “rules of thumb”), which is invariably flawed, being working hypotheses and became more or less
and base their decisions on their perception of the unrebuttable conclusions; worse, the intelligence
status quo, rather than on an objective compar- system became too willing to find confirmations of
ison of known variables.33 Options that provide them in evidence that should have been recognized at
quick returns generally are preferred to those that the time to be of dubious reliability. Collectors and
delay them, even though delay may bring superior analysts too readily accepted any evidence that sup-
returns.34 ported their theory that Iraq had stockpiles and was
“In short, our brains are naturally lazy.” At developing weapons programs, and they explained
its worst, bounded rationality can degenerate into away or simply disregarded evidence that pointed in
dysrationalia, or “the inability to think and behave other directions.”40
rationally despite having adequate intelligence.” This destructive dynamic extended to the White
President George W. Bush, in the view of at least House. President George W. Bush never called for
one noted psychologist, was a dysrationalic deci- a debate among his staff about whether there was
sion maker, as the examples provided in Chapters 1 a connection between Al Qaeda and Iraq, “one key
and 9, and later in this one, suggest.35 reason” justifying America’s war with Iraq, which
arguably was the most critical decision of his pres-
“Satisficing” Decisions Bounded rationality, in idency. Startlingly, Bush “sometimes assumed that
sum, results in suboptimal decisions. If not optimal, he knew his aides’ private views [about an invasion]
then, what are they? without asking them one-on-one”; Bush, in fact,
Herbert Simon answered this question by never sought the advice of his secretaries of defense
making up a word. He called the decisions made by and state and CIA director. Nor, for that matter, did
people in organizations “satisficing” decisions—that he consult his own father, who, in 1991, had led a
is, they satisfied the makers of decisions and sufficed successful invasion of Iraq.41
enough for the organization to get by, or, combined,
satisficed.36 This was radical thinking in its day (and, Making Good Decisions Despite the many mental
in some circles, it still is), when top executives were and social obstacles that inhibit good strategic deci-
assumed to be omniscient. sion making, good decision makers remain.

Victims of Groupthink Regrettably, in addition Vigilant Decision Making Vigilant decision


to their own bounded minds, decision makers are making consists of employing ways to encourage
limited by other factors as well. Because stress accom- the group to participate more effectively in making
panies decision making, avoidance and denial are good decisions and to minimize groupthink.42 These
frequently the handmaidens of the decision process. group-improving means include: employing a large
When stressed decision makers are making deci- number of techniques to encourage dissent; bring-
sions within the context of a tightly knit in-group, ing in “representatives of people in the organization
“groupthink” is the consequence. Groupthink is with different points of view,” rather than relying
an over-conformity among decision makers that solely on “trusted staff”; critically assessing the
82 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

costs and risks of each choice; and plumbing diverse were much less likely than the randomly-selected
sources of knowledge.43 ones to consult any advisers and to engage in any
“information-gathering of some sort.” In other
Fast Decision Making Not only do good decision words, they knew what was right. Outstanding
makers gather more data and counsel more exten- executives were much more likely to say that their
sively than poor decision makers when making difficulties stemmed from combinations of high pro-
decisions, they also develop more alternatives to spective costs; notably, their decisions would: be
solve problems. Counter-intuitively, even though widely unpopular with colleagues, overseers, and
these activities are time consuming, they never- external stakeholders; flout “the wishes of their own
theless make their decisions more rapidly than do Administration”; involve “emotionally wrenching
those who do not engage in them. These unexpected issues regarding employees”; or simply gore too
patterns of information-sensitive, advice-seeking, many oxen. Fully half of the outstanding executives,
option-generating—yet speedy—decision making compared with a fifth of the randomly-selected ones,
lead to “superior performance” by executives.44 “essentially made the decision themselves.”
“The executive must be able to organize for
Thinking Dispositions Thinking dispositions are vigilant decision-making for . . . important decisions,
rational, psychological, decision-making touch- but be prepared to turn this approach off when
stones that, surprisingly, do not correlate, or, at courage is required.”49
best, only weakly so, with cognitive ability. They
include: a capacity for thoughtful reflection; digging
out information before deciding (good decision The Bounds of Organizational Rationality
makers in government rely on written sources and Just as the rationality of organizational members is
“outside academics” much more than mediocre bounded, so is the rationality of organizations them-
decision makers45); trying to match one’s degree of selves.
certainty with the strength of the evidence; examin-
ing one’s biases and correcting for them; a willing- Types of Organizational Decision Making How an
ness to wait until good solutions become apparent;46 organization makes decisions depends on whether
and consciously countering confirmation bias, or its stakeholders agree or disagree about what their
the regrettable reality that first impressions (which, organization should do (that is, its goals), and
recall, often misstate the problem) “are remarkably agree or disagree about what causes the attainment
perseverant and unresponsive to new input, even of those goals. Table 4-1 matches these “decision
when such input logically negates the original bias issues” with decision-making strategies.50
of the impressions.”47 As one ages, however, the like-
lihood of one using thinking dispositions lessens, Efficiency and Analytical Decision Making In
and they are partially replaced by a greater reliance organizations in which everyone agrees on organiza-
on bias and irrationality; the consequence is riskier tional objectives and how to fulfill them, efficiency is
decisions.48 readily apparent. Executives in our hypothetical cor-
poration of International Widget have a solid notion
Forget All That: Courageous Decision Making The of what they want to do (maximize profits), and they
techniques of vigilant decision making, and perhaps understand how to cause those profits (manufacture
some of the thinking dispositions, are discarded widgets cheaply and sell them aggressively).
when those public administrators who have estab- Because efficiency is obvious in businesses, ana-
lished reputations for excellence are confronted with lytical decision making is dominant; there is little or
making a particular type of tough decision: the cou- no debate about cause and effect, and decisions are
rageous decision. made on the basis of shared perceptions.
In an analysis of how “outstanding” and ran-
domly-selected federal senior executives made “their Effectiveness and Judgmental Decision Making As
most difficult” decisions, “the central, and to us sur- we explain in Chapter 7, in many public and non-
prising finding,” was that the outstanding executives profit organizations efficiency is very difficult to
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 83

TABLE 4-1
Societal Assessment and Organizational Decision-Making Strategies
by Causation and Outcome
Standards of Desirability and Preferred Outcomes
Crystallized Standards and Ambiguous Standards and
Agreement about Outcomes Disagreement about Outcomes
Agreement Efficiency, or economic, tests are Social tests are used by society to
used by society to assess the assess the organization.
organization.
Beliefs about Computational, or analytical, Compromise, or bargaining,
cause and decision making is used by the decision making is used by the
effect organization. organization.
Example: a research lab Example: Congress
Disagreement Effectiveness tests are used Social tests are used by society
by society to assess the to assess the organization.
organization.
Judgmental decision making is Inspirational and/or authoritarian
used by the organization. decision making is used by the
organization.
Example: Department Example: Some nonprofit
of Defense social service agencies

determine. Effectiveness, or an organization’s ability Inspirational and/or Authoritarian Decision


to fully complete its tasks, however, is usually easier Making What sort of strategies can an organ-
to assess. ization use when its decision makers disagree
In these organizations, in which members still about both goals and causality? And, yes, there
agree about goals but are uncertain about how to are such “organizations.”51 As we detail in
achieve them, decisions are made judgmentally. Chapter 10, some organizations in the third sector
Hence, we see Homeland Security spending as much seem  to  exemplify  this combination, and their
money as it can muster as a means of maximizing members are not  merely  uncertain about whether
its goal of effectiveness (that is, its untested security or not  they are  achieving  their goals; they are
capability), but International Widget spending as uncertain even  about what  those goals  are. Under
little money as possible as a means of maximizing its these circumstances, inspirational decision making,
goal (that is, its profits). or authoritarian decision  making, or both, are
favored.
Compromising, or Bargaining, Decision Making In Inspirational and authoritarian decision making
those organizations in which members believe that are employed in these organizations because the
they know what causes what, but who disagree alternative could be chaos; when decision makers
about organizational goals, neither efficiency nor are unable to discern efficiency and effectiveness,
effectiveness is clear. So what is a decider to do? rational (i.e., analytical), or even partially rational
Under these conditions, compromising, or bar- (i.e., judgmental), decision-making “strategies”
gaining, decision making is in order. The classic simply are not possible. “Inspiring” the organi-
example is any legislature; legislative decision zation, and/or cracking down on dissidents (who
makers agree that a proposed law will cause certain are  no more qualified than the decision makers
outcomes, but disagree about the desirability of to make decisions), are the only decision-making
those outcomes. options left.
84 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

Mismatching Organizations and Decision Making good” decisions. Persuasion consumes the most time
Table 4-1 illustrates which decision-making strategy of all four tactics, and seems to be favored by public
ought to be used by each type of organization if deci- administrators, who spend an inordinate amount of
sions are to succeed. Unfortunately, in nearly six out their time talking with subordinates and peers; “this
of ten strategic decisions, decision makers select a talk accomplishes administration.”56
strategy that is inappropriate to the kinds of bounds Recently, the emergence of “the nudge” has
that constrain their organization. As a result, these made persuasion a more effective tactic. “Nudge”
decisions “were much less successful” than those is shorthand for the framing of policies and pro-
that were made in conjunction with the decision cedures in ways (such as by simplifying choices
strategy that matched (as shown in Table 4-1) their and sending reminders) that more effectively per-
type of organization.52 suade people to adopt and implement them.57 The
president introduced, in 2009, the nudge to regu-
Organized Anarchies and the Garbage Can of latory agencies; established, in 2014, a Social and
Decision Making The messiest forms of decision Behavioral Sciences Team to promote it; and, in
making—that is, judgmental, compromising, inspi- 2015, issued Executive Order 13707 to implement
rational, and authoritarian decision making—all the nudge government-wide. Its use has increased
associate with public or nonprofit organizations. college enrollments of low-income applicants and
These messy methods characterize organized anar- reduced federal employees’ waste of paper, among
chies, which are composed of a “loose collection of other achievements.
ideas” in which participants do not define their pref-
erences very precisely and do not fully understand Edicts The edict, which simply orders that a policy
what their organization actually does.53 be executed, is employed to implement 30 percent of
Organized anarchies use an erratic, irrational decisions. The edict is the least effective tactic, with,
decision-making process that is a figurative “garbage at best, a successful average adoption rate of 50
can.” In making decisions, the organized anarchy percent, and it associates with the lowest quality of
“bumbles along, and discovers preferences through decision: “adequate.” Public administrators disdain
action more than it acts on the basis of preferences,” the edict, and rarely administer by “appealing to
resulting in decisions that are “a collection of choices authority or using strong-arm tactics.”58
looking for problems . . . solutions looking for issues
to which they might be the answer, and decision Participation Participation refers to stakeholders
makers looking for work.”54 cooperatively implementing the decision, and it is
used 13 percent of the time. Participation averages
an adoption rate of 80 percent and associates with
Bounded Rationality and the “good to outstanding” decisions. Although there is
Implementation of Strategic Decisions no known instance of all stakeholders participat-
Just as making big decisions is beset by bounded ing (“token” participation is more common),59 the
rationality, so is implementing them. Studies of 467 broader and deeper the participation, the greater
strategic decisions in all sectors found that decision the rate of successful adoption of the decision.60
makers rely on four implementation tactics (selected Participative decision making is markedly present in
by top and middle managers with roughly equal fre- government agencies.61
quency), and that the more commonly used tactics
rarely correlated with the successful implementa- Intervention Finally, intervention, used to execute
tion, or even with the quality, of the decision.55 a modest 8 percent of decisions, involves managers
justifying a need for change, establishing new perfor-
Persuasion Our first tactic is persuasion, which mance standards, and demonstrating the feasibility
relies on “experts” to sell a new policy, and it is used of the decision and the improvements that will result
to implement 49 percent of decisions. Decisions that from it.
are persuasively implemented have an average adop- With a 90 percent adoption rate and the strong-
tion rate of 58 percent and are rated as “adequate to est association with “good to outstanding” decisions,
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 85

it is both the most the most successful and the least nonprofit counterparts,71 and procedures are more
used tactic. Its resource demands are modest, its constricting.72 Overall, “the image of public organ-
implementation the fastest, and it works effectively izations that emerges is one of little organizational
“regardless of the situation.”62 coherence in the identification of strategic decisions.
In contrast to executives in other sectors, those In addition, the ability of top-level managers to
in government appear to rely heavily on intervention, control the decisions and actions of their organiza-
overcoming “bureaucratic obstacles” by introducing tions is called into question.”73
training programs (24  percent), demonstrating the
benefits of new policies (23  percent), consultating Bargaining versus Analyzing When making deci-
with stakeholders (20 percent), and persistence (20 sions, public administrators “place too great an
percent) to get their way.63 Public administrators use emphasis on bargaining . . . but they do seem to
far more kinds of control mechanisms and informa- understand the limits of analysis,” in contrast to
tion sources than do corporate managers to imple- corporate managers, who “seem to place too much
ment decisions.64 reliance on analytics and too little on bargaining.”
Effective administration, it appears, is not dic- Public administrators believe that negotiating, in and
tated by decree; it is done by the down and dirty, of itself, legitimizes decisions, and thereby creates,
and this seems to be especially the case in the public unfortunately, “a false perception of support for a
sector. As a seasoned federal administrator put it, decision.”74
“A presidential declaration doesn’t make much
happen.” Rather, intervention “is what presidential A Complex Process Governments’ decision makers
management means—not hovering above the grimy must deal with vastly more, and more complex, deci-
fray, but plunging into it and getting dirty.”65 sion criteria that are far broader in scope than those
in business,75 who are measurably more likely to
focus on a single and straightforward datum—that
Decision Making in Public Organizations: of financial performance—when making decisions.76
A Different Dynamic As we describe in Chapter 6, new information tech-
Whether the sector is public or private “creates nologies have proven helpful in sorting and simpli-
substantive differences” in decision making.66 Here fying data for all decision makers, but the unique
are some. complexity of public decision making persists none-
theless.
An Attenuated Autonomy About six out of ten
Americans think that protesting against “unjust Taking It Slowly and Cautiously Public executives
public policies” and participating in “community who have business experience view governments as
decision-making” are “very important . . . obliga- conservative cultures that are slow to change,77 and
tions” that they “owe the country.”67 In part because research suggests that decisions are indeed made
of these views, public administrators are “monitored more slowly in public organizations than in private
by everyone around them.”68 Over the past twelve ones.78
months, 19 percent of local residents had contacted Slower decision making may be a product of
elected officials (longtime and wealthier residents the fact that civilian agencies are less likely to take
and baby boomers contact them the most), and 24 risks than private companies, regardless of the
percent had attended a local public meeting (a prac- organizational mission.79 A large-scale study of state
tice favored by longtime, older, and wealthier resi- and local employees found that an astounding 40
dents).69 percent of them had “high risk aversion” (another
Legislatures, of course, also attenuate agency 30 percent had high to moderate risk aversion), and
autonomy, and the greater the partisan split in the just 2 percent had “low risk aversion.”80
legislature, the less discretionary authority that the Any organization with a cautionary culture
legislature will grant to its agencies.70 and cautious administrators is also likelier than less
Hence, decision making in public organiza- cautious organizations to have top managers who
tions is less autonomous than in their private and have low levels of trust in their employees; a fuzzier
86 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

organizational mission (these two characteristics Unfortunately for them, and their states, there is
seem to be especially salient); ribbons of red tape; empirically “strong support” for the proposition that
weak linkages between promotion and performance; “citizen input provides [state] administrators with
and high involvement with elected officials.81 Most valuable site-specific information and contributes
of these features generally are found far more fre- to more efficient and effective public programs.”90
quently in the public sector than in the other two. State agencies that have higher levels of autonomy
and a greater control of their budgets are more open
The Vortex: Participation and Consultation to public comment than are less autonomous agen-
“Publicness is associated with greater decision par- cies with weaker budgetary control.91
ticipation [increasingly, agencies form decisions by Although city and county managers can,
using “large-group interaction methods” that can and do, handily shut out “troublesome” outsider
involve as many as 2,000 people at one time82], but involvement, even in communities where “citizens
not smoothness.”83 are ranked high in terms of placing pressure on the
Indeed not. Governments’ decision makers swirl administration to include them in the deliberative
sporadically through a “vortex” of intense meetings process,”92 these policymakers are at least begin-
and conversations with each other, and are much ning to communicate with citizens much more
more likely than those in private organizations to substantively than in the past (recall Chapter 1 in
engage in both formal and informal interaction with this regard).93 This is to the good, as higher levels
others when making decisions.84 of perceived public participation in local hearings
and budget formulation lead to a greater sense of
Consulting with Whom? Public administrators accountability among administrators in improving
network extensively with internal “peers and under- program performance, and citizen involvement asso-
lings” when making decisions.85 This is a good thing: ciates positively with more responsive policies and
A thorough review concludes that “the greatest higher public trust.94 All of this results in a benefi-
organizational gains from employee participation cent cycle of increasingly better local governance.95
[in decision making] may come from producing
better decisions.”86 Ignoring Bosses and Overseers At the oversight
In marked contrast to business managers, level, public administrators are, surprisingly, less
however, when public administrators make deci- than fully communicative with the legislators or
sions they often “discount networking” with “exter- board members to whom they report, and this lapse
nal constituencies,” notably agency clients, citizens, “has important implications. Oversight bodies have
and oversight bodies. This is not such a good thing. a big impact on public sector decisions. Their scru-
If clients and overseers were more involved in public tiny can be intense, and politics is far more pervasive
administrators’ decision making, it would “improve than in private organizations.”96
their chances of success.”87 The disinclination of public administrators to
consult with their overseers may have its roots in
Ignoring Clients and Citizens Public bureaucrats their lack of confidence in them. Executives with
tend to resist the involvement of clients and other backgrounds in both government and business
citizens when making decisions. This is an error. think that, compared with corporate board direc-
When federal agencies hold public meetings tors, legislators are less consistent, less informed on
when making rules, they encounter fewer “rulemak- issues, less likely to agree with administrators on
ing stalemates” and are sued less frequently over the organizational goals,97 and even that government is
rules than are agencies that held few or no meet- less transparent than business.98
ings; “public meetings can improve administrative Moreover, oversight bodies question agency
behavior.”88 decisions in particularly vexing ways, and this,
In the states, agency heads “are less than satis- too, can curtail communication. Legislators and
fied” with clients’ and citizens’ very marginal influ- board members “derail” agency decisions “after a
ence on their decision making, even though they decision is made, and long after the objecting over-
themselves consider their influence to be trivial.89 sight body has been asked for their views. . .. Public
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 87

organizations face fickle oversight, not the pervasive managers who relied primarily on soliciting the
monitoring and tinkering with ideas that the litera- views of experts and used hard data made the
ture suggests.”99 highest quality decisions. Public administrators who
relied more on studying issues or bargaining with
Caution, Communication, and Unappreciated stakeholders were less successful.106
Peril Because public administrators usually have
negotiated intensively (at least with peers and Life-or-Death Decisions: Imprimatur of the Public
underlings) in making their decisions, they often are Sector When making risky decisions, all decision
supremely confident in their quality and ultimate makers play to some extent to their own biases.107
success. Unfortunately, they seriously underestimate The riskiest of decisions are those that can result in
the level of risk that their decisions entail, which is people living or dying, a risk that is almost exclusive
a direct result of their poor communication with to the public sector.
their clients, citizens, and overseers. Corporate deci- Two crucial factors emerge when life-or-death
sion makers, by contrast, view “the same decisions” decisions are being made. They are: hope and time.
produced by such a process “as having considerable If the decision maker perceives that there is some
risk,” and these public/private differences hold up reason to hope for a problem’s future solution that
“no matter the cognitive makeup of the manager or will be superior to the choices presently available,
the culture to which he or she was exposed.”100 then he or she will adopt a decision-making strat-
Obviously, decision makers who ignore their egy of coolly rational vigilance—that is, the decision
clients and bosses can produce decisions that “can maker not only will use most of the techniques of
be very dangerous” to the decision makers, especially vigilant decision making and thinking dispositions
“if an oversight body opposes” their decisions.101 that characterize good decision making, but also will
Yet, this may be precisely the decision-making situa- develop several options, a contingency plan, and a
tion in public organizations. fully thought-out execution.
If, however, the decision maker has no hope
The Quality Question In sum, decision making for a satisfactory solution, then he or she is more
in public organizations, in contrast to its practice in likely  to engage in dysrationalic defensive avoid-
private ones, seems to be: a process that relies more on ance,  a posture in which denial, rigidity, and pro-
bargaining than analysis; is slower, sloppier, and crastination reign. Defensive avoidance “satisfies a
murkier; is more intense, constrained, and compli- powerful emotional need” to avoid the possibility of
cated; is more consultative, but containing elements of failure and guilt by inducing “pseudocalm” in the
groupthink; and is risk averse, but unwittingly risky. decision maker.
There is little research that clearly links each Defensive avoidance works fine, at least for the
of these characteristics with objectively-defined dilatory decider, until time runs out. When events
better or worse decisions, but what data we have close in, the decision maker’s defensive avoidance
do not augur well for public organizational decision is shattered, “thought processes are disrupted,” and
making. As we have noted, participative decision he or she snaps into hypervigilance mode, searching
making is present in public agencies, and, even when “frantically for a solution” that promises “immedi-
confined only to agency employees, it associates with ate relief.”108
superior decisions.102 But the negatives outnumber The price of this syndrome can be horrendously
the positives: limited decision-making autonomy,103 high. For two years, Philadelphia’s otherwise able
slow decision making,104 and a tendency toward and hands-on mayor had defensively avoided dealing
groupthink105 all correlate with poorer decisions, with a scofflaw cult that had been outrageously
and each, to some degree, characterizes decision abusing its neighbors for more than a decade, even
making in governments. though the mayor had long been informed that he
In one of the few attempts to match the had the legal authority to remove the commune from
decision-making techniques used by each sector with its premises. When media pressure and angry resi-
the quality and successful implementation of the dents finally brought the matter to a head, in 1985,
decisions made, it was determined that government two brief meetings were held, a planning group was
88 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

appointed that was “remarkably low in rank for such “One of the most astounding debacles in the history
a major operation,” and the mayor repaired to his of American municipal government,” including an
home before police served warrants at the cult’s row inferno that swept through three city blocks, leaving
house. The commune refused to be served; police sixty-one homes in cinders, 250 people homeless, and
unleashed water and tear gas; the cult responded six adults and five children dead.109
with bullets, and the police retaliated with more
than 8,000 rounds of firepower. Philadelphia’s city
manager informed the mayor that police had pro- Decision Making in Nonprofit
posed dropping from a helicopter a bomb on the Organizations: More Talk, Fights, Risk
commune’s roof, and “the mayor paused only thirty Decision making in the third sector has its own
seconds before approving the idea.” The result? distinctiveness.

A MONUMENTAL MAP MESS IN GEORGIA

We have noted that public agencies are far more Dry Branch; Deepstep and Sharp Top; Between and
influenced by factors in their external environments Experiment; and Gay and Climax.
than are private companies and nonprofit associations. Some victimized villages had long histories,
To cite just one example, the decisions made by public cultural significance, or really outraged residents who
organizations, no matter how managerially rational, protested that the decision was “a slap in the face.”
are exposed far more frequently to second-guessing Transportation officials responded to these and other
and reversal by environmental forces. Here is an “pretty impassioned” objections with, “the map was
instance of what we mean. getting illegible.”
Still, the Department quickly reinstated thirty-one
The Georgia Department of Transportation had finally “placeholders,” as the Census Bureau dismissively
decided to clean up its map. The Department designs dubs very small communities, and pledged to
and publishes the state’s official travel map, and its reconsider more. The governor then wrote the
administrators had been fretting for at least eight years Department’s board, asking it to “take another look”
over how to make their map clearer and more useful to at its decision, and, fewer than twenty-four hours
most travelers. later (and less than a month after the Department
Clarifying Georgia’s official map was no mean had announced its decision to simplify its map), the
challenge. It was strewn with unincorporated board reversed itself and reinstated all the vanished
communities that are so small that the U.S. Census villages.
Bureau does not recognize them. In Georgia, there are The Georgia Department of Transportation had met
519 of these boroughs, and in 2006 the Department its Waterloo. Nevertheless, the fine folks in Waterloo, as
of Transportation made the unusual, if understandable, well as those solid souls in Yellow Dirt, Hopeulikit, and
decision to eliminate all of them from the map’s 2007 Po Biddy Crossroads, remain vigilant.
edition.
Sources: Gene Bluestein, Associated Press, “Official State
In its decision to unclutter its cartography, the Map Zaps 519 Communities,” Atlanta Journal-Constitution
Department deleted such delightful designations (December 10, 2006) and “Georgia May Return Hundreds
as Rose Dhu, Dewy Rose, and Due West; Phinizy, of Towns That Were Wiped off the Map,” Savannah Morning
Funkhouser, and Flowery Tree; Pin Point and Poetry News (December 15, 2006). “DOT Has Lost Its Way on Map
Tulip; Retreat and Roosterville; Cloudland and Kansas; Plan” (editorial) and Jack Wilkinson, “Folks Wiped off State
Map Take Offense,” both in Atlanta Journal-Constitution
Sand Hill and Sandfly; Ty Ty and Talking Rock; Hemp (December 15, 2006), and Ariel Hart, “Tiny Towns Go Back
and Hickory Level; Jake and Juliette; Lowell and Clem; on Highway Map,” Atlanta Journal-Constitution (January 4,
Chattoogaville and Centralhatcheee; Gum Branch and 2007).
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 89

Consultative Decision Making Nonprofit strategic ‘coalitional’ species; groups compete with each other
decision makers appear to be uniquely consultative; for status and influence.”115
they “recycle” decisions back to earlier stages in We note this reality because, from the perspec-
the decision-making process, and take many more tive of organization theory, coalition management
“steps” than in the private sector.110 This process deftly defines the art of administration: “In the
works well for the third sector (but not for the other highly complex organization, power is dispersed. . ..
two), as bargaining in nonprofit organizations asso- [and] the central power figure is the individual who
ciates with making better decisions and implement- can manage the [dominant] coalition.”116 “The true
ing them successfully.111 basis for human action is not avarice—the lust for
personal gain and comfort, but envy—the lust for
Conflictive Decision Making Conflicts break primacy.”117
out earlier in the decision-making process of non-
profit organizations than in for-profit ones, and
third-sector executives—who believe that conflict The Power of Subordinates
defines  issues  more sharply and thus produces Some seventy years ago, Simon observed that sub-
better decisions—are less averse to conflict than ordinates, especially “professional men, [are] apt
are their corporate counterparts, who think just the to have relatively narrow zones of acceptance” of
opposite.112 administrative directives, “particularly in the areas
of their own professional competences. . .. In a very
Riskier Decision Making Third-sector admin- real sense, [the administrator] is merely a bus driver
istrators are especially fond of throwing the dice, whose passengers will leave him unless he takes
and have been known to radically change the very them in the direction they wish to go. They leave
missions of their organizations if they thought it him only minor discretion.”118
useful,113 an option not available to public agen- Simon’s notion has merit for public admin-
cies and a limited one for private companies. istrators. Guerrilla government describes career
Twenty-six percent of managers and profession- bureaucrats who, quietly or brazenly, work against
als  in the  independent sector report that their the wishes of their superiors, for good or ill.119 The
organization encourages them “to take risks,” com- empirical evidence suggests that both public exec-
pared with 21 percent of federal administrators utives and elected politicians have only “limited
and 20  percent of for-profit managers. Nonprofit influence” over the “street-level bureaucrats” who
employees also are much less concerned with implement policy; these bureaucrats’ understand-
compensation and  job security than are those in ing of the policy and their “knowledge of the rules”
government and the  private  sector.114 With  the are “more important” to them than their superiors’
obvious exception of the public sector’s dominance preferences.120
of life-or-death decision making,  these  charac- Public administrators, at least the more tal-
teristics strongly  suggest that decision  making  in ented ones, seem to appreciate these administrative
the third  sector is a riskier  business than in the limitations. They comprehend that their subordi-
other two. nates demand their “obedience to roles. . .. Cabinet
officers . . . no less than a clerk, [are] constrained to
perform their roles in such a way as to demonstrate
ADMINISTRATION IN obeisance to norms. . .. To unseasoned actors, behav-
ing capriciously . . . might seem the quintessential
ORGANIZATIONS evidence of power. But such a strategy cannot endure
An important variant of decision making is admin- in an organized setting.”121
istration, or strategic decision making writ small. Humbleness and humility, in sum, count;
Administration is based on coalitions, or informal “humble CEOs connect to top and middle manag-
alliances designed to advance individual goals. ers” by making both groups feel empowered, and
Coalitions appear to be basic to the human condi- this, in turn, “is connected to integration in the top
tion, and “many biologists believe that . . . we are a management team.”122
90 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

Supervision is the least effective control mechanism,


The Powers of Administrators but the remaining five all bring desired administra-
Fortunately, researchers have identified two kinds of tive results. Public administrators must use “a more
administrative, or leadership, power that facilitate complex system of control” than business manag-
subordinates’ acceptance of their executives’ roles. ers because they “have to supervise a workforce
One is position power, a category that includes employing an unclear technology.”125
four “power bases.” They are: Control, specifically
of information and the work environment; reward
power, or the positive recognition of another; coer- Administration in Public Organizations:
cive power, or the capacity to punish; and legitimate A Different Dynamic
power, or the acceptance of the leader by others. The tasks that public administrators must adminis-
The other kind of power is personal power, and ter are far more “complex” than those managed by
this includes three power bases: Expert power, or private managers,126 rendering public administra-
the perception that the leader is knowledgeable; ref- tion all the more difficult.
erent power, or the personal attraction that a leader
holds for others; and charisma, or the leader’s ability The Whirlwind Public administrators have little
and will to exert great change.123 control over how they use their time, and are more
Corporate managers exercise a very high level “rushed” to get things done.127 They are far more
of control over the critical positional power bases of consumed with managing crises, and devote far
rewards, coercion, and legitimacy, but public admin- more time to doing so, than their private-sector
istrators have little, if any, control over them and are counterparts.128
reduced to relying on personal power bases to lead. More effective public administrators are more
It is noteworthy in this regard that public employees flexible and accord scant effort to “time manage-
perceive their executives to be far more inspirational ment” and planning than less effective public admin-
and personally involved with them than do corpo- istrators. Quite the contrary holds true in the private
rate employees.124 sector: more effective industrial managers plan their
days, and less effective ones do not.129
Public administration, it appears, is different.
The Mechanisms of Administrative Control
Once administrators have established their power The Pressures To “accomplish” their convoluted
bases, then they can exercise greater power. They do and ill-defined missions, public administrators must
this through six major “mechanisms of administra- confront many more “conflicting environmental
tive control.” demands” and “external stakeholders” than business
These mechanisms include: supervision, or the managers.130
direct observation and provision of feedback to sub- Consider budgets. “External” actors, notably
ordinates; input control, or the cutting or increas- legislators and lobbyists, appear to be “more crucial”
ing of resources to subunits; behavior control, or in forming agency budgets than are agency ambi-
the structuring by administrators of individual and tions, executives, and even performance.131
group activities; output control, or the evaluation Or consider personnel. Subordinates are more
of subunits’ productivity; selection-socialization difficult to control because they often are not hired
control, or the internalization of selected norms and by those to whom they report, and can ally them-
values in subunits; and environmental control, or the selves with powerful outside interests.132
constraints imposed by the organization’s external Here is an example: the notorious closing,
task environment (public administrators implement in 2013, of two of the three lanes to the George
environmental control by obtaining feedback from Washington Bridge, the most heavily trafficked
their communities). bridge in America, rendering Fort Lee, New Jersey,
Public administrators, relative to their coun- into the equivalent of a parking lot for four days.
terparts in the private sector, use all six mecha- The closings seem to have been a result of guberna-
nisms in surprisingly broad and balanced ways. torial appointments to, and alleged interference in,
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 91

the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, ■ Engage new employees with a welcoming
which owns the bridge. The Authority, which a had first-year program that introduces them to the
a well-deserved reputation for administrative excel- agency’s culture.
lence since its founding in 1921, was decimated by ■ Communicate to build trust. Ask employees
the terrorist attacks of 2001 on New York’s Twin for their feedback and advice, and tell them
Towers, in which eighty-four of its top administra- whether you used it; meet regularly with each
tors, including its able executive director, perished. employee to review progress; and lead by
According to an outside audit, the tragedy “took a example.
significant emotional toll on the psyche of the organ- ■ Hold employees accountable for their
ization.” New Jersey’s governor, first elected in 2010, performance.
immediately “set about stuffing the weakened agency ■ Closely link recognition, rewards, and
with his supporters,” who numbered eighty when the sanctions to performance.
lanes were closed, allegedly by an Authority appoin- ■ Give all employees the opportunity to grow
tee of the New Jersey governor and at the governor’s and develop.
office’s request. By the time of the closing, top-level
New Jerseyans and New Yorkers at the Authority
“were barely speaking” to one another, including, LIMITED CHANGE: THE IMPACT
apparently, the board chair (a New Jerseyan) and OF TECHNOLOGY AND PEOPLE ON
its executive director (a New Yorker), who was not
informed of the lane closings for all four days, and THE PUBLIC ORGANIZATON
ordered them opened when he learned of them.133 Governments are not associated with swift-paced
The Port Authority exemplifies those realities change. As one study put it, “high-publicness organi-
that force public executives to interact far more fre- zations . . . show a slow change rate” and “a low rate
quently and formally with outside groups than their of change.”138 But public organizations do change.
corporate counterparts,134 sometimes for good, and
other times not.
Despite these handicaps, however, public admin- The Likely Limited Role of Technology
istrators serve the public with grace. “The ‘insensi- Without question, the organization’s technology, or
tive’ stereotype” of government bureaucrats—that what the organization does and how it does it, is
they are “uncaring, inflexible. . .. and generally central to what any organization is, and changing
inept in dealing with the public”—is simply wrong. its technology causes systemic change throughout
“The modal finding indicates public employees who any organization. However, legislatures rarely, if
are more sensitive than private employees. Public ever, allow a government agency to change what
employees value qualities associated with sensitiv- it does, and public technology is itself resistant to
ity, empathy, broad mindedness, good interpersonal change.
relations, forgiveness, politeness, helpfulness—more Executives who have served in the private and
than or equal to private employees.”135 Ironically public sectors believe, accurately, that, compared to
(and inaccurately), however, public managers are business, government and nonprofits are driven by
overly self-critical on this score, and “tend to feel processes.139 Changing a process in any organization
that their organizations satisfy customers less than involves extensive convincing and coordinating, and
do private organizations with their products and is a much slower affair than changing a product. A
services.”136 study of 101 banks found that, over eleven years,
“product innovations [were] adopted at a greater
Lessons Learned Public administrators have rate and speed than process innovations.”140 Hence,
learned some practical lessons about how to admin- even within the same type of organization, and even
ister well. Here are the main ones.137 within the same organization, processes change
much more slowly than do products.
■ Hire with care, and be alert to an employee’s Governments and nonprofits produce processes,
performance during the probationary period. such as policies, programs, and services; rarely do
92 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

they produce products, such as pickles, planes, and systemic change to tinkering144] . . . but middle
widgets. It follows that the public or nonprofit managers [30 to 62 percent] and front-line staff”
organization necessarily changes less rapidly than (24 to 29 percent).145
do private organizations, simply because of the
process-intensive nature of its work. Human Choice or Environmental Determinism?
Organizational members count in changing their
organizations. But do they count as much as the
People Changing Their Public riptides of the darkling sea that drenches the
Organization organization?
If not technology, then what about people? All organizations’ external environments are
It is commonly thought that government growing more complex, and this complexity is heavy
bureaucrats resist organizational change and busi- with organizational and personal peril. The sociol-
ness executives relish it. Wrong. A study of 343 man- ogist, Charles Perrow, famously identified normal,
agers in both sectors unearthed an “unexpected” or inevitable, accidents as those disasters that are
finding: “Public managers are more change-oriented born of the complexity inherent in “human-machine
than managers in business organizations.” Relative systems.” Examples range from airplane crashes to
to business managers, public administrators are meltdowns of nuclear power plants. Interactions in
much likelier to generate new ideas and projects; these normal accidents “are not only unexpected,
are more imaginative, intuitive, experimental, and but are incomprehensible for some critical period of
future-oriented; exploit more possibilities (and, in time.”146
the process, are more inclined to ignore “practical How well, or if, organizational decision makers
realities”); hold stronger opinions about the need can deal with complex environmental forces is “one
for organizational change; and are much more prone of the most pervasive and central arguments” in the
to introduce new processes, services, and reorgani- field.147 That argument is human choice (that is, the
zations. “Business managers’ potential for [organi- organization’s decision makers choose organiza-
zational] change is actually comparable to Swedish tional destiny) versus environmental determinism
vicars”—in other words, not much.141 (the environment’s powerful forces determine organ-
izational destiny).
Middle Managers: Paladins of Public It does not behoove us to review at length
Change Who is more likely to cause change in gov- this professorial dispute.148 In a nutshell, however,
ernments—elected officeholders, nonprofit public- the  advocates of human choice hold that leader-
interest groups, agency clients, citizens, or stodgy old ship is significant, perhaps paramount, in achiev-
bureaucrats? The bureaucrats, hands down. “Despite ing  organizational success. Others have a more
controls . . . career public servants” at all levels of pantheistic perspective: “The Tolstoyan view of
government “do innovate,” and initiate innovations leaders as chips tossed about by the tides of history
far more frequently than any other group.142 rather than masters of events cannot be rejected a
Contrary to conventional wisdom, it is not priori.”149
necessarily the top bureaucrats who change public We do not subscribe to the view that the organ-
organizations, although public executives hired ization’s people are merely the pathetic pawns
from outside the organization associate positively of omnipotent environmental forces—and with
with “comprehensive organizational change.”143 “A reason: a decade-long international study, for
surprising result” of a study of significant change in instance, determined that (mostly private-sector)
governments over eight years “is that the most fre- managers’  one-point increment on a five-point
quent initiators of innovations were not politicians “management score” associated with a 23 percent
[who account for 18 to 36 percent of all innova- increase in productivity.150 We do believe, however,
tions] . . . or even agency heads [23 to 36 percent, that the public organization’s environment makes it
although senior public managers, while “con- harder for people in the public sector than in the
servative and  cautious in the implementation of private and independent sectors to change their
major organizational change,” prefer implementing organizations.
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 93

on average, are received and processed each year by


UNLIMITED CHANGE: THE all agencies, at a cost of more than $480 million.153
IMPACT OF THE ENVIRONMENT To meet an FOIA request, federal administrators
must execute no fewer than fifteen distinct tasks,
ON THE PUBLIC ORGANIZATION and it takes from ten to 100 median days to do so.154
The environment that surrounds and suffuses the The workload caused by FOIA requests grows
public organization appears to be the primal engine ever more onerous, largely because of radically
of its change. rising requests (up by 57 percent over ten years155),
burgeoning backlogs, and a steady decline in the
nearly 4,000 employees currently assigned to handle
Change in Public Organizations: Politics, requests.156 Two-thirds of the agencies are now
Pressures, and Prohibitions unable to fulfill “basic FOIA requests.”157 Irritated
Government agencies are pressured to change when requesters filed 3,350 lawsuits over ten years against
specific elements in their environments change. agencies, which, in their view, had failed to respond
Agencies that are dominated by professionals are adequately; a sampling of 1,672 of these lawsuits
pushed to adjust when outside observers perceive a found that a modest 7 percent of them were decided
loss of professional competence; those that are pro- largely in the filers’ favor.158
tected by patrons, such as legislators, are threatened In 2016, Congress passed the FOIA Improvement
with change when they lose their patrons; and those Act, which added further to agencies’ workloads.
that have endlessly churned the same old unrespon- The act codified the “presumption of openness” of
sive rut suddenly are challenged by new and sus- all federal records, effectively requiring that records
tained expectations. be released unless there is a foreseeable harm or legal
Pressure to change is no guarantee of change. prohibition in doing so; set a time limit of twenty-five
Frustratingly, even when public administrators pro- years on how long agencies could keep confidential
actively address these challenges, change still remains records of internal deliberations; required a proac-
stymied unless the agency’s leaders can gain “the tive release of information on persons expressing
support of oversight bodies,” and then only when several times their interest in certain records; and
agencies “are allowed to be responsive” to environ- established a Chief FOIA Officers Council to enforce
mental demands. “Creating such arrangements is and promote all this.
always difficult and often impossible.”151 In the states, similar problems persist.
Washington State identified “more than 250 open
government-related issues,” several of which
Ordering Agency Openness resulted in six-figure fines imposed on state and
All legislatures pass laws that change their govern- local agencies. Some states have undertaken costly
ments’ agencies. Some statutes radically open public training programs to comply with sunshine laws;
organizations to all manner of penetration by innu- in Washington, the training involves a substantial
merable environmental forces, and to an extent that 5,000 to 6,000 officials.159
is unheard of in the other sectors. While there is doubtless much good that derives
from sunshine laws, they clearly distract public
Burned by Sunshine An example is provided by administrators from the efficient fulfillment of their
sunshine laws, which require that agencies provide, agencies’ missions.
with some restrictions, to those who request it any
information that they have about anyone and any- Influenced by Agency Advisory Committees Many
thing. The federal government, all the states, and the public agencies are legislatively required to appoint
District of Columbia have sunshine laws.152 advisory committees that recommend policies. In
The federal sunshine law is the Freedom of Washington alone, there are about a thousand active
Information Act (FOIA) of 1966, which exempts committees in any given year composed of more
information pertaining to national security, citizen than 70,000 members advising around fifty agen-
privacy, and Congress. Some 700,000 FOIA requests, cies, at an annual cost of more than $350 million,
94 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

averaged over ten years. They hold more than 7,000 interests view agency rulemaking with great seri-
meetings a year, and, of those committees that meet ousness because, as we explained in Chapter 1, an
(a fifth hold no meetings annually), 71 percent of agency’s “rule” can amount to a major public policy.
their meetings are closed to the public.160 Agency rulemaking is relatively unconstrained
Often, agency advisory committees are domi- by the president, Congress, and the courts;166 it is
nated by the special interests that their agencies reg- special interests that wield the power.
ulate. Almost a fourth of federal committee members These interests are effective. Federal agencies
themselves think that their committees have too alter 49 percent of their decisions in favor of lob-
many members whose interests are directly affected byists purely as a result of the formal notice-and-
by the advice that their committees provide to their comment process.167 Even allowing for a bit of
agencies.161 braggadocio, it is nonetheless notable that from
“Because of concerns that special interests had over a fourth to more than two-fifths of lobbyists
too much influence over federal agency decision claim that they have their way in federal rulemaking
makers,” Congress passed the toothless Federal three-quarters of the time,168 with business interests
Advisory Committee Act of 1972, which appoints enjoying a “disproportionate influence over rule-
the General Services Administration and the Office making outputs.”169
of Government Ethics as loose overseers of commit- Perhaps because federal rule makers are con-
tee appointments. Unsurprisingly, “some agencies cerned about the disproportionate influence of
may continue to inappropriately use representa- special interests, for 35 percent of proposed major
tives” of regulated interests, as there are no penalties rules, and for 44 percent of proposed minor rules,
for noncompliance with the act.162 In 2010, a presi- the feds fail to notify the public that it can comment
dential memorandum removed all registered lobby- them.170
ists from federal advisory committees, and, although
lobbying groups complained, special interests likely State Rulemaking and Special Interest Power All
continue to be represented. states and the District of Columbia have adminis-
The states also open their agency advisory trative procedure acts, and they open agencies to a
committees to special interests: 65 percent of state startling quantum of special interest power.
lobbyists list “serving on advisory committees” as a Special interests’ general influence with state
favored influencing technique.163 agencies that are making rules is impressive;
77 percent of state lobbyists submit comments
Undermined by Administrative Procedure Acts An on proposed rules and even “help draft regula-
even more agency-permeating, and more question- tions,” and more than half engage “in regulatory
able, class of legislation is administrative procedure negotiations.”171
statutes that federal, state, and local legislatures Administrative procedure acts are crucial in
have enacted. both the access and influence of special interests. The
Administrative procedure acts permit “notice greater the access to state agencies enabled by an
and comment” by the public about proposed agency administrative procedure act, the higher that agency
rules, a requirement that conventional wisdom hails heads will rank the impact of interest groups on their
as “refreshingly democratic.”164 Research indicates, agencies’ rulemaking,172 an opinion fortified by fact:
however, that notices and comments are neither “As the interactions between . . . agencies and third
refreshing nor democratic. parties increase, so too does the influence of these
parties over agency policies and decisions.”173 In
Federal Rulemaking and Special Interest Power forty-five states, lobbyists may go over the agency’s
Federal agencies spend, on average, about four years head and appeal to entities that review any new rules
(ranging from one year to an astonishing fourteen) proposed (proposed, not enacted) by an agency.174
to make a rule.165 Access brings results. “Interest group power . . .
This vast amount of time implies that agencies is significantly influential” in an estimated 80 percent
must deal with formidable forces when making rules, of state agency rulemaking.175 As with federal
and they do—specifically, special interests. Special patterns, business interests dominate the states’
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 95

notice-and-comment process, and benefit most from environment—subtleties that only it, apparently, can
it relative to other groups.176 sense—that it readily and even radically responds to
them. The environment need not be comprised only
of obvious and brutish forces to change the public
The Osmotic Impact of the Agency’s organization; osmosis works, too.
Environment Whether they are rough or refined, environ-
Perhaps of greater impact on the inner workings of mental forces change the accountability, structure,
government agencies are not laws, but rather envi- hierarchy, procedures, and autonomy of public
ronmental forces that frequently are more nuanced organizations far more profoundly than these pres-
than we realize. sures alter private and nonprofit organizations.
Of course, all of us are aware that, in gov-
ernment, legislatures, which distribute budgets
and make laws, have an obvious impact on public La Bureaucratie
bureaucracies. But, even in this pure power rela- The word, bureaucracy, derives from the French
tionship, there are unspoken subtleties. States with bureau, or office, and the Greek kratos, or power,
congressional committee members who oversee the which combine, in French, as la bureaucratie. By the
Federal Emergency Management Agency receive early nineteenth century, the word had wended its
much larger disaster-relief funds than those states way to Britain as the Anglicized bureaucracy, which
without them, even though the emergencies are of then meant (in Britain, at least), “office,” or “admin-
comparable severity.177 The Internal Revenue Service istrative,” “tyranny.”181
audits far fewer individual income tax returns from There is a small but “growing of set of empiri-
taxpayers in congressional districts that are impor- cal findings that suggest public organizations are not
tant electorally to the president or which have repre- always highly bureaucratic,”182 but, as the quotation
sentatives on key oversight committees.178 itself suggests, governments are far more subject to
Other environmental forces do not even know unique environmental pressures than are businesses
that they are forces. and nonprofits, and those pressures result in rela-
Consider this: If a disease is merely men- tively greater bureaucratization.
tioned in the Washington Post twelve times over Government bureaucracies can be frustrating,
twelve months, then one full month, on average, is silly, or both.
knocked off the time that it takes the Food and Drug Consider frustration. A fifth of politically-
Administration to approve a drug that purports to appointed executives in Washington cite the
alleviate it. If the ailment is mentioned two-dozen “bureaucratic nature of government” as an obstacle
times over a year, then the approval time declines by to “recruiting future political leaders.” Of the more
two months, and so on. This is the case regardless of than four-fifths of federal career executives who
the severity of the disease, its frequency, its cost, and have considered leaving government, 31 percent
the availability of other drugs.179 report that a main motivation is its “bureaucracy/
Or this: Not only does coverage in the New inflexibility/slowness,”183 as exemplified by the
York Times about a disaster abroad associate with average of twelve years that it takes for an endan-
a heightened probability that the United States will gered species to be placed on the federal endangered
send assistance to the afflicted country, but each species list; forty-two such species became extinct
story results, on average, in almost $600,000 more while waiting.184
in additional aid. One story in the Times is worth Consider silliness. A few years ago, a Secret
more in American disaster relief than 1,500 deaths. Service agent dutifully registered his Glock pistol
This remains the case even after controlling for before boarding a plane. The agent then passed
national wealth and the number of people killed or through airport security, which discovered that he
left homeless.180 was carrying a penknife. Security returned to the
These instances bespeak an environmen- agent his Glock, but confiscated his penknife.185
tal determinism of a rare order. The public Consider both. The U.S. Office of Strategic
organization is so attuned to nuances in its task Services, the precursor to the CIA, published, in
96 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

1944, a secret thirty-two page Simple Sabotage Field at the national level, is heightening. Over fifty-six
Manual instructing its Second-World-War spies in years, the number of layers of federal senior man-
such techniques as how to burn down buildings. agement grew by more than three times, hitting
Chapter 5 is dedicated to tips on how to sabotage seventy-one managerial layers in 2016.193 For good
the effectiveness of one’s organization via jiu-jitsu- measure, over thirteen years twenty new layers of
like moves that are common in bureaucracies. These middle management were added as well.194
include: “misunderstanding” orders; droning on end- Government’s girth grows, too. Over fifty-six
lessly at meetings (a third of work-meeting attendees years, the number of cabinet departments more than
report feeling drowsy or actually napping during doubled to fifteen in 2016, and the number of federal
a meeting186); referring matters to committees for executives in them burgeoned by more than six times,
further study (and assuring that the committees are toting up to 3,265 in 2016. As a result, innovative,
as large as possible—never fewer than five members); but odd, executive titles are increasingly common,
referring matters already decided back for more dis- such as Deputy Assistant Deputy Administrator and
cussion; undermining efficient workers and promot- Principal Deputy Deputy Assistant Secretary.195 We
ing inefficient ones; and, when really critical work are not making these up.
must be done, holding a conference instead.187 The Over thirteen years, 13,000 more middle man-
manual’s anonymous writers, thoroughly steeped in agers were added to the federal hierarchy, while, over
government, understood bureaucracy and its many twenty-two years, the number of lower-level federal
foibles. employees plummeted by two-thirds.196 These trends
Standard dictionaries generally agree on the may explain why, over eleven years, the proportion
following: Bureaucracy is a combination of organ- of supervisors and managers in the federal workforce
izational hierarchy and red tape. Hierarchy refers to grew by 7.5 percent, but the average number of sub-
layers of administrative units ranked one above the ordinates whom they supervised actually declined by
other. Red tape is a large number of reports, forms, 7 percent, and currently stands at fewer than eight
procedures, and, most especially, rules. subordinates per supervisor.197
Hierarchy and red tape are symbiotic. Hierarchy The situation seems to be quite a bit better at
produces red tape: “the larger the number of hier- the state and local levels. Managers, who comprise
archical levels, the greater the demand for explicit 12.7 percent of all “management, professional, and
rules.”188 And red tape produces hierarchy: legisla- related” workers in the private sector, account for
tive rulemaking adds to “the structural complexity just 8.1 percent of these employees in the public
of bureaucratic action” in all sectors.189 sector, or a remarkable difference of more than
A consideration of bureaucracy’s two defining 36 percent. The federal government comes relatively
components follows. close to the corporate marker, at 11.6 percent, or
9 percent fewer managers, but state governments, at
8.8 percent, have 31 percent fewer managers than
Hierarchy and Government the private sector, and local governments, with just
Our first half of bureaucracy is hierarchy. 6.3 percent of their management, professional, and
related employees who are managers, amounts to a
High on the Hierarchic Hog Governments live striking difference of 50 percent.198
high on the hierarchic hog. Two-fifths of federal
employees at all ranks say that, in their agencies, Hierarchy and Effective Government How much
there are “too many layers of supervisors and man- hierarchy is too much?
agers” between them and top management, com- Anthony Downs’s famous law of hierarchy con-
pared to less than a fourth each of business190 and tends that the taller (i.e., the more hierarchical layers)
nonprofit employees191 who say this. and more complex the hierarchy, the more effort and
In contrast to corporate hierarchies, which are expense that are required for “internal” administra-
dramatically flattening (over seventeen years, man- tion to the detriment of “external” achievement.199
agerial levels between division heads and the CEO In the public sector, hierarchy can both under-
declined by a fourth),192 the public hierarchy, at least mine and improve organizational effectiveness. For
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 97

example, more hierarchy in schools correlates with almost entirely by external sources, such as special
lower academic performance by pupils,200 but also interests and legislatures.207
with better attendance and lower dropout rates.201
In fact, the extent of hierarchy “is not related” to Reams of Reports A basic building block of red
governmental failures. Instead, “the only consistent tape is reports. Congress first required that an
results” of empirical investigations are that public agency (the Mint) write an annual report in 1792,
organizational failures correlate with a large number but today that steadily-expanding number is 4,238
of goals and a high level of difficulty involved in annual reports208 from 466 agencies and nonprofit
achieving those goals,202 a relationship that also is organizations, ranging from the state of the asso-
common in other sectors. ciation of veterans of the Spanish-American War
Where hierarchy contributes most to public (two reports per year, actually, even though the last
organizational effectiveness is in those agencies that veteran died in 1992) to dog- and cat-fur protec-
are playing defense. Greater hierarchy associates tion (involving “at least 15 employees in at least
with centralized decision making, which, in turn, six different offices”). The estimated annual cost
“works best” in defending the organization against of these reports is $163 million. Many go unread
external threats. Lesser hierarchy correlates with by congressional members and staffers (one staffer
decentralized decision making, which works best stated, “We used them as doorstops. Literally. The
when agencies are prospecting for new opportunities thicker ones, we used them as doorstops”), and a
in their environments.203 few bright bureaucrats have quietly stopped sending
them; no one in Congress has noticed. Nevertheless,
Goldilocks Hierarchy All that said, however, if these reports stick around; one analysis concluded
we use organizational size as an indicator of hier- that only about 6 percent could be usefully aban-
archy, we find that Downs’s law accrues signifi- doned,209 although Congress has identified only
cant support. An analysis of ninety-seven federal six-tenths of 1 percent that could be eliminated or
agencies concluded that large size, as measured by consolidated.210
personnel and budgets, correlates positively with
lower goal achievement. So does small size, at least Rules Rule As we explained in Chapter 1, a
when  measured by only the number of employ- bureaucracy’s rules can have the same or larger
ees.  In these cases, effectiveness increases with social impact as a legislature’s laws. Here, however,
employee growth  until an “optimal, ‘Goldilocks’ we concentrate on the centrality of rules in red tape.
organizational size—not too small, not too big, The amount of government rules more than
but  just right’’ is attained. Should the agency’s doubles every decade because “the stock of rules
workers continue to expand, however, the effective- expands due to a powerful internal dynamic: that is,
ness of  both  individual  employees and the agency rules breed rules.”211
fades.204 Washington publishes from 2,500 to 4,500 new
The same indicator may be present in state gov- regulations per year, ranging from the routine to the
ernments; larger state governments have more inci- profound.212 More than seven out of every ten laws
dents of corruption (as measured by the proportions enacted by Congress spawn rules written in agen-
of public officials convicted for graft) than smaller cies that are meant to “clarify the policy sketched in
ones.205 legislation.”213 These and other rules add up; there
are sixteen federal regulations, on average, for every
law.214 These regulations are rarely brief; the annual
Red Tape and Government compendium of federal rules, The Federal Register,
Bureaucracy’s other half is red tape. typically tops 80,000 pages.215
Smaller governments are not immune. Michi-
Ribbons of Red Tape Public organizations are gan’s government has some 17,100 rules.216 There
wrapped in more red tape than are private and are sixty-four separate sources of law governing
nonprofit ones (the independent sector has the least New York City’s public schools, including 850 pages
red tape206)—ribbons more—that are spooled out of state law, another 720 pages of state regulations,
98 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

15,000 formal decisions by the state commissioner red tape constrains public employees from helping
of education, hundreds of pages of collective bar- them.223
gaining agreements, thousands of pages of federal
law affecting schools, and more thousands of Perceptions of Red Tape and Public Worker
pages of regulations promulgated by the schools’ Productivity For at least a generation, and
chancellor.217 longer,224 public employees have been far more
convinced (and, as noted earlier, accurately so225)
The Riddle of Red Tape What do we actually know than their private-sector counterparts that their
about red tape (i.e., reports, rules, procedures, etc.) organizations ensnare them in greater tangles
and efficient governance? Not much. Although red of red tape.226 But even when public managers
tape is almost universally blamed for public admin- and private consultants are working together on
istration’s inefficiencies, a “purported relationship the same  project, “government managers per-
[that] is central to public management theory and ceive higher levels of organizational red tape and
practice” (a third of top state administrators, for contracting red tape than their  consultants.”227
example, cite “less red tape” as a primary reason for Similarly, red tape  affects the job involvement of
privatizing some of their programs218), there is, in nonprofit managers much less  negatively than it
fact, a “dearth of research on the red tape-perfor- affects that of their government counterparts,228
mance hypothesis.”219 and nonprofit employees are less likely than public
workers to think that red tape renders their tasks
Red Tape’s Known Negatives Here is what we more complicated.229
know about red tape and its negative, or potentially This is not good for public employee produc-
negative, impact on governance. tivity. Government managers who perceive higher
levels of red tape believe that they are stressed,230
Red Tape and Bigger Bureaucracies Red tape and that their performance is inadequately recog-
births more bureaucrats. Legislative rulemaking in nized.231 These managers are: less engaged in their
general introduces more “actors . . . to the [policy] jobs;232 more risk aversive;233 more dissatisfied with
implementation process.”220 When Washington their jobs;234 and display greater alienation—red
imposes more regulations on the intergovernmen- tape “is a consistently negative and statistically sig-
tal grants system, school districts respond by hiring nificant influence in all alienation models.”235
more administrators.221 Public administrators who perceive a lot of red
tape have narrow frames of reference,236 and work
Red Tape, Communication, and Public Performance in highly unionized governments.237 (Public union
Red tape can affect “task-oriented communica- members who are highly committed to union values,
tion” in agencies to the point that it raises or lowers however, see less red tape in their agencies relative
agency performance. In agencies with “an average to those with lower commitment.238) Those manag-
level of rule orientation,” these directives increase ers who report less red tape have “broader frames
“the likelihood of excellent performance” by a fifth, of reference” and “richer career experiences” than
but, in those with higher-than-average rule orienta- those who perceive more,239 and work in govern-
tions, “even excellent communication is linked to ments that have introduced significant personnel
decreases in performance.”222 reforms.240

Red Tape and Client Fairness Internal red tape, Red Tape and Efficiency The reality is that red
or the kind that restricts public employees but not tape sometimes causes inefficiencies, but often it does
agency clients, “surprisingly . . . does have a substan- not, and sometimes it can increase efficiency. To gain
tial impact on equity.” This type of red tape “inflicts an idea of red tape’s role in the efficiency of one’s
considerable damage” on the fairness with which own organization, one should scan the following
agency clients are treated, possibly because red tape areas: red tape’s functionality, or dysfunctionality,
penalizes those clients who are “less able to under- in achieving goals; whether its compliance burden
stand and overcome” complicated rules, and internal is heavy or light; and how employees experience red
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 99

tape in their own jobs.241 What we know about red Internally, a body of rules “radically reduces the
tape’s role in efficiency follows. number of decisions” that an executive “must make
without sacrificing centralized coordination,”248 a
Red Tape’s Negligible Effect on Productivity In condition that almost defines efficiency.
what may be the most detailed examination of “the Externally, rules help an organization to
red tape myth” to date, it was determined that red “increasingly respond to environmental challenges
tape’s supposedly negative impact on public per- in a programmed way.” Over time, a bureaucracy’s
formance is “somewhat weaker and less pervasive rules expand “with decreasing increments” because
than public management theory and conventional a corpus of intelligent rules has boosted organiza-
wisdom suggest. . .. [It] does not have any salient tional efficiency by adapting organizational proce-
effects on efficiency [and] does not seem to have any dures to patterns of environmental pressures.249
appreciable impact on customer satisfaction” with There is, however, more at stake than efficiency.
agency services.242 The “bureaucratization of the nation-state has
More specifically, at least in the views of public wrought a fundamental transformation whereby
employees, “not all forms of red tape are equally rules themselves have become the primary means
important from a performance perspective.” The through which social change is accomplished.”250
presence of red tape in information systems does Rigid rules and inflexible procedures help assure
associate negatively with the “perceived effective- that bureaucrats and citizens alike are treated fairly,
ness” of those systems, but red tape is “borderline impartially, and equally. In a word, red tape can
insignificant” in human resources and its perceived provide justice, an idea that is central to democratic
effects on procurement and budgeting are “not sta- government.
tistically significant.”243

Green Tape Rules need not be “red tape” in the sense You Can Lead a Bureaucracy to Slaughter
that they foment negativity among public adminis- but You Can’t Make It Shrink
trators. Rules can be green tape, or well-formulated Can governments be made less bureaucratic? Not
regulations that facilitate “higher rule abidance” really: public organizations “are imprisoned” by the
and, thereby, greater agency efficiency. “Compliance environments that they inhabit.251
with rules . . . can be an essential element of both a Their imprisonment is a consequence of their
project’s success and its accountability.”244 Written operating, by necessity and definition, in non-market
(not spoken) rules that are not overly controlling, environments, a condition that deprives them of a
whose purposes are understood by stakeholders, and simple, accurate measure of their organizational
which clearly work effectively, “significantly corre- success: making money. Making money, by contrast,
late” with green tape. Consistency in applying rules, is the universal measure of efficiency and effective-
oddly, seems not to matter.245 ness for businesses (in the form of profits) and non-
profit organizations (if not “profits,” technically,
Goldilocks Rules As green tape implies, just as then at least balancing the books).
there is “Goldilocks hierarchy,” noted earlier, there Public agencies thus “are caught in a complex
also seem to be Goldilocks rules. The most effective of external relationships and to cope they develop
rules, in other words, are neither overly vague nor high levels of internal control.”252 These controls, of
overly prescriptive, in that those “moderate” rules course, are hierarchy and red tape, which, in com-
that balance flexibility of implementation with clear bination, clumsily and incompletely substitute for
guidelines are the most effective and productive.246 the straightforward money metric that is denied to
In fact, when rules violate either of these poles, the governments. Hierarchy and red tape control spend-
possibility of public corruption is enhanced.247 ing, coordinate activities, and work to assure the fair
treatment of clients and employees.
Red Tape and Longer-Term Efficiencies Where red There is little that can be done to change this
tape may have its most positive effect is by inducing fact of public organizational life. “The confluence
longer-term organizational efficiencies. of top-down and bottom-up pressures” emanating
100 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

from the public organization’s environment renders difficulty—perhaps the major difficulty—often
“simple hierarchy . . . the only possibility for public encountered by nonprofits seeking change.259
agencies,” and their “organizational survival is
increasingly based on conformity to externally
imposed rules. . .. External agents . . . cannot them- The Cesspool Syndrome: How Independent
selves remove the conditions that favor tall hierar- Organizations Die
chies and elaborate systems of rules.”253 So, even Due largely to the whimsies of external forces, non-
if those “external agents,” such as elected officials, profit organizations are more likely to “die” than
slash the resources of public agencies, their hierar- are public agencies. This is especially true if the
chies and red tape still persist undiminished. organization is young (at least 17 percent of new
“You can lead a bureaucracy to slaughter but American nonprofits disappear within ten years260),
you can’t make it shrink.”254 small, and located in an area where the popula-
tion is not growing.261 Mission can play a part,
too. “Corporations engage in espionage against
Administrative Autonomy and the nonprofits [or at least those with missions, such as
Performance of Public Organizations consumer rights, that they disapprove of] with near
Our final point about the power of the public impunity.”262
organization’s environment is that, because the How does the independent organization deal
environment constrains the autonomy of public with these environmental pressures? Here is how a
organizations more than private and nonprofit ones, college library dealt with them.
it weakens their performance. National surveys of The library summoned fourteen sequen-
local public works directors, for example, consist- tial strategies to cope, including: queuing at peak
ently find that working in a “political environment” periods (e.g., keeping library patrons in waiting
is the primary set of “impediments to effective man- rooms “outside” the organization); setting priorities
agement.”255 By contrast, when public organizations within the queue; eliminating the lowest priorities;
are granted greater independence, at least up to a expediting the most frequent requests; encouraging
point, they perform better. entrepreneurs to provide services for several librar-
Empirical investigations almost uniformly ies at lower cost; creating branch facilities; creat-
draw this conclusion. We cite three out of many. ing  a mobile reserve (such as teams of personnel
Citizen advisory boards are more effective in transferable to units as needed); developing spe-
meeting their goals when they have a higher “degree cific performance standards; reducing those stand-
of independence” from external actors.256 “The ards soon  thereafter; brainstorming for a “magic
best” public  school districts out of 534 of them formula”; promoting self-service (for example,
“are affected by far fewer forces in their environ- letting patrons into the stacks, an uncommon
ments.”257 And if “poor performers” among two practice at the time—librarians themselves would
dozen nuclear power plants, which are under close retrieve requested volumes), which is a radical strat-
regulatory scrutiny, “are given more autonomy, this egy because it represents a deliberate reduction of
analysis suggests, their safety record is likely to organizational sovereignty; “escaping” by permit-
improve.”258 ting a takeover or accepting mass resignations;
limiting work to capacity as determined by rigid
rules, the denial of error, and the refusal of chal-
THE IMPACT OF THE lenge; and, ultimately, salvaging component units,
ENVIRONMENT ON THE which is the equivalent of death for larger nonprofit
organizations.263
INDEPENDENT ORGANIZATION The library, in a very real sense, had no choice
Organizations in the independent sector also but to play out this scenario. Unlike the Defense
are highly influenced by their external environ- Department, it could not rely on legislative largesse,
ments. Resistance to internal change by stakehold- and, unlike International Widget, it could not control
ers outside a nonprofit, for example, is a major environmental demands by simply hiking prices.
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 101

Nonprofit organizations often respond to a debt level that is higher than those of similar
increasing environmental stress in the way our organizations (a higher debt causes donors to with-
hapless library did—that is, by becoming more neg- draw).271
ative, rigid, and irrational. When small, independent Those charities that act on the principle that
colleges “moved from moderate to severe decline,” charity begins at home, prosper. A 1 percent increase
decision making centralized, planning atrophied, in their fundraising budgets results in a 1.36 percent
inflexibility hardened, the “college’s climate” polit- increase in contributions.272 If, however, a nonprofit’s
icized, and “special-interest group activity” accel- funds are perceived as excessive, then future dona-
erated.264 This is “the cesspool syndrome.” As the tions take a hit.273
organization accommodates decline, “dreck,” rather A nonprofit’s subunits’ propensity to share
than “cream” (which can and does depart), rises to information and cooperate with one another also
top, thereby furthering more decline.265 can defend against decline; “the trigger of decline,”
in fact, often forces these behaviors, which, in turn,
reverse decline.274
Defying Death in the Independent Sector
How do nonprofit organizations avert dying? Externally Averting Decline “The most impor-
tant consideration in order to avoid organizational
Characteristics of Successful Third-Sector death” in the independent sector is to vigorously
Organizations Size and mission matter. engage in “extroverted activities, which enhance an
Nonprofit organizations that are larger and organization’s visibility and embeddedness in the
which have larger boards of directors receive, rel- local community.” These activities include devel-
ative to their smaller counterparts, more donations oping “broad external ties” with governments,
from all sources.266 Organizational size makes no donors, and others in order to “avoid social closure
difference in the ability of nonprofits to adaptively and ensure access to resources.”275 Nonprofits that
innovate (an obviously important component of diversify and reach out to their environments enjoy a
survival and success), with one significant excep- faster rate of organizational growth than those that
tion: the bigger the board, the greater the number of do not, although those that are more reliant on fees
organizational innovations in all areas.267 and sales are partial exceptions.276
Mission matters. In general, donors favor those This sort of inter-organizational cooperation
organizations that focus on art and culture, and are in a hostile environment also is attainable in public
statistically less enthusiastic about those with mis- organizations, where “inevitable” conflict among
sions involving law, public advocacy, and health similarly charged agencies can be supplanted by pro-
and human services.268 “High net worth” donors, ductive cooperation,277 but it is essentially unobtain-
however, give most frequently to nonprofits that able to private firms.278
focus on “basic human needs,” followed by missions
involving religion, health, and youth and family ser-
vices, respectively. The “number one reason” why NOTES
these wealthy donors give to a nonprofit, identified
1. Stafford Beer, “Managing Modern Complexity,”
by 54 percent of them, is its mission.269
The Management of Information and Knowledge.
Panel on Science and Technology (11th meeting).
Internally Averting Decline Those independent Proceedings before the Committee on Science
organizations that are most able to stave off envi- and Astronautics. U.S. House of Representatives,
ronmental threats and to thrive are more likely 91st Congress, Second Session, January 27, 1970,
to: establish stable organizational hierarchies; No. 15 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
assign  explicit responsibilities for each employee; Printing Office, 1970), pp. 41–62. The quotation
affiliate their organizations with larger and similar is on p. 43.
enterprises; recruit “a high percentage of higher 2. Bree Nordenson, “Overload! Journalism’s
functionaries among board members”; assure diver- Battle for Relevance in an Age of Too Much
sity among supporters and members;270 and avoid Information,” Columbia Journalism Review
102 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

(November/December 2008), http://www.cjr.org/ (March/April 1994), pp. 193–196. The quotations


magazine/novemberdecember08.php. are on p. 195.
3. James G. March and Herbert A. Simon, Organi- 20. Grant Thornton and Professional Services
zations (New York: John Wiley, 1958), p. 165. Council, 2015 Federal CIO and CISO Survey:
4. James Risen, “Ex-Inspector Says CIA Missed Expanding the Role of the CIO (Alexandria and
Disarray in Iraqi Arms Program,” New York Arlington, VA: Author, 2015), p. 14.
Times (January 26, 2004). 21. Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior: A
5. Samir Khairi Tawfik, as quoted in Jon Lee Study of Decision-Making Processes in Admini-
Anderson, “Saddam’s Ear,” The New Yorker (May stration Organizations, 3rd ed. (New York: Free
5, 2003), p. 68. Press, 1958), pp. 48–52.
6. Jamie Gorelick, as quoted in Joel Achenbach, 22. Gjalt de Graaf and Zeger van der Wal, “On Value
“What Does a President Really Do All Day?” Differences Experienced by Sector Switchers,”
Washington Post (April 27, 2008). Administration & Society 40 (March 2008),
7. Moyzisch, however, had the last word, and his pp. 79–103. The quotation is on p. 79.
revenge, by writing after the war a book detail- 23. Jennifer A. Chatman, “Matching People and
ing the episode: L. C. Moyzich, Operation Cicero Organizations: Selection and Socialization in
(New York: Coward-McCann, 1950). In 1952, his Public Accounting Firms,” Administrative Science
book was made into an Oscar-nominated movie, Quarterly 26 (September 1991), pp. 459–484.
5 Fingers. Moyzich, somewhat appropriately, was 24. Simon, Administrative Behavior.
played by Peter Lorre. 25. George Miller, “The Magic Number Seven, Plus
8. U.S. Office of the Inspector General, Central or Minus Two,” Psychological Review 63 (March
Intelligence Agency, OIG Report on CIA 1956), pp. 81–97.
Accountability with respect to the 9/11 Attacks 26. Suzanne Langer, Mind: An Essay on Feeling (Balti-
(Washington, DC: Author, June 2005), pp. xiii–xiv. more: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1988).
9. Gordon Tullock, The Politics of Bureaucracy 27. John S. Hammond, III, Ralph L. Keeney, and
(Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press, 1965), Howard Raiffa, “The Hidden Traps in Decis-
pp. 137–141. ion Making,” Harvard Business Review 76
10. Dana Priest and William M. Arkin, “A Hidden (September/October 1998), pp. 47–58.
World, Growing Beyond Control,” Washington 28. Vykinta Kigyte, Shane Connelly, Chase Thiel, and
Post (July 19, 2010). Data are for 2010. Lynn Davenport, “The Influence of Anger, Fear,
11. See, for example, Friedrich Hayek, “The Use of and Emotion Regulation on Ethical Decision
Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Making,” Human Performance 25 (4, 2013),
Review 35 (Fall 1945), pp. 519–530. pp. 297–326.
12. Martha S. Feldman and James G. March, 29. Antoine Bechara, “The Role of Emotion in
“Information in Organizations as Signal and Decision-Making: Evidence from Neurological
Symbol,” Administrative Science Quarterly 26 Patients with Orbitofrontal Damage,” Brain and
(June 1981), pp. 171–186. The quotation is on Cognition 55 (1, 2004), pp. 30–40.
p. 182. 30. Langer, Mind.
13. Hemphill and Associates, as cited in “Data Data,” 31. Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, “Choices,
Inc. Magazine (January 1999), p. 70. Values, Frames,” American Psychologist 39 (June
14. Pitney Bowes, Workplace Communications in the 1984), pp. 341–350.
21st Century, as cited in ibid. 32. James Brown and Zi-Lei Qiu, “Satisficing When
15. Reuters Business Information Survey, as cited in Buying Information,” Organizational Behavior
ibid. and Human Decision Processes 51 (June 1992),
16. Feldman and March, “Information in Organi- pp. 471–482.
zations as Signal and Symbol.” 33. Kahneman and Tversky, “Choices, Values, Frames.”
17. Ibid., p. 178. 34. Robert Frank, “Shrewdly Irrational,” Sociological
18. Ibid., p. 183. Forum 2 (September 1987), pp. 21–41.
19. E. Sam Overman and Donna T. Lorraine, 35. Keith E. Stanovich, What Intelligence Tests Miss:
“Information for Control: Another Management The Psychology of Rational Thought (New Haven,
Proverb?” Public Administration Review 54 CN: Yale University Press, 2009), pp. 66, 2.
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 103

36. Simon, Administrative Behavior. Arthur Tuden,“Strategies, Structures, and Processes


37. Irving Janis, Victims of Groupthink (Boston: of Organizational Decision,”  Comparative Studies
Houghton-Mifflin, 1972), p. 13. in Administration, James D. Thompson, Peter
38. Commission on the Intelligence Capabilities of B.  Hammond, Robert W. Hawkes, et al., eds.
the United States Regarding Weapons of Mass (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1959),
Destruction, Report to the President of the pp. 195–216.
United States (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 51. Melissa M. Stone, Barbara Bigelow, and William
Printing Office, 2005), p. 10. Crittenden, “Research on Strategic Management
39. Select Committee on Intelligence, United States in Nonprofit Organizations: Synthesis, Analysis,
Senate, 109th Congress, Report on Postwar Find- and Future Directions,” Administration & Society
ings About Iraq’s WMD Programs and Links to 31 (July 1999), pp. 378–423.
Terrorism and How They Compare with Prewar 52. Paul C. Nutt, “Making Strategic Choices,” Journal
Assessments, together with Additional Views of Management Studies 39 (January 2002),
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing pp. 57–96. The quotation is on p. 67.
Office, 2006), pp. 5–6. 53. Michael Cohen, James G. March, and Johan
40. Commission on the Intelligence Capabilities of Olsen, “A Garbage Can Model of Organizational
the United States Regarding Weapons of Mass Choice,” Administrative Science Quarterly 17
Destruction, Report to the President of the United (March 1972), pp. 1–25.
States, p. 10. 54. Ibid., pp. 1–2.
41. Bob Woodward, “10 Take Aways From the Bush 55. Unless noted otherwise, this discussion is based
Years,” Washington Post (January 18, 2009). on Paul C. Nutt, “Tactics of Implementation,”
42. Irving L. Janis, Groupthink (Boston: Houghton Academy of Management Journal 29 (July 1986),
Mifflin, 1982). pp. 230–261, and Nutt’s “Leverage, Resistance,
43. Steve Kelman, Ronald Sanders, Sarah Taylor, and  the  Success of Implementation Approaches,”
and Gayatri Pandit, “I Won’t Back Down”?: Journal of Management Studies 35 (March
Complexity and Courage in U.S. Federal Executive 1998), pp. 213–240. We are citing in the text only
Decision-Making (Cambridge, MA: Harvard Ash percentages that are drawn from the larger and
Center, 2014), pp. 12–13. more recent study (376 decisions), but the per-
44. Kathleen M. Eisenhardt, “Making Fast Strategic centages from the earlier study (ninety-one) are
Decisions in High-Velocity Environments,” comparable.
Academy of Management Journal 32 (September 56. Peter C. Gronn, “Talk as Work: The Accomplishment
1989), pp. 543–576. of School Administration,” Administrative Science
45. Kelman, Sanders, Taylor, and Pandit, “I Won’t Quarterly 28 (March 1983), pp. 1–21.
Back Down”?, p. 12. 57. Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge:
46. Robert H. Ennis, Critical Thinking (Upper Saddle Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and
River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1996). Happiness (New York: Penguin, 2009).
47. Lee Ross, Mark R. Lepper, and Michael Hubbard, 58. Sandford Borins, “Loose Cannons and Rule
“Perseverance in Self-perception and Social Breakers, or Enterprising Leaders? Some Evidence
Perception: Biased Attributional Processes in the about Innovative Public Managers,” Public
Debriefing Paradigm,” Journal of Personality and Administration Review 60 (November/December
Social Psychology 32 (5, 1975), pp. 880–891. The 2000), pp. 498–507.
quotation is on p. 880. 59. Nutt, “Tactics of Implementation,” and Nutt,
48. Valerie F. Reyna, Christina F. Chick, Jonathan “Leverage, Resistance, and the Success of
C. Corbin, and Andrew N. Hsia, “Developmental Implementation Approaches.”
Reversal in Risky Decision Making: Intelligence 60. David J. Hickson, Richard. J. Butler, David Cray,
Agents Show Larger Decision Biases than College et al., Top Decisions: Strategic Decision Making
Students,” Psychological Science 25 (January in Organizations (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass,
2014), pp. 76–84. 1986).
49. Kelman, Sanders, Taylor, and Pandit, “I Won’t 61. James L. Perry, Debra Mesch, and Laurie
Back Down”?, pp. 5, 8, 9, 11. Paarlberg, “Motivating Employees in a New
50. Table 4-1 is partly based on James D. Thompson and Governance Era: The Performance Paradigm
104 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

Revisited,” Public Administration Review 66 Organizations,” Management Science 36 (January


(July/August 2006), pp. 505–514. 1990), pp. 436–448.
62. Nutt, “Leverage, Resistance, and the Success of 77. Thomas R. Davies, “The Inside Story,” Governing
Implementation Approaches,” pp. 222, 232. (December 2003), p. 64.
63. Borins, “Loose Cannons and Rule Breakers, or 78. Robert T. Golembiewski, Humanizing Public
Enterprising Leaders?” p. 505. Organizations (Mt. Airy, MD: Lomond, 1985).
64. Kent D. Peterson, “Mechanisms of Administrative 79. Myung Jae Moon, “The Pursuit of Managerial
Control over Managers in Educational Innovation: Does Organization Matter?” Public
Organizations,” Administrative Science Quarterly Administration Review 59 (January/February
29 (December 1984), pp. 576–581. 1999), pp. 31–43.
65. Daniel Benjamin, “The Decider Who Can’t Make 80. Paul J. Yakoboski and Joshua M. Franzel, 2014
Up His Mind,” Washington Post (July 6, 2008). Retirement Confidence Survey of the State and
66. Gordon Kingsley and Pamela Norton Reed, Local Government Workforce (Washington,
“Decision Process Models and Organizational DC: TIAA-CREF Institute and Center for
Context: Level and Sector Make a Difference,” Governmental Excellence, 2014), p. 5.
Public Productivity & Management Review 14 81. Barry Bozeman and Gordon Kingsley, “Risk
(Summer 1991), pp. 397–413. The quotation is Culture in Public and Private Organizations,”
on p. 409. Public Administration Review 58 (March/April
67. Meg Bostrom, By, or for, the People? A Meta- 1998), pp. 109–118.
analysis of Public Opinion of Government (New 82. John M. Bryson and Sharon R. Anderson, “Ap-
York: Demos, 2006), p. 24. Figures, 61 and 59 plying Large-Group Interaction Methods in the
percent, respectively, are for 1999. Planning and Implementation of Major Change
68. Peterson, “Mechanisms of Administrative Control Efforts,” Public Administration Review 60 (March/
over Managers in Educational Organizations,” April 2000), pp. 143–162.
p. 595. 83. David Coursey and Barry Bozeman, “Decision
69. National Research Center, as cited in Mike Making in Public and Private Organizations:
Maciag, “Speaking Up,” Governing (July 2014), A Test of Alternative Concepts of ‘Publicness’,”
pp. 56–57. Figures are for 2012–2014. Public Administration Review 50 (September/
70. Cole D. Taratoot and David C. Nixon, “With October 1990), p. 525.
Strings Attached: Statutory Delegations of 84. Hickson, Butler, Cray, et al., Top Decisions.
Authority to the Executive Branch,” Public 85. Nutt, “Comparing Public and Private Sector
Administration Review 71 (July/August 2011), Decision-Making Practices,” p. 312.
pp. 637–644. 86. Perry, Mesch, and Paarlberg, “Motivating Emplo-
71. Marianne Antonsen and Torben Beck Jorgensen, yees in a New Governance Era,” p. 509. Emphasis
“The ‘Publicness’ of Public Organizations,” Public is original.
Administration 75 (Summer 1997), pp. 337–357. 87. Nutt, “Comparing Public and Private Sector
72. Lewis C. Mainzer, Political Bureaucracy (Glen- Decision-Making Practices,” p. 312.
view, IL: Scott, Foresman, 1973). 88. Jongkon Lee, “Public Meetings for Efficient Ad-
73. Kingsley and Reed, “Decision Process Models and ministrative Performance in the United States,” Public
Organizational Context,” p. 409. Performance & Management Review 37 (March
74. Paul C. Nutt, “Comparing Public and Private 2014), pp. 388–411. The quotations are on p. 388.
Sector Decision-Making Practices,” Journal of 89. Jeffrey L. Brudney and Deil S. Wright, “The
Public Administration Research and Theory 16 ‘Revolt in Dullsville’ Revisited: Lessons for
(April 2006), pp. 289–318. The quotation is on Theory, Practice, and Research from the American
p. 312. State Administrators Project, 1964–2008,” Public
75. Marianne Antonsen and Torben Beck Jorgensen, Administration Review 70 (January/February
“The ‘Publicness’ of Public Organizations,” Public 2010), pp. 26–37. The quotations are on p. 30.
Administration 75 (Summer 1997), pp. 337–357. Data are for 1984, 1994, 2004.
76. Charles R. Schwenk, “Conflict in Organizational 90. Milena I. Neshkova and Hai (David) Guo, “Public
Decision Making: An Exploratory Study of Participation and Organizational Performance:
Its Effects in For-Profit and Not-for-Profit Evidence from State Agencies,” Journal of
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 105

Public  Administration Research and Theory 22 Assessment of Alternatives for Decision Making,”
(April 2012), pp. 267–288. The quotation is on Journal of Public Administration Research and
p. 267. Theory 9 (April 1999), pp. 305–349.
91. Milena Neshkova,“Does Agency Autonomy Foster 107. Michael L. DeKay, Dalia Patino-Echeverri, and
Public Participation?” Public Administration Paul S. Fischbeck, “Distortion of Probability
Review 74 (January/February 2014), pp. 64–74. and Outcome Information in Risky Decisions,”
92. Kaifeng Yang and Kathe Callahan, “Citizen Organizational Behavior and Human Decision
Involvement Efforts and Bureaucratic  Respon- Processes 109 (May 2009), pp. 78–92.
siveness: Participatory Values, Stakeholder 108. Irving L. Janis and Leon Mann, Decision Making:
Pressures, and Administrative Practicality,” Public A Psychological Analysis of Conflict, Choice,
Administration Review 67 (March/April 2007), and Commitment (New York: Free Press, 1977),
pp. 249–264. The quotation is on p. 257. pp. 46, 85, 51, 74.
93. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity 109. Jack H. Nagel, “Psychological Obstacles to
and Change in the Role of City Managers,” Administrative Responsibility: Lessons of the
Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington, DC: MOVE Disaster,” Journal of Policy Analysis and
International City/County Management Asso- Management 10 (Winter 1991), pp. 1–23. The
ciation, 2010), pp. 10–18. quotations are on pp. 9, 1.
94. Donna Milam Handley and Michael Howell- 110. Schwenk, “Conflict in Organizational Decision
Moroney, “Ordering Stakeholder Relationships Making.”
and Citizen Participation: Evidence from the 111. Nutt, “Public-Private Differences and the
Community Development Block Grant Program,” Assessment of Alternatives for Decision Making.”
Public Administration Review 70 (July/August 112. Schwenk, “Conflict in Organizational Decision
2010), pp. 601–620. Making.”
95. Christopher A. Cooper, H. Gibbs Knotts, and 113. See, for example, Melissa Middleton Stone,
Kathleen M. Brennan, “The Importance of Trust “Competing Contexts: The Evolution of a
in Government for Public Administration: The Nonprofit Organization’s Governance System
Case of Zoning,” Public Administration Review in Multiple Environments,” Administration &
68 (May/June 2008), pp. 459–467. Society 28 (May 1996), pp. 61–89.
96. Nutt, “Comparing Public and Private Sector 114. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit,
Decision-Making Practices,” p. 312. For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors (Princeton,
97. W. Michael Blumenthal, “Candid Reflections of a NJ: Princeton Survey Research Associates 2002),
Businessman in Washington,” Fortune (January p. 3.
29, 1979), pp. 2, 6, 49; Donald Rumsfeld, “A 115. Robert Wright, “The Accidental Creationist,” The
Politician-Turned-Executive Surveys Both Worlds,” New Yorker (December 13, 1999), p. 63.
Fortune (September 10, 1979), pp. 88, 94. 116. James D. Thompson, Organization in Action:
98. Davies, “The Inside Story,” p. 64. Social Science Bases of Administrative Theory
99. Nutt, “Comparing Public and Private Sector (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967), p. 142.
Decision-Making Practices,” p. 313. Emphasis is 117. James G. March, A Primer on Decision Making:
original. How Decisions Happen (New York: Free Press,
100. Ibid., p. 312. 1994), p. 119.
101. Ibid. 118. Simon, Administrative Behavior, pp. 131, 134.
102. Perry, Mesch, and Paarlberg, “Motivating 119. Rosemary O’Leary, The Ethics of Dissent:
Employees in a New Governance Era.” Managing Guerrilla Government (Washington,
103. Marshall W. Meyer, Bureaucratic Structure and DC: CQ Press, 2006).
Authority: Coordination and Control in 254 120. Peter J. May and Soren C. Winter, “Politicians,
Government Agencies (New York: Harper & Managers, and Street-Level Bureaucrats:
Row, 1972). Influences on Policy Implementation,” Journal of
104. Eisenhardt, “Making Fast Strategic Decisions in Public Administration Research and Theory 19
High-Velocity Environments.” (July 2009), pp. 453–476. The quotations are on
105. Janis, Victims of Groupthink. p. 470.
106. Paul C. Nutt, “Public-Private Differences and the 121. Nicole Woolsey Biggart and Gary G. Hamilton,
106 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

“The Power of Obedience,” Administrative Science of  Government (New York: Harper & Row,
Quarterly 29 (December 1984), pp. 540–549. 1971).
The quotation is on p. 548. 133. Elizabeth Kolbert, “Red Light,” The New Yorker
122. Amy Y. Ou, Anne S. Tsui, Angelo J. Kinicki, et al., (January 27, 2014), pp. 19–20.
“Humble Chief Executive Officers’ Connections 134. Henry Mintzberg, The Structure of Organizations
to Top Management Team Integration and Middle (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1979).
Managers’ Responses,” Administrative Science 135. J. Norman Baldwin, “Public Versus Private
Quarterly 59 (March 2014), pp. 34–72. Employees: Debunking Stereotypes,” Review of
123. John R. P. French, Jr. and Bertram Raven, “The Public Personnel Administration 11 (Fall 1990–
Bases of Social Power,” Group Dynamics: Spring 1991), pp. 1–27. The quotations are on
Research and Theory, Dorwin Cartwright and p. 9.
Alvin Zander, eds. (New York: Harper & Row, 136. Moon, “The Pursuit of Managerial Innovation,”
1968), pp. 238–259; Bass, Stodgill’s Handbook of p. 38.
Leadership, Rev. ed.; and Gary A. Yukl, Leadership 137. With exception noted, the following list is based,
in Organizations, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: with some license taken, on U.S. Merit Systems
Prentice-Hall, 1989). French and Raven originated Protection Board, Managing for Engagement:
the five powers of reward, coercion, legitimacy, Communication, Connection, and Courage
reference, and expertise. Later, Bass added cha- (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
risma and Yukl added control over information Office, 2009), pp. 66–74.
and the work environment. 138. Antonsen and Jorgensen, “The ‘Publicness’ of
124. Leanne E. Atwater and Wendy J. Wright, Public Organizations,” pp. 350–351.
“Power and Transformational and Transactional 139. Davies, “The Inside Story,” p. 64.
Leadership in Public and Private Organizations,” 140. Fariborz Damanpour and Shathi Gopalakrishnan,
International Journal of Public Administration 9 “The Dynamics of the Adoption of Product
(June 1996), pp. 963–990. and  Process Innovations in Organizations,”
125. Peterson, “Mechanisms of Administrative Control Journal of Management Studies 38 (January
over Managers in Educational Organizations,” 2001), pp.  45–66. The years covered were
p. 595. 1982–1993.
126. Antonsen and Jorgensen, “The ‘Publicness’ of 141. Jon Aarum Andersen, “Assessing Public Managers’
Public Organizations,” p. 337. Change-Oriented Behavior: Are Private Managers
127. Lyman W. Porter and John Van Maanen, “Task Caught in the Doldrums?” International Journal of
Accomplishment and the Management of Time,” Public Administration 33 (May 2010), pp. 335–345.
Managing for Accomplishment, Bernard Bass, The quotations are on pp. 335, 337, 342, respec-
ed. (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1970), tively; the data are on p. 341.
pp. 180–192. 142. Borins, “Loose Cannons and Rule Breakers, or
128. Alan W. Lau, Cynthia W. Pavett, and Arthur Enterprising Leaders?” p. 500.
R.  Newman, “The Nature of Managerial Work: 143. Anders R. Villadsen, “New Executives from
A Comparison of Public and Private Sector Jobs,” Inside or Outside? The Effect of Executive
Academy of Management Proceedings (August Replacement on Organizational Change,” Public
1980), pp. 339–343. Administration Review 72 (September/October
129. Ibid. 2012), pp. 731–740.
130. Antonsen and Jorgensen, “The ‘Publicness’ of 144. Kuotsai Tom Liou and Ronnie Korosic, “Imple-
Public Organizations,” p. 337. menting Organizational Reform Strategies in State
131. Jay Eungha Ryu, Cynthia J. Bowling, Chung- Governments,” Public Administration Quarterly
Lae Cho, and Deil S. Wright, “Effects of 33 (Fall 2009), pp. 429–452. The quotation is on
Administrators’ Aspirations, Political Principals’ p. 445.
Priorities, and Interest Groups’ Influence on State 145. Borins, “Loose Cannons and Rule Breakers, or
Agency Budget Requests,” Public Budgeting & Enterprising Leaders?” p. 500. Total figures add
Finance 27 (Summer 2007), pp. 22–49. The quo- up to more than 100 percent because some inno-
tation is on p. 43. vations had more than one initiator.
132. John W. Macy, Public Service: The Human Side 146. Charles Perrow, Normal Accidents: Living with
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 107

High-Risk Technologies, 2nd ed. (Princeton, NJ: Agencies Fail to Fulfill Basic FOIA Requests,”
Princeton University Press, 1999), p. 9. Emphasis Govexec.com (April 28, 2015). Figure is for
is original. 2015.
147. Lawrence G. Hrebiniak and William F. Joyce, 158. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Freedom
“Organizational Adaptation: Strategic Choice of Information Act: Litigation Costs for Justice
and Environmental Determinism,” Administrative and Agencies Could Not Be Fully Determined,
Science Quarterly 30 (September 1985), pp. 336– Highlights page.
349. The quotation is on p. 336. 159. Jenni Bergal, “States Train Officials in Public
148. We have changed our mind. In earlier editions Records Access,” Stateline (November 24, 2014).
of this book, we held a different view and dis- 160. Wendy Ginsberg, The Federal Advisory
coursed at length on the academic disputations Committee Act: Analysis of Operations and Costs
involving organizational determinism and choice. (Washington, DC: U.S. Congressional Research
The reader may wish to consult the eighth edition Service, 2015). Figures are for 2004–2014. Final
(2001), pp. 101–105. two meeting figures are for 2014.
149. Herbert Kaufman, Time, Chance, and 161. Thomas Cronin and Norman Thomas, “Federal
Organizations: Natural Selection in a Perilous Advisory Processes: Advice and Discontent,”
Environment Chatham, NJ: Chatham House, Science 171 (February 26, 1971), pp. 771–779.
(1985), p. 69. 162. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
150. Nicholas Bloom, Raffaella Sadun, and John Van Advisory Committee Act: Issues Related to the
Reenen, “Does Management Really Work?” Independence and Balance of Advisory Com-
Harvard Business Review 90 (November 2012), mittees, GAO-08-611T (Washington, DC: U.S.
pp. 77–80, 82, 148. Government Printing Office, 2008), Highlights
151. Paul C. Nutt, “Prompting the Transformation of page.
Public Organizations,” Public Performance & 163. Anthony J. Nownes, Clive S. Thomas, and Ronald
Management Review 27 (June 2004), pp. 9–33. J. Hrebenar, “Interest Groups in the States,”
The quotations are on pp. 27, 25, 30. Emphasis Politics in the American States: A Comparative
added. Analysis, 9th ed., Virginia Gray and Russell L.
152. As derived from data in Freedom of Information Hanson, eds. (Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2008),
Center, University of Missouri, State FOI Laws pp. 98–126. Figure (p. 107) is for Ohio and West
(Columbia, MO: Author, 2008), http://www. Virginia.
nfoic.org/foi-center/state-foi-laws.html. 164. Michael Asimow, “On Pressing McNollgast to the
153. U.S. Department of Justice, Summary of Fiscal Limits: The Problem of Regulatory Costs,” Law
Year 2015 Annual FOIA Reports Published and Contemporary Problems 57 (Winter 1994),
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing pp. 127–137. The quotation is on p. 129.
Office, 2016). 165. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
154. As derived from data in U.S. Government Rulemaking: Improvements Needed to Monitoring
Accountability Office, Freedom of Information and Evaluation of Rules Development as Well as
Act: Processing Trends Show Importance of to the Transparency of OMB Regulatory Reviews,
Improvement Plans, GAO 07-491T (Washington, GAO-09-205 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2007), Printing Office, 2009), Highlights page.
pp. 6, 28. 166. Jason Webb Yackee and Susan Webb Yackee,
155. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Freedom “Administrative Procedures and Bureaucratic Per-
of Information Act: Litigation Costs for Justice formance: Is Federal Agency Rule-making ‘Ossi-
and Agencies Could Not Be Fully Determined, fied’?” Journal of Public Administration Research
GAO-16-667 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government and Theory 20 (April 2010), pp. 261–282.
Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. Figure 167. As derived from data (p. 117) in Susan Webb
is for 2006–2015. Yackee, “Sweet-Talking the Fourth Branch:
156. Sean McCalley, “Agencies: Record-setting FOIA The Influence of Interest Group Comments on
Backlog Out of Control,” Federalnewsradio.com Federal Agency Rulemaking,” Journal of Public
(May 8, 2015). Administration Research and Theory 16 (January
157. Katherine McIntire Peters, “Two-Thirds of 2006), pp. 103–124.
108 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

168. Cornelius M. Kerwin, Rulemaking: How Govern- American Journal of Political Science 46 (July
ment Agencies Write Law and Make Policy, 3rd ed. 2003), pp. 490–505. A total of 450 new drugs
(Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2003), p. 205. were reviewed, 1977–2000.
169. Jason Webb Yackee and Susan Webb Yackee, “A 180. A. Cooper Drury, Richard Stuart Olson, and
Bias Towards Business? Assessing Interest Group Douglas A. Van Belle, “The Politics of Human-
Influence on the U.S. Bureaucracy,” Journal of itarian Aid: U.S. Foreign Disaster Assistance,
Politics 68 (February 2006), pp. 128–139. The 1964–1995,” Journal of Politics 67 (May 2005),
quotation is on p. 129. pp. 454–473. A total of 2,337 disasters were
170. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal reviewed.
Rulemaking: Agencies Could Take Additional 181. Matthew Holden, Jr., Continuity and Disruption:
Steps to Respond to Public Comments, GAO-13- Essays in Public Administration (Pittsburgh:
21 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing University of Pittsburgh Press, 1996), p. 58.
Office, 2012), Highlights page. 182. Bradley E. Wright and Sanjay K. Pandey,
171. Nownes, Thomas, and Hrebenar, “Interest Groups “Transformational Leadership in the Public
in the States,” p. 107. Sector: Does Structure Matter?” Journal of Public
172. Neal D. Woods, “Promoting Participation? An Administration Research and Theory 20 (January
Examination of Rulemaking Notification and 2010), pp. 75–89. The quotation is on p. 84.
Access Procedures,” Public Administration Review 183. Mark A. Abramson, Steven A. Clyburn, and
69 (May/June 2006), pp. 518–530. Elizabeth Mercier, Results of the Government
173. Christine A. Kelleher and Susan Webb Yackee, Leadership Survey: A 1999 Survey of
“Who’s Whispering in Your Ear? The Influence Federal Executives (Washington, DC: The
of Third Parties Over State Agency Decisions,” PricewaterhouseCoopers Endowment for the
Political Research Quarterly 59 (December 2006), Business of Government, 1999), pp. 8–9.
pp. 629–643. The quotation is on p. 629. 184. Kaita Karath, “Yet Another Thing Driving Species
174. Dennis O. Grady and Kathleen M. Simon, “Political to Extinction: U.S Government Bureaucracy,”
Constraints and Bureaucratic Discretion: The Case Govexec.com (August 29, 2016).
of State Government Rule Making,” Politics & 185. Tom Brokaw witnessed and recounted this inci-
Policy 30 (December 2002), pp. 650–655. Data dent on “Morning Joe,” CSNBC Cable Television
are for 1997. (November 24, 2010).
175. Paul Teske, Regulation in the States (Washington, 186. Hilton Hotels, Inc., Wake Up! 1 in 3 of Your
DC: Brookings, 2004), p. 195. We are extrapolat- Meeting Attendees Are Falling Asleep (New York:
ing somewhat liberally from Teske’s findings, who Author, 2016).
notes that interest groups are “significantly influ- 187. Strategic Services (Provisional), Simple Sabotage
ential in eight of the ten cases” that he analyzes in Field Manual (Washington, DC: Author, 1944).
his book. These cases are quantitative analyses of 188. Donald P. Warwick, with Marvin Meade and
ten policy areas in all the states. Theodore Reed, A Theory of Public Bureaucracy:
176. Christopher Jewell and Lisa Bero, “Public Parti- Politics, Personality, and Organization in the
cipation and Claimsmaking: Evidence Utilization State Department (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
and Divergent Policy Frames in California’s University Press, 1975), p. 114.
Ergonomics Rulemaking,” Journal of Public 189. Meier and O’Toole, Bureaucracy in a Democratic
Administration Research and Theory 17 (October State, p. 62.
2007), pp. 625–650. 190. Brookings Institution, Health of the Public
177. Thomas A. Garrett and Russell Sobel, “The Service (Princeton, NJ: Princeton Survey Research
Political Economy of FEMA Disaster Payments,” Associates, 2001), http://www.brook.edu. Figures
Economic Inquiry 41 (July 2003), pp. 496–509. are for 2001.
178. Marilyn Young, William F. Shugart, II, and 191. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit,
Michael Reksulak, “The Political Economy of For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors, p. 14.
the IRS,” Economics & Politics 13 (July 2001), Figure is for 2001.
pp. 201–220. 192. Raghuram Rajan and Julie Wulf, The Flattening
179. Daniel P. Carpenter, “Groups, the Media, Agency Firm: Evidence from Panel Data on the Changing
Waiting Costs, and FDA Drug Approval,” Nature of Corporate Hierarchies, NBER Working
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 109

Paper 9633 (Washington, DC: National Bureau Theory 23 (October 2012), pp. 663–686. The
of Economic Research, 2003). Figure is for quotation is on p. 678.
1986–2003. 205. Rajeev K. Goel and Michael A. Nelson,“Corruption
193. Paul C. Light, People on People on People: and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis,”
Fact Sheet on the Continuing Thickening of Public Choice 97 (October 1998), pp. 107–120.
Government (New York: New York University, Data are for 1983–1987.
2017), p. 1. In 1960, there were seventeen layers. 206. Philip H. Mirvis and Edward J. Hackett, “Work
194. Paul C. Light, Creating High Performance Govern- and Work Force Characteristics in the Nonprofit
ment: A Once-in-a-Generation Opportunity Sector,” Monthly Labor Review 106 (April 1983),
(New York: New York University, 2011), p. 10. pp. 3–12.
Figure is for 1980–1992. 207. Warwick, et al., A Theory of Public Bureaucracy,
195. Light, People on People on People, pp. 1, 3–4. In pp. 72–80, 188–191.
1960, there were seven cabinet departments and 208. Figure is for 2016.
451 senior executives. 209. “Unrequired Reading,” Washington Post (May 3,
196. Light, Creating High Performance Government, 2014). Figures are for 2014.
p. 10. Middle managers figure is for 1980–1992. 210. Congress eliminated fifty-three reports in 2014
Lower-level employees figure is for 1983–2003. and identified another 223 that could be elimi-
197. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems Protect- nated or consolidated in 2016.
ion Board, As Supervisors Retire: An Opportunity 211. Arjen van Witteloostuijn and Gjalt de Jong,
to Reshape Organizations (Washington, DC: U.S. “Ecology of National Rule Birth: A Longitudinal
Government Printing Office, 2009), p. 6. Figures Study of Dutch Higher Education Law, 1960–
are for 1998–2008. 2004,” Journal of Public Administration Research
198. Gerald Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private and Theory 20 (January 2010), pp. 187–213. The
and Public Sector Workers (Washington, DC: U.S. quotation is on p. 207.
Congressional Research Service, 2014), p. 16. 212. Lisa Rein, “Obama Wants Regulations to Be
Figures are for 2013. Effective, but Agencies Are Ignoring His Orders,
199. Anthony Downs, Inside Bureaucracy (Boston: Study Finds,” Washington Post (November 5,
Little, Brown, 1967), pp. 75–78, 262. 2015).
200. John Bohte, “School Bureaucracy and Student 213. Meier and O’Toole, Bureaucracy in a Democratic
Performance at the Local Level,” Public Admini- State, p. 60.
stration Review 61 (January/February 2001), 214. Clyde Wayne Crews, Jr., Ten Thousand
pp. 92–99. Commandments 2015: An Annual Snapshot of
201. Kevin B. Smith and Christopher W. Larimer, “A the Federal Regulatory State (Washington, DC:
Mixed Relationship: Bureaucracy and School Competitive Enterprise Institute, 2016), p. 2.
Performance,” Public Administration Review 64 215. U.S. Office of the Federal Register, Federal
(November/December 2004), pp. 728–736. Register Pages Published Annually (Washington,
202. Kenneth J. Meier and John Bohte, “Not with a DC: Author, 2016).
Bang, but a Whimper: Explaining Organizational 216. Associated Press, “Michigan Announces Net
Failures,” Administration & Society 35 (March Reduction of 2,100 Rules,” Freep.com (November
2003), pp. 104–121. The quotations are on 12, 2015). Figure is for 2015.
p. 104. 217. Diane Ravitch, “Burden of Rules, Regulations Is
203. Rhys Andrews, George A. Boyne, Jennifer Eroding School Discipline,” Savannah Morning
Law, and Richard M. Walker, “Centralization, News (January 3, 2005).
Organizational Strategy, and Public Service 218. Keon S. Chi, Kelley A. Arnold, and Heather M.
Performance,” Journal of Public Administration Perkins, “Privatization in State Government:
Research and Theory 19 (January 2009), pp. Trends and Issues,” Spectrum 76 (Fall 2003),
57–80. The quotation is on p. 57. p. 14. Figure is for 2002.
204. Chan Su Jung, “Navigating a Rough Terrain 219. Gene A. Brewer and Richard M. Walker,
of Management: Examining the Relationship “The Impact of Red Tape on Governmental
between Organizational Size and Effectiveness,” Performance: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of
Journal of Public Administration Research and Public Administration Research and Theory 20
110 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

(January 2010), pp. 233–257. The quotation is on 232. Word and Park, “Working across the Divide: Job
p. 234. Involvement in the Public and Nonprofit Sectors,”
220. Meier and O’Toole, Bureaucracy in a Democratic pp. 103–133. The quotation is on p. 125.
State, p. 62. 233. Bozeman and Kingsley, “Risk Culture in Public
221. John Meyer, W. Richard Scott, and David Strang, and Private Organizations.”
“Centralization, Fragmentation, and School 234. Feeney and Bozeman, “Stakeholder Red Tape,”
District Complexity,” Administrative Science p. 721.
Quarterly 32 (June 1987), pp. 188–201. 235. Leisha DeHart-Davis and Sanjay K. Pandey “Red
222. James L. Garnett, Justin Marlowe, and Sanjay Tape and Public Employees: Does Perceived Rule
K. Pandey, “Penetrating the Performance Dysfunction Alienate Managers? Journal of Public
Predicament: Communication as a Mediator Administration Research and Theory 15 (January
or Moderator of Organizational Culture’s 2005), pp. 133–149.
Impact  on Public Organizational Performance,” 236. Branco L. Ponomariov and P. Craig Boardman,
Public Administration Review 68 (March/April “Organizational Pathology Compared to What?
2008), pp. 266–281. The quotations are on Impacts of Job Characteristics and Career
p. 277. Trajectory on Perceptions of Organizational Red
223. Brewer and Walker, “The Impact of Red Tape Tape,” Public Administration Review 71 (July/
on Governmental Performance,” pp. 233, 248. August 2011), pp. 582–597.
Emphasis is original. 237. Feeney and Rainey, “Personnel Flexibility and
224. Mirvis and Hackett, “Work and Work Force Red Tape in Public and Nonprofit Organizations,”
Characteristics in the Nonprofit Sector.” p. 819.
225. Warwick, et al., A Theory of Public Bureaucracy, 238. Randall Davis, “Union Commitment and
pp. 72–80, 188–191, Stakeholder Red Tape,” Review of Public
226. Moon, “The Pursuit of Managerial Innovation,” Personnel Administration 33 (December 2013),
p. 38. pp. 365–383.
227. Mary K. Feeney and Barry Bozeman, “Stakeholder 239. Ponomariov and Boardman, “Organizational
Red Tape: Comparing Perceptions of Public Pathology Compared to What?” p. 593.
Managers and Their Private Consultants,” 240. Feeney and Bozeman, “Stakeholder Red Tape,”
Public Administration Review 69 (July/August p. 819.
2009),  pp. 710–726. The quotation is on 241. Nina M. van Loon, Peter L. M. Leisink, Eva Knies,
p. 710. and Gene A. Brewer, “Red Tape: Developing and
228. Jessica Word and Sung Min Park, “Working across Validating a New Job-Centered Measure,” Public
the Divide: Job Involvement in the Public and Administration Review 76 (July/August 2016),
Nonprofit Sectors,” Review of Public Personnel pp. 662–673.
Administration 29 (June 2009), pp. 103–133. The 242. Brewer and Walker, “The Impact of Red Tape on
quotation is on p. 125. Governmental Performance,” pp. 247–248.
229. Mary K. Feeney and Hal G. Rainey, “Personnel 243. Sanjay K. Pandey, David H. Coursey, and Donald
Flexibility and Red Tape in Public and Nonprofit P. Moynihan, “Organizational Effectiveness and
Organizations: Distinctions Due to Institutional Bureaucratic Red Tape: A Multimethod Study,”
and Political Accountability,” Journal of Public Public Performance & Management Review 30
Administration Research and Theory 20 (October (March 2007), pp. 398–425. The quotation is on
2010), pp. 801–826. p. 416.
230. David Giauque, Simon Anderfuhren-Biget, and 244. David S. Kassel, “Performance, Accountability,
Frederic Varone, “Stress Perception in Public and the Debate over Rules,” Public Administration
Organisations,” Review of Public Personnel Review 68 (March/April 2008), pp. 241–252. The
Administration 33 (March 2013), pp. 58–83. quotation is on p. 241.
231. Hal G. Rainey, Sanjay Pandey, and Barry Bozeman, 245. Leisha DeHart-Davis, “Green Tape and Public
“Research Note: Public and Private Managers’ Employee Rule Abidance: Why Organizational
Perception of Red Tape,” Public Admini- Rule Attributes Matter,” Public Administration
stration Review 55 (November/December 1995), Review 69 (September/October 2009), pp. 901–
pp. 567–574. 910. The quotations are on p. 906.
The Fabric of Organizations: Forces 111

246. Paraskevi S. Christoforou and Blake E. Ashforth, Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 8 (July
“Revisiting the Debate on the Relationship 2008), pp. 1–19.
between Display Rules and Performance: 261. Dag Wollebaek, “Survival in Local Voluntary
Consolidating the Explicitness of Display Rules,” Associations,” Nonprofit Management &
Journal of Applied Psychology 100 (January Leadership 19 (Spring 2009), pp. 267–284.
2015), pp. 249–261. 262. Gary Ruskin, Spooky Business: Corporate
247. Gjalt de Graaf and L.W.J.C. Huberts, “Portraying Espionage against Nonprofit Organizations
the Nature of Corruption Using an Exploratory (Washington, DC: Essential Information, 2013).
Case Study Design,” Public Administration The quotation is on p. 4.
Review 68 (July/August 2008), pp. 640–653. 263. Richard L. Meier, “Communications Overload:
248. Downs, Inside Bureaucracy, p. 145. Proposals from the Study of a University Library,”
249. Martin Schulz, “Limits to Bureaucratic Growth: Administrative Science Quarterly 7 (March 1963),
The Density Dependence of Organizational Rule pp. 529–544. The quotation is on p. 540.
Birth,” Administrative Science Quarterly 43 264. John D. Sellars, “The Warning Signs of Insti-
(December 1998), pp. 845–876. The quotations tutional Decline,” Trusteeship 2 (November/
are on pp. 845, 870. December 1994), p. 13.
250. Marshall W. Meyer, Change in Public Bureau- 265. Arthur G. Bedeian and Achilles A. Armenakis, “The
cracies (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Cesspool Syndrome: How Dreck Floats to the Top
Press, 1979), p. 219. of Declining Organizations,” Academy of Manage-
251. Antonsen and Jorgensen, “The ‘Publicness’ of Public ment Executive 12 (February 1998), pp. 58–67.
Organizations,” p. 350. Emphasis is original. 266. Greg Chen, “Does Meeting Standards Affect
252. Ibid. Charitable Giving? An Empirical Study of
253. Warwick, et al., A Theory of Public Bureaucracy, New York Metropolitan Charities,” Nonprofit
pp. 76, 192, 200, 210. Management & Leadership 19 (Spring 2009),
254. Ibid., p. 210. pp. 349–365.
255. Claire L. Felbinger, “Impediments to Effective 267. Kristina Jaskyte, “Does Size Really Matter?
Management in Bureaucracies: The Perceptions Organizational Size and Innovations in Nonprofit
of Public Works Directors,” Public Productivity Organizations,” Nonprofit Management &
& Management Review 14 (Autumn 1990), Leadership 24 (Winter 2013), pp. 229–247.
pp. 7–17. The quotations are on pp. 12, 15. 268. Chen, “Does Meeting Standards Affect Charitable
256. David G. Houghton, “Citizen Advisory Boards: Giving?”
Autonomy and Effectiveness,” American Review 269. Ruth McCambridge, “Stalking the High Net
of Public Administration 18 (September 1988), Worth Donor: U.S. Trust Report Provides
pp. 282–295. The quotation is on p. 293. Guidance on Their Habits,” Nonprofitquarterly.
257. Jeff Gill and Kenneth J. Meier, “Ralph’s Pretty- org (October 25, 2016).
Good Grocery versus Ralph’s Super Market: 270. Wollebaek, “Survival in Local Voluntary Asso-
Separating Excellent Agencies from the Good ciations,” p. 274.
Ones,” Public Administration Review 61 (January/ 271. Thad Calabrese and Cleopatra Grizzle, “Debt,
February 2001), pp. 9–17. The quotation is on Donors, and the Decision to Give,” Journal of
p. 14. Public Budgeting, Accounting & Financial Man-
258. Alfred A. Marcus, “Implementing Externally agement 24 (Summer 2012), pp. 221–254.
Induced Innovations: A Comparison of Rule- 272. Chen, “Does Meeting Standards Affect Charitable
Bound and Autonomous Approaches,” Academy Giving?”
of Management Journal 31 (June 1988), pp. 235– 273. Thad D. Calabrese, “Do Donors Penalize Non-
256. The quotation is on p 249. profit Organizations with Accumulated Wealth?”
259. Sean Buchanan and Patricia Bradshaw, “The Public Administration Review 71 (November/
Voice from Outside: Stakeholder Resistance in December 2011), pp. 859–869.
Nonprofit Organizations,” Nonprofitquarterly. 274. Dean C. Ludwig, “Adapting to a Declining
org (December 13, 2011). Environment: Lessons from a Religious Order,”
260. Teresa D. Harrison and Christopher A. Laincz, Organization Science 4 (February 1993),
“Entry and Exit in the Nonprofit Sector,” B.E. pp. 41–56. The quotation is on p. 54.
112 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

275. Wollebaek, “Survival in Local Voluntary Asso- 277. Richard Callahan, “Governance: The Collision of
ciations,” pp. 272, 273, 280. Politics and Cooperation,” Public Administration
276. Joseph Galaskiewicz, Wolfgang Bielefeld, and Review 67 (March/April 2007), pp. 290–301.
Myron Dowell, “Networks and Organizational 278. Kathryn R. Harrigan, “Strategic Formulation in
Growth: A Study of Community-Based Non- Declining Industries,” Academy of Management
profits,” Administrative Science Quarterly 51 Review 4 (June 1980), pp. 599–604.
(September 2006), pp. 337–380.
CHAPTER

The Fibers of
Organizations: People


T hreads” served as our metaphor for theo-
ries of organizations. “Fabric” referred to the
interwoven forces that form organizations. And
sphere. Perhaps it should not surprise us, then, that
public administrators also value advancement less,4
and score “significantly higher” in their tolerance for
“fibres”—the woof, weft, and tensile strength of delayed gratification5 than corporate managers.
organizations—describes people in organizations. Where compensation does matter to public
employees is as a way of keeping score. In an experi-
ment, a random sample of state workers was granted
WHY WORK FOR THE PEOPLE? full knowledge of their colleagues’ salaries. Those
Sixty-three percent of government workers prefer to with salaries below the median for their depart-
work for government rather than business (preferred ments and for the same jobs reported much lower
by 36 percent),1 and local government employees satisfaction with both their pay and their jobs, and
appear to feel the most positive about working for there was a “significant increase in the likelihood of
government.2 looking for a new job.” Those employees earning
above the median, however, reported no higher sat-
isfaction at all, and were no more inclined to stay
The Draw of the Public Sector with their employer than they had been before they
The reasons why people enter, or do not enter, public knew that their pay was higher than the median.6
service are reasonably clear. When it comes to compensation, governments
can’t win.
Starkly Different Values Those people who enter
government careers have high public service moti- Making a Difference The classic view of public
vation (i.e., the desire to serve society in a secular administration is that of a calling, and, to a surpris-
context), positive views of the public sector, and ing degree, it still is. A study of zookeepers found that
negative perceptions of the private one. Those who they “were more likely to see their work as a moral
enter business hold values that are “completely duty, to sacrifice pay, personal time, and comfort.”7
opposite. . .. Differences between both groups are During the disastrous roll-out of HealthCare.gov, in
larger and more classical than current literature and 2013, frontline workers bent the rules and worked
previous studies suggest.”3 overtime to help applicants gain access to services far
more than they “moved away” from serving clients
Money Does Not Make Their World Go Around As under extraordinarily difficult circumstances.8
we noted in Chapter 3, high salaries are consider- Additional research confirms that mission
ably less important to those who work in govern- matters.9 Thirty-seven percent of federal managers
ment than they are to those who enter the corporate and professionals cite “doing something worthwhile”

113
114 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

as their primary reason for taking their jobs, com- Sixty-six percent of federal administrators and
pared with just 28 percent of businesspeople.10 professionals say that “job security” was their prin-
Holding a public administrative office correlates cipal motivation for accepting their jobs (including
more strongly with public service motivation than nearly half, a plurality, of upper-level new federal
any other factor, including even one’s “personal char- hires,22 and an astounding 97 percent of entry-level
acteristics.”11 (Personal characteristics that associate ones,23 who say this), compared with 57 percent of
with high levels of public service motivation include for-profit managers.24 The need for security tran-
women, people with more education, and members scends one’s public career; those who work in the
of professional associations.12) public sector also share a uniquely strong desire
There is a tangible connection between public for secure retirements.25 In contrast to compensa-
service motivation and making a difference—a good tion, governments win in this sphere: government
difference. employees at all levels are satisfied with their pen-
Organizationally, “public service motivation sions (82  percent) and retirement healthcare insur-
tends to be positively related to job satisfaction, ance (80 percent), compared with nongovernment
choosing a public sector job, individual and organ- employees’ 57 percent for each of the two job
izational performance, organizational and job com- aspects; these are the highest disparities in the study
mitment, person-organization fit, and organizational of thirteen aspects.26
citizenship behavior.” It also associates with reduced
“turnover intentions” among employees. A massive
literature review found that not only could public The Draw of the Independent Sector
agencies identify their applicants’ levels of public The sector with the most committed professionals is
service motivation when hiring, but that effective the independent one.
managers could raise their employees’ public service Money matters much less to these workers than
motivation.13 those in other sectors. Full-time nonprofit employ-
Public administrators’ service motivation also ees earn only 67 percent of what for-profit employ-
associates with a desire to do something worth- ees earn in salaries and benefits, and 73 percent of
while that extends beyond bureaucracy’s bounds. what government workers earn, yet rate their pay
They bring their service ethos to the professional as fair.27 (At least sixty-seven nonprofit chief exec-
associations that they join, “and these values, in utives, however, are paid between $500,000 and
turn, are positively related to board behavior.”14 $1 million—compensation that exceeds that of
Governments’ managers are more compassionate any public counterpart—and the median CEO pay
than the average American;15 they volunteer for exceeds $120,000.28)
charity work (educational and political organiza- The opportunity to do “something worthwhile”
tions are favored16), they match them in contrib- in their organizations means much more. An impres-
uting money to charity,17 they donate blood more sive 65 percent say this is why they work in the inde-
frequently than their private-sector counterparts, pendent sector, a percentage that is two-fifths higher
and “Overall, public servants are far more active in than that for the federal sector and almost three-
civic affairs than are other citizens,” and appear to fifths higher than the corporate one.29 “Purpose-
be “catalysts” in improving society at large.18 This is driven” Americans, according to one study, make
a good thing, as a large body of research finds that up 28 percent of the population, but account for
volunteering for,19 and giving money to,20 others 46  percent of nonprofit employees, second only to
correlate with better health and happiness and educators, at 48 percent.30 Those who work in non-
employees’ perception that their work positively profit organizations also serve as volunteers more
affects the well-being of others, which is one of job intensively than either their public31 or private32
satisfaction’s most important components.21 counterparts.
And job security means much less to nonprofit
A Deep-Seated Need for Security There is a employees. A slender 30 percent state that “having
fourth motivation underlying why people work for a secure pay check” is the primary reason they
government, and it eclipses all else. It is: job security. accepted their jobs, compared with 59 percent of
The Fibers of Organizations: People 115

federal employees and 68 percent of private-sector “unbureaucratic personality” that is found in non-
managers.33 Nonprofit employees are more inclined conformist, risk-prone public administrators who
to undertake riskier behavior and make riskier bend rules in order to provide better service.37 Of
choices than are workers in the other two sectors.34 greater importance, the syndrome itself seems to be
weak or even absent in most American bureaucra-
cies. As we explained in Chapter 1, the vast major-
THE BEHAVIORAL BUREAUCRAT ity of Americans are pleased by how bureaucrats
Organizational people are different. Very different. treat them, indicating that citizens are dealing either
with unbureaucratic rule-benders or (we think more
likely) rule-abiding bureaucrats in agencies that are
“Administrative Man” suffused with a public-service ethic. As noted in
In Models of Man,35 Herbert Simon contrasted psy- Chapter 4, following well-designed regulations can,
chological, or Freudian, man, as the model of the in fact, lead to greater public organizational success
human condition used by psychologists to predict and accountability, thereby completing this benefi-
the behavior of individual persons who are beset by cent circle.
ticks, quirks, and emotional needs, with rational, or
economic, man, which is the model used by econ-
omists to predict the behavior of the economy. The Energetic, Committed Bureaucrat
Economic man has the same goal (acquiring money) Americans work hard. On average, they work
as everyone else in the economy, and behaves (ration- longer than do workers in other developed countries
ally) just like everyone else to achieve it. (among which the United States ranks twenty-eighth,
Administrative man bridges psychological man or ninth from the bottom, for a healthy “work-life
and rational man. Administrative man has all the balance”38), or about thirty-four hours per week; a
unique idiosyncrasies and limited reasoning power fifth of Americans work forty-nine hours or more
of psychological man, but, like economic man, also per week,39 and more than two-fifths take no vaca-
understands the mission of the organization, and tions, not even of one day.40 And their work hours
knows that his or her interests and those of the are growing; Americans work eleven more hours per
organization can be somehow synchronous and week, on average, than they did in the 1970s.41
complementary. (Recall, in this light, our discussion
of “rational interest” in Chapter 3.) Public Administrators Public administrators seem
to “hang in there” with the same tenacity as their
private-sector counterparts,42 and studies “do not
“The Bureaucratic Personality” and “The indicate a terrible malaise in the public sector if the
Unbureaucratic Personality” private sector is used as a baseline.”43
This freakish fusion of the Freudian and the fiscal, Where employees in the public and private
when combined with any organization’s obses- sectors diverge is in the depth of commitment to
sion with minimizing uncertainty, can produce their jobs, and some research suggests that public
“the bureaucratic personality,” a phrase that res- administrators may hold a passion for their work
onates with “Veblen’s concept of ‘trained incap- that borders on the unhealthy. Half of federal exec-
acity,’ Dewey’s notion of ‘occupational psychosis’ utives, but not much more than a third of business
or Warnotte’s view of ‘professional deformation.’” executives, say that their career provides them with
Rendering the bureaucracy ever more rigidly rule- the most “life satisfaction.”44
bound results in “overconformity” among its
bureaucrats, who have made inflexibility and indif- Bureaucratic Burnout Burnout among American
ference an art form.36 managers attains “serious proportions in both
Not all bureaucrats succumb to this sad syn- arenas,” but burnout in the public sector is “not
drome, and some American public administrators appreciably worse” than in the private sector.45
working in centralized bureaucracies that are berib- Eighty-five percent of federal employees who are
boned in reams of red tape rebel by developing an eighteen to twenty-nine years old feel that they get
116 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

to use their “strengths to do what you do best every but more than six out of ten also would recom-
day” at work versus 82 percent of their non-federal mend their government as a place to work55—more
counterparts. But, at thirty and thereafter, federal than doubling from under a fourth in the mid-
workers say this consistently less frequently than do 1980s.56
non-federal employees, and, when they are sixty-five As we noted in Chapter 3, federal employee
or older, there is an eleven point gap between the engagement (of which, recall, job satisfaction is one
two groups.46 Growing federal retirement rates of four components) decreased in the 2010s, and the
reflect this possible burnout; the federal workforce same may be said of their job satisfaction. Federal
already is shrinking, and, by 2017, 31 percent of workers’ morale is the lowest it has ever been since
federal employees were eligible to retire.47 an annual survey of federal workers began in 2003.
Burnout is not limited to the feds. “City employ- “In every measure of workplace satisfaction, federal
ees feel more time stress than their state and federal employees ranked significantly lower than their
counterparts,”48 and it is indisputable that some private sector counterparts. The one exception:
types of local employment, such as public safety, federal workers are more likely to enjoy their jobs,”
have inherently high levels of stress. with 96 percent of them “willing to put in extra
effort to accomplish their work.”57
Nonprofit Professionals Nonprofit employees may State and local employees slightly lead federal
be the most devoted to their jobs. They score highest workers in their overall job satisfaction: state
in “total energy and investment in the job,” followed employees by two percentage points, and local ones
by government workers and corporate employees, by five.58
respectively.49
Third-Sector Satisfaction Nonprofit workers,
however, may be the happiest of campers. A remark-
The Dissatisfied Bureaucrat, the Satisfied able 58 percent say that they are “very satisfied
Nonprofit Professional? with their jobs overall,” and no other sector comes
Most Americans like their work. National polls close to this: 49 percent of federal employees and
taken over three decades find that, in nearly every 44 percent of corporate ones are “very satisfied,”59
survey, four-fifths of Americans report that they are and 39 percent of state workers and 50 percent of
satisfied with their jobs, two-thirds would take the local employees “liked their jobs very much.”60
same job again “without hesitation,” and only one
out of eight is dissatisfied with his or her job.50 Gaining Recognition: The Frustrated, Hypercritical
Bureaucrat Public administrators are significantly
Bureaucratic Satisfaction Bureaucrats provide less satisfied with how they are recognized than are
some variation on these themes, although the their corporate counterparts.61 Recall that, when
research on this topic is singularly opaque, and con- public professionals learn that their peers are earning
tradictory findings on the job satisfaction of public higher salaries than they are for the same work (and
administrators are “equally abundant.”51 There is, pay is a potent form of recognition), their dissatis-
however, at least one commonality in this literature: faction soars and the job search is on.62
public employees who possess emotional intelli- The reasons underlying public administrators’
gence, or the ability to comprehend, harness, and frustration are enigmatic. It may be a consequence
manage moods in themselves and in others, are more of uniquely high psychological needs for recogni-
satisfied with their jobs than are those who lack such tion, or their unhappiness “could simply reflect more
intelligence.52 stringent norms or expectations among government
From the 1960s through the 1970s, the managers” of their colleagues than are held by cor-
job  satisfaction of federal workers was low and porate executives.63
falling lower.53 For the last three decades, however, There is, in fact, some evidence that public
job satisfaction has risen steadily, and, over thirty administrators do hold their colleagues to unusu-
years, from 64 to 75 percent of federal employees ally high, even harsh, standards. A review of surveys
report that they are not only satisfied in their jobs,54 found that “Federal workers are the major purveyors
The Fibers of Organizations: People 117

of the misrepresentation that the government has


too many poor performers. . . . Federal workers seem Born to Conserve or Born to Rebel?
almost obsessed with describing the poor-performer Let us consider, first, birth. The order of the per-
problem.”64 son’s birth relative to his or her siblings, if any, is
the primary factor in determining a person’s pro-
Gaining Recognition: The Upbeat Nonprofit pensity to rebel—that is, to engage in revolutionary
Professional Twenty-six percent of nonprofit pro- creativity.68
fessionals say that their organizations need to do Those who are “firstborns” in a family iden-
better in rewarding “a job well done.”65 This is half tify with power and strength, and, when “later-
or less of the proportions (noted earlier) of federal borns”  enter into the family picture, firstborns
and private-sector employees who are unhappy use their power, strength (and size), to defend their
about their recognition. This low level of nonprofit position in the family structure (and perhaps long
dissatisfaction is all the more impressive when we after they have left it; adult firstborns with siblings
realize that independent-sector employees are less have substantially less net worth than those without
likely to be promoted on the basis of performance siblings69). Firstborns tend to be more jealous,
(and are less likely to be promoted, period) than are aggressive, defensive, and confident than later-
their counterparts in the private sector.66 borns,  and are overrepresented among Nobel  lau-
reates  and political leaders. Winston Churchill,
George  Washington, and Rush Limbaugh are
A Management Challenge firstborns.
So here we have, in sum, the public and nonprofit Laterborns (and firstborns who had deep con-
managers’ maze: Compared with business admin- flicts with their parents), by contrast, tend to identify
istrators, government executives are faced with with fellow underdogs, question authority and the
employees who are hypercritical loners determined status quo, be more open, imaginative, independ-
to do something of social importance, pouting prima ent, generous, and liberal than their firstborn sib-
donnas demanding unremitting recognition but who lings. Laterborns are disproportionately represented
are uninterested in being bought off with monetary among explorers, rebels, and heretics. Vladimir
bonuses. Lenin, Thomas Jefferson, and Bill Gates are later-
Managers in the independent sector share these borns.
characteristics—with a vengeance. They are more Why is this? The answer is biological and
committed to making a difference in society and Darwinian: Childhood is the search for a stable
have lower needs for wealth, recognition, and job niche in the family structure, just as evolution is
security than either public administrators or private the  result of the cell’s search for a stable niche in
ones. According to some research, nonprofit employ- nature. Both processes pertain to Charles Darwin’s
ees also have a greater need to dominate colleagues “principle of divergence,” which holds that diver-
and may be wilier in getting their way than are their sification (whether in the family or in nature) is a
private-sector counterparts.67 tactic that helps the individual minimize competi-
Certainly, these are precisely the kinds of quali- tion with  other individuals for scarce resources.
ties that we want in our public and nonprofit admin- Therefore, it “pays” firstborns to be conservers
istrators. But they make for a tough workforce to and protective of all the love and rewards that they
manage—and to be managed by. (once) were receiving from their families on an
exclusive basis, just as it “pays” laterborns to seek
new ways of gaining entry to that love and those
GROWING INTO THE rewards.
Though not infallible, birth order is the major
ORGANIZATION determining factor in explaining why some people
The circumstances under which people are born and defend the establishment and other revolt against it.
how they mature determine how people perceive Firstborns are, literally, born to conserve. Laterborns
their organization and behave in it. are, literally, born to rebel.
118 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

employees are incompetent, dishonest, and lazy, than


Life’s Turning Points students who do not have internships.74
Birth order plays a large part in the progressive Reality shock is, regrettably, pervasive: “Studies
mastery of psychological tasks that determine what have consistently found that almost all workers in
sort of an adult one becomes. How one approaches all sectors are engaged when they begin a job,” but,
these tasks is known as “turning points.” just six months later, not even two-fifths of them
The first turning point occurs from birth to remain engaged.75
year one, when trust or mistrust is inculcated into
one’s psyche as a result of one’s early experiences Settle Down! By their thirties, employees have
with others. From one to six, the development overcome their reality shock and enter a period of
of autonomy (which “concentrates on keeping “settling down”76 and “career consolidation.”77 Not
potential rivals out . . . most often directed against everyone, however, settles down. In one examination,
encroachments by younger siblings”) versus shame a tenth of the sample remained “perpetual boys” and
and doubt. From six to ten, initiative (that is, “antic- never matured, while a larger group simply stag-
ipatory rivalry” directed against “those who have nated;78 in another, 45 percent of managers “had
been there first”) or guilt. From ten to fourteen, major difficulties” during their career-consolidation
industry (the child  “learns to win recognition by phase and could not create the basis for “an even
producing things”) or inferiority. From fourteen to moderately satisfactory mid-life.”79
twenty, identity versus role confusion. From twenty
to forty, intimacy or isolation. From forty to sixty- Mid-Life. Crisis! Although a “mid-life transition”
five, generativity (an “interest in guiding the next may occur from one’s late thirties through early
generation  . . . a parental kind of responsibility”) sixties, it is more likely to happen during one’s
versus stagnation. And from sixty-five until death, mid-forties, and it may be experienced more by
ego integrity (“an emotional integration which women than by men.80 One adopts new lifestyles,
permits participation by followership as well as spouses, and careers; or one accepts that one’s life
acceptance of the responsibility of leadership”), as and work have gone as far as they are likely to go,
opposed to overwhelming despair.70 and is fine with it; or one becomes embittered over
Should one take a negative path at any given one’s sorry lot.81
turning point, all is not lost; with effort, a positive It appears that if one has less egocentrism and
path can be taken at the next turning point.71 We narcissism, and more tolerance, flexibility, and open-
know that most Americans (who already are among ness, one improves one’s chances of weathering the
the happiest people on earth72) choose positive paths mid-life crisis.82 But some administrators find this
because most grow happier as they grow older. In period so traumatic that they become “organiza-
their younger years, men and African-Americans are tional sleepwalkers.”83
less happy than women and whites, but these differ-
ences vanish over time.73 Meaning, Identity, and Disengagement Con-
tentment with one’s life and organization typically
rebounds during the late forties and fifties. This is a
Turning Points and the Organization period of “acceptance,”84 or “keeping the meaning”
Life’s turning points are reflected in organizational of one’s life and personal principles.85 Alternatively,
behavior. however, people can become inflexible over a set of
principles that may have grown hollow over time.
Reality Shock When twenty-somethings enter The roller coaster of intertwined life and career
their first “real” jobs, then “reality shock” often can takes yet another dip in the mid-to-late fifties,
slap them in the chops, and they must cope with and continues to decline, although not as rapidly,
bottom-scraping disillusion. In the public sector, through the early sixties as one nears retirement.86
students who have governmental internships are “As people enter mid-life, extrinsic rewards for
measurably more cynical about, and less trustful of, higher levels of performance and achievement lose
government, and hold a stronger belief that public their luster, as interest in affirming one’s identity and
The Fibers of Organizations: People 119

concerns for protecting the self-concept increase.”87 by “small” power distance believe, among other
“The longer employees work in an organization, the things, that: inequality should be minimized; super-
more engagement decreases until only 20 percent are iors should be accessible; and all should have equal
engaged after 10 years of service.”88 rights. Cultures with a “large” power distance believe
that: a social order rightly assures proper inequal-
Opportunity Lost These realities betoken a lost ities in society; superiors should be inaccessible; and
opportunity for public executives. Not only are ener- power should have privileges.
gized young Turks enduring a disorienting reality
shock, but experienced old hands are withering: Uncertainty Avoidance Uncertainty avoidance
“a better job of managing industrial scrap is done is the degree to which a culture feels threatened
than of managing the careers of older workers” in by ambiguity. Cultures with “weak” uncertainty
the United States.89 The organization that is shrewd avoidance have lower stress levels; believe time is
enough to invest extra time and attention to its free; accept dissent; are more risk prone; are youth
employees in their twenties, and which provides oriented; and are not enamored by a lot of rules.
opportunities for counseling their youthful col- “Strong” uncertainty-avoidance cultures: experience
leagues to employees in their sixties, not only could greater stress; believe time is money; promote con-
reverse alienation among both the young and the sensus over dissent; are security conscious, distrust-
old, but also have a happier, more productive, and ful of the young, and like a lot of rules.
more loyal workforce. Commonsensical as this is,
there is, regrettably, “a strong aversion on the part of Individualism-Collectivism Indivi dualism-
both mentors and protégés” in government toward collectivism refers to a continuum ranging from
an organizational program that would impose such personal to social centeredness. In an individualist
relationships.90 culture society is seen as a loose grouping of people
whose primary concern is caring for themselves;
leadership is the ideal; and decisions are made by the
NATIONAL CULTURE AND THE individual. In a collectivist culture: society reflects
a tight social framework in which in-groups are
ORGANIZATION distinguished from out-groups, and the in-group is
Just as birth order and aging influence how people expected to take care of the individual member in
inside organizations behave in them, so does the exchange for his or her total allegiance to it; mem-
larger society in which they live. National culture, bership in the in-group is the ideal; and decisions are
or “the collective mental programming of people made by the group.
in an environment,”91 is perhaps the single greatest
external determinant of organizational behavior. Masculinity-Femininity The masculinity-feminin-
One indicator: senior corporate executives judge a ity dimension is a continuum ranging from a mas-
startling 42 percent of their managers assigned to culine pole, in which assertiveness, performance,
projects overseas to have failed.92 money, independence, ambition, and indifference to
others dominate, to a feminine extreme in which nur-
turing, the environment, interdependence, service,
Dimensions of National Culture and caring for others are the preeminent values.
Certainly the most systematic and massive attempt
to categorize national cultures in ways that are Long-Term/Short-Term Orientation Finally, long-
potentially useful to managers is by Geert Hofstede, term/short-term orientation refers to a cultural per-
who identified five dimensions of national culture.93 spective relative to time. Nations with a long-term
orientation are directed toward the future, and value
Power Distance One dimension is power distance, thrift and persistence. Countries with a short-term
which refers to “the extent to which a society accepts orientation are more poised toward the past and
the fact that power in institutions and organizations present, and place premiums on respect for tradition
is distributed unequally.”94 Societies characterized and fulfilling social obligations.
120 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

National Culture and Managerial Authority In


Patterns of Geography and Language general, the smaller a culture’s power distance, the
Countries tend to group along these dimensions by less power that management has, and subordinates
geographic proximity. For example, the seven Latin are more likely to participate in decision making. In
American countries that Hofstede surveyed are all cul- the smallest power distance countries (e.g., Israel,
tures that accept large inequalities of power relation- Norway) “the very idea of management prerogatives
ships, strongly avoid uncertainty, and are collectivist. is not accepted.”95
Asian countries are large power  distance countries, Nations with large power distances, such as
collectivist, and have a long-term orientation. France and Italy, show little interest in participative
Common language plays a part, too. All ten decision making, suggesting that workers in these cul-
English-speaking countries, including those in tures “feel even more comfortable with superiors who
Africa and Asia, are accepting of uncertainty and are real autocrats,”96 and they are much more accept-
are masculine; and, except for those in Asia, all are ing of bullying by bosses than are workers in small
individualistic. power distance societies.97 Even so, large power dis-
The United States: is a small power distance tance associates with a high level of stress at work.98
country; a weak uncertainty avoidance nation
(in fact, it is well below average, indicating high National Culture and the American Organization
risk-taking propensities and tolerance for dissent); is American organizations, on the whole, tend to
exceptionally individualistic and masculine; and has protect the rights of individuals more effectively, are
a short-term orientation. better attuned to reality, are characterized by more
cooperation and innovation, and are generally more
open than European organizations. But the uniquely
National Culture and Organizational heavy presence of professional specializations (a
Behavior product of American culture) in American organ-
National culture affects organizational behavior in izations leads to the creation of many centers of
intriguing ways.

GETTING AHEAD

National cultures are reflected in their bureaucracies, Curzon, viceroy of India (1899–1905), that he
even when those bureaucracies administer cultures far would be suitable for promotion to the Residency at
removed from their own. From 1858 to 1947, the Civil Hyderabad. Sir David sent a telegram to the viceroy
Services of the Crown in India (composed, typically, of that read, in its entirety, “Psalm 132, verse 1.” Lord
about 1,000 civil servants, of whom about a fifth were Curzon looked up the biblical citation, which states:
routinely absent due to leaves and illness) administered “Lord, remember David.” Curzon, then in the hills of
some 400 million Indians, Pakistanis, Bangladeshis, northern India, telegraphed back, “Psalm 75, verse 6.”
and Burmese. Their management was sufficiently (“For promotion cometh neither from the East, nor
adroit that Joseph Stalin, the Soviet dictator, from the West, nor from the South.”) Encouraged, Sir
grumbled in 1939 to Joachim von Ribbentrop, the David replied, “Psalm 121, verse 1.” (“I will lift up
Nazi foreign minister, that it was “ridiculous . . . that mine eyes to the hills, from whence cometh my help.”)
a few hundred Englishmen should dominate India.” The viceroy ended the exchange with, “I Kings, 2, verse
How did one advance in such a civil service? Here 23,” which reads, “Go up, thou bald head.”
is one way. Sir David had won his promotion.
Source: David Gilmour, The Ruling Caste: Imperial Lives
Sir David Barr, “a man who was bald and diffident in the Victorian Raj (New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux,
as well as talented,” was persuaded to remind Lord 2005), pp. 217–218.
The Fibers of Organizations: People 121

authority that produce an abnormally high number power and sense of personal identity from internal
of jurisdictional disputes and render coordination organizational factors; are loyal to the organization
difficult. as a whole; well satisfied with everything in it; sus-
Americans’ passion for due process of law picious of outsiders; and often are oriented toward
(another cultural characteristic) results in reams of the past.
rules to protect each employee from injustices. But Marvick’s institutionalists are all that and
more rules compound the turf wars and magnify the more. They are deeply demanding of organizational
role of the organization’s “lawyers,” or any official advancement and prestige. (In contrast to nonprofit
who is in a position to delineate organizational turf managers, who place a high value on opportunities
and untangle red tape. Lawyers, loosely defined, for “increased responsibility,” government managers
often are effective enemies of innovation and change. prefer “advancement opportunities,”103 suggesting
Hence, “willful individuals can block the intentions that institutionalists may be closer to the norm in
of whole communities for a long time . . . and gen- public agencies than we might find comfortable.)
erally, a large number of vicious circles will protect Institutionalists tend not to stress the task-oriented
and reinforce local conservatism.”99 features of their jobs, but prefer to emphasize its
Despite these cultural obstacles, however, culture benefits (recall that public administrators display an
also enhances organizational health. A meta-analysis inordinate interest in retirement plans104), and are
of 287 studies found that small power distance and highly sociable, optimistic, complacent, and fiercely
large individualism and masculinity, features that loyal to their agency and co-workers.
are deeply embedded in American culture, correlate, Institutionalists can become rule-oriented and
positively and strongly, with both high job satisfac- inflexible; their sociability can degenerate into
tion and high performance.100 cliquishness, their loyalty into recalcitrance to
change, and they resist objective performance evalu-
ation. Yet, institutionalists stabilize the bureaucracy,
ORGANIZATIONAL POLITICS and furnish the needed lubrication among interper-
In 1954, Dwaine Marvick published a little-known sonal relationships.
monograph about the personality types that he dis- The personnel files of institutionalists reveal
covered among federal administrators and profes- that they are typically mid-level bureaucrats with
sionals. His research was prescient because, three long careers in government, often in the military;
years later, the sociologist, Alvin Gouldner, published are encumbered by few family ties; possess relatively
his famous articles on “Cosmopolitans and Locals,” low educational attainments; and frequently change
based on his observations of employees in a small positions (though do not necessarily advance) within
college, which had an enduring academic impact.101 the government.
Marvick’s research, however, is more nuanced
and, obviously, more pertinent to public administra-
tors. Moreover, it is practical. Marvick asked, “What Specialists: Professional and Maladjusted
must management do in order to cope with persons Specialists cluster at the opposite end of the spec-
having different career perspectives?”102 To answer trum. They are similar to Gouldner’s cosmopolitans,
this, Marvick trisected public bureaucrats according who relate to factors external to the organization,
to “career types,” classifications that associate with such as their professional associations; are more
characteristics that can be found in any personnel loyal to a subunit of the organization than to the
file. When combined with Marvick’s insights, these organization as a whole; are dissatisfied with many
data provide useful knowledge about one’s organi- aspects of it; and are more highly educated, special-
zational colleagues. ized, and alienated from their colleagues.
Again, as with institutionalists, Marvick’s spe-
cialists are all that and more. Specialists are not par-
Institutionalists: Loyal and Lethargic ticularly concerned about advancement, and have
Marvick’s first career type is the institutionalists, who virtually no interest in organizational status. What
correspond to Gouldner’s locals. Locals derive their they do want very badly, however, is to use their
122 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

professional skills. They are loners and are by far Like institutionalists, hybrids are very concerned
the most critical of their agency’s performance and with acquiring executive positions and moving up
of bureaucratic procedures generally; hence, they are to higher-paying jobs (interestingly, in this light,
“manifestly maladjusted” in their working relation- hybrids typically have far heavier family responsi-
ships.105 Although they are less likely to be involved bilities than either institutionalists or specialists), are
in group decisions, specialists actually have more not especially critical of bureaucratic paraphernalia,
influence within the agency than institutionalists. and are well adjusted to their jobs. Like specialists,
Specialists tend to displace the agency’s goals hybrids are uninterested in organizational prestige,
because their individual projects are more important and become disgruntled when distracted from their
to them than the organization’s welfare, and this pro- work.
pensity can diminish organizational performance. Hybrids bring the most dangers and benefits to
Moreover, their highly critical cast and lack of place the organization. Their chief peril lies in their insta-
commitment can cause sinking morale. Yet, when bility. Hybrids are fair weather friends, “superficial
properly placed, specialists can get things done, and and showy performers.”107 Their lack of both place
they are not inclined to heighten organizational ten- and skill commitments renders them unpredictable.
sions by competing politically with colleagues. Yet, precisely because they have no sublimated needs,
In terms of career histories, specialists usually hybrids are the most likely to assess, accurately and
have more experience in private companies and less holistically, the dynamics and problems of the organ-
military time than institutionalists; unlike institu- ization. Although later studies have concluded that
tionalists, who occupy generalized managerial slots, the person who is likeliest to enhance both organi-
specialists are high ranking, highly educated, and, zational stability and innovation is one who blends
obviously, highly specialized professionals. the qualities of institutionalists and specialists—that
is, he or she is loyal to the organization and sensitive
to the environment108—Marvick found that hybrids
Institutionalists, Specialists, and must be watched, for they are prone to change the
Organizational Innovation organization purely for their own self-betterment.
Although specialists traditionally have been credited Hybrids’ personnel files show that they are
as the sole founts of organizational innovation, and highly educated professionals, occupying relatively
institutionalists as their wary obstructionists, we are high ranks, and have significant work experience in
learning that organizational creativity is strength- both the private and public spheres.
ened less when specialists work alone, and more
when specialists and institutionalists work together.
Specialists know better what to do, and institu- WHAT IS LEADERSHIP?
tionalists know better how the organization could The people generally cited as the likeliest to alter
do it. Less effective is a combination of two special- organizations are called leaders.
ists; their outer-directed needs and ignorance of the
local organization result in less innovative organiza-
tions. The least innovative organizations are those The Leadership Literature
characterized by two institutionalists, neither one of Although the term, “leader,” surfaced in the English
whom clearly understands what innovations might language around 1300, “leadership” did not appear
be useful, so they choose few, if any.106 until another half millennium had passed.109 Given
its relatively recent origin, it is surprising that no
aspect of organizational behavior has had more
Hybrids: Political and Unpredictable written about it than has leadership; the number
Gouldner found only two career types, cosmopoli- of publications about leadership appears to double
tans and locals, in his campus observations. Marvick, from each preceding decade,110 and there may be
however, uncovered a third: hybrids, or politicized some 10,000 published studies on the subject.111
experts. Hybrids draw their characteristics from Despite the fact that most of the country’s found-
both institutionalists and specialists. ers, as recounted in Chapter 1, questioned the whole
The Fibers of Organizations: People 123

idea of political leadership (John Adams, the second and relationships to achieve it, “and then trying
president, wrote that the people should “consider to insure that those people actually do the job.”
themselves the fountain of power. . .. They must be Leadership’s way of accomplishing these three tasks
taught to reverence themselves, instead of adoring is to set a direction—create a vision—for the organ-
their [civil] servants, their generals, admirals, ization, and then align people, communicate, and
bishops, and statesmen”112), the United States is the inspire to fulfill it. Administration plans and budgets
frothing fount for much of the leadership literature. for the vision, and organizes, staffs, controls activi-
Americans “are unabashed in their zest for leader- ties, and solves problems to implement it.118
ship [and] leadership has become something of a cult In periods of slow change and a placid environ-
concept,”113 as indicated by the fact that American ment, administration is of greater significance; in
companies spend some $14 billion a year on leader- times of rapid change and a turbulent environment,
ship-training seminars.114 leadership is. “A peace time army can usually survive
Not so in other countries. The French, for with good . . . management up and down the hierar-
example, have no word that translates well as “lead- chy . . . . A war time army, however, needs competent
ership” (the classic French word for leader is chef), leadership at all levels. No one yet has figured out
and are reduced, in a culture that officially bans the how to manage people effectively into battle; they
Anglicization of its language, to referring to le lead- must be led.”119
ership, and leader is beginning to replace chef. (Zut,
alors!) Germans, Italians, Spaniards, and some Latin
Americans carry embarrassing fascist baggage in Are Leaders Needed?
their words for leader—führer in German, duce in This dramatic and inspiring image of “The Leader”
Italian, and caudillo or jefe in Spanish—which may at the head of charging warriors persuades the less
explain their intellectual disinclination to dwell on palpitating among us to ask: Are we being conned?
leadership. Do we really need leaders?
In light of its scholarly popularity, at least in the More precisely put, do organizations need hier-
United States, it is passing strange that so few agree archical leaders, or those people who occupy high
on what leadership even means. One reviewer found executive office? This question is even more radical
that more than three-fifths of the writings on lead- than that of whether we need leaders, because chief
ership never defined it,115 and another unearthed executives do a lot more than lead. “Leadership”
130 different definitions of leadership among those is only one of ten distinct roles, such as distur-
writers who bothered to define it.116 bance handler and spokesperson, that an executive
Leadership “is an influence relationship among plays,120 and these executive duties are common to
leaders and followers who intend real change that both the public and private sectors, perhaps because
reflect their mutual purposes.”117 We like this defini- “the private sector is becoming more like the public
tion because it stresses non-coercive manipulation by sector.”121
both leaders and followers; the presence of multiple
leaders as well as multiple followers; the purposeful The Leadership Con? At least one writer has
attainment of substantive change; and teamwork. forcefully argued that top executives have kept
their posh positions by promoting an unexamined
ideology that assumes executives are needed; exec-
Leadership or Administration? utives’ “dramaturgical” behavior (firm handshakes,
Is leadership different from administration? Yes. Is unwavering gazes, etc.) that conveys an image of
one more important to organizational success than executive importance; and a “bureaupathologi-
the other? No. cal” enforcement of rigid rules designed to assure
Leadership deals with change. Administration subordinates’ subservience and loyalty.122 One is
copes with complexity. Both are equally vital to reminded by these techniques of Mel Brooks’ line in
organizational success. his role as the governor in the film, Blazing Saddles:
Both leadership and administration involve “Gentlemen, we’ve got to protect our phony
“deciding what needs to be done,” creating the work baloney jobs here!”
124 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

If executives are nothing more than con artists, automatic’ . . . that do not need their presidential
then how do organizations get things done? The leaders.”130
answer: Those who get things done in organizations
are Marvick’s specialists, who have the knowledge In the Nonprofit Sector The same external factors
and skills that are crucial to the achievement of trump leadership in the independent sector. An organ-
organizational objectives.123 ization’s “external legitimacy” heavily outweighs
changes in internal leadership and management in
The Limits of Leadership The preceding polemic predicting the long-term survival of newly-founded,
frames the question. But is it possible that organiza- social service organizations.131
tions really do not need (or would even be better off
without) chief executives and top administrators? Leaders Matter In a very real sense, however, these
Well, yes, at least in a fairly substantial minority analyses obscure a fundamental point, which is that
of organizations in all sectors. (We do not discuss leaders can and do have an impact on their organiza-
the private sector at length, but suffice it to note tions. The real question is: How much impact?
that CEOs account for less than 5 percent of the
variation in corporate performance,124 and changes In the Public Sector Despite the limitations on
in CEOs loom less large in generating profits than public leadership, noted earlier, leadership has “an
do time, industry, and company characteristics.125) enormous impact” on “follower satisfaction,”132
Why? Because environmental forces, and, less com- and, “ultimately, the research shows that supervi-
monly, internal ones (such as smoothly functioning sory proficiency” in government “is critical to . . .
teams of employees), can render leaders moot. employee motivation, engagement . . . [and] reten-
tion.”133 Leaders are more effective than rules in
In the Public Sector In the states, “there is little preempting ethical violations in public organiza-
evidence that a governor’s formal powers signifi- tions.134
cantly affect policy outcomes,” which “are attribut- We also know that competent public leaders
able largely to the impact of economic development correlate with effective governance. Public leaders
rather than to the governor’s power.”126 At the local can make work more meaningful to their employees,
level, most of the variance in big-city budget alloca- “which, in turn, has a positive influence on employee
tions is attributable not to the entry of new mayors, job outcomes”; this is especially true in healthcare
but rather to environmentally-determined charac- and education programs, less so in local govern-
teristics of the cities themselves.127 Public school ment.135 “Leadership plays an important role”
superintendents account for a modest three-tenths of in whether emergency managers view their crisis
1 percent of “student differences in achievement. . .. networks as effective.136 “Mayoral quality is asso-
orders of magnitude smaller than that associated ciated with . . . improved local public finance.”137
with any other major component of the education Those governments that have superior manage-
system,” including “student characteristics, teachers, ment capacity perform better than governments
schools, and districts.”128 with low capacity, and leadership, in turn, is central
Internal organizational factors also can also in enhancing “the impact of capacity” on public
render hierarchical leadership “not always very performance.138 Able government supervisors are
necessary, especially if community members do not crucial “to individual and organizational perfor-
‘need’ a leader in order to be motivated to make mance,”139 and high-quality leadership is central to
their contribution. . . . In some situations, especially higher federal agency performance.140
where the work or membership is intrinsically satis-
fying and work groups are cohesive, the presence of In the Nonprofit Sector In the independent sector,
a leader is redundant.”129 But even effective teams of “managerial power” and ability are positively and
engaged employees are not always needed to render “highly correlated with job involvement” (which,
executives irrelevant; placidity will do. An analy- recall, is critical to higher individual and organiza-
sis of college presidents concluded that 16 percent tional performance), trumping even gender, age, eth-
presided over “uneventful” campuses “running ‘on nicity, and education.141
The Fibers of Organizations: People 125

A scholar who tried to make some sense of 120


LEARNING LEADERSHIP: THE of these trait studies (essentially all of them) could
discern no commonalities among leaders.145 If not
EVOLUTION OF A THEORY shared traits, then, what made them leaders?
The evolution of leadership theory during the last
century and in this one has been characterized by
ebbs, eddies, and flows. “Contrary to popular belief, The Leader in the Grip of the Group,
none of the theories have become completely extinct. 1930–1970
They reappear decade after decade, sometimes dis- To answer this question, researchers began to study
guised, sometimes in another form, basically intact how leaders interacted with small groups, and to
and flourishing.”142 identify which of their behaviors associated with
effective leadership.

The Leader: Alone and Glorious, Leadership Behaviors By the 1940s, inspired
1900–1930 largely by Kurt Lewin’s seminal research on leader-
We noted in Chapter 3 that the pioneers of man- ship styles,146 researchers had identified two distinct
agement theory typically treated members of organ- clusters of behaviors that they believed were useful
izations as identical automatons who did as they to leaders in providing leadership, and these clusters
were told. But there lurked in this early literature an have had a lasting impact on leadership theory.
exception—the leader. When these writers consid- One cluster is composed of consideration behav-
ered the leader, their hearts beat aflutter; impersonal iors that relate to interpersonal warmth, concern for
sameness was tossed out the window, and creative, the feelings of subordinates, and a participative/
visionary, and mythic heroes swaggered in. communicative style of leadership. The other cluster
is structuring, or task, behaviors, and includes direct-
The Triumph of the Will? No longer were schol- ness, obtaining task-related feedback, and achieving
ars talking about the limitless capacities of clerks to goals.
cower and laborers to labor, but of dizzying social Investigators in this tradition find that both
forces that only leaders could bring to heel. A con- behavioral clusters can work well in leading groups,
ference held in 1927 defined leadership, in decidedly but which cluster works depends upon the nature of
Teutonic terminology, as “the ability to impress the the group. Leadership is viewed as interactive and
will of the leader on those led and induce obedience, nondirective, and leadership is defined as “personal-
respect, loyalty, and cooperation.”143 This view, with ity in action under group conditions.”147
some modifications, persists decades later, when Scholars have developed two major approaches
leaders remained transcendent figures endowed to understand leaders’ behaviors and their groups’
with a “gift of grace” who soared grandiosely at an responses to them.
“institutional level” over torpid, timid technicians,
who toiled in the organization’s innards and kept its Contingency Approaches One approach is rooted
hum-drum routines running from day to day.144 in contingency theory, which, as we explained in
Chapter 3, treats the organization as an entity that
Leadership Traits Unsurprisingly, much ado was is constantly forced to adapt to its surrounding envi-
made during this period about leaders’ “traits,” or ronment. When applied to leadership, this approach
those personal qualities that made them leaders. emphasizes that leaders must deal with contingen-
Researchers would score and compare “leaders” cies—that is, unexpected or unintended events or
(who typically were identified as leaders by nothing possibilities
more than the office that they held in the organi- Fred Fiedler is perhaps the prime contributor
zation) with “followers” on such dimensions as to this line of thought.148 Fiedler found that when
dominance, physical appearance, masculinity, and a group trusts its leader, has a clear task struc-
other characteristics that were thought to constitute ture, and the leader has the power to reward and
leadership. punish followers, the leader has high control of the
126 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

group. In a high-control situation, a task-motivated agencies challenged by low level of performance and
leader  is  the leader with the most effective set of perturbations in the external environment.”157
behaviors.
When the group is distrusting, its task struc- “Cow Psychology” Ultimately, some scholars
ture is ambivalent, and the leader has less power who  studied leaders and groups got a bit carried
to reward and punish, the leader has moderate away. As early as the 1940s, leadership had
control. In these situations, a relationship-motivated morphed, startlingly, into “that relationship which
leader is needed because an invariably frustrated is characterized by love of the members for the
task-motivated leader moves too quickly, too puni- central person.”158
tively—and less effectively. It was, perhaps, this view that gave birth to the
When the group is not supportive of its leader, phrase, “cow psychology,” or the disparaging term
its task is foggy, and the leader’s authority to dis- applied to a literature that seemed to treat groups
pense rewards and punishments is ambiguous, low as herds of cows, and “cow psychology” was how
control is the consequence. In a low-control situa- leaders herded groups in the direction they wanted.
tion, which often amounts to a crisis situation, the This unease translated into a new phase of leader-
task-motivated leader once again surfaces as the ship theory, one that concentrated on the leader’s
most effective. relationships with not merely the group, but the
Although the contingency model has been the organization.
subject of some controversy, most empirical tests of
it find it to be reflective of the real world.149
Culture and Charisma: The Leader and the
Transactional Approaches Still, the contingency Organization, 1970–Present
approach has limitations. It concentrates only on the By the 1970s, leadership researchers were finding
problems confronting the leader in dealing with a that, whereas small-group models could, in several
small group, but not the leader’s subordinates and respects, be adapted successfully to large organiza-
the problems confronting them. What kinds of trans- tions, there were some differences.159
actions, or exchanges, occur between and among
leaders and followers that facilitate or impair both Leadership Behaviors and Organizational Cultures
the leader’s and the group’s effectiveness? One difference is the presence of organizational
Consideration behavior works best when the culture, or the shared mores, customs, processes,
group’s task is distasteful,150 and when its members and attitudes of the organization’s members.
are open151 and have strong needs for personal Organizational “culture affects leadership as much
growth in their jobs.152 Structuring behavior is more as leadership affects culture.”160
effective when the group’s task is unstructured,153 The local organizational culture “matters most”
and when its members are dogmatic154 and content in the molding of corporate leaders—far more, in
with routine, even boring, work.155 fact, than the more cosmopolitan phenomenon of
professionalism. Employees who work for the same
Consideration, Trust, and Public Organizational company, no matter what their jobs, are 30 percent
Performance When leaders employ considera- more likely to exhibit similar leadership competen-
tion behaviors in their decision making, the group’s cies than are employees who have the identical job,
members’ “commitment to the decision, attachment but who work in different companies.161 Culture
to the group, and trust in its leader” also increase.156 counts.
Just as popular trust in government correlates
very positively with better governing (recall Chapter Transformation and Charisma During the 1970s
1), so it is with public leaders and their employees. and 1980s, theorists became fascinated with trans-
When public workers trust their leaders, those leaders formational leadership, which occurs “when one or
“preside over more productive organizations” than more persons engage with others in such a way that
do less trusted leaders, “and are better able to main- leaders and followers raise one another to higher
tain and even increase organizational outcomes in levels of motivation and morality.”162 Eventually,
The Fibers of Organizations: People 127

the concept was extended to a resurrection of Max committed to, their organization’s mission.172 They
Weber’s notion of charisma. Charismatic leaders are have a greater, and positive, impact on public
those “who by force of their personal abilities are workers who already have high levels of public
capable of having a profound and extraordinary service motivation.173
effect on followers,” causing them “to accomplish In one study, transformational leaders alone
outstanding feats,”163 and who possess an “idealized attained marginal gains in performance, but when
vision” of the organization’s future that they attempt they caused their government employees to meet
to fulfill via unconventional, often risky, means.164 the people whom their services benefitted, and they
Whether this sort of leadership is called trans- placed their workers in situations that encouraged
formational or charismatic, Max is back. them to change their own behavior (or either one),
“the performance effects . . . were much greater.”174
Does Charisma Transform? Often, charisma On the minus side, hierarchical authority (but
does transform, or at least changes organizations not red tape) and poor communication associate
for the better. For example, charismatic leadership with “a lower prevalence of transformational leader-
associates positively with “increased financial per- ship” in government,175 which is regrettable because,
formance” in (of all things) banks,165 and a study as we have noted, such leadership can correlate with
of mid-level managers in an energy company con- creativity.176 Moreover, public transformational
cluded that “leadership effectiveness, as measured leadership is characterized by its “ineffective imple-
by the achievement of organizational outcomes, mentation”;177 bears only a scant relationship to the
is a direct function of a leader’s transformational motivation of followers, and is “not significantly
behaviors.”166 In general, transformational leader- related to unit performance.”178
ship associates with greater employee creativity, but
only when there is also an innovative organizational Independent Charisma In nonprofit settings, the
climate and employees identify positively with their findings are clearer and more upbeat. Female leaders
leader.167 There are, however, variations in the public (who are found in the nonprofit sector far more
and nonprofit sectors. extensively than in the other two) have a more trans-
formative leadership style than do male leaders.179
Charismatic Government At the very top of gov- Nonprofit workers display more “positive emo-
ernment, “personality and charisma do make a dif- tions” for transformational leaders than for trans-
ference” in presidential performance.168 A study of actional ones. When transformational leaders are
presidents from George Washington through George leading, independent employees’ workplace satisfac-
W. Bush found that their “grandiose narcissism” tion is higher, they work harder, their organizations
associated positively with “superior overall great- are more effective,180 administrative innovation is
ness,” and enhanced public persuasiveness, crisis greater,181 and they “positively affect” their organ-
management, and agenda setting, but also with izations’ fiscal accountability, mission adherence,
more “congressional impeachment resolutions and governance, and effectiveness.182 Volunteer satisfac-
unethical behaviors.”169 “Strong leadership from tion is also higher, but, alas, transformational leader-
executives with strong commitment, a vision of ship does not correlate with more donations.183
where they would like to go, and a willingness to
take risks” correlates positively with countries that Transformation or Transaction? What the research
successfully make the wrenching transformation suggests is that charisma works best when charisma
from socialism to capitalism.170 is what the organization needs. The more critical
When we slip a bit further down the chain of question, however, is one of matching the leader’s
command, however, the evidence blurs. behaviors with the needs of the organization.
On the plus side, charisma can be helpful in Not all (in fact, passing few) organizations are in
getting one’s way in small groups of government need of transforming change, simply because they are
workers.171 Transformational leaders appear to doing a “satisficing” job already. It is in these fairly
increase public employees’ public service motiva- normal situations that transactional leadership—
tion and render them more focused on, and more which rests on a civilized exchange of views and
128 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

arguments—has a special place. “Good leaders help such power is much less easily acquired in an envi-
change their institutions, not through transforma- ronment in which public executives have little if any
tion and the articulation of new goals or values, but control over the selection of board members. In a
through transactions that emphasize selected values deep difference with corporate and nonprofit boards,
already in place and move the institution toward government boards almost always are appointed by
attaining them. . . . Those who espouse the impor- legislatures or elected chief executives, or are elected
tance of transformational leadership should pause to directly by the people.
consider what life would be like in an organization Public-sector boards, in contrast to those in the
whose programs, procedures, and core values could private and nonprofit sectors, often are composed
be called into question by each new president.”184 disproportionately of energetic and myopic busy-
Transactional leaders do not abjure change, but, bodies, nearly two-fifths of whom believe that their
unlike transformational leaders, they do avoid dra- primary duties are either both management and pol-
conian change because transmogrifying revolutions icymaking or just management, as opposed to just
can be destructive to a reasonably well-functioning policymaking. “Board governance is a prominent
organization. Effective organizational leadership, part of public administration . . . and it is an unu-
whether it is transformational or transactional, is sually intrusive part for public administrators who
leadership that is tailored to the conditions of the report to boards.”187
organization at the time. This verity is especially the case in local
governments.
City council members are far more enthusias-
LEADING PUBLIC AND tic about mucking in “administrative matters” than
making policy, and this tendency is accelerating over
NONPROFIT ORGANIZATIONS time.188 Many city councils are increasingly micro-
Leaving aside theories of leadership, how do leaders managing, provincial, parochial, bloated, bickering,
actually lead? We start at the top. and balkanized bodies that give them “an image of
irresponsible flakiness.”189
“County commissioners are heavily involved in
Leadership at the Top administration,” with counts ranging from 44 to 80
Boards of directors, or trustees, are small groups percent of commissioners, depending on the study
that lead, oversee, make policy for, possess legal and the administrative area, engaging in managerial
control of, and form the mission of almost all organ- activities.190
izations. Research consistently indicates that the Boards of education spend an astonishing 54
more committed, energetic, and able board members percent of their time on administration and only
in every sector are, the more likely that their organi- 3 percent on policy and oversight.191 Their “greatest
zations will exhibit high performance.185 Aside from problem . . . is their tendency to micro-manage and
this commonality, however, board leadership varies become bogged down in minutiae.”192
widely according to sector, but we concentrate here In a depressing parallel with corporate chief
only on public and nonprofit boards. executive officers (CEOs),193 when local govern-
ments are performing poorly, their chief adminis-
The Public-Sector Board Nearly all public exec- trative officers (who report to councils) often blame
utives report directly to boards of directors or their their top team members, who then leave these organ-
rough equivalents, legislative oversight commit- izations at more rapid rates than their top adminis-
tees and local councils. Yet, “despite an enormous trators.194
amount of discussion about leadership in public
agencies, there has been relatively little broad-scale The Third-Sector Board More than four-fifths
empirical analysis.”186 Still, there is some. of nonprofit board chairs describe their leadership
As we observed in Chapter 1 (and discuss style as one of delegating responsibility and consen-
further in Chapter 11), public executives often dom- sus- and team-building; just 8 percent ascribe to the
inate the bodies to which they nominally report. But “take-charge, forge-ahead” school.195
The Fibers of Organizations: People 129

The members of the boards of public-service services soared from 10 percent to 36 percent over
nonprofit organizations are difficult to recruit, eleven years.201
tend to be middle-aged and older, and, in contrast As with corporate boards (about four-fifths of
to many public-sector boards, nonprofit boards the CEOs “at most big companies” chair their own
mostly do what they are supposed to do: that is, boards202), there is an unseemly coziness among non-
they are “very active” in financial oversight and profit board members and their executive directors.
policymaking, and largely uninvolved in day-to-day Fifteen percent of third-sector CEOs serve as voting
management. Regrettably, at least from the perspec- board members,203 and their organizations suffer
tives of the employees and missions of these organ- pretty much across the board: financial oversight,
izations, their boards of directors generally spurn policymaking, and community relations are weaker,
fund-raising.196 and outside influence is stronger.204 Of greater sig-
When nonprofit boards have few members nificance, when the executive director serves on the
who are women, but many old, prestigious men, the board, the organization’s accountability is measur-
boards are lethargic and the executive director or ably lessened (one study of community-based non-
board chair calls most of the shots. Conversely, when profits found that their executive directors had views
third-sector boards have a relatively large number of that were more similar with each other than with
women and younger members who have high levels the residents of their own communities, even though
of commitment to the organization’s mission, the the communities were significantly different205), and
board is dynamic and its members work effectively these organizations are less likely to have outside
as a team.197 audits and policies concerning whistle blowing and
More broadly, however, the dominance dynamic conflicts of interest.206
often moves from the preeminence of the executive This is unfortunate, as conflicts of inter-
director “to board-led control, and, subsequently, est are often apparent. Twenty-one percent of all
to collaboration within a paradoxical trust-distrust public-serving nonprofit organizations, and 41
relationship.” Consequently, “no single mode of percent of the large ones, report that they have
CEO or board predominance” can be sustained over engaged in “financial transactions with board
time,198 which leads, of course, to dithering and members.”207 The nation’s more than 2,300 non-
indecision. profit hospitals, which are among the largest non-
A few boards, about a sixth, devote a dispro- profits in the country, conduct business with their
portionately large amount of time to raising funds at board members at a rate that is six times greater
the expense of their service mission. This  imbal- than all other types of nonprofits.208
ance  is more likely to occur when the organiza- There is some good news (at least for executive
tion is  more financially dependent on a for-profit directors) in these practices, however: when execu-
corporation, there is “a racial mismatch between tive directors serve on their boards, their salaries are
the  board and agency clientele,” and the board is higher than when they do not serve on the board.209
dominated by “economic elites.”199 Relatedly, more Sometimes this lagniappe is large, such as the family
than 70  percent of board members have only a foundation in Chicago that, over five years, paid two
limited  sense of accountability, believing that they family members more than $1 million, but donated
were accountable only to their board or to no only $175,000 to charities.210
one.”200
A newer wrinkle in board membership is the
explosive expansion of finance professionals who Sector and Successful Leadership
serve. Financiers, who comprise just 6 percent of the Just as the leadership behavior of board directors
private non-farm workforce, expanded their share of differs markedly by sector, so does that of appointed
nonprofit board memberships from 18 to 19 percent chief executives.
to 34 to 40 percent, depending on the type of non-
profit, over twenty-eight years, an expansion that Successful Public Leadership Administrators in
seems to have profited the nonprofits: the percent- both the public and private sectors agree that leaders
age of the fifty largest donors who were in financial in government have considerably less discretion and
130 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

authority to lead than their private-sector counter- perceive that there is much of a match between their
parts,211 and, logically, it follows that public exec- leadership abilities and actually accomplishing their
utives also “are evaluated as better transactional agency’s goals.221 This, admittedly dubious, distinc-
leaders” than transformational ones.212 tion may be ascribed to at least two possibilities.
One is that many agencies, at least those that
Public versus Private Leadership Public and private have quantifiable goals, have been shown to be
leaders display virtually identical “power-motivation fulfilling them. The other is the fact that, as we
behavior,” or the desire to make an impact and discuss throughout this book, agency missions are
enhance one’s position213 (government leaders place frequently saturated by a pervasive and ethereal
a premium on outperforming “someone else” by vagueness compared with crisp corporate ones.
surpassing “some self-imposed standard of excel- Small wonder, perhaps, that top public executives
lence”214), but, beyond that similarity, leaders’ behav- are “consistently, and often dramatically, more
ior differs sharply in the two sectors. optimistic” about their agencies’ organizational
In contrast to the private sector, successful successes than are lower-placed agency workers,222
public leaders are more desirous of change (and, agency clients, and other outside stakeholders.223
as we explained in Chapter 4, they are better than When organizational success itself cannot be readily
private leadership in achieving it215), organizational understood, a condition that is not unknown (but
growth, and new projects, and they are more lawful not, thankfully, universal) in the public sphere, then
and less directive. Superiors and subordinates per- leadership’s success, when defined in organizational
ceive the executives of public agencies as being much terms, is far less tenable. Thus, in the public sector,
less successful when they direct and coordinate their successful leadership is cast in human terms.
agencies (it is precisely the opposite in the private
sector), and much more effective when they closely Successful Nonprofit Leadership In addition to
monitor their subordinates’ work for legal compli- nonprofit organizations’ uniquely avid receptivity
ance and reach out to lend a helping hand to their to transformational leaders, noted earlier, third-
fellow workers (again, just the reverse in corpora- sector executive directors, in contrast to their public
tions).216 and private counterparts, place little emphasis on
involving their boards in “strategy and planning,”
A Supportive, Affective Public Leadership Helping “financial oversight,” “policy oversight,” provid-
their employees is exceptionally important to ing “guidance and expertise” to the organization,
public-sector leaders. Federal executives score “sub- or even cultivating a good “relationship” between
stantially better” in their consideration behaviors themselves and their board members. Instead, 55
than on other measures.217 An astounding 78 percent percent of top nonprofit executives rank “fund
of city managers have a “primary leadership style” development” first out of thirteen “key roles” that
(out of four possible styles) that is “high support- their boards should play; no other role gains even
ive and low directed behavior.”218 Public executives close to half.224
are deeply committed to mentoring co-workers and
giving them the freedom to grow and mature in their
jobs, and their co-workers respond very favorably to WHY ARE SO MANY LEADERS
this treatment.219
The most effective leaders in the high-stress LOSERS?
fields of first responders, law enforcers, and social We have been singing the songs of successful leaders,
workers are “affective leaders” who are skilled in but we all have known stupendously inadequate
“emotional labor” that involves relationships and bosses in every sector, and these “leaders” can be
rapport, compassion and connectedness. “Emotional deeply destructive. A large literature review found
labor is inherent in effective public service.”220 that employees’ hostile “attitudes towards the
leader” is the single most significant correlation
Attaining Agency Objectives? Well, Not So Much with employees’ “counterproductive work behav-
Unlike business leaders, public leaders do not ior,” a phrase nicer than “sabotage,” but its rough
The Fibers of Organizations: People 131

equivalent. The second highest correlation with as threats to their positions, despite the serious harm
workers’ destructive behavior is the “bad leaders” that such isolation causes overall productivity.227
themselves, suggesting that employees’ negative Sound familiar? We hope not.
views of their leaders are based on the reality of their
leaders’ incompetence.225
How do these incompetents get selected? Race and the Unconscious
Mediocrities, or worse, are chosen as top “leader- Four-fifths of Americans have, at an unconscious
ship material” in distressingly large numbers because level, “pro-white associations,” which, for most
sociopathic, white, handsome, and tall men are over- people, are “utterly incompatible” with their con-
represented among them. scious values. “About half” of blacks have pro-white
associations, simply because blacks are a minority
that is embedded in a majoritarian culture which
Mostly Male links itself with “good things.”228
Because we provide details in Chapter 9, we shall This is, perhaps, difficult to accept. But how else
note here only that male executives are significantly does one explain, for example, that federal admin-
overrepresented in the public sector (and much more istrators increase their funding to nonprofits that
so in the private one). Men are underrepresented serve poor neighborhoods as neighborhood poverty
in the independent sector, where female executives grows, but decrease their funding as these neigh-
dominate. borhoods’ African-American populations expand,
even though poverty still grows?229 It is very hard
to conclude (at least for us) that Washington is
“The Psycho-Path to Disaster” awash with bureaucrats who are conscious racists,
“Estimates vary, but approximately 3.9 percent of but the unconscious argument seems, regrettably, to
corporate professionals can be described as having have legs.
psychopathic tendencies, a figure considerably higher In 2015, the Supreme Court appeared to recog-
than is found in the general population, [where] nize this reality, writing that “unconscious prejudices
approximately one percent . . . falls within the psy- and disguised animus . . . escape easy classification
chopath category.” Because executives who work in as disparate [i.e., unfair] treatment,” but they existed
the public and nonprofit sectors have, almost by defi- nonetheless.230
nition, greater public service motivation than those
in the private one, we suspect that the proportion of
psychopaths in these sectors may be lower than 3.9 Hey, Good Lookin’! Whatcha Got Cookin’?
percent, but that is merely speculation and neither Money and Bias, of Course
sector is psychopath free, as indicated by incidents “Physically formidable” men associate more in
of public and nonprofit corruption. most people’s minds with leadership potential than
Psychopathic organizational leaders fall short of weak-appearing men;231 “competent”-looking CEOs
monstrous psychopaths, such as Hitler and Stalin, run larger companies, on average, and enjoy an 11
and are best described as “psychopaths lite,” or to 14 percent greater compensation, than not-so-
sociopaths. They are masters of suck-up and kick- competent-looking CEOs;232 and those who have
down, “unburdened by a conscience,” and are glib, “facial attractiveness” associate positively with
callous, shameless, unremorseful, exploitive, para- short-term higher stock prices and more advanta-
sitic, manipulative, impulsive, bullying (as we detail geous mergers and acquisitions, but not with superior
in the introduction to Part III, corrupt public officials personal or corporate performance.233 When times
often are “domineering”), self-centered, sexually get tough, a corporate CEO’s good looks correlate
promiscuous, and chronic liars who blame others for with organizational harm; “inferences of leadership
their failures. “The only thing that counts with these ability from the faces of American [CEOs] predicted
people is to win.”226 “Winning,” in these sociopathic their companies’ financial performance prior to the
terms, also includes isolating star-performing subor- Financial Crisis of 2008 but not after.”234 In fact,
dinates because power-driven leaders perceive them it may be possible that some physically attractive
132 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

CEOs have “too much executive presence,” and, by on average, just a fraction under six feet tall, or
“grooving on the perks,” holding too many “audi- three inches taller than the average American male.
ences” in their offices, and making themselves the Less than 15 percent of American men measure six
“focal point” of communication, they distance them- feet or taller, and fewer than 4 percent are at least
selves from productive employees, thereby reducing six feet two inches, compared with 58 percent and
organizational productivity.235 “almost a third,” respectively, of the CEOs; less
When attractive CEOs perceive themselves to than 1 percent of the CEOs were short, at under five
be attractive (which seems highly plausible for most feet six. “Being short is probably as much a handi-
or all of them), they are more likely to support ine- cap [to career success] . . . as being a woman or an
quality236—not a good sign for those seeking salary African-American. . .. We see a tall person and we
raises. swoon.”242
There is a notable exception to the attrac-
tive-CEO/dysfunctional-organization relationship.
In a study of “large, visible donations” to nonprof- The Public Perspective
its, men engaged in “competitive helping displays” In government, these problems are compounded by
(think amorous peacocks) when they were solicited institutional dysfunctions, notably the traditional
by attractive women, giving donations that were practice of promoting employees based on seniority
“around four times greater than when males give to (which is “the only way to reward them for their . . .
less-attractive female (or male) fundraisers or when contribution,” but which results in promoting “some
they respond to a large donation made by a female people who just stink at being supervisors”); the
donor.” (Competitive helping displays were not a difficulties (described in Chapter 9), often insur-
factor between female donors and male fundraisers, mountable ones, inherent in assessing employee per-
whether attractive or unattractive.)237 formance in the public sector (difficulties shared, to
Not an exception to the rule, but a variation be sure, by the independent sector); and legislative
of it, is the appearance of the nonprofit executive. resistance to investing in the civil service.243
Nonprofit executives who are the most successful So, why are so many leaders losers in all sectors?
at raising money look more like teddy bears than Because leaders often are hired according to criteria
sharks. A study of the 100 highest-revenue non- that have nothing to do with intelligence, experi-
profits found that those CEOs whose faces exuded ence, and ability.
“warmth” headed organizations that had higher total
revenue and privately-sourced funding and more effi-
cient fundraising than did those CEOs who looked
NOTES
less cuddly and whose faces expressed “power.”238
1. Mike Micheli, “Most Government Workers
Like Working in the Public Sector,” Government
Swoon Song Executive (December 4, 2012). Figures are for
2012.
In addition, height counts, which gives men a
2. Samantha L. Durst and Victor S. DeSantis, “The
built-in advantage over most women. Of forty-three
Determinants of Job Satisfaction among Federal,
American presidents, only five, or 12 percent, have State, and Local Government Employees,” State
been significantly below the average height of and Local Government Review 29 (Winter 1997),
American men, and three have been barely below pp. 7–16.
the average height; the rest were taller.239 Each extra 3. Zeger van der Wal and Anne Oosterbaan, “Govern-
inch over the average height results in an average ment or Business: Identifying Determinants of
of about $1,000 more in annual income, after con- MPA and MBA Students’ Career Preferences,”
trolling for education and experience, and taller Public Personnel Management 42 (June 2013),
women earn more than shorter women.240 pp. 230–258. The quotations are on p. 230.
In a survey of “several hundred” Fortune 4. Sean T. Lyons, Linda E. Duxbury, and Christopher
500 companies, their male CEOs (more than 95 A. Higgins, “A Comparison of the Values and
percent of these CEOs are male or white241) were, Commitment of Private Sector, Public Sector,
The Fibers of Organizations: People 133

and Parapublic Sector Employees,” Public 15. David J. Houston and Katherine E. Cartwright,
Administration Review 66 (July/August 2006), “Spirituality and Public Service,” Public Admini-
pp. 605–618. stration Review 67 (January/February 2007),
5. Richard W. Stackman, Patrick E. Connor, and pp. 88–102.
Boris W. Becker, “Sectoral Ethos: An Investigation 16. Nevbahar Ertas, “Public Service Motivation
of the Personal Values Systems of Female and Theory and Voluntary Organizations,” Nonprofit
Male Managers in the Public and Private Sectors,” and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 43 (April 2014),
Journal of Public Administration Research and pp. 254–271.
Theory 16 (October 2006), pp. 577–597. The 17. David J. Houston, “‘Walking the Walk’ of Public
quotation is on p. 577. Service Motivation: Public Employees and
6. David Card, Alexandre Mas, Enrico Moretti, and Charitable Gifts of Time, Blood, and Money,”
Emmanuel Saez, Inequality at Work: The Effect of Journal of Public Administration Research and
Peer Salaries on Job Satisfaction, NBER Working Theory 16 (January 2006), pp. 67–86.
Paper No. 16396 (Cambridge, MA: National 18. Gene A. Brewer, “Building Social Capital: Attitudes
Bureau of Economic Research, 2010), p. 1. and Behavior of Public Servants,” Journal of Public
7. J. Stuart Bunderson and Jeffery A. Thompson, Administration Research and Theory 13 (January
“The Call of the Wild: Zookeepers, Callings, and 2003), pp. 5–20. The quotation is on p. 5.
the Double-edged Sword of Meaningful Work,” 19. Francesca Borgonovi, “Doing Well by Doing
Administrative Science Quarterly 54 (March Good: The Relationship between Formal Volun-
2009), pp. 32–57. The quotation is on p. 32. teering and Self-Reported Health and Happiness,”
8. Lars Tummers and Philip Rocco, “Serving Clients Social Science & Medicine 66 (November 2008),
When the Server Crashes: How Frontline Workers pp. 2321–2334.
Cope with E-Government Challenges,” Public 20. Elizabeth W. Dunn, Lara B. Aknin, and Michael
Administration Review 75 (November/December I. Norton, “Spending Money on Others Promotes
2015), pp. 817–827. Happiness,” Science 319 (March 21, 2008),
9. Bradley E. Wright, “Public Service and Motivation: pp. 1687–1688.
Does Mission Matter?” Public Administration 21. J. Richard Hackman and Greg R. Oldham, “Moti-
Review 67 (January/February 2007), pp. 54–63. vation through the Design Theory of Work: Test of
10. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit, a Theory,” Organizational Behavior and Human
For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors (Princeton, Performance 16 (August 1976), pp. 250–279.
NJ: Princeton Survey Research Associates 2002), 22. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, In Search of
p. 3. Figures are for 2001. Highly Skilled Workers: A Study on the Hiring of
11. Leonard Bright, “Public Employees with High Upper Level Employees from Outside the Federal
Levels of Public Service Motivation: Who Are Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
They, Where Are They, and What Do They Want?” Printing Office, 2008), p. 29. Figure, 47 percent, is
Review of Public Personnel Administration 25 for 2006.
(June 2005), pp. 138–154. 23. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Attracting the
12. Donald P. Moynihan and Sanjay K. Pandey, “The Next Generation: A Look at Federal Entry-Level
Role of Organizations in Fostering Public Service New Hires (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Motivation,” Public Administration Review 67 Printing Office, 2008), p. 35. Figure is for 2006.
(January/February 2007), pp. 40–53. 24. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit,
13. Adrian Ritz, Gene A. Brewer, and Oliver For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors, p. 3. Figures
Neumann, “Public Service Motivation: A are for 2001.
Systematic Literature Review and Outlook,” 25. Young-joo Lee and Vicky M. Wilkins, “More
Public Administration Review 76 (May/June Similarities or More Differences? Comparing
2016), pp. 414–426. The quotation is on p. 420. Public and Nonprofit Managers’ Job Motivations,”
14. Beth Gazley, “Good Governance Practices in Public Administration Review 71 (January/
Professional Associations for Public Employees: February 2011), pp. 45–56.
Evidence of a Public Service Ethos?” Public 26. Justin McCarthy, “Gov’t Workers Happier with
Administration Review 74 (November/December Retirement Plans, Other Benefits,” Gallup.com
2014), pp. 736–747. The quotation is on p. 737. (September 9, 2015).
134 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

27. Philip H. Mirvis and Edward J. Hackett, “Work Attitudes in Public and Private Organizations: A
and Work Force Characteristics in the Nonprofit Review and Extension,” Paper presented at the
Sector,” Monthly Labor Review 106 (April 1983), 1985 Annual Meeting of the American Political
pp. 3–12. Data (pp. 7, 10) are for 1977. Science Association (New Orleans, August 29–
28. Charity Navigator, 2014 CEO Compensation September 1, 1985), p. 9.
Study (Glen Rock, NJ: Author, 2014), pp. 9, 3. 44. Barry Z. Posner and Warren H. Schmidt, “The
29. As derived from data in Brookings Institution, Values of Business and Federal Government
Health of the Nonprofit, For-Profit, and Public Executives: More Different Than Alike,” Public
Service Sectors, p. 3. Figures are for 2001. Personnel Management 25 (Fall 1996), pp. 277–
30. Anna Tavis and Imperative, 2015 Workforce 290.
Purpose Index (New York: New York University, 45. Robert T. Golebiewski, Robert A. Boudreau,
2015). Ben-Chu Sun, et al., “Estimates of Burnout
31. Lee and Wilkins, “More Similarities or More in Public Agencies: Worldwide, How Many
Differences?” Employees Have Which Degrees of Burnout, and
32. Houston, “‘Walking the Walk’ of Public Service With What Consequences?” Public Administration
Motivation.” Review 58 (January/February 1998), pp. 59–64.
33. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit, 46. Steve Ander, Older U.S. Federal Employees Use
For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors, p. 3. Figures Their Strengths Less (Washington, DC: Gallup,
are for 2001. 2013), p. 2.
34. Chung-An Chen and Barry Bozeman, 47. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
“Organizational Risk Aversion: The Public and Workforce: Recent Trends in Federal Civilian
Non-Profit Sectors,” Public Management Review Employment and Compensation, GAO-14-215
14 (March 2012), pp. 377–402. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
35. Herbert A. Simon, Models of Man, Social and Office, 2014), Highlights page. Shrinkage began
Rational (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1957). in 2013.
36. Robert K. Merton, “Bureaucratic Structure 48. Tobin Im, “An Exploratory Study of Time Stress
and Personality,” Social Forces 18 (May 1940), and Its Causes among Government Employees,”
pp. 560–568. The quotations are on p. 563. Public Administration Review 69 (January/
37. Leisha DeHart-Davis, “The Unbureaucratic February 2009), pp. 104–115. The quotation is
Personality,” Public Administration Review 67 on p. 112.
(September/October 2007), pp. 892–903. 49. Mirvis and Hackett, “Work and Work Force
38. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Characteristics in the Nonprofit Sector,” p. 10.
Development, “Work-Life Balance,” OECD 50. Karlyn Brown, Attitudes About Work and Leisure
Better Life Index (Washington, DC: Author, in America (Washington, DC: American Enterprise
2013). Institute, 2001). Figures are for 1972–2000.
39. Joanne H. Gavin and Richard O. Mason, “The 51. Carole A. Jurkiewicz, Tom K. Massey, Jr., and
Virtuous Organization: The Value of Happiness Roger G. Brown, “Motivation in Public and
in the Workplace,” Organizational Dynamics 33 Private Organizations: A Comparative Study,”
(Winter 2004), pp. 379–392. Public Productivity & Management Review 21
40. Zainab Mudallal, “Nearly Half of Americans (March 1998), pp. 230–250. The quotation is on
Didn’t Take a Vacation Day in 2014,” Govexec. p. 230.
com (January 6, 2015). 52. Eran Vigoda-Gadot and Galit Meisler, “Emotions
41. Maren Hogan, “Defining Qualities of the Worst in Management and the Management of
Managers,” SmartBlog on Leadership (May 20, Emotions: The Impact of Emotional Intelligence
2014). and Organizational Politics on Public Sector
42. Hal G. Rainey, “Public Agencies and Private Employees,” Public Administration Review 70
Firms: Incentive Structures, Goals, and Individual (January/February 2010), pp. 72–86.
Roles,” Administration & Society 15 (August 53. Frank T. Paine, Stephen J. Carroll, and Burt A.
1983), pp. 207–242. Leete,“Need Satisfactions of Managerial Personnel
43. Hal G. Rainey, Carol Traut, and Barry Blunt, in a Government Agency,” Journal of Applied
“Reward Expectancies and Other Work-Related Psychology 50 (June 1966), pp. 247–249, and
The Fibers of Organizations: People 135

Bruce E. Buchanan, II, “Government Managers, Quarterly 9 (Fall 2002), pp. 6–16. The quotation
Business Executives, and Organizational Commit- is on p. 12. Figure is for 2001.
ment,” Public Administration Review 34 (July/ 66. Jed Devaro and Dana Brookshire, “Promotions
August 1974), pp. 339–347. and Incentives in Nonprofit and For-Profit
54. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal Organizations,” Industrial & Labor Relations
Government: A Model Employer or a Work Review 60 (April 2007), pp. 311–339.
in Progress? Perspectives from 25 Years of the 67. James R. Rawls, Robert A. Ulrich, and Oscar T.
Merit Principles Survey (Washington, DC: U.S. Nelson, “A. Comparison of Managers Entering
Government Printing Office, 2008), p. 20, and U.S. or Reentering the Profit and Nonprofit Sectors,”
Office of Personnel Management, 2010, 2011, Academy of Management Journal 18 (September
and 2015 Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey 1975), pp. 616–622.
Results (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 68. The following discussion is drawn from the
Printing Office, 2010, 2011, 2015, 2016), Q. 13. massive research of Frank U. Sulloway, Born to
Figures are for 1986–2014. Rebel (New York: Little, Brown, 1997).
55. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 69. Lisa A. Keister, “Sharing the Wealth: The Effects
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 40. of Siblings on Adults’ Wealth Ownership,” Demo-
56. Warren H. Schmidt and Barry Z. Posner, “Values graphy 40 (August 2003), pp. 521–542.
and Expectations of City Managers in California,” 70. Erik H. Erikson, Childhood and Society (New
Public Administration Review 47 (September/ York: Norton, 1950), pp. 219–234. The quo-
October 1987), pp. 404–409. The figure is on tations are on pp. 224–226, 231, 233. Erikson,
p. 408. perhaps the most well known of the adult psy-
57. Bill Brantley, “The Key to Government Employee chologists, does not segment adult development
Engagement,” PA Times Online (March 3, 2015). by age spans as we do in the text, but we doubt
58. Samantha L. Durst and Victor S. DeSantis, “The that most readers could easily identify with
Determinants of Job Satisfaction among Federal, some of the terms that he uses instead, such as
State, and Local Government Employees,” State “muscular-anal” and “locomotor-genital.”
and Local Government Review 29 (Winter 1997), 71. Ibid. This extra effort often benefits, in Erikson’s
pp. 7–16. Figures are for 1988. view, from intense psychoanalysis.
59. Brookings Institution, Health of the Nonprofit, 72. John Helliwell, Richard Layard, and Jeffrey
For-Profit, and Public Service Sectors, p. 6.  Figures Sachs, eds., World Happiness Report, 2016
are for 2001. Emphasis added. (New York: Earth Institute, Columbia University,
60. Durst and DeSantis, “The Determinants of Job 2016), p. 20. The U.S. ranks thirteenth out of 157
Satisfaction among Federal, State, and Local countries.
Government Employees,” p. 12. Figures are for 73. Yang Yang, “Social Inequalities in Happiness in
1988. the United States, 1972–2004: An Age-Period
61. Hal G. Rainey, “Perceptions of Incentives in Cohort Analysis,” American Sociological Review
Business and Government: Implications for Civil 73 (April 2008), pp. 204–226.
Service Reform,” Public Administration Review 74. Nicholas Henry, “Are Internships Worthwhile?”
39 (September/October 1979), pp. 440–448. Public Administration Review 39 (May/June
62. Card, Mas, Moretti, and Saez, Inequality at Work. 1979), pp. 245–257.
63. James L. Perry and Lyman W. Porter, “Factors 75. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Managing
Affecting the Context for Motivation for Public for Engagement—Communication, Connection,
Organizations,” Academy of Management Review and Courage (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
7 (January 1982), pp. 89–98. The quotation is on Printing Office, 2009), p. 2.
p. 96. 76. Daniel J. Levinson, with Charlotte N. Darrow,
64. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Poor Edward B. Klein, Mariah H. Levinson, and
Performers in Government: A Quest for the Braxton McKee, The Seasons of a Man’s Life
True Story (Washington, DC: U.S. Government (Alfred A. Knopf, 1978), p. 79.
Printing Office, 1999), p. 36. 77. George E. Vaillant, Adaptation to Life (Boston:
65. Paul C. Light, “The Content of Their Character: Little, Brown, 1977).
The State of the Nonprofit Workforce,” Nonprofit 78. Ibid., p. 228.
136 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

79. Levinson, et al., The Seasons of a Man’s Life, 97. Jennifer Loh, Simon Lloyd D. Restubog, and
p. 320. Thomas J. Zagenczyk, “Consequences of Work-
80. Roger Gould, Transformations: Growth and place Bullying on Employee Identification and
Change in Adult Life (New York: Simon and Satisfaction among Australians and Singaporeans,”
Schuster, 1978) p. 294. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology 41 (March
81. Vaillant, Adaptation to Life, p. 234. 2010), pp. 236–252.
82. Michael Maccoby, The Leader (New York: Simon 98. Mark F. Peterson, Peter B. Smith, et al., “Role
& Schuster, 1981), p. 221. Conflict, Ambiguity, and Overload: A 21-Nation
83. Manfred F. R. Kets De Vries, “Organizational Sleep- Study,” Academy of Management Journal 38
walkers: Emotional Distress at Mid-Life,” Human (April 1995), pp. 429–452.
Relations 52 (November 1999), pp. 1377–1401. 99. Michel Crozier, The Bureaucratic Phenomenon
84. Manfred F. R. Kets de Vries, Danny Miller, et al., (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964),
“Using the Life Cycle to Anticipate Satisfaction p. 236.
at Work,” Journal of Forecasting (Spring 1984), 100. Thomas W. H. Ng, Kelly L. Sorensen, and
pp. 161–172. Frederick K. K. Yim, “Does the Job Satisfaction-
85. Vaillant, Adaptation to Life. Job Performance Relationship Vary across Cult-
86. Kets de Vries, Miller, et al., “Using the Life Cycle ures?” Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology 40
to Anticipate Satisfaction at Work.” (September 2009), pp. 761–796.
87. Ruth Kanfer and Phillip L. Ackerman, “Aging, 101. Alvin W. Gouldner, “Cosmopolitans and Locals:
Adult Development, and Work Motivation,” Toward an Analysis of Latent Social Roles,”
Academy of Management Review 29 (July 2004), Administrative Science Quarterly 2 (December
pp. 440–458. The quotation is on p. 450. 1957 and March 1958), pp. 281–306 and 444–
88. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Managing 480, respectively.
for Engagement, p. 2. 102. Dwaine Marvick, Career Perspectives in a Bur-
89. Martin M. Greller and Linda K. Stroh, “Making eaucratic Setting, University of Michigan Gov-
the Most of ‘Late-Career’ for Employers and ernmental Studies, No. 27 (Ann Arbor, MI:
Workers Themselves: Becoming Elders Not University of Michigan Press, 1954), p. 28.
Relics,” Organizational Dynamics 33 (Spring 103. Lee and Wilkins, “More Similarities or More Diff-
2004), pp. 202–214. The quotation is on p. 202. erences?” p. 45.
90. Dee W. Henderson, “Enlightened Mentoring: A 104. Ibid.
Characteristic of Public Management,” Public 105. Marvick, Career Perspectives in a Bureaucratic
Administration Review 39 (November/December Setting, p. 134.
1985), pp. 857–863. The quotation is on p. 863. 106. Thomas S. Robertson and Yoram Wind, “Organi-
91. Geert Hofstede, “Motivation, Leadership, and zational Cosmopolitanism and Innovativeness,”
Organization: Do American Theories Apply Academy of Management Journal 26 (June 1983),
Abroad?” Organizational Dynamics 9 (Summer pp. 332–338.
1980), pp. 42–63. The quotation is on p. 43. 107. Marvick, Career Perspectives in a Bureaucratic
92. Right Management, Many Managers Found Setting, p. 145.
to Fail in Overseas Assignments (Philadelphia: 108. To cite just one example: Jean A. Wallace, “Org-
Author, 2013). anizational and Professional Commitment in
93. The following discussion is drawn from Geert Professional and Nonprofessional Organizations,”
Hofstede, Culture’s Consequences: International Administrative Science Quarterly 40 (June 1995),
Differences in Work-Related Values (Beverly pp. 228–255.
Hills, CA: Sage, 1980), and Geert Hofstede, 109. Bernard M. Bass, Stogdill’s Handbook of Leader-
“Cultural Constraints in Management Theories,” ship, Rev. ed. (New York: Free Press, 1981), p. 7.
Academy of Management Executive 7 (January The word “leadership” first appeared in the late
1993), pp. 21–32. nineteenth century, and then only in writings
94. Hofstede, “Motivation, Leadership, and Organi- about the British parliament.
zation,” p. 54. 110. As derived from data in Joseph C. Rost, Leadership
95. Ibid. p. 58. for the Twenty-first Century (New York: Praeger,
96. Ibid., p. 57. 1991), p. 46.
The Fibers of Organizations: People 137

111. Bernard M. Bass, Stodgill’s Handbook of Lead- Superintendents: Vital or Irrelevant? (Washington,
ership: Theory, Research, and Managerial DC: Brookings, 2014), p. 1.
Applications, 3rd ed. (New York: Free Press, 129. Eleanor Fujita,The Evaluation of College Presidents:
1990). Figure is an estimate. Bass counted more Dimensions Used by Campus Leaders (College
than 7,800 published studies of leadership Park, MD: National Center for Postsecondary
as of the late 1980s, so our estimate likely is Governance and Finance, 1990), p. 20.
conservative. 130. Anna Neumann and Estela M. Bensimon,
112. Quoted in Joshua Rothman, “Shut Up and Sit Constructing the Presidency: College Presidents’
Down,” The New Yorker (February 29, 2016), Images of Their Leadership Roles, a Comparative
pp. 64–69. The quotation is on p. 64. Study (College Park, MD: National Center for
113. “American Survey: The Leadership Thing,” The Postsecondary Governance and Finance, 1990),
Economist (December 9, 1995), p. 31. pp. 19–20. Emphasis added.
114. Rothman, “Shut Up and Sit Down,” p. 64. 131. Jitendra V. Singh, David J. Tucker, and Robert
115. Rost, Leadership for the Twenty-first Century, J. House, “Organizational Legitimacy and the
p.10. Figure is for circa 1910–1990. Liability of Newness,” Administrative Science
116. James MacGregor Burns, Leadership (New York: Quarterly 31 (June 1986), pp. 171–193.
Harper & Row, 1978), p. 2. 132. Tracey Trottier, Montgomery Van Wart, and
117. Rost, Leadership for the Twenty-first Century, XiaoHu Wang, “Examining the Nature and
p. 102. Significance of Leadership in Government
118. John P. Kotter, “What Leaders Really Do,” Harvard Organizations,” Public Administration Review 68
Business Review 68 (May/June 1990), pp. 103– (March/April 2008), pp. 319–333. The quotation
111. The quotations are on p. 104. is on p. 329.
119. Ibid., p. 104. 133. John Crum, “Improving the Performance of
120. Henry Mintzberg, The Nature of Managerial Federal Supervisors,” Issues of Merit (Washington,
Work (New York: Harper & Row, 1973). DC: U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, April
121. Alan W. Lau, Arthur R. Newman, and Laurie 2010), pp. 2–3. The quotation is on p. 2.
A. Broedling, “The Nature of Managerial Work in 134. James Down, Richard Cowell, and Karen Morgan,
the Public Sector,” Public Administration Review “What Determines Ethical Behavior in Public
40 (September/October 1980), pp. 513–520. The Organizations: Is It Rules or Leadership?” Public
quotation is on p. 519. Administration Review 76 (November/December
122. Victor A. Thompson, Modern Organizations 2016), pp. 898–909.
(New York: Knopf, 1961). 135. Lars G. Tummers and Eva Knies, “Leadership and
123. Ibid. Meaningful Work in the Public Sector,” Public
124. Ethan R. Mollick, “People and Process, Suits Administration Review 73 (November/December,
and Innovators: The Role of Individuals in Firm 2013), pp. 859–868. The quotation is on p. 859.
Performance,” Strategic Management Journal 33 136. Michael McGuire and Chris Silvia, “Does Leader-
(9, 2012), pp. 1001–1015. ship in Networks Matter? Examining the Effects
125. Stanley Lieberson and James F. O’Connor, of Leadership Behaviors on Managers’ Perceptions
“Leadership and Organizational Performance: of Network Effectiveness,” Public Performance &
A Study of Large Corporations,” American Socio- Management Review 33 (September 2009), pp.
logical Review 37 (August 1972), pp. 117–130. 34–62. The quotation is on p. 54.
126. Thomas R. Dye, “Executive Power and Public 137. Claudia N. Avellaneda, “Mayoral Quality and
Policy in the States,” Western Political Quarterly Local Public Finance,” Public Administration
27 (December 1969), pp. 73–82. The quotation is Review 69 (May/June 2009), pp. 469–486. The
on p. 938. quotation is on p. 469.
127. G. R. Salancik and Jeffrey Pfeffer, “Constraints on 138. Rhys Andrews and George A. Boyne, “Capacity,
Administrative Discretion: The Limited Influence Leadership, and Organizational Performance:
of Mayors on City Budgets,” Urban Affairs Testing the Black Box Model of Public Manage-
Quarterly 12 (April 1977), pp. 475–498. ment,” Public Administration Review 70 (May/
128. Matthew M. Chingos, Grover J. (Russ) June 2010), pp. 443–453. The quotation is on
Whitehurst, and Katharine M. Lindquist, School p. 450.
138 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

139. Crum, “Improving the Performance of Federal 156. M. Audrey Korsgaard, David M. Schweiger,
Supervisors,” p. 2. and Harry J. Sapienza, “Building Commitment,
140. Partnership for Public Service, The Federal Attachment, and Trust in Strategic Decision-
Leadership Challenge (Washington, DC: Author, Making Teams: The Role of Procedural Justice,”
April 2012). Academy of Management Journal 38 (February
141. Jessica Word and Sung Min Park, “Working across 1995), pp. 60–85. The quotation is on p. 60.
the Divide: Job Involvement in the Public and 157. Yoon Jik Cho and Evan J. Ringquist, “Managerial
Nonprofit Sectors,” Review of Public Personnel Trustworthiness and Organizational Outcomes,”
Administration 29 (June 2009), pp. 103–133. The Journal of Public Administration Research and
quotation is on p. 126. Theory 21 (January 2011), pp. 53–86. The quota-
142. Rost, Leadership for the Twenty-first Century, tion is on p. 53.
p. 28. 158. Fred Redl, “Group Emotion and Leadership,”
143. Quoted in ibid., p. 47. Psychiatry 5 (November 1942), pp. 574–584. The
144. Daniel Katz and Robert L. Kahn, The Social quotation is on p. 576.
Psychology of Organizations (New York: Wiley, 159. Burns, Leadership.
1966). 160. Bernard M. Bass and Bruce J. Avolio, “Transfor-
145. Ralph M. Stodgill, “Personal Factors Associated mational Leadership and Organizational Culture,”
with Leadership: A Survey of the Literature,” Public Administration Quarterly 17 (Spring 1993),
Journal of Psychology 25 (June 1948), pp. 35–71. pp.112–122. The quotation is on p. 113.
146. Kurt Lewin, Ronald Lippitt, and Ralph K. White, 161. Thomas Kell and Gregory T. Carrott, “Culture
“Patterns of Aggressive Behavior in Experimentally Matters Most,” Harvard Business Review 83
Created Social Climates,” Journal of Social (May 2005), pp. 22–24.
Psychology 10 (March 1939), pp. 271–299. 162. Burns, Leadership, p. 20.
147. E. S. Bogardus, Leaders and Leadership (New 163. Robert House, “A 1976 Theory of Charismatic
York: Appleton-Century, 1934), p. 3. Leadership,” Leadership: The Cutting Edge, James
148. Fred E. Fiedler, A Theory of Leadership Effect- G. Hunt and Lars Larson, eds. (Carbondale, IL:
iveness (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1967). Southern Illinois University Press, 1977), pp. 189–
149. Michael J. Strube and Joseph E. Garcia, “A Meta- 207. The quotation is on p. 196.
Analytical Investigation of Fiedler’s Contingency 164. Jay A. Conger and Rabinda N. Kanungo,
Model of Leadership Effectiveness,” Psychological “Toward a Behavioral Theory of Charismatic
Bulletins 90 (September 1981), pp. 307–321. Leadership in Organizational Settings,” Academy
150. Robert J. House, “A Path-Goal Theory of of Management Review 12 (November 1987),
Leadership,” Administrative Science Quarterly 16 pp. 637–647.
(September 1971), pp. 321–338. 165. Celeste P. M. Wilderom, Peter T. van den Berg,
151. Stanley E. Weed, Terrance R. Mitchell, and and Uco J. Wiersma, “A Longitudinal Study
William Moffitt, “Leadership Style, Subordinate’s of the Effects of Charismatic Leadership and
Personality, and Task Type as Predictors of Organizational Culture on Objective and Perceived
Performance and Satisfaction With Supervision,” Corporate Performance,” The Leadership Quar-
Journal of Applied Psychology 61 (February terly 23 (October 2012), pp. 835–848. The quota-
1976), pp. 58–66. tion is on p. 835.
152. Ricky N. Griffin, “Relationships Among Indivi- 166. Flavia Cavazotte, Valter Moreno, and Mateus
dual Task Design, and Leader Behavior Variables,” Hickmann, “Effects of Leader Intelligence, Per-
Academy of Management Journal 23 (December sonality and Emotional Intelligence on Trans-
1980), pp. 665–683. formational Leadership and Managerial
153. House, “A Path-Goal Theory of Leadership.” Performance,” The Leadership Quarterly 23 (June
154. Weed, Mitchell, and Moffitt, “Leadership Style, 2012), pp. 443–455. The quotation is on p. 443.
Subordinate’s Personality, and Task Type as 167. Peng Wang and Joseph Rode, “Transformational
Predictors of Performance and Satisfaction With Leadership and Follower Creativity: The Mode-
Supervision.” rating Effects of Identification with Leader and
155. Griffin, “Relationships Among Individual Task Organizational Climate,” Human Relations 63
Design, and Leader Behavior Variables.” (August 2010), pp. 1105–1128.
The Fibers of Organizations: People 139

168. Robert J. House, William D. Spangler, and James Sector: Measurement and Consequences,” Public
Woycke, “Personality and Charisma in the U.S. Administration Review 63 (March/April 2003),
Presidency: A Psychological Theory of Leader pp. 229–242. The quotation is on p. 229.
Effectiveness,” Administrative Science Quarterly 179. Marloes L. Van Engen and Tineke M. Willemsen,
36 (September 1991), pp. 364–396. The quota- “Sex and Leadership Styles: A Meta-Analysis of
tion is on p. 364. Research Published in the 1990s,” Psychological
169. Ashley L. Watts, Scott O. Lilienfeld, Sarah Francis Reports 94 (February 2004), pp. 13–18.
Smith, et al., “The Double-Edged Sword of 180. Anette Rohmann, “Relationships between
Grandiose Narcissism: Implications for Successful Leadership Styles and Followers’ Emotional
and Unsuccessful Leadership Among U.S. Experience and Effectiveness in the Voluntary
Presidents,” Psychological Science 24 (December Sector,” Nonprofit & Voluntary Sector Quarterly
2013), pp.  2379–2389. The quotations are on 38 (April 2009), pp. 270–286.
p. 2379. 181. Kristina Jaskyte, “Predictors of Administrative
170. John Williamson and Stephen Haggard, “The and Technological Innovations in Nonprofit
Political Conditions for Economic Reform,” Organizations,” Public Administration Review 71
The Political Economy of Policy Reform, John (January/February 2011), pp. 77–86.
Williamson, ed. (Washington, DC: Institute for 182. Bobbi Watt Geer, Jill K. Maher, and Michele T.
International Economics, 1993), pp. 525–599. The Cole, “Managing Nonprofit Organizations: The
quotation is on p. 539. Importance of Transformational Leadership and
171. Jason L. Jensen, “Getting One’s Way in Commitment to Operating Standards for Non-
Group  Decision-Making: Influence Tactics Used profit Accountability,” Public Performance  &
in Group Decision-Making Settings,” Public Management Review 32 (September 2008),
Administration Review 67 (March/April 2007), pp. 51–75.
pp. 216–227. 183. Patrick Dwyer, Joyce Bono, Mark Snyder, et al.,
172. Bradley E. Wright, Donald P. Moynihan, and Sanjay “Sources of Volunteer Motivation: Transformat-
K. Pandey, “Pulling the Levers: Transformational ional Leadership and Personal Motives Influence
Leadership, Public Service Motivation, and Outcomes,” Nonprofit Management and Leader-
Mission Valence,” Public Administration Review ship 24 (Winter 2013), pp. 181–205.
72 (March/April 2012), pp. 206–215. 184. Robert Birnbaum, How Academic Leadership
173. Nicola Belle, “Leading to Make a Difference: A Works: Understanding Success and Failure in the
Field Experiment on the Performance Effects of College Presidency (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass,
Transformational Leadership, Perceived Social 1992), pp. 30–31.
Impact, and Public Service Motivation,” Journal 185. There is a spate of research that supports this
of Public Administration Research & Theory 24 statement, but the following five-year study exam-
(January 2014), pp. 109–136. ined twenty-nine for-profit corporate boards, six
174. Ibid., p. 109. nonprofit boards, and four boards of government-
175. Bradley E. Wright and Sanjay K. Pandey, “Trans- owned enterprises, and came to the same conclus-
formational Leadership in the Public Sector: Does ion. See: Richard Leblanc and James Gillies,
Structure Matter?” Journal of Public Admini- Inside the Boardroom (Mississauga, Canada:
stration Research and Theory 20 (January 2010), Wiley, 2005).
pp. 75–89. The quotation is on p. 85. 186. Trottier, Van Wart, and Wang, “Examining the
176. Wang and Rode, “Transformational Leadership Nature and Significance of Leadership in Govern-
and Follower Creativity.” ment Organizations,” p. 329.
177. Graeme Currie and Andy Lockett, “A Critique of 187. Jerry Mitchell, “Representation in Government
Transformational Leadership: Moral, Professional Boards and Commissions,” Public Administration
and Contingent Dimensions of Leadership within Review 57 (March/April, 1997), pp. 160–167.
Public Services Organizations,” Human Relations The quotation is on p. 166.
60 (February 2007), pp. 341–371. The quotation 188. James H. Svara, “The Shifting Boundaries
is on p. 341. between Elected Officials in Large Council-
178. Mansour Javidan and David A. Waldman, Manager Cities,” Public Administration Review
“Exploring Charismatic Leadership in the Public 59 (January/February 1999), pp. 44–53.
140 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

189. Rob Gurwit, “Are City Councils a Relic of the 202. Jonathan D. Glater and David Leonhardt, “Bill
Past?” Governing (April 2003), pp. 20–24. The Addressing Business Fraud Is Seen as First Step,”
quotation is on p. 21. New York Times (July 25, 2002).
190. James H. Svara, “Leadership and Professionalism 203. Freiwirth, Hiland, Burns, et al., “Voices of Board
in County Government,” The American County: Chairs.” Figure is for 2016.
Frontiers of Knowledge, Donald C. Menzel, ed. 204. Francie Ostrower, Nonprofit Governance in the
(Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press, United States: Findings on Performance and Acc-
1996), pp. 109–127. The quotation is on p. 118. ountability from the First National Representative
191. Lynn Olson and Ann Bradley, “Boards of Study (Washington, DC: Urban Institute, 2007).
Contention,” Education Week Special Journal 205. Rebeccaa J. Kassane and Jeff Gingerich, “Do
Report (April 29, 1992) pp. 30–39. You See What I See? Nonprofit and Resident
192. Ellen Todras, The Changing Role of School Perceptions of Urban Neighborhood Problems,”
Boards, ERIC Digest No. 84 (Eugene, OR: Eric Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 33
Clearinghouse on Educational Management, May (June 2004), pp. 311–333.
1993), p. 1. 206. Herman, “Are Public Service Nonprofit Boards
193. See, for example, Lucia Bebchuk and Jesse Meeting Their Responsibilities?” p. 388.
Fried, Pay without Performance: The Unfulfilled 207. Ibid. Figures are for 2006. A large organization is
Promise of Executive Compensation (Cambridge, one that spends at least $10 million annually.
MA: Harvard University Press, 2004). 208. Ruth McCambridge, “WSJ: Hospitals Do Business
194. George A. Boyne, Oliver James, Peter John, with Board Members at 6X the Rate of Other
and Nicolai Petrovsky, “Does Public Service Nonprofits,” Nonprofitquarterly.org (August 22,
Performance Affect Top Management Turnover?” 2016). Data are for 2014.
Journal of Public Administration Research and 209. Edward R. Dyl, Howard L. Frant, and Craig A.
Theory 20, Supplement 2 (April 2010), pp. i261– Stephenson, “Governance and Funds Allocation
i279. in United States Medical Research Charities,”
195. Judy Freiwirth, Mary Hiland, Michael Burns, et Financial Accountability and Management 16
al., “Voices of Board Chairs: A National Study (November 2000), pp. 335–352.
on the Perspectives of Nonprofit Board Chairs,” 210. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax-
Nonprofitquarterly.org (October 12, 2016). Exempt Sector: Governance, Transparency, and
196. Robert D. Herman, “Are Public Service Nonprofit Oversight Are Critical for Maintaining Public
Boards Meeting Their Responsibilities?” Public Trust, GAO-05-561T (Washington, DC: U.S.
Administration Review 69 (May/June 2009), Government Printing Office, 2005), pp. 13–14.
pp. 387–390. The quotations are on p. 389. 211. Robert Hooijberg and Jaepil Choi, “The Impact
197. Vic Murray, Pat Bradshaw, and Jacob Wolpin, of Organizational Characteristics on Leadership
“Power In and Around Nonprofit Boards: A Effectiveness Models: An Examination of
Neglected Dimension of Governance,” Nonprofit Leadership in Private and Public-Sector Organi-
Management & Leadership 3 (Winter 1992), pp. zation,” Administration & Society 33 (September
165–182. 2001), pp. 403–431.
198. Wendy Reid and Johanne Turbide, “Growth Crises 212. Trottier, Van Wart, and Wang, “Examining the
and Three Phases of Governance Response,” Nature and Significance of Leadership in Govern-
Nonprofitquarterly.org (December 19, 2013). ment Organizations,” p. 330.
199. Kelly LeRoux, “Managing Stakeholder Demands,” 213. Jon A. Andersen, “Assessing Public Managers’
Administration & Society 41 (April 2009), pp. Change-Oriented Behavior: Are Public Managers
158–184. The quotations are on p. 158. in the Doldrums?” International Journal of Public
200. Judith L. Millesen, “Who ‘Owns’ Your Non- Administration 33 (May 2010), pp. 335–345. The
profit?” The Nonprofit Quarterly (September 21, quotation is on p. 342.
2002). 214. Jon Aarum Andersen, “Public versus Private
201. Garry W. Jenkins, “The Wall Street Takeover of Managers: How Public and Private Managers
Nonprofit Boards,” Stanford Social Innovation Differ in Leadership Behavior,” Public Admini-
Review 13 (Summer 2015), ssireview.org. Figures stration Review 70 (January/February 2010),
are for 1989–2014 and 2003–2013, respectively. pp. 131–141. The quotations are on p. 137.
The Fibers of Organizations: People 141

215. Andersen, “Assessing Public Managers’ Change- Personality and Social Psychology 107 (December
Oriented Behavior.” 2014), pp. 1033–1055.
216. Hooijberg and Choi, “The Impact of Organi- 228. Malcolm Gladwell, Blink: The Power of Thinking
zational Characteristics on Leadership Effective- without Thinking (New York: Back Bay Books,
ness Models.” 2007), pp. 84–88.
217. Trottier, Van Wart, and Wang, “Examining the 229. Eve E. Garrow, “Does Race Matter in Govern-
Nature and Significance of Leadership in Govern- ment Funding of Nonprofit Human Services
ment Organizations,” p. 329. Organizations? The Interaction of Neighborhood
218. George L. Hanbury, II, “Leadership ‘Fit’ and Poverty and Race,” Journal of Public Admini-
Effectiveness: Trust and Performance,” Paper pre- stration Research & Theory 24 (April 2014),
sented at the Annual Conference of the American pp. 381–405.
Society for Public Administration (Phoenix, AZ, 230. Justice Anthony Kennedy, in Texas Department
March 2002), p. 27. of Housing and Community Affairs v. Inclusive
219. Hooijberg and Choi, “The Impact of Organi- Communities Project, Inc.
zational Characteristics on Leadership Effective- 231. Aaron W. Lukaszewski, Zachary L. Simmons,
ness Models.” and James R. Cameron, “The Role of Physical
220. Meredith A. Newman, Mary E. Guy, and Sharon Formidability in Human Social Status Allocation,”
H. Mastracci, “Beyond Cognition: Affective Lead- Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 110
ership and Emotional Labor,” Public Admini- (March 2016), pp. 385–406.
stration Review 69 (January/February 2009), 232. John R. Graham, Campbell R. Harvey, and Manju
pp. 6–20. The quotation is on p. 17. Puri, “A Corporate Beauty Contest” (December
221. Hooijberg and Choi, “The Impact of Organi- 19, 2013). Paper presented at the American
zational Characteristics on Leadership Effective- Finance Association’s annual meeting, Denver,
ness Models.” CO, 2011.
222. M. Andrew Frazier and James E. Swiss, “Con- 233. Joseph T. Halford and Hung-Chia Hsu, “Beauty Is
trasting Views of Results-Based Management Wealth: CEO Appearance and Shareholder Value”
Tools from Different Organizational Levels,” (Milwaukee: University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
International Public Management Journal 11 (2, December 19, 2013).
2008), pp. 214–234. The quotation is on p. 214. 234. Nicholas O. Rule and Konstantin O. Tskhay, “The
223. Rhys Andrews, George A. Boyne, Jae M. Moon, Influence of Economic Context on the Relation-
and Richard M. Walker, “Assessing Organizational ship between Chief Executive Officer Facial App-
Performance: Exploring Differences between earance and Company Profits,” The Leadership
Internal and External Measures,” International Quarterly 25 (October 2014), pp. 846–854. The
Public Management Journal 13 (2, 2010), quotation is on p. 846.
pp. 105–129. 235. Eblin Group, “Three Signs That You Have Too
224. William A. Brown and Chao Guo, “Exploring Much Executive Presence,” Eblingroup.com
the Key Roles for Nonprofit Boards,” Nonprofit (April 9, 2015).
& Voluntary Sector Quarterly 39 (June 2010), 236. Peter Belmi and Margaret Neale, “Mirror, Mirror
pp. 536–546. on the Wall, Who’s the Fairest of Them All?
225. Birgit Schyns and Jan Schilling, “How Bad Are Thinking that One Is Attractive Increases the
the Effects of Bad Leaders? A Meta-analysis Tendency to Support Inequality,” Organizational
of Destructive Leadership and Its Outcomes,” Behavior and Human Decision Processes 124
The Leadership Quarterly 24 (February 2013), (March 2014), pp. 133–149.
pp. 138–158. The quotations are on p. 138. 237. Nicholas J. Raihani and Sarah Smith, “Competitive
226. Manfred F. R. Kets de Vries, “The Psycho-Path to Helping in Online Giving,” Current Biology 25
Disaster: Coping with SOB Executives,” Organi- (May 2015), pp. 1183–1186. The quotation is on
zational Dynamics 43 (January–March 2014), pp. p. 1183.
17–26. The quotations are on pp. 18, 19. 238. Daniel E. Re and Nicholas O. Rule, “Predicting
227. Charleen R. Case and Jon K. Maner, “Divide and Firm Success from the Facial Appearance of Chief
Conquer: When and Why Leaders Undermine Executive Officers of Non-Profit Organizations”
the Cohesive Fabric of Their Group,” Journal of (Toronto: University of Toronto, 2016).
142 PA R T I I Public and Nonprofit Organizations

239. Gert Stulp, Abraham P. Buunk, Simon Verhulst, Asian- or Hispanic-Americans, for a total of 4.4 per-
and Thomas V. Pollet, “Tall Claims? Sense and cent. In 2014, women accounted for 4.6 percent.
Nonsense about the Importance of Height in 242. Gladwell, Blink, p. 5.
US Presidents,” The Leadership Quarterly 24 243. Kellie Lunney, “Ex-HR Chiefs: Some Federal
(February 2013), pp. 159–171. Managers Just Can’t Manage,” Government
240. Steven E. Landsburg, “Short Changed,” Slate.com Executive (December 5, 2013).
(March 25, 2002).
241. DiversityInc. In 2013, 1.2 percent of these CEOs
were African-Americans, and 1.6 percent each were
PART

III

Public and Nonprofit


Management: Curbing
Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency
Public and nonprofit management is the develop- Fiscal decentralization, a corollary of federal
ment or application of methodical and system- systems, also appears to reduce corruption in coun-
atic techniques that are designed to analyze and tries, even in those that are highly politicized.5
make the operations of governments and public-
service  nonprofit organizations more efficient and Culture and Corruption National cultures that
effective. are poor and rural, and which have centralized
In Part III, we review the public and nonprofit governments,6 politically disengaged citizenries,7 a
sectors’ experiences with public management’s repressed press,8 citizens who are distrusting of each
major methods, each of which was initially estab- other,9 greater regulatory activity (which seems to
lished, in large part and occasionally in whole part, offer more opportunities to corrupt),10 and poorly
as a reaction to corrupt governance, and each still is paid public officials11 who were recruited into gov-
used to curb it. ernment by means other than a merit-based person-
nel system12 associate with high rates of corruption.
The impact of religion on global graft is
CORRUPTION’S CAUSES AND mixed,13 but in the United States, faith is irrelevant.
CONTINUANCE: THE LARGER The depth of religious belief in the American states
“is not related to instances of government corrup-
PICTURE tion . . . despite reasons to expect otherwise.”14
Before we enter in the thorny thicket of American cor- An agency’s culture also can encourage graft
ruption, let us address graft from a global perspective. when: there is no “clear integrity policy”; colleagues
are loyal to one another; and supervision is too lax
or too oppressive (surprisingly, oppression spawns
Corruption’s Causes more misconduct than laxity).15 These cultural prob-
Corruption’s causes are structural, cultural, and, of lems worsen, and the probability of graft rises, when
course, personal. an agency is confronted by unrealistically high per-
formance goals, punishment is inflicted when they
Governmental Structure and Graft A large are not met, and oversight is weak.16
“number of administrative units in a country lowers
corruption,”1 and “the finding in earlier research The Corrupt Public Official Money is the leading
that federalism increases corruption is not robust”;2 reason why public officials become corrupt (although,
in fact, the illegal, tax-evading, “shadow economy is “strikingly, the corrupt official rarely receives a gift
smaller in federal countries than in unitary states,”3 for which concrete compensation is expected”—
although “an increase in the income tax rate will there is “no clear quid pro quo”), followed closely
unambiguously increase the taxpayer’s level of by love, friendship, and status. Corrupt officials
evasion.”4 often have domineering personalities, are popular,
144 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

and are viewed as effective, characteristics that give who favor low taxes may “hold their noses and
them “space to maneuver.” (In fact, large physical vote” for continued corruption.25
spaces, such as disproportionately big desks, can
cause the people occupying them to feel “more pow-
erful,” which, in turn, leads to “increases in dishon- COMPREHENDING CORRUPTION
est behavior.”17) They slowly “‘slide down’ toward
corruption” and maintain “a long, institutionalized IN AMERICA
relationship” with their corruptors. Corrupt officials Recall that in the introduction to Part I we out-
rarely think of themselves as corrupt, even though lined the prodigious public price of corruption, but,
they commit multiple corrupt acts.18 A variation beyond those data, what do we know about graft?
on this final point is that corrupt powerful people Not much: “In the literature on corruption, there is
who perceive that their power is legitimate are more much speculation on its nature, but there are hardly
corrupt and hypocritical than are those who see any empirical qualitative studies on the nature of
themselves as holding power illegitimately.19 corruption.”26 We address what there is here.
Lord Acton’s famous phrase, uttered in 1887,
that, “Power tends to corrupt, and absolute power
corrupts absolutely,” is not really accurate. Gaining Tradition! Good Old Graft
power merely reveals its owner’s already-existing Traditionally, political corruption has meant fraud
character, for good or ill. Moral power holders do or graft—that is, crooked public (and, we are learn-
not misuse their power, but less moral ones do. A ing, nonprofit) officials embezzling governments’
high level of power “interacting” with high testos- or independent organizations’ money, or accepting
terone in a leader often leads to the leader’s corrup- bribes to waste it. Graft committed by government
tion.20 “Psychological research strongly suggests employees against their organizations accounts for
that we should care a great deal about our leaders’ 16 percent of all known graft, nonprofit workers
personalities . . . because no position is prestigious make up 12 percent, and business employees com-
or noble enough to make a person of questionable prise the rest.27 Plundering the public and nonprofit
character behave themselves.”21 purses can range from a single perpetrator’s petty
larceny to the creation of a kleptocracy.

Corruption’s Continuance Corruption as Sneaky-Pete Politics Consider


The continuance of those governmental and cultural a cluster of small, cheek-by-jowl towns in south-
conditions, just listed, that produce corruption also eastern Los Angeles County, California. Each has
ensure its persistence. Additionally, the more central- a largely working-class and immigrant population,
ized the government, the more “fused” that political extraordinarily low voter turnout (often less than a
power is within it, and the less access that the press tenth of the electorate), high voter fraud, an unbal-
has to the government, the more likely that corrupt anced budget, exceptionally high taxes, deep debt,
officials will survive attempts to prosecute them.22 and corruption at the top (corruption, we should
Democracies are largely free of these conditions, note, that is on steroids). Some examples follow.
and the more vibrant the democracy—that is, large
numbers of citizens voting regularly in competitive Living Well in Bell As the result of a 2005 munici-
elections—the more honest the government.23 By pal election in which fewer than 400 residents voted,
contrast, in democracies where there is low voter town officials lived well in Bell. Its city manager
turnout corruption often is deeply entrenched.24 commanded a compensation that topped out at
Regrettably, some voters prefer corrupt democ- $1.5 million, but with the added bonus of guaran-
racies to honest ones. In democratic jurisdictions, teed annual increases of 12 percent. (It greatly facil-
graft often associates with reduced public spend- itated the city manager’s gluttonous graft that the
ing. If citizens’ demands for services are “relatively mayor, who signed off on all this and much more,
elastic,” then this association sometimes leads to could not read English.) Compensation for other
lower taxes. “Under this condition,” some citizens officials ranged from $400,000 to $546,000. The
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 145

part-time mayor and other council members each a corner of Los Angeles County without acknowledg-
were paid almost $100,000. (Towns of comparable ing the league’s national champion: Rita Crundwell,
size—30,000 to 40,000 people—pay their council who served as the appointed treasurer and comp-
members an average wage of $4,800.28) troller of Dixon (population, fewer than 16,000,
These and other irregularities almost bank- and Ronald Reagan’s boyhood home), Illinois, for
rupted Bell. The mayor stoutly defended these sala- thirty years. Over that time, Crundwell embezzled
ries, including his, by insisting that “our streets are nearly $54 million, forcing the city to drastically cut
cleaner.” It is impossible to make this stuff up. In services, including letting employees go for lack of
2011, 95 percent of Bell’s voters recalled four council funds, freezing salaries for two years, and nixing
members and elected a new mayor and council, none the purchase of new radios for police. In 2013,
of whom had ever held elected office. Crundwell was sentenced to nearly twenty years in
After four years of legal wrangling, the judge federal prison. Her embezzlement is thought to be
described the city manager as “a godfather of sorts,” the largest municipal fraud in American history.
and sentenced him to twelve years in state prison
(not to mention close to three years in federal prison
for tax fraud) and fined him almost $9 million in res- Corruption as Conquest: Janitorial Joys
titution. The judge called the assistant city manager On occasion, an otherwise-honest public agency is
“a hog,” and sentenced her to almost twelve years effectively “captured” by a corrupt sub-organiza-
and fined her more than $8 million. The mayor and tion that, for all intents and purposes, is the reigning
the other six council members received lesser but power center that really runs, or at least sufficiently
still stiff fines, and three were sentenced to prison intimidates, the larger organization.
and one to home confinement. An example is New York City’s 8,500 school
custodians, who control a half-billion dollar budget
Maywood’s Miseries The luckless town of for 1,200 schools. Custodial scandals have erupted
Maywood, faced with a fiscal crisis, threatened with since 1924, and to this day the custodians are “sys-
cancellation of its insurance coverage, and fed up tematically transforming their schools into enter-
with its historically surly police force, outsourced all prises for bribery, extortion, theft, and nepotism.”
its services in 2010, with most, unfortunately, going Custodians give themselves, friends, and family “no-
to neighboring Bell, which assigned its hoggish assis- show jobs” and pay them fraudulent overtime, steal
tant city manager to administer them. Just weeks school funds to renovate their homes, and extort
later, Bell’s scandals surfaced, and, within a year, the contractors. “Most principals [are] terrified of what
town had dismissed Bell. But Bell had left a mess they dubbed custodians’ ‘reigns of terror.’”29
in Maywood: missing records, no budget for nine
months, fiscal data so shambolic that it could not
be determined if the town was solvent, and a broad Corruption as Culture: Murder and
federal investigation of Maywood officials. Mortification
The most ominous sort of traditional graft is that
Is There Something in the Water? There is more. which defines the civic culture itself, and this kind of
Two Commerce council members were convicted of corruption can morph into one mean monster.
corruption in 2010 and 2012. Three former council Consider the case of Phenix City, in Russell
members in Lynwood were convicted, in 2012, of County, Alabama. Over the course of a century, both
misappropriation of funds, including illegally boost- localities had evolved in such a way that, by the
ing their own salaries. In 2013, Cudahy’s former 1950s, virtually every local official had some person-
mayor, council member, and administrator were ally-rewarding connection with racketeering; the rest
convicted of extortion and accepting bribes. The list of Alabama was mortified. Alabama’s newly-elected
goes on. Perhaps there is something in the water. attorney general, who had won on the pledge that he
would clean up corruption, was assassinated shortly
The Champ We cannot abandon the cornucopia of after the election. Alabama’s governor appointed a
corruption plaguing some little local governments in military force to take charge of both jurisdictions,
146 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

and declared martial law in Russell County. One donors or anyone else. Reynolds surrendered an
hundred fifty-two people eventually were convicted unspecified amount of his personal assets to the
of corruption.30 court, and was sternly ordered to never, ever get
into the charity business again; in other words, he
walked.
Fraud in the Independent Sector To say that the case’s outcome was unsatisfy-
There are three kinds of corruption in the independ- ing is an understatement. Reynolds skated, in part,
ent sector: nonprofit organizations that defraud because honest nonprofits characteristically ignore
governments, or defraud their donors, and nonprofit the damage being done to them by corrupt nonprof-
employees who defraud their organizations. its, and resist the sort of regulation that would quash
their frauds more quickly.35 And they also walked
Defrauding Government Two official examina- because government was asleep at the switch; it is
tions of nonprofits found that from more than 3 telling that, despite clear evidence of fraud, it not
percent (or more than 55,000) to nearly 4 percent only took decades before official action began, but
(64,200) of income-tax-exempt organizations owe that the IRS was nowhere to be found in the pros-
the federal government close to $1 billion in unpaid ecution of the tax-exempt wretched charity empire.
taxes; about 70 percent of this tax debt is “substan- As a result of Washington’s atrophying oversight, the
tial” delinquent payroll taxes. The twenty-five most states are increasingly aggressive in overseeing non-
egregious offenders repeatedly withheld employee profits.36
wages, paid their executives salaries of more than
$1 million, and attempted to bribe officials of Defrauding Nonprofits “Charity officials stole or
the Internal Revenue Service (IRS), among other misused at least $1.28 billion from 152 nonprofit
“abusive activity.”31 organizations over a seven-year period”—but “very
little empirical research about fraud in nonprof-
Defrauding Donors Nonprofits that defraud gov- its exists.”37 We do know that 10 percent of 1,000
ernment are likely to also defraud their donors. nonprofits reported to the IRS a “significant [but
A notorious instance is Cancer Fund of America unexplained] diversion of funds,” amounting to
(CFA), a title chosen by its founder, Jim Reynolds, more than a half-billion dollars over five years. This
Sr., in order to confuse its prospective donors is money that has “gone missing,” but where it has
with the wholly legitimate American Cancer gone, no one seems to know. One distinct possibil-
Society, which  had fired Reynolds for question- ity is that it illegally has gone missing into nonprofit
able practices in 1984. Shortly thereafter, Reynolds officials’ pockets.38
founded CFA. Almost all fraud committed against these organ-
CFA spent less than 5 percent of the $75 izations (98 percent) is committed “solely by offend-
million that it collected over four decades on cancer ers within the organization,” over a third of whom
patients,32 but it was only one of a “wretched charity are managers. More than three-fifths are women
empire” composed of four cancer charities, each (who, along with older employees, account for the
headed by a member of the Reynolds family, that greatest losses), whereas in the other two sectors
channeled 97 percent of the funds they raised (an most fraudsters are men. Corruption involving col-
estimated $187 million) to the family.33 lusion between employees and outsiders occurs in
Although alarums had been sounded for years just 2 percent of instances of fraud; nonprofit cor-
and Reynolds’ “charities” occasionally paid some ruptive collusion appears to be lower than in the
fines, law enforcement did not get serious about private and public sectors.
their scams until 2015, when all fifty state attor- The smaller the nonprofit, the likelier it is to be
neys  general and the Federal Trade Commission a victim of fraud, “a finding counter to public-sector
“pursued the most ambitious and largest multi-state fraud research.” Independent-sector organizations
prosecution of a nonprofit” in history.34 In 2016, are more likely to endure significantly heavier losses
the case was settled. The empire was dissolved, but to fraud when they neglect external audits, anony-
it had virtually no money left with which to repay mous hot lines, and fiscal controls.39
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 147

contests, however, and by the 1980 election, the


THE EVOLUTION OF AMERICAN presidential candidates brayed the phrase no fewer
than eighty-three times; it has made strong showings
GRAFT ever since.43
The roots of Americans’ concern with corruption are Fraud has always been with us, but more
dense and deep, and extend to the very founding of recently fraud has taken on a renewed and even less
the United States itself: The word, “corruption,” or acceptable presence. The savings and loan scandal of
some variant of it, appears in The Federalist Papers the 1980s, in which $125 billion of taxpayers’ treas-
no fewer than fifty-eight times.40 ure were used to bail out thousands of savings and
American perspectives on corruption, and the loan associations that had, often fraudulently, “lost”
ways in which Americans choose to battle it, have the savings of millions of investors, was the direct
altered over the years. result of their irresponsible deregulation. Multi-
billion-dollar levels of fraud in Medicare, Defense,
and Housing and Urban Development (and, in the
Graft Parties On, 1900–1940 2000s, Big Fraud’s comeback in the reconstruc-
During much of the twentieth century, and earlier, tions following the invasion of Iraq and Hurricane
political reformers attacked graft, which was pro- Katrina) rendered the public even angrier over tra-
foundly partisan, pervasive, and patronage-based, by ditional fraud, and reinforced its intolerance of it.
promoting the professionalism of public administra- Beginning in the 1970s, events exploded that
tion and isolating public administrators from politics altered, perhaps permanently, the public’s perception
(recall Chapter 2). Ultimately, this “anti-patronage of corruption.
vision of corruption control,” expanded into a “pro-
gressive vision” that argued for the wholesale reform Waste and Incompetence as Corruption: The Fall of
of the political system from top to bottom.41 New York New York City’s fiscal crisis of 1975, in
which the city narrowly averted default only because
Washington bailed it out with more than $9 billion,
Graft as a Nuisance, 1940–1970 was primarily a product of plain waste, or avoida-
By the 1940s, the reformers had made considerable ble expenses that result from inefficient practices or
headway. A consequence was that graft was seen systems, or inadequate controls.
less as a systemic problem, and more as a sporadic The city’s debacle made a deep impression on
phenomenon that could be dealt with over time by the public, which began to equate governmental
applying the principles of administration (recall waste and incompetence with public corruption, a
Chapters 2 and 3) to improve governments’ organ- perception that has grown over time. An academic
ization, processes, and budgeting, which would review of the literature on governmental waste iden-
secure the public’s treasure. “Out of reform, moral tified a type of waste it titled, “Corruption, Fraud,
in its motivation, came reorganization, technical and Theft, and Red Tape.”44 Red tape equates with cor-
managerial in connotation.”42 ruption, fraud, and theft? The title of a mudsling-
ing book put it succinctly: Government Racket:
Washington Waste From A to Z.45 Waste is a racket?
Our New and Messy Meaning of Corruption,
1970–Present Abuse as Corruption: The Fall of the White
The queerly comforting thing about good old- House Between 1973 and 1975, a “third rate
fashioned graft is that we can readily understand burglary” (to quote the president’s press secretary)
it. Beginning in the 1970s, however, corruption has metamorphosed into the mother of all political scan-
been perceived as including not only traditional dals—“Watergate,” or President Richard Nixon’s
fraud, but other, less clear, meanings as well, notably efforts to cover up his aides’ burglary of the offices
waste and abuse, among others. In the presiden- of his opposition’s party. Watergate, besides forcing
tial election of 1960, the term, “waste, fraud, and Nixon’s unprecedented resignation and incarcerat-
abuse,” was not uttered. It was spoken in subsequent ing some forty top aides and burglars, also marked
148 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

the jelling of the public’s perception that abuse of


authority—or the illegal, unethical, or inappropriate Perceptions of American Corruption
misuse of the power vested in one’s public office— The United States stacks up better than most in
constitutes corruption. popular perceptions as an honest government. It
Because Watergate’s abuse involved burglary ranks seventeenth out of 175 countries in terms of
and perjury (but not fraud), it was flatly criminal. its perceived corruption—not a mortifyingly low
However, a subsequent scandal, “Whitewater,” was ranking, certainly, but not one that conveys bragging
merely inappropriate and unethical, yet still roiled rights, either. From 1995 (when the ranking began)
the body politic almost as violently as had Watergate. to 2011, the United States’ ranking sank by more
Whitewater concerned Congress’s appointment of a than a third, hitting twenty-fourth in 2011, but,
special prosecutor to investigate some of President beginning in 2012, the trend began to reverse.47
Bill Clinton’s personal investments. The prosecutor Over fifty years, the number of Americans
found no provable financial improprieties, but did who said that “quite a few government officials are
expose that the president had had an affair with a crooked” more than doubled, from 24 percent to 52
White House intern. percent.48 A majority states that “corrupt political
Most Americans viewed the prosecutor’s leaders” are the nation’s top problem.49
zealous expansion of his original mission to be, at Government workers have their own views
best, inappropriate, and Clinton’s sexual exploita- about the extent of public corruption, and their
tion of a young intern as unethical (and his lying perceptions differ from those of the public. Federal,
about it under oath was criminal). These abuses state, and local employees report that “overtly
led to the demise of the twenty-one-year-old inde- illegal” misconduct in their workplaces has declined
pendent prosecutor law; the U.S. Supreme Court’s by an average of two-fifths over seven years.50
unprecedented disbarment of a president; Congress’s
impeachment, trial, and acquittal of the president;
and hardened Americans’ opinion that abusing The Extent of Fraud
power is corruption. Annually, fewer than 3,000 public officials and
“others involved” (who comprise about a third of
The Lump The result of these and similar incidents is the total) are charged, convicted, or awaiting trial
that not only does traditional fraud anger Americans for public corruption.51 The leading charges are
more than ever, but “corruption” has metamor- theft and bribery in programs involving federal
phosed into a blurred lump in not just the popular funds; high ranking or elected officials are found in
mind, but in everyone’s mind. Not only are fraud, only 2 percent of these corruption cases, and most
bribery, and graft perceived as corruption, as they cases involve low-ranking federal or local officials.
always have been, but waste, abuse, incompetence, Happily, overall corruption is in decline.52
impropriety, indecency, and political differences now Typically, from more than 300 to over 400 of
are seen as corruption as well. These are really “less these prosecutions involve federal officials in any
serious ethical breaches than true corruption,” but given year.53 Four percent of federal employees have
they nevertheless dilute “our focus on real corrup- observed over the past year the altering of financial
tion, which continues unabated,” a “trend” that has records in the federal government; 3 percent have
been “accelerating over the last couple of decades.”46 noted stealing; and 2 percent are aware of bribery.
Each of corruption’s new and messy meanings can be These figures are bad, but not horrid. Federal
and has been subject to criminal charges. employees are “the only government employees to
indicate observance of misconduct at levels signifi-
cantly lower than the U.S. average.”54
CONFRONTING CORRUPTION Known financial fraud committed by federal
employees against the federal government accounts
IN AMERICA for considerably less than 1 percent of the federal
What is the extent of political graft in the United budget. “Nevertheless, though relatively small in
States, and what is being done about it? terms of the percentage of the budget impacted,
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 149

[fraud] has proven to be extremely costly” simply low voter turnout associates with greater corrup-
because of the immensity of the federal budget.55 tion), and this pays off, at least for a select few.
From roughly 250 to 350 state officials and Cities that discourage voter turnout through such
from 600 to 750 local officials per year are charged, devices as holding local elections on dates that differ
convicted, or awaiting trial for public corruption.56 from the dates of national or state elections (this
Seven percent of state workers and 6 percent of local decreases turnout by 14 percent, on average), not
employees have observed over the past year the mailing polling place locations (5 percent), or requir-
altering of financial records in their governments; 8 ing voters to register one month before the election
percent of state workers and 10 percent of local ones (4 percent), among other inhibitors, correlate with
note theft; and 4 percent of each report bribery. The larger proportions of city council members who
rates of each of these perceived corruptions match both run for re-election and who win. Despite these
their U.S. averages.57 and other obstacles to voting in some jurisdictions,
however, municipal employees and homeowners
still turn out in impressively high numbers; in these
Inhibiting American Graft: Cultural, cities, “the proportion of the budget spent on payroll
Political, and Structural Factors is higher and the proportion of taxes from property
The United States is largely free of those national taxes is lower” than in cities that encourage turnout,
cultural conditions, noted earlier, that encourage and significantly so. Hence, “a low-turnout envi-
corruption. ronment may allow incumbents to win reelection
without being responsive to the general public.”60
Cultural Inhibitors American culture, with its The good news is that, when there is a high
premium on openness and access (or, as we discussed incidence of corruption in the American states,
in Chapter 5, its “small power distance”), discour- voter turnout increases, a tribute to the honesty and
ages corruption. Relative to large power distance common sense of Americans.61
cultures, open and accessible countries “have a very When it comes to corruption, voting counts.
high proportion” of public employees who report
unethical or illegal conduct in their agencies; more
whistleblowers (in fact, most) receive “positive reac- Curbing Corruption: The Case for Balance
tions from peers”; and more (again, a majority) see and Will
the misconduct corrected.58 The field has come a long way in discovering devices
that can lead to cleaning up corrupt governance, but
Structural Inhibitors Americans enjoy a relatively there remains “confusion in the literature on which
prosperous economy; live mostly in urban areas; and anticorruption methods work best and most effi-
their governments are bombarded unrelentingly by a ciently.”62
robust, sometimes rabid, press. These factors inhibit
corruption. Old, New, and a Balanced Approach Traditional
In addition, Americans are governed by a decen- corruption controls—such as audits, inspections,
tralized and diffused public sector, a condition that, and civil service reform—work, but often only up to
as explained earlier, discourages graft on a global a point. For example, all the recommendations (and
scale. then some!) of the early-twentieth-century reform-
An unexpected structural factor is population: ers had long been in place in the Pentagon even as,
In those American states with isolated capitals in in the late twentieth century, it was being “sold” to
sparsely populated regions, corruption is considera- an unheard-of extent to corrupt private contractors.
bly more common. This seems to be attributable, in These were the years of the infamous $600 toilet
part, to less media coverage than the capital.59 seats, yet “hundreds of thousands of employees had
no task other than to keep scrupulously close tabs
Political Factors Incumbent public officials have on contractors. Seventy-nine separate offices issued
been known to make it difficult to vote, sometimes voluminous acquisition regulations. . . . [which]
to protect their fraudulent shenanigans (recall that equaled five times the length of Leo Tolstoy’s novel
150 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

War and Peace. The Army once promulgated fifteen corruption charges half of the city’s taxi, building,
pages of specifications for sugar cookies alone.”63 and plumbing inspectors.
Let us not be too quick to dismiss these hoary But there are difficulties when grass-roots gov-
practices because “a strong case can be made to ernments pursue grass-roots graft. In New York’s
remain sharp” in using traditional controls, which case, “It took a while to figure out how to do this—
account for “approximately one-third” of all the more than a hundred years”—even though the
origins of corruption cases. No other method department’s “daily work consists of rounding up
of exposing public misconduct, such as whistle people whose crimes are so small, so unnecessary,
blowing, remotely approaches this level.64 and so amazingly stupid that their capture is an act
This is not to argue for abandoning newer of mercy.”67
methods of corruption control that are being discov- State attorneys general and district attorneys
ered, if often inadvertently. For example, although “are generally not equipped with the resources
information systems, performance measures, and needed for a political undercover investigation”;
public program evaluations all were adopted for most are elected, which can lead to their reluctance
purposes other than curtailing corruption, each has to investigate corrupt officials in their own parties;
proven to be useful in doing so. New “fraud apps” and “they often are hampered by state laws that are
on smartphones (carried by about two-thirds of less expansive than federal ones.”68
American adults) have eclipsed traditional hot lines As a consequence, the federal government is
for citizens reporting local corruption, and their central to the curtailment of corruption at every gov-
reports appear to be rising as a result.65 ernmental level, initiating “perhaps as many as 80
The key to curbing corruption is one of flexibly percent” of all prosecutions for public corruption in
and continuously mixing methods in a balanced and the United States.69
sensitive manner. “The right mix of corruption con-
trols will undoubtedly differ” from government to
government, and from agency to agency within the Big Graft: Deep, Systemic, and Legal
same government, and the “optimal mix” of those We have been discussing American graft largely from
controls will alter over time.66 a small-ball perspective. But there are far deeper and
more systemic forms of corruption. Regrettably, at
Exposing Is Not Disposing We are not imply- least in Washington, these forms are entirely legal—
ing that the many methods of public management but are no less corrupt for it.
can, in and of themselves, actually eliminate graft.
Rather, they were designed only to discourage cor- Washington’s Corrupt Perpetrations One such
ruption by making its entry less easy and its discov- form, which we discuss in detail in Chapter 11, is
ery more likely. Washington’s revolving door, which arguably has
Even to merely discourage graft, however, cor- rendered Congress and federal regulatory agencies
ruption controls must first be used. Otherwise, they the handmaidens of special interests; Wall Street is
are irrelevant. Whatever the extent of the corrup- particularly notorious in this regard, but there are
tion—whether it is of the garden variety, such as many additional examples.
purloining a pencil from the office, or it is the garden The other is the Supreme Court, which has effec-
itself, such as a putrescence that permeates a polity— tively ruled that money displaces people in politics,
political will is the ultimate key to its disposal. and that corruption must be defined in such a starkly
limited way that the Court’s definition verges on the
inaccurate, or is, at best, breathtakingly incomplete.
Prosecuting Corruption: The Crucial
Federal Role Money Is Speech Congress first regulated money
State and local governments investigate and prose- in politics in 1907, when it passed the Tillman Act,
cute fraud, some quite successfully. New York City’s which banned corporate political contributions.
Department of Investigation, founded in 1873, is Over the next sixty-seven years, Congress enacted
exemplary; in just one decade, its officers arrested on laws that further restricted money’s political role.
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 151

Congress’s rationale throughout was consistently Both decisions have rendered the United States
the same: the outsized influence of a wealthy few tax code, at nearly four million words, the world’s
could cause corruption and greater political inequal- longest.75 Why? Because “America is unique among
ity, and undermine public trust of government. democracies in requiring, at all levels of politics,
In 1976, however, in Buckley v. Valeo, the that vast amounts of cash be raised from the private
Court held seven-to-one that political donations sector” to win elections. To raise this money, legis-
were a form of expression, and thus were pro- lators sell amendments to the tax code to special
tected under the First Amendment (the Freedom interests, which may account for the fact that, since
of Speech Clause). The United States seems to be 2001, Congress has made, on average, one change
alone in equating money with expression, as it is “a to the tax code every day.76 Buying an advantageous
view shared by no other Western democracy.”70 The line in the tax code is “the world’s ultimate ‘pay for
Court also rejected Congress’s longstanding position play’ setup.”77
that political contributions from the rich could lead Understandably, four-fifths of Americans,
to political inequality. “regardless of their political philosophy, party iden-
tification, age, education, sex, or income level,”
Corporations Are People—Just a Different Sort would vote to limit the amount of campaign money
of People Who Never Die In 2010, in Citizens that congressional candidates could spend.78
United v. Federal Election Commission, the Court
confirmed, five-to-four, split along partisan lines, Graft as a Quid-Pro-Quo Microdot In 2014, the
the Orwellian notion that money is speech, and Court plopped the cherry on this soured sundae
further ruled that the Constitution protects not only in McCutcheon v. Federal Election Commission,
political donations from individuals, but also con- decided five-to-four, again along partisan lines. The
tributions from associations of individuals, such as ruling defined corruption in the most microscopic
corporations and unions. Thus the Court arrived and narrow terms conceivable: as a quid pro quo
at the equally Orwellian conclusion that a corpora- (in essence, a direct bribe for a specific service),
tion, which is “an association of individuals, created even though corruption, as we explained earlier,
by law or under authority of law, having a contin- almost never operates as a quid pro quo, and, when
uous existence independent of the existences of its it rarely does so, it is confined largely to the lower
members and powers and liabilities distinct from levels of the food chain. This was something that the
those of its members,”71 is a person; it just happens Founders had fully understood; of the hundreds of
to be a person who is immortal and different from occasions that the topic of graft surfaced during the
individual persons, in that, for example, corpora- Constitutional Convention and in the subsequent
tions do not breathe. For good measure, the Court state ratification debates, corruption meant quid pro
also redefined “undue influence” (which, of course, quo only about 1 percent of the time.79
is precisely what special interests want for their To expand the power of the rich in elections
money) to mean the much mellower, even positive, in which each citizen supposedly is involved as an
“responsiveness.” Small wonder, perhaps, that about equal with every other citizen, and then to limit
four-fifths of Americans oppose Citizens United.72 the prosecution of those who unduly influence pol-
icymakers to a form of graft that is almost never
Purchasing Public Policies The consequences of present in actuality, is very deep and systemic cor-
Buckley and Citizens United? “There is quite possi- ruption indeed.
bly more money in American politics today than at
any point in the country’s history.”73 And, perhaps,
fewer people contributing most of that money than FROM ANTICORRUPTION TO
ever before: fewer than 32,000 donors accounted EFFICIENCY: THE MORPHING OF
for 29 percent of all disclosed political fundraising
at the federal level in 2014.74 (Since 2010, Congress PUBLIC MANAGEMENT
has been extraordinarily reluctant to force disclo- A cruel irony of corruption controls is that, through
sure of who makes campaign contributions.) their increasingly labyrinthine fiscal systems and
152 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

time-consuming and enervating checks, rules, and openness to new ideas plummet, but their frustration
red tape, they can stymie efficient and productive and cynicism soar; a wait-them-out-and-wear-them-
governing.80 down mentality emerges among careerists. Because
Public administration, like any other phenom- an unhappy workforce usually is an unproductive
enon, is subject to W. Ross Ashby’s law of requisite workforce, goes the argument, the new techniques
variety, which states that regulatory (or, in our case, are themselves counterproductive.
governing) mechanisms must equal in their com- There is another side to this: a competition of
plexity those of the systems that they are meant to new approaches can result in improved adminis-
control.81 In its public plumage, Ashby’s law pertains tration, if administrators are both confident and
not only to more tangled forms of corruption, but discerning enough to pick and choose among tech-
also to increasingly convoluted problems of more niques—or even parts of techniques, old as well
efficient governing. as new—that would improve the performance of
In Part III, we address these complexities, which, their agencies and nonprofit organizations. It is
in the public and nonprofit sectors, are expressed an approach that works. Although many of the
largely in terms of information systems, performance methods of public management “have ended up
measurement, program evaluation, finance, bevies of being castigated and even ridiculed, these methods
budgetary formats, human capital management, and have provided an ever-improving series of public
the assessment and management of individual per- management techniques that can, and indeed are,
formance, among other techniques; some are new, improving government performance.”85
others are old, and all are complicated. Depending on the circumstances that public
Public officials sometimes get a bit carried away and nonprofit administrators face, some or all of
with new management techniques. “These days the the notions advanced in Part III could be useful and
hip subject” among politicians “is management rewarding. But to mindlessly adopt them simply
theory,”82 although those officials who indulge in because they are there likely would result in less
managerial “flavors of the month” are somewhat effective management.
delusional. Public organizations that “adopt fash-
ionable management practices” are statistically
more likely to be staffed by administrators who NOTES
“overestimate” their organizations’ service perfor- 1. Rajeev K. Goel and Michael A. Nelson, Causes of
mance relative to how their clients and other exter- Corruption: History, Geography and Government
nal stakeholders view their performance.83 (Helsinki, Finland: Bank of Finland Institute for
Worse, however, time and hard work are expended Economies in Transition, 2008), p. 17.
by staff to establish one “management-by-best-seller” 2. Alok K. Bohara, Neil J. Mitchell, and Carl
technique, only to see it cavalierly discarded by top F. Mittendorff, “Compound Democracy and
management when another hot management notion the Control of Corruption: A Cross-Country
cruises down the consultants’ turnpike. “The level Investigation,” Policy Studies Journal 32 (Winter
2004), pp. 481–499. The quotation is on p. 481.
of federal reform,” for instance, “appears to parallel
3. Desiree Teobaldelli, “Federalism and the Shadow
the frenzy of management improvement fads in busi-
Economy,” Public Choice 146 (March 2011), pp.
ness. . .. Federal employees have faced one competing
269–289. The quotation is on p. 269.
reform after another, leading to confusion, wasted
4. Gideon Yaniv, “Tax Evasion, Conspicuous
motion, and frustration in priorities with fads and Consumption, and the Income Tax Rate,” Public
fashions that are now out of favor.”84 State and local Finance Review 41 (May 2013), pp. 302–316. The
governments are also complicit. quotation is on p. 302.
When managerial faddism strikes, those admin- 5. Yener Altunbas and John Thornton, “Fiscal
istrators who toil in the bureaucracy’s bowels some- Decentralization and Governance,” Public Finance
times are forced to behave like a school of fish, Review 40 (January 2012), pp. 66–85.
darting without warning first one way and then 6. Goel and Nelson, Causes of Corruption, p. 17.
another, in a pointless effort to be “with it”—if also 7. Dong Chul Shim and Tae Ho Eom, “Anticorruption
witless. As a consequence, managers’ morale and Effects of Information Communication and
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 153

Technology (ICT) and Social Capital,” International 21. Michael W. Kraus, “Psychology Suggests that
Review of Administrative Sciences 75 (March Power Doesn’t Make People Bad—It Just Reveals
2009), pp. 99–116. Their True Natures,” Govexec.com (October 14,
8. Johann Graf Lambsdorff, “Corruption in Empirical 2016).
Research—A Review,” Paper presented at the 22. Moshe Maor, “Feeling the Heat? Anticorruption
International Anti-Corruption Conference, (Durban, Mechanisms in Comparative Perspective,”
South Africa, December 10–15, 1999), p. 11. Governance 17 (January 2004), pp. 1–28.
9. Rafael F. La Porta, Florencia Lopez-De-Silanes, 23. Alok K. Bohara, Neil J. Mitchell, and Carl
Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, “Trust in F. Mittendorff, “Compound Democracy and
Large Organizations,” AEA Papers and Proceedings the Control of Corruption: A Cross-Country
87 (May 1999). Investigation,” Policy Studies Journal 32 (Winter
10. Goel and Nelson, Causes of Corruption, p. 17. 2004), pp. 481–499.
11. Caroline Van Rijckeghem and Beatrice Weder, 24. Tetsuya Fujiwara, “The Impact of Political
Corruption and the Rate of Temptation: Do Low Corruption on Voter Turnout in Industrial
Wages in the Civil Service Cause Corruption? Democracies,”  Paper presented at the Annual
(New York: International Monetary Fund, Meeting of the Midwest Political Science
1997). Association, (Chicago: April 2005).
12. Peter B. Evans and James E. Rauch, “Bureaucratic 25. Marco Pani, Hold Your Nose and Vote: Why Do
Structure and Economic Performance in Less Some Democracies Tolerate Corruption? IMF
Developed Countries,” Journal of Public Economics Working Paper No. 09/83 (Washington, DC:
75 (January 2000), pp. 49–71. International Monetary Fund, 2009), p. 1.
13. Lambsdorff,“Corruption in Empirical Research—A 26. De Graaf and Huberts, “Portraying the Nature
Review,” p. 13. of Corruption Using an Exploratory Case Study
14. Patrick Flavin and Richard Letet, “Religion and Design,” p. 650.
Government Corruption in the American States,” 27. Janet Greenlee, Mary Fischer, Teresa Gordon,
Public Integrity 15 (Fall 2013), pp. 329–344. The and Elizabeth Keating, “How to Steal from a
quotation is on p. 329. Nonprofit: Who Does It and How to Prevent It,”
15. Gjalt de Graaf and L.W.J.C. Huberts, “Portraying Nonprofitquarterly.org (December 21, 2007).
the Nature of Corruption Using an Exploratory 28. Ruben Vives, “Bell Council Seeks Resignations of 3
Case Study Design,” Public Administration Review City Officials,” Los Angeles Times (July 21, 2010).
68 (July/August 2008), pp. 640–653. 29. Lydia Segal, “Roadblocks in Reforming Corrupt
16. John Bohte and Kenneth J. Meier, “Goal Agencies: The Case of the New York City School
Displacement: Assessing the Motivation of Custodians,” Public Administration Review 62
Organizational Cheating,” Public Administration (July/August 2002), pp. 445–460. The quotations
Review 60 (March/April 2000), pp. 173–182. are on pp. 445–446, 448.
17. Andie J. Yapp, Abbie S. Wazlawek, Brian J. Lucas, 30. For a good treatment of the Phenix City follies, see
et al., “The Ergonomics of Dishonesty: The Effect Alan Grady, When Good Men Do Nothing: The
of Incidental Posture on Stealing, Cheating, and Assassination of Albert Patterson (Tuscaloosa, AL:
Traffic Violations,” Psychological Science 24 (11, University of Alabama Press, 2003).
2013), pp. 1–9. 31. U.S. Treasury Inspector General for Tax
18. De Graaf and Huberts, “Portraying the Nature Administration, Some Tax-Exempt Organizations
of Corruption Using an Exploratory Case Study Have Substantial Delinquent Payroll Taxes
Design,” pp. 647, 643, 645, 644, 649, 648. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
19. Joris Lammers, Diederik A. Stapel, and Adam Office, 2014), pp. 8, 3. Figures are for FY 2012 (3.8
D. Galinsky, “Power Increases Hypocrisy: percent) and FY 2006 (3.1 percent).
Moralizing in Reasoning, Immorality in Behavior,” 32. Ruth McCambridge, “Cancer Charity Case
Psychological Science 21 (May 2010), pp. 737–744. Settled—But the Money’s Gone and Reynolds
20. Samuel Bendahan, Christian Zehnder, Francois Walks,” Nonprofitquarterly.org (March 31, 2016).
P. Pralong, and John Antonakis, “Leader 33. Rick Cohen, “Reynolds’ ‘Wretched Charity Empire’
Corruption Depends on Power and Testosterone,” Finally Succumbs to Government Oversight,”
ScienceDirect.com (July 7, 2014). Nonprofitquarterly.org (May 20, 2015).
154 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency

34. McCambridge, “Cancer Charity Case Settled—But 51. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of the
the Money’s Gone and Reynolds Walks.” United States, 2016 (Bethesda, MD: Author, 2016),
35. Cohen, “Reynolds’ ‘Wretched Charity Empire’ Table 369. Figures are for 2000, 2010, 2012, 2013.
Finally Succumbs to Government Oversight.” 52. Adriana S. Cordis and Jeffrey Milvo, “Measuring
36. Lloyd Hitoshi Mayer, “The Rising of the States Public Corruption in the United States: Evidence from
in Nonprofit Oversight,” Nonprofitquarterly.org Administrative Records of Federal Prosecutions,”
(August 8, 2016). Public Integrity 18 (2, 2016), pp. 127–148.
37. Kristy Holtfreter, “Determinants of Fraud Losses in 53. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of
Nonprofit Organizations,” Nonprofit Management the United States, 2016, Table 369. Figures are for
& Leadership 19 (Fall 2008), pp. 45–63. The quo- 2000, 2010, 2012, 2013.
tation is on p. 46. 54. Ethics Resource Center, National Government
38. Ruth McCambridge, “Washington Post Investigates Ethics Survey, pp. 20, 19. Figures are for 2007.
‘Significant Diversions’ in Nonprofit Funds as 55. Sandra T. Welch, Sarah A. Holmes, and Jeffrey W.
Reported to IRS,” Nonprofitquarterly.org (October Stawser, “Fraud in the Federal Government: Part
23, 2013). Figures are for 2008–2013. I—The Perpetrators and the Victims,” Government
39. Holtfreter, “Determinants of Fraud Losses in Accountants Journal 46 (Spring 1997), pp. 24–27.
Nonprofit Organizations,” pp. 47, 52, 57. The quotation is on p. 24.
40. George Will, “End Run on Free Speech,” Savannah 56. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of
Morning News (May 25, 2009). the United States, 2016, Table 369. Figures are for
41. Frank Anechiarco and James B. Jacobs, “Visions of 2000, 2010, 2012, 2013.
Corruption Control and the Evolution of American 57. Ethics Resource Center, National Government
Public Administration,” Public Administration Ethics Survey, pp. 25, 31. Figures are for 2007.
Review 54 (September/October 1994), pp. 465–473. 58. Marit Skivenes and Sissel Trygstad, “When
The quotation is on p. 466. Whistle-Blowing Works: The Norwegian Case,”
42. Leonard D. White, The Administrative Histories: Human Relations 63 (July 2010), pp. 1071–1097.
The Federalists (New York: MacMillan, 1948), The quotation is on p. 1071.
p. 16. 59. Felipe R. Campante and Quoc-Ahn Do, Isolated
43. Annenberg Campaign Data Base, as cited in Paul C. Capital Cities, Accountability and Corruption:
Light, The True Size of Government (Washington, Evidence from US States (Cambridge, MA: Kennedy
DC: Brookings, 1999), p. 88. School of Government, Harvard University, 2012).
44. William Stanberry and Fred Thompson, “Toward 60. Jessica Trounstine, “Turnout and Incumbency in
a Political Economy of Government Waste: First Local Elections,” Urban Affairs Review 49 (2, 2012),
Step, Definitions,” Public Administration Review pp. 167–189. The quotations are on pp. 189, 179.
55 (September/October 1995), pp. 418–427. 61. Monica Escaleras, Peter Calcagno, and William
45. Martin L. Gross, Government Racket: Washington Shughart, “Corruption and Voter Participation,”
Waste from A to Z (New York: Bantam, 1992). Public Finance Review 40 (November 2012),
46. Mark Funkhouser, “The 3 Flavors of Corruption,” pp. 789–815. The quotation is on p. 789.
Governing.com (January 2015). 62. De Graaf and Huberts, “Portraying the Nature
47. Transparency International, Corruption Perceptions of Corruption Using an Exploratory Case Study
Index 2014 (Berlin: Author, 2015). Design,” p. 650.
48. American National Election Studies, “Are Govern- 63. Andy Pasztor, When the Pentagon Was for
ment Officials Crooked, 1958–2008,” http://www. Sale: Inside America’s Biggest Defense Scandal
electionstudies.org/nesguide/2ndtable/t5a_4_1.htm. (New York: Scribner, 1995), p. 10.
49. Pew Global Attitudes Project, Global Opinion 64. Gjalt de Graaf, “A Report on Reporting: Why
Trends, 2002-2007 (Washington, DC: Author, Peers Report Integrity and Law Violations in Public
2008), pp. 35, 114, 121. Figure, 51 percent, is for Organizations,” Public Administration Review 70
2007. Only “illegal drugs” score higher. (September/October 2010), pp. 767–779. The quo-
50. As derived from data in Ethics Resource Center, tation is on p. 776.
National Government Ethics Survey: An Inside 65. Rebecca Beitsch, “New Apps Help Taxpayers
View of Public Sector Ethics (Arlington, VA: Report Waste, Fraud and Abuse,” Pewtrusts.org
Author, 2008), p. 3. Figure is for 2000–2007. (April 22, 2016).
PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management: Curbing Corruption, Enhancing Efficiency 155

66. Frank Anechiarco and James B. Jacobs, The 76. National Taxpayer Advocate, 2012 Annual Report
Pursuit of Absolute Integrity: How Corruption to Congress (Washington, DC: U.S, Government
Control Makes Government Ineffective (Chicago: Printing Office, 2013).
University of Chicago Press, 1996), p. 198. 77. Zakaria, “How Trump Exposed the Corruption in
67. Larissa MacFarquhar, “Busted,” The New Yorker the U.S. Tax Code.”
(February 1, 2010), pp. 50–57. The quotations are 78. Gallup Poll, as cited in Megan Thee-Brenan. “Polls
on p. 53. “Decade” refers to the 1990s. Show Broad Support for Campaign Spending
68. Alan Greenblatt, “The Corruption Puzzle,” Caps,” New York Times (April 2, 2014).
Governing (July 2008), pp. 24–30. The quotations 79. Lepore, “The Crooked and the Dead,” p. 25.
are on p. 29. 80. Anechiarco and Jacobs, The Pursuit of Absolute
69. Corporate Crime Reporter, Public Corruption in Integrity.
the United States (Washington, DC: Author, 2007). 81. W. Ross Ashby, Introduction to Cybernetics
70. Fareed Zakaria, “How Trump Exposed the (London: Chapman and Hall, 1961).
Corruption in the U.S. Tax Code,” Washington 82. “Leviathan Reengineered,” The Economist
Post (October 6, 2016). (October 19, 1996), p. 41.
71. “Corporation,” The Random House Dictionary of 83. Rhys Andrews, George A. Boyne, Jae M. Moon,
the English Language, unabridged ed. (New York: and Richard M. Walker, “Assessing Organizational
Random House, 1966), p. 327. Emphasis added. Performance: Exploring Differences between Inter-
72. ABC-Washington Post Poll 1, Public Views of nal and External Measures,” International Public
Citizens United v. Federal Election Commission Management Journal 13 (2, 2010), pp. 105–129.
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2010). The quotations are on p. 105.
73. Jill Lepore, “The Crooked and the Dead,” The New 84. Paul C. Light, “A Government Ill Executed: The
Yorker (August 25, 2014), pp. 22–28. The quota- Depletion of the Federal Public Service,” Public
tion is on p. 23. Administration Review 68 (May/June 2008),
74. Peter Olson-Phillips, Russ Choma, Sarah Bryner, pp. 413–419. The quotation is on p. 417.
and Doug Weber, “The Political One Percent of 85. Harry P. Hatry, “The Alphabet Soup Approach:
the One Percent: Megadonors Fuel Rising Cost You’ll Love It!” The Public Manager 21 (Winter
of Elections in 2014,” Sunlightfoundation.com 1992–1993), pp. 8–12. The quotation is on p. 8.
(April 30, 2015).
75. Sean D. Ehrlich, Access Points: An Institutional
Theory of Policy Bias and Policy Complexity
(New York: Oxford, 2011).
CHAPTER

Clarifying Complexity:
The Public’s
Information Resource
I n an age in which information technology
(IT) saturates society, it is worth recalling the
little-known fact that the public sector has long
DATA FOR PUBLIC
been crucial in inventing IT’s diverse devices. ADMINISTRATORS
A Census Bureau employee, Herman Hollerith, Recall from Chapter 4 that the use of hard data,
invented for use in the 1890 census a punch card typically provided by computers, has a direct rela-
and tabulation  machine, the forerunner of the tionship with public administrators making superior
computer. (Hollerith later  founded the Tabulating decisions and with those decisions being accepted at
Recording  Company,  now known as IBM.) The higher rates, correlations that appear to be unique
Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency was to government.5 For example, when counties adopt
central in creating the global positioning system, a IT, more people become involved in decision making
project it began in 1959, and, in 1969, the agency and better decisions are made, developments that
invented “packet switching,” which led to the have, unsurprisingly, a positive and “direct effect on
Internet. performance.”6
Despite immense and complex IT problems that So, with apologies for stating the obvious,
pervade the public sector, governments nevertheless data are important in making good decisions. But
remain central to the viability of IT. Washington which data?
spends more than $90 billion annually on IT, a sum
that not only is unequaled in the United States, but
likely the world. State and local governments spend The Data Deluge
more than $60 billion each year, an amount that is Never before in human history have there been
rising by about 4 percent annually.1 so many data. Globally, there are more than a
Some eight decades ago, Herbert Simon pre- billion  websites7 that tote up to an estimated
dicted that “how to process information” would 1,000  exabytes of digital data. One exabyte (or
emerge as the core challenge for all executives.2 Simon one quintillion bytes) equals 7,400 Libraries of
was more prescient than even he may have known. Congress, and digital data long ago surpassed
Today, top public administrators do indeed spend by  a factor of millions all the information in all
most of their time seeking and analyzing informa- the books  ever written.8 The data deluge has
tion,3 and there are some 1.6 million “data-centric” grown so  humongous that the increasingly inade-
jobs in the federal, state, and local governments, or quate exabytes have been replaced by zetabytes (a
7.4 percent of all public-sector employees. Eighteen number  followed  by  twenty-one zeros); by 2020,
percent of all governments’ data-centric workers are the  worldwide  database  will  amount to forty-four
managers.4 zetabytes.9

156
The Public’s Information Resource 157

More than 200 billion emails are sent and safety. Local fire fighters use GIS to determine the
received per day worldwide, and the typical corpo- fastest route to a fire.
rate user sends and receives an estimated 122 emails Office of Management and Budget (OMB)
each day; both numbers are growing.10 There is Circular A-16, issued in 1953 and revised many
reason to question how useful to public administra- times since, is the basis of federal GIS policy.
tors these emails are. Nearly half of federal employ- Regrettably, about half of the more than $4 billion
ees are “uncomfortable” (26 percent), or “slightly” that Washington spends annually on its numerous
so (22 percent), about “being candid in internal geographic information systems is “redundant.”15
email communications,” suggesting that prob- National efforts have been made since 1990 to
lems are not being addressed in their discomfiting coordinate federal and state geospatial data, but the
entirety.11 Of the Pentagon’s 700 million monthly pricey problem is a stubborn one.
emails, a slender 14 percent is “actually legitimate. State and local governments are thought to
The rest are a mixture of malicious password phish- spend twice as much on geographic information
ing attempts, chock full of viruses, or the bane of systems as Washington expends, or about $8 billion
modern humanity’s existence: spam.”12 per year.16 Sixty-five percent of cities and counties
have a GIS and related systems in operation.17

Focusing and Narrowing Decision Options Enterprise Risk Management Enterprise risk
How can the pathetically bounded rationality of management is the use of analysis to determine the
decision makers remotely comprehend this flood potential opportunities or perils that accompany any
of data? Much of the benefit derived from The strategic decision in an effort to exploit the opportu-
Computer in its ability to winnow data (or, as we nities and minimize the perils.
explained in Chapter 4, incoherent facts) that then The Office of Federal Student Aid was the first
can be used as knowledge (or meaningful informa- federal bureau to introduce enterprise risk man-
tion) in public and nonprofit decision making. agement, in 2004, in an effort to reduce the high
Organizations in all sectors have tried, with default rate on the $1.2 trillion in student loans—a
some success, to convert data into knowledge. Most sum “rivaling the entire loan business of JPMorgan
of us are vaguely familiar with the management Chase with a staff roughly the size of the National
information system, which passively summarizes Weather Service”18—that it had made or guaranteed
data in ways that are useful to decision makers and loans to forty million borrowers. Its use was so suc-
is now a commonplace in all sectors. Less familiar, cessful that the Government Accountability Office
perhaps, is the decision support system, which, in (GAO) removed student loans from its “high-risk”
tandem with decision makers, proactively analyzes list of programs that are unduly vulnerable to fraud,
data and addresses unstructured issues, such as waste, abuse, and mismanagement.
“what if” scenarios. Because enterprise risk management can sub-
Most public agencies have decision support stantially reduce risk taking, it is good to know
systems, most are pleased with them,13 and they can that federal agencies have been judged to be ahead
save governments money.14 Three overlapping vari- of corporations in their handling of risk manage-
ations of these systems are increasingly vital in nar- ment.19 This is remarkable, given the fact that only
rowing administrative choices. half of agencies have “a formalized risk manage-
ment function,” and just 20 percent have a “chief
Geographic Information Systems A geographic risk officer.”20
information system (GIS) is a location-related com-
puter program that typically combines geospatial Big Data Analytics Our final example of a deci-
data with maps and aerial photographs. Its uses are sion support system is big data analytics, or simply
wide. Following the crash of the Columbia space analytics, which is the extensive analysis of huge
shuttle, in 2003, Washington used Texas’s GIS to amounts of data and the use of models to drive deci-
assist in recovering the widely scattered remains. sion making. Potentially, big data analytics is a very
States use it to identify where roads need improved big deal.
158 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Analytics has improved programs ranging from informing “policy decisions,” and 29 percent “have
how effectively teachers teach, to curbing politi- developed some early applications” in doing so; 13
cal graft (in New York, analytics led to arrest of percent say that analytics’ use in these areas is “not
the speaker of the state assembly for alleged cor- on the radar.”30 Sixty-seven percent of state auditors
ruption), to “predictive policing,” which identifies have used analytics “to identify potential audit or
where a crime will occur before it happens (shades investigative targets,” and all have increased “avail-
of the 2002 movie, Minority Report, in which “pre- able resources” for analytics, including 19 percent
guilty” people were arrested before they committed who had increased resources by more than 100
the crime). percent.31
A survey of federal, state, and local cybersecu- Even more resources may be needed, as the
rity professionals found that 86 percent believed that cost of computer fraud to the states “likely has run
analytics would improve cybersecurity (although into the billions of dollars in recent years as states
just 28 percent were fully leveraging analytics to do have moved services online and as identity theft
so, and only a third had made analytics a priority).21 has exploded. . .. [although] nobody knows the true
The U.S. Office for Anticipating Surprise (yes, there costs yet.” Fortunately, big data analytics is capable
is such an agency) sponsors a competition for an of matching identities, and some states are using
analytics “psychic” program that can foresee data this capacity to arrest fraudsters, saving millions.32
breaches days before they would occur. Thirteen percent of the states have placed data ana-
The probability that analytics will be used is lytics as a “priority initiative” in combatting “fraud,
greatly enhanced by high levels of governmental waste, and abuse,” and 42 percent “have developed
transparency and accountability.22 some early applications” in this area; just 5 percent
say that big data’s use against fraud is “not on the
Federal Big Data Seventy-four percent of federal radar.”33
inspectors general (IGs) report that data analytics
has had “some” or a “major impact” in identifying Local Big Data Three-fourths of sixty-five mid-
risk areas,23 and 71 percent “use data analytics to sized and large American cities have “some form of
identify potential audit or investigative targets,” initiative around the use of data analytics.” Nearly a
with “over 40%” stating that “at least” a fourth of fourth assigned a chief data officer to lead the initi-
their investigations were initiated because they had ative.34
used analytics.24 All IGs have increased analytics
resources, with a fifth increasing these resources by
50 to 100 percent, and 5 percent by more than 100 KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT:
percent over three years.25 It has been authoritatively MANAGING THE PUBLIC’S
estimated that, by using big data analytics, particu-
larly in tax collection and healthcare, Washington INFORMATION RESOURCE
could reduce annual deficits by $220 billion.26 The public sector’s challenges of collecting, process-
Unfortunately, there is some distance to travel. ing, analyzing, and using information are known as
Eighty-four percent of federal chief information knowledge management.35
officers (CIOs) state that their data analytics systems
are in the early stages of maturity,27 and, worse, 52
percent of federal “leaders” have little understand- Uniquely Governmental: Complexity
ing of the method;28 in 2012, Washington began a and Immensity
$200 million Big Data Research and Development In 2013, the U.S. Department of Health and Human
Initiative designed, in part, to correct this deficiency. Services opened its new portal, HealthCare.gov,
designed to enable at least twenty million Americans
State Big Data A third of the states have at least to buy affordable health insurance; it cost nearly
one big data project underway.29 Fourteen percent $1 billion. Its debut did not go swimmingly. On
of the states have placed data analytics as a “prior- its first day of operation, six people bought insur-
ity initiative” in developing “business insights” and ance through it. (To add insult to injury, OMB’s IT
The Public’s Information Resource 159

Dashboard continued through the day to flash a Regrettably, simplifying the public sector’s IT
green light following the crash, signaling that OMB has some complexities of its own. The American
considered the portal to be “low risk.”) By its second Internet (including, certainly, governments’ infor-
day, the number had soared to 248. A prominent jour- mation systems) still is regulated, in part, by the
nalist observed that “the mess that was Healthcare. Communications Act of 1934, a law that originally
gov will be used to scare public administration stu- addressed the vexing complexities of rotary phones.
dents for generations to come.”36 The fiasco did These complexities do redound to the public’s
have the benefit of focusing federal attention on the benefit in one sense: governments’ “knowledge
disaster of digital governance in Washington more workers” are most attracted to their jobs by “intel-
intensely than ever before; new laws, agencies, and lectual stimulation and challenge.” Those in the
programs quickly followed, all designed to address independent sector, by contrast, cite contributing
this huge and pervasive problem. to society, and those in the private sector prefer the
Eventually, the glitches were largely eliminated opportunities for “advancement and prestige” that
and enrollment hit its target, but HealthCare.gov their positions offer.41
illustrates a pair of IT realities that are unique to
government: complexity and immensity. Immensity Governments undertake the largest IT
projects of any sector, and the bigger the project,
Complexity “High-level data managers” in gov- the likelier it will fail. Indeed, any IT project that
ernment deal with greater interdependence among is budgeted at $10 million or more, regardless of
systems, more red tape, different criteria in pur- sector, will fail at least partially.42 An estimated 20 to
chasing hardware, and more extensive “extra- 30 percent of IT projects in all sectors are “total fail-
organizational linkages” than do their counterparts ures” (i.e., the project is abandoned), and 30 to 60
in business,37 and, very likely, nonprofits as well. percent are “partial failures,” involving “cost over-
Even by governmental standards, federal IT runs or other problems.”43 Especially cost overruns;
networks are inordinately complex. Seventy-four the average cost overrun for IT developments in all
percent of federal IT executives state that their sectors is almost 200 percent.44
networks are complex or very complex, with most A slim 18 percent of federal, state, and local
saying that complexity had increased in recent governments’ IT projects succeed, a success rate that
years and that they expected it to continue to do so. is from half to a third lower than projects in manu-
Complexity, according to more than half of these facturing, finance, and retail.45
executives surveyed, reduces IT reliability, speed, A fifth of all “major investments” in federal IT
security, and raises maintenance costs. (Facts support are at “medium risk” of failure, and about half of
these views: “inadequate capacity to manage tech- 1 percent were “moderately high or high risk.”46
nological complexity” is the “root cause” underly- Consider, for example, the Department of Homeland
ing fourteen agencies being listed on GAO’s current Security’s $1.7 billion Electronic Immigration System
high-risk list.38) These executives believe that simpli- (originally budgeted at $536,000), which takes twice
fication would save, on average, 18 percent of their as long to process immigration forms than it takes
IT budgets.39 clerks to process them by hand.47
A major component of IT’s complexity is that It is, therefore, good news that, beginning in
of purchasing IT, an endeavor fraught with frag- 2010, the feds were at last making “the tough man-
mentation and murk. Efforts to simplify it have met agement decisions to terminate, halt or turn around
with mixed success. More successful, perhaps, has failing projects,” possibly bringing to a “quiet
been PortfolioStat, an initiative launched in 2012 close . . . the era of grand design” in federal knowl-
to reduce duplication in agencies’ IT investments, edge management.48 Still, even though almost two-
which saved, over three years, “approximately thirds of agency CIOs rate upcoming IT projects at
$1.1 billion,” an “understated” sum.40 The Federal a lower risk of failure than does GAO,49 progress is
Information Technology Acquisition Reform Act evident: “78 percent of all federal IT projects deliver
of 2014 is aimed at resolving the thorny issues that on budget, which the government defines as being
beset federal IT purchasing. within 10 percent of original budgeted costs,” and
160 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

“overall, 79 percent of agency IT projects are com- period.54 Consequently, 52 percent of federal execu-
pleted on time.”50 tives state that they do not have the IT services that
A third of the states have at least one big IT they need, and 63 percent say that the current speed,
project (almost three-fourths of these projects have or lack thereof, of IT services hinders their mission
budgets exceeding $100 million) underway in at effectiveness (“At least once a week, it takes up to an
least one department; 39 percent of their managers hour just to log on”).55
thought that “the last several large, critical projects Only 15 percent of federal executives think that
[were] generally all successful,” and the rest were their agency is “making new technologies availa-
“mixed.”51 ble to its employees at the same pace as the private
sector.”56 This lapse may explain in part why “inad-
equate and aging information systems” are the basis
Managing the Nation’s Knowledge of twenty-three agencies’ appearance on GAO’s
Seventy-two percent (up by a remarkable 10 points high-risk list, and why improving “legacy infor-
in a year) of “federal leaders” state that digital tech- mation systems” is, historically, the leading “root
nology increased their agency’s productivity, and 91 solution” (out of seven) for agencies removing them-
percent believe that it enables them “to better serve selves from the list.57
stakeholders and do their own jobs more effec-
tively.”52 Yet, the federal government’s experience A Managerial Morass Federal agencies spend an
with computers has been as maddening as comput- average of more than $36,000 per employee on
ers themselves are beneficial. IT, or more than six times larger than the less than
$5,000 per employee in the private sector; in the
The Federal IT Anti-System When the White view of some observers, the agencies are not getting
House’s first chief information officer arrived on their money’s worth.58
the scene in 2009, he discovered that his office had Part of the frustration in improving federal
one lone data center (“We had no redundancy”); IT may be attributable to the failure of the system
82 percent of all White House IT “had reached the that has been used to track its “progress.” Most of
end of life”; during his first forty days on the job, OMB’s thirty-six indicators of agencies’ IT admin-
the White House’s email system was inoperative istrative progress, which cost from $150 million
23 percent of the time, including one period that to $308 million annually to track, “are not useful
lasted twenty-one hours (“In my professional career, for managing IT,” and two-thirds of the indicators
there has not been a worst day since or ever”); and “only help agency CIOs to some or no extent.”59 A
that staffers, including the president’s chief of staff, year-long cooperative effort between the federal and
were still using floppy disks, an obsolete technology private sectors concluded that improved “technol-
dating from the 1980s.53 ogy business management” could save the feds $5.8
billion over five years.60
Outmoded IT Ancient and crumbling IT is not
limited to the White House. Federal agencies Dysfunctional Decentralization Federal agencies,
spend, on average, 78 percent of their annual IT on average, use a scant 27 percent of their com-
budgets on running and maintaining outmoded puters’ processing power, and under 40 percent
“legacy systems” (some agencies spend more than of their  storage power; servers in some agencies
90 percent), and the percentage is climbing. Some stand idle 93 percent of the time.61 Forty percent of
legacy systems date back more than a half century federal “data assets” are stored four or more times,
(the Department of the Treasury and its Internal at an estimated cost of nearly $17 billion over ten
Revenue Service [IRS] have the oldest of any agency) years; over a fourth of the agencies are using more
and their developers are long dead. These enormous than half of their storage space to keep copies of
and increasing expenditures—$61 billion annually, redundant data.62 And, worse, these counts do not
up 9 percent over seven years—have caused spend- include the one-third of Washington’s informa-
ing on “development, modernization, and enhance- tion  services’ budget that is outsourced to private
ment” to decrease by about a fourth over the same companies.63
The Public’s Information Resource 161

In 2010, an effort was initiated to consolidate In 2014, the White House announced the
40 percent of all 10,584 energy-guzzling data centers founding of the U.S. Digital Service, a centralized
that the federal government maintained in that year. agency charged with removing digital barriers to
Nearly seven years later, 4,300 had been cut, saving service delivery government-wide, and placed it in
nearly $3 billion, with additional savings projected OMB. The Digital Service was soon backed up by
at $5 billion. Half of the consolidated or eliminated the Commerce Department, which includes at least
centers had been cut by just five agencies;64 72 two agencies that are among the largest data col-
percent of federal IT managers said that their agency lectors in government. The department created, in
had, over roughly the same period, kept the number 2015, the Commerce Data Corps designed to assist
of their data centers the same or increased them.65 agencies with IT.
Still, the feds expected to cut 50 percent of their data In 2016, three existing programs—the Office
centers by 2019, surpassing the original goal of 40 of Citizen Services and Innovative Technologies
percent.66 and 18F (so named for its location at 18th and F
streets—who said that the feds are not the hippest
Public Pain The public suffers from these inef- of cool cats?), both created by GSA in 2010 and
ficiencies and failures. Although the Paperwork 2014, respectively, and the Presidential Innovation
Reduction Act of 1980 demanded that agencies Fellows Program, founded by the White House
lighten the public’s paperwork burden, that load in 2012—were collapsed into a new bureau, the
actually grew by 17 percent over six years, amount- Technology Transformation Service, within GSA.
ing to more than eight billion, rapidly-growing, It is charged with solving IT problems related to
“burden hours” on the public.67 customer service at the agency level, an area evi-
The computer-based problems of the bureau- dently in need of help; only 45 percent of federal
cracy go beyond burdens. Because of “soft- clients think that agency representatives understand
ware glitches,” for instance, the Social Security their  digital needs, compared with 66 percent of
Administration shortchanged some 700,000 retirees private-sector customers.71
by $850 million in Social Security payments, includ- Still, gains are gradually being made. Agency
ing the multiple sclerosis victim who went without managers are “generally satisfied” with the ser-
payments for four years, accumulated $60,000 in vices that they receive from the U.S. Digital Service
medical debts, and lost her house and car.68 and 18F (pluralities are “very satisfied”).72 Yearly
Small wonder that 66 percent of Americans say “report cards” on buying and managing IT, issued
that they are satisfied with federal digital services, by Congress since 2015, grade most agencies with
compared with 70 percent for local governments and a “C” or “D,” but “Fs” are declining and “As” occa-
nearly 77 percent for all sectors; even cable compa- sionally appear. Between 2010 and 2015, GAO
nies and airlines fare more favorably than the feds.69 made 803 recommendations to improve IT acqui-
sitions and operations, and 46 percent of them had
Recent Efforts to Improve the Federal IT Anti- been fully implemented by 2016.73
System: Mixed Results IT morphs far faster than
federal efforts to manage it. Nearly four decades Managing People: A Federal Cyber Crisis There
after Congress, in 1980, passed the first Paperwork are more than 100 different cyber job categories74
Reduction Act (generally recognized as the initial and some 93,000 civilian cyber workers in the
congressional attempt to improve federal IT), which federal government, accounting for about one out
directed OMB to develop a government-wide infor- of every twenty-two federal employees.75 On the
mation resources management plan, OMB contin- face of it, they work in a culture that supports IT:
ues to plod away at it. In 2012, for example, the “An overwhelming majority” of federal executives
feds began implementing a “digital government “across all demographics (93%) embrace digital
strategy”; three years later, 65 percent of federal technology in the workplace,”76 but it is less clear
executives did not know if their own agencies even that these administrators extend their support for
had a “digital strategy that is currently being imple- information technology to the technologists respon-
mented.”70 sible for making the technology work. It is also
162 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

unclear whether Washington is hiring and retaining Administrative difficulties for federal CIOs
the more talented knowledge workers. appear to be growing. Out of thirteen major CIO
responsibilities, eight remained their responsibilities
People Problems at the Top The important at the same level over seven years, but CIOs actually
Information Technology Management Reform Act had lost ground in the remaining five.85
of 1996, later re-titled to the Clinger-Cohen Act, Deeper, cultural problems also are present,
required that the twenty-seven largest agencies notably the failure of federal executives to view IT
appoint CIOs. In 2009, the president appointed the as a strategic asset (one compared “IT to toilets—
first CIO and a complementing “federal chief tech- just necessary infrastructure, nothing special”), and
nology officer” for the whole of government. Both a general dissing of CIOs in general (“Sure, you have
officials report directly to the president and work a seat at the table, but you’re treated like a child who
together to coordinate IT planning, spending, and has to sit with the adults because the kids’ table is
policymaking. full”).86
In the view of some, the more than 250 federal All this considered, it should not surprise us
CIOs “have been set up for failure by a political and that, even though federal CIOs themselves state
bureaucratic system that has changed little since the that it takes three to five years “to become effec-
Clinger-Cohen Act became law.”77 tive,” the median time in office for permanently-
There is much to support this statement. The appointed CIOs is a shocking one year and eleven
appointments process was, until recently, politicized months (average CIO tenure in the private sector
(“the Clinger-Cohen Act was totally bastardized is five years and eleven months, and lengthening87),
to fit political agendas”78) and remains slow to the with most leaving because of the “political environ-
point of delaying important projects. Often, man- ment” and more lucrative opportunities elsewhere;88
agement skills are negligible, and their agency col- senior-level federal software engineers, for example,
leagues believe that CIOs “‘routinely do not follow earn from $24,000 to $33,000 less than their coun-
even some of the more basic project management terparts in the private sector.89
practices,’ leading to project failure after project In 2014, some steps were taken to lift CIOs
failure.”79 Consider, in this regard, HealthCare. out of their bureaucratic ruts when the Federal
gov: despite the receipt of eighteen written warnings Information Technology Acquisition Reform Act
(including eleven from top IT professionals in the (“the most significant federal IT reform since the
private sector) that the entire project was misman- Clinger-Cohen Act of 1996”90) was enacted. Among
aged and off course, its federal developers ignored other advances, the act promised a significant role
them and ploughed blithely on, resulting in its spec- for CIOs in decision making, budgeting (includ-
tacular inaugural failure.80 ing a required CIO approval of the IT portion of
The educational backgrounds of federal IT exec- their agencies’ annual budget requests to Congress),
utives suggest that they may be in over their heads. and programming (including the banning of repro-
Out of twenty-four departmental and major agency gramming an agency’s IT funds without its CIO’s
CIOs, just eight had degrees in IT fields. The major- approval).
ity had majored in the liberal arts, science, business, A related attempt at improving the IT executive
or non-IT-related engineering, among others; two suites has been the appointment of chief data officers
had master of public administration degrees.81 (CDOs). The Federal Communications Commission
Ultimately, however, “the lack of authority appointed the government’s first CDO, in 2010, and
provided CIOs” amounts to “the greatest single at least seven additional civilian agencies, including
failure of government IT”;82 although the Clinger- the largest, have followed suit. In 2015, the presi-
Cohen Act requires that CIOs in the twenty-three dent named the first government-wide CDO, porten-
major departments report directly to their secretary tously titled the White House’s “chief data scientist
or deputy secretary, half do not,83 even though 77 in residence.”
percent of these departments’ top CIOs think that it Although how CDOs differ from CIOs is still
is important to do so, an increase of more than two- sorting itself out, CDOs focus on the data them-
fifths from seven years earlier.84 selves—e.g., data sharing, data transparency—and
The Public’s Information Resource 163

CIOs concern themselves with information technol- software engineers earn from $8,000 to $14,000
ogy—e.g., its purchase, its management. less than their corporate counterparts.102
One analysis concluded that 69 percent of Although the feds have tried to correct the
federal agencies with a CDO were managing big situation, their efforts have been ineffective, even
data workloads and 61 percent were using big data counterproductive. Despite, over twenty years,
in decision making, compared with 40 percent and hiring knowledge managers at higher grade levels,
28 percent, respectively, of those without one.91 paying them more, and promoting them faster
CDOs are needed. For example, the Social Security than  their comparably educated and experienced
Administration listed 6.5 million recipients on its counterparts in other fields, they perform at the
rolls who, it stated, were 112 years old or older; same levels and stay in government just as long.
estimates are that there are around thirty-five people Washington is paying more for less, or, at best, the
worldwide of that remarkable age.92 same.103
In 2015, Washington tried, once again, to seri-
People Problems in the Bureaucratic Bowels When ously address its IT personnel problems, hiring
we descend from the apex of the federal IT hierar- 3,000 new IT and cybersecurity professionals in that
chy, we find that the problems among those occu- year, and another 3,500 the next.
pying humbler bureaucratic stations may be worse
than at the top; federal IT specialists have the Records Management: From Risky to Responsible
lowest employee engagement scores of any of five In 1980 or thereabouts (no one is sure about the
“mission-critical” occupations surveyed—just 64 year), federal records managers misplaced the
percent report that they are engaged in their work.93 Wright brothers’ patent for the world’s first air-
Why is this? plane. More than a generation later, in 2016,
One reason is perceived poor hiring. A slender researchers unearthed (literally) the priceless paper
37 percent of IT specialists think that their agencies from a fifteen-foot-high stack of records kept in
are able to recruit people “with the right skills,”94 a Kansan  cave. Indiana Jones was not among
perhaps because, in part, it takes an average of more the  researchers,  but the circumstances would have
than 100 days for federal agencies to hire IT special- suited him.
ists, compared with a norm of seven to fourteen days Thus we arrive at another critical federal IT
in “the leading private sector companies.”95 issue: managing records. The Federal Records
Training is less than the best, with 34 percent Act of 1950 instructs agencies and the National
of IT workers stating that they are not satisfied with Archives and Records Administration to manage
it.96 Even though the Electronic Government Act their records in order to document all federal “pol-
of 2002 requires it, agencies’ use of leading train- icies and transactions,” hardly a trivial charge.
ing practices for IT professionals is “generally not Each federal agency spends, on average, more
extensive.”97 than $34 million per year managing an average of
Regrettably, as a consequence of these and other 209 million records, ranging from laws to emails.
failures, top federal IT officials anticipate that from Federal administrators estimate that they lose, on
20 to 70 percent of the federal IT workforce will average, 18 percent of their annual budgets due to
depart during the next five years,98 and more than inefficient records management.104
a third of IT specialists say that they “are actively Records grow. The administration of George W.
eyeing the exits.”99 In fact, 12 percent more IT Bush generated “about 35 times the amount of data
workers leave federal employment than are hired.100 produced by the Clinton administration,” its imme-
Worryingly, for every federal IT worker who is under diate predecessor.105 Two years into his second term,
thirty years old, there are ten who are over fifty, an the administration of Barack Obama had surpassed
average age that is steadily increasing, and those IT one billion emails (a record), which were added to
employees under thirty “are significantly less likely the twelve billion papers and parchments (enough
to stay in the government for the long-term than to circle the earth eighty-four times and for which
their predecessors did.”101 Not surprising, perhaps, 1.5 million trees had given their all) already in the
when we realize, for example, that entry level federal Archives.106
164 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Despite records management’s centrality to


knowledge management, it received scant federal Subnational Knowledge Management
attention for decades. In the 1930s, the chief archi- “IT challenges are even greater [than Washington’s]
vist stumbled over “‘valuable records . . . piled on at the state and local level as those governments
dust-covered shelves mingled higgledy-piggledy struggle to keep up with IT security threats and com-
with empty whiskey bottles,’”107 and GAO has been pliance issues.”115 For starters, 64 percent of the grass-
calling Congress’s attention to this “remarkably per- roots governments must comply with often-complex
sistent” lapse since 1981.108 federal IT mandates, and 47 percent must comply
Recently, federal interest in records management with three or more. Four percent of state IT officials
has picked up, and progress is evident. In 2011, the say that they “lack the necessary tools and processes
president signed a memorandum meant to modernize to monitor and effectively respond to issues,” but
records management, and, by the close of 2014, from four times that percentage—16 percent—of local
twenty to twenty-three agencies out of twenty-four officials say the same. Sixty-one percent of state and
had met all seven modernization requirements.109 In local IT professionals, the highest proportion, cite a
2014, Congress enacted the Presidential and Federal “limited budget” as their chief “IT governance and
Records Act Amendments, the first statutory change compliance concern,” followed by 54 percent who
to the Federal Records Act of 1950, which enlarged say “limited manpower.”116
the definition of a “federal record” to include elec-
tronic documents. In 2015, the Coalition for Public Managing Knowledge in State Governments IT is a
Sector Information Governance Leadership, a group vexatious problem in the states. Although 31 percent
of nonprofit organizations, pitched in to help agen- of the states own and operate “all state IT assets and
cies manage records. operations,” the outsourcing of “some . . . IT appli-
The results of these initiatives were encouraging; cations and services” has nearly doubled, from 42 to
over five years those agencies rated as “high risk” in 79 percent, over six years.117 Courthouses in all fifty
their records management plummeted by more than states have introduced some form of e-filing, and “at
half, from 46 to 20 percent, and those rated “low least two dozen states have implemented statewide
risk” septupled from 5 to 34 percent.110 e-filing for attorneys”; millions of dollars are being
saved and a lot of office space is being opened up as
Managing Telework Telework, a federal practice a result.118
initiated by Congress in 2000, refers to working Still, problems persist. Nearly two dozen years
away from one’s office via computer. went by before all the states were in compliance
Telework facilitates continuity of operations, with the federal requirement that state informa-
reduces employee absences, increases productivity, tion systems for enforcing child support payments
and improves recruitment, retention, and work/life be operational,119 and, even though Congress has
balance. Nearly half a million federal employees offered funds since 1994 for states to develop infor-
telework, a jump of 70 percent over three years.111 mation systems that detect child abusers, there is a
Fifty-two percent of federal managers say that median delay of two-and-half years in bringing these
employees who telework are more productive, and systems online.120 After six years had elapsed since
none say that they are less productive.112 Congress enacted the legislation, just sixteen states
Telework is an area ripe with potential savings. had completed applications for federal funding for
“An estimated $14 billion annually could be derived IT that tracks sex offenders.121
from Federal telework as a product of the Telework These difficulties may be ascribable to uncon-
Enhancement Act of 2010.”113 First, however, nected and disconnected state CIOs, who are
Washington must get a better grip on managing present in every state. Unconnected because they
telework; for example, GSA, whose mission states, have an average tenure of just twenty-six months.122
in part, “to deliver the best value in . . . technology And disconnected because an “overwhelming” 79
services to government and the American people,” is percent of CIOs blame “salary rates and pay grade
unable to determine how many full-time teleworkers structures” as the prime obstacles in attracting and
are on its own payroll.114 retaining talent (the states’ minimum IT salaries are
The Public’s Information Resource 165

25 percent below that of the private sector, and their center of federal technology and innovation policy,
maximum salaries are 8 percent below123), followed and the White House followed up in the same year
by the civil service system at 48 percent.124 Yet, the with a $160 million program to fund “smart cities”
able IT professionals themselves are far more con- research.
cerned with starkly different variables of job sat- Larger cities with higher voter registration levels
isfaction, placing their greatest emphasis on clear are likelier to adopt new electronic services for citi-
communication, clear job descriptions, participa- zens,131 and, when they do, they make major, long-
tory management, support for career development, term improvements in their relations with citizens
opportunities for advancement, and family-friendly and fiscal controls;132 an astonishing 92 percent of
workplace policies.125 Forty-two percent of top state municipal finance directors report that “computers
CIOs do not report to the governor.126 (The public have improved their government’s efficiency and
sector is at least ahead of the independent sector in productivity.”133
this regard, where 59 percent of CIOs do not report In light of this bounty of e-benefits, it is small
to the chief executive.127) In addition, CIO positions wonder that city managers rank the “use of new
are surprisingly political, with many CIOs resigning technologies” in the top tier (out of four tiers) of
when a new governor arrives.128 their priorities.134 But this high ranking also reflects
A few states also have chief data officers; challenges, mostly involving relations between
Colorado became the first state to appoint one, in administrators who provide computer services and
2010, and at least six more states followed. And those who use them, and the difficulties of hiring and
with good reason. Seven out of ten state officials in training competent technical staff.
forty-six states said that “data problems were fre- Nevertheless, local governments are making
quently or often an impediment to doing their busi- major knowledge-management gains. In 1982, 22
ness effectively”; no one said “rarely.” California’s percent of cities and counties contracted out their
state auditor uncovered that the government had “data processing” to private companies,135 a pro-
collected 200,000 hours of questionable sick leave portion that has been nearly halved to 12 percent
(“instead of eight hours [of sick leave] it was 80 and today;136 59 percent now have their own separate
in one case, 800”), valued at $6 million. Bad data, or IT departments. Almost all cities and counties (94
no data, are a consistently recurring problem in the percent) have put council agendas and minutes on
states (and localities), and are caused by: minimal line; citizens can request services at 58 percent of
or no data sharing among agencies (or even within them, pay utility bills at 53 percent, and pay taxes
agencies), poor definitions, privatization (“When at 36 percent.137
government services are privatized, often the data Local governments seem to wring the great-
on performance is greatly diminished”—Medicaid est efficiencies from IT. Eighty-seven percent, the
is an outstanding example), ineffective centralized top scorer, of local officials say that e-government
controls over IT, and under-trained IT workers.129 has improved customer service, increased the effi-
Just as nonprofits joined to assist Washington ciency  of business processes (52 percent), changed
with its records management, noted earlier, so have the role of departmental staff (39 percent), and
they begun to assist states in their data management. reduced the number of departmental staff overall
Results First is dedicated to using data to improve (8 percent).138
state governmental performance. Relative to the federal and many state govern-
ments, some local governments have become the
Managing Knowledge in Local Governments Local “employer of choice” for IT professionals, “in spite
governments are the nation’s information resource of public sector constraints.”139 New York City
leaders, accounting for some 9,000 different appli- became the first local government to appoint a CDO,
cations, or four times the number of federal digital in 2011, followed by five more metropolises.140 Los
applications, and three times that of state applica- Angeles is not among them, which may explain why
tions.130 Small wonder that, in 2016, the prestig- the city recently discovered that it was losing more
ious President’s Council of Advisors on Science and than $20 million a year because of “fumbled tax
Technology recommended that cities be placed at the data.”141
166 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Just as nonprofits have helped the federal and ■ Remember to be a pessimistic, “recalcitrant,
state governments manage their data more pro- suspicious, and skeptical adopter” of IT.144
ductively, so they have assisted local governments. Most information system projects fail.
In 2015, Bloomberg Philanthropies created What
Works Cities, offering millions to aid cities in
improving city services through better data usage. PRIVACY VERSUS POLICY:
Harvard University’s Ash Center promotes “Data- THE PARTICULAR PROBLEM
Smart City Solutions,” and Code for America uses
data-knowledgeable volunteers to render local ser- OF THE PUBLIC COMPUTER
vices more effective. There are other examples. Around 90 percent of Americans consistently state
that they are concerned over problems of personal
privacy,145 a dramatic increase from only 35 percent
Best Practices for Knowledge Management in 1970.146
As the public information resource grows ever
There is “an extremely limited body of knowledge”
more pervasive, a duo of devilish dilemmas has grown
about managing information resources in the public
ever more ominous. At what point does the collec-
sector,142 but what little there is143 we have reduced
tion of personal information for purposes of making
to six guidelines that we believe have a particular
better public policy become an invasion of a citizen’s
salience. They are:
privacy? Where lies the delicate balance between pro-
■ Strong, skilled leadership is essential. Clear tecting the people and protecting the person?
communication of changing needs and the Examples of this tension are many, such as the
unambiguous assignment of responsibility are intelligence community’s massive scooping up of
critical. Public employees in particular must be Americans’ telephone calls following 9/11 (“bulk
pushed to “get with the program,” as they tend telephone metadata” were purged in 2015). Or
to hunker down until this fad, too, shall pass. cellphone manufacturers’ selling phones so secure
■ The goals of new information systems must (a terrorist’s dream) that even they, and often law
clearly align with legislative and agency goals, enforcement, cannot access their data.
and be comprehensively integrated throughout An unusually vivid, but little known, instance of
the organization. The clearer this strategic the privacy-policy paradox is the denial of research-
alignment, the likelier that legislative support ers’ access to personal “administrative micro-data”
will continue. held by American governments at all levels (a prac-
■ Organizational processes, not software or tice not followed in other democracies); this policy
hardware, should be the focus in introducing has had a direct and negative impact on the adjust-
and managing information resources. Once ment and improvement of policies and programs
the administrative processes are right, then the because such data, which can be quickly “de-identi-
software can be rewritten to accommodate fied,” are far more accurate than are survey data.147
them. When  such shortsighted privacy policies are pre-
■ Develop strong skills among information cluded, the public can benefit. For example, a 1979
resource managers, strong relationships injunction prohibiting media access to Medicare
between these managers and the rest of the records prevented Pulitzer-Prize-winning investiga-
organization, and rigorous performance tive reporting on fraud until a court overturned it;
measures. privacy, at least for those who did not defraud the
■ Minimize risks. New data systems can threaten government, was maintained in the reporting, and
traditional turfs and political relationships. costly corruption was exposed.
To minimize these risks, wring agreements
about project specifications from department
heads, unbundle projects into separate modules Stealing You: Identity Theft
to isolate failures, and employ experts when Perhaps the invasion of privacy that Americans fear
needed. most is identity theft, or the stealing of personal
The Public’s Information Resource 167

information for fraudulent use, typically for eco- “unusual” tax returns, and issue old-school paper
nomic gain. Nearly 5 percent of the adult popula- checks, a procedure that has had a “noticeable [and
tion are victims of identity theft, with reported losses positive] impact” in reducing improper payments
amounting to more than $50 billion every year.148 based on fraudulent tax returns.155
Government officials may not be well attuned Where Washington needs the greatest improve-
to the sensitivity of private data. Twenty-eight ment is in notifying citizens when federal agencies
million identities are illegally released annually lose personal data to hackers. Although there is a
from public-sector systems, two-thirds of which spate of federal laws and regulations requiring com-
are released by accident (most of the remainder panies and nonprofits to notify victims when their
are released by hackers).149 In addition, about 200 personally identifiable information is compromised,
million bits and pieces of personal records are there is no federal policy requiring that federal agen-
exposed—mostly, it appears, inadvertently—on cies do the same, and it appears that less than 30
the Internet per year, many by public officials who percent of agencies bother to do so.156
“viewed the new technology as a natural extension
of the public domain and rushed to put information
[e.g., divorces, bankruptcies] online.”150 Protecting Privacy: Federal Efforts
Government is not the largest sector targeted Just 6 percent of Americans say that they are “very
by identity thieves, but it is large. Over ten years, confident” that the records maintained by federal
“Government/Military” accounted for an average of agencies will be kept private and secure. Relatively
nearly 16 percent of all identity-theft “data breaches,” speaking, the feds fare well; out of eleven industries,
and the closely associated “Education” and “Medical/ only credit card companies garner more popular
Health Care” categories accounted for averages of confidence than Washington, at 9 percent.157 Six
more than 15 percent and 26 percent, respectively.151 percent, however, is still a miniscule 6 percent.
These numbers are relative: no public theft remotely As Americans’ worries have deepened, each of
compares with what happens in the private sector, the three branches of the federal government has
such as the more than one billion identities and com- grown more involved in the issue.
puter passwords looted from Yahoo, Inc., in 2016.
The federal government is especially vulner- The Judiciary’s Zone of Privacy In 1977, in
able to identity theft. Over five years, the number Whalen v. Roe, the Supreme Court recognized for
of reported “security incidents involving person- the first time a constitutionally protected “zone of
ally identifiable information” of federal employees privacy” that entitles each person to have his or her
exploded by 144 percent, and, at last count, stood at personal information kept private.
nearly 26,000 stolen identities per year.152 The courts since have developed a three-
Most scams to file phony claims for federal tax pronged test, based on the Constitution’s Fourth
returns are based on stolen identities.153 In 2014, Amendment (the Unwarrantable Search and Seizure
identity thieves submitted fraudulent tax returns Clause), that should be used in balancing an
amounting to $22.5 billion to the IRS (which, it employee’s right to privacy with an employer’s need
should be said, prevented or recovered 88 percent to know. These  tests are: reasonableness—man-
of the funds involved), but the government still paid agement must obtain the consent of an employee
out more than $3 billion to fraudsters. In 2015, before it intrudes on his or her privacy; compelling
about 724,000 people’s personal information may interest—a serious issue must be present; and job
have been stolen from the IRS (another 570,000 relatedness—the intrusion cannot exceed the scope
attempts were clearly unsuccessful).154 In 2017, the of organizational necessity.
IRS launched its Identity Theft Tax Refund Fraud
Information Sharing and Analysis Center to further Congress, Privacy, and Policy Congress has
reduce emerging and current identity theft schemes enacted two principal laws that reconcile personal
leading to tax fraud. privacy with federal procedures. The Privacy Act of
The states are beset with similar problems. 1974 assures individual access to personal federal
Fifteen states and the District of Columbia flag records. The Electronic Government Act directs
168 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

agencies to provide “privacy impact assessments” governments from releasing Social Security numbers,
when purchasing new information technologies or disclosing personal information by state depart-
initiating new collections of personal information. ments of motor vehicles, and electronically trans-
Congress has passed at least four additional laws mitting personal health information. Only fourteen
that protect people’s financial and other personal states, however, comply with federal mandates con-
records from monitoring by federal agencies, and cerning the protection of personal data owned by
another five statutes that shield these records from private companies.162
the view of colleges and corporations. Although forty-six states have enacted privacy
laws, twenty-one states have no “privacy program”
The Executive Branch and the Protection of in place to implement their laws (if they have laws
Privacy Aside from violations following 9/11, at all), nine are “just starting” a program, and eight
federal agencies traditionally have “generally com- do not know if they have one.163 Those programs
plied with key requirements and guidance pertaining that do exist seem primitive. For example, it is not
to . . . privacy,”158 and compliance with the Privacy a great stride in privacy protection that “more than
Act is “generally high,” with 71 percent of agencies 20 states” (and some counties) have redacted Social
enforcing “the requirement that personal informa- Security numbers from their records, yet tout this as
tion should be complete, accurate, relevant, and “a major shift in public records laws.”164 Nor is the
timely before it is disclosed to a nonfederal organ- fact that just 11 percent of the states have a chief
ization.”159 OMB has issued at least a half-dozen privacy officer (defined as more than “75% of time
memoranda that protect against identity theft, a spent in managing privacy”), and 26 percent “have
crime over which seven federal agencies have some no one dedicated to privacy issues.”165 By contrast,
jurisdiction,160 and, in 2015, GAO added the protec- 77 percent of financial services companies have chief
tion of “personally identifiable information” to its privacy officers.166 All in all, it appears that more
list of high-risk areas. state and local records of personal data are exposed
Federal officials take these directives seriously. annually than are comparable federal records.167
Over five years, 1,300 IRS employees were investi- There is some good news. Forty-seven states
gated for prying in personal income tax returns, and have enacted “security freeze laws” that block
420 were found guilty.161 unauthorized persons from obtaining private credit
An accelerating trend is the appointment of information,168 and forty-five require that citizens
agency executives charged with protecting personal be notified of data breaches that affect them.169
privacy. The IRS, in 1993, appointed the federal gov- In 2013, ten states enacted more than two dozen
ernment’s first “privacy advocate,” and Congress soon privacy laws,170 and, over two years, seventeen states
began requiring, through legislation, “chief privacy banned employers’ access to the personal social
officers” in selected agencies. In 2007, Congress media of their employees.171
passed the Implementing Recommendations of the
9/11 Commission Act, which extricated Congress
from this thorny thicket by authorizing the presi- CYBERCRIME
dent’s Privacy and Civil Liberties Oversight Board to There are nearly 79,000 “publicly known cyberse-
require any agencies that it chose to appoint privacy curity vulnerabilities and exposures” in all sectors
and civil liberties officers. In 2013, the first chief “with more being added each day,”172 so it is not
privacy officer was appointed to the White House, surprising that the director of the Federal Bureau
and, in 2015, the White House announced the for- of Investigation (FBI) has stated that “cyber risk
mation of the first government-wide council (the will shortly eclipse terrorism as our top domestic
Federal Privacy Council) of chief privacy officers. threat.”173 No doubt he was aware that there are
“at least fifty-thousand computer viruses” infecting
the worldwide web, ranging from “worms” to “war
Protecting Privacy at the Grass Roots driving,” and “any fool can enter, alter, and destroy
Congress requires state and local agencies to shield even the most seemingly impregnable Web sites.”174
personal data. Three laws enacted since 1990 bar all Speaking of fools, a survey of 1,000 American,
The Public’s Information Resource 169

Australian, and European office workers found that government networks are nearly twice as likely to
a fifth would sell their organizations’ passwords for be infected with ransomware or similar malware
$1,000 or less.175 than are networks in small and medium-sized
businesses.182

Hacking: Harrowing and Humiliating Imperiled Infrastructure Eighty-four percent of


Perhaps the most notorious form of cybercrime American public- and private-sector cybersecurity
is hacking, or the illegal accessing of databases. professionals believe that a hack that “disrupts crit-
Usually, hacking involves theft of some sort, but a ical infrastructure,” such as dams and nuclear reac-
variation of hacking is hactivism, a blend of hacking tors, is likely within the current year.183
and activism that is disruptive hacking for a cause, They are right to be concerned. Government-
such as Black Lives Matter. Hactivism is aimed sponsored hackers, thought to be Chinese, Iranian,
largely at state and local governments. Russian, and even some associated with the terrorist
Every year, approximately seven out of every ten Islamic State, tried to penetrate, or penetrated (an
American organizations in all sectors are hacked,176 estimated dozen attempts were successful in the
accounting for estimated annual losses of $100 2000s), the U.S. electrical grid, including hackers
billion.177 Fifty-nine percent of the American private who stole vast and vital data from an electric
sector’s publicly-released data breaches are attrib- utility with eighty-two plants in eighteen states and
utable to outside hackers. For all American govern- Canada. According to the Federal Energy Regulatory
ments it is 47 percent, and for the nonprofit sector it Commission, “a coordinated attack on just nine
is 44 percent.178 critical power stations could cause a coast-to-coast
More than three-fifths of 1,600 cyber experts blackout that could last months.”184
predict that a major cyber “attack causing wide- In 2003, GAO added “critical cyber infrastruc-
spread harm,” defined as “significant loss of life or ture protection” to its list of high-risk areas, and it
property losses/damage/theft at the levels of tens of is still on it.
billions of dollars,” would occur sometime within
the next ten years.179 In Government, We Steal Hardware! An underap-
Some of the more virulent forms of hacking preciated variant of hacking government databases
include the following. is the simple theft of computers themselves. These
thefts account for 19 percent of data breaches in the
Robbery by Ransomware Ransomware occurs global public sector,185 and a surprisingly similar
when a hacker shuts down a computer and unlocks 20 percent in the American one, compared with 11
it only after the owner has paid the hacker. From percent in the American private sector and less than
2005 though 2015 the FBI received some 9,600 5 percent in its nonprofit sector.186
ransomware complaints from all sources, costing Here is an example: in 2006, an employee of
more than $24 million annually.180 Then, in 2016, the Department of Veterans Affairs, in violation of
the situation worsened—dramatically. “Unique ran- standing, but laxly-enforced, regulations, took home
somware attempts” (attempts, not complaints to the a departmental computer for work-related use. That
FBI) exploded by an almost inconceivable 16,000 evening, the computer was stolen, and, with it, the
percent—from not even four million in 2015 to names, Social Security numbers, and other personal
more than 638 million attempts in 2016.181 information of more than twenty-six million veter-
Ransomware increasingly is being used against ans. It was the largest theft of personal data from
governments, including American federal agencies, a government in history. Fortunately, the computer
police stations, hospitals, and even public librar- eventually was returned (anonymously), with no
ies.  Sixty-seven percent of government networks apparent lifting of the data in it.
and 72 percent of education networks in the United With the immense effort and expense involved
States “triggered critical malware or ransomware in defending against hacking, it turns out that gov-
alerts, compared to just 39 percent of other net- ernments could be far more effective in their fight
works triggering similar alerts.” State and local against cybercrime if they just locked the doors.
170 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Hacking the Federal Government National gov- data losses, substantially more than the worldwide
ernments around the globe experience nearly fifty figure of the 1 percent of “cyber incidents” that are
times more “cyber incidents” than any other indus- attributed to “espionage.”195 The United States is
try,187 and the government of the United States is no the prime target for international cyberattacks in all
exception. sectors that likely are supported by a foreign country,
More than half of federal agencies experience a suffering more than twice as many of these cyberat-
“cybersecurity incident” on a weekly (23 percent) or tacks than the runner-up (Canada).196 The eighteen
daily (31 percent) basis.188 These incidents increased federal agencies with the most sensitive information
by 1,303 percent over ten years, and currently stand cite “cyber attacks from ‘nations’ as the most serious
at around 80,000 annually,189 or about one in three and most frequently-occurring threat to the security
of all such incidents in all sectors in the United of their systems.”197
States.190 All of these numbers could be higher Here are some examples: according to reports,
because the feds are not required to publicize their the Russians not only breached the emails of the
data losses. joint-chiefs-of-staff and the commander-in-chief,
The largest reason for such losses, at 37 percent, but, in 2015, effectively strolled into the foyer of the
is “miscellaneous errors,” a category that includes IRS website (no sophisticated malware was used)
many relatively harmless minor mishaps, and 24 and wandered out with $50 million in fraudulent
percent, the next highest, are “non-malicious inci- tax refunds, adversely affecting 330,000 taxpayers,
dents.”191 Fifty-three percent (a growing proportion) despite the fact that GAO had issued eight reports
of federal IT managers believe that the major cause of over nine years warning IRS of vulnerabilities that
data breaches is careless or untrained federal employ- the Russians allegedly exploited. In 2016, American
ees (only 23 percent of these officials think that these intelligence officials stated that the Russian gov-
breaches are the mischief of malicious insiders), fol- ernment had “weaponized” its hacking; it was
lowed by the “general hacking community,” at 46 behind the penetration of the Democratic National
percent, and foreign governments, at 38 percent.192 Committee during a presidential campaign, had
leaked potentially damaging information about its
Hacking State Governments Among state agen- candidate, and had attempted intrusions into voter
cies, there is mostly good news. Over two years, registration databases.
hacking declined by 45 percent and the insertion
of malicious software fell by 15 percent. External Oh, Oh, OPM In 2014, federal officials began to
financial fraud, such as stealing Medicaid benefits suspect the presence of the mother of all cyber espi-
by using stolen personal data, was up by two-thirds, onage attacks. From 2012 through 2015, cyberspies,
but had attained just 12 percent of all external this time alleged to be Chinese, penetrated the Office
breaches.193 of Personnel Management (OPM) and its contrac-
tors, and lifted the personnel records of 21.5 million
federal and contracted employees and many others.
Cyberspying: Sinister and Slippery The fingerprints of 5.6 million people were also
A particularly nasty form of hacking is cyberspying, stolen. Federal officials voiced fears that the hackers
or cyber espionage, which is the illegal penetration could identify American spies.
of databases by foreign governments. Americans The assault on OPM was the largest known
seem to understand the gravity of cyber espionage; breach of federal employees’ personal data, although
their support for increased security measures to its magnitude was about all that was known. There
protect national security has nearly doubled over was “an interval of about 17 months during which
three years, from 24 to 46 percent.194 the United States likely will never know what data
In 2015, the president declared cyberspying to the bad guys touched.”198
be a “national emergency.” He had reason. The cyberspy debacle was compounded by
OPM’s starkly maladroit management. OPM spent
The Extent of Cyber Espionage Cyber espio- less on cybersecurity than any other agency.199 Since
nage accounts for 16 percent of all known federal at least 2005, federal auditors and inspectors had
The Public’s Information Resource 171

harshly and repeatedly warned OPM of its ghastly websites scores an average of ten points lower than
cybersecurity. OPM was “shockingly careless” and that of their counterparts in the banking and social
“encrypted nothing,” effectively granting “full access media sectors.209
to database administrators in China.”200 An inde- Once a cyberattack occurs, the feds are unlikely
pendent IT expert, on learning of OMB’s deficien- to deal with it well. In 2014, GAO reported that the
cies, called them “shocking,” and another emailed, twenty-four major agencies “did not consistently
“Reading now, jaw on floor.”201 demonstrate that they had effectively responded to
During the crisis, OPM’s inspector general cyber incidents. . .. or take actions to prevent their
wrote that OPM’s CIO had misinformed him and recurrence,” and this is still the case today.210 Just
had “hindered and interfered with” his office’s over- 40 percent of federal cyber executives think that
sight.202 Such infighting surfaced, perhaps, because their “agency’s incident response plan is effective in
the head of OPM at the time was a political appoin- responding to cyber attacks.”211 More than three-
tee who had just left her previous job as the national fifths of major federal agencies lack full contingency
political director for the president’s re-election cam- plans should a cyberattack wipe their data clean,
paign of 2012, and had no experience in personnel such as happened to Sony Pictures Entertainment, in
management; she was forced to resign in 2015. 2014 (of Sony’s some 7,000 employees, eleven con-
The good news is that the next OPM director, stituted its “information security team”).212
Beth Cobert, had, after just a year and a half, taken In 1997, GAO placed information security on
“OPM from the agency that suffered the biggest its list of high-risk areas, where it remains today.
hacks in the history of the federal government and
built it into a model of federal cybersecurity capabil- Mysteries of the Federal Cybersecurity Workforce
ities and systems modernization.”203 Personnel problems are particularly vexing. There
are an estimated 125,000 to 135,000 federal cyber-
security personnel, an estimate that includes not only
CYBERSECURITY civilian employees, but also contractors and soldiers
Although securing the public’s knowledge resource (roughly 70 percent of the total are employed by
is vital, securing it is not being done well. the Pentagon). There is no official federal tally of,
and no one really knows, how many cybersecurity
workers there are in the government, or even in indi-
Federal Cyber In-Security vidual agencies.213 It was only in 2014 that Congress
A third of federal IT units deal with, on average, legislated that agencies designate a chief information
more than 1,000 security alerts every day, and 7 security officer (CISO).
percent receive over 50,000 alerts daily, overwhelm- The startling absence of basic data may be
ing volumes that amount to “something of a new attributable to the fact that, until 2016, there was no
challenge” for security managers.204 These floods consistent federal job description for cybersecurity,
may explain why 92 percent, and growing, of all a description that entails seven broad categories and
federal data breaches are detected by someone other more than fifty work roles.214 This systemic weak-
than the target.205 ness may have underlain hiring difficulties. It takes,
Just 26 percent of federal IT professionals feel on average, six months for two-thirds of federal
that their agencies’ data are “fully protected.”206 employers to hire qualified cybersecurity profession-
They have a point. Despite “hundreds of recom- als, compared with one-third of industry employers
mendations” from federal inspectors, all of the who say the same.215
twenty-four major federal agencies “continue to be
afflicted by persistent information security control Spending Madly. And Badly? In the four years
weaknesses.”207 following 9/11, federal expenditures for computer
An extensive analysis of six industries found security quadrupled, then leveled off to about $6
that the effectiveness of the federal government’s billion annually, and, beginning in 2010, spending
cybersecurity ranked third, and that of its defense doubled to between $10 billion and $14 billion, or
contractors ranked fourth.208 The security of federal roughly 15 percent of the federal IT budget. “The
172 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

annual cybersecurity spending of the U.S. federal Workforce Strategy, the first consolidated and coher-
government is bigger than any national cyber- ent Guide for Cybersecurity Event Recovery, and
security market (including both public and private the first Cybersecurity National Action Plan, which
sector), exceeding [by] at least twofold the largest addressed legacy IT, fragmented administrative pro-
cybersecurity-spending countries.”216 cesses, and cyber workforce vacancies, among other
Still, 75 percent of federal “IT decision makers challenges. OMB Circular A-130 was revised (its first
and influencers” list “budget constraints” as their major tweaking since 2000) to consolidate policy
top challenge (out of six options) for protecting updates, establish continuous security reviews, and
their agencies’ data.217 And, despite its massive direct the implementation of the Cybersecurity
spending relative to other countries, federal cyber- National Action Plan. The White House, for the first
security dollars are not always plentiful when com- time, identified who was in charge of responding to
pared with the private sector; the cybersecurity cyberthreats to the United States—the Department
budget of the Department of Homeland Security, of Justice, with the Department of Homeland
which Congress charged in 2002 with protecting Security responsible for responding to agency and
the nation’s information infrastructure, is a fourth company requests for immediate help in fending off
less than the combined budgets of just two of the hacker assaults.
nation’s leading banks.218 Those federal IT functions Over time, federal agencies have shown them-
that are contracted out to the private sector may be selves to be unusually open to executive recom-
in worse shape; more than half of these companies, mendations for improving their cybersecurity. An
46 percent of which had experienced a breach over astounding 94 percent of GAO’s recommendations
the past year, had simultaneously cut spending on for information security improvements were imple-
cybersecurity.219 mented by the agencies over twenty-six years (from
1983 through 2008). This is the highest agency
The President and Cybersecurity The beginning acceptance rate for any type of GAO recommen-
of the executive branch’s interest in cybersecurity dation, surpassing the overall average rate by an
is marked by OMB Circular A-130, issued in 1985, impressive thirteen points.221 More recently (from
which established an IT security certification process 2009 through 2015), GAO made “about 2,000
managed by the National Institute of Standards and recommendations” to federal agencies to correct
Technology. or improve their cybersecurity, of which “about 58
In 2003, the U.S. Computer Emergency Readiness percent” were implemented.222
Team, a public-private partnership designed to co- Most neutral observers give the Obama admin-
ordinate responses to cyberattacks, was launched, istration high marks for trying to rectify the over-
and, in 2009, the Department of Homeland whelming problems of federal cybersecurity (“the
Security opened its National Cybersecurity and administration took the cyber threat seriously from
Communications Integration Center, charged with day one. . .. [and] made an unprecedented all-fronts
coordinating the private and public sectors’ coun- effort to secure cyberspace”), but most observers
terattacks. also conclude that, despite some significant suc-
In 2015, the president created the Cyber cesses, federal cybersecurity is about where it started
Threat Intelligence Integration Center to co- at the beginning of the new administration, in 2009.
ordinate terrorism-related information. The White This running-in-place occurred because reforms
House released a Cybersecurity Strategy and could not keep up with the pace of the constantly
Implementation Plan, the first update of strategy shifting threat.223
since the pre-smart-phones year of 2000, when a
revision of OMB Circular A-130 did so. During the Congress and Cybersecurity Congress has passed
last seven months of 2015, “critical vulnerabilities” more than fifty laws that have provisions relating
in federal agencies were slashed from 363 to three.220 to information security. Some of the early form-
In 2016, the first government-wide chief infor- ative laws include the Computer Security Act of
mation security officer was hired. 2016 also saw 1987, which authorized the National Institute of
the unveiling of the first Federal Cybersecurity Standards and Technology to develop computer
The Public’s Information Resource 173

security standards; the Paperwork Reduction Act A modest 27 percent of these CISOs are confident
of 1995, which placed responsibility for developing in their states’ ability to protect themselves against
cybersecurity policies with OMB; the Clinger-Cohen external attack, in contrast to a serene, and worri-
Act of 1996, which directed agencies to enforce some, 66 percent of other “state officials” who also
those policies; and the Federal Information Security have such confidence.234
Management Act (FISMA) of 2002, which created a Fifty-one percent of state CISOs have staffs
comprehensive cybersecurity framework.224 ranging from six to fifteen,235 a big jump from just
Although FISMA was “game-changing” four years earlier, when 49 percent had staffs of one
legislation that improved data security,225 the act also to five236 (now just 24 percent do237); 83 percent of
resulted in “unsustainable” snarls of red tape because state CIOs report that from 1 to 2 percent of their
it failed to distinguish between high- and low-level states’ IT workforce are “dedicated cybersecurity
risk,226 and wasted as much as $500 million a year professionals.”238 These are disturbingly low numbers
because of its “outdated manual reporting require- when compared with the more than a hundred pro-
ment”227—each year, agencies had to check off fessionals employed by financial services organiza-
boxes in paper binders to verify their security con- tions of “similar size to that of an average state,”239
trols, a creaky procedure that was ineffective against and their budgets are even tinier, amounting to just 1
hackers. (The 2016 update of OMB Circular A-130 to 2 percent of the states’ overall IT budgets.240 Fully
replaced this box-checking with continuous reviews.) four-fifths of CISOs consider their underfunding to
To address some of these and a few other issues, be the number one barrier facing their programs; no
Congress passed, in 2014, the Federal Information other concern comes remotely close.241
Security Modernization Act, a revision of FISMA, State CISOs have high turnover rates, largely
which required CISOs in the agencies and author- because of significantly larger salaries in the private
ized the secretary of homeland security to issue sector. “Half the states have new CISOs compared to
“binding operational directives” to force agencies two years ago. . .. And half the ones in the jobs two
to strengthen their cybersecurity. In 2015, Congress years ago were new compared to two years before
enacted the Cybersecurity Information Sharing Act, that.”242 Unfortunately, “people with IT security
which permits the sharing of Internet information skills are the most difficult to recruit and retain for
between Washington and the private sector. the states.”243 Small wonder that state CIOs have
Unfortunately, there remains “no overarching placed “security” as the top skill set that they want
framework of legislation in place” that addresses when recruiting and retaining IT employees.244
federal cybersecurity.228

Additional Actions Needed for Attacking


Cybersecurity in the States Hacking
Seventy percent of state governments report at least Cybersecurity in all sectors could be radically
one data breach per year,229 suggesting a far lower improved without, it would seem, a hugely strenu-
threat level than that of the federal government. Still, ous effort. Simply addressing the top thirty known
the threat is serious. According to one expert, “You cybersecurity vulnerabilities could help prevent as
can get pretty much everything on someone out of much as 85 percent of all cyberattacks.245
state computers. . .. It makes them a very attractive Improving at least some cybersecurity weak-
target to cybercriminals,”230 which may explain why nesses in the public sector seems comparably
86 percent of state officials say that managing cyber- straightforward, such as accelerating the hiring of
security is among their most stressful responsibili- cybersecurity specialists, reforming their personnel
ties, compared with 73 percent of federal officials.231 systems, and budgeting cybersecurity more care-
Although “most states do not have established fully and generously. Resolving cybersecurity chal-
cybersecurity legislation in place,”232 98 percent of lenges with big data analytics remains potent but
the states (including the District of Columbia) have underused. Surveys of federal, state, and local cyber-
chief information security officers, a heartening 90 security professionals found that 86 percent believed
percent of whom report directly to the state CIO.233 that analytics would improve cybersecurity, although
174 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

just 28 percent were fully leveraging analytics to do information as possible available electronically to
so, and only a third had made analytics a priority.246 other agencies and the public, generally is cited as
“Experts and leading organizations” identify the basis of federal e-gov.
“four key attributes of successful” information secu- Perhaps, however, federal e-gov’s greatest
rity measures. They should be: “[1] quantifiable, [2] impact is economic. Paper and print are pricey.
meaningful (i.e., have targets for tracking progress, Washington spends $1.4 billion for printing and
be clearly defined, and be linked to organizational reproduction each year.251 Just clicking the “Print”
priorities), [3] repeatable and consistent, and [4] icon on a federal computer costs agencies up to $2
actionable.” billion a year, a cost that seems egregious when we
To determine whether information security realize that federal employees discard 35 percent of
measures are indeed successful, they should be eval- what they print on that same day.252
uated according to three criteria that are common Electronic government offers the surest way to
to all sectors. They are: the measure’s compliance significantly lower these costs. For example, it costs
with standards, policies, and laws; the effectiveness the feds a dollar to issue a paper check, but just a
of information security controls; and the overall dime to do so electronically,253 and only 38 percent
impact of the information security program. In of the 19 million invoices sent by all civilian agencies
securing information, federal agencies tend to rely annually are transmitted electronically; the remain-
on compliance measures at the expense of more ing 12 million are paper checks.254 “E-rulemaking”
effective impact measures,247 a condition that likely by regulatory agencies could save $94 million over
is true among the grass-roots governments as well. three years.255 It costs the IRS just nineteen cents to
process an e-filed return, compared with a whopping
$3.29 to process a paper one;256 in 2016, the IRS
E-GOV: LEAN, SEEN, AND CLEAN announced that it would eliminate 8 percent of its
personnel (or 7,000 jobs) as a result of its replacing
GOVERNMENT paper tax returns with electronic ones.
The often gloomy caverns of public knowledge man- The potential savings of digital government
agement do have at least one bright and shining light: dawned on Congress in 1996, when it passed the
E-gov. Electronic government, e-government, e-gov, Debt Collection Improvement Act, which directed
dot-gov, or digital government is the introduction of agencies to make all payments, except tax refund
governmental websites that furnish information to payments, via electronic fund transfers.
users and portals that facilitate services for users. The effects have been salutary. More than four-
All governments in the United States offer more fifths of all federal benefits programs use at least
than 5,300 e-gov websites; the federal government one electronic payment method,257 and over three-
provides from 1,300 to over 2,000 sites (counts vary, quarters of all citizens who receive these payments
depending on the counter), plus “24,000 sub-sites acquire them electronically.258 A satisfying 97 percent
and micro-sites.”248 All federal agencies and almost of all income tax returns are filed electronically.259
all state and local agencies have websites, and 53 Washington receives reasonably high marks
percent of all adult Internet users have visited at from its e-gov users. According to quarterly surveys,
least one.249 Sixty-five percent of Americans have federal agencies receive scores in the mid-seventies
used the Internet to find data or information pertain- (out of 100); scores of eighty or above reflect a
ing to government. Of this 65 percent, 37 percent “threshold of excellence (highly satisfied visitors),”
search for federal information, 34 percent seek state whereas scores of seventy or lower reveal “much
government data, and 32 percent look for local gov- room for improvement.” The comparable score for
ernment information.250 the federal government “overall” is sixty-four.260

Federal.gov State.gov
The Government Paperwork Elimination Act of The states have lagged somewhat in maximizing
1998, which directs agencies to make as much their use of IT. Consider the state office in California
The Public’s Information Resource 175

that verifies eligibility for Medicaid. In the absence limited expertise as well.269 It follows, perhaps, that
of an automated phone answering system, staff- a fourth of local governments contract out the oper-
ers answer calls only after the phone has rung an ation of their websites to the private sector.270
average of twenty-three times.261
Still, progress has been made. All the states
provide forms and information electronically for pur- In Love with E-Gov
poses of professional licensing, and half permit at least Everybody loves e-gov.
partial online registration for licensing. As a result of
mandates in the federal Personal Responsibility and Governments Love E-Gov More than eight out of
Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996, all ten senior employees in the federal, state, and local
states now use bankcards to deliver some federal and governments believe that digital government will
state welfare benefits.262 Thirty-six states have  an have a positive impact on government, and “not a
electronic purchasing system, and most of the rest single public official” states that e-gov affects gov-
are moving toward “e-procurement.”263 Purchasing ernment operations negatively.271 One example: in
transaction costs have been slashed by more than 90 2015, Denver provided an app, called “pocketgov,”
percent as states replace paper with computers.264 to citizens seeking city services, ranging from report-
The states increasingly have been working with ing potholes to obtaining voter registration infor-
one another to share and coordinate data. As a result mation; the city saves $250,000 a year because the
of Hurricane Katrina, five Gulf states formed, in resultant reduced call volume requires fewer staff.272
2014, the National Accuracy Clearinghouse, which
uses cutting edge IT to locate duplicate benefit appli- The Governed Love E-Gov Although there is
cations almost in real time, flagging duplicates and some evidence that most citizens rate governmental
notifying the relevant states of them. “Alabama portals lower than their commercial counterparts,273
and Mississippi saw a 74 percent and 71 percent 90 percent of Americans believe that interacting elec-
decrease, respectively, in the average number of dual tronically with government saves time and energy;274
participants per month.”265 75 percent of voters are more likely to vote for can-
States that are the most likely to adopt didates who champion digital tools over those who
“e-government innovation” have larger economies; do not (liberals and conservatives agree that more
better educated and more homogeneous popula- funding is needed for e-gov);275 and 62 percent of
tions; and Republican-controlled legislatures that are citizens feel more positive about government because
highly professional, with committees dedicated to of digital interactions.276 Two-thirds of e-gov users
e-gov in each chamber. It is the variables that do not think that e-gov has made it more convenient for
associate with the states’ use of e-gov, however, that them to conduct transactions with the government,
are surprising. These factors include: the presence of and three-fourths credit it for making it easier to
an information technology department in the execu- stay informed about public services.277
tive branch; governments that have higher per capita These numbers are all the more gratifying when
revenues; higher urbanization; greater racial diver- we realize that prospective users may have had to
sity; higher voter turnout; more competitive parties; overcome the off-putting titles of some public portals,
and “greater policy liberalism” among citizens.266 such as the federal titles (now thankfully abandoned),
WhiteNoseSyndrome.gov, AmeriCorpse.gov, and
Dix.gov.278 We are not making these up.
Local.gov
By 2000, 96 percent of cities and counties had web- A Surfeit of Satisfying Surprises Digital govern-
sites, and progress was evident in providing more ment has brought benefits that have startled even its
sophisticated e-services.267 Local progress is all the most ardent advocates. Here are some.
more impressive because, to expand web-based ser-
vices, local governments must surmount privacy E-Gov Promotes Civic Engagement People who
concerns, confidentiality laws,268 and financial obsta- have greater access to the Internet, and who use it
cles, and smaller governments often must overcome more frequently (including access to, and use of,
176 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

government portals), “are more likely to be civi- When corrupt officials are denied face-to-face
cally engaged,” ranging from voting to volunteering, contact with citizens and their transactions with
“than non-users.”279 them are automatically recorded—conditions that
are greatly advanced by e-gov—the possibility of
E-Gov Encourages Trust in Government More bribery dramatically diminishes. Analyses of global
than six out of ten of Americans believe that e-gov data not only support this relationship, but also
can make governments more accountable.280 The show that e-gov and IT have “a consistently positive
more that citizens use governmental websites, the impact on reducing corruption” that matches those
more satisfied they are with e-gov; “e-government of “traditional anti-corruption factors,” such as pro-
satisfaction,” in turn, is positively associated with fessional and honest public administration and law
trust in government.”281 Of the visitors to federal enforcement.289
websites who were highly satisfied with their expe-
rience, a remarkable 88 percent “put their trust E-Gov and Citizen E-Fraud Regrettably, e-gov also
behind the agency.”282 correlates with high rates of fraud perpetrated on
governments by crooked citizens.
E-Gov Improves Governing Digital government E-gov facilitates this fraud because govern-
associates with a bevy of markers that indicate ments send electronic payments automatically to
better governance. Fifty-two percent of federal vast numbers of claimants. Federal agencies send
executives think it is important for interagency col- out more than 191 million checks and payments to
laboration,283 and large majorities of local admin- claimants every month.290 Most claims are adjudi-
istrators believe that e-gov improves public service cated by computers using rule-based systems, minus
to, and communication with, citizens.284 E-gov also any human intervention. Fraudsters need only to
induces superior financial accountability and greater learn the rules, then submit huge numbers of claims
transparency285 and “leads to radical and struc- electronically with relative impunity. “The IRS issues
tural . . . political and administrative reforms” that 1,100 refunds to the same address in Lithuania, and
strengthen governments’ overall accountability.286 there’s no software to catch this?”291
In 2014, the Digital Accountability and
Transparency Act (or DATA Act) was enacted, Improper Payments: The Essence of Electronic
which established government-wide data standards, Fraud The core of electronically defrauding gov-
reduced the reporting requirements for the recipi- ernments is improper payments, which are govern-
ents of federal awards, and set uniform coding for ment checks with incorrectly calculated sums, or
all federal spending. Such uniformity is desperately which are sent inadvertently to the wrong recipients,
needed, as, in just one year, well over half (or $619 such as dead people. Most federally-issued improper
billion) of federal “assistance awards (e.g., grants payments are improperly high, but many are
and loans)” were improperly reported.287 The DATA improperly low. Improper payments peaked in Fiscal
Act is modeled on the massive stimulus bill of 2009 Year 2010 at 5.5 percent of all federal outlays,292
(the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act), in and have been falling, if somewhat erratically, since.
which less than 1 percent of spending was lost to Roughly a third of improper overpayments are “gen-
fraud, a percentage that is “significantly lower than erally recoverable.”293
most government spending.”288 Over eleven years, all federal improper pay-
ments, found in 124 programs in twenty-two agen-
cies, totaled a startling $1 trillion.294 Improper
E-Gov and E-Graft: A Double-Edged Sword federal payments cost each federal taxpayer more
Frustratingly, e-gov both reduces official graft and than $1,100 annually.295
raises public fraud. Just ten programs account for 93 percent of all
improper payments.296 Three programs are especially
E-Gov and Official Corruption E-gov correlates, susceptible to fraud—Medicare, Medicaid, and the
clearly, strongly, and positively, with the curtailment Earned Income Tax Credit Program—and they pay
of corruption. out more than 75 percent of all improper payments.297
The Public’s Information Resource 177

Not all improper payments, by any means, An estimated 10.5 percent of federal Medicaid
are the illegal loot of fraudsters, but some are. spending is lost to improper payments, a growing
Washington initially responded to electronic fraud amount;303 over the previous three years, Medicaid’s
by concentrating on fraud, but largely overlooked improper payments averaged 9.8 percent.304 In
electronics. The Computer Matching Act of 1974 just one year, thirty-five state laws directed toward
was an early, if limited, start in the right direction; Medicaid abuse were enacted; at least ten states have
it  authorized the matching of data from two or appointed inspectors general just for Medicaid.305
more information systems in an effort to minimize An estimated 12.1 percent of Medicare spend-
fraud. Seven major agencies have signed eighty- ing is lost to improper payments,306 a percentage
two agreements to match data.298 Some years that includes the largest known healthcare fraud
ago,  federal agencies estimated that they saved in U.S. history (uncovered in 2016), involving 301
“at least” $900 million each year through their perpetrators and 900 million fraudulently-obtained
data-matching agreements,299 a sum that surely has Medicare dollars. Medicare fraud has grown so
increased since. profitable and penetrable that narcotics dealers and
Eventually, Washington caught on that e-gov organized crime are tapping into it.
was the crucial tool of twenty-first-century fraud- None of this should be too shocking when we
sters, but it was only in 2002 that Congress, for realize that Medicaid and Medicare process almost
the first time, passed legislation merely to ferret out five million claims a day, and must respond within
just how much money was being sent in improper thirty days. Due to limited funds, only about 3
payments. Since then, Congress has enacted at least percent of claims can be reviewed.307
seven additional laws to reduce electronic fraud Nevertheless, progress in the battle to curtail
and improper payments by establishing procedures healthcare fraud is underway and is paying off.
for collecting overpayments, improving oversight, In 2013, Washington announced that the growth
directing agencies to share data on the deaths of rate in healthcare spending was the lowest ever in
federal beneficiaries, and applying the techniques of forty-seven years, and that the rate of healthcare
risk management and big data analytics. price inflation was the lowest in fifty years, a pair
of satisfying and continuing trends that were attrib-
This Is Sick! The Special Case of Healthcare utable in part to the reduction of overpayments in
Fraud “Fraud, waste, abuse, error, and improper Medicare.308 In 2016, a chief data officer was hired
payments” are estimated to account for as much as a to, among other tasks, target healthcare fraud. A
fourth of all healthcare payments made in the public federal task force dedicated to curtailing healthcare
and private sectors. “True fraud has always been fraud, created in 1997 (and supplemented, in 2007,
estimated [since 1983, when tracking first began] with a Medicare Fraud Strike Force), reports that it
by many sources at 3 to 10 percent of total health has scooped up more than $29 billion over twenty
care payments,” with estimates of “waste, abuse, and years in fraudulent claims, and, for every dollar
error” accounting for 15 to almost 30 percent.300 spent on detecting healthcare fraud, Washington
Two immense healthcare programs, Medicaid saves $6.10 (a three-year average), a sum that is
(which serves the poor) and Medicare (the elderly), steadily increasing.309
are responsible for about half of all federal improper
payments,301 amounting to more than $70 billion
annually, with Medicare accounting for three-fifths THE INFORMATION RESOURCE
of the total.302 Medicaid’s questionable claims
were placed on GAO’s high-risk list in 2003, and AND THE FUTURE OF GOVERNING
Medicare’s in 1990 (when the list was originated); It is difficult to overstate the computer’s impact.
both remain on the list to this day, and their removal Galileo and Copernicus showed us that human beings
from it likely would require legislation. As with are not at the center of the universe, “attended by
improper payments in general, it is not known how sun and stars”; Darwin demonstrated that humanity
many of these healthcare payments are fraudulent, is not “the species created and specially endowed by
but some are. God with soul and reason”; with Freud, humankind
178 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

“ceased to be the species whose behavior was— Open data also save money: capturing their
potentially—governable by rational mind”; and the full potential could save governments worldwide
computer is teaching us that the human race is not up to an estimated $1 trillion annually through
uniquely capable of intelligently manipulating its lowered costs and more efficient operations.317 In
environment.310 San Francisco, for instance, riders’ access to real-
Consider how the computer is transfiguring time public transit data saves the city more than $1
governance. million per year.

Open Data and Effective Governance Blue Skies?


Open data, or open government, mean that govern- Over a half-century, computers evolved from mon-
ments render their information as accessible as is strous mainframes to pocket-sized pods and pads,
possible to the public, often by sharing data among and now are entering a new paradigm that has sig-
agencies. nificant implications for government and, indeed, all
Over two years, the number of countries provid- of society.
ing open government data sets more than doubled Cloud computing, or on-demand, utility, or grid
to 106, or 55 percent of all members of the United computing enables cheap, quick, and easy access to a
Nations.311 The federal government launched, in shared pool of computing resources that are elastic,
2009, its open data site, data.gov, which has almost require minimal management, and are location- and
200,000 data sets in seventy agencies; in 2016, data. device-independent. In other words, due to addi-
gov was expanded to the U.S. Data Federation to tional network bandwidth and storage capacity, one
implement government-wide data standardization, can inexpensively, or even at no cost, access informa-
among other goals. At least thirty-six states, and tion at any time, from anywhere, and with anything.
forty-six cities and counties have created open data Four billion people own at least one mobile device
sites since the first ones appeared in 2009.312 (3.5 billion own a toothbrush), so “The Cloud” is
A third of official “publishers and users of open here to stay.318
data” at all governmental levels want “to make as Washington committed its agencies to cloud
much of our data open as possible,” led by the feds, computing in 2009. Fewer than 8 percent of agen-
at 56 percent, followed by the states (38 percent), cies’ estimated annual spending on IT is committed
and counties and cities (32 and 31 percent, respec- to The Cloud, though this percentage is growing.319
tively); 6 percent of all respondents “don’t produce Eighteen percent of federal CIOs are “just getting
open data,” and 11 percent produce “the minimum started” in adopting The Cloud, and a slender 8
legally required,”313 which, one hopes, was not the percent are “exactly where they wanted to be” with
case of the Georgia state legislator who wrote his it.320
re-election website only in Japanese, which trans- Seventy-one percent of the states have a formal
lated into gibberish.314 “cloud first” policy (17 percent), or an informal
Eighty-six percent of all public officials state that policy, or are developing a policy, and 76 percent are
open data increases citizens’ trust of government, 66 using The Cloud to replace ancient legacy IT systems
percent say that it “sparks economic development,” (40 percent) or are developing a strategy to do so (90
and 25 percent report that their government is plan- percent of state CIOs consider at least a fifth of their
ning to invest more in open data within the next six systems to be legacies).321
months.315 An impressive 90 percent of nonprofit organiza-
Public attitudes reflect official ones. Fifty-six tions in eighty-eight countries are using cloud com-
percent of Americans agree that open data will render puting.322
public officials more accountable to the public, and Some experts on the public cloud question that
from 45 to 49 percent think that open data result in vast savings—perhaps just 5 percent—will result
better government decisions, allow citizens “to have from it, but do believe that the increased flexibil-
more impact on government affairs,” and improve ity, efficiency, and speed, among other advantages,
the quality of government services.316 render The Cloud eminently worthwhile.323 Fifty-five
The Public’s Information Resource 179

percent of federal IT professionals, for example, 3. See, for example, Marc A. Levin,“The Information-
say that cloud computing makes data management Seeking Behavior of Local Government Officials,”
easier.324 American Review of Public Administration 21
(December 1991), pp. 271–286.
4. William Hawk, Regina Powers, and Robert
From Bureaucrat to “Infocrat”? Rubinovitz, The Importance of Data Occupations
IT already is slimming those defining bases of in the U.S. Economy (Washington, DC: U.S.
bureaucracy, hierarchy and red tape. IT receives Department of Commerce, 2015), pp. 13–14.
“high scores on . . . eliminating layers” of bureau- 5. Paul C. Nutt, “Public-Private Differences and the
Assessment of Alternatives for Decision Making,”
cracy,325 and “is associated with reduction in red
Journal of Public Administration Research and
tape.”326
Theory 9 (April 1999), pp. 305–349.
The more transformative bureaucratic changes,
6. Theresa Heintz and Stuart Bretschneider, “Infor-
however, appear to be personal. “Infocrats,” who
mation Technology and Restructuring in Public
communicate with citizens electronically, or not at all Organizations: Does Adoption of Information
(because IT communicates for them), are replacing Technology Affect Organizational Structures,
bureaucrats, who communicate personally.327 This Communications, and Decision Making?” Journal
may not be such a bad thing for citizens, as research of Public Administration Research and Theory 10
indicates that when automation replaces face-to-face (October 2000), pp. 801–828.
interaction, bureaucratic bias is reduced and citizens 7. Adrienne LaFrance, “How Many Websites Are
are more likely to receive the benefits to which they There on the Internet?” Nextgov.com (September
are entitled.328 But it may not be such a good thing for 30, 2015).
bureaucrats, as the emergence of computer-depend- 8. As derived from data in Bree Nordenson,
ent “screen-level” and “system-level bureaucracies” “Overload! Journalism’s Battle for Relevance in an
shrivels administrative discretion and downgrades Age of Too Much Information,” Cjr.org (Columbia
traditional bureaucratic positions.329 Journalism Review) (November/December 2008).
And the growing public knowledge resource 9. Frank Konkel, “Assessing the Obama
may be a really bad thing for elected officeholders, Administration’s Tech Legacy,” Nextgov.com
particularly for their hold on power. Because info- (October 6, 2016).
crats are far more cognizant of the uses of this 10. The Radicati Group, Email Statistics Report,
resource than are elected officials, these “non-elected 2015–2019 (Palo Alto, CA.: Author, 2015), p. 4.
public officials have a free playing field, [and] know Figures are estimates for 2015.
11. Daniel Pitcairn and Zoe Grotophorst, “The
better than the people’s representatives” the con-
State of Internal Workplace Communication,”
ditions and opinions of these representatives’ own
Govexec.com (March 5, 2015).
constituencies.330
12. Frank Konkel, “Only 1 in 7 of the Pentagon’s
The computer is not merely mutating governing.
Emails Is Legit,” Nextgov.com (September 23,
It is transfiguring democracy. 2015).
13. Robert P. McGowan and Gary A. Lombardo,
“Decision Support Systems in State Government:
NOTES Promises and Pitfalls,” Public Administration
1. “Government Slideshow: IT Spending Priorities Review, Special Issue: Public Management
in Local Government,” CIOInsight.com (June 10, Information Systems, 46 (November 1986), pp.
2010). Subnational governments spent $50 billion 581–582.
in 2010–2011; figure has been updated, based on 14. C. E. Teasley, III, and Susan W. Harrell, “A Real
4 percent annual increases, for 2015–2016. Garbage Can Model: Measuring the Costs of
2. Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior: Politics with Computer Assisted Decision Support
A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Software (DSS) Programs,” Public Administration
Administrative Organizations, 3rd ed. (New York: Quarterly 19 (Winter 1996), pp. 479–492.
Free Press, 1976), p. 292. The first edition was 15. U.S. General Accounting Office, Geographic
published in 1945. Information Systems: Challenges to Effective
180 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Data Sharing, GAO-03-874T (Washington, DC: CIO Survey: Charting the Course (Lexington, KY,
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), p. 5. Alexandria,  VA, and Washington, DC: Authors,
16. U.S. General Accounting Office, Geographic 2014), p. 8.
Information Systems: Challenges to Effective 30. National Association of State Chief Information
Data Sharing, p. 6. Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTia, The
17. Donald F. Norris and Christopher Reddick, 2016 State CIO Survey: The Adaptable State CIO
“E-Government 2011: Trends and Innovations,” (Lexington, KY, Alexandria, VA, and Washington,
Municipal Year Book, 2012 (Washington, DC: Authors, 2016), p. 15.
DC: International City/County Management 31. Kearney & Company and Association of
Association, 2012), pp. 83–94. Government Accountants, Meeting Accountability
18. Danielle Douglas-Gabriel, “How the Attempt Challenges, pp. 13–14. Figures are for 2014.
to Fix Student Loans Got Bogged Down by the 32. Jeffrey Stinson, “States Turn to Data to Hit Back
Middlemen,” Washingtonpost.com (August 23, at Fraudsters,” Stateline (November 20, 2014).
2015). 33. National Association of State Chief Information
19. Ponemon Institute and Tripwire, Inc., The State of Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTia, The
Risk-Based Security Management (Portland, OR: 2016 State CIO Survey, p. 15.
Authors, 2013). 34. Alfred T. Ho and Bo McCall, Ten Actions to
20. Grant Thornton and AGA, Driving Collaboration Implement Big Data Initiatives: A Study of 65
and Innovation: Achieving the CFO Mission Cities (Washington, DC: IBM Center for The
in Uncertain Times (Alexandria, VA: Authors, Business of Government, 2016). The quotation is
2014), pp. 3, 7. Figures are for 2014. on p. 1.
21. MeriTalk, Go Big Security (Alexandria, VA: 35. The notion of “knowledge management” first
Author 2015). appeared in Nicholas Henry, “Knowledge
22. Michael J. Keegan, “Introduction—Analytics Management: A New Concern for Public
and Risk Management: Tools for Making Better Administration,” Public Administration Review
Decisions,” The Business of Government (Spring 34 (May/June 1974), pp. 189–196. In 2006,
2010), pp. 41–42. Oxford University Press issued a catalogue,
23. Kearney & Company and Association of titled Knowledge Management & Information
Government Accountants, Accelerating Change: Technology, touting more than fifty books and
The 2015 Inspector General Survey (Arlington, journals in the area.
VA: Authors, 2016), p. 16. 36. Ezra Klein, “Why Obamacare Makes Me
24. Kearney & Company and Association of Optimistic about US Politics,” Vox (May 22,
Government Accountants, Meeting Accountability 2015).
Challenges (Arlington, VA: Authors, 2014), p. 13. 37. Stuart Bretschneider, “Management Information
Figures are for 2014. Systems in Public and Private Organizations: An
25. Kearney & Company and Association of Empirical Test,” Public Administration Review 50
Government Accountants, Accelerating Change, (September/October 1990), pp. 536–545.
p. 16. Figures are for 2012–2015. 38. Donald F. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving
26. Quadrennial Government Technology Review, as Results: Lessons for Improving Government
cited in Joseph Marks, “Smarter Use of IT Could Management from GAO’s High-Risk List
Reduce the Deficit by $220 Billion, Group Says,” (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business
Nextgov.com (October 30, 2012). of  Government, 2016), p. 16. Figures are for
27. Grant Thornton and Professional Services 2015.
Council, 2015 Federal CIO and CISO Survey: 39. MeriTalk, The Federal Simplicity Report:
Expanding the Role of the CIO (Alexandria and Navigating Network Complexity (Washington,
Arlington, VA: Author, 2015). DC: Author, 2014).
28. Rutrell Yasin, “How Agencies Can Reap More 40. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Value from Analytics,” GCN (January 4, 2013). Information Technology: Additional OMB and
29. As derived from data in National Association Agency Actions Needed to Ensure Portfolio
of State Chief Information Officers, Grant Savings Are Realized and Effectively Tracked,
Thornton, and TechAmerica, The 2014 State GAO-15-296 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
The Public’s Information Resource 181

Publishing Office, 2015), Highlights page. Figure Systems, GAO-16-696T (Washington, DC: U.S.
is for 2013–2015. Government Publishing Office, 2016), p. 9.
41. Sean T. Lyons, Linda E. Duxbury, and Christopher Figures are for FY 2010–FY 2017.
A. Higgins, “A Comparison of the Values of 55. Government Business Council and Accenture,
Commitment of Private Sector, Public Sector, Bringing Federal IT Up to Speed: A Candid
and Parapublic Sector Employees,” Public Survey of Federal Managers (Washington, DC,
Administration Review 66 (July/August 2006), and Arlington, VA: Authors, 2014), pp. 12, 14, 15.
pp. 605–618. 56. National Academy of Public Administration,
42. Standish Group, Extreme Chaos (West Yarmouth, Federal Leaders Digital Insight Study (2016), p. 4.
MA: Author, 2001). Data are for 2014.
43. Shaun Goldfinch, “Pessimism, Failure, and 57. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving Results, pp. 16,
Information Systems Development in the Public 23. Data are for 2015 and 1990–2015, respec-
Sector,” Public Administration Review 67 tively.
(September/October 2007), pp. 917–929. The 58. International Association of Information
quotations are on p. 917. Technology Asset Managers, Understanding the
44. Standish Group, Extreme Chaos. Federal Government’s “IT Insecurity” Crisis
45. Ibid. (Canton, OH: Author, 2015). Figures are for 2014.
46. As derived from data in U.S. Government 59. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Accountability Office, Information Technology: Chief Information Officers: Reporting to OMB
Reform Initiatives Can Help Improve Efficiency Can Be Improved by Further Streamlining and
and Effectiveness, GAO-14-671T (Washington, Better Focusing on Priorities, GAO-15-106
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2014), (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
Highlights page. Figures are for 2014. Office, 2015), p. 18.
47. U.S. Department of Homeland Security, Office 60. Federal Commission on IT Cost, Opportunity,
of Inspector General, U.S. Citizenship and Immi- Strategy, and Transparency, Report (New York:
gration Services Information Technology Manage- TBM Council, 2016).
ment: Progress and Challenges (Washington, DC: 61. Geoff Colvin, “Uncle Sam’s First CIO,” Fortune
Author, 2014). (July 25, 2011), pp. 56–61. Figures are for 2011.
48. “Say Goodbye to the Era of Grand Design,” 62. MeriTalk, Consolidation Aggravation: Tip of
Federal Computer Week (September 27, 2010), the Data Management Iceberg (Alexandria, VA:
p. 3. Author, 2014).
49. U.S. Government Accountability Office, IT 63. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting
Dashboard: Agencies Need to Fully Consider Office, Contracting for Information Technology
Risks When Rating Their Major Investments, Services, GAO-03-384R Contracting for IT
GAO-16-494 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Services (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. Printing Office, 2003), p. 2, and Colleen O’Hara,
50. Jack Moore and Caitlin Fairchild, “A New Look Diane Frank, and Dan Caterinicchia. “Budget
at How Federal IT Reform is Faring in 5 Charts,” Hawks Watch IT Projects,” Federal Computer
Nextgov.com (April 23, 2015). Week (August 2001), pp. 28–30.
51. National Association of State Chief Information 64. Frank Konkel, “The Government Finally May
Officers, Grant Thornton, and TechAmerica, The Have Found All Its Data Centers,” Nextgov.com
2014 State CIO Survey, pp. 7–9. (December 7, 2016). Figures are for FY 2010–FY
52. National Academy of Public Administration, 2015.
Federal Leaders Digital Insight Study (Washington, 65. MeriTalk, Consolidation Aggravation. Figure is
DC: Author, 2016), pp. 4–5. Figures are for 2015. for 2010–2014.
53. Patrick Thibodeaux, “White House CIO’s First 66. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Data
40 Days Included ‘Worst Day’ Ever,” New York Center Consolidation: Agencies Making Progress,
Times (March 13, 2012). but Planned Savings Goals Need to Be Established,
54. As derived from data in U.S. Government GAO-16-323 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Accountability Office, Information Technology: Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. Figures
Federal Agencies Need to Address Legacy are for FY 2011–FY 2015.
182 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

67. U.S. General Accounting Office, Paperwork 83. Frank Konkel, “CIO Authority ‘Still a Major Issue’
Reduction Act, pp. 4–12. Figures are for 1995– Across Government,” Nextgov.com (December 7,
2001. 2016). Figure is for 2016.
68. Vartabedian, “Federal Computers: A System Gone 84. As derived from data in U.S. Government
Haywire?” Accountability Office, Federal Chief Information
69. Partnership for Public Service and Accenture, Officers: Opportunities Exist to Improve Role in
Serving Citizens: Strategies for Customer-Centered Information Technology Management, GAO-11-
Government in the Digital Age (Washington, DC, 634 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
and Arlington, VA: Authors, 2014). Figures are Office, 2011), p. 24. Figures are for 2004–2011.
for 2014. 85. Ibid., p. 21. Figures are for 2004–2011.
70. National Academy of Public Administration, 86. Linda Cureton, “3 Reasons We Don’t Need
Federal Leaders Digital Insight Study (Washington, Federal CIOs,” Information Week Government
DC: Author, 2015), p. 5. Figure is for 2012–2015. (July 22, 2014).
71. Sean Applegate, “How to Unleash the Full 87. CIO Magazine staff, “2014 State of the CIO,”
Potential of Government Digital Services,” Cio.com (January 2, 2014).
Nextgov.com (March 21, 2016). 88. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
72. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Digital Chief Information Officers: Responsibilities,
Service Programs: Assessing Results and Reporting Relationships, Tenure, and Challenges,
Coordinating with Chief Information Officers GAO-04-823 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Can Improve Delivery of Federal Projects, GAO- Printing Office, 2004), p. 20. Figures are for 2004.
16-733T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 89. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen
Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. Hamilton, Cyber In-Security II, p. 25. Figures are
73. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Infor- for 2015.
mation Technology: Improved Implementation 90. Grant Thornton and Professional Services Council,
of Reform Law Is Critical to Better Manage 2015 Federal CIO and CISO Survey, p. 4.
Acquisitions and Operations GAO-17-263T 91. MeriTalk, Calling the Plays: The Evolving Role of
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing the CDO and Federal Big Data (Alexandria, VA:
Office, 2015), p. 7. Author, 2016).
74. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, 92. U.S. Office of the Inspector General, Social Security
E-Government Act Implementation (Washington, Administration, Audit Report: Numberholders
DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015). Age 112 or Older Who Did Not Have a Death
75. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen Entry on the Numident (Washington, DC: U.S.
Hamilton, Cyber In-Security II: Closing the Government Publishing Office, 2015).
Federal Talent Gap (Washington, DC and 93. Jack Moore, “Why Are Federal IT Workers So
McLean, VA: Authors, 2015), p. 4. Figures are Miserable?” Nextgov.com (October 8, 2015).
official and are for 2014. Figure is for 2015.
76. National Academy of Public Administration, 94. Ibid. Figure is for 2015.
Federal Leaders Digital Insight Study (2016), p. 4. 95. Nancy Scola, “White House Launches ‘U.S.
Data are for 2014. Digital Service,’ with HealthCare.gov Fixer at the
77. Allan Holmes, “Federal IT Flunks Out,” CIO Helm,” Washington Post (August 11, 2014).
(May 15, 2006). 96. Moore, “Why Are Federal IT Workers So
78. Ibid. Miserable?” Figure is for 2015.
79. Allan Holmes, “5 Reasons Why Clinger-Cohen 97. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Failed,” Nextgov.com (August 11, 2010). Information Technology: Training Can Be
80. Office of Inspector General, U.S. Department of Enhanced by Greater Use of Leading Practices,
Health and Human Services, HealthCare.gov: GAO-04-791 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
CMS Management of the Federal Marketplace, A Printing Office, 2004), Highlights page.
Case Study (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). 98. TechAmerica and Grant Thornton, CIO/CISO
81. As derived from data in Eli Gorski, “What CIOs Insights: Achieving Results and Confronting
Really Study,” Fcw.com (September 8, 2015). Obstacles (Arlington and Alexandria, VA:
82. Holmes, “Federal IT Flunks Out.” Authors, 2014). Figures are for 2014.
The Public’s Information Resource 183

99. Moore, “Why Are Federal IT Workers So 113. Brittany Ballenstedt, “Federal Telework Surge
Miserable?” Figure is for 2015. Could Save $14 Billion Annually,” Nextgov.com
100. As derived from data in Partnership for Public (January 24, 2014).
Service and Booz Allen Hamilton, Cyber 114. U.S. General Services Administration, Office of
In-Security II, p. 5. Data are for 2014. Inspector General, GSA’s Program for Managing
101. Grant Thornton and Professional Services Council, Virtual Employee and Teleworkers Needs
2015 Federal CIO and CISO Survey, p. 2. Improvement (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
102. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen Publishing Office, 2015).
Hamilton, Cyber In-Security II, p. 25. Data are 115. Eric Pfeiffer, “Survey: Many State and Local
for 2014. Governments Stuck in ‘Reactive Mode” for
103. Gregory B. Lewis and Zhenhua Hu, “Information IT Security Threats,” Government Executive
Technology Workers in the Federal Service: More (November 29, 2014).
Than a Quiet Crisis?” Review of Public Personnel 116. Dell Software, Maintain Your IT Budget with
Administration 25 (September 2005), pp. 207– Consistent Compliance Practices (Chantilly, VA:
224. The quotations are on pp. 207, 222. Data Market Connections, 2014), pp. 4, 3, 6.
are for 1976–2003. 117. National Association of State Chief Information
104. Iron Mountain, Federal Records Management: Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTia, The
Managing the Storm (Washington, DC: Author, 2016 State CIO Survey, p. 5. Figures are for
2013). 2010–2016.
105. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 118. Jenni Bergal, “Courts Plunge Into the Digital
Information Management: The Challenges of Age,” Stateline (December 8, 2014). Figures are
Managing Electronic Records, GAO-10-838T for 2013.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 119. “S.C. Child Support System Almost Operational,”
Office, 2010), p. 11. Savannah Morning News (March 27, 2010).
106. Chief Archivist Robert Connor, quoted in Charles S. 120. U.S. General Accounting Office, Child Welfare:
Clark, “National Archives Chief Outlines 80-Year States Face Challenges in Developing Information
Clean-Up Job,” Govexec.com (February 23, Systems and Reporting Reliable Child Welfare Data,
2015). GAO-04-267T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
107. Clark, “National Archives Chief Outlines 80-Year Printing Office, 2003). Figure is for 2003.
Clean Up Job.” 121. Maggie Clark, “States Still Resisting National Sex
108. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Offender Law,” Stateline (October 1, 2012).
Information Management: The Challenges of 122. Ellen Perlman, “Topside Turnover,” Governing
Managing Electronic Records, p. 5. (April 2007), p. 40. Figure is for 2007.
109. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 123. Kyle Roerink, “With $100 Million in IT Contracts,
Information Management: Additional Actions Are Nevada Joins States Leaning on Private Sector,”
Needed to Meet Requirements of the Managing Las Vegas Sun (November 18, 2014). Figures are
Federal Records Directive, GAO-15-339 for 2012.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing 124. National Association of State Chief Information
Office, 2015). Officers, State IT Workforce: Under Pressure
110. U.S. National Archives and Records (Lexington, KY: Author, 2011), p. 13. Figures are
Administration, Records Management Self- for 2011.
Assessment 2014 (Washington, DC: U.S. 125. Soonhee Kim, “IT Employee Job Satisfaction
Government Printing Office, 2015), p. i. Figures in the Public Sector,” International Journal
are for 2010–2014. of Public  Administration 32 (October 2009),
111. Frank Konkel, “More Feds Telework Than Ever pp. 1070–1097.
Before Despite Managers’ Resistance,” Nextgov. 126. As derived from data in Jack Gallt, Chris Dixon,
com (March 20, 2017). Figures are for 2012– and Mary Gay Whitmer, “Trends in State
2015. Information and Technology Management,”
112. Brittany Ballenstedt, “Telework Participation Book of the States (Lexington, KY: Council of
Skyrockets, Meets Less Management Resistance,” State Governments, 2004), pp. 439–442. The data
Nextgov.com (April 30, 2013). are on p. 440. Figure is for 2003.
184 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

127. Ruth McCambridge, “Does Your Information Experiences from the City of Phoenix,” Review of
Technology Department Report to the CEO? Public Personnel Administration 25 (Fall 2005),
If Not, Why Not?” Nonprofitquarterly.org pp. 225–242. The quotations are on p. 225.
(November 8, 2013). Figure is for 2013. 140. Steve Towns, “Which States and Cities Have Chief
128. Jeffrey Stinson, “Elections Shake Up Top State IT Data Officers,” Government Technology (June 13,
Jobs,” Stateline (November 6, 2014). 2014).
129. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “The 141. Peter Jamison, “L.A. Is Losing $20 million a Year
Causes, Costs and Consequences of Bad Govern- because of Fumbled Tax Data, Audit Finds,” L.A.
ment Data,” Governing.com (June 24, 2015). Now (August 19, 2015).
Figure is for 2014. 142. Stephen J. Bajjaly, “Managing Emerging Infor-
130. Forester Research, Inc., as cited in “e-Gov mation Systems in the Public Sector,” Public
Momentum,” Governing (August 2001), p. 46. Productivity and Management Review 23
These figures are projections. (September 1999), pp. 40–47. The quotation is on
131. Christopher Weare, Juliet A. Musso, and p. 46.
Matthew L. Hale, “Electronic Democracy and the 143. We have relied largely on: Sharon S. Dawes,
Diffusion of Municipal Web Pages in California,” Anthony M. Cresswell, and Theresa A. Pardo,
Administration & Society 31 (March 1999), “From ‘Need to Know’ to ‘Need to Share’: Tangled
pp. 3–27. Problems of Information Boundaries, and the
132. Alana Northrop, Kenneth L. Kraemer, Debora Building of Public Sector Knowledge Networks,”
Dunkle, et al., “Payoffs from Computerization: Public Administration Review 69 (May/June
Lessons Over Time,” Public Administration Review 2009), pp. 392–402; Bajjaly, “Managing Emerging
50 (September/October 1990),” pp. 505–514. Information Systems in the Public Sector”; and U.S.
133. Glen Hahn Cope, “Budgeting for Performance in General Accounting Office, Improving Mission
Local Government,” Municipal Year Book, 1995 Performance Through Strategic Information
(Washington, DC: International City/County Management and Technology.
Management Association, 1995), pp. 42–52. The 144. Goldfinch, “Pessimism, Computer Failure, and
quotation is on p. 51. Information Systems Development in the Public
134. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity Sector,” p. 917.
and Change in the Role of City Managers,” 145. Epic.org, Public Opinion on Privacy (Washington,
Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington, DC: Author, 2015).
DC: International City/County Management 146. Harris polls, as cited in Robert S. Boyd, “An
Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. Datum (p. 14) is Eagle’s Eye,” Savannah Morning News (July 22,
for 2010. 1990).
135. Harry P. Hatry and Carl F. Valente, “Alternative 147. David Card, Raj Chetty, Martin Feldstein, and
Delivery Approaches Involving Increased Use of Emanuel Saez, Expanding Access to Administrative
the Private Sector,” Municipal Year Book, 1983 Data for Research in the United States (Washington,
(Washington, DC: International City Management DC: National Science Foundation, 2011).
Association, 1983), pp. 199–217. Figure is on 148. U.S. Government Accountability Office,  Iden-
p. 200. tity Theft: Governments Have Acted to  Protect
136. George C. Homsy and Mildred Warner, Personally Identifiable Information, but Vulner-
“Intermunicipal Cooperation: The Growing abilities Remain, GAO-09-759T (Washington,
Reform,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2009),
(Washington, DC: International City/County Highlights page.
Management Association, 2014), pp. 53–65. 149. Symantic, Symantic 2016 Internet Security Threat
Figure (p. 57) is for 2012. Report (New York: Author, 2016).
137. Norris and Reddick, “E-Government 2011,” 150. John Pulley, “Sorting the Personal from the
pp. 86, 90. Public,” Fcw.com (October 29, 2007). Figure is
138. Ibid., p. 89. for 2007, and is provided by Identity Truth.
139. G. Zhiyong Lan, Lera Riley, and N. Joseph Cayer, 151. Identity Theft Resource Center and IDT911, Data
“How Can Local Government Become an Employer Breach Reports (San Diego, CA: Author, 2016).
of Choice for Technical Professionals? Lessons and Figures are for 2005–2015.
The Public’s Information Resource 185

152. As derived from data in U.S. Government Public Records in the Digital Age,” Book of the
Accountability Office, Information Security: States, 2008 (Lexington, KY: Council of State
Federal Agencies Need to Enhance Responses to Governments, 2008), pp. 218–222. The quota-
Data Breaches, GAO-14-487T (Washington, DC: tions are on p. 218. Figure is for 2008.
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2014), p. 3. 165. National Association of State Chief Information
Figure is for 2009–2013. Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTia, The
153. Elaine S. Povitch, “It’s Tax Season, and States Are 2016 State CIO Survey, p. 23.
Battling Bogus Requests for Refunds,” Pewtrusts. 166. Deloitte and National Association of State
org (February 16, 2016). Information Officers, State Governments at Risk
154. U.S. Government Accountability Office, (2010), pp. 15–16. Figures are for 2010.
Information Security: IRS Needs to Further 167. William Jackson, “Data Breaches at State, Local
Improve Controls over Taxpayer Data and Agencies Expose Data about Millions,” Govern-
Continue to Combat Identity Theft Refund ment Computer News (October 20, 2008), p. 18.
Fraud, GAO-16-589T (Washington, DC: U.S. 168. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Government Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights Identity Theft: Governments Have Acted to
page, p. 4. Protect Personally Identifiable Information, but
155. Liz Farmer, “States Go Old School to Fight Tax Vulnerabilities Remain, pp. 7–8. Figure is for
Fraud,” Governing.com (March 22, 2017). Figure 2009.
is for 2017. 169. As derived from data in “States with Notice of
156. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Infor- Security Breach Laws,” Defendyourdollars.org
mation Security: Federal Agencies Need to (February 2010). Figure is for 2009.
Enhance Responses to Data Breaches. 170. Somini Sengupta, “No U.S. Action, So States Move
157. Harry P. Madden, Americans’ Attitudes about on Privacy Law,” New York Times (October 30,
Privacy, Security and Surveillance (Washington, 2013).
DC: Pew Research Center, 2015), p. 4. Data are 171. Jeffrey Stinson, “Password Protected: States Pass
for 2015. Anti-Snooping Laws,” Stateline (July 8, 2014).
158. U.S. General Accounting Office, Information Figure is for 2012–2014.
Management: Selected Agencies’ Handling of 172. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Personal Information, p. 1. Information Security: Actions Needed to Address
159. U.S. General Accounting Office, Privacy Act: Challenges, GAO-16-885T (Washington, DC:
OMB Leadership Needed to Improve Agency U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016), p. 2.
Compliance, Highlights page. Figure is for 2016.
160. U.S. Government Accountability Office,  Identity 173. Cited in Peter J. Beshar, “Ben Franklin’s Cyber
Theft: Governments Have Acted to Protect  Per- Solution,” The Hill (September 8, 2014).
sonally Identifiable Information, but Vulner- 174. Michael Specter, “The Doomsday Click,” The
abilities Remain, pp. 17–18. OMB figure is for New Yorker (May 28, 2001), pp. 101–107. The
2005–2009. quotations are on pp. 101–102.
161. Kristin Davis, “Your Life Is Just a Stroke Away,” 175. Tom Temin, “Let’s Talk about Government
Baltimore Sun (July 21, 1996). Corruption,” Federalnewsradio.com (March 31,
162. Zeichner Risk Analytics study, as cited in Jonathan 2016).
Krim, “States Seen as Lax on Database Security,” 176. Computer Emergency Response Team, Carnegie
Washington Post (March 26, 2003). Data are for Mellon University, Cert/CC Statistics 1988–2005
2003. (Philadelphia: Author, 2005), http://www.cert.org.
163. Deloitte and National Association of State 177. Michael McConnell, director, U.S. Office of
Information Officers, State Governments at National Intelligence, as cited in Lawrence Wright,
Risk: A Call to Secure Citizen Data and Inspire “The Spymaster,” The New Yorker (January 21,
Public Trust (Washington, DC, and Lexington, 2008), pp. 51–52.
KY:  Authors, 2010), pp. 16–17. Figures are 178. As derived from data in Privacy Rights
for 2010. Clearinghouse, Chronology of Data Breaches
164. Kay Stimson, “Secretaries of State: Focused (San Diego, CA: Author, 2014). Figures are for
on Redacting Social Security Numbers from 2013, and government figures include the military.
186 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

179. Lee Rainie, Janna Anderson, and Jennifer 194. Lauren Cassani Davis, “How Do Americans
Connolly, “Cyber Attacks Likely to Increase,” Pew Weigh Privacy Versus National Security?”
Research Internet Project (October 29, 2014). Nextgov.com (February 3, 2016). Figures are for
Figures are for 2014–2025. 2013–2016.
180. Jenni Bergal, “Criminals Increasingly Hold 195. Verizon, Inc., 2016 Data Breach Investigations
Government Computers for Ransom,” Stateline Report.
(October 13, 2016). Figure is for 2005–2015. 196. John McDuling, “America Is the Prime Target
181. SonicWall, 2017 Annual Threat Report (Santa of International Cyberattacks,” Nextgov.com
Clara, CA: Author, 2017). (February 23, 2014). Datum is for 2013.
182. Sentinel IPS, as cited in GCN Staff, “Malware, 197. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Ransomware Are Twice as Likely to Hit State, Information Security: Agencies Need to Improve
Local Network,” Gcn.com (December 1, 2015). Controls over Selected High-Impact Systems,
Data are for 2015. GAO-16-501 (Washington, DC: U.S Government
183. Isaca.org, ISACA January 2016 Cybersecurity Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page.
Snapshot US Results (Rolling Meadows, IL: 198. Aliya Sternstein, “Congressional Probe Says OPM
Author, 2016). Hackers Arrived in 2012 and We Will Never Know
184. Garance Burke and Jonathan Fahey, “AP What They Took.” Nextgov.com (September 7,
Investigation: US Power Grid Vulnerable to 2016).
Foreign Hacks,” Yahoo.com (December 21, 2015). 199. Jack Moore and Caitlin Fairchild, “Federal Cyber-
185. Verizon, 2014 Data Breach Investigations Report: security by the Numbers: The Biggest Spenders and
Public Sector (New York: Author, 2014). the Biggest Threats,” Nextgov.com (April 5, 2016).
186. As derived from data in Privacy Rights 200. Ariel Rabkin, “How to Make Data Security a
Clearinghouse, Chronology of Data Breaches. Priority for the Government,” Techpolicydaily.
Data are for 2013, and government figure includes com (August 26, 2015).
the military. 201. Quoted in Steven Norton and Clint Boulton,
187. Verizon, 2014 Data Breach Investigations Report: “Years of Tech Mismanagement Led to OPM
Public Sector. Breach, Resignation of Chief,” Wsj.com (July 10,
188. Stephen Weigend, “Agencies Identify Biggest 2015).
Threats to Cybersecurity,” Federal Computer 202. Patrick E. McFarland, quoted in Eric Yoder,
Week (January 25, 2010), p. 33. Figures are for “OPM Officials Hindering Scrutiny of Hacked
2009. Computer Systems, Watchdog Says,” Washington
189. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Post (August 6, 2015).
Information Security: Actions Needed to Address 203. Billy Mitchell, “How Beth Cobert Resurrected
Challenges, p. 3. Figures are for 2006–2015 and OPM IT After Historic Cyber Breaches,”
2015, respectively. Fedscoop.com (January 18, 2017).
190. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Annual 204. FedScoop staff, “Cyber Alert Overload Creates
Report to Congress: Federal Information New Challenges for Feds,” Fedscoop.com (May
Security Management Act (Washington, DC: U.S. 18, 2016).
Government Printing Office, 2014), p. 31. Figures 205. Verizon, Inc., 2016 Data Breach Investigations
are for FY 2013. Report.
191. Verizon, Inc., 2016 Data Breach Investigations 206. Market Connections, Federal Network Security
Report (New York: Author, 2016). Survey Report (Alexandria, VA: Author, 2015),
192. Solarwinds and Market Connections, Solarwinds p. 3. Figure is for 2015.
Federal Cybersecurity Survey 2015 (Washington, 207. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Cyberse-
DC, and Asheville, NC: Authors, 2014). Data are curity: Continued Attention Needed to Protect Our
for 2014. Nation’s Critical Infrastructure and Information
193. Deloitte and National Association of State Systems, pp. 10, 9. Datum is for 2010.
Information Officers, State Governments at 208. Ben Fagan, OPM Is Not Alone: More Third Party
Risk: A Call for Collaboration and Compliance Risk in the Federal Government (Cambridge,
(Washington, DC, and Lexington, KY: Authors, MA: Bitsight Technologies, 2015). Data are for
2012), p. 17. Figures are for 2012. 2015.
The Public’s Information Resource 187

209. Aliya Sternstein, “Who Needs Heartbleed 224. Eric A. Fischer, Federal Laws Relating to
When Many Dot-Govs Don’t Even Encrypt Cybersecurity: Discussion of Proposed Revi-
Communications?” Nextgov.com (June 11, 2014). sions  (Washington, DC: U.S. Congressional
210. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Research Service, 2012), p. 2. Updated figure is
Information Security: Actions Needed to Address for 2016.
Challenges, p. 11. 225. William Jackson, “Update: The Case for FISMA
211. ISC and KPMG, The State of Cybersecurity Reform,” Government Computer News (April 5,
from the Federal Cyber Executive Perspective 2010), p. 7.
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2016), p. 14. Figure is 226. Jamil Farshchi and Ahmad Douglas, “How
for 2016. to Move Past the FISMA Mindset,” Federal
212. Aliya Sternstein, “Most Federal Agencies Computer Week (September 13, 2010), p. 20.
Wouldn’t Be Able to Bounce Back from a Sony 227. Wyatt Kash, “A Cyber Bill Worth Enacting,”
Hack,” Nextgov.com (December 18, 2014). Government Computer News 29 (June 21, 2010),
213. Booz Allen Hamilton and Partnership for Public p. 4.
Service, Cyber In-Security: Strengthening the 228. Fischer, Federal Laws Relating to Cybersecurity,
Federal Cybersecurity Workforce (Washington, p. 1.
DC: Authors, 2009), p 7. Data are for 2009, and 229. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
exclude the intelligence agencies. Information Officers, State Governments at
214. National Initiative for Cybersecurity Education, Risk: A Call for Collaboration and Compliance
NICE Cybersecurity Workforce Framework (Washington, DC, and Lexington, KY: Authors,
(Washington, DC: Author, 2016). 2012), p. 3.
215. FedScoop staff, “Cyber Alert Overload Creates 230. Srini Subramanian, as quoted in Jeffrey Stinson,
New Challenges for Feds.” Figures are for 2016. “Cyberattacks on State Databases Escalate,”
216. Market Research Media, U.S. Federal Cyber- Stateline (October 2, 2014).
security Market Forecast 2015–2020 (June  24, 231. Ponemon Institute, as cited in Armanda Ziadeh,
2015). “State v. Fed: Who Does Cyber Security Better?”
217. Market Connections, Federal Network Security Gcn.com (November 4, 2015). Figures are for
Survey Report, pp. 17, 9. Figure is for 2015. 2015.
218. Frank Konkel, “Want to Avoid Another OPM? 232. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
Spend More, Industry Says,” Nextgov.com Information Officers, 2016 Deloitte-NASCIO
(January 8, 2016). Cybersecurity Study (Washington, DC, and
219. Mohana Ravindranath, “Why Are Government Lexington, KY: Authors, 2016), p. 18.
Contractors Cutting Their Cybersecurity 233. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
Budgets?” Nextgov.com (July 15, 2015). Data are Information Officers, State Governments at Risk
for 2014–2015. (2014), pp. 7, 11.
220. Moore and Fairchild, “Federal Cybersecurity by 234. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
the Numbers.” Information Officers, 2016 Deloitte-NASCIO
221. Daniel Byler, Steve Berman, Vishwa Kola, and Cybersecurity Study, p. 3.
William D. Eggers, Accountability Quantified: 235. Ibid., p. 15.
What 26 Years of GAO Reports Can Teach Us 236. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
about Government Management (Washington, Information Officers, State Governments at Risk
DC: Deloitte, 2015). Figures are for 1983–2008. (2014), p. 11. Figure is for 2012.
222. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Infor- 237. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
mation Security: Department of Education and Information Officers, 2016 Deloitte-NASCIO
Other Federal Agencies Need to Better Implement Cybersecurity Study, p. 15.
Controls, GAO-16-228T (Washington, DC: U.S. 238. National Association of State Chief Information
Government Publishing Office, 2015), Highlights Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTIA, 2016
page. Figures are for FY 2009–FY 2015. State CIO Survey, p. 2.
223. Joseph Marks, “Obama’s Cyber Legacy: He Did 239. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief
(Almost) Everything Right and It Still Turned Out Information Officers, State Governments at Risk
Wrong,” Nextgov.com (January 1, 2017). (2010), p. 18.
188 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

240. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief 256. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2010 Tax
Information Officers, State Governments at Risk Filing Season: IRS’s Performance Improved in
(2014), p. 4. Some Key Areas, but Efficiency Gains Are Possible
241. Deloitte and National Association of State Chief in Others, GAO-11-111 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Information Officers, 2016 Deloitte-NASCIO Government Printing Office, 2010), p. 6. Figures
Cybersecurity Study, p. 7. are for 2009.
242. Stinson, “Elections Shake Up Top State IT Jobs.” 257. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Electronic
Data are for 2010–2012 and 2012–2014. Payments: Many Programs Electronically
243. Steven Spano, as quoted in Jessie Bur, “States Disburse Federal Benefits, and More Outreach
Seek Federal Collaboration in Cybersecurity,” Could Increase Use, GAO-08-645 (Washington,
Meritalk.com (May 24, 2016). DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008),
244. National Association of State Chief Information Highlights page. Figures are for 2008.
Officers, The 2014 State CIO Top 10 (Washington, 258. U.S. General Accounting Office, Electronic
DC: Author), pp. 2–13. Transfers: Use by Federal Payment Recipients Has
245. US-CERT, Alert (TA15-119A) Top 30 Targeted Increased but Obstacles to Greater Participation
High Risk Vulnerabilities (Washington, DC: Remain, GAO-02-913 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Author, 2015). Government Printing Office, 2002). Figure is for
246. MeriTalk, Go Big Security (Alexandria, VA: 2002.
Author 2015). 259. “Administration Touts Progress on Goals,”
247. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Infor- FederalTimes.com (February 13, 2014). Figure is
mation Security: Concerted Effort Needed to for 2013.
Improve Federal Performance Measures, GAO- 260. Dave Lewan, The ForeSee E-Government
09-617 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Satisfaction Index (Q1 2015) (Ann Arbor, MI:
Printing Office, 2009), Highlights page. ForeSee, 2015), pp. 5–6.
248. Jason Miller, “GSA Now in Charge of Dot-Gov 261. Charles S. Clark, “‘Technophobic’ Washington
Domain Policy, Issuance,” Federal News Radio Drags Down Government Innovation, Carly
(January 14, 2015). Fiorina Says,” Government Executive (January
249. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of 2013).
the United States, 2016, 4th ed. (Bethesda, MD: 262. Shane Harris, “Getting Down to Business,”
Author, 2016), Table 1166. Figure is for 2012. Governing (September 2002), p. 42.
250. Pew Research Center, Americans’ Views on Open 263. National Association of State Procurement
Government Data (Washington, DC: Author, Officials, 2015 Survey of State Procurement
2015). Figures are for 2014–2015. Practices (Lexington, KY: Author, 2015), p. 5.
251. Nicole Blake Johnson, “Agencies Move to 264. “Slowdown Ahead for Financing E-Procurement,”
Eliminate Paper Use, Boost Electronic Business,” Governing (July 2001), p. 70.
Federal Times (April, 2011), FederalTimes.com. 265. Stephanie Kanowitz, “State Data Clearinghouse
Figure is for 2010. Cuts Duplicate Benefits Payments,” Gcn.com
252. Stephen Seidel and Jason Ye, “Smarter Printing (August 20, 2015).
Could Cut Costs, Energy Use in Half,” Nextgov. 266. Caroline J. Tolbert, Karen Mossberger, and
com (May 16, 2013). Ramona McNeal, “Institutions, Policy Innovation,
253. Johnson, “Agencies Move to Eliminate Paper and E-Government in the American States, “Public
Use,  Boost Electronic Business.” Figures are for Administration Review 68 (May/June 2008),
2010. pp. 549–563. The quotation is on p. 554.
254. Charles S. Clark, “Federal Paper Pushing Costs 267. John O’Looney, “Use of the Internet for Citizen
Taxpayers Millions,” Govexec.com (December 8, Participation and Service Delivery,” Municipal
2015). Year Book, 2001 (Washington, DC: International
255. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Electronic City/County Management Association, 2001),
Rulemaking: Progress Made in Developing pp. 28–34.
Centralized E-Rulemaking System, GAO-05-777 268. Civic Resource Group, Cities on the Internet,
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 2001: E-Government Applied (Santa Monica,
Office, 2005), p. 7. CA: Author, 2001). Figures are for 2001.
The Public’s Information Resource 189

269. David Coursey, “E-Government: Trends, Benefits, 283. Government Business Council and Accenture,
and Challenges,” Municipal Year Book, 2005 Bringing Federal IT Up to Speed, p. 18.
(Washington, DC: International City/County 284. Coursey, “E-Government,” p. 17. Figure is for
Management Association, 2005), pp. 14–21. 2004.
270. Evelina R. Moulder, “E-Government: Trends, 285. Vicente Pina, Lourdes Torres, and Sonia Royo,
Opportunities, and Challenges,” Municipal Year “Is E-Government Leading to More Accountable
Book, 2003 (Washington, DC: International and Transparent Local Governments? An Overall
City/County Management Association, 2003), View,” Financial Accountability & Management
pp. 39–45. Figure (p. 43) is for 2002. 26 (February 2010), pp. 3–20.
271. Council for Excellence in Government, The New 286. Hiroko Kudo, “Does E-Government Guarantee
E-Government Equation, p. 24. Figures are for Accountability in Public Sector? Experiences in
2003. Italy and Japan,” Public Administration Quarterly
272. Charles Chieppo, “Government in Your Pocket,” 32 (April 2008), pp. 93–120. The quotations are
Governing.com (April 2015). on p. 93.
273. Forrest V. Morgeson, III, and Sunil Mithas, 287. As derived from data in U.S. Government
“Does E-Government Measure Up to E-Business? Accountability Office, Data Transparency:
Comparing End User Perceptions of U.S. Federal Oversight Needed to Address Underreporting
Government and E-Business Web Sites,” Public and Inconsistencies on Federal Award Website,
Administration Review 69 (July/August 2009), GAO-14-476 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
pp. 740–752. Printing Office, 2014), Highlights page. Figures
274. Adobe Public Sector Blog, “A Frustrated are for FY 2012.
Citizenry” Adobe.com (October 21, 2015). Figure 288. Joseph Marks, “The Data Act Is About to Shake
is for 2015. Up Federal Operations,” Nextgov.com (April 28,
275. Adobe Public Sector Blog,“Digital Bipartisanship,” 2014).
Adobe.com (December 7, 2015). Data are for 289. Dong Chul Shim and Tae Ho Eom, “E-Government
2015. and Anti-Corruption: Empirical Analysis of
276. Adobe Public Sector Blog, “A Frustrated International Data,” International Journal of
Citizenry.” Figure is for 2015. Public Administration 31 (3, 2008), pp. 298–316.
277. Council for Excellence in Government, The New The quotation is on p. 298.
E-Government Equation: Ease, Engagement, 290. As derived from data in Alec MacGillis, “Obama’s
Privacy and Protection (Washington, DC: Author, ‘70 Million Checks’ Per Month: Actually, It’s Even
2003), pp. 2, 5. Figures are for 2003. More Than That,” Washington Post (July 26,
278. Aliya Sternstein, “The Dot-Gov Rejects: The 2011). Figure is for 2011.
1,000 Government Websites Shuttered Over Past 291. Frank Abagnale, quoted in Charles C. Clark,
10 Years,” Nextgov.com (April 8, 2015). “Reformed Con Man Wows Agency Accountants
279. Corporation for National and Community with Anti-Fraud Tips,” Govexec.com (September
Service and National Conference on Citizenship, 15, 2015).
Civic Life in America: Key Findings on the Civic 292. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Improper
Health of the Nation, Issue Brief (Washington, Payments: Recent Efforts to Address Improper
DC: Authors, 2010), pp. 11, 22–23. Payments and Remaining Challenges, GAO-
280. Council for Excellence in Government, 11-575T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
E-Government: To Connect, Protect, and Serve Printing Office, 2011), p. 3. Highlights page.
Us (Washington, DC: Author, 2002), pp. 19–20. Figure is for FY 2010 (when improper payments
Figures are for 2001. accounted for 5.5 percent of outlays) through FY
281. Eric C. Welch, “Linking Citizen Satisfaction with 2013.
E-Government and Trust in Government,” Journal 293. Sean Reilly, “Improper Payment Rate Falls Again,”
of Public Administration Research and Theory 15 FederalTimes.com (December 31, 2013).
(Summer 2005), pp. 371–392. The quotation is on 294. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Fiscal
p. 371. Outlook: Addressing Improper Payments and
282. Lewan, The ForeSee E-Government Satisfaction the Tax Gap Would Improve the Government’s
Index, p. 6. Fiscal Position, GAO-16-92T (Washington, DC:
190 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), p. 3. 305. Susan Milligan, “Medicaid Expansion Spurs
Figure is for FY 2003, when records were first States Fight Fraud, Overpayments,” Pewstates
kept, through FY 2014. (March 4, 2014). Figures are for 2013.
295. Dan Zitting, “Follow the Data Trail: Using 306. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services,
Analytics to Defeat Fraud,” Routefifty.com “Medicare/Payment Accuracy.” Figure is average
(March 5, 2017). Figure is for FY 2014. for FY 2014–FY 2015.
296. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 307. Ibid.
Improper Payments: Moving Forward with 308. Office of the President of the United States,
Governmentwide Reduction Strategies, GAO- Trends in Health Care Cost Growth and the Role
12-405T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government of the Affordable Care Act (Washington, DC:
Printing Office, 2012), Highlights page. U.S. Government Printing Office, 2013), pp. 1–2.
297. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Fiscal Years covered are 1965–2012 and 1962–2012,
Outlook: Addressing Improper Payments and respectively.
the Tax Gap Would Improve the Government’s 308. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Medicaid:
Fiscal Position, Highlights page. Figure is for FY CMS Has Taken Steps, but Further Efforts Are
2014. Needed to Control Improper Payments, GAO-
298. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Computer 17-386T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Matching Act: OMB and Selected Agencies Need Publishing Office, 2017), Highlights page. Figure
to Ensure Consistent Implementation, GAO-14- is for FY 2016.
44 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 309. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services
Office, 2014). Figure is for FY 2013. Three-point- and U.S. Department of Justice, Health Care Fraud
five percent figure is for FY 2009–FY 2014. Sixty- and Abuse Program: Annual Report for Fiscal
five percent figure is for FY 2011. Year 2015 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
299. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Taxpayer Publishing Office, 2016), pp. 1, 8. Fraud recovery
Information: Options Exist to Enable Data figure is for 1997–2015. Return on investment
Sharing between IRS and USCIS but Each figure is average for 2013–2015.
Presents Challenges, GAO-06-100 (Washington, 310. Herbert A. Simon, The Shape of Automation for
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005), p. 1. Men and Management (New York: Harper &
Figure is for 2000. Row, 1965), p. 52.
300. International Institute for Analytics, Health Care 311. United Nations, as cited in Wyatt Kash, “Number
Payment Integrity through Advanced Analytics of Countries Embracing Open Government
(Portland, OR: Author, 2015), pp. 1, 3. Surges,” Fedscoop.com (August 1, 2016). Figures
301. U.S. Government Accounting Office, Improper are for 2014–2015.
Payments: Progress Made but Challenges 312. Jeffrey Stinson, “Open Data Is Open for Business,”
Remain in Estimating and Reducing Improper Stateline (June 5, 2014). Figures are for 2014.
Payments, GAO-09-628T (Washington, DC: U.S. 313. Socrata and EMC Research, 2016 Socrata Open
Government Printing Office, 2009), Highlights Data Benchmark Survey (Seattle, WA: Authors,
page. Figure is for FY 2008. 2016).
302. As derived from data in U.S. Department of 314. Tyler Jett, “State Rep. Tom Weldon’s Campaign
Health and Human Services, “Medicare/Payment Website Entirely in Japanese,” Timesfreepress.
Accuracy” and “Medicaid/Payment Accuracy,” com (March 17, 2016).
Paymentaccuracy.gov. Figures are for FY 2015. 315. Socrata and EMC Research, 2016 Socrata Open
303. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Medicaid: Data Benchmark Survey.
CMS Has Taken Steps, but Further Efforts Are 316. Pew Research Center, Americans’ Views on Open
Needed to Control Improper Payments, GAO- Government Data, p. 2. Figures are for 2014–2015.
17-386T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 317. McKinsey & Company, Public-Sector Digitization:
Printing Office, 2017), Highlights page. Figure is The Trillion-Dollar Challenge (Washington, DC:
for FY 2016. Author, 2014).
304. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 318. Frank Konkel, “Why ‘Cloud Is Here to Stay,’”
“Medicaid/Payment Accuracy.” Figure average is Nextgov.com (March 16, 2015).
for FY 2013–FY 2015. 319. Frank Konkel, “Report: 97% of Government
The Public’s Information Resource 191

Has IT Plan,” Nextgov.com (November 2, 2016). Better Understanding of Intranet Implementation


Figure is for FY 2017. and Its Effect on Red Tape,” Journal of Public
320. Grant Thornton and Professional Services Council, Administration Research and Theory 17 (October
2015 Federal CIO and CISO Survey, p. 7. 2007), pp. 379–404. The quotation is on p. 379.
321. National Association of State Chief Information 327. Ignace Snellen, “Electronic Governance:
Officers, Grant Thornton, and CompTia, The Implications for Citizens, Politicians and Public
2016 State CIO Survey, pp. 11, 10. Servants,” International Review of Administrative
322. TechSoup Global, 2012 Global Cloud Computing Sciences 65 (June 2002), pp. 190–194.
Survey Results (San Francisco: Author, 2012). 328. Jeffrey B. Wenger and Vicky M. Wilkins, “At the
323. Jason Miller, “Agencies Not Seeing Dollar Signs Discretion of Rogue Agents: How Automation
in the Cloud,” Federal News Radio (January 16, Improves Women’s Outcomes in Unemployment
2015). Insurance,” Journal of Public Administration
324. Robert L. Mitchell, “Redistricting for the Masses,” Research and Theory 19 (April 2009), pp. 313–
Computerworld (May 23, 2011), pp. 21–23. 333.
325. Kuotsai Tom Liou and Ronnie Korosec, 329. Mark Bovens and Stavros Zouridis, “From
“Implementing Organizational Reform Strategies Street-Level to System-Level Bureaucracies: How
in State Government,” Public Administration Information and Communication Technology
Quarterly 33 (Fall 2009), pp. 429–452. The quo- Is Transforming Administrative Discretion and
tation is on p. 447. Control,” Public Administration Review 62
326. Eric W. Welch and Sanjay K. Pandey, (March/April 2002), pp. 174–184.
“E-Government and Bureaucracy: Toward a 330. Snellen, “Electronic Governance,” p. 194.
CHAPTER

The Constant Quest:


Efficient and Effective
Governance
A ll governments have issues of efficiency
and effectiveness. A probably apocryphal
example: following World War II, a British com- ■
addressed to them . . . much time is spent on
unimportant business.”
Robert Morris: “No man living can attend
mission  charged with modernizing government the daily deliberations of Congress and
discovered that the civil service was paying a full- do executive parts of business at the
time  worker to light fires along the Dover cliffs same time.”
should a Spanish Armada loom, a fleet last spotted ■ Thomas Jefferson: “Nothing is so embarrassing
in 1588. nor so mischievous in a great assembly as the
Although our example might seem to belie it, details of execution. The smallest trifle of that
more productive public administration is colos- kind occupies [legislators’ time] as long as the
sally consequential. The federal government, for most important act of legislation, and takes
instance, could save as much as $995 billion by [the] place of everything else.”
2025 by increasing their efficiency by a modest 1
These frustrations over inefficient government
percent.1 If the feds “could achieve the 15 percent or
led James Madison, in particular, to use “an effi-
more productivity improvement we typically expect
ciency argument” for creating, as a vital part of
from a major private-sector change program,”
the nation’s new Constitution, a separate execu-
the savings would tally to “more than $445 per
tive branch authorized to implement congressional
citizen.”2 Multiply that figure by more than 330
legislation. “We have been taught that the separa-
million people, and suddenly we are talking about
tion of powers was meant to provide mutual checks,
real money.
with consequent inefficiency in operation,” a con-
Efficient and effective public administration
sequence  often hailed by political scientists as the
has lain leadenly on the minds of American public
reasonable price of protecting citizens from des-
officials even before there was a United States of
potic governmental efficiency. But the founders’
America. Consider some complaints about the lack
“primary  need was to achieve efficiency. . .. The
of productive public administration made by some
modern cult of checks as the primary virtue of
distinguished Americans who served in Congress
the  Constitution was not shared by its framers.”
under the Articles of Confederation, that odd
Indeed not. The term, “check,” appears a mere five
interregnum when the government had no exec-
times in the founders’ Federalist Papers, and then
utive branch, thereby forcing legislators to also be
only when referring to “governmental machin-
administrators:
ery,” and the word is nowhere to be found in the
Constitution.3
■ Thomas Burke: Because members of Congress
“cannot reject any [administrative] business

192
Efficient and Effective Governance 193

hard to change, even for reasons of gaining greater


WHY CAN’T GOVERNMENT efficiency.
BE MORE EFFICIENT AND
Global Governmental Bureaucratization As we
EFFECTIVE? discussed in Chapter 4, no government (not just
An analysis of the federal government’s forty-one American ones) can be streamlined—that is, reduced
“most visible failures” (as determined by the amount in its hierarchy and red tape—to the extent that a
of news on such topics as the 9/11 attacks) over thir- company or nonprofit organization can be.
teen years found that its most notorious failures were
growing over time.4 Small wonder that an astonish- Environmental Turbulence When the external
ing 98 percent of Americans think that government environment of public organizations becomes more
wastes “a lot” (72 percent) of or “some” (26 percent) turbulent—a condition that arguably is amplifying
tax money. Federal officials concur; 66 percent cite over time—then that turbulence has a measurably
“achieving operational efficiency” as their “most “negative effect” on the performance of government
pressing” management issue, and nothing else comes agencies.7
even remotely close.5
Public efficiency and effectiveness remain elusive
for the many reasons, which we explain next. Before Eight Political Reasons
doing so, however, let us place these productivity In addition, there are eight political reasons why
problems in perspective. In 1990, the Government American governments cannot attain the same level
Accountability Office (GAO) created its “high-risk” of efficiency and effectiveness that is found in the
list of federal programs that are unduly vulnerable other two sectors. These, at least in theory, should be
to fraud, waste, abuse, and mismanagement; over more responsive to reform than the three preceding
the ensuing twenty-five years, a total of fifty-seven reasons.
programs were placed on the list. These are hell-
ishly complex and difficult programs that require Public Unions What evidence we have suggests
enormous effort to be removed from the list (six that public unions can equate with less governmen-
programs, which were among the original fourteen tal efficiency and effectiveness. We address this in
placed on the list in 1990, are still on it), but it is Chapter 9.
striking that two-fifths of them have been removed.
“The good news is that” these high-risk problems Politicized Public Executives We also address in
“are solvable. . .. Although cynics might believe oth- Chapter 9, and in this chapter, the systemic ineffi-
erwise, success is possible.”6 ciencies that accompany public executives who
With that pleasantly upbeat note, we descend are hired more for political reasons than for their
into the depressing reasons underlying public administrative proficiency.
inefficiencies.
Dumb Public Policies Some public policies waste
money simply because they are self-evidently dumb,
Three Fundamental Reasons at least from an administrative perspective, if not,
For cultural, structural, and environmental reasons— perhaps, from a political one. Does it really make
reasons that are not subject to easy, or possibly even sense, for instance, to send monthly unemployment
human, change—government is unable to match the checks to 2,362 millionaires and multi-millionaires?8
efficiency of the private and nonprofit sectors. Or to ship coal from the United States to heat its mil-
itary bases in Germany (which has a lot of coal)?9
Constrained American Governments As we Other policies are formally assessed for their
reviewed in Chapter 1 and throughout Part II, efficiency and effectiveness, but continue to waste
American governments (but not private and inde- money even after it is conclusively shown that they
pendent organizations) function in a culture that are unproductive—or even counterproductive—
is uniquely constraining; thus, they find it very because they nevertheless are retained. “Despite
194 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

decades of efforts and trillions of dollars in spend- Congress demands that the program be implemented
ing, rigorous evaluations typically find that around by two or more entities; sometimes these entities are
75 percent of [federal] programs or practices that other federal agencies, but often they are not, ren-
are intended help people do better at school or at dering coordinated and efficient management even
work have little or no effect.”10 more difficult.16
For example, systematic evaluations have shown Worse, most federal agencies execute three or
the following: out of eleven of Washington’s “large more of the fifteen “budget functions”—that is,
social programs,” initiated in 1990 and costing more Washington’s biggest, and wholly different, public
than $10 billion annually, ten showed only “weak or policies, such as “National Defense.” The Department
no positive effects.” A federal after-school program of Agriculture spends only about two-fifths of its
designed to improve students’ behavior positively appropriated funds on agriculture; another two-
associated with increases in suspensions and other fifths goes to income security programs.17
punishable incidents. These and other dysfunctional It is, obviously, not easy for top administrators
programs are still with us.11 to wrap their minds around multiple major policies
Subnational governments are not immune. In and still administer them well.
the states, the notorious “scared straight” programs,
in which youths are subjected to prison-style disci- A Bevy of Bosses In contrast to the chief executive
pline in an effort to dissuade them from criminal officers of companies and nonprofit organizations,
behavior, actually results in an average of 12 percent who report to a single board of directors, the heads
of its participants becoming more likely to commit of government agencies typically report to dozens of
crimes.12 Of the estimated 25,000 teacher education their equivalents in the form of legislative oversight
programs in universities, states closed or prevented committees. Consider the fate of the Department
student enrollments in “fewer than 60” badly fal- of Homeland Security. The department “and its
tering programs over five years, and just a dozen subcomponents are accountable to more than 100
education schools or departments were closed or committees, subcommittees [at least eighty-eight
suspended.13 committees and subcommittees, and growing18],
Local governments spent an estimated $12 caucuses and commissions. The redundancy places
billion over fifteen years to build or renovate an enormous burden on the department, consuming
forty-five private sports stadiums; because tax-free staff who set aside departmental work to respond
municipal bonds (explained in Chapter 8) were used to a multitude of congressional inquiries, and the
to finance thirty-two (or 71 percent) of them, federal time of executives who are called to testify.”19 Every
tax revenue shrank by $3.7 billion,14 and local gov- Senator, and at least 412 of the 435 Representatives,
ernments gained essentially nothing for their subsi- or 95 percent, have some degree of responsibility for
dization: “A wide array of studies have shown that homeland security.20
professional teams add virtually no income to local Why is this? Because legislative committees
economies. In fact, some of them find that large that oversee prominent public policies attract large
subsidies actually [take] . . . money out of the local numbers of legislators, who are fully aware that
economy.”15 the resultant publicity enhances their prospects for
re-election. Indeed, when the 9/11 Commission rec-
Parsing Policy Implementation A favorite pre- ommended some consolidation, “committees were
occupation of legislatures is that of creating a unwilling to give up their piece of jurisdiction.”21
single public policy, and then scattering, like seeds Hence, “there has been no move toward consolida-
to the wind, slices of that policy among passels of tion of. . .. the crazy-quilt of congressional oversight”
public agencies, with (of course) the firm mandate of the department, a condition that “perpetuates the
that the agencies somehow manage the policy effi- fragmentation of responsibility that led to 9/11.”22
ciently and effectively. This is particularly the case
in Washington. Ignorant, Uninterested, and Bullying Legislators
In an astonishing 85 percent of “new or sub- Members of Congress and their staffs exhibit an
stantially revised programs” enacted by Congress, ignorance of how executive agencies work. A former
Efficient and Effective Governance 195

staffer who later became an under secretary recalled, “at least” seventeen additional agencies.27 Even after
“I was stunned at the things I had not known as GAO’s commendable (and continuing) digging, the
a Hill staffer about the challenges, restrictions and head of GAO stated before Congress that there still
complexities of operating in the executive branch— is not even a complete list of federal programs.28
relative ignorance about the budget process, the These redundancies brings not only vast
federal hiring process, procurement and how rule- waste—eliminating or reducing these inefficiencies
making works.”23 “will result in approximately $125 billion in finan-
Some of this ignorance is attributable to shorter cial benefits” over fifteen years29—but also consider-
congressional tenures, which undermines congres- able hardship for both taxpayers and the recipients
sional learning about government. In the 2015–2016 of government services.
session, nearly half of Representatives and Senators Here is an example that affects taxpayers:
had served six years or fewer.24 Washington’s forty job training programs (four-
Despite the creation, in 2012, of a Government teen of which serve fewer than 4,000 trainees each,
Efficiency Caucus, there is also a declining con- and one serves just 318) are administered by seven
gressional interest in executive agencies. A former agencies at an annual cost of nearly $12 billion,
Representative observed that “professional knowl- including administrative costs that range from an
edge is given less attention than it was decades ago,” eyebrow-raising 7 percent of all expenditures to an
as indicated by the fact that the number of com- eye-popping 20 percent.30
mittee and subcommittee hearings is three-fifths of And here is an example—federal human ser-
what it was thirty years earlier, a decline that also vices programs—that affects clients: “Six federal
contributes to congressional ignorance about the agencies . . . [and uncounted] state and local agen-
agencies. And the quality of those hearings is in cies, as well as for-profit and nonprofit agencies
doubt. Former Defense Secretary and Director of directly provide services. . .. This array of programs
Central Intelligence, Robert Gates, wrote that most [is] too fragmented and overly complex—for clients
members of Congress are “uncivil, incompetent in to navigate, [and] for program operators to admin-
fulfilling basic constitutional responsibilities, micro- ister effectively. . .. Individuals often must visit mul-
managerial, parochial, egotistical, thin-skinned, tiple offices to apply for aid and provide the same
often putting self (and reelection) before country,” information and documentation each time. . .. The
adding that congressional hearings are “rude, insult- complexity and variation in eligibility rules and
ing, belittling, bullying, and all too often highly per- other requirements among programs contribute
sonal attacks [that] . . . violated nearly every norm of to time-consuming and duplicative administrative
civil behavior as they postured and acted as judge, processes that add to overall costs. Some programs
jury, and executioner.”25 Stern letter to follow. provide similar services through separate programs,
resulting in additional inefficiencies.”31
Duplication, Overlap, Fragmentation, and Related When programmatic fragmentation, duplica-
Inefficiencies Legislatures are often guilty of cre- tion, and overlap are avoided, efficiency soars. For
ating programmatic duplication, overlap, and frag- instance, the administrative expenses of the Social
mentation, three particularly pernicious sources of Security Administration, which has the exclusive
wasted dollars, but the federal government is exem- authorization to manage Social Security programs,
plary in these questionable practices. An impressive have not exceeded 1 percent of its annual expendi-
68 percent of federal managers state that agencies tures since 1989.32 Similarly, the U.S. Postal Service,
are “ripe for cuts when it comes to eliminating waste which processes two-fifths of the world’s snail mail
and redundancy.”26 and has suffered deep cuts (38 percent of all mail
Over the course of five years, the Government deliveries now are delivered after 5:00 P.M. because
Accountability Office identified 645 “actions,” or of staff cuts33), but retains the exclusive authoriza-
ways to reduce or eliminate duplicative, overlapping, tion to deliver mail, ranks at the top of all federal
or fragmented programs and practices and other agencies for customer engagement,34 and is the most
inefficiencies that were uncovered in some 249 policy efficient mail service out of all 159 national postal
“areas” found in all fifteen cabinet departments and services analyzed.35
196 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Congress and the agencies are making progress. unusually closely with Congress.39 The remaining
Over five years, 51 percent of all 645 actions needed eleven have “virtually never [been] combined to
to reduce overlap, fragmentation, duplication, and eliminate program duplication. Missions are not
waste had been fully addressed, 31 percent par- realigned or even rationalized. Program laps upon
tially so, and 18 percent had not yet been addressed, program. Responsibilities are not coordinated.”40
saving $75 billion.36 Permit us a pertinent side note. GAO’s thought-
The core of the problem, however, remains ful, multi-year research on governmental reorgan-
Congress. It would appear that no program, no ization found that the odds of success increase if:
matter that it is identical to a heaving host of others, stakeholders are involved in decision making; exec-
is so redundant that Congress not only will protect utive and legislative roles are balanced and a con-
it, but often add more redundancy. Should we be sensus is reached; high-risk areas are identified; and
surprised that it was only in 2010 that Congress, programmatic duplication, overlap, and fragmenta-
for the very first time (!), required reports on pro- tion are reduced.41
grammatic duplication, fragmentation, overlap, and
related inefficiencies that it, itself, had created? The States’ Iron Triangles Although “more than
half”42 of the governors are empowered, at least in
Iron Triangles Why do programmatic duplica- theory, to reorganize by executive order their civil
tion, fragmentation, and overlap persist? Much services,43 the iron triangle endures.
of the reason is the presence of the iron triangle, The states’ efforts to reorganize began in the
or the exceptionally strong bonds that exist among early twentieth century, and took the form of five
the agency, its legislative oversight committees, and reorganizational waves.44 Despite all this roiling,
the affected special interests. Each of these three tri- however, “by the middle of the twentieth century
angular sides is direly threatened by any proposed state bureaucracies often contained one hundred to
rearrangement of their relationships, and, therefore, two hundred units”45 all ostensibly reporting to the
the iron triangle almost always succeeds in block- governor, the legislature, or an independent board,
ing executive branch reorganizations regardless of and coordinated management was hardly the rule.
the benefits, such as attaining greater efficiency, that Between 1965 and 1990, twenty-six states reduced
restructuring would bring. the number of their agencies, and, in limited ways,
reorganized, mostly by introducing, for the first
Washington’s Iron Triangles Because any pro- time, a cabinet-based executive branch.46 These
posed reorganization of the executive branch must reorganizations were less than sweeping, and those
be approved by Congress, Congress is clearly the few agencies that were eliminated commonly “had
federal triangle’s toughest side. In 1938, for example, minuscule budgets,” or “their functions continue to
Franklin Delano Roosevelt, at the apogee of his pres- be performed by other agencies.”47 Each state typi-
idential power, was roundly crushed in Congress cally retains hundreds of boards and commissions,
when he attempted to implement the sensible rec- but unfilled vacancies persist, meetings are often
ommendations of the prestigious Committee on rare, redundancy is common, many missions long
Administrative Management, noted in Chapter  2. have been met, and their costs are high.48
This “defeat . . . was the worst that President
Roosevelt would suffer in three terms as President.”37
As a consequence of the iron triangle, there have WHY CAN’T GOVERNMENT—
been only a dozen “major” reorganizations over AND THE NONPROFIT SECTOR—
sixty-four years, and some seem not all that major, BE MORE EFFICIENT AND
or even reorganizational, such as re-titling the War
Department to the Defense Department.38 In fact, EFFECTIVE?
only one of these reorganizations has been deemed There are two additional reasons why the public
successful (when Congress approved 70 percent of sector cannot attain the efficiency and effectiveness
the first Hoover Commission’s recommendations of of the private sector, and which, uniquely, also apply
1949), and then only because the president worked to the nonprofit sector.
Efficient and Effective Governance 197

The other is information technology, which has


Process Change Equals Glacial Change displaced labor. An example: In 1983, cleri-
It is an inescapable and stubborn fact that the core cal  workers accounted for 20 percent of federal
activity of all governments, and essentially of all non- civilian employees; today, they account for 6
profit organizations, is providing services. Providing percent.53  As a former federal secretary observed,
services is, of course, a process, and processes, as “The stuff I did  15 or 16 years ago is no longer
we explained in Chapter 4, are far more difficult to necessary. Now we all need some level of computer
change, even for reasons of greater efficiency, than literacy.”54
are products, which are produced almost exclusively
by the private sector.
UNDERSTANDING PUBLIC
Technology, Productivity, and Service PRODUCTIVITY
Quality Three-fourths of top public administrators cite
In his uniquely insightful essays, William Baumol “improved productivity”—that tall, tough, prickly,
has  shown how the public and independent and dry Saguaro cactus of public management—as
sectors also are unable to exploit new technologies their most important issue.55
to boost productivity to the extent that the private
sector can.49
Productive Definitions
The Quality Quest In the product-intensive private We define productivity, a phrase subject to myriad
sector, investments can be made in technologies interpretations in the literature, as efficiency and
that increase productivity by replacing labor. But in effectiveness in the public and nonprofit sectors.
the service-intensive public and nonprofit sectors, Efficiency is the full accomplishment of a job
technologies cannot replace labor because their using the fewest resources possible, or “the biggest
workers are direct, hands-on producers of services, bang for the buck.” Effectiveness is the full produc-
and quality is a defining component of service effi- tion of the intended result.
ciency and effectiveness. (The single most important We remind ourselves of these basic definitions
“operational issue,” by far, to senior government because the terms are not as universal as one might
executives in five developed countries, including expect. There is, for example, no word in Russian
the United States, is “improved quality of service,” for efficiency, although there is one for effective-
identified by a remarkable 84 percent.50) Hence, it is ness. Those who ever faced the fearsome might of
extremely difficult to make social workers more pro- the Red Army know that the Russians understand
ductive by expanding their caseloads, to make police effectiveness.
and fire fighters more productive by decreasing their There are additional notions that are impor-
numbers, or to make nonprofit program managers tant in understanding public and nonprofit produc-
more productive by cutting their funding. In these tivity. Inputs are the resources used by a program,
instances, the quality of service inevitably suffers. such as money, people, or time. Outputs are the
“The same might be said for playing a string quartet final products of a program, such as the amount of
with two instruments: More productive, perhaps, trash collected per dollar expended. Outcomes, or
but it’s not the same thing.”51 impacts, are the social or economic changes that are
produced by a program’s outputs, such as improved
Happily, There Are Exceptions As with most gen- public health resulting from trash collected and dis-
eralizations, there are exceptions. Two technologies posed of.
have produced savings in all sectors.
One is technologies and practices that use less
energy and fewer resources. The federal government Ghettos in the Vastness
has decreased its energy consumption by two-fifths, “The amazing thing about public productivity
since record keeping began in 1975.52 research is different clusters of researchers investigate
198 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

the same problems in different ways . . . the majority


of researchers in one cluster are not aware, let alone The Evolution of Public Efficiency and
familiar with, the studies of the other clusters . . . Effectiveness
all these differences put researchers into intellectual Aside from the creation of the Constitution itself
ghettos.”56 and, with it, an executive branch, governments’
Well said. The productivity literature tends attempts to improve their own productivity can be
to focus on performance measurement and traced back to at least 1816, when the U.S. House
program  evaluation, activities that we devote of Representatives established a standing committee
the  bulk of this chapter to. In reality, however, to examine the operations of the War Department.61
the  attainment of greater efficiency and effective-
ness  in the public and nonprofit sectors entails Efficiency for Good Government, 1900–1939 In the
methods that cover far vaster plains of ghet- modern era, Washington first demonstrated that it was
toized  territory. Hence, we address in this and concerned with federal productivity when President
other chapters (or ghettos of our own making) the Robert A. Taft appointed, in 1910, the Commission
primary proposals—e.g., introducing risk manage- on Economy and Efficiency. In 1937, the president’s
ment, eliminating improper payments, and broad- Committee on Administrative Management, detailed
ening electronic government, among many, many in Chapter 2, published its  impressive report, and
others—for more efficient and effective governing minced no words about the centrality of efficiency to
and managing. good government: “Efficiency is thus axiom number
There are also pre-existing conditions that one in the value scale of administration. This brings
can, indirectly but clearly, raise or lower productiv- administration into apparent conflict with the value
ity. These include: creating a unit that shares best scale of politics.”62
practices, standardizes training, and solicits advice The states did not evidence much interest in
from experts, which leads to later and greater improving governmental efficiency until well into
efficiencies;57 the presence of a national govern- the twentieth century, but this was far from the case
mental form that is federal (higher governmental in local governments, where most governing was
efficiency), rather than unitary (lower efficiency);58 done. At the beginning of the twentieth century, aside
assuring, as noted in Chapter 5, a reasonable level from the national defense and diplomacy budgets,
of job security for public employees, while improv- nearly three-fourths of all public expenditures were
ing their performance; and expanding the manage- expended by local governments.63
ment of public programs. The federal government The New York Bureau of Municipal Research,
meets only 64 percent of its strategic initiatives founded in 1906, and its proliferous progeny (noted
and wastes more than a tenth (or $101 million) in Chapter 2), were pioneers in the development
for every $1  billion that it spends on projects and of public performance measures; many of these
programs.59  Only 11 percent of the federal, state, “bureaus of efficiency” actually featured the word,
and local governments  have senior-level program “efficiency” in their titles.64 What are now the
managers or their equivalents, compared with Government Finance Officers Association and the
22 percent in the  private sector, and governments International City/County Management Association
risk $148 million (or 15  percent) out of every $1 cast these local efforts on a national stage in the
billion spent because of poor program manage- 1920s and 1930s.
ment.60 (In  2016, Congress passed the Program
Management Improvement  and Accountability Managing for Efficiency and Effectiveness, 1970–
Act, which instructed agencies  to  designate senior 1980 From the 1940s through the 1960s, gov-
administrators responsible for program manage- ernments grew more interested in controlling costs,
ment strategy and policy, and provided them with largely by introducing new budgeting formats and
a career path.) organization development efforts, and less con-
There is no lack of proven, practical ways to cerned with enhancing public productivity per se.
improve public and nonprofit productivity. And they With the advent of the 1970s, however, this lack-
are all over the map. adaisical orientation altered rather dramatically.
Efficient and Effective Governance 199

Scholars suddenly were asking, “Why does public expanded existing agencies or created new ones
administration ignore evaluation?”65 charged with the state-wide evaluation of program
effectiveness and efficiency,71 but the number of
Federal Forward—Fitfully In 1970, a powerful states in which most major agencies conducted pro-
Senator alerted GAO that it was “distressing that we ductivity analyses was only nominally more than it
have no real measures of the efficiency of the federal had been at the close of the 1970s.72
sector.”66 The Senator was ignored by the execu- Local governments more than retained their
tive branch, but not by the legislative one, which, position of leadership. By the end of the eighties,
in 1978, passed the Inspector General Act, which an astounding four-fifths of municipal governments
created offices of inspectors general (IGs) in federal were conducting program evaluations.73
agencies. IGs, as we detail later, have since waxed
into powerful evaluators of federal performance. A New Public Management, 1991–Present In the
final decade of the twentieth century, public man-
State and Local Governments: Learning and agers were so frustrated over being chained (they
Leading The 1970s marked the first real com- believed) to antiquated practices which prohibited
mitment by the states to assessing their programs. them from governing well, that the term, “libera-
Between 1970 and 1980, the number of states in tion management,” was coined to express their felt
which most major agencies were conducting produc- need for greater flexibility.74 Liberation management
tivity analyses doubled, from one-fifth to two-fifths.67 soon morphed into the new public management
The 1970s also were a decade for local govern- (also known as reinventing government or public
ments to rediscover productivity, often as a conse- quality management), or a proactive commitment
quence of renewed professional interest in the area. to entrepreneurial and accountable innovation in
In 1971 fewer than two-fifths of these governments governance for the purpose of raising governmental
had some form of program evaluation unit in even efficiency, effectiveness, and responsiveness.
one agency, a proportion that had burgeoned to The new public management’s main methods
nearly two-thirds only five years later.68 for fulfilling this mission include: granting public
administrators greater freedom to manage, while
A Mixed Passel of Productivity, 1981–1990 continuing to assure their accountability to the law,
During the 1980s, governments’ efforts to improve professional values, and the public interest; enhanc-
their efficiency and effectiveness varied widely by ing competition and collaboration with other gov-
governmental level. ernments and the private and nonprofit sectors;
greater accountability to, and transparency for, citi-
A Committed Federal Bureaucracy Despite White zens; and the aggressive use of knowledge to antici-
House resistance and a steep decline during the pate events and adapt to them.
1980s in federal funding for evaluating program per- All this leads to a much greater emphasis on
formance, the number of evaluations produced by certain kinds of public management that have been
federal agencies remained about the same as in earlier stressed only intermittently in the past, notably
years, “suggesting continued executive branch inter- performance measurement and feedback, program
est in obtaining evaluation information.”69 In 1982, evaluation, strategic planning, “customer” service,
GAO created its Division of Program Evaluation training, decentralization, and streamlining procure-
and Methodology, which “pioneered some of the ment, budgeting, and human resources management.
agency’s most groundbreaking studies.”70 (Although By the mid-1990s, when the new public man-
the division was eliminated due to budget cuts, in agement was faddishly hot, just 10 percent of
1996, its values arguably had seeped throughout federal, state, and local agencies had had “no expe-
GAO over the fourteen years of its existence.) The rience” with the bundle of techniques that comprise
bureaucracy was at least holding its own. it.75 And its impact on governmental efficiency may
have been deeper than commonly realized. One indi-
State Stabilization and Local Leadership By the cation: From 1990 to 1999, employment by all gov-
mid-1980s, legislatures in thirty-five states had ernments fell from 17 percent of the workforce to
200 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

15.7 percent, the lowest since the early 1960s and Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, which
the lowest in each of the years that followed, includ- required the speedy spending of hundreds of billions
ing the Great Recession of 2007–2009.76 of dollars in stimulus funds to shorten the Great
Recession. All top executives, including the presi-
The New Federal Management Beginning in the dent, were acutely aware of the political risk should
1990s, no president has let program performance fiscal scandals surface, and “that urgency brought
drift quietly away. And their bureaucrats back them, out the best in accountability and opportunities for
consistently selecting “operational efficiency” as collaboration. It had us doing business differently,
their most pressing management issue.77 without cutting corners. . .. driving through those
Within three months after being sworn into competing stakeholders in real time.”87
office in 1993, President Bill Clinton created the That drive included the abandonment of the
National Performance Review, composed of some President’s Management Agenda and PART (which,
250 experienced federal employees, declaring that, regrettably, had become “incredibly adversarial as
“Our goal is to make the entire federal government agencies became defensive”88), and the redirection
both less expensive and more efficient.78 of the PIC’s mission into one of reconfiguring how
By 2000, the National Performance Review, the government assessed program performance.
“the longest-running reform in the history of the Obama moved instead to emphasizing priorities and
Federal Government,”79 had had nearly two-thirds placing responsibility for improving performance
of its 1,200 recommendations implemented,80 pro- away from the Office of Management and Budget
ducing more than 4,000 new customer service stand- (or OMB, which created an Evidence and Evaluation
ards and scrapping 250 programs, 2,000 field offices, team during this period) and to the agencies. Obama,
and 426,200 jobs.81 Historically, the federal civilian however, did create, in 2011, an Office of Social
workforce, which comprised about 1 percent of the Innovation and Civic Participation, charged with
population from 1960 to 1990,82 was cut by an integrating data with domestic policymaking, in the
unprecedented 11 percent during the nineties,83 and White House. In 2016, Congress passed unanimously
federal civilian employees have accounted for two- the Evidence-based Policymaking Commission Act,
thirds of 1 percent of the population since 2000.84 which founded the commission of that name.
Among the Review’s achievements were the intro-
duction of electronic tax filing and performance pay The New State Management By the close of the
for senior executives, but its unsophisticated cutting 1990s, from 5 to 39 percent of state agencies had
of employees left some agencies so weakened that fully implemented at least one of eleven innova-
they have yet to recover, and it is similarly regrettable tions stemming from the new public management,
that the effort ignored serious civil service reform.85 a modest headway that led analysts to conclude
In 2002, President George W. Bush replaced the that “there is a clear possibility” that these reforms
National Performance Review with his President’s “will not be widely and quickly adopted across the
Management Agenda to implement management states.”89
reforms, a Performance Assessment Rating Tool Nevertheless, when states do adopt these inno-
(PART) to grade agency progress, and a cross- vations, efficiency frequently follows. A survey of
agency Performance Improvement Council (PIC) to nearly 300 state agencies found that “taking risks,
coordinate these activities. When Bush left the White being innovative, and being proactive [which is “the
House, in 2009, more than 1,000 programs had been most influential factor of the three”] contribute pos-
assessed. Fewer than a fifth received the top rating itively to organizational performance.”90
of “effective” (hardly a starry-eyed adjective); the Interestingly, state employees are sophis-
remainder were rated lower, including 3 percent that ticated critics of the new public management’s
were “ineffective” and 17 percent which could not many methods; 72 percent of them believe that the
be assessed because of insufficient data. Congress “harder,” more systematic and analytic techniques,
was unresponsive in making improvements.86 notably, strategic planning, performance measure-
President Barack Obama had the good luck (if ment, and process improvements, plus the “softer”
that is the phrase) of implementing the American factor of performance feedback, have a significantly
Efficient and Effective Governance 201

greater impact on improving agency performance of program accomplishments, particularly progress


than do the softer methods of customer service, towards pre-established goals.”99
empowerment, teamwork, training, employee Measuring performance is done by applying
awards, and recognition programs.91 performance measures, which are quantified indi-
cators of program efficiency. Performance measures
The New Local Management City and county are also known as performance indicators, a nod to
administrators were the original engines behind the fact that public and nonprofit performance often
the new public management. It was they who, in cannot be precisely measured, but, at best, merely
the early 1980s, introduced their governments to “indicated.”
Quality Circles, a technique that gathers small Measuring public performance has grown
groups of employees to analyze and solve problems immeasurably as a dominating concern of both the
and which is generally acknowledged to be the basis public and public administrators. Seventy percent
of the new public management. of Americans “favor creating a system of evaluating
Their enthusiasm has not lagged. City man- government agencies by the [objective] results they
agers support “reinvention” by better than nine to produce rather than by the programs they initiate
one.92 “Nearly all” of them “believe that taxpay- or the money they spend,”100 and many of the major
ers should be treated as customers, competition in professional associations of public administrators
service delivery is acceptable, government should have officially endorsed performance measurement.
be mission-driven and entrepreneurial, and non-tax
revenue sources should be developed.”93
Their enthusiasm is also infectious: “City coun- Some Benefits of Performance
cils are very agreeable to proposals to reinvent gov- Measurement
ernment,” adopting 70 percent of eight reforms that Raising the public and independent sectors’ effi-
associate with the new public management when ciency and effectiveness remains the prime potential
they are recommended by their city managers.94 benefit of using performance measures, but there are
Local governments are walking the reinvention other rewards, too.
walk. Collaboration abounds; 55 percent of all city One is higher job satisfaction. More than eight
and county services are delivered, in whole or in part, out of ten federal employees who believe that they
by organizations other than the governments that work in high-performing agencies report that they
are paying for them.95 Customer service is on the are satisfied with their jobs, compared to six out of
forefront; better than seven out of ten municipalities ten government-wide.101
have initiated new programs to improve services.96 Another is the little-known finding that effective
The new public management works remarkably performance measurement systems are interchange-
well in local jurisdictions. Innovative entrepreneuri- able—in other words, administrators, for the most
alism correlates positively with improved local gov- part, do not have to begin with the wheel, but can
ernmental performance.97 When local governments borrow, or easily adapt, systems used in one policy
adopt a “market orientation” in their governing, area and apply it in another, an advantage that brings
“consumer satisfaction” becomes “quite strong,” its own efficiencies. “Performance improvements can
particularly when local officials view themselves as be made by learning from other areas.”102
competing with alternative service providers, such as Performance measurement also can be effective
companies.98 in ridding governments of probably inept politi-
cians and bureaucrats. When a local government’s
published performance scores are among the lowest
MEASURING PUBLIC AND when compared with those of other localities, incum-
bents running for re-election suffer, on average, a 6
NONPROFIT PERFORMANCE percent loss in voter support. (Unfortunately for
A foundation of the public sector’s effort to improve incumbents, high scores do not produce electoral
its efficiency and effectiveness is performance meas- benefits.)103 And, when published performance
urement, or “the ongoing monitoring and reporting scores for core services drop by 10 percent, the
202 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

average turnover rate for local senior managers This lack of comprehension about performance
increases by 3 percent.104 measures reflects the larger fact that, public execu-
Perhaps, however, performance measurement’s tives, like all of us, are victims of bounded ration-
most lasting contribution may be its strengthening ality (discussed in Chapter 4), and this has a very
of government’s legitimacy in society. Performance real impact on how they deal with performance
measurement “is being embraced with equal fervor measures. At least twenty states, for example, are
by conservatives and liberals. Conservatives see it as developing or have performance-based funding of
a way of bringing accountability to government; lib- higher education,108 and public university presi-
erals see it as a way to illustrate that government is dents are much more likely to accept such funding
worth paying for—and may even be worth paying if: the state  legislature is largely Democratic
more for.”105 (Democrats are deemed more supportive of gov-
ernment programs than Republicans); graduation
rates are  high (an indicator common to success-
Some Limitations of Performance ful university performance); the environment in
Measurement which the information on university performance
The limitations of performance measures outnum- is evaluated is  relatively  stable; and the presidents
ber their benefits, which is not to say that they are themselves  hold a conservative political ideology
useless; far from it. But before performance meas- and  believe that performance-based funding is
urement can deliver benefits, its limitations must be desirable.109
understood.
Measuring Is Not Enough A massive and unusu-
Not Everything Can Be Measured Perhaps the ally sophisticated analysis found that merely meas-
gravest limitation of performance measurement is uring program performance tends “to have a small
that quantifying the performance of some public but positive impact on performance in public organ-
and nonprofit programs simply cannot be done. izations,” but when measuring is done by perfor-
Highway safety departments, for instance, with their mance management systems that use best practices,
straightforward mission, have found performance then measuring is “two to three times more effective”
measures to be rewardingly productive, but child in improving organizational performance “than the
welfare programs, with a necessarily more subjec- ‘average’ performance management system.”
tive, judgmental mission, have not. We list best practices for performance measure-
In addition, efficiency is irrelevant for many ment later in the chapter, but if a performance man-
public programs because their concerns are values, agement system (a term that is “as much art as a
rights, or the law. Examples include whose picture science” and for which “there is no single acceptable
will be on the $20 bill and restoring voting rights definition”) contains at least two of the following
to felons. “important elements,” then its greater effectiveness
is relatively assured. These elements are: setting
Not Everyone Gets It Many bureaucrats also just goals and measures; using benchmarking (discussed
don’t get it. A large sampling of federal agencies later) and incentives; using performance infor-
found that, rather than relying on the three stand- mation in strategic planning; using performance
ard performance indicators of inputs, outputs, and evidence in decision making; linking budgets and
outcomes, they instead used an astounding 1,355 subgroup autonomy to the achievement of perfor-
differing (and growing106) “efficiency measures.” mance goals; and publicizing performance targets
Although “about 90 percent” of the agencies had and results.110
developed at least one efficiency measure, 42 percent
of these agencies lacked either an input measure (87
percent of the 42 percent) or an output or outcome Measuring Federal Performance
measure (13 percent). As GAO delicately put it, A “lack of good performance metrics” is a “root
“This could result in measures that do not capture cause” of programs having high financial and
efficiency.”107 other risks in twenty-three federal agencies, and
Efficient and Effective Governance 203

strengthening those metrics is a major means of Perhaps the GPRA Modernization Act’s most
reducing those risks.111 notable new performance requirement is that if an
Strengthening federal performance measure- agency fails to meet its performance targets in three
ment is new. In 1991, not even a tenth of federal years, Congress will consider revising or terminat-
agencies were measuring their performance in ing the programs in question. The legislation also
useable ways.112 In part because the federal gov- mandated more performance reporting, and legis-
ernment “came late to this revolution,”113 the feds’ lated agency-based “chief operating officers” and
ability to measure agency performance ranked “on a “program improvement officers” (PIOs); PIOs now
scale of 10 about at a 2.”114 comprise the membership of the Performance
But Washington displayed an early determina- Improvement Council. As a Senator put it, “This is
tion to raise this ranking. The National Performance the biggest little bill that nobody ever heard of.”120
Review, initiated by the president in 1993, and the In 2014, OMB reported that most of the GPRA
Government Performance and Results Act of 1993 Modernization Act’s goals were met, or that “the
(GPRA, also known as the Results Act) point by agencies achieved notable progress.”121 Agency-
their titles alone to this conclusion. The Results based PIOs concur, with 74 percent giving their
Act, uniquely, marked the first time that Congress agencies a grade of “B” or “A” in rating their “pro-
required measurable program performance, a legal gress in performance management” since the act’s
basis that makes the fading of federal performance passage.122 Most agency officials state that the act
measurement far less likely. has had a positive effect in achieving agency goals
and has improved accountability and efficiency;123
Partial Progress in the Second Millennium By they also report greater use of performance informa-
2004, almost nine out of ten agencies had perfor- tion as they “experience the routines established by
mance measures in place,115 and, by 2007, roughly the Modernization Act.”124
half of agency administrators were using informa- It appears that only Congress is a slacker in
tion obtained from performance measurement to a using performance information, with 53 percent of
“great or very great extent.”116 PIOs saying that Congress uses their agencies’ per-
Nevertheless, even though federal administrators formance information “not at all” or “some” of the
are finding that using performance measurements time.125
is becoming easier over time,117 government-wide
usage of performance information slipped slightly
over six years. Senior executives use such informa- Measuring State Performance
tion (48 percent of the agencies’ performance spe- As with Washington, the state capitals are making
cialists state that their “department’s top leadership significant gains in measuring their performance.
uses performance data to drive decision-making to
a ‘great’ or ‘very great’ extent”118) more than their Measurable State Strides Every state has a per-
non-senior counterparts, a gap that undermines the formance management program, although the
more widespread use of performance information in sophistication and extent of those programs vary
decision making.119 widely, and all states mandate a budget process that
A glimmer of potential relief lies in the presi- demands from agencies data that measure their pro-
dent’s appointment, in 2009, of the federal govern- grams’ outputs.126
ment’s first “chief performance officer,” who reports Over ten years, forty-two states enacted
directly to the president. more than 100 laws that “support the use of
evidence-based programs.” Over three years, twenty-
The Government Performance and Results nine states “reported using cost-benefit studies to
Act Modernization Act In 2010, the president inform policy or budget decisions,” an increase of
signed  into law the Government Performance 48 percent,127 although, over the same period, every
and Results Act Modernization Act (GPRA state produced at least one cost-benefit analysis
Modernization Act), noted in Chapter 2, an act of (twenty-one, apparently, did not inform policy or
some significance. budget decisions).128
204 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

More than seven out of ten department admin- them as “very effective” (only 5 percent say that they
istrators in the states say that the efficiency and are “ineffective”) in improving efficiency.139 Not
effectiveness of their agency has been enhanced even 1 percent of city managers think that the payoff
because of performance measures,129 and the data derived from performance measures is not worth the
support their views: Using performance measures in effort to adopt and use them.140
state agencies correlates positively with improved Those local governments that are most suc-
communication and service quality.130 cessful in using these measures have: a participa-
tive management style; high levels of privatization;
Markers of Measurement Success Those states an emphasis on economic development; a compar-
that establish comprehensive systems for man- atively low reliance on state and federal sources of
aging performance are more likely to: integrate revenue;141 politically conservative elected officials;142
goals throughout their agencies; provide strong extensive civil service reforms;143 and use measures
“strategic guidance”; balance bottom-up and top- government-wide, not just in some bureaus.144
down approaches; and display significantly supe- Unfortunately, local politicians are less inclined
rior accountability and performance in their public to use performance information when they most
administration.131 need to use it—when times are tough. Local “politi-
Somewhat surprisingly, state legislatures that cians who face high fiscal austerity use performance
are peopled by part-time citizen-legislators “are information to a lesser extent than colleagues who
associated with better administrative practices [in] face less fiscal austerity,” preferring instead to avoid
the managerial use of performance measures . . . than blame for cutting programs by questioning the infor-
professional legislatures.”132 A large state population mation’s reliability.145
seems to be the sole variable that associates with the In contrast to state legislators, local citizens are
states’ long-term use of performance measures.133 more trusting and “find basic performance infor-
mation credible even when a local government is
A Time to Trust? State agencies typically self- reporting on itself.”146
report their own performance to their legislatures.
Unfortunately, there is the troubling reality that
legislators often do not trust those reports, and Measuring Nonprofit Performance
they are less trusted by legislators than information In the nonprofit sector, performance measurement
coming from any other source. Other than legisla- remains an “emerging issue” that is relegated “pri-
tors’ own personal experiences with the agency, marily, and almost exclusively, to monitor and assess
outside audits of agency performance are legislators’ the use of funds.” The more significant challenge of
most trusted source of information.134 using performance measures to actually improve
organizational performance receives only “limited
attention.”147
Measuring Local Performance Those relatively few nonprofit organiza-
Performance measures are used by six out of ten tions that use performance measures find that
cities and counties, two-fifths of which use them they pay  dividends. Employing a broad range of
government-wide.135 More populous cities and those performance measures correlates positively with
with a city manager are the most likely to adopt per- more  effective strategic decision making in non-
formance measures.136 Performance measurement profit  organizations.148 Not only does using per-
and management are likelier to be adopted and, cru- formance measures associate with “substantial
cially, stay actively in place if introduced gradually, improvement” in these organizations’ performance,
rather than radically.137 but, “somewhat surprisingly,” independent organ-
From two-thirds to four-fifths of top city admin- izations that used “common performance meas-
istrators cite the improvement of managerial and ures” received “large increases in funding” from
budgetary decisions and the assurance of greater the state legislature.  Those that used measures
accountability as their main reasons for adopting that were unique to them, by contrast, “were cut
performance measures,138 with 38 percent rating dramatically.”149
Efficient and Effective Governance 205

measures usually focus on timeliness, accuracy, and


PERMUTATIONS AND courtesy. Although responsiveness sometimes can
PRACTICES OF PERFORMANCE be objectively measured (for example, the time that
it takes for an ambulance to arrive at an accident),
MEASUREMENT determining whether or not the response is of ade-
Measuring public and nonprofit performance is quate quality is often a subjective judgment. (Does an
complicated, clarifying, and constrained. average arrival time of thirty minutes amount to ade-
quate service quality, or should it be five minutes?)

Measures: The Fundamental Five


Governments use five, generally recognized, kinds The Measurement Mire
of performance measures. All levels of government At least eight issues of performance measurement
employ these indicators, and Washington’s use of have been identified that public administrators
each of them grew at “statistically significant” rates should be cognizant of before they employ them.155
over a decade.150
Measuring the Wrong Thing Imprecision in defin-
Workload, or Output, Measures Workload, or ing what one wants to measure can result in meas-
output, measures simply calculate the amount of uring something else entirely. This happens a lot; 18
work performed. An example is tons of trash col- percent of federal performance improvement officers
lected. The federal, state, and local governments use think that they, themselves, are “measuring the right
output indicators more than any other.151 things to assess progress toward key agency goals”
just some of the time or not at all, and another 40
Unit Cost, or Efficiency, Measures Unit cost, or percent believe that they do so only moderately.156
efficiency, measures assess the monetary expense of Here is an example: In determining how much gov-
a program’s inputs per unit of output. An example is ernment should invest in health, safety, and related
the cost of trash collected per residence. programs, it was decided that government must
Efficiency measures are used least by all govern- know how much a human life was worth, resulting
mental levels.152 This is unfortunate, because using in widely varying determinations, depending on who
efficiency indicators increases the probability that was doing the calculating. But the real question is
governments will use them to improve operational less the worth of a human life and more one of peo-
efficiency; output measures, by contrast, do not have ple’s willingness to pay, through taxes, for their own
this association.153 health, and this determination can be made through
The extent of governments’ use of the remain- analyzing opinion polls or prices in markets where
ing three indicators falls at levels between those of risk is a factor.
workload and efficiency measures.154
Using Meaningless—or Corrupted—Performance
Citizen Satisfaction Measures Citizen satisfaction Data Public and nonprofit administrators often
measures assess the extent to which a jurisdiction’s are constrained in collecting performance data, con-
residents feel that their needs have been met by a straints that can range from the understandable to
program. Often this is done via surveys. the contemptible. Although it cannot be determined
how widespread these practices are, they all result in
Outcome, Impact, or Effectiveness Measures unreliable performance data.
Outcome, impact, or effectiveness measures quantify Put-upon public administrators have been
the extent to which a program’s goals are being met known to “estimate” their performance data simply
and whether the desired effects are being fulfilled. because collecting more accurate information is too
onerous or even impossible, as illustrated by some
Service Quality Measures Service quality measures court house clerks, who, when asked how they col-
are value-based assessments of management’s respon- lected data required for their weekly reports, replied,
siveness to clients’ needs or expectations. These “We put down something that sounds reasonable.”157
206 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Less understandable are performance data that Shifting Costs Instead of Saving Costs Because
result from “signals” by superiors. Consider, for agency programs are often measured in isolation,
example, this: “During my more than 30 years as a program managers can claim that they are saving
cop, I produced and sometimes created crime statis- public funds when in reality they are merely shift-
tics. . .. No official order was ever given to underre- ing costs to other programs. For example, a hospital
port or not report crimes . . . [but the] mayor didn’t allegedly shipped its dying patients to nursing homes
like high crime stats with no arrests.. . . Consequently, shortly before they expired—a practice that not only
it was a bad idea for a rookie to report a robbery shifted costs, but also resulted in splendidly declin-
with no arrests.”158 ing mortality rates for the hospital.161
And then there are those perfectly glowing data
that have been manufactured out of whole cloth, often Disguising Subgroup Differences with Aggregate
with the connivance of top executives. Examples Indicators By concentrating only on “the big
include the falsified records concerning patient wait picture,” performance measures can hide criti-
times in the Veterans Administration  (some veter- cal (and perhaps, embarrassing) information. For
ans died during extended waiting periods), and instance, the Census Bureau has been known to
the public education bureaucrats and teachers in at report an annual rise in all Americans’ incomes (an
least ten major cities who illegally upped their stu- aggregate indicator of good news), but fail to note
dents’ scores on standardized tests. that the rich are getting richer and the poor poorer
Unreliable or dishonest performance data (or subgroup differences that are bad news).162
appear more frequently when: resources are scarce,
demands are extreme, the daily activities of adminis- Ignoring the Limitations of Objective Measures
trators are not closely monitored, and performance Even when properly done, measuring performance
is linked to incentives and sanctions.159 Each of these can take us only so far. For years, the Internal
conditions, but especially the final one, was present Revenue Service (IRS) measured the performance of
in the corruption of veterans’ and students’ data. its agents on the basis of a single indicator: collection
rates. The result was some ruthless agents, dubious
Differing Interpretations of the “Same” Concept practices, anguished taxpayers, and an overhauled,
Different officials sometimes define what they reorganized, and redirected IRS when Congress
want to measure differently, and definitions often responded to rising public anger in 1998 by passing
have an impact on agency fortunes for good or the IRS Restructuring and Reform Act.
ill. If an agency “client,” for example, is defined as
someone who occasionally phones in, then the agen- Failing to Address How and Why Questions When
cy’s client-based budget is likelier to expand, but if performance measures are used in isolation, and
“client” is defined more narrowly (and more accu- do not consider relevant how-and-why questions,
rately) as someone who regularly receives services, such as poor management or over-funding, they can
then its budget could contract. be useless or even counterproductive. What if, for
instance, the sole employer in a town closed down?
Displacing Goals “In Poland under communism, Performance measures of the town’s employment
the performance of furniture factories was meas- agency would tell us only that the agency was failing
ured in the tonnes of furniture shipped. As a result, to find jobs for unemployed townspeople. They
Poland now has the heaviest furniture on the would not tell us, however, that there were no jobs
planet.”160 Weight displaced furniture as Poland’s in town.
furniture-production goal because of the perfor-
mance measure used. However, had the Polish com-
munists instead stipulated free-standing items of Benchmarking Performance: From
furniture, rather than tonnage, as their measure of Measurement to Comparison
performance, Poland might now have the lightest— Benchmarking is the comparison of a program’s
and the tiniest—furniture on the planet. measurement data with data generated by exter-
nal, comparable programs. Governments that use
Efficient and Effective Governance 207

performance indicators typically track them over costs,171 and its use enhances the probability that
time to determine whether performance is going performance measures will influence governmental
up or down. Benchmarking, however, does this and operations.172
more. It asks: Are we doing this particular job as But there are problems. One is the all-too-
well as, or better or worse than, other organizations human resistance to criticism, which can adversely
like ours in similar circumstances? affect benchmarking’s use. “Empirical research
shows that [some agencies] may ignore information
Benchmarking’s Spread Information technology (including benchmark information) that indicates
is making benchmarking’s adoption easier,163 but its that their relative performance is poor.”173
spread is uneven. Benchmarking also remains difficult to imple-
In the mid-1990s, the federal government ment, and perhaps the major impediment is that gov-
founded a couple of benchmarking groups that ernments, particularly local ones, often define terms
soon expired. Federal benchmarking was resur- differently from one another. A study of seven big
rected in 2013, when a cross-agency Benchmark cities across the globe, for example, found that just
and Improve Mission-Support Operations group six of some 1,200 performance indicators had been
was established to improve efficiency via bench- applied in precisely the same way.174 And, unless
marking, and, in  2014, OMB established a cross- comparisons are precise, benchmarks are usually
agency Benchmark and Improve Mission-Support useless.
Operations, “the first-of-its-kind benchmarking Nonprofit organizations are, admirably, taking
effort” at the twenty-four major agencies, involving it upon themselves to rectify this lack of a “common
150 organizations and forty measures that meas- language” in local benchmarking. In 2013, the
ured performance in areas ranging from human International Organization for Standardization
capital to contracting.164 released “ISO 37120,” its eminently forgettable
Almost three-fourths of state agencies compare moniker for forty-six benchmarks of municipal
their agencies’ performance data with data from success that can be applied worldwide. Similarly,
other government agencies, at least sometimes;165 in 2014 the American Productivity and Quality
a half-dozen states have actually enacted legisla- Center introduced its “City Government Process
tion that specifically requires their governments to Classification Framework,” which seems to have at
benchmark.166 least diminished the phenomenon of “people debat-
Seventy percent of cities compare their perfor- ing about what services the city is offering.”175
mance with similar programs conducted by other
governments or businesses “usually” (19 percent)
or “sometimes” (51 percent),167 and 31 percent of Accounting for Public Performance
cities and counties cooperatively coordinate formal In 1972, largely as a result of interest displayed
benchmarking systems.168 by GAO, the nonprofit Financial Accounting
The independent sector uses benchmarking to Foundation (FAF) was chartered with the mission
track and compare annual online giving.169 of improving public financial accountability. FAF
oversees two other independent organizations. The
Benchmarking’s Benefits and Limitations Bench- Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) was
marking may be as close as the public and nonprofit created in 1973 with a charge of improving federal
sectors can get to an equivalent of competition in accounting, and, in 1993, its mission was expanded
the free market, and this could result in greater to include nonprofit accounting. In 1984, the
efficiency. An unusually thorough study of per- Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB)
formance management concluded that “bench- was founded with a similar charge, but aimed at
marking, in particular, appears to be an effective state and local governments. When New York
method  for  learning who is performing well.”170 City nearly defaulted, in 1975, the state legislature
Public administrators report that benchmarking required that the city use accounting principles that
provides some “substantial benefits,” notably the GASB embraced when it was founded nine years
identification of unusually high programmatic later (in 2005, New York placed these principles in
208 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

its new city charter); the city has not neared bank- contain “a relatively small number”—from thirty
ruptcy since. to forty—of measures when compared not only
FASB has promoted GAO’s use of performance with those nations’ performance reports (more
audits, which are examinations of public and non- than a hundred measures flood each of Australia’s
profit programs that are designed to determine reports).182 A limited number of measures often is a
their efficiency and effectiveness. Similarly, from sure sign of high-quality reporting, in no small part
its origins, GASB has moved “beyond the realm because it increases the likelihood that the report
of monetary accounting . . . and into the realm of will be read and acted upon.
performance measurement.”176 In 1999, it issued its
innocuously titled, “Statement 34,” which calls for Grass-Roots’ Performance Reporting Studies of
comprehensive “performance reporting” by state performance reports issued by state agencies and
and local governments. Statement 34 quickly united city governments find low overall quality (although
most of the major associations of grass-roots gov- cities exhibited “substantial progress made in quality
ernments in opposition to GASB (the Government and quantity over the past 10 years”), with only 1
Finance Officers Association terminated its signif- percent of state reports rated as high quality;183 local
icant financial support of GASB and called for its reports’ quality was “virtually identical with our
dissolution), resulting in a “new and higher level study of state agencies.”184
of strain in the already-tense relationship between State and local governments’ performance
GASB and state and local officials.”177 reports often swamp their readers with measures.
Why are subnational governments so threat- A state case in point is Oregon, which ended up
ened? Because the ratings of municipal bonds, which with 259 state-wide measures (plus hundreds of
all state and local governments issue, are determined agency and local ones) during the 1990s, including
by outside accountants; bond ratings, in turn, deter- numeric targets for traveling in cities and entertain-
mine the cost to governments of borrowing money; ing foreign visitors. A state official conceded that
and the cost of borrowing money significantly Oregon’s performance measures were “a little out
determines the cost of governing. Thanks to GSAB, of control.”185
“management performance” now looms large in the “Many city and county governments use
determination of municipal bond credit ratings.178 between 150 and 1500 indicators,”186 and there may
Today, all the states audit performance,179 as be, on average, more than thirty performance meas-
do at least 70 percent of large American cities.180 ures for each municipal service.187
These audits are taken seriously. An analysis of
3,788 potentially embarrassing performance audits
conducted in federal, state, and local agencies found Pruning the Plethora of Performance
that only twenty-six were ignored by managers.181 Measures
When it comes to measuring governmental per- Using too many measures to assess agency perfor-
formance, never underestimate those quiet power- mance is counterproductive because doing so “is
houses who sport green eyeshades. daunting for most officials and for the public.”188
Fortunately, a pair of closely interrelated develop-
ments is rendering both statistics and the measures
Reporting Performance that they underlie more useable to administrators.
Central to measuring performance is reporting it so They are PerformanceStat and dashboards.
that citizens and decision makers can use it to save
taxpayers’ dollars. PerformanceStat PerformanceStat is a catch-
all phrase that encompasses a variety of statistical
Washington Measures Up “The United States programs intended to fulfill specific performance
stands out” in the high quality of federal perfor- objectives by using pertinent current data that are
mance reports. The quality of federal performance regularly shared, coordinated, and rapidly followed
reporting not only surpasses that of Australia, up by decision makers. Most of the PerformanceStat
Canada, and Ireland, but Washington’s reports also action is occurring at the local level.
Efficient and Effective Governance 209

PerformanceStat’s origins can be traced to amounting to $8.7 billion, “were in need of manage-
the New York Police Department’s CompStat ment attention.”194
(for Comparative Statistics), initiated in 1994 and The best dashboards are simple, such as
designed to reduce serious crime via weekly analyses FEMA’s “Waffle House matrix.” Waffle House res-
of crime statistics in each of its precincts; the city’s taurants never close, but, should they do so during
murder rate dropped by two-thirds in just five years. an emergency, then FEMA instantly knows that it
In 2000, Baltimore expanded CompStat to CitiStat, has a more serious problem than is normal in the
including not only law enforcement, but other areas community.195
as well, and in only two years almost halved the Achieving dashboard simplicity, however, is far
blood lead levels in children.189 Nearly two dozen from simple. In contrast to the well-received efforts
cities are copying Baltimore’s success190 (although to develop a common “language” for local govern-
28 percent of cities and counties, mostly large ones, ments’ use in benchmarking, discussed earlier, KPIs
use undefined “stat systems”191); examples include founder in a “quagmire” of well-meaning (and often
CincyStat, which tracks eighteen municipal depart- profitable) lists that offer from twenty-five to some
ments in Cincinnati, and BlightStat, which focuses 17,000 “key” indicators that are so generic (“the
on urban decay in New Orleans. problem with generic performance measures—
In 2007, Maryland, inspired by Baltimore’s indeed, the problem with generic anything—is
success, adopted StateStat, the first state-wide that. . .. they can lull a manager into a nonthinking
PerformanceStat. A “handful of states” are following [yet self-congratulatory] complacency”) that wading
Maryland’s lead.192 through those lists to find a few KPIs that might be
“Some federal agencies” began, in the early 2010s, useful to one’s own particular program is likely not
to adopt their own versions of PerformanceStat,193 worth the time.196
such as the Federal Emergency Management Agency Federal interest in developing dashboards
(FEMA), which created FEMAStat to improve its began with the Reports Consolidation Act of 2000,
crisis response. In 2015, OMB introduced FedStat which was enacted to “force agencies to build self-
(not to be confused with FedStat.gov, a portal that discipline” in performance reporting, and which led
the public can access for federal statistics) for the to improving their transparency and accountabil-
whole of government, in an effort comply with the ity.197 In 2010, the Patient Protection and Affordable
GPRA Modernization Act. Care Act set up the Commission on Key National
Indicators, charged with implementing such a
From Data to Dashboards Strategic measure- system.
ment, key management systems, total organiza- The basis of the yet-to-be-developed government-
tional performance systems, or outcome-oriented wide federal dashboard is more than seventy agen-
performance management systems, all refer to the cies that currently collect statistics about their pro-
winnowing and simplifying of performance meas- grams (more than fifty laws enacted since 1993
ures and integrating them with large-scale goals. legislate unique performance measures for individ-
This winnowing has brought us key performance ual programs!198), each of which “was established
indicators (KPIs), also called key results measures, separately in response to different needs,” but,
or those measures that are central in attaining stra- together, amount to a “federal statistical system”
tegic goals. These indicators often are presented that is coordinated by ten “principal federal statis-
in the form of dashboards, which clearly and suc- tical agencies.”199
cinctly summarize progress, or the lack thereof, in An impressive 47 percent of cities and counties
achieving those goals. Increasingly, dashboards are link performance measures to goals stated in their
replacing inevitably-dated annual reports as records strategic plans and regularly review their progress,
of performance. and 17 percent use a dashboard-like “balanced
Dashboards also can save money. OMB created scorecard” of measures.200 Boston is developing
an information technology (IT) dashboard, in “CityScore,” which aims to “summarize dozens of
2009, to rate federal IT investments. OMB later measures” into a single daily number on how well,
discovered that 24 percent of all 738 investments, or badly, the city is performing.201
210 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Two Measured Notes of Measurement Hope Lessons Learned about Measures


Two phenomena appear to bode well for the future ■ Be realistic about the political and
of performance measurement. organizational context in which the measures
will be used—or not be used.
A Tipping Point? One is that, for at least a couple ■ Align agency-wide measures with agency-wide
of reasons, we appear to have reached a tipping goals.
point in our ability to use performance measures in ■ Always test measures in advance.
practical and productive ways. ■ Keep the number of measures used to the
First, the unrelenting fiscal squeeze on govern- barest minimum.
ments and third-sector organizations has promoted ■ Wherever possible, include quantifiable
more cost-effective programs, and performance meas- outcome measures but assure that they
ures are critical in determining cost-effectiveness. are pertinent to the program’s mission and
Second, as a result of “better technology” and “a recognize that the broader the phenomenon
growing body of research” compiled by “multiple being measured, the less control that the agency
clearinghouses” over some twenty years, in tandem will have over outcomes.
with “easier access” to that research and other data, ■ Use benchmark measures and recognize
administrators are at last able “to more accurately and grade unit performance as it pertains to
measure the performance and cost-effectiveness” of benchmarking.
their services.202 These trends seem likely to intensify ■ Ensure that executive and legislative staffers
over time. agree on what key performance indicators will
appear in budget documents “that legislators
Easily Assessing Public and Nonprofit will see.”204
Competence The second reason has long been ■ When it comes to performance measures, trust
with us, but overlooked. Although, throughout this but always verify.
chapter, we have bemoaned the many difficulties
inherent in assessing the performance of public and
nonprofit organizations, there is a simple way to Lessons Learned about Process
judge at least their general operational competence, ■ Identify the organization’s key failure—its most
and about which surprisingly little is written. consequential performance deficit.
When public and nonprofit organizations take ■ Assure the presence of the five internationally
an exceedingly long time to respond to requests, recognized standards for high-quality
both internal and external, for decisions, or never performance management, i.e., performance
respond, and when upper management demands goals that are specific, measurable, relevant,
responses and reports from subordinates with achievable, and which have sensible deadlines
exceedingly brief deadlines, then one can be assured attached.205
that the organization is incompetently managed. ■ Set a specific, and, if possible, quantifiable,
Incompetent management, of course, strongly performance target. This is particularly
implies poor performance. important. “The extent of performance
How is your organization doing? improvement is influenced positively by
the presence of a target,”206 and there is
“no evidence of any of the dysfunctional
LESSONS LEARNED: MINIMIZING effects” of performance targets, such as
THE PITFALLS OF PERFORMANCE managers ignoring untargeted programs, “that
have been hypothesized” in the literature.207
MEASUREMENT “Goal clarity” associates positively
In sum, here is what we have learned about success- with “more extensive results-oriented
fully measuring public and nonprofit performance, reform efforts” and stakeholders’ commitment
and using those measures to improve performance:203 to the agency.208
Efficient and Effective Governance 211

■ Improve the usefulness of performance the quality of performance data, and link the
information by assuring that the information is data with the organization’s strategic goals.
readily accessible, easily understood, and that ■ Recognize that running a successful
managers can and do use it to make decisions. measurement program does not require a
■ Link budgets and/or organizational autonomy large staff, but that selecting enthusiastic and
to the achievement of performance goals. adaptable people to manage it is essential.
■ Use performance information in strategic ■ Use personal incentives, including monetary
planning. rewards, to achieve performance goals.
■ Be timely. Public administrators are finding ■ Be sensitive to the needs of frontline
“performance-tracking software,” which supervisors because, according to some 1,500
integrates budgetary and performance data, studies, “the most effective way to improve
to be extremely useful in this regard, causing organizational performance is to improve first-
some governments to abandon annual, and level supervisors.”212
inevitably dated, management reports, “long ■ Assure that top leadership demonstrates
considered akin to the Bible among public- its commitment and allocates resources to
sector managers.”209 achieving results.
■ Review, revise, and update measures frequently. ■ Anticipate the emergence of transformational
■ Check for distortions by ensuring that the leaders. “In direct contradiction with
mission is actually being accomplished. expectations,” a public organization’s
■ Communicate clearly. Present plainly. Organize use of performance measures positively
data around desired outcomes. Show not only associates “with significant increases
percentages of targets met, but trends as well. in a chief administrative officer’s use of
Assure that the public can easily access and transformational leadership behaviors.”213
understand performance information. Who knew?
■ Learn to make modifications in order to ratchet
up performance again.
■ To assure that performance EVALUATING PUBLIC AND
measurement continues, secure its own
home in the bureaucracy; get it on the NONPROFIT PROGRAMS
organization chart. Program evaluation is our second pillar of govern-
mental and nonprofit productivity.

Lessons Learned about People


■ Do not introduce performance measurement Public and Nonprofit Program Evaluation:
unless vital political support is guaranteed. Purposes and Paranoia
■ Align views of senior administrators about Public and nonprofit program evaluation, or evalu-
agency productivity with those of elected ation research, is the “individual systematic studies
politicians, as this “is associated with better conducted periodically or on an ad hoc basis to
organizational performance.”210 assess how well a program is working.”214
■ Actively involve stakeholders. Including in Program evaluation differs from performance
the process not only agency personnel, but measurement on two dimensions: focus and use.
also “external professionals,” especially those Performance measurement focuses on whether a
in the central budget office, “improves the program has achieved its measurable goals, whereas
perception of measurement quality” among a program evaluation examines a greater range of
stakeholders, notably legislators and agency information in a larger context.
employees.211 In terms of use, performance measurement is
■ Train personnel to use performance used mostly as an early warning system to manag-
information to make decisions, set performance ers should a program falter, and as a method for
goals, develop performance measures, assess improving accountability to the public; a program
212 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

evaluation, by contrast, is a deeper inquiry into a Program and Problem Monitoring Program and
program’s performance and context, and seeks to problem monitoring tracks how relevant issues
develop a comprehensive assessment of how it might and methods of service delivery may be changing,
be improved. and whether the program remains in legal com-
Although a program evaluation can be threat- pliance.  Its unique value is that it enables admin-
ening, especially to those who manage the program istrators to follow the evolution of problems
being evaluated, its threat can be overstated. Not and the  program’s effect on them over time. An
even 1 percent of the evaluations of some 600 example is the GAO’s study of the Comprehensive
municipal programs “led to termination of the eval- Employment and Training Act, which tracked
uated activities,” but 78 percent of these evalua- changing program costs, characteristics of the par-
tions “led to adjustments of program activities.”215 ticipants, and its effectiveness in placing partici-
Despite the aura of paranoia that sometimes seems pants in jobs.221
to suffuse program evaluation, it draws far short of
a slash-and-burn attack on public or nonprofit man- Process, or Implementation, Evaluations The
agement; it can result, however, in improving pro- process, or implementation, evaluation assesses the
grammatic productivity. extent to which a program is operating as intended.
It can be very helpful in determining the effects of
a program on its clientele group, and, when used
Permutations of Public and Nonprofit in tandem with an effectiveness evaluation (dis-
Program Evaluation cussed next), in answering questions of accountabil-
A diversity of forms of program evaluation has ity. Examples are those studies that focus on how
flourished, and the many overlapping categories of innovations in the public sector are circulated and
program evaluations likely exceed 100.216 For our become routine among governments.222
purposes, we have reduced the major taxonomies to
six types,217 and they comprise its “everyday reper- Effectiveness, Outcome, or Impact Evaluations An
toire,” representing “widespread agreement in the effectiveness, outcome, or impact evaluation assesses
field with regard to common practice in program the extent to which a program achieves its objec-
evaluation.”218 They are not particularly neat cate- tives and identifies unintended outcomes. An
gories, and we present them, roughly, in the order important aspect of these evaluations is that of esti-
that they are appropriate to use as the program is mating whether a program’s outcomes would have
conducted over time. occurred anyway—that is, without the program.
“This, of course, is the quintessential accountability
Front-End Analyses A front-end analysis is a question.”223
program evaluation that estimates how feasible a A well-known effectiveness evaluation is the
proposed new program might be and its possible Kansas City Police Department’s study about the
effects. An example is the GAO’s study of teenage effectiveness of police patrols in preventing crime. It
pregnancy that was provided to Congress before found that there were no statistically significant dif-
legislation was introduced proposing service pro- ferences in crime rates, citizen attitudes, the reported
grams for pregnant teenagers.219 number of crimes, citizen behavior, or even in the
rate of traffic accidents among areas where: no
Evaluability Assessments An evaluability assess- police patrols were sent out, and police responded
ment judges the reasonableness of the original only to specific calls for help; patrols were main-
assumptions justifying a program. Usually conducted tained at previous levels; and patrols were doubled
early in the course of a program’s unfolding and or tripled in size.224
focusing on its implementation and management, it
determines whether a later and fuller evaluation is Meta-Evaluations, or Evaluation Syntheses A
worth undertaking. An example is the assessment of meta-evaluation, or an evaluation synthesis, which
whether the federal Senior Executive Service has met is the most comprehensive, retrospective, and flex-
its goals.220 ible type of evaluation, re-analyzes findings from
Efficient and Effective Governance 213

previous evaluations to find out what has been An examination of twenty-two “high priority”
learned about a public program. An example is regulations (which, as we discussed in Chapter 4, can
GAO’s study of drinking-age laws and their effects amount to vital public policies) proposed in 2014,
on highway safety.225 each of which would have an economic impact of
at least $100 million annually, found that the most
basic tenets of performance assessment were largely
Evaluating Federal Programs ignored. Thirty-six percent of the proposed rules
With performance measurement gaining federal failed to even state the problem that the rule was
ground, program evaluation soon followed. meant to address (even though Executive Order
“Over a third” of federal agency officials use 12866 of 1994 had mandated, twenty years earlier,
evaluations to a “moderate or greater extent” to that the problem must be identified), and, in many
support changes in budgets, policy, or program cases where the problem was stated, “it was not
management.226 The benefits of their use are sub- related to the rules the agency proposed”; 64 percent
stantial. Four-fifths of those federal managers who did not include any quantitative means to evaluate
were involved in program evaluations stated that the the rules’ success; 77 percent failed to even sketch
evaluations improved program management or per- how administrators intended to collect performance
formance and the assessment of its effectiveness or data; and none contained a plan or time frame for
value. Two-thirds thought that the evaluation con- reviewing the regulations’ success or failure.230
tributed “to allocating resources within a program,” Once a program is functioning, evaluating it can
and more than three-fifths said that it streamlined be a hit or miss affair. Just 37 percent of federal man-
the program.227 agers report that “an evaluation has been completed
within the past 5 years of any program . . . they were
Congress Gets With the Program A singular involved in,” and 40 percent did not even know if
development in this regard was the Government an evaluation had been completed.231 “About a
Performance and Results Act of 1993, noted earlier, quarter” of these respondents “were not familiar
which launched the first comprehensive effort to with their agencies’ various [program evaluation]
evaluate federal productivity. Eleven additional, capacity-building activities.”232
interacting laws (the most significant of which is the Just a fourth of the twenty-four major agencies
Chief Financial Officers Act of 1990, which is “the have “a stable source of funding” for evaluation,233
most comprehensive financial management reform a weakness that would appear to be easily recti-
legislation in 40 years,” resulting in “a clear cultural fied: based on the “rough calculations” of biparti-
change”228), enacted from 1978 to 1996, address san experts in federal management, “less than $1
financial and information management. When exe- out of every $100 of [federal] government spending
cuted in tandem with the GPRA (and, of course, the is backed by even the most basic evidence that the
GPRA Modernization Act as well), they “provide money is being spent wisely.”234
a powerful framework” for attaining stronger
“results-oriented management,” largely through
program evaluation.229 A monumentally impor- Evaluating State and Local Programs
tant product of these statutes debuted in 1998: the The grass-roots governments have made significant
federal government’s first-ever (!) government-wide gains in evaluating their programs.
audited financial statements. All states use some method of managing for
results,235 and budget offices in forty-five states
The Bureaucracy Struggles Despite this impres- conduct program evaluations.236 The proportion of
sive legal foundation, federal program evaluation states in which most major agencies conduct pro-
has some way to travel. The journey begins well ductivity analyses more than doubled over three
before an evaluation is undertaken, and here federal decades, from a fifth to more than half.237
administrators again have problems that reflect their Performance evaluations can lead states to
confusion, noted earlier, about what a performance engage in evidence-based policymaking, which is
measure even is. “the systematic use of program evaluations and
214 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

outcome analyses (‘evidence’) to guide govern- of the Office of the Special Inspector General for Iraq
ment policy and funding decisions.” Five states— Reconstruction. Created by Congress in 2003, the
Connecticut, Minnesota, Oregon, Utah, and office ultimately exposed corruption that resulted
Washington—are the leaders in this field; eleven in ninety convictions and 245 serious disciplinary
states practice evidence-based policymaking more actions.241 A politically-embarrassed Congress and
than most; twenty-seven states and the District of a conniving White House secretly terminated it, in
Columbia “demonstrate modest engagement”; and 2006, after it uncovered billions of dollars lost to mis-
seven states “are trailing.”238 management and theft; only after the press exposed
Three-quarters of cities long have been using these machinations was the office reinstated.
program evaluations, a level that experts generally In part because of this sorry episode, Congress
believe to be the maximum that is reasonably possi- passed, in 2008, the Inspector General Reform Act,
ble for the adoption of any innovative technique of which enhanced IGs’ training; made it more difficult
public management. Thirty-six percent of municipal to remove or transfer IGs, among other adjustments
administrators rate them as “very effective” in man- that enhanced their independence; and charged them
aging and decision making.239 with addressing “integrity, economy, and effective-
ness issues that transcend individual Government
agencies.”
Uniquely Governmental: The Even with this legislation, however, some agen-
Inspector General cies resist cooperating with their own IGs, and
We noted earlier that, in 1978, Congress passed some IGs have been heavily politicized by the White
the Inspector General Act, which has had lasting House (in 1981, President Ronald Reagan asked for
and ongoing ramifications for federal productivity. the resignations of all IGs) and Congress, such as
But IGs are not limited to federal agencies; they are the temporary IG who improperly tampered with
found at all governmental levels. reports in an effort to land a permanent appoint-
Inspectors general are public administrators ment. When IGs are confirmed by the Senate (these
who are charged with evaluating government pro- IGs “tend to be the closest to the president and are
grams; improving agency performance; exposing among the most political”), which has the power
waste, fraud, and abuse; and helping administrators to decide in which agencies IGs should be Senate-
eliminate these problems. confirmed, there is “the strongest negative effect” on
the recovery of wasted funds, and agencies with the
IGs: The Federal Experience Uniquely, IGs report highest number of political IGs “see the most drastic
directly to the heads of agencies to which they are decrease” in their effectiveness.242
assigned and to Congress. In the larger agencies, IGs Federal IGs also must deal with declining
are appointed by the president and confirmed by resources and bureaucratic frustrations. Forty-
the Senate (in smaller agencies they are appointed five percent of IGs report that their staffing levels
by agency heads with no Senate confirmation), and, had declined over three years; 19 percent state that
again uniquely, the presidentially-appointed IGs turnover had increased over the past year, and just
may communicate directly to Congress without the 7 percent say that turnover had decreased; and 43
permission of OMB. percent report that the hiring process was “lengthy
IGs are now emplaced in seventy-two federal and results in delays,” and an additional 18 percent
bureaus, employ more than 14,000 professionals, maintain that “significant re-engineering of the
and save the government nearly $47 billion annu- process is needed.”243 In fact, the time that it takes
ally via audit recommendations and recoveries, an to hire IGs themselves has more than doubled from
amount that increases each year. For every dollar the Reagan administration’s average of 224 days to
invested in inspectors general, the government saves the Obama administration’s average of 613 days.244
eighteen.240 IGs are not perfect, and they sometimes appear
Despite this commendable record, political to relish the role of a “gotcha gang” in unearth-
backing for the IGs ranges from indifference to out- ing administrative inefficiencies, such as the IG
right hostility, as evidenced by politicians’ treatment who was quoted in the Washington Post as stating
Efficient and Effective Governance 215

(he denied it) that his own agency had “a crime rate if less tempting than eating dessert, usually results in
higher than downtown Detroit.”245 Regrettably, there a healthier diner.
remains only a tepid propensity of IGs to work with Central to a nonprofit program’s health, and
line managers in writing their final recommendations, to the fiscal health of the nonprofit organization
and there is no measurable increase in their inclina- itself, is the selection of its evaluator. When non-
tion to do so over time.246 Which may explain why profits tout their own program’s efficiency, the more
there are 15,222 IG recommendations that remain “efficient appearing” ones fare “no better over time
unimplemented by the agencies, foregoing more than than less efficient appearing organizations” in terms
$87 billion in potential savings, and why 11 percent of donations.252 When, however, a respected exter-
of all IG offices complain of “obstruction tactics” used nal evaluator gives an organization top marks for
by their agencies to deny them agency documents.247 its cost-effectiveness, then contributions can soar
Congress tried to deal with this latter issue by as much as 30 percent higher than those with the
passing the Inspector General Empowerment Act of lowest scores. “Meeting one extra standard [of best
2016, which assures IGs full and prompt access to governance and management practices] is associated
agency records. with an increase in public support of more than 7
Even with these difficulties, however, and in light percent.”253
of the immense savings attributable to inspectors Similarly, when a prestigious external evaluator
general, “It is safe to say,” testified the Comptroller gives a nonprofit organization a “pass” rating for its
General of the United States, “that the federal gov- accountability, it rakes in “statistically significant”
ernment is a lot better off today because of the IGs’ more donations, but a “did not pass” assessment has
efforts.”248 a “nonsignificant” impact.254
Donors, in short, give to causes that they like,
The Relatively Well-Supported State IGs and regardless of the competency (and, perhaps, honesty)
Auditors Fourteen states and the District of with which those causes are managed. Donors,
Columbia have inspectors general,249 although all however, give quite a bit more to well-managed—
states have state auditors, their rough equivalents. and well-evaluated—causes.
When compared with their federal counterparts,
state IGs and auditors are reasonably well supported.
Twenty-one percent of state IGs and audi- PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT
tors reported that the number of their staffers PROGRAM EVALUATION
had declined, or a third fewer than what federal
IGs reported, and 26 percent said that staff levels IN PRACTICE
had increased, a positive difference of nearly two- Practicing program evaluation can be reduced to
fifths with federal IGs (of whom only 16 percent four fundamental steps: selecting, defining, design-
reported increases). Just 9 percent of state IGs and ing, and implementing.
auditors said that turnover had climbed, or almost
three-fourths lower than that of federal IGs. Just
18 percent of state IGs and auditors had problems Selecting Evaluators: Inside
with their state’s hiring process, a rate that is three- or Outside Jobs?
fifths lower than that of their federal counterparts, Program evaluators can be drawn from employees
and a notable 73 percent felt that their state’s hiring inside the agency or nonprofit running the program,
process was “timely,” a proportion that was more or consultants hired from outside of it, but, irre-
than three times that of federal IGs, at 22 percent.250 spective of whether evaluators are insiders or out-
siders, only a program’s top executives should select
them; doing so relaxes, at least to some degree, the
Evaluating Nonprofit, Public-Serving natural tensions that exist between managers and
Programs evaluators.255
“Program evaluation is the ‘eat your vegetables’ of Inside evaluators often have a more thorough
the nonprofit sector,”251 but eating one’s vegetables, knowledge of the organization than outsiders, and
216 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

are in a better position to conduct the evaluation Critical to defining the problem is, oddly, defin-
over a longer period of time. ing success. That is, how do we know, and when
Outsiders are likelier to examine the program do we know, that our program is successful? When
more intensively and objectively than inside evalu- program managers have clear understandings of
ators. Regrettably, outside evaluators are also more what programmatic success means, they can upgrade
likely to engage in kerfuffles with program managers their definition of success, and their productivity,
because they are principally interested in long-term, over time.260
occasionally wholesale, change; are more accept-
ing of disruptions; and sometimes question the Is Evaluating the Program Worthwhile? Once
basic premises of the organization itself. Outsiders the organization’s problem is defined, then another
also have been known to flaunt their findings (and question arises: Is the program worth the expense
their own self-assessed intelligence), and managers and energy involved in evaluating it?
to cover up failures—a less than stellar combina- To answer this, five questions must be addressed:
tion for a useable evaluation.256 Ironically, however,
because “people use paid advice significantly more ■ Validity. How much confidence can
than free advice,”257 managers may be more inclined administrators have in the evaluation’s findings
to accept the evaluations of paid outsiders than of and conclusions?
“free” insiders. ■ Relevance. Will its results be useful?
The U.S. Department of Labor has organized ■ Significance. Will the research provide the
its program evaluations in a manner that exploits program’s administrators with substantially
the benefits of both internal and external evaluators more insights than they can glean from their
by establishing not only a central evaluation office, own observations?
but evaluation offices in each of its bureaus as well. ■ Efficiency. Will the value of the research exceed
Its evaluators are “internal” to the department, but its cost?
“external” to the programs being evaluated, an ■ Timeliness. Will the study be completed in time
arrangement that has changed “a static organiza- to meet organizational schedules?
tional culture into one that integrates performance If the responses to these questions are affirmative,
management, evaluation- and innovation-based then the evaluation is worth undertaking.
processes.”258

Designing the Evaluation


What Is Your Problem?
In designing a program evaluation “there is often
The best program evaluations are the products of
a tradeoff between the breadth of a study and the
detailed definitions and careful consideration.
precision of results,” a tradeoff that does not plague
basic research.261 With breadth comes fuzziness, and
Defining the Problem All the evaluation’s par-
with precision, narrowness.
ticipants, from evaluators to decision makers,
must fully comprehend the program’s history,
The Study Plan Preparing a detailed study
goals, and why it is being evaluated—that is, what
plan is  the initial step in designing an evalua-
is the  problem to address. Attaining this systemic
tion. A  study  plan should include the following
understanding requires writing a list of the intended
components:
benefits  (including qualitative ones) of the evalu-
ation; who will receive those benefits, or possible ■ A clear statement of the problem.
unintended benefits or adverse consequences; and ■ The objectives of the research.
those goals that may be in conflict with, or sup- ■ A careful listing of the assumptions and
portive of, one another. “The importance of taking constraints to be used in addressing the
such a comprehensive view of objectives [and problem.
avoiding “oversimplified statements”] cannot be ■ The resources to be committed.
overstated.”259 ■ The methods to be employed.
Efficient and Effective Governance 217

■ Measures of the evaluation’s attainment of its


objectives. Implementing Evaluations
■ Lines of communication. Once designed, the evaluation can be conducted, a
■ Specific procedures for amending the study phase that has its own difficulties.
plan.
■ A schedule for completing major components Darkling Desires One such difficulty is that of
of the evaluation, including a final deadline. evaluators’ hidden motives. Evaluators may wish
■ Specific procedures for using the results of the to make a program look better than it actually is—
evaluation. inside evaluators for political reasons internal to the
organization conducting the program, and outside
Comparing Groups When designing an effective- evaluators as a means of enhancing their chances
ness evaluation, which arguably is the most reveal- for lucrative follow-up contracts. In human services
ing and useful type, evaluators often must create programs, for example, consultants conducting an
a control group, composed of clients who are evaluation “will want to sign up only those clients
excluded from receiving the benefits of a program, who seem to have the greatest chance of success, not
and an experimental group, or clients who receive those with deeper and more intractable problems.
its benefits. Doing so is their main, if not exclu- The process is known as ‘creaming.’”264
sive, method of assessing a program’s effectiveness,
and this is especially true for human services pro- Competent and Incompetent Evaluators All pro-
grams, among others. Yet, as a practical matter, “it fessions host members who are skilled and less
is difficult to refuse service to those who seek it and skilled, and program evaluation is no exception.
provide service to those who resist it.”262 If, however, Among evaluators, the entrepreneur has excellent
evaluators succumb to these pressures, the evalua- analytical and political skills, and is the most adroit
tion will be ruined. at resolving programmatic issues; the politician is tal-
ented politically, but less so intellectually; the techni-
Privacy, Confidentiality, and Informed Consent Let cian is solid analytically, but, politically, not so much;
us add one more piquancy to this stew: Lawyers and the pretender is a phony on both counts.265
have questioned the legality of evaluators randomly Evaluators also have been typed as strategiz-
assigning participants to control groups and exper- ers, who work effectively with program managers
imental groups.263 To fend off potential lawsuits, as as management consultants; academics, who rarely
well as for ethical reasons, it is critical that evalua- even see managers (often, they dreamily “speculate,”
tors understand the notions of privacy, confidential- endlessly and unproductively, on evaluation’s role
ity, and informed consent, and that they incorporate in “democracy and efficiency,” or never progress
them into the evaluation’s design. beyond “developing hypotheses, defining terms”266);
Privacy refers to the state of the person, and thus and paternalistic, condescending clinicians, who
is a matter between the evaluator and the respond- treat managers as if they were diseased and they, the
ent. If the respondent freely answers the evaluator’s clinicians, have the cure.267
questions, then privacy is protected, but if the ques- One gets the idea. Program evaluators can range
tions are deemed by the respondent to be embarrass- from the intelligent and able, to the brainless and
ing or prying, then it is not. pompous, to the self-serving and corrupt. Caveat
Confidentiality refers to a state of information. emptor.
The legal fact of the matter is that social science
research records, such as those obtained by evalu- Selections Have Consequences What are the con-
ators, are not protected under law as a privileged sequences of selecting an incompetent evaluator? We
communication, as are the records of lawyers and offer two examples.
physicians. Private consultants breezily promised to evalu-
Informed consent refers to whether or not a ate 120 drug treatment centers, interview 9,000 drug
respondent understands what he or she is agreeing abusers, and do it all in thirteen months, but, after
to. seven months, just nine centers had been evaluated
218 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

and 1,270 clients interviewed at a cost of more than because line administrators must deal with many
$2 million. The evaluation was abandoned.268 kinds of information, of which the evaluation is just
Another example: when a program chief one part, it is appropriate for the evaluator to with-
received, six months late, an evaluation conducted draw once the evaluation is done.272
by an outside firm, she discovered “not only that the The other wing contends that the evaluator
work was poor,” but that, to her dismay, the firm had should assume an active role in promoting the eval-
“lifted almost word for word” at least one section uation’s use, largely because of evaluators’ “con-
of its report from her own work. “Can’t your staff sensus” that decision makers “do not pay much
think for itself?” she asked. Inexcusably, her office attention to the research their money is buying”
continued its $13 million contract, despite une- and that evaluations “bounce off the policy process
quivocal proof that its plagiarizing personnel were without making much of a dent.”273
unqualified to evaluate programs. It wasn’t only the There can be little question that this some-
evaluators who were incompetent.269 times happens; to offer one, especially unfortu-
nate,  example: only half of the twenty-four major
Unethical Evaluators When ethical issues arise in federal agencies report that Congress requests, or
conducting program evaluations, what do the eval- is even interested in, their “program evaluation
uators do? More often than not, they disagree on studies.”274
whether or not an ethical question is even present. This is, of course, frustrating, and the evaluation
“The bad news is that one voice” among evaluators community increasingly appears to be tilting toward
“does not exist” when ethics are involved, although a more activist role. Evaluators tout tactics—e.g.,
evaluators who are for-profit, private consultants “rational persuasion,” “coercion and inducement,”
are “less likely than those in other settings,” such as and, most notably, consensual cooperation, or
universities, to think that a situation is unethical.270 collaborative modes of evaluation (i.e., evalua-
Once it is determined that ethics have been vio- tors establishing an intimate working relationship
lated, more than nine out of ten researchers report it, with managers when evaluating their programs)—
but to whom they report it depends on how close they designed to get their reports acted upon.275 There is,
are to the research. Three-fourths of research admin- in fact, evidence that “stakeholder involvement” in
istrators will report unethical practices to “externally evaluating programs facilitates “the meaningful use
accountable individuals,” ranging from university of evaluations.”276
officers to the press, whereas 58 percent of hands-on The peril of collaboration, of course, is one of
researchers are more likely to report such incidents “misutilization,” which is evaluator-speak for those
to colleagues on their own research teams and to no “serious questions about the evaluator’s ability
one else. This propensity among researchers raises to maintain a sufficiently bias-free stance due to
the question of whether their “behavior constitutes pressures emanating mainly from the program
professional self-regulation or cover-up.”271 community.”277 A survey of more than 2,500 pro-
fessional program evaluators found that 42 percent
had encountered “misrepresentation pressure,”
USING PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT 70 percent of whom had faced it more than once;
“stakeholder pressure led to actual misrepresenta-
PROGRAM EVALUATIONS tion in 16% of all episodes,” including instances in
Are program evaluators responsible for the evalu- which the evaluation was simply changed without
ation being used, or, once they have completed the the evaluator’s consent.278
evaluation, should they instead leave it to the tender Among nonprofit organizations, collaborative
mercies of the program’s administrators? modes appear to corrupt evaluations because the
more power that “stakeholder groups” hold over
such factors as funding and data access, “the more
Passive or Active Evaluation? evaluators were willing to modify their [evaluation]
These questions lie at the heart of a consuming design choices to accommodate perceived stake-
debate in evaluation circles. One wing argues that, holder concerns.”279
Efficient and Effective Governance 219

evaluation provides an “intellectual background”


Does Program Evaluation Matter? for policymakers that outlasts those “operating fea-
We rather favor the more passive, less collaborative sibilities” of the moment that stymie an evaluation’s
model in promoting evaluation use, not only because instant implementation. An evaluation creates a
it more tightly safeguards against program stake- “gradual cumulative effect” that changes “the con-
holders contaminating the evaluation, but for two ventions policymakers abide by” and reorders “the
additional reasons as well. goals and priorities of the practical policy world.”286
Enlightenment seems to brighten when budgetary
Evaluations Are Used We noted earlier that some pressures increase.287
federal program evaluations are never undertaken Evaluation—and enlightenment—count.
(but should be), and Congress indicates no interest
in about half of those that are. Nevertheless, deci-
sion makers use evaluations more extensively and NOTES
immediately than evaluators seem to realize. Over
1. Bernard Le Masson, Brian J. Moran, and Steve
twenty-six years, GAO evaluated federal agencies’
Rohleder, Coup D’etat: Radically Rethinking
programs that resulted in more than 40,000 rec-
Public Services (Alexandria, VA: Accenture, 2013).
ommendations for programmatic change; agen- 2. Francois Bouvard, Thomas Dohrmann, and Nick
cies accepted and implemented a remarkable 81 Lovegrove, “The Case for Government Reform
percent of them.280 Recall also that the evaluations Now,” McKinsey Quarterly (June 2009) pp. 1–13.
of some 600 municipal programs led to adjustments The quotation is on p. 2. Figure is for FY 2010.
in almost four-fifths of them—essentially the same 3. Garry Wills, A Necessary Evil: A History of American
proportion of GAO’s recommendations that were Distrust of Government (New York: Simon &
accepted by federal agencies.281 Schuster, 1999), pp. 72–73, 75. Emphasis is original.
Evaluations are used even more broadly when 4. Paul C. Light, “A Cascade of Failures: Why
the evaluator is competent282 and program manag- Government Fails and How to Stop It,” Brookings
ers believe that they and the evaluation have solid (July 14, 2014). Data are for 2001–2014.
political support. These managers are influenced by 5. Excellence in Government, Survey: Federal Man-
“all types of information” that they glean from the agers Rank Operational Efficiency as Top Priority
evaluation, largely spurning “anecdotal accounts” in in 2013 (Washington, DC: Author, 2013), p. 1.
favor of “large-scale and case study data.”283 6. Donald F. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving Res-
There is reason to believe that program evalua- ults: Lessons for Improving Government Man-
tions will be used even more in the future, as some agement from GAO’s High-Risk List (Washington,
federal agencies have “given evaluation more clout” DC: IBM Center for the Business of Government,
by requiring local governments seeking federal 2016), pp. 11, 22. Figures are for 1990–2015.
7. George Boyne and Kenneth Meier, “Environmental
grants to implement only those policies that have
Turbulence, Organizational Stability, and Public
been professionally evaluated as being effective.284
Service Performance,” Administration & Society
Over five years, the departments of Education,
40 (January 2009), pp. 799–824.
Health and Human Services, and Labor distributed
8. Donald Hirasuna, Receipt of Unemployment Insu-
nearly $6 billion in grants to subnational govern- rance by Higher-Income Unemployed Workers
ments for seven “proven programs”285—not a par- (“Millionaires”) (Washington, DC: Congressional
ticularly sizable sum as federal intergovernmental Research Service, 2012), p. 4. Figure is for 2009.
grants go, but clearly amounting to substantive steps 9. John Kamensky, “Can We Focus on What Works?”
in the right direction. Govexec.com (June 17, 2015).
10. Ron Haskins, “Social Programs That Work,” New
Evaluations Are Enlightening Evaluation also York Times (December 31, 2014).
has longer-term effects that are both important 11. John Bridgeland and Peter Orszag, “Can
and under-recognized by evaluators. This is “the Government Play Moneyball?” The Atlantic
enlightenment function” of evaluation research. (July/August 2013), pp. 62–68.
In this view (backed by some evidence), program 12. Ibid.
220 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

13. Stephen Sawchuk, “States Slow to Close Faltering 28. Emily Kopp, “Agencies Plow Ahead with DATA
Teacher Ed. Programs,” Education Week Act Despite Big Hurdles,” Federalnewsradio.com
(December 16, 2014). Data are for 2009–2010, (July 29, 2015).
2013–2014. 29. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2016
14. Ted Gayer, Austin J. Drukker, and Alexander K. Annual Report, p. 20. Figure is for 2010–2025.
Gold, Tax-Exempt Municipal Bonds and the 30. Paul C. Light, Creating High Performance Gov-
Financing of Professional Sports Stadiums ernment: A Once-in-a-Generation Opportunity
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 2016). Data are for (New York: New York University, 2011), p. 21.
2000–2015. 31. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Human
15. Richard Florida, “The Never-Ending Stadium Services Programs: Opportunities to Reduce
Boondoggle,” Citylab (September 10, 2015). Inefficiencies GAO-11-531T (Washington, DC:
16. Kenneth J. Meier and Laurence J. O’Toole, Jr., U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011), Highlights
Bureaucracy in a Democratic State: A Governance page.
Perspective (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins 32. Social Security Online, Actuarial Publications:
University Press, 2006), p. 56. Administrative Expenses, http://www.ssa.gov/
17. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal Budget: oact/STATS/admin.html.
Agency Obligations by Budget Function and 33. Lisa Rein and Lynh Bui, “Is Your Mail Arriving
Object Classification for Fiscal Year 2003, GAO- After Dark? Service Cuts Are to Blame, Watchdog
04-834 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Says,” Washington Post (July 22, 2014). Figure is
Printing Office, 2004), Highlights page. Figures for 2013.
are for 2003. 34. Forrester Research, U.S. Federal Customer Experi-
18. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen ence Index, 2015 (Cambridge, MA: Author, 2015).
Hamilton, Securing the Future: Management 35. Alberto Chong, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-
Lessons of 9/11 (Washington, DC, and Herndon, de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer, Letter Grading
VA: Authors, 2011), p. 21. Figure is for 2011. Government Efficiency, Working Paper 18268
19. Partnership for Public Service, Government Dis- (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
service (Washington, DC: Author, 2015), p. 17. Research, 2012).
20. Center for Strategic and International Studies 36. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2017
and Business Executives for National Security, Annual Report, pp. 7–8. Figures are for 2011–
Untangling the Web: Congressional Oversight 2016.
and the Department of Homeland Security 37. Alasdair Roberts, “Why the Brownlow Committee
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2004), p. 2. Figures Failed: Neutrality and Partisanship in the Early
are for 2004. Years of Public Administration,” Administration
21. Partnership for Public Service, Government & Society 28 (May 1996), pp. 3–38. The quotation
Disservice, p. 17. is on p. 3.
22. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen 38. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen
Hamilton, Securing the Future, p. 21. Hamilton, Securing the Future, p. 4. Figure is for
23. Quoted in Partnership for Public Service, Govern- 1947–2011.
ment Disservice, p. 9. 39. U.S. General Accounting Office, Executive Reor-
24. Ibid., p. 7. ganization Authority: Balancing Executive and
25. Ibid., p. 14. Congressional Roles in Shaping the Federal
26. Kellie Lunney, “Federal Managers Support Cuts, Government’s Structure, GAO-03-624T
Fewer Contractors,” Government Executive (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
(November 7, 2011). Office, 2003), p. 9.
27. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2017 40. National Commission on the Public Service,
Annual Report: Additional Opportunities to Urgent Business for America, p. 36.
Reduce Fragmentation, Overlap, and Duplication 41. U.S. Government Accountability Office, National
and Achieve Other Financial Benefits, GAO-17- Protection and Programs Protectorate: Factors
491SP (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publi- to Consider when Reorganizing, GAO-16-140T
shing Office, 2016), pp. 1–2, 4, 23–24. Figures are (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
for 2011–2016. Office, 2015), Highlights page.
Efficient and Effective Governance 221

42. Thad Beyle and Margaret Ferguson, “Governors 55. KPMG International, Performance Agenda, p. 8.
and the Executive Branch,” Politics in the American Figure is for 2007.
States: A Comparative Analysis, 9th ed., Virginia 56. Geert Bouckaert, “The History of the Productivity
Gray and Russell L. Hanson, eds. (Washington, Movement,” Public Productivity & Management
DC: CQ Press, 2008), pp. 192–228. The quotation Review 14 (Fall 1990), pp. 53–89. The quotation
is on p. 218. is on p. 83.
43. Thad Beyle, “The Executive Branch,” State 57. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
Constitutions for the Twenty-first Century: The Streamlining Government: Key Practices from
Agenda of State Constitutional Reform (Albany, Select Efficiency Initiatives Should Be Shared
NY: SUNY Press, 2006), pp. 67–84. The reference Governmentwide, GA0-11-908 (Washington,
is on p. 80. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011),
44. Thad L. Beyle, “Enhancing Executive Leadership in Highlights page.
the States,” State and Local Government Review 58. Desiree Teobaldelli, “Federalism and the Shadow
27 (Winter 1995), pp. 18–35. Economy,” Public Choice 146 (March 2011),
45. Richard C. Elling, “Administering State Programs: pp. 269–289.
Performance and Politics,” Politics in the American 59. Project Management Institute, as cited in Charles
States: A Comparative Analysis, 8th ed., Virginia S. Clark, “Program Management Bill Heads to
Gray and Russell L. Hanson, eds. (Washington, Obama’s Desk,” Govexec.com (December 6,
DC: CQ Press, 2004), pp. 261–289.The quotation 2016).
is on p. 267. 60. Charles S. Clark, “Program Managers Too Scarce
46. James Conant, “Management Consequences in the Federal Government, Survey Concludes,”
of the 1960–1990 ‘Modernization’ of State Govexec.com (June 12, 2013).
Government,” Handbook of State Government 61. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Investing
Administration, John J. Gargan, ed. (New York: in Federal Productivity and Quality (Washington,
Marcel Dekker, 2000), pp. 13–32. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1992).
47. Elling, “Administering State Programs,” p. 267. 62. Luther Gulick, “Science, Values, and Public
48. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Bidding Administration,” Papers on the Science of
Boards Goodbye,” Governing (August 2009), Administration, Luther Gulick and L. Urwick, eds.
pp. 54–55. (New York: Institute of Public Administration,
49. See, for example, William Baumol, Welfare Econo- 1937), pp. 189–195. The quotation is on p. 192.
mics and the Theory of the State (Cambridge, MA: 63. Frederick C. Mosher and Orville F. Poland, The
Harvard University Press, 1965), one of Baumol’s Costs of American Governments: Facts, Trends,
numerous contributions. Myths (New York: Dodd, Mead, 1964), pp. 12–15.
50. KPMG International, Performance Agenda: An 64. Mordecai Lee, Bureaus of Efficiency: Reforming
International Government Survey (Toronto: Local Government in the Progressive Era (Mil-
Author, 2007), p. 8. Figure is for 2007. waukee, WI: Marquette University Press, 2008).
51. John E. Petersen, “Productivity Pinch,” Governing 65. Orville F. Poland, “Why Does Public Admini-
(September 2003), p. 62. stration Ignore Evaluation?” Public Administra-
52. U.S. Energy Information Administration, as cited tion Review 31 (March/April 1971), pp. 201–202.
in Charles S. Clark, “Agency Energy Use Reduced The quotation is on p. 201.
to 40-Year Low,” Govexec.com (December 7, 66. Senator William Proxmire, quoted in Thomas
2015). Figure is for FY 1975–FY 2014. D. Morris, William H. Corbett, and Brian L.
53. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal Usilaner, “Productivity Measures in the Federal
Government: A Model Employer or a Work in Government,” Public Administration Review 32
Progress? Perspectives from 25 Years of the Merit (November/December 1972), pp. 753–763. The
Principles Survey (Washington, DC: U.S. Govern- quotation is on p. 754.
ment Printing Office, 2008), p. 9. Current figure is 67. Robert C. Burns and Robert D. Lee, Jr., “The
for 2007. Ups and Downs of State Budget Process Reform:
54. Susie M. Grant, as quoted in Michael A. Experience of Three Decades,” Public Budgeting
Fletcher, “A Sea Change in the Secretarial Pool,” & Finance 24 (Fall 2004), pp. 1–19. Figures
Washington Post (May 11, 2000). (p. 10) are for 1970–2000.
222 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

68. Richard E. Winnie, “Local Government Budgeting, Reinventing Government (Washington, DC:
Program Planning, and Evaluation,” Urban Data Author, 2001), p. 1.
Services Report 4 (May 1972), entire issue, and 80. Al Gore, Creating a Government That Works
as derived from data in Rackham S. Fukuhara, Better and Costs Less: Status Report of the
“Productivity Improvement in Cities,” Municipal National Performance Review (Washington, DC:
Year Book, 1977 (Washington, DC: International U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994).
City Management Association, 1977), pp. 193– 81. National Partnership for Reinventing Govern-
200. Figures are for 1971–1976. ment, “Accomplishments, 1993–2000,” pp. 1–2.
69. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal Eval- 82. Max Stier, as cited in Fred Hiatt, “600,000 Bad
uation: Fewer Units, Reduced Resources, Diff- Hires?” Washington Post (April 27, 2009).
erent Studies From 1980, GAO/PEMD-87-9 83. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of Census,
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2006,
Office, 1987), p. 1. 125th ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
70. Juliet Eilperin, “Cuts Kill GAO Evaluation Printing Office, 2006), Table 481.
Division,” Roll Call (July 11, 1996), p. 1. 84. Max Stier, as cited in Hiatt, “600,000 Bad Hires?”
71. Judith R. Brown, “Legislative Program Evaluation: 85. Charles S. Clark, “Reinventing Government—
Refining a Legislative Service and a Profession,” Two Decades Later,” Government Executive
Public Administration Review 44 (May/June (April 28, 2013).
1984), pp. 258–260. 86. Bridgeland and Orszag, “Can Government Play
72. Burns and Lee, “The Ups and Downs of State Moneyball?”
Budget Process Reform,” p. 10. 87. Danny Werfel, Comptroller General of the United
73. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib, States, quoted in Charles S. Clark, “Comptroller
“Management Tools in Municipal Government: Outlines Strategy to Simplify Government,”
Trends over the Past Decade,” Public Admini- Government Executive (February 6, 2013).
stration Review 49 (May/June 1989), pp. 240– 88. Charles S. Clark, “Could Obama’s Push for
248. Figure is for 1987. Evidence-Based Program Evaluations Cross
74. B. Guy Peters, The Future of Governing: Four Party Lines?” Government Executive (October 8,
Emerging Models (Kansas City, KS: University 2014).
Press of Kansas, 1996). 89. Jeffrey L. Brudney, F. Ted Hebert, and Deil S.
75. Samantha L. Durst and Charldean Newell, “Better, Wright, “Reinventing Government in the
Faster, Stronger: Government Reinvention in American States: Measuring and Explaining
the 1990s,” American Review of Public Admini- Administrative Reform,” Public Administration
stration 29 (March 1999), pp. 61–76. The quota- Review 59 (January/February 1999), pp. 19–30.
tion is on p. 63. Figure is for 1996. The quotation is on p. 29.
76. Gerald Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private 90. Younhee Kim, “Improving Performance in U.S.
and Public Sector Workers (Washington, DC: U.S. State Governments: Risk-Taking, Innovativeness,
Congressional Research Service, 2014), p. 3. Years and Proactiveness Practices,” Public Performance
following 1999 are 2000–2013. & Management Review 34 (September 2010),
77. Mark Micheli, “What the Heck is Operational pp. 104–129. The quotation is on p. 104.
Efficiency?” Government Executive (February 1, 91. Andy Frazier, “The Significance of the Hard
2013). Framework on Agency Performance,” Public
78. Cited in Al Gore, From Red Tape to Results: Performance & Management Review 32
Creating a Government That Works Better and (September 2008), pp. 76–102. The quotations
Costs Less, Report of the National Performance are on p. 76.
Review (Washington, DC: U.S. Superintendent 92. Barry M. Feldman, “Reinventing Local Govern-
of Documents, 1993), p. 1. In 1998, the National ment: Beyond Rhetoric to Action,” Municipal
Performance Review was re-titled the National Year Book, 1999 (Washington, DC: International
Partnership for Reinventing Government. City/County Management Association, 1999), pp.
79. National Partnership for Reinventing Government, 20–24. Data (pp. 23–24) are for 1998.
“Accomplishments, 1993–2000: A Summary,” 93. Richard C. Kearney, Barry M. Feldman, and
History of the National Partnership for Carmine P. F. Scavo, “Reinventing Government:
Efficient and Effective Governance 223

City Manager Attitudes and Actions,” Public Electoral Support for Incumbent English Local
Administration Review 60 (November/December Governments,” Journal of Public Administration
2000), pp. 535–548. Data (p. 544) are for 1997. Research and Theory 17 (October 2007),
94. Timothy B. Krebs and John P. Peliserro, “What pp. 567–580.
Influences City Council Adoption and Support 104. George A. Boyne, Oliver James, Peter John, and
for Reinventing Government? Environmental Nicolai Petrovsky, “Does Public Service Perform-
or Institutional Factors?” Public Administration ance Affect Top Management Turnover?” Journal
Review 70 (March/April 2010), pp. 258–267. of Public Administration Research and Theory 20,
Figure is for 1997. The quotation is on p. 260. Supplement 2 (April 2010), pp. i261–i279.
95. George C. Homsy and Mildred E. Warner, 105. Jonathan Walters, “The Benchmarking Craze,”
“Intermunicipal Cooperation: The Growing Governing (April 1994), p.37. Emphases are orig-
Reform,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 inal.
(Washington, DC: International City/County 106. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Managing
Management Association, 2014), pp. 53–65. for Results: Enhancing Agency Use of Performance
Figure (p. 55) is for 2012. Information for Management Decision Making.
96. Richard C. Kearney, “Reinventing Government Trend is for 1997–2003.
and Battling Budget Crises: Manager and Muni- 107. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Stream-
cipal Government Actions in 2003,” Municipal lining Government: Opportunities Exist to Streng-
Year Book, 2005 (Washington, DC: International then OMB’s Approach to Improving Efficiency,
City/County Management Association, 2005), pp. GAO-10-394 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
27–32. Figure (p. 31) is for 2003. Printing Office, 2010), pp. 8–9, Highlights page.
97. Rhys Andrews, George A. Boyne, and Richard M. Data are for 2008–2010.
Walker, “Strategy Content and Organizational 108. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “States
Performance: An Empirical Analysis,” Public Start Making Colleges Work for Funding,”
Administration Review 66 (January/February Governing.com (April 2016).
2006), pp. 52–63. 109. Thomas Rabovsky, “Support for Performance-
98. Richard M. Walker, Gene A. Brewer, George Based Funding: The Role of Political Ideology,
A. Boyne, and Claudia N. Avellaneda, “Market Performance, and Dysfunctional Information
Orientation and Public Service Performance: Environments,” Public Administration Review 74
New Public Management Gone Mad?” Public (November/December 2014), pp. 761–774.
Administration Review 71 (September/October 110. Gerrish, “The Impact of Performance Management
2011), pp. 707–717. The quotations are on p. 714. on Performance in Public Organizations,” pp. 61,
99. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance 51, 52, 50.
Measurement and Evaluation: Definitions and 111. Donald F. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving
Relationships, GAO/GGD-98-26 (Washington, Results: Lessons for Improving Government
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1998), p. 3. Management from GAO’s High-Risk List
100. Americans Talk Issues Foundation, as cited in (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
Kevin Merida, “Americans Want a Direct Say in Government, 2016), pp. 16, 23.
Decision-Making, Pollsters Find,” Washington 112. U.S. General Accounting Office, Program
Post (April 17, 1994). Figure is for 1994. Performance Measures. Federal Agency Collection
101. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Working and Use of Performance Data, GAO/GGD-92-
for the Government: What Federal Employees 65 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Think, 1999 Employee Survey (Washington, DC: Office, 1992), Highlights page.
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1999). 113. Christopher Wye, quoted in Jeff Shear, “It’s Time
102. Ed Gerrish, “The Impact of Performance Man- to Win One for the GPRA,” National Journal
agement on Performance in Public Organizations: (October 26, 1996), p. 1042.
A Meta-Analysis,” Public Administration Review 114. Frank Hodsoll, quoted in Charles F. Bingham,
76 (January/February 2016), pp. 48–66. The quo- “Installing the M-Team,” Government Executive
tation is on p. 63. (January 1992), p. 25.
103. Oliver James and Peter John, “Public Management 115. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Managing
at the Ballot Box: Performance Information and for Results: Enhancing Agency Use of Performance
224 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Information for Management Decision Making, 126. Julie Melkers and Katherine Willoughby, Staying
GAO-05-927 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government the Course: The Use of Performance Measurements
Printing Office, 2005), Highlights page. In 2004, in State Governments (Washington, DC: IBM
89 percent of federal agencies had performance Center for the Business of Government, 2004).
measures. 127. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Foun-
116. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Govern- dation, Evidence-Based Policymaking (Phila-
ment Performance: Lessons Learned for the Next delphia, PA, and Washington, DC: Authors, 2014),
Administration on Using Performance Infor- p. 3. Figures are for 2004–2014 and 2008–2011,
mation to Improve Results, GAO-08-1026T respectively.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 128. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Foun-
Office, 2008), p. 8. dation, States’ Use of Cost-Benefit Analysis:
117. U.S. General Accounting Office, Results-Oriented Improving Results for Taxpayers (Philadelphia,
Government: GPRA Has Established a Solid PA, and Washington, DC: Authors, 2013), p. 4.
Foundation for Achieving Greater Results, Figure is for 2008–2011.
GAO-04-38 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 129. Governmental Accounting Standards Board,
Printing Office, 2004), p. 38. Performance Measurement at the State and Local
118. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thorn- Levels: A Summary of Results (Washington, DC:
ton, Putting Together the Performance Pieces Author, 2002), p. 6. Figure is for 2001.
(Washington, DC, and Alexandria, VA: Authors, 130. Katherine G. Willoughby, “Performance Measure-
2015), pp. 2, 10. Figures are for 2015. ment and Budget Balancing: State Government
119. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Manag- Perspectives,” Public Budgeting & Finance 24
ing for Results: Agencies’ Trends in the Use of (June 2004), pp. 21–39. Data are for 2003.
Performance Information to Make Decisions, 131. Donald P. Moynihan and Patricia W. Ingraham,
GAO-14-747 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government “Look for the Silver Lining: When Performance-
Printing Office, 2014), Highlights page. Based Accountability Systems Work,” Journal of
120. Senator Mark Warner, quoted in John M. Public Administration Research and Theory 13
Kamensky, “Congress Overhauls Results Act, (Fall 2003), pp. 469–562.
Wants Results,” PA Times (March/April 2011), 132. Carolyn Bourdeaux and Grace Chikoto, “Legis-
p. 8. lative Influence on Performance Management
121. Charles S. Clark, “OMB Cites Progress on Agency Reform,” Public Administration Review 68
Performance Goals,” Government Executive (March/April 2008), pp. 253–265. The quotation
(February 13, 2014). is on p. 253.
122. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thornton, 133. Robert D. Lee, Jr. and Robert C. Burns,
Taking Measure: Moving from Process to Practice “Performance Measurement in State Budgeting:
in Performance Management (Washington, DC, Advancement and Backsliding from 1990 to
and Alexandria, VA: Authors, 2013), pp. 15, 14. 1995,” Public Budgeting & Finance 20 (March
Figure is for 2013. 2000), pp. 38–54.
123. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Mana- 134. Carolyn Bourdeaux, “Integrating Performance
ging for Results: Agencies Report Positive Effects Information into Legislative Budget Processes,”
of Data-Driven Reviews on Performance but Public Performance & Management Review 31
Some Should Strengthen Practices, GAO-15-579 (June 2008), pp. 547–569.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 135. Anne Spray Kinney and John Ruggini, “Mea-
Office, 2015), Highlights page. suring for a Purpose: Trends in Public-Sector
124. Donald P. Moynihan and Alexander Kroll, Measurement and Management Practices,”
“Performance Management Routines That Work? Government Finance Review 24 (August 2008),
An Early Assessment of the GPRA Modernization pp. 14–23. Figures (p. 16) are for 2006.
Act,” Public Administration Review 76 (March/ 136. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib, “Perfor-
April 2016), pp. 314–323. The quotation is on mance Measurement in Municipal Government:
p. 314. Assessing the State of the Practice,” Public
125. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thorn- Administration Review 59 (July/August 1999),
ton, Taking Measure p. 10. Figure is for 2013. pp. 325–335.
Efficient and Effective Governance 225

137. Ana Yetano, “What Drives the Institutionalization Management Review 33 (March 2010), pp. 342–
of Performance Measurement and Management 354. The quotations are on p. 342.
in Local Government?” Public Performance & 148. Kelly LeRoux and Nathaniel S. Wright, “Does Per-
Management Review 37 (September 2013), pp. formance Measurement Improve Strategic Deci-
59–86. sion Making? Findings from a National Survey
138. David H. Folz, Reem Abdelrazek, and Yeonsoo of Nonprofit Social Service Agencies,” Nonprofit
Chung, “The Adoption, Use, and Impacts of Leadership & Voluntary Sector Quarterly 39
Performance Measures in Medium-Size Cities: (August 2010), pp. 571–587.
Progress Toward Performance Management,” 149. Janet Carlson, Alison S. Kelley, and Ken Smith,
Public Performance & Management Review 33 “Government Performance Reforms and Non-
(September 2009), pp. 63–87. Data (p. 70) are for profit Human Services: 20 Years in Oregon,” Non-
2004. profit Leadership & Voluntary Sector Quarterly
139. Gregory Streib and Theodore H. Poister, “Perfor- 39 (March 2010), pp. 630–652. The quotations
mance Measurement in Municipal Governments,” are on p. 652.
Municipal Year Book, 1998 (Washington, DC: 150. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Govern-
International City/County Management Asso- ment Performance: Lessons Learned for the Next
ciation, 1998), pp. 9–15. Figures (p. 11) are for Administration on Using Performance Informa-
1997. tion to Improve Results, p. 4. “Decade” refers to
140. Robert P. McGowan and Theodore H. Poister, 1997–2007.
“The Impact of Productivity Measurement 151. As derived from data in: ibid., Figure 1, p. 4;
Systems on Municipal Performance,” Paper pre- Governmental Accounting Standards Board, Per-
pared for delivery at the 1984 Annual Conference formance Measurement at the State and Local
of the American Political Science Association Levels, pp. 5–6; and Poister and Streib, “Perfor-
in Washington, DC, August–September 1984, mance Measurement in Municipal Government,”
pp. 12–13. p. 329. Federal data are for 2007; state data are
141. David H. Foly and William Lyons, “The for 2001; and municipal data are for 1997.
Measurement of Municipal Service Quality and 152. Ibid., all three citations.
Productivity,” Public Productivity Review 10 153. David N. Ammons and William C. Rivenbark,
(Winter 1986), pp. 21–33. “Factors Influencing the Use of Performance Data
142. Bente Bjornholt, Martin Baekgaard, and Kurt to Improve Municipal Services: Evidence from the
Houlberg, “Does Fiscal Austerity Affect Political North Carolina Benchmarking Project,” Public
Decision-Makers’ Use and Perception of Perfor- Administration Review 68 (March/April 2008),
mance Information?” Public Performance & pp. 304–318.
Management Review 39 (3, 2016), pp. 560–580. 154. As derived from data in: U.S. Government
143. Jonathan P. West, “City Government Productivity Accountability Office, Government Performance:
and Civil Service Reforms,” Public Productivity Lessons Learned for the Next Administration
Review 10 (Fall 1986), pp. 45–59. on Using Performance Information to Improve
144. Poister and Streib, “Performance Measurement in Results, p. 4, Figure 1; Governmental Accounting
Municipal Government.” Standards Board, Performance Measurement at
145. Bjornholt, Baekgaard, and Houlberg, “Does the State and Local Levels, pp. 5–6; and Poister
Fiscal Austerity Affect Political Decision-Makers’ and Streib, “Performance Measurement in
Use and Perception of Performance Information?” Municipal Government,” p. 329.
p. 560. 155. This discussion is based (with some modifications)
146. Gregg G. Van Ryzin and Cecelia F. Lavena, mostly on: Burt Perrin, “Effective Use and Misuse
“The Credibility of Government Performance of Performance Measurement,” American Journal
Reporting,” Public Performance & Management of Evaluation 19 (Fall 1998), pp. 367–379.
Review 37 (September 2013), pp. 87–103. The 156. Partnership for Public Service and Grant
quotation is on p. 87. Thornton, Putting Together the Performance
147. Claire Moxham, “Help or Hindrance? Examining Pieces, p. 13. Figures are for 2015.
the Role of Performance Measurement in UK 157. Perrin, “Effective Use and Misuse of Performance
Nonprofit Organizations,” Public Performance & Evaluation,” p. 374.
226 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

158. Joseph T. McNamara, “Crime Statistics—Only Theoretical Analysis and Explorative Case Studies
Game in Town,” Savannah Morning News in Dutch Water Boards,” Public Performance &
(February 5, 2002). Management Review 30 (June 2007), pp. 496–
159. John Bohte and Kenneth J. Meier, “Goal 520. The quotation is on p. 516.
Displacement: Assessing the Motivation of 174. ERM, Global City Indicators Program Report
Organizational Cheating,” Public Administration (Toronto: Author, 2008).
Review 60 (March/April 2000), pp. 173–182. 175. Eric Pfeiffer, “New Tool Creates ‘Common Langu-
160. “Report on Business,” Toronto Globe and Mail, age’ for Success in City Governments,” Govexec.
“about 1996,” as quoted in Perrin, “Effective Use com (January 23, 2015).
and Misuse of Performance Evaluation,” p. 367. 176. Paul D. Epstein, “Redeeming the Promise of
161. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Poisoned Performance Measurement: Issues and Obstacles
Measures,” Governing (May 1998), p. 60. for Governments in the United States,” Organi-
162. Cited in Perrin, “Effective Use and Misuse of zational Performance and Measurement in the
Performance Measurement,” p. 376. This occurred Public Sector: Toward Service, Effort, and Accom-
in 1996. plishment Reporting, Arie Halachmi and Geert
163. Vicente Pina, Lourdes Torres, and Sonia Royo, Bouckaert, eds. (Westport, CN: Quorum Books,
“Is E-Government Leading to More Accountable 1996), pp. 51–76. The quotation is on p. 62.
and Transparent Local Governments? An Overall 177. Penelope Lemov, “Rough SEAs,” Governing
View,” Financial Accountability & Management (February 2007), p. 53.
26 (February 2010), pp. 3–20. 178. Dwight V. Denison, Wenli Yan, and Zhirong
164. Charles S. Clark, “OMB Trumpets Progress on (Jerry) Zhao, “Is Management Performance a
Tracking Contractor Performance and Other Factor in Municipal Bond Ratings? The Case
Cross-Agency Goals,” Govexec.com (December of Texas School Districts,” Public Budgeting &
19, 2014). Finance 27 (Winter 2007), pp. 86–98.
165. Melkers, Willoughby, James, et al. Performance 179. Council of State Governments, Book of the States,
Measurement at the State and Local Levels, p. 12. 2004 (Lexington, KY: Author, 2004), Table 4.29.
Figure is for 2001. “Performance audits include economy and effi-
166. Julia Melkers and Katherine Willoughby, “The ciency audits and program audits.”
State of the States: Performance-Based Budgeting 180. John D. Heaton, Linda J. Savage, and Judith K.
in 47 out of 50,” Public Administration Review Welch, “Performance Auditing in Municipal
88 (January/February 1998), pp. 66–73. Governments,” Government Accountants Journal
167. Poister and Streib, “Performance Measurement in 42 (Summer 1993), pp. 51–60. Figure is for 1992.
Municipal Government,” p. 331. 181. Peter Babachicos, Daniel Kyle, et al., “Why Perfor-
168. Kinney and Ruggini, “Measuring for a Purpose,” mance Audits Preceding Scandals Were Ignored,”
p. 18. Figure is for 2006. Government Accountants Journal 45 (Spring
169. Aine Creedon, “Benchmarks Study Indicates 1996), pp. 10–18.
Trends in Online Giving,” Nonprofitquarterly.org 182. Richard Boyle, Performance Reporting: Insights
(March 29, 2013). from International Practice (Washington, DC: IBM
170. Gerrish, “The Impact of Performance Management Center for the Business of Government, 2009),
on Performance in Public Organizations,” p. 63. pp. 11, 13–14.
171. David N. Ammons, Charles Coe, and Michael 183. Ken A. Smith, Rita Hartung Cheng, Ola M. Smith,
Lombardo, “Performance-Comparison Projects and Ottalee Schiffel, “Performance Reporting by
in Local Government: Participants’ Perspectives,” State Agencies: Bridging the Gap between Current
Public Administration Review 61 (January/ Practices and GASB Suggested Criteria,” Journal
February 2001), pp. 100–110. The quotation is of Government Financial Reporting 57 (Summer
on p. 106. 2008), pp. 42–47. Data are for 2007.
172. Ammons and Rivenbark, “Factors Influencing the 184. Kenneth A. Smith and Lee Schiffel, “Improvements
Use of Performance Data to Improve Municipal in City Government Performance Reporting,”
Services.” Journal of Government Financial Management 58
173. Sandra Tillema, “Public Sector Organizations’ Use (Summer 2009), pp. 36–42. The quotations are on
of Benchmarking for Performance Improvement: pp. 37, 39. The ten-year data are for 1997–2007.
Efficient and Effective Governance 227

185. Dana Milbank, “It’s in the Cards that Oregon Will United States, GAO-11-396 (Washington, DC:
Get Even Better by 2010,” Wall Street Journal U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011), p. 10.
(December 9, 1996). 200. Kinney and Ruggini, “Measuring for a Purpose,”
186. Ronald C. Nyhan and Herbert Marlowe, “Perfor- pp. 18–19. Figures are for 2006.
mance Measurement in the Public Sector: Chal- 201. Peter Schworm, “Boston Eyes Single Number to
lenges and Opportunities,” Public Productivity & Grade City Hall,” Bostonglobe.com (October 8,
Management Review 18 (Summer 1995), pp. 333– 2015).
348. The quotation is on p. 336. 202. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Founda-
187. Alfred Tat-Kei Ho and Anna Ya Ni, “Have Cities tion, Evidence-Based Policymaking, pp. 3, 2.
Shifted to Outcome-Oriented Performance 203. In addition to works cited in the following bullets,
Reporting?—A Content Analysis of City Budgets,” this discussion is based on Perrin, “Effective Use
Public Budgeting & Finance 25 (Summer 2005), and Misuse of Performance Evaluation”; Gerrish,
pp. 61–83. Datum (p. 72) is for 2002. “The Impact of Performance Management on
188. Nyhan and Marlowe, “Performance Measurement Performance in Public Organizations”; Robert D.
in the Public Sector,” p. 336. Behn, Performance Leadership: 11 Better Prac-
189. Mark A. Abramson, Jonathan D. Gould, and tices That Can Ratchet Up Performance, 2nd ed.
John M. Kamensky, Four Trends Transforming (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
Government (Washington, DC: IBM Center for Government, 2006); U.S. Government Account-
the Business of Government, 2003), p. 10. ability Office, Managing for Results: Agencies’
190. Timothy B. Clark, “Stats Surge Continues in Trends in the Use of Performance Information
Cities and States,” GovExec.com (February 18, to Make Decisions, p. 5; and Kathe Callahan
2015). Figure is for 2015. and Kathryn Kloby, Moving Toward Outcome-
191. Kinney and Ruggini, “Measuring for a Purpose,” Oriented Performance Measurement Systems
p. 18. Figure is for 2006. (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
192. Clark, “Stats Surge Continues in Cities and Government, 2009).
States.” 204. Judy Zelio, Five Actions to Enhance State
193. Ibid. Legislative Use of Performance Information
194. Kevin C. Desouza, Creating a Balanced Portfolio (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
of Information Technology Metrics (Washington, Government, 2008), p. 3.
DC: IBM Center for the Business of Government, 205. Boyle, Performance Reporting, p. 13.
2015), p. 11. Figures are for 2015. 206. George A. Boyne and Alex A. Chen, “Performance
195. Jennifer Steinhauer and Michael S. Schmidt, Targets and Public Service Improvement,” Journal
“Man Behind FEMA’s Makeover Built Philosophy of Public Administration Research and Theory 17
on Preparation,” New York Times (November 3, (October 2007), pp. 455–477. The quotation is on
2012). p. 455.
196. Robert D. Behn, “Avoid Getting Caught in the 207. Steven Kelman and John N. Friedman, “Perfor-
Quagmire of Key Performance Indicators,” mance Improvement and Performance Dysfunct-
Government Executive (December 12, 2014). ion: An Empirical Examination of Distortionary
197. Valerie J. Richardson, Increasing Transparency Impacts of the Emergency Room Wait-Time Target
and Accountability in Federal Performance in the English National Health Service,” Journal
Reporting: Lessons from the OMB Pilot Program of Public Administration Research and Theory 19
(Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of (October 2009), pp. 917–946. The quotation is on
Government, 2009), p. 6. p. 917.
198. Kathryn E. Newcomer, “How Does Program 208. Kaifeng Yang and Sanjay K. Pandey, “How
Performance Assessment Affect Program Do Perceived Political Environment and
Management in the Federal Government?” Public Administrative Reform Affect Employee
Performance & Management Review 30 (March Commitment?” Journal of Public Administration
2007), pp. 332–350. The datum is on p. 334. Research and Theory 19 (April 2009), pp. 335–
199. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Key 360. The quotation is on p. 335.
Indicator Systems: Experiences of Other National 209. Jonathan Walters, “Computing Performance,”
and Subnational Systems Offer Insights for the Governing (June 2010), pp. 48–49.
228 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

210. Richard M. Walker, Chan Su Jung, and George A. 221. U.S. General Accounting Office, CETA Programs
Boyne, “Marching to Different Drummers? The for Disadvantaged Adults—What Do We Know
Performance Effects of Alignment between Political About Their Enrollees, Services, and Effectiveness?
and Managerial Perceptions of Performance GAO/IPE-82-2 (Washington, DC: U.S. Govern-
Management,” Public Administration Review 73 ment Printing Office, 1982).
(November/December 2–13), pp. 833–844. The 222. Robert K. Yin, “Life Histories of Innovations:
quotation is on p. 833. How New Practices Become Routinized,” Public
211. Yi Lu, “Improving the Design of Performance Administration Review 41 (January/February
Measures: The Role of Agencies,” Public Per- 1981), pp. 21–28.
formance & Management Review 32 (September 223. Chelinsky, “Evaluating Public Programs,” p. 268.
2008), pp. 7–24. The quotations are on p. 21. 224. George L. Kelling, Tony Pate, Duane Dieckman,
212. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, A Call to and Charles E. Brown, The Kansas City
Action: Improving First-Level Supervision of Preventive Patrol Experiment: Summary Report
Federal Employees (Washington, DC: U.S Govern- (Washington, DC: The Police Foundation, 1974).
ment Printing Office, 2010), p. 1. 225. U.S. General Accounting Office, Drinking-Age
213. Bradley E. Wright and Sanjay K. Pandey, “Trans- Laws: An Evaluation Synthesis of Their Impact on
formational Leadership in the Public Sector: Does Highway Safety, GAO/PEMD-87-10 (Washington,
Structure Matter?” Journal of Public Admini- DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1987).
stration Research and Theory 20 (January 2010), 226. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Program
pp. 75–89. The quotation is on p. 85. Evaluation: Some Agencies Reported that Net-
214. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance working, Hiring, and Involving Program Staff
Measurement and Evaluation: Definitions and Help Build Capacity, GAO-15-25 (Washington,
Relationships, p. 3. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2014),
215. Peter Dahler-Larsen, “Surviving the Routinization Highlights page. Figures are for 2014.
of Evaluation: The Administrative Use of Eva- 227. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Program
luations in Danish Municipalities,” Administration Evaluation: Strategies to Facilitate Agencies’ Use
& Society 32 (March 2000), pp. 70–92. The quo- of Evaluation in Program Management and Policy
tation is on p. 70. Making, GAO-13-570 (Washington, DC: U.S.
216. For examples, see the seventh edition (1998) of Government Printing Office, 2013), Highlights
this book, pp. 213–217. page. Figures are for 2013.
217. We have collapsed the Evaluation Research Soci- 228. U.S. Government Accountability Office, CFO
ety’s six types of program evaluation and the GAO’s Act of 1990: Driving the Transformation of
four into six types. See Evaluation Research Society Federal Financial Management, GAO-06-242T
Standards Committee, “Evaluation Research (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Society Standards for Program Evaluation,” Office, 2005), Highlights page.
Standards for Evaluation Practice, P. H. Rossi, ed. 229. U.S. General Accounting Office, Managing for
(San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1982) and U.S. General Results: The Statutory Framework for Perfor-
Accounting Office, Performance Measurement mance-Based Management and Accountability,
and Evaluation: Definitions and Relationships. GAO/GGD/AIMD-98-52. (Washington, DC: U.S.
218. Eleanor Chelinsky, “Evaluating Public Programs,” Government Printing Office, 1998), pp. 1, 3.
Handbook of Public Administration, James L. 230. Sofie E. Miller, Learning from Experience:
Perry, ed. (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1989), pp. Retrospective Review of Regulations in 2014
259–274. The quotation is on p. 269. (Washington, DC: George Washington University
219. U.S. General Accounting Office, Teenage Regulatory Center, 2015).
Pregnancy: 500,000 Births a Year But Few Tested 231. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Program
Programs, GAO/PEMD-86-16BR, (Washington, Evaluation: Strategies to Facilitate Agencies’ Use
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1986). of Evaluation in Program Management and Policy
220. Bruce B. Buchanan, II, “The Senior Executive Making. Highlights page. Figures are for 2013.
Service: How Can We Tell If It Works?” Public 232. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Program
Administration Review 41 (May/June 1981), Evaluation: Some Agencies Reported that
pp. 349–358. Networking, Hiring, and Involving Program Staff
Efficient and Effective Governance 229

Help Build Capacity, Highlights page. Figures are 1994), pp. 147–154, and Kathryn E. Newcomer,
for 2014. “The Changing Nature of Accountability:
233. Ibid. Figure is for 2014. The Role of the Inspector General in Federal
234. Bridgeland and Orszag, “Can Government Play Agencies,” Public Administration Review 58
Moneyball?” p. 62. (March/April 1998), pp. 129–136. Data are for
235. Moynihan and Ingraham, “Look for the Silver 1992–1996.
Lining,” p. 469. 247. Committees on Homeland Security and Govern-
236. National Association of State Budget Officers, mental Affairs and the Judiciary, U.S. Senate,
Budget Processes in the States (Washington, DC: Empowering Inspectors General: Supporting the
Author, 2008), p. 10. Figure is for 2008. IG Community Could Save Billions for American
237. Burns and Lee, “The Ups and Downs of State Taxpayers (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Budget Process Reform,” p. 10. Figures are for Publishing Office, 2016), pp. 2–3. Data are for
1970–2000. 2016.
238. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Foun- 248. U.S. General Accounting Office, Inspectors
dation, How States Engage in Evidence-Based General: Enhancing Federal Accountability, GAO-
Policymaking (Washington, DC, and Chicago: 04-117T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Authors, 2017), p. 1. Figures are for 2016. Printing Office, 2003), p. 1.
239. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib, “Muni- 249. Eric Eyre, “W. Va. Lawmakers Propose Inspector
cipal Management Tools from 1976 to 1993: An General Office to Root Out Corruption,”
Overview and Update,” Public Productivity & Wvgazettemail.com (August 27, 2015). West
Management Review 18 (Winter 1994), pp. 115– Virginia became the fourteenth state to hire an
125. Figures (p. 122) are for 1993. inspector general in 2015.
240. Council of the Inspectors General on Integrity and 250. As derived from data in Kearney & Company
Efficiency, Progress Report to the President, Fiscal and Association of Government Accountants,
Year 2014 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Meeting Accountability Challenges (Alexandria,
Printing Office, 2015), p. i. VA: Authors, 2014), pp. 8, 10, 11. Figures are for
241. U.S. Office of the Special Inspector General for Iraq 2013.
Reconstruction, Learning from Iraq (Washington, 251. Steve Boland, “The Right Tools Can Make
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2013). This Evaluation Less Painful, More Productive,”
was the office’s final report. Disciplinary actions Nonprofit Quarterly (January 23, 2012).
refer to suspensions and debarments, explained in 252. Peter Frumkin and Mark T. Kim, “Strategic
Chapter 11. Positioning and the Financing of Nonprofit
242. John Hudak and Grace Wallack,” Political Organizations: Is Efficiency Rewarded in the
Appointees as Barriers to Government Efficiency Contributions Marketplace?” Public Admini-
and Effectiveness,” Brookings.edu (April 11, stration Review 61 (May/June 2001), pp. 266–
2016). 275. The quotations are on p. 266.
243. Kearney & Company and Association of 253. Greg Chen, “Does Meeting Standards Affect
Government Accountants, Accelerating Change: Charitable Giving? An Empirical Study of
The 2015 Inspector General Survey (Alexandria, New York Metropolitan Charities,” Nonprofit
VA: Authors, 2015), pp. 9, 12, 13. Figures are for Management & Leadership 19 (Spring 2009),
2012–2015, 2014–2015, and 2015, respectively. pp. 349–365. The quotation is on p. 363.
244. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thornton, 254. Margaret F. Sloan, “The Effects of Nonprofit
Walking the Line: Inspectors General Balancing Accountability Ratings on Donor Behavior,”
Independence and Impact (Washington, DC, and Nonprofit Management & Voluntary Quarterly
Alexandria, VA: Authors, 2016), pp. 7–8. 38 (April 2009), pp. 220–236. The quotations are
245. Quoted in Tom Shoop, “The IG Enigma,” on p. 220.
Government Executive (January 1992), p. 39. 255. Henry W. Riecken, “Principal Components of the
246. As derived from data in Kathryn E. Newcomer, Evaluation Process,” Professional Psychology 8
“Opportunities and Incentives for Improving (November 1977), pp. 392–410.
Program Quality: Auditing and Evaluating,” 256. Francis G. Caro, “Evaluation Research: An
Public Administration Review 54 (March/April Overview,” Readings in Evaluation Research,
230 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Francis G. Caro, ed. (New York: Russell Sage Disagreements about Ethics,” Evaluation Review
Foundation, 1971), pp. 1–34. 24 (August 2000), pp. 384–406. The quotations
257. Francesca Gino, “Do We Listen to Advice Just are on pp. 384, 403.
Because We Paid for It? The Impact of Advice 271. Neil S. Wenger, Stanley G. Kornman, Richard Berk,
Cost on Its Use,” Organizational Behavior and and Honghu Liu, “Reporting Unethical Research
Human Decision Processes 107 (November Behavior,” Evaluation Review 23 (October 1999),
2008), pp. 234–245. The quotation is on p. 234. pp. 553–570. The quotation is on p. 553.
258. Frank Konkel, “How the Right People Analyzing 272. See, for example, Carol H. Weiss, “Evaluation
the Best Data Are Transforming Government,” for Decisions: Is Anybody There? Does Anybody
Nextgov (May 23, 2014). Care?” Evaluation Practice 9 (Spring 1988),
259. U.S. General Accounting Office, Evaluation and pp. 5–19.
Analysis to Support Decision-Making, p. 14. 273. Carol H. Weiss, “Research for Policy’s Sake: The
260. Mary E. Poulin, Phillip R. Harris, and Peter R. Enlightenment Function of Social Research,”
Jones, “The Significance of Definitions of Success Policy Analysis 3 (Fall 1977), pp. 531–545. The
in Program Evaluation,” Evaluation Review 24 quotation is on p. 532.
(October 2000), pp. 516–536. 274. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Program
261. U.S. General Accounting Office, Evaluation and Evaluation: Some Agencies Reported that
Analysis to Support Decision-Making, p. 13. Networking, Hiring, and Involving Program Staff
262. Caro, “Evaluation Research,” p. 24. Help Build Capacity, Highlights page. Figure is
263. Riecken, “Principal Components of the Evaluation for 2014.
Process,” p. 408. 275. Thomas V. Bonoma, “Overcoming Resistance to
264. Jonathan Walters, “Investing in Outcomes,” Change Recommended for Operating Programs,”
Governing (June 2009), pp. 46–48. The quotation Professional Psychology 8 (November 1977),
is on p. 47. pp. 451–463.
265. Arnold J. Meltsner, Policy Analysts in the Bureau- 276. Kelli Johnson, Lija O. Greenseid, Stacie A. Toal,
cracy (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, et al., “Research on Evaluation Use: A Review
1976), pp. 50–81. of the Empirical Literature from 1986 to 2005,”
266. William D. Coplin, Astrid E. Merget, and Carolyn American Journal of Evaluation 30 (September
Bourdeaux, “The Professional Researcher as 2009), pp. 377–410. The quotations are on p. 377.
Change Agent in the Government-Performance 277. Lynn M. Shulha and J. Bradley Cousins, “Eva-
Movement,” Public Administration Review 62 luation Use: Theory, Research, and Practice
(November/December 2002), pp. 699–711. The Since 1986,” Evaluation Practice 18 (Fall 1997),
quotations are on pp. 701–702. pp. 195–208. The quotation is on p. 200.
267. K. A. Archebald, “Alternative Orientations to 278. Michael Morris and Brittany Clark, “You Want
Social Science Utilization,” Social Science Infor- Me to Do What? Evaluators and the Pressure
mant 9 (April 1970), pp. 7–35. to Misrepresent Findings,” American Journal of
268. H. Donald Messer, “Drug Abuse Treatment: An Evaluation 34 (March 2013), pp. 57–70. The
Evaluation That Wasn’t,” Program Evaluation at quotations are on p. 57.
HEW: Research Versus Reality: Part 1: Health, 279. Tarek Azzam, “Evaluator Responsiveness to
James G. Abert, ed. (New York: Marcel Dekker, Stakeholders,” American Journal of Evaluation
1979), pp. 113–168. 31 (March 2010), pp. 45–65. The quotation is on
269. Dr. Lois Ellen Datta, chief, Headstart Evaluation p. 65.
Branch, Office of Education, as quoted in Daniel 280. Daniel Byler, Steve Berman, Vishwa Kola, and
Guttman and Daniel Willner, The Shadow William D. Eggers, Accountability Quantified:
Government: The Government’s Multi-Billion What 26 Years of GAO Reports Can Teach Us
Dollar Giveaway of its Decision-Making Powers about Government Management (Washington,
to Private Management Consultants, “Experts,” DC: Deloitte, 2015). Figures are for 1983–2008.
and Think Tanks (New York: Pantheon, 1976), 281. Dahler-Larsen, “Surviving the Routinization of
p. 167. Evaluation,” p. 70.
270. Michael Morris and Lynette R. Jacobs, “You 282. Johnson, Greenseid, Toal, et al., “Research on
Got a Problem with That? Exploring Evaluators’ Evaluation Use.”
Efficient and Effective Governance 231

283. Yang and Pandey, “How Do Perceived Political 285. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Foun-
Environment and Administrative Reform Affect dation, Evidence-Based Policymaking, p. 3. Figure
Employee Commitment?” p. 335. is for 2009–2014.
284. Carol H. Weiss, Erin Murphy-Graham, Anthony 286. Weiss, “Research for Policy’s Sake,” pp. 535, 544.
Petrosino, and Allison G. Gandhi, “The Fairy 287. John Bridgeland and Peter Orszag, “A Moneyball
Godmother—and Her Warts,” American Journal Approach to Government,” Politico (October 18,
of Evaluation 29 (March 2008), pp. 29–47. The 2013).
quotation is on p. 29.
CHAPTER

The Public
Trough: Financing and
Budgeting Governments
I n government, money is blood. Currency courses
through the body politic, carrying with it civic
health or public pestilence, depending upon how
Federal General Revenue
General revenue accounts for 62 percent of total
governments derive and disburse their dollars. federal revenue, down by over a fourth from 89
percent in 1950.2
As we detail next, over the past seventy or so
DEFINING PUBLIC FINANCE years, the personal income tax has displaced vir-
Now for something more prosaic: definitions. tually all other sources of federal general revenue,
The basis for governments’ budgets is public Social Security and Medicare, which are retirement
finance, or the raising by governments of revenues and health insurance programs for people aged
that are then expended to fund public policies. Fiscal sixty-six and older, dominate special funds.
policy is government’s effort to fund public pro-
grams through its taxing, spending, and borrowing The Personal Income Tax The personal, or indi-
decisions. As a consequence of these decisions, the vidual, income tax, is a general tax on the annual
vast majority of Americans pay less in federal, state, income of each person. It began (aside from a few
and local taxes than they paid thirty years earlier.1 intermittent and brief appearances in the 1800s)
A general tax is the major method of generat- with the ratification, in 1913, of the Constitution’s
ing general revenue. General revenue, or general- Sixteenth Amendment, which permits the federal
purpose revenue, is money that the government government to tax all incomes. The personal
collects and may spend for any purpose. A general income tax accounts for a whopping 77 percent of
fund is that part of the public budget which is com- Washington’s general revenue, up by more than two-
posed of general revenue. General fund expendi- thirds from 46 percent in 1950.3
tures, or discretionary spending, is the allocation of
general revenue to fund any purpose. A special fund The Corporate Income Tax The corporate, or cor-
is composed of those revenues that may be expended poration, income tax is a general tax on the annual
only for a specific, pre-established purpose, or what profits of businesses. The first federal corporate
is known as nondiscretionary spending. income tax was enacted in 1909. It contributes 17
percent of general revenue, down by over two-fifths
from 30 percent in 1950.4
FINANCING THE FEDERAL
The Excise Tax The excise tax is a general tax
GOVERNMENT on specific items that usually is paid by their man-
Federal finance is fraught with foment. ufacturer. The main excise taxes are placed on
232
Financing and Budgeting Governments 233

companies that make gasoline, alcoholic beverages, 27 percent of total federal revenue, or more than a
telephone systems, and tobacco products. From quintupling from 5 percent in 1950.10
the Revolutionary War through the early twentieth
century, the excise tax was Washington’s most pro-
ductive tax. Today it accounts for less than 5 percent Federal Expenditures
of general revenue, falling by more than three- Federal expenditures top $4 trilllion per year. After
quarters from 22 percent in 1950.5 adjusting for inflation, federal spending exploded by
a startling fivefold from 1950 to 2005.11 In general,
Gift and Estate Taxes The gift tax is a general federal spending since 1950 gradually has lessened
tax on the transfer of property by one person for the military and enlarged for social programs,
to another, and the person making the transfer and formula-based expenditures have cut deeply
receives  nothing,  or less than full value, in return. into discretionary spending.
The estate tax is a general tax on a person’s right
to transfer his or her property when he or she dies. Spending on What? The federal government
Together, gift and estate taxes account for less than spends 71 percent of its money on payments for
1 percent of general revenue, or half of their take individuals, which are federal grants to individual
in 1950.6 persons. In any given year, 35 percent of the 219
million Americans with personal incomes, whether
from government or other sources, receive some
Social Insurance and Retirement Receipts kind of cash benefit from the federal government,12
Social insurance and retirement receipts are not but 55 percent of American adults (including major-
general revenue and cannot be used for discretion- ities of both Democrats and Republicans) have,
ary expenditures. They account for 33 percent of at one time or another, received these payments
total federal revenue, a tripling from 11 percent in to individuals in the form of benefits from the
1950.7 six major entitlement programs—Social Security,
The five special funds that comprise these Medicare, Medicaid, welfare, unemployment, and
receipts are: Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (or food stamps.13 Fifteen percent of federal dollars is
Social Security); Disability Insurance (nine major allocated to national defense, and 6 percent pays the
programs, targeted, for the most part, at people aged interest on the national debt.14
fifty to sixty-four); Hospital Insurance (or Medicare);
Unemployment Insurance; and relatively small sums Nondiscretionary versus Discretionary Expendi-
paid toward the retirement funds of federal and rail- tures Another way of understanding federal
road employees. expenditures is to separate them into nondiscretion-
Social Security and Medicare account for ary and discretionary spending.
84 percent of all social insurance and retirement Federal nondiscretionary spending is conducted
receipts.8 These two massive programs (which are through twenty-six major mandatory and related
primarily responsible for the fact that Washington programs, a category that includes interest on the
spends seven times more, per capita, on the elderly national debt and sixteen large entitlement pro-
than it spends on children9) are funded with what grams, such as Social Security and Medicare, which
are called, with unfortunate coyness, “insurance are funded by formulas.
contributions.” Insurance contributions are actu- In 1962, only 32 percent of all federal expendi-
ally a compulsory payroll tax, and they derive their tures had to be spent on mandatory and related pro-
name from the Federal Insurance Contributions Act grams, and a comfortable 68 percent was reserved
(FICA) of 1935, which underwrites Social Security for discretionary purposes. Over a half-century
and Medicare exclusively. Employers and employ- later, these proportions had more than reversed:
ees pay this tax in equal shares, and their combined 69 percent of spending is for nondiscretionary pro-
tax rate has quintupled from about 3 percent of grams, and 31 percent is for discretionary ones.15
payrolls in 1950 to over 15 percent currently. The We can gain a sense of the gravity of this rever-
payroll taxes collected through FICA account for sal when we realize that federal revenue amounts to
234 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

about 19 percent of gross domestic product (GDP); revenue because they may not be spent for any
mandatory programs spend around 13.6 percent purpose that the legislature chooses. Instead,  they
of GDP and are rising (in 1980, they accounted for are paid to, and kept by, the agency  providing
9.6 percent of GDP); and security-related programs the service. The rationale for including user  fees
expend about 5 percent of GDP. Discretionary civil- in general revenue is that governments are free to
ian programs are being ever more squeezed.16 choose to offer special services. No one mandated
that they do so; they did so at their discretion.

GRASS-ROOTS’ REVENUES Earmarking General Revenue Complicating


When we leave the world of Washington and con- further the role of general revenue at the grass roots
sider the financing of state and local governments, is the propensity of some governments to convert
new kinds, categories, and complexities of revenue general-purpose revenue into special purpose
emerge. revenue by earmarking general tax revenue for par-
ticular uses. California is a conspicuous example.
Some 500 amendments bind California’s constitu-
General Revenue tion, rendering it, after India’s, the longest and most
In these governments, general revenue officially is convoluted in the world, containing “so many set-
composed not only of general tax revenue, but also asides and mandates that the legislature can control
of intergovernmental revenue, fees collected from only about seven per cent of the budget.”18 The
users of special public services, and miscellaneous remaining 93 percent of general revenue effectively
general sources. has been reserved for special purposes, ranging from
prisons to schools.
Intergovernmental Revenue Intergovernmental
revenue is money that state and local governments
receive from other governments. Although intergov- Own Source Revenue
ernmental revenue is an official component of these Due to the presence of intergovernmental revenue,
governments’ general revenue, which, in theory, can state and local governments must identify their own
be spent for anything, it is problematic because, in source revenue, or income that these governments
reality, it typically arrives in state and local coffers garner from within their own boundaries.
in the form of grants that narrowly specify how they There are two types of own source revenue.
may be spent. The public finance community jus-
tifies its inclusion in general revenue because state General Revenue From Own Sources One type
and local governments, at their own discretion and is general revenue from own sources, which is all
volition, apply for and accept intergovernmental general revenue, other than intergovernmental
grants and spend the intergovernmental revenue revenue, collected by state or local governments—
in them. specifically, general taxes, service charges, and mis-
cellaneous general revenue.
User Fees A user fee, also called a service charge
or a fee for services, is generally related to a vol- Other Than General Revenue The other type is
untary transaction or request for government goods other than general revenue, which is own source
(such as a license to practice a profession) or services revenue that cannot be used for discretionary spend-
(such as hospital care) that are above and beyond ing. There are three official sources of other than
what is normally available to the public. Although general revenue.
user fees are appropriately associated with state
and local governments, the federal government also Insurance Trusts One is insurance trusts that are
collects user fees, amounting to about 1 percent of funded by government employees’ contributions to
federal general revenue.17 three special funds. The funds are: workers’ compen-
Like intergovernmental revenue, service charges sation funds for work-related injuries; unemploy-
somewhat flout the philosophic foundation of general ment insurance funds; and worker retirement funds.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 235

Utilities and Liquor Stores The two other it.23 The sales tax accounts for 46 percent of all state
sources of other than general revenue are tax revenue, down by over a fifth from 59 percent in
government-owned  and -operated utilities and 1950.24
liquor stores. Both collect customer payments for
publicly provided goods. State Income Taxes The decline in sales tax
Utilities are electric and gas power plants, revenue is attributable to the rise of the state
water and sewer works, and public transit. Most income tax. Wisconsin was the first state to impose
utilities  are owned by local governments. Most an  income tax, both personal and corporate,
liquor stores are owned by the seventeen states that in 1911.
have them, but only Pennsylvania and Utah exercise Forty-three states and the District of Columbia
complete control over all liquor sales. (FYI: alco- levy the personal income tax, including two, New
holic beverages cost 7 percent more, on average, Hampshire and Tennessee, which limit this tax
when sold in state-owned stores than in private- to dividends and interest income.25 Because of
ly-held stores.19) New  Hampshire’s and Tennessee’s limitations, the
literature commonly states that there are forty-
one  states with a “general,” or “broad-based,”
FINANCING STATE personal income tax. The individual income
tax  generates 37 percent of state tax revenue,
GOVERNMENTS more  than quadrupling its 9 percent share in
The fifty states collect more than $2.1 trillion in 1950.26
revenue annually.20 Forty-six states and the District of Columbia
use the corporate income tax,27 which accounts for
5 percent of all state tax revenue,28 down from its
State General Revenue 7 percent share in 1950.29 The 29 percent decline
Seventy-seven percent of total revenue is general of the state corporate income tax collections over
revenue, and 68 percent of the states’ general revenue more than seven decades has been attributed to
comes from their own sources.21 shrewd tax planning by corporations30 that occurs
As we elaborate next, intergovernmental in tandem with a cutthroat competition among state
revenue, the personal income tax, service charges, governments that are frantically lowering their cor-
and miscellaneous general revenue have grown porate income taxes to lure companies to relocate to
as the  states’ sources of general revenue, and at their states.31
the expense of the corporate income tax and the
sales tax. State Intergovernmental Revenue As shown
in Figure 8-1, intergovernmental revenue con-
State General Tax Revenue State general taxes tributes 31 percent of the states’ general revenue.
contribute 50 percent of all general revenue, having Intergovernmental revenue’s share of the states’
shrunk by 29 percent since 1950, when their share general revenue has grown by more than two-fifths
stood at an impressive 70 percent. Taxes’ portion of since 1950, when it accounted for 22 percent.32
own source general revenue, at 68 percent, has slid
by a fourth since 1950, when taxes accounted for 90 State Service Charges and Miscellany Charges
percent of own source general revenue.22 for services, led by education, account for 11
percent  of all general revenue and 16 percent of
The State Sales Tax The most important tax for general revenue that is derived from the states’ own
the states is the sales tax, which is a general tax on sources.
the selling price of goods and services that usually is The remaining sources of state general revenue
paid at the point-of-sale, such as a retail store. West are miscellaneous ones, primarily interest earnings
Virginia levied the first state sales tax in 1921, when but also special assessments and property sales,
states relied heavily on property taxes, and today among others. Miscellaneous general revenue
forty-five states and the District of Columbia impose accounts for 7 percent of total general revenue and
236 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Federal Government

Federal Direct Grants Federal Pass-Through Grants Federal Direct Grants


to the States: Estimated to the States: Estimated to Localities: 5% of
20% of State Revenue 10% of State Revenue Local Revenue

State Governments
Intergovernmental Revenue Accounts for 31% of State General Revenue

Local Payments Federal Pass-Through State Direct Grants


to the States: 1% of Grants Passed by States to Localities: 20% of
State Revenue to Localities: 11% of Local Revenue
Local Revenue

Local Governments
Intergovernmental Revenue Accounts for 36% of Local General Revenue

FIGURE 8-1
Intergovernmental Revenue as Percentages of State and Local Governments’ General Revenue, Fiscal Year 2013
Sources: As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local Government Finances by Level of Government and by State: 2013,”
Census of Governments, 2013 (Washington, DC: Author, 2016), and David B. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism: Slouching toward Washington, 2nd
ed. (New York: Chatham House, 2000), p. 227.
Note: “Estimated” intergovernmental revenue refers only to estimates of pass-through and direct grants as percentages of total federal grants to the
states and localities; all other percentages are not estimated, and are firm.

11 percent of general revenue that is derived from total state revenue (a decrease of about a sixth since
the states’ own sources.33 the mid-twentieth century, when its share was 28
Combined, service charges and miscellaneous percent), and 44 percent of state own source general
general revenue account for 18 percent of all general revenue (increasing by  more than a fifth from 36
revenue (more than doubling from 8 percent in percent). Insurance trusts, with a share of 96 percent,
1950) and 27 percent of own source general revenue dominate this category.35
(a tripling from 9 percent).34 These two sources, plus
the less dramatic rise in intergovernmental revenue,
largely explain why taxes are declining as contribu- State Expenditures
tors to the states’ general funds. In brief, state spending for public welfare and educa-
tion has displaced highways and kept other spending
flat over the last seven decades.
State Other Than General Revenue The states’ largest single expenditure for a
Other than general revenue (i.e., insurance trusts, governmental program, at 39 percent of all direct
utilities, and liquor stores) makes up 23 percent of general expenditures (that is, excluding general
Financing and Budgeting Governments 237

expenditures funded by intergovernmental revenue),


is public welfare, a tripling from 13 percent in FINANCING LOCAL
1950. Education accounts for 23 percent (about
four-fifths is for higher education), more than dou- GOVERNMENTS
bling from  10  percent in 1950, followed by hospi- America’s 90,056 local governments44—both
tals and  health at 9 percent (two-thirds of which general-purpose governments (i.e., counties, cities,
is for  hospitals, and  hospitals and health nearly towns, and townships), and special purpose govern-
match  the same proportion of 8 percent that they ments (school districts and special districts)—collect
had in 1950), and highways at 8 percent (less than over $1.7 trillion in revenue annually.45 Not surpris-
half of the 17 percent share that highways held in ingly, “fiscal management” has been “the dominant
1950).36 priority of city managers” (and likely of all top local
managers) ever since the first study of the issue was
conducted nearly forty years ago.46
State Tax and Expenditure Limitations
The states do not like to tax, or even spend, and
thirty states have imposed on themselves at least one Local General Revenue
tax or expenditure limitation, commonly known as General revenue accounts for 87 percent of all local
tax and expenditure limitations, or TELs.37 revenue, and 64 percent of local general revenue that
Seven state legislatures have legislated revenue comes from local governments’ own sources.47
limits on their own state governments, including Details follow, but, in summary, local taxes have
three that also limit state expenditures. In addition, declined as a share of local general revenue since
since Arkansas originated the practice, in 1934, 1950, but sales and personal income taxes have
sixteen states now require legislative “superma- increased their share of tax revenue at the expense
jorities,” ranging from 60 percent to 75 percent of of the property tax. Service charges, miscellaneous
legislators’ votes in both chambers, to raise some general revenue, and intergovernmental revenue
or all taxes, including three states that also require have grown as general revenue sources.
voter approval; one, Colorado, requires only voter
approval to raise taxes.38 Local General Tax Revenue General tax revenue
Twenty-six states cap expenditures, including contributes 35 percent of all local general revenue,
three that also limit taxes.39 a portion that has shrunk by nearly half since 1950,
The fiscal impact of these limits is small at when it accounted for 68 percent. Still, taxes con-
best.  Even the most effective tax-and-spend- tribute an impressive 64 percent of the general
tamping policies (most notably, legislative super- revenue that local governments collect from their
majorities and popular referenda) result in only own sources, a modest decline of 7 percent from
2 to 3 percent less spending, and, in the wealthier 69 percent in 1950.48
states, caps actually correlate with more spending!40
Others find that “the ineffectiveness of [state TELs] The Local Property Tax The principal general tax
is unambiguous.”41 for local governments is the property tax, an ancient
A study of TELs enacted in the forty-eight form of taxation that is a general tax on personal
contiguous states over twenty years found that, wealth. Homeowners pay the greatest share of the
contrary to their supporters’ claims, they had no tax, which, on average, amounts to 1 percent of their
effect on the growth of both personal income per homes’ value and 3 percent of their annual income.49
capita and employment per capita, but did cor- To determine a property’s value, governments
relate with a negative impact on a state’s level of (counties usually are responsible for the administra-
employment.42 Those TELs that place stricter limits tion of the property tax) hire and train professional
on state revenue correlate with lower credit ratings assessors, who employ one or more of the follow-
(leading to higher interest payments), whereas those ing assessment methods: base the property’s value
that restrict spending associate with higher credit on how much the property last sold for (a method
ratings.43 sometimes dubbed, with leaden irony, “welcome
238 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

stranger”); estimate the price that it currently municipalities, and is paid by more than 23 million
would fetch in the open market; estimate how much people.58 Local personal income taxes account for
it would cost to replace it; or estimate how much less than 5 percent of all local tax revenue, up from
sustainable net income it will produce. Once the a fraction of 1 percent in 1950.59
assessment is made, the property tax is levied on a Seven states permit their local governments
predetermined fraction (say, 60 percent) of the prop- to collect corporate income taxes. New York City
erty’s assessed value. accounts for 84 percent of all locally collected cor-
All states permit their local governments to levy porate income taxes, followed by the District of
property taxes, which generate 73 percent of all local Columbia, at 6 percent.60 The corporate income
tax dollars. In 1950, the property tax accounted for tax amounts to about 1 percent of all local tax
88 percent of local tax revenue, a share that has revenue.61
since slipped by a sixth. Even into the 1960s the
property tax continued to generate nearly nine out Local Service Charges and Miscellany Just prior
of ten dollars of tax revenue.50 to the tax revolt that was presaged, in 1978, by the
Bucking, but not reversing, this declining tax passage of California’s Proposition 13 (described
trend is the fact that local governments will, among in Chapter 1), which slashed local property taxes,
other revenue-raising responses, raise the property charges, or fees, for local services, accounted for a
tax when the states cut their intergovernmental aid. modest 11 percent of all municipal general revenue
Cities and towns offset these cuts by raising the in the country and 18 percent of cities’ general
property tax by an average of nine cents for each revenue that came from their own sources.62 Since
state dollar cut,51 and school districts raise it by 1977, after adjusting for inflation and population
twenty-three cents per dollar cut.52 shifts, user charges exploded by 143 percent per
Raising the property tax, however, can be capita in the 112 largest cities, while taxes other
self-defeating. When the average income-tax deduc- than the property tax shot up by 88 percent; the
tions permitted for interest on home mortgage property tax grew by a niggling 17 percent.63
payments and property taxes are doubled, average Today, charges, led by hospitals and sewerage,
spending per student in local public schools increases contribute nearly 18 percent of all local general
by 10 percent; it appears that spending for other ser- revenue and almost 28 percent of the general
vices may also increase.53 revenue that local governments draw from their
In part, the shrinking of the property tax is own sources.64 Charges have increased by nearly
attributable to state legislatures allowing their local two-thirds as a proportion of local general revenues
governments to introduce competing sales and since 1975, and by more than half as a share of local
income taxes. Forty-three states authorize their local general revenue from own sources.65
governments to levy, if they so choose, taxes on sales, Hiking fees for services is clearly the pre-
personal income, or both.54 ferred option for local governments. “Nearly three-
quarters” of city and town managers accord raising
The Local Sales Tax In 1950, just one state permit- service charges their “highest” preference (out of
ted at least some of its local governments to collect nine possible responses) for dealing with stressed
sales taxes,55 and today thirty-eight do.56 The sales budgets.66 Their attraction to service charges is
tax accounts for 12 percent of all local tax dollars, understandable. Unlike raising unpopular local
doubling from 6 percent in 1950.57 taxes, which only state legislatures can do, “all cities
have the discretion to impose charges.”67 In addition,
Local Income Taxes Philadelphia introduced the service charges also enable local (and, indeed, all)
first local tax on personal income, in 1939, and cur- governments to draw revenue from sources that are
rently seventeen states permit at least some types tax exempt, such as charitable organizations. Cities
of their local governments to impose a tax on indi- that have property tax limits and a strong-mayor
vidual incomes or payrolls. Although the number form of government, rather than a council-manager
of local individual income taxes is in decline, it form, are more likely to favor charges than those
still is used by 4,943 local jurisdictions, mostly that do not.68
Financing and Budgeting Governments 239

Together, 82 percent of cities and counties Washington is a large, and largely hidden, source of
employ “user fees” to deliver services (only the prop- local revenue.
erty tax, at 100 percent, ranks higher), a proportion Figure 8-1 above illustrates these intergovern-
that does not include several other categories that mental fiscal flows in terms of their percentages of
certainly sound like user fees, such as “development state and local general revenue.
review fees” (52 percent, the next highest), “local
impact fees” (37 percent), and “mortgage or prop-
erty transfer fees” (17 percent).69 Local Other Than General Revenue
The remaining sources of local general revenue Other than general revenue (i.e., utilities, insurance
are miscellaneous ones, led by interest earnings. trusts, and liquor stores) accounts for 13 percent of
Miscellaneous general revenue accounts for 5 total local revenue, up by more than two-fifths from
percent of all local general revenue and 8 percent 9 percent in the mid-twentieth century, and 23 percent
of the general revenue that local governments draw of local own source general revenue, up by more than
from their own sources.70 half from 15 percent.76 Almost two-thirds of other
Combined, service charges and miscellaneous than general revenue is generated by  local utilities,
general revenue account for 23 percent of all local followed by insurance trusts at over a third.77
general revenue (more than doubling from 11
percent in 1950) and 36 percent of own source
general revenue (also more than doubling, from Local Expenditures
17 percent).71 Succinctly stated, local expenditures for hospitals
and health have expanded, while those for highways
Local Intergovernmental Revenue Intergovern- and public welfare have shrunk as shares of direct
mental revenue, at 36 percent, surpasses by 1 general spending over some seventy years.
percent general tax revenue’s contribution to all Education accounts for 42 percent of total
local general revenue. Intergovernmental revenue’s direct general expenditures by all local governments,
share has increased by over a tenth since 1950, when not too far from its 39 percent share in 1950. More
it accounted for 32 percent.72 than four-fifths of education funds are disbursed by
On paper, at least, 87 percent of local intergov- school districts.
ernmental revenue is provided by state governments Eleven percent of total direct general spending
and 13 percent as direct federal grants.73 However, by all local governments is channeled to public safety
an estimated one-third of the intergovernmental (i.e., police, fire fighters, corrections, and inspec-
revenue that local governments receive from their tions). Six percent of the total goes to police, which
states has actually been furnished by Washington was less than 5 percent in 1950. Less than 8 percent
in the form of pass-through grants.74 Pass-through is allocated to hospitals and health (three-fifths of
grants are funds granted by the federal government which is for hospitals, and hospitals and health are
to the states with the stipulation that the states pass up by three-fifths from their better than 5 percent
on these funds to a “sub-recipient,” typically their share in 1950), followed by interest on the debt
local governments, for use in specific programs that and highways, each of which consumes 4 percent.
have been earmarked by Washington. (Highways accounted for nearly 12 percent in 1950,
If we count these federal pass-through a decline of two-thirds.) Public welfare accounts
grants  as intergovernmental revenue that local- for less than 4 percent of total direct expenditures,
ities receive  from Washington, rather than from down from over 9 percent in 1950, a decline of more
the states, then the money that Washington pro- than half; counties spend about six out of every ten
vides increases its share of local intergovernmental of welfare dollars.78
revenue, rising from 13 percent (in direct federal
grants only) to an estimated 42 percent (direct
grants plus pass-through grants). Washington’s Local Tax and Expenditure Limitations
contribution to local general revenue more than As with the states, local governments also have tax
triples from 5 percent to an estimated 16 percent.75 and expenditure limitations.
240 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

State-Imposed TELs Forty-six states have imposed local services, ranging from wastewater plants to
some form of TEL on their local governments. Four libraries. “These findings buttress previous reports
of these states, however, require only that their local that residents will pay for local public services and
governments fully disclose their finances, a wholly are willing to be reasonable when confronted with
reasonable “limitation.”79 matters of local public finance.”85 Stunningly, the
Four states limit their local governments’ poor are “overwhelmingly” more willing to pay for
general revenue growth, and eight limit local general local services than are the wealthy.86
expenditure growth.80
By far the states’ most favored form of local tax The Effects of Local TELs A massive study of
limitation, however, focuses on their local govern- TELs’ impact on the finances of 724 cities over
ments’ primary source of tax revenue, the property thirty-six years found that TELs’ overall impact is
tax. As early as the 1880s, when the states began the reverse of what its advocates believe, and actu-
granting home rule to their communities, legisla- ally leads to more revenue. “TELs lead to consid-
tures were restraining their local governments’ use erable reductions in property taxes but substantial
of the property tax,81 and today thirty-three states increases in sales taxes, income taxes, and user
limit property tax rates in their municipalities, coun- charges per capita. . .. resulting in a net gain of total
ties, or school districts, including twenty-three that municipal general own-source revenue per capita. . ..
impose this limit on all three types of local govern- TELs may have unintended consequences and lead
ment. A dozen states limit how much a property may to bigger government.”87
be assessed. Twenty-eight combine caps on both tax TELs also raise other costs to citizens. An anal-
rates and property assessments, a policy known as a ysis of nearly 2,700 counties over thirty years con-
property tax levy limit, which constrains the growth cluded that tax and expenditure limitations led to
of overall property tax revenue.82 increases in the counties’ service charges.88

Local Voter-Imposed TELs Voters in 13 percent


of cities have enacted TELs on their municipal gov-
ernments that are “distinct from (and more stringent TAXING TIMES: DETERMINING
than) any fiscal restriction imposed by their state gov- TOLERABLE TAXES
ernment.” Of these cities, 42 percent constrain prop-
In 1938, when taxes imposed by all governments
erty tax rates, 15 percent limit property tax levies,
relieved Americans, on average, of 17 percent of
and 7 percent cap assessments. Nine percent impose
their income, “nearly half” of the citizenry thought
limits on local sales taxes (no state legislature has
that they paid too much in taxes relative to what
done this83), and 6 percent limit their own general
they got in return. Today, a “remarkably similar”
revenue or expenditures. Voters in cities with home
46  percent think this, even though the average tax
rule charters, that are in metropolitan areas which
bite has nearly doubled.89
have few municipalities, and that have rapidly chang-
That Americans’ views of taxes remain fairly
ing populations are the most likely to adopt TELs.84
constant over time, even as their taxes rise, may
reflect tax systems that might be improving with age.
Do TELs Reflect Local Preferences? The irony in
local TELs, whether they are mandated by the states
or (in a small minority of municipalities) local voters, The Five Fundamental Features of
is that most local residents display a firm willingness Tolerable Taxes
to pay for local services. It is not at all clear that these
All tax systems share five features that determine
limitations actually are what most people want.
their tolerability to taxpayers. They are:90
A survey of more than 1,400 households
in politically and fiscally conservative Phoenix, ■ Transparency: A tax’s structure that taxpayers
Arizona, found that from more than half to nearly are able to understand.
four-fifths of all respondents were willing to pay ■ Administerability: Government can collect the
for twenty-three (or 82 percent) out of twenty-eight tax easily and cost-effectively.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 241

■ Simplicity: Low costs to taxpayers in The Federal Experience Income taxes are vital
complying with tax policy. to federal finance. Washington’s taxes on personal
■ Efficiency Costs: The price of creating and and corporate incomes amount to 54 percent of all
collecting the tax. federal revenue, and the federal government rakes in
■ Equity: The fairness of the tax. Happily, a 82 percent of all income-tax dollars collected by all
review of research on this issue concluded governments combined.96
that, “The United States has by far the most The downside of federal income taxes is that
progressive income, payroll, wealth and they fail, in the view of many, to fulfill the five crite-
property taxes of any developed country.”91 ria of a tolerable tax.
But, as we shall, see some equity problems
remain. Transparency Is Tarnished “Numerous tax provi-
sions have made it more difficult for taxpayers to
Adjusting any one of these elements invariably alters
understand how their tax liabilities are calculated,
each of the remaining four.
the logic behind the tax laws, and what other tax-
payers are required to pay.”97 Witness, for example,
the massive confusion among taxpayers concerning
Understanding the Income Tax tax policies: each year, the Internal Revenue Service
The income tax is the single most consequential and (IRS) receives 299 million website visits, 277 million
productive tax in public finance. website searches, and 77 million telephone calls, and
all concern taxpayers’ tax questions.98
Issues with Income Taxes Together, personal and
corporate income taxes account for almost two- Administerability Is Occluded Administerability is
fifths of all tax dollars collected by all governments, not merely the responsibility of the IRS, but is also a
including those governments that do not levy income duty of taxpayers, employers, tax professionals, and
taxes.92 a teeming host of others. Estimates of their adminis-
A regressive income tax taxes higher incomes trative costs range from $100 billion to $200 billion
at a lower rate than it taxes lower incomes. A pro- per year,99 so administerability is as important as the
portional income tax, or flat tax, taxes all incomes, word itself is awful.
high and low alike, at the same rate. A progressive
income tax taxes higher incomes at a higher rate Simplicity Is Scarce As we noted in the introduc-
than it taxes lower incomes. tion to Part III, the United States’ tax code totes up to
Although pollsters find that majorities of nearly four million words, and is the world’s longest.
Americans “have not heard the term ‘progres- France’s and Germany’s tax codes are less than a
sive taxes,’ philosophically it is the approach they tenth of the length of that of the United States.100
prefer.”93 Accordingly, most governments, including The instruction booklet accompanying Form
the federal one, that levy a broad-based personal 1040, the individual itemized income tax form, has
income tax try, at least nominally, to apply a mod- grown from two pages in 1935 to 211 pages today.
erately progressive tax rate; eight of the forty-one Individual income taxpayers, 94  percent of whom
states with this tax, however, levy flat tax rates on hire accountants or buy software to help them
personal income.94 prepare their tax returns, devote thirteen hours, on
The federal corporate income tax is ostensibly average, to tax preparation.101 There are no compre-
progressive, ranging from 15 to 35 percent. When hensive estimates of the cost to taxpayers of com-
the average state corporate income tax is included, plying with the federal tax system, but the broader
corporations in the top tax tier pay just under studies suggest a magnitude of 2 to 5  percent of
39 percent. GDP.102 Small wonder that 56 percent of Americans
The states emulate Washington, but use a differ- have a “negative reaction to doing their income
ent (and more straightforward) method: thirty-three taxes,” and 26 percent “hate doing them.” (Twenty-
of the forty-seven states with a corporate income tax nine percent rather like the experience, and 5 percent
employ a flat rate.95 “love” it.)103
242 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

The complexity and staggering size of the Its Social Security portion, which accounts for
federal tax code likely lower business activity. The more than four-fifths of the payroll tax, is quite
United States’ top two “most problematic factors for regressive. After an employee has been paid a set
doing business” are tax rates and tax regulations, amount ($118,500 in 2016) for the year, the Social
respectively.104 Security tax stops, and then re-starts at the begin-
ning of the next calendar year. (For example, if an
Efficiency Is Impaired Though difficult to measure, employee were paid $237,000 in 2016, then the
partial estimates “suggest that the overall efficiency contribution to Social Security would disappear
costs imposed by the tax system are large – on the from his or her paycheck after June, and reappear
order of several percentage points” of GDP.105 in January of 2017.) If an employee’s annual pay
Taxpayers’ voluntary compliance with tax does not exceed the pre-established payroll limit,
policy is central to a tax system’s efficiency, and it is then the tax never stops, and this is the case for
heartening that relatively few Americans deliberately the vast majority of Americans: about four-fifths
evade taxes. The untaxed underground economy in of all  Americans,113  an  astounding 86 percent of
the United States is estimated to be 8 percent of all households with wage earners, and about two-
GDP, compared with, say, Greece’s, at 30 percent.106 thirds of all taxpayers (including retirees, who pay
Nevertheless, because of persistent levels of noncom- no payroll tax), pay more in regressive payroll
pliance by less than 9 percent of American taxpay- taxes than they pay in progressive federal personal
ers, an estimated 16 to 17 percent of federal income income taxes.114
taxes owed go uncollected each year, figures that The remaining fifth of the payroll tax, Medicare,
decline by 3 points apiece after investigations are differs from Social Security in that it has no payroll
conducted.107 Reducing this net tax gap (about $385 cap, and is a flat tax. Nevertheless, the “average effec-
billion following recovery investigations) by just 1 tive tax rate” of the payroll tax, both Social Security
percent would fund, for example, the annual budget and Medicare combined, is clearly regressive, with
of the entire National Park Service.108 the richest fifth of payroll taxpayers taxed at a rate
that is more than two-fifths lower than the average
Equity Issues Tax expenditures—that is, exemp- rate paid by each of the remaining four fifths.115
tions, tax credits, deductions, exclusions, deferrals, The Corporate Income Tax: The federal cor-
preferential tax rates, and other loopholes—from porate income tax, like the personal one, also con-
federal personal and corporate income taxes more tains equity issues, notably that of at least eighty
than doubled over thirty years, and the tax revenue tax expenditures.116 As a result, and even though
lost because of them tripled.109 Today, there are an the federal corporate income tax ostensibly ranks
astonishing 169 personal and corporate income tax among the most burdensome such tax in the world,
expenditures, divided about equally between the two at least on paper, large profitable corporations paid,
income taxes, which reduce tax revenue by $1.23 on average over seven years, just 14 percent of
trillion annually, an amount comparable to federal their pretax income in federal taxes. At least two-
discretionary spending.110 thirds of all American corporations and 42 percent
Personal Income and Payroll Taxes: Due in part of the larger ones paid no federal tax over seven
to tax expenditures, 45 percent of American house- years, and nearly a fifth of all large companies that
holds, almost all of them at the lower income rungs, made a profit paid no federal tax over five years.117
pay no federal personal income tax at all.111 Likely Washington loses more than $181 billion annually
because of the complexity engendered by this tangle in corporate income tax revenue because of tax
of tax expenditures, taxpayers do not always claim expenditures.118
what they are due; 14 percent of tax filers fail, for
example, to collect an education credit for which
they are probably eligible.112 Understanding the Sales Tax
A different sort of inequity pervades that The sales tax is the purview of the states, accounting
important variant of the personal income tax, the for 34 percent of the states’ (and almost 11 percent of
compulsory payroll tax (or FICA, described earlier). local governments’) own source general revenue.119
Financing and Budgeting Governments 243

A Regressive Tax Although the sales tax taxes although it is generally less regressive than the sales
all consumers at the same rate, its burden inevita- tax.125
bly falls on those consumers who are poor. Because As a practical matter, the property tax con-
the poor must spend a greater proportion of their centrates on people’s homes as its major source of
money on essentials, such as medicine and food, the revenue. Middle-class homeowners have a relatively
indigent effectively are taxed at a higher rate than large portion of their wealth tied up in their resi-
are the wealthy. dences. By contrast, the wealthy have proportion-
States have attempted to alleviate the more ately less of their wealth parked in their homes.
regressive elements of the sales tax by exempting Hence, the property tax collects a greater propor-
basic necessities. All of the forty-five states with a tion of the middle class’s wealth than it collects from
sales tax exempt prescription drugs, and thirty-seven the rich. It also collects relatively more money from
exempt groceries.120 These sorts of measures relieve, the poor. The poor rent their homes more frequently
but cannot eliminate, the sales tax’s structurally than the better-off classes, and their landlords pass
regressive nature. on the cost of their property taxes to their tenants.

Issues of Inequity, Intricacy, and Obscurantism In Relieving Regression State governments have
addition, the sales tax seems to be uncommonly attempted to ameliorate the regressiveness of the
buffeted by the political winds of the day. Powerful local property tax through four main mechanisms.
(or at least stealthy) legislators have been known to One is assessing or taxing residential property
exempt favored constituents from the sales tax with less than commercial property. Half the states either
no apparent economic or philosophic rationale for assess residential property at lower levels (eighteen)
doing so. or tax residential property at lower rates (seven)
Florida’s legislature, for example, has exempted than commercial property.
some 440 transactions from its sales tax, thereby Another is the circuit breaker, which auto-
exempting more than two-fifths of all purchases matically “trips” when the property tax overloads
and slashing sales tax revenue by more than three a property owner’s pre-established income level.
out of every ten sales-tax dollars.121 Charges for The owner is not required to pay above that level.
charter fishing trips in Florida’s waters are exempt, Thirty-five states have circuit breaker programs, and
but not charges for fishing rods; food for racehorses two-thirds of these states offer circuit breakers to
is exempt, but not food for cats and dogs; lawn renters as well as to homeowners.126 Because circuit
mowing services are exempt, but not lawn mowers. breakers often are poorly publicized and application
One state senator confessed that he had voted procedures can be onerous, however, it appears that
unwittingly for many of these exemptions because perhaps less than half of eligible property owners
they had been “sneaked through.”122 take advantage of circuit breakers.127
Florida is by no means the exception. Thirty Forty-seven states protect homeowners through
states have exempted the sale of custom computer homestead exemptions, which shield from property
programs, and thirteen exempt “repairers.”123 The taxes some portion of the value of a home, or through
logic justifying these and other exemptions is not property tax credits, which straightforwardly reduce
obvious. the property tax bill. Twenty-six states apply one or
both of these interrelated policies to nearly all home-
owners, and the remainder limit them to the elderly
Understanding the Property Tax (eighteen states), disabled (twenty-three), or veterans
The property tax, as the principal tax for local gov- (forty-one). Fifty-seven percent of these programs
ernments, accounts for 47 percent of local govern- are funded entirely by local governments, 28 percent
ments’ (and 1 percent of state governments’) own by the states, and 15 percent by local and state gov-
source general revenue.124 ernments.128
While helpful, these attempts to ameliorate the
Another Regressive Tax As with the sales tax, property tax cannot render it progressive because, as
the  property tax has some regressive elements, with the sales tax, it is structurally regressive.
244 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

America’s Most Disliked Tax The property tax government. State government revenues, for
is the most disliked tax among Americans.129 Not example, decrease as the wealth gap widens
only does it penalize property taxpayers with fixed because  the rich can, and do, shield their incomes
incomes, but it also has severe problems of adminis- and assets more effectively than the poor and
terability because it relies on the varying consistency middle class. Furthermore,  the rich spend  propor-
of government assessors who determine the value of tionately less of their income  than  others, thereby
individual properties—a “lack of uniformity” that is limiting revenue  generated  by the sales tax, on
its “greatest problem.”130 which the states rely far more heavily than do the
federal and local governments. “A one-unit increase
in the share of income going to the top percentile [of
THE FUTURE OF TAXES income earners] had a negative impact on [state] tax
Whether federal, state, or local, tax systems cry for revenue growth.”136
reform. A major reason (but not the only reason) A related consequence is that income inequal-
why reform is critical is the widening wealth gap, ity stymies needed public policymaking. The greater
which has been accelerated, in part, by tax policy. the income inequality, the deeper the political polar-
ization of the United States, which leads directly to
political gridlock.137
The Widening Wealth Gap and Its Crushing It follows that higher income inequality cor-
Consequences relates strongly and positively with less social and
About three-fifths of the public agree or strongly economic upward mobility.138 Forty-three percent
agree that “differences in income in America [are] of American children born to the poorest families
too large,” a figure that has remained in this numer- (the bottom fifth in income) remain in poverty as
ical ballpark since the late 1980s.131 adults, and a slender 4 percent become the highest
Americans’ belief is founded on fact. Since earners.139
1979, the top 1 percent of income earners more Additional destructive social effects of wide
than doubled their share of the nation’s inflation- wealth inequalities include higher rates of homicide,
adjusted, after-tax income, rising from 8 percent to infant mortality, drug abuse, obesity, teenage births,
17 percent, and now account for nearly 24 percent and imprisonment, and lower rates of life expec-
of Americans’ total income, a share that has not tancy and educational performance.140
been seen since 1928. For the most affluent fifth, Reforming tax policies, whether federal, state,
income increased by 10 percent; for the three-fifths or local, can reduce the deleterious effects of the
of the population in the middle, it declined by 2 to wealth gap. There can be additional benefits as well,
3 percent, and, for the bottom fifth, income slid by but, depending on the reform, some damage is possi-
18 percent.132 Over thirteen years, the middle class ble, too. We consider these next.
shrank in every single state.133 America’s income gap
is not only far wider than Europe’s (with the single
exception of Georgia), Canada’s, and Japan’s, but Rethinking Federal Taxes
it is even wider than India’s, Iran’s, and Uganda’s, Proposals for federal tax reform range from the
among others.134 incremental to the radical.
Well, so what? So quite a lot, actually. Putting
aside concerns over social justice that a wide wealth Reforming Federal Income Taxes A satisfying
gap can engender, the gap also has some very practi- 61 percent of Americans (including majorities of
cal, and destructive, effects. Democrats, Republicans, and independents) view
For one, large income disparities damage econo- their own federal tax payments as fair, and most
mies. Greater income inequality associates with less regard paying taxes as a civic duty. At least three-
rapid economic growth, whereas lesser inequality fifths of Americans, however, are deeply troubled by
correlates with faster growth.135 their perception that some corporations and wealthy
Lower economic growth associates, obvi- people do not pay their fair share of federal income
ously, with lower tax revenue for all levels of taxes.141
Financing and Budgeting Governments 245

Enter reform. Proposed reforms of the income that a federal sales tax is a “good idea,” and nearly
tax focus on the rich, tax expenditures, and simpli- two-fifths believe that it is a bad one.148
fication. Another consumption tax is the value-added
tax, or VAT, which taxes the difference between a
Bracketing the Top The concentrating, after- firm’s sales and its purchases of goods and services,
tax real income at the top has been abetted by the logic being that each sale marks a value added
federal income tax policies that, over three decades, to the product purchased. The VAT also has been
increasingly have favored the very rich.142 The top defined, less charitably, as “an embedded sales tax
tax  bracket taxes individual annual incomes of that hides all those nickels and dimes along the pro-
about $400,000 and higher at 39.6 percent. But the duction chain.”149 Introduced in 1954 by France,
top 400 earners rake in, on average, nearly a thou- the VAT is now used by 136 countries, every one
sand times that amount, or almost $345 million of which also has an income tax. There is some evi-
annually per capita.143 Not only would a few more dence that a value-added tax may be “less expen-
brackets at the top bring in “tens of billions of sive to administer than an income tax,” although it
dollars” in new revenue, but they also would vastly is complex and compliance burdens are weighty.150
improve tax equity, with only marginal effects on
the remaining four factors. Adding more progres-
sive tax brackets is a proposed reform that, perhaps Rethinking State and Local Taxes
unsurprisingly, garners “overwhelming support” “Every state fails the basic test of tax fairness. . .. The
among taxpayers, both conservative as well as lower one’s income, the higher one’s overall effec-
liberal.144 tive state and local tax rate.”151 Still, over twenty-
seven years, combined federal and state tax policies
Tackling Tax Expenditures Eliminating or nar- reduced income inequality; about two-thirds of that
rowing tax expenditures, particularly the two largest reduction is attributable to the feds.152
loopholes—employer contributions to medical The poorest fifth of Americans (who earn less
insurance premiums and deductions of mortgage than $18,000) pay, on average, nearly 11 percent
interest on owner-occupied homes—not only would of their incomes in state and local taxes, and the
render Washington’s income taxes more equitable, rate steadily decreases, without exception, for each
but also more efficient, simple, transparent, and wealthier quintile that follows, one after the other.
administerable.145 For example, on average, the next poorest fifth pays
slightly less than 10 percent; the wealthiest fifth
Simplifying Taxes Simplifying income reporting pay not even 8 percent, and the top 1 percent (who
by integrating the personal and corporate income earn a minimum of $419,000) pay a bit more than
taxes, or by replacing their progressive rates with flat 5 percent. In the ten states with the most regressive
ones, would improve the system’s efficiency, simpli- taxes, the poorest fifth can pay a rate that is as much
city, and administerability, but perhaps not its equity as seven times higher, and the middle fifth can pay a
and transparency.146 rate that is up to three times higher, than that of the
richest 1 percent.153
A Federal Tax on Consumption? Some reformers As one would expect, the ten most regressive
focus not on income but on outgo, and urge that states heavily rely on sales and excise taxes for their
Congress eliminate, or at least radically reduce, the revenue, and provide no circuit breakers for the
income tax and make up the loss with some sort of property tax; five of these states have “little or no
consumption tax. American consumption taxes (i.e., income tax,” three tax income at a flat rate, and two
sales and excise taxes) currently account for about have a “low top rate.”154
4 percent of GDP, much less than in Europe.147 The personal income tax, however, is not
Consumption taxes, while rife with equity issues, immune. Of the forty-one states with broad-
can generate immense revenue. based personal income taxes, all but one (and the
One such proposal is the imposition of a national District of Columbia) copy large swaths of the
retail sales tax. Less than a fourth of Americans think income tax expenditures found in the federal tax
246 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

code—loopholes that often associate with effectively went to Harvard”157), economists generally agree
regressive tax bills. Although these forty states are that, as long as annual deficit spending does not
not obliged to link their tax expenditures with federal surpass annual economic growth, deficits cause little
ones, the states appear to follow Washington’s lead; economic harm. Many economists peg a relatively
when the federal personal income tax was last over- safe rate of deficit spending at around 2 percent of
hauled, in 1986, “most [states] accepted the bulk of GDP or lower, and a perilous rate at 5 percent or
the changes.” Should the states copy the hypothetical higher.158
elimination of forty-two of the major federal per-
sonal income tax expenditures (which account for The Awful Eighties The federal budget balanced
80 percent of foregone federal revenue), then total (that is, income equaled or surpassed outlays) in
state individual income tax revenue would increase two-thirds of the 129 years stretching from 1789 to
by 34 percent.155 1916, after which fiscal discipline deteriorated.159
So, how should states and localities reform In only four years since 1950 have there been
their tax systems? Eliminate or reduce their reliance surpluses. Historically, deficits have not been large
on regressive taxes, particularly the sales tax, and as a percentage of GDP, but, beginning in the 1980s,
introduce or refine progressive taxes, especially the this tradition was abandoned, as Washington’s
personal income tax. The catch here, however, is “commitment to traditional fiscal rules, such as bal-
that the states’ income taxes, both personal and cor- ancing revenues and spending . . . eroded.”160
porate, are highly volatile and are becoming more In just three years, deficits doubled from 3
so, and the revenue that they generate is growing percent of GDP in 1980, to an astonishing 6 percent
at an ever-slowing rate, a “nasty combination” that in 1983, and, by 1992, deficit spending had increased
renders budgeting even more difficult.156 fivefold. Observers attribute this quintupling to the
“watershed” Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of
1981, which cut individual income taxes by about a
OF DEFICITS AND DEBTS: fourth but ignored spending.161
Before 1980, conservatives had routinely
WASHINGTON’S GIFTS accused Washington of “tax-and-spend” profligacy;
Much of the fiscal turmoil that is battering govern- after 1980, this profligacy was better described as
ments can be laid at Washington’s door. “borrow and spend”—or, as some wags would have
it, “spend and spend.”

Understanding Federal Deficits


A deficit occurs when a government’s annual spend- Congress’s Quixotic Quest: Decreasing
ing exceeds its annual income. To make up the dif- Deficits, 1985–2001
ference, the government raises taxes or borrows Americans understand the gravity of the big and
money. For well over a generation, Congress has unremitting deficits of the last four decades. “A
favored lower taxes and bigger borrowing. sweeping majority,” 70 percent, worry about the size
of the federal deficit “some” or “a lot.”162
Federal Deficits and the Economy In general, Congress listened, and launched a long, and
small or no federal deficits and little or no federal quixotic, quest to lower deficit spending.
borrowing are good for the economy because they
lower long-term interest rates and check inflation. Failure Initially, Congress enacted two laws
Under certain circumstances, such as a recession, designed to bring the deficit under control: the
even very high deficit spending can actually help Balanced Budget and Emergency Deficit Control
restore the economy’s health. Acts of 1985 and 1987. The 1985 act was designed
Keeping in mind the caveat that economics is a to achieve a balanced budget by 1990, which the
field distinctive for its disputatiousness (as a distin- 1987 act extended to 1993, through sequestration,
guished economist once remarked, “Ask five econo- or a series of automatic, across-the-board spend-
mists and you’ll get five different answers—six if one ing cuts (interest payments and most entitlement
Financing and Budgeting Governments 247

programs were exempt) that would come into play Congress almost immediately ignored the caps,
if the federal budget did not fall within $10 billion indulging in a spending frenzy that vitiated the
of targeted deficit reductions. Congress avoided the PAYGO principle that it had adopted in 1990. (In
unpleasantness of sequestration by adopting overly 2010, at the president’s request, Congress passed
optimistic economic forecasts in its budget making, the Statutory Pay-As-You-Go Act, which reinstated
and the laws never lived up to expectations. PAYGO in law, a status that “can help prevent
further deterioration” of federal finances, but will
Success Congress got relatively tough in 1990 and not balance budgets.166) Congressional wiliness in
passed the Budget Enforcement Act. The legislation circumventing the caps took many creative forms,
required that new discretionary spending, new tax including simply raising the cap limit, but a favorite
cuts, and congressional expansion of entitlement was the use of “emergency” funding, which was
programs (but, significantly, not budgetary expan- exempt under the act. “Emergencies” included
sions that were already built into the design of these funding the decennial census, an item that has been
programs) must be offset with new, or reallocated, in the Constitution for all or parts of four centuries.
revenue. This requirement was known as “PAYGO,” Average annual emergency funding in 1999–2002
an acronym for “pay as you go.” PAYGO’s spending was five times greater than in 1991–1998.167
caps were set in the legislation to expire automati-
cally in 2002. Nirvana Attained? The Budget Surpluses In 1999
(Fiscal Year 1998), the federal government not
Cents and Sensibility The Omnibus Budget only had no deficit, but also produced an impres-
Reconciliation Act of 1993, which passed the Senate sive surplus of $70 billion. It was the first surplus
by one vote (the vice president’s), raised taxes by in twenty-nine years, or since 1968, when a modest
some $250 billion, and cut programs by a similar surplus of $3 billion was achieved. In 2000, the
amount, over five years. Mostly as a result of the surplus hit $127 billion, and, in 2001, $236 billion.
act and its predecessor, the Budget Enforcement Act, Though welcome, these surpluses were not
from 1992 to 2000 federal spending as a percent- wholly deserving of full-throated cheering because
age of GDP declined steadily by about 1 percent per they included (as do all federal deficit/surplus cal-
year.163 culations) the surpluses generated by Social Security
and the Postal Service. Because Washington does
Frustration and Finances In 1996, a still-frustrated not include these unique “off-budget entities” in its
Congress passed the Line-Item Veto Act, which, spending (i.e., in its budgets), but does include them
remarkably, granted the president the line-item in its revenue, its books look better than they are.
veto, or rescission, which is the power of the elected For instance, including the off-budget entities in the
chief executive to delete parts of a bill passed by the surplus budgets would have converted the 1999 and
legislature, but still sign the remaining bill into law. 2000 surpluses into deficits and eradicated most of
(Forty-three governors have this authority.) In 1998, the 2001 surplus.168
the Supreme Court ruled that the act was unconsti-
tutional because it allowed the president to “cancel”
a budget item, rather than “decline to spend” it.164 Federal Fiscal Follies, 2001–2012
It seems clear that rescission would have lowered Washington welcomed the millennium with una-
deficits. If presidents had had the line-item veto, they bashed and unprecedented fiscal irresponsibility.
would have trimmed federal spending by an average In 2001, Congress passed, at the president’s
of nearly 7 percent annually over five years.165 urging, the Economic Growth and Tax Relief
Reconciliation Act, which cut federal taxes by a
Congressional Cheating Despite declining deficits, record $1.35 trillion over ten years. Congress added,
deficit wrangling intensified, and, in 1997, Congress expanded, accelerated, or deepened these and other
enacted the Balanced Budget Act, which solemnly cuts over the ensuing six years.
pledged to eliminate federal deficits by 2002 via As revenue shriveled, spending splurged. In
more stringent spending caps. 2002, the Budget Enforcement Act’s spending caps
248 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

automatically terminated and, with them, any legal When the deadline for raising the debt ceiling
obstacles (no matter how limp) to profligacy. After came up for renewal, in 2011, many of Congress’s
eight years in which federal spending as a percentage new members (who were far more passionate about
of GDP had steadily declined, federal spending as a smaller, more constrained government than bal-
percentage of GDP actually grew, from 18 percent of anced budgets) insisted that they would vote not to
GDP in 2001 to over 20 percent in 2007.169 raise it unless it was accompanied by spending cuts
Compounding these trends was war. Between and no new taxes. And they had the votes to block it.
2001 and 2016, the wars on terror (e.g., Afghanistan, The political establishment was shocked. The
Iraq, Pakistan, Syria), including interest rates on debt ceiling had been raised routinely since the
borrowed money to fund them (about $500 billion), Second Liberty Bond Act of 1917 established it.
cost nearly $3.7 trillion; when projected costs to The business establishment was even more
care for veterans are included, the total reaches shaken, and understandably so. If the ceiling were
almost $4.8 trillion. Other than World War II, the not extended, then the nation would default on its
wars on terror were America’s costliest. And, unlike debts. Default, or a debtor’s illegal refusal to pay a
other American wars, which were funded largely by debt, would assure long-term economic catastrophe.
taxes, the wars on terror were funded almost entirely To continue paying its debts, and avoid catastrophe,
by borrowing.170 Washington would have to cut spending by some
Needless to say, these foolhardy fiscal policies $600 billion per year, cuts that would be pretty cat-
affected federal deficits, which, like a bad penny, astrophic in and of themselves.173
returned in 2002. Calamity was barely averted when, with just a
few hours remaining before the United States would
Fiscal Free-Fall and Keynesian Cures Then the be forced to stiff its creditors, Congress raised the
bottom fell out. In the final days of 2007, the United debt ceiling. The price was steep: No new revenues
States spiraled into economic free-fall, and sank into but significant spending cuts—$917 billion over ten
the deepest recession since the Great Depression of years.
the 1930s. It got worse. In 2011, one of the three principal
In response, Washington applied Keynesian credit rating firms lowered its rating of long-term
measures. Between 2008 and 2010, Congress cut U.S. Treasury bonds from AAA, the highest possible
taxes even deeper and pumped almost $2 trillion rating (which all rating agencies had accorded the
into the economy. As a consequence, from 2009 bonds since 1941), to AA+, the next highest, because
through 2012 federal deficits were considerably the firm’s analysts were concerned about the size of
more than $1 trillion per year and, astoundingly, the U.S. debt and, even more, by Washington’s ina-
ranged from 7  percent to more than 10 percent of bility to deal with it.
GDP. Times have been worse. The World War II The debt-ceiling brawl itself cost more than an
years saw deficits ranging from 14 to 30 percent of additional $1.3 billion in added federal borrowing
GDP.171 Still, it is worth keeping in mind that only costs and employee overtime,174 during which the
eight nations have GDPs that are larger than each stock market plummeted by 17 percent. Household
one of America’s trillion-dollar-plus deficits.172 wealth fell by $2.4 trillion between the second and
third quarters of 2011.175
Stupidity Squared By 2011, Washington was bor- Americans were not pleased with what they
rowing forty-one cents out of every dollar that it viewed as an irresponsible political circus that rattled
spent, and, in January of that year, the largest fresh- their, and the globe’s, confidence in the nation’s
man class in more than sixty years entered the House fiscal accountability. “Nearly three-quarters” of
of Representatives. It was a perfect storm. Americans polled “offered a negative word” about
The storm sought to drown the debt ceiling. This the budget negotiations, led by “ridiculous,” “dis-
misleading moniker implies that Congress votes to gusting,” and “stupid”; “just 2 percent had any-
incur yet more debt, but, in reality, the debt ceiling thing nice to say.”176 A clear majority favored, and
merely requires that Congress vote to pay the nation’s still favors, what virtually every economist believes
debt that Congress itself already has racked up. is a necessity: a balanced approach to a balanced
Financing and Budgeting Governments 249

budget,  one that includes more revenue as well as passed a Bipartisan Budget Act, which raised the
less spending.177 dollars permitted under the sequestration caps
for fiscal years 2014 through 2015 in exchange
Stupidity Cubed The law that raised the debt ceiling for extending sequestration to 2022 and 2023. In
was the Budget Control Act of 2011, which also 2015, Congress passed another Bipartisan Budget
stipulated that, if Congress failed to produce at least Act, which increased spending by $112 billion. The
$1.2 trillion in cuts before 2013, then, from 2013 relieving result of both acts was that there were no
to 2021, an annual across-the-board sequestration defense and nondefense sequestration cuts made in
totaling $1.2 trillion would automatically take place. fiscal years 2014 through 2017.
These mindless sequestrations were widely viewed
as so destructive (61 percent of Americans, including An Awful Anachronism The federal debt ceiling is
majorities in both parties, would undo some or all of an anachronism. The only other democratic nation
the cuts, compared with just 18 percent who would with a comparable policy is Denmark.
keep all of them178) that Congress would be forced Most American states also have debt caps, but
to make more reasoned cuts and add revenue. they are designed for flexibility and not to cap the
Wrong. Sequestration began in 2013, and, over total debt level. More often than not, for example,
that fiscal year alone, nineteen out of twenty-three the states express these caps as ratios (e.g., 4 percent
agencies surveyed curtailed hiring and/or cut train- of personal income), which reflect natural economic
ing, sixteen reduced or delayed contracts for “core growth, and eschew Washington’s policy of using
mission activities,” and seven furloughed 770,000 absolutist dollar amounts, a policy that increasingly
employees.179 Sixty-one percent of federal contrac- is causing grave fiscal mischief.186
tors surveyed reported significant revenue losses
due to sequestration.180 It cost the states more than
$5 billion in federal grants and loans.181 Locally, A Remarkable Reversal, 2013–Present
sequestration cut 41,000 very poor households from Despite congressional hostility to raising taxes, in
rent assistance and enlarged class sizes in some ele- 2013 thirteen federal taxes went into effect that
mentary schools, among other negative effects.182 were new, renewed, raised, or phased, ranging
Sequestration cost Americans an estimated 1.6 from increased rates on capital gains on the highest
million jobs over the year.183 incomes, to the automatic renewal of the higher, pre-
Internationally, sequestration (along with the 2011 payroll tax for Social Security and Medicare.187
federal government’s partial shutdown of 2013, These taxes, plus spending cuts initiated in the same
discussed later) altered national defense policies; a year and lower-than-anticipated healthcare costs and
former high American Defense executive reported interest rates, resulted, beginning in 2013, in annual
that his colleagues in four large Asian countries deficits that were less than $1 trillion. In Fiscal Year
agreed “that sequestration helped convince them 2015, the deficit was 2.5 percent of GDP; it is pro-
[of] the need to start adjusting strategic perspective jected that deficits will range from 2.3 to 3.3 percent
to accommodate a rise of China because apparently of GDP from fiscal years 2016 to 2021 and quite
the U.S. has a dysfunctional system and they can’t possibly less thereafter, as their trajectory after 2016
even pay their government employees.”184 is essentially downhill. Since 2012, deficit spending
In the same year that sequestration began, has fallen at a faster rate than at any time since the
Representatives introduced a bill that would estab- end of World War II.188
lish a national park on the moon! (We are not making This trend is very good news indeed: a perma-
this up.) One is reminded of Walter Lippmann’s nent deficit reduction of only 1 percent as a share
famous phrase: “With exceptions so rare they are of GDP would, after fifty years, amount to nearly
regarded as miracles of nature, successful democratic $2,000 in real higher annual income for every man,
politicians are insecure and intimidated men.”185 woman, and child in the United States.189
In an apparent reality test of Lippmann’s assess- Still, difficulties remain. Under current policies,
ment, an intimidated Congress, in 2013, reacted Social Security’s trust fund will be “exhausted” by
to the broad revulsion of its own recklessness and 2033,190 and Medicare’s trust (whose shortfalls for
250 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

just the program’s prescription benefit “alone exceed 101 percent of GDP from 2016 to 2021. (The gross
the unfunded obligations for Social Security”191) debt’s record was achieved in 1946, when its share
will remain fully solvent only until 2024.192 was 122 percent of GDP.)198
Among those developed countries with the
highest total-debt-to-GDP ratios, the United States
Understanding Federal Debt ranks seventh. (Japan tops the list.) Almost 31
Big deficits bring big debt. The federal government percent of it is owed to foreign countries, led by
owes a total debt of nearly $19.6 trillion193 (a sum China, which is owed less than 8 percent, followed
projected to hit more than $23 trillion by 2021), or closely by Japan.199 The United States would have
102 percent of annual GDP.194 Congress incurred to cut costs or raise revenues by nearly 12 percent
the nation’s first debt in 1790 ($75 million to finance to bring down its gross debt to a reasonable level
the Revolution), and the only year in which the by 2030; by contrast, that figure in twenty-five
United States had no debt was in Fiscal Year 1834 developed countries amounts to an average of
(1834–1835). 8 percent.200
Historically, a humongous federal debt has
been an aberration. From the nation’s first fiscal What Are the Consequences of Big Debt? It is not
year of 1797, the federal debt as a percentage of entirely clear how debt, whether national or total,
the economy “rose substantially only as the result affects the economy. Economists find “some evi-
of wars and recessions.”195 After 1980, however, this dence” of a positive correlation between slow eco-
pattern changed radically, even though the times nomic growth and high governmental debt, but are
were mostly peaceful and prosperous. unsure about which one causes the other.201 What
is clearer is that a large debt: often requires higher
Public, or National, Debt The traditional type of interest payments on it, thereby mandating higher
federal debt is public, or national, debt, which is taxes or reduced services; hinders “policymakers’
composed largely of the federal government’s debts ability to use tax and spending policies to respond
owed to foreign countries and to holders of its to unexpected challenges”; and heightens “the prob-
bonds, such as U.S. Savings Bonds. ability of a sudden fiscal crisis.”202
In 1980, public debt accounted for nearly 26 As we detail later in the chapter, state and local
percent of GDP. By the fall of 2007, just prior to the governments are far less saddled by big debt than
advent of the Great Recession, it had swollen by a is their federal cousin, and the same may be said of
third to over 35 percent. Public debt peaked at more the nonprofit sector, which seems to manage its debt
than 74 percent in 2015, and was projected to range more frugally than the public one. It is estimated to
from more than 75 percent to nearly 77 percent of have from $440 billion to $550 billion in total long-
GDP from 2016 to 2021. (The public debt’s all- term debt, spending over $20 billion, or 3.7 percent
time record in this regard was achieved in 1946, of its total debt, a year in interest payments. All in
when it accounted for not quite 109 percent of the all, there is “a fairly conservative and judicious use
economy.)196 Today, nearly half of the public debt is of debt by the nonprofit sector.”203
the direct result of wars and tax cuts.197

Gross, or Total, Debt The other sort of federal debt SUBNATIONAL SORROWS
is relatively new and is known as gross, or total, debt, Subnational governments borrowed recklessly
or public debt plus intragovernmental debt, which during the early nineteenth century to fund infra-
is composed mostly of debts owed to trust funds, structure projects, and, by 1840, they were defaulting
notably those of Social Security and Medicare. on their debts on a massive scale. One consequence
Between 1980 and the fall of 2007, the gross of these defaults is that all the states closely restrict
debt’s share of GDP nearly doubled, from 33 the finances of their local governments. Another
percent to 64 percent. It peaked in 2014 at almost is that forty-nine states now require that their
104 percent of GDP, and was projected to steadily budgets be balanced, and the sole state that does
decline from over 105 percent to a bit more than not, Vermont, “typically has a balanced budget.”204
Financing and Budgeting Governments 251

Besides providing fiscal responsibility, balanced the total, this analysis includes costs associated with
budget requirements also blunt the capacity of state public employees and healthcare-related tax breaks.)
politicians to shift state spending to more politically American governments’ healthcare spending, at
visible programs (usually at the expense of educa- 11.2 percent of GDP, surpasses the total healthcare
tion), such as corrections and welfare, just prior to expenditures of any other nation, including those
gubernatorial elections.205 that provide universal healthcare.211
Admittedly, some state governments have played These impressive figures have particular signif-
games in balancing their budgets (as has Congress), icance for the grass-roots governments. Over three
such as leaving what “balanced budget” means decades, state and local governments’ health-related
undefined, borrowing long-term to fund current spending nearly doubled, from 12 percent of overall
expenditures, or omitting long-term spending obli- expenditures to 20 percent.212 It is projected that
gations from their budgets. A regrettable result can healthcare’s costs for states and localities will surpass
be a “never-ending sense of crisis, [which] leads to all their other costs, including personnel, by 2060.213
stop-and-go funding of vital programs . . . stifles the On the other hand, the rate of growth in healthcare
need for serious discussions about policy. . .. [and] costs is the slowest in five decades, at 1.6 percent
leaves states vulnerable when economic downturns annually over five years and getting slower;214 this
occur.”206 When all is said and done, however, state slowing rate could relieve fiscal pressures for states
and local governments long have taken “harsh and localities (not to mention Washington).
austerity measures” to balance their budgets “that
would face far more resistance in Washington.”207 Medicaid and Its Expansion Much of the overall
growth in publicly-provided healthcare is attribut-
able to Medicaid, a federal healthcare grant for the
Linked poor that began in 1965. Over fourteen years, the
Perversely, and despite these mostly good fiscal amount of the states’ own money spent on Medicaid
efforts by subnational governments, “the fundamen- (which accounts for nearly 17 percent of the
tal fiscal problems of the federal government” and states’ own general expenditures) grew by almost
those of state and local governments “are similar two-fifths.215 Prior to the passage, in 2010, of the
and are linked.”208 Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, which
Linked, indeed. Federal “negative impacts” on expanded Medicaid’s coverage to 17 million addi-
the states, such as “the failure of the federal govern- tional recipients, the feds picked up 57 percent, on
ment to solve problems in state finances that only average, of Medicaid’s costs. The states contributed
it can solve” (such as its shielding international tax the rest, which, over fifteen years, crept modestly
shelters from taxation, among other issues), have upward, rising from 14.4 percent to 15.8 percent of
reduced Washington’s “positive impacts” by fully the states’ general fund dollars.216
one-third, and these negativities are accelerating.209 With the expansion of Medicaid coverage, in
2010, Washington now provides an average of 67
percent of the more than $500 billion spent annu-
Healthcare: The Ultimate Linkage ally through Medicaid, and the states contribute the
Nowhere is this linkage of federal, state, and local rest.217 Washington covers or will cover, on average,
fiscal challenges clearer than in healthcare. an estimated 93 percent over nine years, and the
states’ overall Medicaid costs inch up by less than
The Cost of Public Healthcare Healthcare spend- 3 percent of what the states would have spent over
ing in the United States accounts for almost 18 the same period without the Affordable Care Act’s
percent of GDP.210 Federal, state, and local govern- expanded coverage. This low estimate for the states
ment spending for healthcare accounts for more than actually “overstates the net impact on state budgets
64 percent of all national healthcare spending, and because it does not reflect the savings that state and
is projected to exceed 67 percent by 2024. (Unlike local governments will realize in healthcare costs
official estimates, which calculate that all govern- for the uninsured.”218 Nor does this modest esti-
mental expenditures for healthcare is 43 percent of mate reflect that about three-quarters (a growing
252 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

proportion) of the portion of Medicaid funding for new hires, at least five states stopped providing any
which the states are responsible are provided not by health premium contributions for certain retirees,
the states, but instead by state taxes levied on health- and “over a dozen” states raised age or service-year
care providers, such as hospitals, and funds trans- requirements for retirees to be eligible for health
ferred to the states by their local governments.219 benefits.225
Moreover, those states that have accepted Subnational retirees’ healthcare benefits have
expanded Medicaid (thirty-two by 2016, and slowly suffered because of high and rising costs. Retirees’
growing), in contrast to states that have spurned it unfunded healthcare costs (that is, the shortfall
(largely for ideological reasons), “have harvested between the benefits that governments promised
enormous rewards,” including: “drastically reduced” to their retirees and what governments have saved
uncompensated costs for charity cases, which states to pay for them), at $587 billion, are the second
must shoulder, a reduction that also has directly largest long-term obligation that the states have—
strengthened struggling rural hospitals; superior larger even than the states’ outstanding debt, which
economic growth (Medicare-expansion states expe- ranks third. Unfunded retiree healthcare liabilities
rienced annual growth rates of 2.4 percent in the in the states amount to 4.2 percent of personal
health sector, versus 1.8 percent in those that did income (which is a measure of the states’ economic
not accept expansion); and recipients who are more resources) in all fifty states.226
satisfied with their healthcare than those in non-
expansion states, a satisfaction that translates into
“boosts in approval ratings” for governors in expan- Pensions and Public Penury
sion states.220 Some 19.5 million subnational public employees
and 9 million beneficiaries227 are covered by almost
Healthcare for State and Local Employees and 4,000 retirement plans. These are big increases; it
Retirees The next highest subnational health- was only in 1947 that all states offered retirement
related cost after Medicaid is health insurance for state plans (the first such plans appeared in the 1920s),
and local governments’ employees and retirees.221 and, by 1962, there were barely five million state and
Greater percentages of state and local govern- local employees participating in fewer than 2,400
ments offer health insurance to their employees than plans.228 Unlike the private sector, where federal law
do private-sector employers, and the percentage of governs pension plans and requires their insurance,
subnational public employees who choose to partici- public retirement systems depend on the whimsies
pate in healthcare coverage is considerably higher of annual government revenues and public officials.
than those in the private sector.222 Unsurprisingly,
80 percent of government workers are satisfied with Underfunded Public Pensions Eighty-two percent
their health insurance benefits, compared with 57 of all public workers are satisfied with their retire-
percent of their corporate counterparts.223 ment plans, compared with just 57 percent of non-
Complications arise, however, in retirees’ health- governmental employees.229 Yet, paradoxically, just
care insurance. 18 percent, and declining, of full-time subnational
On the one hand, retirees’ health insurance is government workers are “very confident” about the
relatively good. Forty-nine states offer newly-hired prospects of their retirement incomes.230
employees some healthcare coverage when they Why is this? Perhaps it is because subnational
retire, and thirty-eight states contribute insurance government employees are learning more about the
premiums toward healthcare coverage for their shaky finances underlying their “guaranteed” retire-
retirees. By contrast, in private-sector firms with 200 ment plans. State and local retirees’ unfunded pen-
employees or more, such coverage has declined from sions, which, at $968 billion (at least), is the largest
66 percent of firms to 28 percent over twenty-five unfunded obligation that the states have, and they
years.224 grow more rapidly than the other two long-term
On the other hand, subnational retirees’ health- obligations, retirees’ healthcare and subnational
care benefits have suffered. Over fifteen years, one debt. (Washington falls nearly $762 billion short of
state (Idaho) cancelled retiree health coverage for what it needs to fully fund federal pensions,231 an
Financing and Budgeting Governments 253

amount that almost seems sort of reasonable when (Why the legislature accepted so readily the pension
we consider its subnational counterparts.) When we board’s recommendations is a mystery, as it has a
add unfunded healthcare benefits for state and local long history of questionable practices; for example,
retirees, the total is nearly $1.6 trillion; over three- the system’s chief executive confessed to accepting
fifths of this amount is for pensions, and less than bribes, including cash in paper bags, “covering years
two-fifths is for healthcare. The states’ unfunded of corruption.”240) California’s pension obligations
retirement costs tote up to 6.9 percent of personal increased, on average, by more than 25 percent.241
income; when combined with unfunded healthcare Within a decade, these obligations were haunt-
liabilities for retirees, the total is 11.1 percent of per- ing the state like Marley’s ghost. A board member
sonal income.232 of the state’s mammoth pension system (it covers
The funding of state pension plans (which typ- more than 1.6 million state and local employees,
ically include local as well as state retirees) peaked excluding educators, and, with investments of $159
in 2001 at an admirable 100 percent, but since has billion, is the largest public pension in the country)
plummeted; state and local plans are 26 percent admitted that, “This was probably the worst public
short of the amount needed to meet their retirement policy decision in the state’s history. . .. We had no
obligations.233 Just 41 percent of state governments idea what we were doing.”242
and the District of Columbia make their full annual Precisely. Politically astute and powerful public
required contribution to their pension plans.234 unions exploit this universal ignorance of govern-
The unfunded liability of state pension plans is the ments’ fiscal futures for their members’ ends. It
equivalent of more than three full years of the states’ perhaps is no accident that, on average, state and
total general revenue, an equivalency that is “almost local governments contribute more than twice as
exactly the same” for city and county plans.235 much to their pension funds than do their employ-
Unsurprisingly, the famed financier, Warren ees,243 or that from 2004 to 2016, the percentage
Buffett, has called state and local pension plans a of state and local employee costs devoted to retire-
“gigantic financial tapeworm.”236 ment and savings nearly doubled, from 6 percent to
11 percent of those costs.244 But union negotiators
Pension Politics Because the effects of pensions often are abetted by elected officials who are certain
on public finances are long-term, their fiscal impact in their knowledge that any future fiscal problems
cannot possibly be known to anyone, including generated by the catastrophically costly retirement
those who fund the pensions. benefits that they negotiate will never be problems
This universal ignorance has only rarely for them.
worried governments. Between 2000 and 2010 Seventeen percent of retired members of
(years that included the Great Recession of 2007– Congress, for example, receive annual pensions of at
2009), thirty-one states passed laws that expanded least $100,000, compared with 1 percent of retired
the range of state and local employees who can retire federal employees.245 Legislators in eleven states
when they reach fifty or fifty-five years of age or allow themselves retirement that is earlier than that
after working twenty to twenty-five years; the con- for most state workers (in Pennsylvania, the differ-
sequence has been “a massive increase in the scope ence is ten years—fifty, as opposed to sixty, years
of who qualifies for retirement benefits.”237 old); seventeen states add other earnings (four states)
Here is an example: In 1999, when California’s or expense reimbursements (thirteen) to legislative
economy was booming, the legislature blithely salaries, thereby inflating pensions (Kansas and
accepted the state pension board’s recommendations Kentucky add both); in a remarkable twenty-three
(the Senate did so after forty-five seconds of discus- states, legislators, unlike most state employees, may
sion and with no dissenting votes238), and allowed collect their state pensions and a state salary simul-
some workers to retire at age fifty with pensions taneously, and without restrictions.246 In Kentucky,
pegged at 90 percent of their salaries and lowered state legislators’ pensions are well over four-fifths
the retirement age for others by five years (such as funded in full, but the pension fund for state govern-
the lifeguard who retired at fifty-seven with a six- ment employees, entailing obligations of more than
figure pension239), among a bevy of other benefits. $12 billion, is not even one-fifth funded.247
254 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Bumbling Bureaucrats Questionable management three introduced a defined contribution plan, thereby
also undermines public pensions. Occasionally, this “shifting some investment risk to employees.”254
management is more than questionable; in 2010, the In addition, the courts have declared as fair
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) charged game the pensions of the retirees of bankrupt local
New Jersey’s pension system with securities fraud, governments. This is new. Historically, the courts
an event that was historically unprecedented, and, have held that state constitutions protect public
in 2013, it did so again with Illinois. Corruption is pensions in these circumstances, but, in 2013, bank-
a continuing problem in a number of public pension ruptcy judges ruled in separate cases involving
systems. Detroit, Michigan, and Stockton, California, that the
Almost all states hire pricey outside manag- Constitution of the United States and federal bank-
ers, often who work on Wall Street, to manage ruptcy laws trumped state constitutions, and that
their pension funds, and “most state pensions hold retirees’ pensions could be cut.
about 75 percent of their investments in risky assets
such as stocks, private equity or hedge funds.”248
(It appears that only Nevada does not rely on Wall State and Local Debt
Street, and instead indexes its fund.) The states are State and local governments owe more than $2.9
losing money with this arrangement. An analysis of trillion in outstanding debt. The states owe over $1.1
the thirty-three states with pension funds managed trillion, and localities owe more than $1.8 trillion.255
by outsiders, which also had disclosed their data, State and local governments always have
concluded that investing in passive index funds, carried debt, but, unlike the federal government’s
rather than in actively managed funds, would have debt, which is akin to a happy-go-lucky teenager’s
returned 1.62 percent more per year over five years. credit card debt, the grass-roots governments’ debt
Much of this differential is attributable not only to generally has resembled a responsible homeowner’s
these outside managers’ subpar investing (an analy- fixed mortgage. Forty-nine states prohibit them-
sis of 660 state-administered plans graded 1 percent selves from spending in deficit; forty-eight states
of them as “A” and 11 percent as “F”249), but also impose debt ceilings on their cities, and forty on
to the fees (often hidden) that they charge;250 total their counties.256
disclosed and undisclosed fees charged to the states “States and cities carry much less debt rela-
tote up to an estimated $20 billion annually, plus tive to the size of their economies than do troubled
another $5 billion when cities’ and counties’ fees are national governments like those of Greece or Spain
thrown in.251 “By indexing most of their portfolios (or the United States, for that matter),”257 devoting
. . . the 33 state funds . . . could save $5 billion in from 5 to 8 percent of their revenue to paying inter-
[disclosed] fees annually, while obtaining similar (or est on their debt, “which is considered a reasonable
better) returns to those of active managers,” poten- level.”258 There is “little evidence,” in fact, that the
tially reducing their “unfunded pension liabilities by size of state debt affects state borrowing costs.259
$70 billion within two years.”252 In the view of many analysts, “state and local
Consolidating what often is a plethora of local governments really don’t have a crushing debt
retirement boards also brings savings. Consolidating problem.” What they do have, of course, is a crush-
Massachusetts’ 105 local boards would save an esti- ing revenue problem.260
mated $25 million per year, more than $2 million of Still, subnational governments must pay off
which is devoted to stipends for board members.253 their debts, and to do so they borrow.

The Consequences The people who suffer most


from cynical or maladroit managers are state and Grass-Roots Borrowing: The Mysterious
local employees and pensioners. Over just three Municipal Bond
years, thirty-five states reduced pension benefits for State and local governments’ borrowing is executed
current and (for the most part) future employees, almost exclusively through a device that is unique to
including eighteen that lowered benefits for retirees; them: the municipal bond. (A growing, but still rel-
half the states raised employee contributions; and atively small, trend is direct bank loans, which often
Financing and Budgeting Governments 255

are unencumbered by disclosure requirements and Whoopee! Tax Free! Municipal bonds typically
can be riskier for taxpayers.) sell quickly, and individual investors, who hold “up
A municipal bond, or municipal security, is a cer- to 75 percent of the total value of municipal securi-
tificate of ownership of a specified portion of a debt ties outstanding,” are their biggest buyers.267
due to be paid by a state agency or local government Why is this? Because the interest income gener-
to an individual holder and usually bearing a fixed ated by almost all of them is exempt from the federal
rate of interest. Special districts, school districts, and and most state and local taxes on personal income.
similar statutory authorities issue 64 percent of all Congress exempts from the individual income
long-term municipal bonds, municipalities and coun- tax about 95 percent of all municipal bonds, and
ties account for 19 percent, and the states issue 12 has done so for as long as there has been such a tax
percent (another 5 percent are short-term bonds).261 (the Revenue Act of 1913 initiated this policy), even
They sell them in the $3.7  trillion municipal bond though, since 1992, the exemption, which is “one of
market, the second largest securities market in the the largest” loopholes in the federal tax code, has
nation, and the only major one that remains virtually cost the government from almost $24 billion268 to
free from oversight by the Securities and Exchange about $43 billion269 in lost revenue each year. There
Commission.  That freedom may explain why, in is in Congress a Municipal Finance Caucus whose
2016, the SEC announced (an unprecedented move) sole purpose is that of protecting these bonds’ tax-
its censure of seventy-one state and  local govern- free status.
ments involving forty-five states for failing to disclose On the other hand, the tax break leverages more
certain financial information about municipal bonds than $400 billion a year for infrastructure projects.
that they sold to investors, indicating a problem that, Eliminating the exemption could increase state and
according to the SEC, is “widespread and pervasive.” local borrowing costs by as much as 2 percent, and
hike infrastructure costs by 25 percent.270
Of Obligations and Money Makers There are two Thirty-eight of the forty-three states that levy a
major kinds of municipal bonds. personal income tax (including New Hampshire and
General obligation bonds have the full faith and Tennessee, which, as noted earlier, levy the tax only
backing of the government issuing them, a backing on interest and related income) exempt the bonds’
that includes raising taxes, if need be, to cover their interest income if the bonds were issued by them or
obligations. This may explain why most states and their local governments. Florida, Indiana, and the
two-thirds of cities and towns, which are among the District of Columbia extend this exemption to bonds
primary issuers of these bonds, require that all local issued in every other state as well.271 These practices
bond measures be approved by voters.262 were upheld by the Supreme Court in 2008.272
Revenue bonds fund projects, such as college
dormitories, that generate revenue, and are by far
the most common bond issued by special-purpose The Blessing of Bankruptcy?
governments—school districts, special districts, and There is a possible hatch through which some
public authorities. In contrast to general obligation governments could escape their fiscal woes: they
bonds, revenue bonds are “nonguaranteed,” and could declare bankruptcy, which is a legal finding
lack the full faith and credit of the governments that that imposes a court-supervised restructuring of a
issue them, but compensate for this deficiency by debtor’s finances. Recently, there have been some
paying higher interest to their buyers. eye-popping public bankruptcies, such as Alabama’s
Revenue bonds are now governments’ bond Jefferson County’s declaration of bankruptcy in
of choice. In 1950, they accounted for a slender 2011, which revealed a record-breaking $4.2 billion
17  percent of all municipal bond sales,263 peaked in unpaid debt. The county was soon overshadowed
in the mid-1980s at 80 percent,264 and have since by Detroit, in 2013, when it filed for bankruptcy
slipped to a still respectable 60 percent.265 to the tune of at least $18 billion, the biggest local
Both general obligation and revenue bonds government bankruptcy ever, as measured by both
rarely default; historically, far less than 1 percent dollars and population. (Jefferson County righted its
default.266 finances in 2013 and Detroit in 2014.)
256 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Congress does not allow state governments to power to declare bankruptcy, as local governments
go bankrupt, but, with the passage, in 1934, of the may not file petitions under Chapter 9 without the
Municipal Bankruptcy Act, local governments may authorization of their states.276
default and declare bankruptcy under Chapter 9 of Typically, states rescue their fiscally faltering
the United States Code. The law prohibits federal localities: twenty-two states “actively and regularly
judges from mandating tax hikes in their restructur- review” their local governments’ finances in an effort
ing, but it does allow local governments to not only to detect fiscal stress,277 and twenty states have laws
stiff their creditors, but to also renege on their con- that authorize state intervention into the finances of
tractual obligations. municipalities or counties that are in fiscal difficul-
About 650 local governments have filed for ties; twenty-nine states can take over school districts
bankruptcy since the first one, in 1937,273 and they that are in fiscal or academic trouble. New Jersey
have averaged slightly more than eight per year since was the first to do so, in 1989, and, since then, the
1980. A slim 18 percent were general-purpose gov- states have taken over or reorganized about fifty
ernments;274 the rest were special-purpose govern- school districts nationwide.278 Rescue, however, is
ments, and almost all of these were special districts.275 by no means assured.
Just twelve states permit Chapter 9 filings; When all is said and done, declaring bankruptcy
another dozen authorize bankruptcy under certain is no panacea. “The fantasy of using bankruptcy to
conditions; three states allow their local govern- suspend government runs up against a hard truth:
ments limited authorization to declare bankruptcy; even in bankruptcy, cities and states don’t disap-
and two specifically prohibit local bankruptcy. The pear—nor do their obligations.” Almost always,
remaining twenty-one states simply do not address even bankrupt governments ultimately pay off their
the subject, in effect denying their localities the debts.279

FROM FISCAL FALTER TO FLINTY FATE

An emergency financial manager, commonly shortened From 2010 to 2015, Michigan’s emergency
to emergency manager, is a state-appointed official who managers ruled six municipalities and five school
takes over the finances of a local government, usually districts. In general, they proved to be effective. By
after a court has placed it in receivership, and who 2016, after fifteen uninterrupted years of emergency
is charged with restructuring its debt. Receivership managers, no Michigan city was run by an emergency
occurs when a person legally is charged with custodial manager, and just two school districts were. Without
responsibility for the property of others who cannot its emergency manager, Detroit might still be in
meet their financial responsibilities or have actually bankruptcy.
declared bankruptcy. Despite their fiscal competence, Michigan’s
In Michigan, which has one of the most emergency managers are permitted to be so tough
sweeping local financial intervention laws in the that their wards’ spirits can be broken. Pontiac’s
nation, emergency managers are appointed by three sequential emergency managers over four years
the governor, and report only to the governor and “gutted” the city’s government, slashing its workforce
the legislature. Unlike other states, they have no by more than four-fifths and its budget by about two-
obligation to consult with local residents and officials, fifths; Pontiac emerged from receivership, but it is
and have the exclusive authority to make all decisions “not really a city anymore” (Yaccino).
on local budgets and virtually everything else; local Although Michigan’s emergency managers
residents and officials have the exclusive authority to are effective in purely fiscal matters, they can be
complain. insensitive, or even blind, to larger public issues.

(continued)
Financing and Budgeting Governments 257

(continued)
Nowhere does this reality ring more clearly than in 2015, state workers in Flint quietly placed purified
Flint, a city of 98,000 that lost half of its population water coolers in their office building, even as state
over fifty years and is plagued by a poverty rate of officials in Lansing, the capital, were stonewalling.)
42 percent. Though never bankrupt, Flint was placed in To add insult to injury, Flint residents paid more for
receivership from 2002 to 2004 and again from 2011 water during the crisis, than any of the 500 largest
to 2015. It was during these final four years that five community water providers across the nation until a
different emergency financial managers ran Flint. At court order rolled back water charges in 2015.
least two of them made decisions that had catastrophic In October 2015, eighteen months following the
consequences for the lives of the city’s residents. switch to the lead-laden water, the state permitted Flint
to switch back to Lake Huron and Detroit for its water,
In April 2014, Flint’s drinking water was officially although toxicity remained because of infrastructure
switched from Lake Huron’s water, purified by Detroit, damage caused by the river water and managerial
to the Flint River’s water, treated by the Flint city’s misfeasance.
waterworks, as a cost-cutting measure. Although federal, state, and local officials resigned
Flint’s managers failed to add corrosion-control following the Flint crisis, there can be little doubt
chemicals (at a nominal cost of about $100 per day) that the state was almost solely responsible for it; in
that were needed to offset the pipe corrosion caused April 2015, for example, as a condition for obtaining a
by the river water, which was nineteen times more state loan of $7 million to right its finances, the state
corrosive than the lake water. The river water leached prohibited Flint from returning to Detroit for its water.
lead from Flint’s ancient pipes. Too much lead in blood (The prohibition was waived when, six months later,
can cause life-long damage in speech, teeth, bones— the state provided Flint with $6 million to reconnect
and brains—among other disabilities, particularly in with Detroit.) In 2016, largely as a result of the
children. From 6,000 to 12,500 children were exposed Flint fiasco, Michigan’s credit rating was lowered and
to lead poisoning, and the percentage of Flint’s children criminal charges were filed against thirteen state and
with elevated blood-lead levels may have doubled to as local employees and engineering consultants, including
much as 5 percent. The poisonous water also associated two of Flint’s former emergency managers. In 2017,
with breakouts in Flint of E. coli and Legionnaires’ Michigan agreed to replace Flint’s lead or galvanized-
disease (which killed a dozen people); more than 100 steel water lines by 2020, a replacement that would
people suffered gastrointestinal disease because they be completed six years after the city’s residents began
were afraid to wash their hands. drinking toxic water.
Almost immediately following the switch, Flint’s tap Flint, tragically, exemplifies the perils of public
water turned brown and smelly. State officials dismissed administrators focusing narrowly and obsessively on
the complaints of townspeople, national negative news a single, if important, aspect of public management
coverage, and the findings of experts who determined (in Flint’s case, the public’s money) at the expense of
that the water was dangerous. They also ignored larger responsibilities (in Flint, the public’s permanent
the implications of the decision by a local General disease, damage, and debilitation).
Motors plant to stop using Flint’s corrosive water in Sources: Steven Yaccino, “Lessons for Detroit in a City’s
manufacturing. (Not all state officials thought Flint’s Takeover,” New York Times (March 23, 2013), and various
water was safe; at the height of the crisis, in January news reports.

Is Revenue Running Out? levels as a percentage of personal income since the


Healthcare and pension costs, not to mention declin- 1950s280), have been burgeoning budgetary banes
ing tax revenue (as we observed in Chapter 1, all for decades. Over thirty years, expenditures by state
taxes imposed by all governments are at their lowest and local governments “grew faster than own-source
258 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

revenues in almost all states.” Budgets balanced


because of the growth in federal grants, and also A Muted Note of Hope
because, during the final dozen of those years, states Most of us have heard (often, it seems, endlessly)
and localities increasingly borrowed money, rather of the need for greater transparency in govern-
than spend tax and other revenues, to fund capital ment. Transparency, without doubt, is a critical
projects, such as roads and schools.281 component of good governance in general, but,
This is not a sustainable situation; indeed, it is a in public finance, greater transparency actually
grim one. Closing the anticipated fiscal gap for sub- correlates  measurably with greater fiscal account-
national jurisdictions will require them to cut their ability. As a unique study of forty-one countries
expenditures, or increase revenue, by 18 percent each concluded, “the more information the budget dis-
and every year until at least 2060,282 an increase of closes,” the greater the likelihood that citizens will
27 percent from just one year earlier.283 hold politicians to account and that budgets will be
balanced.286
The bad news here is that, even though “at least
A Dismal Science: Deficits, Debt, 85 percent” of Americans agree “overwhelmingly . . .
and Democracy across all levels of government” that public “officials
In 1984, President Ronald Reagan quipped that he should be accountable to citizens about financial
was “not worried about the deficit. It is big enough management and . . . provide transparent finan-
to take care of itself,” a comment bookended nearly cial information,” it appears that governments fail
two decades later by Vice President Dick Cheney, to deliver on both scores. Although the figures are
who reportedly stated, “deficits don’t matter.” improving, 51 percent of Americans are dissatisfied
Both remarks lend credence to economists’ with the federal government’s fiscal transparency
dismal doubt about democracy: Democracies are and accountability (so, for that matter, are federal
unable to avoid burying future generations in debt administrators287), 49 percent are less than satisfied
due to the need of elected policymakers to, as with those of state governments, and 40 percent
Alexander Hamilton put it, boost “their own pop- with local governments’.288
ularity or to make other sinister account” by giving The good news, however, is that, beginning in
voters bigger benefits, lower taxes, and larger defi- 2009, Washington, by creating new websites, opened
cits and debt. “The consequence is,” America’s first its budgetary books to unprecedented levels of trans-
treasury secretary continued, “that the Public Debt parency, and, through legislation and regulation, by
swells, ’till its magnitude becomes enormous, and that same year had “tipped the balance” in the states
the Burthens of the people gradually increase ’till as well, pushing them “to the point of no return” in
their weight becomes intolerable. Of such a state increasing their own fiscal transparencies.289
of things, great disorders in the whole political When citizens know more about their govern-
economy, convulsions & revolutions of Government, ments’ money, governments manage it more respon-
are a Natural offspring.”284 sibly290—a muted note of hope on which we close
Despite heartening trends in deficit reduction, our discussion of public finance.
the core issue remains one of Congress’s refusal to
address national fiscal policy and debt. “It is not that
the size of the debt itself is the problem. . . . Instead, PUBLIC BUDGETING: SPENDING
it is the recent trend that is ominous. For that trend
results not from a deliberate political decision to FOR PUBLIC POLICY
spend in deficit, but rather from nothing more than In the United States, spending by all governments
the sum of myriad decisions regarding taxing and amounted to 7.5 percent of GDP in 1913.291 One
spending that, collectively, now substitutes for fiscal hundred years later, that figure had quintupled to
policy. In a very real sense, the federal government 37 percent.292
has no fiscal policy, for the tail of political expedi- Spending is achieved by developing and imple-
ency has long wagged the dog of prudent policy in menting a budget. A budget is “a series of goals with
Washington.”285 price tags attached.”293
Financing and Budgeting Governments 259

Budgets are beyond dollars. They are choices, Both of these interrelated efforts pressured
policies, and philosophies. Unsurprisingly, therefore, governments to adopt a consolidated executive
“60 percent of all roll call votes in Congress are on budget, which is a comprehensive plan of expendi-
budget-related issues.”294 tures for the whole of government, formulated by
We shall address seven budgetary formats that the elected chief executive, and subject to approval
the public sector and some independent organizations by the legislature. The first consolidated executive
have used since the early twentieth century (earlier, budget was adopted, via constitutional amendment,
there was no budgeting). In government, these by Maryland in 1916, largely because the state had
formats reflect changing  public  opinion  about the grossly overspent its revenues.
proper place of government,  expanding from a
narrow concern over corruption control to a focus The Budget and Accounting Act of 1921 In
on government proactively and efficiently solving 1912, the President’s Commission on Economy and
large social problems. Efficiency proposed a consolidated executive budget
Each budget system has federal, state, for the federal government (or, as the Commission
local,  or even corporate antecedents that were put it, simply “a national budget,” unconsciously
in use years  before the time frames (which apply indicating just how primitive early public financial
exclusively  to the federal government) indi- management was),296 a suggestion fulfilled nearly
cated in the  headings. And, while budget formats a decade later with the passage of the Budget and
may fade, they do not fade away. Like vam- Accounting Act of 1921. The act created the Bureau
pires, budgetary formats  often metamorphose of the Budget (BOB), reporting to the treasury sec-
into forms that differ  from their initial  incar- retary, and established the General Accounting
nations, or, like  Frankenstein, parts of  them are Office (re-titled, in 2004, to the Government
stitched  together in ways that  create new forms. Accountability Office, or GAO), which reports to
Budget systems always live beyond their nominal life Congress, as the legislative check on federal money
spans,  lurking  in the sunless recesses of budgetary management.
bureaucracies.295 The Budget and Accounting Act was historic
legislation that radically improved federal efficiency
and finance. In its first year of operation, the Budget
LINE-ITEM BUDGETING, Bureau cut federal expenditures by an astonishing
35 percent and raked in a record surplus.297
1921–1949
During the early twentieth century, the budget was
expanded from a tool that kept track of expenses What Is Line-Item Budgeting?
(often inadequately) into a system for assuring gov- The consolidated executive budget, a major gov-
ernmental honesty. ernmental innovation when introduced, nonethe-
less assumed a very traditional form: the Line-Item
Budget.
Reform! Introducing the Public Budget A Line-Item Budget is what most of us visualize
The Progressive Movement expressed these dynam- when we think about budgets. Each line on a sheet
ics, and they ultimately resulted in historic budget- of paper has an item, or object (for example, pencils,
ary change. 112), on the left side followed by a cost ($75.00)
on the right side. Hence, the first public budgets
The Consolidated Executive Budget During the acquired their descriptive title of Line-Item, or
early twentieth century, Progressives pushed two Objects-of-Expenditure, Budget which is the alloca-
reforms: fiscal reform, which advocated such novel- tion of resources according to the cost of each item,
ties as auditing governments’ books, and the “admin- from pencils to personnel, used by an agency.
istrative integration movement,” which promoted
strengthening the power of the executive branch by Honesty, Efficiency, and Inflexibility The Line-
consolidating agencies. Item Budget rapidly became associated with
260 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

governmental honesty, efficiency, and less propi- by expanding its staff by a factor of ten and relying
tiously, inflexibility. In 1923, Charles G. Dawes, increasingly on public administrators, rather than
as first director of the Budget Bureau, wrote: “The accountants, to manage federal spending. In 1939,
Bureau of the Budget is concerned only with the Executive Order 8248 formalized BOB’s new mana-
humbler and routine business of government. . . . it gerial emphasis by transferring it from the Treasury
is concerned with no question of policy, save that of Department to the newly-founded Executive Office
economy and efficiency.”298 of the President.

Inputs and the Budgetary Treatment of Paperclips


and Parks The Line-Item Budget covers inputs Clarifying Programs and Performance
only, meaning that it deals only with what it takes The broadening of budgeting into management illus-
to make a project continue. Consider two examples: trated with increasing clarity two growing problems
paperclips and parks. Under a Line-Item Budget, the of federal administration: the rapidly deteriorat-
only policy-related questions that a public admin- ing coherence of the budget itself and its failure to
istrator would be channeled into asking are: How capture how well policies performed.
many paperclips do we need and what will they
cost? Or how many parks do we need and what will The Programs Problem The Line-Item Budget has
it cost to build and maintain them? no capacity to show policymakers what programs
public money is being spent for, and was never
meant to. The federal Line-Item Budget of 1949
The Legacies of Line-Item Budgeting dumped on its readers some one-and-a-half million
The Line-Item Budget fulfills a vital financial func- words printed on 1,625 pages. The first Hoover
tion: it shows in detail what public administrators are Commission questioned the Line-Item Budget’s
spending their money on. Consequently, four-fifths of utility as a document that facilitated more effective
all cities and counties still use Line-Item Budgeting, public management, and advocated organizing the
often “in conjunction with another type of budget budget by “programs.”301
format.”299 But its scope is limited, and when it is
used at broader organizational levels, it can result “in The Performance Problem The second issue
micro-management at the macro level.”300 involved the gnawing question of whether the
money being budgeted for public policies was actu-
ally doing any good. In the 1940s, the Budget Bureau
PROGRAM/PERFORMANCE introduced “Functional Budgeting,” or “Activity
Budgeting,” which involved the development of per-
BUDGETING, 1950–1964 formance measures and standards and their linkage
Although lone voices were heard through- to an agency’s budget. The first Hoover Commission
out the 1920s and 1930s advocating a budget strongly encouraged BOB’s initiative, and gave it one
attuned  to  identifying broader programs and gov- of the names by which we know it: “Performance
ernment performance, the shift to this kind of think- Budgeting.”
ing came with President Franklin D. Roosevelt’s
New Deal. The Emergence of Program/Performance
Budgeting The Hoover Commission’s 1949 report
brought swift results. In that same year, Congress
The New Deal and the Need for passed amendments to the National Security Act
a New Budget of 1947, which established Program/Performance
Roosevelt assumed the presidency in 1932, and Budgeting (P/PB) in the Defense Department, and,
immediately focused federal power on wrenching the in 1950, Congress enacted the Budgeting and
economy out of the Great Depression. Between 1932 Accounting Procedures Act, which emplaced it in
and 1940, federal expenditures more than doubled, the remaining agencies. A new budgetary age was
and the Budget Bureau faced up to this challenge at hand.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 261

What Is Program/Performance Budgeting?


PLANNING-PROGRAMMING-
We call it Program/Performance Budgeting, but
this kind of budget more commonly is known as BUDGETING SYSTEM, 1965–1971
either a Program Budget, emphasizing its budg- P/PB swept through governments, but, once its
eting of discrete operations, or a Performance sweep was complete, its limitations grew increas-
Budget,  stressing its focus on agency efficiency ingly aggravating.
and effectiveness and their measurement. In reality,
when it was introduced it did both, so we call it
Program/Performance  Budgeting and define it as An Emerging New Standard for Budgetary
a system of resource allocation that organizes the Theory
budget document by operations and links the pro- Those limitations revolved around questions of per-
ductivity  of  those operations with specific budget formance and policy.
amounts.
The Performance Problem (Again) Half of
Inputs and Outputs P/PB considers outputs, as well Program/Performance Budgeting, the performance
as inputs The Budget Bureau’s role evolved from a half, was not working well. As the second Hoover
fiduciary one to that of clarifying what policies the Commission’s report of 1955 circumspectly noted
budget was paying for and assuring efficiency in with exquisite tact, “the installation of performance
program delivery. budgeting . . . has met with varying degrees of
success.”302
Of Paperclips and Parks What did this new role
of the budget signify for our examples of paper- The Policy Problem Although P/PB rewards effi-
clips and parks? In terms of programs, the Program/ ciency in implementing public policy, or tries to,
Performance Budget asks: To what programs do it cannot enlighten us if those policies are worth
paperclips and parks pertain? Do we have a paper- having in the first place. As a New York legislator
clips program? Do we have a parks program? In exclaimed after looking over his state’s Program/
terms of performance, P/PB asks: How many papers Performance Budget, “Who the hell cares how much
will be clipped? How many people will be served by a pound of laundry costs?”303 The more important
the parks? question is: Why is there a policy that requires the
state to wash laundry?

The Legacies of Program/Performance The Emergence of Planning-Programming-


Budgeting Budgeting These concerns eventually led to an
The most lasting and pervasive impact of P/PB was interest in Planning-Programming-Budgeting System
its organization of the budget by programs. It hauled (PPBS), also known as Planning-Programming-
public administrators out of the micro-mire of the Budgeting, a budgeting concept that was birthed
Line-Item Budget and revealed the much bigger in the auto industry; variants of it had been used
picture of the programmatic purposes of the public as early as 1924 by General Motors Corporation.
budget. Elements of PPBS first emerged  in  federal circles
The other pillar of P/PB—its focus on meas- during World War II, but it was in 1961, when
uring results and linking those results with agency Robert McNamara, the chief executive officer of
budgets—was less successful, but merely its intro- Ford Motor Company, became secretary of defense,
duction expanded the vision of budgeters from one that PPBS made its major impact.
of controlling costs to viewing the budget as a means The Defense establishment that McNamara
of fulfilling public purposes. entered was beset by almost cutthroat competi-
tion among the services. McNamara and his “whiz
kids” (a not entirely affectionate appellation given
the McNamara team by the military) shook up the
262 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

services by reestablishing central control through


the imposition of Planning-Programming-Budgeting. The Legacies of Programming-Planning-
PPBS remains the Pentagon’s budgeting system to Budgeting System
this day. PPBS is, perhaps, the single most comprehensively
President Lyndon B. Johnson was sufficiently “rational” budgeting system ever perpetrated in
impressed that, in 1965, he ordered PPBS to be American governments.
adopted throughout the federal government.
Benefits of PPBS Washington’s experience with
PPBS suggests that PPBS brings benefits. Few federal
What Is Planning-Programming-Budgeting administrators ever “argued against the goals of
System? PPBS,” and it “is credited with instituting improve-
The Planning-Programming-Budgeting System is a ment in federal program management,” including
method of resource allocation designed to improve better information, more systems analysis, and “a
governmental efficiency and effectiveness by estab- long-standing legacy of increases in the amount and
lishing long-range planning goals, analyzing the quality of program evaluation.”305
costs and benefits of alternative programs that When PPBS’s two dominant features, rigorous
would meet these goals, and articulating programs rationality and analysis, are present in a government’s
as budgetary and legislative proposals and long-term budgetary format, then budget making “reduces
projections.304 expenditures in aggregate.”306 This is, of course, pre-
cisely what public budgeting is meant to do.
Inputs, Outputs, Outcomes, and Alternatives PPBS
is concerned not only with inputs and outputs, but Limitations of PPBS PPBS’s complexity, rigidity,
also with outcomes (defined in Chapter 7—in other and obsession with details and uniformity are its
words, impacts or effects) and alternatives. The overriding weaknesses, and make it very difficult
budget agency is seen more than ever before as a to adopt and use. It did not help that, at least in
centralized, systemic, planning, and policymaking Washington, PPBS also was clumsily introduced.
body—a far cry from Dawes’ statement of 1923 President Johnson gave his administrators all of six
about budgeting being concerned with the “humbler months to have PPBS up and running, but the sole
and routine business of government.” department to implement it successfully and perma-
nently, Defense, consumed no fewer than ten years
Of Paperclips and Parks In terms of paperclips to phase it in.307
and parks, PPBS expands our queries to include their Understandably, perhaps, PPBS overwhelmed
outcomes and alternatives. most federal agencies. The secretary of agriculture,
To determine the outcomes, or effects, of paper- whose department had been identified by the Budget
clips, we must ask: What impact do clipped papers Bureau as one of only five that had made substantial
have on the agency’s mission-related outcomes? We progress in adopting PPBS,308 phoned the director
then must ask about alternatives: Should we use of BOB and began the conversation with, “Elmer,
staples instead? I have a stack of PPBS papers on my desk about
When we ask about the outcomes of parks, we four feet high. What am I supposed to do with
inevitably must ask: What are parks really meant to them?”309 So traumatized were most federal admin-
do? Parks provide recreation, or an opportunity for istrators by their experience with PPBS, that, for the
their visitors to “re-create.” But how do we deter- remaining third of the twentieth century, every suc-
mine this? Counting outputs, such as the number of cessive budgetary format had, as defining features,
park visitors, no longer is adequate. Finding alter- high levels of plasticity and an outstanding ease of
natives to parks is even tougher, and requires that adoption.
we consider the whole recreational system, and even It is doubtful that PPBS’s limitations can be
beyond. After all, those who visit parks in the wee overcome. When a federal agency brought back
hours may be exclusively muggers and their victims, PPBS, in 2002, it found, seven years later, that the
lending an entirely new meaning to “re-creating.” same “difficulties that led to the abandonment [of
Financing and Budgeting Governments 263

PPBS] by the civilian bureaucracy almost 40 years mission, BBO is at somewhat of a loss. Goals are set
ago” were still front and center.310 centrally, but only after extensive consultation.

Of Paperclips and Parks In relating BBO to our


BUDGETING-BY-OBJECTIVES, ongoing examples of paperclips and parks, we ask:
How much does it cost to keep us in paperclips and
1972–1977 parks? What do paperclips and parks actually do?
With Richard Nixon’s election as president in 1968, How effective are paperclips in achieving the agen-
the federal government moved steadily away from cy’s mission? We do not ask, however, what alterna-
the policy-planning mission of PPBS, and toward a tives there are to paperclips or to parks.
managerial and political one.
The clearest and earliest indicator of this shift
was the reorienting and renaming, in 1970, of the The Legacies of Budgeting and Managing
Bureau of the Budget to the Office of Management by Objectives
and Budget (OMB). Its new title reflected Nixon’s We have scant statistical data about BBO’s linkage
effort to politicize federal management,311 and OMB with governments’ efficiency, but BBO’s foundation
soon became known in Washington as the “Office and stalking horse, Management-by-Objectives,
of Meddling and Bumbling,” a moniker that, thank- clearly correlates with significant increases in public
fully, OMB has long since shed. productivity—gains of 58 percent, on average, and it
In 1971, OMB dispatched a memorandum to matches those of the private sector.316
all federal agencies that, “with remarkably little Although the federal government’s brief
comment,”312 officially terminated PPBS, rendering interlude with BBO left little legacy, “to some
it “an unthing.”313 extent,  the basic concepts of MBO—negotiating
Policymakers quickly turned to a new thing: goals and  holding subordinates accountable for
Budgeting-by-Objectives (BBO). In 1973, Nixon for- achieving  them—have survived in federal manage-
mally initiated BBO with a memorandum to twenty- ment practices.”317 MBO has proven itself to be
one agencies, and, in 1975, OMB issued Circular quite “versatile” in local governments, especially
A-11, effectively extending BBO to all agencies. in the areas of “quality enhancement, cost control,
productivity improvement, and special problem
solving.”318
What Is Budgeting-by-Objectives?
Budgeting-by-Objectives has its roots in a tech-
nique of project management called Management- ZERO BASE BUDGETING,
by-Objectives (MBO), which got its start in
the private sector.314 When used as a budget- 1977–1980
ing system,  MBO morphs into Budgeting-by- A new face in the White House brought with it a
Objectives,  which may be defined “a process new budgeting concept. That new face was Jimmy
whereby organizational goals  . . . are set through Carter’s, who, as governor of Georgia, was the first
the participation of organizational members in elected executive to introduce Zero Base Budgeting
terms of results expected,”315 and resources are allo- (ZBB) to government.
cated according to the extent to which those goals ZBB was not entirely unknown in federal
are achieved. circles prior to Carter’s arrival; the Department
of Agriculture had been using it since the early
Inputs, Outputs, and Outcomes BBO is concerned 1960s.319 Nevertheless, in 1977, Carter broadened
with inputs, outputs, and outcomes, but not with ZBB to the whole of government through OMB
alternatives. It deals primarily with the effective- Bulletin No. 77-9. In contrast to PPBS, ZBB made
ness of governmental programs, but when it comes rapid headway. One seasoned bureaucrat noted,
to pushing policymakers to ask what else might “Never has any management fad so completely
government do to accomplish a particular social taken over this town.”320
264 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

legislature specifically prohibits it; arguably, sunset


What Is Zero Base Budgeting? legislation is a direct result of zero-based thinking
Zero Base Budgeting is the allocation of resources about program prioritization.323
to agencies on the basis of those agencies periodi- At the local level, city budget directors give ZBB
cally reevaluating, through intense consultation, the their highest ratings for its ability to facilitate the
need for all of the programs for which the agency reallocation of budgets to higher priorities and to
is responsible, and justifying the continuance or ter- cut budgets rationally.324
mination of each program in the agency’s budget
proposal. In other words, an agency reassesses what Limitations of ZBB ZBB does not seem to reduce
it is doing from top to bottom from a hypothetical spending by the federal and state governments,325
“zero base.” but it does increase paperwork. Federal paperwork
exploded by of 229 percent, on average, during
Alternatives The odd aspect about ZBB is that ZBB’s first year of implementation,326 and ZBB is
it really does not pay much attention to inputs, thought to outstrip even PPBS in producing paper.327
outputs, and outcomes. Rather, it fixates on alterna- And, despite its radical-sounding title, Zero
tives. What should we do instead? Base Budgeting is far from revolutionary; very few
federal, state, and local agencies, and even indus-
Of Paperclips and Parks So what impact would trial organizations, submit ZBB budget requests that
ZBB have on an agency’s use of paperclips or a city’s actually start at zero.328 “ZBB was initially intended
parks program? At the agency level, the head of to get away from ‘incrementalism’ but ended up by
the Office of Paper-Fastening Technologies would being, perhaps, the most incremental of any budget-
be deciding between purchasing more paperclips, ing approach.”329
staples, tape, or glue, but at the top level, the chief
executive might be choosing between purchasing
more paperclips or closing more parks. Ultimately, TARGET BASE BUDGETING,
paperclips and parks would be rank-ordered in
terms of their relative usefulness to the government’s 1981–PRESENT
overall mission. In 1981, newly-elected President Ronald Reagan
abandoned the longstanding presidential tradition
of theatrically introducing a new budgetary format,
The Legacies of Zero Base Budgeting and instead quietly slipped in Target Base Budgeting
Does Zero Base Budgeting work? Yes, but within (TBB) by directing OMB only to officially terminate
narrow limits and only under certain circumstances. its predecessor, ZBB. (Elements of ZBB nevertheless
persisted in federal budgeting until 1994.330) Even
Benefits of ZBB Program managers clearly feel though TBB was not entirely new to Washington
that they participate more in the budgetary process, (some agencies had been using it by other names
and communication among all levels of the bureau- since the 1940s331), Reagan’s embrace of it was revo-
cracy is enhanced when ZBB is introduced. These lutionary, and today it continues to work in tandem
seem to be the most conclusive findings of the with its budgetary successors at all governmental
research.321 levels.
At the heart of ZBB is the prioritization of
programs, and this feature may be its most lasting
benefit, particularly in the states. In 1975, just prior What Is Target Base Budgeting?
to ZBB’s adoption by Washington, not even three Target Base Budgeting, also known as Target
out of ten state budgets prioritized programs, but Budgeting, Fixed-Ceiling Budgeting, and Top-Down
today more than eight out of ten rank them.322 At Budgeting, is a method of allocating resources to
the peak of ZBB’s popularity, thirty-six states had agencies in which agency spending limits (and, often,
enacted sunset laws, which automatically terminate agency goals, too), or “targets,” are set by the elected
public programs after a set period of time, unless the chief executive.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 265

The radical thing about Top-Down Budgeting controlling for inflation; its employees were reduced
is that it reverses the traditional budgetary process, by 14 percent, and its crucial enforcement staff by
which is “bottom-up”: instead of departments 23 percent. IRS’s workload, however, grew by 7
sending their budget requests up the hierarchy, the percent, or more than nine million new returns.334
chief elected executive sends down to them the As a result, IRS leaves around $400 billion a year
budget that they are permitted to request (typically, uncollected, or roughly the equivalent of the annual
this target is based on revenue forecasts), and then federal deficit.
leaves the achievement of departmental goals to the Because of budget and personnel cuts, there is
departments’ devices. a less than 1 percent chance that the IRS will audit
your return,335 and performing fewer audits costs
Inputs, Outputs, and Outcomes The most salient Washington $8 billion annually;336 for every dollar
feature of TBB is that it focuses on the chief exec- spent on tax enforcement, IRS collects six.337 In
utive’s sole mission (Reagan’s mission was, with the Dallas, Texas, the IRS office no longer pursues tax-
exception of the armed forces, a smaller govern- payers who owe less than $1 million (if you owe
ment), and the mission is achieved by redirecting $999,000, you are home free in Dallas).338 This
resources (that is, inputs) to that mission to assure decision seems particularly unwise when we learn
the outputs and outcomes desired. Alternatives are that “targeted” IRS audits “that focus on high-
irrelevant; the government is not interested in them. income taxpayers produce more than $47 for every
$1  spent,”339 or about eight times more than the
Of Paperclips and Parks In terms of how TBB return on normal tax enforcement.
would deal with paperclips and parks, it might push Comparable cuts occur in the states. In Montana,
us into choosing either paperclips or parks to the for example, each dollar cut from its revenue depart-
exclusion of all other programs. Let us say that we, ment led to three dollars lost in revenue.340
as the government’s top policymaker, chose paper- Accountancy agencies also more than pay for
clips. Parks would wither, as would all other public themselves. For every dollar invested in the budget
programs, to the extent that we could politically of the Government Accountability Office, its 3,000
defend and advance our paperclip mission by prising employees return $112 in saved federal expendi-
every penny from other programs. tures.341
Our final example: over three years, Congress
cut almost $6.3 billion, adjusted for inflation, from
Cutback Management: TBB’s Administrative IRS (which suffered 70 percent of the total), GAO,
Adjunct inspectors general (who generate $8.79 for every
TBB is based on revenue, and when revenue declines, one dollar in their budgets,342 yet rank budgetary
the federal government, which had mindless seques- constraints as their top concern343), and “program
tration imposed upon it, and the grass-roots govern- integrity initiatives” designed to reduce waste, fraud,
ments, which are almost always mandated by law to and abuse in two large departments. It is difficult to
balance the books, must cut costs. conceive of a slew of more counterproductive cuts,
which “increased waste, fraud, and abuse by around
Costly Cost Cutting: Governments’ Self-Lobotomies $27.2 billion over the same [three-year] time period.”
Cutting governments’ spending is fraught with When we combine the $6.3 billion in cuts with the
self-defeating snares. Cutting agencies that are $27.2 billion in lost funds that resulted from them,
self-funded, make profits, collect taxes, or conduct there emerges “an estimated $20.9 billion in higher
audits is particularly shortsighted. These sorts of budget deficits as a consequence of these misguided
cuts have been described as a governmental “self- austerity measures.”344
lobotomy.”332 Although, as the foregoing findings suggest,
The Internal Revenue Service is a prime more information is becoming available about what
example. IRS generates an estimated four dollars kinds of cuts “actually wind up costing money, real
for each dollar in its budget.333 Yet, over six years specifics about how much every dollar in budgetary
(2010–2016), its funding was slashed 17 percent, cuts actually cost [still] are few and far between.”345
266 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Enter Cutback Management Thus we arrive at an futility includes cutting costs. Reorganizations of the
administrative extension of TBB: cutback manage- federal government “virtually never” realize greater
ment, which is the bundle of managerial techniques cost savings;347 state reorganizations bring no new
that lower costs when governments are confronted “economies into bureaucracy”;348 and analyses of
by fiscal constraints. State, but particularly local, restructuring in local governments arrive at compa-
governments developed these techniques. rable conclusions.349
The techniques of cutback management include There are four primary techniques of cutback
short-term and long-term approaches. management that are geared for the longer haul.

Cutting Back for the Short Term Examples of Improving Productivity As we detailed in Chapter
short-term cutbacks include reducing temporary 7, all levels of government are deeply engaged in
employees, deferring maintenance, and postponing improving productivity in the forms of performance
purchases. measures and other methods. Sixty to 70 percent of
Short-term cutback management does little state agencies manage cutbacks by introducing pro-
more than buy time; its cuts are inherently transi- ductivity improvements.350
tory, and often harbor hidden long-term costs, but
appear to be the most commonly used. Using Alternative Delivery Systems At root, alter-
Eighty to 90 percent of state agencies rely on native methods of service delivery are those means
short-term methods, and they are handily their most of providing public services that rely, in whole or
favored approach.346 part, on people who are not employees of the gov-
Two short-term techniques are especially ernment sponsoring the program, and we review
common, and illuminate the deficiencies of the these methods in Chapters 11 and 12. Forty to 60
approach. percent of state agencies cut back by using these
approaches.351
Freezing Hiring One is the hiring freeze, which
means that, when employees quit or retire, no Rearranging Intergovernmental Relations As  we
replacement is hired or fewer vacancies are filled. A explain in Chapter 12, governments often can
problem arises when hiring freezes harm vital pro- achieve economies of scale and simplify processes by
grams more than lesser ones. entering into intergovernmental service agreements,
annexing adjacent territory (by local governments),
Across-the-Board Budget Cuts Undifferentiated, and undertaking regional approaches to governing.
or across-the-board, budget cuts reduce the From two- to three-fifths of state agencies reduce
budgets  of all agencies and programs by the same fiscal stress by simply shifting their programs to
percentage. Typically, these cuts hurt those agen- local governments.352
cies that have a high proportion of skilled workers
providing critical services, such as those “analy- Prioritizing Programs Finally, agencies can prior-
sis shops” mentioned earlier, whereas they do not itize programs, and then cut the lowest-ranked pro-
have a major impact on agencies which deliver a grams, a method favored by 60 to 70 percent of state
routine service, such as mowing highway medians, agencies.353
that easily can be slowed down to accommodate a
budget cut.
Lessons Learned Authorities agree that the fol-
lowing steps should be taken when faced with cut-
Cutting Back for the Long Term Reducing expend-
backs:354
itures permanently requires longer-term approaches.
An all-too-common, but misguided, proposal ■ Top management should lead efforts to manage
in this regard is that of reorganizing government declining resources.
agencies so that they can manage policy areas more ■ Be sure that all interested parties are informed
efficiently. As we explained in Chapter 7, such reor- of the need for cutbacks, and solicit their views
ganizations are difficult and often futile, and this on those cutbacks. Share information.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 267

■ Big data analytics (described in Chapter 7) available revenue because the chief executive is
should guide decision making. setting their targets, based on projected revenue.
■ Determine the criteria for how priorities
should be set. Ideally, these priorities should Seeing the Big Picture through a Common Language
be established well before the advent of a of the Budget TBB also has greatly smoothed
budget crisis, as it is this step that can identify communication between public administrators and
programs that, if cut, could cost more money legislators by providing them with a common budget
than they save. While these criteria should be vocabulary. This, in turn, has enhanced the ability of
determined by the chief executive, the views top executives to understand, through a budgetary
of other employees in the agency should lens, the “big picture” of how the whole of govern-
be carefully considered, and if possible, ment spends its funds—all its funds.
implemented. Use teams in planning cuts.
■ Establish a preliminary and tentative priority Enhancing Executive Control TBB’s top-down
list based on the explicit criteria that have been target setting accords the elected chief executive
developed for priority setting. much more budgetary control over the agencies.
■ Attempt to build some public consensus Prior to the adoption of TBB, elected chief execu-
through various meetings to develop a final tives relied on their agency heads to identify where
priority list. their budgets could be cut. “How does one convince
■ Ensure that elected officials and other pertinent administrators to collect information that might
decision makers approve of the priority list. help others, but can only harm them?”356 The
■ Understand that there will never be complete answer, of course, is that one cannot. TBB resolves
agreement in the priority setting process, but this dilemma by capping or cutting agency budgets,
keep explaining to the public at large and to and then letting agency administrators deal with it.
agency employees why the priorities have been
set in the manner that they have.
■ Preserve core organizational competencies by PERFORMANCE-BASED
“carefully managing the reduction of organized
complexity.” This process includes the finding BUDGETING, 1993–PRESENT
of a new identity for the downsized agency; A new budgeting phase is now with us, and it re-
identifying and integrating its “key strategic invokes, for at least the third time in the evolution of
components”; taking care of those employees the budget, the vexing problem of paying for meas-
being let go before assimilating those who urable performance, rather than shelling out public
remain; and “dramatically” slowing the pace of money to government agencies simply because the
cutbacks by “strategically waiting.”355 agencies are there. Welcome to Performance-Based
■ Public executives faced with cutting public Budgeting (PBB).
programs should be accessible, and remain
honest, open, professional, and unflappable in
the painful process of prioritization. Cutback What Is Performance-Based Budgeting?
management is, above all, a process of conflict Performance-Based Budgeting, also known as
reduction. Budgeting for Results, Results Budgeting, Mission
Budgeting, Entrepreneurial Budgeting, Performance
Budgeting, and Performance-Informed Budgeting, is
The Legacies of Target Base Budgeting a system of resource allocation that “links the per-
In addition to cutback management, TBB has left formance levels” of programs with “specific budget
several legacies of consequence, all of them positive. amounts.”357

Budgetary Realism TBB is an unusually realistic Inputs, Outputs, Alternatives, and Outcomes Even
budgeting system because it is driven by revenue. though the scope of Performance-Based Budgeting
Agency budgets have a greater likelihood of reflecting would seem, at first glance, to be as comprehensive as
268 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Programming-Planning-Budgeting, it is less complex despite the facts that a lurching economy and an ide-
and, probably, less ambitious. ologically fractured Congress are known to under-
Just like Program/Performance Budgeting,  PBB mine the full potential of federal PBB.365
addresses inputs and outputs. Somewhat like
Programming-Planning-Budgeting and Zero Base
Budgeting, PBB considers alternatives, but largely Budgeting for State Performance
in terms of alternative delivery systems that could All the states now have laws or executive orders
wring out greater efficiency and effectiveness; it that include the routine collection and reporting
is much less likely than either format to consider of performance data for budgetary purposes.366
alternative policies. Like Programming-Planning- All but one of these requirements were enacted
Budgeting, Budgeting-by-Objectives, and Target after 1990,367 so the states’ interest in Performance-
Base Budgeting, PBB also addresses outcomes, but Based Budgeting is recent, renewed, and real: 44
essentially just two: efficiency and effectiveness. And, percent of state budget officers use the term “per-
although PBB may be less challenging on some fronts formance budgeting” to describe their budgeting
than Programming-Planning-Budgeting, it is far from approach.368 Thriving economies correlate, strongly
simple; three-fourths of state budgeters think that and positively, with the states’ intense usage of
PBB has “increased my workload.”358 PBB.369

Of Paperclips and Parks With the foregoing in Administrators, Legislators, and PBB An analysis
mind, PBB would steer budgeters to ask the follow- of the states’ use of PBB over fifteen years found that
ing questions: How many papers are being clipped? it “is only selectively applied by legislators in most
How many people are the parks serving? Are there states, whereas “top executive policy makers, middle
alternative paper-fastening technologies and non- managers, and staff embrace and utilize PBB systems
park options that would be more efficient and effec- more extensively,” largely because it “functions
tive? Are our desired outcomes—i.e., more efficient more effectively for executive management than for
and effective paper-fastening and park support ser- legislative purposes.”370
vices—being realized? Still, PBB can have some impact on legislative
budget making. In 1993 legislatures in the five states
that led in PBB’s use were not swayed by perfor-
Budgeting for Federal Performance mance information,371 but, a dozen years later, such
“The federal government has been pursuing per- information “influenced legislative budgeting delib-
formance-informed budget reforms for more than erations” in the five leading states.372
50 years”359 (at least), but, by 1990, this pursuit
enjoyed “far broader and more enthusiastic support There Oughtta Be a Law Surprisingly, whether
throughout the bureaucracy than earlier efforts.”360 PBB is legislated or is an administrative policy makes
Bureaucratic enthusiasm culminated in 1993 with the a significant difference in how well PBB functions.
passage of the Government Performance and Results Of the thirty-nine states where PBB is the law, 26
Act (also known as the Results Act), directing agen- percent are “strong users of performance informa-
cies to link budget inputs with performance outcomes. tion for budgetary decision making,” and 20 percent
The early auguries are cautiously promising. are “weak” users. Of the eleven states without a law,
Federal fiscal and budgetary management improved none are categorized as strong users, and 64 percent
during the 1990s.361 During the following decade, as weak ones.
agencies’ performance scores affected agency There also oughtta be a better law. The states
budget allocations in “statistically significant”362 that use PBB most effectively have laws that often:
and “limited yet important”363 ways. And, in the link their states’ budgets, performance measures,
2010s, these trends strengthened (63 percent of and strategic plans; reward high performance and
agency-based performance improvement officers, sanction low performance; specify benchmarks,
for example, state that “performance information outcome measures, a role for citizens, and the fre-
is used in making [agency] budget decisions”364), quency of performance reports; and identify who is
Financing and Budgeting Governments 269

responsible for strategic planning, measuring, evalu- used by managers to restructure activity planning
ating, and checking.373 and reallocate resources.”385

Benefits of Budgeting for State Performance


Three-quarters of state budget officers think that The Possible Legacy of Performance-Based
PBB has made their states “better off,” and almost Budgeting
two-fifths report that “some changes in appropria- Governments have tried tying budgets to perfor-
tions are directly attributable” to PBB.374 mance before, and typically have been disappointed.
These changes bring benefits. “Those states that As we explained in Chapter 7, measuring perfor-
have begun to make policy decisions based on [PBB] mance in both the public and independent sectors
have saved impressive amounts of money—some in is fraught with difficult, and sometimes insurmount-
very short periods of time,” and have laid a “foun- able, problems. “Although performance measures
dation for a leaner, more effective government” in have certainly helped management, you’d need to
the future.375 PBB has “a statistically significant and look far and wide [at least in the opinion of these
positive effect on budget outcomes,” and the citizens observers] to find good examples of budgets that
of these states benefit directly from it: state govern- have been clearly formed by performance meas-
ments that use PBB spend $332 more per capita ures.”386 If Performance-Based Budgeting fulfills the
annually than those that do not.376 investment being placed in it, then it will leave a
legacy of lasting magnitude.

Budgeting for Local Performance


Nearly half of cities and counties “use performance TWO USEFUL, BUT RARELY USED,
measures to justify departmental budget requests.”377
Some four decades earlier, only a fourth of cities used BUDGETARY TOOLS
at least one measure in even one department, essen- We have reviewed a bevy of budgetary formats, but,
tially precluding the possibility of linking budgets regardless of the format used, legislatures rarely
with performance.378 “About 70 percent” of the permit agencies to use a pair of budgetary tools that
largest cities and counties use performance measures almost always facilitate greater efficiency, savings,
in their budgets.379 and other benefits.
Almost three out of ten city managers have
recommended to their councils that they change
their “budget format to fund outcomes instead The Biennial Budget
of inputs,”380 and report that this was among the One is the biennial, or two-year, budget. Congress
most difficult, but worthwhile, innovations that they traditionally has favored one-year, or annual,
undertook.381 budgets, but, in 2015, it passed the Bipartisan
Their efforts are not wasted: Twelve percent Budget Act, which included a biennial budget.
of all cities reward their departments for meeting Multiyear budgets are godsends for agencies; the
their performance targets by granting them addi- Pentagon commended (as did other agencies) the
tional budget allocations.382 More than nine out biennial budget as “a break from almost a decade of
of ten of those cities that use performance meas- continuing resolutions, last-minute budget deals and
ures city-wide (two-fifths of cities do so383) report occasional government shutdowns. ‘Having some
that budgetary reallocations have resulted from certainty is absolutely huge for us.’”387
using performance-measurement data, including 11 More broadly, biennial budgeting and appropri-
percent where reallocations were substantial.384 In ating eases legislative workloads, permits improved
the context of traditional, incremental, public budg- planning, allows for more thorough legislative over-
eting, these are significant shifts. sight of departments, and makes it more likely that
All in all, PBB, when “strong executive lead- the budget process is completed on time.388
ership” is present, “can improve local budgeting Twenty states use two-year budgeting. One-year
despite severe political constraints. . .. [and] can be budgets are used in the remaining thirty states.389
270 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

that could rival those that were attained almost


The Budget Rollover instantly when three new budgetary tools were
A second useful tool is the budget, or allocation, introduced, simultaneously, in 1921: consolidated
rollover, which is the ability of an agency to keep all, executive budgets, budget analysts, and account-
or a portion, of its unspent budget dollars that were ants; recall that these tools cut federal spending by
allocated for the fiscal year, and spend those unspent an astonishing 35 percent in a single year.
dollars in subsequent years.
Because rollovers are almost always disallowed
by legislatures, agencies expend what funds remain ACQUIRING BUDGETS:
during the final days of the fiscal year in a frenzied ADMINISTRATORS AND
effort to “prove” to allocators that they need, and
use, every single cent that they are allocated; to not ARGUMENTS
spend all of their budgets, and then return those Conventional wisdom holds that rapidly-grow-
unspent dollars to the general fund, could convince ing budgets result in more effective agencies. This,
allocators that the agency is over-budgeted and however, seems not to be the case. Rather, stable
result in lower future budgets. “budgetary incrementalism,” or minor annual
Hence, an analysis of 14.6 million federal pro- adjustments in an agency’s budget, has “a beneficial
curement contracts let over five years found that, effect” on agency performance.394
during the final week of the fiscal year, agencies spent This fact of budgetary life, however, has not
nearly five times as much on contracts than they restrained many bureaucrats from aggressively
spent, on average, in each previous week of the fiscal seeking bigger budgets, and their most effective
year.390 Everyone, from those who allocate budgets method is political. “What really counts in helping
to those who receive them, fully understands this an agency get the appropriations it desires? As
longstanding game of use-it-or-lose-it. several informants put it in almost identical words,
The game’s continuance is all the more puzzling, ‘It’s not what’s in your estimates but how good a
however, when we realize that rollovers produce politician you are that matters.’”395
both higher quality and larger savings. To be a good budgetary politician requires the
A study of 686 federal information technology use of standing strategies and opportunistic tactics.396
(IT) contracts found that those contracts which were
procured in the final week of the fiscal year were,
according to the agencies’ chief information officers, Standing Strategies for Securing Budgets
from two to six times more likely to be of lower Standing strategies are used on a continuing basis by
quality than contracts that were procured during an agency. There are three variants.
the preceding fifty-one weeks. By contrast, when a
rollover is permitted (the Department of Justice has Find, Serve, and Use a Clientele for the Services
had, since 1992, the unique authority to roll over 4 You Perform An agency, when threatened, mobi-
percent of its IT appropriation), contracting quality lizes its clients. Public safety and parks departments,
is quite high and there is no year-end spending for example, often have solid bases of citizen defend-
spike.391 ers, and they are not above deploying them in budg-
Alternatively, Congress could fund the agencies etary battles.
an estimated 13 percent less than it allocates cur-
rently, and the agencies would be signing contracts Establish Confidence in the Mind of the Reviewer
that still would be comparable in quality to con- That You Can Carry Out the Complicated Program
tracts that are let without the benefit of rollovers.392 (Which He or She Seldom Understands) Efficiently
Introducing rollovers to federal agencies (not to and Effectively If those who allocate budgets
mention state and local ones, where the absence of believe in an agency’s abilities, big budgets are
rollovers has been criticized as “a powerful disincen- almost certain. A prime example is the Department
tive for agencies . . . to create efficiencies that result of Defense, at least when the Republican Party is in
in cost savings”393) might achieve historic savings power.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 271

Capitalize on the Fragmentary Budgetary Review onto the sticker price. Only when pressed did they
Process The Pentagon has successfully argued that acknowledge that one of the extras happens to be
the development of new weapons systems cannot the engine.” As one Representative ruefully noted,
be held to a rigid schedule. When combined with “I’ve learned that you’ve got to ask exactly the right
Congress’s fragmentary budget review process, question at exactly the right time.”397
Defense projects are extended, often reluctantly, year
after year on the logic that there is little choice if the
research is to pay off. The Budget-Minimizing Bureaucrat
If the foregoing review of budget-acquiring strate-
gies and tactics sounds cynical, it is. To be cynical,
Opportunistic Tactics for Securing Budgets however, is not necessarily to be scrofulous.
Opportunistic tactics are designed to capitalize on Overall, government employees, relative to
unusual opportunities that might defend or expand private-sector workers, generally support policies,
the agency’s budgetary base. There are three varia- such as bigger budgets, that lead to larger gov-
tions. ernments,398 but, when we ascend a bit higher up
the public hierarchy, government executives “are
Guard Against Cuts in Old Programs There are no more likely than the average citizen to favor
several ways that an agency can defend its programs, bigger government budgets.”399 Although there
but a favored one is to eliminate its most popular are indications that some agency chiefs behave as
ones. When the National Institutes of Health (NIH) “budget-maximizing bureaucrats” who will always
decided to start a dental research program, Congress try to fatten their budgets,400 most public execu-
directed that it be funded by drawing money from tives are actually “budget-minimizing bureaucrats.”
other programs. NIH obliged, cutting their pro- Senior federal administrators “are more frugal and
grams in heart disease, cancer, and mental health. less inclined to favor increased government spending
Ultimately, Congress not only restored these funds, than the general public. . .. even on issues that fall
but also boosted the budget for dental research. within their own departments’ jurisdictions.”401
A similar executive bias is found in state and
Inch Ahead with Old Programs NIH traditionally local governments. “To a substantial extent,” surveys
has inched ahead with old programs by reducing the of state agency heads conducted over five decades
number of research grants (“Look! We’re economiz- have “debunked” theories of budgetary “bureau-
ing!”), but increasing the total dollars in them (thus cratic maximizing,” and find instead a “substantial
inching ahead). component of conservers.”402 And a stunning 92
percent of city managers report that “budgetary
Add New Programs When an agency wants to constraints” are “very influential in their decision
add new programs, a truckload of tactics is at its making.”403
disposal. Because the new and novel often are dis-
trusted by those who allocate budgets, agencies
may present new programs as old and dull ones; as LEGISLATING BUDGETS:
only temporary; as money-savers; as ways to reduce
backlogs; as so trivial they warrant no examination; POLITICIANS AND POWER
or as merely logical continuations of old programs. Just as getting a budget is a political process, so is
Selling new programs can deteriorate into “the granting one.
sort of haggling more likely to be found at a car deal-
ership than a Senate conference room.” For example,
“Air Force officials assured cost-conscious lawmak- Legislating Federal Budgets
ers that they had swung a deal to get . . . Raptor Despite the recent adoption of a biennial budget
fighter jets for the bargain-basement price of $110 (which may or may not be continued), making
million each. Of course, if they wanted a few extras federal budgets is a process that increasingly is
that could lump another $40 million to $60 million nearing collapse.
272 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

The Congressional Budget and Impoundment spending under greater congressional control, and
Control Act of 1974 In 1974, Congress decided the impoundment of funds was stringently limited.
to gain a comprehensive grip on the budgetary
process, and enacted the Congressional Budget The Congressional Budget Office Finally, the act
and Impoundment Control Act, also known as the established a Congressional Budget Office (CBO) as
Congressional Budget Act. The act introduced six a budgetary counter bureaucracy to offset the power
quasi-revolutionary changes into what had been an of the president’s OMB, improve Congress’s analyti-
impenetrable insiders’ budgetary game. cal base, and make fiscal projections.

Comprehensive Budget Committees The Congress- Congress Gets into the Act The Congressional
ional Budget Act established, for the very first time Budget Act has been described as “the most impor-
(incredibly), in each chamber a budget committee tant change in the budget process since the Budget
responsible for reviewing the president’s annual and Accounting Act of 1921.”405 The act let the
budget proposals as a whole and determining their sun shine in on congressional budget making by
potential effects on the economy. decentralizing Congress’s appropriations and
budget-making powers; assured that Congress
Concurrent Budget Resolutions The act requires adopts budgets, openly and explicitly, by major-
that, on two prescribed dates every year, Congress ity vote; established a system for instilling fiscal
must vote explicitly on the budget as an entire responsibility; and maintained the president’s budg-
package and on budget priorities. In 1982, Congress etary role.
abandoned the first of these votes, which set budget-
ary targets, but retained the second on the “binding The Ruination of Resolution and Reconciliation
concurrent budget resolution,” which remains the For  a generation, the act met expectations, and
only time that Congress votes on budget priorities, forced Congress to vote on total spending and the
total spending and revenue, and the size of the deficit. deficit’s size—votes that Congress frequently avoided
before the act’s passage in 1974—and it prevented
Reconciliation The key in forcing Congress to Congress from allocating funds which exceeded the
vote as a body on budgets is “reconciliation,” which total spending that it had approved in the budget
was “almost an afterthought in 1974, [but] has in resolution.
many ways become the most important part of the After Fiscal Year 1998, however, the budget
process.”404 Reconciliation empowers the budget process and fiscal discipline have been largely aban-
committees in each chamber to require, if need be, doned. In fiscal years 1999, 2003, 2005, 2007, and
other committees to bring their policies’ costs within 2011 through 2017 (the latest year at this writing),
overall spending limits. So central is this power Congress failed to pass binding concurrent budget
that, since 1974, federal budgets are expressed as resolutions, the act’s key provision.406 Instead, one
“Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Acts.” or both chambers enacted deeming resolutions, an
unofficial device that gives, or “deems,” new spend-
A Budget-Making Timetable The act imposed ing caps for each appropriation, even though the
some logic on the budgetary process by stipulating, total budget has not been agreed upon. This, of
among other requirements, that Congress may not course, defeats the act’s purpose of strengthening
adjourn until all budgetary differences have been budgetary discipline.
ironed out.
A Tardy and Terrible Timetable Congress has
Improved Spending Controls Patterns of “back- passed all twelve of its regular appropriations bills
door spending” had developed that were not on time in only six years since 1974.407 “The last
subject to the regular appropriations process, and time Congress passed all of its spending bills by the
President Nixon had grown increasingly enamored October 1 deadline, Seinfeld was on television and
of impounding (that is, not spending) funds appro- people were dancing the Macarena,”408 or Fiscal
priated by Congress. The Act brought backdoor Year 1997.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 273

When time runs out, Congress passes a continu- department-wide or broader shutdowns in the
ing spending resolution, or a continuing resolution, federal government since the act went into effect.416
which is a temporary appropriations act that typi- The latest shutdown occurred in 2013, and was
cally permits an agency to spend what it was allo- triggered by a congressional dispute over the contin-
cated the previous year, but does not actually grant uance of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care
it the money to do so. In all but three years out of Act of 2010. At sixteen days, it was the third longest
thirty-one, Congress has passed continuing resolu- in shutdown history, and it furloughed some 850,000
tions,409 which last, on average, three months. From federal employees, or two-fifths of the civilian work-
1999 to 2009, their duration lengthened,410 but, force, who saw their incomes decline by 40 percent
since then, their duration steadily shortened, further and their weekly spending by 20 percent;417 it added
amplifying “the havoc caused by a disruptive budg- $2.5 billion in retroactive federal compensation
etary process.”411 costs,418 and shrank the economy from an estimated
Because agency administrators are uncertain 0.1 to 0.15 percent each week,419 including $414
about their budgets, they may hoard funds and post- million in lost local revenue because of 401 closed
pone contracting and purchasing; worried contrac- national parks.420 Congress, which had precipitated
tors and vendors, consequently, raise prices. Hiring all this misery and much more, also suffered: ice
is frozen. “You’re almost guaranteeing that there cream was cut from congressional lunches.421
will be incompetence, because the agencies don’t
have the resources to do the job.”412 The Emergence of OMB President Reagan, in his
first year in office (1981), transferred from the agency
The Radical New Role of Revenue Forecasting The heads to OMB their longstanding responsibility for
Congressional Budget Act requires that each year the shepherding through Congress the president’s pro-
Congressional Budget Office make economic pro- posed budgets. Not only was OMB’s budget-making
jections on which revenue forecasts can be based. hand strengthened, but its policymaking hand was
Regrettably, these forecasts have been “a bit too as well, rendering OMB’s administrators “arguably
high” (1.1 percent, on average) in every year over the most powerful people on the civilian side of the
thirty-six years; in some years, forecasts have over- government,” a stature that OMB has since retained
estimated revenue by 10 to 25 percent.413 and broadened.422
Why is this? For one, economic forecasts are
based on a welter of changing variables, such as
pretax corporate profits, the GDP deflater, and the Legislating State Budgets
yield on ten-year Treasury Notes, among many Few of Washington’s bizarre budgetary byways are
others. “Each of these things is the product of mul- found in state capitals.
tiple factors, and each of those depends on multiple Unlike Congress, state legislatures do not shut
factors, and so on, with the whole thing becoming down government. They do, however, run into budget
an ever-branching Tree of Uncertainty.”414 impasses, sometimes for months, largely because
For another, infinitesimal changes in economic of slowing revenue, and for the most part these
assumptions can yield immense differences in pre- disputes are far less partisan than in Washington.
dicted federal revenue. The prospect of rosy scenar- Nevertheless, employees are paid (occasionally
ios can tempt, and has tempted, budget makers into through emergency spending) and schools remain
tweaking economic assumptions in ways that ease, open. Disruptions, however, do occur, and delays in
but greatly distort, their revenue estimates. payments for social programs and to contractors are
Originally meant to guide policymaking, common.423
revenue estimating, to quote a Washington lobbyist, There are, however, are two similarities between
“has become policy.”415 state budgeting and federal budgeting.
First, as in Washington, all states have budget
Budget Brawls The Congressional Budget Act also offices in their legislative branches as well as in their
correlates with increasingly bitter budgetary battles executive ones. Over time, these offices have grown
within Congress, which have resulted in eighteen “more competitive in terms of their organizational
274 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

and technological capacities,” and their “struggle for revenue forecasts than when they work separately.
dominance” likely will continue.424 These joint forecasts actually add small, but still
And, second, all states forecast revenue, a prac- “significant dollar amounts,” to state budgets.430
tice that has become central in budgeting at all gov-
ernmental levels. A Withering of the Governors’ Budget-Making
Powers? The power to estimate revenue associates
Revenue Forecasting in the States: An Increasing positively with the power to shape the budget,431
Inaccuracy All governors’ budget proposals and, in twenty-one states, these estimates are calcu-
contain revenue estimates. lated in the legislature; they are done by the exec-
The accuracy of these estimates can be criti- utive branch in sixteen states, and they are a joint
cal. In New York, for instance, a 1 percent error effort between the legislative and executive branches
in forecasting what the general fund’s revenue will in thirteen.432
be amounts to nearly half of what the state spends The fact that less than a third of the governors
annually on public assistance.425 retain the exclusive power to forecast revenue reflects
From 1975 through 1992, state forecasters’ a slipping budgetary authority. Gubernatorial budg-
revenue estimates were, on average, 2.1 percent etary power peaked in the mid-twentieth century,
lower per year than the revenues that the states actu- when the introduction of the executive budget in the
ally collected. This low-ball error was deliberate, states was largely completed. In only 36 percent of
as budgeters were well aware that if they collected the states do budget officials in both the legislative
more revenue than they projected, they would be and executive branches agree that their governors
viewed as “heroes,” rather than as “villains.” When are their states’ primary budget formulator,433 a
economic times were tough, however, and accurate drop of nearly two-fifths over just a dozen years.434
forecasts were essential, “the average forecast error In addition, the process of legislative budget
. . . was near zero.”426 making itself erodes gubernatorial authority in most
Since then, state revenue forecasting has grown states. As the budget is being formulated, legislatures
befogged. From 1987 through 2001, the median in twenty-nine states split their governors’ proposed
error rate averaged 3.5 percent per year, but after budget into “pieces” (that is, spending bills, often
2001, the error rate grew; between 2009 and 2011, it hundreds of them), a practice that “increases the
nearly doubled to 6 percent, falling off to more than chance that pieces of the budget will be isolated and
2 percent thereafter. Growing revenue volatility is the captured by special interest groups . . . weakening
culprit, particularly in the personal and corporate executive authority.”435
income taxes, in which unpredictable fluctuations “It is not so much that the governors have lost
caused by capital gains play an increasing role.427 [budget-forming] power in recent years as that the
In addition, “political pressures on budget fore- legislatures have gained power.”436
casters [explain] a large fraction of forecast errors.”
In gubernatorial re-election years, the average The Rise of State Budget Offices Budget analysts
budget deficits are, on average, twenty-seven dollars and similar professionals in state budget offices have
more per capita than in non-election years because increased by a fifth since 1975,437 and their profes-
sitting governors demand rosy (and balanced) budg- sionalism has deepened. Almost three-fifths of the
etary scenarios that will benefit their re-election.428 “professional personnel” in these offices have at
Compounding this growing mess is the recent least a master’s degree,438 compared to not even a
introduction of tax-cut “triggers,” which reduce sixth thirty years earlier,439 and fully eight out of ten
taxes or initiate tax refunds or credits provided were working in their state governments prior to
that revenue goals, based on increasingly inaccurate their appointment.440
revenue forecasts, will be met; at least eight states These trends have empowered the budgeters.
have or will have triggers, and they are not working The proportion of state budget offices that control
well.429 the expenditure of legislatively-appropriated funds
When budget officers in both branches work by line agencies has grown over three decades
together, their governments gain more accurate from about three-quarters to “virtually all budget
Financing and Budgeting Governments 275

offices.”441 Budgeters are now policymakers, wield- budget. Forty-three states set the fiscal year for their
ing “significant influence in state policymaking.”442 local governments. Laws in thirty-one states specify
the budget form that their cities must use, and thirty-
two states do so for counties. The clear trend is one
Legislating Local Budgets of additional states adopting these and other restric-
With the rapid introduction of chief administrative tions.448
officers into local governments during the twentieth State involvement in the budgetary affairs of
century and in this one, local budgeting significantly their local governments is sometimes needed, but
improved its usefulness and accountability. it is not without problems. Because they are often
part of state constitutions, state budgetary regula-
Revenue Forecasting in Local Governments All tions are usually rigid, across-the-board, and quickly
cities and counties monitor financial trends and fore- become dated; thus, they cause unnecessary ineffi-
cast their revenues and expenses. In contrast to the ciencies in local administration. More gravely, they
federal and state governments, revenue-estimating sometimes favor special interests over the general
tensions between executives and legislators are interest, thereby “creating budget processes” that
largely absent because budget professionals in the override local priorities and minimize services.449
executive offices dominate local revenue forecasting.
Local legislators appear “to play only an informal,
indirect role” in the process.443 “BUDGETEERS”: HUMBLE
Local forecasters routinely under-forecast
revenue by 1 to 7 percent. “Unlike other levels of NEVERMORE
government, local finance officials receive limited More than 29,000 budget analysts work in American
political or bureaucratic scrutiny that might induce governments, accounting for an impressive 88
more accurate forecasts.”444 percent of all budgeters in the country.450 They are
an ill-understood lot.
Making and Managing Local Budgets Typically, We quoted earlier the first budget director of
the city or county manager recommends a budget the United States to the effect that his office was
to the local council, which approves the proposed concerned only with the “humbler,” hum-drum,
budget with few, if any, alterations of consequence. housekeeping ticky-tack of government, and never,
However, citizens are quite involved in local budget heavens forefend, with any “question of policy.”451
formulation. More than three-quarters of officials This obsequious and misleading, but influential,
state that their cities are very likely (45 percent) or claim suggests not only that budgeting is humble, but
likely (31 percent) “to set up some sort of delibera- that budgeters are, too. (The ponderous irony here is
tive public engagement process” to address specific that the budgeter who made this claim was himself
budgetary issues.445 far from humble; he also served as ambassador to
Better financial management in local govern- Britain, vice president, and, for good measure, won
ments associates with outsiders. Top local finance the Nobel Peace Prize.) Some empathetic academ-
managers who are more innovative and attentive to ics think that our benighted budgeters could benefit
their governments’ financial viability are more likely from a bit of cheerleading, and the word, “budget-
to have been hired from outside their government eer,” is increasingly common in the literature—a sign
rather than having been promoted from within,446 of an apparent effort to boost the presumably low
and appointing outside financial-oversight boards self-esteem of bottom-lining budgeters by identify-
appears to be “an effective tool” in improving local ing them with more raffish company: buccaneers,
fiscal accountability.447 privateers, profiteers, musketeers, and mutineers.
We suspect that few, if any, budget officers need
Enter the State Budgeting in local governments a literary artifice to bolster their allegedly anemic
differs markedly from budgeting in the federal and egos. Indeed, public budgeters seem quite comfort-
state governments because the states stipulate, often able in their own skins: as one of only two public
in miasmic detail, how their local governments may administrative professions commanding salaries
276 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

that are roughly comparable to those of their cor- 14. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
porate counterparts,452 budgeters are recognized Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, Table
as highly valued contributors to good governance, 494. Figures are for FY 2015.
and they are happily immersing themselves in the 15. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Management
“humbler and routine business of government,”453 and Budget, “Historical Tables,” Tables 1.1, 8.5.
knowing full well that those routines, in reality, Figures are for FY 2015.
often do involve determining major questions of 16. Jeffrey D. Sachs, “Our Dangerous Budget and
public policy. What to Do About It,” New York Review of
Books (February 6, 2014).
17. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
User Fees: Fee Design Options and Implications
NOTES for Managing Revenue Instability, GAO-13-820
1. Binyamin Amin Appelbaum and Robert Gebeloff, (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
“Complaints Aside, Most Face Lower Tax Burden Office, 2013). Highlights page. Figure is for FY
than in 1980,” New York Times (November 29, 2013.
2012). Datum is for 1980–2012. 18. Hendrik Hertzberg, “The States We’re In,” The
2. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Management New Yorker (August 24, 2009), pp. 19–20. The
and Budget, “Historical Tables,” The President’s quotation is on p. 20.
Budget for Fiscal Year 2017 (Washington, DC: 19. Andrew Seaman, “Liquor Costs More at State-
U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016), Tables Owned Stores in U.S.: Study,” Reuters Health
2.1, 2.5. Current figure is for FY 2015. For pur- (November 7, 2012). Datum is for 2012.
poses of this discussion, federal general revenue 20. U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local
is the sum of revenues provided by personal and Government Finances by Level of Government
corporate income taxes, excise taxes, and gift and and by State,” Census of Governments, 2013
estate taxes. (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). Figure is for FY
3. As derived from data in ibid. Current figure is for 2013.
FY 2015. 21. As derived from data in ibid. Figure is for FY
4. As derived from data in ibid. Current figure is for 2013.
FY 2015. 22. As derived from data in ibid. and American
5. As derived from data in ibid. Current figure is for Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signi-
FY 2015. ficant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2,
6. As derived from data in ibid., Tables 1.1, 2.5. pp. 73, 72. Current figures are for FY 2013.
Current figure is for FY 2015. 23. As derived from data in Federation of Tax
7. Ibid., Table 2.2. Current figure is for FY 2015. Administrators, State Sales Tax Rates and Food
8. As derived from data in ibid., Table 2.4. Figure is & Drug Exemptions (Washington, DC: Author,
for FY 2015. 2016). Figure is for 2016.
9. Julia B. Isaacs, Public Spending on Children 24. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
and the Elderly from a Life-Cycle Perspective “State and Local Government Finances by Level
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 2009), p. 2. of Government and by State,” and American
10. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Management Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signi-
and Budget, “Historical Tables,” Tables 1.1, 2.4. ficant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2,
Figure is for FY 2015. p. 72. Current figure is for FY 2013, and includes
11. John J. DiIulio, Jr., 10 Questions and Answers taxes  on general and selective sales and gross
about America’s “Big Government,” (Washington, receipts.
DC: Brookings.edu, 2017). 25. As derived from data in Federation of Tax
12. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Administrators, State Individual Income Taxes
Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, 4th ed. (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). Figure is for FY
(Bethesda, MD: Author, 2016), Tables 554, 557. 2016.
Figures are for FY 2013. 26. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
13. Pew Research Center, A Bipartisan Nation of “State and Local Government Finances by Level of
Beneficiaries (Washington, DC: Author, 2012). Government and by State,” and American Council
Financing and Budgeting Governments 277

on Intergovernmental Relations, Significant VA: Mercatus Center, George Mason University,


Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 72. 2010).
Current figure is for 2013. 41. Benjamin Zycher, State and Local Spending: Do
27. As derived from data in Federation of Tax Tax and Expenditure Limits Work? (Washington,
Administrators, Range of State Corporate Income DC: American Enterprise Institute, 2013), p.1.
Tax Rates (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). 42. Suho Bae, Seong-gin Moon, and Changhoon
Figure is for FY 2016. Jung, “Economic Effects of State-Level Tax and
28. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, Expenditure Limitations,” Public Administration
“State and Local Government Finances by Level Review 72 (September/October 2012), pp. 649–
of Government and by State.” Figure is for FY 658. Data are for 1985–2005.
2013. 43. Judith Stallman, Steven Deller, Lindsay Amiel, and
29. As derived from data in American Council on Craig Maher, “Tax and Expenditure Limitations
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features and State Credit Ratings,” Public Finance Review
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 72. 40 (September 2012), pp. 643–669.
30. Gary Cornia, Kelly D. Edmiston, David L. Sjoquist, 44. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract
et al., “The Disappearing State Corporate Income United States, 2016, 4th ed. (Bethesda, MD: 2016),
Tax,” National Tax Journal 58 (March 2005), Table 459. Figure is for 2012.
pp. 115–139. 45. U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local
31. Robert Tannenwald, Are State and Local Revenue Government Finances by Level of Government
Systems Obsolete? (Washington, DC: National and by State.” Figure is for FY 2013.
League of Cities, 2004). 46. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity
32. As derived from data in American Council on and Change in the Role of City Managers,”
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington,
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2 (Washington DC: International City/County Management
DC: Author, 1998), p. 73. Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. The quotation is
33. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, on p. 14. Emphasis added. The initial study of this
“State and Local Government Finances by Level topic is Paul E. Peterson, City Limits (Chicago:
of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY University of Chicago Press, 1981).
2013. 47. U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local
34. As derived from data in ibid. and American Government Finances by Level of Government
Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signifi- and by State.” Figure is for FY 2013.
cant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, 48. As derived from data in ibid. and American
pp. 72–73. Current figures are for FY 2013. Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signifi-
35. As derived from data in ibid. (both citations, but cant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2,
pp. 52, 72 for the latter). Current data are for FY p. 75. Current figure is for FY 2013.
2013. “Mid-twentieth century” figures are for FY 49. Tax Foundation, Property Taxes on Owner-
1952. Occupied Housing, by State, tax-foundation+1
36. As derived from data in ibid. (both citations, but +property+tax+value+of+hom. Figures are for
p. 85 for the latter). Current figures are for FY 2009.
2013. 50. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the
37. Tax Policy Center, The Tax Policy Briefing Book Census, “State and Local Government Finances
(Washington, DC: Author, 2010), Entry 3. Figure by Level of Government and by State,” and U.S.
is for 2008. Advisory  Commission on Intergovernmental
38. Bert Waisanen, State Tax and Expenditure Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal Feder-
Limits—2008 (Denver, CO: National Conference alism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 74. Current figure is for FY
of State Legislatures, 2010). Figures are for 2013.
2008. 51. Yongshong Wu, “How Municipal Property
39. Ibid. Figures are for 2008. Tax Responded to State Aid Cuts: The Case of
40. Matthew Mitchell, T.E.L. It Like It Is: Do State Massachusetts Municipalities in the Post-2001
Tax and Expenditure Limits Actually Limit Fiscal Crisis,” Public Budgeting & Finance 29
Spending? Working Paper No. 10-71 (Fairfax, (December 2009), pp. 74–89.
278 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

52. Richard F. Dye and Andrew Reschovsky, of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY
“Property Tax Response to State Aid Cuts in the 2013.
Recent Fiscal Crisis,” Public Budgeting & Finance 65. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the
28 (June 2008), pp. 87–111. Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,
53. Kelly Edmiston and Kenneth Spong, “Tax 1986, Table 475.
Incentives for Homeownership and the Provision 66. Richard C. Kearney, “Reinventing Government
of Local Public Services,” Public Finance Review and Battling Budget Crises: Manager and Muni-
40 (January 2012), pp. 116–144. cipal Government Actions in 2003,” Municipal
54. National Conference of State Legislatures, Local Year Book, 2005 (Washington, DC: International
Option Taxes (Denver, CO: Author, 2011). Figure City/County Management Association, 2005),
is for 2011. pp. 27–32. The quotations are on p. 30. Figure is
55. Scott Mackey, Critical Issues in State-Local for 2003.
Fiscal Policy, Part 2: A Guide to Local Option 67. Bruce A. Wallin, Budgeting for Basics:
Taxes (Denver, CO: National Conference of State The Changing Landscape of City Finances
Legislatures, 1997). (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2005), p. 6.
56. National Conference of State Legislatures, Local 68. Hee Soun Jang and Myungjung Kwon, “Enter-
Option Taxes. Figure is for 2011. prising Government: The Political and Financial
57. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, Effects of Fee-Supported Municipal Services,”
“State and Local Government Finances by Level Public Administration Quarterly 38 (Summer
of Government and by State,” and U.S. Advisory 2014), pp. 128–162.
Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 69. George C. Homsy and Mildred E. Warner. “Inter-
Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, municipal Cooperation: The Growing Reform,”
Vol. 2, p. 74. Current figure is for FY 2013. Municipal Year Book, 2014 (Washington, DC:
58. Joseph Henchman and Jason Sapia, Local Income International City/County Management Asso-
Taxes: City- and County-Level Income and Wage ciation, 2014), pp. 53–65. Data (p. 64) are for
Taxes Continue to Wane (Washington, DC: Tax 2012.
Foundation, 2011). Figures are for 2008. 70. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
59. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local Government Finances by Level
“State and Local Government Finances by Level of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY
of Government and by State,” and U.S. Advisory 2013.
Commission on Intergovernmental Relat- 71. As derived from data in ibid. and American
ions, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signifi-
1995, Vol. 2, p. 74. Current figure is for FY cant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2,
2013. p. 74.
60. Taxpolicycenter.org, How Do State and Local 72. As derived from data in ibid. (both citations).
Corporate Income Taxes Work? (Washington, Current figure is for FY 2013.
DC: Author, 2016). Data are for 2015. 73. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
61. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local Government Finances by Level
“State and Local Government Finances by Level of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY
of Government and by State.” Figure is for FY 2013.
2013. 74. David B. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism:
62. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, Slouching toward Washington, 2nd ed. (New
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1986, York: Chatham House, 2000), p. 227. Figure
106th ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government is the  average for seven selected years, 1957–
Printing Office, 1986), Table 475. Figures are for 1990.
1975. 75. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the
63. Anthony Flint, “In Hard Times, Cities Turn to Census, “State and Local Government Finan-
Fees,” At Lincoln House (May 2015). Figures are ces by Level of Government and by State.” Figures
for 1977–2012. are for FY  2013. We have assumed that one-
64. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, third  of  federal aid to the states continues to be
“State and Local Government Finances by Level pass-through grants to local governments.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 279

76. As derived from data in ibid. and American 89. Nina Easton, “How Obama Plans to Pay for His
Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signi- Agenda: A Little Tax Here. A Little Tax There.
ficant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, And Soon You’re Talking Real Money,” Fortune
pp. 52, 74. Current data are for FY 2013. “Mid- (May 24, 2010), p. 52. Current figures are for
twentieth century” figures are for 1952. 2009, when taxes accounted for an average of
77. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, 30 percent of income.
“State and Local Government Finances by Level 90. Much of the following discussion is drawn
of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY from U.S. Government Accountability Office,
2013. Understanding the Tax Reform Debate: Back-
78. As derived from data in ibid. and American ground, Criteria, and Questions, GAO-05-1009SP
Council on Intergovernmental Relations, Signi- (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
ficant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, Office, 2005).
p. 87. Current figures are for FY 2013. Education 91. Dylan Matthews, “Other Countries Don’t Have a
data exclude libraries. ‘47%,’” Washington Post (September 19, 2012).
79. Daniel R. Mullins and Bruce A. Wallin, “Tax 92. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
and Expenditure Limitations: Introduction and Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, Tables
Overview,” Public Budgeting & Finance 24 461, 498. Figure is for 2014.
(December 2004), pp. 2–15. Figures (pp. 7, 4–5) 93. Meg Bostrom, By, or for, the People? A Meta-
are for 2002. analysis of Public Opinion of Government (New
80. Ibid., p. 7. Figures are for 2002. York: Demos, 2006), p. 18. Data are for 2003.
81. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 94. As derived from data in Federation of Tax
Relations, Tax and Expenditure Limits on Local Administrators, State Individual Income Taxes.
Governments, M-194 (Washington, DC: U.S. Figure is for 2013.
Government Printing Office, 1995), p. 1. 95. As derived from data in Federation of Tax
82. Mullins and Wallin, “Tax and Expenditure Administrators, Range of State Corporate Income
Limitations,” p. 7. Figures are for 2002. Tax Rates. Figure is for 2013.
83. Ibid. Datum is for 2002. 96. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
84. Leah Brooks and Justin Phillips, “Municipally Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, Tables
Imposed Tax and Expenditure Limits,” Land 461, 498. Figures are for FY 2014.
Lines 21 (April 2009), pp. 8–13. The quotation is 97. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Under-
on p. 9. Data are for 2007. standing the Tax Reform Debate, p. 49.
85. Nicholas O. Alozie and Catherine McNamara, 98. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax
“Gender Differences in Willingness to Pay for Administration: Information on Selected Foreign
Urban Public Services,” Urban Affairs Review 45 Practices That May Provide Useful Insights,
(January 2010), pp. 377–390. The quotation is on GAO-11-439 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
p. 381. Printing Office, 2011), p. 4. Figures are for FY
86. Nicholas O. Alozie and Catherine McNamara, 2010.
“Poverty Status and Willingness to Pay for Local 99. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Under-
Public Services,” Public Administration Quarterly standing the Tax Reform Debate, p. 51.
33 (Winter 2009), pp. 520–531. The quotation is 100. Sean D. Ehrlich, Access Points: An Institutional
on p. 520. Theory of Policy Bias and Policy Complexity
87. Rui Sun, “Reevaluating the Effect of Tax and (New York: Oxford, 2011).
Expenditure Limitations,” Public Finance Review 101. Demian Brady, Tax Complexity 2016 (Alexandria,
42 (January 2014), pp. 92–116. The quotation is VA: National Taxpayers Union, 2016).
on p. 92. Data are for 1970–2006. 102. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax
88. Changhoon Jung and Suho Bae, “Changing Policy: Summary of Estimates of the Cost of the
Revenue and Expenditure Structure and the Federal Tax System, GAO-05-878 (Washington,
Reliance on User Charges and Fees in American DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005).
Counties, 1972–2002,” American Review of 103. “A Third of Americans Say They Like Doing Their
Public Administration 41 (January 2011), pp. Income Taxes,” Pew Research (April 11, 2013).
92–110. Figures are for 2013.
280 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

104. World Economic Forum, “United States 3rd,” 116. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Corporate
Global Competitive Index, 2016–2017 ed. Tax Expenditures: Information on Estimated
(Zurich: Author, 2016). Revenue Losses and Related Federal Spending
105. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Under- Programs GAO-13-339 (Washington, DC: U.S.
standing the Tax Reform Debate, p. 40. Government Printing Office, 2013), Highlights
106. John E. Peterson, “Sacramento’s Socratic page. Figure is for 2011.
Moment,” Governing (July 2010), p. 50. 117. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Corpo-
107. Treasury Inspector General for Tax Admini- rate Income Tax: Most Large Profitable U.S.
stration, Delinquent Taxes May Not Be Collected Corporations Paid Tax but Effective Tax Rates
Because Required Research Was Not Always Differed Significantly from the Statutory Rate,
Completed Prior to Closing Some Cases As GAO-16-363 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Currently Not Collectible (Washington, DC: Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. Figures
Author, 2014). Figures are for 2001 and 2006. are for 2006–2012 and 2008–2012, respectively.
108. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Fiscal 118. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Corpo-
Outlook: Addressing Improper Payments and the rate Income Tax: Effective Tax Rates Can Differ
Tax Gap Would Improve the Government’s Fiscal Significantly from the Statutory Rate, GAO-13-
Position, p. 34. Figures are for FY 2006. 520 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
109. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Gov- Office, 2013), Highlights page. Figure is for
ernment Performance and Accountability: Tax 2010.
Expenditures Represent a Substantial Federal 119. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
Commitment and Need to Be Reexamined, GAO- “State and Local Government Finances by Level
05-690 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY
Printing Office, 2005). Figures are for 1974–2004. 2013.
110. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax 120. As derived from data in Federation of Tax
Expenditures: Opportunities Exist to Use Administrators, State Sales Tax Rates and Food
Budgeting and Agency Performance Processes to & Drug Exemptions. Figures are for 2013.
Increase Oversight, GAO-16-622 (Washington, 121. George F. Will, “A Taxing Challenge,” Washington
DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016), Post (February 6, 2005).
Highlights page. Data are for FY 2015. 122. Quoted in Michael Sandler, “State Sales Tax
111. Catie Hill, “45% of Americans Pay No Federal ‘Not in Synch,’” St. Petersburg Times (August 7,
Income Tax,” MarketWatch (April 18, 2016). 2003).
112. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Fiscal 123. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Outlook: Addressing Improper Payments and Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal
the Tax Gap Would Improve the Government’s Federalism, 1995, Vol. 1, M-197 (Washington,
Fiscal Position, GAO-16-92T (Washington, DC: DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995), pp.
U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), p. 37. 89–90. Figures are for 1994.
Figure is for FY 2009. 124. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
113. U.S. Treasury Department, as cited in Robert J. “State and Local Government Finances by Level
Samuelson, “Tax Revolt, RIP?” Washington Post of Government and by State.” Figures are for FY
(April 13, 2015). 2013.
114. Leonard E. Burman and Greg Leiserson, Two- 125. Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy,
Thirds of Tax Units Pay More Payroll Than Who Pays: A Distributional Analysis of the Tax
Income Tax (Washington, DC: Tax Policy Center, Systems in All Fifty States, 5th ed. (Washington,
2007), p. 1. Figures are for 2006. DC: Author, 2015).
115. As derived from data in Rachel M. Johnson 126. David Baer, State Programs and Practices for
and Jeffrey Rohaly, The Distribution of Reducing Residential Property Taxes (Washington,
Federal Taxes,  2009–12 (Washington, DC: Tax DC: American Association of Retired Persons,
Policy  Center, 2009), pp. 5, 8, 13, 20. Data are 2003), p. ii. Figures are for 2003.
for 2009–2012 and include Medicare and the 127. Andrew Reschovsky, The State Role in Providing
employee and employer portions of the Social Property Tax Relief (Madison, WI: University of
Security tax. Wisconsin, no date), http://www.leg.state.nv.us.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 281

128. Adam H. Longley, “How Do States Spell Relief?” 141. William A. Galston, Polling Spotlight: America’s
Land Lines (April 2015), pp. 24–31. Data are for Shifting Attitudes on Taxes (Washington, DC:
2012. Broookings.edu, 2017).
129. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 142. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Trends in the
Relations, Changing Public Attitudes on Gover- Distribution of Household Income, between
nments and Taxes, Reports S-1 through S-23 1979 and 2007.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 143. David Cay Johnson, Tax Rates for Top 400
Office, 1972–1994). Earners Fall as Income Soars, Tax Analysts Doc
130. John L. Mikesell, Fiscal Administration: 2010-3372 (Washington, DC: Tax Analysts,
Analysis and Applications for the Public Sector 2010). Figure is for 2007.
(Homewood, IL: Dorsey, 1982), p. 230. 144. James Surewiecki, “Soak the Very, Very Rich,”
131. “Repeated surveys by the National Opinion The New Yorker (August 16 & 23), p. 33. A
Research Center since 1987,” as cited in Peter Quinnipiac poll of 2010 is cited.
Whoriskey, “With Executive Pay, Rich Pull Away 145. President’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax
from the Rest of America,” Washington Post (June Reform, Simple, Fair, & Pro-Growth: Proposals
18, 2011). to Fix America’s Tax System (Washington, DC:
132. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Trends in the U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005).
Distribution of Household Income between 1979 146. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Under-
and 2007 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government standing the Tax Reform Debate, p. 22.
Printing Office, 2011). 147. Eduardo, Porter, “Combating Inequality
133. Tim Henderson, “The Shrinking Middle Class, May Require Broader Tax,” New York Times
Mapped State by State,” Stateline (March 19, (November 27, 2012).
2015). Datum is for 2000–2013. 148. Bostrom, By, or for, the People? p. 18. Figures, 24
134. U.S. Central Intelligence Agency, “Distribution and 38 percent, respectively, are for 2003.
of Family Income—Gini Index,” World Factbook 149. Easton, “How Obama Plans to Pay for His
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Agenda.”
Office, 2016). 150. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Value-
135. Jonathan D. Ostry, Andrew Berg, and Added Taxes: Lessons Learned from Other
Charalambos  G. Tsangarides, Redistribution, Countries on Compliance Risks, Administrative
Inequality, and Growth (Washington, DC: Costs, Compliance Burden, and Transition, GAO-
International Monetary Fund, 2014). 08-566 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
136. S&P Capital IQ, Income Inequality Weighs Printing Office, 2008). The quotation is on p. 4.
on State Tax Revenues (New York: Author, 2014), 151. Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy,
p. 1. Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax
137. John Voorheis, Nolan McCarty, and Boris Shor, Systems in All Fifty States, 5th ed. (Washington,
Unequal Incomes, Ideology and Gridlock: How DC: Author, 2015).
Rising Inequality Increases Political Polarization 152. Daniel H. Cooper, Byron F. Lutz, and Michael J.
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, Palumbo, The Role of Taxes in Mitigating Income
2015). Inequality Across the U.S. States (Boston, MA,
138. Alan B. Kreuger, The Rise and Consequences and Washington, DC: Federal Reserve Bank of
of Inequality in the United States (Washington, Boston and Federal Reserve Board, 2015). Data
DC: President’s Council of Economic Advisers, are for 1984–2011.
2012). 153. Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy, Who
139. AEI-Brookings Working Group on Poverty and Pays? Figures are for 2015.
Opportunity, “Facts on Poverty and Opportunity 154. Ibid. Figures are for 2015.
that Progressives and Conservatives Can Agree 155. Anne Stauffer and Mark Robyn, “Federal Tax
On,” Brookings.edu (Washington, DC: Author, Reform Raises Questions, Possible Revenue
2015). Changes for States,” Pewtrusts.org (March 8,
140. Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett, The Spirit 2016).
Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Societies 156. Elaine S. Povich, “Volatile Income Tax Revenue
Stronger (New York: Bloomsbury, 2009), p. 19. Stumps States,” Stateline (October 13, 2014).
282 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

157. “Edgar Fiedler,” BrainyQuote.com. Limit: Analysis of 2011-2012 Actions Taken and
158. Louis Uchitelle, “Politicians May Be Up in Arms Effect of Delayed Increase on Borrowing Costs,
about Government Deficits, but Economists GAO-12-701 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Aren’t,” New York Times (November 8, 1996), Printing Office, 2012).
and John M. Berry, “The Deficit Is (a) Still Really 175. U.S. Department of the Treasury, The Potential
Big, or (b) No Big Deal,” Washington Post (March Macroeconomic Effect of Debt Ceiling Brink-
24, 1994). manship (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
159. Allen Schick, The Federal Budget: Politics, Policy, Printing Office, 2013), p. 3.
Process (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2007), p. 10. 176. Washington Post and Pew Research Center survey,
160. The Peterson-Pew Commission on Budget as cited in Jon Cohen, “Budget Talks in a Word:
Reform, Tied to the Mast: Fiscal Rules and Their ‘Ridiculous,’ ‘Disgusting’ and ‘Stupid’ Top Poll,”
Uses (Washington, DC: Author, 2011), p. 1. Washington Post (August 1, 2011).
161. Philip G. Joyce, “Congressional Budget Reform: 177. CNN, Washington Post-ABC, and Pew Research
The Unanticipated Implications of Federal Center surveys, as cited in Peyton M. Crayhill,
Policymaking,” Public Administration Review 56 “Polls: Did the Public Get What It Wanted
(July/August 1996), pp. 317–327. The quotation in  Debt  Deal?” Washington Post (August 1,
is on p. 317. 2011).
162. Associated Press/Ipsos survey, as cited in Robert 178. James Oliphant, “Poll: Majority of Americans
Tanner, Associated Press, “Headed for a Crash?” Say Bag Sequestration,” Government Executive
Savannah Morning News (September 4, 2005). (December 10, 2013).
Figure is for 2005. 179. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2013
163. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Management Sequestration: Agencies Reduced Some Services
and Budget, “Historical Tables,” Table 1.2. and Investments, While Taking Certain Actions
164. The case is Clinton v. City of New York. to Mitigate Effects, GAO-14-244 (Washington,
165. U.S. General Accounting Office, Line-Item Veto: DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2014),
Estimating Potential Savings, AFMD-92-7 Highlights page.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 180. Charles S. Clarke, “Contractors Report Revenue
Office, 1992). Figure is for 1984–1989. Losses from Sequestration,” Government Exe-
166. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Budget cutive (December 17, 2013).
Process: Enforcing Fiscal Choices, GAO-11-626T 181. Rick Cohen “Economic Policy Institute:
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Federal Sequester’s Effect on State Budgets,”
Office, 2011), p. 8. NonProfitQuarterly.org (June 3, 2013).
167. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, The Budget 182. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2013
and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2004–2013 Sequestration: Selected Federal Agencies Reduced
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Some Services and Investments, While Taking
Office, 2003), Appendix A. Short-Term Actions to Mitigate Effects, GAO-14-
168. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, “His- 452 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
torical Tables,” Table 1.1. Office, 2014).
169. Ibid., Table 1.2. 183. Congressional Budget Office, as cited in Erik
170. Neta C. Crawford, Costs of War (Boston: Boston Wasson, “CBO: Sequester Cuts Would Cost Up to
University, 2016). 1.6 million Jobs through 2014,” The Hill (July 25,
171. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, “His- 2013).
torical Tables,” Table 1.3. 184. Partnership for Public Service, Government
172. As derived from data in International Monetary Disservice (Washington, DC: Author, 2015),
Fund, Report for Selected Countries and Subjects p. 24.
(New York: Author, 2010), Table 5. Data are for 185. Walter Lippmann, The Public Philosophy (New
2009. York: New American Library, 1955), p. 27.
173. Henry J. Aaron, “Our Outlaw President? Obama 186. Josh Goodman, “Debt Ceilings without Drama,”
Should Ignore the Debt Ceiling,” Brookings Stateline (February 7, 2013).
(September 30, 2013). 187. Robert Bluey, “Commentary: 13 Tax Hikes for
174. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Debt 2013,” Savannahnow.com (March 2, 2013).
Financing and Budgeting Governments 283

188. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, “His- 204. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Balancing
torical Tables,” Table 1.3. Act,” Governing (October 2011), pp. 64, 66. The
189. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal quotation is on p. 64.
Debt: Answers to Frequently Asked Questions, 205. Pi-Han Tsai, “State Fiscal Rules and Composition
An Update, GAO-04-485SP Federal Debt Changes in Public Spending before the Election,”
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Public Finance Review 42 (January 2014), pp.
Office, 2004), pp. 41–42. Figure is for 2003–2054. 58–91.
190. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Citizen’s 206. The Volcker Alliance, Truth and Integrity in State
Guide to the 2012 Financial Report of the United Budgeting: Lessons from Three States (New York:
States Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Gov- Author, 2015), p. 1.
ernment Printing Office, 2012), p. vi, n. 6. 207. Dan Morgan, “How States Handle Debt May Not
191. U.S. Government Accountability Office, The Work for Nation,” Washington Post (February 28,
Nation’s Long-Term Fiscal Outlook, August 1995).
2007 Update: Despite Improvement in the 208. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State
Annual Deficit, Federal Fiscal Policy Remains and Local Governments: Persistent Fiscal Chal-
Unsustainable, GAO-07-1261R (Washington, lenges Will Likely Emerge within the Next
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2007), p. 2. Decade, GAO-07-1080SP (Washington, DC: U.S.
192. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Citizen’s Government Printing Office, 2007), pp. 2, 4.
Guide to the 2012 Financial Report of the United 209. Iris J. Lav, “Piling on Problems: How Federal
States Government, p. vi, n. 6. Policies Affect State Fiscal Conditions,” National
193. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Financial Tax Journal 56 (September 2003), pp. 535–554.
Audit: Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years The quotation is on p. 538.
2016 and 2015 Schedules of Federal Debt, GAO- 210. World Bank, Health Expenditure, Total (% of
17-104 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government GDP) (New York: Author, 2016).
Printing Office, 2016), Highlights page. 211. David U. Himmelstein and Steffie Woolhandler,
194. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, “His- “The Current and Projected Taxpayer Shares of
torical Tables,” Table 7.1. Current figure is for FY US Health Costs,” American Journal of Public
2016. Health 106 (March 2016), pp. 449–452. Figures
195. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal are for 2013.
Debt: Answers to Frequently Asked Questions, 212. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State
An Update, p. 17. Emphasis added. and Local Governments: Fiscal Pressures Could
196. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Have Implications for Future Delivery of Inter-
“Historical Tables,” Table 7.1. governmental Programs, Highlights page. Figures
197. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, Tax Cuts, are for 1978–2008.
Wars Account for Nearly Half of Public Debt by 213. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State
2019 (Washington, DC: Author, 2012). Datum is and Local Governments’ Fiscal Outlook: 2014
for 2001–2019. Update, GAO-15-224SP (Washington, DC: U.S.
198. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Government Printing Office, 2014), p. 6.
“Historical Tables,” Table 7.1. 214. David Brooks, “Great News! We’re not
199. As derived from data in Brian Dumaine, “Who’s Doomed  to Soaring Health Care Costs,” New
Most in Debt?” Fortune (August 15, 2011), p. 22. York Times (November 6, 2015). Figures are for
Figures are for 2011. 2010–2015.
200. International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Monitor 215. As derived from data in “Medicaid Consumes
(New York: Author, 2015), Statistical Table 13a. Growing Slice of States’ Dollars,” Pewtrusts.org
201. Balazs Egert, “Myth or Reality,” OECD Econo- (June 11, 2015). Figures are for FY 2000–FY
mics Department Working Papers, No. 993 (Paris: 2013.
OECD, 2012), p. 1. 216. John Holahan and Irene Headen, Medicaid Cover-
202. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, CBO’s 2011 age and Spending in Health Reform (Washington,
Long-Term Budget Outlook, pp. 3–4. DC: Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the
203. Woods Bowman, “The Price of Nonprofit Debt,” Uninsured, 2010), p. 3. Figures are for 1995–
Nonprofitquarterly.org (August 6, 2015). 2010.
284 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

217. As derived from data in U.S. Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Accountability Office, Medicaid: Overview of Office, 2012), Highlights page, and Nari Rhee,
Key Issues facing the Program, GAO-15-746T Pensionomics 2014 (Washington, DC: National
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing Institute on Retirement Security, 2014), p. 2.
Office, 2015), Highlights page. Figures are for FY 228. William G. Gale, Sarah E. Holmes, and David
2014. C. John, Lessons for the States from the Federal
218. January Angeles and Matt Broaddus, Federal Government’s CSRS-to-FERS Transition
Government Will Pick Up Nearly All Costs (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2016), p. 3. Current
of Health Reform’s Medicaid Expansion figures are for 2013.
(Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy 229. McCarthy, “Gov’t Workers Happier with
Priorities, 2012), p. 1. Figures are for 2014–2022. Retirement Plans, Other Benefits.” Figures are for
Emphasis is original. 2015.
219. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Medi- 230. Paul J. Yakoboski and Joshua M. Franzel, 2014
caid Financing: States’ Increased Reliance on Retirement Confidence Survey of the State and
Funds from Health Care Providers and Local Local Government Workforce (Washington, DC:
Governments Warrants Improved CMS Data TIAA-CREF Institute and Center for State and
Collection, GAO-14-627 (Washington, DC: U.S. Local Government Excellence, 2014), p. 15.
Government Printing Office, 2014), Highlights 231. Stephen Losey, “Federal Pension Systems’
page. Figure, 74 percent, is for 2012 and pertains Unfunded Liabilities Skyrocket,” Federal Times
to California, Illinois, and New York. (February 21, 2012). Figure is for 2011–2012.
220. Benjamin Geyerhahn, “4 Ways States Benefit 232. Pew Charitable Trusts, “Long-Term Obligations
When They Expand Medicaid,” Routefifty.com Vary as a Share of State Resources.” Figures are
(June 2, 2016). for 2013.
221. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State and 233. Alicia H. Munnell and Jean-Pierre Aubry, The
Local Governments’ Fiscal Outlook: April 2013 Funding of State and Local Pensions, 2015-2020
Update, GAO-13-546SP (Washington, DC: U.S. (Boston: Center for Retirement Research, Boston
Government Printing Office, 2013), p. 4. College, 2016). Figure is for 2015. Pew Center on
222. Rex L. Facer, II and Lori L. Wadsworth, “Emplo- the States, The Trillion Dollar Gap: Underfunded
yee Benefits: Patterns and Challenges for Public State Retirement Systems and the Road to Reform
Organizations,” in Public Human Resource (Washington, DC: Author, 2011), p. 1. Figure is
Management: Problems and Prospects, 6th ed., for FY 2010.
Richard C. Kearney and Jerrell D. Coggburn, eds. 234. As derived from data in Keith Brainard and
(Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2016), pp. 154–168. Alex Brown, The Annual Required Contribution
Data (p. 157) are for 2012. Experience of State Retirement Plans, FY 01 to
223. Justin McCarthy, “Gov’t Workers Happier with FY 13 (Washington, DC: National Association of
Retirement Plans, Other Benefits,” Gallup.com State Retirement Administrators, 2015), pp. 2, 3.
(September 9, 2015). Figures are for 2015. Figure is for 2013.
224. Pew Charitable Trusts and MacArthur Found- 235. Robert Novy-Marx and Joshua Rauh, “The Crisis
ation, State Retiree Health Plan Spending in Local Government Pensions in the United
(Washington, DC, and New York: Authors, States,” Paper presented at the Brookings-Nomura-
2016), pp. 2, 11. Figures are for 2013; decline Wharton Research Conference on Growing
in private-sector healthcare figures are for 1988– Old: Paying for Retirement and Institutional
2013. Money Management after the Financial Crisis,
225. Ibid., p. 2. Data are for 2000–2015. Washington, DC, October 15, 2010, p. 4. Figure,
226. Pew Charitable Trusts, “Long-Term Obligations 3.2 years, is for 2006.
Vary as a Share of State Resources,” Pewtrusts. 236. Quoted in Noah Buhayar and Zachary Tracer,
org (November 1, 2016). Data are for 2013. “Buffett Says Pension Tapeworm Means Decade
227. As derived from data in U.S. Government Ac- of Bad News,” Bloomberg (March 3, 2014).
countability Office, State and Local Government 237. Thomas Frank, “States Expand Lucrative
Pension Plans: Economic Downturn Spurs Efforts Pensions to More Jobs,” USA Today (December 9,
to Address Costs and Sustainability, GAO-12-322 2011).
Financing and Budgeting Governments 285

238. Charles Duhigg, “Public Unions Take On Boss Downturn Spurs Efforts to Address Costs and
to Win Big Pensions,” New York Times (June 21, Sustainability, Highlights page. Figures are for
2011). 2008–2011.
239. Ibid. 255. U.S. Bureau of the Census, “State and Local
240. Dale Kasler, “Ex-CalPERS Chief Admits Receiving Government Finances by Level of Government
$200,000in Bribes in Paper Bag, Shoebox,” and by State.” Figures are for FY 2013.
Sacramento Bee (July 11, 2014). 256. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
241. Tad Friend, “Contract City,” The New Yorker Relations, Tax and Expenditure Limits on Local
(September 5, 2011), pp. 34–40. The data are on Governments, pp. 3, 5–10. Figures are for 1994.
p. 38. 257. Roger Lowenstein, “Broke Town, U.S.A.,” New
242. Ibid. York Times (March 3, 2011).
243. Iris J. Lav and Elizabeth McNichol, Misunder- 258. Ryan Holeywell, “How Bad Is It?” Governing
standings Regarding State Debt, Pensions, and (May 2011), pp. 26–30. The quotation is on p. 28.
Retiree Health Costs Create Unnecessary Alarm 259. Mark D. Robbins and Bill Simonsen, “Do Debt
(Washington, DC: Center on Budget and Policy Levels Influence State Borrowing Costs?” Public
Priorities, 2011), p. 14. Public employees con- Administration Review 72 (July/August 2012),
tributed 13 percent of public pension revenues, pp. 498–505.
employers 27 percent, and investment earnings 60 260. Lowenstein, “Broke Town, U.S.A.” Robert
percent, 1982–2009. Kurtter, a managing director at Moody’s, is
244. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employer Costs quoted. Emphasis is original.
for Employee Compensation (Washington, DC: 261. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
Author, 2016). Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, Table
245. Stephen Losey, “1 in 6 Retired Lawmakers Get 469. Figures are for 2010.
Six-Figure Pensions,” Federal Times (November 262. Evelina R. Moulder, “Municipal Form of Gov-
6, 2012). Figures are for 2012. ernment: Trends in Structure, Responsibility,
246. As derived from data in Thomas Frank, “State and Composition,” Municipal Year Book, 2008
Lawmakers Pump Up Pensions in Ways that You (Washington, DC: International City/County
Can’t,” USAtoday.com (April 16, 2012). Management Association, 2008), pp. 3–8. Figure
247. John Cheves, “Kentucky Legislators Keep Their (p. 6) is for 2006.
Pensions Separate and Undisclosed,” Herald- 263. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
leader.com (November 20, 2016). Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1951, 72nd
248. Andrew Vaz, “Unfunded State Pension Plans and ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Investment Boards,” Patimes.org (February 17, Office, 1951). Table 406 refers to nonguaranteed
2017). debt as a percentage of long-term debt.
249. Urban Institute, The State of Retirement: Grading 264. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
America’s Public Pension Plans (Washington, DC: Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1992,
Author, 2014). 112th ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
250. Jeff Hooke and John J. Walters, Wall Street Fees Printing Office, 1992), Table 458.
and Investment Returns for 33 State Pension 265. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
Funds (Rockville, MD: Maryland Public Policy Statistical Abstract United States, 2016, Table
Institute, 2015). 469. Figure is for 2015.
251. Jeff Hooke, as cited in Liz Farmer, “The Hidden 266. Lowenstein, “Broke Town, U.S.A.”
Wall Street Fees That Could Be Costing Pensions 267. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Municipal
$20 Billion a Year,” Governing.com (May 24, Securities: Options for Improving Continuing
2016). Disclosure, GAO-12-698 (Washington, DC: U.S.
252. Hooke and Walters, Wall Street Fees and Invest- Government Printing Office, 2012), Highlights
ment Returns for 33 State Pension Funds, p. 2. page. Figure is for 2012.
253. Marie Szaniszio, “Study: Consolidate State’s 105 268. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax
Pension Systems,” Boston Herald (July 26, 2013). Policy: Tax-Exempt Status of Certain Bonds
254. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State Merits Reconsideration, and Apparent Noncom-
and Local Government Pension Plans: Economic pliance with Issuance Cost Limitations Should Be
286 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Addressed, GAO-08-364 (Washington, DC: U.S. 1795), as published in The Papers of Alexander
Government Printing Office, 2008), pp. 15–16. Hamilton, Vol. 18, Harold C. Syrett, ed. (New
269. Stephen C. Fehr, “Governors Fear Loss of Bond York: Columbia University Press, 1973), p. 80.
Tax Exemption,” Stateline (February 26, 2013). 285. John Steele Gordon, Hamilton’s Blessing: The
Figure is for 2012. Extraordinary Life and Times of our National
270. Ibid. Figures are for 2012. Debt (New York: Walker, 1997), p. 5. Emphasis is
271. As derived from data in Securities Industry and original.
Financial Markets Association (SIFMA), State 286. Bernardino Benito and Francisco Bastida, “Budget
Taxation of Municipal Bonds for Individuals, Transparency, Fiscal Performance, and Political
http://www.investinginbonds.com. Data are for Turnout: An International Approach,” Public
2014. Administration Review 69 (May/June 2009), pp.
272. The case is Department of Revenue of Kentucky 403–417. The quotation is on p. 403.
v. Davis. 287. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
273. Martin Ives and Thad Calabrese, “Employee Fiscal Year 2010 U.S. Government Financial
Benefit Financing and Municipal Bankruptcy,” Statements: Federal Government Continues to
Journal of Government Financial Management Face Financial Management and Long-Term
62 (Spring 2013), pp. 12–18. Figure is for 1937– Fiscal Challenges, GAO-11-363T (Washington,
2014. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011).
274. Adrienne Lu, “States Intervene When School 288. Association of Government Accountants, Public
Districts Hit Financial Trouble,” Stateline (May Attitudes Toward Government Accountability
24, 2014). and Transparency 2010 (Alexandria, VA: Author,
275. As derived from data in Holeywell, “How Bad Is 2010), pp. 2–3. Figures are for 2009.
It?” p. 30. Figure is for 1980–2010. 289. “Utah budget executive,” as quoted in John
276. Pew Charitable Trusts, The State Role in Local Kamensky, “Transparency: New Frontier for
Government Financial Stress (Washington, DC: Performance Management,” The Business of
Author, 2013), p. 8. Figures are for 2013. Government (June 2009), pp. 16–18. The quota-
277. Pew Charitable Trusts, State Strategies to Detect tions are on p. 18.
Local Fiscal Distress (Washington, DC: Pewtrusts. 290. International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Transparency,
org 2016). Accountability, and Risk (New York: Author,
278. Lu, “States Intervene When School Districts Hit 2012).
Financial Trouble.” 291. John Micklethwait and Adrian Woodridge, The
279. Lowenstein, “Broke Town, U.S.A.” Fourth Revolution: The Global Race to Reinvent
280. John E. Petersen, “Debtor’s Dilemma,” Governing the State (New York: Penguin Press, 2014),
(May 2004), p. 78. p. 9.
281. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State 292. “Chart 2.12, Government Spending as Pct GDP,”
and Local Governments: Fiscal Pressures Usgovernmentspending.com. Figure is for FY
Could Have Implications for Future Delivery 2013.
of Intergovernmental Programs, GAO-10-899 293. Aaron Wildavsky, The Politics of the Budgetary
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Process, 2nd ed. (Boston: Little, Brown, 1974),
Office, 2010). The quotation is on the Highlights p. 4.
page. Thirty-year data are for 1977–2007. 294. Al Gore, From Red Tape to Results: Creating a
Balanced-budget data are for 1995–2007. Government that Works Better and Costs Less,
282. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State Mission-Driven, Results-Oriented Budgeting
and Local Governments’ Fiscal Outlook: 2014 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Update, p. 3. Figure is for 2014–2060. Office, 1993), p. 1.
283. U.S. Government Accountability Office, State and 295. Much of the following discussion, at least as it
Local Governments’ Fiscal Outlook: April 2013 pertains through the 1960s, is based on: Bertram
Update, pp. 1–2. In 2013, the projected figure was M. Gross, “The New Systems Budgeting,” Public
14.2 percent. Administration Review 29 (March/April 1969),
284. Alexander Hamilton, Report on a Plan for the pp. 113–137, and Allen Schick, “The Road to
Further Support of Public Credit (January 16, PPB: The Stages of Budget Reform,” Public
Financing and Budgeting Governments 287

Administration Review 26 (December 1966), 310. William F. West, Eric Lindquist, and Katrina
pp. 243–258. N. Mosher-Howe, “NOAA’s Resurrection of
296. President’s Commission on Economy and Eff- Program Budgeting: Déjà Vu All Over Again?”
iciency, The Need for a National Budget Public Administration Review 69 (May/June
(Washington, DC: Author, 1912). 2009), pp. 435–447. The quotation is on
297. “The Nobel Prize for Peace 1925,” Nobelprize. p. 435.
com, http://nobelprize.org/, and as derived from 311. Richard P. Nathan, The Plot That Failed: Nixon
data in U.S. Office of Management and Budget, and the Administrative Presidency (New York:
“Historical Tables,” Table 1.1. Data are for FY John Wiley and Sons, 1975).
1921–FY 1922. 312. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance
298. Charles G. Dawes, The First Year of the Budget Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Insights for
of the United States (Washington, DC: U.S. GPRA Implementation, p. 39.
Government Printing Office, 1923), p. ii. 313. Allen Schick, “A Death in the Bureaucracy: The
299. Glen Hahn Cope, “Budgeting for Performance in Demise of Federal PPB,” Public Administration
Local Government,” Municipal Year Book, 1995 Review 33 (March/April 1973), pp. 146–156. The
(Washington, DC: International City/County quotation is on p. 146.
Management Association, 1995), pp. 42–52. The 314. The first major expression of MBO is gener-
quotation is on p. 42. ally credited to Peter Drucker, The Practice
300. Verne B. Lewis, “Reflections on Budget Systems,” of Management (New York: Harper & Row,
Public Budgeting & Finance 8 (March 1988), 1954).
pp. 4–19. The quotation is on p. 7. 315. Jong S. Jun, “Management by Objectives and
301. U.S. Commission on Organization of the Exe- the Public Sector, Introduction,” Public Admini-
cutive Branch of Government, Budgeting and stration Review 26 (January/February 1976), pp.
Accounting (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 1–4. The quotation is on p. 3.
Printing Office, 1949), p. 8. 316. Robert Rodgers and John E. Hunter, “A Foun-
302. Quoted in U.S. General Accounting Office, dation of Good Management Practice in
Performance Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Government: Management by Objectives,” Public
Insights for GPRA Implementation, GAO/ Administration Review 52 (January/February
AIMD-97-46 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 1992), pp. 27–39.
Printing Office, 1997), p. 34. 317. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance
303. Quoted in Allen Schick, Budget Innovation in the Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Insights for
States (Washington, DC: Brookings, 1971), p. 127. GPRA Implementation, p. 45.
304. This definition is based on one contained in U.S. 318. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib,
General Accounting Office, Performance Budg- “MBO in Municipal Government: Variations
eting: Past Initiatives Offer Insights for GPRA on the Traditional Management Tool,” Public
Implementation, p. 35. Administration Review 55 (January/February
305. Ibid., p. 40. 1995), pp. 48–56. The quotations are on
306. Christopher G. Reddick, “Testing Rival Theories p. 55.
of Budgetary Decision-Making in the U.S. States,” 319. Aaron Wildavsky and Arthur Hammond,
Financial Accountability and Management 19 “Comprehensive Versus Incremental Budgeting
(Winter 2004), pp. 315–335. The quotation is on in the Department of Agriculture,” Administrative
p. 315. Science Quarterly 10 (December 1965), pp. 321–
307. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance 346.
Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Insights for 320. Quoted in Donald F. Haider, “Zero Base: Federal
GPRA Implementation, pp. 35–41. Style,” Public Administration Review 37 (July/
308. Edwin L. Harper, Fred A. Kramer, and Andrew M. August 1977), pp. 400–406. The quotation is on
Rouse, Implementation and Use of PPB in Sixteen p. 401.
Federal Agencies (Washington, DC: U.S. Bureau 321. Frank D. Draper and Bernard T. Pitsvada,
of the Budget, 1969). “ZBB—Looking Back After Ten Years,” Public
309. Orville Freeman, quoted in Lewis, “Reflections on Administration Review 41 (January/February
Budget Systems,” p. 11. 1981), pp. 76–83.
288 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

322. Robert C. Burns and Robert D. Lee, Jr. “The 336. Editorial Board, “Congress Should Let the IRS
Ups and Downs of State Budget Process Reform: Do Its Job, Not Tie Its Hands,” Washington Post
Experience of Three Decades,” Public Budgeting (May 1, 2016). Figure is for 2015.
& Finance 24 (September 2004), pp. 1–19. 337. Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, “Don’t Get
Figures (p. 4) are for 1975 and 2000, and include Mad at the IRS on Tax Day, Pray for It to Get
the District of Columbia. More Powerful,” Latimes.com (April 15, 2016).
323. Richard C. Kearney, “Sunset: A Survey and 338. Lisa Rein, “In Dallas, the IRS Says It Can’t Chase
Analysis of the State Experience,” Public Admini- Tax Cheats Who Owe Less than $1 Million,”
stration Review 50 (January/February 1990), Washington Post (April 8, 2015).
pp. 49–57. Figure is for 1976–1981. 339. Hacker and Pierson, “Don’t Get Mad at the IRS
324. Perry Moore, “Zero-Base Budgeting in American on Tax Day, Pray for It to Get More Powerful.”
Cities,” Public Administration Review 40 (May/ 340. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, The Costs
June 1980), pp. 253–258. of Cuts (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the
325. U.S. General Accounting Office, Streamlining Zero- Business of Government, 2011).
Base Budgeting Will Benefit Decision-Making, 341. U.S. Government Accountability Office, GAO:
PAD 79-74 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Summary of Performance and Financial Infor-
Printing Office, 1979), and Allen Schick, Zero- mation Fiscal Year 2016 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Base 80: The Status of Zero-Base Budgeting in Government Publishing Office, 2017).
the States (Washington, DC: National Association 342. John Hudak and Grace Wallack, Sometimes
of  State Budget Officers and Urban Institute, Cutting Budgets Raise Deficits: The Curious Case
1979). of Inspectors’ General Return on Investment
326. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2015) p. 10. Figure
Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Insights for is for 2010–2014.
GPRA Implementation, p. 49. 343. Kearney & Company and AGA, AGA’s Annual
327. Harry P. Hatry, “The Alphabet Soup App- Inspector General Survey: Effective Oversight
roach: You’ll Love It!” Public Manager 21 (Winter in a Changing Environment (Alexandria, VA:
1992–1993), pp. 8–12. The quotation is on Authors, 2013). Datum is for 2013.
p. 9. 344. Stein and Gelfond, How Shortsighted Spending
328. Frank D. Draper and Bernard T. Pitsvada, Cuts Increase Waste, Fraud, and Abuse. Figures
“ZBB—Looking Back After Ten Years,” Public are for FY 2011–FY 2014.
Administration Review 41 (January/February 345. Barrett and Greene, The Costs of Cuts.
1981), pp. 76–83. 346. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil
329. Hatry, “The Alphabet Soup Approach,” p. 9. S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public
330. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance Administration Across the 50 States: Linking
Budgeting: Past Initiatives Offer Insight for Practice, Theory, and Research through the
GPRA Implementation, p. 49. American State Administrators Project, 1964–
331. Lewis, “Reflections on Budget Systems,” p. 15. 2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental
332. Paul Grastis and Haley Sweetland Eduards, “The Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 21. Figures
Big Lobotomy,” Washingtonmonthly.com (June, are for 1981–1984 and 2001–2004, when states
July, August 2014). had to cut budgets by about 5 percent per
333. Harry Stein and Hilary Gelfond, How Shortsighted annum.
Spending Cuts Increase Waste, Fraud, and Abuse 347. National Commission on the Public Service,
(Washington, DC: Center for American Progress, Urgent Business for America: Revitalizing
2014). the Federal Government for the 21st Century
334. Chuck Marr and Cecile Murray, IRS Funding (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Cuts Compromise Taxpayer Service and Weaken Office, 2003), p. 36.
Enforcement (Washington, DC: Center on Budget 348. Kenneth J. Meier, “Executive Reorganization
and Policy Priorities, 2016). of Government: Impact on Employment and
335. Charles S. Clark, “There’s Now a Less Than Expenditures,” American Journal of Political
1 Percent Chance Your Tax Returns Will Be Science 24 (August 1980), pp. 396–412. The quo-
Audited,” Govexec.com (November 4, 2015). tation is on p. 410.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 289

349. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Coming & Finance Review 21 (March 2001), pp. 1–21.
Together, Breaking Apart,” Governing (March Period is 1992–2000.
209), pp. 58–59. 362. John B. Gilmour and David E. Lewis, “Assessing
350. Brudney, Bowling, and Deil, Continuity and Performance Budgeting at OMB: The Influence of
Change in Public Administration Across the 50 Politics, Performance, and Program Size,” Journal
States, p. 21. of Public Administration Research and Theory 16
351. Ibid. (April 2006), pp. 169–186. The quotation is on
352. Ibid. “Shifting programs” includes intergovern- p. 169.
mental agreements. 363. John B. Gilmour and David E. Lewis, “Does
353. Ibid. Performance Budgeting Work? An Examination
354. The sources for the following list are Frank of the Office of Management and Budget’s
Sackton, “Financing Public Programs Under PART Scores,” Public Administration Review 66
Fiscal Constraints,” Managing Public Programs: (September/October 2006), pp. 742–752. The
Balancing Politics, Administration, and Public quotation is on p. 750.
Needs, Robert E. Cleary and Nicholas Henry, 364. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thornton,
eds. (San Francisco: Jossey Bass, 1989), pp. Taking Measure: Moving from Process to Practice
147–166; Paul C. Nutt and Michael F. Hogan, in Performance Management (Washington, DC,
“Downsizing Guidelines Found in a Success and Alexandria, VA: Authors, 2013), p. 7. Figure
Story,” Public Performance & Management is for 2013.
Review 32 (September 2008), pp. 103–131; and 365. Joyce, “The Obama Administration and PBB.”
U.S. Government Accountability Office, Declining 366. Julia C. Melkers and Katherine G. Willoughby,
Resources: Selected Agencies Took Steps to Staying the Course: The Use of Performance
Minimize Effects on Mission but Opportunities Measurement in State Governments (Washington,
Exist for Additional Action, GAO-17-79 DC: IBM Center for the Business of Government,
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing 2004).
Office, 2016). 367. Julia C. Melkers and Katherine G. Willoughby,
355. Nutt and Hogan, “Downsizing Guidelines Found “The State of the States: Performance-
in a Success Story,” p. 122. Based Budgeting Requirements in 47 out of 50,”
356. Aaron Wildavsky, Speaking Truth to Power Public Administration Review 58 (January/
(Boston: Little Brown, 1979), p. 212. February 1998), pp. 66–75. The datum is on
357. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance p.  68. Hawaii’s Executive Budget Act dates to
Budgeting: State Experiences and Implications 1970.
for the Federal Government, GAO/AFMD-93- 368. Elaine S. Povich, “State Budgeting with an Eye on
41 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Results,” Stateline (August 28, 2014). Figure is for
Office, 1993), p. 1. 2013.
358. Julia E. Melkers and Katherine G. Willoughby, 369. Yilin Hou, Robin S. Lunsford, Katy C. Sides,
“Budgeters’ Views of State Performance- and Kelsey A. Jones, “State Performance-Based
Budgeting Systems: Distinctions across Branches,” Budgeting in Boom and Bust Years: An Analytical
Public Administration Review 61 (January/ Framework and Survey of the States,” Public
February 2001), pp. 54–64. The quotation is on Administration Review 71 (May/June 2011),
p. 61. Figure is for 1997. pp. 370–388.
359. Philip G. Joyce, “The Obama Administration 370. Ibid., pp. 370, 377.
and PBB: Building on the Legacy of Federal 371. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance
Performance-Informed Budgeting?” Public Budgeting: State Experiences and Implications
Administration Review 71 (May/June 2011), pp. for the Federal Government.
356–367. The quotation is on p. 356. 372. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Per-
360. Donald F. Kettl, Reinventing Government? formance Budgeting: States’ Experiences Can
Appraising the National Performance Review Inform Federal Efforts, p. 9.
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 1994), p. 43. 373. Yi Lu, Katherine Willoughby, and Sarah Arnett,
361. Philip G. Joyce and Roy T. Meyers, “Budgeting “Legislating Results: Examining the Legal Systems
During the Clinton Presidency,” Public Budgeting of PBB Systems in the States,” Public Performance
290 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

& Management Review 33 (December 2009), Public Administration Review 59 (July/August


pp. 266–287. Figures are for 2008. 1999), pp. 325–335.
374. Melkers and Willoughby, “Budgeters’ Views of 385. Ho, “PBB in American Local Governments,” pp.
State Performance-Budgeting Systems,” p. 61. 391, 399.
Figures are for 1997. 386. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “Did
375. Center on the States, Pew Charitable Trusts, We Say That? Public-Sector Predictions That
Trade-off Time: How Four States Continue to Never Came True,” Governing.com (January
Deliver (Washington, DC: Author, 2009), p. 2. 2017).
376. Kenneth A. Kiase and Michael J. Dougherty, 387. Jared Serbu, “Despite Lower Funding Level,
“The Impact of Performance Budgeting on State Two-Year Budget Deal Is ‘Huge’ for Pentagon,”
Budget Outcomes,” Journal of Public Budg- Federalnewsradio.com (November 16, 2015).
eting,  Accounting, & Financial Management 20 388. Alice M. Rivlin, “Biennial Budgeting: A First Step
(Fall  2008), pp. 277–298. The quotation is on Toward Budget Process Reform,” Committee
p. 295. on the Budget, U.S. House of Representatives
377. Anne Spray Kinney and John Ruggini, “Mea- (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
suring for a Purpose: Trends in Public-Sector Office, November 18, 2015).
Measurement and Management Practices,” 389. The Volker Alliance, Truth and Integrity in State
Government Finance Review 24 (August 2008), Budgeting, p. 7. Figures are for 2015.
pp. 14–23. The quotation is on p. 18. Figure (47 390. Jeffrey B. Liebman and Neale Mahoney, Do
percent) is for 2006. Expiring Budgets Lead to Wasteful Year-End
378. Harry P. Hatry, “The Status of Productivity Spending? Evidence from Federal Procurement
Measurement in the Public Sector,” Public (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Administration Review 38 (January/February Research, 2013). Figures are for 2004–2009.
1978), pp. 28–33. Figure is for 1977. 391. Ibid.
379. Alfred Tat-Kei Ho, “PBB in American Local 392. Ibid.
Governments: It’s More than a Management 393. Mark Headd, “Is Government IT Built to Fail?”
Tool,” Public Administration Review 71 (May/ Government Technology (June 18, 2014).
June 2011), pp. 391–401. Figure is for 2011. 394. Simon Calmar Andersen and Peter B. Mortensen,
380. Richard C. Kearney, “Reinventing Government “Policy Stability and Organizational Performance:
and Battling Budget Crises: Manager and Is There a Relationship?” Journal of Public
Municipal Government Actions in 2003,” Administration Research and Theory 20 (January
Municipal Year Book, 2005 (Washington, 2010), pp. 1–22. The quotation is on p. 1.
DC: International City/County Management 395. Wildavsky, The Politics of the Budgetary Process,
Association, 2005), p. 27–32. Figure, 29 percent, p. 64.
is for 2003. 396. The following discussion of budgetary strategy
381. Richard C. Kearney, Barry M. Feldman, and is drawn from ibid., pp. 63–127. Wildavsky calls
Carmine P. F. Scavo, “Reinventing Government: these “ubiquitous” and “contingent strategies.”
City Manager Attitudes and Actions,” Public We think that our terms are clearer.
Administration Review 60 (November/December 397. Jeffrey McMurray, Associated Press, “Tight
2000), pp. 541–542. Budgets Heighten Scrutiny of F/A-22 Raptor,”
382. Julia Melkers and Katherine Willoughby, Savannah Morning News (April 4, 2004).
“Models of Performance-Measurements Used in Representative John Murtha is quoted.
Local Governments: Understanding Budgeting, 398. James C. Garand, Katherine T. Parkhurst, and
Communication, and Lasting Effects,” Public Rusanne Jourdan Seoud, “Bureaucrats, Policy
Administration Review 65 (March/April 2005), Attitudes, and Political Behavior: Extension
pp. 180–190. Figure is for 2000. of the Bureau Voting Model of Government
383. Kinney and Ruggini, “Measuring for a Purpose,” Growth,” and “Testing the Bureau Voting Model:
p. 16. Figure is for 2006. A Research Note on Federal and State-Local
384. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib, Employees,” Journal of Public Administration
“Performance Measurement in Municipal Gov- Research and Theory 1 (April 1991), pp. 177–212
ernment: Assessing the State of the Practice,” and pp. 229–233, respectively.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 291

399. Gregory B. Lewis, “In Search of Machiavellian Options and Increased Workload in Selected
Milquetoasts: Comparing Attitudes of Bureaucrats Agencies, GAO-09-879 (Washington, DC: U.S.
and Ordinary People,” Public Administration Government Printing Office, 2009). Period ana-
Review 50 (March/April 1990), pp. 220–227. The lyzed is 1999–2009.
quotation is on p. 222. 411. Eric Katz, “Seeing Red,” Government Executive
400. William A. Niskanen, Bureaucracy and Repre- (November/December 2015), pp. 32–33. The
sentative Government (Chicago: Aldine Atherton, quotation is on p. 33.
1971). 412. Leon Panetta, as quoted in David Ignatius, “Life
401. Julie Dolan, “The Budget-Minimizing Bureaucrat? in Budget Limbo,” Washington Post (November
Empirical Evidence from the Senior Executive 1, 2007).
Service,” Public Administration Review 62 413. CBO blog post, as cited in Charles S. Clark,
(January/February 2002), pp. 42–50. The quota- “CBO Has Overestimated Revenues Since 1982,”
tions are on pp. 45, 42. Govexec.com (November 11, 2015). Figures are
402. Jeffrey L. Brudney and Deil S. Wright, “The ‘Revolt for FY 1982–FY 2016.
in Dullsville’ Revisited: Lessons for Theory, Prac- 414. Joel Achenbach, “Pick a Number, Any Number,”
tice, and Research from the American State Admi- Washington Post (November 20, 1995).
nistrators Project,” Public Administration Review 415. Mark Bloomfield, quoted in Albert B. Crenshaw,
70 (January/February 2010), pp. 26–37. The quo- “Putting Their Best Guess Forward,” Washington
tations are on p. 31. Data are for 1964–2008. Post (May 23, 1993). Emphasis is original.
403. Killian and Choudhury, “Continuity and Change 416. As derived from data in Clinton T. Brass,
in the Role of City Managers,” p. 13. Figure is for Shutdown of the Federal Government: Causes,
2010. Processes, and Effects, RL34680 (Washington,
404. Philip G. Joyce, “Congressional Budget Reform: DC: U.S. Congressional Research Service, 2011),
The Unanticipated Implications of Federal Policy p. 2. Figure is for FY 1977–FY 2010, plus the
Making,” Public Administration Review 56 (July/ 2013 shutdown.
August 1996), pp. 317–325. The quotation is on 417. Michael Gelman, Shachar Kariv, Matthew
p. 319. D. Shapiro, et al., How Individuals Smooth
405. Allen Schick, “The Majority Rules: Don’t Look Spending: Evidence from the 2013 Government
Now, but the Congressional Budget Process Is Shutdown Using Account Data (Cambridge, MA:
Working,” Brookings Review 14 (Winter 1996), National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015).
pp. 42–55. The quotation is on p. 43. 418. U.S. Office of Management and Budget,
406. Partnership for Public Service, Government Impacts and Costs of the October 2013 Federal
Disservice, p. 22, and Committee for a Responsible Government Shutdown (Washington, DC: U.S.
Federal Budget, Appropriations Watch, FY 2017 Government Printing Office, 2013).
(Washington, DC: Author 2016). 419. Marc Labonte, The FY2014 Government
407. Bill Heniff, Jr., The Congressional Budget Process Shutdown: Economic Effects (Washington, DC:
Timetable (Washington, DC: Congressional Congressional Research Service, 2015).
Research Service, 2008), p. CRS-2, for 1974–2008 420. U.S. National Park Service, Effects of the 2013
count. Continuing resolutions continued, FY Government Shutdown on National Park Service
2009–FY 2015. Visitor Spending in Gateway Communities
408. Gregory Korte, “Congress Examines Budget (Washington, DC: Author, 2014).
Process,” USA Today (October 4, 2011). 421. Philip Bump, “Let Us Now Pity Congress, Which
409. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Budget Must Go Without Ice Cream in the Shutdown,”
Issues: Effects of Budget Uncertainty from Con- Atlantic Wire (October 4, 2013).
tinuing Resolutions on Agency Operations, GAO- 422. Steven Mufson, “‘PADs’ Wise to Ways of Power,”
13-464T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Washington Post (April 25, 1990).
Printing Office, 2013), and Partnership for Public 423. Elaine S. Povich, “States Go Overtime on Budgets,
Service, Government Disservice, p. 22. Period Hurting Programs,” Stateline (September 24,
analyzed is 1999–2014. 2015).
410. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Continuing 424. Katherine G. Willoughby and Mary A.
Resolutions: Uncertainty Limited Management Finn, “Organizational Professionalism and
292 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Technological Sophistication: Budget Offices in Institute of Government, State University of New


the South,” Public Productivity & Management York, 1993), p. 20.
Review 18 (Fall 1994), pp. 19–35. The quotation 436. Irene S. Rubin, The Politics of Public Budgeting:
is on p. 33. Getting and Spending, Borrowing and Balancing,
425. Nelson A. Rockefeller Institute of Government 6th ed. (Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2010), p. 129.
and Pew Center on the States, States’ Revenue 437. Robert D. Lee. Jr., “Educational Characteristics
Estimating: Cracks in the Crystal Ball (Albany, of Budget Office Personnel and State Budgetary
NY, and Washington, DC: Authors, 2011). Processes,” Public Budgeting & Finance 11
426. Robert Rodgers and Philip Joyce, “The Effect of (September 1991), pp. 69–79, and as derived
Underforecasting on the Accuracy of Revenue from data in National Association of State
Forecasts by State Governments,” Public Admini- Budget Officers, Budget Processes in the States
stration Review 56 (January/February 1996), (Washington, DC: Author, 2008), p. 15.
pp. 48–56. The quotations are on pp. 48–49. 438. Robert D. Lee, Jr., Ronald W. Johnson, and
427. Nelson A. Rockefeller Institute of Government Philip G. Joyce, Public Budgeting Systems, 8th ed.
and Pew Center on the States, Managing Volatile (Boston: Jones and Bartlett, 2008), p. 55.
Tax Collections in State Revenue Forecasts 439. Burns and Lee, “The Ups and Downs of State
(Albany, NY, and Washington, DC: Authors, Budget Process Reform,” p. 14. Figures include
2015). the District of Columbia.
428. Richard T. Boylan, “Political Distortions in State 440. Robert D. Lee, Jr. and Robert C. Burns, “U.S. State
Forecasts,” Public Choice 136 (September 2008), Budget Directors: Characteristics, Experience,
pp. 411–427. The quotation is on p. 426. and Attitudes,” Public Budgeting & Finance 23
429. Elaine S. Povitch, “‘Triggers’ Cut State Taxes; (June 2003), pp. 39–52. Figure (p. 42) is for 2000
But Are They Good Policy?” Pewtrusts.org and includes the District of Columbia.
(November 16, 2015). 441. Burns and Lee, “The Ups and Downs of State
430. William R. Voorhees, “More Is Better: Conceptual Budget Process Reform,” p. 13. Figures are
Forecasting and State Revenue Forecast Error,” for 1970–2000 and include the District of
International Journal of Public Administration 27 Columbia.
(November 2004), pp. 651–671. The quotation is 442. James J. Gosling,” The State Budget Office and
on p. 651. Policy Making,” Public Budgeting & Finance 7
431. Glenn Abney and Thomas P. Lauth, “The End of (March 1987), pp. 51–65.
Executive Dominance in State Appropriations,” 443. Ronald W. Schack, “Local Government Revenue
Public Administration Review 58 (September/ Estimation Practices,” Municipal Year Book, 2000
October 1998), pp. 388–394. (Washington, DC: International City/County
432. John L. Mikesell, “Revenue Estimation/Scoring by Management Association, 2000), pp. 3–7. The
States: An Overview of Experience and Current quotation is on p. 3.
Practices with Particular Attention to the Role of 444. Howard A. Frank and Yongfeng Zhao, “Deter-
Dynamic Methods,” Public Budgeting & Finance minants of Local Government Revenue Fore-
32 (Summer 2012), pp. 1–24. Figures are for casting Practice: Empirical Evidence from
2011. Florida,” Journal of Public Budgeting, Accounting,
433. Abney and Lauth, “The End of Executive & Financial Management 21 (Spring 2009), pp.
Dominance in State Appropriations.” 17–35. The quotation is on p 17.
434. As derived from data in ibid. and Glenn Abney and 445. William Barnes and Bonnie Mann, Making Local
Thomas P. Lauth, “Perceptions of the Impact of Democracy Work: Municipal Officials’ Views
Governors and Legislatures in the Appropriations about Public Engagement (Washington, DC:
Process,” Western Political Quarterly 40 National League of Cities, 2010), pp. 7–8. Figures
(Fall 1987), pp. 335–342. Figure is for 1982– are for 2009.
1994. 446. W. Bartley Hildreth, Samuel J. Yeager, Gerald
435. National Commission on the State and Local R. Miller, and Jack Rabin, “Implications of
Public Service, Hard Truths/Tough Choices: An Successful Career Paths of Top Local Government
Agenda for State and Local Government Reform, Finance Managers,” Public Budgeting & Finance
First Report (Albany, NY: Nelson A. Rockefeller 30 (December 2010), pp. 82–97.
Financing and Budgeting Governments 293

447. David S. T. Matkin, “Before There Was Enron, analysts’ percentage is drawn from the total of
There Was Orange County: A Study of Local those “industries with the highest concentration
Government Financial-Oversight Committees,” of employment in this occupation.”
Public Budgeting & Finance 30 (September 451. Dawes, The First Year of the Budget of the United
2010), pp. 27–50. The quotation is on p. 27. States, p. ii.
448. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 452. Michael A. Miller, “The Public/Private Pay Debate:
Relations, State Laws Governing Local Gov- What Do the Data Show? Monthly Labor Review
ernment Structure and Administration, M-186 119 (May 1996), pp. 18–29. Refers to state and
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing local budget officers only. The other profession
Office, 1993), pp. 41–47. Data are for 1990. is personnel specialists. In 2015, private sector
449. Rubin, The Politics of Public Budgeting, pp. 130– and federal budget analysts had annual mean
138. The quotation is on p. 133. wages of about $80,000. State analysts’ wages
450. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of Labor were about $65,000, and local governments paid
Statistics, Occupational Employment Statistics approximately $69,000. See U.S. Bureau of Labor
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing Statistics, Occupational Employment Statistics,
Office, 2016), Table 13-2031. Figures are for 2015 Table 13-2031.
and include 5,380 budget analysts in colleges, uni- 453. Dawes, The First Year of the Budget of the United
versities, and professional schools, almost all of States, p. ii.
which are publicly supported. The public budget
CHAPTER

Managing Human
Capital in the Public and
Nonprofit Sectors
B eginning in 1955, when public employees
were first recorded by level of government, the
number of employees of the federal civilian, state,
WHO WANTS TO WORK FOR
THE PUBLIC OR NONPROFIT
and local governments steadily grew as a percent-
age of the workforce, peaking, in 1975, at 19.2 SECTORS? AND WHO DOESN’T?
percent;  by 2013, it had slid to 16 percent. Local Over five consecutive years, the percentage of under-
governments  grew the most rapidly, followed by graduates who planned to work for the federal, state,
the states; their combined public employees roughly or local government “immediately after graduation”
tripled. The number of federal civilian employ- declined by nearly half—from over 10 percent to
ees remained essentially flat.1 Almost 22 million more than 5 percent. Just 2 percent planned to
people currently work for all American govern- work for the federal government.3 Local govern-
ments.2 Managing them is a challenge of no modest ments, however, exert a particular pull; 82 percent
dimensions. of women and 74 percent of men who once worked
Personnel administration, or personnel man- in local government would “consider returning” to a
agement, is the planning and policymaking for, and local government leadership position.4
managing of, employees, and is limited to “internal” Barely half, 52 percent, of students in masters of
processes, such as compensation. During the 1980s, public administration (MPA) and similar programs
a more modish moniker emerged: human resource express interest in being employed by government,5
(or resources) management, which expands the field and, at the twenty top programs, not even half are.
by including “external” processes, such as profes- Almost two-thirds of the top twenty programs’ grad-
sional development. Currently, human capital man- uates who enter government service switch to other
agement is in fashion, which views employees as sectors, and nearly three-quarters of those who leave
valuable assets that can be further enriched through government depart for “more challenging work”
greater investment, and aligns human capital poli- (only a fourth leave for better salaries).6
cies with the organization’s mission. Personnelists, More generally, white people, Republicans, and
or professionals and specialists in the field, often those who never served in the military are overrepre-
use these terms interchangeably, as do we. (For the sented among those Americans who spurn working
sake of brevity, we shall use “HR” [for “human for government.7 An astonishing 56 percent of cor-
resources”], the most commonly used initials that porate and nonprofit managers are not (21 percent),
designate all three titles.) Nevertheless, they do have or “not at all” (35 percent), interested in working for
differences: each successive title represents a broader the federal government, and only 17 percent express
concept that places an increasing emphasis on the any interest in doing so. These administrators rank
worth of employees. Washington “lowest [in its] ability to provide a

294
Managing Human Capital 295

competitive environment, innovation and creativity, 1836, it had five departments and 336 employees.15
and attracting the best and brightest, in comparison During most of this period of very limited govern-
with the private and independent sectors.”8 ment indeed, the first half-dozen presidents favored
These private- and independent-sector manag- “government by gentlemen,”16 or those who were
ers may have a case. Although 90 percent of federal reputed to be persons of character and competence,
employees state that they “are constantly looking for qualities that were defined largely by a respected
ways to do their jobs better,” just 54 percent (a declin- family background and a high degree of formal edu-
ing number) “feel encouraged to come up with new cation. Being a member of the establishment counted
and better ways of doing things,” compared with 68 for a lot: over the course of the country’s first forty
percent of corporate employees who say this.9 years, almost two-thirds of the eighty to a hundred
None of this is good news for governments, but or so top appointees were drawn from the landed
the real story lies with growing student interest in gentry, merchant, and professional classes.17
working in the independent sector. Almost 22 percent
of undergraduates state that “the nonprofit or teach-
ing fields” are their “ideal career,”10 and certainly Government by Spoilers, 1828–1880
this applies to students of public administration and Even as they were being governed by gentlemen,
policy. Sixty-one percent of the directors of these pro- however, Americans were growing less gentlemanly
grams report that they have seen an increase over the in their politics. When independence was declared,
past year in student interest in working in a nonprofit in 1776, over four-fifths of the states required that,
organization.11 A plurality, 21 percent, of these stu- to vote, men must own land or have paid taxes, but,
dents state that their “ideal area of work” following by 1830, only half of the states retained these stip-
graduation would be the nonprofit sector.12 (MPA ulations. As a result, far more men could vote, and
programs have responded to their students’ interest: many could not be described as gentlemen. When
fully half of all master’s-level nonprofit management combined with a populist candidate—in the form
programs are found within MPA programs.13) of Andrew Jackson in the election of 1828—voting
The decision to start careers in the independent turnout more than tripled from the previous election
sector, rather than the public one, works out well (16 percent turnout), and surpassed half of all eligi-
for those who make it. “Compared to those working ble voters for the first time.18
in the public sector, managers in nonprofits report These fundamental political changes meant only
greater freedom in deciding how to carry out their one thing: spoils. If presidents were to emerge, like
job functions, more control over their work sched- Jackson, from the class that earned its own living,
ules, and greater opportunities for pay increases.”14 then politics had to be made to pay.
Contrary to conventional wisdom, however,
Jackson maintained past establishmentarian pat-
THE EVOLUTION OF PUBLIC terns, dismissing about the same share of political
appointees as had his gentlemanly predecessors.19
HUMAN CAPITAL MANAGEMENT John Tyler (1841–1845) was the first president to
The evolution of public HR management in the implement a comprehensive spoils system, a prac-
United States can be roughly divided into six phases. tice that reached its apex with the presidency of
Depending upon the phase in question, America’s gov- Abraham Lincoln (1861–1865), but spoils contin-
ernments have been dominated, in successive turns, by ued to mar government for the next several decades.
its aristocrats, corrupt officials, ardent reformers, “sci- It is difficult for those of us reared in an environ-
entific” managers, dynamic administrators, and timid ment of largely honest government to appreciate the
clerks. We consider this evolution next. extent—and the brazenness—of the spoils period.
After an election, newspaper advertising typically
swelled with such announcements as, “WANTED —
Government by Gentlemen, 1789–1827 A GOVERNMENT CLERKSHIP at a salary of not
In 1789, the federal government started off with less that $1000 per annum. Will give $100 to anyone
three departments (State, Treasury, and War), and, by securing me such a position.” Following the election
296 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

of 1880, newly-elected President James A. Garfield, Similarly, the act set up no body of permanent,
according to a government archive, found “hungry high-level, professional public administrators, as is
office-seekers lying in wait for him like vultures for the norm in Western Europe. The unintended con-
a wounded bison.”20 sequence is that Washington now oozes presidential-
ly-appointed political executives, who, as we discuss
later, consistently underperform relative to careerists.
Government by the Good, 1881–1905 The act gave America one more gift that, like
The corrupt excesses of the spoils system eventually political executives, keeps on giving. It omitted the
resulted in a reform movement that was determined British requirement that an applicant could enter
to rid government of those bureaucrats who owed public service only at the lowest grade, thereby
their office to nothing more than party hackwork. opening the apertures into which corrupt (if legal)
Between 1861 and 1882, sixty-four civil service revolving doors were later installed.
reform bills were introduced in Congress, but not
one of them was passed by even one chamber.21 “Goodness” versus “Badness” “Government by
The  assassination of President Garfield by a the good”24 led, in 1907, to President Theodore
deranged office seeker, in 1881, changed Congress’s Roosevelt’s Civil Service Rule I, which prohibited
collective mind. almost seven out of ten federal workers from par-
ticipating in political campaigns and barred the
The Civil Service Act of 1883 and Its Long-Lasting solicitation of political contributions from federal
Legacies Just two years following Garfield’s assas- employees. These reforms were strengthened and
sination, Congress passed the Civil Service Act (also broadened by the Political Activities Act, also known
known as the Pendleton Act, after its legislative as the Hatch Act, of 1939.
sponsor), which created a bipartisan Civil Service In 1940, the Hatch Act was amended to extend
Commission charged with creating a nonpartisan its coverage to state and local workers whose salaries
federal service. Initially, the legislation’s reach was are paid entirely or in part with federal funds, and
modest, covering a fraction more than one out of to prohibit these employees from running for public
every ten federal civilian employees.22 The act’s com- office. All the states have enacted their own legis-
mitment to neutrality and fairness was strengthened lation that restricts, in various ways, their employ-
by subsequent presidential directives that prohib- ees’ political activities, including thirty-six states
ited an employee’s removal for political or religious that have passed “little Hatch Acts” that reflect the
reasons (in 1896), and guaranteed due process for federal version.25
those who had been hired competitively (1897). More recently, Washington has lightly loosened
Although the Civil Service Act was influenced political restrictions on government workers. The
by the British public service, the Senate inserted Hatch Act Reform Amendments of 1993 lifted the
some major provisos that were uniquely American. 1907 prohibition on federal employees participating
One such clause was that civil service exam- in political campaign, but they still may not be can-
inations must be “practical in character.” A conse- didates in partisan elections or engage in political
quence of such practicality was that it provided the activity while on duty. In 2012, Congress passed the
basis for a future system of position classification, 2012 Hatch Act Modernization Act, which contin-
but, less propitiously, it also reflected a regrettable ues the ban on entering elections for those state and
anti-intellectualism and anti-professionalism. local employees who are paid entirely with federal
In stark contrast to Western Europe, the law laid grants or loans, but lifted the prohibition from those
no tracks between the civil service and the universi- who are paid only in part with federal funds. In
ties, and it was only in 1905 that the Civil Service 2016, the Supreme Court ruled that it is unconstitu-
Commission first observed that “the greatest defect tional to discharge or demote a (in this case, local)
in the Federal Service is the lack of opportunity for government employee because he or she supports a
ambitious, well-educated young men”;23 a serious particular political candidate.26
effort to correct that deficiency surfaced, eventually, Over time, civil service commissions, which
in the 1930s. typically administered these and similar policies,
Managing Human Capital 297

became associated “with morality, with a con-


notation of ‘goodness’ vs. ‘badness,’ quite apart Government by Policymaking
from  the  purposes for which people were Administrators, 1937–1954
employed.”27 To put it crassly but clearly: the In 1937, the report of the president’s Committee
bureaucrats responsible for keeping government on Administrative Management (more commonly
moral and apolitical, and the bureaucrats respon- known as the Brownlow Committee, after its chair,
sible for getting a job done, became increasingly Louis Brownlow) was published, and, for the first
distinct entities. time since its founding, the usefulness and power
of the Civil Service Commission were quietly ques-
tioned. “Personnel was seen as a principal, if not the
Government by Scientific Managers, major, tool of management,”35 and the committee
1906–1936 recommended that each major agency have its own
Despite government by the good, good government personnel manager reporting to its top administra-
remained elusive. In 1912, an analyst decried the tor. The president quickly complied, in 1938, with
“snail like pace” of government employees, alleging Executive Order 7916. The Hoover Commission’s
that they wasted from 40 to 70 percent of their work first report, issued in 1949, also took up this cudgel,
time.28 and “little Hoover commissions” in many states did
The influential New York Bureau of Municipal the same. Today, agency-based HR offices are com-
Research (detailed in Chapter 2), a privately-sup- monplace.
ported think tank founded in 1906, agreed with this There was more. “Administration” also
assessment, and its first forays focused on getting expressed the long-denied reality that public admin-
public “workers to do the work they were hired to istrators make public policy.
do,” a concentration that quickly incorporated a Although the Brownlow Committee bowed
“strong link between the bureau and scientific man- briefly to the belief, still widely held, that politics and
agement.”29 (We reviewed scientific management in administration were separate entities, it also concen-
Chapter 3.) Scientific principles of public adminis- trated on those administrative “positions which are
tration were part of an inconsistent but soothing actually policy-determining” (consistency, evidently,
amalgam of civil-service beliefs that packed merit, was dismissed as the hobgoblin of small minds).36
morality, neutrality, and efficiency into one concep- When, in 1953, Dwight D. Eisenhower, a
tual lump. Republican, assumed the presidency after two
It was, nonetheless, a likable lump, and it left decades of Democratic government, he discov-
legacies. A major one is the position classification ered, maddeningly, a huge civilian bureaucracy
system, first adopted by Chicago in 1912, and which that had more than quadrupled in size since the
has been described as “the ascendancy of scientific last Republican administration, and which was
management.”30 The council-manager form of local run by entrenched Democratic policymakers, who,
government emerged as a direct outgrowth of the perversely, were protected by civil service regula-
period’s precepts; the first government to adopt a tions  that were based on the premise that politics
council-manager plan was Sumter, South Carolina, should not intrude on administration! Although aca-
in 1912, and, by 1930, 418 local governments had demia during this period was barely beginning to rec-
adopted it.31 ognize that bureaucrats made public policy, elected
Certainly government by scientific managers policymakers clearly understood that they did.
served to extend the reach and power of the Civil
Service System. Between 1900 and 1930: the propor-
tion of federal civilian employees administered by Government by Professionals,
the Civil Service Commission shot from 46 percent 1955–Present
to 80 percent;32 the number of states that had merit By mid-century, another value was entering the
systems expanded from two to nine;33 and cities milieu of public HR: professionalism.
with civil service commissions nearly quadrupled The professional period encompasses two dis-
from sixty-five to 250.34 tinct systems of public HR. One is Specialized Public
298 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Professional Systems, or those public personnel A Centralized, Sovereign, and Strong HR Office
systems that are geared to the career needs of high- The merit principle also demands that human
ly-educated specialists. The other is the Professional capital management be sovereign and separate from
Public Administration System, which reflects the the rest of government, and that agencies may select
idea that HR systems should encourage effective applicants only from lists that personnel adminis-
and efficient management by competent generalist trators have pre-approved. (Traditionally, only a
administrators. meager three candidates are listed, a practice that
These professional systems are two of the five Washington initiated in 1888.) If the civil service
systems of public human capital management, each were not independent and powerful, this argument
with its own values and mission, which we con- continues, a more partisan and corrupt government
sider next; the remaining three are the Civil Service, would be the unacceptable consequence.
Collective, and Political Executive systems. We begin
with the Civil Service System. Personnel Administrators Rule! Sounds good,
but there were problems. Most notably, a sovereign
civil service grew obsessed with writing and impos-
THE CIVIL SERVICE SYSTEM: ing rules on every other agency. By the 1990s, the
federal government’s chief HR bureau, the Office
THE MEANING OF MERIT of Personnel Management (OPM), had filled a stag-
The civil service has been the historic heart of public gering 7,000 pages with its regulations,38 a practice
administration. The general Civil Service System, or emulated by personnel offices in state and local gov-
merit system (a phrase that emphasizes the values of ernments as well. These swamps of civil service rules
public service, in contrast to its bureaucratic struc- reflected the disturbing reality that “compliance
ture), is career personnel who have tenure and who with regulations [had become] the central focus of
are administered according to traditional merit prac- the personnel system.”39
tices.
The Murkiness of Merit The position description
and its classification, equity, testing, and a sover-
The Meaning of Merit eign and strong central personnel office remain the
Just what are these practices? underlying principles of the Civil Service System.
As we shall see throughout this chapter, however,
The Position Most centrally, the overriding “developments since World War II have befogged
practice of the merit system is its emphasis on the meaning of merit principles and confused the
the position, and the system assumes that govern- content of merit systems.”40
ment  positions can be objectively and correctly
classified.
The Profession of Public Human
Fairness as Classification HR managers hold Capital Management
dear one value that eclipses all others. That value is There are more than 60,000 managers and special-
equity, or equal work for equal pay.37 Personnelists ists in human resources, labor relations, compensa-
identify equal work by the job classification system, tion, benefits, training, and development who work
but line administrators have scant interest in equal in government, comprising 16 percent of the total
work; their priority is paying people for productiv- public human capital workforce in all sectors.41
ity. Ultimately, the two mindsets collide. Over two-fifths of these civil service administra-
tors and professionals are women, more than nine
Hiring and Promoting by Score “Merit” in the out of ten are college graduates, and they have long
merit system is determined by one’s scores on tests, career histories in their field and in government.42
which, in turn, are the bases for entry and promotion. Public personnel employees appear to have a high
Politics, ethnicity, gender, and other non-meritorious job satisfaction (and with some reason—they are
factors are actively suppressed. one of only two categories of public professionals
Managing Human Capital 299

whose salaries are comparable with those of their terms of quality (53 percent are ranked as “poor”),53
corporate counterparts43), and most perceive their as substantiated by the fact that 44 percent of the
jobs as being a long-term career.44 announcements for supervisory positions provide
What do governments’ human capital manag- “no substantive information about the nature
ers do? Their major duties, listed in the order of the of the position’s supervisory responsibilities.”54
most time that they devote to them, are: recruiting “Consequently,” according to federal personnel spe-
and hiring; benefits administration; pay administra- cialists, “many announcements can actually discour-
tion; developing HR policy, such as retirement plans; age potential applicants from applying for Federal
position classification; training and development; jobs.”55
processing grievances; appraising and measuring Even more damaging than the announcement
employee performance; brokering conflict; manag- of recruiting may be the process of recruiting.
ing diversity; and collective bargaining, among other A modest 45 percent of “hiring managers” state
activities.45 that they “actively and personally” participate in
HR professionals also may influence dispropor- recruitment.”56 Worse, nearly four-fifths of HR
tionately the morale of their public agencies. It seems staffers believe that “at least some of the time man-
that if HR workers are happy in their work, then their agement had someone in mind to fill the position
agencies’ co-workers are happier than the overall prior to advertising the vacancy.” In fact, two-fifths
norm. “Agency morale has a lot to do with satisfac- of these specialists report that “had been asked to
tion in the . . . human resources workforces.”46 re-advertise a vacancy because the selecting official
wanted to hire someone who was not on the referral
list,” and that this happened “always, most of the
Recruiting Bureaucrats time, or some of the time”; this manipulative prac-
Recruiting new talent into the public sector could tice is flatly illegal.57
stand some improvement. Three-fifths of young When federal recruitment is done well, the
adults report that no one, including government, has results can be dramatic. A year after the Peace Corps
ever asked them if they would consider working in simplified and accelerated its recruitment, applica-
government.47 tions soared by more than 70 percent, a two-decades
high.58
Federal Recruiting: Awful Announcements, Corr-
upted Processes Forty-three percent of  federal Grass-Roots Recruiting Asked “which workforce
workers think that their agencies are able to recruit issues are important to your organization?” more
people with the right skills, 32 percent think not, and than nine out of ten state and local officials replied
a suspiciously high 25 percent “neither agree nor that “recruiting and retaining qualified personnel
disagree,”48 suggesting, perhaps, that these respond- with needed skills to public service”; the rest stated
ents prefer not to cast themselves as difficult people. that it was “somewhat important.” No other issue
Finding qualified job candidates is the top concern comes close to this top-ranked response.
of federal executives, but 78 percent of federal HR State and local governments are abandoning
executives think that programs for acquiring new printed media in recruiting and are going full-blast
talent are inadequate.49 About two-thirds of the electronic. Eighty-four percent of these governments
topmost federal bureaucrats, the Senior Executive cite “online job advertising” as their “most suc-
Service (SES), believe that recruiting qualified candi- cessful” recruitment practice in “reaching qualified
dates to the SES is “somewhat difficult” (44 percent) candidates,” followed by “government web sites”
or “very difficult” (24 percent).50 (51 percent) and “social media (28 percent); “state/
There are some reasons underlying these local newsletters,” the next highest, attains a wan
numbers. As much as a third of all federal job open- 17 percent.59 Those states with “more usable Web
ings are never publicly announced,51 and a third of sites [receive] significantly more applications per job
those that are announced “are typically open for less opening.”60
than two weeks.”52 The feds themselves rate only The states are introducing major reforms
2 percent of their job announcements as “good” in designed to decentralize and simplify recruiting. A
300 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

plurality of states, twenty-two, have decentralized Worse are “mission-critical skills gaps both
recruitment to the agencies, and another eighteen within federal agencies and across the federal work-
share this responsibility with the central personnel force . . . [that] impede the government from cost-
bureau.61 Nevertheless, nearly four out of ten state effectively . . . achieving results.” There are “nearly
agency heads think that the complexity of person- two dozen occupations with significant program-
nel procedures is their most serious impediment for matic impact” that have skills gaps, including six
recruiting.62 occupations, such as cybersecurity, that are govern-
Local governments have focused on proac- ment-wide.69
tive  recruitment. Most solicit applications from Executive Order 13562, issued in 2010, directed
minority and women’s organizations, state and agencies to simplify résumé-format requirements
private employment agencies, unions, profes- and recruit on campuses, a pair of directives that
sional  organizations, and use internships as a may improve the quality of applicant pools.
recruiting tool.63
The Internship Issue Internships are a favored
way  of getting a job. In the private sector, 50
Hiring Bureaucrats percent of interns are hired permanently, but in
Hiring well is one of the public sector’s more vexing federal circles, where some 60,000 student employ-
issues. ees toil  annually, just 7 percent are.70 To correct
this  bleak situation, Executive Order 13562, just
Federal Hiring: A Study in Mismanagement More noted, ended two internship programs that had
than two decades ago, the chief federal person- attracted nearly half of new federal employees.
nel administrator characterized the finding of an They were replaced by a more “student friendly”
entry-level administrative position as “intellectually Presidential Management Fellows Program (begun
confusing, procedurally nightmarish, inaccessible in 1977) and a new Pathways Program composed
to students and very difficult to explain.”64 Small of two new internship programs for high school stu-
wonder that, despite at least seven major attempts dents and recent post-secondary graduates, respec-
by federal agencies to reform federal hiring over nine tively; all potentially lead to federal careers. Four
years,65 a startling 21 percent of federal workers years after Pathways became effective, in 2012, all
think that the process by which they themselves chief human capital officers surveyed reported using
were hired was “unfair”—these are the applicants it in the past year;71 nearly 6 percent of “Pathways
who were hired, not rejected!—a percentage that is internships” and “Pathways recent graduates” are
at least three times greater than those in businesses hired into permanent positions.72
and nonprofit organizations.66
There has been some improvement; the Federal Fragmentation The federal government
Competitive Service Act of 2015 eliminated the has no standard job application form, and nearly
strange policy that prohibited an agency from hiring two-fifths of college students do not understand
highly-qualified applicants whom another agency those forms that it does have.73 These forms must
had declined to hire because it had a surplus of such be submitted to one of 105 hiring, or appointment,
applicants. For the most part, however, federal hiring authorities (down from more than 200 ten years
remains a nightmare. Here is why. earlier74), each of which has its own hiring proce-
dures; some are government-wide, others are limited
Applicant Pools The hiring challenge starts with to single agencies or portions of them. Just twenty
who is available for hire. Even though nearly three- (or 9 percent) of these hiring authorities account for
fourths of federal agencies foresee higher skill and 91 percent of all federal hires. Of the 105 appoint-
educational levels being needed for their own work- ment authorities, two (one of which hires only physi-
forces,67 almost two-fifths of federal managers cite a cians for Veterans Affairs) account for 38 percent of
“shortage of qualified applicants” as their “primary all federal hires, and the remaining 103 are each in
obstacle in hiring employees”; no other obstacle the single digits, or fractions of 1 percent,75 or (in the
comes remotely close to this one.68 case of twenty authorities) not used at all.76
Managing Human Capital 301

Even within federal agencies, fragmentation because of its unpopularity among the agencies.
flourishes. In one program, the hiring process had Most agencies90 ended up relying on that “least
110 steps involving forty-five people.77 effective available predictor of job performance,”91
the unassembled examination, which ranks appli-
Confused Candidates Fifty-seven percent of federal cants based on their self-reported education and
employees found their hiring process to be “confus- experience.
ing,” about double the percentages in the private and In 2002, Congress strengthened these question-
nonprofit sectors.78 Even when Washington does able practices by passing the Chief Human Capital
find “outstanding candidates, the complexity of the Officers Act, which allowed agencies to ignore
hiring process often drives all but the most dedicated applicants’ test scores in favor of their own ranking
away.”79 systems. Solid research shows that when managers
overrule test results and hire according to their own
A Glacial Process Seventy-nine percent of federal judgment, their organizations “systematically end up
employees describe their hiring process as “slow,” a with worse hires.”92
proportion that is significantly higher than those of Executive Order 13562 of 2010, noted earlier,
nonprofit (50 percent) and corporate (42 percent) directed that screening and selection be reformed,
workers who say this.80 Almost a third of entry- improved, and accelerated. As a result, agencies and
level new hires cite “the length of the process” as OPM moved toward a greater use of testing; by
the “greatest obstacle” in their federal job search, 2014, competitive examinations were used to hire
far outdistancing all six of the other hurdles.81 A 23 percent of all federal new hires, far fewer than in
remarkable four-fifths of SES executives think that the past, but it was the method most used to hire.93
the hiring process for senior executives is too slow OPM, in 2015, introduced USA Hire, a digital-
(16 percent thought the process was “about right”).82 ly-based test that, in many ways, is a return to the
Of course, as HR officials themselves admit, universal entry test that had prevailed from 1955 to
“the longer the process takes, the more applicant 1981. The test is fair to minorities, scoring is instan-
attrition is likely to occur,”83 which may explain taneous, which should speed hiring, and taking the
why nearly nine out of ten major agency heads state test is procedurally simple, which should encourage
that slow hiring is a moderate-to-great problem.84 more applications; prior to the Peace Corps’ reforms,
Executive Order 13562 of 2010, noted earlier, mentioned earlier, not even a fourth of its applicants
also directed agencies to address this problem by completed their applications, but after the reforms,
requiring that they dramatically shorten hiring 95 percent did.94
schedules. Still, it takes, on average, 100 days (and Still, a new and needed test will not, by itself,
lengthening) to hire a federal employee.85 solve all screening problems. A remarkable 44
percent of supervisors had no say in the new hires
Restoring Health to Sickly Screening and Selection whom they supervise, which may be why only 71
When government uses robust selection procedures, percent of them are “very satisfied” with these
the productivity of its managers and professionals employees, compared with 80 percent who were
increases by an impressive 17 percent.86 Regrettably, involved in their selection.95
for thirty-four years (1981–2015), federal screen-
ing was so sickly that it was thought to be actually Federal Hiring’s Crotchety Consequence Fewer
harming the quality of applicant pools.87 than a fourth of all new federal hires are hired for
Since 1955, Washington had relied principally entry-level positions, less than a quarter of whom
on a single “universal” test for entry to most agen- are hired immediately after graduation; in fact, the
cies, and it filtered from half to three-fifths of all average age of new federal hires is a mature thirty-
applicants.88 In 1981, the judiciary banned it on the three.96 Hence, we have a really elderly federal civil-
grounds that had an adverse impact on minorities.89 ian workforce.
OPM found no replacement until 1990, and then The proportion of federal workers who are
only because the courts demanded it; the test was twenty-nine or younger has been more than halved,
used, tepidly, for four years and was then abandoned from 15 percent97 to 7 percent, over thirty-one
302 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

years.98 By contrast, 12 percent of local government solid majority of upper-level new federal hires (59
employees, 15 percent of state workers, and 24 percent)108 and a dominating plurality of entry-level
percent of private-sector employees are under thirty ones (40 percent)109 who were hired from outside
years of age.99 “The federal government workforce the government (outsiders account for 29 percent of
is older, on average, than any other sector of employ- all new federal hires110) nevertheless are drawn from
ees in the United States,”100 and younger workers are the private sector. Overwhelmingly, these sector
not staying long in the federal employ. Employees switchers cite “job security” as their leading motiva-
who are thirty-three or under stay in the federal tion for making the switch.111
government, on average, fewer than four years,101 State mid- and upper-level administrators who
and nearly 9 percent of all those who leave the gov- were hired from corporations typically supervised
ernment are under thirty, “a significant figure given few corporate subordinates, and their switch often
their tiny presence in the workforce.”102 entailed a public-sector promotion.112
These trends have significant portents for pro- Do these patterns imply that the public sector
ductivity: after the first five years in a federal agency, has a special attraction for managers whose corpo-
employee engagement in his or her job drops 12 rate careers are stuttering, or even stuck, and only
percentage points.103 Just how engaged is the oldest then does government become their belated second
workforce in America? choice? It is an all-the-more intriguing question
when we realize that only 3 percent of upper-level
Does Washington Hire Well? In spite of itself, new federal hires113 and 4 percent of entry-level
Washington may be hiring fairly well. ones114 who are hired from outside the government
Twenty-nine percent of federal executives and are drawn from the independent sector—the sector
top professionals who were hired from outside the that, as we observed in Chapter 4, far surpasses the
government think that the quality of federal supervi- other two in terms of its employees’ disdain for job
sors is better than in their last place of employment security and their strong need for socially meaning-
(just 12 percent believe it is worse), and 21 percent ful work.
think that the quality of their co-workers is higher
(10 percent believe otherwise).104
Most of the data support these opinions. Almost Classifying Bureaucrats
half of all entering federal employees have college Position classification is a core tenet of the Civil
degrees in specifically relevant fields.105 There is Service System. Indeed, employees in the civil service
“little difference in the education levels and grade are also known as “classified” employees.
point averages” among applicants who accept offers
of federal employment and those who take other Classifying Federal Employees Until 1923, when
options, an indication that Washington competes the Classification Act was enacted, federal supervi-
successfully in hiring.106 sors had unlimited autonomy to determine the pay
of workers, and federal employees were growing
State Hiring State governments share at least one increasingly angry about their lack of rigor and,
hiring issue with Washington: “The size of the appli- often, fairness. The act authorized the Civil Service
cant pool for career professional positions is not Commission to group federal positions into rational
likely to be large [and] the quality of the applicant classes and pay their occupants accordingly.
pool is not likely to be very strong.”107 Nevertheless, A more comprehensive Classification Act was
as we describe later, the education and profession- enacted in 1949. It established the dominant classifi-
alism of state (and local) executives have improved cation system, the General Schedule (GS), composed
vastly over the last half century. of fifteen grades for civilian workers, and, within
these grades, there are roughly 420 to 450 occu-
A Caveat about Federal and State Hiring Still, a pations, as OPM continuously revises the number.
caveat is in order. At the very top are the 8,000 or so members of the
Despite corporate managers’ contempt for Senior Executive, Senior Professional, and Senior
working in the federal government, noted earlier, a Foreign services, each with its own classification
Managing Human Capital 303

system. Blue-collar and Postal Service employees, The Senior Executive Service fares not much
and about twenty agencies, also have their own better. Over four years in the 2010s, “more than
systems. 85 percent” of SES careerists “were rated in the top
two of five categories.”123 By 2015, more than 71
Classifying at the Grass Roots All state govern- percent had received performance bonuses averag-
ments have position classification systems. Eight ing $10,746, and a tad less than 49 percent “received
states have decentralized classification from their the highest possible performance rating of ‘outstand-
central personnel office to the agencies, and another ing.’”124 In 2016, OPM imposed tighter regulations
eight distribute this duty between their HR and line regarding SES performance assessments.
agencies.115 All state governments and virtually all local
A dozen states require their cities to adopt clas- ones formally rate their bureaucrats. Because these
sification plans,116 although almost all local gov- systems are in flux, we address them later in terms of
ernments of any size have them. Most cities and performance pay.
counties use a single classification system, although,
oddly, the smaller the jurisdiction, the more likely
that there will be multiple systems.117 Paying Bureaucrats
One of the more significant issues of public pay is
its comparability with private-sector pay. (Whether
Rating Bureaucrats public compensation is comparable with that of the
At the federal level, the Civil Service Act of 1883 independent sector is much less of an issue because,
set the first, if vague, standard for assessing the per- as we detailed in Chapter 5, the average nonprofit
formance of bureaucrats, stipulating that promotion compensation is 27 percent less than governments’.)
should be based on merit, but neglected to estab- One must enter prudently this thorny thicket. A
lish a system for assessing merit. An appropriations review of this literature revealed that researchers’
act of 1912 directed the Civil Service Commission “conclusions may be more closely linked to meth-
to establish a uniform efficiency rating system for odology and ideology than is desirable.”125 For
personnel in all agencies, replete with annual formal example, the Federal Salary Council, using a contro-
performance reviews (a mandate that is still with us), versial methodology, has, for decades, issued annual
and the Performance Rating Act of 1950 required reports stating that federal salaries are at least a third
each agency to set up an employee appraisal system. lower than their counterparts’ salaries in business;
Beginning in 1995, OPM steadily decentralized the conservative Heritage Foundation has stated that
personnel evaluation to the agencies. Today, in the federal employees earn 22 percent more, on average,
twenty-four major agencies, 71 percent of perma- than comparable positions in the private sector
nent non-SES employees are rated under a five-level (which has far more part-time employees, which the
system, which OPM had mandated for decades; 13 Foundation counts); and the Congressional Budget
percent are assessed by a pass/fail method (the least Office concluded that overall federal pay was 16
informative of any assessment method,118 down percent higher than private-sector pay 2005–2010,
from 45 percent of all federal employee evaluations and 17 percent higher 2011–2015, but that feds with
eight years earlier119); 9 percent are rated in a three- graduate degrees (e.g., public administrators) were
level scale; and 6 percent in a four-level one.120 paid less.126 With all this said, however, some find-
In all four rating systems combined, 39 percent ings seem straightforward.
of employees are rated as “Fully Successful,” 33
percent as “Outstanding” (the highest) and 27 The Federal Experience By the 1980s, federal sal-
percent as “Exceeds Fully Successful.” Three-tenths aries were falling well behind those in business, and
of 1 percent are “Minimally Successful,” and one- large numbers of federal executives and professionals
tenth of 1 percent are “Unacceptable.”121 Ratings were leaving for the private sector because of it.127 In
such as these—i.e., better than 99 percent are “Fully 1990, Congress addressed these problems by enact-
Successful” or higher—have been the norm for many ing the Federal Employees Pay Comparability Act,
years.122 which stated that General Schedule salaries would be
304 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

raised to match salaries for comparable nonfederal attributable to the public sector’s greater proportion
positions (less 5 percent due to superior federal ben- of jobs that require higher levels of education or
efits) in five years, beginning in 1994, and that GS physical risk, and heavier unionization.133
pay would be adjusted to reflect local nonfederal pay When we compare the grass-roots employees
(85 percent of federal employees work in places other with private employees who are working in the same
than the District of Columbia128). The act created jobs, however, then they fare far less well.
a  Federal Salary Council to recommend each year State employees are paid, on average, 11 percent
appropriate salary adjustments to the president. less than their private-sector equivalents, and their
Over the course of the next twenty-five years, total compensation is nearly 7 percent less. High
presidents rejected every salary recommendation unemployment and vibrant public unions associate
by the Federal Salary Council, and, in 2011, local- most strongly with high state wages. “Surprisingly,”
ity pay (which turned out to be unworkable as and “contrary to conventional wisdom,” however,
designed) was frozen; it was unfrozen in 2015. In large state budgets and sufficient finances to offer
the words of a normally sober-sided analyst, the law competitive wages are “not related” to a state’s
is “anemic,” “egregious,” and a “farce.”129 (Tell us “ability to recruit and retain talented candidates”
what you really think.) and are “not found to influence state public-private
About two-thirds of all federal civilian employ- wage gaps.”134
ees consistently report that they are satisfied with Local government workers are paid, on average,
their pay,130 and with some reason—a large analysis 12 percent less than their corporate counterparts
concluded that, “on average, 44% of federal govern- in the same jobs, and their overall compensation is
ment employees are thriving financially, compared more than 7 percent less.135
with 34% of all other workers in the U.S.”131 As in Washington, the higher that one ascends
This is far from the case with federal executives’ the hierarchy, the wider the wage gap grows. A
compensation, which still is not even “on a par . . . massive analysis of forty-three corporate, state, and
with counterpart positions in state or local govern- local positions found that “the differences in pay
ment.”132 Consider just two examples: the salaries of between the two sectors were most pronounced
state university presidents and city managers, other in the higher paid professional and administrative
than in the smallest colleges and towns, commonly jobs.” Indeed, in 95 percent of these positions, public
match or exceed those of federal cabinet secretaries. pay was lower than private pay, and, in the remain-
The compensation of chief executive officers (CEOs) ing 5 percent (or two positions), government’s pay
who head large corporations or nonprofit organiza- merely “approached” the private sector’s pay for the
tions are many times greater than those of cabinet same jobs.136
secretaries, even though these CEOs are responsible In another unfortunate parallel with the federal
for far smaller budgets. Google, Inc., for example, experience, the compensation of state and local
has some 40,000 employees and distributes about employees, especially administrators and profession-
$3 billion a year in grants; its CEO’s annual com- als, has, since the late 1980s, been steadily declining
pensation has topped $100 million, not to mention relative to their counterparts in the private sector.137
nearly $6 billion in stocks. By contrast, the U.S.
Department of Health and Human Services hires
62,000 employees and distributes more than $330 Training Bureaucrats
billion in grants and payments; its secretary’s salary Training workers to improve their workplace skills
is less than $204,000. is closely and clearly linked with organizational pro-
ductivity.138 “The most effective private firms” spend
The State and Local Experience In general, state from 3 to 5 percent of their budgets on training.139
and local employees are paid well. Their total com- The Australian government—often cited as a model
pensation costs (that is, pay plus benefits) are 51 of efficient and effective public administration—
percent higher than those of private-sector workers; spends an impressive 5 percent of its budget on
salaries and wages are 43 percent higher, and ben- training, which Australians cite as being the “most
efits are 73 percent higher. These disparities are useful” of their government’s innovations.140
Managing Human Capital 305

Training heightens nonprofit,141 federal,142 training over the course of a year;156 these officers,
and state and local employees’143 job satisfaction, among other duties, guard the White House and
engagement, and organizational commitment, and were doing so when, in 2014, a knife-wielding
lowers their inclination to consider quitting their intruder ran across the lawn and penetrated deep
jobs—not a surprising correlation in light of the into the executive mansion.
fact that, as government training expenditures A promising innovation is the growing use of
rise, so do promotion rates, and significantly so.144 training via computers. Seventy percent of “federal
Evidence also suggests that a greater investment in leaders” (GS 13 and higher) think that “digital tech-
training reduces public employees’ discrimination nology has improved access to training relevant to
charges.145 agency mission.”157

Training Feds Most federal training emerged when Training at the Grass Roots Nearly three-quarters
the Government Employees Training Act was enacted of state and local officials report that they receive
in 1958, and today there are Management Deve- “regular training,”158 a proportion that is far higher
lopment Centers and a Federal Executive Institute than that of the feds. State administrators spend an
dedicated to training federal administrators. average of twenty-five hours a year in “formal class-
Even though “career development and training room training.”159
was the strongest driver” subject to administrative It appears that most training for these adminis-
control that correlates significantly with increased trators is conducted by universities.160 About four-
employee engagement,146 Washington spends a fifths of these officials have used universities for a
modest 1.3 percent of its “personnel budget” on variety of services, and rank them as comparable
training,147 and, still worse, federal administrators to services furnished by the private sector, but they
are prone to focus on training programs when they accord their very highest marks to their training pro-
need to cut budgets, and to cut them back more grams.161
than other programs.148 (Or, worse, never spending State governments devote, on average, “more
training funds in the first place; the Department of than 1.3 percent” of their annual payrolls to training,
Homeland Security spends just 1 percent of its $1.4 a conservative calculation, with some states spending
billion training budget, a laxity going back many “upwards of 5 percent.” Impressively, average state
years.149)The proportion of all federal workers who training expenditures per employee nearly doubled
say that they need more training to do their jobs rose over just three years.162 “Unfortunately, many states
from less than a third in the early nineties to almost report that the training budget is the first thing elim-
half by the end of the decade, and has been stuck inated in spending freezes or budget cuts.”163
at that level ever since.150 Small wonder that just More than nine-tenths of the states impose train-
53 percent of federal workers express satisfaction ing requirements on municipal and county employ-
with their training,151 compared with 62 percent of ees, focusing on police and fire fighters; only a small
private-sector workers.152 minority of states requires training for “other” local
This need for more training seems to be present employees.164
at every level of the federal service, from top, to
middle, to bottom. Nearly two-thirds of the Senior
Executive Service has not received “formal execu- Bolstering Bureaucrats’ Bravery
tive coaching,” a rising proportion,153 even though Whistleblowers, who are found in all sectors,
those with fewer than ten years of experience are a courageous (some would say crazy) class
ranked training and development third as “the key of employees who “blow the whistle” on their
driver of satisfaction and commitment, not pay.”154 organizations for engaging in shoddy or corrupt
More than a third of new supervisors receive no practices. (Persons who expose governments’ secu-
formal training at all, and, of the 64 percent who rity secrets—all national governments have such
are trained, almost half are trained for just a week secrets, and they have them for the same reason that
or less.155 The Secret Service’s uniformed officers middle-aged people wear clothes—do not qualify as
received an average of just twenty-five minutes of whistleblowers.)
306 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Encouraging Whistle Blowing The federal, state, soared by 56 percent, and, across the whole of gov-
and local governments have enacted laws that ernment, by 27 percent, “driven in large part due to
encourage whistle blowing. an onslaught of new cases from VA.”172

Federal Encouragement The most significant legis- Grass-Roots’ Encouragement Twenty-nine states
lation that Congress has passed is the 1986 amend- (nineteen of which and the District of Columbia
ments to the False Claims Act of 1863. They permit limit themselves to Medicaid fraud), Chicago,
the federal government to award whistleblowers New York, Philadelphia, and Allegheny County
from 15 to 30 percent of any money recovered from (in Pennsylvania) have enacted laws that reward
fraudulent practices, with the exception of tax fraud, whistleblowers.173
that they report in any federally funded contract or
program. The Whistleblowers The typical whistleblower
These amendments have been quite effective. in the public and private sectors is a well-educated
Prior to their passage, only three out of ten federal family man in his late forties who has been in his
workers who observed an illegal or wasteful activity organization about seven years and has a strong
reported it, but, following their enactment, fully half belief in “universal moral codes.”174 It has been
did so.165 A decade after their passage, more than authoritatively estimated that “80 percent of [gov-
1,100 companies were exposed by whistleblowers ernment] whistleblowers are motivated to improve
for defrauding the government, compared with just the system, not tear it down.”175 A slim 13 percent
twenty during the previous decade.166 of public workers who observe misconduct decline
The Tax Relief and Health Care Act of 2006 to report it, compared with 41 percent of nonprofit
extended the False Claims Act’s policies to whis- employees and 54 percent of private-sector employ-
tleblowers who report tax fraud involving at least ees.176
$2 million. Each year, the Internal Revenue Service Federal whistleblowers have a stronger public
(IRS) receives nearly 500 tips on more than 1,900 service motivation (described in Chapter 5), higher
alleged tax cheaters that meet this threshold,167 pay, and higher levels of education than those who
but “about 66 percent” of all claims that had been do not blow whistles,177 although it appears that
submitted three to four years earlier “were still in “senior-level [federal] employees . . . are less likely
process.”168 The IRS states that its lethargy is the to think they could report wrongdoing without
result of its extending greater appeals rights to those reprisal.”178
accused,169 but critics charge that enforcement “has
been hampered by excessive secrecy and contin- The Retaliators People exposed by whistleblowers
uing animosity within the agency’s old guard.”170 are more likely to retaliate when they perceive the
Still, nearly $2 billion was collected over four years whistleblowers to be “strong threats” to their egos
because of tax whistleblowers.171 or to “a prosperous system,” and possess high levels
The Fraud Enforcement and Recovery Act of of “Machiavellianism,” among other factors.179
2009 allows the feds to share pertinent informa- If the organization itself has “high levels of
tion with whistleblowers and state agencies, thereby group cohesiveness,” a “highly unethical climate,”
raising incentives and lowering barriers for prospec- or there exists a shared perception that unethical
tive whistle blowing. behavior is legitimate, then the probability of retali-
Despite these useful laws, it seems that the most ation also grows.180 The more entrenched the organ-
effective encouragement of whistleblowers occurs izational corruption, the more vicious the vengeance
within the agencies. When a new secretary of the leveled against those who expose it.181
Veterans Affairs Department (VA) was appointed to Anecdotal evidence suggests that government
turn around the scandal-plagued agency, scandals “supervisors who punish whistleblowers for report-
that had been exposed in 2014 by a whistleblower in ing wrongdoing rarely are punished themselves.”182
the first place, the secretary convincingly announced This was the case, for example, when a federal food
that he would protect whistleblowers, and then services manager blew the whistle on a fly infesta-
did so; within a year, VA whistleblower disclosures tion; his supervisors tried to fire him for eating four
Managing Human Capital 307

stale sandwiches, and then reassigned him to clean In 2015, the Supreme Court held that “inter-
a morgue for two years (including handling body preting the word ‘law’ to include rules and regula-
parts); there is no record of his supervisors being tions could defeat the purpose of the whistleblower
disciplined.183 statute” because it could permit an agency to insu-
late itself from prosecution for retaliation by simply
Shielding Whistleblowers Because whistle blowing writing a rule that prohibits whistleblowing. Hence,
can be rough, tough, and perilous, Congress and a federal employee could disclose “sensitive” infor-
state legislatures have taken steps to shield whistle- mation about an agency and be protected if the dis-
blowers from reprisals. Doing so is critically impor- closure violated no law, even though it did violate a
tant because the more that potential whistleblowers regulation.187
fear retaliation (which is the single most effective In sum, almost any whistleblower may report
damper in reporting misconduct184), the more that his or her concerns directly to an inspector general
misconduct flourishes in the organization.185 or to a congressional committee and be protected
from retribution.
Shielding Federal Whistleblowers The Civil Service
Reform Act of 1978 created, for the first time, spe- Not Shielding Federal Whistleblowers There is,
cific legal bans on retaliating against federal whistle- however, a notable chink in this shield: the vul-
blowers. Because not one case was made to protect nerability of whistleblowers in the intelligence
whistleblowers after 1979, a disgusted Congress community.
passed the stronger Whistleblower Protection Act in The Intelligence Community Whistleblower
1989. Protection Act of 1998 is so toothless (uniquely, it
More recent legislation includes the Notification contains no ban on reprisals) that the Pentagon’s
and Federal Employee Antidiscrimination and acting inspector general testified that the act’s title
Retaliation (No FEAR) Act of 2002, which requires is “a misnomer.”188 In 2012, Presidential Policy
agencies to be more accountable for violations Directive 19 shielded whistleblowers who have
of whistleblower protection laws. The American access to classified information, provided that
Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 shields they  exposed only waste, fraud, or abuse. Title VI
nonfederal employees from retaliation when they of the Intelligence Authorization Act of 2014 appears
expose wasteful, dangerous, or illegal acts in the to codify the directive, and expands portions of it.
use of economic recovery funds. The Whistleblower If, however, a whistleblower in the intelligence com-
Protection Enhancement Act of 2012, which munity discloses his or her concerns to the media,
passed unanimously in both chambers, significantly he or she is unprotected against retaliation and even
extended a variety of protections to whistleblow- criminal charges. Still lacking, however, is a clear,
ers. The National Defense Authorization Act of secure path for these whistleblowers to contact
2013 shields whistle-blowing subcontractors in the Congress directly and confidentially. Even so, there
Defense Department. has been a steady increase in the intelligence com-
There also has been a flurry of recent protections munity’s whistle blowing since the reforms were
that are not laws. In 2012, the Justice Department passed.189
appointed its first whistleblower ombudsman, who is
charged with protecting and educating whistleblow- Shielding Whistleblowers at the Grass Roots
ers government-wide. In 2013, the Whistleblower Thirty-seven states also have passed an odd
Protections Pilot Program was initiated to shield mishmash of laws that protect whistleblowers.
whistleblowers who worked for federal contractors, Twenty-one apply these laws to both public- and
subcontractors, and grantees; an official investiga- private-sector whistleblowers; eight state govern-
tion of complaints of reprisal by these employers ments and the District of Columbia protect only
“did not find that reprisal had occurred in any of their own employees; seven cover whistleblowers
them.”186 In 2014, a Senate Whistleblowers Caucus who work in any government, but none who are
was founded to assure that existing protections were privately employed; and one, North Dakota, shields
enforced in the agencies. only private-sector employees.190
308 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

The Court Steps In (It) In 2006, in Garcetti v. halved, and today just 3 percent perceive reprisals,194
Ceballos, the Supreme Court overruled, five-to-four, an inarguably low proportion when compared with
the lower court’s decision and held that Richard the private sector, where 15 percent (a rising per-
Ceballos, a local government whistleblower, was not centage) of workers believe that they were retaliated
protected from being “disciplined” (in reality, retal- against because they had reported misconduct.195
iated against—he had been reassigned, transferred,
and denied a promotion) under the First Amendment What Happens to Whistleblowers? Here is how
(the Freedom of Speech Clause) on the dubious dis- an unusually courageous federal whistleblower suc-
tinction that Ceballos had expressed his opinion as cinctly described his experience after he blew the
an employee (and a well-informed one), rather than whistle: “They shrivel you up.”196
as a citizen. If whistle blowing causes personal pain, however,
In 2014, the Court modestly modified its rather it also can bring personal gain. One such boon is
radical ruling, unanimously holding, in Lane v. emotional. Over four-fifths of whistleblowers in all
Franks, that public employees are protected from sectors, only 5 percent of whom reported “no retalia-
retaliation when they testify in court about miscon- tion,” say that they would do it again.197 As a govern-
duct that they observed in the workplace. ment whistleblower put it, “Finding honesty within
Garcetti had the potential to kill whistle myself was more powerful than I expected.”198
blowing; Lane may have reduced this prospective Another is financial. Washington alone has
death to a suppurating wound. awarded more than $2 billion to whistleblowers;
the average award is $1.5 million, with the largest
Have Legal Protections Helped? Despite awards topping $100 million.199
Garcetti, the new laws have protected whistleblow-
ers. Consider their sad lot before these statutes were Does Whistle Blowing Work? Whistle blowing
enacted. A survey of more whistleblowers than in works, but with the stipulation that there are not
“any previous survey” in all sectors (74 percent of many whistleblowers. Blown whistles account for
whom worked in governments and 5 percent in the only a “tiny” 9 percent of all the initial reports
independent sector), which was conducted just prior exposing unethical or illegal conduct in public agen-
to the passage of the Whistleblower Protection Act, cies, compared with 35 to 39 percent that result from
found that, after whistleblowers blew their whistles, “regular controls, accountants, [and] police.”200
95 percent of them in all sectors reported some form Although it is less effective when corruption is
of retaliation, ranging from harassment or transfer- deeply rooted, more than half of all whistle blowing,
ence (almost a fifth each) to losing their jobs (more regardless of sector, results in an external investiga-
than three-fifths).191 tion. More than three-fifths of whistleblowers saw
Subsequent legislation seems to have substan- evidence of positive change within their organiza-
tially alleviated this suffering. During the first year tions after they blew the whistle.201 Washington has
in which the Whistleblower Protection Act went into collected more than $48 billion as the direct result of
effect, there were more allegations of reprisals made blown whistles since 1987.202
by whistleblowers that were upheld by administra-
tive law judges than were upheld in the previous Whistle Blowing in the Independent Sector It may
ten years. Although about a fifth of federal civilian be the case that there are fewer whistles blown in the
employees consistently express “fear of reprisal” nonprofit sector because there may be less miscon-
should they disclose a “suspected violation of any duct in it than in the other two. At least employ-
law, rule or regulation,”192 few employees who actu- ees in all sectors think so: “an amazing” 82 percent
ally disclose such suspicions perceive subsequent of nonprofit employees think that their employers
reprisals. In 1989, the year that the act was passed, have  “strong moral values and principles,” com-
nearly 7 percent of federal whistleblowers who had pared with 30 percent of public employees and 60
disclosed “health/safety danger or unlawful behav- percent of private ones; comparable findings hold
ior” in their agencies felt that they were retaliated for additional indicators of organizational ethics
against.193 That figure has since been more than and practices.203
Managing Human Capital 309

Nevertheless, when a whistle is blown in a


nonprofit, retaliation far exceeds those in the other Keeping Competent Bureaucrats
sectors. Recall that just 3 percent of federal whistle- Have governments been able to retain their more tal-
blowers and 15 percent of corporate ones perceive ented employees?
retaliation, but about two-thirds of nonprofit whis-
tleblowers (a proportion that is roughly compara- Keeping Federal Talent Although about 1 percent
ble to federal retaliation rates, noted earlier, prior of federal employees claim that they plan to leave the
to the passage of the Whistleblower Protection Act government within the year, few actually do so.210
of 1989): lost their jobs or were forced to retire; Federal employees born after 1980 (who constitute
received negative job evaluations; or were black- 16 percent of federal civilian employees), however,
listed from getting another job in their fields, among seem relatively anxious to leave; their median time
other sanctions. And these were the punishment rates in the federal service is fewer than four years.211
for those nonprofit whistleblowers who reported Increasingly, this seems to be the case with
misconduct internally in their organizations; if they federal executives as well, nearly two-fifths of
exposed it to external sources, sanctions increased whom are approached with more lucrative job
from two-thirds to about three-quarters to four- offers outside of government. Although 26 percent
fifths. About a third reported that their retaliators of these officers state that they intend to leave their
were punished.204 agencies within the year, less than 10 percent do
so (still a stiff rate), compared with more than 13
percent of private-sector CEOs who leave their
Securing Bureaucrats’ Jobs companies.212
The popular image of the Civil Service System is
one of a job for life; 58 percent of Americans think Keeping State and Local Talent In state and local
that government offers better job security than busi- governments there is a brain drain. States are losing
ness, compared with 13 percent who say the same high-quality male employees and managers, and
for business versus government, or a factor of better local governments are losing high-quality minority
than four.205 Do, in fact, government employees and female employees and clerical workers.
actually have more secure jobs than private-sector Some good news: Almost a fourth of those
employees? federal, state, and local employees who leave their
You bet they do. governments land jobs in other governments.213
The median job tenure for workers in all gov-
ernments is 7.7 years, compared with 3.6 years in
the private sector, or less than half as long as gov- THE SLIPPAGE OF THE CIVIL
ernmental tenure.206 Over the course of a quarter
century, the median job tenure of public-sector SERVICE SYSTEM
workers grew from six years to seven, but that of It is manifestly apparent that, after decades of dom-
private-sector employees remained stuck at fewer inance, the Civil Service System is in trouble. The
than four years.207 reasons for this may be systemic and structural.
Americans commonly assume that the long Research consistently finds that the connection
tenures that job security brings equate with medio- between even a strongly professional personnel
cre performance. This is far from the case, at least in office and the development of organizational talent
government, for two reasons. to be, at best, obscure.214
First, multiple studies have found that greater job
security correlates clearly and positively with higher
productivity in governments,208 and, second, even A Faltering Federal Civil Service
when there is relatively little job security in the public Here is an insight into Washington’s civil service
sector, there is no “strong evidence” that managers problem: more than half of agency-based chief
take advantage of it by dismissing low-performing human capital officers “volunteered” in interviews
employees at a significantly accelerated rate.209 that “bold reform of our civil service system is
310 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

necessary.”215 Six years later, that figure had reached The core of the General Schedule, the job clas-
more than three-fifths.216 sification system, has just six specialists maintaining
its standards (a decrease of 166 percent over a dozen
A Slippage of Centralized Control The first indi- years), and just 3 percent of HR staffers spend more
cation of a deteriorating federal Civil Service System than half of their time on classification (73 percent
surfaced in 1994, when the Office of Personnel spend no time on it); about 30 percent of white-collar
Management shocked traditionalists by chucking job standards have not been updated since 1990.224
the revered, 10,000-page Federal Personnel Manual, The GS’s evisceration was so sudden, so swift, and so
which had been federal civil service policy for severe that “fragmentation within the civil service”
half a century, and replacing it with a web-based is now the rule.225
compilation of all personnel rules and laws that OPM’s marginalization correlates with a shrink-
amounted to  a tenth of its former self.217 In 1996, ing respect of it. Barely half, the lowest ranking out
OPM created in the agencies some 650 delegated of eight options, of “seasoned political appointees”
examining units, in which agency personnel perform think that managing their relationships with OPM
all hiring-related tasks but do not technically hire, is important.226 One out of three federal adminis-
although hiring is, in fact, done by the agencies. trators (the highest negative response in the survey)
During the 1990s, OPM eliminated nearly half of its complains that OPM accords them little or no help
employees, “a far greater reduction than that of any in recruiting, developing, or utilizing employees.227
other Federal agency,”218 and, from 1991 to 1998, Small wonder that, among the twenty-four major
personnel professionals in all federal agencies were federal agencies, OPM’s “employee engagement”
cut by a fifth.219 (i.e., morale) ranks eighteenth.228
The 2000s saw more change. The Chief Human
Capital Officers Act of 2002 mandated the appoint- Federal Human Capital Management: Dissed and
ment of chief human capital officers in all major Destroyed? In fact, there is a shrinking respect
agencies, and authorized OPM to grant direct-hire for personnel management in general, even among
authority to the agencies, which allows them, in cases HR managers! Although the most recent data show
of shortages of qualified applicants or emergencies, some improvement over four years, 19 percent of
to hire applicants without regard to standing civil chief human capital officers do not believe that their
service regulations. Although direct-hire authority “agency leadership” views their staffs as “trusted
accounts for a modest 2 percent of all hires,220 its business advisors,” rather than as clerical paper
significance in this context is its further undermining shufflers.229
of centralized control. The upshot of all this is that federal HR man-
At the same time, the agencies themselves were agement (sometimes called the “rule police” or the
decentralizing their personnel management. A poll of “department of no”) itself has been badly compro-
representative agencies found that all of them were mised. Nearly four-fifths of federal chief operating
using “alternative service delivery” (that is, entities officers, who have a uniquely broad perspective
other than the agency, in whole or part) for at least on their agencies’ administration, think that their
some of their “human capital activities.”221 agency has made very little or little (18 percent) or
moderate (59 percent) progress over the past two
OPM: Dissed and Destroyed? By the end of the years in “meeting its top priorities” in HR; these are
2000s, it was clear that OPM had lost it historic grip the most dismal statistics out of five management
on human resources. That iconic symbol of its power, areas plumbed.230
the General Schedule, which covered 98 percent of In 2001, the Government Accountability Office
federal civilian employees at its peak, in 1983, and placed “strategic human capital management” on
94 percent as late as 1995, applies to just 78 percent its government-wide high-risk list of programs that
today.222 (In OPM’s defense, it first called for an over- are unduly vulnerable to fraud, waste, abuse, and
haul of the GS in 2002.) About half of all civilian mismanagement, and it remains there today; worse,
workers are now exempt from at least some of the the topic is “directly mentioned” in eighteen of the
laws that associate with the Civil Service System.223 current list’s thirty-two high-risk areas (“most of the
Managing Human Capital 311

riskiest issues . . . are rooted in human capital”), and the states; “almost everything a state does is labor
HR “ranks as one of the areas where the least pro- intensive.”240
gress has been made.”231 But change was afoot. In 1996, Georgia initi-
Over twenty-five years, the proportion of federal ated civil service reforms that were the most sweep-
employees who were covered under personnel ing of any government at the time; other states
systems other than the General Schedule increased followed. Forty-seven states have decentralizaed
by more than three-fold, from 6 to 21 percent.232 hiring, transferring them from personnel bureaus to
“The federal government is quickly approaching the departments.241 Sixteen states have contracted
the point where ‘standard governmentwide’ human out at least some of their personnel services to the
capital policies and processes are neither standard private sector.242
nor governmentwide.”233 There has been a discernible decline in
In reviewing this sad research, one is reminded state-employee job security in thirty-one states,
of Catbert, the perennially “evil director of human twenty-eight of which have adopted, in whole or part,
resources” in the popular comic strip, Dilbert. at-will employment—that is, employees serve at the
sufferance of their supervisors sans protection  by
the merit system.243 Arizona, Colorado, Florida,
Civil Service Slippage at the Grass Roots Georgia, Tennessee, and Texas have, for all intents
For more than thirty years, Congress encour- and purposes, eliminated their civil services.244
aged state and local governments to adopt merit States most likely to implement these reforms
systems. The 1939 amendments to the Social tend to have relatively weak public unions,
Security Act of 1935 mandated that states estab- Republican-controlled governments, high adminis-
lish systems for  their  unemployment-security and trative245 and legislative professionalism, low unem-
public-assistance employees, or lose their Social ployment, and plentiful resources.246 “Electorally
Security funds. All states quickly complied. The dominant majorities” in legislatures prefer reform as
Intergovernmental Personnel Act of 1970 offered a means of gaining greater control of the bureau-
grants to subnational governments to expand and cracy, whereas “weaker majorities, foreseeing elec-
refine their civil services, but, as Congress grew toral loss,” resist reform as a means of insulating the
disenchanted with merit systems, funding vanished bureaucracy.247 The presence of a central oversight
within a decade. body charged with bringing coherence and con-
As in Washington, the Civil Service System’s sistency to state pay correlates with the successful
grass-roots’ reach peaked in the 1980s, when about implementation of reforms.248
three-fourths of the states had comprehensive merit Has the stature of state merit systems been dimin-
systems,234 and 60 percent of all state employees ished by these reforms? Yes. In 1983, the heads of per-
worked in them.235 Eighty-eight percent of cities sonnel agencies in thirty-nine states reported directly
with populations of more than 50,000 had merit to the governor,249 but two decades later, this held true
systems,236 and an estimated 95 percent of all mun- in only twenty states.250 Less than half of those states
icipal employees worked in them.237 with formal cabinets include the HR director in them,
These numbers would soon wither. By the and, increasingly, HR operations are being buried in
1990s, literally hundreds of grass-roots’ personnel administrative services departments.251 Georgia’s per-
reforms were in the offing.238 sonnel reforms, cited as the “most dramatic reforms”
of any state,252 were hailed by prestigious profession-
Civil Service Reform in the States: Radical and als as “likely the best in the country.”253
Revolutionary At the end of the first millen- There are, however, some benefits for civil ser-
nium, “the general picture that emerges [in state vices in reformed states. The more that governments
governments] is one of administrators trapped by decentralize human resource activities, the more that
rigid, slow, and cumbersome systems that are inca- “positive relationships” develop between “senior
pable of  meeting government’s human resources line managers” and human capital executives, and
needs.”239 This was especially unfortunate since per- these relationships increase HR’s influence and per-
sonnel is the single largest consumer of revenue in formance.254
312 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Civil Service Reform in Communities As with the true at the federal level, where morale in most agen-
states, personnel is localities’ largest single devourer cies has been in decline for years, a decline that may
of dollars, so it follows that civil service reform is be linked to the corresponding decline of HR man-
at the heart of local governmental reform; perhaps agement.264
70 percent of all local reforms relate to personnel It is notable, therefore, that just the reverse
policies.255 is happening in the private sector. “Over the past
Five percent (precisely the percentage it was 15 years . . . [there has been] a dramatic change.
thirty years earlier256) of cities and counties contract Today . . . HR chiefs report directly to the CEO,” and
out their “personnel services” to a for-profit corpo- experience as a human capital officer increasingly
ration, more than 1 percent are delivered by another leads to the CEO’s suite. This is happening because
government, and half a percent contract with a businesses are recognizing that HR management is
nonprofit organization. Nearly 9 percent of local crucial to the health of the company.265
governments deliver personnel services via “public Working on the assumption that the current fate
employees in part,” meaning that corporate or non- of public human capital management, at least at the
profit employees are involved, as well as the govern- federal level, is unlikely to improve any time soon,
ment’s own employees.257 what, if any, responsibilities make sense for the Civil
Service System to manage? The answer is those
human resource duties that are more efficiently
The Impact of Civil Service Reform managed by a central office, notably research, labor
Civil service reform has been remarkably successful. relations, compensation administration, and, most
The states, where reforms have been relatively especially, employee development and training.
radical, provide the best examples of this. Hiring, The Civil Service System does have a future.
promoting, reassigning, and firing have been stream- Nevertheless, it is a future that will require some
lined,258 and, although at-will employees are dis- adaptation.
missed more expeditiously than are employees who
are protected by civil service regulations, at-will
employment does not associate with greater numbers THE COLLECTIVE SYSTEM:
of employees being fired.259 State employees who
serve at will are “significantly less negative about BLUE-COLLAR BUREAUCRATS
the full range” of civil service reforms than are their Our second public human capital system is the
co-workers who are in the civil service,260 but state Collective System, and it refers primarily to blue-
personnel managers display, at best, only a rueful collar workers and white-collar professionals whose
acceptance and some distrust of at-will reform.261 jobs are administered via agreements between man-
An understandable concern among traditional- agement and organized workers. The core of the
ists was that reform would re-introduce unfettered Collective System is worker solidarity; in a word,
patronage to state government, but this has not hap- unions.
pened. “Patronage hiring appears to proceed along Efforts to organize public employees first sur-
typical levels,”262 and reforms have “not produced faced in the 1830s, and with reason: wages and
widespread concerns about politicization of an inde- working conditions typically were abysmal. For
pendent public service” among those senior state example, in 1907, New York’s health department
administrators who are charged with preventing its condemned 35 percent of the city’s fire stations as
politicization.263 uninhabitable, and fire fighters worked twenty-one
hours a day and had only one day off in eight.266

A Modest Proposal
We have noted that a sad consequence of public per- The Scope of Organized Labor
sonnel reform is that HR directors, and the enter- With the passage, in 1935, of the National Labor
prise of public human capital in general, often are Relations Act (the Wagner Act), which guaranteed
sidelined, ignored, or dissed. This seems especially private-sector workers the rights to unionize, bargain
Managing Human Capital 313

collectively, and strike, unions surged forward. At on the level of government, representation by unions
its apex, in 1953, organized labor included almost is about 3 to 5 percent higher than is membership
a third of all nonagricultural employees in the in them. Overall, members of public unions earn
nation.267 somewhat more than do employees represented by
Since then, union membership has shrunk to a unions; a marginal exception is the federal govern-
third of its former self, accounting for 11 percent of ment, where the reverse is true.277
all workers,268 a proportion not seen since the Great
Depression of the early 1930s, when Americans were The Third-Sector Collective System Unions are
just looking for work, not justice at work. the least represented in nonprofits; just 6 percent this
workforce is organized, where they concentrate in
Public Employees: Labor’s Life-Blood Union colleges and hospitals.278
membership would be far lower were it not for the
public sector. In 1953, 36 percent of private-sector
employees, and 12 percent of public-sector workers, A Unique Value
were organized.269 Since then, private-sector union The distinctive value of the Collective System is
membership has shriveled, and stands at less than 7 (you guessed it!) collectivism, a value that places it
percent of private-sector employees.270 at odds with each of the other four human capital
By contrast, union membership in governments systems.
is five times that of the private sector. Since 1953, The other systems contend that the state is sov-
unions’ share of the public workforce has almost ereign, and therefore its workers may not challenge
tripled to over 35 percent and now virtually equals it. The Collective System, by contrast, holds that the
labor’s 1953 slice of private-sector workers.271 state is not sovereign, and that public employees
Forty-nine percent of all union members work for have the right to collectively challenge it to improve
governments.272 their working conditions. The Seventh Circuit Court
of Appeals strengthened this position by ruling, in
The Federal Collective System In 1912, with 1968, that regulations prohibiting public employees
the passage of the Lloyd-La Follette Act, federal from organizing are unconstitutional.279
employees secured the right to organize and to peti- The other public personnel systems also hold
tion Congress to redress their grievances. In 1978, that the individual worker be judged on the basis
Congress made an exception in the form of Public of his or her work’s quality and productivity.
Law 95-610, which bans unionization of the armed The Collective System argues that the individual
forces. Twenty-seven percent of all federal civilian employee should be absorbed in a collective effort to
employees273 belong to about 125 unions or similar better the conditions of all workers.
organizations in roughly 2,200 bargaining units, Among the conflicts that result from these fun-
figures that have remained fairly constant over the damental differences are disputes over: employee
years.274 participation and rights (equal treatment versus
union shop); recruitment (competitive selection
The Grass-Roots Collective System Thirty percent versus union membership); pay (job analysis versus
of state employees and 41 percent of local workers negotiation); working conditions (determination by
are members of unions.275 Fire fighters have long led legislatures and management versus negotiation);
the list as the most heavily organized public employ- and grievances (determination by personnel special-
ees, followed by teachers and police. These and other ists versus union representation to third-party arbi-
grass-roots employees are represented by nearly trators).
34,000 bargaining units.276

Representation versus Membership All public Want to Fire Your Boss?


unions represent slightly more workers than those Collectivism correlates with a unique employee–
who actually are members of them. Unions repre- employer relationship that is found only in govern-
sent 39 percent of all public employees; depending ment. Union members are bargaining for benefits
314 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

with elected bosses whose jobs they can threaten, or Federal Bargaining Washington bitterly battled
effectively fire, through elections. As a long-serving bargaining with unions for the better part of the
elected official put it, “You learned pretty quickly twentieth century, but, in 1962, Executive Order
that you don’t want to upset these guys.”280 10988 declared peace by stating that certain condi-
Although the American Federation of State, tions of employment could be negotiated collectively.
County and Municipal Employees (AFSCME) long The Federal Service Labor-Management Relations
has been among the biggest spenders in federal elec- Reform Statute of 1978 cast into law the right of
tions, and often the biggest spender,281 public labor’s federal employees to bargain.
political power can be overstated. Private-sector In 1993, Executive Order 12871 significantly
unions’ ability to get out the vote long has dwarfed expanded the scope of issues that unions could nego-
that of government unions, which chalk up relatively tiate and created a National Partnership Council of
few electoral wins at the federal and state levels.282 union members and management to resolve issues.
Locally, however, public unions are more suc- In 2001, Executive Order 13203 repealed Executive
cessful at the ballot box (although it appears that Order 12871 and decentralized to the agencies
teachers’ unions are in decline as an electoral force). the authority to adopt a labor-relations strategy
Depending on the methodology used, local gov- best suited to their needs, tilting federal negotia-
ernment employees’ turnout in municipal elections tion policies more in favor of management.287 In
exceeds general turnout by 4 to 5 percent, or by 11 2009, Executive Order 13522 created the National
to 12 percent if they live in the locality for whose Council on Federal Labor Management Relations,
government they work.283 Moreover, local gov- which effectively reinstated the disbanded National
ernment unions also can “significantly affect the Partnership Council, but with three additional union
turnout levels” of sympathetic voters who are not members, and the president signed a memorandum
local government employees.284 that returned to the policies expressed in Executive
Order 12871 of 1993.

Bargaining with Governments Grass-Roots Bargaining Although Congress long


Collective bargaining, or collective negotiations, is a ago addressed collective negotiations for private-
method in which representatives of employees and sector and federal workers, it has never done so for
employers jointly make policies about employees’ the grass-roots governments, leaving them to their
working terms and conditions. own devices. In 1958, New York City became the
The number of all workers covered by a collec- first major local government to legalize collective
tive bargaining agreement peaked in 1979, and, over bargaining with unions. In 1959, Wisconsin passed
the ensuing thirty-four years declined by 47 percent the first state law allowing public employees (specif-
to 16 million. Historically, collective bargaining ically, its municipal workers) to bargain collectively.
has largely been the preserve of the private sector Ironically, Wisconsin, in 2011, pioneered a radical
(in 2002, for example, 66 percent of all government reduction in the number and types of public workers
workers had negotiating rights, compared with 78 who could negotiate collectively, withdrawing col-
percent in the private sector285), but, in 2009, this lective-bargaining rights from essentially all its state
relationship reversed for the first time, and the public and local employees, save those in public safety posi-
sector had over 9 percent more workers covered by tions, and enacting anti-union right-to-work legisla-
negotiated agreements than did the private one. By tion; four years later, the state’s union members in all
2013, the traditional pattern had reestablished itself, sectors was down by more than two-fifths, “mostly
and businesses had nearly 10 percent more workers teachers [whose union had shrunk by 30 percent]
who bargained collectively (8.1 million) than did and other public workers.”288
governments (7.9 million). Of those public employ- Currently, thirty-four states and the District of
ees who are covered by a negotiated agreement, 59 Columbia require collective bargaining for some
percent work for a local government, 27 percent for or all public employees. In eleven states, collective
the states, 8 percent are federal civilian employees, bargaining is permitted, and in five it is prohib-
and 6 percent are Postal Service workers.286 ited,289 three of which stipulate that meet-and-confer
Managing Human Capital 315

negotiations be used instead.290Meet-and-confer government is an exception, where unionized


negotiations require that both sides must talk with employees earn slightly less, on average, than non-
each other, but management has the final decision. union employees.300
About a dozen states have passed laws requiring Among state workers, however, “state employee
goldfish-bowl, or sunshine, bargaining, in which union density [is] the most consistent and impor-
the public is made aware of negotiations as they are tant determinant of compensation,”301 and those in
happening.291 unions are paid 12 percent more, on average, than
Ninety-four percent of all cities engage in collec- those who are not. Organized labor brings home the
tive bargaining,292 and twenty-eight states authorize bacon for primarily blue-collar local workers, where
their counties to bargain collectively.293 union members average 25 percent more than non-
union workers,302 and in some cities they are paid
Mediation, Conciliation, and Arbitration Should double their private-sector counterparts.303
labor and management reach an impasse, mediation, The dramatic differences in union and non-
or the voluntary use of an impartial third party to union pay, at least at the grass roots, obscure some
resolve differences and suggest compromises, can underlying factors that mitigate these disparities.
be introduced. Conciliation is an option, too, and The wage increases negotiated by public-sector
it differs from mediation in that the third party may unions generally have less of a financial impact on
not suggest solutions to problems. their governments than the increases negotiated by
Should mediation or conciliation fail, arbi- private-sector unions have on their companies,304
tration, which is a formal process of hearings and which may explain why, out of twenty-six policy
fact finding, may be brought in. Arbitration may priorities, city managers rank “staff unions” a lowly
be voluntary, in which both sides agree beforehand twenty-third.305 Of eleven “spending areas” in 162
to accept the arbitrator’s decision, or compulsory, large cities, spending for salaries and wages as a
or binding, in which both sides must, under law, share of general expenditures withered over twenty-
accept as final the arbitrator’s decision. In 2001, the five years, declining from an average of 50 percent
Supreme Court ruled that employers may compel to 43 percent. The cities’ spending per capita on pay
their workers to take job-related disputes to arbi- increased by only a fifth, whereas average spending
tration.294 across the board grew by almost twice that rate;
Twenty-one states and the District of Columbia municipal employee pay is statistically tied with the
require arbitration,295 and public workers favor long-benighted budgets of local public libraries for
it. Nearly a fourth of all their grievances contain a the lowest rate of growth.306
demand for arbitration,296 and public unions con-
sistently win more arbitrations than private-sector
unions.297 Arbitration, however, does have a singular Striking Government
public benefit: it seems to be more effective in mini- There is scant agreement on whether public employ-
mizing strikes by government workers than are prohi- ees have a right to strike, with some arguing that
bitions against striking and penalties for doing so.298 striking is an act of insurrection, and others contend-
ing that it is a fundamental freedom. The courts have
held that there is no constitutional right of public
Pay and Public Unions workers to strike, but neither has the judiciary pro-
Public unions long have devoted full-time staffs to hibited the enactment of laws permitting them to
analyzing governments’ budgets with an eye toward strike.
winkling out more money for their members, and
with some success, although “the effects of unions Striking Washington The Taft-Hartley Act of 1947
on compensation are smaller in the public than in was the first legislation to prohibit strikes by federal
the private sector.”299 employees. In 1970, more than 210,000 postal
Overall, unionized public employees earn workers violated the law by staging an unprece-
15 percent more pay than workers who are not dented walkout; the Labor Department met almost
union members. The heavily white-collar federal all their demands, and the strike was over in just
316 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

two weeks. A nonplussed Congress soon divested 1990s, fewer than five per year in the 2000s, and
itself of its postal problem by passing the Postal barely four per year, 2010–2015.312
Reorganization Act of 1970, which transformed the
Post Office Department, a federal agency, into the
Postal Service, a federal corporation. More broadly, Days of Glory . . . Gone
Congress reasserted its anti-strike policy with the The glory days of unionized government workers
Civil Service Reform Act of 1978, which forbids have been waning since the early eighties. By the
strikes and slowdowns by federal employees. mid-1990s, it was apparent that “public sector
In 1981, however, 95 percent of the 13,000 unionism . . . has topped out, both in membership
members of the Professional Association of Air and market share,” with declines evident in both.313
Traffic Controllers (PATCO), possibly justifiably, These declines accelerated in the 2010s. State
probably arrogantly, and certainly foolishly, struck. governments, mostly in the Midwest and South,
President Ronald Reagan promptly decertified began passing laws designed to rein in public unions,
PATCO—that is, the federal government no longer and these laws correlate positively with falling union
recognized PATCO as the official representative membership.314
of its members—and dismissed more than 11,000 These currents are occurring within a larger
air traffic controllers, breaking their union in the culture of growing anti-unionism, but particu-
process. Reagan’s decertification was historic, and larly anti-public unionism. Pluralities of Americans
arguably strengthened the hand of all governments support “changing state laws to limit the bargain-
in dealing with unions. ing power of state employee unions” (49 percent),
and believe that states in which government workers
Striking the Grass Roots Thirteen states directly belong to unions are generally “more harmful” than
protect their public employees’ right to strike (eleven helpful to those states (46 percent).315 Teachers’
states include teachers307), although all of them unions are the canary in the coal mine in these
place clear restrictions (most commonly, prohibit- trends, with public disapproval of them growing by
ing strikes by public safety workers) on that right. A 29 percent in just four years,316 states increasingly
dozen states cover state and local employees; Rhode weakening teachers’ job security,317 and teachers’
Island’s law applies only to state workers.308 union membership shrinking.318
During the 1960s and 1970s, strikes by state
and local workers surged, reflecting unions’ indiffer-
ence toward the taxpayers who paid their members’ A Threatening Court?
wages. When asked where the money for higher Adding to public labor’s woes about a disaffected
pensions for his members would be coming from, public is the Supreme Court’s apparent backtracking
a union officer replied, revealingly, “That’s the gov- in its longstanding support of unions, both public
ernment’s problem. Just because there is a pinch and private. The dominant decisions in the Court’s
for money, it’s no excuse to make the employees do backtrack, however, have all focused on public
without.”309 unions.
Labor’s arrogance attenuated in 1979, when In 1977, the Court ruled, in Abood v. Detroit
New Orleans’ police struck just prior to Mardi Gras, Board of Education, that employees could not be
effectively canceling the holiday and costing the city forced to join a union that used its dues to advance a
millions. This stunning gaffe focused the public’s political agenda with which they disagreed because
perception of organized labor’s gluttony, and con- doing so would violate the First Amendment (the
tributed to a dramatic shrinking of its power. Major Freedom of Expression clause). Still, because unions
strikes and work stoppages by government workers represented these employees, who benefitted from
toppled from their peak in that year—when there the unions’ collective bargaining agreements as
were 583 of them310—and never recovered. The much as union members did, they nevertheless were
number of strikes and stoppages by state and local required to pay their “fair share” of union dues that
employees, which averaged 340 per year during the were not spent on political activities; mostly, “fair-
1970s,311 averaged six a year during the 1980s and share fees” cover the costs of collective bargaining.
Managing Human Capital 317

Fair-share fees, or agency fees, or union-security city employees today that it had then—some seven
fees, are union fees paid by employees who are not decades ago!
members of unions but are represented by them, and But there is some systemic evidence that also
they amount to less than union dues—often, not suggests unions undermine governments’ efficiency
much less, and many observers think that the fees and effectiveness. Over eight years, “the price of state
are critical to union finances. and local public services has increased 41 percent
Those twenty-five states that do not require fair- nationally compared with 27 percent in private ser-
share payments are right-to-work states; they do not vices,”320 although it is unclear how much of this
require workers to join unions in union shops, and disparity is attributable to public unions.
have effectively banned fair-share payments. Other data provide clearer linkages. For
The Court reaffirmed its foundational decision example, “there is an association between strong
in Abood, and, with it, fair-share payments, in at least teachers’ unions and lower student performance,”321
four subsequent decisions over the ensuing forty or perhaps because unions may protect some teachers’
so years. Then, in 2014, the Court held, five-to-four, abuse of their responsibilities; a startling 27 percent
in Harris v. Quinn, that home-healthcare workers of full-time teachers are “chronically absent,”
were not “full-fledged public employees” because defined as missing eleven or more days of regular
they could be hired and fired by the people whom classes, with some school districts reporting that
they were assisting—even though most of these more than 75 percent of their teachers are chroni-
workers are not paid by their patients and are paid cally absent.322
instead by Medicaid, a federal program. Though On the other hand, here is a little-known corre-
narrow in scope, Harris directly threatened unions lation: the deeper a public employee’s commitment
in those states that require fair-share payments, and to his or her union, the greater the employee’s job
“suggested that a majority [of the Court] was sick satisfaction, the higher his or her public service moti-
and tired of this Abood nonsense, and might be vation, and the lower his or her perception of red
grateful if someone—anyone—would bring them a tape.323 (Recall from Chapter 4 that a public work-
case that would drive a stake through its heart.”319 er’s perception of a lot of red tape associates with
In 2016, the Supreme Court was brought job disengagement and dissatisfaction, risk aversion,
just such a case: Friedrichs v. California Teachers resentment, and alienation.)
Association. To the surprise of many, the Court When we consider, however, the negatives asso-
deadlocked, four-to-four, effectively letting stand ciated with public unions—e.g., costly pensions and
a lower court ruling that had upheld Abood. The healthcare benefits (noted in Chapter 8), self-serving
deadlock was the result of the death of a conserv- political pressure exerted on elected officials, higher
ative justice, in 2016, and the Senate’s odd refusal costs for the grass-roots governments, strikes and
to conduct hearings on his replacement until 2017. slowdowns (considerably fewer than in the 1970s,
Friedrichs is unlikely to be the final word on Abood. but still disruptive), popular disdain of public unions
that arguably affects adversely governments’ pro-
ductivity—then public unions may subtract more
Are Public Unions Good or Bad for the than they add to efficient and effective governance.
Public? A Summing Up
Many of us have long heard anecdotal accounts of
the high costs of public unions to governments and THE POLITICAL EXECUTIVE
taxpayers, such as California’s prison guards’ union SYSTEM: POLICYMAKING
which lobbied so successfully for more prisons and AND POLITICS IN PUBLIC
stricter sentencing, and, hence, more prisons, more
prisoners—and more guards—that 11 percent of ADMINISTRATION
the state’s budget now goes to the penal system, sur- The Political Executive System fixates on policy—
passing higher education’s percentage. Or Buffalo, that is, developing and implementing a policy
New York, which has lost half of the population agenda for the elected chief executive. Political
that it had in 1950, but retains the same number of executives—“the true nexus between politics and
318 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

administration”324—are those public officials “application process discourages high-quality candi-


appointed to an office without tenure, and who have dates from applying.”337
significant policymaking powers. “The cascade of failures that have beset the
federal government [is] rooted, first and foremost,
in the appointments process and the vacancies it so
Political Executives in Washington often produces.”338
There are some 9,000 federal full- and part-time jobs
whose occupants’ tenure expires with the president’s The Rise of the White House Loyalty Test In the
term; many are appointments to obscure boards 1960s, the appointment of political executives was “a
and commissions.325 About 4,100 of these “politi- highly centralized and personalized process revolv-
cal” jobs are for executives who are nominated or ing around the respective department and agency
appointed by the president, and who serve at the heads,” and when a rare difference of opinion arose
president’s pleasure;326 these positions have bal- between the secretary and the White House staff
looned by fourteen-fold since 1960.327 To place this over a candidate, “the secretary generally won.”339
number in perspective, their counterparts in Britain, Beginning in the 1970s, however, the White
France, and Germany each number about 100.328 House grew increasingly intrusive. As a result, “the
Article II, Section 2, of the Constitution requires views of politically appointed officials more and
that 1,212 of these positions (e.g., cabinet secretar- more closely resembled the . . . party and ideology
ies, ambassadors) be nominated by the president and . . . of the administration they were serving.”340
confirmed by the Senate,329 up from seventy-one in No one can reasonably dispute the desirability
1933.330 of a democratically elected chief executive establish-
ing his or her control over the executive branch, and
Baroquely Burdensome: The Appointment Process appointing loyalists can be an important means for
“The senior executive hiring process is broken.”331 doing so. But appointing loyalists, let alone compe-
The time to acquire a Senate confirmation of a tent loyalists, is far more challenging than often is
nominee has more than doubled since the 1980s, realized. A former presidential personnel assistant,
when it averaged fewer than four months, to nearly who was notorious for his obsession with political
eleven months in the 2010s.332 “At least half of the control of the civil service, admitted, “It’s an awfully
delays appear to involve bureaucratic red tape and difficult job just to handle the presidential appoin-
duplication of effort,” and a fourth involve inappro- tees . . .. if you try to do too much, you may be
priate senatorial interference.333 In 2004, the Senate diluted to the point where you’re not as effective.”341
rejected reforms proposed by the House.
In 2013, a frustrated Senate finally voted to Politicization’s Presidential Peak Scholars gener-
effectively confirm presidential nominees by a ally agree that the two administrations of President
simple majority vote, rather than by a two-thirds George W. Bush (2001–2009) were the culmination
vote, which had been its practice for more than 200 of the “politicized presidency” in recent history, and
years. Still, the process remains remarkably stymied. they exemplify how political loyalty corrodes profes-
In 2015, a fourth (103) of the top 379 Cabinet-level sional competence; a comparison of Bush’s political
positions were vacant, and the Senate had confirmed appointees versus his professional appointees, using
the lowest number of non-military positions during the Bush administration’s own performance rating
the first session of Congress in nearly thirty years.334 system, found that agency performance suffered,
Almost a fourth of presidential appointees measurably and deeply, under the political appoin-
describe the appointments process (which demands tees.342 (We are not suggesting that federal politiciza-
that candidates answer as many as 1,000 congres- tion evaporated after 2009, as the State Department
sionally-imposed written questions that test “for would seem to demonstrate on occasion,343 but
almost everything but a candidate’s qualifications politicization clearly was less in the Barack Obama
for service”335) as “embarrassing” and a fifth find administration than it was at its peak.)
it “confusing.”336 Over two-fifths, a growing plu- In the Bush White House, “substantive policy
rality, of senior executives think that their own discussions were rare, and were routinely trumped
Managing Human Capital 319

by political considerations.” Ultimately, Bush’s expense of experience, professionalism, and compe-


demand for loyalty “constituted a direct challenge tence. What have been the results?
to the possibility of competence” ever encroaching
into his administration.344 An Uncaring Elite? Over five decades, the average
Bush’s demand was felt throughout the bureau- percentages of presidential appointees who thought
cracy. From 2000 to 2007, federal employees’ per- that “accomplishing important public objectives”
ceptions that they had “experienced coercion related brought them the most satisfaction plummeted
to political activity in the preceding 2 years” nearly by more than three-fifths, and bottomed out at a
doubled, an unprecedented spurt in its growth rate. remarkably modest 15 percent.351 Of seventeen
(It rebounded to its 2000 level in 2010.)345 factors affecting these executives’ length of tenure
When Hurricane Katrina slammed into the Gulf in office (which, as we detail later, is extraordinarily
Coast, in 2005, the administration’s systemic incom- brief), the “least important” is “resources,” suggest-
petence became painfully and publicly obvious. Its ing little interest among them in actually achieving
response amounted to a catastrophic opera buffa anything; in fact, even “a very large increase” in their
that “crystallized negative perceptions” about a budgets would only “moderately” influence them to
“bungling administration” that were “far from fully extend their service.352
realized before Katrina hit.”346 In the year follow-
ing Katrina, a Pew survey found that “the term most An Avaricious Elite? Fully 30 percent of presiden-
frequently associated with the president was ‘incom- tial appointees state that, once appointed, they earn
petent.’”347 “a lot more” money, and only 6 percent earn “a lot
The Federal Emergency Management Agency less.”353 When better-paid positions outside of gov-
(FEMA) was the chief bureau that dealt with ernment are offered, these appointees snap them up:
Katrina’s aftermath. It was headed by a political the “primary” determinant of how long they stay in
appointee with no prior experience in emergency office is whether or not they are offered larger sala-
management (this had been mostly the norm ever ries elsewhere.354
since FEMA’s founding, in 1974348), and, although When no outside offers are dangled, some polit-
Bush brayed that FEMA’s director was “doin’ a ical executives, in violation of policy, “burrow in”
heckuva job” in responding to the crisis, public to civil-service-protected positions. President Jimmy
outrage forced the director’s resignation two months Carter initiated, in the 1970s, an ongoing effort to
following the hurricane. Even in Katrina’s woebe- discourage the practice, but burrowers subsequently
gone wake, however, Bush remained determined more than tripled in fewer than five decades.355 More
to assure a politicized FEMA. In signing the Post- recently, an audit of thirty agencies found that, in
Katrina Emergency Management Reform Act of twenty-eight of them, sixty-nine political executives
2006, which required that future FEMA directors be burrowed in from 2010 through 2015.356
professionally qualified, Bush issued a “signing state-
ment” in which he insisted that he was not legally An Inept Elite? Should we be surprised that just
bound to appoint qualified directors. 11 percent of political executives themselves think
Why destroy an agency whose singular mission that their colleagues “represent the best and the
is to save lives that are in imminent danger? “Why,” brightest that America has to offer”?357
asked a former presidential chief of staff, “politicize More than a quarter century ago, only 18
FEMA when you’ve got Commerce?”349 percent of the Senior Executive Service’s retired
By the close of his presidency, public approval careerists believed that political appointees had
of Bush’s performance was “the lowest in the Gallup “good leadership qualities,” and just 15 percent
Poll’s history.”350 thought that they had “good management skills.”
Sixty-three percent of these executives who had been
Fifty Years of Politicization For roughly fifty years supervised by “noncareer” political appointees cited
(the following studies cover, altogether, 1964–2016), the “politicization” of their agencies as their “reason
presidential appointments commonly (but not for leaving,” compared with just 37 percent of those
always) tilted toward loyalty and politicization at the who reported to careerist, non-political appointees;
320 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

half of the former group stated that they left because intense,”364 a demoralization that appears to be
of their immediate supervisors’ “incompetence” based on fact. The more political executives there
versus a third of the latter; and 46 percent of those are in a federal agency, the lower employee produc-
who reported to political appointees attributed their tivity: “Each additional political appointee reduces
departure to their “ethical concerns about practices individual employee performance by .002” on an
at higher agency levels,” compared with 30 percent eleven-point scale.365 As we detailed in Chapter
of those who reported to careerists.358 (It is of note, 7, even inspectors general, who are charged with
in this last regard, that political appointees receive increasing efficiency, can be politicized, and, when
half the amount of training in merit system princi- they are, productivity suffers.
ples and prohibited personnel practices than do new These realities have not been lost on federal
federal supervisors;359 in a fifth of agencies, political career executives, who have grown more rule bound,
appointees receive no training in these areas.360) clerical, and hermitic, communicating less with
Times have not changed much since. Currently, “other sectors of government or with other actors in
60 percent of SES members who were in the process the political system.”366 These limiting self-percep-
of leaving government (97 percent of whom were tions are reinforced by a federal culture that stresses
doing so voluntarily) cited the “political environ- technical skills (14 percent, and growing, of senior
ment” as the reason for their departure, with 42 executives report that more than 55 percent of their
percent stating that it was a factor to a “great” or work is of “a technical/professional nature”) over
“very great extent,” followed by “senior leadership,” leadership (just 10 percent, and declining, say that
at 53 percent, and “organizational culture,” at 51 more than 55 percent their work is of “an advisory
percent.361 Each of these reasons has an obvious, nature to top management”).367 The regrettable result
and negative, linkage with the competence of polit- is that federal personnel are promoted to senior posi-
ical appointees. tions “even if they do not have executive ability.”368
It seems clear that too many political appoin- We see this possible decline in executive ability
tees are in over their heads. After more lucrative job reflected in polls. The percentage of federal chief
offers, their main motivation to leave government is human capital officers who think that a presidential
“the difficulty of public administration”—in other “focus on improving the SES is needed” (67 percent)
words, they find managing federal agencies to be is more than triple that of those who think not (19
just too, too hard.362 Perhaps this is the reason why, percent).369 Over five years, from 50 to 54 percent of
unlike the other 2.1 million federal civilian employ- federal employees expressed “a high level of respect
ees, the 4,000-odd political executives are not subject for my organization’s senior leaders.”370 A slender
to annual assessments of their performance. 22 percent of them think that “overall,” members of
the SES are “effective leaders most of the time”; 26
A Failed Elite? Despite monumental presiden- percent believe that they are “not effective leaders”
tial efforts to hire loyalists who will unwaveringly at all, and another 25 percent think that they are
implement their agendas, political executives are “effective leaders less than half of the time.” More
not much good at it. The “primary result” of a thor- than three-quarters of federal executives and man-
oughgoing analysis of them is that “ideological allies agers state that “there is a problem with the SES,”
rarely make optimal appointees.”363 Fulfilling presi- three-fifths believe that the government would be
dential agendas is done by public administrators, not “better off” or “the same” “without the SES,” and
by partisan hacks. more than half would refuse a promotion, if offered,
to the SES (27 percent would accept),371 despite the
The Costs of Incompetent Political Executives fact that more than three-fourths agree that “SES
Presidents’ preferences for politicized loyalists over positions in their agencies are viewed as prestig-
much of the past five decades have harmed the ious.”372 According to a member of the SES, joining
federal government’s management capacity in sur- it “used to be an honor. Now it’s a joke.”373 The
prisingly systemic ways. problem has grown so grave, and so obvious, that,
The federal workforce’s “decline in morale in 2015, the president announced some needed, but
is sharpest where politicization has been most limited, reforms to the SES.
Managing Human Capital 321

It has not always been like this. The federal four-fifths of municipalities’ elections are nonpar-
service historically has boasted smart, visionary, tisan. Nonpartisan ballots are universal in school
tenacious, and tough executives, who, against enor- districts, and this seems to be the case in special dis-
mous odds, accomplished great things. Those federal tricts as well, although 44 percent of special districts’
administrative heroes (the noun is no exaggeration) boards have no elected members whatsoever, only
chronicled in Ken Burns’ documentary, “America’s appointed ones, a rising trend.376
Best Idea,” who created the world’s first national The number of mayors who hold the exclusive
parks system and who often sacrificed their health power to develop municipal budgets sank by 35
and wealth in the effort, exemplify the federal service percent over fifteen years, and today just 11 percent
at its finest. retain this authority.377 Mayors who possess the sole
Is this selfless, courageous class of federal exec- power to appoint department heads declined by 37
utives still with us? percent over ten years, and only 17 percent still have
this capability.378

Political Executives at the Grass Roots The Entry of Professionalism As politicization


In contrast to developments in Washington, in passes, professionalism enters.
the political executive systems of state and local
governments politicization is down and profession- In State Governments In the states, interest in
alism is up. developing a cadre of professional public exec-
utives  bloomed in the 1960s as part of admin-
The Passing of Politicization The Supreme istratively-inspired reorganizations that swept
Court has been involving itself in the area of most state governments for three decades.379 Four
patronage-based political appointments since 1976, states  had executive personnel systems in place
and the clear drift of judicial opinion is one of reduc- before Washington founded its Senior Executive
ing the power of patronage at the grass roots. Service, in 1978, and at least fourteen states now
have them.380
In State Governments Perhaps the most important In 1964, fewer than two-thirds of state agency
anti-patronage decision is the Supreme Court’s 1990 heads had a bachelor’s degree (by contrast, nine-
ruling in Rutan v. Illinois Republican Party, in which tenths of their federal equivalents had completed
the Court banned party affiliation as a factor in the college381). Two decades later, these administrators
hiring, promoting, or transferring of most of Illinois’ had attained educational parity with their federal
60,000 gubernatorial appointees. (As this large counterparts, and today 95 percent have a baccalau-
number suggests, few gubernatorial appointees are reate degree or higher.382
political executives; most are of humbler station.) Another criterion of professionalism is commit-
The governor of Illinois was shocked, saying the ment to a career, and this they have. State agency
decision “turns politics on its head.”374 heads have worked in their governments for a
States that traditionally have had a lot of polit- median of eighteen years, and thirteen years in their
ical appointees—Illinois, Indiana, Massachusetts, agencies. Their years in service have grown by a
New York, North Carolina, Pennsylvania, and West third over fifty or so years.383
Virginia—have taken steps to reduce the power As with federal careerists, senior state career
of partisan politics in their personnel systems as a administrators worry over the quality of their polit-
direct consequence of Rutan. “Nobody wants to be ical executives. A tiny 4 percent of these officials
sued. They tend to pay attention to a major decision agree that “increased numbers of political appoin-
like this.”375 tees enhance [state] government effectiveness,” and
an overwhelming 80 percent disagree (24 percent
In Local Governments What is true for the “strongly” so) that they do.384
states is even more in evidence among local gov-
ernments. Although partisan elections are still In Local Governments Local governmental inter-
used by more than four-fifths of counties, nearly est in developing a deep pool of executive talent
322 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

associates with their dramatically accelerating adop- public sector organizations suggest that it can often
tion, beginning immediately after World War II, of take at least 5 to 7 years before the initiatives are
the council-manager plan and similarly professional fully implemented and the related cultures are trans-
forms of government. formed in a sustainable manner.”391
Top local administrators are well educated and If public executives were to stay only briefly in
experienced. Only 2 percent of city managers lack office, Alexander Hamilton wrote, it would “occa-
a bachelor’s degree; a fifth has only a bachelor’s sion a disgraceful and ruinous mutability in the
degree; and nearly four-fifths hold advanced degrees. administration of government.”392
Fifty-one percent hold a master of public adminis- Arguably, it has.
tration degree.385
As with state agency heads, local chief admin- Sector and Experience Matter A hoary myth, at
istrative officers are in it for the longer haul, and least in Washington, is that political executives, with
have worked for local government for an average of their lifetimes of cosmopolitan administrative expe-
nearly twenty-one years.386 riences in a rich variety of settings, administer better
than career federal executives. Do they?
No. A seminal analysis of 242 federal bureau
Experience and Sector: Our New chiefs found that politically-appointed chiefs got
Understanding of Public Executive Quality “systematically lower management grades than
Who manages better, political appointees or career bureau chiefs drawn from the civil service.” Why?
bureaucrats? The federal government offers a unique Because the career bureau chiefs had twice as much
insight here because it has a vastly greater propor- federal experience, and this is “significantly related
tion of “in-and-outers” than do state and local gov- to management performance.”393
ernments, and it has a single system in which each of Other research finds much the same. The
its agencies (and, by association, their directors) is more years that big-city mayors serve in office,
ranked for its comparative performance against all the more  physically developed their cities and the
other agencies. more effective their law enforcement and social ser-
vices.394 The longer the tenure of municipal budget
The Less Experienced Political Executive The officers, the more efficiently they manage public
average tenure of Washington’s top political funds.395
appointees in their positions is about eighteen Experience trumps even that other major
months,387 compared with twice that time—more measure of professional capability, education. This is
than three years—for their careerist counterparts.388 the case with both federal careerists (political exec-
Presidentially-appointed executives, on average, utives are more highly educated)396 and hands-on
have more than nine, usually discontinuous, years mayors in cities with a “strong-mayor” form of gov-
of experience in different positions, whereas career ernment.397
executives average an impressive twenty-six contin-
uous years of federal service, or three times that of
political appointees.389 SPECIALIZED PUBLIC
PROFESSIONAL SYSTEMS: THE
Turnover and Time Matter Merely the fact that
federal political executives remain so briefly in office PERSON OVER THE POSITION
undermines agency achievement. An analysis of A profession is an easily identifiable and special-
“several hundred public organizations” over nine ized occupation, normally requiring at least four
years found that high rates of turnover were “nega- years of  college education, which offers a life-
tively related” to their performance.390 time career  to the persons in it. The emergence of
When more ambitious missions are undertaken, numerous specialized professions in governments
brief executive tenures almost guarantee organiza- brought to public human capital management a
tional failure. “The experiences of successful major new value: the person and the management of his
change management initiatives in large private and or her career.
Managing Human Capital 323

and, as we described in Chapter 5, professional “spe-


The Scope of Specialized Public cialists” are “manifestly maladjusted” in their gov-
Professional Systems ernment workplaces.400
Beginning around 1955, the proportion of special- Put bluntly, professionals who choose the public
ized professionals working in the public sector grew service often must overcome their antipathy for its
dramatically. two major features: politics and bureaucracy.
More than 56 percent of all public-sector To make matters worse, professionals with
employees are in “management, professional, and different specializations sometimes engage in infight-
related” fields, compared with less than 38 percent ing that inevitably undermines public productivity,
in the private sector. Nearly 49 percent of all federal an all-too-common phenomenon, for example,
civilian employees, almost 63 percent of state between city managers and city attorneys, whose
workers, and more than 55 percent of local govern- mutual “suspicions and competition” lead to “signif-
ment employees work in these occupations. (Recall icant” downturns in “municipal government effec-
from Chapter 4 that public managers account for tiveness.”401
just over 8 percent of the category, or more than a The scarcer the professionals available to an
third fewer managers than in the private sector; the agency—whether federal, state, or local—for hire,
remaining 92 percent are specialized professionals.) the greater the likelihood that these professionals
Educators, trainers, and librarians dominate state will control the agency’s HR system. In Washington,
and local workers who are in the management, pro- OPM has “excepted virtually all of the established
fessional, and related fields, accounting for nearly 26 and general professional fields, [and] a great many
percent of these state employees and over 34 percent emergent professions” from its official purview.402
of local workers.
The heavy professionalization of the public
sector is reflected in relative education levels. Fifty-
THE PROFESSIONAL PUBLIC
four percent of government employees have a bach- ADMINISTRATION SYSTEM:
elor’s or an advanced academic or professional EMBRACING THE PROFESSIONS
degree (47 percent of federal workers, 58 percent
of state employees, and 54 percent of local ones), OF POLITICS AND MANAGEMENT
compared with 35 percent of private-sector workers. In stark contrast to Specialized Public Professional
The proportion of government employees who hold Systems, the Professional Public Administration
advanced degrees is increasing over time, and at a System not only tolerates politics (as in public) and
faster clip than in the corporate sector.398 bureaucracy (as in administration), but actually
embraces them. Its central value is high-performance
public and nonprofit organizations.
The Public Implications of Specialized
Public Professionalism
Professions embody expertise, prestige, autonomy, The Roots of the Professional Public
dignity, and formal learning, values that often are Administration System
incompatible with politics. The historic struggles of The Professional Public Administration System is the
public professions to purge themselves of politics— result of a trio of developments that emerged in the
for example, the city manager versus party hacks; the 1970s.
librarian versus ignorant censors; the environmental
scientist versus political ideologues—all reflect this The Model Public Personnel Administration Law
resistance. of 1970 In 1970, the now-defunct National Civil
Nor do professionals like bureaucracy, which Service League released its sixth and last Model Public
they often view as an impediment to the free exercise Personnel Administration Law. Like its predecessors,
of their specializations. Federal employees in some it was deeply influential among personnelists, but
professions, such as science, express much less satis- also radically different from them, reflecting “a sea
faction with their work than do federal executives,399 change in the views of the cognoscenti about what
324 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

the public service should be.”403 It eschewed tradi- the president on policy and coordinates the gov-
tional merit principles and instead resurrected the ernment’s personnel programs. OPM also manages
values of the Brownlow Committee of 1937, urging another of the act’s creations, the Senior Executive
that personnel administrators integrate themselves Service, which is not protected by civil service reg-
with, and assist, line managers in managing. ulations.
Eight years following the model law’s release, The act also created the Federal Labor Relations
Washington enacted the first major reform of its per- Authority, which is charged with developing and
sonnel policies in ninety-five years, the Civil Service enforcing policies for unions.
Reform Act. By the mid-1970s, close to two-thirds A three-member, bipartisan Merit Systems
of all state and local civil services reported that they Protection Board adjudicates employee appeals,
were greatly influenced by the model law, and over investigates allegations that federal personnel laws
half had taken steps to make their personnel direc- have been violated, and may order agency compli-
tors more responsive to executive leadership.404 ance with its rulings.

Watergate and the Muffled Mouthpiece for “Merit” Roots, Reforms, and Results The consequence of
“Watergate,” the most searing political scandal of these developments has been the gradual emergence
the twentieth century, erupted in 1973 and burned of new thinking about people in the public service,
on through most of 1974. Its effects “unquestionably and this thinking is expressed in the Professional
were to tarnish the reputation of the public service in Public Administration System. Most particularly,
general. . . . And the U.S. Civil Service Commission, it focuses on loosening rigid position classification
which had been set up in part as a watchdog of the protocols and managing employee performance.
integrity of the civil service system, did not attack, or
growl, or even bark until the affair had ridden most
of its course. . . . Watergate generated doubts in the Reforming Classification
nation as a whole . . . about the public service as a The effort to reform position classification consists
whole.”405 of two primary initiatives.

The Civil Service Reform Act of 1978 If federal The Attributes of Effective Classification One is
human resource administrators were notably the identification those attributes that an effective
weak-kneed when it came to protecting the merit public job classification system should have. These
principle from presidential corruption, fiercely include the following:407
frustrated career managers saw them as posi-
tively  untamed in harassing them with the merit ■ Equity: All employees with comparable
principle. qualifications and responsibilities should be
This widespread resentment resulted in a hugely assigned to the same grade level and be paid
ambitious study of federal personnel administra- within ranges that are comparable to similar
tion involving more than 1,500 personnelists who qualifications and responsibilities in the private
pushed for reforms that ultimately were codified in sector.
the Civil Service Reform Act of 1978. “Here was ■ Transparency: The classification system
the culminating event of ‘government by managers,’ should be predictable and comprehensible to
espoused four decades earlier” by the Brownlow management, employees, and taxpayers.
Committee.406 ■ Flexibility: The classification system should
The act created three new bureaus for federal allow for adjustments in pay (among other
human capital management. Their directors and potential adjustments) within a uniform,
deputy directors, or board members, are nominated government-wide system so that agency needs
by the president, confirmed by the Senate, and serve and missions may be fulfilled.
at the president’s pleasure. ■ Adaptability: Fundamental reviews of
The Civil Service Commission was replaced by the entire classification system should be
the Office of Personnel Management, which advises undertaken periodically so that the system’s
Managing Human Capital 325

adaptability to changing workplace and broadbanding system,” and four use it on “a limited
workforce characteristics is assured. scale.”418 “About 12 percent of the states” have
■ Simplicity: The classification system should adopted broadbanding for at least three-fourths of
enable employee mobility among agencies, their employees, and their average number of “active
maintain a rational number of occupations job titles” (370) is just a fourth of those in states that
and meaningful differences in skills and have paybanded less extensively (1,536).419
performance within those occupations, and be Unions often resist broadbanding, arguing
cost-effective and easily managed. that its flexibility opens the civil service to political
■ Appropriateness: Positions should be classified patronage and discrimination; they were successful,
based on mission needs, and employees in 2016, in derailing it in New Jersey.
should be classified according to their unique Broadbanding is generally thought to be a
abilities so that those positions may be filled necessary first step before additional managerial
appropriately. reforms can be installed, and this seems to be true in
the states. In those states that have salary banded to
Broadbanding The second reform initiative is a significant extent, the numbers of employees who
broadbanding, paybanding, or salary banding, each are eligible for inclusion in a half-dozen innovative
of which refers to the reduction of position classifi- “pay strategies” outpace by two to six times those
cations into broad clusters of job “families.” in states that have not; transfer rates within these
Although the 420 federal occupations have been governments are about two-thirds lower, suggest-
grouped into twenty-three “occupational families,” ing greater contentment among public employees in
the grouping “falls short in implementation.”408 paybanded agencies.420
Only 14 percent of federal chief human capital More than half of cities have consolidated some
officers think that the General Schedule’s classifica- position classifications, and, indeed, were the public
tion system should be retained,409 and personnelists sector’s leaders in doing so.421
have recommended that the fifteen grades in the GS
be roughly halved in number,410 or even reduced by
two-thirds to five grades.411 Some 250,000 federal Managing Public and Nonprofit
employees are in broadbanding systems.412 Employees’ Performance
Personnelists also have proposed that the thou- While important, reforming classification is far less
sands of position classifications in state and local critical to the Professional Public Administration
governments be slashed to a few dozen,413 and these System than performance management, or clearly
governments have responded. expressing what is expected of an employee, and
Each state maintains, on average, some 2,000 then reasonably demonstrating whether he or she
position classifications.414 This large number inev- has fulfilled expectations.
itably produces oddities. California, for example, In governments, regrettably, the “absence of
had 3,666 classifications that were explained on good performance management practices [consti-
“1,022 pages of teeny-weeny print.”415 The state tutes a] critical flaw,” and this is one of the litera-
had a detailed classification for piano players, even ture’s “most consistent findings.”422
though the state had hired no pianist to play over When performance management is done well,
at least the preceding four years; four types of “cus- employees in all sectors exhibit greater job satisfac-
todians” and two types of “janitors” (each one of tion, turnover declines, and productivity increases,423
which required a separate application); and position and, in the public sector, programs improve, their
descriptions which pertained to an agency that had accountability is enhanced, collaboration with
been abolished eleven years earlier.416 (California is other  agencies increases, and there is greater con-
actively investigating broadbanding.) tinuity during leadership transitions.424 Even when
By the mid-1990s, the states were recognizing done well, however, performance management,
the problem, and five times as many states were while often heralded as unshackling employees
cutting their position classifications than were from counterproductive rules (recall the longed-for
adding them.417 Today, a dozen states use “a full-scale “liberation management,” noted in Chapter 7), it
326 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

actually “is likely to . . . increase the total population business, however, about 5 percent of companies
of rules,” typically introducing new rules for perfor- have abandoned performance reviews.435
mance measures and targets.425 Why is this? Rater bias (a sophisticated analysis
To be effective in the public and nonprofit found that performance ratings “reveal more about
sectors, performance management must overcome the rater than they do about the ratee”436), fuzzy per-
three unique obstacles: appraising performance, dis- formance standards, poorly written job descriptions
ciplining poor performers, and rewarding good ones. (federal job descriptions “typically exceed 1,500
words, and many of them are incomprehensible, at
least to the uninitiated”437), inadequate documenta-
Performance Management Challenge 1: tion and communication, process errors, and little or
Appraising Employees’ Performance no training (fewer than three out of ten new federal
Performance appraisal, also known as performance supervisors receive any training about documenting
assessment or performance rating, is the evaluation their employees’ performance, and only a fifth is
of an employee’s actual achievements and productiv- trained in “helping all employees improve their per-
ity in his or her job. formance.”438), are a few of the factors that reduce
Although appraisals of government workers both the reliability and the reputation of public and
have a long history (Congress first ordered assess- nonprofit performance rating.439
ments of federal workers in 1842), they never really The most intransigent problem is that the per-
addressed the idea that public administrators should formance of some public and nonprofit employees is
produce results. Reformers were quite satisfied that far less subject to assessment than others. Service to
the merit system did nothing more than inhibit clients, for instance, can be assessed by how many
public employees from routinely plundering the calls an administrator answers per hour, and how
public till. Hence, for many decades, a “productive” often his or her answers satisfy callers. But how
government worker was one who simply did not does one quantify the performance of the inter-
commit criminal acts and followed the rules. national staff of the U.S. Treasury, which is sup-
Over time, this modest objective was replaced posed to monitor developments in the international
by efforts to rate individual performance. The economy, coordinate with other governments, and
federal government, forty-nine states426 (nearly nine push for certain policies? Unsurprisingly, perhaps,
out of ten state classified employees, on average, research has found that, when performance apprais-
are appraised at least annually427), and over four- als are used at lower organizational levels, where job
fifths of cities and counties428 (although 22 percent responsibilities are often clearer and more quantifi-
of top city and county managers report that they able, the appraisals are more accurate and useful.440
receive no review429) now use performance assess- In addition to the difficulties inherent in assess-
ments. They are not cheap; an analysis of the federal ing individual public performance, there sometimes
government’s annual performance appraisals of its seems to be an obsession among some bureaucrats
2.1 million civilian employees estimated they cost not to be held accountable for poor performance,
at least $600 million every year.430 An analysis of which renders assessment even more problematic.
a large company concluded “completing the forms, “Blame avoidance behaviors on the part of public
holding the meetings, and creating the ratings con- managers are witnessed even in a regime with few
sumed close to 2 million hours a year.”431 incentives, no consequences linked to performance,
and limited transparency to citizens”; the lower the
The Pit of Performance Assessment Obtaining performance, the greater the effort to avoid blame.441
feedback on one’s professional performance has a
clear correlation with greater productivity.432 It is, Successful Performance Assessment To success-
therefore, worrisome that dissatisfaction with per- fully assess individual performance requires both
formance rating is much more pronounced in gov- personal and organizational approaches.
ernment (where it has “devolved into an odious At the personal level, ongoing “constructive
ritual that employees and managers alike would just performance conversations” are the single great-
as soon avoid”433) than it is in business.434 Even in est factor that can be controlled by management
Managing Human Capital 327

in increasing a federal employee’s engagement;442 collaboration; employee satisfaction with it shot to


77 percent of state and local employees who are a “staggering” 97 percent.449
engaged in their jobs say that they receive the right During the 2000s, Georgia completed a sophis-
amount of communication from their supervisors, ticated “ePerformance” system that provided imme-
compared with 25 percent of these workers who are diate performance feedback to all pertinent parties,
not engaged.443 To accomplish this engaging com- linked pay with performance, reduced job descrip-
munication, assessors must be adequately trained in tions by nearly four-fifths, and introduced explicit
leading, managing, and communicating, including, core competencies for not only employees, but also
if possible, setting clearly-expressed performance for those who assess employees’ performance.450
measures. To mitigate against personal favoritism in
the rating process, establish transparency, account-
ability mechanisms, and “independent reasonable- Performance Management Challenge 2:
ness reviews” by outside agencies, such as human Coping with Incompetents
resource offices.444 The dark side of performance appraisal is that
Organizationally, performance assessments it sometimes fails to identify “poor performers,”
should be embedded in a coherent system, based or “nonperformers,” as incompetent government
on consensual values and goals that focus on employees are officially described.
improving not only individual performance, but
organizational performance as well. Individual and The Costs and Challenges of Incompetents Even a
organizational objectives should be closely aligned, few poor performers can have a disproportionately
and individual competencies, as well as performance, negative impact on the productivity of the entire
should be assessed. Although some governments public workplace,451 leading to increased turnover
“still approach performance appraisals as discrete and absenteeism.452 Dealing with a poor performer
events, most have implemented systems that encom- can cost up to three times the poor performer’s
pass sets of activities to assess, develop, and reward pay.453
employees.”445 There can be little question that correcting
Of greatest importance, performance reviews poor performance is a tough challenge, princi-
should be continuous and treated as a responsibil- pally because incompetent employees are sublimely
ity that is shared between assessors and those who unaware that they are incompetent. Their lack of
are assessed. Annual performance reviews (which skills not only leads to their poor performance, but
the federal and most state and local governments also renders them “unable to recognize their poor
require), in this context, should be a summary doc- performances.” They display “dramatic overconfi-
ument, created by the manager and the employee. dence” about their abilities despite having received
“substantial” negative feedback. They possess “little
The Prospects for Performance Appraisal There insight into the depth of their deficiencies relative to
is a flickering glimmer of hope on this human their peers. . .. [and] overestimate their performances
resources horizon. even when given strong incentives for accuracy.” Top
More than three-fifths, up from about half ten performers, by contrast, tend “to underestimate
years earlier, of federal managers use “performance their performances,”454 a syndrome that can extend
information” to reward “government employees I to entire work groups. When incompetents concen-
manage or supervise,”446 and the number of federal trate in their own, self-protective groups, they col-
workers who think that their performance assess- lectively hide their incompetence by underreporting
ments are “appropriate” or “fair” has risen from 55 their failures; competent groups, by contrast, report
percent in 1986447 to 70 percent currently.448 their failures fully and honestly.455
State governments also seem to be making
progress. In 1998, Washington replaced its perfor- Coping with Federal Incompetents “The exact
mance rating system (which 93 percent of the state’s number of poor performers in the federal govern-
employees loathed) with a system that eliminated ment is unknown.”456 Federal employees, however,
rating scales in favor of greater communication and report that up to a fourth of their co-workers “are
328 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

not up to par,” a figure that is matched by employees incompetent bosses had “induced a mental handicap
in the private sector,457 but federal supervisors deem that had to be tolerated.”467 Or the patent exam-
not even 4 percent of their employees to be poor per- iner whose work was deemed “unacceptable” (the
formers.458 lowest-possible rating) three years in a row, falsely
Whatever their number, each year only a frac- inflated his work hours by at least 40 percent, and
tion of 1 percent of federal employees are denied was warned nine times about his lousy performance,
automatic salary increases, demoted, leave voluntar- was allowed to resign with “a clean slate [with] no
ily for reasons of performance or misconduct, or are conduct or performance record.”468
fired.459 Data going back some two decades consist- This sad record applies to incompetence—and
ently show that less than one-fourth to less than one- corruption—at the top. The most glaring example is
half of 1 percent of federal employees are dismissed Veterans Affairs. VA executives found guilty of using
annually for poor performance,460 and more than their authority for personal gain, falsifying patient
two-fifths of these are fired during the probationary waiting lists (resulting in some veterans’ deaths), and
period, when employees have far fewer job protec- financial mismanagement (including failure to spend
tions.461 As the civil service itself notes, “removing 40 percent of the VA’s multi-billion-dollar budget for
or demoting inadequate performers still remains rel- private healthcare, in 2013), a small handful of top
atively rare in the civil service.”462 executives were fired, and many of these were subse-
And getting rarer. Over five years, the annual quently reinstated.
percentage of feds fired for all reasons, including non-
performance, steadily declined, from 0.57 percent to Why Do Incompetent Federal Employees Hang
0.46 percent of the civilian workforce—a significant On? Nonperformers are deeply entrenched in their
drop of 19 percent. By contrast, the private sector jobs, and average an astonishing fourteen years in
dismisses 3.2 percent, on average, per year, or almost the federal employ.469
six times that of Washington.463 How could this be? There are several reasons.
A Little-Used Probationary Period: One is that
A Pernicious Personnel Problem How bad is it? federal supervisors and managers rarely use the
Pretty bad. single best opportunity that they have to rid them-
Consider some “inadequate performers” whom selves of poor performers—new employees’ one-to-
the federal civil service kept. The postal worker who two-year-long probationary periods. Supervisors let
was reinstated and awarded back pay after being go less than 2 percent of probationary employees,
fired for shooting a colleague in the workplace.464 Or even though 31 percent of them state that they “do
those employees, some of whom had six-figure sala- not expect to retain the probationer,”470 and manag-
ries and bonuses, who spent up to eight hours a day ers remove less than one-half of 1 percent of proba-
in their offices watching pornography because they tionary supervisors.471
were “bored” or had “not enough work to do.”465 An Awful Appeals Process: Another reason is
(As there are no reports of any of these viewers a tangled appeals process involving no fewer than
being fired, a congressman queried, “How much five federal agencies, each of which vary in their
porn would it take for an . . . employee to lose their authority, procedures, and body of case law, and an
job?”466 And, presumably, simply not working and appeal may be brought before one or more of these
being paid for it is also frowned upon.) Or the part- bodies.472 Most of these agencies appear to back
timer who broke a secretary’s jaw when she com- line managers; a major one (it receives about 25,000
plained about filing delays; the part-timer received appeals annually), for example, finds for employees
a transfer, a permanent job, and a nearly $4,000 just 1 percent of the time.473
raise. Or the biologist who was let go because it The more vexing issue is the inordinate time
took him four months to do what his supervisors consumed by the appeals process. Because of a mul-
could do in two days; he was reinstated because no tiplicity of boards and processes, it is difficult to pin
one had explained what “too slow” meant. Or the down just how much time an appeal consumes, but
secretary who was fired for incompetence, but who one appellants’ dismissal process takes a “total esti-
was reinstated and transferred because coping with mated time” of 170 to 370 days;474 another takes
Managing Human Capital 329

nearly a year, on average.475 Consider the case of is the main reason for granting leaves of a month
the agency driver who was suspended, appealed or more) and other reasons. Paid leaves spanning
to at least three appeals agencies over four years years cost the government an estimated $3.1 billion
(for three years he received no pay, and in the fourth in salaries alone, a number that does not include
was paid for doing nothing), and (Surprise!) won his benefits—pensions, vacations, sick days, etc.—which
job back.476 also continued and accrued.485 Of course, in all these
Why the appeals process is so convoluted is a instances, the taxpaying public foots the bill.
mystery because federal employees have no greater A Supine System: Consider this: even though the
legal protections than do workers in any other sector, IRS Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998 stipulates
or even in state and local governments.477 that IRS employees who are found to be “willfully
Taking Unsatisfactory Action: Supervisors are tax noncompliant” must be fired, just 39 percent of
where the rubber meets the road when confront- these willful employees were terminated, resigned, or
ing incompetents. Almost six out of ten federal retired over ten years.486 To top things off, over three
supervisors state that they have encountered prob- years, IRS rehired 323 former employees “despite
lems of employee performance or conduct over substantiated or unresolved prior conduct or per-
the preceding two years.478 Nearly nine out of ten formance issues,” nearly a fifth of whom ended up
supervisors counsel a poorly-performing employee, with “new conduct or performance issues,” including
spending a remarkable five hours per working week, some who had not paid their taxes.487
on average, doing so,479 a time commitment that The IRS showcases the systemic problems
matches that of the private sector.480 (Over half of inherent in dismissing poorly performing federal
supervisors think that their counseling failed.) More employees. For more than thirty years, federal
than a fourth take formal action (almost two-thirds employees have rated their government’s handling
think it failed). And a third give the employee “a less of poor performers as one of its greatest failures,
than satisfactory performance rating”481 (although and often as its single greatest failure.488 Forty-
not even a third of 1 percent receive an “unaccept- five percent disagree,489 and just 28 to 29 percent
able” rating482). agree,490 that “steps are taken” in their workplaces
Regrettably, supervisors often take “discipli- “to deal with a poor performer who cannot or will
nary” action that effectively rewards incompetents not improve.” “A whopping 78 percent of [federal]
and sanctions productive employees. In a survey of employees say the process for letting someone go is
federal employees, 37 percent (by far the highest out so cumbersome it discourages firing bad apples.”491
of six possible responses) reported that their super- Regrettably, senior executives seem a bit discon-
visors gave poor performers “fewer responsibilities,” nected on this score; 68 percent think that steps
and, in 21 percent of the cases, “no action” was are indeed taken to deal with poor performers, in
taken. Both actions (or non-actions) result in slack contrast to all other employees who disagree; this
that must be taken up by those who are performing is the second largest gap between SES members and
well. In 27 percent of the actions, supervisors simply employees in the study.492
made their problem someone else’s by transferring Forty-two percent of upper-level federal manag-
their nonperformers to another agency.483 ers and professionals who were hired from outside
Or supervisors grant the offender extended the government state that their agencies are “worse”
administrative leave (an excused absence without than their previous employer in “dealing effectively
loss of pay and benefits), such as the disruptive with poor performers,” and just 7 percent say that
employee who, after two failed attempts by supervi- their agencies handle them “better.”493
sors to remove him, received 5,881 hours of admin- More than two-fifths, a rapidly growing plural-
istrative leave.484 The three-fifths of federal agencies ity, of the Senior Executive Service think that their
that keep track of their administrative leaves placed, agencies fail to deal “effectively with executives who
over three years, more than 57,000 employees on perform poorly.”494 Of the 76 percent of federal per-
leave for at least a month, including 263 workers sonnel who think that the SES has “a problem,” 60
who collected paychecks for one to three years, while percent, by far the highest percentage out of nine
waiting for resolution of alleged misconduct (which possible responses, believe that problem is that it
330 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

is “too hard to fire poor performers in the SES.”495 even 5 percent of administrators report that agree-
Although the president, in 2015, issued an executive ments reached with state workers through collective
order that improved some aspects of the SES (e.g., bargaining is a “serious impediment” to their mana-
streamlined hiring, raised pay), it did not address the gerial authority.506
performance problem.
Federal supervisors receive little support from Coping with Local Incompetents Local managers
above. Although two-fifths of them state that they have taken some care in laying a groundwork to
are ignorant of relevant laws,496 only about a fifth of deal with nonperformers. Of the more than nine out
new supervisors receive training in managing poor of ten cities that have collective bargaining agree-
performers.497 A fifth say they dislike confronta- ments, 91 percent insert a management rights clause
tion,498 but just 22 percent of new supervisors are (some  four-fifths of which accord management the
trained in conflict management.499 right to take disciplinary action) in at least one of
All this leads to sinking supervisory morale. their contracts.
The less support that supervisors receive from upper Urban managers handle employee appeals with
management in dealing with incompetents, the more considerable dispatch. In 53 percent of munici-
likely that they will give up and leave the agency.500 palities, appeals are resolved, on average, within a
Congress Intervenes (Temporarily): In the first month or less, and, in 91 percent, in three months
week of 2017, a new and conservative Congress or fewer.507
made it easier for Congress to cut the federal
workforce and its pay. It did so by reinstating the Coping with Nonprofit Incompetents Nonprofit
“Holman Rule,” which permits the Committee on employees estimate that 19 percent of their col-
Appropriations in the House of Representatives to leagues are not performing well. Fifty-two percent
fire workers and lower salaries, without hearings or perceive that their organization does “very” or
due process, simply by inserting such a provision for “somewhat” well in disciplining poor performers;
specific agencies that are listed in a spending bill. 44 percent disagree.508 And some facts back up these
The rule was first adopted in 1876, dropped between perceptions: although there is some evidence that
1895 and 1911, and resurrected until 1983, when it nonprofit CEOs do not hire development directors
was again eliminated. The House stipulated that the well (26 percent of whom are “novices”), it is none-
rule would be effective only for 2017, although it theless notable that, “overall, 25% of executives
could, of course, be extended. reported that their previous development director
was fired,” and 62 percent of them were fired for
Coping with State Incompetents State administra- “poor performance.”509
tors seem to be doing a better job of dealing with These are much more favorable percent-
incompetents than their federal counterparts. The ages than those of their federal and private-sector
rate at which state employees are dismissed, while counterparts, and may indicate that independent
still low at less than 2 percent,501 is nonetheless six organizations respond in more rational ways to
times greater than the percentage of federal employ- incompetent employees, perhaps because their pres-
ees who are separated for poor performance.502 ence places them at greater organizational risk; as
Twenty-two percent of new hires in state govern- we explained in Chapter 4, nonprofit organizations
ments are not retained during the probationary likely are more vulnerable to “dying” than are public
period, a rate that is more than ten times that of the and private ones.
federal one.503
Although a third of state agency heads think Some Helpful Hints on Dealing with Incompetents
that personnel rules make it difficult to discipline Not all is lost in the battle against incompetents.
or discharge poor performers,504 they nevertheless Research has found that, regardless of sector, some
terminate classified workers in a speedy twenty-nine underused techniques can be effective. These include:
days, on average, for “performance issues,” and
an even briefer eighteen for “behavioral issues.”505 ■ Confront with clarity, empathy, and privacy.
Even in highly unionized state governments, not When supervisors deal with a poor performer
Managing Human Capital 331

quickly, directly, issue more warnings and (and, in theory but not in practice, deduction from)
formal sanctions more frequently, fire (when the salaries of employees that reflect changes in their
possible) promptly when warnings fail, and purchasing power. The other is the step increase, or
do so while treating the underperformer with a salary raise that is granted as a public employee
dignity, their units’ productivity is higher than automatically ascends each “step” within each pay
those of supervisors who do not.510 Of course, grade; performance need be only satisfactory.
any conferences with poor performers should
be done in private. Paying Performers in Washington We noted
■ Put all the rotten apples in the same barrel. earlier that, for decades, more than 99 percent of
Not only does isolating them reduce their federal employees have been rated by their super-
ability to infect good apples, but a bunch of visors as “Fully Successful” or higher, indicating
egocentric, energetic, destructive, overbearing that the federal government has attempted paying
people often can come up with excellent, for performance for some time, but with not much
creative ideas.511 success.
■ Make accountability human. When radiologists
saw photographs of patients whose X-rays An Erratic Rush Toward Performance Pay Congress
they were examining, their diagnostic accuracy first addressed performance pay in 1923, when the
quintupled relative to when they did not see Classification Act established a “graphic rating
their patients’ photographs.512 scale,” which supervisors used to unilaterally rate
■ Let the sunshine in. Employees are less honest employees’ performance and raise, lower, or retain
and more selfish when they work in dark their pay as they saw fit. It was less than popular, and
recesses or wear sunglasses in their office.513 the Civil Service Commission replaced the scale in
Light up the workplace and beware the 1935; Congress passed acts to deal with performance
employee who sports shades in it. pay in 1954 and 1962, only to be frustrated.
In 1978, Congress passed the Civil Service
Reform Act, which requires that administrators be
Performance Management Challenge 3: paid for performance, but it fails to specify how per-
Performance and Pay formance pay should be implemented. Consequently,
Our third and final component of performance Washington has struggled.
management is that of developing and implement- Congress mandated, in 1984, a “Performance
ing incentives that encourage higher performance by Management and Recognition System,” which estab-
employees. Performance pay, also known as incentive lished a commonsensical pay-for-performance plan
pay, performance-related pay, performance-based to limit the proportions of employees who could be
pay, pay for performance, pay for contribution, or included in each of the five performance-rating cat-
pay for competence links pay and other rewards, in egories used at the time. The plan was soon derailed
whole or in part, to individual, group, and/or organ- by organized labor and Representatives of districts
izational performance. close to Washington, where large numbers of federal
Although, as we have noted, many Americans employees vote. In 1993, Congress let the sun set on
express little interest in working for government, its failed system.
this alters when performance pay is introduced; 51 With the inauguration of George W. Bush, in
percent say that they would be “most interested in 2001, performance pay was reenergized. Nevertheless,
exploring a job in government [because of] oppor- all of Bush’s initiatives—performance pay systems in
tunities for growth and advancement based on per- the departments of Defense and Homeland Security
formance.”514 and a Human Capital Performance Fund—fizzled.
Despite popular enthusiasm, however, almost Bush’s successor, confronted by a historically deep
all governments still retain a pair of public-pay recession, put performance pay on the back burner
pillars, neither one of which is on speaking terms in favor of mandating pay caps.
with performance. One is the cost-of-living adjust- After nearly three decades of federal flounder-
ment, which is an automatic annual addition to ing, involving a dozen demonstration projects, fewer
332 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

than 43,000 employees (obviously, considerably at least three documented performance discussions
less than 1 percent) are covered by formal pay-for- with each employee per year, establishes deadlines
performance systems.515 for improving the performance of underperformers,
and requires disciplinary action if improvement does
Performance Incentives and Promotions Congress not take place.
first addressed incentives for performance (that Over time, Washington seems to have improved
is, awards for individual productivity that are not its management of performance pay. Forty-one
incorporated into base pay) with the Incentive percent of federal workers think that “awards in my
Awards Act of 1954. Today, 62 percent of full- work unit depend on how well employees perform
time federal civilian employees receive cash merit their jobs”522 (34 percent do not think so523), and
bonuses, amounting, on average, to 1.6 percent of this proportion represents more than a doubling
salary, or time-off awards for performance. In some over thirty-three years.524 More than three-fifths
agencies, 90 percent receive such recognitions.516 (In of federal managers, up from about half ten years
the typical workgroup, from only 15 to 20 percent earlier, use “performance information” to reward
of workers are considered to be extraordinarily pro- “employees I manage or supervise.”525
ductive by their co-workers.517) Seventy-one percent, Most of these auguries are welcome. But there
and growing, of the Senior Executive Service receives remains some way to go.
bonuses for performance.518 In addition, 99.9
percent of federal workers get each and every step Paying Performers at the Grass Roots Paying for
increase that is available to them.519 Apparently, the performance seems to be working at the grass roots.
federal government has exceptional performers, or is A gratifying 55 percent of state and local officials
overly generous in recognizing performance, or just “strongly” (19 percent) or “somewhat” (36 percent)
gives out performance awards willy-nilly. agree that “promotions [and, inferentially, pay] in
Promotion is also supposed to be a solid indi- my work unit are based on merit.”526
cator of performance. In 2009, Washington finally The leading hindrance in improving state agency
terminated its arbitrary “time-in-grade” rule, first performance is that of “adequately rewarding out-
imposed in 1952, which required employees to spend standing employees”; more than half of state agency
at least one year in a grade before they could be pro- managers identify it as a “serious problem.”527
moted, a policy that seemed at odds with promot- There has been some, if mixed, progress in rec-
ing (and paying) for performance. As with bonuses, tifying this problem. Although the proportion of
however, it should give us pause that promotions state employees who are eligible for cost-of-living
are being awarded with record-breaking generos- adjustments increased from 48 to 70 percent in just
ity. In 2014, for the first time in the history of the three years, those who are eligible for step increases
General Schedule, more than half of all the employ- declined from a fourth to a fifth over the same
ees covered by it were in the General Schedule’s top period.528 “Pay-for-performance salary increases”
three grades (GS 12 through 15).520 Although it is expanded their share of pay systems, however, and
encouraging that at least one analysis found that the “are now the second most available compensation
major reason for the proportional expansion, from strategy” in the states, exceeded only by cost-of-
1977 through 1993, of administrators who occupy living adjustments.529
higher positions in the federal hierarchy was their Surprisingly, “drastic levels of civil service
rise in quality, that finding may now be as inaccurate reform” in the states (detailed earlier) “signifi-
as it is dated.521 cantly and positively influenced the effectiveness of
pay-for-performance,” and had little, if any, impact
Some Possible Performance Progress In 2016, on how employees perceived the fairness of perfor-
the Pentagon (which accounts for nearly two-fifths of mance appraisal.530
all non-postal, permanent civilian employees) began Seven out of every ten local governments have
phasing in its new Civilian Personnel Management pay-for-performance plans.531 Close to half of the
System, which weds quality step increases with per- largest counties pay for performance “very often”
formance reviews, requires that supervisors hold (36 percent) or “often” (11 percent); only a fourth
Managing Human Capital 333

never use performance pay.532 Sixty-two percent administrators grown over performance pay’s diffi-
of the 78 percent of top city and county managers culties that they even refrain from uttering the term,
whose performance is reviewed report that their pay “merit pay.”544
is tied to performance.533 State employees also exhibit considerable dis-
satisfaction with performance pay.545
Should It Be Done? The Case to Countermand At the local level, there appears to be mixed
Performance Pay Most analyses of paying-for- support. Among top and upper city administrators,
performance in the public sector conclude that it “performance-related pay is associated with greater
“consistently fails to deliver on its promise” of job satisfaction, especially among employees who
improving individual and organizational perfor- possess stronger public service motives. . .. [although
mance.534 “Traditional or alternative reward systems it] may be particularly important to [those same]
should be used instead of pay-for-performance, which employees who have lower levels of public service
can be counterproductive”535 as it “almost always motivation.”546
produces hidden costs,” among other deficiencies.536
That may not be the half of it: there is evidence Can It Be Done? When public performance pay
suggesting that performance pay actually correlates falters, “inept” administrators are often blamed.
with lower performance. But the more culpable causes may well be stubborn,
One of the “most interesting findings” in perhaps immutable, institutional and cultural con-
one study “is that the ability to reward a good straints that are unique to the public sector. These
manager . . . consistently lowers governmental per- include: squeezed budgets; stiff public resistance to
formance. The reasons for this finding are not alto- big bonuses for bureaucrats; and greater transpar-
gether clear, but it appears that differential pay for ency in government547 (where, for example, salaries
public managers (and possibly other employees) usually are public knowledge, which may reduce
creates dissension and takes a heavy toll on gov- performance pay’s impact—one study found that
ernmental performance—a finding that is consistent governmental “monetary incentives tend to have a
with the public management literatures on public larger performance effect when they are secret rather
service motivation and pay for performance but than disclosed,” and secret compensation is rare in
which runs counter to conventional wisdom and the public sector). Nonmonetary incentive pay, by
management practice.”537 contrast, seems to be “less prone . . . to some of the
Public employees seem to largely concur. Just motivational drawbacks encountered when using
21 percent of federal workers agree that “pay monetary incentives,” at least for those in the helping
raises depend on how well employees perform their public professions, such as nurses.548
jobs,”538 and 52 percent disagree.539 When we dig If it is to be done, “the shift to pay for perfor-
a bit deeper, barely 26 percent of federal staffers mance,” to quote one understated assessment, “is
agree that “promotions in my work unit are based going to be difficult.”549
on merit,” but a disconnected 47 percent of manag-
ers believe this to be the case—a stark difference of It’s All Relative Let us place this bleak portrait
21 percent, the largest such difference in the analy- into some perspective.
sis.540 When we move a bit further up the scale, 79 It is well worth keeping in mind that the private
percent of SES members think that pay correlates sector wins no prizes in matching performance with
positively with performance, compared with less pay. An analysis of 137 empirical studies found
than 30 percent of all other employees, a difference that more than 40 percent of the performance
of 39 percent—again, the largest such difference in pay  rewarded to corporate CEOs is the result of
the analysis.541 Performance pay leads to lower job their companies’ size (the bigger the company, the
satisfaction among federal employees,542 and those bigger the percentage), “while firm performance
few federal workers who favor performance pay accounts  for less than 5%” of their presumed
appear to be among the poorer performers. They are “performance” pay.550
“extrinsically motivated” (recall Chapter 3) and dis- Similarly, nonprofit CEOs’ compensation is
engaged from their jobs.543 So sheepish have federal far more a function of organizational size and the
334 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

amount of readily-available funds (the bigger the state employee from being fired, even for “arbitrary,
organization and the greater the liquidity, the larger vindictive, and malicious reasons,” because the gov-
the compensation) than of executive performance: ernment needs “broad discretion” to make “subjec-
“While pay-for-performance is a factor in determin- tive” judgments about its workforce, judgments that
ing [these executives’] compensation, it is not prom- are based on factors which are not only difficult to
inent.”551 Pay-for-performance works well, however, “quantify,” but even to “articulate.”
for nonprofit fundraisers, where there is “a signifi- Engquist potentially provides the power to
cant and positive relationship between money raised erase a third of public administrators’ performance-
and compensation.”552 management problems—that of disciplining and
dismissing incompetent employees. The only down-
side is that it also can be used to dismiss excellent
The Prospects of Performance employees.
Management
Considering the looming impediments to imple- Lessons Learned We have learned that some
menting effective public and nonprofit performance organizational factors encourage, indirectly but
management—i.e., inaccurate (or impossible) per- clearly, more effective performance management.
formance appraisals, limited success in ridding These include: employees who are engaged in their
governments (especially the federal one) of incompe- jobs;555 organizational and managerial flexibility;556
tents, and the passel of problems inherent in paying high levels of trust and professionalism in the organ-
for public performance—is there light at the end of ization; and useful performance appraisals.557
this gloomy tunnel? More proactively, public and nonprofit
Well, there are some weak-wattage glows. For administrators also can act in ways that will result
instance, more than nine out of ten top federal per- in better performance management. These include
sonnel executives think that their agencies do “a the following.558
good job of aligning organizational goals to individ-
ual performance” to a “moderate” (44 percent) or ■ Evaluate the effectiveness of the agency’s
“great or very great extent” (51 percent).553 current performance appraisal system.
There are, happily, additional reasons to hope. ■ Establish a separate budget for the
performance pay system.
Far-Reaching Rulings One is the stance of the ■ Involve employees, including union officials, in
Supreme Court under Chief Justice John Roberts, building a high performance organization and
beginning with his appointment in 2005. A in revising the pay system.
review of the Roberts Court’s decisions in gov- ■ Assure that there is a “clear separation of
ernment-worker  cases concluded that they “more interests,” such as separate career paths,
narrowly define the constitutional rights of “between politicians and senior civil
public employees,” a trend that shows no sign of servants.”559
abating.554 These decisions could, in theory, apply ■ Communicate goals clearly.
to nonprofit employees as well. While we support ■ Link individual objectives with organizational
broadly defined constitutional rights for all, it is goals.
nonetheless notable that the current Court favors, ■ Make sure that rewards are high and clearly
in effect, the authority of government supervisors differentiated.
over employees. ■ Link performance pay with additional
In terms of performance management, the incentives, such as promotion.
Court’s most notable—indeed, startlingly radical— ■ Select supervisors who are flexible and who
ruling is that of Engquist v. Oregon Department of will effectively manage performance.
Agriculture, in which the Court held that, provided ■ Hold every supervisor accountable for effective
discrimination played no part in an employee’s dis- performance management.
missal, the Constitution’s Fourteenth Amendment ■ Arrange so that the system can be reviewed
(the Equal Protection Clause) does not prohibit a both internally and externally.
Managing Human Capital 335

■ Provide supervisors with the training, We consider next how broadened civil rights
resources, and managerial support they need to and affirmative action affect only the administration
improve their employees’ performance. of public and nonprofit organizations, so we shall
■ Say “thank you” when it is warranted. not be addressing some clearly important civil rights
legislation—e.g., the Voting Rights Act—which does
Between the potentially revolutionary Engquist not directly alter organizational behavior.
ruling and the slow but steady learning curve
about how to manage performance, the prospects
for improving at least some public and nonprofit Civil Rights for Protected Classes
employees’ performance seem at least possible, and Washington has defied discrimination by extending
even cautiously encouraging. civil rights.

Race, Religion, and National Origin In 1941,


DEFYING DISCRIMINATION: THE President Franklin D. Roosevelt issued Executive
EXTENSION OF CIVIL RIGHTS Order 8802, which barred discrimination on the
AND THE ENTRY OF AFFIRMATIVE basis of race, religion, or national origin in industries
with federal contracts
ACTION
A civil right is the assurance that the law is applied The Elderly In 1967, Congress passed the Age
equally to all in the protection of personal liberties Discrimination in Employment Act. The act, as
that belong to a person by dint of his or her status amended in 1974 and 1981, prohibits compulsory
as a resident of a particular society. Affirmative retirement in most jobs for reasons of age, and pro-
action is the policy of proactively hiring and pro- tects all workers from age discrimination who are
moting qualified members of disadvantaged groups, forty years old or older. It covers some 75 million
and assuring the expansion of government contracts Americans, or about half of the nation’s labor pool.
which are signed with qualified businesses that are
owned by members of disadvantaged groups. The Disabled In 1990, Congress enacted the
Compared with relatively passive civil rights, Americans with Disabilities Act, which prohibits
affirmative action is aggressive and demands that discrimination against the mentally and physically
organizations demographically reflect the society disabled in employment and accommodations, and
that they are in. Among other objectives, affirmative affects about 18 percent of the population. (The
action seeks to eliminate “glass ceilings” (organiza- federal government is a leader in this area; more
tion-wide limitations on advancement for certain than 14 percent, and rapidly growing, of its civil-
groups), “sticky floors” (jobs with limited potential ian employees are disabled.561) Although the act is
for promotion), and “glass walls” (fields that employ hailed as “one of the most sweeping nondiscrimina-
few people from disadvantaged groups). tion pieces of legislation since the Civil Rights Act of
Also in contrast to civil rights, which come with 1964,”562 disabled employees have won less than a
a logical body of law, affirmative action’s “various tenth of the suits brought under its auspices.563
laws and rules grew without a strong governmen-
tal or legal theory binding them coherently together.
Therefore, some of the laws are conflicting and con- Civil Rights for Sexual Minorities
tradictory and exceedingly difficult to interpret.”560 Because Congress has not extended antidiscrimi-
For more than a half century, Washington has nation legislation to the lesbian, gay, bisexual, or
extended civil rights legislation to, and formed and transsexual (LGBT) community, EEOC does not list
implemented affirmative action policies for, specific it as a protected class; nevertheless, governments at
groups. These groups are, according to the federal all levels have taken steps to shield this group from
Equal Employment Opportunity Commission discrimination.
(EEOC), protected classes, which include any person These steps seem needed, as there are some
covered by federal antidiscrimination legislation. decidedly odd patterns of pay in all sectors in this
336 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

area. Gay men (who earn about 15 percent less than rights policies in the states.574 Transgendered people,
heterosexual men) may be the victims of negative however, may be targets of state discrimination.
discrimination relative to heterosexual men in the “At least” 225 local governments prohibit employ-
workplace, but lesbian women (who earn from a ment discrimination on the basis of gender identity,
fifth to a third more than heterosexual women) may but three states—Arkansas, North Carolina, and
be the beneficiaries of positive discrimination rela- Tennessee—have enacted laws that overrule their
tive to heterosexual women.564 localities by stating that “sex” must be defined as
From 5 to 8 percent of college-degreed gay men that which appears on one’s birth certificate.575
and lesbians work in federal, state, and local govern-
ments, and 16 percent and 22 percent, respectively,
of these groups work in the independent sector.565 Affirmative Action for Protected Classes
(It follows that LGBT people are more likely than The acknowledged originator and archangel of
heterosexuals to hold altruistic work values.566) affirmative action is President Lyndon Baines
Until 1975, federal agencies were required to Johnson.
consider sexual orientation in assessing an applicant
for employment. Executive Order 13087, issued in Race, Religion, and National Origin In 1965,
1998, protected federal employees from discrimina- Johnson signed Executive Order 11246, which
tion on the basis of their sexual orientation. In 2009, directed all organizations that had federal contracts
federal benefits were extended to same-sex partners, to take “affirmative action” (marking the debut
and, in 2013, to same-sex spouses. In 2014, the of this phrase) to provide equality of opportunity,
president issued an executive order banning federal irrespective of race, religion, or national origin. The
contractors from discriminating against their LGBT order remains Washington’s first, and still central,
employees. In all, “more than 100 executive actions affirmative action policy.
and regulatory changes” have been issued to improve
the lives of LGBT people.567 Women In 1967, Johnson issued Executive Order
These executive actions are doubtless good, 11375, which added women to the ranks of those
but fall short of legislative actions, which would be who are covered by Executive Order 11246.
better. “Surprisingly,” in those twenty-one states and
the District of Columbia that had banned same-sex Vietnam Era Veterans In 1974, Congress enacted
partners by statute, rather than by executive order, the Vietnam Era Veterans’ Readjustment Assistance
as was done by sixteen states, gay and lesbian rep- Act, which requires federal contractors to apply
resentation in state and local governments was “sig- affirmative action in the hiring and advancement of
nificantly higher.”568 In 2013, the Supreme Court more than eight million veterans of the Vietnam War.
decided two cases that extended same-sex spousal
benefits to workers in all sectors.569 Minority- and Women-Owned Businesses In 1977,
Nearly 3 percent of federal employees self- Congress passed the Public Works Employment Act,
identify as LGBT,570 and they appear to be rep- which initiated set-side programs, or policies that
resented in “the supervisory, managerial, and require governments to reserve (or “set aside”) a
executive ranks in the same proportion as they are portion of their contracts for businesses owned by
in the overall Federal workforce.”571 Extraordinarily minorities or women. These companies typically
few federal employees—about 1 percent, the lowest account for about a tenth of all federal contract
rate of any discrimination category—allege that dollars,576 and uncounted slices of state and local
they were victims of discrimination because of their contracts.
sexual orientation,572 although 3 percent of feds The Supreme Court, in 1980, ruled that set-
state that they have witnessed discrimination based asides were constitutional,577 but later partially
on sexual orientation.573 backtracked. Adarand Constructors, Inc. v. Peña,
As in the federal government, “relatively few” settled in 1996, pertained to the federal government,
formal sexual-orientation charges of discrimina- holding that, in order to be constitutional, set-asides
tion followed the introduction of applicable civil must be “narrowly tailored” to accommodate a
Managing Human Capital 337

“compelling” public interest, and were subject to render federal enforcement virtually universal. In
“strict scrutiny” by the judiciary. 1990, the Supreme Court upheld that the Federal
In response to Adarand, the president suspended Communications Commission may take race into
those set-asides that set numerical goals, cutting at account in distributing broadcast licenses.582
least $1 billion in set-aside contracts.578 A decade fol-
lowing Adarand, applications to a large federal fund Judicial Enforcement Perhaps the judiciary’s most
submitted by white-owned organizations were three notable innovation in enforcement is that of “dis-
times more successful, and were awarded almost four parate impact,” a doctrine first enunciated by the
times more dollars, than were their minority-owned Supreme Court in 1971, in Griggs v. Duke Power
counterparts.579 Similarly, women-owned businesses Company; overturned in 1989 by the Court in
win 21 percent fewer federal contracts than do men- Ward’s Cove Packing Co. v. Antonio; and reinstated
owned businesses, even though the characteristics of by Congress in the Civil Rights Act of 1991.
the businesses owned by both genders are virtually Disparate, or adverse, impact holds that employ-
identical.580 ees who allege discrimination in the workplace do not
Earlier, the Court had issued a similar decision, have to prove that their employer deliberately tried
in 1989, that targeted subnational governments. City to discriminate against them, but only that they have
of Richmond v. J.A. Croson Co. forced state and been disproportionately harmed by workplace pol-
local governments to undertake disparity studies, or icies. Disparate impact was the judiciary’s basis for
analyses that demonstrate whether or not set-asides disqualifying, in 1981, the universal test for assessing
are needed to counter discrimination. “In nearly all federal job applicants that had been used since 1955,
of the disparity studies” in one large sample, “there noted earlier. Over the years, the Supreme Court has
was little serious evaluation” and virtually all these cited adverse impact in deciding cases that involved
jurisdictions blithely were continuing their set-aside gender, religion, race, national origin, and age.
programs.581 In supposedly complying with Croson, In 2009, in Ricci v. DeStefano, the Court held
the grass-roots governments happily talked the talk, that governments may not use disparate impact as
but, in contrast to Washington, discreetly declined to a rationale to dismiss valid test results, and thereby
walk the walk. disqualify employees who passed the test from being
promoted, merely because they feared being sued by
protected test-takers who failed the test.
Federal Enforcement of Affirmative Action
All three branches of the federal government have Retaliation Enforcement EEOC also investigates
affirmatively enforced affirmative action. charges of employer retaliation against those
employees who lodged discrimination complaints,
Congressional Enforcement The critical law in and it may fine employers for retaliating. In 2008,
the enforcement of affirmative action is the Equal the Supreme Court supported these practices in cases
Employment Opportunity Act of 1972. The act involving racial583 and age584 discrimination.
established the EEOC, which investigates charges of Complaints of retaliation have more than
employment discrimination in all sectors, and may doubled over fourteen years, and constitute almost
fine employers if it finds discrimination. half of all allegations of discrimination, the largest
category by far,585 perhaps because “it is often easier
Executive Enforcement The EEOC is the executive for employees to demonstrate that they were retali-
branch’s chief enforcer, but it is far from the only one. ated against than that they were victims of discrimi-
The Department of Labor’s Order Number 4 of nation in the first place.”586
1971 (now Revised Order Number 4, issued in 1978)
requires federal contractors to establish plans  and
timetables for achieving specific affirmative-action Affirmative Action and the Grass-Roots
goals. Governments
For organizations without federal contracts, Understandably, some state and local governments,
regulatory agencies enforce affirmative action, which perhaps most, were initially resistant to affirmative
338 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

action, but top local administrators wrung a change about  college admissions and corporate advance-
in attitude. By the mid-1970s, more than four-fifths ment policies.
of all municipal affirmative action plans had been
initiated by city managers, who were “far and away Two Definitive Decisions For the next quarter-
the principal initiators of affirmative action in their century, the judiciary hemmed and hawed, churn-
governments”; about half of them had developed ing out a series of largely ambivalent rulings that
these plans with no support whatsoever from their wobbled either for diversity or ignored it. In 2003,
own city councils.587 the Supreme Court decided a pair of cases, both
By the mid-1980s, affirmative action had seeped brought by the University of Michigan, which clar-
into grass-roots bureaucracies, with only 6 percent ified its views.
of municipal personnel directors opposed to quotas In Gratz v. Bollinger and Grutter v. Bollinger,
for minorities and women.588 By the end of the the Court ruled that attaining diversity is a con-
decade, over two-thirds of cities and counties had stitutionally defensible goal, but, to pass constitu-
government-wide affirmative action policies, up tional  muster, the diversity-relevant components
from about half fifteen years earlier.589 of admissions policies should be largely free of
numbers, characterized by vaguely expressed goals,
and imbued with human judgment. The university
“Reverse Discrimination” and the Quota subsequently tried many new programs meant to
Question increase diversity, but, thirteen years later, none
How is success measured in affirmative action? Can had  “resulted in as many students of color” as
an employer succeed by merely promising (earnestly, before the rulings.590 The Court, in 2013, upheld
of course) to review the job applications of a few this “strict scrutiny” interpretation of affirma-
more people in the protected classes? Or does tive action in college admissions, but, in 2016, re-
success mandate that all fit white men under forty affirmed that considering race in admissions was a
years of age be fired and replaced by people from the legitimate means of assuring a diverse student body,
protected classes? which it deemed to be a desirable value in its own
These queries bring us quickly to the ques- right.591
tion of quotas, or the hiring and promoting of spe-
cific numbers of applicants from protected classes. The “Quota Bill” of 1991 We cannot leave the
Usually, these numbers reflect each protected class’s subject of quotas without noting that imposing them
percentage in the general population or labor force. can sometimes be perversely counterproductive. In
The rub is that qualified applicants who are not 1991, Congress passed a Civil Rights Act that made
from protected classes might not be hired. When it much more difficult—and costly—for employ-
this occurs, the charge of “reverse discrimination” is ers to fire workers in protected classes. Opponents
occasionally leveled. derided the act as a “quota bill.”
Employers soon circumvented the act by aban-
Two Defining Decisions The Supreme Court doning their standard practice of firing an unsatis-
first addressed reverse discrimination, in 1978, in factory employee outright “for cause” (a procedure
the famous case of Regents of the University of that accounts for about a fifth of all workers who
California v. Bakke, and, in the following year, heard are let go), and relying instead on laying off groups
the “blue-collar Bakke” case, United Steel Workers of workers (including protected workers whom
v. Weber. employers actually wanted to fire for cause) when
Both cases involved quotas for minorities, business was down. The practice made discrimina-
and both Bakke and Weber, who were white men, tion very hard to prove.
alleged  that they had been denied their rights African-American men are now fired for cause
because of those quotas. In both cases, the Court much less frequently, but this reduction has been
held that affirmative action was constitutional and cancelled out by their far more frequent layoffs; for
legal, and that race could be a factor (in Bakke, white men, the ratio of firings to layoffs has stayed
race could even be a “plus”) in making decisions the same.592
Managing Human Capital 339

test writers to unwittingly slant their tests’ ques-


Tests: The Validation Vexation tions in ways that reflect the majority culture, and
Quotas are closely related with how applicants thereby handicap those test takers who were reared
are tested for hiring and promotion; public admin- in minority cultures. The Supreme Court ruled, in
istrators consistently identify “test results” as the 1975, that culturally-biased tests are illegal, even
single greatest disqualifier of minorities seeking when the employer is not discriminating intention-
employment.593 ally,599 and added, in 1982, that even when no dis-
For nearly fifty years, the courts have been inter- crimination is present, the use of culturally-biased
vening in how governments test their job applicants. tests is still illegal!600
The crux of their intervention is test validity, or the
level of confidence that employers can reasonably A Missing and Misperceived “Problem” As a result
have in the power of an examination to predict how of all this, many managers in all sectors perceived
well, or how badly, an applicant will fare in a job. themselves to be perched on the ticklish horns of an
The courts long have held that such tests must be exquisite dilemma. If they used a cognitive-ability
valid. test to hire and promote, they not only lessened the
The judiciary has focused on two types of test chances of adding more minorities and women to
validity: the validity of tests in assessing an appli- their organizations, but also risked a judgment of
cant’s relevant skills and qualifications to succeed in adverse impact. If they used other, less predictive and
a specific job (which, as a practical matter, are useful valid tests, they may add more minorities and women
mostly at the lower levels of organizational hierar- who might contribute less to their organizations.
chies), and their validity in measuring an applicant’s These perceptions were and are inaccurate. The
cognitive ability, or his or her thinking capacity, e.g., courts have held, quite consistently, that if a public
reasoning and problem-solving abilities. agency uses a cognitive-ability test that has been
developed and validated, preferably by experts using
Validating Tests for Job Skills In 1971, the Supreme professional standards, and if the cutoff scores are
Court ruled in the landmark case, Griggs v. Duke properly set, then the test is legal.601
Power Co., that to hire people on the basis of qual-
ifications which could not be shown to be relevant Skittish Governments These courtly realities took
to the knowledge and skills that are actually needed decades to develop into a solid body of case law,
to do the job in question is discriminatory under the during which time governments were understanda-
Civil Rights Act of 1964. To their credit, the grass- bly skittish.
roots governments (where the heart of the public As we described earlier, the feds were feck-
part of this problem lay) acted quickly. Immediately less. Thirty-four years passed by without a useable
following Griggs, the proportion of state and local cognitive-ability test before OPM finally announced,
governments that validated these tests for job rele- in 2015, USA Hire, the competitive entry examination
vance burgeoned from 54 percent594 to 87 percent595 that meets the standards of a valid cognitive-ability
in only five years. test. Developed by personnel psychologists, general
aptitude is once again assessed, but also other attrib-
Validating Tests for Cognitive Ability Cognitive- utes, such the ability to work in teams.
ability tests have the greatest validity for managerial State and local governments were also at sea,
positions. They have the lowest costs, can be used by but largely responded better than the feds. In the
all entry levels, and are “likely the best single predic- 1980s, many of these governments introduced race
tor of job performance.”596 norming, or adding points to a test score if the test
But there are problems. African-Americans and taker is from a minority group. The logic, which
Hispanic-Americans usually score lower than whites seemed quite justifiable at the time, was that if the
on these tests,597 and women score slightly lower Supreme Court could declare veterans’ preference, or
than men.598 the policy of adding points to veterans’ test scores,
Why is this? Researchers and justices attribute to be constitutional, which the Court did in 1979,602
these disparities to cultural bias, or the tendency of then why not do the same for minorities?
340 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Congress intervened, and confused the issue. In are granted less authority than their male colleagues,
1991, it enacted a Civil Rights Act which banned which, in turn, lowers their pay relative to men.610
race norming, but nevertheless still required pref- The deprivations do not end there. “A primary
erential treatment of applicants from protected factor” in those government pension plans that are
classes. among the most “significantly” underfunded (recall
In 2001, the Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals Chapter 8) is the presence of “more female active
reconciled some of the act’s incongruities by ruling participants in the plan, suggesting another risk to
that race norming is illegal, but banding is not.603 women’s retirement income.”611
Banding is the consolidation of test scores, such As a consequence of these and other inequities,
as replacing a specific numeric score (e.g., “90”) most of which occur in all sectors, three policies have
with, say, a letter score (e.g., “A,” which includes the emerged that are designed to curb sexual discrimina-
numeric scores of 90 through 100). Banding solves tion in employment. Each has a special relevance for
a lot of problems because numeric scores can be so women, though none is the sole preserve of women.
close as to become meaningless. The Supreme Court
once heard a case in which a local agency promoted The Bona Fide Occupational Qualification Until
a woman over a man, who then sued despite the fact the 1960s, there were numerous state protective
that his test score was only two points (out of 100) labor laws which prohibited women from entering
higher than hers, and the position’s 238 occupants jobs that were deemed to be too strenuous for them.
were entirely male. (The Court ruled in favor of the Congress eventually intervened. The Equal Pay
woman.)604 Act of 1963 banned several artificial job qualifi-
The cobwebs of federal, state, and local cations, and the Civil Rights Act of 1964 required
cognitive-ability testing have been largely cleared. that  employers specify only a “bona fide occu-
Nearly a fifth of all cities and counties use pational qualification reasonably necessary” to
cognitive-ability tests,605 and 95 percent of large accomplish a task.
cities use them in hiring.606 Both laws were challenged in the courts, but
to little avail. The Supreme Court ruled, in 1968,
that protective labor laws could not be used to deny
Women’s Work? women jobs or promotions,612 and the Fifth Circuit
Women comprise half of the world’s population, but Court of Appeals held, in 1969, that, in judging the
contribute just 37 percent to the global gross domes- validity of a job qualification, the burden of proof
tic product (GDP). Should a country simply match lies with the employer.613
the country that was merely “best in region” in
terms of fairness for women in the workplace, then The Curious Question of Comparable Worth
the worldwide GDP would increase by a remark- Comparable worth means that employees in one
able 26 percent over ten years.607 The GDP of the position classification should be paid the same as
United States could grow by an equally remarkable employees performing comparable tasks in another
25 percent over ten years, if women attained “full classification, even though the tasks themselves may
gender equality.”608 It is, therefore, all the more trou- be quite different. As a practical matter, comparable
bling that working women are held back, even in worth works to raise the salaries of employees in
countries that are relatively enlightened, such as the position classifications dominated by women.
United States. Even in the American public work- Comparable worth assumes that the social
place, however, women hoe a rocky row. A national value of occupations can be assessed and compared,
survey of 1,600 of these employees “from different and this can be a tricky business. For instance, do
levels of the public sector,” found that women are the musicians in a city’s symphony orchestra, when
more likely than men to be single or divorced, have compared with the plumbers in its municipal water-
fewer or no children, and have more onerous house- works, endure comparable stress, have comparable
hold responsibilities.609 responsibilities and importance, and contribute com-
Women who work in government also are paid parable levels of knowledge and skills to the city?
less than men, apparently because, in part, women In the only major judicial decision on this question,
Managing Human Capital 341

the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals ruled, in 1985, believe that there was more sexual harassment in
probably not, deciding that Washington State was their former workplaces, compared with 7 percent
not obliged to award back pay to 15,500 employees who think there was less.620
in position classifications dominated by women.614
Nevertheless, perhaps because popular opinion Harassing Harassment Most private firms, the
favors comparable worth by as much as three to federal government, at least two-thirds of the states
one,615 governments have been responsive. Twenty (only eight states clearly fail to address this issue),621
states have raised pay for women, eight states have and almost nine out of ten local governments622 have
enacted laws establishing the principle of com- policies prohibiting sexual harassment.
parable worth for all state employees, and only These policies appear to have had a salutary
five states have failed to undertake some sort of effect. Although sexual harassment in the general
comparable-worth activity.616 population has stayed steady over the years, with
Ten percent of cities and 12 percent of counties nine-tenths of 1 percent of American adults stating
have adopted comparable worth.617 that they have been sexually harassed (almost evenly
Implementing comparable worth is, paradox- divided between men and women),623 sexual harass-
ically, both economical and difficult. In the eight ment charges (which constitute 11 percent of all dis-
states that passed comparable worth laws, the aggre- crimination charges received annually) declined by
gate gender pay gap ranged from 14 to 31 percent 40 percent over fourteen years in all sectors, even
in state agencies, but closing these gaps required as the totality of all charges rose by 16 percent.624 It
relatively modest expenditures that ranged from appears that more public employees than ever—for
1 to 4 percent of total state payrolls. Downsides, example, 93 percent of federal male employees, up
however, were evident: pay compression intensified, from 35 percent fourteen years earlier—understand
with some employees being paid more than their what sexual harassment is.625
own supervisors; state salaries declined relative to
private-sector salaries; and men left their state jobs The Court Weighs In In 1986, the Supreme Court
at greater rates.618 heard its first sexual harassment case, and decided
Today, comparable worth, at least in the states, that the Civil Rights Act of 1964 covered sexual
essentially has been achieved. In all the states, male harassment, in effect declaring it to be a form of dis-
state employees have suffered an “average wage crimination.626 Victims of such discrimination, the
penalty,” and female workers enjoy an “average Court ruled in 1992, could sue their harassers for
wage premium,” relative to the private sector.619 damages.627
In the following year, the justices agreed unani-
The New Meaning of Sex at Work Sexual har- mously that women are different from men. The Court
assment is a comment or act by a co-worker in the held that sexual remarks that may not be offensive
workplace, or a workplace environment, that is inter- to men could offend a “reasonable woman,” thereby
preted by a worker to have sexual overtones, and creating a “hostile environment” in the workplace.
causes discomfort in, or is offensive to, the worker. Such a woman could sue for relief “before the harass-
ing conduct leads to a nervous breakdown.”628
Who Harasses and Where? More than two-fifths In 1998, the Court decided three cases that did
of women and nearly a fifth of men who work in much to clarify the legalities of sexual harassment.
federal agencies report incidents of “unwanted In one, the justices unanimously found that harass-
sexual attention” that occurred over the preceding ment could occur in same-sex situations.629 In two
two years. Perspective, of course, is pertinent, and overlapping cases, they held that even if an employer
it appears that sexual harassment in government was not aware of a supervisor harassing a subordi-
does not attain its levels in the private sector. Nearly nate, the employer was still liable for damages if the
two-thirds of women executives in industry report subordinate had suffered adverse action, such as a
that they have been sexually harassed—a third more demotion, but if that subordinate had ignored valid
than in government. Twenty-two percent of federal complaint procedures, then he or she could expect
workers who have worked outside the government little judicial protection.630
342 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Regardless of how accurate or inaccurate


What a Strange Trip It’s Been: The minorities’ concerns may be, however, their concerns
Unique Experiences of Minority still matter. When government employees think that
and Women Public Administrators they have been treated unfairly they appeal more
The work experiences of minority and female public decisions, file more discrimination and safety com-
administrators differ from those of majority and plaints, and take more sick leave than do workers
male public administrators. who think that they are treated fairly.639 These
and similar behaviors occur in even the Defense
Public Administrators of Color: Mixed Perceptions, Department when its employees perceive unfair-
Mixed Evidence Minority employees in the federal ness.640 The Pentagon, of course, is one of the most
government think that their lot is improving. Asian- “closed-model” public organizations in the real
Americans display the highest job satisfaction; world, and which, in theory, should have employees
whites, blacks, and Hispanics are closely aligned who are indifferent to fairness.
on this dimension.631 The percentage of African- Regrettably, changing minorities’ perceptions
American workers who perceive that “they had been of discrimination for the better is easier said than
denied a job, promotion or pay increase” because done. Even when minority and white employees
of their race declined by three-fourths over fifteen have equal levels of understanding about the dynam-
years, and fell by three-fifths for Hispanic employees ics of their workplaces, minority anxiety does not
over the same period; currently, 9 percent of each lower, nor does job satisfaction rise; by contrast,
group perceives discrimination.632 when whites better understand these dynamics, their
In the states, views may differ. African-American anxiety lessens and their satisfaction increases.641
public administrators report “that they experience
career-impeding supervisory behaviors at a greater Women Public Administrators: Competent and
rate than their white colleagues.”633 Confident. And Better? Men and women are
The evidence supporting these perceptions is becoming more accepting of working for women,
mixed. Federal administrators and professionals but still have some distance to travel. In 1953, 66
of color, for instance, have lower pay grades, “even percent of Americans said that they would rather
after controlling for education, experience, and work for a man, and 5 percent preferred working
other advancement-related factors,” and “receive, for a woman. Today, precisely half as many—33
on average, lower performance ratings”; yet they percent—would prefer a male boss (26 percent of
still have “generally comparable” promotion men and 39 percent of women), and four times
rates.634 We take some umbrage with the final point; as many—20 percent—would rather work for a
as we detail later, their advancement rates clearly female boss (14 percent of men and 25 percent of
have fared a lot better over the years than being just women).642
“generally comparable” with whites.635 Moreover,
64 percent of federal employees state that the “fear Women in Government Governments hire women
of being accused of discrimination . . . prevent[s] in greater proportions than does the private sector,
the firing of poor performers.”636 Yet, it cannot be and the gap is growing over time. The federal gov-
denied that federal managers of color face admin- ernment is a bit of a disappointment in this regard,
istrative challenges that their white counterparts however, where the percentage of female employees
do not: the higher the proportion of “racial/ethnic matches that of the private sector; both percentages
minorities” in an agency’s managerial positions, for round out at 42 percent. By contrast, women consti-
example, the lower all of its employees’ job satis- tute 58 percent each of the employees in both state
faction.637 and local governments, or over a fourth more than
An examination of more than 248,000 per- in federal agencies and private businesses.643
formance appraisals of state employees found “no Women in the federal employ offer “more pos-
support” for the argument that management’s use itive views about their jobs than men.”644 Thirteen
of performance-rating instruments resulted in an percent of female federal employees perceive that
adverse impact on minority employees.638 “they had been denied a job, promotion or pay
Managing Human Capital 343

increase” because of their gender, a decline of more public administrators have personal values that, as
than two-fifths over fifteen years,645 and are only “numerous studies” suggest, share “a significant sim-
marginally more likely than men to think that they ilarity” with those of their male counterparts;655 are
were denied a job benefit due to their gender.646 as committed to the public service as men;656 “have
State governments hire women more rapidly almost identical responsibilities” as men;657 prioritize
than any other employer. Over thirty-seven years, tasks the same as men;658 have political and profes-
the states increased their proportion of female sional characteristics that are “indistinguishable”
employees by nearly 14 percent. For the federal gov- from men’s;659 and, in marked contrast to the generic
ernment, the figure was almost 11 percent; for local finding in the broader literature, which concludes
governments and the private sector, the rounded that women are less organizationally confident than
figure is 9 percent each.647 men, women are “as confident as men in their ability
to supervise their workforce.”660
Managerial Differences between Women and Where male and female public administrators
Men There is now a large body of research that part ways is in the kinds of skills and tasks at which
compares men and women on characteristics that they are more effective. Women public administra-
are pertinent to organizations in all sectors. tors surpass their male counterparts in listening,
Women most surpass men in their service orien- communicating,661 compassion, and their attrac-
tation (of considerable consequence to governments tion to policymaking.662 They are less experienced
and nonprofits) and they fall most behind men in professionally (they are also younger)663 and spend
their emotional self-control and self-confidence.648 less time on “internal management” than men.664
Women remember better than men,649 and co- Women are less effective than men in networking
operate more with colleagues than men, who usually “the external environment” of their agencies,665
prefer to work alone.650 Women’s cooperative char- an activity that produces more positive organiza-
acter works well for organizations because the more tional outcomes for men than for women. By con-
women who are in a group, the more collectively trast, “networking with peers is more beneficial for
intelligent the group is, largely because women are women” as individuals than for men who work in
more socially perceptive than men.651 Female leaders government.666
are more participative, democratic, and egalitarian
than their male counterparts, who are more auto- Female Public Administrators Deliver But here
cratic, directive, and more desirous of personal is the bottom line: despite some evidence that men
power and achievement.652 Women leaders also in the public sector dislike being supervised by
have a more transformative leadership style than do women,667 female public administrators deliver, and
leaders who are men.653 perhaps more so than male ones. The more women
“Benevolent” male managers are viewed more in a nation’s labor force and in its legislature, the
positively by employees than are benevolent female lower the level of corruption; this finding is “large
managers, and benevolent men induce better per- in magnitude, highly significant and robust.”668 The
formance. “Authoritarian” female managers create more women who work directly with citizens in
more hostility among subordinates than do author- an agency, the higher the agency’s performance.669
itarian male managers, and authoritarian women Women public administrators “consistently get
lower performance. Hence, “a useful strategy is to better performance” than men from the boards and
adopt behaviors that are perceived as a positive devi- councils to which they report.670 Women workers
ation from their gender role,” such as men behaving are more likely than men to report problems that
benevolently.654 higher management should know about.671 And
federal female administrators “typically” receive
Gender Similarities and Differences among Public higher performance ratings than men in the same
Administrators Of course, most of these gender dis- grades and in the same agencies.672
tinctions are also found among public administrators, Should we be surprised that, “most interest-
but women and men who work in government also ingly,” government’s top women executives “rate
share a number of the same characteristics. Women themselves as relatively more influential than do
344 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

their male colleagues”?673 Perhaps it is worth noting Remarkably, even when a second set of files demon-
in this regard that a high level of testosterone “does strated clearly superior performance by “affirmative
not predict [a person’s] status within the group.”674 action hires,” they still received lower rankings.680

Public Opinions about Affirmative Action In light


Backlash! of these downsides in affirmative action, white and
Although Americans, regardless of ethnicity, are black opinions about it are somewhat surprising.
growing more accepting of one another,675 there has White support for affirmative action has grown
been some backlash over affirmative action. significantly since the mid-1990s,681 an ironic trend
in light of the proportion of African-Americans who
Affirmative Action’s Odder Outcomes No doubt, think that “Washington should make every effort to
some odd interpretations—odd, at least, by tradi- improve the social and economic position of blacks”
tional criteria—of how affirmative action should declined by roughly half from 1970 to 1992, and has
be applied have fueled some disaffection with it hovered at around two-fifths ever since.682
among whites and minorities alike. Pasadena, for Still, there is controversy. Eleven percent of
instance, grants preferences to Armenian-Americans Americans say that they have been hurt, and only
seeking city contracts; Cincinnati favors citizens of 4 percent say that they have been helped, by affirm-
“Appalachian regional origin”; and Massachusetts ative action.683 White men have long harbored the
protects Portuguese-Americans.676 deepest reservations. (Researchers have found that
Other examples include the apparently unpleas- white males protect their “self-esteem [and] sense
ant couple who sued their local chapter of Mothers of self-competence” by choosing to believe that
Against Drunk Driving on the grounds that they had “affirmative action is a quota-based policy.”684)
been barred from joining due to the chapter’s “per- Although a solid majority of white men currently
sonality bias.” Or the lawyer who won in court the support affirmative action,685 17 percent (compared
right of “nerds” to gain entry to a nightclub.677 The with 9 percent of white women) say that they have
nasty and nerdy are protected classes? been hurt by the policy. On this question, political
White cynicism also plays a part, as exemplified ideology plays little, if any, part, and the responses
by the fifty-three San Francisco police officers who of conservative and liberal white people are virtually
claimed that they were Native Americans and were identical.686
duly hauled before the EEOC, which reclassified
all of them as white. Or Los Angeles, which estab- A Grass-Roots Rebellion? In 1996, California’s
lished “ethnic review committees” that investigated voters initiated the first state-wide rebellion over
“ethnic discrepancies” among teachers.678 Shades of affirmative action, and approved Proposition 209,
the Third Reich, which also investigated ethnic dis- which prohibits the state’s government from granting
crepancies. race- and gender-based preferences in hiring, promot-
ing, contracting, and college admissions. From 1998
Affirmative Action as Stigma? These and similar through 2012, voters in Arizona, Florida, Michigan,
episodes have, in the view of some, delegitimized Nebraska, New Hampshire, Oklahoma, Texas, and
affirmative action. Twenty-seven percent of the public Washington enacted, by solid majorities, clones of
thinks that affirmative action stigmatizes minorities, Proposition 209; in 2008, Colorado’s electorate
and far more African-Americans (37 percent) than defeated that state’s version by a hair’s-breadth’s
whites (26 percent) believe this to be true.679 margin of 1.6 percent.
Two extensive experiments support this view. These referenda have consequences. “Employ-
People were given specially-created files that showed ment among women and minorities dropped sharply”
identical performance levels among women manag- following Proposition 209’s passage, suggesting
ers, and were asked to rank them and award salary “that affirmative action programs in California
increases. When certain managers were identified either had been inefficient . . . or had been effective
as “affirmative action hires,” they were ranked while in place but had failed to create lasting change
as less competent and granted smaller increases. in employers’ prejudicial attitudes.”687 Following
Managing Human Capital 345

the passage of anti-affirmative action referenda, top society has that ability. Justice and life cannot be
state universities in California, Florida, Michigan, reasonably separated, and the people-versus-person
and Texas saw “a significant drop in the enrollment argument contends that they can. “The black person
of black and Hispanic students.”688 who moves up the line thanks to affirmative action
In 2014, in Schuette v. Coalition to Defend may not logically ‘deserve’ the place he gets. But, for
Affirmative Action, the Supreme Court upheld the same reason, the white person who loses that
Michigan’s referendum to ban affirmative action place doesn’t ‘deserve’ it either. . . . The point is that
in college admissions, effectively upholding similar a pure, discrimination-free society is not merely a
bans in the eight other states that had them and hopeless ideal; it is a logical mirage.”690
leaving affirmative action’s future to state voters.
Is Diversity Desirable? A cornerstone of affirm-
ative action, and a gigantic judicial justification of
Is Affirmative Action a Defensible Policy? it (though perhaps slightly less gigantic after the
As the backlash indicates, affirmative action is a con- Court’s 2014 decision in Schuette), is that it pro-
troversial policy. Why? motes diversity on campuses and in workplaces. But
is diversity so desirable that it warrants the billions
Is Affirmative Action Un-American? Affirmative of dollars spent through affirmative action policies
action is sometimes accused of violating the to achieve it?
American tradition of equality of opportunity by Yes. A massive and unique analysis concludes
singling out certain groups for advantageous treat- that groups and governments, schools and cities, col-
ment. But history suggests otherwise. Veterans’ pref- leges, companies, and countries, all perform meas-
erence (which, ironically, seems to result in the feds urably better when they are more diverse, and this
hiring fewer women689), need-based student loans is especially true when it comes to raising organiza-
and scholarships, and small business set-asides, tional performance. “Ability matters. But—here’s the
enacted by Congress twenty-four years before it catch—so does diversity.” In fact, collective diversity
enacted minority business set-asides, are examples of consistently “trumps” individual ability.691 Indeed,
policies that favor certain groups precisely because a group’s intelligence is only moderately associated
those groups are disadvantaged. Whether affirmative with the average intelligence of the people in the
action is a good or bad policy, it remains a wholly group.692 In every sector, the more diverse organi-
American one. zations make more accurate predictions and solve
problems better.693
The People versus Person Problem A deeper cri- In the public sector: greater racial diversity in
tique holds that affirmative action perpetrates its elected bodies associates with less division and con-
own injustices by granting advantages to already- flict;694 greater gender diversity in the top manage-
advantaged individuals in disadvantaged groups ment of municipalities corresponds with “higher
(e.g., wealthy African-Americans), and denying financial performance” (but only if there is also good
advantages to disadvantaged persons who are not cross-functional teamwork);695 agencies in which
in disadvantaged groups (e.g., impoverished white their workers most closely resemble the populations
men). Would affirmative action’s elimination result that their agencies serve are perceived by employ-
in greater justice? ees to be more inclusive working environments and
Our answer is no. The contention that, because experience lower levels of discrimination;696 leads
some undeserving people may benefit from affirm- to more public accountability, greater popular trust
ative action, we should close it down is a classic in government, and readier cooperation and com-
expression of the odd rationale that, because a good pliance with government;697 “on the whole, studies
policy is not perfect, we should discard that policy show” that greater diversity in governments “leads to
because it is merely good. . . . policy outcomes that benefit represented groups,”
Worse, the argument also assumes that we have whether female, male, black, brown, or white;698 in
a perfect method for fairly assessing and ranking the fact, “the mere existence of a passively represented
relative merit of every single person in society. No bureaucracy can itself improve outcomes.”699
346 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Those states with anti-discrimination laws for in those agencies with greater racial diversity than
gays are far more likely to attract innovative com- the norm.708 Somewhat surprisingly, older public
panies and high-tech firms than are states without administrators manage diversity more skillfully than
them.700 “The leading indicator of a metropolitan younger ones.709
area’s high-technology success is a large gay popu-
lation.”701
Similar success is found in the private sector, The Effects of the Efforts
with its uniquely clear metrics of performance: the What has affirmative action, a public policy for six
more racially and gender-diverse businesses have decades, achieved?
significantly, even dramatically, more market share, “The majority of the empirical research demon-
customers, sales, and profits.702 strates the positive impact” of affirmative action “on
Diversity also correlates, strongly and positively, educational policies and employment opportunities
with personal growth. The more diverse the univer- for minorities and women.” Affirmative action “is
sity, the more likely that there will be “widespread decidedly less significant when it comes to other
beneficial effects,” including superior retention rates, major goals such as hiring, equal pay, and the elimi-
grades, and self-confidence among students “irre- nation of discrimination once minorities and women
spective of race.”703 are hired.”710
So, yes, diverse workplaces and campuses are Its impact has been especially salubrious in the
desirable, with, as we explain next, a qualification. public and nonprofit sectors.

Diversity Management: The Crucial Component The Federal Record Washington has made signif-
Diversity’s benefits do not appear automatically. icant progress in providing equal opportunity to its
Rather, its benefits can be reaped only when diversity employees. An analysis of more than 40,000 recom-
is managed well. mendations made by the Government Accountability
Diversity improves collective performance: only Office over twenty-six years found that 87 percent
when “identity diversity,” such as gender or ethni- of those recommendations that concerned affirma-
city, is “linked with cognitive diversity,” which is a tive action were implemented by the agencies, or six
product of experience and training; only when diver- points higher than the average rate of 81 percent.711
sity is “relevant” (“we cannot expect that adding a An analysis of Senate-confirmed top federal execu-
poet to a medical research team would enable them tives in more than eighty positions over forty-two
to find a cure for the common cold”); only when the years found that President Barack Obama, for
people in diverse groups “get along” (if they do not, the first time in history, had appointed minorities
then “the cognitive differences between them may be and women to more than half (nearly 54 percent)
little more than disconnected silos of ideas”);704 and of those posts; the next highest was less than 38
only when people participate equally in a group’s percent, under President Bill Clinton.712
conversations.705 “Well-managed identity diversity
does produce benefits.”706 Federal Employees of Color More than 34 percent
American governments seem to manage diver- of all federal civilian, non-postal employees are
sity reasonably well. Federal employees’ complaints minorities.713
of discrimination have declined over time, even as In 1980, African-Americans comprised 15
complaints from all other employment categories percent of all federal employees and 5 percent of
have, on average, risen substantially.707 An anal- senior and executive positions; by 2013, these per-
ysis of a “very large sample of federal employees” centages were 18 and 11 percent, respectively.
in sixty-seven agencies found that those workers In 1980, 4 percent of all federal civilian employ-
in agencies with high levels of racial diversity per- ees were Latinas and Latinos, and fewer than fifty
ceived “lower organizational effectiveness” in their Hispanics were in senior and executive positions;
agencies. “But strikingly, where they perceive that by 2013, 8 percent of all federal employees were
diversity is effectively managed,” they also think Hispanic, and 4 percent of senior and executive
that their agencies’ “effectiveness is higher,” even administrators were Hispanic.
Managing Human Capital 347

Federal Women Employees Women have made and administrators; by 2013, these percentages were
steady progress in the federal employ. In 1980, 11 and 6 percent, respectively. In many state govern-
women comprised 45 percent of all federal employ- ments, “Latinos are typically underrepresented,”721
ees and 4 percent of senior and executive positions; although Hispanics have doubled, at a minimum,
by 2013, these percentages were nearly 44 and 34 their representation in every occupational category
percent, respectively. in state governments. In 1964, less than 1 percent
Education may account for the dramatic of Latinas and Latinos were state agency heads; by
increase of women at the top. Forty-six percent 2008, nearly 2 percent were.722
of female federal administrators have a bachelor’s At the local level, there is less progress. More
degree or higher, compared with 38 percent eight- than 93 percent of chief administrative officers, city
een years earlier. Male federal administrators with a and county managers, are whites; less than 3 percent
baccalaureate degree actually slipped over the same each are African-American or Hispanic.723
period, from 56 to 54 percent.714
These educational trends, among other factors, State and Local Women Employees In 1980,
are reflected in more equitable pay. Over two decades, women comprised 41 percent of all state and local
the federal government’s overall gender pay gap employees (again excluding educators) and 23 percent
shrank from women earning 30 percent, on average, of local officials and administrators; by 2013, these
less than men to 13 percent less, and, among senior percentages were 46 and 42 percent, respectively.
executives, just 1 percent less. Nationwide, women In state governments, “women are generally
earned, on average, 19 percent less.715 Women in the overrepresented” relative to the civilian labor force
Senior Executive Service earn salaries that are nearly within their states,724 and have increased their
$500 higher, on average, than their male counter- representation in every occupational category in
parts.716 state governments.725 Twenty-nine percent of state
With fairer salaries has come greater respect: department heads are women, up from just 2 percent
Over sixteen years, the proportion of women federal in 1964,726 and women state executives command
employees who agreed that “women and men are salaries that are “similar” to those of men.727
respected equally” at work grew by a fourth, and Local governments also have made impres-
now stands at two-fifths.717 sive strides: “Of the three levels of government, the
local level has apparently had the greatest progress
The Grass-Roots’ Record State and local jurisdic- toward gender equity.”728
tions have made substantial advances in developing Unfortunately, this is much less the case in local
fairer places to work, but the advances are not con- executive suites. Despite the fact that nearly three-
sistent for all groups. fifths of master of public administration degrees
(a credential that many cities and counties require
State and Local Employees of Color Thirty-five for their top executives—more than two-fifths of
percent of all full-time state and local government these executives have the degree729) are awarded
employees (excluding educators) are minorities.718 to women, only 20 percent of city and county chief
In 1980, African-Americans comprised 16 appointed executives are women, up from 13 percent
percent of all state and local employees and 6 thirty-two years earlier.730
percent of officials and administrators, the top-paid
job category; by 2013, these percentages were 19 Why the Lag in Local Governments? The chief
and more than 13 percent, respectively. Black people appointed executives of general-purpose local gov-
have made progress in all occupational categories ernments are at least twice as white and male as
over thirty-three years, and, in many state govern- are their counterparts in the federal and state gov-
ments, African-Americans “are overrepresented.”719 ernments. This seems to be much less the case with
In 1964, 1 percent of state agency heads were black; special-purpose local governments; more than two
by 2008, 10 percent were.720 decades ago, a fourth of the executive directors of
In 1980, Hispanics comprised 4 percent of all public authorities, for example, were women,731 and
state and local employees and 2 percent of officials their representation is likely higher today.
348 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

The sad situation at the top of municipal and nonprofit’s percentage of minority staffers, the larger
county bureaucracies is less a function of curmudg- its assets.743
eonly top local executives (who, recall, were early Nonprofit CEOs view fundraising as crucial to
and unappreciated champions of affirmative action) their organizations’ success (and, often, survival), so
and more a reflection of the city council members it is heartening to learn that “race is generally not
and county commissioners who appoint them. significant (either black or other)” as a variable in
determining the compensation of chief development
A Palpably Progressive Public Sector Both min- officers, professional fundraisers, staffers, and con-
orities and women find the public sector welcom- sultants.744
ing, entering it at a more rapid rate than the private Although it has made progress, the independ-
sector,732 and also are more likely than whites ent sector in general has not extended workplace
and men to recommend government as a place to opportunities to people of color to the degree that
work.733 the public sector has.
Women who work in governments are “decreas-
ing their levels of occupational segregation in civil Independent Women Employees This is far from
service employment and moving toward achieving a the case for women. Beginning in the early 1980s,
representative bureaucracy. . .. Women appear to be “the entire foundation field became overwhelm-
most successful, both financially and career-wise, in ingly  ‘female,’”745 and now fully three-quarters of
historically male-dominated fields.”734 all public-serving nonprofit full-time employees,
A review of analyses of the pay gap in federal, and 90 percent of nonprofit administrators, are
state, and local governments found a “consensus” women.746
among them to the effect that “the wage gap between Forty-three percent of nonprofit organizations’
white males and both minorities and women per- board members are women747 (compared with less
sists, although it is lower in the public sector than in than 17 percent on the boards of Fortune 500 com-
the private sector.”735 panies748) and 52 percent of their CEOs are white
At the federal level, women comprise 34 percent women.749 Women are more likely to be board chairs
of the SES, but they account for less than 15 percent or CEOs when the association has a smaller budget,
of executives in the private sector.736 “Federal agen- is relatively new, is in a city other than Washington,
cies are on a par, or even ahead, of their corporate DC, and has a large percentage of women serving on
counterparts in the initiation of new recruitment, its board.750
training, and development” of members of disad- Despite their takeover of the independent sector,
vantaged groups.737 issues for women persist. Women CEOs in the inde-
“In the aggregate, state and local governments pendent sector earn from 6 to 23 percent less than
are doing considerably better than the private sector their male counterparts, although this is real pro-
in living up to the challenge of attaining sexual and gress from fifteen years earlier, when the gap was 21
racial-ethnic employment equity,” establishing a to 47 percent less.751
record that is “quite impressive.”738 This disparity seeps down through the non-
profit organization. A national study of professional
The Third Sector Record In terms of providing fair fundraisers found “a gender-pay gap, even after
workplaces, the independent sector is best described controlling for all factors traditionally associated
as a strangely mixed bag. with pay differentials between males and females,”
notably organizational size and location, and profes-
Independent Employees of Color Nearly 25 sional experience and education. Chief development
percent of all public-serving nonprofit, full-time officers, staffers, and even consultants who were
employees are people of color,739 a doubling from women had “significantly” lower compensation
thirty-one years earlier. Thirteen percent of their than their male counterparts.752 On average, female
board members (a tripling over twenty-five years),740 fundraisers earn salaries that are a fourth lower
and 8 percent of their CEOs741 (a quadrupling over than male fundraisers, and hold a larger number of
the same period742) are minorities. The larger the lower-paying jobs than men. Moreover, the gender
Managing Human Capital 349

wage gap for these employees almost doubled over also have virtually identical levels of confidence in
seventeen years.753 reaching their goals—27 percent of women and 28
These inequities are self-defeating for not percent of men), but, after two years, just 16 percent
only the usual reasons, but seem particularly peril- of women, versus 34 percent of men, hope for the
ous for nonprofits when we realize that, over four executive suites.759
decades, women, both single and married, have These perceptions are based on fact. Women’s
gained “greater influence over charitable decision odds of advancement at every level in corporate
making.”754 America are 15 percent lower, on average, than are
In sum, the third sector seems to be on a rough those of men (the higher one rises, the lower the pos-
par with the public one in terms of advancing sibility of her advancement further gets), despite the
women up the executive ladder (with the very large fact that female senior managers are 20 percent less
exception of city and county governments, which likely than men to leave the company. And just 28
fall well behind nonprofits), but it lags far behind percent of senior-level women are “happy with their
governments in closing the gender wage gap. careers,” compared with 40 percent of their male
counterparts.760
A Word on Perspective For purposes of placing all Why is this? To a statistically significant degree,
this in perspective, let us now consider the situation women corporate managers “are viewed with sus-
of minorities and women in the private sector. picion and . . . their commitment and competence
The proportion of CEOs of the Fortune 500 are over-tested” when decisions on advancements
companies who are minorities is less than 5 percent are being made.761 Indeed. Fifty-nine percent of men
(less than 1 percent are African-American).755 Recall received “critical feedback” in their corporate per-
that their nearest public and nonprofit counterparts formance reviews, but 88 percent of women received
surpass or match this figure: over a sixth of the such criticism, and, of the critical reviews received
federal SES, a tenth of state agency heads, 5 percent by men, just a bit more than 2 percent were crit-
of city managers (which, at least, equals the percent- icized for personality traits (e.g., “bossy,” “abra-
age of major corporate CEOs), and 8 percent of non- sive”), but a remarkable 76 percent of the women
profit CEOs are executives of color. were.762 Women in business are more likely than
Similarly, just 4 percent of Fortune 500 CEOs men to experience retaliation when reporting mis-
are women,756 compared (as we also noted earlier) conduct.763
with over a third of federal SES members, almost a Women seem to have gotten the message.
third of state department heads, nearly a fifth of city Corporate women managers, in contrast to their
managers, and more than half of nonprofit CEOs. counterparts in government (who, recall, equal
Why are so few corporate CEOs women? Let us men in their confidence to supervise and believe
count the ways. that they wield greater influence than men), are less
First, women are put off by what they per- confrontational than men and prefer avoidance to
ceive to be overly cutthroat organizations, usually argument.764 Not surprising, when we realize that
corporations. “Competitive workplaces” in the 66 percent of male workers in business say that they
private sector “significantly decrease the propensity can question management without fear, compared
of women to apply for a job compared to that of with just 56 percent of female employees.765
men.”757 And, once ambitious women are hired in Compared with the private sector, then, minor-
the private sector, they soon become disillusioned, ities and women in the public and nonprofit sectors
perhaps because they have fewer mentors: “only not only are doing good, but doing well.
10 percent of senior-level women report that four
or more executives have helped them advance com-
pared to 17 percent of senior-level men.”758 A Demographic Solution?
Whatever the reason, women’s disillusionment Is affirmative action responsible for the growing
is real. Forty-three percent of women starting a cor- diversity of American organizations? Possibly not.
porate job aspire to be top executives, compared “Only a small fraction of the public”—a modest
with 34 percent of men (entering women and men 16 percent—“reports having been directly affected
350 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

by affirmative action programs,” whether for good Careers (Washington, DC: Authors, 1998). Figure
or ill.766 is for 1998.
Although it seems irrefutable that affirmative 6. Paul C. Light, The New Public Service
action has played a positive role in expanding diver- (Washington, DC: Brookings, 1999), pp. 89–90.
sity, demographic trends may be the core cause. 7. Gregory B. Lewis and Sue A. Frank, “Who
Most broadly, the population of the United States Wants to Work for the Government?” Public
will be a “majority minority” nation by 2044, when Administration Review 62 (July/August 2002),
white people will make up slightly less than half of pp. 395–344. Figures are for 1998.
the population.767 8. Council for Excellence in Government and Gallup
Organization, Within Reach . . . But Out of
This trend will have an impact on the labor
Synch: The Possibilities and Challenges of Shaping
force. In 1950, white men comprised 70 percent of
Tomorrow’s Government Workforce (Washington,
the civilian workforce.768 Since then, their share has
DC: Authors, 2007), pp. 6, 8. Data are for 2006.
slipped to 43 percent, and likely will slide further.769
9. Partnership for Public Service, Innovation
The drainage of white males from the labor pool (Washington, DC: Author, 2015), pp. 2–3.
reflects America’s dwindling supply of young white 10. Partnership for Public Service and National
men,770 and minorities and women are replacing Association of Colleges and Employers, College
them in jobs they once held. Students Are Attracted to Federal Service, but
Between 1980 and 2012, the proportion of Agencies Need to Capitalize on Their Interest,
workers in the civilian labor force who were not p. 2. Figure is for 2013.
white expanded from 13 percent to 20 percent.771 11. National Association of Schools of Public Affairs
The largest future increases likely will be among and Administration, Nonprofit Survey Summary
Asian-Americans and Hispanics.772 (Washington, DC: Author, 2008). Figure is for
In 1950, women constituted 30 percent of the 2008.
civilian labor force.773 Today, women constitute 12. National Association of Schools of Public Affairs
47 percent of the labor force, a proportion that is and Administration. Student Survey (Washington,
expected to remain steady for the ensuing decade.774 DC: Author, 2008). Figure is for 2008.
Demographics dictate diversity. 13. As derived from data in Roseanne M. Mirabella,
Nonprofit Management Education (Boston: Seton
Hall University, 2012). Figure is for 2011.
14. Kelly LeRoux and Mary K. Feeney, “Factors
NOTES Attracting Individuals to Nonprofit Management
1. Gerald Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private over Public and Private Sector Management,”
and Public Sector Workers (Washington, DC: Nonprofit Management & Leadership 24 (Fall
U.S. Congressional Research Service, 2014), 2013), pp. 43–62. The quotation is on p. 43.
p. 2. 15. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Evolution
2. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of of Federal White-Collar Pay (Washington, DC:
the United States, 2016, 4th ed. (Bethesda, MD: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2010).
Author, 2016), Table 651. Figure is for 2014. 16. Frederick C. Mosher, Democracy and the Public
3. Partnership for Public Service and National Service, 2nd ed. (New York: Oxford University
Association of Colleges and Employers, College Press, 1982), p. 57.
Students Are Attracted to Federal Service, but 17. Sidney H. Aronson, Status and Kinship in the
Agencies Need to Capitalize on Their Interest Higher Civil Service (Cambridge: Harvard
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2014), p. 2. Figures University Press, 1964), p. 61.
are for 2013. 18. Erik W. Austin, Political Facts of the United States
4. Emerging Local Government Leaders, Push/Pull: Since 1789 (New York: Oxford University Press,
Changing Jurisdictions (Washington, DC: Author, 1986), pp. 370–376, 328. In 1828, voting hit 52
2015). Figures are for 2015. percent.
5. National Association of Schools of Public Affairs 19. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service,
and Administration and George Washington pp.  66–72, and Aronson, Status and Kinship in
University, Attitudes Toward Public Service the Higher Civil Service, p. 61.
Managing Human Capital 351

20. The quotations are cited in Ann Gerhart, “A New Administration Review 61 (September/October
Deal,” Washington Post (March 28, 2005). 2001), pp. 585–597. The datum is on p. 592.
21. Kenneth D. Ackerman, Dark Horse—The Surprise 38. James Read, “Looking for Guidance,” Issues of
Election and Political Murder of James A. Garfield Merit (Spring 2014), pp. 2–3.
(New York: Carroll and Graf, 2003), p. 298. 39. Collleen A. Woodard, “Merit by Any Other
22. Stahl, Public Personnel Administration, p. 42. Name—Reframing the Civil Service First
23. U.S. Civil Service Commission, Twenty-second Principle,” Public Administration Review 65
Report (Washington, DC: U.S. Government (January/February 2005), pp. 100–118. The quo-
Printing Office, 1905), quoted in Mosher, tation is on p. 110.
Democracy and the Public Service, p. 69. 40. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service,
24. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service, p. 66. pp. 217–218.
25. James S. Bowman and Jonathan P. West, “State 41. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of Labor
Government ‘Little Hatch Acts’ in an Era of Civil Statistics, Occupational Employment Statistics
Service Reform,” Review of Public Personnel (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publish-
Administration 29 (March 2009), pp. 20–40. ing  Office, 2016), Tables 11-3111, 11-3121,
Figure (p. 22) is for 2007. 11-3131, 13-1071, 13-1075. Figures are for
26. The case is Heffernan v. City of Paterson. 2015, and include 1,180 training and devel-
27. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service, p. 68. opment managers in colleges, universities, and
28. Benjamin F. Welton, “The Problems of Securing professional schools, almost all of which are pub-
Efficiency in Municipal Labor,” Annals of the licly supported. Public employee percentages are
American Academy of Political and Social Science drawn from the totals of those “industries with
XLI (May 1912), pp. 103–114. The quotation is the highest concentration of employment in this
on p. 103. occupation.”
29. Daniel W. Williams, “Measuring Government in 42. Hays and Kearney, “Anticipated Changes in
the Early Twentieth Century,” Public Adminis- Human Resource Management.”
tration Review 63 (November/December 2003), 43. Michael A. Miller, “The Public/Private Pay
pp. 643–659. The quotations are on p. 649. Debate: What Do the Data Show?” Monthly
30. Norma M. Riccucci and Katherine C. Naff, Labor Review 119 (May 1996), pp. 18–29. Refers
Personnel Management in Government: Politics to state and local personnel specialists only. The
and Processes, 6th ed. (Boca Raton, FL: CRC other profession is budgeters.
Press, 2008), p. 175. 44. Myron D. Fottler and Norman A. Townsend,
31. “Inside the Year Book,” Municipal Year Book, “Characteristics of Public and Private Personnel
2006 (Washington, DC: International City/ Directors,” Public Personnel Management 6 (July
County Management Association, 2006), p. x. 1977), pp. 250–258.
32. O. Glenn Stahl, Public Personnel Administration, 45. Hays and Kearney, “Anticipated Changes in
8th ed. (New York: Harper & Row, 1983), p. 42. Human Resource Management,” p. 593. Data are
33. Anirudh V. S. Ruhil and Pedro J. Camoes, for 1998.
“What Lies Beneath: The Political Roots of State 46. Jory Heckman, “IT, HR Worker Satisfaction
Merit Systems,” Journal of Public Administra- Foretells Overall Agency Ratings,” Federalnews
tion Research and Theory 13 (January 2003), radio.com (July 18, 2016). HR workers surpassed
pp. 27–42. The figures are on p. 30. IT workers on this measure.
34. Riccucci and Naff, Personnel Management in 47. Council for Excellence in Government, Gallup,
Government, p. 34. and Accenture, The Appeal of Public Service,
35. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service, p. 103. p. 4. Figure is for 2008, and is reasonably con-
36. Committee on Administrative Management, sistent over time. See Council for Excellence in
Personnel Administration in the Federal Service Government and Peter D. Hart Research, Calling
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Young People to Government Service, p. 7.
Office, 1937), pp. 7–8. 48. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016
37. Steven W. Hays and Richard C. Kearney, Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey (Washington,
“Anticipated Changes in Human Resource DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016),
Management: Views from the Field,” Public Q. 21.
352 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

49. HCMG, Cornerstone, and WBR Digital, Building More  They Remain the Same,” Paper presented
a Culture of Excellence and Engagement at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political
(Washington, DC: Authors, 2015). Science Association (Chicago, 2003). Figure is for
50. Senior Executives Association, Recruiting 2000–2001.
Qualified Senior Leadership: How Are We Doing? 63. Siegrun Fox Freyss, “Continuity and Change in
(Washington, DC: Author, 2015), p. 9. Figures are Local Personnel Policies and Practices,” Municipal
for 2015. Year Book, 1996 (Washington, DC: International
51. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, as cited in City/County Management Association, 1996),
Paul C. Light, “To Restore and Renew: Now Is pp. 11–17.
the Time to Rebuild the Federal Public Service” 64. Constance Horner, director, OPM, as quoted in
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 2001). Judith Havemann, “New Federal Job Exams Set
52. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Impact for June,” Washington Post (April 22, 1990).
of Recruitment Strategy on Fair and Open 65. Joe Davidson, “Federal Hiring Remains a Work in
Competition for Federal Jobs (Washington, DC: Progress after Many Fixes,” Washingtonpost.com
U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), p. 12. (October 4, 2016). Figure is for 2008–2016.
Figure is for 2011. 66. Princeton Survey Research Associates, Final
53. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Help Topline Report: Health of the Nonprofit, For-
Wanted (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Profit, and Public Service Sectors (Princeton, NJ:
Printing Office, 2003), p. 9. Author, 2002), p. 13. Figures are for 2000–2001.
54. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Supervisory 67. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Evolving
Job Announcements: Truth in Advertising,” Issues Workforce Demographics: Federal Agency Action
of Merit (April 2010), pp. 1, 7. The quotation is and Reaction (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
on p. 1. Figure is for 2009. Printing Office, 1993), p. 29.
55. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Taking 68. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Accom-
Aim at Federal Hiring,” Issues of Merit (July plishing Our Mission: Results of the Merit
2008), p. 3. Principles Survey 2005 (Washington, DC: U.S.
56. Eric Katz, “Agencies Show Little Progress in Government Printing Office, 2007), p. 14. Figure,
Improving Federal Hiring Process,” Govexec.com 38 percent, is for 2005.
(January 2, 2015). 69. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
57. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Impact Workforce: OPM and Agencies Need to
of Recruitment Strategy on Fair and Open Strengthen Efforts to Identify and Close Mission-
Competition for Federal Jobs, pp. 16, 34. Figures Critical Skills Gaps, GAO-15-223 (Washington,
are for 2011. DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015),
58. T. Rees Shapiro, “Peace Corps Applications Highlights page.
Surge Amid Recent Reforms,” Washington Post 70. Partnership for Public Service, Leaving Talent
(October 8, 2014). Figure is for 2013–2014. on the Table: The Need to Capitalize on High
59. Center for State & Local Government Excellence, Performing Student Interns (Washington, DC:
State and Local Government Workforce: 2015 Author, 2009), Executive Summary page. Figures
Trends (Washington, DC: Author, 2015), pp. 6, 4. are for 2007.
60. Sally Coleman Selden, Human Capital: Tools and 71. Federalnewsradio.com, WFED Federal CHCO
Strategies for the Public Sector (Washington, DC: Survey 2016 (Washington, DC: Author, 2016),
CQ Press, 2009), p. 35. p. 13.
61. Sally Coleman Selden, Patricia Wallace Ingraham, 72. As derived from data in U.S. Government
and Willow Jacobson, “Human Resource Accountability Office, Federal Hiring: OPM
Practices in State Government: Findings from a Needs to Improve Management and Oversight
National Survey,” Public Administration Review of Hiring Authorities, GAO-16-521 (Washington,
61 (September/October 2001), pp. 598–607. DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016), p.
Figures, pp. 600–601, are for 1998. 9. Figure is for 2014.
62. Richard C. Elling, Lyke Thompson, and Valerie 73. Marilyn Mackes, National Association of Colleges
Monet, “The Problematic World of State and Employers, “Keys to Finding Quality Entry-
Management: The More Things Change the Level Employees,” Paper presented to the National
Managing Human Capital 353

Academy of Public Administration (Washington, of Delegated Examining Units: Hiring New


DC, 2001). Figure, 37 percent, is for 2001. Employees in a Decentralized Civil Service
74. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Appointment Authorities: Cutting Through the Office, 1999), p. 5.
Confusion (Washington, DC: U.S Government 91. Partnership for Public Service, Asking the
Printing Office, 2008), p. i. Figure is for 2005. Wrong Questions: A Look at How the Federal
75. As derived from data in U.S. Government Government Assesses and Selects Its Workforce
Accountability Office, Federal Hiring: OPM (Washington, DC: Author, 2004), p. 1.
Needs to Improve Management and Oversight of 92. Mitchell Hoffman, Lisa B. Kahn, and Danielle Li,
Hiring Authorities, p. 9. Figures are for 2014. Discretion in Hiring (Cambridge, MA: National
76. Nicole Ogrysko, “New Proposals Needed to Break Bureau of Economic Research, 2015), p. 1.
Gov’t Hiring Status Quo, Senate, Agencies, Say,” 93. As derived from data in U.S. Government
Federalnewsradio.com (September 29, 2016). Accountability Office, Federal Hiring: OPM
Figure is for 2014. Needs to Improve Management and Oversight of
77. “The Memo That Roared,” Washington Post Hiring Authorities, p. 9.
(June 19, 2009). 94. Shapiro, “Peace Corps Applications Surge Amid
78. Princeton Survey Research Associates, Final Recent Reforms.” Figure is for 2013–2014.
Topline Report, p. 13. Figures are for 2000–2001. 95. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal
79. National Commission on the Public Service, Appointment Authorities, p. 29. Figures are for
Leadership for America: Rebuilding the Public 2005.
Service (Washington, DC: Author, 1989), p. 28. 96. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Attracting
80. Princeton Survey Research Associates, Final the Next Generation, pp. 6, 8, 17, 20. Figures are
Topline Report, p. 13. Figures are for 2000–2001. for 2005.
81. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Attracting 97. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal
the Next Generation, p. 49. Figure is for 2005. Government: A Model Employer or a Work
82. Senior Executives Association, Recruiting in Progress? Perspectives from 25 Years of the
Qualified Senior Leadership, p. 9. Figures are for Merit Principles Survey (Washington, DC: U.S.
2015. Government Printing Office, 2008), p. 9.
83. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Taking 98. Lisa Rein, “Millennials Exit the Federal Work-
Aim at Federal Hiring,” p. 2. force as Government Jobs Lose Their Allure,”
84. U.S. General Accounting Office, Human Capital: Washingtonpost.com (December 15, 2014).
Opportunities to Improve Executive Agencies’ Figures are for 1983–2014.
Hiring Processes, p. 3. 99. As derived from data in Partnership for Public
85. Davidson, “Federal Hiring Remains a Work in Service and Booz Allen Hamilton, Unrealized
Progress after Many Fixes.” Figure is for 2015. Vision: Reimagining the Senior Executive Service
86. Frank L. Schmidt, John E. Hunter, Alice  N. (Washington. DC, and Herndon, VA: Authors,
Outerbridge, and M. H. Trattner, “The Econ- 2009), p. 7. Figures are for 2009.
omic Impact of Job Selection Methods on 100. As derived from data in Partnership for Public Service
Size, Productivity and Payroll Costs of the and Booz Allen Hamilton, Unrealized Vision, p. 7.
Federal Work Force: An Empirically Based 101. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Millennials:
Demonstration,”Personnel Psychology 39 (Spring Finding Opportunity in Federal Service
1986), pp. 1–30. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
87. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Fair Office, 2014). Figure, 3.8 years, is for 2013.
and Equitable Treatment: Progress Made and 102. Rein, “Millennials Exit the Federal Workforce as
Challenges Remaining (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Jobs Lose Their Allure.” Figure is for
Government Printing Office, 2009), p. 11. 2013.
88. Riccuci and Naff, Personnel Management in 103. Andrea Zappone and Matthew Sigafoose, “Enga-
Government, p. 268. Figures are for 1960–1980. ging the Federal Workforce: How to Do It &
89. The 1981 decision was actually a consent decree Prove It,” OPM.gov (February 23, 2015).
that OPM signed in the case, Luevano v. Campbell. 104. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, In Search
90. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Role of Highly Skilled Workers, p. 33. Figures are for
354 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

2006, and pertain to those hired for grades 12–15 Resource Practices in State Government,” p. 600.
in the General Schedule. Figures are for 1998.
105. Larry M. Lane and James E. Wolf, The Human 116. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Resource Crisis in the Public Sector: Rebuilding Relations, State Laws Governing Local Gov-
the Capacity to Govern (New York: Quorum ernment Structure and Administration, M-186
Books, 1990). (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
106. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal Re- Office, 1993), p. 49. Figure is for 1990.
cruiting: Comparison of Applicants Who Accepted 117. N. Joseph Cayer, “Local Government Person-
or Declined Federal Job Offers, GAO/GGD- nel  Structure and Policies,” Municipal Year
92-61BR (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Book, 1991 (Washington, DC: International City/
Printing Office, 1993), p. 3. County Management Association, 1991), pp. 3–13.
107. James B. Conant and Dennis L. Dresang, 118. U.S. General Accounting Office, Posthearing
“Retaining and Recruiting Career Professionals,” Questions Related to Pay for Performance, p. 2.
Revitalizing State and Local Public Service: Per- 119. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Performance
formance, Accountability, and Citizen Confidence, Appraisal Systems: Quality vs. Quantity,” Issues of
Frank D. Thompson, ed. (San Francisco: Jossey- Merit (September 2006), p. 1. Figure is for 2005.
Bass, 1993), pp. 104–140. The quotation is on 120. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
p. 127. Workforce: Distribution of Performance Ratings
108. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems Across the Federal Government, 2013, GAO-
Protection Board, In Search of Highly Skilled 16-520R (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Workers: A Study on the Hiring of Upper Level Publishing Office, 2016), p. 6.
Employees from Outside the Federal Government 121. Ibid.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 122. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, The Fact
Office, 2008), p. 13. Figure is for 2006. Book, 1999: Federal Civilian Workforce Statistics
109. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Protection Board, Attracting the Next Generation, Office, 1999), p. 71.
p. 20. Figure is for 2006. 123. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Results-
110. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Who Oriented Management: OPM Needs to Do More
Gets Selected for Federal Jobs?” Issues of Merit to Ensure Meaningful Distinctions Are Made in
(August 2001), pp. 1–3. Figure is for 1998–2001. SES Ratings and Performance Awards, GAO-
111. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems 15-189 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Protection Board, In Search of Highly Skilled Publishing Office, 2015) Highlights page. Figure
Workers, p. 29, and Attracting the Next Gen- is for 2010–2013.
eration: A Look at Federal Entry-Level New Hires 124. Nicole Ogrysko, “Half of Senior Executives
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Earned Highest Possible Performance Rating
Office, 2008), p. 35. In 2006, 47 percent, a plu- in 2015,” Federalnewsradio.com (November 2,
rality, of upper-level hires and 97 percent of entry- 2016).
level ones cited job security as their leading reason 125. Miller, “The Public/Private Pay Debate,” p. 19.
for joining the federal service. 126. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Comparing
112. Xuhong Su and Barry Bozeman, “Dynamics of the Compensation of Federal and Private-Sector
Sector Switching: Hazard Models Predicting Employees, 2011 to 2015 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Changes from Private Sector Jobs to Public and Government Publishing Office, 2017).
Nonprofit Sector Jobs,” Public Administration 127. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Why Are
Review 69 (November/December 2009), pp. Employees Leaving the Federal Government?
1106–1114. Results of an Exit Survey (Washington, DC: U.S.
113. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, In Search Government Printing Office, 1990).
of  Highly Skilled Workers, p. 13. Figure is for 128. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, “Federal
2006. Government,” Career Guide to Industries, 2010-
114. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Attracting 2011 Edition (Washington, DC: U.S Government
the Next Generation, p. 20. Figure is for 2006. Printing Office, 2011).
115. Selden, Ingraham, and Jacobson, “Human 129. Kenneth L. Yoder, “Federal Employee Pay
Managing Human Capital 355

Comparability,” Armed Forces Comptroller 144. As derived from data in Selden, Human Capital,
(March 22, 2002), http://www.allbusiness.com. p. 89. Data are for 2003–2006.
130. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 145. Charles S. Clark “More Federal Employees View
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results, Lack of Training as Discrimination,” Government
Q. 70. Figure is for 2012–2016. Executive (March 14, 2014).
131. Jessica Mangskau and Steve Ander, “U.S. Federal 146. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Employment Related to Higher Financial Well- Workforce: Preliminary Observations on Strength-
Being,” Gallup (March 5, 2015). ening Employee Engagement During Challenging
132. National Commission on the Public Service, Times, GAO-15-529T (Washington, DC: U.S.
Urgent Business for America: Revitalizing  the Government Publishing Office, 2015), p. 16.
Federal Government for the 21st Century 147. Kettl, Reinventing Government? p. 20. Figure is
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing for 1992.
Office, 1993), pp. 23–24. 148. U.S. General Accounting Office, Training Budgets:
133. Ken McDonnell, “Benefit Cost Comparisons Agency Budget Reductions in Response to the
between State and Local Governments and Balanced Budget Act, GAO-GGD-86-98BR
Private-Sector Employers,” EBRI Notes 29 (June (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
2008), pp. 2–6. Figures are for 2007. Office, 1986), p. 2.
134. Jared J. Llorens, “Uncovering the Determinants of 149. Charles S. Clark, “DHS Reports Spending Only 1
Competitive State Government Wages,” Review Percent of Its $1.4B Training Budget,” Govexec.
of Public Personnel Administration 28 (December com (January 27, 2016). Figures are for FY 2014.
2008), pp. 308–326. The quotations are on 150. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Accom-
p. 308. plishing Our Mission, p. 16. Figures are for 1992–
135. Keith A. Bender and John S. Heywood, Out of 2005.
Balance? Comparing Public and Private Sector 151. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016
Compensation over 20 Years (Washington, DC: Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results, Q. 68.
Center for State & Local Government Excellence 152. Partnership for Public Service, Improving the
and National Institute on Retirement Security, Employee Experience (Washington, DC: Author,
2010), p. 16. Data are for 2008. 2015), p. 7. Figure is for 2014.
136. As derived from data in Miller, “The Public/ 153. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior
Private Pay Debate,” pp. 23, 22. Executive Service Survey Results for Fiscal Year
137. Bender and Heywood, Out of Balance? pp. 9–14. 2011 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
138. Patrick L. Owens, Jr., “One More Reason Not Office, 2012), p. 133.
to Cut Your Training Budget: The Relationship 154. Partnership for Public Service, Improving Lead-
Between Training and Organizational Outcomes,” ership: Perspectives from the Senior Executive
Public Personnel Management 35 (Summer 2006), Service (Washington, DC: Author, 2015), p. 4.
pp. 163–172. Data are for 2013 and 2014.
139. National Commission on the Public Service, 155. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, A Call  to
Leadership for America, p. 43. Action: Improving First-Level Supervision
140. Donald F. Kettl, Reinventing Government? of Federal Employees (Washington, DC: U.S
Appraising the National Performance Review Government Printing Office, 2010), p. 34. Data
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 1994), p. 20. are for 2009.
141. Brookings Institution, Winning the Talent War: 156. Eric Katz, “Embattled Secret Service Spent Just 25
Brookings Survey Finds the Nonprofit Sector Has Minutes Training the Average Officer in 2013,”
the Most Dedicated Workforce (Washington, DC: Government Executive (February 12, 2015).
Author, 2002), p. 2. 157. National Academy of Public Administration and
142. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Power ICF International, Federal Leaders Digital Insight
of Federal Employee Engagement (Washington, Study (Washington, DC, and Fairfax, VA: Authors
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008), 2015), p. 9.
pp. 27–36. 158. “Happy on the Job?” Governing (August 2013),
143. Owens, “One More Reason Not to Cut Your p. 54. Figure, 74 percent, is for 2013.
Training Budget.” 159. Pew Center on the States, People Forward: Human
356 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Capital Trends and Innovations (Washington, 172. Eric Katz, “Whistleblower Disclosures Sky-
DC: Author, 2009), p. 3. Figure is for 2007. rocketed Last Year, Driven by VA Employees,”
160. Charles J. Spindler, “University-Based Public Govexec.com (January 19, 2016). Figures are for
Sector Management Development and Training,” 2014–2015.
Public Productivity & Management Review 15 173. Taxpayers Against Fraud, States with False Claims
(Summer 1992), pp. 439–448. Acts (Washington, DC: Author, 2014). Figures are
161. Joseph W. Whorton, Jr., Frank K. Gibson, and for 2014.
Delmer D. Dunn, “The Culture of University Public 174. Unpublished study by Karen L. Soeken and
Service: A National Survey of the Perspectives Donald L. Soeken, “A Survey of Whistleblowers:
of Users and Providers,” Public Administration Their Stressors and Coping Strategies,” 1987,
Review 46 (January/February 1986), pp. 38–47. as reported in Clyde H. Farnsworth, “Survey
162. Selden, Human Capital, pp. 85, 89. Expenditure is of Whistle Blowers Finds Retaliation but Few
for 2007. Growth figure is for 2003–2006. Regrets,” New York Times (February 27, 1987).
163. Pew Center on the States, People Forward, p. 23. 175. Michael Horowitz, IG, DoJ, as cited in Mieke
164. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Eoyang, “Should Intelligence Whistleblowers Be
Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern- Protected?” Nextgov.com (January 25, 2016).
ment Structure and Administration, p. 49. Figures 176. Joyce Rothschild, “The Fate of Whistleblowers
are for 1990. in Nonprofit Organizations,” Nonprofit and
165. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Whistle- Voluntary Sector Quarterly 42 (February 2013),
blowing in the Federal Government: An Update pp. 886–901. Data are on p. 896.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 177. Janet P. Near and Marcia P. Miceli, “Wrongdoing,
Office, 1993), p. ii. Figures are for 1983 and Whistle-Blowing, and Retaliation in the U.S.
1992. Government: What Have Researchers Learned
166. Bloomberg Business News, “Some Criticize from the Merit Systems Protection Board (MSPB)
Whistleblowers as Bounty Hunters,” Baltimore Survey Results?” Review of Public Personnel
Sun (June 16, 1996). Administration 28 (September 2008), pp. 263–
167. U.S. Internal Revenue Service, Whistleblower 281.
Office, Annual Report to Congress on the Use of 178. James Gerard Caillier, “Agency Retaliation
Section 7623 (Washington, DC: Author, 2010). Against Whistle-Blowers,” Public Integrity 15
Figures are for FY 2009. (Winter 2013), pp. 29–50. The quotation is on
168. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax p. 29.
Whistleblowers: Incomplete Data Hinders IRS’s 179. John J. Sumanth, David M. Mayer, and Virginia
Ability to Manage Claim Processing Time and S. Kay, “Why Good Guys Finish Last: The Role
Enhance External Communication, GAO-11- of Justification Motives, Cognition, and Emotions
683 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing in Predicting Retaliation against Whistleblowers,”
Office, 2011), Highlights page. Data are for 2007– Organizational Psychology Review (1, 2011),
2008, 2011. pp. 165–184.
169. U.S. Internal Revenue Service, Whistleblower 180. Ibid., pp. 167–168.
Office, Annual Report to Congress on the Use of 181. Marcia P. Meceli and Janet P. Near, “What Makes
Section 7623 (Washington, DC: Author, 2010). Whistle-Blowers Effective? Three Field Studies,”
Figures are for 2009. Human Relations 55 (April 2002), pp. 455–479.
170. Michael Hudson, “IRS Red Tape, Old Guard Slow 182. Lisa Rein, “VA’s Own Internal Probe Finds
Whistleblowing on Corporate Tax Cheats,” i watch Impunity of Agency at Scandal-Ridden Hospital,”
(June 22, 2011), http://www.iwatchnews.org. Washingtonpost.com (December 16, 2015).
171. U.S. Government Accountability Office, IRS 183. Emily Wax-Thibodeaux, “He Blew the Whistle on
Whistleblower Program: Billions Collected, the VA—and then Was Almost Sacked for Eating
but Timeliness and Communication Concerns Stale Sandwiches,” Washington Post (September
May Discourage Whistleblowers, GAO-16-20 21, 2015).
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing 184. Ethics Resource Center, Retaliation: The Cost to
Office, 2015), Highlights page. Data are for Your Company and Its Employees (Arlington, VA:
2011–2015. Author, 2010), p. 1.
Managing Human Capital 357

185. Michael Griffin and Tracy Davis, Sourcing 198. Quoted in Farnsworth, “Survey of Whistle
Competitive Advantage from Organizational Blowers Finds Retaliation but Few Regrets.”
Integrity: The Hidden Cost of Misconduct 199. Reuters, “Whistleblower Rewards Top $2 Billion”
(Arlington, VA: Corporate Executive Board, (January 2, 2008), http://www.reuters.com.
2007). Figures are for 1986–2008.
186. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Contrac- 200. Gjalt de Graaf, “A Report on Reporting: Why
tor Whistleblower Protections Pilot Program: Peers Report Integrity and Law Violations in
Improvements Needed to Ensure Effective Imple- Public Organizations,” Public Administration
mentation, GAO-17-227 (Washington, DC: U.S. Review 70 (September/October 2010), pp. 767–
Government Publishing Office, 2017), Highlights 779. The quotations are on pp. 772, 770.
page. 201. Jos, Tompkins, and Hays, “In Praise of Difficult
187. The case is Department of Homeland Security v. People,” p. 555.
MacLean. 202. U.S. Department of Justice, Civil Division, Fraud
188. Statement of Mr. Thomas F. Gimble, Acting Statistics – Overview (Washington, DC: U.S.
Inspector General, Department of Defense, before Government Publishing Office, 2016). Figure is
the Subcommittee on National Security, Emerging for FY 1987–FY 2015.
Threats, and International Relations, House 203. Rothschild, “The Fate of Whistleblowers in
Committee on Government Reform on National Nonprofit Organizations,” p. 892.
Security on Whistleblower Protection, April 14, 204. Ibid., pp. 896–897.
2006 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 205. Center for State and Local Government Excell-
Office, 2014), p. 8. ence, Security: What Americans Want from a Job
189. Office of the Inspector General of the Intelligence (Washington, DC: Author, 2007), p.  5. Figures
Community, Semiannual Report (Washington, are  for 2007 and apply only to subnational
DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016). governments.
190. As derived from data in National Conference 206. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employee Tenure
of State Legislatures, State Whistleblower Laws in 2016 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
(Washington, DC: Author, 2009). Data are for Publishing Office, 2016).
2009. 207. Craig Copeland, “Employee Tenure, 2008,” EBRI.
191. Philip H. Jos, Mark E. Tompkins, and Steven W. org Notes 31 (January 2010), pp. 2–12. The quo-
Hays, “In Praise of Difficult People: A Portrait of tation is on p. 2. Trend figures are for 1983–2008.
the Committed Whistleblower,” Public Admini- 208. R. Paul Battaglio, Jr., “Public Service Reform
stration Review 49 (November/December 1989), and Motivation: Evidence from an Employment
pp. 552–561. Data, pp. 553–554, are for 1987– At-Will Environment,” Review of Public Person-
1988. nel Administration 30 (September 2010), pp.
192. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 341–363. The author cites eight other studies sup-
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 17. porting this finding.
193. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems 209. Ibid. and Matthew M. Chingos, Ending Teacher
Protection Board, Prohibited Personnel Practices: Tenure Would Have Little Impact on Its Own
A Study Retrospective (Washington, DC: U.S. (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2014).
Government Printing Office, 2010), p. 15. 210. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Ensuring
194. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Prohibited the Federal Government Has an Effective Civilian
Personnel Practices: Employee Perceptions Workforce, Q. 84. Figure is for 2008, but is quite
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing steady over time.
Office, 2011), p. 32. Current figure is for 2010. 211. Emily Kopp, “OPM: Millennial Feds Like Their
195. Ethics Resource Center, Retaliation, p. 5. Figure is Jobs, but Don’t Stay Long,” Federalnewsradio.
for 2009. In 2007 it was 12 percent. com (October 7, 2014).
196. Ernest Fitzgerald, quoted in Mary McGrory, 212. Center for the Study of Democratic Institutions,
“The Whistleblower’s Lament,” Washington Post Survey on the Future of Government Service
(September 22, 1996). (Nashville, TN: Author, 2015). Figures are for
197. Jos, Tompkins, and Hays, “In Praise of Difficult 2014.
People,” p. 555. 213. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Ensuring
358 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

the Federal Government Has an Effective Civilian 225. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Human
Workforce, Q. 84. Capital: Selected Agencies’ Statutory Authorities
214. Ed Michaels, Helen Hatfield-Jones, and Beth Could Offer Options in Developing a Framework
Axelrod, The War for Talent (Cambridge, MA: for Governmentwide Reform, GAO-05-398R
Harvard Business School Press, 2001), and Baruch Human Capital Authorities (Washington, DC:
Lev, Intangibles: Management, Measurement, and U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005), p. 1.
Reporting (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2001). 226. G. Edward DeSeve, Speeding Up the Learning
215. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thornton, Curve: Observations from a Survey of Seasoned
Elevating Our Federal Workforce: Chief Human Political Appointees (Washington, DC: IBM
Capital Officers Offer Advice to President Obama Center for the Business of Government, 2009),
(Washington, DC, and Alexandria, VA: Authors, p. 6. Figure, 52 percent, is for 2008.
2009), p. ii. Figure is for 2008. 227. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Civil Service
216. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Thornton, Evaluation: The Evolving Role of the U.S. Office
Embracing Change: CHCOs Rising to the of Personnel Management (Washington, DC: U.S.
Challenge of an Altered Landscape (Washington, Government Printing Office, 1999), p. 24. Figure
DC, and Alexandria, VA: Authors, 2014), p.  23. is for 1997.
Figure, 62 percent, is for 2014 and refers to 228. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Power
respondents who thought that reform should have of Federal Employee Engagement (Washington,
a high priority to a great or very great extent. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008),
217. Gary S. Marshall, “Whither (or Wither) OPM?” p. 24. Figure is for 2005.
Public Administration Review 58 (May/June 229. Partnership for Public Service and Grant
1998), pp. 280–282. Thornton, Embracing Change, p. 25. Figure
218. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Federal is  for 2014. The term, “paper shufflers,” is
Human Resources Management for the 21st ours;  the  study uses instead, “transactional
Century (Washington, DC: U.S. Government manager.”
Printing Office, 1997), p. 8. 230. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen
219. John Crum, “Lessons Learned: Making Strategic Hamilton, Bridging Mission and Management
Hiring Decisions,” Issues of Merit (September (Washington, DC, and McLean, VA: Authors,
2011), pp. 2–3. 2015), p. 15.
220. As derived from data in U.S. Government 231. Donald F. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving
Accountability Office, Federal Hiring: OPM Results: Lessons for Improving Government
Needs to Improve Management and Oversight of Management from GAO’s High-Risk List
Hiring Authorities, p. 9. Figure is for 2014. (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
221. U.S. General Accounting Office, Human Capital: Government, 2016), pp. 13–14.
Selected Agencies’ Use of Alternative Service 232. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Human
Delivery Options for Human Capital Activities, Capital: OPM Needs to Improve the Design,
GAO-04-679 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Management, and Oversight of the Federal
Printing Office, 2004). Classification System, GAO-14-677 (Washington,
222. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2014),
Government: A Model Employer or a Work in Highlights page. Figures are for 1988–2013.
Progress? p. 9. Current figure is for 2007. 233. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Human
223. U.S. General Accounting Office, Human Capital: Capital: Selected Agencies’ Statutory Authorities
OPM Can Better Assist Agencies in Using Could Offer Options in Developing a Framework
Personnel Flexibilities, GAO-03-428 (Washington, for Governmentwide Reform, p. 1.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), p. 7. 234. Stahl, Public Personnel Administration, p. 41.
Figure is for 2003. The laws in question are “Title 235. Riccucci and Naff, Personnel Management in
5 laws,” for Title 5 in the U.S. Code, which codi- Government, p. 34.
fies most federal policies for federal workers. 236. Ibid. Figure is for the mid-1980s.
224. “The Future of Position Classification: Not Only 237. Andrew W. Boessel, “Local Personnel Manage-
‘What?’ But ‘Who?’” Issues of Merit (Spring 2015), ment,” Municipal Year Book, 1974 (Washington,
p. 7. Figures are for 2001–2013 and 2011, respectively. DC: International City Management Association,
Managing Human Capital 359

1974), pp. 92–93. Figure is for 1974, and excludes 252. Robert M. Sanders, “GeorgiaGain or
education. GeorgiaLoss? The Great Experiment in State Civil
238. Steven W. Hays, “Trends and Best Practices in Service Reform,” Public Personnel Management
State and Local Human Resource Management,” 33 (Summer 2004), pp. 151–164. The quotation
Review of Public Personnel Administration 24 is on p. 151.
(October 2004), pp. 256–275. 253. “Georgia: Grading the States, 2005,” Governing
239. Jerrell D. Coggburn, “Personnel Deregulation: (February 2005), p. 49.
Exploring Differences in the American States,” 254. Stephen T. T. Teo and John J. Rodwell, “To Be
Journal of Public Administration Research and Strategic in the New Public Sector, HR Must
Theory 11 (April 2001), pp. 223–244. The quota- Remember Its Operational Activities,” Human
tion is on p. 227. Resource Management 46 (Summer 2007),
240. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “HR pp. 265–284.
Directors Get a Personnel Downgrade,” Governing 255. Sally Coleman Selden, “Human Resource Man-
(April 2015), pp. 56–57. The quotation is on p. 57. agement in American Counties, 2002,” Public
241. Selden, Ingraham, and Jacobson, “Human Personnel Management 34 (Spring 2005), p. 61.
Resource Practices in State Government,” p. 600. Figure is for 2002.
Figure is for 1998. 256. Harry P. Hatry and Carl F. Valente, “Alternative
242. As derived from data in Keon S. Chi, Kelley A. Delivery Approaches Involving Increased Use of
Arnold and Heather M. Perkins, “Privatization the Private Sector,” Municipal Year Book, 1983
in Government: Trends and Issues,” Spectrum 76 (Washington, DC: International City Management
(Fall 2003), pp. 12–21. The datum is on p. 16. Association, 1983), pp. 199–217. Figure (p. 200)
Figure is for 2002. is for 1982.
243. Steven W. Hays and Jessica E. Sowa, “A Broader 257. George C. Homsy and Mildred Warner, “Inter-
Look at the ‘Accountability’ Movement: Some municipal Cooperation: The Growing Reform,”
Grim Realities in State Civil Service Systems,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 (Washington, DC:
Review of Public Personnel Administration 26 International City/County Management Asso-
(June 2006), pp. 102–117. ciation, 2014), pp. 53–65. Figures (p. 57) are for
244. Jonathan Walters, Life after Civil Service Reform: 2012.
The Texas, Georgia, and Florida Experiences 258. Walters, Life after Civil Service Reform, pp. 5, 12.
(Washington, DC: IBM Endowment for the 259. Sally Coleman Selden, “The Impact of Discipline
Business of Government, 2002), pp. 5, 12, and on the Use and Rapidity of Dismissal in State
Melissa Maynard, “Civil Service Changes Gain a Governments,” Review of Public Personnel
Foothold,” Stateline (June 12, 2012). Administration 26 (June 2006), pp. 335–355.
245. Coggburn, “Personnel Deregulation,” p. 241. 260. J. Edward Kellough and Lloyd G. Nigro,
246. J. Edward Kellough and Sally Coleman “Dramatic Reform in the Public Service: At-Will
Selden, “The Reinvention of Public Personnel Employment and the Creation of a New Public
Administration: An Analysis of the Diffusion of Workforce,” Journal of Public Administration
Personnel Management Reforms in the States,” Research and Theory 16 (July 2006), pp. 447–466.
Public Administration Review 63 (March/April The quotation is on p. 447.
2003), pp. 165–176. 261. R. Paul Battaglio, Jr., “Public Service Reform
247. Robert J. McGrath, “The Rise and Fall of Radical and Motivation: Evidence from an Employment
Civil Service Reform in the U.S. States,” Public At-Will Environment,” Review of Public Per-
Administration Review 73 (July/August 2013), sonnel Administration 30 (September 2010),
pp. 638–649. The quotations are on p. 647 pp. 341–363. The quotation is on p. 341.
248. Walters, Life after Civil Service Reform, p. 39. 262. Walters, Life after Civil Service Reform, pp. 5, 12.
249. Chi, “Trends in State Civil Service Systems,” p. 406. 263. Bowman and West, “State Government ‘Little
250. As derived from data in Book of the States, 2004 Hatch Acts’ in an Era of Civil Service Reform,”
(Lexington, KY: Council of State Governments, p. 35.
2004), pp. 389–482, Table 8.1. Figure is for 2003. 264. Howard Risher, “How HR Departments Can
251. Barrett and Greene, “HR Directors Get a Assert Their Value,” Government Executive
Personnel Downgrade.” (January 9, 2015).
360 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

265. “Why Chief Human Resources Officers Make Election Losses,” Governing.com (November 21,
Great CEOs,” Harvard Business Review 92 2014).
(December 2014), pp. 30–34. The quotations are 283. Yosef Bhatti and Kasper Hansen, “Public Employ-
on p. 30. This is a synopsis of a paper by David ees Lining Up at the Polls—The Conditional Effect
Ulrich and Ellie Filler. of Living and Working in the Same Municipality,”
266. Hugh O’Neill, “The Growth of Municipal Public Choice 156 (September 2013), pp. 611–629.
Employee Unions,” Unionization of Municipal 284. J. Ryan Lamare, “Union Influence on Voter Turnout:
Employees, Robert H. Connery and William V. Results from Three Los Angeles County Elections,”
Farr, eds., Proceedings of the Academy of Political Industrial and Labor Relations Review 63 (April
Science (New York: Academy of Political Science, 2010), pp. 454–470. The quotation is on p. 454.
December 1970), pp. 1–13. 285. U.S. General Accounting Office, Collective
267. Seymour Martin Lipset and Ivan Katchanovski, Bargaining Rights: Information on the Number of
“The Future of Public Sector Unions in the U.S.,” Workers with and without Collective Bargaining
Journal of Labor Research 22 (Spring 2001), Rights, GAO-02-835 (Washington, DC: U.S.
pp. 229–244. Government Printing Office, 2002), p. 6.
268. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Union Members— 286. Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private and
2015 (Washington, DC: Author, 2016), Table 3. Public Sector Workers, p. 5. Decline in all workers
269. Lipset and Katchanovski, “The Future of Public with negotiated agreements is for 1979–2013.
Sector Unions in the U.S.” 287. James R. Thompson, “Federal Labor-Management
270. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Union Members— Relations Reforms Under Bush: Enlightened
2015, Table 3. Management or. . .” Review of Public Personnel
271. Ibid. Figure is for 2015. Administration 27 (June 2007), pp. 105–124. The
272. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, as cited in Terence quotation is on p. 105.
P. Jeffrey, “48.9 Percent of Union Members 288. Dave Umhoefer, “For Unions in Wisconsin, a
Worked for Government in 2015,” CNSNews. Fast and Hard Fall since Act 10,” Jsonline.com
com (January 28, 2016). (November 28, 2016). Figures are for 2011–2015.
273. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Union Members— 289. As derived from data in James Joyner, “Collective
2015, Table 3. Bargaining Rights by State,” Outside the Beltway
274. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Union (Washington, DC: Outside the Beltway, 2011).
Recognition and Agreements in the Federal Data are for 2011.
Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 290. David A. Dilts, William J. Walsh, and Constanza
Printing Office, 1991), pp. 6–7. Hagmann, “State Labor-Management Relations
275. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Union Members— Legislation: Adaptive Modeling,” Journal of
2015, Table 3. Collective Negotiations in the Public Sector 22
276. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of (1, 1993), pp. 79–86. Alabama, Kansas, and West
the United States, 1986, 106th ed. (Washington, Virginia have meet-and-confer requirements.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1986), 291. Marvin J. Levine, “The Status of State ‘Sunshine
Table 714. Figure is for 1982. Bargaining’ Laws,” Labor Law Journal 30
277. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Union Members— (November 1980), p. 713.
2015, Tables 3, 4. 292. Robert Hebdon “Labor-Management Relations
278. Rick Cohen,“Unions and the Nonprofit Workforce: in the United States, 1999,” Municipal Year
A Few Considerations,” Nonprofitquarterly.org Book, 2000 (Washington, DC: International City/
(August 8, 2013). County Management Association, 2000), p. 23
279. The case is McLaughlin v. Tilendis. 293. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
280. Joe Nation, as quoted in Charles Duhigg, “Public Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern-
Unions Take On Bosses to Win Big Pensions,” ment and Administration, p. 49. Figure is for 1990.
New York Times (June 21, 2011). 294. The case is Circuit City Stores, Inc. v. Adams.
281. John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, The 295. U.S. General Accounting Office, Collective
Fourth Revolution: The Global Race to Reinvent Bargaining Rights: Information on the Number of
the State (New York: Penguin Press, 2014), p. 115. Workers with and without Collective Bargaining
282. Alan Greenblatt, “Unions Rethink Strategy After Rights, p. 10 n.
Managing Human Capital 361

296. G. W. Bohlander, “Public Sector Grievance (New York: Dunellen, 1973), p. 218.
Arbitration: Structure and Administration,” 310. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of
Journal of Collective Negotiations in the Public the United States, 1984, 104th ed. (Washington,
Sector 21 (2, 1992), pp. 271–286. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1984),
297. Debra J. Mesch and Olga Shamayera, “Arbitration Table 731.
in Practice: A Profile of Public Sector Arbitration 311. As derived from data in ibid. and U.S. Bureau of the
Cases,” Public Personnel Management 25 (Spring Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,
1996), pp. 119–136. 1974, 95th ed., 1977, 98th ed., and 1980, 101st
298. Dane M. Partridge, “Teacher Strikes and Public ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Policy: Does the Law Matter?” Journal of Office, 1974, 1977, 1980), Tables 596, 684, and
Collective Negotiations in the Public Sector 25 721, respectively. Figure is for 1970–1979.
(1, 1996), pp. 3–21. The quotation is on p. 3. 312. As derived from data in Michael H. Cimini,
299. David Lewin, Jeffrey H. Keefe, and Thomas A. “1982–1997 State and Local Government
Kochan, “The New Great Debate about Unionism Work Stoppages and Their Legal Background,”
and Collective Bargaining in U.S. State and Local Compensation and Working Conditions 30 (Fall
Governments,” Industrial & Labor Relations 1998), pp. 32–38, Table 5, and U.S. Bureau of
Review 65 (October 2012), pp. 749–778. The Labor Statistics, Major Work Stoppages, http://
quotation is on p. 749. www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/all_nr.htm.
300. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of Labor 313. Leo Troy, “Has Public Sector Unionism Topped
Statistics, Union Members—2015, Table 4. Out? What Is the Clinton Administration Doing
301. Richard C. Kearney, “The Determinants of State About It?” Government Union Review 17 (Spring
Employee Compensation,” Review of Public 1996), pp. 1–40. The quotations are on p. 1.
Personnel Administration 23 (December 2003), 314. Maggie Clark, “Union Membership Continues
pp. 305–322. The quotation is on p. 305. Steady Decline in 2012,” Stateline (January 24,
302. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of Labor 2013).
Statistics, Union Members—2015, Table 4. 315. Gallup Historical Trends, Labor Unions
303. Peter Jamison and Catherine Saillant, “Public, (Washington, DC: Author, 2014). Figures are for
Private Sector Wage Gap Heavily Favors Many 2011.
L.A. City Workers,” Los Angeles Times (April 25, 316. Stephanie Simon, “The Fall of Teachers Unions,”
2015). Politico (June 13, 2014). Figures are for 2009–
304. Richard C. Kearney, with David G. Carnevale, 2013.
Labor Relations in the Public Sector, 3rd ed. (New 317. Stephanie Simon, “California Teachers Lose Big in
York: Marcel Dekker, 2001). Court,” Politico (June 10, 2014).
305. As derived from data in Jerri Killian and Enamul 318. Simon, “The Fall of Teachers Unions.”
Choudhury, “Continuity and Change in the Role 319. Jack Grovum, “After Supreme Court Ruling,
of City Managers,” Municipal Year Book, 2010 Fewer State Workers to Organize,” Stateline (July
(Washington, DC: International City/County 4, 2014).
Management Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. 320. Barry Bluestone, “A Future for Public Unions?”
Figure (p. 14) is for 2010. Boston.com (July 18, 2009). Figures are for
306. Bruce A. Wallin, Budgeting for Basics: 2000–2008.
The Changing Landscape of City Finances 321. Sean Nicholson-Crotty, Jason A. Grissom, and Jill
(Washington, DC: Brookings, 2005), pp. 8–9. Nicholson-Crotty, “Governance and the Impact
Figures are for 1977–2000. of Public Employee Unions on Organizational
307. Melissa Maynard, “Public Strikes Explained: Performance,” Public Performance & Manage-
Why There Aren’t More of Them?” Stateline ment Review 35 (March 2012), pp. 422–448. The
(September 25, 2012). quotation is on p. 422.
308. Riccucci and Naff, Personnel Management in 322. U.S. Department of Education, as cited in
Government, p. 509. Figures are for 2000. Alejandra Matos, “1 in 4 U.S. Teachers Are
309. The “pension specialist” of the AFSCME, quoted Chronically Absent, Missing More than 10 Days
in Sterling Spero and John M. Capozzola, The of School,” Washington Post (October 26, 2016).
Urban Community and Its Unionized Bureaucracy Data are for 2013–2014 school year.
362 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

323. Randall S. Davis, “Unionization and Work Process (Washington, DC: Brookings and Heritage
Attitudes: How Union Commitment Influences Foundation, 2000), p. 10. Figures are averages for
Public Sector Job Satisfaction.” Public Admini- 1984–1999.
stration Review 73 (January/February 2013), 337. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior
pp. 74–84. Executive Service Survey Results for Fiscal Year
324. Frederick C. Mosher, Democracy and the Public 2011, p. 133.
Service (New York: Oxford University Press, 338. Light, “Recommendations Forestalled or  For-
1968), p. 166. This is the first edition of this book. gotten?” p. 414. Emphasis is original.
Unless noted otherwise, all references to this work 339. Dean E. Mann and Jameson W. Doig, The
are of the second (1982) edition. Assistant Secretaries: Problems and Processes
325. Committee on Homeland Security and Gov- of Appointment (Washington, DC: Brookings,
ernmental Affairs, U.S. Senate, United States 1965), pp. 99, 165.
Government Policy and Supporting Positions 340. Joel D. Aberbach and Bert A. Rockman, “The Past
(Plum Book), 2016, (Washington, DC: U.S. and Future of Political-Administrative Relations:
Government Publishing Office, 2016). Figure is Research from Bureaucrats and Politicians to In
for 2016. the Web of Politics—and Beyond,” International
326. Lisa Rein, “The Plum Book Is Here for Those Journal of Public Administration 29 (12, 2006),
Angling for Jobs in Trump’s Washington,” pp. 977–995. The quotation is on p. 988.
Washington Post (December 4, 2016). Figure is 341. Fred Malek, presidential personnel assistant in
for 2016. the Nixon Administration, as quoted in Pfiffner,
327. National Commission on the Public Service, “Political Appointees and Career Executives,”
Urgent Business for America, p. 18. In 1960, there pp. 63–64. Emphasis is original.
were 286 political executive positions. 342. Nick Gallo and David E. Lewis, “The Con-
328. James P. Pfiffner, “Political Appointees and Career sequences of Presidential Patronage for Federal
Executives: The Democracy-Bureaucracy Nexus Agency Performance,” Journal of Public Admini-
in the Third Century,” Public Administration stration Research and Theory 22 (2, 2011),
Review 47 (January/February 1987), pp. 57–65. pp. 219–243.
329. Committee on Homeland Security and 343. American Academy of Diplomacy, American
Governmental Affairs, U.S. Senate, United States Diplomacy at Risk (Washington, DC: Author,
Government Policy and Supporting Positions 2015).
(Plum Book), 2016. Figure is for 2016. 344. Donald P. Moynihan and Alasdair S. Roberts,
330. Pfiffner, “Political Appointees and Career Exe- “The Triumph of Loyalty Over Competence:
cutives,” p. 58. The  Bush Administration and the Exhaustion
331. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen of the Politicized Presidency,” Public Admini-
Hamilton, Unrealized Vision, p. ii. stration Review 70 (July/August 2010), pp. 572–
332. Darren Samuelsohn, Obama’s Vanishing Adminis- 581. The quotations are on pp. 574, 575. Emphasis
tration (Washington, DC: Politico, 2016). Figures is original.
are for 2015. 345. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Prohibited
333. Paul C. Light, “Nominate and Wait,” New York Personnel Practices: Employee Perceptions
Times (March 24, 2009). Data are for 2009. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
334. Darren Samuelsohn, Obama’s Vanishing Admini- Office, 2011), p. 29.
stration (Washington, DC: Politico, 2016). Figures 346. Dan Balz, “Bush’s Hurricane Damage,”
are for 2015. Washington Post (August 28, 2007).
335. Paul C. Light, “Recommendations Forestalled 347. Moynihan and Roberts, “The Triumph of Loyalty
or Forgotten? The National Commission on the Over Competence,” p. 578.
Public Service and Presidential Appointments,” 348. Christopher Cooper and Robert Block, Disaster:
Public Administration Review 67 (May/June Hurricane Katrina and the Failure of Homeland
2007), pp. 404–417. The quotation is on p. 408. Security (New York: Times Books, 2006).
336. Paul C. Light and Virginia L. Thomas, The 349. Leon Panetta is quoted.
Merit and Reputation of an Administration: 350. Moynihan and Roberts, “The Triumph of Loyalty
Presidential  Appointments on the Appointments Over Competence,” p. 578.
Managing Human Capital 363

351. Light and Thomas, The Merit and Reputation of 364. Moynihan and Roberts, “The Triumph of Loyalty
an Administration, p. 5. Studies cover 1964–1989 Over Competence,” p. 579.
to 1984–1999. 365. Laura Langbein, “Controlling Federal Agencies:
352. B. Dan Wood and Miner P. Marchbanks, III, The Contingent Impact of External Controls
“What Determines How Long Political Appointees on Worker Discretion and Productivity,” Inter-
Serve?” Journal of Public Administration Research national Public Management Journal 12 (1,
and Theory 18 (July 2008), pp. 375–396. The 2009), pp. 82–115. The quotation is on p. 103.
quotations are on pp. 391, 393. Emphasis is orig- 366. Aberbach and Rockman, “The Past and Future of
inal. Study covers 1982–2003. Political-Administrative Relations,” pp. 987–988.
353. Light and Thomas, The Merit and Reputation of 367. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior
an Administration, p. 6. Figures are averages for Executive Survey Results for Fiscal Year 2011
1984–1999. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
354. Wood and Marchbanks, “What Determines How Office, 2012), pp. 138–139.
Long Political Appointees Serve?” p. 390. 368. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen
355. Ibid., p. 35, and Gregg Carlstrom, “Bush Appoin- Hamilton, Unrealized Vision, p. 14.
tees ‘Burrow In’,” FederalTimes.com (November 369. Federalnewsradio.com, WFED Federal CHCO
30, 2008), FederalTimes.com. Figure is for 1964– Survey 2016, p. 8.
1999, 2001–2008. 370. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016
356. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Office Federal Employment Viewpoint Survey Results,
of Personnel Management: Actions Are Needed Q. 61. Figures are for 2012–2016.
to Help Ensure the Completeness of Political 371. Federal News Radio, Senior Executives Asso-
Conversion Data and Adherence to Policy, GAO- ciation, and Federal Managers Association, Senior
16-859 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Executive Service (Washington, DC: Authors,
Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page. 2015). Figures are for 2015.
357. Light and Thomas, The Merit and Reputation of 372. Partnership for Public Service and McKinsey
an Administration, p. 9. Figure is an average for & Company, A Pivotal Moment for the Senior
1984–1999. Executive Service (Washington, DC: Authors,
358. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Senior 2016), p. 8.
Executive Service: Views of Former Federal 373. Quoted in Emily Kopp, “Fixing the SES: ‘This
Executives (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Used to Be an Honor. Now It’s a Joke,’” Federal
Printing Office, 1989), pp. 20–21. Data are for News Radio (February 9, 2015).
1989. 374. James R. Thompson, as quoted (p. 58) in Jeffrey
359. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Everyone L. Katz, “The Slow Death of Political Patronage,”
Knows the ABCs: What About the ASPs and Governing (April 1991), pp. 58–62.
PPPs?” Issues of Merit (Fall 2016), pp. 1, 7. 375. Stephen Allred, as quoted in ibid., p. 62.
360. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The 376. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Census of Govern-
Merit System Principles: Guiding the Fair and ments, 1992, Vol. 1, No. 2 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Effective Management of the Federal Workforce Government Printing Office, 1995).
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing 377. As derived from data in Tari Renner and Victor
Office, 2016). Figure is for 2014. S. DeSantis, “Municipal Form of Government:
361. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior Issues and Trends,” Municipal Year Book, 1998
Executive Service Exit Survey Results April (Washington, DC: International City/County
2015  (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Management Association, 1998), pp. 30–40,
Publishing Office, 2015), pp. 5, 9. Figures are for and Evelina R. Moulder, “Municipal Form of
2014. Government: Trends in Structure, Responsibility,
362. Wood and Marchbanks, “What Determines How and Composition,” Municipal Year Book, 2008
Long Political Appointees Serve?” p. 390. (Washington, DC: International City/County
363. Anthony Bertelli and Sven E. Feldmann, “Strategic Management Association, 2008), pp. 3–8. Figures
Appointments,” Journal of Public Administration are for 1991 and 2006.
Research and Theory 17 (January 2007), pp. 378. As derived from data in Susan A. MacManus and
19–38. The quotation is on p. 36. Charles S. Bullock, III, “The Form, Structure, and
364 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Composition of America’s Municipalities in the 2005), p. 9. Figure for political appointees is for
New Millennium,” Municipal Year Book, 2003 1992, and the authors provide some evidence that
(Washington, DC: International City/County the percentage has not changed much since then.
Management Association, 2003), pp. 3–18. Figure for careerists is for 2003.
Figures (p. 13) are for 1991 and 2001. 390. Kenneth J. Meier and Alisa Hicklin, “Employee
379. James Conant, “Management Consequences Turnover and Organizational Performance: Test-
of the 1960–1990 ‘Modernization’ of State ing a Hypothesis from Classical Public Admini-
Government,” Handbook of State Government stration,” Journal of Public Administration
Administration, John J. Gargan, ed. (New York: Research and Theory 18 (October 2008), pp. 573–
Marcel Dekker, 2000), pp. 13–32. Twenty-six 590. The quotation is on p. 573.
states reorganized their governments, 1965–1990. 391. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
380. Frank P. Sherwood and Lee J. Breyer, “Executive Chief Information Officers: Responsibilities,
Personnel Systems in the States,” Public Admini- Reporting Relationships, Tenure, and Challenges,
stration Review 47 (September/October 1987), GAO-04-823 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
pp. 410–416. The figure is on p. 411. Printing Office, 2004), p. 22. The quotation is a
381. Mann and Doig, The Assistant Secretaries, p. 120. summary of GAO’s much broader research, U.S.
In 1964, 90 percent of the assistant secretaries General Accounting Office, Results-Oriented
and deputy agency administrators were college Cultures: Implementation Steps to Assist Mergers
graduates. and Organizational Transformations, GAO-03-
382. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil 669 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public Office, 2003).
Administration Across the 50 States: Linking 392. Alexander Hamilton, The Federalist No. 72.
Practice, Theory, and Research through the 393. David E. Lewis, Political Appointments, Bureau
American State Administrators Project, 1964– Chiefs, and Federal Management Performance
2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University, Woodrow
Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 11. Current Wilson School of Public and International Affairs,
figures are for 2008. 2005), pp. 4, 2.
383. Ibid., p. 13. Current figures are for 2008. Growth 394. Andrew Douglas McNitt, “Tenure in Office of
figures are for 1968–2008. Big City Mayors,” State and Local Government
384. Bowman and West, “State Government ‘Little Review 42 (Winter 2010), pp. 22–35.
Hatch Acts’ in an Era of Civil Service Reform,” 395. Carolyn Cain, Enamul Choudhury, and James C.
p. 24. Figures are for 2007. Clingermayer, “Turnover, Trust, and Transfers:
385. Killian and Choudhury, “Continuity and Change An Examination of Local Government Budget
in the Role of City Managers,” p. 11. Figure is for Execution,” International Journal of Public
2009. Administration 27 (August/September 2004),
386. International City/County Management Asso- pp. 557–576.
ciation, ICMA State of the Profession Survey 396. Ferrara and Ross, Getting to Know You, p. 9.
2012 Summary (Washington, DC: Author 2014), Figure is for 1992, but the authors provide some
p. 3. evidence that it is still roughly correct.
387. Patricia W. Ingraham, “Building Bridges or 397. As derived from data (pp. 478–479) in Claudia N.
Burning Them? The President, The Appointees, Avellaneda, “Mayoral Quality and Local Public
and The Bureaucracy,” Public Administration Finance,” Public Administration Review 69 (May/
Review 47 (September/October 1987), pp. 425– June 2009), pp. 469–486.
435. The figure is on p. 429. 398. Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private and
388. Lewis, Political Appointments, Bureau Chiefs, and Public Sector Workers, pp. 16, 11. Figures are for
Federal Management Performance, p. 35. Figure is 2013.
for 2004. 399. Franklin P. Kilpatrick, Milton C. Cummings, Jr.,
389. Joseph A. Ferrara and Lynn C. Ross, Getting to and M. Kent Jennings, The Image of the Federal
Know You: Rules of Engagement for Political Service (Washington, DC: Brookings, 1964).
Appointees and Career Executives (Arlington, 400. Dwaine Marvick, Career Perspectives in a
VA: IBM Center for the Business of Government, Bureaucratic Setting, University of Michigan
Managing Human Capital 365

Governmental Studies, No. 27 (Ann Arbor, MI: of the States (Lexington, KY: Council of State
University of Michigan Press, 1954), p. 134. Governments, 2004), pp. 405–412. The data are
401. Doyle W. Buckwalter and J. Ivan Legler, “City on p. 410.
Managers and City Attorneys: Associates or 418. Cortney Whalen and Mary E. Guy, “Broadbanding
Adversaries,” Public Administration Review 47 Trends in the States,” Review of Public Personnel
(September/October 1987), pp. 393–403. The Administration 28 (December 2008), pp. 349–
quotations are on p. 393. 366. Figures (p. 349) are for 2008.
402. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service, 419. Selden, Human Capital, p. 147. Figures are for
pp. 136–137, 140–141. 2007.
403. Ibid., p. 103. 420. National Academy of Public Administration,
404. Jean J. Couturier, “The Quiet Revolution in Public Modernizing Federal Classification: An Oppor-
Personnel Laws,” Public Personnel Management 5 tunity for Excellence (Washington, DC: Author,
(May/June 1976), pp. 150–168. 1991), p. 148. Data are for 2007, and refer to
405. Mosher, Democracy and the Public Service, states that have broadbanded at least 75 percent
pp. 104–105. of their workforces.
406. Ibid., p. 107. 421. Jonathan West, “City Personnel Management:
407. The following list is based, loosely, on: U.S. Issues and Reforms,” Public Personnel Manage-
Government Accountability Office, Human ment 13 (Fall 1984), pp. 317–334. Figure, 56
Capital: OPM Needs to Improve the Design, percent, is for 1983.
Management, and Oversight of the Federal 422. James L. Perry, Trent A. Engbers, and So Yun Jun,
Classification System, Highlights page. “Back to the Future? Performance-Related Pay,
408. Ibid. Figures are for 2013. Empirical Research, and the Perils of Persistence,”
409. Partnership for Public Service and Grant Public Administration Review 69 (January/
Thornton, Elevating Our Federal Workforce, p. 3. February 2009), p. 45.
Figure is for 2008. 423. Robert L. Mathis and John H. Jackson, Human
410. National Commission on the Public Service, Resource Management, 12th ed. (Mason, OH:
Urgent Business for America, p. 27. Thomson South-Western, 2008), pp. 353–354.
411. Partnership for Public Service and Booz Allen 424. U.S. General Accounting Office, Managing
Hamilton, Building the Enterprise: A New for Results: Emerging Benefits from Selected
Public Service Framework (Washington, DC, and Agencies’ Use of Performance Agreements, GAO-
Herndon, VA: Authors, 2014). 01-115 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
412. James R. Thompson, “Commentary: Pay-banding: Printing Office, 2000).
What Have We Learned,” FederalTimes.com (June 425. Mads L. F. Jakobsen and Peter B. Mortensen,
4, 2007). Figure is for 2007. “Rules and the Doctrine of Performance
413. National Commission on the State and Local Management,” Public Administration Review 75
Public Service, Hard Truths/Tough Choices, p. 27. (March/April 2016), pp. 302–321. The quotation
414. Jonathan Walters, “Untangling Albany,” is on p. 302.
Governing (December 1998), p. 20. 426. Selden, Ingraham, and Jacobson, “Human
415. John Ortiz, “California Government Includes Resource Practices in State Government,” p. 605.
State Pianist Classification,” Sacramento Bee Rhode Island is the exception.
(January 30, 2015). Position classification figures 427. Pew Center on the States, People Forward, p. 5.
are for early 2015. By the end of 2015, the state Figure, 87 percent, is for thirty responding states
had 3,151. in 2007.
416. Ibid. and John Ortiz, “The State Worker: Job 428. Freyss, “Continuity and Change in Local Personnel
Titles Reveal California’s Hoarding Disorder” Policies and Practices,” p. 15. Figure is for 1995.
and “Bureaucrats Take On Bureaucracy,” 429. Ron Carlee, Martha Perego, and Evelina R.
Sacramento Bee (October 27 and January 30, Moulder, “CAO Salary and Compensation:
2015, respectively). The Big Picture,” Municipal Year Book, 2013
417. Keon S. Chi, “Trends in State Civil Service (Washington, DC: International City/County
Systems: Personnel Agencies, Reform Efforts, Management Association, 2013), pp. 63–71.
Classifications and Workforce Planning,” Book Figure is for 2011.
366 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

430. Jeff Neal, “Why Bother with Performance (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Reviews?” Federalnewsradio.com (September 23, Office, 2008), p. 6. Figures are for 1997–2007.
2013). 447. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal
431. Marcus Buckingham and Ashley Goodall, Government: A Model Employer or a Work in
“Reinventing Performance Management,” hbr. Progress? p. 33.
org [Harvard Business Review] (April, 2015). 448. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016
Emphasis is original. Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results,
432. Alina Tugend, “Uncertainty about Jobs Has a Q. 15.
Ripple Effect,” New York Times (May 16, 2014). 449. Hays, “Trends and Best Practices in State and
433. Jonathan Walters, “I Have to Talk to You Local Human Resource Management,” p. 267.
About Your Job. . .” Governing (March 2001), 450. Heather Kerrigan, “Making Performance a
pp. 44–45. Priority,” Governing (April 2011), pp. 54–55.
434. Hal G. Rainey, Carol Traut, and Barry Blunt, 451. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal
“Reward Expectancies and Other Work-Related Workforce for the 21st Century: Results of the
Attitudes in Public and Private Organizations: Merit Principles Survey 2000 (Washington, DC:
A Review and Extension,” Review of Public U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), p. 24.
Personnel Administration 5 (July 1986), pp. 50–72. 452. Partnership for Public Service, Asking the Wrong
435. Howard Risher, “As Companies Shed Annual Questions, p. 3.
Reviews, Should Government Follow Suit?” 453. Corporate Leadership Council, Literature Review:
Govexec.com (July 28, 2015). Employee Selection Tests, Catalog No. 070-198-
436. Buckingham and Goodall, “Reinventing Perfor- 213 (Washington, DC: Author, 1998).
mance Management.” 454. Joyce Ehrlinger, Kerri Johnson, Matthew Banner,
437. Kellie Lunney, “Held Back,” Government Exe- et al., “Why the Unskilled Are Unaware: Further
cutive (January/February 2015), pp. 16–22. The Explorations of (Absent) Self-Insight among the
quotation is on p. 15. Incompetent,” Organizational Behavior and
438. U.S Merit Systems Protection Board, A Call to Human Decision Processes, 105 (January 2008),
Action, pp. 35–36. Data are for 2009. pp. 98–121. The quotations are on pp. 117–119.
439. Dennis M. Daley, Performance Appraisal in the 455. Amy C. Edmondson and Anita L. Tucker,
Public Sector (Westport, CN: Quorum, 1992). “Why Hospitals Don’t Learn from Failures:
440. Perry, Engbers, and Jun, “Back to the Future?”, Organizational and Psychological Dynamics that
pp. 39–51. Inhibit System Change,” California Management
441. Etienne Charbonneau and Francois Bellavance, Review 45 (2, 2003), pp. 55–72.
“Blame Avoidance in Public Reporting,” Public 456. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Issues
Performance & Management Review 35 (March Related to Poor Performers in the Federal
2012), pp. 399–421. The quotation is on p. 399. Workplace, GAO-05-812R Poor Performers in
442. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal the Federal Workplace (Washington, DC: U.S.
Workforce: Preliminary Observations on Strength- Government Printing Office, 2005), p. 2.
ening Employee Engagement During Challenging 457. Light, “To Restore and Renew.” Figure is for 2001.
Times, p. 15. 458. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Poor
443. Katherine Barrett and Richard Greene, “What Performers in Government: A Quest for the
Employee Surveys Reveal about Working in True Story (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Government,” Governing.com (June 9, 2016). Printing Office, 1999), p. 6. Figure, 3.7 percent, is
444. U.S. General Accounting Office, Posthearing for 1998.
Questions Related to Pay for Performance, GAO- 459. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal
03-793R Pay for Performance (Washington, DC: Supervisors and Poor Performers (Washington,
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), pp. 1–2. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1999),
445. Selden, Human Capital, p. 116. pp. 15–16.
446. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Govern- 460. As derived from data in ibid., pp. 7, 15; U.S.
ment Performance: Lessons Learned for the Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the
Next Administration on Using Performance United States, 1998, 118th ed. (Washington, DC:
Information to Improve Results, GAO-08-1026T U.S. Government Printing Office, 1998), Table
Managing Human Capital 367

561; U.S. Government Accountability Office, of Probationary Periods Are Needed to Address
Federal Workforce: Improved Supervision and Substandard Employee Performance, p. 15. Refers
Better Use of Probationary Periods Are Needed to the Chapter 43 process.
to Address Substandard Employee Performance, 475. U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission,
GAO-15-191 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Annual Report on the Federal Workforce Fiscal
Publishing Office, 2015), p. 22; and Andy Medici, Year, 2010 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
“Federal Employee Firings Hit Record Low in Printing Office, 2011), Figures 7, 12.
2014,” FederalTimes.com (February 24, 2015). 476. Lisa Rein, “Fight for Job Leaves Stephen Patrick
Figures are for 1997, 2004–2014. Idle and on the Federal Payroll,” Washington Post
461. Kevin R. Kosar, “The Common Perception Is (October 9, 2011).
True,” Weeklystandard.com (May 25, 2015). 477. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Poor Perfor-
Figure, 41 percent, is for 2000–2014. mers in Government, p. 33.
462. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal 478. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal
Supervisors and Poor Performers, p. 8. Supervisors and Poor Performers (Washington,
463. Andy Medici, “Federal Firings Continue to DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1999),
Drop: Lower Grades, TSA Fired the Most,” pp. 13, 17. Figure is for 1996.
FederalTimes.com (June 23, 2014). Figures are for 479. U.S. General Accounting Office, Performance
2009–2013. Management: How Well Is the Government
464. Ricccucci and Naff, Personnel Management in Dealing with Poor Performers? GAO/GGD-91-7
Government, p. 27. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
465. Bonnie Kristian, “Government Employees Say Office, 1990), pp. 32–33.
They’re Only Watching Porn at Work Because 480. The Future Foundation and SHL, Getting the
They’re Bored,” The Week (August 1, 2014). Edge in the New People Economy (London and
466. Charles S. Clark, “Lawmakers Wonder ‘How New York: Authors, 2004), p. 31.
Much Porn’ It Takes to Fire an EPA Employee?” 481. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal
Government Executive (May 8, 2014). Supervisors and Poor Performers, pp. 19, 13, 17.
467. James B. King, then-director of OPM, as cited Figures are for 1996.
in Frank Greve, “Civil Service Can Be a Job for 482. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Issues
Life,” Baltimore Sun (November 29, 1993). Related to Poor Performers in the Federal
468. Katherine McIntire Peters, “What Does It Take Workplace, p. 11. Figure is for 2003.
to Get Fired by a Federal Agency?” Govexec.com 483. Government Business Council, “The People
(August 26, 2015). Problem,” Government Executive (January/
469. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Poor February 2015), pp. 24–25. Figures are for 2014.
Performers in Government, p. 13. 484. Katherine McIntire Peters, “Despite Drugs, Sex
470. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Pro- with a Minor and More, EPA Employees Still Got
bationary Period: A Critical Assessment Oppor- Paid,” Govexec.com (November 11, 2015).
tunity (Washington, DC: Author, 2005), pp. 9, 7. 485. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Figures are for 1998–2001. Paid Administrative Leave: Additional Guidance
471. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems Needed to Improve OPM Data, GAO-15-79
Protection Board, Supervisory Probationary (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
Period: A Missed Opportunity (Washington, DC: Office, 2015), Highlights page, pp. 25, 30. Figures
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011). Figure is are for 2011–2013.
for FY 2007. 486. Treasury Inspector General for Tax Admini-
472. National Commission on the Public Service, stration, Review of the Internal Revenue Service’s
Urgent Business for America, pp. 40–41. Process to Address Violations of Tax Law by Its
473. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Annual Own Employees (Washington, DC: U.S. Treasury
Report for FY 2015 (Washington, DC: U.S. Department, 2015).
Government Publishing Office, 2016). Findings 487. Treasury Inspector General for Tax Admini-
figure excludes dismissed appeals. stration, Additional Consideration of Prior
474. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Conduct and Performance Issues Is Needed When
Workforce: Improved Supervision and Better Use Hiring Former Employees (Washington, DC: U.S.
368 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Treasury Department, 2014), pp. 5–6. Figures are Period, p. 9. Figures are 22 percent and 1.6
for 2010–2013. percent, respectively.
488. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Federal 504. Elling, Thompson, and Monet, “The Problematic
Supervisors and Poor Performers, p. 8 (which World of State Management.” Figures are for
cites studies beginning in 1981), and U.S. Office of 2000–2001.
Personnel Management, 2014 Federal Employee 505. Pew Center on the States, People Forward, p. 28.
Viewpoint Survey, Q. 23. Figures are for 2007.
489. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2014 506. Elling, Thompson, and Monet, “The Problematic
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey (Washington, World of State Management.” Figures are for
DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), 2000–2001.
Q. 23. 507. As derived from data in Robert Hebdon “Labor-
490. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 Management Relations in the United States,
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey (Washington, 1999,” Municipal Year Book, 2000 (Washington,
Q. 23. Figures are for 2012–2016. DC: International City/County Management
491. Government Business Council, “The People Association, 2000), pp. 22–27.
Problem,” p. 25. Figure is for 2014. 508. Light, “The Content of Their Character,” p. 15.
492. Partnership for Public Service, Improving Leader- Figures are for 2001–2002.
ship, p. 2. Figures are for 2014. 509. Jeanne Bell and Marla Cornelius, Under-
493. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, In Search developed:  A National Study of Challenges
of Highly Skilled Workers, p. 33. Figures are for Facing Nonprofit Fundraising (San Francisco and
2005. Oakland, CA: Evelyn & Walter Haas, Jr. Fund
494. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior and CompassPoint, 2013), p. 6. Figures are for
Executive Service Survey Results for Fiscal Year 2013.
2011, p. 137. 510. Charles A. O’Reilly III and Barton A. Weitz,
495. Federal News Radio, Senior Executives “Managing Marginal Employees: The Use of
Association, and Federal Managers Association, Warnings and Dismissals,” Administrative Science
Senior Executive Service. Figures are for 2015. Quarterly 25 (3, 1980), pp. 467–484.
496. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Remov- 511. Perry Klebahn, as cited in Huggy Rao and
ing Poor Performers in the Federal Service Robert  I. Sutton, Bad to Great: The Path to
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Scaling  Up Excellence (New York: McKinsey.
Office, 1995), p. 6. Figure is for 1994. com, 2014).
497. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, A Call to 512. Srini Tridanadapandi, Senthil Ramamurthy, James
Action, p. 36. Figure is for 2009. J. Galgano, and James M. Provenzale, “Increasing
498. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Removing Rate of Detection of Wrong-Patient Radio-
Poor Performers in the Federal Service, p. 7. Figure graphs: Use of Photographs Obtained at Time of
is for 1994. Radiology,” American Journal of Roentgenology
499. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, A Call to 200 (April 2013), pp. W345–W352.
Action, p. 37. Figure is for 2009. 513. Vanessa K. Bohns, Francesca Gina, and Chen-Bo
500. Dennis M. Daley, “The Burdens of Dealing with Zhong, “Good Lamps Are the Best Police:
Poor Performers: Wear and Tear on Supervisory Darkness Increases Dishonesty and Self-Interested
Organizational Engagement,” Review of Public Behavior,” Psychological Science 21 (4, 2010),
Personnel Administration 28 (March 2008), pp. 311–314.
pp. 44–59. 514. Council for Excellence in Government, Gallup,
501. Selden, Human Capital, p. 63. “Involuntary sep- and Accenture, The Appeal of Public Service, p. 5.
arations” were 1.76 percent in 2007 and 1.95 Figure is for 2008.
percent in 2000. 515. Selden, Human Capital, p. 141. Figures are for
502. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems 1980–2007.
Protection Board, Federal Supervisors and Poor 516. Christopher Lee and Hall Straus, “Two-Thirds of
Performers, pp. 7, 15. Figure is for 1997. Federal Workers Get a Bonus,” Washington Post
503. Selden, Human Capital, p. 51, and U.S. Merit (May 17, 2004). Figures are for FY 2002.
Systems Protection Board, The Probationary 517. Howard Risher, Pay for Performance: A Guide for
Managing Human Capital 369

Federal Managers (Washington, DC: IBM Center 534. Perry, Engbers, and Jun, “Back to the Future?”
for the Business of Government, 2004), p. 41. p. 47.
518. Kellie Lunney, “71 Percent of Career Senior 535. Adrian Ritz, Gene A. Brewer, and Oliver
Executives Received Bonuses in Fiscal 2015,” Neumann, “Public Service Motivation: A
Govexec.com (November 1, 2016). Systematic Literature Review and Outlook,”
519. Editors, “Hold Poor Performers Accountable, Public Administration Review 76 (May/June
Starting Now,” FederalTimes.com (February 28, 2016), pp. 414–426. The quotation is on p. 414.
2013). 536. Antoinette Weibel, Katja Rost, and Margit
520. OPM, as cited in Andy Medici, “Pay Freezes Osterloh, “Pay for Performance in the Public
Accelerate GS ‘Grade Creep,’” FederalTimes.com Sector—Benefits and (Hidden) Costs,” Journal of
(July 14, 2014). Public Administration Research and Theory 20
521. Gregory B. Lewis, “Grade Creep in the (April 2010), pp. 387–412. The quotation is on
Federal Service?” American Review of Public p. 387.
Administration 27 (March 1997), pp. 4–21. 537. Gene A. Brewer and Richard M. Walker,
522. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 “The Impact of Red Tape on Governmental
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 25. Performance: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of
523. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2014 Public Administration Research and Theory 20
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 25. (January 2010), pp. 233–257. The quotation is on
524. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal p. 249.
Government: A Model Employer or a Work in 538. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016
Progress? p. 30. In 1983, 17 percent agreed with Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 33.
the statement. 539. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2014
525. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Gov- Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey, Q. 33.
ernment Performance: Lessons Learned for the 540. Partnership for Public Service, Positioned for
Administration on Using Performance Infor- Change: Understanding Staff/Manager Alignment
mation to Improve Results, GAO-08-1026T (Washington, DC: Author, 2014), p. 5. Figures are
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing for 2013.
Office, 2008), p. 6. Figures are for 1997–2007. 541. Partnership for Public Service, Improving
526. “Happy on the Job?” p. 54. Figure is for 2013. Leadership, p. 2. Figures are for 2014.
527. Richard C. Elling, “Bureaucracy: Maligned Yet 542. Sungjoo Choi and Andrew B. Whitford. Merit-
Essential,” Politics in the American States: A based Pay and Employee Satisfaction in Federal
Comparative Analysis, 6th ed., Virginia Gray and Agencies, Issues in Governance Studies No. 63
Herbert Jacob, eds. (Washington, DC: CQ Press, (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2013).
1996), pp. 286–318. The quotations are on p. 543. Seong Soo Oh and Gregory B. Lewis, “Can Perfor-
292. Figure, 51 percent, is for the “mid-1980s.” mance Appraisal Systems Inspire Intrinsically
528. Selden, Human Capital, p. 143. Figures are for Motivated Employees?” Review of Public Person-
2004–2007. nel Administration 29 (June 2009), pp. 158–167.
529. Pew Center on the States, People Forward, p. 5. The quotation is on p. 160.
530. Jungin Kim, “Impact of Performance Appraisal 544. Risher, Pay for Performance, pp. 4, 7.
Justice on the Effectiveness of Pay-for-Perfor- 545. Here are a couple of examples among several:
mance Systems After Civil Service Reform,” J. Edward Kellough and Lloyd G. Nigro, “Pay
Public Personnel Management 45 (June 2016), for Performance in Georgia State Govern-
pp. 148–170. The quotation is on p. 148. ment:  Employee Perspectives on Georgia Gain
531. Freyss, “Continuity and Change in Local after 5 Years,” Review of Public Personnel
Personnel Policies and Practices,” p. 15. Figure is Administration, 22 (June 2002), pp. 146–166,
for 1995. and  James S. Baldwin, Marc G. Gertz, Sally C.
532. Selden, “Human Resource Management in Gertz, and Russell L. Williams, “Civil Service
American Counties, 2002,” p. 81. Figures are for Reform in Florida State Government: Employee
2002. Attitudes One Year Later,” Review of Public
533. Carlee, Perego, and Moulder, “CAO Salary and Personnel Administration 23 (December 2003),
Compensation,” p. 68. Figure is for 2011. pp. 286–304.
370 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

546. Edmund Stazyk, “Crowding Out Public Service ‘Performance-Based Pay’ Reform”; U.S. General
Motivation? Comparing Theoretical Expectations Accounting Office, High-Risk Series: Strategic
with Empirical Findings on the Influence of Human Capital Management; Organisation  for
Performance-Related Pay,” Review of Public Economic Co-operation and Development,
Personnel Administration 33 (September 2013), Performance-Related Pay Policies for Government
pp. 252–274. Employees (Paris: Author, 2005); and U.S.
547. Perry, Engbers, and Jun, “Back to the Future?” Merit Systems Protection Board, Managing for
p. 47. Engagement: Communication, Connection, and
548. Nicola Belle, “Performance-Related Pay and Courage (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
the Crowding Out of Motivation in the Public Printing Office, 2009), pp. 66–74.
Sector: A Randomized Field Experiment,” Public 559. Carl Dahlstrom and Victor Lapuente, “Explaining
Administration Review 75 (March/April 2015), Cross-Country Differences in Performance-
pp. 230–241. The quotations are on p. 230. Related Pay in the Public Sector,” Journal of
549. Risher, Pay for Performance, p. 10. Public Administration Research and Theory 20
550. Henry L. Tosi, Steve Werner, Jeffrey P. Katz, (July 2010), pp. 577–600. The quotation is on
and Luis R. Gomez-Mejia, “How Much Does p. 577.
Performance Matter? A Meta-Analysis of CEO 560. Reginald Wilson, Affirmative Action: Yesterday,
Pay Studies,” Journal of Management 26 (2, Today, and Beyond (Washington, DC: American
2000), pp. 301–339. The quotation is on p. 301. Council on Education, 1995), p. 6.
551. Elizabeth K. Keating and Peter Frumkin, “The 561. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Report on
Price of Doing Good: Executive Compensation in the Employment of Individuals with Disabilities
Nonprofit Organizations,” Policy and Society 29 in the Federal Executive Branch, Fiscal Year 2015
(3, 2010), pp. 269–282. The quotation is on p. 279. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
552. Debra Mesch and Patrick M. Rooney, “Deter- Office, 2016).
minants of Compensation: A Study of Pay, Per- 562. Pan S. Kim, “Disability Policy: An Analysis of the
formance, and Gender Differences for Fundraising Employment of People with Disabilities in the
Professionals,” Nonprofit Management & Leader- American Federal Government,” Public Personnel
ship 18 (Summer 2008), pp. 435–463. The quota- Management 25 (Spring 1996), pp. 73–88. The
tions are on pp. 441, 458. quotation is on p. 73.
553. Partnership for Public Service and Grant 563. American Bar Association, as cited in: Laurie
Thornton, Bracing for Change (Washington, Asseo, “High Court Limits Disabilities Law,”
DC, and Alexandria, VA: Authors, 2012), p. 17. Washington Post (June 22, 1999).
Figures are for 2012. 564. Dan A. Black, Hoda R. Makar, Seth G. Sanders,
554. Robert Roberts, “The Supreme Court and the and Lowell J. Taylor, “The Earnings Effects
Continuing Deconstitutionalization of Public of Sexual Orientation,” Industrial & Labor
Personnel Management,” Review of Public Person- Relations Review 56 (April 2003), pp. 449–470.
nel Administration 29 (March 2009), pp.  3–19. 565. Gregory B. Lewis and David W. Pitts,
The quotation is on p. 4. “Representation of Lesbians and Gay Men in
555. Carol Rusaw, “Professionalism under the Federal, State, and Local Bureaucracies,” Journal
‘Performance-Based Pay’ Reform: A Critical of Public Administration Research and Theory
Assessment and Alternative Development Model,” 21 (January 2011), pp. 159–180. Figures (p. 167)
Public Personnel Management 38 (Winter 2009), are for 2000, and refer to percentages of same-
pp. 35–53. sex partners.
556. U.S. General Accounting Office, High-Risk Series: 566. Eddy Ng, Linda Schweitzer, and Sean Lyons,
Strategic Human Capital Management, GAO-03- “Anticipated Discrimination and a Career Choice
120 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing in Nonprofit,” Review of Public Personnel Admini-
Office, 2003). stration 32 (December 2012), pp. 332–352.
557. Perry, Engbers, and Jun, “Back to the Future?” 567. Benyamin Applebaum and Michael D. Shear,
p. 47. “Once Skeptical of Executive Power, Obama Has
558. Unless noted otherwise, the following list is based Come to Embrace It,” New York Times (August
on: ibid.; Rusaw, “Professionalism under the 13, 2016). Figure is for 2016.
Managing Human Capital 371

568. Lewis and Pitts, “Representation of Lesbians 581. George R. La Noue and John C. Sullivan, “Race
and Gay Men in Federal, State, and Local Neutral Programs in Public Contracting,” Public
Bureaucracies,” p. 169. Figures are for 2000. Administration Review 55 (July/August 1995),
569. The cases are United States v. Walden and pp. 348–356. The quotation is on p. 354.
Hollingsworth v. Perry. 582. The case is MetroBroadcasting v. Federal Com-
570. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2014 munications Commission.
Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey Results, p. 31. 583. The case is CBOCS West, Inc. v. Humphries.
571. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Sexual 584. The case is Gomez-Perez v. Potter.
Orientation and the Federal Workplace, p. ii. 585. U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission,
Datum is for 2010. Retaliation-Based Charges FY 1997-FY 2013.
572. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, “Sexual 586. Linda Greenhouse, “Justices Say Law Bars
Orientation, Workplace Treatment, and the Retaliation Over Bias Claims,” New York Times
Limitations of Survey Data,” Issues of Merit (May 28, 2008). Datum is for 1993–2008.
(September 2009), p. 4. Figure is for 2005, 2007. 587. Robert J. Huntley and Robert J. McDonald,
573. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Sexual “Urban Managers: Organizational Preferences,
Orientation and the Federal Workplace: Policy and Managerial Styles, and Social Policy Roles,”
Perception (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Municipal Year Book, 1975 (Washington, DC:
Printing Office, 2014), p. ii. International City Management Association,
574. U.S. General Accounting Office, Sexual Orient- 1975), pp. 149–159. Data (for 1974) and quota-
ation-Based Employment Discrimination: States’ tion (emphasis added) are on p. 157.
Experience with Statutory Prohibitions, GAO- 588. Lana Stein, “Merit Systems and Political
02-878R (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Influence: The Case of Local Governments,”
Printing Office, 2002), p. 2. Public Administration Review 47 (May/June
575. Nicole DuPuis, Trevor Langan, Christina McFarland, 1987), pp. 263–271. Data (p. 270) are for 1986.
et al., City Rights in an Era of Preemption: A 589. Evelina R. Moulder, “Affirmative Action in
State-by-State Analysis (Washington, DC: National Local Government,” Municipal Year Book 1991
League of Cities, 2017), p. 10. Figures are for 2016. (Washington, DC: International City Management
576. As derived from data in U.S. House of Association, 1991), pp. 47–52.
Representatives, Committee on Government 590. Robert Barnes, “University of Michigan
Reform—Minority Staff, Special Investigations Offers to Be Test Case for Race Admissions,”
Division, Dollars, Not Sense: Government Washingtonpost.com (December 8, 2015).
Contracting Under the Bush Administration 591. The cases are known as Fisher v. University of
(Washington, DC: Author, 2006). Texas I (2013) and Fisher v. University of Texas II
577. The case is Fullilove v. Klutznick. (2016).
578. Mitchell F. Rice and Maurice Mongkuo, “Did 592. Paul Oyer and Scott Schaefer, “Sorting, Quotas,
Adarand Kill Minority Set-Asides?” Public and the Civil Rights Act of 1991: Who Hires
Administration Review 58 (January/February When It’s Hard to Fire?” Journal of Law and
1998), p. 85, and Federal Register, cited in Ann Economics 45 (April 2002), pp. 41–68.
Devroy, “Affirmative Action Rules Are Revised,” 593. Moulder, “Affirmative Action in Local Govern-
Washington Post (May 23, 1996). ment,” p. 51, and Evelina R. Moulder, “Affirmative
579. U.S. Government Accountability Office, New Action: The Role Local Governments Are
Markets Tax Credits: Minority Entities Are Less Playing,” Municipal Year Book 1986 (Washington,
Successful in Obtaining Awards Than Non- DC: International City Management Association,
Minority Entities, GAO-09-536 (Washington, 1986), pp. 24–28 (the data are on p. 26).
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2009), 594. Jean Couturier, “Court Attacks on Testing: Death
Highlights page. Data are for 2005–2008. Knell or Salvation for the Civil Service System,”
580. U.S. Department of Commerce analysis, as citied Good Government 88 (Winter 1971), pp. 10–12.
in Jackie Calmes, “Businesses Owned by Women 595. Couturier, “The Quiet Revolution in Public
Less Likely to Win U.S. Contracts, Study Shows,” Personnel Laws.” Figures are for 1971–1976.
New York Times (February 2, 2016). Figure is for 596. Elizabeth L. Schoenfelt and Leslie C. Pedigo,
2014. “A Review of Court Decisions on Cognitive
372 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

Ability Testing, 1992–2004,” Review of Public Men,” Public Administration Review (September/
Personnel  Administration 25 (September 2005), November 2011), pp. 740–750. The quotation is
pp. 271–287. The quotation is on p. 272. on p. 740.
597. See, for example, James L. Outtz, “The Role of 611. Tim V. Eaton and John R. Nofsinger, “Funding
Cognitive Ability Tests in Employment Selection,” Levels and Gender in Public Pension Plans,”
Human Performance 15 (Spring 2002), pp. 161– Public Budgeting & Finance 28 (September 2008),
171, and Kevin R. Murphy, “Can Conflicting pp. 108–128. The quotations are on p. 108.
Perspectives on the Role of g in Personnel 612. The case is Rosenfeld v. Southern Pacific Co.
Selection Be Resolved?” pp. 173–186, in the same 613. The case is Weeks v. Southern Bell Telephone and
issue. Telegraph Co.
598. Earl Hunt, “When Should We Shoot the 614. The case is American Federation of State, County,
Messenger? Issues Involving Cognitive Testing, and Municipal Employees (AFSCME) v. State of
Public Policy, and the Law,” Psychology, Public Washington.
Policy, and Law 2 (September/December1996), 615. James E. Campbell and Gregory B. Lewis, “Public
pp. 486–505. Support for Comparable Worth in Georgia,”
599. The case is Albemarle Paper Co. v. Moody. Public Administration Review 46 (September/
600. The case is State of Connecticut, et al. v. Adele. October 1986), pp. 432–437.
601. Schoenfelt and Pedigo, “A Review of Court 616. Susan E. Gardner and Christopher Daniel, “Imple-
Decisions on Cognitive Ability Testing, 1992– menting Comparable Worth/Pay Equity: Experi-
2004.” ences of Cutting-Edge States,” Public Personnel
602. The case is Personnel Administrator v. Feeney. Management 27 (Winter 1998), pp. 475–489.
603. The case is Chicago Firefighters Local 2, et al. v. 617. N. Joseph Cayer, “Local Government Personnel
City of Chicago, et al. Structure and Policies,” Municipal Year Book,
604. The case is Johnson v. Transportation Agency, 1991 (Washington, DC: International City/County
Santa Clara County (1987). Management Association, 1991), pp. 8–13.
605. “Local Government Recruitment and Select- 618. Gardner and Daniel, “Implementing Comparable
ion Practices,” Municipal Year Book, 1986 Worth/Pay Equity,” and U.S. General Accounting
(Washington, DC: International City Manage- Office, Pay Equity: Washington State’s Efforts
ment Association, 1986, p. 46. Figure is for 1984– to Address Comparable Worth, GAO/GGO-
1985. 92-87BR (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
606. Stein, “Merit Systems and Political Influence,” Printing Office, 1992).
p. 267. 619. Jared J. Llorens, “Uncovering the Determinants of
607. Jonathan Woetzel, Anu Madgavkar, Kweilin Competitive State Government Wages.”
Elingrud, et al., The Power of Parity: How 620. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Sexual
Advancing Women’s Equality Can Add $12 Harassment in the Federal Workplace: Trends,
Trillion to Global Growth (New York: McKinsey Progress, Continuing Challenges (Washington,
Global Institute, 2015). Figure is for 2015– DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995),
2025. pp. vii, viii, 20, 19. Figures are for 1994.
608. As derived from data in Kweilin Ellingrud, Anu 621. Cynthia S. Ross and Robert E. England, “State
Madgavkar, James Manyika, et al., The Power of Governments’ Sexual Harassment Policy
Parity: Advancing Women’s Equality in the United Initiatives,” Public Administration Review 47
States (New York: McKinsey Global Institute, (May/June 1987), pp. 259–262. Data (p. 261) are
2016). Figure is for 2015–2025. for 1985.
609. Leslie E. Tower and Mohamad G. Alkrady, “The 622. Cayer, “Local Government Personnel Structure
Social Costs of Career Success for Women,” and Policies,” p. 12.
Review of Public Personnel Administration 28 623. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
(June 2008), pp. 144–165. The quotation is on Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016,
p. 144. Table 343. Figure is for 2006.
610. Mohamad G. Alkadry and Leslie E. Tower, 624. As derived from data in U.S. Equal Employment
“Covert Pay Discrimination: How Authority Opportunity Commission, Charge Statistics, FY
Predicts Pay Differences between Women and 1997–FY 2013, and Sexual Harassment Charges:
Managing Human Capital 373

EEOC and FEPA Combined, FY 1997–FY 2011. Politics in the Workplace,” Journal of Management
Figures are for 1997–2011. 22 (Spring 1996), pp. 23–44.
625. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Sexual 642. Rebecca Riffkin, “Americans Still Prefer a Male
Harassment in the Federal Workplace: Trends, Boss to a Female Boss,” Gallup.com (October 14,
Progress, Continuing Challenges (Washington, 2014). Figures are for 2014.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995), 643. Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private and
pp. 7, 18. Public Sector Workers, p. 10.
626. The case is Meritor Savings Bank v. Vinson. 644. Partnership for Public Service, Gender Gaps and
627. The case is Franklin v. Gwinnett County Public Racial/Ethnic Divides, p. 1. Data are for 2011.
Schools. 645. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems
628. The case is Harris v. Forklift Systems, Inc. Protection Board, Prohibited Personnel Practices:
629. The case is Oncale v. Sundowner Offshore Services. A Study Retrospective, p. 9. Figures are for 1992–
630. The cases are Faragher v. City of Boca Raton and 2007.
Burlington Industries, Inc. v. Ellerth. 646. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal
631. Partnership for Public Service, Gender Gaps and Government: A Model Employer or a Work in
Racial/Ethnic Divides (Washington, DC: Author, Progress? p. 41.
2012). Data are for 2011. 647. Mayer, Selected Characteristics of Private and
632. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems Public Sector Workers, p. 9. Current figures are
Protection Board, Prohibited Personnel Practices: for 2013. Growth figures are for 1976–2013.
A Study Retrospective, p. 8. Figures are for 1992– 648. Greg Young, Women, Naturally Better Leaders
2007. for the 21st Century (New York: Routledge,
633. Ugorji O. Ugorji, “Career-Impeding Supervisory 2016), p. 8.
Behaviors: Perceptions of African American 649. Marion Eals and Irwin Silverman, “The Hunter-
and European American Professionals,” Public Gatherer Theory of Spatial Sex Differences:
Administration Review 57 (May/June 1997), Proximate Factors Mediating the Female
pp. 250–255. The quotation is on p. 254. Advantage in Recall of Object Arrays,” Ethology
634. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Fair and and Sociobiology 15 (March 1994), pp. 95–105.
Equitable Treatment, p. 60. 650. Peter J. Kuhn and Marie-Claire Villeval, Are
635. Government Business Council, “The People Women More Attracted to Cooperation than
Problem,” p. 25. Figure is for 2014. Men? (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
636. Government Business Council, “The People Economic Research, 2013).
Problem,” p. 25. Figure is for 2014. 651. Anita Williams Woolley, Christopher F. Chabris,
637. Sungjoo Choi, “Demographic Diversity of Mana- Alex Pentland, et al., “Evidence for a Collective
gers and Employee Job Satisfaction,” Review of Intelligence Factor in the Performance of Human
Public Personnel Administration 33 (September Groups,” Science 330 (October 29, 2010),
2013), pp. 275–298. pp. 686–688.
638. H. E. Hennessey, Jr. and H. John Bernardin, “The 652. Alice H. Eagly and Blair T. Johnson, “Gender and
Relationship between Performance Appraisal Leadership Style: A Meta-Analysis,” Psychological
Criterion Specificity and Statistical Evidence of Bulletin 108 (September 1990), pp. 233–256.
Discrimination,” Human Resource Management 653. Marloes L. Van Engen and Tineke M. Willemsen,
42 (Summer 2003), pp. 143–158. The quotation “Sex and Leadership Styles: A Meta-Analysis of
is on p. 143. Research Published in the 1990s,” Psychological
639. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Fair and Reports 94 (February 2004), pp. 13–18.
Equitable Treatment, p. 66. 654. Ah-Chih Wang, Jack Ting-Ju Chiang, Chou-Yu
640. Ellen V. Rubin, “The Role of Procedural Justice in Tsai, et al., “Gender Makes the Difference:
Public Personnel Management: Empirical Results The Moderating Role of Leader Gender on the
from the Department of Defense,” Journal of Relationship between Leadership Styles and
Public Administration Research and Theory 19 Subordinate Performance,” Organizational
(January 2009), pp. 125–143. Behavior and Human Decision Processes 122
641. Gerald R. Ferris, Dwight D. Fink, Dharm P. S. (July 2013), pp. 101–113. The quotation is on
Bhawuk, et al., “Reactions of Diverse Groups to p. 101.
374 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

655. Richard W. Stackman, Patrick E. Connor, and Administration Research & Theory 22 (October
Boris W. Becker, “Sectoral Ethos: An Investigation 2012), pp. 649–673.
of Personal Values Systems of Female and Male 668. Johann Graf Lambsdorff, “Corruption in
Managers in the Public and Private Sectors,” Empirical Research—A Review,” Paper presented
Journal of Public Administration Research and at the International Anti-Corruption Conference
Theory 16 (October 2006), pp. 577–590. The (Durban, South Africa: December 10–15, 1999),
quotation is on p. 589. p. 13.
656. Leisha DeHart-Davis, Justin Marlowe, and Sanjay 669. Kenneth J. Meier, Sharon H. Mastracci, and
K. Pandey, “Gender Dimensions of Public Service Kristin Wilson, “Emotional Labor in Public
Motivation,” Public Administration Review 66 Organizations: An Empirical Examination of
(November/December 2006), pp. 873–887. the Link to Performance,” Public Administration
657. Julie Dolan, “Gender Equity: Illusion or Reality Review 66 (November/December 2006), pp. 899–
for Women in the Federal Executive Service?” 909, and Kenneth J. Meier and Jill Nicholson-
Public Administration Review 64 (May/June Crotty, “Gender, Representative Bureaucracy, and
2004), pp. 299–306. Law Enforcement: The Case of Sexual Assault,” in
658. Dennis M. Daley and Katherine C. Naff, “Gender the same issue, pp. 850–860.
Differences and Managerial Competencies,” 670. Meier, O’Toole, and Goerdel, “Management
Review of Public Personnel Administration 18 Activity and Program Performance,” p. 32.
(April 1998), pp. 41–56. 671. Victoria Bishop, Catherine Cassell, and Helge
659. Dorothy Olsheski and Raphael Caprio, “Com- Hoel, “Preserving Masculinity in Service Work: An
paring Personal and Professional Characteristics Exploration of the Underreporting of Customer
of Men and Women State Executives: 1990 Anti-Social Behaviour,” Human Relations 62
and 1993 Results,” Review of Public Personnel (January 2009), pp. 5–25.
Administration 16 (January 1996), pp. 31–40. 672. Gregory B. Lewis, “Race, Sex, and Performance
660. Daley and Naff, “Gender Differences and Mana- Ratings in the Federal Service,” Public Admini-
gerial Competencies.” stration Review 57 (November/December 1997),
661. Richard A. Fox and Robert A. Schuhmann,“Gender pp. 479–489. The quotation is on p. 479.
and Local Government: A Comparison of Women 673. Dolan, “Gender Equity,” p. 299.
and Men Managers,” Public Administration 674. Michael J. Zyphur, Jayanth Narayanan, Gerald
Review 59 (May/June 1999), pp. 231–242. Koh, and David Koh, “Testrosterone-Status Mis-
662. DeHart-Davis, Marlowe, and Pandey, “Gender match Lowers Collective Efficacy in Groups:
Dimensions of Public Service Motivation.” Evidence from a Slope-as-Predictor Multilevel
663. Kenneth J. Meier, Lawrence J. O’Toole, Jr., and Structural Equation Model,” Organizational
Holly T. Goerdel, “Management Activity and Behavior and Human Decision Processes 110
Program Performance: Gender as Management (November 2009), pp. 70–79. The quotation is on
Capital,” Public Administration Review 66 p. 70.
(January/February 2006), pp. 24–36. 675. David Fasenfest, Jason Booza, and Kurt Metzger,
664. Willow S. Jacobson, Christine Kelleher Palus, Living Together: A New Look at Racial  and
and Cynthia J. Bowling, “A Woman’s Touch? Ethnic  Integration in Metropolitan Neighbor-
Gendered Management and Performance in State hoods, 1990–2000 (Washington, DC: Brookings,
Administration,” Journal of Public Administration 2004).
Research and Theory 20 (April 2010), pp. 477– 676. Ralph R. Reiland, “Affirmative Action or Equal
544. The quotation is on p. 477. Opportunity?” Regulation 18 (Summer 1995),
665. Meier, O’Toole, and Goerdel, “Management pp. 12–13.
Activity and Program Performance,” p. 32. 677. Edward Felsenthal, “Are Civil-Rights Laws Being
666. Jacobson, Palus, and Bowling, “A Woman’s Interpreted Too Broadly?” Wall Street Journal
Touch?” p. 477. (June 10, 1996).
667. Jason A. Grissom, Jill Nicholson-Crotty, and 678. “Disadvantaged Groups, Individual Rights,” The
Lael Keiser, “Does My Boss’s Gender Matter? New Republic (October 15, 1977), p. 7, and Eliot
Explaining Job Satisfaction and Employee Marshall, “Race Certification,” in the same issue,
Turnover in the Public Sector,” Journal of Public p. 19.
Managing Human Capital 375

679. Pew Research Center for the People and the 693. Page, The Difference, pp. xxiii, 162.
Press, Conflicted Views of Affirmative Action 694. Jason A. Grissom, “The Determinants of Conflict
(Washington, DC: Author, 2003), p. 3. on Governing Boards in Public Organizations:
680. Madeline E. Heilman, Caryn J. Block, and Peter The Case of California School Boards,” Journal
Stathatos, “The Affirmative-Action Stigma of of Public Administration Research and Theory 20
Incompetence: Effects of Performance Information (July 2010), pp. 601–628. The quotation is on p.
Ambiguity,” Academy of Management Journal 40 601.
(June 1997), pp. 603–625. 695. Niels Opstrup and Anders R. Villadsen, “The
681. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press, Right Mix? Gender Diversity in Top Management
Trends in Political Values and Core Attitudes, Teams and Financial Performance,” Public
1987–2007 (Washington, DC: Author, 2007), Administration Review 75 (March/April 2015),
p. 40. pp. 291–301.
682. American National Election Studies, Guide to 696. Rhys Andrews and Rachel Ashworth, “Rep-
Public Opinion and Electoral Behavior, Table resentation and Inclusion in Public Organizations:
4B.4. Evidence from the U.K. Civil Service,” Public
683. Pew Research Center for the People and the Administration Review 75 (March/April 2015),
Press, Conflicted Views of Affirmative Action, pp. 279–288.
p. 3. 697. Norma M. Riccucci and Gregg G. Van Ryzin,
684. Miquel M. Unzueta, Brian Lowery, and Eric D. “Representative Bureaucracy: A Lever to Enhance
Knowles, “How Believing in Affirmative Action Social Equity, Coproduction, and Democracy,”
Quotas Protects White Men’s Self-Esteem,” Public Administration Review 77 (January/
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision February 2017), pp. 21–30.
Processes 105 (January 2008), pp. 1–13. The quo- 698. Sally Coleman Selden, “A Solution in Search of a
tations are on p. 1. Problem? Discrimination, Affirmative Action, and
685. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press, the New Public Service,” Public Administration
Trends in Political Values and Core Attitudes, Review 66 (November/December 2006), pp. 911–
1987–2007, p. 40. 923. The quotation is on p. 918.
686. Pew Research Center for the People and the 699. Riccucci and Van Ryzin, “Representative
Press,  Conflicted Views of Affirmative Action, Bureaucracy,” p. 21.
pp. 5, 2, 3. 700. Huasheng Gao and Wei Zhang, “Employment
687. Caitlin Knowles Myers, “A Cure for Discri- Nondiscrimination Acts and Corporate Inno-
mination? Affirmative Action and the Case of vation,” Management Science (published online
California’s Proposition 209,” Industrial & Labor June 15, 2016).
Relations Review 60 (April 2007), pp. 379–396. 701. Richard Florida and Gary Gates, Technology
The quotation is on p. 379. and Tolerance: The Importance of Diversity to
688. Adam Liptak, “Supreme Court Upholds High-Technology Growth (Washington, DC:
Michigan’s Affirmative Action Ban,” New York Brookings.edu, June 1, 2001).
Times (April 22, 2014). 702. Cedric Herring, “Does Diversity Pay? Racial
689. “How You Hire and Who You Hire: The Composition of Firms and the Business Case
Implications of the Appointing Authority,” Issues for Diversity,” American Sociological Review 72
of Merit (Fall 2014), p. 4. (April 2009), pp. 208–224.
690. Michael Kinsley, “The Spoils of Victimhood,” The 703. Mitchell J. Chang and Alexander W. Astin,
New Yorker (March 27, 1995), pp. 62–69. The “Who Benefits from Racial Diversity in Higher
quotation is on p. 67. Education?” Diversity Digest 2 (Winter 1997),
691. Scott E. Page, The Difference: How the Power of http://www.diversityweb.org/Digest/W97/res
Diversity Creates Better Groups, Firms, Schools, earch.html.
and Societies (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University 704. Page, The Difference, p. xxiii.
Press, 2007), pp. xxiii, 162. 705. Woolley, Chabris, Pentland, et al., “Evidence for a
692. Woolley, Chabris, Pentland, et al., “Evidence for a Collective Intelligence Factor in the Performance
Collective Intelligence Factor in the Performance of Human Groups.”
of Human Groups.” 706. Page, The Difference, p. 314.
376 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

707. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Fair and Government Printing Office, 2014). Figures are
Equitable Treatment, p. 68. Data are for FY for 1992–2012.
2005–2008. 716. Lisa Rein, “Women Who Want to Get Ahead
708. Sungjoo Choi and Hal G. Rainey, “Managing Should Look to the Federal Government, Not Cor-
Diversity in U.S. Federal Agencies: Effects of porate America,” Washingtonpost.com (October
Diversity and Diversity Management on Employee 25, 2016).
Perceptions of Organizational Performance,” 717. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Women in
Public Administration Review 70 (January/ the Federal Government p. 48. Figures are for
February 2010), pp. 109–121. The quotations are 1991–2007.
on p. 116. 718. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
709. Yongbeom Hur, Ruth Ann Strickland, and Dragan Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016,
Stefanovic, “Managing Diversity: Does It Matter Table 487. Figure is for 2013. Unless noted oth-
to Municipal Governments?” International erwise, the following figures on state and local
Journal of Public Sector Management 23 (5, governments’ minority and women employ-
2010), pp. 500–515. ees are drawn from the following sources: per-
710. Selden, “A Solution in Search of a Problem?” centages  for  1980 are derived from data in
p. 914. U.S. Bureau  of the Census, Statistical Abstract
711. Daniel Byler, Steve Berman, Vishwa Kola, and of the United States, 1982–1983, 103rd ed.
William D. Eggers, Accountability Quantified: (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
What 26 Years of GAO Reports Can Teach Us Office, 1982), Table 504, and percentages for all
about Government Management (Washington, subnational employees, officials, and administra-
DC: Deloitte, 2015). Figures are for 1983–2008. tors in 2013 are from ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
712. Anne Joseph O’Connell, as cited in Juliet Statistical  Abstract of the United States, 2016,
Eilperin, “Obama Has Vastly Changed the Face Table 487.
of the Federal Bureaucracy,” Washington Post 719. Jared J. Llorens, Jeffrey B. Wenger, and J. Edward
(September 20, 2015). Figures are for 1977–2015. Kellough, “Choosing Public Sector Employment:
713. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest The Impact of Wages on the Representation of
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016, Women and Minorities in State Bureaucracies,”
Table 487. Figure is for 2013. The following Journal of Public Administration Research and
figures on federal minority and women employ- Theory 18 (July 2008), pp. 397–413. The quota-
ees are drawn from the following sources: per- tions are on p. 397.
centages for 1980 are derived from data in U.S. 720. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil
Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public
the United States, 2011, 130th ed. (Washington, Administration Across the 50 States: Linking
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011), Practice, Theory, and Research through the
Table  499; percentages for all federal employ- American State Administrators Project, 1964–
ees in 2013 are from ProQuest LLC, ProQuest 2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental
Statistical  Abstract of the United States, 2016, Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 11.
Table 519; percentages for executive and 721. Llorens, Wenger, and Kellough, “Choosing Public
senior employees in 2013 are from U.S. Office Sector Employment,” p. 397.
of Personnel Management, Senior Executive 722. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
Service  Facts & Figures (Washington, DC: Change in Public Administration Across the 50
Author, 2015). States, p. 11.
714. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Women 723. Kimberly L. Nelsen and James H. Svara,
in the Federal Government: Ambitions and “Upholding and Expanding the Roles of Local
Achievements (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Government Managers,” Municipal Year Book,
Printing Office, 2011), p. 15. Figures are for 2014 (Washington, DC: International City/County
1991–2009. Management Association, 2014), pp. 3–20. Figures
715. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Govern- (p. 7) are for 2012.
mentwide Strategy on Advancing Pay Equality in 724. Llorens, Wenger, and Kellough, “Choosing Public
the Federal Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Sector Employment,” p. 397.
Managing Human Capital 377

725. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Public Administration Review 44 (May/June
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016, 1984), pp. 244–245. Data are for 1980.
Table 487. Datum is for 2013. 739. Council on Foundations, 2014 Grantmakers
726. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and Salary and Benefits Report (Arlington, VA:
Change in Public Administration Across the 50 Author, 2015).
States, p. 11. Current figure is for 2008. 740. Jessica Chao, Julia Parshall, Desiree Amador,
727. Olsheski and Caprio, “Comparing Personal and et al., Philanthropy in a Changing Society:
Professional Characteristics of Men and Women Achieving Effectiveness through Diversity (New
State Executives.” York: Rockefeller Philanthropy Advisors, 2008),
728. Gayle A. Lawn-Day and Steven Ballard, pp. 6, 19. Current data are for 2006. Trend data
“Speaking Out: Perceptions of Women Managers are for 1982–2006.
in the Public Service,” Review of Public Personnel 741. Council on Foundations, 2014 Grantmakers
Administration 16 (January1996), pp. 41–58. The Salary and Benefits Report (Arlington, VA:
quotation is on p. 42. Author, 2015).
729. International City/County Management 742. Chao, Parshall, Amador, et al., Philanthropy in a
Association, ICMA State of the Profession Survey Changing Society, pp. 6, 19. Datum is for 1982–
2012 Summary, p. 6. 2006.
730. Heidi Voorhees and Rachel Lange-Skaggs, 743. Council on Foundations, 2014 Grantmakers
“Women Leading Government,” PM Magazine Salary and Benefits Report.
(January/February 2015). MPA figure (59 percent) 744. Mesch and Rooney, “Determinants of Compen-
is for 2006. CAO figure is for 2012 and 1981. sation,” p. 457.
731. Jerry Mitchell, “Education and Skills for Public 745. Chao, Parshall, Amador, et al., Philanthropy in a
Authority Management,” Public Administration Changing Society, p. 21.
Review 51 (September/October 1991), pp. 429– 746. Council on Foundations, 2014 Grantmakers
437. Figure (p. 431) is for 1990. Salary and Benefits Report.
732. Friedman and Di Tomaso, “Myths about 747. Alliance for Board Diversity, as cited in Erin Lamb,
Diversity,” and Audrey J. Cohen, “Predictors “Women in Power—Or, Not So Much: Gender
of Public and Private Employment for Business in the Nonprofit Sector,” Nonprofitquarterly.org
College Graduates,” Public Personnel Manage- (January 21, 2015). Figure is for 2013.
ment 22 (Spring 1992), pp. 167–186. 748. Alliance for Board Diversity, Missing Pieces:
733. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, The Federal Women and Minorities on Fortune 500 Boards—
Government: A Model Employer or a Work in Fact Sheet (Washington, DC: Author, 2014).
Progress? pp. 19–20. Figure is for 2012.
734. Bethany G. Sneed, “Glass Walls in Bureaucracies: 749. Chao, Parshall, Amador, et al., Philanthropy in a
Examining the Difference Departmental Function Changing Society, p. 21. Figures are for 2006.
Can Make,” Public Administration Review 67 750. Ronald G. Shaiko, “Female Participation in
(September/October 2007), pp. 880–891. The Association Governance and Political Rep-
quotations are on pp. 888, 880. resentation: Women as Executive Directors,
735. Selden, “A Solution in Search of a Problem,” Board Members, Lobbyists, and Political Action
p. 917. Committee Directors,” Nonprofit Management &
736. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Women Leadership 8 (Winter 1997), pp. 121–139.
in Federal Service: A Seat at Every Table 751. Chuck McLean, 7 Key Findings from GuideStar’s
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing 2015 Nonprofit Compensation Report
Office, 2015). (Washington, DC: GuideStar, 2015). Figures are
737. Eleanor V. Laudicina, “Managing Workforce for 1998–2013.
Diversity in Government: An Initial Assessment,” 752. Mesch and Rooney, “Determinants of Com-
Public Administration Quarterly 19 (Summer pensation,” pp. 458–459.
1995), pp. 170–192. 753. Susan D. Sampson and Lynda L. Moore, “Is There
738. Nelson Dometrius and Lee Sigelman, “Assessing a Glass Ceiling for Women in Development?”
Progress Toward Affirmative Action Goals in State Nonprofit Management & Leadership 18 (Spring
and Local Governments: A New Benchmark,” 2008), pp. 321–339. Gender gap figure is derived
378 PA R T I I I Public and Nonprofit Management

from data on p. 326 and is for 2005. Gap widen- 764. Rosabeth Moss Kanter, Men and Women of the
ing figure is for 1988–2005. Corporation (New York: Basic Books, 1997),
754. Women’s Philanthropy Institute, Indiana Univer- and Joyce K. Fletcher, Disappearing Acts:
sity, Womengive /16 (Bloomington, IN: Author, Gender, Power, and Relational Practices at Work
2016), p. 3. Datum is for 1970s–2000s. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1999).
755. Jillian Berman, “Soon, Not Even 1 Percent of 765. Ethics & Compliance Initiative, Men, Women and
Fortune 500 Companies Will Have Black CEOs,” Ethical Leadership.
Huff Post (April 2, 2015). Figure is for 2015. 766. Pew Research Center for the People and the Press,
756. Domini, The Benefits of Board Diversity Conflicted Views of Affirmative Action, p. 3.
(Providence, RI: Author, 2015). Figure is for Figure is for 2003.
2013. 767. William H. Frey, “New Projections Point to a
757. Jeffrey A. Flory, Andreas Liebbrandt, and John Majority Minority Nation in 2044,” Brookings
A. List, Do Competitive Work Places Deter (December 12, 2014).
Female Workers? A Large-Scale Natural Field 768. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
Experiment, NBER Working Paper No. 16546 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1952, 73rd
(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Research, 2010), p. 31. Office, 1952), Table 208.
758. Lean In and McKinsey & Company, Women in 769. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
the Workplace 2015 (Palo Alto, CA, and New Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016,
York: Authors, 2015), p. 18. Table 605. Current figure is for 2012.
759. Julie Coffman and Bill Neuenfeldt, Everyday 770. Judith J. Friedman and Nancy Di Tomaso,
Moments of Truth: Frontline Managers Are Key “Myths about Diversity: What Managers Need to
to Women’s Career Aspirations (New York: Bain. Know About Changes in the U.S. Labor Force,”
com, 2015). California Management Review 38 (Summer
760. Lean In and McKinsey & Company, Women in 1996), pp. 54–77. The datum is on p. 58.
the Workplace, 2015 (Palo Alto, CA, and New 771. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
York: Authors, 2015), pp. 7, 6, 14. Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016,
761. Alison M. Konrad and Kathy Cummings, “The Table 605.
Effects of Gender-Role Congruence and Statistical 772. U.S. General Accounting Office, The Changing
Discrimination on Managerial Advancement,” Workforce: Demographic Issues Facing Emplo-
Human Relations 50 (October 1997), pp. 1305– yers, GAO/T-GGD-92-61 (Washington, DC: U.S.
1328. Government Printing Office, 1992), pp. 1–7.
762. Kieran Snyder, “The Abrasiveness Trap: High- 773. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the
Achieving Men and Women Are Described Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,
Differently in Reviews,” Fortune (August 26, 1952, Table 208.
2014). 774. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
763. Ethics & Compliance Initiative, Men, Women and Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016,
Ethical Leadership (Arlington, VA: Author, 2016). Table 605. Current figure is for 2012.
PART

IV

Implementing Public Policy

In the fourth and final part of Public Administration And how is it that the complexity of federal admin-
and Public Affairs, we explain how to get things istration has grown ever more challenging and con-
done. Although we touched upon certain aspects voluted, as indicated by the fact that the feds must
of getting things done in Chapter 4, notably in our manage nine times more pages of rules—more than
discussion of administration in organizations, in 80,000 pages currently—than there were in 1953?4
Part IV we take a broader view. The answer to both questions is: Government
Implementation is the execution and deliv- by proxy.5 Rather than expand the civil service to
ery of public policies by organizations or arrange- accommodate the explosions in workload and com-
ments among organizations. It is perhaps the most plexity, Washington elected instead to use the private
“hands-on” facet of public administration, but the sector, subnational governments, and the nonprofit
subject of implementation is, surprisingly but justifi- sector to implement its burgeoning programs and
ably, theoretical and often abstract. policies. In fact, the federal government spends only
We approach the complicated arena of public 7 percent of its budget on the civilian programs that
policy execution in slices of narrowing breadth. federal administrators directly implement,6 and the
That is, we treat first the making of public policy number of federal civilian employees is not some
itself, then the implementation of public policy by two million, as Washington contends, but in reality
the three sectors, then by only the public sector, and is more than nine times that figure, or 19.5 million!
finally by individual public administrators. How is this massive growth in indirect federal
Hence, in the introductory chapter to Part IV, employees possible? Well, we start with the
we explain what is being implemented—that is, 2.1 million civilian employees that Washington cur-
public policy, and how it is made and adjusted. rently admits to, and then we add what are called
The following two chapters focus on the insti- indirect federal employees, or those employees who
tutions that governments use to implement public work outside the federal government, but who are
policy. Their use has extended the reach of govern- paid or mandated by the feds.
ment far beyond its nominal station. Indirect federal employees are difficult to count,
In light of this reach, here are a couple of inter- but here are the best and most current estimates:
esting questions: How is it that the federal civilian 7.5 million workers in the private sector who work
workforce has stayed about the same size, at around largely via federal contracts; 7.7 million employees
two million employees since 1951, (give or take who work in state and local governments because
as many as 200,000, roughly, above or below that federal regulations effectively require their presence
figure over seven decades),1 but federal spending, (about 4.7 million employees7) or federal grants
after controlling for inflation, has quintupled since fund them (another three million, a conservative
that year?2 Over twenty-five years, the amount of estimate8); and 2.2 million workers in the non-
expenditures for which each federal employee was profit sector, who are employed for the most part
responsible doubled, again controlling for inflation.3 under federal grants, plus a large dollop of federal
380 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

contracts.9 When we add these 17.4 million indirect


workers to direct federal employees, the count, as NOTES
noted, nears 20 million federal employees; about 1. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, “Executive
two out of every five American households have in Branch Employment Since 1940,” (Washington,
them someone who is working for the federal gov- DC: OPM.gov, 2015). Figure is for 1951–2014.
ernment.10 2. John J. DiIulio, Jr., 10 Questions and Answers
As a consequence of these facts, “more federal about America’s “Big Government,” (Washington,
employees were responsible [over the course of a DC: Brookings.edu, 2017).
quarter century] not for managing programs but 3. Donald F. Kettl, “From Intergovernmental to
for managing proxies who managed programs on Intersectoral,” Public Administration Evolving:
the government’s behalf.”11 At least one analyst From Foundations to the Future, Mary E. Guy and
Marilyn M. Rubin, eds. (New York: Routledge,
has argued that indirect federal workers should be
2015), pp. 18–36. Data are for 1980–2015.
replaced by a million more federal bureaucrats.12
4. The compendium of federal rules, The Federal
As we also detail in these two chapters, govern-
Register, burgeoned from 8,912 pages of rules in
ment by proxy is not the exclusive preserve of the
1953 to 80,035 pages in 2015. See U.S. Office of the
federal government; states and localities practice it Federal Register, Federal Register Pages Published
with a vengeance as well. As in Washington, these Annually (Washington, DC: Author, 2016).
governments also use the private and independent 5. Donald F. Kettl, Government by Proxy (Washington,
sectors to implement their policies. But, largely unlike DC: Congressional Quarterly Press), 1988.
Washington, states enter into compacts with other 6. Ibid.
states to implement region-wide policies, and pay, 7. As derived from data in: Paul C. Light, Fact Sheet
or simply order, their local governments to conduct on the New True Size of Government (Washington,
state policies in which their localities may have little DC: Brookings, 2003), p. 4, and U.S. Bureau of the
interest. Again in contrast with Washington, local Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,
governments enter into a vast array of intergovern- 1999, 119th ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
mental arrangements and charter special districts to Printing Office, 1999), Table 534. Figures are for
implement their programs. The federal, state, and 1996–1997.
local governments also create businesses to execute 8. DiIulio, 10 Questions about America’s “Big
their policies, and these variations are explained as Government.”
well. 9. Ibid.
Finally, and perhaps of greatest importance, we 10. Light, Fact Sheet on the New True Size of
focus on the specific area of ethical decision making Government, p. 3.
by individual public administrators in the formu- 11. Kettl, “From Intergovernmental to Intersectoral,”
p. 26.
lation and implementation of public policies, and
12. John J. DiIulio, Jr., Bring Back the Bureaucrats
close our book with some thoughts on the passion
(West Conshohocken, PA: Templeton, 2014).
of public administration.
CHAPTER

10
0

Understanding
and Improving
Public Policy
P ublic policy is a course of action adopted and
pursued by government. Public policy analysis
is the study of how governmental policies are made
Act (GPRA) of 1993, and the Office of Management
and Budget’s far-reaching decision in 1994 to staff
its critical resource management offices with policy
and implemented, and the application of available analysts, secured the place of policy analysis in the
knowledge to governmental policies for the purpose federal structure.
of improving their formulation and implementation.1 Today, “policy analyst” is an official job descrip-
tion in the federal civil service, most state capitals,
and some large local governments. Although the
PUBLIC POLICY ANALYSIS: A market for policy analysts is quite a bit smaller than
that for public administrators, policy analysis now
BRIEF HISTORY “is one of the established knowledge industries.”3
The evolution of public policy analysis has two very It is an industry with some impact. Nonpartisan
separate tracks. One is practical, the other academic. policy research organizations “—even those in
highly politicized environments—have a significant
impact on policymaking, mainly by providing infor-
Public Policy and the Policymakers mation and analysis to decision-makers but also in
Woodrow Wilson was the first president to hire influencing public policy outcomes.”4
social scientists. Herbert Hoover also used them
to conduct the first analyses of national economic
and social trends, but Franklin Delano Roosevelt’s Public Policy and the Professoriate
aggressive expansion of government in the 1930s Academia was left in the wake of governments’ pro-
resulted in numerous new federal agencies that relied gress in policy analysis.
on social scientists to devise new public policies.
It was President Lyndon Johnson who accorded Origins It was only in 1951 that the first book on
(if inadvertently) policy analysis a permanent place the topic appeared,5 but the field was then left to
in the federal establishment. Johnson’s attempt, systems analysts and their ilk who worked in think
in 1965, to mandate the Planning-Programming- tanks. In 1965, the first academic conference on
Budgeting System government-wide (recall Chapter policy analysis for social scientists was held,6 and,
8), though largely a failure, ultimately had a lasting in 1971, the Policy Studies Organization, the first of
impact on many agencies in that it “diffused among the public policy associations, was founded; by the
government practitioners . . . systemic procedures for end of the seventies, it boasted some 1,100 members,
rigorously testing policy alternatives.”2 The enact- almost seven out of ten of whom were political
ment of the Government Performance and Results scientists.7
381
382 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

The emergence of public policy can be under- process-focused. It relates to the first part of our
stood, in large part, as political science’s effort to fill definition of public policy analysis: “the study of
the vacuum left by public administration’s depar- how governmental policies are made and imple-
ture, described in Chapter 2. For a half-dozen years mented.” The curriculum typically focuses on spe-
during the 1970s, when public administration’s cific issues, and courses often are titled “The Politics
exodus was in full flood, the number of independent of . . .” some substantive area, such as energy or the
schools and departments of public administration, environment.
and the number of public-policy papers presented Charles E. Lindblom is, perhaps, the leading
at the annual conferences of the American Political representative of the incrementalist paradigm; it was
Science Association, each virtually doubled.8 he who coined the term disjointed incrementalism as
a description of the policymaking process.15 (Earlier,
Homes for Public Policy Public policy now has he called it “muddling through,”16 a much clearer
three homes in universities—its original home of polit- and less pompous moniker.) Disjointed refers to the
ical science (where public policy courses seem to have gap between the assessments of problems and how
displaced courses on “the everyday management of governments actually respond to those problems.
public agencies”9), and newer ones in public adminis- Incrementalism means that policymakers imple-
tration and stand-alone policy programs—plus some ment—very slowly, very few, and very small—policy
huts in economics, psychology, and sociology.10 changes.
Public administration schools and departments The incrementalist paradigm is conservative,
seem to be doing their job: a survey of “senior state gradual, and likely the most politically feasible par-
and local public officials” who had an advanced adigm. It assumes that policymakers lack the brains,
degree in a “government-related field” (52 percent time, and money to fashion systemic and innovative
had Masters of Public Administration degrees and policies.
15 percent, the next highest, had Masters of Public The paradigm contains six subsets, or models,
Policy) found that 88 percent agreed that their of how policy is made, and we consider each in turn.
courses prepared them for a governmental career,
and 91 percent said that they would prefer to hire
someone with a degree similar to theirs.11 The Elite/Mass Model
Public policy’s newest academic home is free- The elite/mass model, often credited to C. Wright
standing schools, most of which emerged in the Mills,17 contends that a powerful policy-making elite,
1980s and thereafter, and which meld the curricula whose members share common values, governs a
of political science and public administration.12 passive, apathetic, and ill-informed mass. Public
Public policy programs have been criticized as policies are designed, above all else, to preserve the
having a “grandiosity” of mission and focusing on status quo.
global and national policies at the expense of sub- Whether the public is apathetic or not, it is clear
national ones.13 Regrettably, the interest that stu- that Congress is controlled by policymaking elites. A
dents enrolled in these schools have in government three-decades study of “1,779 policy issues” found
“declines from entry to graduation,” and some of the following: When economic “elites” (in this case,
these students display “a troubling aversion to gov- the top tenth of individual income earners) supported
ernment, [which] the policy training process . . . may a policy issue, it had a 45 percent chance of passing,
even confirm.”14 and if they opposed, the chances withered to 18
percent; when lobbyists for big business supported
it, it had a 47 percent chance of passage, and, when
THE INCREMENTALIST these lobbyists opposed, a 16 percent chance. When
PARADIGM OF PUBLIC both elites and business supported a policy change,
enactment soared to 60 to 70 percent. If support
POLICYMAKING from even one of those two interests was lacking,
The incrementalist paradigm, favored by political then the proposed policy was never passed.  The
science, is substantive, descriptive, objective, and “average citizens’ influence on policy making . . . is
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 383

near zero. . .. In the United States . . . the majority revolution in political science, it largely was swept
does not rule.”18 aside in favor of studies that relied more on the
group and systems models.

The Group Model


The group model of policymaking, exemplified by The Neo-Institutionalist Model
the work of Arthur F. Bentley,19 views the policy- The institutionalist model has experienced a resur-
making process in hydraulic terms, in which interest rection, of a sort, that might best be described as
groups pressure one another to gain policies that are neo-institutionalism. The neo-institutionalist model,
advantageous to them. Although it traditionally is illustrated in Table 10-1 and created by Theodore
associated with legislatures, it also works for bureau- J. Lowi,23 categorizes public policies according
cracies. The group model explains why some groups to four policymaking subsystems (or what Lowi
“capture” the agencies that ostensibly regulate them, calls  “arenas of power”) that are determined by
thereby defining the public’s interest as the group’s whether the probability of government coercion
interest.20 is remote or immediate, and whether the target of
that coercion is the conduct of individual citizens
or a system.
The Systems Model Each power arena associates with policymaking
The systems model, shown in Figure 10-1, and fre- variables that are unique to it, but there are some
quently attributed to David Easton,21 conceives of institutional commonalities: If the possibility of gov-
the policy process as being cyclical and unending. ernment coercion is remote, then the policy will be
Policy is originated, implemented, adjusted, re- formed primarily in the legislature; if immediate,
implemented, re-adjusted, ad infinitum. then the bureaucracy will dominate policymaking.
In a redistributive power arena, the proba-
bility of government coercion is immediate and
The Institutionalist Model government targets a system. Power is reallocated
The institutionalist model, personified in the writing throughout the polity on a fundamental scale—so
of Carl J. Friedrich,22 focuses on legalities and organ- fundamental, in fact, that redistributive policies
ization charts. With the onrush of the behavioral involve “not use of property but property itself, not

Environment: Social and Economic Variables in the Polity

The “black box” (or the


Inputs: demands, “conversion process,” or Outputs: goods, service,
resources, support, “withinputs”): structures, and symbols to public
opposition procedures, policymakers’ and other policymakers
psycho-social framework

Feedback: The Influence of Outputs on the Environment

FIGURE 10-1
The Systems Model of Public Policymaking and Implementation
384 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

TABLE 10-1
The Neo-institutionalist Model of Public Policymaking and Implementation
Target of Government Coercion
Probability of Government Coercion Conduct of Individual Conduct of System
Remote Distributive policy arena, e.g., Constituent policy arena, e.g.,
agricultural subsidies reapportionment of legislature
Policymaking behaviors and Policymaking behaviors and
characteristics: characteristics:
Decentralized Centralized
Disaggregated Systematic
Local National
Partisan/electoral Ideological
Logrolling Partisan/electoral
Legislatively centered Logrolling
Legislatively centered
Immediate Regulative policy arena, e.g., Redistributive policy arena, e.g.,
elimination of fraudulent advertising progressive income tax
Policymaking behaviors and Policymaking behaviors and
characteristics: characteristics:
Decentralized Centralized
Disaggregated Systemic
Local National
Special interests Ideological
Bargaining among groups Special interest
Bureaucratically centered Bargaining among groups
Bureaucratically centered

equal treatment but equal possession, not behav- In a constituent power arena, coercion is
ior but being.” These policies tend to be highly improbable and policymakers target a system; creat-
ideological, involving battles between the “haves” ing a new agency is an example.
and “have-nots,” are secretive, and have low par-
tisan visibility.24 Examples include Social Security,
Medicare, and Medicaid. Redistributive policies, The Organized Anarchy Model
which are made mostly by administrators, are also, The organized anarchy model is illustrated in
ironically, the most difficult to administer of any Figure 10-2 and was originated by John W. Kingdon.26
policy type.25
The remaining three power arenas are less laden Streams of Problems, Politics, and Policies Basic
with drama. In a distributive power arena, coercion to the model is the presence of three “streams” that
is unlikely and benefits flow directly to each person; constitute the policymaking process.
examples include procurement decisions and pork The first of these is the problems stream, which
barrel legislation. involves defining a problem, focusing policymakers’
In a regulative power arena, coercion is likely attention on it, and then either resolving the problem
but, as with distributive policies, benefits are pro- with a new policy or letting it fade away. Problems
vided to individuals; for instance, the Federal typically are defined in terms of values, such as con-
Aviation Administration may punish violators of its servative or liberal; comparisons, such as the United
safety regulations. States versus Iran; and categories—for example, is
PROBLEM STREAM

1. Getting attention 2. Problem is defined 3. Problem


via: according to: fades

indicators, values,
focusing events, comparisons,
feedback, categories of
budget prioritization policy

WINDOW OPENS
POLITICAL STREAM TO STRUCTURE POLICY IS
DECISION AGENDA; ENACTED
1. Formulation of THREE STREAMS 2. Consensus building 3. Tilt effect
Governmental Agenda by bargaining among
CONVERGE
participants
Major forces include:
national mood
organized interests,
changes in government,
visible cluster of
participants
POLICY STREAM

1. Formulation of 2. Softening-up phase 4. Consensus building


Decision Agenda (e.g., trial by persuasion
(balloons) among participants
Major forces include: 3. Some ideas survive 5. Tilt effect
ideas,
policy entrepreneurs, Criteria for survival
hidden cluster of include:
participants technical feasibility,
value acceptability,
anticipation of
future constraints

FIGURE 10-2
The Organized Anarchy Model of Public Policymaking and Implementation
386 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

public transit for the disabled a “transportation” Windows A window is the opportunity to change
problem or a “civil rights” problem? Categorizing an agenda or create a policy, and a window typically
the problem becomes quite significant in how the is opened by a shift in the national mood. When a
problem is resolved. window opens that results in a restructuring of the
It is in the political stream that the governmen- governmental agenda, it could be solely the result
tal agenda—that is, the list of issues to be resolved— of developments in either the problem stream or
is formed. Actors in this stream comprise its visible the political stream. But for a window to open that
cluster, composed of political executives, legislators, results in a restructuring of the decision agenda
and lobbyists who negotiate to arrive at a consen- requires the convergence of all three streams. In this
sus. Eventually, a “bandwagon,” or “tilt,” effect case, the role of the policy entrepreneur is critical.
occurs that is a consequence of an intensifying desire
among the participants to be “dealt in” on the policy
resolution. THE RATIONALIST PARADIGM
It is in the policy stream that the decision
agenda is formulated, or the list of possible policies OF PUBLIC POLICYMAKING
that could resolve the issue. The stream’s actors com- The rationalist paradigm, favored by public admin-
prise its hidden cluster, composed of career admin- istration, is theoretical, effectual, prescriptive, and
istrators, staffers, and lobbyists (who are powerful normative. It relates to the second part of our defi-
players in both the visible and hidden clusters). Ideas nition: “the application of available knowledge to
and the role of the policy entrepreneur, or the person governmental policies for the purpose of improving
who holds a deep and abiding commitment to a par- their formulation and implementation.” Courses—
ticular policy change, are paramount. e.g., Intergovernmental Relations, Urban Affairs—
are more systemic.
Phases If luck is with the policymakers, a tilt effect The rationalist paradigm is illustrated in
will occur in both the political and policy streams, Figure 10-3 and is associated with Yehezkel Dror,27
but for different reasons. In the political stream, the among others. It focuses on the formation of a sys-
tilt’s cause is negotiation, and in the policy stream temic metapolicy, or a policy for policymaking
it is rationality. From there, a “softening-up phase” procedures that will assure better policies for each
occurs in which trial balloons (i.e., proposed policies) of the full range of issues confronting society. The
are released concerning solutions to the problem. muddled, bounded rationality of the incremental-
These proposals survive according to whether they ist paradigm is eschewed in favor of methodically
are technically feasible, socially acceptable, and are assigning relative weights to all social values; listing
perceived to be free of future constraints, such as all policy alternatives and their consequences; and
budget limitations. selecting the most effective policy to implement.

1. Setting and weighting


of operational goals.

Input: Data in the form


Comparison of policy
of accurately quantified
Preparation of a full set of Calculations of effects (using criterion
social values and the 2. Preparation of a full Policy
predictions of costs and expected effects of efficiency) and
administrative capacity set of alternative policies. Output
benefits of alternatives. of each policy. selection of policy with
to comprehend and
highest net expectation.
use those data.

3. Establishing an inventory
of values and their weights.

FIGURE 10-3
The Rationalist Paradigm of Public Policymaking and Implementation
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 387

We review the two models of the rationalist would favor rigging the sales tax so that gas-
paradigm next, although we should note that the dis- guzzling Bentleys would be taxed at a higher rate
tinctions between them are not as clear-cut as they than compact, electrically-powered Volts. In this
are in the subsets of the incrementalist paradigm. way, the general citizenry would be relieved of the
common costs of a buyer’s choice to buy a Bentley,
but the buyer still would have the freedom to buy
The Rational Choice Model one.
In 1963, a modest collection of scholars met to
discuss, in their words, “developments in the ‘no- Optimality Rational choice is concerned with
name’ fields of public administration.”28 Since then, Pareto optimality, a concept developed by the econ-
names have been acquired, and they include rational omist, Vilfredo Pareto,29 which is a change in eco-
choice, public choice, and political economy, all of nomic policy that makes people as best off as they
which refer to the identification of the optimal mix can be without making anyone worse off.
of social values as the basis for selecting a public Figure 10-4 displays how Pareto optimal-
policy. ity works in a total social context, including the
Rational choice basks in the sunbeam of social economy. It posits a hypothetical social value
engineering. In addressing the issue of energy and (“X”) relative to the accomplishment of all other
the automobile, for example, a political economist social values. The indifference curve refers to the

Value
X
10
Indicates a higher
return on Value X
at the expense of
lower returns on all Indifference curve
other social values

Point of Pareto optimality, or the


Achievement of Value X

most rational public policy

Value achievement
curve
Indicates a lower
return on Value X
in exchange for
higher returns on
all other social values

1 All other
1 Achievement of all other social values 10 social values

FIGURE 10-4
Pareto Optimality
388 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

combination of values about which society is indif- by government, and what kinds are delivered
ferent (at least up to a point); the value achievement more efficiently by other sectors. The model rests
curve indicates the optimal combination of values on two  foundations: exclusion and consumption,
that it is possible for government to encourage. The or use.
point of optimal achievement of Value X and all
other social  values constitutes the point of Pareto Exclusion Exclusion refers to the degree of control
optimality. that both the buyer and seller have over a particular
commodity. High exclusionary control occurs when
Tradeoffs Figure 10-4 also illustrates what the a buyer and seller must agree on a price. Low exclu-
political economists mean by a tradeoff, or what sionary control occurs when price is not an issue.
value is being exchanged, and at what cost and For example, all ships within sight of a lighthouse
benefit, for what other value. In other words, every can benefit from its service.
time Value X is achieved more fully, all other values
are correspondingly reduced in achievement. Consumption or Use Consumption, or use, refer to
how goods are consumed and services are used.
Externalities Executing public policies is a process Individual consumption, or use, occurs when
that is far from tidy, and policies meant to solve goods are consumed or services are used by a single
problems in one social arena can cause problems in person and others are denied access to them. A fish
others. This phenomenon is called an externality, or is an example; once it is consumed by one person, it
spillover effect; that is, the impact of a public policy is gone.
in one sphere “spills over” into other spheres. Joint consumption, or use, occurs when goods
Externalities may be positive or negative, are consumed or services are used simultaneously by
intended or unintended. For example, a positive, many consumers or users without being diminished
intended spillover effect of reducing corporate taxes in quality or quantity. An example is a television
might be to raise employment levels. A negative, broadcast; all viewers may “consume,” or use, a tele-
unintended externality of the same policy might be vision program “jointly” without the program being
to reduce the financial resources available to the diminished.
government for welfare programs. Using the notions of exclusion and consumption,
we can classify goods and services into four kinds of
“pure forms” that can be applied to the sector best
The Public Goods and Services Model equipped to deliver them more efficiently.31
The public goods and services model, diagrammed
in Table 10-2 and exemplified by the work of L. L. Private Goods and Services Private goods and
Wade and R. I. Curry, Jr.,30 deals with what kinds services are pure, individually-consumed goods and
of goods and services are delivered more efficiently individually-used services for which exclusion is

TABLE 10-2
Goods and Services According to the Criteria, of Exclusion and Consumption
Consumption/Use
Exclusion Individual Use Joint Use
Feasible Private goods and services (a bag of groceries, Toll goods and services (cable television,
a haircut, a meal in a restaurant) telephone service, theaters, libraries, electric
power)
Unfeasible Common-pool goods and services (water in a Collective, or public, goods and services (peace
public well, fish in the ocean, air to breathe) and security, public safety, pollution control,
weather forecasts, public television, radio)
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 389

completely feasible. An example is any commodity


in the marketplace. The private sector is the most Arguments over Incrementalism
efficient provider of private goods and services; gov- One problem is that, although the two camps concur
ernment’s role is largely limited to assuring their that the policymaking process is incremental, they
safety and honest representation, although govern- part company over incrementalism’s desirability.
ment’s use of vouchers and subsidies is a case of the The incrementalists hold that incremental poli-
public sector involving itself in the distribution of cymaking works well because the human element is
private goods and services. central to it. The rationalists’ restrictively linear and
technical myopia leads them to make predictions
Toll Goods and Services Toll goods and services are and policies that are often wrong.33 By contrast, bar-
pure, jointly-consumed goods and jointly-used ser- gaining among many stakeholders results in better
vices for which exclusion also is completely feasible. policy, but, should it not, then at least their poor pol-
An example is cable television. Like private goods, icies would be far more limited in their impact than
toll goods generally are supplied most efficiently by would the rationalists’ systemic policies.
the private sector, but, unlike private goods, many The rationalists counter that, “like beautifully
toll goods are natural monopolies. Hence, govern- muscled illiterates, incrementalists . . . have overde-
ment’s role is one of assuring that monopolies are veloped powers of political calculation and under-
granted in a controlled way, and regulated so that developed powers of social imagination.”34 Poor
suppliers do not exploit their monopolistic privileges policies are the pernicious products of the deceit
unfairly. that is inherent in any bargaining-based policy.
Negotiation often requires that rivals hide their real
Common-Pool Goods and Services Common-pool goals, and, as a result, critical realities may be over-
goods and services are pure, individually-con- looked and poor policies may result. Worse, trans-
sumed goods and individually-used services for formational policies (or what politicians sometimes
which exclusion is not feasible. Breathable air is a call “grand bargains”), even when they are clearly
common-pool good. needed, are dismissed by the incrementalists in favor
Common-pool goods and services bring us to of tinkering.
“the tragedy of the commons.”32 Common-pool
goods can be tragic because they are a “commons”
that “belongs” to everyone, and, consequently, Incremental Policymaking? Not So Much
are easily squandered and possibly exhausted. Another issue is that neither paradigm is as grounded
Breathable air can be destroyed by polluters (think in reality as it might be. Policymaking is not as incre-
Beijing); hence, government’s role is to prevent, mental as both paradigms aver. Although incremen-
through regulation, this from happening. talism’s more limited and specific models remain
relevant, incrementalism overall is “a spent intel-
Public Goods and Services Public, or collective, lectual force” that remains, remarkably, “dead yet
goods and services, are pure, jointly-consumed flourishing” in academic circles.35 Perhaps incremen-
goods and jointly-used services for which exclusion talism’s intellectual demise is attributable to its real-
is not feasible. An example is public safety. The mar- world inaccuracies. We consider some of these next.
ketplace cannot supply public safety because it is
used simultaneously by many people, and using it Does Incrementalism Mean Small Changes?
does not diminish its quality or quantity. Here gov- Adherents of both paradigms contend that incre-
ernment is the most appropriate provider. mental policymaking means, in part, that public
policy is the product of small changes. But just what
does “small” policy change actually mean?
PARADIGMATIC PROBLEMS Analysts have found, “surprisingly,” that, in the
The incrementalist and rationalist paradigms have federal budget, “a low proportion of changes are
problems. small by any logical standard. During most years,
more than one-fifth of budgetary changes are greater
390 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

than 50 percent, and nearly half are more than 10 (understanding the process versus improving it),
percent.”36 Another examination concluded that and which disagree over whether incremental pol-
there are as many big policy changes as small ones in icymaking helps or hurts society. Both paradigms
the formulation of public policy in general.37 have, at best, only a limited comprehension of how
so-called “incremental” policymaking actually works
Does Incrementalism Mean Slow Policymaking? in practice.
Contrary to incrementalism’s contention that the What is needed is “a third approach,” one that
policy process is slow, the evidence suggests that it threads its way between the cynical biases of incre-
is not slow, and can happen very quickly. The “grad- mentalism and the utopian longings of rationalism;
ualism model” does not describe change in the policy one that does not substitute numbers for important
agenda “particularly well.” Instead, “a subject rather intangibles, but which does use hard analysis to illu-
suddenly ‘hits,’” and the proportion of policymak- minate choices.40
ers who express interest in a prospective new policy Enter strategic planning.
can  triple from a third to nearly all within a single
year.38
A THIRD APPROACH: THE
Policymaking Is Rarely Incremental If incremen- STRATEGIC PLANNING PARADIGM
tal policymaking is defined as small policy changes OF PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT
made slowly, then the empirical evidence demon-
strates that few—fewer than three out of every ten— POLICYMAKING
changes in public policy are made incrementally.39 Strategic planning is the identification, prioritization,
and communication of major policy goals by organ-
izations on a continuing basis, and the integration
A Pair of Pouting Paradigms of those goals into the management, budgeting, and
So here is what we are left with: two paradigms of performance measurement systems of organizations.
the policy process that have utterly different goals Figure 10-5 illustrates the paradigm.

Incrementalist Resources

Traditions, values, and Budgetary, political, managerial, and Agency leadership:


aspirations of agency intellectual resources of agency and abilities and policy
and its personnel its line personnel priorities

PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT STRATEGIC PLANNING

Analyses of long-term Analyses of short-term political Interagency competition:


environmental trends: trends: threats, opportunities, perceptions and
threats and opportunities perceptions, and directions directions

Rationalist Resources

FIGURE 10-5
The Public and Nonprofit Strategic Planning Paradigm
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 391

Strategic planning debuted in 1962 as the brain- almost two-thirds wed their administrators’ salary
child of Alfred Chandler, Jr., who applied it solely to increases with accomplishing their strategic goals.48
corporations.41 Since then, it has been adopted by Communities that succeed in their strategic
the public and independent sectors. plans have a “powerful process sponsor” (that is,
one or, typically, more, major figures who endorse
strategic planning); a strong “process champion”
Public Strategic Planning (often a skilled administrator); an agency-wide
Governments, mostly local ones, began adopting expectation of disruptions and delays; and a willing-
strategic plans in the 1970s. ness to be flexible.49 Technical difficulties may loom
even larger than political ones in implementing local
Federal Strategic Planning In 1998, the first-ever planning.50
federal government-wide strategic plan was released.
It was both a singular achievement and the direct Perils, Problems—and Advantages—of Public
consequence of the Government Performance and Strategic Planning Public strategic planning
Results Act of 1993. Thanks to the GPRA, planning differs significantly from its corporate counterpart.
was penetrating the bureaucracy; a decade following
its passage, 70 percent of federal managers consid- Governments Are Different City managers and
ered “strategic goals to a great or very great extent in mayors agree that the single greatest obstacle to suc-
allocating resources,” a rising proportion.42 cessful strategic planning is the “need to gain greater
Over the years, however, the GPRA’s limita- control over the external political environment.”51
tions grew more apparent, so, in 2010, Congress Research backs up these officials’ perception that
enacted the GPRA Modernization Act, which aligns governments’ tumultuous external environment dis-
the agencies’ strategic plans with presidential terms rupts the sequential, step-by-step planning that we
and links annual performance goals with strategic associate with the private sector in unique ways,
plans. (We described the act’s related requirements often through arbitrary time constraints, such as
to improve interagency collaboration and perfor- budget and election schedules, that can rush or delay
mance in Chapters 2 and 7, respectively.) strategic decisions in ways that they no longer are
strategic.52 Hence, not only is strategic planning used
State Strategic Planning In 1970, just a third of less in the public sector than in the private one, but
the governors provided written “overall policy guid- governments also are unable to prepare a plan that
ance” (clearly strategic planning, if not so named) to resembles the thick, slick corporate version; indeed,
their agencies in preparing agency budget requests;43 a “well-crafted” strategic plan in local governments
by the mid-nineties, two-fifths of the states had fully amounts to a modest five to seven pages.53
implemented strategic planning and another two-
fifths had partially done so.44 Its adoption by state The Sky Is Falling: The Henny Penny School of
agencies is closely related to a new governor assum- Public Planning Sadly, some observers belong
ing office, sound state finances, substantial state to the Henny Penny school of strategic planning,
experience with the private sector, and when similar asserting that, because of these chaotic conditions,
agencies in neighboring states have adopted it.45 the public-planning sky is falling and it cannot
succeed; the “bold moves” that strategic planning
Local Strategic Planning Sixty-two percent of ostensibly demands of organizations are rendered
cities and counties have strategic plans, and they “almost completely impossible” in government.54
gather no dust: fully half have been revised within Well. Let us remind ourselves that bold moves
the past eighteen months or so, often involving offi- are not necessarily central to successful strate-
cials, citizens, businesspeople, and educators, among gic planning, which simply charts “a third way.”
others.46 More than a third of cities have completed Successful agencies use strategic planning as it
a full cycle of at least one strategic plan over the should be used, scampering between plodding incre-
last five years;47 over four-fifths of cities specifi- mentalism (when they adopt politically prudent
cally budget for their plans’ goals; and, remarkably, “protective” strategies) and rip-roaring rationalism
392 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

(when “developmental,” or even “transformational,” to better performance,”60 and “quantified strategic


strategies are in order).55 priorities lead to better organizational outcomes”
in the public sector—most notably, improved per-
Implementing the Strategic Plan: Public Planning’s formance.61 In light of these benefits, it is significant
Managerial Advantage We discussed in Chapter that, in those cities that have completed two or more
2 the highly networked, collaborative, interactive, strategic plans, an average of three-fifths of their
cross-functional—and quite effective—governance plans’ goals were fulfilled.62
(i.e., Paradigm 6) that characterizes public adminis- Even when accounting for variables that admin-
tration today. Networked governance also results in istrators (local administrators, in this study) cannot
the effective execution of the strategic plan. control—e.g., city size, location, wealth—strategy
A five-year study of 7,600 managers in 262 matters. “A low-performing municipality tends to
companies determined that a slender 9 percent could have a predominantly outward [strategic] orienta-
rely on colleagues in other divisions to implement tion . . . whereas a higher-performing municipality
the plan, and only half could rely on them even most . . . [has a] both inward and outward orientation.”63
of the time; about the same held true for external
actors, such as suppliers. Thirty percent cited failure
to coordinate across units as their “greatest chal- Nonprofit Strategic Planning
lenge,” and, although four-fifths of the companies “Many nonprofit organizations do not use strategic
had cross-functional committees to coordinate plan- planning.”64 Why not?
ning activities, just a fifth of their managers thought
that they worked well. “When managers cannot rely The Resistant Independent Organization The
on colleagues in other functions and units [not to reasons are internal and external.
mention external partners], they compensate with a Internally, third-sector administrators resist
host of dysfunctional behaviors [e.g., delays, dupli- strategic planning because it is more difficult than in
cation] that undermine execution.”56 public and private organizations to attain agreement
Here is public strategic planning’s underly- among stakeholders about what, precisely, their
ing managerial advantage: networking is critical organization’s goals even are. Recall, in this regard,
in implementing strategic plans, and frequently- the lower right quadrant in Chapter 4’s Table 4-1,
collaborative governments manage networking far which illustrates that some nonprofits succumb to
more effectively than the inherently competitive “inspirational” or “authoritarian” decision making
private sector. simply because the unacceptable alternative is
admitting to chaos.
Strategic Planning Improves Public Productivity Externally, the “most critical” reason why non-
Although it has long been known that “strategic profit associations plan at all is that their donors
planning positively influences firm performance” exert “coercive pressure” to force the organization
in  the private sector,57 it only recently has been to “submit a plan of action, leading several authors
determined that there also is a strong and posi- to conclude that nonprofits plan when they have to
tive correlation between it and improved public plan.” This is “one of the strongest research find-
performance. ings” in the field.65
Ninety percent of state agency heads cite “clar- This top-down, donor demand for strategic
ifying agency priorities” and “management direc- planning is known as strategic philanthropy, and it
tions” as strategic planning’s single most useful says a lot that it is a target of nonprofit profession-
feature, followed closely by its utility as a “guide to als’ steaming ire. To wit: nonprofits “have been trying
policy decisions.”58 A head-snapping 93 percent of to demonstrate the nakedness of this autocratic and
municipal officials think that strategic planning is insistent emperor [i.e., strategic philanthropy] for
worth the time and expense that it entails, and only more than a decade, with its proponents meanwhile
2 percent say that it is not.59 acting as if we [nonprofits] were regressive spoil-
Facts support these views. “Logical, clearly sports. . .. imprisoned by logic frameworks, theories of
planned strategies” in government “are a useful route change, and elegant PowerPoint decks.”66 O-Kaaaay.
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 393

The Symbolic Uses of Nonprofit Planning? Because In addition, to be successful strategic planning
most of the independent organizations that have must be continuous, constant, and collaborative.
strategic plans were forced by external powers Regular meetings of executives and planners must
to adopt them, their plans “may be largely sym- be held to adjust plans, develop goals and methods
bolic . . . and the planning process may be decoupled for their attainment, assign specific responsibilities,
from other strategic activities,” such as improving assure cross-functional collaboration, and check
performance.67 off those goals that have been met. Failure to do so
results, again, in dusty, unread, and inevitably dated
Factors for Nonprofit Strategic Success Those plans. As President Dwight D. Eisenhower, a superb
independent organizations that have successful stra- strategic planner, put it: “plans are worthless—but
tegic plans are: larger; have decentralized manage- planning is everything.”72
ment and sophisticated executive directors who play Finally, force upper and middle managers to
a “critical role” in their plan’s success; are governed read the plan, at least annually, and then act on it,
by boards that focus on policy issues rather than by holding budget hearings each year. If their budget
on administration; and feature high levels of trust requests are not linked to the plan’s goals, then their
and healthy working relationships among directors, budgets will suffer.
board members, and operational units.68 Nonprofit
organizations that make strategic decisions also are
more likely to use performance measures and have NOTES
effective governance, diverse funding sources, and a 1. Our definition is based loosely on Harold D.
highly educated executive director.69 Lasswell, A Pre-view of Policy Sciences (New York:
American Elsevier, 1971), pp. 1–2.
Does Independent Strategic Planning Work? Yes! 2. William N. Dunn, Public Policy Analysis: An
Nonprofit organizations that seriously plan stra- Introduction, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
tegically correlate strongly and positively with: Prentice-Hall, 1994), p. 49.
improved performance (just as in public and 3. Ibid., p. 50.
private organizations); organizational growth, 4. John A. Hird, “Policy Analysis for What? The
both in funding and membership; greater effective- Effectiveness of Nonpartisan Policy Research
ness in mission attainment; and improved board Organizations,” Policy Studies Journal 33
effectiveness.70 (Spring 2005), pp. 83–105. The quotation is on
p. 83.
5. Daniel Lerner and Harold D. Lasswell, eds., The
Successful Strategic Planning: Executives, Policy Sciences: Recent Developments in Scope and
Planners, Continuity, Collaboration, and Method (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press,
Budgets 1951).
6. Austin Ranney, “Preface,” Political Science and
To succeed, strategic planning in all sectors must
Public Policy, Austin Ranney, ed. (Chicago:
start with the organization’s highest decision makers.
Markham, 1968), pp. vii–viii.
It is not done by planners. “First we ask: who is
7. Susan B. Hansen, “Public Policy Analysis: Some
leading the planning? If it is a planner . . . we are in Recent Developments and Current Problems,”
trouble.”71 Why? Because only top officers can link Political Science: The State of the Discipline,
the three critical components of strategic planning: Ada W. Finifter, ed. (Washington, DC: American
goals, actions, and outcomes. Political Science Association, 1983), pp. 217–246.
When chief executives are not involved in the 8. Nicholas Henry, Public Administration and Public
planning process, the usual consequence is all too Affairs, 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
well known: irrelevant, unread plans. Planners Hall, 1989), p. 291.
are most useful when they provide strategic deci- 9. Howard Risher, “Amid All the Pomp, Where Are
sion makers with pertinent information, and then the Public Management Degrees?” Govexec.com
nag  them to act on that information in a timely (May 19, 2015).
manner. 10. Dunn, Public Policy Analysis, p. 50.
394 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

11. J.B. Wogan, “Want to Govern? Survey Says, Attend 27. Yehezkel Dror, Public Policy Making Reexamined
Policy School,” Governing (July 24, 2014). (San Francisco: Chandler, 1968), p. 8.
12. Steven G. Koven, Frank Goetz, and Michael 28. Vincent Ostrom “Editorial Comment: Develop-
Brennan, “Profiling Public Affairs Programs: The ments in the No-Name Fields of Public Admin-
View from the Top,” Administration & Society 40 stration,” Public Administration Review 24
(November 2008), pp. 691–710. (January/February 1964), pp. 62–63.
13. James Piereson and Naomi Schaefer Riley, “The 29. Vilfredo Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique
Problem with Public Policy Schools,” Washington (Geneva, Switzerland: Droz, 1896).
Post (December 6, 2013). 30. L. L. Wade and R. I. Curry, Jr., A Logic of Public
14. Carol Chetkovich, “What’s in a Sector? The Policy: Aspects of Political Economy (Belmont, CA:
Shifting Career Plans of Public Policy Students,” Wadsworth, 1970).
Public Administration Review 63 (November/ 31. E. S. Savas, Privatizing the Public Sector: How
December 2003), pp. 660–674. The quotations are to Shrink Government (Chatham, NJ: Chatham
on pp. 660, 670–671. House, 1982), p. 33.
15. Charles E. Lindblom, The Policy Making Process 32. Garrett Hardin, “The Tragedy of the Commons,”
(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1968). Science 162 (December 13, 1968), pp. 1243–
16. Charles E. Lindblom, “The Science of Muddling 1248.
Through,” Public Administration Review 19 33. William Ascher, “Forecasting Potential of Complex
(Spring 1959), pp. 79–88. Models,” Policy Sciences 13 (May 1981), pp. 247–
17. C. Wright Mills, The Power Elite (New York: 267.
Oxford University Press, 1956). 34. George Keller, Academic Strategy: The Management
18. Martin Gilens and Benjamin I. Page, “Testing Revolution in Higher Education (Baltimore: Johns
Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Hopkins University Press, 1983), p. 113.
Groups, and Average Citizens,” Perspectives on 35. Jonathan Bendor, “Incrementalism: Dead yet
Politics 12 (3, 2014), pp. 564–581. Data are for Flourishing,” Public Administration Review 75
1980–2009. The quotations are on pp. 564, 576. (March/April 2015), pp. 194–205.
Emphasis is original. 36. Sarah Anderson and Laurel Harbridge, “Incre-
19. Arthur F. Bentley, The Process of Government mentalism in Appropriations: Small Aggregation,
(Bloomington, IN: Principia Press, 1949). First Big Changes,” Public Administration Review 70
published in 1908. (May/June 2010), pp. 464–474. The quotation is
20. Louis M. Kohlmeier, The Regulators: Watchdog on p. 464.
Agencies and the Public Interest (New York: 37. Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Poli-
Harper & Row, 1969). cies, p. 81.
21. David Easton, The Political System (New York: 38. Ibid., p. 80.
Knopf, 1953). 39. Ibid., p. 82.
22. Carl J. Friedrich, Constitutional Government and 40. Amitai Etzioni, “Mixed Scanning: A Third Approach
Democracy (Boston, Little, Brown, 1941). to Decision Making,” Public Administration Review
23. Theodore J. Lowi, “Four Systems of Policy, Politics, 27 (December 1967), pp. 385–392.
and Choice,” Public Administration Review 33 41. Alfred Chandler, Jr., Strategy and Structure:
(July/August 1972), pp. 298–310. Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise
24. Theodore J. Lowi, “American Business, Public (Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of
Policy, Case-Studies, and Political Theory,” World Technology Press, 1962).
Politics 16 (July 1964), pp. 677–693. The quota- 42. U.S. General Accounting Office, Results-Oriented
tions are on p. 691. Government: GPRA Has Established a Solid
25. Thomas J. Greitens and M. Ernita Joaquin, Foundation for Achieving Greater Results, GAO-
“Policy Typology and Performance Measurement: 04-38 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Results from the Program Assessment Rating Tool Office, 2004), p. 43. Figure is for 2003.
(PART),” Public Performance & Management 43. Robert C. Burns and Robert D. Lee, Jr., “The
Review 33 (June 2010), pp. 555–570. Ups and Downs of State Budget Process Reform:
26. John W. Kingdon, Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Experience of Three Decades,” Public Budgeting &
Policies, 2nd ed. (New York: Longman, 2003). Finance 24 (Fall 2004), pp. 1–19.
Understanding and Improving Public Policy 395

44. Jeffrey L. Brudney, F. Ted Hebert, and Deil S. Administration Review 46 (July/August 1986),
Wright, “Reinventing Government in the American pp. 321–327.
States: Explaining Administrative Reform,” Public 56. Donald Sull, Rebecca Homkes, and Charles Sull,
Administration Review 59 (January/February “Why Strategy Execution Unravels—and What to
1999), pp. 19–30. Do about It,” hbr.org [Harvard Business Review]
45. Frances Stokes Berry, “Innovation in Public Man- (March 2015).
agement: The Adoption of Strategic Planning,” 57. C. Chet Miller and Laura B. Cardinal, “Strategic
Public Administration Review 54 (July/August Planning and Firm Performance: A Synthesis of
1994), pp. 322–329. Figures are for 1992. More than Two Decades of Research,” Academy
46. Evelina R. Moulder, “Citizen Engagement: An of Management Journal 37 (December 1994),
Evolving Process,” Municipal Year Book, 2010 pp. 1649–1665. The quotation is on p. 1649.
(Washington, DC: International City/County 58. Frances Stokes Berry and Barton Weschler, “State
Management Association, 2010), pp. 28–32. Data Agencies’ Experience with Strategic Planning:
(p. 29) are for 2009. Findings from a National Survey,” Public Admini-
47. Gregory Streib and Theodore H. Poister, “The Use stration Review 55 (March/April 1995), pp. 159–
of Strategic Planning in Municipal Governments,” 168. The quotation is on p. 165. Data are for 1992.
Municipal Year Book, 2002 (Washington, DC: 59. Streib and Poister, “The Use of Strategic Planning
International City/County Management Asso- in Municipal Governments,” pp. 23–24. Data are
ciation, 2002), pp. 18–25. for circa 2001.
48. Theodore H. Poister and Gregory Streib, 60. Richard M. Walker, Rhys Andrews, George A.
“Elements of Strategic Planning and Management Boyne, et al., “Wakeup Call: Strategic Management,
in Municipal Government: Status after Two Network Alarms, and Performance,” Public
Decades,” Public Administration Review 65 Administration Review 70 (September/October
(January/ February 2005), pp. 45–56. 2010) pp. 731–741. The quotation is on p. 738.
49. John M. Bryson and William D. Roering, “Initiation 61. George A. Boyne and Alex A. Chen, “Performance
of Strategic Planning by Governments,” Public Targets and Public Service Improvement,” Journal
Administration Review 48 (November/December of Public Administration Research and Theory
1988), pp. 995–1004. 17 (July 2007), pp. 455–478. The quotation is on
50. George A. Boyne, Julian S. Gould-Williams, p. 455.
Jennifer Law, and Richard M. Walker, “Problems 62. Poister and Streib, “Elements of Strategic Planning
of Rational Planning in Public Organizations: An and Management in Municipal Government,” p.
Empirical Assessment of the Conventional 51. Figures are for circa 2001.
Wisdom,” Administration & Society 36 (July 63. Hans Knutsson, Ola Mattison, Ulf Ramberg, and
2004), pp. 328–350. Torbjorn Tagesson, “Do Strategy and Management
51. Gregory Streib, “Strategic Capacity in Council- Matter in Municipal Organisations?” Financial
Manager Municipalities: Exploring Limits and Accountability & Management 24 (August 2008),
Horizons,” International Journal of Public pp. 295–319. The quotations are on p. 295.
Administration 15 (9, 1992), pp. 1737–1755. The 64. Melissa M. Stone, Barbara Bigelow, and William
quotation is on p. 1737. Crittenden, “Research on Strategic Management
52. Gerald J. Miller, “Unique Public-Sector Strategies,” in Nonprofit Organizations: Synthesis, Analysis,
Public Productivity & Management Review 13 and Future Directions,” Administration & Society
(Winter 1989), pp. 133–144. 31 (July 1999), pp. 378–423. The quotation is on
53. International City/County Management Asso- p. 383.
ciation, “Strategic Planning: A Guide for Public 65. Ibid, p. 391.
Managers,” IQ Report 34 (August 2002), 66. Ruth McCambridge, “The Strategic Philan-
p. 9. thropy Crowd: Qualified Apologies-R-Us,” Non-
54. Miller, “Unique Public-Sector Strategies,” pp. 137– profitquarterly.org (April 6, 2016).
138. 67. Stone, Bigelow, and Crittenden, “Research on
55. Barton Weschler and Robert W. Backoff, “Policy- Strategic Management in Nonprofit Organi-
making and Administration in State Agencies: zations,” pp. 408–409.
Strategic Management Approaches,” Public 68. Ibid., pp. 406, 408–409.
396 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

69. Kelly LeRoux and Nathaniel S. Wright, “Does 71. Michael Aiken and Jerald Hage, “The Organic
Performance Measurement Improve Strategic Organization and Innovation,” Sociology 5
Decision Making? Findings from a National Survey (January 1971), pp. 63–82. The quotation is on
of Nonprofit Social Service Agencies,” Nonprofit p. 80.
Leadership & Voluntary Sector Quarterly 39 72. Quoted in David A. Nichols, “As Israel-Iran
(August 2010), pp. 571–587. Tensions Mount, a Lesson for Obama from
70. Stone, Bigelow, and Crittenden, “Research on Eisenhower,” Washington Post (March 7, 2012).
Strategic Management in Nonprofit Organizations,”
p. 391.
CHAPTER

11

Intersectoral
Administration

G overnments source. Sourcing is the selection of


an entity and a method that public administra-
tors judge to be the most appropriate and efficient
among governments and for-profit and nonprofit
organizations for the purpose of achieving specific
public policy goals. Figure 11-1 illustrates the major
for delivering a public program or service, or imple- characteristics of these sectoral configurations, and
menting a public policy. arrays them on a public-private continuum.
Public administrators making sourcing deci-
sions may, in keeping with tradition, insource—
that is, designate their own agency as the entity to WHY PRIVATIZE?
implement their agency’s program. Or, instead, they Governments’ decision to collaborate with busi-
might choose to outsource a program—that is, use nesses and nonprofit organizations in implement-
an entity other than their own agency. ing public policies stems from several positive
A major outsourcing method that governments impulses (and a few negative ones). They include
at all levels use is privatization, or government the following:
selling goods and property to the private and non-
profit sectors, and government buying goods, prop- ■ Savings: Savings often can be realized. For
erty, and services from those sectors. Most countries example, civil service rules on pay scales
privatize primarily by selling off assets, often state- and benefits may be skirted by using private
owned companies, to the private sector, but the gov- contractors who pay only minimum wages and
ernments of the United States (which also sell assets) offer few benefits to their employees.
prefer purchasing from the private and nonprofit ■ Cost clarification: A particularly important
sectors. form of collaboration, contracting out the
The federal government privatizes primarily by delivery of government services to the private
purchasing goods, property, and services for its own and nonprofit sectors, clarifies the true costs of
use, but state and local governments privatize prin- public programs by placing those programs in
cipally by contracting with companies and funding the competitive marketplace.
nonprofit organizations to deliver their services ■ Fiscal easements: Cumbersome fiscal
to their jurisdictions’ residents. (All governments procedures can be bypassed and revenues
also collaborate with other governments to deliver raised in ways that more constitutional
services, but that is a topic we have reserved for approaches inhibit.
Chapter 12.) ■ Human capital easements: Governments can
We call these incredibly convoluted phenom- hire people of unusual talent without paying
ena intersectoral administration, which is the man- as much attention to sometimes inconvenient
agement and coordination of the relationships public personnel policies.
397
Public Sector Independent Sector Private Sector

Governments and Government Public-Serving Member-Serving Government- Private Corporations


Government Corporations/Public Nonprofit Associations Nonprofit Associations Sponsored
Agencies Authorities and and Organizations and Organizations Enterprises E.g., Union Pacific
Special Districts Railroad
E.g., Governments of E.g., United Way E.g., AFL-CIO E.g., Federal National
the United States E.g., Amtrak Railway Mortgage Association Microsoft, Inc.
Harvard University Republican Party
California State Port Authority of New Federal Home Loan Mom and Pop’s
University York and NewJersey Episcopal Church Medinah Country Mortgage Corporation Grocery
Club
Finance Department
South Florida Federal Home Loan
of the City of
Cleveland Conservancy District Banks

Selected Selected Selected Selected Selected Selected


Characteristics Characteristics Characteristics Characteristics Characteristics Characteristics

Created by society Created by Created by private Created by private Created and regulated Created by private
to formulate, government to citizens to provide and citizens to provide and by the U.S. investors to earn
interpret, and administer a public administer public administer member Government to money for investors
execute public service benefits benefits protect its interests
policies Privately owned and
Publicly owned and Privately owned and Privately owned and Two are publicly controlled
Publicly owned and controlled controlled controlled owned, three are
controlled privately owned Funded by private
Funded by user fees, Funded by earned Funded by earned investors
Funded by taxes taxes, borrowing, income, government income and/or Credit markets and
and other and/or government contracts and grants, membership dues, investors perceive Seek profits
government appropriations, in and/or private in whole or in part implied financial
revenues whole or in part donations, in whole or backing by the U.S. Pay taxes
in part Do not seek profits Government
Do not seek profits Independent or part
of a government Do not seek profits Do not pay taxes Seek profits
Do not pay taxes agency
Do not pay taxes Donations/dues are Do not pay corporate
Do not seek profits not tax deductible income taxes, but
Donations are tax some pay property
Do not pay taxes deductible taxes

Public Private

FIGURE 11-1
Organizations and Characteristics of the Public, Independent, and Private Sectors
Intersectoral Administration 399

■ Experimentation: Using other sectors to governments has made privatization immensely


experiment with new policies and procedures easier to implement. This is especially the
appears to be highly valued among public case when conservatives, who embrace this
administrators, or at least among the more orthodoxy far more fervently than liberals, are
talented ones. Cities that privatize associate in power.5
with “innovative managerial and institutional
strengths.”1 This orthodoxy has deep roots. The highly influential
■ Lowered political risk: Government municipal research bureaus (mentioned in preced-
becomes less visible when public policies are ing chapters) of the early twentieth century were
implemented by organizations other than supported by “a small number of wealthy business
government, and avoiding risk, particularly people,” and their staffs, unsurprisingly, “gave defer-
political risk, is a major motivation to ence in their publications to the wonders of business
outsource.2 efficiency, regardless of the accuracy of the claim.”6
■ Image enhancement: Privatization can enhance The orthodoxy lives on. Here are two examples
the image of lean but effective governance. drawn from government and academia.
The personnel working for government can When a Senator questioned an official why the
be expanded through agreements with other federal government relied so heavily on contrac-
sectors, even though the official size of the civil tors to vet prospective employees (contractors who,
service remains the same or decreases. as we discuss later, failed spectacularly in doing
■ Greater leverage: Public services can be this), the official replied that contractors (on whom
enhanced by private- and independent-sector Washington lavished $1 billion annually to conduct
organizations that already may be doing what background checks) were cheaper than government
the government wishes to do. employees. Were there analyses showing this? No.
■ Economic development: Outsourcing can assist Then how did he know? He just did. The exasper-
the economic development of a jurisdiction, ated Senator stated, “I’m tired of this assumption
especially local ones, by channeling public that contractors are cheaper. I just think it’s easier”
funds, through contracts and subsidies, to for the official to make such an assumption.7
companies and nonprofit organizations, which When the woefully mismanaged town of Ecorse,
then add more people to their payrolls. Michigan, was restored to fiscal health in 1990, a
■ Emergency management: Government often process that was accompanied by contracting out
collaborates with volunteers and nonprofit almost every service in sight to the private sector,
organizations when emergencies occur. academics concluded that the “Ecorse experiment
■ Incentive to improve public productivity: The shows that . . . privatized services have the power
“threat of privatization,” and the possible loss to weed out incompetence and inefficiency, and the
of their government jobs, according to a review private sector can respond to changing conditions
of this research, may spur public employees to much more quickly than can bureaucracies.”8
raise governmental performance.3 The belief that business is better is deeply
■ Pinstripe patronage: “Pinstripe patronage,” entrenched in America’s most powerful institutions.
such as no-bid contracts and revolving doors, As we shall learn in this chapter, it is a belief that is
is inherent in collaborative arrangements, and often misplaced.
it can advance public officials’ legitimate and
even inspiring visions of a better future, or, as
we describe later, erode efficient and effective FEDERAL PRIVATIZATION
governance by sustaining conflicts of interest No governmental level is as deeply entrenched in
and graft.4 privatization as is the national one, an entrenchment
■ An American orthodoxy: Finally, the belief, that began in 1789, when Congress directed that the
held by many in government and academia secretary of the treasury should “provide for con-
(and, certainly, in business) that businesses tracts which shall be approved by the President” to
deliver services more efficiently than build and maintain a lighthouse on Chesapeake Bay.9
400 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Like all governments, the federal one both sells hovered in the neighborhood of a half-trillion dollars
to and buys from the private sector. We start with annually, account for two-fifths of federal discre-
selling. tionary spending. Four departments, led by Defense
(Washington’s Croesus of contracting, spending 63
percent of all contract dollars), are followed, respec-
Federal Fire Sales tively, by Energy, Health and Human Services, and
Washington is profoundly into the business of pur- Veterans Administration, which, together, account
veying the people’s property. The federal govern- for another 15 percent of contract spending.17
ment is the biggest electronic vendor in the world, Perhaps the most significant new wrinkle in
selling about $3.6 billion of its assets, ranging from federal purchasing is that Washington is buying
horses to helicopters, over the Internet each year.10 fewer goods and more services. A federal service
The Pentagon alone sells or donates nearly $3.2 contract is a legal agreement for the provision by the
billion annually in unneeded property, excluding real private sector of a wide swath of services, such as
estate.11 consulting, training, or leasing, to the federal gov-
Increasingly, however, Washington also is ernment.
ridding itself of real estate, and with good reason. In 1985, service contracts amounted to only
The federal government is the largest property 23 percent of all federal contracting dollars.18 Today,
owner in the United States, owning nearly 39 they account for 60 percent.19 Remarkably, even in
million acres, more than 254,000 buildings con- the Pentagon, service contracting, at 52 percent of
taining over 2.5 billion square feet, and almost all Defense contracts, surpasses all other Defense
478,000 “structures” (e.g., airfields, harbors); contracting (i.e., supplies and equipment, including
annual operating costs for all this top $22 billion. weapon systems), a “major shift.”20
In addition, the feds spend another $7 billion or so As an indication of their growing importance,
to lease land, buildings, and structures, for a total Congress, in 2003, passed the Services Acquisition
of more than $29 billion per year.12 Although most Reform Act, which encourages the use of perfor-
of these numbers are in decline, Congress neverthe- mance-based service contracts. In 2013, the General
less contends that 7,000 real properties, worth $350 Services Administration (GSA) pioneered its revo-
billion, are “unneeded.”13 In 2003, the Government lutionary One Acquisition Solution for Integrated
Accountability Office (GAO) placed federal real Services for managing service contracts, which, by
property on its “high-risk” list of areas that are most accounts, has rendered the bid process fairer
unduly vulnerable to fraud, waste, abuse, and mis- and simpler for bidders, and more cost-effective for
management, where it remains. government.

Humongous Hiring: “Indirect” Federal Employees


The Enormity of Acquisitions The Congressional Budget Office “is unaware of any
Huge as Washington’s selling is, it pales by compari- comprehensive information about the size of the
son to its buying. Federal purchasing, also known as federal government’s contracted workforce,”21 but
procurement or acquisitions, is the federal govern- as we noted in the introduction to Part IV, there are
ment’s contracting with organizations in the private an estimated 7.5 million “indirect” federal employees
and nonprofit sectors to buy goods, property, and working in the private sector, or well over three times
services. the number of federal direct employees, plus mil-
lions more indirect employees in the nonprofit sector
Portentous Purchasing Globally, governments’ (detailed later in this chapter) and in state and local
spending on procurement amounts to $4.4 trillion governments (discussed in Chapter 12).
per year—an estimate, but no less staggering for
it.14 The United States government is the largest pur-
chaser in the world.15 Almost 16 million contracts Federal Philosophies of Purchasing
are let each year by federal agencies.16 Washington’s On what basis does the federal government ration-
contract expenditures, which historically have alize its enormous acquisitions? It has done so, over
Intersectoral Administration 401

time, through its development of various philoso- will continue to constitute a critical component of
phies of procurement. any future wars.27
In 2011, the Office of Federal Procurement
OMB Circular A-76 The first expression of these Policy issued Policy Letter 11-01, “Performance of
philosophies appeared in 1955, when what is now Inherently Governmental and Critical Functions,”
the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) issued a seventy-five page compendium containing an
Bureau of the Budget Bulletin Number 55-4, which expanded, but essentially unchanged, definition of
stated straightforwardly that the government would inherently governmental function and two dozen
rely on the private sector for commercial goods and illustrative, but not exhaustive, examples of it. It is
services so that it would not be competing with busi- not apparent that the letter has significantly clarified
ness. its meaning.
In 1966, OMB altered this philosophy when Identifying activities that are “inherently gov-
it issued OMB Circular A-76, “Performance of ernmental,” in sum, “is like trying to nail Jell-O to
Commercial Activities,” which reiterated the 1955 the wall; only nailing Jell-O is easier.”28
bulletin, but added that the government should
perform those functions that “are inherently govern- Identifying Commercial Activities Commercial
mental in nature.” activities are those functions that are more appro-
Here were the makings of a magnificently messy priately conducted by businesses rather than by
mire. What functions are governmental, and which government. In 1998, Congress mandated that the
are commercial? government’s commercial activities be identified
every year by passing the Federal Activities Inventory
Identifying Inherently Governmental Activities— Reform Act (the FAIR Act).
Or Not An inherently governmental activity, first More than 700 specific commercial activities
defined in the Federal Activities Inventory Reform have been unearthed.29 About a fourth of all federal
Act of 1998, “is a function that is so intimately activities are “competable commercial,” which
related to the public interest as to mandate perfor- potentially could be privatized, and another quarter
mance by Government employees. . .. Governmental are “noncompetable commercial,” or functions that
functions normally fall into two categories: (1) the have been exempted from competition by statute or
act of governing . . . and (2) monetary transactions other means.30 The remaining half is composed of
and entitlements.”22 governmental activities.
This description may sound crisp, clear,
and concise, but, alas, it is not. Consider war. The Costs of Comparing Costs OMB Circular
Most of us think that war, which constitution- A-76 and the FAIR Act were the bases of competitive
ally can be  declared only by Congress, is about sourcing, or public-private competitions, which were
as “inherently  governmental” as it gets, but the cost comparisons that determined whether federal
Constitution  also empowers Congress to “grant agencies or private companies would win federal
Letters of Marque and Reprisal”—that is, to contracts to conduct Washington’s competable com-
authorize privateers to make war on the nation’s mercial activities. Philosophically, or, perhaps, ide-
behalf. Privateering faded following the War of ologically, these competitions reflected a view that
1812, perhaps because, just as Congress taxes the business was more cost effective than government.
fees that it pays its contractors, it taxed the booty The Pentagon initiated its own version of com-
looted by its privateers.23 petitive sourcing in 1975, it was extended to civil-
Today, privateers are back. For example, 53 ian agencies in 1981, and it was reinvigorated in
percent of the Pentagon’s personnel in Afghanistan the 1990s during the administration of President
and Iraq were not warriors, but contracted workers.24 Bill Clinton, which conducted a record number
More than 2,000 of them were killed in the conflicts, of public-private competitions. President George
or a quarter of all American deaths,25 and some were W. Bush’s administration revised OMB Circular
awarded medals ostensibly reserved exclusively for A-76, in 2003, to facilitate the competitions, but, in
soldiers.26 It is officially projected that contractors 2007, the Washington Post exposed vile treatment
402 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

of veterans at the recently privatized Walter Reed Procurement’s Personnel: The Contracting Cadres
Hospital, and, since that year, Congress has prohib- The primary purchasing personnel are an “acquisi-
ited public-private competitions in all federal agen- tion workforce” that numbers over 73,000, the core
cies via its annual appropriations. of which is more than 37,000 contracting officers
Congress’s action reflected problems that who are responsible for managing federal acquisi-
loomed larger than a single hospital. Competitive tion policies.38
sourcing was largely a failure, in part because the Congress’s first foray into upgrading the con-
effort “ran aground on shoals of incomplete data,”31 tracting cadres was its creation, in 1976, of the
and a pricey one. It cost from $150 million to $300 Federal Acquisition Institute, and, in 2004, GSA
million annually;32 each cost comparison took an opened its Center for Acquisition Excellence; both
average of a disruptive four years and three months are dedicated to training procurement officers
to complete;33 and, at the end of the day, “no one . . . government-wide.
really knew . . . how much on balance it had saved Agencies, however, prefer to train their own
the American taxpayer.”34 In fact, federal agencies, purchasing staffs. In 1990, Congress established
not companies, won 91 percent of the public-private a separate career path for the Pentagon’s acqui-
competitions, a rising figure,35 suggesting that the sitions specialists, and, in 1991, founded the
private sector was, in general, less efficient than the Defense Acquisition University. The departments
federal one in conducting federal programs. of Homeland Security, Treasury, and Veterans
Administration operate their own dedicated train-
ing centers, and seventeen major agencies use other
Washington’s Buying Bureaucracy sources to train, including some that rely on the
The federal government has developed a host of pro- vendors whom their administrators are expected to
cesses and personnel to manage its purchasing. oversee.39
These are, for the most part, constructive
Procurement’s Policies, Procedures, and moves, but whether training actually has improved
Processes Congress took an interest in privatiza- purchasing is unknown due a lack of data.40 We do
tion more than six decades ago, and has, over the know, however, that little progress has been made in
years, enacted legislation that mandated advertised addressing the skills gap, unstable budgets, and inad-
and data-driven bidding for federal contracts, estab- equate oversight, which have slowed improvement
lished an appeals system for bidders who fail to win in acquisitions.41 In fact, every one of seven inde-
contracts, and prohibited contract officers from dis- pendently-conducted surveys of acquisition officials
cussing employment prospects with, and slipping taken over twelve years “overwhelmingly identified
inside information to, contractors with whom they general business acumen, risk identification and mit-
are negotiating. igation, negotiating skills and knowledge of buying
Although Congress has placed the decision to complex technology capabilities as significant gaps
outsource squarely in the agencies, the Office of in the federal acquisition workforce’s skills. . ..
Federal Procurement Policy, created by Congress This is not a failure of the workforce, but of our
in 1974 and plunked into OMB, is responsible for collective slowness to recognize the need for major
providing overall direction for government-wide change in how we train, educate and support that
procurement policies and procedures. GSA assists workforce.”42 Seventy percent of experts in Defense
agencies in purchasing and related projects with the acquisitions believe that a major problem of military
goal of assuring that the government gets good value procurement (“one of the most studied problems
for the dollar. in the history of government”43) is the workforce
Washington’s privatization procedures are itself, a workforce plagued by unclear career paths,
contained in the Federal Acquisition Regulation, a high turnover, and few incentives, among other
massive document in excess of 1,800 pages,36 plus difficulties.44
agency supplements amounting to another 2,900 This is regrettable because senior procurement
pages. By contrast, the Australian government’s pro- managers already dwell in “an embedded culture
curement regulations total ninety-three pages.37 of uncertainty avoidance” that “invariably” leads
Intersectoral Administration 403

to their failing to use more cost-effective procure- occasionally, its privatization has damaged the
ment methods.45 According to federal purchasing public interest, sometimes deeply.
executives, more than three-quarters of whom rate We build our case on four fundaments: the
their agencies’ promotion of acquisition innovation growing power of private contractors, consultants,
as “fair” (at 53 percent) or “poor” (24 percent), the and lobbyists (the distinctions among them are typ-
two “biggest impediments[s] to being innovative ically dim, if not illusory) to shape federal policy;
with acquisitions” are the “risk adverse culture of incompetent contract management; corrupt contract
program managers” (29 percent) and “contracting management; and the burgeoning body of proof that
officers” (24 percent).46 federal outsourcing is generally less efficient and
Worse, in 2003 Congress required that sixteen effective than insourcing.
civilian agencies appoint “chief acquisition officers”
charged with enforcing accountability. A decade
later, however, 87 percent were political appointees The Shadow Government: Contractors,
rather than careerists, and, for 75 percent, acquisi- Consultants, and Lobbyists
tion was not their primary duty.47 Unfortunately, By 1961, federal contracting was sufficiently perva-
these officers have yet to meet expectations.48 sive that President Dwight D. Eisenhower, former
The good news is that an estimated two-fifths Supreme Commander of Allied Forces in World
of the federal acquisition workforce has fewer War II and a pro-industry Republican, in his tele-
than five years of experience (although, appar- vised farewell address to the nation, coined the term,
ently, not great experience), and another two-fifths “military-industrial complex,” warned Americans
are  eligible to retire or will be shortly. These facts of its “grave implications,” and stated that its “total
offer  “the opportunity of a lifetime” to emerge influence—economic, political, even spiritual—is felt
from the “mid-20th century, industrial business in every city, every State house, every office of the
model” currently  used  by procurement specialists Federal government.”52
via a “generational shift” that could “fundamen-
tally change the culture and the way in which we Shadowy Contractors By any standard, Ike’s state-
deploy, train and empower the [federal acquisition] ment not only was stunning in its implications for
workforce.”49 democratic governance, but also eerily prescient.
Today, the federal government itself describes its
administrative circumstances as “a contractor-
THE CASE AGAINST FEDERAL dependent environment.”53 “It is now commonplace
for agencies to use contractors to perform activities
CONTRACTING historically performed by government employees,”54
Most Americans think that government delivers converting “what had once been an ‘arms-length’
public services more efficiently than business. Only relationship” to one that now is “virtually indistin-
about a sixth of the general public (17 percent) and guishable.”55
college seniors (16 percent) express “the most con- This intimacy has serious portents. As federal
fidence” in businesses to deliver public services.50 officials note, “the closer that contractor services
More than nine out of ten citizens, however, “do not come to supporting” government’s core responsibil-
believe that the [federal] government gets best value ities, the greater the risk “of influencing the govern-
from its contractors.”51 ment’s control and accountability.”56 Small wonder,
In 2008, a weak signal wafted from Congress to perhaps, that outsourcing “is negatively related to
the effect that it might be starting to question con- job satisfaction” among federal employees.57
tracting out; the Clean Contracting Act of that year
narrowed standards for what could be outsourced. The Netherworld of Consultants This risk atten-
The case against federal contracting is by no uates when federal administrators hire contractors
means universal. Some policies and programs will who are private consultants because their “advice”
always make sense to outsource. But, we suggest, can mold “basic management decisions” that can
Washington has gone too far, and, more than quickly wax into federal policy. Agencies contract
404 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

with at least 52,000 consultants a year,58 although rate.68 But, as we shall see in this discussion, it gets
no one seems to really know how many there are,59 worse.
but it is known that, over thirteen years, agency
spending on “Professional, Administrative, and Lobbyists by the Load Some 28,000 “Government
Management Services” burgeoned by 146 percent Relations individuals,” a term that includes lobby-
in inflation-adjusted dollars, and now is nearing ists (current, retired, and expired69), political action
$100 billion per year.60 Other sources place the cost committees, and related groups in Washington, are
of “service contracts” at more than $320 billion registered with Congress.70 Of these people and
annually.61 groups, fewer than 4,500 are “active contract lob-
In multiple reports dating from 1961, GAO byists” (that is, lobbyists whose names appear on
has criticized consultants’ “excessive involvement in more than one annual lobbying report and whose
agency management” that is “influencing agencies’ spending is “non-zero”), an increase of 70 percent
control of Federal policies and programs.”62 “We’ve over twelve years.71
seen situations where an agency contracts out so Some political scientists think that the number
much of its data gathering and policy analysis that it of Washington lobbyists is much higher than any
thinks it has control, but the consultant is, in effect, of these counts, and is closer to 100,000 because a
making the decision.”63 number of lobbyists maintain that they are really
These are basic issues. They deal with who just (highly paid) “advisors” to special interests,
makes public policy in an advanced democracy— which, they argue, means that they are not lobbyists,
representatives of the public interest or of private and therefore are not required to register as such.72
interests. In addition, any enforcement of lobbyists’ registra-
OMB first addressed these concerns in 1980, tion “is all but non-existent.”73
and it has consistently demanded that agencies retain
their “inherently governmental decision-making Fixed Fortunes? So there are lots of lobbyists in
authority” when contracting with consultants and Washington. So what? Are they actually effective in
other service contractors.64 A decade following the enriching their patrons with taxpayers’ money?
initial issuance of this policy, however, over a fifth of Pretty much. For every dollar that the fifty largest
federal contracts for consultants’ services appeared corporations paid to lobbyists over six years, they
to involve “inherently governmental functions.”65 received $130 in tax breaks and more than $4,000
in federal loans, loan guarantees, and bailouts.74 The
Lobbyland It is but a short hop from consultants 200 “most politically active” for-profit corporations,
to lobbyists: both are deeply involved in acquiring all of which have political action committees and
government contracts and other benefits for their contracted lobbyists, disclosed that they had spent
employers, both are highly influential in shaping $5.8 billion over six years to influence federal poli-
government policies and how they are administered, cies; during this time they were awarded $4.4 trillion
and both are external to government (although not in federal contracts and support (an amount that is
always, as illustrated by the registered lobbyist who two-thirds of what individual income taxpayers paid
“earned” a salary of $143,000 from a federal agency during the period), or $760 from Washington for
for a four-hour work week, while simultaneously col- each one dollar that they spent there. Although the
lecting $1.3 million for his “side-gig” as a lobbyist66). 200 companies accounted for less than 1 percent of
Americans do not like lobbyists. Seventy-one the 20,500 clients who hired lobbyists during those
percent think that they have “too much power,” six years, their lobbying expenditures constituted “a
a score that places lobbyists at the top out of ten whopping 26 percent of the total spent.”75
dreary possibilities.67 The people have a point, as, We are not suggesting that there were not some
for instance, special interests appear to have unusu- legitimate reasons for the feds to channel $4.4 tril-
ally destructive effects on the economy. A study of lion to these 200 firms, but it does seem naïve to
lobbyists found that the deeper the influence of inter- believe that there are no connections among cam-
est groups, the steeper the decline in the economy’s paign contributions, lobbying expenditures, and
growth rate and the greater the rise in its inflation federal allocations.
Intersectoral Administration 405

The Rapidly Rotating Revolving Door Who better following the start of the savings-and-loan crisis of
to lobby government than those who know it from the 1980s, 1,100 financial officials had been prose-
the inside? Thus we arrive at the repellant revolving cuted for “major” fraud and 839 convicted.80
door, or the process by which public officials resign In the aftermath of the Great Recession, at
and then work as bag men or women for the same least one federal judge questioned DOJ’s prosecuto-
special interests with which they formerly dealt. rial inertia, and the department’s inspector general
The revolving door is spinning ever faster, and wrote that, even though “DOJ and its components
at the expense of the public. have repeatedly stated publicly that mortgage fraud
is a high priority,” many departmental components
The Sin of Spin: The Blob Isn’t “sin” a trifle strong “ranked mortgage fraud as the lowest ranked crim-
when describing the revolving door? inal threat in its lowest crime category. . .. [or as] a
Hardly. The revolving door fosters an untoward low priority, or not listed as a priority.”81
and indivisible intimacy among consultants, con- As these learned views imply, Wall Street, perhaps
tractors, lobbyists, bureaucrats, and policymakers because of The Blob, usually wins when challenged
that verges on the gluttonous and the carnal. in court. Nineteen major Wall Street firms, amount-
Consider “The Blob,” which is Washington- ing to “a Wall Street’s who’s who,” settled, over
speak for the staffers who work in those agencies fifteen years, “at least” fifty-one fraud cases with the
and congressional committees that regulate the SEC—settlements in which the firms had promised
finance industry and “the army of Wall Street repre- to never, ever breach the same anti-corruption laws
sentatives and lobbyists that continuously surrounds again, but did, frequently. These repeat offenders
and permeates them. . .. The Blob moves together. “often pay a relatively small price” in penalties, and
. . . They dine, drink, and take vacations together. . .. typically neither admit nor deny guilt in the settle-
they frequently intermarry. . .. Ideally, you and your ment, a practice that protects them from later law-
spouse take turns” working for the finance industry suits. In 2011, SEC admitted in court that it had not
and its regulators and policymakers.76 Over fifteen brought any contempt charges against any “large
years, at least thirty-seven employees of Goldman- financial firms,” including “chronic violators,” over
Sachs, the nation’s largest financial firm, worked the last ten years.82 The statutes of limitations began
as high federal executives, including two who to run out in these cases in 2012.
were a commissioner or chaired the Securities and And Wall Street wins in Congress, too. The
Exchange Commission (SEC), the main regulator Blob assured that Congress’s bailout of the financial
of the finance industry; two presidents of powerful industry, in 2008, worked to the industry’s advan-
New York Federal Reserve Bank; and five secretaries tage. The “empirical evidence [shows] that campaign
of the treasury.77 contributions from the financial services sector influ-
Perhaps as a consequence of this intense and enced legislative voting on the banking bailout.”83
endless interaction among financiers and the feds, Small wonder, considering that the Securities and
eight years after the beginning of the Great Recession, Investment industry consistently contributes more
the Department of Justice (DOJ) had jailed just one money to congressional campaigns than does any
Wall Street executive (and not a top one) for finan- other sector.84
cial crimes, a hapless employee of a Swiss bank who The Blob’s manipulation of Congress is long-
had handled his defense so maladroitly that “pros- standing. In 2003, Congress reduced the personal
ecutors simply got their man by default.”78 The big income tax on long-term capital gains, a type of
fish, however, such as the chief executive officer income on which the very wealthy have an almost
(CEO) of JPMorgan Chase, which was fined more exclusive monopoly (and for some it is their only
than $20 billion for financial malfeasance, not only income), from 20 percent to 15 percent for those
escape punishment, but are rewarded; its CEO, who who paid 25 percent or more of their income in
presided over the malfeasance, receives an annual federal taxes. In 2013, Congress retained the 15
compensation of $20 million.79 By contrast, during percent tax rate, but ruefully raised the rate for
the Great Depression the head of the New York those in the highest tax bracket to 20 percent, which
Stock Exchange was imprisoned, and, nine years is almost precisely the same percentage (there is a
406 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

tenth of 1 percent difference) paid by the average The revolving door seems to concentrate at
taxpayer.85 the top; in one agency, 56 percent of “former high-
ranking officials” who had departed over four years
Systemic Sins Spin’s sins are not limited to Wall were “compensated” by contractors to whom they
Street. More than half of all consulting contracts had awarded contracts when those officials were
awarded by the Department of Defense, less than a employed by the agency.93
fifth of which are openly bid, go to former Pentagon Conversely, almost a third—a plurality—of all
employees. More than seven out of ten of them upper-level federal executives and professionals who
could have been conducted in-house by federal are hired from outside the government were working
employees.86 for a federal contractor when hired.94
Administrators in the Department of Energy, When big money is involved, the revolving door
which privatizes about 90 percent of its budget and reaches warp speed. Three-fourths of the more than
is second only to Defense in the dollars that it con- 600 registered lobbyists who represent the oil and
tracts out, “bounce,” in the words of one of its own, gas industry, for instance, have “revolving-door con-
“back and forth between government and industry nections,” including “dozens of former presidential
just like Ping-Pong balls.”87 appointees.”95
Nor is the sin of spin confined to the executive The revolving door is hardly the exclusive aper-
branch. The evidence strongly suggests that those ture of the executive branch. In the 1970s, just 3
members of Congress who voluntarily retire with percent of retiring members of Congress became
the intent of becoming lobbyists harbor “ambitions lobbyists.96 Times change. Over a dozen years in the
that potentially jeopardize the interest of the public.” 1990s and 2000s, 43 percent of all 198 Senators (50
They sponsor significantly more bills, and are more percent) and Representatives (42 percent) who left
successful in getting their bills passed, during their Congress registered as lobbyists.97 Today, more than
final term in office than do voluntarily-retiring 420 former members of Congress are registered lob-
members in their final term who do not intend to byists.98
become lobbyists.88 A notoriously effective lobby- Parallel patterns pertain for congressional staff-
ist stated that he “owned” about 100 members of ers. Over ten years, more than 5,400 congressional
Congress, an ownership that he attained by promis- staffers left Congress to become Washington lobby-
ing positions in his firm to key congressional staff- ists.99 The propensity of staffers to leave Congress for
ers, at triple their current salaries, when they were lobbying positions doubtless has been encouraged by
“ready to retire” from federal service;89 ultimately, relentlessly burgeoning workloads and salaries that
he was among twenty-one people, including White shrank (in constant dollars) over four years by 9 to
House officials, congressional staffers, and a con- 20 percent for top staffers100—staffers who appear
gressman who were convicted, jailed, or granted to benefit financially more as lobbyists than do those
plea bargains. lobbyists who left less exalted aeries.101 Merely
Should we be surprised that 58 percent of working in Washington (with its forced intimacy
Americans think that former members of Congress with living-large lobbyists and their career tempta-
should be banned from lobbying, and only 22 percent tions) associates with almost twice as many staffers
believe that they should be permitted to lobby?90 who are seriously interested in seeking employment
elsewhere (63 percent) relative to those staffers who
The Scope of Spin Washington’s revolving door are based in districts and states (36 percent).102
began its rapidly accelerating spin during the 1980s,
and, by the late 1990s, 12 percent of Washington’s Lucre’s Lure Federal officials who leave for the
registered lobbyists were former federal officials.91 private sector are lured by greener pastures. Consider
Today, 44 percent of all registered active lobbyists in the case of Rahm Emanuel, a former presidential
Washington are former government employees, up chief-of-staff who departed the White House to enter
from just 18 percent a dozen years earlier; over four- an investment firm as a self-described “relationship
teen years, the number of these “revolvers” nearly banker.” In fewer than three years, Emanuel left the
quadrupled from 482 to 1,846.92 firm, carting away $16.2 million in the process.103
Intersectoral Administration 407

Lobbying firms prefer revolvers, such as Emanuel, longer; stocks rise by almost 1 percent on the first
and pay handsomely for them. The estimated median day and by over 1 percent on the second.111
compensation for an active Washington lobbyist Investors obviously understand that there is a
who lists “a government staff position somewhere link, and a strong one, between profits and politics,
in their lobbyist disclosure forms” is $300,000, a perhaps because revolvers more than pay for them-
growing amount that is almost three times that of selves. Former federal employees who lobby spend a
lobbyists who do not list government experience.104 fourth of all lobbying expenditures in Washington,
Over fourteen years, the real pay earned by all but more than compensate for their spendthrift ways
active contract lobbyists nearly doubled to more by raking in two-thirds of all lobbying firms’ fees.112
than $1.3 billion. “All of that new revenue came in
the form of revenues associated with revolving door Slowing the Spin? In 2007, in an effort to slow
lobbyists.”105 During the same 14 years, from 7 to the revolving door’s spin, Congress passed the
10 percent of revolvers earned at least $1 million in Honest Leadership and Open Government Act,
one or more years, compared with just 2 percent of which bans high-level administrators from lobbying
those without government experience.106 their former agencies for two years following retire-
Over the same fourteen years, former members ment. Congress was less forthcoming in slowing its
of Congress who became lobbyists actually earned own revolving door, although the act does apply
less, on average, than did those who once held the same prohibition on Senators from lobbying
non-elective federal offices, such as administra- Congress, lesser limitations on staffers, and none
tors and staffers, perhaps because former Congress on Representatives. All members and senior staffers,
members had less substantive knowledge than former however, must disclose any current negotiations with
bureaucrats.107 Of course, former members still earn prospective employers. Congress also enacted, in the
substantially more than when they were in Congress, Defense Authorization Act of 2008, a similar policy
and some earn spectacularly more, such as the dozen for retiring senior Defense acquisition officials.
former Representatives and Senators whose revenues In 2009, the president issued an executive
increased by an average of 1,452 percent from their order that prohibited exiting government executives
final year’s full congressional salaries to their first from lobbying for foreign governments, a policy re-
year’s “partial salaries” as lobbyists.108 inforced by a similar order in 2017.
In the 1960s, just 2 percent of former members These and other modest reforms soon were being
of Congress became lobbyists, perhaps because they grossly violated by former members of Congress
“earned about the same as he had in government. and aides.113 Former senior Defense officials may be
Today he or she can easily expect to make ten times doing the same, but no one knows since no one, in
as much.”109 violation of the law, is tracking their retirement.114
In explaining why so many of her colleagues More to the point, the laws fall short of dealing with
resist more meaningful lobbying reform, a con- the central issue, which is that a large number of
gresswoman observed that, “It’s because there’s a federal officials appear to be advancing their own
lot of money involved.”110 One is reminded by her future interests at the expense of the public’s present
observation of a phrase favored by American youth: interest.
“Duh.” Remember The Blob?

Stockholders’ Delight Certainly Washington’s


revolving-door lobbyists are rolling in dough, but A Crisis of Competence
the real money is made by the special interests that Some federal contracting is a model of compe-
hire them. When corporate executives are hired by tence.  A comparison of the Defense Department’s
the Pentagon, their companies’ stock prices rise, on and companies’ costs in buying identical elec-
average, by nearly 1 percent on the day following tronic and engine parts, for example, found that
the announcement; “effects are larger for top gov- the Pentagon paid much less than did the business
ernment positions.” Conversely, when businesses hire sector. These savings were credited to the fact that
Defense officials their stock prices jump higher and Defense “was already using commercial practices
408 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

commonly followed by large firms,” including tough seems that most of what Snowden leaked concerned
bargaining.115 NSA’s surveillance of other countries and terrorist
Regrettably, however, in the dank and darkling groups.
depths of federal contracting, such competence is Of NSA’s estimated 40,000 employees, about
not always the case. An example follows. 1,000 are, like Snowden, infrastructure analysts,
most of whom work for contractors. Infrastructure
Snowed About a third of the federal government’s analysts have wide-ranging access to files, but
intelligence professionals who have top secret secu- Snowden also convinced some two dozen colleagues
rity clearances are employed by private companies to illegally give him their passwords. Snowden used
working under federal contracts.116 These contrac- those passwords to steal a stunning 1.5 million docu-
tors receive 70 percent (or more than $40 billion) ments. His activities were largely unaudited, if at all,
of the classified intelligence budget, and earn almost perhaps because NSA, apparently, had not installed
twice as much as their federal counterparts.117 readily available anti-leak technology in Snowden’s
No one seems to be particularly well informed workplace networks.123
about the contractors who have these clearances; the Just before NSA’s secrets began leaking world-
secretary of defense, for example, candidly admitted, wide, Snowden fled first to China and then to
“This is a terrible confession. I can’t get a number Russia, which granted him an unending “tempo-
on how many contractors work for the Office of the rary asylum.” Over a period of months, Snowden
Secretary of Defense.”118 Neither do the intelligence slipped at least some of the documents to WikiLeaks,
agencies have much of a clue of how many contrac- Britain’s Guardian newspaper, and other outlets.
tors they have and their costs.119 Quite aside from his criminality, “Snowden was,
Similarly dire defects are found in highly sen- at best, a marginal hire. . .. There’s little evidence that
sitive information systems. A review of six major he had the ideal technical capability, track record,
agencies (including the departments of Defense, or behavioral profile for the work he was hired to
Homeland Security, and State) that had outsourced do.”124
the control of at least some of their information secu- So how did he get hired?
rity and computer systems, found that five of them Snowden was hired because, beginning in 1996,
were “inconsistent in overseeing” their contractors, some three-quarters of federal background checks
including one agency which was unaware that its were privatized,125 and they were privatized with
contractor failed to even vet its employees.120 In the gross incompetence. The largest single vetting firm
department most responsible for domestic safety, was the U.S. Investigations Services (USIS), which
Homeland Security, a third of its roughly 600 major was responsible for as much as 45 percent of all
information systems that are currently in use “reside federal screening126 and 65 percent of all outsourced
in contractor facilities,” and more than four-fifths of vetting.127 USIS was created, in 1996, by simply
its information resources’ staffers are outside con- spinning off federal screeners, who immediately
tractors.121 incorporated USIS and signed contracts (worth
These remarkably reckless practices came home nearly $3 billion) with their former employer, the
to roost in 2013, when Edward Snowden, an infra- Office of Personnel Management (OPM), to vet can-
structure analyst (also known as a system adminis- didates for federal jobs. The contracts specified that
trator) with a top secret clearance at the National private vetting firms were to be paid according to
Security Agency’s (NSA) contractor, Booz Allen how many background checks, including many for
Hamilton, violated his oath of office and down- top secret security clearances, that they conducted,
loaded highly classified documents. (According and  firms were awarded bonuses for exceeding
to some wags, NSA actually stands for “No Such targets.
Agency,” a nod to its unique sensitivity.) Snowden It beggars the imagination that a decision
later stated that he had planned the theft long before could be made to privatize background checks for
he was hired.122 security posts, and then pay the checkers on the
Snowden’s motive, he said, was to expose NSA’s basis of piecework, replete with bonuses for com-
secret and massive spying on Americans, although it pleting more checks than anticipated. This was a
Intersectoral Administration 409

prescription for quick, inept, incomplete, and fraud- A Pervasive Problem The Snowden debacle is an
ulent vetting. USIS, as it turned out, was under inves- example of a more systemic incompetence in federal
tigation for rushed background checks and fraud (as privatizing. Much of this incompetence (and, as we
were the two other major vetting contractors) as the shall see, corruption as well), stems from the com-
result of a whistleblower’s suit filed in 2011. No sur- plexity of federal contracting. The GAO, large plural-
prise, that. ities of senior federal executives,131 and majorities of
Perhaps it goes without saying that USIS vetted acquisitions officials,132 contractors,133 and Defense
Snowden. A federal investigation found that not only personnel,134 do not believe that the procurement
was Snowden’s vetting incomplete, but that USIS process serves the best interests of the government.
had not even verified Snowden’s earlier employment When GAO created its high-risk list, in 1990,
with the Central Intelligence Agency.128 four areas directly concerned federal contracting;
In 2014, OPM did not renew USIS’s contracts twenty-five years later, all four were still on it, and
and Congress reinstated OPM as the final check one more had been added! “Ineffective contract
for security clearances, appropriating $2 billion management” is a “root cause” of seventeen agencies
to be used mostly for that purpose. In the same being on the current list.135 Eighty-eight percent of
year, the  Justice Department filed a $1 billion suit the thirty-two high-risk areas, which are “represent-
against USIS, alleging that the firm had filed at least ative of a cross-section of federal programs, includ-
665,000 flawed background checks (including a top ing giant ones,” on the current list “work through
secret clearance for an employee who, five months proxy [or third-party] or hyper-proxy administrative
following Snowden’s defection, murdered twelve arrangements”; private contractors are often those
co-workers), or two-fifths of the total, over four proxies.136
years. Federal contracting’s main flaws follow.
In 2015, USIS (and the other two private vetting
services) declared bankruptcy, but the damage was Time Is Money Federal purchases of less than
done. At the very least, Snowden’s theft and flight $100,000 take an average of three months to com-
revealed that American intelligence probably could plete, compared with one to four weeks in the
see and hear every electronic communication any- private sector.137
where by anyone (Americans’ support for these
activities is low; just 16 percent support government A Counterproductive Contracting Culture The
monitoring of cellphones and emails129), and resulted culture of federal contracting emphasizes agencies
in America’s allies, rivals, and enemies searching for keeping the contract at the expense of acquiring their
more effective protections. money’s worth.138 As a former procurement officer
Other consequences were more damaging. put it, “It doesn’t matter if you screw everything up,
Because of Snowden, the Washington Post published as long as you keep the dollars flowing.”139
details of Washington’s top secret “black budget” for
intelligence. His actions brought about an estimated A Dearth of Due Diligence Some kinds of federal
“cost to business” of $22 billion to $180 billion;130 contracts require that administrators assess the
a needed review of NSA’s practices; the expenditure past performance of prospective contractors before
of billions of dollars in reworking intelligence gath- awarding them contracts, but, in nearly seven out of
ering procedures; new processes and protections for ten of these contracts, contractors’ previous perfor-
whistleblowers in the intelligence agencies; and the mance is never assessed.140
possible conveyance of highly classified secrets to Federal contract administrators also seem to be
China, Russia, and many others. rather relaxed in assuring promptness and quality in
L’affaire Snowden personifies the perils of their expectations of contractors. “Indefinite delivery/
federal privatization. At every failed point (and every indefinite quality contracts” accounted “for about a
point was a failure)—from outsourcing, to vetting, third” of all contract dollars over five years.141
to hiring, to managing, to processing, to auditing,
to guarding, to securing—an outside contractor was Ballooning Bid Protests As federal contract
critical and pivotal. budgets shrink, federal bid protests grow, a trend
410 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

that is time-consuming and costly. Over eight years, In 2005, Washington began to decrease fragmen-
bid protests lodged by those who bid for contracts tation and increase leverage by introducing strategic
unsuccessfully grew by 60 percent to more than sourcing, which meant the consolidation of similar
2,600 annually. These appellants, such as the one purchases within each agency. Over five years, stra-
who submitted 150 baseless protests in a single year tegic sourcing saved Washington an average of 25
and was suspended from protesting, are not having percent—a satisfyingly greater proportion than
much success; federal officials approve their protests the savings of 10 to 20 percent attained by private
just 13 percent of the time, down from 21 percent companies using strategic sourcing. Regrettably, less
eight years earlier. Still, protests are expected to con- than 10 percent, on average, of federal purchasing
tinue rising.142 was strategically sourced during those five years,
compared with up to 90 percent in the private sector.
Expensive Change Orders The Pentagon, that Had the feds used strategic sourcing to the full extent
Croesus of contracting, alters a whopping 63 percent possible, their savings would have nearly tripled.150
of weapon systems’ requirements after their devel- In 2014, OMB expanded strategic sourcing to
opment has begun, and this dubious practice asso- acquisition shared services, or the replacement by a
ciates with “significant program cost increases.”143 single organization of several departments’ common
Over the course of a decade, in fact, Defense spent administrative operations for purchasing. The inter-
“at least $46 billion in then-year dollars. . .. [on] at agency fragmentation of federal purchasing is pricey;
least a dozen major programs [that] were terminated an example: there is a 300 percent range in the price
without any operational systems being fielded.”144 paid by agencies for the same laptop.151
In 2015, the feds projected that shared services
Rules That Create Costs Procurement regulations would bring savings of $1 billion over ten years.
tote up to 12 percent or more in additional contract More than 90 percent of procurement officials in
costs.145 Until recently, federal purchasers of weapon federal agencies and private-sector organizations
systems spent, “on average, over 2 years completing report cost reductions attributable to its use.152
numerous information requirements,” averaging, in But implementing acquisition shared services takes
total, 5,600 staff days to document and sometimes time—often a lot of time: for instance, “The consol-
involving “56 organizations at 8 levels.”146 When idation of [federal] payroll providers—from 26 to
these regulations and procedures are changed, errors four—took nearly a decade, but [and this is the crit-
result—not only in the contracts themselves, but ical point] persistence paid off.”153
also in the government’s system-wide procurement Each year, more than half of what agencies spend
database; 20 to 30 percent of the database’s records on all their purchasing is spent in just ten purchasing
contain errors, including improper payments, which categories, such as “Facilities and Construction,” the
lead to waste.147 largest.154 These ten concentrations of similar goods
In 2015, the Pentagon introduced its Electronic or services beg for a purchasing system that capi-
Coordination Tool to more effectively manage the talizes on their natural efficiencies, so, also in 2014,
mass of procurement procedures, and it seems to be Washington introduced category management, or
working; documentation and review now takes two placing a range of comparable products into sep-
months, down considerably from two years.148 arate groups, and then many government agencies
buying these products as one; its scope is the total
Federal Fragmentation and Little-Used Leverage procurement spending of the whole organization—
More than 500 federal organizations spend almost in this case, the federal government.
a half-trillion dollars annually in purchases “with Developed by the British government in 2005
only occasional collaboration across organizational (where it reduced prices and the number of trans-
lines.” Federal acquisition is so fragmented that actions and reports and improved data accuracy,
87 percent of all federal procurement transactions among other benefits155), category management is
amount to less than 10 percent of all procurement one of fifteen Cross-Agency Priority Goals required
spending (the 87 percent are less than $150,000 per by the Government Performance and Results Act
transaction).149 Modernization Act of 2010. In 2015, the Strategic
Intersectoral Administration 411

Sourcing Leadership Council, created in 2012 to and contractors with secret and top secret security
implement strategic sourcing in the seven largest clearances had declined by 17 percent.160 In 2015,
agency purchasers, was charged with managing the all the intelligence agencies adopted a long-in-the-
ten largest purchasing categories. Two years follow- works, “baked-in” cloud-computing environment,
ing its introduction, the White House announced built from scratch, that not only is expected to
that category management had saved $2 billion. detect future would-be Snowdens very quickly, but
Nearly nine in ten federal procurement executives also will lower expenses and improve intelligence.
think that category management will “dramatically In 2016, OPM began hiring 400 additional back-
change” purchasing (18 percent), or at least “will be ground checkers, and OPM and OMB set up a new
helpful” (71 percent) in doing so.156 National Background Investigations Bureau, with
All three of these purchasing innovations have 2,500 federal employees, 6,000 contract workers,
brought or will bring significant savings. But the and a director appointed by the president.
narrow use of strategic sourcing, and the tardy intro-
ductions of acquisition shared services and category A Slow Start in Determining Contractors’
management, are concerning if not depressing. Performance The Government Performance and
Results Act of 1993 required agencies to measure
Insecure Security Contracting Contractors are their contractors’ performance through the use of
used to staff such critical and potentially life-threat- “performance contracts.” Years after its passage,
ening jobs as “border patrol, intelligence gathering, however, progress in implementing performance
drone operations, militia training and more. . .. Most contracting remained “excruciatingly slow,”161 and
of our diplomatic security is now contracted out. So only a slender 11 percent of contracts met perfor-
is security at many federal buildings.”157 mance-based criteria nine years later.162
Consider some failings of these practices. An With the passage of the 2013 National Defense
audit of six American embassies in dangerous Authorization Act, which mandated the development
countries found that none had fully met the terms of a strategy for reporting contractors’ performance,
for screening private security contractors, placing marked improvements were evident. In 2013, all
the embassies in peril. Washington hired a British federal agencies fulfilled 32 percent of their contrac-
security firm to secure the perimeter of its facility tor evaluations that were due; by 2014, the figure
in Benghazi, Libya; the firm then hired local guards, was 49 percent, with GSA, which oversees federal
who vanished when the facility was attacked, in contracting, ranking among the lowest percentages
2012, killing four Americans, including the ambas- in both years.163 While this is largely good news, it
sador.158 “Four to five dozen” newly hired Secret is not good news that more than half of required
Service officers were posted in “sensitive positions” performance reporting is not being done. “The U.S.
(including “a little more than two dozen” who were Government—the largest consumer of goods and
assigned to the White House, where they were privy services in the world—has not developed an acces-
to sensitive information) without completing the sible and efficient system for rating and reviewing
required clearance process.159 government contractors.”164
These patterns indicate that Edward Snowden
is far from unique as an example of badly done Costly Cost-Reimbursement Contracts Cost-
security vetting (in 2016, another NSA-contracted reimbursement contracts ask contractors to make a
employee of Booz Allen Hamilton was found to good-faith effort to meet estimated costs, but stipu-
have in his home sensitive, including top secret, late that the government will pay any costs exceed-
information spanning twenty years that could fill ing that estimate.
200 computers, and was indicted in 2017), but at Cost-reimbursement contracts involve “high
least the Snowden episode had some salutary effects. risk for the government” because the prospect that
Shortly after his defection, NSA announced that it government will pay contractors more than it con-
was replacing some 90 percent of its infrastructure tracted for is quite possible, and the government
analysts, such as Snowden, with computers. Two must cover contractors’ expenditures even if they fail
years following Snowden’s flight, federal employees to complete the work. “The complete picture of the
412 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

government’s use [of these contracts] is unclear,” but Bye-Bye Bidding The Clean Contracting Act of
it appears that they accounted for at least a fourth 2008 limited noncompetitive, or sole source, con-
of all federal contracting dollars in 2008,165 and the tracts, but there are few signs that it has succeeded in
dollars expended through them were expanding by doing so. According to the most recent official data,
11 percent, on average, per year, from 2000 through a third or so of contract dollars (31 to 34 percent)
2008.166 were not awarded competitively over five years.171
The feds do have options that would amelio- The Defense Department, which accounts for more
rate the problem. Fixed-cost, or fixed-price, con- than three-fifths of federal contract spending, awards
tracts do not reimburse contractors for costs that less than half of its contract dollars to firms that are
surpass  the  agreed-upon cost; encouragingly, the involved in “a meaningful competition between two
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of or more vendors.” The Pentagon’s percentage of
2009 authorized their maximum use, and, from competitively-awarded contracts has been declining
2011 through 2015, agencies used these contracts for nearly a decade.172
to manage an impressive average of 63 percent of How do agencies circumvent the bid procedure?
all contract dollars.167 Another superior variant to Much of this circumvention is legal, if still question-
cost-reimbursement contracts is time-and-materials able. Contracting officers have the power to waive
contracts, which the government pays fixed, hourly bidding requirements, and they waive with gusto.
rates for all expenses within a pre-established Depending on the study, from about a third to nearly
ceiling. nine-tenths of all contracts are officially exempted
from “the fair opportunity process,”173 and “in
Porky Profits The contractors for the Pentagon many cases agencies don’t disclose what they spent
(which, recall, spends more than six out of ten on the sole source contracts.”174
contract dollars) accrue “abnormal or excessive In addition, agencies are not above using
profits. . .. when compared with their industry guile. Fully two-thirds of all federal solicitations
peers.” Profits grew even more excessive following for business have already been effectively awarded
the significant consolidation of the defense indus- without bidding. The administrator in charge of
try, in 1992, “due to both the improved bargain- releasing public notices for bid lists several “scams”
ing power and increased political influence of the (his word) that agencies use to avoid bids, such as
newly combined firms.” Ironically, excessive profits miscoding a contract in the notice so that poten-
increase when corporate governance is poor—spe- tial bidders can never find it (“That happens pretty
cifically, when the CEO and the board chair are the often”); mentioning a particular firm in the ad itself
same person, a combination long recognized in the (“That’s a pretty clear tip off that there’s not going
research as producing overly empowered executives to be any competition”); and mandating bidding
and scant oversight.168 deadlines so absurdly brief that only pre-selected
Fat profits might also be a result of some federal bidders can meet them. As one federal contrac-
contractors who may have violated the U.S. Service tor put it, “Anybody who believes you read [these
Contract Act of 1965 and two executive orders notices] and get your contracts is out of it. You’d
issued in 2014, which assure certain minimal levels starve.”175
of pay and benefits for low-wage employees working A cousin of the no-bid contract is the single-bid
under federal contracts.169 Nearly two million contract, which also can be awarded legally. It
private-sector workers working under federal con- appears, however, that “single-bid guidance” is not
tracts earn less than twelve dollars per hour; if they followed in awarding two-fifths of them.176
worked full time, they would earn $24,000 per year, Compounding all this is that the contractors
which “hovers near the poverty level” for a family themselves may not solicit competitive bids from
of four.170 their subcontractors. (Federal contractors appear
In 2015, GSA launched CALC.gov, which to subcontract about 70 percent of their work.177)
allows contracting officers to see hourly pay rates Construction contractors, on whom the feds spend
for 48,000 labor categories, greatly easing past prac- more than $30 billion a year, hire subcontrac-
tices and a step in the right direction. tors who “typically perform 60 to 90 percent of
Intersectoral Administration 413

the work,” yet a review found “no evidence” that and human rights, among others—were brought by
bidding by subcontractors had occurred.178 the federal government against 206 of its top con-
It seems likely that competitive bidding will tractors. Fifty-eight percent of these firms had vio-
remain stuck in its federal swamp for some time, as lated the law more than once (no misconduct was
the number of potential bidders has declined over proven for 28 percent). The government collected
the past several years.179 at least  $92 billion in fines, court judgments, and
settlements (not  counting confidential and similar
settlements).184
A Crisis of Corruption An example: The Justice Department’s Operation
Incompetence and inefficiency in federal contracting Ill Wind of 1986–1988 exposed “America’s biggest
are one thing. Dishonesty and corruption are quite defense scandal.” “No one will ever know how much
another, and these are present as well. the phony contracts and sweetheart deals really cost
taxpayers,” but it is known that they amounted to
Low-Balling and Lying Even when contracts billions, and resulted in over ninety convictions for
are let competitively, and even though the Federal fraud and bribery (among other crimes) of contrac-
Acquisition Regulation requires officials to do busi- tors, companies, consultants, and federal executives,
ness only with “responsible sources” that have a including the assistant secretary of the Navy.185
“satisfactory record of integrity and business ethics,”
subterfuge and deceit remain. Stiffing the Law Another sort of corruption occurs
Contractors’ initial estimated costs for hundreds when contractors violate federal laws that are unre-
of major projects built over nine decades in twenty lated to their contractual performance, but still are
countries, including the United States, on five con- awarded new contracts.
tinents were, on average, 28 percent short of their Thirteen percent of all federal contract dollars
actual costs!180 This gap remained quite consistent have gone to companies convicted of labor law
over time; indeed, the current difference between the violations,186 and nearly a fifth flow to corpora-
Pentagon’s contractors’ first estimates for weapon tions that have been convicted of seriously violat-
systems and their final costs is a remarkably similar ing federal health and safety regulations, including
average of 26 percent—and rising.181 The “over- violations that resulted in the deaths of thirty-five
whelming statistical significance” of these data is workers in some of those companies over the course
that “the cost estimates used to decide whether such of a single year.187
projects should be built are highly and systemati- Of the fifty largest penalties imposed for violat-
cally misleading,” and are “best explained by strate- ing health and safety laws, 16 percent were levied
gic misrepresentation, that is, lying.”182 against seven federal contractors. Fully half of the
Regrettably, low-balling and lying are practices fifty most egregious incidents of wage theft—that is,
in which the agencies are complicit. According to a companies that had cheated their employees out of
federal cost containment expert, prospective con- the wages due them—were perpetrated by twenty
tractors know that if they tell administrators “how companies that held federal contracts.188
much something is really going to cost, they may
scrub it. And they know that if they [i.e., adminis- Stiffing the Taxpayer A particularly pernicious
trators] tell the Congress how much it’s really going form of corruption concerns those companies that
to cost, Congress may scrub it. So you start in with are awarded federal contracts but fail to pay taxes.
both sides knowing that it is going to cost more.”183
Offshore Contractors Some companies pay no
Stiffing the Government Over twenty years taxes because they are headquartered in tax haven
(1995–2015), nearly 2,500 misconduct cases— countries, yet still, inexcusably, receive government
involving seventeen types of misconduct, including contracts. In just one year, these offshore contrac-
those concerning labor, the environment (the two tors received $846 million in federal contracts, yet
most common violations), fraud, “defective pricing,” cost the treasury an estimated $4 billion in lost tax
poor performance, health, taxes, ethics, antitrust, revenue.189 “Large tax haven contractors” also are
414 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

“more likely to have a tax cost advantage” in com- contracting with federal tax delinquents. Its efficacy
peting for federal contracts “than large domestic is yet to be determined.
contractors.”190
In the states, the 269 “major” overseas American Why Does Corruption in Contracting Continue?
corporations for which we have data paid less than Corruption in federal contracting continues for a
half of the state corporate taxes that would have host of reasons.
been due had they been headquartered domestically.
(They paid in state taxes about 3 percent of their Congress Congress prohibits the IRS from dis-
profits, but we do not know if they received federal closing to other agencies information about which
or state grants.)191 contractors do not pay taxes without the consent of
In short, taxpayers are stiffed twice—first by those contractors. Congress could eliminate this pro-
offshore contractors who pay no taxes, and then by hibition, but as yet has not.
the government that pays some of these contractors
with taxpayers’ money. And, to add insult to injury, Complexity At least some of the reason why federal
federal contractors who pay their taxes and hire agencies keep contracting with high-flying felons is
American workers are at a competitive disadvantage practical. Few, if any, other contractors could take
with those contractors who do not. over some of the big, complex projects that these
big, complex companies manage, so firing them may
Contentedly Corrupt Contractors Other contrac- not be a realistic option.
tors avoid paying taxes by simply cheating. Some
33,000 contractors with all federal agencies, other Politics Politics also plays a part, and a significant
than the Defense Department, owe Washington one. Should an agency actually cancel a contract,
more than $3.3 billion in federal taxes.192 When we it is virtually certain that at least one member of
throw in the Pentagon, more than 27,000 Defense Congress will intervene. This can be an administra-
contractors owe another $3 billion in federal tor’s worst nightmare because it “drastically disrupts
taxes.193 Then there are the dumbfounding facts that the careers of those associated with” the cancella-
almost 700 contractors who are working for the tion.199 Hence, federal “contractual relationships
Internal Revenue Service (IRS) owe as much as $5.4 may be more like treaties than contracts in that often
million in delinquent taxes,194 and that 8,400 federal no real separation occurs. . .. Once integrated into
employees and contractors (more than half of whom the public sector, firms tend to remain there.”200
are employees) who qualify for security clearances
owe some $85 million in unpaid taxes.195 Federally Fixed on Felons Do they ever. Over sev-
Altogether, these deadbeats account for nearly enteen years, there were 941 instances of miscon-
two-fifths of all federal contractors.196 duct committed by the federal government’s top 100
The states are not immune; more than 4,600 contractors, which accounted for 55 percent of all
federal contractors who collected $1.8 billion in federal contract dollars.201 These big enchiladas are
federal contracts in just one year owed their state almost never suspended (a temporary exclusion from
governments $17 million in unpaid state taxes.197 completing work) or debarred (an exclusion of up to
In sum, more than 60,000 documented contrac- three years), despite long records of serious, includ-
tors owe more than $6 billion in unpaid taxes, yet ing criminal, violations. Not one of the twenty-five
receive many billions more in federal funds. Criminal major corporations convicted of defrauding the
acts abound in all these instances. federal government in the 1980s was banned from
Other contented contractors include forty-nine further contract work.202 During the 1990s and
of the 100 largest federal contractors that receive 2000s, the top ten federal contractors shelled out
federal grants or tax credits, in addition to their top- almost $3 billion in fines and penalties for 280
of-the-line fees.198 instances of proven or alleged misconduct, but not
In 2015, an interim rule amending the Federal one of them was excluded from further work.203
Acquisition Regulation was adopted that prohibited, Agencies sign contracts with proven felons
with some minor exceptions, federal agencies from because they often are unaware of their felonies.
Intersectoral Administration 415

Various glitches may conceal from agencies an 200 contractors federal employees, and paying them
astounding 99 percent of the exclusions that other the same salaries; the savings were achieved by elim-
agencies have levied on their prospective contractors inating service fees. Accountants in the private sector
for past violations.204 earn, on average, less than $100,000, and lawyers
In addition, agencies sometimes fail to check about $221,000; federal accountants earn $119,000
the government’s list of excluded companies; and lawyers $175,000; but when federal agencies
or the excluded companies change their identi- contract with accountants for services, they bring
ties; or, astonishingly, some agencies continue to home, on average, nearly $300,000, and lawyers
contract with companies that they themselves make a whopping $555,0000.211
excluded! Examples include the German contrac- Perhaps the most comprehensive of these anal-
tor that the  Army debarred because he tried to yses is a study of thirty-five federal occupational
ship nuclear bomb parts to North Korea, but nev- classifications covering more than 550 service activ-
ertheless needlessly continued its contract with ities. It found that federal employees were less costly
this “morally bankrupt  individual” (to quote the than contractors in thirty-three of the thirty-five
Army’s own assessment) to the tune of another categories. “Fair and reasonable” billing rates (as
$4 million. Or the corporation that the Navy sus- required by law) charged by contractors toted up to
pended because one of its employees had sabotaged “1.83 times more than the government pays federal
repairs on an aircraft carrier that could have caused employees in total compensation, and more than
massive deaths, yet, “less than a month later, the 2 times the total compensation paid in the private
Navy improperly awarded the company three new sector for comparable services.” Only outsourced
contracts.”205 groundskeepers provided statistically significant
savings. The same study cited numerous federal
analyses that also concluded that Washington over-
Is Business Better? pays its contractors.212
Federal contracting costs (more than $472 billion in
Fiscal Year 2016206) long have been more than twice Fed-Up Feds In light of these and other compa-
the costs of the federal civilian payroll ($215 billion rable findings, it should not come as a surprise that
in the same year207), even though there is expand- a stunning 84 percent of federal managers support
ing evidence that federal outsourcing is, in general, “shrinking the contractor workforce to save money,”
far more expensive than federal insourcing. The evi- a proportion that no other money-saving method
dence seems to be slowly dawning on Washington. comes remotely close to nearing.213
The manager-in-chief, President Barack Obama,
A Burgeoning Body of Proof There is a riot of fully concurred, and called for far-reaching reform
recent research which concludes that it costs the of “our broken system of government contracting,”
feds about twice as much to outsource rather than bemoaning contractors who were “paid for services
insource.208 One extensive empirical study con- that were never performed, buildings that were
cluded that “when direct [federal] government pro- never completed, companies that skimmed off the
grams operated by civil servants . . . and grant- and top, [and who] have been allowed to get away with
contract-based third parties . . . were compared, in delay after delay after delay.”214
general terms direct government received signifi-
cantly higher overall . . . [performance] scores and,
more specifically, higher scores for . . . management.” Success! The Reforms of 2009 and Beyond
The sole “marked exception to this generalization” In 2009, the president directed OMB to take steps
was research and development programs, “which that would save up to $40 billion, or about 8 percent
are mostly third-party based.”209 at the time, in annual contracting costs, and success-
For example, bringing back into the Pentagon fully urged Congress to enact three consequential
30,000 outsourced jobs would save an estimated bills: the Weapon Systems Acquisition Reform Act
$44,000 per year for each position.210 Another (which passed unanimously) beefed up weapons’
agency saved $27 million annually simply by making cost estimating and testing; the Fraud Enforcement
416 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

and Recovery Act dramatically expanded the risk for nevertheless has declined by more than three-fifths
institutional recipients of federal funds that engaged over eight years after the introduction of reforms.
in mismanagement or fraud; and the American These are very encouraging developments.
Recovery and Reinvestment Act directed greater
competition in awarding contracts and strengthened
federal follow-up. Outsourcing’s Unabashed Outcome:
These and other actions (from 2009 through Wealthier Washingtonians
2015, the White House issued thirteen contractor- Perhaps the clearest consequence of federal privati-
focused executive orders that led to sixteen new zation is that it has rendered Washington’s residents
regulations) left the contracting community reeling. richer. This has occurred for two reasons.
“Government contracting is plainly entering an era Private-sector employees who are paid through
of . . . an unprecedented level of scrutiny” and “sig- federal contracts collect 60 percent of all federal
nificantly greater risk for contractors,”215 “many” contract dollars, whether for goods or services,223
of whom went “into shock” when they learned of and the federal contracting dollars that flow to the
these reforms, “and left some acquisitions experts Washington, DC, metropolitan area, after controlling
speechless.”216 for inflation, septupled over thirty years. These cas-
In addition, an administrative strengthening cades of cash now account for a startling one-third
was undertaken, and the number of contracting of the metropolis’s gross regional product,224 and
officers was expanded, a long-needed reform. In the a stunning 15 percent of all contracting dollars.225
late 1990s, each of these officers managed some- “The move to contract out more and more govern-
what more, on average, than $11 million in con- ment work proved to be a crucial long-term change”
tracts annually, but from 2001 through 2008, their in the region’s economy.226
workload exploded by 76 percent, to an average The second reason is Washington’s lobby-
amount per officer of well over $19 million in con- ists, whose sole mission is to secure advantages,
stant dollars. By adding more contract officers, the certainly including federal contracts, for their
average amount managed by them was reduced to masters. Lobbyists lurk in every one of the capi-
slightly more than $12 million per officer.217 tal’s crannies and corners, and, because the lay of
None of this was appreciated by contractors. Washington’s lobbying landscape is lush and loaded
In 2015, four associations representing major with lagniappe, its legions of lobbyists, and many
federal  contractors co-signed a “polite, yet terse,” other regional residents, prosper profusely. The
letter to the White House “saying, in so many dollars that Washington lobbyists spend to get
words, that they were fed up with executive orders their way exploded from a self-reported estimate
and presidential memos that target their member of $200 million in 1983227 to self-reported annual
companies.”218 spending that has handily exceeded $3 billion since
And with reason. Unlike many reform efforts in 2008 (between 2000 and 2010, Washington’s lobby-
the past, those of 2009 and beyond seem to be having ing dollars more than doubled).228 Some informed
some positive effects. Six years following their intro- sources believe that the amount is closer to $9 billion
duction, contracting costs (which had more than annually.229
doubled, 2001–2009) had declined by $165 billion The upshot of these two interrelated trends is
in inflation-adjusted dollars (or more than four that Washingtonians now enjoy among the highest—
times greater than the president’s original goal), a and often the highest—median household income of
shrinkage of 27 percent.219 Over seven years, the any metropolitan area in the world, typically alter-
number of federal contractors sank by two-fifths, nating for first place with Bridgeport and Hartford,
from “over 160,000”220 to 97,012.221 Over six Connecticut (favored by hedge fund managers), and
years following the introduction of reforms, sus- San Jose, California (Silicon Valley).230
pensions of contractors grew by 120 percent, and So, if asked what has federal privatization
debarments increased by a fourth, affecting about done for you lately, point proudly to wealthier
4 percent of contractors.222 And, as detailed earlier, Washingtonians.
federal approval of bid protests, while not high,
Intersectoral Administration 417

the privatization of even one major service.240 Fully a


PRIVATIZING IN THE STATES third of the states contract with no one to deliver any
State governments also procure and privatize. of their services—not corporations, not nonprofit
organizations, not other government agencies.241
The states’ reluctance to privatize services can
The States Resistant bring unforeseen benefits, notably by dampening
Relative to the federal and local governments, the the inappropriate influence by outsiders. When state
states privatize with some reluctance. Although state agencies contract with special interests to deliver ser-
procurement spending grew by a third, from a fifth of vices, those interests gain a unique leverage in shaping
all state spending to 30 percent over fifteen years,231 agency policies. “Contracting opens a pathway for
almost two-thirds of state administrators report that organized interests to lobby public managers. . .. The
their governments’ privatization has stayed the same influence of organized interests over state agency
(53 percent) or declined (12 percent) over the past decision making is driven, in part, by whether an
five years.232 State employee associations, such as agency contracts out for public service delivery.”242
unions, and elected officials are the most common-
ly-cited obstacles to state privatization efforts.233
Motives, Money, and Management
Selling Small A modest 14 percent of state offi- Motivation to privatize, savings (if any) derived
cials in just nine states report that “asset sales” are from privatization, and contract management are
even conducted in their states,234 and only a fraction interrelated phenomena.
of 1 percent of state agencies had actually sold state
goods over the preceding five years.235 Motives to Privatize Why do states privatize?
That states privatize their assets so modestly Almost two-fifths of state department heads report
is odd in light of the facts that states have billions that “cost savings” are the primary reason that they
of dollars in assets (roads, parks, etc.) that could be privatize some services, followed, respectively, by a
sold or leased, and Washington has long promoted lack of expertise, more “flexibility and less red tape,”
their privatization. Executive Order 12803, issued in and speedier implementation.243
1992, terminated longstanding federal requirements
that states and localities that sold or leased projects Slim Savings The states’ high hopes that privati-
which had been built with some federal funds had to zation will save money are not borne out in prac-
repay those funds, and, in 1996, Congress legislated tice. Less than a fourth of state agency heads claim
that the Federal Aviation Administration encourage any savings derived from privatization, and a third
the privatization of subnational airports. detect no savings.
Those savings do not amount to much. Of the 18
Privatizing Services Two-thirds of the states,236 percent of executive- and legislative-branch budget
and three-fifths of all state agencies, contract with directors who claim government-wide savings due to
companies to deliver at least one service to their privatization (a figure that is cancelled out by the 18
citizens, and states contract more frequently with percent who detect no savings), well over half report
corporations than they contract with independent savings of just 1 percent or less.244
organizations and other government agencies to do
so.237 Education and transportation agencies con- Modest Management Although the states began
tract with companies the most, where contracting is to appreciate the importance of procurement in the
growing, and health and social service agencies con- 1990s, the states’ administration of privatization
tract the least, where the practice is in decline.238 As seems not as strong as it could be. Just five states
we noted in Chapter 6, information technology is have fully adopted the national Model Procurement
also a major and growing area of state privatization. Code (twenty states have adopted it in part).245
But even in the privatization of services, states Forty-one states permit noncompetitive bidding,
lag. A slender 5 percent of state agency heads (or pos- possibly indicating that competitive bidding may not
sibly less239) report that they have fully implemented be as robust as it should be.246 For example, over
418 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

four years, Nevada awarded 2,305 noncompetitive among the most laxly regulated in the nation (on
contracts amounting to $1.7 billion and 27 percent average, one state employee oversees fourteen insur-
of its contracts, and Mississippi did the same for ance companies and 1,150 agents).259
“at least” 3,370 contracts worth $6.5 billion; New Thirty-five states have enacted “revolving door
Mexico handed out $150 million worth of no-bid prohibitions” against legislators lobbying state
contracts over two years.247 governments after they have left office,260 and “at
State administrators’ propensity to socialize least” thirty-four states have legislated “cooling
with contractors may be a factor in the possible off” periods for ex-legislators that last from one to
deterioration of competitive bidding, as such chum- two years.261 There is little question, however, that
miness “plays a significant role” in these managers’ some—how many is unknown—former legislators
positive perception of contractors, outweighing even lobby their governments following their departure
state administrators’ past experiences in the private from public service. It is known, for example, that at
sector and partaking in activities that are similar to least eight former speakers of Florida’s house of rep-
those of their contractors.248 resentatives became lobbyists following their depar-
Once contracts are let, the states often fail to ture from state government.262
follow up. The states’ monitoring of their contrac-
tors’ performance has been described by “most” state
managers as “the weakest link in their privatiza- PRIVATIZING BY LOCAL
tion process”249 (though growing, only thirty-seven
states provide training in contract management250), GOVERNMENTS
and “less than one-third” of state procurement Privatization long has been a staple of local public
offices “have a consistent way of tracking contract administration.
performance that they share with project adminis-
trators. . .. Contracts . . . are just allowed to drift.”251
When states do assess their contractors, they often Selling Assets, Buying Goods,
do so incompetently.252 and Privatizing Facilities
Less than a fourth of cities and counties sold any assets
(vacant land is the leader, accounting for 70 percent
The States’ Slower Revolving Doors of all sales) to anyone over five years—a higher rate
Although there are some instances of the revolving than the states, but far short of federal levels.263
door in the states, that door appears to revolve far Local purchasing practices are set largely by the
less rapidly than at the federal level. states. Thirty-nine states set purchasing standards for
Fewer than 15 percent of state agency heads,253 their local governments, ranging from competitive
or just a fourth of the comparable percentage for bidding requirements to centralized purchasing.264
their closest federal counterparts,254 are hired directly Almost a third of cities and counties engage in
from corporations. Nor do they quickly skedaddle a privatization practice that is unique to them. They
back to the private sector. State agency directors have privatize facilities—that is, they contract with com-
a median tenure of six years and rising in their present panies to build or buy facilities (most commonly,
positions,255 or twice the average tenure of federal transportation-related facilities), which they then
agency heads who are careerists256 and four times own and operate exclusively for the government,
longer than that of federal political appointees.257 which pays them for their service. Local adminis-
Over thirteen years, 24 percent of 291 former trators cite savings in capital expenditures as the
Michigan officials became lobbyists after leaving leading reason for privatizing facilities, followed by
state government.258 The nation’s 5,926 insurance inexperience in managing them.265
companies (a $1.2 trillion industry with 2.5 million
employees), which are regulated by the states,
happily hired half (fifty-five) of all 109 state insur- Privatizing Local Services
ance commissioners who left office over ten years; As with the states, the dominant form of local
this may explain why the insurance industry is privatization is contracting with the private and
Intersectoral Administration 419

independent sectors to deliver services to their Springs (population, 90,000), Georgia, has only its
citizens. law enforcement personnel on its payroll; Centennial
City managers rank improving the delivery of (104,000), Colorado, has fewer than thirty munici-
local services third out of twenty-six “influences” pal workers;277 and Weston (65,000), Florida, just
that affect their decision making (only “budgetary nine.278 In 2010, Maywood (30,000), California,
constraints” and “staff input,” respectively, rank sacked each and every one of its ninety-six employ-
higher),266 and outsourcing has waxed into a major ees,279 and, in 2012, Highland Park, Michigan, out-
means of doing so; a commanding four-fifths of local sourced all of its schools and the nearly 1,000 pupils
administrators believe that “privatization will rep- in them.280
resent a primary tool to provide local government Other localities take the opposite route, keeping
services and facilities.”267 their employees and outsourcing only their topmost
City and county employees deliver exclusively position, the town manager. Eight small towns in
45 percent of their governments’ seventy-six major North Carolina have done this, contracting with
services. Support functions, most notably secretarial management firms for full- or part-time town man-
services and human resources, are favored.268 The agers, but keeping their public employees on their
percentages of services delivered entirely by govern- payrolls.281
ments’ own local employees have ranged from its
present low of 45 percent to 52 percent (in 1982)
over thirty years.269 Why Local Governments Privatize Services
Service contracting with private for-profit firms There are many motivations that spur localities to
accounts for less than 16 percent of all city and privatize services.
county services, with vehicle towing (at 69 percent)
handily leading the way, but a majority of local New Services The addition of new services is “the
governments contract out only four services (or 5 strongest and most reliable predictor” of privatiza-
percent of the total) to the private sector.270 Over tion among counties.282
thirty years, the practice has accounted for 15 to
18 percent of all services delivered, but it is nearly Saving Money By far the most pervasive internal
universal: at least 99 percent of cities and counties incentive is a desire to cut costs, a motivation cited
contract out some of their services,271 and, at one by a notable 87 percent of city and county man-
time or another, “contracts have been used for every agers.283 This percentage is a dramatic upswing in
service,” from parking to police, that these govern- officials’ views from more than three decades earlier,
ments provide.272 when only 43 percent thought this.284
Sixteen percent of municipal and county ser-
vices, on average, are delivered jointly by public Good Times “There is no evidence that fiscal stress
employees and employees in other sectors, mostly induces privatization” by local governments,285 and,
the private one273—a 30 percent decline from thirty in fact, the wealthier the locality, the more likely it
years earlier.274 The leaders here are tree trimming is to outsource.286 Governmental wealth appears to
and planting, and economic development.275 trump even partisan ideology in the decision to pri-
The remaining local services are delivered vatize.287
by nonprofit organizations, detailed later in this
chapter, and by other governments, considered in Contracting among Friends When local govern-
Chapter 12.276 ments partner with outside organizations, “social
factors” are more important to both parties than any
economic benefits that might result from their col-
Outsourcing in Extremis laborative arrangements, particularly if their admin-
A few local governments reject the very concept of istrators share comparable professional experiences
public employees, choosing instead to outsource and have “genuine affection for each other.”288
the delivery of their services to companies, non- In fact, when there is high turnover among local
profit organizations, and other governments. Sandy officials, contracting out local services to all three
420 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

sectors abruptly and steeply declines, implying that Local administrators’ perceptions about the
there must be an existing foundation of familiarity quality and quantity of available contractors depend
between officials and contractors before contracts heavily on place and circumstance. Suburban gov-
will be let.289 ernments contract out more services to the private
sector than do rural and urban governments, mostly
Bureaucratic Symbiosis The more top-heavy the because there are competitors vying for their busi-
bureaucracy in a school district, the more that its ness, which is crucial in enhancing efficiency, and
bureaucrats will contract with outsiders to do their their residents have at least a middling interest in
jobs for them. Conversely, a large number of con- services.
tracts let by a school district correlates positively with Rural governments (and governments with
the addition of more central office administrators in small populations299) outsource less than suburban
the future. It is “a process that feeds on itself.”290 ones, mainly because there is a dearth of alternative
When there is a small the number of “admin- service suppliers, but also because their citizens evi-
istrative professionals” who process contracts, the dence the least concern with services.
bureaucracy issues even more contracts because Central cities privatize the least, even though
these professionals are more interested in making they are in the most competitive markets and their
“strategic decisions rather than more trivial day-to- residents’ interest in services is highest. But, because
day decisions,” and outsourcing frees them to do just urban governments govern relatively large, often con-
that.291 centrated, populations, which yields them uniquely
advantageous “internal economies of scale” that
Playing Politics An analysis of national surveys are denied to smaller jurisdictions, they are unable
found indications that local “elected officials are to reduce costs through outsourcing to the extent
using private contractors to . . . reward electoral that suburban and rural governments can, simply
constituencies,”292 such as in Washington, DC, because they already are run more efficiently.300
where a review of more than a thousand of its con-
tracts worth about $10 billion found that more than
300 contractors who had won contracts that had Why Local Governments Do Not Privatize
been approved by the District Council had contrib- Services
uted more than $5 million in campaign donations Over three-fifths of cities and counties report that
to council members; another fifth of the donations they encounter no obstacles to privatizing, and this
came from potential contractors seeking Council figure rises with every survey.301 Nevertheless, there
approval.293 are some serious barriers to local privatization.
Cities that are controlled by the Republican
Party contract more with the private sector than Public Opposition Thirty-five percent of cities and
do cities in which the Democrats are in power.294 counties cite “opposition from citizens” as a hurdle
Conservative, smaller, and prosperous municipalities to be overcome in privatizing services,302 the highest
contract out more social services, whereas liberal percentage in twenty years, but not by much.303 In
and larger cities privatize more technical services any event, Americans’ favor government as a pro-
and fewer social ones. Contracting out technical vider of local services. Asked whether companies or
services “is not influenced by economic affluence. . .. local governments could deliver six local services
social services are the contemporary ideological bat- “more efficiently,” Americans favored companies for
tlefield of privatization.”295 delivering just one service, and then by the notably
slender margin of 1 percent.304
Place and Circumstance Twenty-three percent of
city and county managers worry that fewer compe- Employee Opposition The leading impediment
tent competitors in the private sector are bidding to local outsourcing is local employee opposition,
for their contracts,296 a steep decline of more than a at 56 percent,305 a record high; during the 1990s
fourth over five years,297 nearly matching its percent- and 2000s, employee resistance was cited by about
age of two decades earlier.298 30 percent of local officials.306
Intersectoral Administration 421

No doubt, fear over losing their government is school districts, where centralization, cumber-
jobs accounts for much of local workers’ resistance, some procedures, and high risk-aversion have long
but at least some of this concern is misplaced. A guaranteed a “pervasive [procurement] culture of
relatively small number of affected employees, an ‘can’t.’”317
estimated 5 to 7 percent,307 lose their jobs to out- It appears that the ability of general-purpose
sourcing. Fifty-eight percent of them, however, are local governments to manage contracts with the
hired by the private sector, and the rest are placed private sector has been increasingly challenged over
in other government jobs (24 percent) or retire (7 the years, largely due to the growing need to con-
percent).308 tract for increasingly complex services.318 Still, local
Still, there are clear downsides. Although pay governments remain outsourcing innovators, with
usually remains about the same in the private sector, some cities phasing out detailed purchasing require-
benefits are typically less generous, with half of con- ments and instead asking citizens how they would
tractors offering fewer benefits and just 16 percent solve problems and rewarding those with the best
providing more.309 Local employees of color appear answers; such approaches turn “the old system on
to lose their jobs to privatization at a faster rate than its head.”319
white employees.310
Local Leeriness Local administrators are health-
Unions Local employees’ central ally in their ily wary of the private sector, and tend to privatize
anti-privatization posture is organized labor, no only those services that have a low risk of failure
doubt in part because local privatization associates and limited prospects for corporate exploitation
with reduced union membership.311 (e.g., public works and transportation); high-risk
From 1992 to 2007, the proportion of local areas (e.g., health and human services) generally
officials who cited “restrictive labor contracts” as are kept in-house.320 Most local governments insert
an obstacle to privatization grew by a fourth, from “high-powered” incentives and disincentives in their
30 percent to 40 percent.312 In 2012, that percent- long-term contracts with private firms. It is in the
age declined for the first time in two decades—to 36 interest of these governments, however, to not be too
percent.313 heavy-handed, as “rigidly constructed legal agree-
When unions win excessive benefits, however, ments” with the private sector can distort incentives
local governments turn to privatization in an effort and “do little” to fulfill contracted objectives.321
to stem rising labor costs. An analysis of national
polls revealed that, “Contrary to our hypothesis. . . Competing for Contracts Competitive bidding
Unionization may not be the barrier to privatization seems to be used more frequently by local govern-
it was once thought to be.”314 ments than by any other governmental level. Thirty-
seven states require their localities to competitively
Pushback Politicos Forty-three percent of local bid all purchases that exceed a specified amount
administrators cite elected officials as a barrier to (thirty-two), or of a designated type (five).322 Only
contracting out services.315 This proportion has 18 percent of cities and counties select any contrac-
remained pretty constant at roughly two-fifths tors without competitive bidding,323 and even this
(usually a bit more) over twenty years.316 Politicians’ low proportion is shrinking over time.324 Cities with
reluctance to outsource local government jobs doubt- city managers are more likely than are cities without
less is a reflection of the fact that, as we detailed in them to have formal bidding systems.325
Chapter 9, local government workers are unusually That said, there are not many firms competing
active in local elections. for local service contracts; for sixty-seven local ser-
vices (almost all of them), the average number of
alternative providers per service is just two.326
Managing Privatized Local Services
Do local governments manage privatization cost- Assessing Contractors’ Performance—and Acting
effectively? Yes, they do, at least in comparison with on Those Assessments Thirty-eight percent of all
the federal and state governments. An exception cities and counties,327 down from 45 percent five
422 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

years earlier,328 and more than nine-tenths of the The other is a lot of contracting. A long-term
sixty-six largest cities,329 formally evaluate their con- analysis of school districts found that “the most
tractors’ performance in delivering services. striking results from this study are those involving
Local governments act on their assessments. the relationship between contracting and service
Twenty-two percent of cities and counties that had quality. . .. more contracting is associated with the
privatized at least one service over the last five years improvement of performance, which is measured by
brought those services back in-house for reasons of statewide test results.”340
poor corporate performance, which is the leading
reason underlying “reverse contracting,” surpassing
even insufficient savings.330 Over five years, the rate The Firmly Shut Revolving Door
at which local governments engaged in reverse con- In contrast to the federal and some state govern-
tracting slightly exceeded the rate of new outsourc- ments, general-purpose local governments appear
ing.331 Smaller, poorer communities are the most to have virtually no revolvers. All city and county
likely of all local jurisdictions to bring services back chief administrative officers are hired either from
in-house.332 within their own government (21 percent) or from
Waterworks are notable in the cities’ reverse another local government (79 percent),341 and they
contracting. Over twelve years, thirty-three cities have spent an average of nearly seven years in their
(with more on the way) brought back their water current positions.342
systems from the private sector because of undue Revolving doors are more present in special-
costs and questionable management.333 purpose local governments, although our knowl-
edge in this area is limited. We know, for example,
Managed Competition Managed competition that over two years 45 percent of CEOs in 160 large
encourages local governmental departments to transit authorities resigned, and that about two-
compete for service delivery contracts with private thirds of them were immediately hired by public
companies, nonprofit organizations, and each other. transit businesses.343 But many special-purpose gov-
Twenty-three percent of all cities and counties use ernments—housing authorities, waterworks, and
managed competition,334 a decrease of 13 percent school districts are examples—conduct activities
over ten years.335 Managed competition originated in that are already for-profit or whose personnel have
Phoenix in the 1970s, and at least half a dozen major little to offer special interests that have wish lists
cities now use managed competition; it is saving which they want local governments to grant.
them millions.336

The Quality Question Most local administrators WHICH SECTOR DELIVERS


consistently express themselves as quite satisfied with
the quality of privatized services.337 Independent PUBLIC SERVICES BEST?
researchers are less effusive, however, concluding We are just beginning to learn whether contracting
that “there is no discernible relationship one way or out services for delivery to the public, a practice that
the other. In other words, as best we know at present, is almost exclusively the preserve of state and local
contracting does not reduce or increase quality, as a governments, actually brings benefits.
general rule.”338
Still, some contractors deliver higher quality
services than other contractors, and two variables Does Government Partnering with the
that associates most positively with high contracting Private and Nonprofit Sectors Deliver
quality are somewhat surprising. Services More Effectively and Efficiently?
One is trust. Higher levels of trust between The correlation between “public-private partner-
local officials and contractors “result not only in ships” and effectiveness “is actually negative and
lower costs, but also in higher quality of services significant.” Governments’ “partnership with the
and greater responsiveness to the needs of local voluntary sector appears to have no relationship
government.”339 with effectiveness, despite this being a common
Intersectoral Administration 423

approach to delivering many local services.”344 In


sum, businesses deliver public services less effec- Does Government Partnering with the
tively than government, and governments working Private and Nonprofit Sectors Deliver
with nonprofits to deliver services have no impact Services More Equitably?
on effectiveness. Equity, in this case, refers to providing personal
Whether the public, private, or nonprofit sectors attention; raising compassion and trust; and meeting
deliver public services more efficiently is a more the special needs of the disadvantaged, excluded,
nuanced question, but the evidence tilts toward the and underrepresented. As with effectiveness and effi-
conclusion that government delivers services more ciency, neither the nonprofit nor the private sector
efficiently than the other two. contributes much, if anything, to equitable treat-
An analysis of essentially all empirical studies ment when partnering with the public sector. There
(“mostly from local government”) conducted across is an “insignificant” association in public-nonprofit
the globe (“mostly U.S. in origin”) of contracting out partnerships, but a “negative and statistically signif-
services to both the private and public sectors found icant” correlation in public-private partnerships.352
that governments’ savings, on average, amounted Here is an example of the inequity that fre-
from 6 to 12 percent, with the largest savings, 19 quently accompanies public-private partnerships.
to 30 percent, in cleaning, maintenance, and refuse State and local governments increasingly are financ-
collection. Savings never exceeded 30 percent,345 a ing the privatization of their services with the pension
finding that questions the claims of privatization funds of those public employees who were let go and
zealots, some of whom tout savings of 50 percent.346 privatized, but who had contributed to those funds.
But this same analysis also found that, at the “This pattern is surprisingly pervasive. . .. Displaced
very least, government’s efficiency equals that of [public] workers not only stop contributing to the
business. “Cost reductions are attained whether funds, losses that can harm other workers and retir-
public or private sector organizations win contracts. ees, but also often must turn to public assistance to
This finding, that there was no general tendency for survive, undermining the argument that taxpayers
private provision to be any more cost-effective than benefit from these transactions.”353 And, as we noted
public provision of services under contract, is a sig- earlier, not only do half of the companies that hire
nificant one.”347 newly-privatized employees offer benefits (certainly
It sure is. In fact, this same study cited some including pensions) that are stingier than those they
unavoidably limited data which indicated that, when had received from their public employers, but cities
governments contracted out services to the private and counties are remiss in easing the transition of
sector, they saved an average of 14 percent, a third their employees to the private sector (even though
less than when they contracted with other govern- doing so is an insignificant expense), with just 30
ments, which saved them an average of 22 percent.348 percent furnishing some public assistance354 and less
Other comprehensive and methodical analyses than 17 percent conducting programs designed to
conclude that government, on average, consistently smooth their displacement,355 a decline of 16 percent
delivers public services more efficiently than not only over ten years.356
the private sector,349 but the nonprofit one as well.
Government contracting with the private and inde-
pendent sectors “may not necessarily be a suitable
vehicle for enhancing cost-effectiveness” in provid-
PRIVATIZING PUBLIC SERVICE
ing public services, as both sectors display “statis- DELIVERY: LESSONS LEARNED
tically insignificant” relationships with efficiency.350 When all is said and done, what should public
What seems to consistently enhance efficiency administrators at all governmental levels keep in
in providing public services is when governments mind when contracting out service provision? Here
contract with other governments to do so, and when are eight major lessons learned:357
contracting is combined with competition. “Public
versus private matters, but competitive versus non- ■ Strong public support and a political champion
competitive usually matters more.”351 probably are prerequisites for privatization.
424 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

■ Select potential candidates for privatization product (GDP), in contrast to thirteen countries with
carefully. Public programs that have a market economies similar to that of the United States,
distinctive business profile, such as lotteries where these enterprises account for an average of 9
and airports, are the easiest to contract out percent of GDP.360 This is not to say that American
successfully. Those programs that clearly were public enterprises are trivial. Although a definitive
established to serve the public interest are census of public enterprises is nonexistent,361 they
not promising candidates for privatization. nonetheless are a major means by which American
For example, for-profit universities and governments implement public policies.
privatized prisons, in contrast to their public
counterparts, often founder, sometimes
disastrously. Enterprising Washington
■ Privatize gradually. Wholesale, rapid Washington has both embraced and eschewed
privatization often undermines political owning businesses, but has left a legacy of some
support. powerful federal enterprises that have unequaled
■ Develop an accurate costing system before power and autonomy.
contracts are solicited. Define outputs, set
benchmarks, and use activity-based costing, Origins The first federal enterprise is generally
an accounting technique that covers all the thought to be the First Bank of the United States,
expenses of providing a service. chartered in 1792, although President Theodore
■ Inject the maximum amount of competition Roosevelt’s purchase, in 1903, of the Panama
possible. Railroad marks Washington’s involvement with gov-
■ Use well-defined contracts that set performance ernment enterprises as we presently understand them.
measures and incorporate evaluation With the onslaught of the Great Depression,
procedures. Washington took a renewed interest in the govern-
■ Mitigate the impact of privatization on ment enterprise, an interest that redoubled during
displaced public employees. World War II. By 1953, Washington was “the largest
■ Recognize that the weakest links in the electric power producer in the country, the largest
contracting process are those of managing insurer, the largest lender and the largest borrower,
the contract and achieving accountability, the largest landlord and the largest tenant, the
and these two areas require the greatest largest holder of grazing land and timberland, the
attention.358 largest owner of grain, the largest warehouse opera-
tor, the largest ship owner, and the largest truck fleet
operator.”362
THE BUSINESSES OF Such public enterprise did not rest easily with
corporate America, which launched a concerted
GOVERNMENTS drive in the 1950s to bar the feds from competing
We have been describing how governments contract with business. Through a series of executive orders,
with businesses to implement public policies. But most federal enterprises were reorganized or dis-
governments also create businesses to implement mantled. Still, some federal enterprises remain for-
their policies. Although there are many distinctions, midable, providing electricity and other benefits to
titles, and types among them, these quasi-public nearly nine million people in the Tennessee Valley,
enterprises share three characteristics: they have a a contiguous territory that spans seven states, and
unique legal standing that differentiates them from transporting all of the nation’s 25 million railroad
organizations in any of the three sectors; their travelers.
funding often is a blending of public and private
funds; and some are government monopolies while The Federal Fringe Government Aside from
others compete as businesses in the marketplace.359 the fifteen cabinet departments, and an additional
In the United States, state-owned enterprises eighty-eight executive agencies and organizations,
account for a modest 1 percent of its gross domestic there are at least 115 federal “entities” that loosely
Intersectoral Administration 425

cling to the tips of the government’s branches. This been enacted and executive action has been taken
government at the federal fringes is as important as which . . . conflict with both the letter and spirit” of
it is ill understood. Commonly-accepted definitions the act.369
of the various categories of these entities are rare, if
nonexistent, and official counts of them frequently Government-Sponsored Enterprises A government-
differ widely. sponsored enterprise (GSE) is a financial intermedi-
These entities, with the partial exception of ary created by Congress that directs capital to a par-
federal corporations (discussed shortly), are specif- ticular sector of the economy. Figure 11-1 sketches
ically exempted from the sixteen major statutes that its basic features.
address a dozen “key” standards of governance, Congress created the first GSE in 1916, and
accountability, and transparency that apply to line today there are five. These GSEs are charged with
departments and agencies.363 making farming or housing more affordable by
loaning money (and a lot of it: $5.5 trillion, or
Services for Federal Workers There is “a large nearly a third of GDP370) to financial institutions,
but unknown number” of nonappropriated fund and, should they default, these loans ostensibly are
instrumentalities that are created and funded not backed by Washington’s “implicit guarantee” of
by Congress, but by agencies, to provide services payment. This guarantee enables the banks to charge
to federal personnel; an example is military post lower interest rates to farmers and home buyers,
exchanges.364 although it burdens taxpayers because it amounts to
a costly public subsidization of GSEs.371
Research Centers The thirty-nine federally funded Worse, the guarantee is no longer implicit, but
research and development centers are private organi- explicit. In 1987, Congress spent more than $4
zations created by federal agencies to meet long-term billion to bail out an over-extended GSE, the Farm
federal research needs. Agencies contract with these Credit System, and, in 2008, Washington rescued the
centers to conduct research, and they are awarded two largest GSEs (they owned more than four-fifths
a modest 14 percent of all federal expenditures for of all the assets owned by all GSEs combined372),
research and development.365 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Ultimately, the two GSEs received $400 billion
Government Corporations Federal government in bailouts. Short of the Troubled Asset Relief
corporations are federally-chartered organizations Program of 2008, which disbursed $700 billion to
charged with implementing those public policies multitudes of recipients, it was the largest bailout—
that are “predominantly of a business nature,” and ever.373
usually are expected to “produce revenue and are Fannie’s and Freddie’s missions are to encourage
potentially self-sustaining.”366 Figure 11-1 outlines home ownership, and they were rescued because, in
some of their characteristics. light of their holding or guaranteeing nearly half
There are at least nine differing counts of the of all home mortgages in the United States,374 they
number of federal corporations, ranging from eight- were too big to fail.
een to fifty-eight,367 but GAO’s tally of twenty-three Both GSEs had long and troubled histories.
strikes us as a particularly careful one. Eighteen Their regulatory body, citing gross mismanagement,
of these twenty-three, such as the Tennessee Valley imposed record-breaking fines on Freddie ($125
Authority, are “wholly owned” by the federal gov- million in 2003) and Fannie ($400 million in 2004),
ernment, and five, such as the Federal Deposit and fired their executives. In 2006, the Federal
Insurance Corporation, have “mixed ownership” Election Commission fined Freddie a record sum for
involving the feds and private parties.368 violating election laws. Fannie and Freddie remained
The Government Corporation Control Act of unfazed, however, as their congressional protectors
1945 is the basic policy governing federal corpora- were substantial; both GSEs had numbered among
tions, and, by most accounts, it was conscientiously the top twenty lobbying spenders in Washington for
followed until the late 1970s, when special interests years, endlessly pursuing their goal of ever-lighten-
eroded oversight. As a consequence, “legislation has ing their already-featherweight regulation.375
426 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

So, besides rescuing Fannie and Freddie finan- of the characteristics that public authorities and
cially in 2008, Washington took them over. It placed special districts have in common.
them into “conservatorships” (where they remain Confusingly, about half of the allegedly more
today), effectively declaring them to be bankrupt; communal, political, and governmental special dis-
sacked their top officers; abolished their boards of tricts conduct businesslike services, such as water-
directors; convinced Congress to close down and works, that are, supposedly, the sole preserve of
replace their regulatory agency; ended dividends the more managerial, technical, and commercial
to stockholders and stripped them of their right to public authorities. The obverse is equally present.
govern; demanded (in 2012) that they turn their Disney World, a market-oriented enterprise by any
profits over to the government, rather than to their standard, is not a public authority but it is a special
investors (profits returned in 2013); and, mercifully, district—the Reedy Creek Improvement District.
banned them from lobbying. Public authorities and special districts are
In 2011, a major rating agency lowered Fannie’s blithely unbothered by these definitional debates
and Freddie’s credit ratings (and those of the remain- and, as a practical matter, define themselves in terms
ing three GSEs, in whole or part, as well), and of whatever works. “While it might not seem right
Washington began the multi-year process of phasing to equate . . . [public authorities] with special dis-
out both behemoths altogether. tricts, there is also nothing exactly wrong with this
Perhaps it is time to reconsider the value of all equation.”377
government-sponsored enterprises.
Origins In the eighteenth century, and likely earlier,
“Other” Finally, there are fifty other federally various kinds of cooperative associations arose in
established organizations that do “not fit” into any communities that could reasonably be identified
other category, have “narrowly defined” missions as prototypical public authorities which dealt with
that “vary substantially,” and include “private, non- public health, educational, and even ecclesiastical
profit organizations, institutes, banks, funds, foun- affairs.378
dations, and other organizations.”376 In the early 1800s, state governments acceler-
ated their use of public authorities, often chartering
“bodies corporate” to build transportation pro-
State and Local Enterprises and the Public jects. Not infrequently, these charters were bought
Authority via bribes to legislators, and the chartered projects
State and local enterprises precede their introduc- often failed, causing state or local governments to
tion in federal circles by at least two hundred years, default; in the 1870s, “approximately one-fourth of
and continue to be a vibrant part of governing at the indebtedness of major local governments was in
the grass roots. These enterprises are owned and default.”379 These scandals persisted well into the
managed by public authorities. l920s.
Irritated by these practices, Progressive reform-
What Are Public Authorities? A public author- ers of the early twentieth century inserted in vir-
ity is a corporate form of special-purpose govern- tually all state constitutions prohibitions against
ment (excluding school districts), or part of a public lending public money, but also shrewdly pushed for
agency, that is chartered by one or more state or the enactment of the first incorporation laws. These
general-purpose local governments (i.e., municipal- laws established a system for elected officials to
ities and counties), or by popular vote, to fulfill a charter “special municipal corporations”—the fore-
business-oriented public mission. runners of public authorities and special districts—
The rub in this definition is the confounding that were empowered to issue municipal bonds to
presence of special districts, which replicate almost private investors to fund public projects.
all the characteristics of public authorities, except President Franklin Roosevelt, who saw in public
that they are, at least in theory, not corporate, but authorities a means of creating new jobs to battle the
governmental, in form, and are charged with non- Great Depression, persuaded Congress to pass the
commercial public missions. Figure 11-1 lists some Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange
Intersectoral Administration 427

Act of 1934, which rendered revenue bonds healthcare facilities; 2 percent administer ports; and
(explained in Chapter 8) more marketable. Then 1 percent each own and operate utilities or finance
Roosevelt made the grass-roots governments an educational programs. Five percent operate more
offer they could not refuse; he ordered that federal than one enterprise.383
agencies buy all the revenue bonds that they issued.
In 1934, Roosevelt drafted model legislation for Pervasive Public Authorities The scope of these
state and local governments to follow in creating state and local governmental businesses is daunting.
still more public authorities. By 1948, forty-one of Public authorities employ 3 percent of the national
the forty-eight states had adopted variants of it. labor force and account for 15 percent of the nation’s
By the end of World War II, state and local fixed investment.384 They invest more dollars in new
authorities stood at the head of several crossroads. capital facilities than all state and municipal govern-
One option was that, as their federal patron had ments combined.385 The Port Authority of New York
intended, they could “self-liquidate,” or close down and New Jersey alone has more operating revenues
after their capital costs were paid off and turn their than all but nine of the nation’s biggest cities.386
functions over to state or local governments. Or, Local public authorities own and operate essen-
they could continue charging users for their services, tially all of the nation’s commercial airports, 85
and the revenues could be deposited in state or local percent of the country’s municipal water supplies
general funds. Or, public authorities could keep the and wastewater plants, four-fifths of all local public
fees flowing into their own coffers and use those rev- transportation systems, a fourth of the nation’s elec-
enues to finance new projects. trical plants serving over sixteen million customers,
For the most part, they chose the final route, and 800 natural gas utilities that are bankrolled by
thereby facilitating their emergence as independ- nearly four million customer accounts.387
ent, special-purpose governments. Even though
Roosevelt’s bureaucracy for financing grass-roots
authorities was dismantled during the 1950s, many Creating, Governing, and Administering
of Roosevelt’s public authorities lived on, thou- Public Authorities
sands more were added, and virtually all continue to Public authorities operate in an astonishingly uncon-
prosper in their mostly monopolistic marketplaces. strained environment. They often have vague geo-
graphic boundaries, and even may lack a specific
A Slippery Slew The Census Bureau has given constituency.388 In most states, no single department
us an impressively precise, and big, tally of special even maintains an accurate listing of active public
districts—51,146—a number that does not include authorities, nor do authorities report their finances to
those uncounted, but numerous, special districts that the federal Securities and Exchange Commission—
are parts of government departments, and represents which private businesses must do.389
a spurt in growth of 37 percent over five years.380
Many public authorities are folded into this count, Creating Authorities “Authorities have from their
but how many is unknown; five major estimates inception been extremely ‘ad hoc’ in nature—some-
range from 5,000 to 18,000,381 with “many schol- times created by a single municipality, sometimes by
ars . . . [suggesting] that there are between 10,000 several cities or towns, sometimes created by one
to 12,000.”382 state, sometimes by 2 or more.”390
New York and Pennsylvania developed the two
What Do Public Authorities Do? Public authori- basic models for creating public authorities. In New
ties are responsible for a surprisingly broad array of York, public authorities are individually chartered by
public enterprises. Almost half, 45 percent, own and the state legislature. In Pennsylvania, however, local
manage public housing; 18 percent are engaged in governments can create public authorities through
environmental protection; 14 percent are involved a number of different devices, and with little or no
in economic development; 7 percent run public-use interference from the state. More than two-thirds of
facilities, such as parking garages and zoos; 4 the states use the Pennsylvanian approach; in fact,
percent deal with transportation; 3 percent manage only Maine and New York actually require that the
428 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

state legislature enact specific legislation to establish and county managers (58 percent) agree (unusually
each public authority.391 so, for they agree on nothing else) that authority
executives are far freer of political pressures than
Governing Authorities State and local authorities are city and county managers.402 Small wonder,
are headed by boards of directors, typically of “three perhaps, that not one of the responding senior man-
or more citizens,” who usually serve without com- agers of 217 large special districts expressed an
pensation. Most are appointed by elected officials, iota of dissatisfaction with his or her job,403 such
or by the board itself, and typically may not be fired as the executive director of the Los Angeles County
except when they break the law.392 Fair Association, whose annual compensation rose
Board directors tend to have business or profes- steadily and dramatically over five years, eventually
sional backgrounds, and the lack of interest among topping $1 million, despite steadily and dramati-
many of them in the affairs of the authorities that cally decreasing revenues.404 (Following unflattering
they head has been amply documented, with a signif- publicity, the director was let go, and was replaced
icant number appointing surrogates to attend board by a municipal budget analyst at less than half the
meetings, but who, in fact, rarely attend. Vacancies salary.)
on these boards are frequent.393
Although there are some signs that these boards
are trying, tepidly, to engage more citizens,394 public The Relatively Unconstrained Power
oversight is minimal. Many board meetings are not of Governments at the Fringe: Have They
announced; about six citizens, on average, attend Used It Well?
these meetings (not surprising, as authorities “typi- Despite attacks from both the left and right, public
cally hold their meetings on weekday mornings . . . enterprises at all governmental levels “have with-
and the opportunities for average citizens to speak stood such assaults practically unscathed and con-
are extremely limited”395); and the press does not tinue to claim rights of independent management.”405
regularly attend nearly two-thirds of board meetings Public enterprises and special districts are less
(for over a third of authorities, in fact, the media constrained in their actions than any other type of
never attend meetings).396 government. Have they used their independence
well?
Administering Authorities Public authorities are
managed by executive directors, over four-fifths of Federal Failures? Some major federal enterprises
whom are appointed by their boards and the remain- have failed to meet their missions of becoming finan-
der by elected officials.397 cially self-sustaining. Every year, Congress directly
Independently conducted surveys, all taken at allocates, on average, more than $60 billion to eight-
roughly the same time, confirm that these executive een of its twenty-three government corporations, or
directors, in comparison with city managers (who nearly four-fifths of them, and more than $4 billion
are among their closest counterparts), have much to seventeen, a third, of its fifty “other” federal enter-
more secure jobs (authority executives boasted prises.406
average tenures of eight years, compared with five Although graft is minimal, it is not unknown,
for city managers),398 are considerably less educated as attested to by the Postal Service governor who, in
(18 percent had not completed college, compared 1986, pled guilty of accepting bribes.407
with 4 percent of city managers),399 and are signif-
icantly less experienced in their professions (only Grass-Roots Faltering? Without question, public
38 percent of authority executives had previously authorities have left large legacies—roads, skyscrap-
worked for an authority, compared with 100 percent ers, power grids, to name a few—that might not
of city managers who had worked for a city).400 otherwise be present because some lazy, lugubrious
“In a fundamental difference . . . authority general-purpose governments were not fulfilling
executives deal with fewer competing demands and their responsibilities. When these governments do
expectations” than do city managers.401 Majorities their jobs, however, special-purpose governments
of both authority executives (63 percent) and city suffer and the people prosper.
Intersectoral Administration 429

In states with centralized state governments and and special districts, at all organizational levels, are,
local governments that proactively provide services, on average, the highest-paid public employees in the
there are often fewer special-purpose governments, United States,414 with a number taking home more
and those that exist clearly engage in “less govern- than $300,000.415
mental activity.”408 The per capita costs of services Has there been a misuse of managerial freedom
provided by special-purpose governments gener- by public authorities? Yes; the examples are too
ally are higher than the same services provided by legion to conclude otherwise. Is this misuse endemic?
general-purpose governments,409 often because We do not know.
special-purpose governments are so small geographi-
cally they are unable to achieve economies of scale.410
Authority costs are high, at least in part, because THE INDEPENDENT SECTOR: BIG,
of incompetent management. Here are some exam-
ples:411 GROWING, AND INFLUENTIAL
Perhaps no sector in the maze of intersectoral
■ The Port Authority of New York and New
administration has become more prominent more
Jersey built a $21 million luggage tunnel
quickly than has the independent sector. Technically,
without first checking if the airlines wanted it.
the voluntary sector is part of the private sector (the
They did not. The tunnel remains unused and
organizations comprising it are created by private
boarded up.
interests and are privately owned), but we treat it as
■ New York’s Dormitory Authority awarded
a separate sector, which is not uncommon (one of its
millions of dollars in construction contracts to
titles, after all, is the “third sector”).
firms banned by other public agencies because
The hybrid sector owns about 5 percent of all net
of the firms’ ties to organized crime and their
worth in the private sector; accounts for 5.5 percent
long records of violations.
of GDP;416 employs 10.3 percent of the nonfarm
■ In the early 1990s, Washington unilaterally
civilian workforce; and its growth in employment,
took over the nation’s worst public housing,
total annual wages, and number of establishments
expelling in the process the local housing
significantly outpaces those in the private and public
authorities that had managed them with
sectors.417 Nine out of ten American adults belong to
an awesome ineptness. Examples include
at least one nonprofit association.418
the chair of the New York City authority
The primary revenue sources of public-benefit
who redecorated her office in pink at a cost
nonprofits are fees (e.g., tuition paid to nonprofit
of $350,000, and the one-fourth of public
colleges), at 51 percent, a proportion that has held
housing units in New Orleans that were vacant
remarkably steady over twenty years; government
because they were unfit for human habitation
grants and contracts, at 37 percent and rising
(and this was before Hurricane Katrina struck).
from 31 percent over the same period; and private
More recently, more than 25,000 families
giving, at a modest 12 percent and falling from 18
who occupy public housing have incomes
percent.419
that exceed the income limit for government-
subsidized rentals, including one family with an
annual income of nearly $500,000.412 Serving Themselves or Serving Others
Corruption is present as well, and authority employ- There are an estimated 2.3 million nonprofit organ-
ees and officials at all levels have been convicted of izations.420 As shown in Figure 11-1, there are two
numerous instances of fraud, kickbacks, extortion, types.
embezzlement, and other crimes that involved mil- Member-serving organizations are nonprofit
lions of dollars.413 associations that provide benefits to their members.
Despite all this—relatively easy and secure jobs, There are about 550,000 of them.421
less education and experience, high costs to custom- Public-serving, or public-benefit, organizations
ers, and considerable incompetence and corruption— are not-for-profit associations that provide ben-
it appears that the employees of public authorities efits to people who are not their members. There
430 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

are nearly 1.1 million of them,422 they employ 90 greater trust in nonprofits than in either government
percent of all full-time employees in the tax-exempt or companies, volunteer for them more frequently,
independent sector, and their revenues account for and are more likely to buy healthcare and education
about two-thirds of all nonprofit revenue.423 It is on services from them.432
these nonprofit organizations that our discussion
will center.
Governments and the Independent Sector
Until the mid-twentieth century, most nonprofits
The Good that the Third Sector Does existed at the local level and were subject mostly
The recipients of services that are provided by to local regulations. State governments became
nonprofit organizations are far more satisfied with involved with the nonprofit sector as it grew,
those services than are the recipients of services and today all states and the federal government
delivered by governments,424 and faith-based non- require that nonprofits file annual reports of their
profits (excluding religious congregations) provide incomes.433 But the public sector’s influence over its
services that are “equivalent or superior [to] com- independent counterpart extends far beyond this
parable secular organizations.”425 In addition, we modest regulation, and governments can manipu-
are discovering that nonprofits bring other ben- late the regulatory environment of the independent
efits: the greater the number of nonprofits per sector in ways that affect nonprofits’ number, size,
capita in a community, and the more that they diversity, and even the personal characteristics of
engage local residents, there is a lower level of local their executives.434
unemployment.426 Governments play a large and expanding role
in the fiscal health of nonprofits; 56,000 nonprof-
its of all types receive 350,000 grants and contracts
A Remarkably Respected Sector from the federal, state, or local governments, or an
As a consequence of its social contributions, cit- average of six public grants for each nonprofit.435
izens’ confidence in the third sector’s ability to
deliver public policies is high. Even though public Which Nonprofits Get Public Money? Half of all
trust in nonprofits has declined worldwide, it has nonprofits have missions of human services436 (i.e.,
increased in the United States, and nearly two-thirds health, culture, recreation, post-secondary educa-
of Americans trust them.427 And with some reason; tion, and social services437), and it is to these organ-
although American nonprofits constitute 30 percent izations that 70 percent of all the money received
of all corporations, they amount to just 1 percent by all nonprofits from all sources flows.438 Giving
of all corporate bankruptcies, indicative, perhaps, of to human services nonprofits grows faster, and the
“their morality rather than their durability.”428 amount that donors give per donor is higher, than all
When federal and business managers were other categories of nonprofits.439
asked to identify which institution—the federal gov- Human services nonprofits also are the leading
ernment, state and local governments, businesses, or recipients of public dollars, accounting for more than
nonprofits—would they have “the most confidence two-fifths of all governmental spending on human
in” to implement four publicly-relevant functions, services.440 Human services nonprofits receive nearly
nonprofits swept the field, with these managers typi- three-fifths of all the dollars in public grants and
cally giving higher ratings to the independent sector contracts to nonprofits; agencies have some 200,000
than they gave even to their own sectors.429 Sixteen grants and contracts with about 30,000 human ser-
percent of top federal executives leave the federal vices nonprofits, or an average of seven per non-
employ to work in the independent sector, which is profit.441
the third ranking destination out of seven.430 More than half of governments’ grants and con-
A stunning 44 percent, a plurality, of college tracts to nonprofits go to the human services subset
seniors cite the nonprofit sector as the institution of social services,442 i.e., job training, day care, and,
in which they have the most confidence to deliver by far the most fiscally dominant category, “indi-
services,431 and university students in general have vidual and family services,” or welfare.443 Social
Intersectoral Administration 431

services, with some reason, have been referred to as Fortunately, governments rely heavily on grants
the “social services industrial complex.”444 when dealing with independent organizations.
Forty-three percent of all nonprofits that receive
Public Money’s Unique Benefits In light of public public grants and contracts receive only grants; 38
money being the sole source of nonprofit revenue percent receive both; and just 19 percent receive
that is growing, governments wax in nonprofits’ only contracts.457 Federal agencies issue two-and-a-
fiscal importance. Organizations in the independ- half times more dollars sent directly to nonprofits as
ent sector can significantly improve their odds for grants, relative to the dollars paid directly through
attaining government funding by collaborating with contracts.458
other nonprofits, professionalizing their staffs, and
adopting “standard management strategies” for The Federal Government and the Independent
achieving their missions.445 Sector According to the Government Account-
A “higher level of government support” for ability Office, which ought to know, independent
nonprofits associates, in turn, with more privately- organizations are “key partners in delivering federal
donated dollars. “A 1 percent increase in government programs and services.”459
funding is followed by 0.122 percent of rise in public
support.”446 The obverse, however, is not the case: Formidable Federal Funding It appears that federal
there is “no evidence of an effect of private donations funding of the third sector is significant, involving
on government grants” to nonprofits.447 nearly 700 federal programs.460 Analysts estimate
The larger the proportion of government funds that Washington transfers, either directly or through
relative to charitable donations in a nonprofit’s third parties, about the same amount of money to
budget, the more likely that the organization will be: the independent sector that it contracts out to the
larger in membership yet leaner in both its board private sector.461
size and its administrative staff; use fewer volun- Federal fiscal support of public-benefit non-
teers; be less dependent on its own earned income; profits likely has more than doubled in real buying
be more racially diverse in its volunteers, staff, and power over twenty-four years. The increase is attrib-
(probably448) its board;449 be more likely to collab- utable to the growth in healthcare programs and
orate with other organizations;450 be less adminis- some indexed income assistance programs, such as
tratively complex,451 and “substantially” likelier to public housing, and it came at a price: federal spend-
“embrace participatory governance practices.”452 ing on the remaining programs that habitually rely
Governmental funding of nonprofits also associ- on nonprofits to deliver publicly-funded services
ates with more nonprofits in a jurisdiction, and it (notably social services, education, and research,
has a greater impact in this regard than does private among others) declined by nearly a fifth over the
funding.453 same period.462
When nonprofits contract with governments to Washington also supports the third sector indi-
deliver services, their boards often experience “very rectly. About 70 percent (or more than 1.6 million)
significant stresses and challenges, some of which of America’s roughly 2.3 million nonprofits are
may threaten their capacity to govern . . . effec- exempt from federal taxes,463 a policy that began in
tively.”454 In general, however, government support is 1894 with the passage of the Wilson-Gorman Tariff
a winning relationship for the independent sector.455 Act, and was later reinforced with the Revenue Acts
of 1909, 1913, and 1917; indeed, Washington now
Grants over Contracts Public funding of nonprofits lists twenty-nine classifications of tax-exempt non-
in the form of grants, rather than contracts, appears profits. As a result, the federal government foregoes
to produce superior results. Contract-based funding “approximately $50 billion” in annual tax revenues.
forces nonprofit organizations, in contrast to private Public-serving organizations account for about
companies, to hire less professional “temporary staff two-thirds of all federal tax-exempt nonprofits, and
for core service delivery in government-funded pro- member-serving nonprofits make up the rest.464
grams,” which then reduces “the effectiveness of the As shown in Figure 11-1, public-serving associa-
services the agency [provides] to the community.”456 tions also benefit indirectly from a unique tax policy
432 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

that applies only to them. Under Section 501 (c) (3) addition, each year the feds provide them with
of the U.S. Internal Revenue Code, federal taxpay- “approximately $2.5 billion in loan guarantees and
ers who donate to public-serving organizations may $450 million in loans.”466
deduct from their taxable income the value of their
donations, and subnational governments have mostly Washington and Nonprofit Management Direct
followed the federal lead in adopting this policy. federal grants that include a specific requirement,
such as stipulating that they be matched with private
Money Mysteries The preceding data are largely funds, “are particularly effective at stimulating both
educated estimates. Although a database has been additional fund-raising activity and output” among
under development since 2006, it remains the case nonprofits, whereas grants that are not specific
that there are no comprehensive statistical data that “appear to significantly reduce both fund-raising
track federal support for nonprofit organizations.465 and output.”467
Figure 11-2 illustrates why this is: the bulk of federal On occasion, Congress improves the manage-
funding ends up in nonprofit coffers only after it has ment of nonprofits, if inadvertently. The Sarbanes-
been handled by many hands. Oxley Act of 2002, intended to clean up the finance
Some federal funds, such as Medicare’s health industry, also affected the independent sector. “About
subsidies to the elderly, are transferred to non- one in four” nonprofits attributed “better financial
profit organizations because individual recipients controls and reduced risk of accounting fraud” to
have chosen to use their services; the feds annually the act.468 On the other hand, as we noted in the
channel perhaps $145 billion to independent organ- introduction to Part III, Washington (and state gov-
izations in these “fee-for-service payments.” ernments) often fails to deal with obviously fraudu-
Some, such as many federal grants to the states, lent nonprofits.
are passed through the states to nonprofits, or to
local governments that then send them to non- State Governments and the Independent Sector
profits; each year, the emerging sector receives an More than seven out of ten state agencies contract
estimated $55 billion in this fashion from just two with nonprofit associations to deliver services;469
federal grant programs. roughly three-quarters of the funding for this comes
And some, such as research grants to independ- from the federal government in the form of pass-
ent universities, flow directly from federal agencies through grants to the states and their localities.470
to third-sector organizations; Washington annu- Relatively generous state funding correlates pos-
ally disburses $25 billion in grants and $10 billion itively with more nonprofits overall, and more of
in contracts directly to third-sector recipients. In large size, in the state.471

Individuals

Federal State Nonprofit


government government organizations

Local
government

FIGURE 11-2
Paths of Federal Funds to Nonprofit Organizations
Source: U.S. Government Accountability Office, Nonprofit Sector: Increasing Numbers and Key Role in Delivering
Federal Services, GAO-07-1084T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2007), p. 8.
Intersectoral Administration 433

Once acquired, state funding seems to continue estimated that the property tax exemption for
with relative ease, as state administrators rely less nonprofits costs cities about 4 to 8 percent in lost
on quantitative measures to determine the perfor- property tax revenue.479 In Syracuse, New York, for
mance of their nonprofit contractors, at least when example, 51 percent of all property in the city is tax
compared with their for-profit counterparts, and exempt because it is owned by nonprofits or govern-
rely more on qualitative judgments.472 Such laxity ments.480 Yale University owns “about half” of New
is rarely wise, as exemplified by the nonprofit that Haven, Connecticut.481
contracted with South Carolina to restore wetlands A few nonprofits seem to be getting the message.
for a fee of $5 million. Not only did the nonprofit “At least 420 nonprofits” provide 218 local govern-
overspend its contract by $300,000, but it bought ments in twenty-eight states payment in lieu of taxes
properties that not only were not wetlands, but were (PILOTs), which are voluntary contributions made
not even close to the area in question; auditors deter- by tax-exempt nonprofits to governments as a sub-
mined that the entire restoration could have been stitute for property taxes. But these payments do not
done for $743,000.473 amount to much: about 1 percent of the receiving
This sort of laxity seems likely to continue, as localities’ general revenue, with just ten nonprofits
most of the states’ regulation of their charities (and, accounting for most of it.482 From three-quarters to
presumably, other public-serving nonprofits) is a hit- four-fifths of “PILOT activity” is in the Northeastern
or-miss affair. No state has a single law for oversee- United States; higher education contributes about
ing its charities, and states rely instead on a “complex two-thirds of PILOT revenue, and hospitals about
mix” of laws and procedures. Fifty-nine percent of a fourth.483
the states (including five territories and the District
of Columbia) distribute the oversight of charities Local Governments and the Independent Sector
among various agencies. A modest 355 staffers com- Localities and nonprofits evidence an increasing
prise the national total of state professionals who intimacy, as exemplified by the 373 nonprofits in
oversee charities, and 31 percent of the state charity Berkshire County, Massachusetts, which account for
offices have not even one full-time staffer.474 nearly half of its regional economy.484
As with Washington, state governments also As an indication of these close relations, 63
heavily subsidize the independent sector through percent of cities and counties provide links on their
their tax policies. All states exempt charities—1.5 websites to “community organizations” (just 2
million of them—from the local property tax,475 percent more, 65 percent, provide links to “other
saving nonprofits from $17 billion to $32 billion per governments,” which is the highest percentage out of
year.476 The states’ relief of charities from the state eleven possibilities), and 53 percent do so for “non-
corporate income tax, levied by forty-five states, profits.”485
nets the independent sector close to $4 billion per Cities and counties contract out nearly 10
annum; and two dozen of the forty-five states with a percent of all their services to independent organiza-
sales tax do not tax purchases by charitable organi- tions,486 the highest percentage in thirty years; previ-
zations, and another sixteen provide limited exemp- ously, 8 to 9 percent of local services were delivered
tions, totaling about $2.5 billion annually.477 In all, by nonprofits.487 Even though these governments are
state charitable tax policies deprive the states from somewhat leery about contracting with third-sector
$23 billion to $38 billion in tax revenue per year. associations, and prefer contracting out to them
There are signs that the states’ tax relief pol- services that have little likelihood of failing,488 they
icies are slackening, as subnational governments are more satisfied with how nonprofit organizations
increasingly are questioning why “nonprofit” hos- deliver their services than they are with how for-
pitals (one judge ruled that, “for purposes of the profit corporations provide them. Although cities
property tax exemption, modern nonprofit hos- and counties bring back in-house 24 percent of the
pitals are essentially legal fictions”478), private contracts that they have with independent organi-
colleges, and even professional football teams, zations, they reel in 33 percent, or almost two-fifths
among other organizations, pay no business income more, of the contracts that they sign with private
taxes or local property taxes. It is authoritatively companies.489
434 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Like their state counterparts, local administra- support for public services is growing faster than
tors favor qualitative measures of their nonprofit that of the independent sector in general. Public uni-
contractors’ performance over quantitative ones, versities, for example, long have had nonprofit foun-
which they reserve for their business contrac- dations dedicated to raising private funds for them,
tors.490 Unlike their dealings with private compa- but newer recipients of nonprofit largesse are emerg-
nies, local governments shy away from inserting ing, such as the dramatic “rescue by foundation” of
formal rewards and penalties into their contracts bankrupt Detroit. The assistance and expertise that
with nonprofits, preferring to rectify problems of nonprofits provide to governments expands their
productivity through conversation and, less so, capacity to govern.496
with technical assistance.491 Even though one study A number of federal agencies, including the
found “no significant differences” between non- Central Intelligence Agency, have “created or spurred
profit and for-profit local contractors in terms of the creation of philanthropic offshoots that serve as
“performance . . . quality of work, responsiveness mechanisms for accessing private capital. They func-
to government requirements, legal compliance, tion a little like the private foundation arms of . . .
or customer satisfaction,” local administrators state universities.”497 Nearly 400 nonprofits provide
nevertheless trusted nonprofits more, monitored advocacy, volunteers, and funds to the 400 national
them less, granted them greater discretion and con- parks and related federal facilities.498
tracts of longer duration, and contracted with them Not all independent organizations with a federal
for “services characterized by higher levels of task purpose are created by federal agencies. A bipartisan
uncertainty” (i.e., higher risk) compared with for- coalition of sixteen nonprofits called “Transitions in
profit contractors.492 Governance 2016,” for example, used crowdsourc-
But contracts do not tell the whole story, and ing to identify problems and solutions for the newly
it appears that most (52 percent) nonprofits that elected administration.
collaborate with local agencies do not bother with At least nine states have created economic
contracts at all, but rely instead on informal co- development nonprofits, although their effectiveness
operative arrangements. Astonishingly, “although is increasingly questioned.499 Sixteen states count
(as expected) local governments are more likely to funds provided to them by nonprofits toward their
provide funding and equipment with formal agree- spending levels that are required by the $16.5 billion
ments than without,” a fourth of local public dollars federal block grant program, Temporary Assistance
that flow to the third sector “still are provided for Needy Families, which assists low-income
outside the contracting area.”493 families.500
That third-sector executives are able to induce “Roughly half of all state parks . . . now have
local administrators to furnish on faith a fourth of an associated nonprofit ‘Friends of the Park’ group.”
their funding of nonprofits is impressive testimony Nonprofits that aid public parks were created at an
to their powers of persuasion. It is even more impres- estimated rate of two per year, on average, from the
sive that they do so in light of the fact that “non- 1980s to the present, when an estimated average of
profit executives generally exhibit a stronger current twenty each year are being founded. Ninety-seven
of negativity toward intersectoral partnership than percent of these organizations contribute money to
do their public sector counterparts” in local govern- federal, state, and local parks.501
ments.494 Those independent organizations that are What Works Cities, Code for America, the
smaller and younger, or which are led by executive Government Performance Lab, the Sunlight
directors who are men, or those who were never Foundation, the Knight Foundation’s Cities
employed by government, or who endured a bad Challenge, and uncounted but numerous of insti-
experience in an earlier collaboration with govern- tutes of government funded by public universi-
ment, are the most resistant to working with local ties, among other nonprofits, offer their services to
governments.495 improve local governance. Over sixteen years, non-
profits that support local public schools grew by
The Flip Side: Nonprofit Support for Public 260 percent and the funds that they raised expanded
Agencies It is not well known, but philanthropic by 348 percent, whereas the growth of third-sector
Intersectoral Administration 435

organizations overall grew by 196 percent and their transparency and accountability, as nonprofits rarely,
fundraising by 264 percent—rates that are about a if ever, are subject to the same, relatively high, audit-
fourth lower than those of school-supporting non- ing standards as are public agencies, and irregulari-
profits in both cases.502 ties, or worse, can be present.503 Nevertheless, “the
Whether nonprofits provide their services to data suggest, overall, that philanthropic funding for
federal, state, or local governments, these relation- public services is neither a temporary nor a short-
ships are not without problems, particularly those of term trend.”504

A CASE INDEPENDENT GOVERNANCE:


NEIGHBORHOODS RENASCENT

Neighborhood governance is the participation by leaseholders that are governed under local real estate
community-based nonprofit organizations in local contract laws.
governments’ policymaking and administration as they
pertain to their communities. Community associations owe no small debt to
Neighborhood governance exemplifies governing academia, most especially to Professor Charles
by the nonprofit sector, and it takes several forms. Stern Archer, who was central in their creation
One is neighborhood associations, which are at “a time when the greatest minds in public
informal groups of community residents that work with administration were interested in the modern form
local governments to improve their communities. They of homeowners associations—when they invented
got their start with the Housing Act of 1949, which them in 1928” (McKenzie, p. 543). During the
required citizen participation in public hearings dealing ensuing years, according to some, they emerged as
with federal housing projects. During the 1960s and “private governments” that are “a cross between local
1970s, Congress or federal agencies inserted no fewer government and the assistant principal for discipline at
than another 155 provisos into intergovernmental a very strict high school” (White).
grants that mandated citizen participation in local These associations have grown from fewer
decision making (U.S. Advisory Commission on than a thousand in 1960 to 310,000 today, and
Intergovernmental Relations, 1979, p. 4). from responsibility for 700,000 housing units and
Another form is community development two million residents in 1970 to 30 million units
corporations, or organizations that are chartered and 63 million residents (or over two-fifths of all
under state law, created and led by the residents of Americans) today. Community associations govern 24
depressed communities, and link public subsidies with percent of all housing, and, since 1980, fully half of
private investment for the purpose of revitalizing those all new housing has been placed under their rule. Their
communities, particularly housing. They were created governing boards control $51 billion in associations’
by the Economic Opportunity Act of 1964 and the budgets (Community Associations Institute).
Demonstration Cities and Metropolitan Development Common-interest communities may be one of three
Act of 1966. There are more than 240 of them types. More than half are homeowners’ associations
(NeighborWorks). and other planned communities, composed of owners
When it comes to governing neighborhoods, of detached houses or townhouses, and are found
however, the home-grown colossus (it was not created mostly in the suburbs. From 45 to 48 percent are
by Congress, as were the other two) are the residential condominium associations, in which residents of
community associations, community associations, a complex own percentages of its common areas
or common-interest communities, which are and own their apartments. And from 3 to 5 percent
nonprofit organizations of homeowners or long-term are cooperatives, or co-ops, in which a cooperative

(continued)
436 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

(continued)
association owns the building; residents own shares in community, and 81 percent believe that they get a
the corporation and lease their apartments (Korngold, “good” or “great” return on their fees (Foundation
p. 17). for Community Association Research). As we reviewed
Residential community associations impose in Chapter 1, and discuss further in Chapter 12, these
mandatory fees on their members (who also pay are far higher positives than citizens grant their
their property taxes in full) and directly deliver governments along comparable dimensions.
an average of ten services—most commonly, If there is a lesson to be drawn from neighborhood
landscaping, garbage collection, water, sewer, and street governments, perhaps it is this: Smaller governing can
lighting and maintenance—that are (with the possible be better governance.
exception of landscaping) traditional duties of municipal
Sources: U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
governments (U.S. Advisory Commission on Relations, Citizen Participation in the American Federal System,
Intergovernmental Relations, 1989, p. 13). A-73 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979);
Most cities and towns have established formal NeighborWorks, NeighborWorks (Washington, DC: Author,
relations with their “neighborhood organizations,” 2014); Otis White, “Otis White’s Urban Notebook,” Governing
and almost seven out of ten allocate funds to (February 2006), p. 17; Evan McKenzie, “Present at the Creation:
The Public Administration Profession and Residential Private
train them in making decisions for their own
Government,” Public Administration Review 71 (July/August
neighborhoods, a growing practice (Kearney, p. 30).
2011), pp. 543–545; Community Associations Institute, Industry
Sixty-three percent of municipal administrators Data (Falls Church, VA: Author, 2011); Gerald Korngold, “Private
agree or strongly agree that “partnerships” in their Regimes in the Public Sphere,” Land Lines 27 (Winter 2015),
communities “are developed with neighborhood and pp. 14–23. Zogby International and Community Associations
community organizations to involve the public in Institute, What Do Americans Say about Their Community
appropriate public engagement activities” (Nelson and Associations? You Might Be Surprised (New York and Falls
Church, VA: Authors, 2009); Foundation for Community
Svara, p. 12).
Association Research, Statistical Review 2012 (Falls Church,
Fifty-six percent of association officers report
VA, 2012); Richard C. Kearney, “Reinventing Government and
that the level of cooperation between them and local Battling Budget Crises: Manager and Municipal Government
governments is good, and 71 percent state that they Actions in 2003,” Municipal Year Book, 2005 (Washington, DC:
had been treated fairly by local officials (U.S. Advisory International City/County Management Association, 2005), pp.
Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 1989, 27–32; Kimberly L. Nelson and James H. Svara, “Upholding and
p. 20). However, 87 percent, a rising proportion, of Expanding the Roles of Local Government Managers: State of
the Profession 2012,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 (Washington,
residents would not “want to see more government
DC: International City/County Management Association, 2014),
control” of their associations (Zogby International and
pp. 3–20; and U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Community Associations Institute, p. 5). Relations, Residential Community Associations: Private
Seventy percent of residents say that their governing Governments in the Intergovernmental System? A-112
boards “strive to serve the best interests of the (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1989).

IMPLEMENTATION BY Volunteering for Government


INDIVIDUALS: VOLUNTEERS A fourth of American adults do volunteer work,
devoting fifty-one median hours to such service per
AND VOUCHERS year.505 Forty-four percent of Utahans volunteer (the
Some public policies are implemented directly by highest rate of any state), and 18 percent of neigh-
people, and the two most significant methods of boring Nevadans (the lowest).506
implementation by individuals are volunteers and Twenty-one percent of America’s nearly 63
vouchers. million volunteers volunteer for government, or
Intersectoral Administration 437

government-related, programs. More than 14 percent them exceed a relatively small sum (less than $1,000
are involved in “social or community service,” over 5 per fire fighter518), then “the use of volunteers should
percent volunteer in “civic and political” programs, be reconsidered” because it is more cost-effective to
and about 1 percent are in public safety.507 Over a start adding full-time paid professionals.519
fourth of Americans report that they have partici- When governments cut services, and hope that
pated in community crime watches.508 volunteers will fill the vacuum, the results are even
more counterproductive. “Volunteering is likely to
Washington’s Volunteers Congress prohibits decline when government intervention decreases.”520
federal agencies from using volunteers except in spe- Alas, there is no free lunch.
cific circumstances, such as during emergencies or to
further students’ educations. This is passing strange Nonprofits’ Volunteers: Productive and Occasionally
as Congress, beginning in the 1960s, has subsidized Profitable One hour of a volunteer’s time is worth,
thousands of volunteers to work everywhere else. on average, $23.56 to the nonprofit benefiting from
Federal agencies are estimated to directly operate the volunteer’s service.521
from 20 to 30 percent of all organized volunteer When nonprofit organizations are well struc-
programs, and from 20 to 30 percent of these pro- tured and mix volunteers with paid employees,
grams are connected with the public sector.509 volunteers’ attitudes and commitment to the
organization match those of paid employees.522
State Government Volunteers State agencies score (Unbeknownst to their employees, perhaps, non-
a bit better on the use of volunteers than do the feds, profits that include volunteers pay their employees
but not by much. Twelve percent of state administra- less, on average, than those that have no volun-
tors in only seven states report that any volunteers teers.523) In contrast to employees, however, volun-
are used in their governments.510 Not even 2 percent teers also donate money to the organizations that
of all state agencies use volunteers, and their use is in they serve,524 not a surprising occurrence, given that
decline. Corrections and transportation agencies use twice as many volunteers donate to charity (nearly
volunteers the most frequently.511 four-fifths—over 79 percent) as do non-volunteers
(two-fifths).525
Local Government Volunteers Although 27 When nonprofits use volunteers to both provide
percent of local governments use volunteers to services directly to their clients and in program
deliver some sort of service,512 volunteers deliver support roles, they enjoy 50 percent greater total
an average of barely 5 percent of twenty-seven benefits compared with nonprofits that use only vol-
municipal and county services, or two-fifths of all unteers to directly provide services; net benefits also
local services.513 This is a decline of nearly two- accrue at a higher rate, and “challenges” associated
fifths from twenty-five years earlier, when volunteers with managing volunteers do not increase.526
helped deliver 8 percent of nearly half of all local
services.514 Volunteers are used most frequently in
the operation of cultural and arts programs, services Vouching for Citizen Service
for the elderly, museums, and fire prevention;515 vol- Vouchers are coupons with a dollar value that gov-
unteer fire fighters have declined since 1984, when ernments distribute to citizens needing a service; the
there were more than a million of them, to about citizen can choose a provider from competing organ-
788,000 today, although 87 percent of fire depart- izations that the government has pre-selected as eli-
ments are comprised of all or mostly volunteers.516 gible, and the government reimburses the provider
at a pre-set rate. Federal, state, and local vouchers
Governments’ Volunteers: Productive and Occa- are used in “a wide and diverse range of program
sionally Pricey Volunteers can make possible areas” (at least ten very broad areas), ranging from
governmental accomplishments that would not be childcare to transportation.527
possible without them,517 but they can be costly.
Consider America’s volunteer fire fighters. When the Washington’s Voluminous Vouchers The Supple-
annual costs of recruiting, training, and managing mental Nutrition Assistance Program (or SNAP,
438 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

formerly the Food Stamp Program), initiated in A modest 3 percent of cities and counties use
1964, and Medicare, started in 1965, are the federal vouchers to deliver twenty-two local services (over
government’s two principal voucher programs. a third of all local services), although their use is
Under SNAP, the Agriculture Department issues increasing. Favored areas are the operation of food
to poor people coupons, which they may use to buy programs and shelters for the homeless.537
groceries at any store accepting the coupons, and Education, or school, vouchers (originated in
receive a federal discount in the process. Some 46 Milwaukee in 1990) are coupons issued by gov-
million people receive $70 billion in discounted gro- ernments that parents can apply toward the tuition
ceries each year.528 charged by a private school; their children are not
Medicare distribute almost $586 billion in required to attend the public school assigned to
annual health benefits to nearly 51 million people them. There are thirty-eight private school choice
who are sixty-five or older.529 The Tax Equity and programs in eighteen states, the District of Columbia,
Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 allows partici- and a county in Colorado. Although these vouchers
pants the option of using a voucher that lets them come with a high and controversial profile, their
choose a health maintenance organization from a impact, though slowly expanding, remains limited. A
pre-approved list. small fraction of 1 percent of all pupils use vouchers
Lesser-known federal vouchers (which to attend private schools.538
Washington usually dubs “certificates,” a less polit-
ically loaded term) focus on a variety of domes-
tic programs. The Workforce Investment Act of NOTES
1998 introduced vouchers to federal targeted 1. Gerald W. Johnson and John G. Heilman,
training programs. Childcare services use vouch- “Metapolicy Transition and Policy Implementation:
ers so broadly that they have become the nation’s New Federalism and Privatization,” Public Admini-
“primary method” of financing childcare.530 The stration Review 47 (November/December 1987)
Department of Housing and Urban Development’s pp. 468–478. The quotation is on p. 468.
Housing Choice Voucher Program (also known 2. James C. Clingermayer, Richard C. Feiock, and
as “Section 8”), introduced in 1974, accounts for Christopher Stream, “Governmental Uncertainty
almost a fourth of the housing units in federally and Leadership Turnover: Influences on
assisted low-income housing programs,531 and helps Contracting and Sector Choice for Local Services,”
more than two million low-income households pay State and Local Government Review 35 (Fall
rent. Washington’s use of housing vouchers “reflects 2003), pp. 150–160.
a major shift,” rendering vouchers “the centerpiece 3. Byron E. Price, “The Threat of Privatization:
of federal low-income housing policy.” Their use The Impetus Behind Government Performance,”
associates with better outcomes for children, fami- International Journal of Public Administration 30
lies leaving and avoiding welfare, workplace success (11, 2007), pp. 1141–1155.
4. Martin Tolchin and Susan J. Tolchin, Pinstripe
for breadwinners,532 improved physical and mental
Patronage: Political Favoritism from the Clubhouse
health, significantly reduced homelessness and
to the White House and Beyond (Boulder, CO:
overcrowding, and “real, albeit uneven, progress in
Paradigm Publishers, 2010).
helping families move to better neighborhoods than
5. Roland Zullo, “Does Fiscal Stress Induce
they might have otherwise.”533 Privatization? Correlates of Private and Inter-
municipal Contracting, 1992–2002,” Governance
State and Local Vouchers State and local govern- 22 (July 2009), pp. 459–481.
ments use vouchers, too, but, with the exception of 6. Irene S. Rubin, “Who Invented Budgeting in the
childcare,534 far from extensively. United States?” Public Administration Review 53
Six percent of state administrators in just three (September/October 1993), p. 438–444. The quo-
states report that their governments use vouchers.535 tation is on p. 443.
Not even 1 percent of all state agencies actually use 7. Senator Claire McCaskill, quoted in David Francis,
vouchers, however, and their use is in decline. Social “Here’s How Edward Snowden Got ‘Top Secret’
service agencies use them the most.536 Clearance,” Fiscal Times (June 21, 2013).
Intersectoral Administration 439

8. Robert T. Kleiman and Anandi P. Sahu, 20. Zachary S. Huitink and David M. Van Slyke,
“Privatization as a Viable Alternative for Local Beyond Business as Usual: Improving Defense
Governments: The Case of a Failed Michigan Acquisition through Better Buying Power
Town,” Contracting Out Government Services, (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the Business of
Paul Seidenstat, ed. (Westport, CN: Praeger, 1999), Government, 2015), p. 11. Figure is for FY 2013.
pp. 151–165. The quotation is on p. 163. 21. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Federal Contracts
9. Quoted in Norm Ornstein, “Analysis: Government and the Contracted Workforce (Washington, DC:
Privatization Paves the Way for Crony Capitalism,” U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), p. 1.
Government Executive (June 20, 2013). 22. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Policy
10. Graeme Browning, “Dot.gov goes Retail,” Federal Letter 92–1: Inherently Governmental Functions
Computer Week (May 28, 2001), pp. 21–27. Figure (Washington, DC: Author, September 23, 1992).
is for 2001. 23. Alexander Tabbarok, “The Rise, Fall, and Rise
11. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Excess Again of Privateers,” Independent Review 11
Personal Property: DOD Should Further Reassess (Spring 2007), pp. 565–578.
the Priorities of the Disposal Process, GAO-16-44 24. Amber Corrin, “Public vs. Private: A Coalition of
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing the Willing?” Federal Computer Week (January 10,
Office, 2016), Highlights page. Figure is for FY 2010), p. 36. Figure is for 2010.
2014. 25. As derived from data in Steven L. Schooner and
12. Federal Real Property Council, Federal Real Collin D. Swan, “Contractors and the Ultimate
Property Profile (FRPP) Summary Report FY14 Sacrifice,” Service Contractor (September 2010),
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing pp. 16–18. Figures are for 2001–2010.
Office, 2016). 26. Ariana Eunjung Cha and Renae Merle, “Line
13. U.S. House Oversight panel, cited in Charles S. Increasingly Blurred between Soldiers and Civilian
Clark, “Lawmaker: VA Alone Is Sitting on $2 Contractors,” Washington Post (May 13, 2004).
Billion in Underused Property,” Government Exe- 27. U.S. Commission on Wartime Contracting in
cutive (July 30, 2014). Iraq and Afghanistan, Transforming Wartime
14. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Govern- Contracting: Controlling Costs, Reducing Risks,
ment Procurement: United States Reported Final Report to Congress (Washington, DC: U.S.
Opening More Opportunities to Foreign Firms Government Printing Office, 2011).
Than Other Countries, but Better Data Are 28. David Isenberg, as quoted in Peter G. Tuttle,
Needed, GAO-17-168 (Washington, DC: U.S. “Don’t Cut Corners While Outsourcing,” Federal
Government Publishing Office, 2017), Highlights Computer Week (June 28, 2010), p. 15.
page. 29. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
15. Charles S. Clark, “Agencies Should Drive Harder Department of Labor: Better Cost Assessments
Bargains for Supplies, GAO Says,” Govexec.com and Departmentwide Performance Tracking
(August 13, 2015). Are Needed to Effectively Manage Competitive
16. Donald F. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving Results: Sourcing Program, GAO-09-14 (Washington, DC:
Lessons for Improving Government Management U.S. Government Printing Office, 2008), p. 8.
from GAO’s High-Risk List (Washington, DC: 30. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting
IBM Center for the Business of Government, Office, Competitive Sourcing: Greater Emphasis
2016), p. 19. Figure is for FY 2015. Needed on Increasing Efficiency and Improving
17. As derived from data in Bloomberg Government, Performance, GAO-04-367 (Washington, DC: U.S.
BGOV200: Federal Industry Leaders 2016 (New Government Printing Office, 2004), p. 6.
York: Author, 2016), p. 4. Figures are for FY 2015. 31. Charles S. Clark, “Even CBO Is Stumped on the
18. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal Acqui- Size of the Contractor Workforce,” Government
sition: Trends, Reforms, and Challenges, GAO-T- Executive (March 12, 2015).
OCG-00-7 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 32. U.S. Senate, Committee on the Budget, Inefficiency
Printing Office, 2000), p. 6. and Mismanagement: OMB’s Contracting Out
19. NCMA and Bloomberg Government, 2013 Annual Program (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Review of Government Contracting (Ashburn, VA, Printing Office, 1990), cover letter. Figures are
and New York: Authors, 2014), p. 7. estimates.
440 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

33. I. Nye Stevens, Contracting Out and Its Impact on Public Sector Clients and Procurement Selection,”
Federal Personnel and Operations, Hearings before International Journal of Public Sector Management
the U.S. House of Representatives, Committee 21 (7, 2008), pp. 753–776. The quotation is on
on Post Office and Civil Services (Washington, p. 753.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1990), 46. Federal News Radio, WFED Federal CAO Survey
p. 108. 2015 (Washington, DC: Author, 2015), pp. 19–20.
34. Donald F. Kettl, Sharing Power: Public Governance 47. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Chief
and Private Markets (Washington, DC: Brookings, Acquisition Officers: Appointments Generally
1993), pp. 63–64. Conform to Legislative Requirements, but Agencies
35. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Competitive Need to Clearly Define Roles and Responsibilities,
Sourcing: Report on Competitive Sourcing Results, GAO-12-792 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Fiscal Years 2003 and 2004 (Washington, DC: U.S. Printing Office, 2012).
Government Printing Office, 2004), p. 8. 48. Allan V. Burman, “Six Practical Steps to Improve
36. Clay Johnson and Harper Reed, “Why the Govern- Contracting,” The Business of Government (Spring
ment Never Gets Tech Right,” New York Times 2009), pp. 62–66.
(October 24, 2013). 49. Soloway and Kangas, “Fixing Acquisition.”
37. Al Gore, From Red Tape to Results: Creating a 50. Brookings Institution, as cited in Partnership for
Government That Works Better and Costs Less, Public Service, Public Opinion on Public Service
Reinventing Federal Procurement (Washington, (Washington, DC: Author, 2005), p. 6. Public’s
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1993), p. 3. response is for 1998, and seniors’ is for 2002.
38. Federal Acquisition Institute, FY 2012 Annual 51. Primavera Systems, America, Inc.—Annual Share-
Report on the Federal Acquisition Workforce, holder Management Report (Crystal City, VA:
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Author, 2007), p. 1. Figure, 92 percent, is for
Office, 2013), p. 5. 2007.
39. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Acquisition 52. Dwight D. Eisenhower, Farewell Address to the
Workforce: Federal Agencies Obtain Training to Nation (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Meet Requirements, but Have Limited Insight Printing Office, January 17, 1961), p. 2.
into Costs and Benefits of Training Investment, 53. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
GAO-13-231 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Acquisition Challenges and Opportunities in the
Printing Office, 2013). 21st Century, GAO-07-45SP (Washington, DC:
40. Ibid. U.S. Government Printing Office, 2006), p. 15.
41. Professional Development Council and Grant 54. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Sourcing
Thornton, A Closing Window: Are We Missing Policy: Initial Agency Efforts to Balance the
an Opportunity for Change? Professional Deve- Government to Contractor Mix in the Multisector
lopment Council 2014 Acquisition Policy Survey Workforce, GAO-10-744T (Washington, DC: U.S.
(Arlington, VA, and Alexandria, VA: Authors, Government Printing Office, 2010), p. 3.
2014). 55. Burman, “Six Practical Steps to Improve Con-
42. Stan Soloway and Phil Kangas, “Fixing Acquisition: tracting,” p. 65.
An Opportunity Lost?” Govexec.com (January 30, 56. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Sourcing
2015). Data are for 2002–2014. The latest such Policy: Initial Agency Efforts to Balance the
survey at this writing is cited in the preceding Government to Contractor Mix in the Multisector
endnote. Workforce, p. 3.
43. Jared Serbu, “After Decades of DoD Acquisition 57. Kaifeng Yang and Anthony Kassekert, “Linking
Reform, Congress Has Yet to Tackle Cultural Management Reform with Employee Job Satis-
Issues,” Federalnewsradio.com (October 15, 2014). faction: Evidence from Federal Agencies,” Journal
44. Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, U.S. of Public Administration Research and Theory 20
Senate, Defense Acquisition Reform: Where Do (April 2010), pp. 413–436. The quotation is on
We Go From Here? (Washington, DC: U.S. Govern- p. 413.
ment Publishing Office, 2014). 58. OMB, as cited in Frank Greve, “Hired Guns
45. Peter E. D. Love, Peter R. Davis, David J. Edwards, Running the U.S.,” Philadelphia Inquirer (May 19,
and David Baccarini, “Uncertainty Avoidance: 1992). Figure is for 1992.
Intersectoral Administration 441

59. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Veterans Representation,” Interest Groups & Advocacy 3
Affairs Consulting, GAO-13-714R (Washington, (1, 2014), pp. 4–29. The quotation is on p. 27.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2013). 74. Oxfam, as cited in Nicholas Kristof, “The Real
60. Elmendorf, Federal Contracts and the Contracted Welfare Cheats,” New York Times (April 14, 2016).
Workforce. Figures are for FY 2012. Figures are for 2008–2014.
61. Project on Government Oversight, Bad Business: 75. Bill Allison and Sarah Harkins, Fixed Fortunes:
Billions of Taxpayer Dollars Wasted on Hiring Biggest Corporate Political Interests Spend
Contractors (Washington, DC: Author, 2011), p. 4. Billions, Get Trillions (Washington, DC: Sunlight
Figure is for FY 2009. Foundation, 2014), pp. 1–2. Figures are for 2007–
62. U.S. General Accounting Office, Civil Servants and 2012.
Contract Employees: Who Should Do What for the 76. Jeff Connaughton, The Payoff: Why Wall Street
Federal Government? FPCD-81-43 (Washington, Always Wins (Westport, CT: Prospecta Press,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981), p. 6. 2012), p. 147.
63. Al Stapleton of the GAO, as quoted in “Consultants: 77. As derived from data in Paula Reid, “Goldman
New Target for Budget Trimmers,” U.S. News & Sachs’ Revolving Door,” Cbsnews.com (April 10,
World Report (December 1, 1981), p. 40. 2010). Figures are for 1995–2010.
64. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Policy 78. Jesse Eisinger, “Why Only One Top Banker Went
Letter No. 93-1 (Reissued), Management Oversight to Jail for the Financial Crisis,” New York Times
of Service Contracting (Washington, DC: Author, Magazine (April 30, 2014). Period is for 2007–2015.
1994). This directive, issued in 1993, replaced 79. Jeffrey D. Sachs, “The Impunity Trap,” Project
OMB Circular A-120 of 1980. Syndicate (June 3, 2015). Compensation figure is
65. U.S. General Accounting Office, Government for 2013 and 2014.
Contractors: Are Service Contractors Performing 80. “Two Financial Crises Compared: The Savings and
Inherently Governmental Functions? GAO/GGD- Loan Debacle and the Mortgage Mess,” New York
92-11 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Times (April 13, 2011). Figures are for 1983–1992.
Office, 1991), p. 5. 81. U.S. Department of Justice, Office of the Inspector
66. Eric Katz, “Registered Lobbyist Earned $143K General, Audit Division, Audit of the Department
Federal Salary for 4-Hour Government Work of Justice’s Efforts to Address Mortgage Fraud
Week,” Govexec.com (September 10, 2015). (Washington, DC: Author, 2014), p. i.
67. Gallup Historical Trends, Labor Unions (New 82. Edward Wyatt, “Promises Made, and Remade, by
York: Author, 2014). Figure is for 2011. Firms in S.E.C. Fraud Cases,” New York Times
68. Daniel Horgos and Klaus Zimmermann, “Interest (November 7, 2011). Figures are for 1996–2011.
Groups and Economic Performance: Some New 83. Michael Dorsch, “Bailout for Sale? The Vote to
Evidence,” Public Choice 138 (March 2009), pp. Save Wall Street,” Public Choice 155 (June 2013),
301–315. pp. 211–223. The quotation is on p. 211.
69. Debra Mayberry, “37,000? 39,402? 11,500? Just 84. Center for Responsive Politics, Overall Spending
How Many Lobbyists Are There in Washington, Inches Up in 2014: Megadonors Equip Outside
Anyway?” Washington Post (January 29, 2006). Groups to Capture a Bigger Share of the Pie
70. Lobbyists.info., Lobyists.info Unveils 90,000 (Washington, DC: OpenSecrets.org, 2014).
Links from Government Relations Professionals 85. Tax Policy Center, Historical Average Federal
to Congressional Staff Positions Reaching Back 27 Tax Rates for All Households (Washington, DC:
Years (Washington, DC: Author, 2014). Figure is Author, 2014). Figure, 20.1 percent, is for 2010.
for 2014. 86. U.S. General Accounting Office, DOD Use of
71. Lee Drutman and Alexander Furnas, How Consultant Service Contracts, 115083 (Washington,
Revolving Door Lobbyists Are Taking Over K DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981), pp. 5,
Street (Washington, DC: Sunlight Foundation, 10, 4, 3.
2014). Figures are for 2000–2012. 87. Newchy Mignone, former contracting officer in
72. James Thurber on “K Street,” Sunday Morning, the Energy Department, as quoted in Jonathan
CBS Television Network (October 7, 2012). Neumann and Ted Gup, “The Revolving Door:
73. Timothy M. LaPira and Herschel F. Thomas Industry Plums Await Retired U.S. Officials,”
III, “Revolving Door Lobbyists and Interest Washington Post (June 25, 1980).
442 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

88. Adolfo Santos, “Post-Congressional Lobbying 101. LaPira and Thomas III, “Revolving Door Lobby-
and Legislative Sponsorship: Do Members of ists and Interest Representation.”
Congress Reward Their Future Employers?” 102. Society for Human Resource Management and
LBJ Journal of Public Affairs 16 (Fall 2003), pp. Congressional Management Foundation, Life
56–64. The quotation is on p. 62. Data are for in Congress: Job Satisfaction and Engagement
1984–1996. of House and Senate Staff (Alexandria, VA and
89. Jack Abramoff, appearing on “The Lobbyist’s Washington, DC: Authors, 2013), pp. 54, 57.
Playbook,” 60 Minutes, CBS Television Network 103. Connaughton, The Payoff, p. 39.
(November 6, 2011). 104. Lee Drutman and Alexander Furnas, K Street
90. As cited on “K Street.” Pays Top Dollar for Revolving Door Talent
91. Elizabeth Brown, More Than 2,000 Spin Through (Washington, DC: Sunlight Foundation, 2014),
Revolving Door (Washington, DC: Center for p. 1. Data are for 2012.
Public Integrity, 2005), p. 2. Figure is for 1998– 105. Drutman and Furnas, How Revolving Door
mid-2004. Lobbyists Are Taking Over K Street, p. 1. Figures
92. Drutman and Furnas, How Revolving Door are for 1998–2012. Emphasis is original.
Lobbyists Are Taking Over K Street. Figures are 106. Lee Drutman and Alexander Furnas, The Rise of
for 2000–2012 and 1998–2012, respectively. the Million-Dollar Lobbyist (Washington, DC:
93. As derived from data in U.S. Government Sunlight Foundation, 2014), pp. 2–3. Figures are
Accountability Office, Employment Information for 1998–2012.
on Former High-Ranking Coast Guard Officials’ 107. As derived from data in Drutman and Furnas, K
Employment with Major Contractors, GAO- Street Pays Top Dollar for Revolving Door Talent,
13-153R (Washington, DC: U.S. Government p. 1. Data are for 1998–2012.
Printing Office, 2013), Highlights page. 108. Lee Fang, “Analysis: When a Congressman
94. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems Becomes a Lobbyist, He Gets a 1,452% Raise (on
Protection Board, In Search of Highly Skilled Average),” RepublicReport.org (Washington, DC:
Workers: A Study on the Hiring of Upper RepublicReport.org, 2012).
Level Employees from Outside the Federal 109. Alec MacGillis, “Friends in High Places,” The
Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Government New Yorker (November 14, 2016), pp. 36–42.
Printing Office, 2008), p. 13. Upper-level hires The quotation is on p. 39.
refer to Grades 12–15. Figure, 32 percent, is for 110. Representative Marcy Kaptur, as quoted in
2005. Gary Lee, “Trade, National Security, and the
95. Dan Eggen and Kimberly Kindy, “Three of Every Revolving Door,” Washington Post (April 13,
Four Oil and Gas Lobbyists Worked for Federal 1992).
Government,” Washington Post (July 22, 2010). 111. Simon Luechinger and Christoph Moser, The
96. Jill Abramson, “The Business of Persuasion Value of the Revolving Door: Political Appointees
Thrives in Nation’s Capitol,” New York Times and the Stock Market (Lucerne, Switzerland:
(September 29, 1998). University of Lucerne, 2012), p. 1.
97. Public Citizen, Congressional Revolving 112. Brown, More Than 2,000 Spin Through Revolving
Doors: The Journey from Congress to K Street Door, p. 2. Figures are for 1998–2004. We should
(Washington, DC: Author, 2005), p. 1. Figures are note that former federal officials almost always
for 1992–2004. are listed in these forms as members of lobbying
98. OpenSecrets.org, as cited in Suzanne Dovi, “It’s teams that typically include lobbyists who did not
Not Bribery That’s Corrupting Our Democratic serve in the federal government.
System—It’s a Job Offer,” Savannah Morning 113. Eric Lipton and Ben Protess “Law Doesn’t End
News (February 22, 2015). Figure is for 2015. Revolving Door on Capitol Hill,” New York
99. OpenSecrets.org, as cited in ibid. Figure is for Times (February 1, 2014).
2004–2014. 114. Inspector General, U.S. Department of Defense,
100. Charles S. Clark, “Are Underqualified Con- Section 847 for Senior Defense Officials
gressional Staff Impeding Oversight, Wasting Seeking Employment with Defense Contractors
Agencies’ Time?” Govexec.com (March 10, (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
2016). Figures are for 2009–2013. Office, 2016).
Intersectoral Administration 443

115. Joseph Besselman, Ashish Arora, and Patrick 127. Erika Kelton, “Is a Whistleblower Behind Investi-
Larkey, “Buying in a Businesslike Fashion—And gation That Vetted Snowden?” Forbes.com (July
Paying More,” Public Administration Review 60 15, 2013).
(September/October 2000), pp. 421–434. The 128. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Office of
quotation is on p. 421. Inspector General, Final Audit Report: Office
116. Professional Overseas Contractors, “Security of the Federal Investigative Services’ Case
Clearance 101: Number of Contractors with Top Review Process over Background Investigations
Secret Clearances,” Your-poc.com (July 6, 2014). (Washington, DC: Author, 2014).
This source counts 483,263 contractors, or 34 129. Lauren Cassani Davis, “How Do Americans Weigh
percent of the total. Figures are for FY 2012, Privacy Versus National Security?” Nextgov.com
except 70 percent, which is for FY 2007. See also (February 3, 2016). Figure is for 2016.
Dana Priest and William M. Arkin, “National 130. Jackson Janes and Parke Nicholson, “Beyond
Security, Inc.,” Washington Post (July 20, 2010). Spring: How to Save the U.S.-German Alliance,”
Their estimate is 32 percent, or 265,000 contrac- National Interest (September 5, 2014).
tors, in FY 2010. 131. U.S. Merit Systems Protection Board, Workforce
117. Professional Overseas Contractors, “Security Quality and Federal Procurement: An Assessment
Clearance 101.” Data are for FY 2012, except for (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
the 70 percent reference, which is for FY 2007. Office, 1992), p. 40.
118. Robert Gates, quoted in Priest and Arkin, 132. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
“National Security, Inc.” Acquisition Reform: DOD Should Streamline Its
119. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Civilian Decision-Making Process for Weapon Systems to
Intelligence Community: Additional Actions Reduce Inefficiencies, GAO-15-192 (Washington,
Needed to Improve Reporting on and Planning DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015),
for the Use of Contract Personnel, GAO-14-24 Highlights page.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 133. Center for Strategic and International Studies,
Office, 2014). Integrating Civilian and Military Technologies: An
120. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Infor- Industry Survey (Washington, DC: Author, 1993).
mation Security: Agencies Need to Improve 134. Katherine McIntire Peters, “Infographic: What
Oversight of Contractor Controls, GAO-14-612 Defense Personnel Really Think About the
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing Acquisition Process,” Govexec.com (November
Office, 2014), Highlights page. 11, 2014).
121. Booz Allen Hamilton and Partnership for 135. Kettl, Managing Risk, Improving Results, pp. 11,
Public Service, Cyber In-Security: Strengthening 16. Data are for 1990–2015.
the Federal Cybersecurity Workforce (Washington, 136. John J. DiIulio, Jr., “Against Federal ‘Leviathan by
DC: Authors, 2009), p. 2. Figures are for 2009. Proxy’ and for a Bigger, Better, Full-Time Federal
122. Much of the following discussion is drawn Workforce,” Public Administration Review 76
from “The United States of Secrets,” Frontline (July/August 2016), pp. 535–537. The quotation
(Washington, DC: PBS Television Network, May is on p. 536. “Current list” refers to the 2015–
14, 21, 2014). 2016 list.
123. Richard Esposito and Matthew Cole, “How 137. Gore, From Red Tape to Results, pp. 28, 1. Figures
Snowden Did It,” NBC News Investigations are for the early 1990s.
(August 26, 2013). 138. Phillip J. Cooper, “Government Contracts in
124. Tom Monahan, “What Edward Snowden Has Public Administration: The Role and Environment
Taught Us about Hiring,” Government Executive of the Contracting Officer,” Public Administration
(September 5, 2013). Review 40 (September/October 1980), pp. 459–
125. Matt Haldane and Mark Hosendall, “Update 2 – 468.
U.S. Contractor that Vetted Snowden Is Under 139. Quoted in Russell Mitchell, “It Was Mr. Fixit Vs.
Investigation,” Reuters.com (June 20, 2013). The Pentagon—and the Pentagon Won,” Business
126. Chris DiMarco, “Contractor Vetting Organi- Week (December 24, 1990), p. 52.
zation USIS Accused of Defrauding the U.S. 140. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Government,” IC (January 23, 2014). Contractors: Better Performance Information
444 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Needed to Support Agency Contract Award 151. David Shields, “Category Management Will
Decisions, GAO-09-374 (Washington, DC: U.S. Transform Government’s Buying Behavior,”
Government Printing Office, 2009), Highlights About.bgov.com (March 21, 2016).
page. Figure, 69 percent, is for FY 2007. 152. Charles S. Clark, “Shared Services Save Money,
141. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal With One Caveat,” Govexec.com (December 18,
Contracts: Agencies Widely Used Indefinite 2015).
Contracts to Provide Flexibility to Meet Mission 153. Partnership for Public Service and Deloitte,
Needs, GAO-17-329 (Washington, DC: U.S. Helping Government Deliver II (Washington,
Government Printing Office, 2017), Highlights DC, and Arlington, VA: Authors, 2015), p. 24.
page. Data are for 2011–2015. 154. Andy Medici, “Ambitious Plan to Reshape Federal
142. Frank Konkel, “GSA Officials on Increased Bid Contracting Emerges at OFPP,” FederalTimes.
Protests: ‘This Is How It’s Going to Be,’” Nextgov. com (March 18, 2015). Figure is for FY 2014.
com (August 2, 2016). Figures are for 2008– 155. Shields, “Category Management Will Transform
2015. Government’s Buying Behavior.”
143. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Defense 156. Federal News Radio, WFED Federal CAO Survey
Acquisitions: Assessments of Selected Weapon 2015, p. 8.
Programs, GAO-08-467SP (Washington, DC: U.S. 157. Ann Hagedorn, “A Perilous Dependence on
Government Printing Office, 2008), Highlights Contractors,” New York Times (October 2, 2014).
page. Figure is for FY 2007. 158. Ibid.
144. Todd Harrison, Analysis of the FY 2012 Defense 159. Carol D. Leonnig, “Secret Service Officers at White
Budget (Washington, DC: Center for Strategic House Lacked Security Clearances, Officials Say,”
and Budgetary Assessments, 2014), p. viii. Figures Washington Post (June 9, 2015).
are for 2001–2011. 160. Eric Katz, “Federal Agencies Continue to Shed
145. U.S. Defense Systems Management College, Security Clearance Holders,” Govexec.com (June
as cited in Gore, From Red Tape to Results, 30, 2016). Figure is for 2013–2015.
p. 80. 161. Steve Kelman, “The Way to Better Contracts,”
146. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Acqui- Federal Computer Week (May 10, 2010), p. 16.
sition Reform: DOD Should Streamline Its 162. U.S. General Accounting Office, Contract
Decision-Making Process for Weapon Systems to Management: Guidance Needed for Using
Reduce Inefficiencies, GAO-15-192 (Washington, Performance-Based Service Contracting, GAO-
DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2015), 02-1049 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Highlights page. Printing Office, 2002), p. 3. Figure is for 2001.
147. PotomacWave, Inc., as cited in Charles S. Clark, 163. U.S. Government Accountability Office,
“Agencies Rely on Contractor Tool to Spot  Pro- Contractor Performance: Actions Taken to
curement Errors,” Govexec.com (August 24, Improve Reporting Past Performance Information,
2015). GAO-14-707 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
148. Jared Serbu, “Pentagon Says It’s Using Automation Printing Office, 2014), Highlights page.
to Speed Up Acquisition Bureaucracy,” Federal- 164. Senator Tom Carper, quoted in Charles S. Clark,
newsradio.com (June 22, 2015). “Misbehaving Contractors Might Be in Luck At
149. Partnership for Public Service and Deloitte, These Agencies,” Government Executive (August
Acquisition Shared Services: Progress, Lessons 8, 2013).
and Opportunities (Washington, DC, and Arling- 165. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Contract
ton, VA: Authors, 2015), pp. 1, 2. Figures are for Management: Extent of Federal Spending under
FY 2014. Cost-Reimbursement Contracts Unclear and
150. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Key Controls Not Always Used, GAO-09-921
Procurement: Smarter Buying Initiatives Can (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Achieve, but Improved Oversight and Account- Office, 2009), Highlights page. Figure, 26 percent,
ability Needed, GAO-17-164 (Washington, is for 2008.
DC:  U.S. Government Publishing Office, 166. As derived from data in Light, Creating High
2016), pp. 5, 17, 38. Figures are for FY 2011–FY Performance Government, p. 3. Figure is for
2015. 2000–2008.
Intersectoral Administration 445

167. U.S. Government Accountability Office,  Con- 177. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
tracting Data Analysis: Assessment of Subcontracting: Further Actions Needed to
Government-Wide Trends, GAO-17-244SP Improve Oversight of Pass-through Contracts,
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing GAO-15-200 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Office, 2017), Highlights page. Publishing Office, 2014), Highlights page.
168. Chong Wang and Joseph San Miguel, “The 178. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Excessive Profits of Defense Contractors: Construction Subcontracting: Insight into
Evidence and Determinants,” Journal of Public Subcontractor Selectioin Is Limited, but Agencies
Procurement 12 (Fall 2012), pp. 386–406. The Use Oversight Tools to Monitor Performance,
quotations are on p. 386. The authors studied the GAO-15-230 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
128 public firms that received the most contract Publishing Office, 2015), Highlights page. Figure,
dollars in 2008. $32 billion, is for FY 2014.
169. Kellie Lunney, “Are Low-Wage Federal Contract 179. Michael Fischetti, “Distinguishing Fact from
Workers Getting Ripped Off?” Government Myth with Government Contracting Data,”
Executive (April 9, 2015). Federalnewsradio.com (August 23, 2016).
170. Amy Traub and Robert Hiltonsmith, Underwriting 180. Bent Flyvberg, Mette Skamris Holm, and Soren
Bad Jobs: How Our Tax Dollars Are Funding Buhl, “Underestimating Costs in Public Works
Low-Wage Work and Fueling Inequality Projects: Error or Lie?” Journal of the American
(Washington, DC: Demos, 2013), pp. 4–5. Figures Planning Association 68 (Summer 2002), pp.
are for 2012. 279–295. Figure is for 1910–1998.
171. NCMA and Bloomberg Government, Annual 181. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Defense
Review of Government Contracting, 2015 Edition Acquisitions: Assessments of Selected Weapon
(Ashburn, VA, and New York: Authors, 2016), p. Programs, Highlights page. Figure is for FY 2007.
12. Figures are for FY 2010–FY 2014. 182. Flyvberg, Skamris Holm, and Buhl, “Under-
172. Jared Serbu, “DoD Now Awarding More than Half estimating Costs in Public Works Projects,” p. 279.
of Its Contract Spending Without Competitive 183. Gordon Rule, quoted in William Proxmire, Report
Bids,” Federalnewsradio.com (August 22, 2016). from the Wasteland: America’s Military Industrial
Data are for 2016. Complex (New York: Praeger, 1970), p. 83.
173. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting 184. Project on Government Oversight, “Key Trends
Office, Contract Management: Civilian Agency in POGO’s Revamped Contractor Misconduct
Compliance with Revised Task and Delivery Database,” Pogo.org (November 12, 2015).
Order Regulations, GAO-03-983 (Washington, 185. Andy Pasztor, When the Pentagon Was for Sale:
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), Inside America’s Biggest Defense Scandal (New
pp. 22–24, and U.S. Government Accountability York: Scribner 1995), p. 38.
Office, Contract Management: Guidance Needed 186. U.S. General Accounting Office, Worker Pro-
to Promote Competition for Defense Task Orders, tection: Federal Contractors and Violations
GAO-04-874 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government of Federal Labor Law, GAO/HEHS-96-8
Printing Office, 2004), p. 3. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
174. Bob Brewin, “How Agencies Bury Noncompetitive Office, 1995), p. 1.
Procurements,” Nextgov (September 25, 2013). 187. U.S. General Accounting Office, Occupational
175. John O’Mally, editor of Commerce Business Daily Safety and Health: Violations of Safety and Health
(replaced in 2002 by the portal, FedBiz Opps) and Regulations by Federal Contractors, GAO/HEHS-
Vince Villa, consultant, as quoted in “Most Ads 96-157 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
for Contractors Meaningless,” Washington Post Printing Office, 1996), p. 3.
(June 25, 1980). 188. As derived from data in U.S. Government Ac-
176. As derived from data in Inspector General, U.S. countability Office, Federal Contracting: Assess-
Department of Defense, Improvement Needed ments and Citations of Federal Labor Law
with DoD Single-Bid Program to Increase Violations by Selected Federal Contractors, GAO-
Effective Competition for Agencies (Washington, 10-1033 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2012), Printing Office, 2010), Highlights page. Figures
p. i. are for 2005–2009.
446 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

189. Democratic staff, House Ways and Means Debt (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Committee, as cited in Jonathan D. Salant, Office, 2005), p. 2. Figures are for 2004.
Associated Press, “Companies Relocate to Escape 198. Good Jobs First, Uncle Sam’s Favorite Corpor-
Taxes,” Savannah Morning News (May 27, 2003). ations: Identifying the Large Corporations that
Figures are for 2001. Dominate Federal Subsidies (Washington, DC:
190. U.S. General Accounting Office, International Author, 2015), p. 3. Figure is for 2014.
Taxation: Tax Haven Companies Were More 199. W. Henry Lambright, Governing Science and
Likely to Have a Tax Cost Advantage in Federal Technology (New York: Oxford University Press,
Contracting, GAO-04-856 (Washington, DC: U.S. 1976), p. 123.
Government Printing Office, 2004), Highlights 200. Cooper, “Government Contracts in Public Admin-
page. istration,” pp. 462–463.
191. Elaine S. Povich, “Tax Inversions Allow Cor- 201. Project on Government Oversight, Federal
porations to Avoid State Taxes,” Stateline (July Contractor Misconduct Database (Washington,
21, 2014). DC: Author, 2015). Figures are for 1995–2011.
192. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Financial 202. Richard W. Stevenson, “Many Caught but Few
Management: Thousands of Civilian Agency Are Hurt For Arms Contract Fraud in U.S.”
Contractors Abuse the Federal Tax System with Washington Post (November 12, 1990). The
Little Consequence, GAO-05-637 (Washington, period was 1983–1990.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005), 203. Scott Amey, “Suspension and Disbarment: The
Highlights page. Figures are for 2004. Record Shows That the System Is Broken,”
193. U.S. General Accounting Office, Financial Man- Federal Times (March 21, 2005). Figures are for
agement: Some DOD Contractors Abuse the 1990–2003.
Federal Tax System with Little Consequence, 204. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
GAO-04-95 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Procurement: Additional Data Reporting Could
Printing Office, 2004), p. 13. Figures are for 2002. Improve the Suspension and Debarment Process,
194. Charles S. Clark, “IRS Fails to Police Contractors GAO-05-479 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Who Are Behind on Their Taxes,” Government Printing Office, 2005), pp. 2–3. Figure is for
Executive (October 23, 2013). Figures are for 2003.
2012. 205. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Excluded
195. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Security Parties List System: Suspended and Debarred
Clearances: Additional Mechanisms May Aid Businesses and Individuals Improperly Receive
Federal Tax-Debt Detection, GAO-13-733 Federal Funds, GAO-09-174 (Washington,
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2009),
Office, 2013). Highlights page.
196. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting 206. USA Spending.Gov, Overview of Awards by Fiscal
Office, Financial Management: Some DOD Year (Washington, DC: Author, 2017).
Contractors Abuse the Federal Tax System with 207. U.S. Congressional Budget Office, Comparing
Little Consequence; U.S. Government Account- the Compensation of Federal and Private-Sector
ability Office, Financial Management: Thou- Employees, 2011 to 2015 (Washington, DC: U.S.
sands of Civilian Agency Contractors Abuse the Government Publishing Office, 2017), p. 1.
Federal Tax System with Little Consequence, 208. Senate Select Committee on Intelligence, as cited
Highlights page; U.S. Government Accountability in Robert O’Harrow, Jr., “Costs Skyrocket as
Office, Federal Contractors: Better Performance DHS Runs Up No-Bid Contracts,” Washington
Information Needed to Support Agency Contract Post (June 28, 2007); Walter Pincus and Stephen
Award Decisions, Highlights page. Figure, 38 Barr, “CIA Plans Cutbacks, Limits on Contractor
percent, is for FY 2007. Staffing,” Washington Post (June 11, 2007); and
197. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Financial Robert O’Harrow, Jr. and Scott Higham, “Changes
Management: State and Federal Governments Spurred Buying, Abuses,” Washington Post (May
Are Not Taking Action to Collect Unpaid Debt 23, 2007). The average annual cost of a federal
through Reciprocal Agreements, GAO-05-697R contract employee in 2006 was $250,000, com-
Reciprocal Agreements for Collecting Unpaid pared with $126,500 for a federal civil servant.
Intersectoral Administration 447

209. Melvin J. Dubnick and H. George Frederickson, Government,” Fiscal Times (September 28, 2011).
Public Accountability: Performance Measurement, Figure is for FY 2010.
the Extended State, and the Search for Trust 224. Annie Gowen, “Government Dollars Fuel Wealth:
(Washington, DC, and Dayton, OH: National D.C. Enclaves Reap Rewards of Contracting
Academy of Public Administration and Kettering Boom,” Washington Post (August 15, 2011).
Foundation, 2011), p. 49. “Scores” refer to PART Contracting dollars’ growth figure is for 1980–
scores, explained in Chapter 7. 2010.
210. U.S. House Appropriations Committee, as cited in 225. As derived from data in ibid. and Robert Brodsky,
Corrin, “Public vs. Private,” p. 36. “Contracting Spending Dips for the First Time in
211. Pratap Chatterjee, Insourcing (Washington, DC: 13 Years,” Government Executive (February 3,
Center for American Progress, 2012), p. 5. 2011).
212. Project on Government Oversight, Bad Business, 226. Annie Lowery, “Washington’s Economic Boom,
pp. 1, 19–28. Financed by You,” New York Times Magazine
213. Kellie Lunney, “Federal Managers Support (January 10, 2013).
Program Cuts, Fewer Contractors,” Government 227. Connaughton, The Payoff, p. 112.
Executive (November 7, 2011). 228. OpenSecrets.org, Lobbying Database.
214. Barack Obama, Remarks by the President on 229. Thurber on “K Street.”
Procurement (Washington, DC: The White House, 230. Brookings Institution, Global Metro Monitor
2009), p. 3. (Washington, DC: Author, 2014).
215. Vinson & Elkins LLP, “Recovery Act Includes 231. John R. Bartle and Ronnie LaCourse Korosec,
Unprecedented Accountability and Transparency Procurement and Contracting in State
Provisions,” V&E Litigation Update (Houston, Government, 2000 (Syracuse, NY: Syracuse
TX: Author, 2009). University Government Performance Project,
216. John Monroe, “2009 Year in Review,” Federal 2001), p. iv, and Liz Farmer, “Purchase Power: A
Computer Week (December 7, 2010), pp. 20–26. Special Report on State Procurement,” Governing.
The quotations are on p. 22. com (February 17, 2016). Figures are for 2000–
217. NCMA and Bloomberg Government, Annual 2015.
Review of Government Contracting, 2015 232. Keon S. Chi, Kelley A. Arnold, and Heather M.
Edition, pp. 34–35. Current figure is for FY 2014. Perkins, “Privatization in State Government:
218. Emily Kopp, “Contractors Say They’ve Had Trends and Issues,” Book of the States, 2004
It with White House Executive Orders,” (Lexington, KY: Council of State Governments,
Federalnewsradio.com (August 11, 2015). 2004), pp. 465–482. Figures (p. 465) are for
219. NCMA and Bloomberg Government, Annual 2002.
Review of Government Contracting, 2015 233. Keon S. Chi and Cindy Jasper, Private Practices:
Edition, p. 5. Figures are for FY 2009–FY 2014. A Review of Privatization in State Government
220. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal (Lexington, KY: Council of State Governments,
Contractors: Better Performance Information 1998), p. 8. Data are for 1997.
Needed to Support Agency Contract Award 234. Chi, Arnold, and Perkins, “Privatization in State
Decisions, Highlights page. Figure is for FY 2007. Government,” pp. 468, 479. Figures are for
221. NCMA and Bloomberg Government, Annual 2002.
Review of Government Contracting, 2015 235. Chi and Jasper, Private Practices, p. 14. Figure is
Edition, p. 29. Figure is for FY 2014. for 1997.
222. As derived from data in Report by Interagency 236. As derived from data in Chi, Arnold, and Perkins,
Suspension and Debarment Committee on Federal “Privatization in State Government,” p.  479.
Suspension and Debarment Activities for FY 2012 Figure is for 2002. Fourteen states did not respond,
and 2013 and FY 2015 (Washington, DC: U.S. and we assume in this calculation that their lack
Government Printing/Publishing Office, 2014 and of response indicates a lack of contracting.
2016), pp. 15–16 and p. 7, respectively. Figures 237. As derived from data in Yoo-Sung Choi, Chung-
are for FY 2009–FY 2015. Lae Cho, Deil S. Wright, and Jeffrey L. Brudney,
223. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, as cited “Dimensions of Contracting for Service Delivery
in Louis Peck, “America’s $320 Billion Shadow by American State Administrative Agencies:
448 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Exploring Linkages between and Intergovern- 253. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil
mental Relations and Intersectoral Admini- S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public
stration,” Public Performance & Management Administration Across the 50 States: Linking
Review 29 (September 2005), pp. 46–66. Data Practice, Theory, and Research through the
(p. 50) are for 1998. American State Administrators Project, 1964–
238. Chi and Jasper, Private Practices, p. 14. Data are 2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental
for 1997. Services, Auburn University, 2010), pp. 13–14.
239. Ibid. Private-sector figure is for 1994–2008; “fewer
240. Jeffrey L. Brudney, F. Ted Hebert, and Deil S. than 15 percent” is for the 2000s.
Wright, “Reinventing Government in the American 254. As derived from data in U.S. Merit Systems
States: Measuring and Explaining Administrative Protection Board, In Search of Highly Skilled
Reform,” Public Administration Review 59 Workers: A Study on the Hiring of Upper
(January/February 1999), pp. 19–30. Data (p. 23) Level  Employees from Outside the Federal
are for 1995. Government (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
241. Chi, Arnold, and Perkins, “Privatization in State Printing Office, 2008), p. 13. Chapter 9 has
Government,” pp. 479, 465. Figure is for 1998– details.
2002. 255. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
242. Christine A. Kelleher and Susan Webb Yackee, “A Change in Public Administration Across the 50
Political Consequence of Contracting: Organized States, p. 13.
Interests and State Agency Decision Making,” 256. David E. Lewis, Political Appointments, Bureau
Journal of Public Administration Research and Chiefs, and Federal Management Performance
Theory 19 (July 2009), pp. 579–602. The quota- (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University, 2005), p. 35.
tions are on p. 579. Chapter 9 has details.
243. Ibid., p. 467. Figures are for 2002. 257. Patricia W. Ingraham, “Building Bridges or
244. As derived from data in ibid., pp. 468–469. Burning Them? The President, The Appointees,
Figures are for 2002. and The Bureaucracy,” Public Administration
245. National Association of State Procurement Offi- Review 47 (September/October 1987), pp. 425–
cials, 2015 Survey of State Procurement Practices 435. Chapter 9 has details.
(Lexington, KY: Author, 2015), p. 1. 258. Caitlin Ginley, Revolving Door Swings Freely in
246. Ibid., p. 5. America’s Statehouses (Washington, DC: Public
247. Kyle Roerink, “Companies, Individuals Make Integrity, 2012). Figures are for 1992–2004.
$1.7 Billion from Nevada No-Bid Contracts,” 259. Michael J. Mishak, Drinks, Dinners, Junkets
Lasvegassun.com (February 26, 2015). and Jobs: How the Insurance Industry Courts
248. Mary K. Feeney and Craig R. Smith, “Social State Commissioners (Washington, DC: Public
Embeddedness in Outsourcing: What Shapes Integrity, 2016). Data are for 2015; 109 commis-
Public Managers’ Perceptions?” Public Perfor- sioners left office, 2000–2010.
mance & Management Review 31 (June 2008), 260. National Conference of State Legislatures,
pp. 517–546. The quotation is on p. 541. Revolving Door Prohibitions Against Legislators
249. U.S. General Accounting Office, Privatization: Lobbying State Government After They Leave
Lessons Learned by State and Local Governments, Office (Washington, DC: Author, 2012). Figure is
GAO/GGD-97-48 (Washington, DC: U.S. Govern- for 2012.
ment Printing Office, 1997), p. 6. 261. National Conference of State Legislatures, Re-
250. National Association of State Procurement Offi- volving Door Prohibitions (Washington, DC:
cials, 2015 Survey of State Procurement Practices, Author, 2015). Figure is for 2015.
p. 9. 262. Ginley, Revolving Door Swings Freely in America’s
251. Liz Farmer, “Purchase Power: A Special Report Statehouses.
on State Procurement,” Governing.com (February 263. Irwin T. David, “Privatization in America,”
17, 2016). Municipal Year Book, 1988 (Washington, DC:
252. Jenni Bergal, “Policing Private Contractors International City Management Association,
Is Challenge for States,” Stateline (August 5, 1988), pp. 43–55. Figure, 24 percent (p. 52), is for
2014). 1982–1987.
Intersectoral Administration 449

264. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 274. As derived from data in Hatry and Valente, “Alter-
Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern- native Service Delivery Approaches Involving
ment Structure and Administration, M-186 Increased Use of the Private Sector,” pp. 216–217.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Figure fell from 23 to 16 percent, 1982–2012.
Office, 1993), p. 43. Figure is for 1990. 275. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
265. David, “Privatization in America,” p. 50. Figure, tion,” pp. 55–56. Data are for 2012.
32 percent, is for 1982–1987. 276. Categories total more than 100 percent because
266. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity the “ICMA treats the data on service provision
and Change in the Role of City Managers,” separately from the data on service delivery.” See
Municipal Year Book, 2010 (Washington, DC: Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,”
International City/County Management Asso- p. 12.
ciation, 2010), pp. 10–18. The ranking (p. 13) is 277. Alan Greenblatt, “Observer,” Governing (February
for 2010. 2006), pp.17–18.
267. David, “Privatization in America,” p. 43. Figure is 278. Ryan Holeywell, “How Weston, Florida, a City
for 1987. of 65,000, Gets By on 9 Employees,” Governing.
268. George C. Homsy and Mildred E. Warner, com (May 14, 2012).
“Intermunicipal Cooperation: The Growing 279. David Streitfeld, “A City Outsources Everything,
Reform,” Municipal Year Book, 2014 Sky Does Not Fall,” New York Times (July 19,
(Washington, DC: International City/County 2010)
Management Association, 2014), pp. 53–65 (data 280. Stephanie Banchero and Matthew Dolan,
are on pp. 55–57). Current services and percent- “Michigan City Outsources All of Its Schools,”
age are for 2012. In 1982, when the first of these Wall Street Journal (August 2, 2012).
surveys was undertaken, sixty services were ana- 281. Mark D. Bradbury and G. David Waechter,
lyzed. “Extreme Outsourcing in Local Government: At
269. Ibid., Mildred Warner and Amir Hefetz, “Co- the Top and All But the Top,” Review of Public
operative Competition: Alternative Service Personnel Administration 29 (September 2009),
Delivery, 2002–2007,” pp. 11–20 (data are pp. 230–248. Figure is for 2009.
on p. 10), Mildred Warner and Amir Hefetz, 282. Zullo, “Does Fiscal Stress Induce Privatization?”
“Pragmatism over Politics: Alternative Service p. 459.
Delivery in Local Governments, 1992– 283. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
2002,” pp.  8–16 (data are on p. 13), and tion,” p. 59. Figure is for 2012.
as derived from data in Harry  P.  Hatry and 284. Patricia M. Florestano and Stephen B. Gordon,
Carl F. Valente, “Alternative Service Delivery “A Survey of City and County Use of Private
Approaches Involving Increased  Use of the Contracting,” The Urban Interest 3 (Spring 1981),
Private Sector,”  pp.  199–217 (data are  on pp. 22–29. Figure is for 1980.
pp.  216–217),  Municipal Year Book[s], 2009, 285. Zullo, “Does Fiscal Stress Induce Privatization?”
2004, 1983,  respectively (Washington, DC: p. 459.
International City/County Management 286. To cite just one example of many: Timothy B.
Association, 2009, 2004, 1983). Overall data are Krebs and John P. Peliserro, “What Influences City
for 1982–2012. Council Adoption and Support for Reinventing
270. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- Government? Environmental or Institutional
tion,” pp. 55, 57–58. Figures are for 2012. Factors?” Public Administration Review 70
271. David, “Privatization in America,” p. 44. (March/April 2010), pp. 258–267.
272. Rowan Miranda and Karlyn Andersen, “Alternat- 287. Germa Bel and Xavier Fageda, “Why Do Local
ive Service Delivery in Local Government, 1982– Governments Privatise Public Services? A Survey
1992” Municipal Year Book, 1994 (Washington, of Empirical Studies,” Local Government Studies
DC: International City/County Management 33 (August 2007), pp. 517–534.
Association, 1994), pp. 26–35. The quotation is 288. Mary M. Shaw, “Successful Collaboration
on p. 28. Emphasis added. between the Nonprofit and Public Sectors,”
273. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- Nonprofit Management and Leadership 14 (Fall
tion,” p. 55. Figure is for 2012. 2003), pp. 107–120. The quotation is on p. 107.
450 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

289. Clingermayer, Feiock, and Stream, “Governmental 303. Miranda and Andersen, “Alternative Service
Uncertainty and Leadership Turnover,” p. 156. Delivery in Local Government, 1982–1992,”
290. Laurence J. O’Toole, Jr. and Kenneth J. Meier, p. 34, and Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative
“Parkinson’s Law and the New Public Manage- Competition,” p. 17.
ment? Contracting Determinants and Service- 304. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Quality Consequences in Public Education,” Relations, Changing Public Attitudes on
Public Administration Review 64 (May/ Government and Taxes, 1985, S-14 (Washington,
June  2004), pp. 342–352. The quotation is on DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1985), pp.
p. 349. 28–29.
291. Yosef Bhatti, Asmus Leth Olsen, and Lene 305. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
Holm Pedersen, “The Effects of Administrative tion,” p. 60. Figure is for 2012.
Professionals on Contracting Out,” Governance 306. Miranda and Andersen, “Alternative Service
22 (January 2009), pp. 121-–137. The quotations Delivery in Local Government, 1982–1992,”
are on pp. 121, 125–126. p. 34, and Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative
292. Clingermayer, Feiock, and Stream, “Governmental Competition,” p. 17.
Uncertainty and Leadership Turnover,” p. 157. 307. James D. Ward, “Exploring Unintended Conse-
293. Patrick Madden, The Cost of D.C. Council’s quences of Privatization, 1979 to 1999,” Paper
Power Over Contracts (Washington, DC: Wamu. presented at the National Conference of the
org, 2014). American Society for Public Administration (San
294. Clingermayer, Feiock, and Stream, “Governmental Diego, 2000), p. 3.
Uncertainty and Leadership Turnover,” p. 157. 308. Stephen Moore, “How Contracting Out City
295. Ole Helby Petersen, Kurt Houlberg, and Lasse Services Impacts Public Employees,” Contracting
Ring Christensen, “Contracting Out Local Out Government Services, Paul Seidenstat, ed.
Services: A Tale of Technical and Social Services,” (Westport, CN: Praeger, 1999), pp. 211–218. The
Public Administration Review 75 (July/August data are on p. 214.
2015), pp. 560–569. The quotation is on p. 560. 309. Ibid., pp. 216, 214.
296. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Co- 310. Ward, “Exploring Unintended Consequences of
operation,” p. 60. Figure is for 2012. Privatization, 1979–1999,” p. 6.
297. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,” 311. Timothy Chandler and Peter Ferrille,
p. 17. In 2007, the figure was 31 percent. “Municipal Unions and Privatization,” Public
298. Miranda and Andersen, “Alternative Service Administration  Review 51 (January/February
Delivery in Local Government, 1982–1992,” p. 1991), pp. 15–22.
34. In 1992, the figure was 25 percent. 312. Miranda and Andersen, “Alternative Service
299. Robert Mohr and Steven C. Deller, “Alternative Delivery in Local Government, 1982–1992,”
Methods of Service Delivery in Small and p.  34, and Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative
Rural  Municipalities,” Public Administration Competition,” p. 17.
Review 70 (November/December 2010), 313. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal
pp. 894–905. Cooperation,” p. 60.
300. Mildred E. Warner and Amir Hefetz, “Service 314. Clingermayer, Feiock, and Stream, “Governmental
Characteristics and Contracting: The Importance Uncertainty and Leadership Turnover,” p. 156.
of Citizen Interest and Competition,” Municipal 315. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
Year Book, 2010 (Washington, DC: International tion,” p. 60. Figure is for 2012.
City/County Management Association, 2010), pp. 316. Ibid., Miranda and Andersen, “Alternative
19–27. The quotation is on p. 26. Service Delivery in Local Government,
301. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,” 1982–1992,” p. 34, and Warner and Hefetz,
p. 17. Figure, 61 percent, is for 2007. The figure “Cooperative  Competition,” p. 17. Figure is for
was 48 percent in 1992. See Warner and Hefetz, 1992–2012.
“Pragmatism over Politics,” p. 14. The question 317. Tricia Maas and Robin Lake, A Blueprint
was not asked in 2012. for Effective and Adaptable School District
302. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- Procurement (Seattle, WA: Center on Reinventing
tion,” p. 60. Figure is for 2012. Public Education, 2015), p. 4.
Intersectoral Administration 451

318. M. Ernita Joaquin and Thomas J. Greitens, 330. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,”
“Contract Management Capacity Breakdown? p. 20. Figure is for 2002–2007.
An Analysis of U.S. Local Governments,” Public 331. Scott Lamothe and Meeyoung Lamothe, “The
Administration Review 72 (November/December Dynamics of Local Service Delivery Arrangements
2012), pp. 807–815. Analysis covered 1997–2007. and the Role of Nonprofits,” International Journal
319. Christopher Swope, “How Barcelona and Phila- of Public Administration 29 (10/11, 2006),
delphia Are Turning Procurement Upside Down,” pp. 769–797. Data are on p. 790.
Citiscope.org (July 17, 2014). 332. Pascale Joassart-Marcelli and Juliet Musso,
320. Trevor L. Brown, “The Dynamics of Government- “Municipal Service Provision Choices within
to-Government Contracts,” Public Performance a Metropolitan Area,” Urban Affairs Review
& Management Review 31 (March 2008), pp. 40 (March 2005), pp. 492–519. Data are on
364–386. p. 515.
321. Janice Johnson Dias and Steven Maynard-Moody, 333. Emanuele Lobina, Troubled Waters: Misleading
“For-Profit Welfare: Contracts, Conflicts, and Industry PR and the Case for Public Water
the Performance Paradox,” Journal of Public (Brighton, UK, and Boston, MA: Public Services
Administration Research and Theory 17 (April International Research Unit and Corporate
2007), pp. 189–211. The quotations are on Accountability International, 2014). Figure is for
p. 189. 2003–2014.
322. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 334. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern- tion,” p. 62. Figure is for 2012.
ment Structure and Administration, p. 43. Figures 335. Ibid., and Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative
are for 1990. Competition,” p. 18. In 2002, the figure was
323. Sergio Fernandez and Hal G. Rainey, “Local nearly 26.5 percent.
Government Contract Management and 336. Eric Shnurer, “When Government Competes
Performance Survey: A Report,” Municipal Year Against the Private Sector, Everybody Wins,”
Book, 2005 (Washington, DC: International City/ Government Executive (March 11, 2015).
County Management Association, 2005), pp. 3–4. 337. To cite two of at least five analyses of the subject:
Figure is for 2003–2004. Dilger, Moffet, and Struyk, “Privatization of
324. David, “Privatization in America,” p. 51. In 1987, Municipal Services in America’s Largest Cities,”
22 percent permitted no-bid contracts. and David, “Privatization in America.”
325. H. George Frederickson, Gary Alan Johnson, 338. Graeme A. Hodge, Privatization: An International
and Curtis Wood, “The Changing Structure of Review of Performance (Boulder, CO: Westview,
American Cities: A Study of the Diffusion of 2000), p. 156.
Innovation,” Public Administration Review 64 339. Sergio Fernandez, “Understanding Contracting
(May/June 2004), pp. 320–330. Datum is on Performance,” Administration & Society 41
p. 324. (March 2009), pp. 67–100. The quotation is on
326. Amanda M. Girth, Amir Hefetz, Jocelyn M. p. 92.
Johnston, and Mildred E. Warner, “Outsourcing 340. Eunju Rho, “Contracting Revisited: Determinants
Public Service Delivery: Management Responses in and Consequences of Contracting Out for Public
Noncompetitive Markets,” Public Administration Education Services,” Public Administration
Review 72 (November/December 2012), pp. 887– Review 73 (March/April 2013), pp. 327–337. The
900. quotation is on p. 335.
327. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- 341. Victor S. DeSantis and Charldean Newell, “Local
tion,” p. 63. Figure is for 2012. Government Managers’ Career Paths,” Municipal
328. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,” Year Book, 1996 (Washington, DC: International
p. 19. Figure is for 2007. City/County Management Association, 1996),
329. Robert Jay Dilger, Randolph R. Moffett, and Linda pp. 3–10.
Struyk, “Privatization of Municipal Services in 342. Jerri Killian and Enamul Choudhury, “Continuity
America’s Largest Cities,” Public Administration and Change in the Role of City Managers,”
Review 57 (January/February 1997), pp. 21–26. Municipal Year Book, 2010 Washington,
Figure, 92 percent, is for 1995. DC: International City/County Management
452 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Association, 2010), pp. 10–18. Figure, 6.8 years 361. Jerry Mitchell, The American Experiment with
(p. 11), is for 2010. Government Corporations (Armonk, NY: M. E.
343. Michael Noonchester, “Turnovers in Transit,” Sharpe, 1998), p. 19.
Mass Transit (September/October 1991), pp. 48– 362. Annmarie Hauk Walsh, The Public’s Business:
62. Figures are for 1988–1990. The Politics and Practices of Government Cor-
344. Rhys Andrews and Tom Entwistle, “Does Cross- porations (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1978),
Sectoral Partnership Deliver? An Empirical p. 29.
Exploration of Public Service Effectiveness, 363. As derived from data in U.S. Government
Efficiency, and Equity,” Journal of Public Admini- Accountability Office, Federally Created Entities:
stration Research and Theory 20 (July 2010), An Overview of Key Attributes, GAO-10-97
pp. 679–701. The quotations are on pp. 691, 689. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
345. Hodge, Privatization, p. 155. Office, 2009), pp. 9, 25, 26, 34. Data are for
346. William D. Eggers, Rightsizing the Government: 2009.
Lessons from America’s Public Sector Innovators 364. Ibid., p. 16.
(Los Angeles: Reason Foundation, 1993). 365. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
347. Hodge, Privatization, p. 119. Research: Opportunities Exist to Improve the
348. Ibid., p. 99. Management and Oversight of Federally Funded
349. In the Public Interest, Insourcing (Washington, Research and Development Centers, GAO-09-
DC: Author, 2013). 15 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
350. Andrews and Entwistle, “Does Cross-Sectoral Office, 2008), Highlights page. Figure, $13 billion,
Partnership Deliver?” pp. 691, 689. is for 2006.
351. John D. Donohue, The Privatization Decision: 366. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federally
Public Ends, Private Means (New York: Basic Created Entities: An Overview of Key Attributes,
Books, 1991), p. 131. Emphasis is original. pp. 13–14.
352. Andrews and Entwistle, “Does Cross-Sectoral 367. For reasons of space, we shall not list the first
Partnership Deliver?” p. 692. eight of these tallies and their sources, but they
353. David H. Webber, “Protecting Public Pension can be found in the tenth edition of this book
Investments,” Washington Post (November 20, (2007), p. 344, Note 205. The ninth count is ibid.
2014). 368. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federally
354. Moore, “How Contracting Out City Services Created Entities: An Overview of Key Attributes,
Impacts Public Employees,” pp. 216, 214. pp. 13–16. Figure is for 2009.
355. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal 369. Harold Siedman, “United States Experience: The
Cooperation,” p. 62. Figure is for 2012. Need to Reassert the Government Corporation
356. Ibid., and Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Control Act of 1945,” Public Administration and
Competition,” p. 18. Figure is for 2002–2012. Development 18 (August 1998), pp. 295–299.
357. Unless noted otherwise, this discussion is based The quotation is on p. 297.
on Paul Seidenstat, “Theory and Practice of 370. U.S. Federal Housing Finance Agency, About
Contracting Out in the United States,” in Con- FHFA. Figures are for 2014 and include Federal
tracting Out Government Services, Paul Seidenstat, Home Loan Banks.
ed. (Westport, CN: Praeger, 1999), pp. 3–26. 371. Marvin Phaup, “Federal Use of Implied Guar-
358. Mark Considine, “The End of the Line? Account- antees: Some Preliminary Lessons from the
able Governance in the Age of Networks, Partner- Current Financial Distress,” Public Administration
ships, and Joined-Up Services,” Governance 15 Review 69 (July/August 2009), pp. 651–659.
(January 2002), pp. 21–41. 372. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting
359. Rae Andre, “Assessing the Accountability of Office, Government-Sponsored Enterprises: A
Government-Sponsored Enterprises and Quan- Framework for Strengthening GSE Governance
gos,” Journal of Business Ethics 97 (2, 2010), and Oversight, GAO-04-269T (Washington, DC:
pp. 271–289. U.S Government Printing Office, 2004), p. 4.
360. E. S. Savas, Privatization and Public-Private Figure, 81 percent, is for 2003.
Partnerships (New York: Chatham House, 2000), 373. ProPublica, History of U.S. Gov’t Bailouts (New
p. 9. York: Author, 2009).
Intersectoral Administration 453

374. “How Fannie and Freddie Make Their Money,” 388. Osborne M. Reynolds, Jr., Local Government
Wall Street Journal (May 3, 2004). Figure, over 47 Law, 3rd ed. (St. Paul: West, 2009), p. 39.
percent, is for 2003. 389. Walsh, The Public’s Business, p. 289.
375. Tom Raum and Jim Drinkard, Associated Press, 390. Reynolds, Local Government Law, p. 39.
“Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, Spent Millions on 391. Walsh, The Public’s Business, p. 6.
Lobbying,” USA Today (July 17, 2008). Freddie 392. Jerry Mitchell, “Policy Functions and Issues
was fined $3.8 million. for Public Authorities,” Public Authorities and
376. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federally Public Policy: The Business of Government, Jerry
Created Entities: An Overview of Key Attributes, Mitchell, ed. (Westport, CN: Praeger, 1992),
p. 21. pp. 1–14. The quotation is on p. 5.
377. Mitchell, The American Experiment with Govern- 393. Mitchell, The American Experiment with Govern-
ment Corporations, p. 14. ment Corporations, p. 95.
378. Much of the following discussion is drawn from 394. Tanya Heikkila and Kimberley Roussin Isett,
Walsh, The Public’s Business. “Citizen Involvement and Performance Manage-
379. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental ment in Special-Purpose Governments,” Public
Relations, Bankruptcies, Defaults, and Other Administration Review 67 (March/April 2007),
Local Financial Emergencies, A-99 (Washington, pp. 238–248.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1985), 395. Mitchell, The American Experiment with
p. 2. Government Corporations, p. 95.
380. Carma Hogue, Government Organization 396. Donald T. Wells and Richard Scheff, “Performance
Summary Report: 2012 (Washington, DC: U.S. Issues for Public Authorities in Georgia,” in Public
Government Printing Office, 2013). Authorities and Public Policy, pp. 167–176. The
381. For reasons of space, we shall not list each of quotation is on p. 172.
these five tallies and their sources, but they can 397. Mitchell, “Education and Skills for Public
be found in the tenth edition of this book (2007), Authority Management,” pp. 429–437.
p. 345, Note 219. 398. Ibid. and Tari Renner, “Appointed Local Govern-
382. Jerry Mitchell, “Education and Skills for Public ment Managers: Stability and Change,” Muni-
Authority Management,” Public Administration cipal Year Book, 1990 (Washington, DC:
Review 51 (September/October 1991), pp. 429– International  City Management Association,
437. The quotation is on p. 436. 1990), pp. 30–35.
383. Jerry Mitchell, “The Policy Activities of Public 399. Mitchell, “Education and Skills for Public
Authorities,” Policy Studies Journal 18 (Summer Authority Management,” and Victor S. De Santis
1990), pp. 928–942. Figures are for 1989. and Charldean Newell, “Local Government
384. Mitchell Denning and David J. Olson, “Public Managers’ Career Paths,” Municipal Year
Enterprise and the Emerging Character of State Book, 1996 (Washington, DC: International
Service Provisions,” Paper presented at the City/County Management Association, 1996),
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science pp. 3–10.
Association (New York: September 3–5, 1981), 400. Ibid. (both citations).
pp. 6, 9. 401. Mitchell, “Education and Skills for Public
385. Walsh, The Public’s Business, p. 6. Authority Management,” pp. 434–435.
386. Denning and Olson, “Public Enterprise and the 402. Wells and Scheff, “Performance Issues for Public
Emerging Character of State Service Provisions,” Authorities in Georgia,” pp. 174–175.
pp. 6, 9. 403. Jonathan P. West and Evan M. Berman,
387. Robert W. Poole, Jr., Revitalizing State and Local “Job Satisfaction of Public Managers in
Infrastructure: Empowering Cities and States Special Districts,” Review of Public Personnel
to Tap Private Capital and Rebuild America, Administration 29 (December 2009), pp. 327–
Policy Study No. 190 (Washington, DC: Reason 353. Data are for 2008.
Public Policy Institute, 1995), pp. 3–4, and 404. Paul Pringle and Rong-Gong Lin, II, “More than
Denning  and  Olson, “Public Enterprise and the $1 Million Paid to Head of L.A. County Fair
Emerging Character of State Service Provisions,” Assn. as Financial Losses Mount,” Los Angeles
pp. 6, 9. Times (February 19, 2016).
454 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

405. Walsh, The Public’s Business, p. 4. 420. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax-
406. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federally Exempt Organizations: Better Compliance Indi-
Created Entities: An Overview of Key Attributes, cators and Data, and More Collaboration with
pp. 39–41. Figures are annual averages for State Regulators Would Strengthen Oversight
FY 2005–FY 2008. of Charitable Organizations, GAO-15-164
407. Mitchell, The American Experiment with (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
Government Corporations, p. 119. Office, 2015), p. 8. Figures are for 2012.
408. G. Ross Stephens and Nelson Wikstrom, “Trends 421. Ibid., p. 9. Estimated figures are for 2012.
in Special Districts,” State and Local Government 422. Ibid. Estimated figures are for 2012.
Review 30 (Spring 1998), pp. 120–138. The quo- 423. Lester M. Salamon, America’s Nonprofit Sector:
tation is on p. 133. A Primer, 2nd ed. (New York: The Foundation
409. Kathryn A. Foster, The Political Economy of Center, 1999), pp. 22, 36. Figures are for 1995–
Special-Purpose Governments (Washington, DC: 1996 and exclude volunteers.
Georgetown University Press, 2007), pp. 219–221. 424. Kanika Kapur and Burton D. Weisbrod, “The
410. Melissa Maynard, “Cash-Strapped Governments Roles of Government and Nonprofit Suppliers
Turn to Special Districts,” Pewstates.org (October in Mixed Industries,” Public Finance Review 60
2013). (July/August 2000), pp. 275–308.
411. Unless noted otherwise, the following exam- 425. Wolfgang Bielefeld and William Suhs Cleveland,
ples are drawn from Mitchell, The American “Faith-Based Organizations as Service Providers
Experiment with Government Corporations, and Their Relationship to Government,” Non-
pp. 96, 107, 116, 108. profit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 42 (April
412. Office of the Inspector General, U.S. Department 2013), pp. 468–494. The quotation is on p. 484.
of Housing and Urban Development, Overincome 426. National Conference on Citizenship, Civic
Families Residing in Public Housing Units Health and Unemployment II: The Case Builds
(Washington, DC: Author, 2015). Data are for (Washington, DC: Author, 2012).
2014. 427. Edelman, Inc., 2015 Edelman Trust Barometer
413. Mitchell, The American Experiment with (New York: Author, 2015).
Government Corporations, pp. 112–127. 428. Woods Bowman, “Chapter 11—Why Not?”
414. International Personnel Management Association, Nonprofitquarterly.org (August 28, 2009).
Pay Rates in the Public Service: Survey of 62 429. Princeton Survey Research Associates and
Common Job Classes in the Public Sector Brookings Institution, Health of the Public Service
(Washington, DC: Author, 1985). (Washington, DC: Authors, 2001).
415. Kellie Lunney, “The 10 Public Housing Authority 430. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, Senior
Officials Paid the Most from Federal Coffers,” Executive Service Exit Survey Results April 2015
Govexec.com (May 20, 2014). (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Publishing
416. Katie L. Roeger, Amy S. Blackwood, and Sarah Office, 2015), p. 6. Figures are for 2014.
L. Pettijohn, The Nonprofit Almanac 2012 431. Brookings Institution as cited in ibid. Figures are
(Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press, 2013). for 2002.
Figures are for 2010. 432. Fernida Handy, Stephanie Seto, Amanda Wakaruk,
417. Erik Friesenhahn, “Nonprofits in America: New et al., “The Discerning Consumer: Is Nonprofit
Research on Employment, Wages, and Esta- Status a Factor?” Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector
blishments,” Monthly Labor Review (February Quarterly 39 (October 2010), pp. 866–883.
2016), pp. 1–13. Data are for 2007–2012. 433. Paul Arnsberger, Melissa Ludlum, Margaret Riley,
418. American Association of Retired Persons survey, and Mark Stanton, “A History of the Tax-Exempt
as cited in: American Society of Association Sector: An SOI Perspective,” Statistics of Income
Executives, Why Are Associations So Important? Bulletin (Winter 2008), pp. 105–136.
http://www.asaenet.org. 434. Eleanor Brown and Kaitlyn Caughlin, “Donors,
419. Lester M. Salamon, The Resilient Sector: The Ideologues, and Bureaucrats: Government
State of Nonprofit America (Washington, DC: Objectives and the Performance of the Nonprofit
Brookings, 2003), p. 52. Figures are for 1977– Sector,” Financial Accountability & Management
1997. 25 (February 2009), pp. 99–114.
Intersectoral Administration 455

435. Sarah Pettijohn and Elizabeth T. Boris, Nonprofit- Public Finance Review 42 (March 2014), pp. 143–
Government Contracts and Grants: Findings 175. The quotation is on p. 143.
from the 2013 National Survey (Washington, DC: 448. In contrast to the analysis cited, another quan-
Urban Institute, 2013). Data are for 2012. titative study found that “reliance on govern-
436. As derived from data in Elizabeth T. Boris, ment funding decreases the likelihood that
“Introduction: Nonprofit Organizations in nonprofit organizations will develop strong,
a Democracy—Roles and Responsibilities,” representative boards” (p. 468). See Chao Guo,
Nonprofits & Government: Collaboration “When Government Becomes the Principal
& Conflict,  2nd ed., Elizabeth T. Boris and C. Philanthropist: The Effects of Public Funding
Eugene Steuerle, eds. (Washington, DC: Urban on Patterns of Nonprofit Governance,” Public
Institute  Press, 2006), pp. 1–36. Figure (p. 9) is Administration Review 67 (May/June 2007),
for 2004, and combines “Health” and “Human pp. 458–473.
Services.” 449. Melissa Middleton Stone, Mark A. Hager, and
437. Salamon, America’s Nonprofit Sector, p. 55. Jennifer J. Griffin, “Organizational Characteristics
438. C. Eugene Steuerle and Virginia K. Hodgkinson, and Funding Environments: A Study of a Popu-
“Meeting Social Needs: Comparing Independent lation of United Way-Affiliated Nonprofits,”
Sector and Government Resources,” Nonprofits Public Administration Review 61 (May/June
& Government, pp. 81–106. Figures (p. 87) are 2001), pp. 276–289.
for 2002. As derived from data in Steuerle and 450. Hee Soun Jang and Richard C. Feiock,“Public versus
Hodgkinson, “Meeting Social Needs,” p. 101. Private Funding of Nonprofit Organizations,”
Figure is for 2003, and includes “Health,” which Public Performance & Management Review 31
accounted for 57 percent of the total. (December 2007), pp. 174–190.
439. Giving USA Foundation, Giving USA Philan- 451. Stone, Hager, and Griffin, “Organizational Char-
thropy Spotlight: Benchmarking Giving to acteristics and Funding Environments,” pp. 276,
Human Services (Chicago: Author, 2016). Data 285.
are for 2005–2015. 452. Kelly LeRoux, “Paternalistic or Participatory
440. Lester M. Salamon, “Government and the Volun- Governance? Examining Opportunities for
tary Sector in an Era of Retrenchment: The Client Participation in Nonprofit Social Service
American Experience,” Journal of Public Policy Organizations,” Public Administration Review 69
6 (January–March 1986), pp. 1–20. Figure, 42 (May/June 2009), pp. 504–517. The quotations
percent (p. 7), is for 1982. are on pp. 513, 504.
441. Pettijohn and Boris, Nonprofit-Government Con- 453. Jesse D. Lecy and David M. Van Slyke, “Nonprofit
tracts, p. 2. Figures are for 2012. Sector Growth and Density: Testing Theories
442. Salamon, The Resilient Sector, p. 54. Figures are of Government Support,” Journal of Public
for 1997. Administration Research & Theory 23 (January
443. Salamon, America’s Nonprofit Sector, p. 55. 2013), pp. 189–214.
444. Daniel Stid, “The Social Services Industrial 454. David G. Renz, “Adding a Few More Pieces to
Complex,” Washington Post (April 25, 2012). the Puzzle: Exploring the Practical Implications of
445. David F. Suarez, “Collaboration and Professional- Recent Research on Boards,” Nonprofitquarterly.
ization: The Contours of Public Sector Funding org (December 31, 2012).
for Nonprofit Organizations,” Journal of 455. Beth Gazley and Jeffrey L. Brudney, “The
Public Administration Research and Theory 21 Purpose (and Perils) of Government-Nonprofit
(April  2011), pp. 307–326. The quotation is on Partnerships,” Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector
p. 307. Quarterly 36 (September 2007), pp. 389–415.
446. Greg Chen, “Does Meeting Standards Affect 456. Kunle Akingbola, “Staffing, Retention, and
Charitable Giving? An Empirical Study of Government Funding: A Case Study,” Nonprofit
New York Metropolitan Charities,” Nonprofit Management & Leadership 14 (Summer 2004),
Management & Leadership 19 (Spring 2009), pp. 453–465. The quotations are on pp. 463,
pp. 349–365. The quotations are on p. 360. 453.
447. Garth Heutel, “Crowding Out and Crowding In 457. Pettijohn and Boris, Nonprofit-Government Con-
of Private Donations and Government Grants,” tracts, p. 11. Figures are for 2012.
456 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

458. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Non- 468. Tamara G. Nezhina and Jeffrey L. Brudney,
profit Sector: Significant Federal Funds Reach “Unintended? The Effects of Adoption of the
the Sector through Various Mechanisms, but Sarbanes-Oxley Act on Nonprofit Organizations,”
More Complete and Reliable Funding Data Are Nonprofit Management & Leadership 22 (Spring
Needed, GAO-09-193 (Washington, DC: U.S. 2012), pp. 321–346. The quotation is on p. 321.
Government Printing Office, 2009), p. 3. Figure 469. Choi, Cho, Wright, and Brudney, “Dimensions
is for 2006. of Contracting for Service Delivery by American
459. Ibid., Highlights page. State Administrative Agencies,” p. 50. Figure, 71
460. Ibid. percent, is for 1998.
461. Alan J. Abramson, Lester M. Salamon, and C. 470. Woods Bowman and Marion R. Fremont-Smith,
Eugene Steuerle, “Federal Spending and Tax “Nonprofits and State and Local Government,” in
Policies: Their Implications for the Nonprofit Nonprofits & Government, pp. 181–218. Figure
Sector,” in Nonprofits & Government, pp. 107– (p. 194) is for 2001–2002.
140. These researchers estimate (p. 118) that 471. William Luksetich, “Government Funding and
Washington directed $317 billion to the nonprofit Nonprofit Organizations,” Nonprofit and Volun-
sector in FY 2004, when Washington spent more tary Sector Quarterly 37 (September 2008),
than $305 billion on private-sector contracts. pp. 434–442.
See Federal Procurement Data System, Federal 472. Anna A. Amirkhanyan, “Monitoring across
Procurement Report (Washington, DC: Author, Sectors: Examining the Effect of Nonprofit and
2004). For-Profit Contractor Ownership on Performance
462. As derived from data in Abramson, Salamon, Monitoring in State and Local Contracts,” Public
and Steuerle, “Federal Spending and Tax Administration Review 70 (September/October
Policies,”  pp.  118, 111, 117, 113. Data are for 2010), pp. 742–755.
1980–2004. 473. Larry Kaplan, “S.C. Watchdog Questions Agency,
463. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax- Nonprofit Spending on Wetlands,” SavannahNow.
Exempt Organizations: Better Compliance Indi- com (April 30, 2015).
cators and Data, and More Collaboration with 474. Cindy M. Lott, Elizabeth T. Boris, Karin Kunstler
State Regulators Would Strengthen Oversight of Goldman, et al., State Regulation and Enforcement
Charitable Organizations, p. 8. Figures are for in the Charitable Sector (Washington, DC: Urban
2012. Institute, 2016).
464. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 475. Elaine S. Povitch, “Should Nonprofits Have to
Nonprofit Sector: Significant Federal Funds Reach Pay Taxes?” Pewtrusts.org (March 5, 2015).
the Sector through Various Mechanisms, but 476. Daphne A. Kenyon and Adam H. Langley, The
More Complete and Reliable Funding Data Are Property Tax Exemption for Nonprofits and
Needed, Highlights page. Figure is for 2006. Revenue Implications for Cities (Washington, DC:
465. The Federal Funding Accountability and Urban Institute, 2011), p. 2. Figure is for 2009.
Transparency Act of 2006 requires the collecting 477. Bowman and Fremont-Smith, “Nonprofits and
and reporting of data concerning “subawards,” or State and Local Government,” pp. 201–207.
those federal expenditures that end up with non- Figures are for 2001–2002.
profits and other recipients after being funneled 478. Quoted in Rob Meiskins, “Judge Terms
through those entities that received federal money Modern Nonprofit Hospitals a ‘Legal Fiction,’”
directly. Nonprofitquarterly.org (July 7, 2015).
466. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Non- 479. Kenyon and Langley, The Property Tax Exemption
profit Sector: Significant Federal Funds Reach for Nonprofits and Revenue Implications for
the Sector through Various Mechanisms, but Cities, p. 2. Figures are for 2009.
More Complete and Reliable Funding Data 480. Zaid Jilani, “How Parasitic Universities Drain
Are Needed, Highlights page. Figures are for Towns All Across America,” AlterNet (May 15,
2006. 2015).
467. Jeremy Thornton, “Flypaper Nonprofits,” Public 481. Elaine S. Povich, “Short on Cash, Cities and States
Finance Review 42 (March 2014), pp. 176–198. Consider Taxing Nonprofits,” Stateline (October
The quotation is on p. 176. 4, 2016).
Intersectoral Administration 457

482. Adam H. Langley, Daphne A. Kenyon, and Patricia Voluntary Sector Quarterly 39 (February 2010),
C. Bailin, Which Nonprofits Make PILOTs and pp. 51–76.
Which Localities Receive Them? (Cambridge, 496. Gazley and Brudney, “The Purpose (and Perils) of
MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, 2012). Government-Nonprofit Partnerships.”
Figures are for 2000–2011. 497. Rick Cohen, “Philanthropy Funding Government
483. Daphne A. Kenyon and Adam H. Langley, Work? There’s a Foundation for That—Several,
“Nonprofit PILOTS,” Land Lines (July 2016), Actually,” Nonprofitquarterly.org (April 13,
pp. 5–8. 2012).
484. Ruth McCambridge, “A County in Which Half 498. Beth Gazley, “How Philanthropy Props Up
the Economy Is Nonprofit Driven,” Govexec.com Public Services and Why We Should Care,”
(July 9, 2015). Nonprofitquarterly.org (March 27, 2015).
485. Donald F. Norris and Christopher Reddick, 499. Rob Meiksins, “Another Misuse of Nonprofits?
“E-Government 2011: Trends and Innovations,” Local and State Agencies ‘Transform,’” Chicago
Municipal Year Book, 2012 (Washington, DC: Tribune (May 1, 2015).
International City/County Management Asso- 500. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tem-
ciation, 2012) pp. 83–94. porary Assistance for Needy Families: Update on
486. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- States Counting Third-Party Expenditures toward
tion,” p. 55. Figure is for 2012. Maintenance of Effort Requirements, GAO-
487. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,” 16-315 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
p. 14, and as derived from data in Miranda Publishing Office, 2016), Highlights page.
and Andersen, “Alternative Service Delivery in 501. Gazley, “How Philanthropy Props Up
Local  Government, 1982–1992,” p. 31, and Public Services and Why We Should Care,”
Hatry and Valente, “Alternative Service Delivery Nonprofitquarterly.org (March 27, 2015).
Approaches Involving Increased Use of the Private 502. Ibid. School support growth figures are for 1995–
Sector,” pp.  216–217. Figures are for 1982– 2010.
2007. 503. Rick Cohen, “Public Accountability in the Balance
488. Brown, “The Dynamics of Government-to- when Gov’t Agencies Create Nonprofit Wings,”
Government Contracts.” Nonprofitquarterly.org (March 26, 2015).
489. Lamothe and Lamothe, “The Dynamics of Local 504. Gazley, “How Philanthropy Props Up Public
Service Delivery Arrangements and the Role of Services and Why We Should Care.”
Nonprofits,” p. 791. 505. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of
490. Amirkhanyan, “Monitoring across Sectors.” the United States, 2016, Table 598. Figures are for
491. Marvel and Marvel, “Shaping the Provision of 2014.
Outsourced Public Services,” p. 197. 506. Thomas Rotolo and John Wilson, “State-Level
492. Eva Witesman and Sergio Fernandez, Differences in Volunteerism in the United States,”
“Government Contracts With Private Organi- Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 41
zations,” Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quar- (June 2012), pp. 452–473.
terly 42 (August 2013), pp. 689–715. The 507. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of
quotations are on p. 689. the United States, 2016, Table 598. Figures are for
493. Beth Gazley, “Beyond the Contract: The Scope 2014.
and Nature of Informal Government-Nonprofit 508. Council for Excellence in Government and Hart-
Partnerships,” Public Administration Review Teeter Poll, America Unplugged: Citizens and
68 (January/February 2008), pp. 141–154. Their Government (Washington, DC: Authors,
The  figure is on p. 144; the quotation is on 1999), p. 5. In 1999, 27 percent had participated.
p. 146. 509. Rebecca Nesbit and Jeffrey L. Brudney, “Volunteer
494. Gazley and Brudney, “The Purpose (and Use in Local Government Service Delivery,”
Perils  of  Government-Nonprofit Partnerships,” Municipal Year Book, 2013 (Washington, DC:
p. 389. International City/County Management Asso-
495. Beth Gazley, “Why Not Partner With Local ciation. 2013), pp. 79–88.
Government? Nonprofit Managerial Perceptions 510. Chi, Arnold, and Perkins, “Privatization in State
of Collaborative Disadvantage,” Nonprofit and Government,” pp. 468, 479. Figures are for 2002.
458 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

511. Chi and Jasper, Private Practices, p. 14. Data are Resource Development Strategies: Exploring
for 1997. the Link between Individual Volunteering and
512. Nesbit and Brudney, “Volunteer Use in Local Giving,” Public Performance & Management
Government Service Delivery,” p. 79. Figure is for Review 29 (June 2006), pp. 467–496.
2007. 525. Corporation for National & Community
513. As derived from data in Warner and Hefetz, Service, Volunteering and Civic Life in America
“Cooperative Competition,” p. 15. Figures are for (Washington, DC: Author, 2015). Figures are for
2007. The question was not asked in 2012. 2013.
514. As derived from data in Hatry and Valente, 526. Bryan Terry, Amy Harder, and Dale Pracht,
“Alternative Service Delivery Approaches Invo- “Understanding the Value of Volunteer
lving Increased Use of Private Sector,” pp. 216– Involvement,” Journal of Agricultural Education
217. Figures are for 1982. 52 (2, 2011), pp. 118–127.
515. Warner and Hefetz, “Cooperative Competition,” 527. Paul Posner, Robert Yetvin, Mark Schneiderman,
p. 15. Data are for 2007. et al., “A Survey of Voucher Use: Variation and
516. Jen Fifield, “Volunteer Firehouses Struggle to Find Common Elements,” Vouchers and the Provision
Recruits,” Stateline (January 11, 2017). Current of Public Services, C. Eugene Steuerle, Van
figure is for 2014. Doorn Ooms, George Peterson, and Robert D.
517. David Osborne and Ted Gaebler, Reinventing Reischauer, eds. (Washington, DC: Brookings,
Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Committee for Economic Development, and
Is  Transforming the Public Sector (Reading, Urban Institute, 2000), pp. 503–540. The quota-
MA:  Addison-Wesley, 1992), pp. 68, 75, 196, tion is on p. 504.
340. 528. ProQuest LLC, ProQuest Statistical Abstract of
518. William D. Duncombe and Jeffrey L. Brudney, the United States, 2016, Table 598. Figures are
“The Optimal Mix for Volunteers and Paid for 2014.
Staff in Local Governments: An Application to 529. Ibid., Tables 147, 158. Dollar figure is for FY
Municipal Fire Departments,” Public Finance 2013. Enrollee figure is for 2012.
Quarterly 23 (July 1995), pp. 356–384. 530. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services,
519. Jeffrey L. Brudney and William D. Duncombe, Office of the Inspector General, States’ Child
“An Economic Evaluation of Paid, Volunteer, Care Certificate Systems: An Early Assessment
and Mixed Staffing Options for Public Services,” of Vulnerabilities and Barriers (Washington, DC:
Public Administration Review 52 (September/ Author, 1998), p. 3.
October 1992), pp. 474–481. The quotation is on 531. George E. Peterson, “Housing Vouchers: The
p. 474. U.S. Experience,” Vouchers and the Provision of
520. Koen P. R. Bartels, Guido Cozzi, and Noemi Public Services, pp. 139–175.
Mantovan, “‘The Big Society,’ Public Expenditure, 532. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
and Volunteering,” Public Administration Review Introduction to the Housing Voucher Program
73 (March/April 2013), pp. 340–351. The quota- (Washington, DC: Author, 2003), p. 2.
tions are on p. 340. 533. Elizabeth Kneebone and Natalie Holmes,
521. Independent Sector, Independent Sector’s Value of “Promise and Pitfalls of Housing Choice Vouchers
Volunteer Time (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). Vary across Nation,” Brookings.edu (August 14,
Figure is for 2015. 2015).
522. Matthew A. Liao-Troth, “Attitude Differences 534. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
Between Paid Workers and Volunteers,” Nonprofit Introduction to the Housing Voucher Program,
Management and Leadership 11 (Summer 2001), p. 2.
pp. 423–442. 535. Chi, Arnold, and Perkins, “Privatization in State
523. Astrid Pennerstorfer and Birgit Trukeschitz, Government,” pp. 468, 479. Figures are for
“Voluntary Contribution and Wages in Nonprofit 2002.
Organizations,” Nonprofit Management & 536. Chi and Jasper, Private Practices, p. 14. Data are
Leadership 23 (Winter 2012), pp. 181–191. for 1997.
524. David M. Van Slyke and Janet L. Johnson, 537. As derived from data in Elaine Morley,
“Nonprofit Organizational Performance and “Patterns in the Use of Alternative Service
Intersectoral Administration 459

Delivery Approaches,” Municipal Year Book, Sector,” pp. 216–217. Figures and services (p. 39)
1989 (Washington, DC: International City are for 1988. Trend data are for 1982–1988.
Management Association, 1989), pp. 33–44, 538. As derived from data in Alliance for School
and Hatry and Valente, “Alternative Delivery Choice, School Choice Facts (Washington, DC:
Approaches Involving Increased Use of the Public Author, 2014). Figures are for 2013.
CHAPTER

12

Intergovernmental
Administration

T he administration of a “single” domestic


policy  often involves a pastiche of public
administrators, and this is known as intergovern-
Points Previously Made: Less Corruption, More
Efficiency As we noted in the introduction to Part
III, nations with federal structures correlate robustly
mental relations, or the series of financial, legal, with less political corruption and smaller shadow
political, and administrative relationships estab- economies, and, as we explained in Chapter 7, they
lished among all units of government that possess also tax and deliver services more efficiently than
varying degrees  of authority and jurisdictional do those with unitary structures. But there are addi-
autonomy.  These relationships are called feder- tional contrasts.
alism when applied more narrowly to the federal
government’s relations  with state governments, Fiscal Centralization, Federal Systems, and Public
and the states’ relationships with  each other, Employees National fiscal decentralization (a
although the terms  often are used  interchange- universal condition in federal systems, but which
ably. Intergovernmental  administration, some- is essentially absent in centralized ones) associates
times called intergovernmental management, is the with fewer public employees in the national govern-
management and coordination of the relationships ment, but also with more employees in subnational
among governments for the  purpose of achiev- governments and in total. This correlation differs
ing specific policy goals. from the finding that federal systems (not quite the
same thing as fiscal decentralization) equate with
fewer total public workers.1
SOME SYSTEMIC FINDINGS
Fiscal Decentralization and Governmental Growth
ABOUT FEDERALISM The greater the degree of fiscal decentralization in a
The United States, of course, has a federal system of country, the smaller the public sector’s share of its
governance, which refers to a union of national and gross domestic product (GDP),2 and the slower that
subnational governments, with distinct or shared public expenditures, tax burdens, and governments
responsibilities assigned to each governmental level. grow.3 However, the more that public spending (in
A unitary, or centralized, system concentrates power contrast to revenue collecting) is decentralized, the
in the top tier of governments. faster that governments grow.4

From Federal to More Unitary Structures Over


Federal Systems versus Unitary Systems time, federal systems tend to concentrate
Nations with federal systems generally are better off greater  power at the top, and this occurs for two
than those with unitary ones. reasons.
460
Intergovernmental Administration 461

One is that, as societies develop economically, that are originated by other states,8 in contrast to
“demands for equality of treatment over wider geo- the federal government, which virtually disdains
graphical areas” grow, and economies of scale wax state-created innovations.9 (The states, however, have
more appealing. When these demands spill over sub- an indirect but effective impact on Congress; when
national borders, only the national government can many states regulate particular kinds of businesses,
accommodate them efficiently. those businesses pressure Congress to pass a national
This dynamic often is accelerated when major regulation to reduce regulatory confusion.) Local
social disturbances (such as war) break out, and governments, both general- and special-purpose, are
powers that have “always” been the exclusive pre- quick to create and copy new ways of doing things.10
serve of subnational governments are swept away in
favor of nationalizing them.5
GOVERNMENTS, THE
Findings from the States and Communities: CONSTITUTION, AND THE COURTS
Trust and Innovation Americans are governed by a lot of governments,
The greater the degree of fiscal decentralization in an and their number grows.
American state, the higher the level of public trust
in government (a single standard deviation increase
in either revenue or expenditure decentralization America’s Proliferating Governments
correlates with a nearly 4 percent increase in trust- Table 12-1 identifies the 89,055 governments in the
ing residents), and the more local governments in United States by type, and indicates their fluctua-
a state, the higher the level of trust (one standard tions in twenty-year increments since 1942, when
deviation in the number of governments correlates the  first regularly scheduled census of governments
with an almost 2.5 percentage increase in trusting was taken.
people).6 This trust is vital to good governance; as Most of the proliferation of cities and towns
we detailed in Chapters 1 and 11, public trust is crit- occurred in the years following World War II, and
ical in raising governments’ efficiency, effectiveness, was largely due to unplanned metropolitan growth.
and responsiveness. For instance, New Squier, New York, was established
At root, intergovernmental relationships asso- so that a kosher slaughterhouse could be operated,
ciate strongly with innovation. More than four- and Gardena, California, was founded so that its
fifths of all “creativity in government” takes place residents could play poker legally.11
in state and local governments.7 State governments Special-purpose governments evidence the great-
are  notably open to adopting innovative policies est flux. School districts, as a consequence of the school

TABLE 12-1
Number of Governmental Units, by Type: 1942, 1962, 1982, 2002, and 2012
Type of Government 1942 1962 1982 2002 2012
Total 155,116 91,237 81,831 87,900 89,055
U.S. government 1 1 1 1 1
State governments 48 50 50 50 50
Local governments 155,067 91,186 81,780 87,849 89,004
Counties 3,050 3,043 3,041 3,034 3,031
Municipalities 16,220 18,000 19,076 19,431 19,522
Townships 18,919 17,142 16,734 16,506 16,364
School districts 108,579 34,678 14,851 13,522 12,884
Special districts 8,299 18,323 28,078 35,356 37,203
462 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

consolidation movement, have withered by 88 percent


to less than an eighth of their number seventy years The Courts: Necessary and Proper Implied
earlier. (Even so, 46 percent  of school districts still Federal Powers
serve fewer than 1,000 pupils [the national average is The Constitution’s federal features continue to be
3,659], and a third have only one or two schools.12) refined by the courts. Without question, the most
Special districts, largely as a result of popular resist- influential single case in this process is McCulloch v.
ance to consolidating general-purpose local govern- Maryland, which was settled by the Supreme Court
ments, more than quadrupled over the same period. in 1819.
The case involved Maryland’s attempt to tax the
Second Bank of the United States, which was located
The Constitution: The Functions of in Maryland, but soon waxed into an argument over
Federalism whether the United States could even form a bank.
The Constitution focuses on three facets of federalism. The federal government argued that a national bank
could be established because it was an “implied
Separate National and State Identities Most power” under the Constitution.
fundamentally, the Constitution establishes sepa- Chief Justice John Marshall and his colleagues
rate identities for the nation and the states. For the concurred, citing the final sentence of Section 8,
nation, perhaps the most significant statement is Article I, which accords the federal government the
in Article VI: “This Constitution and the Laws of authority “To make all Laws which shall be nec-
the United States . . . shall be the Supreme Law of essary and proper for carrying into Execution . . .
the Land.” The most important clause for the states all the Powers vested by this Constitution in the
is Section 3, Article IV, which stipulates that states Government of the United States.” Hence, Congress
may prohibit the formation of new states, or parts of had the power to do whatever is “necessary and
new states, within their boundaries. proper to implement its specified functions.”

Distinct National and State Responsibilities Four


portions of the Constitution distinguish national and THE EVOLUTION OF
state responsibilities. Section 8, Article I delegates
INTERGOVERNMENTAL
seventeen specific powers to the national govern-
ment, including defense, general welfare, and com- ADMINISTRATION
merce, and leaves the remaining powers to the states. America’s governments have gone through five
The Tenth Amendment, which was added hastily in phases in their administrative relationships. Early
response to such populist rabble rousers as Patrick scholars identified the first two of these phases with
Henry, specifies that these remaining powers are lasting metaphors involving pastry, which we, with
“reserved to the States . . . or to the people,” thereby admittedly dubious judgment, have extended.
drawing a darker line that the national government
could not, presumably, cross. Section 9, Article I
prohibits the national government from exercising The Layer Cake: Dual Federalism,
certain powers, such as taxing state exports, and 1789–1932
its Section 10 forbids the states from undertaking The Constitution recognizes only two levels of gov-
certain actions, such as coining money. ernment: national and state. Hence, the terms, “layer
cake federalism” and “dual federalism,” indicating
Integrating Nation and States Finally, the Consti- that, during the nation’s first 143 years, the federal
tution deals with the integration of the national and and state governments stuck to their very separate
state governments by providing for collaboration knitting. For example, when Congress, in 1854, did
among them in the performance of some vital func- try (unusually) to transfer funds to the states to help
tions. For example, the federal and state governments them treat their indigent insane, the president vetoed
cooperate in amending the Constitution, electing a the bill on the logic that to encourage the states to
president, and, through Congress, enacting laws. “become humble suppliants for the bounty of the
Intergovernmental Administration 463

Federal Government” would reverse “their true rela- total state revenue to a head-spinning 27 percent,
tion to this Union.”13 and direct federal grants as a percentage of all local
In the aftermath of the Civil War, however, revenue quadrupled from 1 percent in 1934 to 4
the nation entered a period of dented dual federal- percent in 1940.21
ism. From 1865 to 1869, the country enacted the During the 1940s, World War II intervened,
Constitution’s Thirteenth, Fourteenth, and Fifteenth followed by a two-term conservative president in
amendments. These new civil rights policies ren- the  1950s. Federal grant dollars slipped signifi-
dered constitutional federal involvement in previ- cantly, rarely exceeding 1 percent of the economy. Even
ously sacrosanct state affairs. by the early 1950s, federal intergovernmental grant
The federal judiciary also began to under- programs numbered fewer than forty,22 and through-
mine state sovereignty. Between 1794 and 1860, out almost all of the fifties, they accounted from 5 to
the Supreme Court voided, on average, about one 6 percent of federal outlays.23 On average, about 14
state law per year. Between 1860 and 1937 (the percent of total state revenue, and 1 percent of all local
year when the Court radically reversed course and revenue, were provided by direct federal grants.24
actively sanctioned a dramatic expansion of federal Washington also chose to continue its policy,
power), however, the Court overruled an average of begun at the nation’s founding, of not wrapping the
nearly seven per year. Dual federalism, if dinged and grass-roots governments in red tape; even as late as
dented, still survived, but at least “the pitiful position 1960, it had imposed only two “major” regulations
in 1860 of the national government was ended.”14 on state and local governments.25
Still, Washington kept its distance from state
and local governments. Even during the first thirty
or so years of the twentieth century, federal intergov- The Pound Cake: Co-Optative Federalism,
ernmental grant programs accounted for less than 1959–1978
one-half of 1 percent of the national economy; their Perhaps “pound cake” best describes federalism
modest number ranged from five to twelve;15 they during its co-optative phase, because Washington
constituted about 3 percent of all federal outlays,16 was pounding state and local governments with
one-half of 1 percent of the states’ total revenue (that hundreds of highly specialized grants that came with
is, general revenue and other than general revenue, strong strings attached. But subnational govern-
as described in Chapter 8) and a trace amount of ments discovered that, at least fiscally, Washington’s
total revenue in local governments.17 pound cake was loaded with sugar and that they had
a sweet tooth.

The Marble Cake: Cooperative Federalism, A Flood of Federal Funds Federal sugar was first
1933–1958 savored in 1959, when the number of grants, and
With the ascension of Franklin Delano Roosevelt the dollars in them, began their explosive growth
to the presidency, in 1933, layer cake federalism that thundered on throughout the next two decades.
sagged and whorled into “marble cake federalism,” Grants and their dollars peaked in 1978, when 492
marking a radical expansion of Washington’s inter- grant programs (almost a tripling from 132 pro-
governmental power and unprecedented coopera- grams in 1960)26 accounted for 3.7 percent of the
tion among all governmental levels. economy,27 matching its record proportion of 1934,
Federal assistance shot from a fraction of 1 and 17 percent of all federal expenditures.28
percent of the economy to 3.7 percent in 1934, and Between 1959 and 1978, federally-furnished
never sank below 2 percent for the remainder of the funding as a portion of state and local budgets
decade.18 The number of federal grant programs more than doubled, attaining nearly 28 percent
more than doubled during the 1930s, and their of these governments’ total outlays and an aston-
funding flexed by a phenomenal factor of fifteen,19 ishing 47 percent of their own source spending.
accounting for almost two-fifths of all federal By 1978, federal grants accounted for 22 percent
spending by 1939.20 Within two years (1932–1934), of all state  revenue,29 and, from 1959 to 1978,
federal grants exploded from less than 1 percent of direct  federal aid  to local governments more than
464 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

tripled, from 8 to 29 percent, and comprised over 9 This trend represents a vast shift in Americans’
percent of all local revenue.30 governmental thinking. In 1936, 56 percent of
As an acerbic observer noted during this period, Americans favored the “concentration of power”
“If Washington offered grants for cancer implants, in the federal government, and 44 percent preferred
cities would line up to apply.”31 that power concentrate at the state level. Eighty
years later, 37 percent favored the feds on this
Washington Rules “During the 1960s and 1970s, dimension, and 55 percent favored the states; this
state and local governments, for the first time, were reversal occurred in the 1970s and 1980s.36 Seventy-
brought under extensive federal regulatory controls.” one percent of Americans trust their local govern-
Over these two decades, Congress enacted thirty- ments, and citizens have expressed greater trust in
four “new laws or major amendments to statutes” local governments than either the federal govern-
that regulated subnational governments, compared ment (which currently garners just 28 percent37) or
with no such regulations whatsoever enacted during state governments (62 percent) since 2000.38
the prior two decades, and it passed 157 preemption
statutes (or laws that remove authority from state The 1980s: Fractured Federalism After 1978,
or local governments and transfer it to Washington), federal assistance to states and communities plum-
compared with the passage of just forty-four such meted—precipitously. Over the next ten years,
statutes during the 1940s and 1950s.32 In the 1970s Washington’s intergovernmental aid as a share of
alone, federal preemptions accounted for almost a GDP fell by almost half, to 2 percent; federal assis-
quarter of all preemptions imposed during the entire tance as a portion of federal outlays declined by
twentieth century.33 more than a third, to 11 percent; direct federal grants
By the end of the 1970s, state and local gov- as a share of total state revenue slipped by nearly a
ernments verged on truly becoming “humble suppli- fourth, to 17 percent, and by a startling two-thirds,
ants” of a federal satrap. to 3 percent of all local revenue.39
Federal regulation of subnational governments,
however, steamed on. Twenty-seven new or substan-
The Crumble Cake: Competitive tially amended regulatory laws were enacted, five
Federalism, 1979–2008 more than in the previous decade; 100 preemption
Around 1979, there were signs that the intergovern- statutes were passed, a modest nine fewer than in
mental cake was beginning to loosen, and deterio- the seventies; and, for the first time ever, there were
rate, into a “crumble cake,” marking the debut of more regulations than grants.40
“Competitive,” or “Fend-for-Yourself,” federalism. Worse, federal intergovernmental administration
“Competitive,” however, no longer referred to sub- and policy withered. After the 1970s, “the network
national governments competing among themselves of federal offices and agencies that was established
for federal grants, as it did during Co-Optative to improve and rationalize intergovernmental man-
Federalism, but meant instead that all governments, agement” was “diminished, disbanded,” and politi-
including the federal one, were competing with each cized.41 Fitful, but not unsuccessful, efforts initiated
other for revenue, as indicated by the fact that, in in the 1930s to form a coherent national policy for
just three years during the 1980s, state tax collec- localities dribbled away in the 1980s, and, by the
tions rose by one-third.34 Elements of Competitive 2000s, “the era of federal urban policy [was], like,
Federalism remain today. way over.”42

Faltering Faith in the Feds Washington, at least The 1990s and 2000s: Deceptive Federalism
in the popular mind, has lost the intergovernmen- Beginning in 1990, Washington re-infused states
tal competition that Competitive Federalism intro- and localities with federal funds. By the mid-2000s,
duced. A remarkable 53 percent of the public, an there were more grant programs than ever—
increase of more than two-fifths over thirteen years, 1,172,43 sponsored by at least twenty-nine agen-
is convinced that the federal government requires cies,44 accounting for over 3 percent of GDP and
“very major reform.”35 16 percent of all federal outlays.45 Direct federal
Intergovernmental Administration 465

grants expanded their 1980s’ share of state and local is that Washington favored a power-sharing empha-
budgets, contributing 20 percent of all state revenue sis with the states, and, increasingly, with localities
(a record proportion—four-fifths—of all state agen- as well. The possible exception was the administra-
cies received  federal assistance46), and 4 percent of tion of President George W. Bush (2001–2009), who
total local revenue.47 was accused of “shift-and-shaft” federalism because
All in all, the two decades appeared to be mostly of his coercive approach. “By one count, Bush signed
good grants news for the grass-roots governments. more than two dozen federal laws that preempted
But appearances can be deceiving. state initiatives, while agencies under his control
One deception that emerged during this period blocked states from taking action on the regulation”
concerned grants for payments for individuals, which of a wide variety of critical areas.57
are federal allocations to state governments that
are earmarked for particular federal programs—
typically, welfare programs—that channel federal The Angel Food Cake: Manna-from-Heaven
funds through state governments to state residents. Federalism, 2009–Present
In 1987, for the first time, the dollars in these Beginning in Fiscal Year 2008, Washington sent
grants surpassed those in traditional program more than $3 trillion per year to the states, or the
grants,48 and, by the end of the 2000s, they accounted equivalent of nearly a fifth of the states’ economies.
for almost two-thirds of all grant dollars,49 twice These expenditures include federal retirement ben-
their proportion in 1978, when they amounted to efits (mostly Social Security payments), nonretire-
less than a third.50 (By 2014, payments for individu- ment benefits (or payments to individuals, such as
als accounted for 72 percent of all federal grants.51) Medicare for the elderly), grants (largely to state
Grants for payments for individuals butter no governments), contracts (essentially to businesses
parsnips for state and local governments. They do and nonprofits), and compensation to federal
not fund state or local programs; they fund only employees, including the military. Grants, at 18
federal ones. percent of federal spending in the states, rank third
The gorilla of grants for payments for indi- after the two largest categories, retirement and non-
viduals is Medicaid, the healthcare grant for the retirement payments to individuals, which account
poor, accounting for 45 percent of all federal inter- for 62 percent.58
governmental grant dollars in 2010, up from 30 Federal grant dollars to state and local govern-
percent in 1990—a growth of 50 percent over two ments, adjusted for inflation, grew by ten-fold over
decades.52 (By 2015, Medicaid’s share had reached the last fifty or so years.59 Currently, federal grants
77 percent.53) From the 1980s through the 2000s, account for 31 percent of state general revenue and
the dollars in all federal intergovernmental grants direct federal grants amount to 5 percent of local
for each and every purpose steadily declined—with general revenue.60
one exception: Medicaid.54 During the 2000s, even The twenty-three “grant-making” agencies
the growth in Medicaid’s funding slowed. sponsor “over 1,670 federal grant programs.”61 Of
By 2006, the shrinkage in Washington’s inter- these, 1,453 are grant programs for subnational gov-
governmental grants no longer could be hidden, and ernments; 13 percent are not currently funded, and
federal grants, including Medicaid, as measured in 11 percent include loan programs or private entities
constant dollars, were in overall decline, sinking by 4 (e.g., universities) as well as public ones, leaving a
percent over three years. Even though direct federal total of 1,099 active grant programs that are directed
assistance had grown by more than three-fifths from at state and local governments.62
2000 to 2008,55 it had shriveled by almost a fourth Federal grant dollars constitute 17 percent of
as a share of total state revenue and it remained all federal outlays. From 2008 through 2015, grant
stuck at precisely the same percentage of all local dollars ranged from 3.1 percent to 4.1 percent
revenue.56 (in 2010) of GDP, and, from 2009 through 2011,
these expenditures matched or surpassed their twin
Crumbling and Devolution An unheralded charac- apexes as percentages of GDP that were attained in
teristic of the aptly named Crumble Cake federalism 1934 and 1978.63
466 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Governors (and, we may safely assume, mayors


FISCAL FEDERALISM as well) love federal grants. Greater grant funding
As the foregoing review implies, money plays an enor- associates positively with: higher approval ratings
mous role in the relations between Washington and for the governor; the governor’s party retaining
the subnational governments. This role is known office, particularly in states that have more compet-
as fiscal federalism, or the granting of funds by one itive elections; and greater gubernatorial success in
government to other governments for the purpose dealing with the legislature on budgetary and policy
of achieving specific policy goals. It would be useful issues.69
to re-check Chapter 8’s Figure 8-1, which charts the In 2013, the Office of Management and Budget
rivers and rivulets of intergovernmental revenue. (OMB), in an attempt to streamline federal grants
procedures, strengthen oversight, and reduce
duplication, consolidated no fewer than eight
A World Turned Upside Down: A Century OMB circulars that dealt not only with grants
of Fiscal Change to subnational governments, but all awards to
At the beginning of the twentieth century, local “nonfederal entities,” including businesses and non-
governments dominated public finance, accounting profits; the policy, Administrative Requirements,
for 58 percent of all governmental expenditures. Cost Principles, and Audit Requirements for Federal
(When we delete national defense and diplomacy, Awards, can be  found in Title 2 of the Code of
localities accounted for an astounding 72 percent Federal Regulations. How successful this effort will
of all governments’ spending.) Washington spent 34 be is unknown; simplifying federal aid was tried by
percent of all public outlays, and the states a nominal Congress as early as 1974, with the passage of the
8 percent.64 Local governments retained their fiscal Joint Funding Simplification Act, but with notably
prominence until 1934.65 limited success.
In 1913, the Constitution’s Sixteenth Amend-
ment, which permits the federal government to The Purposes of Federal Grants Over 55 percent
collect taxes on incomes, was ratified, and intergov- of all federal grant dollars sent to state and local
ernmental finance would never be the same. In just governments is for healthcare (four years earlier, the
a quarter century, Washington emerged as the coun- figure was 45 percent); 94 percent of this growing
try’s reigning fiscal figure, the states had doubled area is devoted to Medicaid, the costs of which
their portion of all public outlays, and local govern- are shared between Washington and the states; 17
ments’ share had declined by nearly a third.66 percent is devoted to income security, notably grants
Spending by the federal government surpassed for needy families and nutritional assistance; 11
all state and local spending in 1970, a pattern percent supports transportation projects, two-thirds
that has continued unabated ever since.67 Today, of which are funneled to highways; and 10 percent
Washington spends 58 percent of all governments’ pertains to education, training, employment, and
outlays. After deleting subnational spending from social services.70
intergovernmental revenue to avoid double count-
ing, the fifty states spend 24 percent of total gov- Types of Federal Grants The most common way
ernmental spending, and the nation’s 89,004 local of distinguishing types of federal grants is as block
governments account for 18 percent.68 grants, which permit the recipient considerable
It is a world turned upside down. leeway in how they are spent (community develop-
ment grants are an example), and categorical grants,
which are quite restrictive and permit funds to be
The Grant-in-Aid: Foundation of Fiscal used only for narrowly defined uses (e.g., nutrition
Federalism for the elderly). “While the distinction between
The foundation of fiscal federalism is the grant-in- ‘block’ and ‘categorical’ grants is useful, it is impor-
aid, or a conditional monetary gift from one govern- tant to recognize that in practice, the labels represent
ment to another that subsidizes an existing program the ends of a continuum: in the middle range, the
or encourages new ones. two types overlap considerably.”71
Intergovernmental Administration 467

There are, however, more refined distinctions. agencies,76 and thirty-four states maintain offices
Eighty-six percent (a growing share) of all federal in Washington77 (Florida’s Victorian mansion in
grant programs are project, or discretionary, grants, Washington is referred to as its “embassy”). More
or funds that are distributed at the discretion of than 1,400 local governments78 spend about $60
federal administrators. Just 13 percent are formula million annually to hire Washington lobbyists, a
grants,72 which are funds distributed by an adminis- figure that doubled in less than a decade.79 “Of the
tratively or legislatively prescribed formula, and the 250 top-grossing [lobbying] firms in Washington,
federal government pays without limit (unless one is 48 have state, local and tribal governments as their
contained in the formula) according to the formula. leading source of revenue, far more than any other
Though small in share, formula grants disburse a sector.”80
whopping 85 percent of all grant dollars.73 Finally, More recently, states are taking over their own
2 percent of all grants are formula/project grants,74 lobbying in Washington, eschewing the traditional
which are funds awarded at the discretion of federal contracted lobbyists, who have experienced a “sig-
administrators, but within the bounds of a formula, nificant decline” of about a sixth over just four
such as the total amount of dollars that may be years.81 State delegations to Washington are taking
awarded to a state. their place, at least in part, because steadily declin-
ing federal discretionary funds has likely made
Washington less relevant to state needs.82
Getting Theirs: Governments Lobbying
Governments Governments and Agencies Lobbying the State
States and localities have organized themselves— Capitals The states are not spared. “Legislative
and formidably so—as lobbies to assure that federal liaisons” for local governments, state agencies, and
grants continue to flow and that federal policies are other public entities comprise an estimated 25 to
responsive. The same may be said for state grants 35 percent of all lobbyists in the capitals of “most
and policies when local governments lobby. Of states,”83 and they are rapidly growing.84
course, the underwriters of all this intergovernmen- Higher education appears to lobby state gov-
tal lobbying, whether national or state, are the tax- ernments the most intensively; in Michigan, colleges
payers. and universities accounted for over two-fifths of all
the lobbying dollars spent by government agencies
Governments Lobbying Washington The most lobbying, followed by “state departments and agen-
powerful of these national lobbies (which also cies” at less than a fourth.85 Forty-three percent, a
promote more professional governance) are the “Big plurality, of a large sample of Georgia’s legislators
7” public interest groups composed of the Council of thought that their state departments’ lobbyists relied
State Governments, the National Conference of State more on information in making their cases than did
Legislatures, the National Governors Conference, the private-sector lobbyists; just 15 percent thought
International City/County Management Association, otherwise.86
the National Association of Counties, the National
League of Cities, and the U.S. Conference of Mayors,
but there are many more. Federal Grants: Distortions at the Grass
In Congress, states have banded together in Roots
ten regional coalitions representing Appalachia, Over six decades, the federal civilian workforce
the Coast, the Gulf of Mexico, Interstate 69, New remained about the same, but state and local
England, the Northeast and Midwest, the Northern employees roughly tripled, in part due to a growing
Border, the Sunbelt, the Upper Mississippi River reliance on federal grants.87 Such ratios imply, accu-
Basin, and the West. Local interests have formed rately, that federal grants often distort a broad array
caucuses for former mayors, municipal finance, of subnational activities.
ports, rural areas, and urban ones.75
The states spend from $7 million to $10 Governments and Grants: There Is No Free Lunch
million each year lobbying Congress and federal Governmental “gifts” of “free money” cost the
468 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

governments that get them. Beginning in 1911, when grant money is not, or never has been, a factor,
Congress required that some of its modest grants because revenue from other sources frequently fills
be matched by state or local contributions,88 and the void.99 (Simply discontinuing the grant-funded
today more than half of all federal grants programs program when the grant runs out is seldom done.)
and, of greater significance, over three-quarters Often, these new sources are new taxes; federal and
of grant dollars, involve some form of matching state “grants indeed result in future state and local
requirements.89 tax increases of roughly 40 cents for every dollar in
But the heavier price of grant funds is more grant money received in prior years.”100
subtle and profound. Almost fifteen percent of all This costly cycle is known as the flypaper effect,
state and local workers are working for these gov- because dollars stick where grants land.
ernments solely because federal grants pay the equiv- In the states, federal policy-specific grants have
alent of their salaries,90 and these federal “grantee “a much stronger effect” on state policies than does
jobs” grew by 18 percent over twelve years.91 any other financial variable, and funds continue to
stick to a particular policy area “for several years”
Policy Perversities In 1928, when federal grants after the grant money is gone.101
to the states did not attain even 1 percent of state The same holds true at the local level. Grants to
budgets,92 6 percent of state agency heads neverthe- cities have a “positive flypaper effect” in eight out of
less reported that “Federal aid led to National inter- ten policy categories.102
ference in affairs that are the appropriate domain
of the State.”93 In 1974, when federal aid to the Money’s Managerial Monkey Wrench Just as
states accounted for 22 percent of state budgets,94 federal assistance perverts policies at the grass roots,
over four-fifths of these executives bemoaned federal it also mangles management.
intrusion.95 By the close of the 2000s, when federal
funding had reached new lows, just 38 percent of In State Governments During the 1970s, when
state agency heads thought that federal “aid imbal- federal assistance attained record shares of state
ance” was skewing state programs, handily the budgets, governors devoted far more time to
lowest percentage ever recorded in all eight surveys “state-federal” matters than they had during the
taken over thirty-four years (1974–2008). The 1960s,103 and over half of their top administra-
pattern in these “roller coaster” figures is clear: The tors contacted federal personnel monthly, weekly,
more federal funds that states receive, the more likely or even daily.104 Since then, “first and foremost,
that state executives will perceive that they have less the expanded scope of federal aid programs pene-
authority to make state policy.96 trated widely and deeply into administrative enti-
Similar patterns pertain in local governments. ties in state government.”105 In almost every survey
When federal funds were flush, about two-thirds of taken over thirty-four years, “roughly half” of state
municipal administrators and approximately four- agency heads report that “federal aid fosters special
fifths of county managers would have made different ‘semi-exempt’ status” from oversight by the gover-
budgetary—that is, policy—decisions had federal nor, legislature, or both.106
funds not been present.97 Local governments appear It gets worse. Those state governments that are
unable to escape their “consistent dependence” on the most competitively disadvantaged in winning
grants, even though they have diversified their own federal grants also have the weakest managerial
revenue sources and “significantly altered” their capacities—they are the “most in need” but are the
structures for handling grants.98 “least equipped to capture grants.” As a consequence,
they are trapped in an inequitable and malignant
The Flypaper Effect State and local officials cycle of ever-diminishing management capacity.107
would be even more irked than they are about grant
money skewing their policies if they knew that, when In Local Governments The same disruptive admin-
grant funds are spent to support a particular policy, istrative patterns that occur in the states are found
spending for that policy continues at substantially in local governments. A decade after Washington’s
higher levels and for longer periods of time than intergovernmental aid had peaked, and direct federal
Intergovernmental Administration 469

grants as a share of local budgets had been slashed assistance (8 percent,115 much of it for corrections
by two-thirds,108 local officials’ contacts with federal and public housing116).
administrators had fallen off by nearly two-fifths,109
suggesting that intergovernmental funds displace The Sensitive States? State grants-in-aid have
local executives in favor of federal managers. only rarely accounted for less than 30 percent of
total local revenue since 1970—a tribute to the
states’ constancy of purpose.117 A study of 162 large
Those Rascally Recipients! cities found that, from 1977 through 2000, federal
At least some of that “creativity in government,” aid per capita dropped by almost three-fifths, but
noted earlier, which flourishes at the grass roots state aid per capita rose by close to half.118 After
seems be the wile that these governments devote to 2000, however, state support of localities, while still
skirting Washington’s wishes over how its grants increasing, dwindled; from 2000 through 2014, state
are used. intergovernmental revenue to general-purpose local
The states withdraw so much of their own governments and school districts rose by 10 percent,
money from programs supported by federal grants but localities’ taxes and other own-source revenues
that, on average, a program actually receives only increased by 29 percent, after adjusting for infla-
forty more cents for every federal dollar granted to tion.119 Of course, the federal government, through
it. In other words, states effectively skim the equiv- its pass-through grants, plays a large fiscal role in the
alent of 60 percent of federal aid and use it for states’ support, and an estimated two-fifths of all the
purposes other than the feds intended.110 There are intergovernmental revenue that local governments
also less visible ramifications. For instance, grants receive, ostensibly from their state governments, is
awarded in non-election years to Republican gov- actually provided by Washington.120
ernors are more likely to exert a downward pres- Intriguingly, the states also are growing more
sure on tax rates than those awarded to Democratic aware of the financial needs of their more distressed
governors.111 cities (as noted in Chapter 8, twenty-two states keep
Local governments look for loopholes. In close tabs on their localities’ finances), a remark-
general, communities favor using federal funds less able development because, “at a time when central
for social services and poor people, and more for cities are more dependent on their states than ever,
construction projects and muzzling taxes.112 The less there is considerable evidence that their clout in
specific the grant, the more likely that local govern- state legislatures is eroding.”121 State aid to needy
ments will use it for “luxury” services, such as rec- cities is increasingly comparable to federal aid in
reational programs, and the less likely that it will be that it is targeted toward the most distressed areas
spent for “normal” services, such as public safety.113 and poorest people, although federal aid seems to
Federal grants clearly meant for anti-poverty pro- be slightly more focused on meeting the needs of the
grams have been used (quite legally) by local gov- most dysfunctional inner cities.122
ernments to subsidize developers in building luxury
hotels and up-market department stores.114
REGULATORY FEDERALISM
Regulatory federalism is the imposition by govern-
Fiscal Federalism in the States ments of rules and mandates on other governments.
Fiscal federalism flourishes within the states, too.

The Purposes of State Grants States concentrate Ruling Robustly


their grants (including federal pass-through grants) Both the federal and state governments regulate
to local governments on education (67 percent, with their subservient governments with relish.
most going to school districts); welfare (11 percent,
almost all of which goes to counties); general The Feds Regulate Every year: Congress enacts
local government support (6 percent); health and more than eight statutes, on average, that clearly
highways (4 percent each); and “miscellaneous” encroach on subnational governance;123 federal
470 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

courts average more than 3,500 decisions relating to Federal Mandates “There is no universally
over 100 federal laws that affect state and local gov- accepted definition of a federal mandate, and
ernments;124 and federal agencies issue an average surprisingly little consensus on the matter.”133
of about 4,250 “final rules” that apply to state and Accordingly, just how many federal mandates there
local governments, a number that grows by a tenth are is unknown, and counts range from thirty-six134
each year.125 Nearly three out of ten state and local to 439.135
workers are employed solely because federal regu- Three of the four kinds of federal mandates are
lations require their presence, a proportion that is bound in the federal grants system; should a recipient
almost twice that of those grass-roots employees government ignore or violate them, it risks losing its
who are effectively funded by federal grants.126 grants. Crosscutting requirements, found in virtually
all federal grant programs, stipulate compliance with
The States Regulate On average, a fifth of the specific federal policies by all governments receiv-
hundreds of measures introduced each year in ing federal assistance. Partial preemptions deny, in
state legislatures directly affect the authority, pro- limited ways, traditional prerogatives of subnational
cedures,  and finances of local governments,127 jurisdictions because Washington demands that they
with counties bearing the brunt (at least relative adopt federal standards. Crossover sanctions permit
to cities) of state regulation.128 States impose on the federal government to punish a state or commu-
their local governments some 4,300 laws that deal nity by reducing or withdrawing federal aid in one
with more than 200 local functions, and these laws or more programs if its standards are not being sat-
are proliferating.129 Sometimes these regulations isfied in another program.
can be miasmic in detail, and legislatures have been A fourth type of federal mandate, direct orders,
known to legislate the procedures for paving city are instructions from Washington to subnational
sidewalks, the methods for removing local weeds, governments that, if not followed, can result in civil
and the design of county stationery.130 Not sur- or criminal penalties. Direct orders have little to do
prisingly, a survey of “well-placed [local] actors with grants, and involve the constitutionally prob-
in a position to know” found that, “for the most lematic prospect of stand-offs between the federal
part  . . . local jurisdictions, especially cities, have and state governments.136
experienced an erosion of authority at the hands of All four sorts of federal mandates have prolifer-
state governments.”131 ated since 1960, with the greatest growth in crossover
States concentrate on five broad areas of local sanctions and direct orders, “the two most openly
affairs: financial management (described in Chapters coercive” types.137 Federal mandates, however, are
1 and 8); human resources management (reviewed not capricious exercises of power. Many, in fact, are
in Chapter 9); changing local boundaries (explained entirely responsible, such as those mandates that
at the close of this chapter); administrative opera- assure civil rights, and these kinds of mandates are
tions (focusing primarily on the assurance of trans- rarely resisted by the governments on which they are
parent governance), and local elections (all states imposed.138 Indeed, some have been welcomed by
set voter qualifications and registration procedures, subnational officials as improving intergovernmen-
and forty-six impose campaign finance disclosure tal cooperation.139
requirements). Only in the area of elections have
state laws governing localities decreased; the great- The Unfunded Federal Mandates Mess An
est growth in these laws has occurred in human unfunded mandate is a far-reaching intergovernmen-
resources and financial management.132 tal regulation that does not provide the resources to
implement it.
Most Americans believe that the costs of federal
The Mandates Maw mandates should be shared among all governmen-
A mandate is a far-reaching intergovernmental regu- tal levels.140 State and local officials are so upset
lation imposed by one government on another gov- by unfunded federal mandates that they declared
ernment that requires the receiving government to a National Unfunded Mandates Day, and the feds
advance specific goals or meet certain standards. themselves acknowledge that “the nation’s state,
Intergovernmental Administration 471

local, and tribal governments urgently need relief errand,” but their costs are considerable.152 For
from the burdens of unfunded federal mandates.”141 decades, Illinois has imposed, on average, an aston-
“Up to 10 percent of a state’s general fund ishing eight new unfunded mandates per year on
budget goes to filling in gaps in federal unfunded municipalities and more than six per year on school
mandates,”142 costing all the states, on average, districts. Illinois’ unfunded enthusiasms (which are
more than $26 billion (and rising) per year.143 Local a “main driver of high . . . local taxes”) have led to
governments, however, appear to bear the brunt of “some of the top local tax rates in the country.”153
unfunded federal mandates. Implementing just ten The states have tried a variety of methods, some
to twelve of them cost cities and counties 12 percent less cynical than others, to alleviate their impact.
of their local tax revenue.144 Forty-two states require that each state mandate’s
In 1995, Congress passed the Unfunded probable fiscal impact on their local governments be
Mandates Reform Act, which bans any unfunded determined before the legislature imposes them,154
mandate, whether contained in legislation or in and seventeen legislatures purport to reimburse their
agency-issued rules, that costs states, localities, or communities for the costs of implementing their
the private sector $50 million (in 1996 dollars) or mandates, but these reforms are often bypassed
more per year to implement. and have provided scant relief.155 Voters in ten
The act has not been particularly effective. states, however, have ratified constitutional amend-
Congress has passed perhaps as many as eleven ments requiring that any unfunded mandate must
laws,145 and federal agencies have issued at least command a “super-majority” vote, ranging from
one rule,146 that affect state and local governments three-fifths to two-thirds, by state legislators to be
but which violate the act’s unenforceable threshold. enacted, and this has been “the best anti-mandates
Worse, the law’s procedures are so complex that it strategy” to date.156
is extremely difficult for administrators to recognize
that they are inadvertently inserting into their new
rules provisos that “nonfederal parties . . . might per- The Wreckage of Regulatory Federalism
ceive as unfunded mandates.” In fact, more than half Just as intergovernmental regulations are proliferat-
(sixty-five) of all 113 “final major rules” issued by ing, so are their costs, both budgetary and preemp-
federal agencies over two years “had not triggered” tory.
the act.147
Budgetary Burdens The many estimates of the
State Mandates The states also mandate, and growing weight of “federal actions,” notably regula-
these mandates matter—more so, apparently, than tions, on state and local governments range “from 2
federal ones. City managers report that state “man- to 3 percent” of their annual budgets “to 20 percent
dates/policies” influence their decision making nearly or more,” costs that could become “a serious chal-
twice as forcefully as federal ones,148 but this influ- lenge to federalism.”157
ence appears to be entirely negative. “In none of the For local governments, stewing at the bottom
[twelve] policy areas do city managers perceive the of the federal hierarchy, the regulatory costs foisted
impact of state mandates [imposed over ten years] as on them by both the federal and state governments
positive; all the mean scores are negative.”149 can be crushing. “From a range of studies, it appears
Wealthy states with intense partisan compe- localities dedicate anywhere from 20 percent to 90
tition and excellent public administration,150 and percent of their expenditures” to implementing both
where local governments dominate state finances federal and state rules and mandates.158
(that is, when they account for more than half of
all state and local tax revenue),151 impose the most Preempting Power at the Grass Roots Over the
mandates on their local governments. course of the 214 years that had elapsed since 1790,
Congress enacted 520 laws that substituted national
The Unfunded State Mandates Mess Determining policies for state and local ones, or prohibited states
the fiscal burden of unfunded state mandates on and communities from exercising powers that had
local governments has been described as a “fool’s previously been theirs. Seventy percent of these laws
472 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

were passed after 1960, and “will likely continue to rulemaking activities.” Of 11,414 final intergovern-
grow.” This “dangerous trend” has broadened from mental rules issued by federal agencies over thirty-
a traditional concentration on interstate commerce three months, a whopping total of five contained a
to health, banking, civil rights, and the environment, legally required assessment of their impact on sub-
and “has already caused a significant shift in the national governments.167
balance of powers and responsibilities that substi- In the states, the Great Recession induced many
tutes subnational self-determination with federal legislatures to lift regulations on their local govern-
will.”159 ments and endow them with new powers, particu-
larly revenue raising powers, a trend that has been
Federal Preemption of State and Local Power In hailed as “Fend-for-Yourself Localism.”168 Thirty-
the states, nearly nine out of ten governors think one percent of city managers report “substantial
that Washington has taken over responsibilities that devolution” of municipal finance (only 19 percent
more appropriately belong to the states;160 seven report “no devolution”) by the states over the
out of ten state agency heads believe that “federal preceding ten years.169
involvement” in their agencies’ policies is moderate Most local officials report that, when the state
to high;161 and large majorities or pluralities of state allows them to raise their own revenue, their govern-
officials report that federal agencies have overridden ments’ fiscal health improves substantially, and they
state decisions and prevented their states from pur- are convinced that fiscal autonomy is “the solution
suing preferred policies “several times.”162 to many of the problems that municipalities face.”170
Perhaps three-quarters of federal intergovern- Unfortunately, 66 percent of city managers state
mental regulations apply only to local governments that they have less authority in financial administra-
or directly affect local governments through the tion, and this was the most negative response in the
states.163 Two-fifths of local officeholders believe survey.171
that Washington plays “an inappropriate role” in
their affairs, and half think that the feds microman-
age their “unrealistic” regulations.164 MONEY, MANDATES, AND
State Preemption of Local Power State regulations WASHINGTON: NOW WHAT?
prod similar reactions from local officials. Nearly three-fifths of Americans believe that
Sixty-four percent of city managers think that Washington “is interfering too much in state and
state laws enacted over ten years are “frequently local matters,” an increase of almost a fifth over
intrusive or preemptive of city government powers close to a half-century.172 Are they right?
or authority,” and more than half report that Probably.
“states have frequently encroached into their terrain
through such actions as mandates, cost shifting, and
raids on local government revenues.”165 Washington’s Intergovernmental Role:
More than nine out of ten county officeholders One Fine Mess after Another
say that the responsibilities of their governments The federal government’s role in intergovernmen-
have increased markedly, but not even a third of tal relations is not merely, in Oliver Hardy’s (of
them think that they have been granted adequate Laurel and Hardy) memorable phrase, “another fine
authority by their states to execute their duties.166 mess,” but several fine messes. To some degree, this
is understandable. The tenfold increase, adjusted for
inflation, over a half century in federal grant dollars
Deregulating Regulatory Federalism? to subnational governments, cited earlier, created
During the 1980s and 1990s, Congress enacted four “greater diversity and complexity in federal grants
laws, and the president issued a couple of executive management.”173
orders, that were designed, at least in part, to provide
regulatory relief to the grass-roots governments. Another Fine Fiscal Mess That said, federal (and
These efforts have had “little effect on agencies’ state and local) management of federal grant dollars
Intergovernmental Administration 473

is shaky. In separate audits covering three different inconsistencies. Environmental policy, for instance,
years, a total of nearly $2.8 billion was found lan- long has been characterized by less money, more
guishing in hundreds of expired—but still open— mandates, and more administrative waivers than
federal grants’ accounts that should have been education and healthcare policies; these inconsisten-
disbursed to thousands of designated recipients. cies correlate with heavier litigation for environmen-
Nearly $10 million had lain peacefully unspent for tal policies than for the other two.179
ten years or more.174 In 2011, in an effort to clean This manic mix of managerial rigidities and
up unspent dollars, the Office of Management and flexibilities has compounded “local problems such as
Budget replaced two boards with a new Council on fiscal inequities and administrative inefficiencies. . ..
Financial Assistance Reform. Although, three years flawed the system of grantee accountability. . ..
later, the number of expired accounts was decreasing, limited the imposition of federal sanctions regarding
the undisbursed money in them was increasing.175 grant performance and fraud . . . [and] have further
Cities in particular have problems spending complicated the ability of both states and localities
federal grants, and it is estimated that cities fail to to adapt to changes in requirements.” These prob-
spend from 9 to 20 percent of allocated grant money lems “have plagued federal grant programming for
in any given year. These lapses are attributed to the last several decades.”180
local “bureaucratic dysfunction or even corruption,”
flawed program design, poorly managed closeouts of The Fragmentation of Federal Grants These
accounts, and a local lack of capacity. But, if Detroit inconsistent policies have contributed to the severe
is any example, these defects can be overcome. fragmentation of the grants themselves, and only
“Once the poster child for ineffective grants man- sporadic efforts have been made to reduce that frag-
agement [in 2013, “every federal grant dollar the mentation.
city received—more than $200 million—was poten- Three-fourths of all grant programs administer
tially at risk of being clawed back” by Washington], less than 2 percent of all grant dollars, and a fifth of
Detroit is now the model for other communities,” all programs are responsible for less than 1 percent of
with less than a quarter of a million dollars “at risk” all dollars. This is intergovernmental fragmentation
in 2015; putting zero federal dollars at risk seems of a rare order. To their credit, federal officials have
likely in the not-too-distant future. Detroit accom- attempted to address the implications of grants frag-
plished this turnaround by investing in information mentation, but these efforts, extending over eighty
technology and a chief development officer.176 years, have largely come to naught, largely because
In addition to no payments, improper pay- of congressional resistance.181 Although “there is no
ments, explained in Chapter 6, concentrate in the authoritative, accurate tally of enacted grant program
federal grant system; five of the ten federal programs consolidations. . .. [and] no commonly accepted
that account for 94 percent of all the dollars lost to definition of what constitutes a grant program con-
improper payments (or $118 billion) are intergovern- solidation,” the Government  Accountability Office
mental grant programs. These five programs alone “identified from  a variety of sources” just fifteen
are responsible for 38 percent of that $118 billion.177 grants that  had been consolidated over thirteen
years.182
Another Fine Managerial Mess As the fiscal mess
suggests, there are some serious problems in federal Unknown Administrative Costs Even though
grants management. For starters: federal officials there are indications that most, if not all, granting
themselves admit that “few executive branch agen- agencies have “mechanisms in place to capture the
cies regularly conduct in-depth program evaluations administrative costs charged to their grant pro-
to assess their [grant] programs’ impact.”178 grams,” it appears that the costs “reported to the
Why is this? federal government understate the actual cost to
administer a grant program.” Or those reports may
Inconsistent Intergovernmental Policies Perhaps bear little relationship with reality because agencies
the overarching problem is that federal intergov- define these costs differently, so “different programs
ernmental policies are fraught with administrative may treat similar costs differently,” resulting in “a
474 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

program with high administrative costs [that] may 85 percent of all grant dollars and 61 percent of all
not be less efficient than a program with low admin- grant programs, were “significantly involved in man-
istrative costs.” aging grants.”187
In addition, many grant programs impose caps
on administrative costs; the sole examination of these Another Fine Judicial Mess Adding to the incon-
caps found that five out of six programs had them, sistencies that permeate federal intergovernmental
ranging, remarkably, from 5 to 26 percent of the policies and administration are inconsistencies that
grant. Because no one seems to agree on just what pervade the federal courts.
comprises administrative costs in the first place, the In policy matters, the judiciary generally shuns
cost caps are largely meaningless and “can make some invoking an overarching intergovernmental princi-
programs look more administratively expensive than ple, and instead tailors its rulings to the policy in
others,” but, in actuality, might be less expensive.183 question, typically supporting Washington in educa-
tion and environmental policies, but tilting toward
Grants, Taxes, and Corruption Regrettably, the the states and communities in healthcare.188
factors just discussed likely have added to the loss Of greater significance, the Supreme Court has
of billions of grant dollars that are sent to tax cheats addressed the federal government’s relations with
who exploit federal confidentiality policies about the states in confusing ways. In 1995, in United
personal tax data. States v. Lopez, the Court, for the first time since
More than 1,200 income-tax-exempt organiza- 1935, limited six decades of its own constitutional
tions that owe Washington around $70 million in interpretations, which had uniformly and vastly
unpaid payroll taxes were awarded $14 billion in extended the reach of the Constitution’s Commerce
direct federal grants.184 Some 39,000 recipients of Clause, and held that the clause could be invoked
$124 billion in federal grants, or 4 percent of those justifiably only when one of three factors was
recipients who directly received just a fifth of all present: instrumentalities of commerce; use or chan-
federal grant dollars, owe $790 million in federal nels of commerce; and activities that substantially
taxes.185 More than 27,000 healthcare providers affect interstate commerce.
who collect federal payments from Medicare, the For the next seven years, however, the Court
healthcare program for the elderly, or 6 percent courted consistency. Lopez was followed by nine
of all such providers, owe more than $2 billion in five-to-four rulings, all made by the same five jus-
federal back taxes.186 tices, who displayed a remarkable “determination
In each of these cases, the tax sums owed were to reconfigure the balance between state and federal
“understated.” Samplings of these scofflaws deter- authority in favor of the states.”189 In five of these
mined that from more than half to over four-fifths decisions, the Court ruled that, because the states
had not disclosed that they owed back taxes when have “sovereign immunity” (a phrase not to be
they applied for their grants, a clear violation of found in the Constitution), states cannot be sued in
federal law and an equally clear indicator of their federal or state courts, rulings that adversely affected
criminal motivation. business owners, state employees, federal agencies,
women, minorities, and the disabled. In 2006, the
Grants Management: A Renewed Federal Focus In Court held that local governments, unlike state gov-
an effort to improve grants administration, the ernments, could be sued.190
Office of Personnel Management created, in 2010, a From 2003 to 2012, the Court shuffled and
new position titled “grants management specialist.” muffled. In three cases, it seemed to reassert some
Two years later, there were 1,414 of these special- federal power over the states,191 and in one it favored
ists working in seventeen of the twenty-two grant- state sovereignty.192
making agencies surveyed; 52 percent, however, In 2012, the Court rendered an important ruling
were in a single department, and “more than half” about federalism in its controversial healthcare
of the agencies made only “limited or no use” of decision that may not be fully appreciated. It held
the specialists. Another 5,100-plus employees in that the Commerce Clause did not justify penaliz-
four departments, however, which accounted for ing an inactivity (in this instance, not buying health
Intergovernmental Administration 475

insurance), a decision that is expected to markedly welfare for the most impoverished Americans,
restrain congressional power.193 research and development, central information gath-
If there is an iota of judicial consistency in this ering, and interstate highways.205
fine mess, it may be that “the Court has moved not Areas that make sense to share between the
so much to grant more power to the states as to federal and state governments are environmental
prune back the power of Congress.”194 and natural resources programs and higher edu-
cation; student grants and loans should be mostly
a federal responsibility, and managing campuses
The Capable States should be a state one.206
The states’ competence has increased markedly since A strong argument can be made for a broad-
the mid-twentieth century, when the states were con- based federal tax on consumption and additional
demned as “the tawdriest, most incompetent, most taxes, the proceeds of which should be shared with
stultifying unit in the nation’s political structure.”195 the states.207
State governments now boast “progressive adminis- States should be “clearly in charge” of those
trative results that border on the revolutionary.”196 areas that require tailoring and adapting to local
State governments are measurably more com- conditions—notably skills training, housing, child-
petent than they were in the early 1980s.197 A peri- care, infrastructures, rural services, and economic
odic  “report card” on state management accords development. Whether the states wish to support
all the states an average grade of “B minus,”198 a these programs is the states’ call: “federal programs
grade that puts state governments on a par with the in these areas are devolved to the states or just wither
nation’s thirty-five largest and wealthiest cities,199 away.”208
and is slightly higher than that of forty similar Local governments should have primary respon-
counties.200 sibility for roads, sanitation, and public safety.209
As the states’ capabilities improved, they simul- Authorities disagree about elementary and second-
taneously assumed greater responsibilities. The ary education, with some holding that it should be
number of different “common administrative agen- a largely local affair,210 and others arguing that it
cies” in the states, each with a unique policy mission, should be entirely a state responsibility.211
has more than doubled since 1959, and now aver-
ages 111 per state. State governments are the largest Who Should Do What? Citizens’ Views Citizens
single employer in most states,201 and they “were largely concur with the experts. Most Americans
a key force in the growth of the national and local agree that Washington should “take the lead” in
governments” during the final half of the twentieth managing healthcare and environmental protection,
century.202 and that the states lead in the delivery of education
and economic development. A plurality of people
differ, if marginally, with the experts only in their
Sorting Out Federalism: Who Should Do belief that the states, rather than Washington, should
What? manage anti-poverty programs.
The question of which levels of government should “The American public has very reasonable and
be responsible for what areas of public policy has consistent ideas about the policy responsibilities of
consumed scholars and policymakers since at least the national, state, and local governments.”212
1940.203 Surprisingly, perhaps, the views of experts,
citizens, and public officials are mostly in harmony. Who Is Doing What? Is any of this near-universal
agreement between scholars and citizens reflected in
Who Should Do What: Experts’ Views By far the which governmental levels actually do what?
greatest budgetary burden on the states is healthcare, Happily, yes. Federal, state, and local budgets
described in Chapter 8. It makes sense for the federal largely correspond with public administrationists’
government to relieve the states of this responsibil- advice and Americans’ preferences about which gov-
ity, and fully take it over.204 Other areas that ration- ernments should do what across nineteen different
ally should be retained as federal functions include policy areas.
476 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

“Public preferences about the national gov-


ernment’s role in specific policy areas are mir- Interstate Cooperation
rored  very  closely by the national government’s Because the Constitution requires that “full faith and
actual [budgetary] commitment in each of these credit shall be given in each state to the public acts,
areas,” and, for nine of these areas, the percentages records, and judicial proceedings of every state,”
of public opinion and federal spending are almost four devices of interstate cooperation have emerged
identical. that are designed to solve their common problems.
Although state and local spending’s correlations
with the public’s preferences are not quite as crisp Interstate Compacts and Commissions The grand-
as is federal spending’s, “the distribution of citizen daddy of interstate cooperation is the interstate
preferences [still] conforms closely to the relative compact, which is a formal agreement between two
efforts of the various governmental levels within the or more states that normally requires congressional
respective policy areas.”213 approval. The first interstate compact was the Treaty
of Beaufort, signed by Georgia and South Carolina
to resolve a boundary question; signed in 1787, it is
A Federal Reset? still in effect.
Without doubt, Washington continues “to hold There are more than 200 interstate compacts in
much of the power and significance” that, beginning operation, but only thirty-six were agreed to during
in the 1930s, it gained over state and local govern- the nation’s first 131 years, so states evidently are
ments,214 but a reset may be in the offing. finding them increasingly useful. The typical state
In 2009, President Barack Obama, “the first has entered into twenty-five of them, spawning 116
genuine big-city president the country has had for interstate commissions to enforce their provisions in
nearly a century,”215 created an Office of Urban education, rivers, and energy, among other fields.216
Affairs and an Office of Intergovernmental Affairs,
and placed both in the White House. He initiated Uniform State Laws Uniform state laws are vir-
a concerted and continuing effort to assist them in tually identical statutes that have been enacted in
their management of federal grants. The president two or more states, often in an attempt to preempt
also lightened the feds’ heavy regulatory hand in national legislation that could deepen the federal
grass-roots’ administration and policymaking, and, government’s involvement in state affairs. The
as noted, poured federal money into states and National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform
localities. State Laws, founded in 1892 and funded by the
Washington accomplished much of this through states, coordinates the process. States that have a
the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of low level of administrative capability favor enacting
2009, which not only pumped more than a third of uniform laws.217
the new funding (about $800 billion) into federal
grants to, or through, the states, but also established National and Regional Associations Beginning
a Recovery Accountability and Transparency Board in the nineteenth century, state governments,
that functioned as central point of contact. The and passels of their politicians and profession-
board and other innovations greatly improved rela- als, founded dozens of national organizations to
tions between the federal government and the grass exchange good-governing ideas among themselves.
roots. Thirty-three states formed three interstate organiza-
tions that promote regional interests. In 1972, the
thirteen-state Southern Growth Policies Board was
FEDERALISM AMONG EQUALS: founded; in 1976, seven states created the Coalition
of Northeastern Governors; and, in 1977, thirteen
THE STATES states formed the Western Governors’ Policy Office.
If the semi-sovereign states occasionally verge on
being “humble suppliants” of Washington, they can Multistate Legal Actions The newest wrinkle in
be Nordic gods when dealing with each other. interstate cooperation is multistate legal actions,
Intergovernmental Administration 477

which refer to states, working through the National psychotics that occurred in cities where they had
Association of Attorneys General, entering into law- de-bused. Some recipient cities sued, and the hospi-
suits with other states against a common adversary, tal lost its national accreditation.
such as the tobacco industry. Larger states with a
high level of administrative capacity favor their
use.218 These litigations are increasingly broadly- INTERGOVERNMENTAL
based; in more than two-fifths of multistate legal
actions initiated since 2000, more than half of the ADMINISTRATION IN THE STATES
states’ attorneys general have been involved.219 The states deal with each other as equals, but their
relationships with their local governments are quite
different.
Interstate Conflict
Despite these manifold methods of interstate co-
operation, all is not happy in the realm of the Creatures of the State
American states. Water wars are rife among many The Supreme Court first addressed the federal place
states. Thirty-nine states impose some sort of sev- of local governments in 1845, holding in Maryland
erance tax—that is, a tariff on natural resources v. Baltimore and Ohio Railroad that “counties are
exported to other states. Other exports are tax free, nothing more than certain portions of the territory
such as air pollution belching from coal-burning into which the state is divided for more convenient
power plants in the Rust Belt and Appalachia, exercise of the powers of the government,” and, in
causing Northeastern states to file suits and petition 1907, the Court ruled in Hunter v. City of Pittsburgh
federal agencies for decades. that a state legislature could decide municipal
Kansas and Missouri have long battled with one boundaries as it saw fit, regardless of the preferences
another in offering hundreds of millions of dollars in of affected residents.
tax breaks to out-of-state businesses in their effort to Both of these landmark cases cast local govern-
lure them to their respective Kansas Cit(ies), which ments as “creatures of the state,” a phrase given to us
are separated by only the states’ line; the “Kansas in 1868 by Judge John F. Dillon of the Iowa supreme
City Border War” has not benefitted either city. court, and which is now known as “Dillon’s rule.”
Other unwanted exports are more personal. Judge Dillon held that local governments have no
South Dakota, for example, gave ninety-three people independence beyond what the state grants them,
charged with felonies the choice of facing prosecu- and no justice has questioned him.
tion or moving to California; all ninety-three hustled
off to the Golden State. Kentucky established a
program for moving its most impoverished denizens The Insidious Introduction of Home Rule
to wealthier areas—including to wealthier states. Despite the powerful presence of Dillon’s rule, local
Hawaii, which contracts with private prisons—in governments gradually have accreted for themselves
eight other states—to house its excess prisoners, home rule, or all forms of local or regional self-
implemented a pilot program to move its homeless governance.
(at least those who volunteered) to other states. (The Missouri gave home rule its start when, in 1875,
homeless would voluntarily leave Hawaii? Really?) it adopted a constitution that delegated to St. Louis
Perhaps the most egregious example in this a power that, until that year, had been the exclusive
regard occurred in Nevada. Over five years, Nevada’s prerogative of the state legislature: “the power to
primary state psychiatric hospital bused more than make a charter.” Charters typically permit localities
1,500 of its mentally ill patients to every state in the to choose their own form of government.
continental United States, but not to those states’ Forty-one state constitutions grant home rule to
psychiatric facilities; it just dumped them in bus ter- their local governments. An additional seven states
minals. More than fifty of these patients were facing grant “limited” home rule, which usually means
criminal charges in Nevada, and there were dozens that home rule is granted by statute, and localities
of crimes, including violent ones, attributed to these must apply to the legislature for it, or that some
478 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

types of local governments are excluded from home as “centralized,” but today a third—sixteen— are. In
rule; Congress authorizes limited home rule for the 1902, all states were “decentralized,” but, by 1977,
District of Columbia.220 none were. Larger states tend to be more decentral-
California, in 1911, was the first state to grant ized, and smaller states are more centralized.230
home rule to its counties. Thirty-six states offer home
rule to their counties,221 and twenty-three of these
offer the option of charters.222 Seventy-eight percent INTERGOVERNMENTAL
of all counties report that “their source of authority ADMINISTRATION AMONG LOCAL
for the structure of government is state law,” and just
9 percent of those counties with a charter option have GOVERNMENTS
charter governments.223 Relative to other governmen- Local intergovernmental administration is distin-
tal forms, charter-form counties meet the needs of guished by its uniquely intense collaboration.
their residents more directly; offer greater flexibility
to county administrators in selecting revenue sources,
choosing which services to provide, and more ways to Local Collaboration and Service Delivery
deal with fiscal stress;224 and are more innovative.225 In 1954, the newly-founded city of Lakewood,
California, contracted with Los Angeles County
and some special districts to provide a plethora of
A Steadier Helping Hand public services in the new city. “The City without a
Although, as we noted earlier, local government Payroll,” as it became known because it had so few
managers typically are deeply resentful about what employees, was the progenitor of the “Lakewood
they perceive as unwarranted state interference, there Plan.” Its impact was profound in California, where
are some positives. Besides providing their localities today 80 percent of the state’s newly-incorporated
with steady fiscal support (at least when compared municipalities adopt the plan,231 but Lakewood’s
with federal support), all the states furnish them with influence extended across the nation as well.
expertise in the form of departments of community
affairs. Thirteen states have enacted laws to control Interlocal Service Contracts More than half of
urban sprawl, which have proven to be modestly America’s general-purpose,232 and many special-
successful,226 and, as we noted in Chapter 8, twenty purpose, local governments enter into interlocal
states have adopted formal procedures for helping service contracts, which occur when a local gov-
local governments in fiscal stress (although “local ernment contracts with and pays one or more other
officials often resent state officials” who infringe local governments to deliver services to its residents.
on their finances, no matter how tattered227), and Almost 24 percent of all city and county services,
twenty-nine states do so for school districts. led by workforce development and job training pro-
State and local departments collaborate, too, grams (nearly two-thirds of them), are delivered “by
particularly when local budgets are small and local another government or entity” (an entity, presum-
“professional incentives” (most notably, perfor- ably, such as a public authority), a proportion that
mance assessments that stress employees’ inter- is growing over time;233 thirty years earlier, “other
agency collaboration) are prominent.228 governments and authorities” delivered 13 percent
“The states have been roundly and soundly of services.234 Their use handily tops every other
chastised for their neglect of urban distress and form of local government service delivery, each one
decline. . .. Yet a balanced view . . . shows the states of which, with the sole exception of local services
on record as taking numerous and varied urban- delivered by nonprofits, is in decline (details are in
oriented policy initiatives.”229 Chapter 11).
Local officials rely almost exclusively on “infor-
mal discussions” to enforce these arrangements,
A Slow Centralization of State Power but the “perceived effectiveness [of these discus-
Overall, there has been a steady, if slow, centraliza- sions] diminishes with the length of the contract.”235
tion of state power. In 1932, no state was categorized Understandably, local administrators prefer “not
Intergovernmental Administration 479

to use other governments for services that require Cost Savings Saving money is the leading reason
extensive monitoring.”236 why local officials enter into interlocal service
Besides interlocal service contracts, there are at arrangements, with 81 percent citing it.242
least three additional ways that local governments
collaborate in delivering services. Economies of Scale Coming in second to savings
is the similar, “achieving economies of scale,” with 70
Joint Service Agreements A joint service agree- percent of cities and counties citing it.243 Economy
ment is the cooperative delivery by two or more of scale has long been a singular prod. More than
governments of a local service to the residents of the thirty years ago, it was the reason “cited almost
participating jurisdictions. More than half of local overwhelmingly in all service categories by both
governments deliver services jointly, led by libraries cities and counties” to enter into interlocal service
and public safety communication.237 arrangements of all types.244

Shared Service Agreements A shared service Opportunities to Collaborate The third-ranking


agreement is the consolidation of functions (support motivator for working with other governments is
services, led by information technology and pur- the strengthening of “collaborative intergovernmen-
chasing, are favored) “from several agencies into tal relations,” cited by 62 percent of local manag-
a single, stand-alone entity.” Public administrators ers,245 a motive that has been strongly cited by local
find that their most bountiful benefits are improved administrators for more than three decades.246
and standardized services and increased collabora-
tion, but not cost savings.238 It appears that the main Greater Local Benefits We observed in Chapter
barrier to sharing services is some governments’ con- 11 that when local governments contract with the
cerns that the approach could lead to a loss in local private and nonprofit sectors to deliver services,
identity.239 those sectors’ efficiency, effectiveness, and equitable-
ness in providing them are either “statistically insig-
Intergovernmental Service Transfers An inter- nificant” or “negative and significant.”247
governmental service transfer is “the permanent The opposite holds true when local governments
transfer of total responsibility for the provision of partner with one another to provide services. “Public-
a service from one governmental unit to another.” public partnerships outperform their sectoral cousins
Forty percent of cities and counties have transferred across all three dimensions of performance” (i.e., effi-
services, and 34 percent of cities and counties have ciency, effectiveness, and equity), and this is the case
received such transfers. Sanitation services are trans- “even when controlling for past performance, service
ferred most frequently.240 expenditure, and organizational environments.”248
Local officials apparently understand and appreciate
A Future of Growth All of these sorts of local col- this reality: not only do they use interlocal agree-
laboration in delivering services will likely grow. ments more than any other contractual or collabo-
At least forty-two state legislatures, an expanding rative system of service provision, but three-fifths of
number, have authorized their local governments them believe that interlocal cooperation promotes
to deliver their services through interlocal service “higher quality/more effective service delivery.”249
arrangements.241

The Context of Collaboration


Motivations to Collaborate In addition to officials’ motivations to collaborate,
Local officials cite a host of reasons underlying their local governments face certain contextual conditions
decision to cooperate with other localities in deliv- that can increase, or decrease, their propensity to
ering their services, but, in contrast to their dealings cooperate with one another.
with the private sector, in which commerce and com-
petition are key, community and collaboration are Public Poverty As we explained in Chapter 11,
crucial when dealing with each other. those local governments that privatize the most are
480 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

wealthier governments, but the opposite is true for “suggesting that governments view other govern-
interlocal service arrangements, which are favored by ments as trusted contract vendors.”261
poorer governments250 and those that shoulder large
debt.251
Concerns over Collaboration: Community
Heavy Responsibilities Localities that have Counts
assumed responsibility for delivering new services,252 Whereas the leading obstacles for contracting out
and which are burdened with many service duties services to the private sector is employees’ and pol-
and employees,253 correlate with a greater willing- iticians’ opposition, the chief impediment for con-
ness to enter into cooperative arrangements. tracting with other governments is a “concern about
loss of community control,” a worry cited by 69
Restrictive State Policies In those states that have percent of local officials, followed by the closely
made municipal annexation more difficult, imposed related “lack of a common vision, shared mission,”
local revenue limitations, and curtailed the creation at 46 percent, and a “lack of trust,” at 43 percent.
of new local governments, especially special dis- “Internal opposition from elected officials” ranks
tricts, there is a much higher probability that their fourth, at 38 percent, and “internal opposition
local governments will cooperate with each other in from employees” hobbles in at a distant fifth, at 29
funding and providing local services.254 percent.262

Professionalism The local manager who is most


likely to collaborate with other governments in Recurring Regionalism
delivering services: networks extensively in regional In light of local officials’ commitment to expanding
associations of governments255 (the smaller the economies of scale, it is not surprising that there is
association, the likelier it is that the manager’s gov- a long history of efforts to establish regional gov-
ernment will participate256); is professionally well ernance within the states. Most of these early exer-
connected; has a master of public administration tions came not from local governments, but from
degree; shares “a common set of professional norms” Washington.
with colleagues in other governments;257 possesses
“specific managerial skills”; and leads a “high- Washington and Regional Governance Congress
capacity” agency.258 City managers who harbor entered this thicket in 1933, when it established
abnormally high levels of professional ambition are the National Planning Board, which, by 1936, had
more likely to sell their city’s services to other local formed planning agencies in every state except
governments, but are much less likely buy services Delaware. This period of “regional reform and plan-
from other jurisdictions.259 ning was the most ambitious in U.S. history.”263
Congress disbanded the board in 1943.
Trust Me Trust plays a part, too, and a large part. Congress re-entered regional planning in 1959,
Local administrators simply have greater with an amendment to Section 701 of the Housing
confidence in the “faithfulness and honesty” Act of 1954, which channeled, over twenty-three
of their colleagues in other local governments years, more than $200 million in “701 planning
than they have in  prospective contractors in the funds” to state, regional, and local planning agencies.
private and nonprofit sectors. This trust intensi- Of even greater significance, however, was the
fies when  those  colleagues have good reputations, issuance of OMB Circular A-95, in 1969, which
strong community  ties, and excellent performance established regional Councils of Government within
records.260 the states as gatekeepers for federal planning grants.
Local governments are much more likely to con- Between the mid-1960s and mid-1970s, these grants
tract out to other governments those services that burgeoned from nine to 160,264 and Councils of
have high risks for “opportunism leading to contract Government rocketed from fewer than fifty in the
failure,” and are much less likely to outsource high- mid-1950s to 669 by 1976.265 By the mid-1970s,
risk services to private or nonprofit organizations, federal regulations and legislation had created some
Intergovernmental Administration 481

2,000 regional policy and planning bodies,266 includ- Fifty-six percent of all intergovernmental service
ing not only Councils of Government, but also inter- contracts let by cities are awarded to counties, which
governmental groupings that specialized in solid also are the principal providers for more than half of
waste disposal, economic development, air quality, all services that are delivered through joint service
disaster assistance, ground transportation, airports, agreements.277
the elderly, crime, or health, among other areas. Of greater significance, larger local governments
are permanently taking over the traditional duties
The Great Washington Walk-Away In 1982, of smaller ones, and at the request of those govern-
Congress abruptly terminated its 701 planning ments. Two-thirds of cities and counties with popu-
funds, and President Ronald Reagan’s Executive lations of at least 250,000 receive intergovernmental
Order 12372 eliminated OMB Circular A-95. service transfers, compared with less than a fifth of
Both actions reduced by roughly a fifth the local jurisdictions with fewer than 10,000 people.278
number of Councils of Government to about Fifty-four percent of all intergovernmental service
500,267 and those that survived cut their staffs and transfers from cities go to counties, and 14 percent
the federal grant dollars that they administered by (the next highest) to regional organizations of gov-
approximately a third.268 Although Congress still ernments.279 These trends have persisted for at least
remains the largest single revenue source for the five decades.280
typical Council of Government, followed by state
grants and membership dues,269 federal support is
at least a third less than it was before 1982.270 A PLACE, PEOPLE, AND POWER:
decade following the great Washington walk-away, THE PUZZLE OF METROPOLITAN
ten states had discarded intra-state regional plan-
ning altogether.271 GOVERNANCE
A vexing question facing urban regions is that of
The Reduced Role of Councils of Government matching their public’s problems with the appropri-
Today, most Councils of Government engage in a ate scope, jurisdiction, functions, and even number
“dual planning and service role,” focusing on eco- of governments that would deal most efficiently and
nomic development, transportation, solid waste, and fairly with those problems. What is the best way, in
land use. From a third to a half of these councils other words, of reconciling area with power?
directly deliver these and other services to regional No question is more critical—and wholly
residents.272 unique—to public administration than is this one.
Increasingly, Councils of Government are
being challenged by “other entities seeking regional
authority,”273 most forcefully by corporate alliances The City: In Sickness and in Health
with regional agendas that work closely with local The populations of almost all central cities are
governments.274 Council heads report, tellingly, that shrinking, and this has grave implications for not
“most key decisions in their regions are made outside only them, but also for their surrounding regions.
of their councils,”275 and they are “somewhat tenta-
tive about the future of their councils as dominant Urban Hemorrhaging In just forty years (1950–
regional structures.”276 1990), the population density of the nation’s 522
largest central cities plummeted, on average, by an
astounding 50 percent.281 These cities lost their citi-
Consolidating and Centralizing Local zens almost entirely to their surrounding suburbs. In
Services 1950, slightly less than 70 percent of Americans in
Just as Washington has co-opted state and local the major metropolises lived in their central cities; by
authority, and just as state governments are central- 2010, nearly 68 percent dwelt in their suburbs, and a
izing power over their local jurisdictions, larger local plurality of jobs were in the outer suburbs as well.282
governments are taking over the responsibilities of When cities are thinly populated relative to their
smaller ones. suburbs, the consequences are not good.
482 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Urbs, ’Burbs, and Economics Of greatest signif- areas cover a fifth of America’s land290 and contain
icance, any jurisdiction that loses population also more than four-fifths of its people.291 Over the past
loses wealth. Average per capita income in the seven decades, their number nearly tripled to 381.292
cities, which had been somewhat higher than in the About two-fifths of all local governments
suburbs, began to decline in 1960, and, by 1990, (and two-fifths of all municipalities) are found in
had hit 85 percent of what suburbanites earned, metro areas, nearly a quadrupling over fifty years,
where it has remained ever since.283 Moreover, 74 and today these areas contain an average of more
percent of the nation’s people living in concentrated than 100 local governments. Allegheny County
areas of poverty—that is, poor people clustered (Pittsburgh), Pennsylvania, may hold the record,
in very impoverished places—are in the big cities, with a staggering 323 “governmental units” of all
although the suburbs’ share is growing over time.284 types.293 These governments govern few citizens—
Increasingly, metropolises are segregated less by fewer than 6,000, on average.294
race, and more by income.285 Focusing only on the proliferating number of
little local jurisdictions in metro areas does not do
Stanching the Bleeding: Diversity and Elasticity justice to their confusing and overlapping nature.
To stanch urban hemorrhaging, both in population More than six out of ten Americans are governed,
and in wealth, cities must grow. To grow, cities must and taxed, by two or more layers of the nation’s
be diverse and elastic. 38,917 general-purpose local governments. In thirty-
The fastest-growing cities are those that draw eight states, citizens are governed and taxed by up
people from all racial groups,286 so it follows that it to two layers of these governments simultaneously,
is in the cities’ self-interest to cultivate diversity. and, in ten states, some residents are governed and
Elasticity is a city’s ability to grow by in-filling taxed by three layers of them!295
vacant areas with people, or by expanding its These counts do not include America’s 50,088
boundaries to include people living in its suburbs, or special-purpose governments, which also tax or
both. “The first law of urban dynamics” is that “only charge fees for services. Residents of metro areas
elastic cities grow,” both in population and terri- fall under the jurisdiction of a half-dozen or more
tory.287 Inelastic cities lose population. Compared of the country’s 37,204 special districts, a figure that
with elastic cities, inelastic cities are older and excludes its 12,884 independent school districts.296
poorer; more racially and economically segregated; The boundaries of at least two-fifths of special dis-
less educated; less prudently managed and fiscally tricts, and two-thirds of school districts, are not
viable; less able to adjust to economic change; enjoy coterminous with those of general-purpose local
faster non-factory (e.g., service jobs) job creation; governments, and meander over them or within
and are less effective in advancing the prosperity of them.297
the entire metropolitan area.288 Given the confusing complexities of metro gov-
Regrettably, urban elasticity is a rare commod- ernance, it is not surprising that “a great deal of
ity. Three national surveys of city managers con- intellectual energy, spanning several decades, has
ducted over ten years consistently found that “the gone into efforts to determine the correct pattern
two major economic development barriers” are the of organization for metropolitan areas.”298 We con-
availability of land, followed by its cost. From two- sider these next.
fifths to more than half cite these impediments to
elasticity.289
Ultralocalism: The Quest for Metropolitan
Efficiency
The Metropolis: Lots of Little, Layered, Ultralocalism299 (an admittedly loaded word), or,
Local Governments more conventionally, governmental fragmentation,
Metropolitan statistical areas are regions with one decentralization, or differentiation, is “the number of
or more cities of at least 50,000 people and their governmental units per 10,000 residents in a metro-
suburbs. (We shall also refer to metropolitan statis- politan area.”300 The more governments per 10,000
tical areas as metro areas or metropolises.) Metro residents, the more governmentally fragmented the
Intergovernmental Administration 483

metropolis. Most metropolitan areas, 89 percent, are Ultralocalism as Irresponsibility In fragmented


highly fragmented.301 metropolises, buck passing is greatly eased.
An example: “A woman tourist who stopped
Ultralocalism: The Theory The scholarly niche overnight at a motel near Miami had to telephone
known as “metropolitan organization,” or “local three police departments to report a suspected
public economies,” is a hands-on variant of public prowler outside her door.” We do not know if any of
choice explained in Chapter 10, and celebrates ultra- these departments responded to her call.
localism on the logic that “multinucleated political Another: There was a fire in a house fewer
systems” provide the most efficient governance for than three blocks from a fire station in Las Vegas,
metro areas.302 Nevada, but just beyond the city limits. Las Vegas
Efficiency is achieved in fragmented metropo- fire fighters had been instructed to prevent the
lises because many cheek-by-jowl governments are fire from reaching city property, so they carefully
collaborating and competing to serve metropolitan watched the house burn until county fire engines
citizens. Collaboration lowers costs by introdu- arrived. Angry neighborhood residents hurled rocks
cing regional economies of scale. Competition can at the immobile city fire engines, causing substantial
produce higher quality services at lower cost because damage.306
it allows metropolitans to “vote with their feet” (a
phrase much favored in this literature), moving Ultralocalism as Dissatisfaction A criticism of
easily from one community to another if they are ultralocalism is that it focuses on lowering taxes
dissatisfied with local governing, and taking their and often ignores citizen satisfaction with ser-
tax revenue with them. By contrast, a single, met- vices.307 The ultralocalists may have their reasons
ropolitan-wide government is less efficient, just as a for this narrow focus, as broader research shows
corporate monopoly is less likely to provide its cus- that centralized metro governments correlate more
tomers with the best goods and services at the best strongly with higher citizen satisfaction with public
price in a marketplace that it monopolizes. services  than do fragmented metropolises.308 This
Ideas have power. By the 1980s, even long- holds true for citizens of color as well as white
standing federal friends of coherent subnational citizens.309
governance had turned “from being a champion If the ultralocalists do, in fact, believe that
of strong regional governance to an advocate of metro residents move to other towns only because
public choice with its tacit acceptance that fragmen- they are unhappy with local taxes, then their belief
tation is good,”303 and Washington had abandoned seems, at best, incomplete. Recall from Chapter 8
its “few national inducements to metropolitan that citizens display a marked willingness to pay for
coherence.”304 local services. (Thirty to 42 percent would pay more
in federal taxes for better services.310) Effective and
Issues with Ultralocalism There long has been well-managed government may matter more than
a persistent perception among local public admin- tax rates.
istrators, which is shared by growing numbers of
researchers, that “multinucleated political systems” Ultralocalism as Inequity “In general, the more
do not cut it. highly fragmented a metro area is, the more seg-
regated it is racially and economically.” Highly
Ultralocalism as Confusion In ultralocalist metrop- fragmented metropolises have far wider income
olises, confusion frequently flourishes. gaps between inner city and outer suburb and
An example: In Louisiana, a speeding motorist more concentrated poverty rates, which is “the
was followed by police from no fewer than seven single most important indicator of an urban area’s
cities before he rolled to a stop. social health,”  than do more centralized metro
Another: When St. Louis County plainclothes areas.311 Worse, poor communities in highly frag-
detectives were conducting a gambling raid, they mented metropolises receive fewer services that
were promptly arrested by police from the town of they need than do poor communities in centralized
Wellston, who were staging their own raid.305 metropolises.312
484 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Ominously, after a decade of dramatic decline So, too, are the gargantuans. There is a long
during the 1990s, concentrated areas of poverty history of practical analyses that promote enhanced
are expanding.313 Ominously? Yes, because concen- efficiency through local governmental consolida-
trated poverty comprises a “critical mass” of “social tion.319 But, in contrast to the ultralocalists, the
tinder”314 that can ignite, and ignition is most likely gargantuans also hold that fixating on govern-
to crackle in ultralocalist metropolises and inelastic mental efficiency when so many metro areas are in
municipalities. advanced states of decay, division, and degradation
The three most disastrous urban race riots of smacks of rearranging the deck chairs on the Titanic.
the 1960s—in Los Angeles in 1965 and in Newark “Reversing the fragmentation of urban areas is an
and Detroit in 1967, in which 100 people died—all essential step in ending severe racial and economic
occurred in highly fragmented metropolitan areas segregation. . .. Areas characterized by geographi-
and in cities with ratings of “zero elasticity” (Newark cally large, multipowered governments,” by contrast,
and Detroit) or “low elasticity” (Los Angeles, which “tend to promote more racial and economic inte-
re-exploded in 1992 at a cost of fifty-five lives). gration and achieve greater social mobility.” Metro
These are the lowest two of the five elasticity rank- government, by definition, radically reduces, even
ings. Miami’s wrenching race riot in 1980, in which eliminates, fragmentation. It recognizes that central
eighteen died, Cincinnati’s three-day riot in 2001, cities and their suburbs are mutually dependent for
and Baltimore’s riot of 2015 also erupted in cities success on each other.320
with zero elasticity.315 Riots also occurred in racially
troubled Ferguson, Missouri, in 2015; Ferguson is A Little-Known Gargantuan Benefit: Prosperous
located in St. Louis County, a metropolis that not Metros An advantage of gargantua not shared by
only has zero elasticity, but, with 146 governments ultralocalist metropolises is economic. An analysis of
of all types, numbers among the most fragmented 263 metropolitan areas containing at least 500,000
metro areas in the country.316 people in twenty-one developed democracies, includ-
Inelastic cities and fragmented metro areas asso- ing the United States, found that “for each doubling
ciate with civic rage. in the number of municipalities per 100,000 inhab-
itants within a metropolitan area, labour productiv-
ity in the metropolitan area decreases by 5–6%.” By
Gargantua: The Quest for Metropolitan contrast, the lower the level of governmental frag-
Efficiency—and Equity mentation, the higher the rate of the gross metro-
Dissatisfaction with the ultralocalist status quo has politan product’s average annual growth per capita;
produced an effort to reform fragmented metropol- the economies of the least fragmented metros, on
itan governance. The movement has been labeled, average, grow about one-and-a-half times greater
memorably, gargantua317 (yet another loaded word), over ten years than the most fragmented.321
but the more accepted terms are centralized govern- Full disclosure: a more limited analysis of the
ment and centrism, regional government and region- fifty-one largest American cities found that “politi-
alism, and metro, or metropolitan, government. cal fragmentation may be inefficient and duplicative,
A metropolitan government is a general-purpose but it does not appear to damage local economic
local government with “all of the powers of a muni- growth”; ultralocalist metros, in fact, may “do a
cipality under state law” (especially “key planning bit better” economically than centralized ones,322
and zoning powers”), which contains within its despite, apparently, the study’s own finding that
limits at least 60 percent of the people living in its fragmented metros are inefficient. That said, the
metropolitan area, and most (but ideally all) of the larger global study strikes us as persuasive.
area’s major cities. A metro government “must exer-
cise exclusive powers within its jurisdiction.”318
The Efficiency Question
The Grails of Gargantua At root, the ultralocalists Central to the debate over ultralocalism versus gar-
are concerned with essentially one value: efficiency gantua is the question of efficiency: which form
in the delivery of local services. delivers services more cost-effectively?
Intergovernmental Administration 485

Much of the ultralocalist literature agrees have some fiscal authority,” and even that number
that metropolitan areas with more local govern- is known to be incomplete.327 Illinois also has the
ments offer a greater variety of services and deliv- second highest effective property tax rate, the fifth
ery mechanisms, spend less, and have a lower rate highest combined state and local gas tax rate, and
of expenditure growth than those with fewer local the eighth highest local tax collections per capita in
governments.323 the nation. Governmental fragmentation, along with
Although this literature implies that these Illinois’ enthusiasm for imposing unfunded mandates
factors lead to more cost-effective services, it on its localities, noted earlier, explain why the state
appears that the main ultralocalist factor associated “consistently ranks in the top quartile when it comes
with efficiency is that of collaboration among gov- to key local government tax statistics.”328
ernments in delivering services.324 Collaboration, as The obverse of fragmented governance is the
we have noted, is one of ultralocalism’s two major fact that little territorial sprawl and greater popu-
components (the other is competition), and inter- lation density associate positively with more effi-
governmental collaboration is but a messier form of cient delivery of services.329 An example: Kansas
economy of scale, which is the essence of efficiency City, Missouri, with 1,460 people per square mile,
in the gargantuan model. Gargantua is predicated is, according to its own officials, simply unable to
on the premise that sweeping away slews of stunted afford the same level of basic services as the city of
local governments and establishing in their place a St. Louis, Missouri, because St. Louis, which was
comprehensive regional government “is much better designed to be compact (the city, but not, alas, St.
than trying to get multiple local governments to act Louis County), has more than three times the popu-
like a metropolitan government.”325 Regional gov- lation per square mile (4,805).330
ernments can deliver economies of scale unilaterally, The road to greater metropolitan efficiency
and without engaging in endless and inefficient bar- seems to be less one of enervating and time-
gaining among localities. consuming collaboration and competition, as the
In addition, as we detailed in Chapter 11, ultralocalists contend, and more one of centralized
central cities—and their centralized governments— government and dense population.
govern far more people than do suburban and rural
governments, and this reality provides cities with far
greater economies of scale—economies that are the Mincing Toward Metro
structural cornerstone of more efficient service deliv- Only 11 percent of metropolitan areas are served
ery. Introducing a centralized government to deliver by regional governments in twenty-one states, and
services for even more people increases economies of most of these are medium-sized communities; only
scale even further. 3 percent of the 80 percent of Americans living in
There are many data to support this view. A metro areas are served by metro governments.331
massive international study of large metropolitan Reformers have developed two main approaches
areas concluded that those with a regional gov- to extend regionalism’s reach.
ernment “strongly negatively correlated with the
development of urban sprawl.” Sprawl, of course, is City-County Consolidation One approach is city-
antithetical to concentrated populations, which are county consolidation, or the unification of the gov-
crucial to capitalizing on economies of scale in deliv- ernments of one or more cities with the surrounding
ering services cost-effectively. In fact, in those metros county in which the boundary lines of the jurisdic-
lacking a central government, sprawl grew, and in tions involved become coterminous. More than four-
those with a central government, sprawl actually fifths of all metro areas are in a single county,332 so
shrank and population density intensified.326 city-county consolidation would seem to be a prom-
When gaggles of governments dominate, effi- ising route toward metropolitan-wide government.
ciency suffers. Consider Illinois, which has more local As a practical matter, however, consolida-
governments than any other state—6,963, accord- tions have not made much progress. According to
ing to the U.S. Census Bureau, although Illinois the U.S. Census Bureau, there are only thirty-four
itself identifies 8,480 localities that “collect taxes or consolidated governments, although the National
486 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Association of Counties cites forty-two.333 Whatever respectively, but the two most problematic proce-
the number, it is tiny, toting up to about 1 percent dures, popular referenda (used in twenty states) and
of all county governments. The first nine city-county judicial determination (six states), have grown.341
consolidations (1805–1907), and two in 1969 and Even though the states have made annexation
1998, were executed by legislative fiats,334 an option more difficult, cities are annexing more than ever.
that remains “fully within the legal powers of most About nine out of ten central cities that can annex
state legislatures, even if at present such sweeping do so,342 and, each decade, cities annex consid-
urban reorganization is beyond legislatures’ desires erably more land and people than in the previous
and political powers.”335 The remainder—twenty- decade.343 On average, more than 60,000 municipal
seven, by one count—was implemented by popular annexations are executed every ten years,344 expand-
referenda, or about a fourth of the 105 such refer- ing the boundaries of more than four-fifths of the
enda held between 1902 and 2010.336 522 largest cities by a minimum of 10 percent.345
Although the perfunctory pace of city-county
consolidations is quickening (more than three- In Sum For the past half century, fragmentation’s
fourths have been achieved since 1947337), citizens friends have formed mainstream thinking about
are not enthusiastic about them. Of the 166 consol- urban administration. Today, this is changing, and
idation attempts (whether by legislative fiat or ref- the result is a renewed regionalism that might have
erendum) initiated since 1800, only 22 percent have been stillborn without recent research on the rela-
been successful.338 Why is this? tions between metropolitan efficiency and citizen
One reason is state legislative reluctance. Only equity.
fourteen states, a declining number, specifically Ideas have power.
authorize their cities and counties to consolidate.339
Another is klutzy consolidation campaigns.
Those that advocate greater governmental efficiency, NOTES
even though this is an entirely valid reason to con- 1. Jorge Martinez-Vazquez and Ming-Hung Yao,
solidate, almost always fail; those campaigns that “Fiscal Decentralization and Public Sector
offer a vision of greater economic development and Employment,” Public Finance Review 37
demonstrate that the “existing political structure” is (September 2009), pp. 539–571.
unable to fulfill it, almost always win.340 2. Jason Sorens, “The Institutions of Fiscal Feder-
alism,” Publius 41 (March 2011), pp. 207–231.
Municipal Annexation An incremental approach 3. Silika Prohl and Friedrich Schneider, “Does
usually is more successful in moving toward metro Decentralization Reduce Government Size? A
government, and the paramount piecemeal proce- Quantitative Study of the Decentralization Hypo-
dure is municipal annexation, initiated in 1854 by thesis,” Public Finance Review 37 (November
Philadelphia, in which cities extend their boundaries 2009), pp. 639–664.
4. Sorens, “The Institutions of Fiscal Federalism.”
to subsume their surrounding territories.
5. Alan T. Peacock and Jack Wiseman, The Growth
During the nineteenth century, suburbs were
of Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom
mostly agreeable to annexation by central cities
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1961),
because it was the cities that could offer a relia-
pp. xxi–xxxi. The quotation is on p. xxv.
ble supply of water, but, in the twentieth century, 6. Oguzhan Dincer, “Fiscal Decentralization and
suburbs built their own water works and, as inner Trust,” Public Finance Review 38 (March 2010),
city crime and poverty grew, suburban resistance to pp. 178–192.
central city takeovers strengthened. 7. Nandhini Rangarajan, “Evidence of Different
States allow their municipalities to annex in five Types of Creativity in Government: A Multimethod
ways. Ten states rely on legislatively-created special Assessment,” Public Performance & Management
boards, and their use has held steady over time. Review 32 (September 2008), pp. 132–163.
The two simplest methods, unilateral annexations 8. Jack L. Walker, “The Diffusion of Innovation in
authorized by state legislatures or city councils, have the American States,” American Political Science
declined over three decades to six and eight states, Review 63 (September 1969), pp. 880–899.
Intergovernmental Administration 487

9. David Lowery, Virginia Gray, and Frank R. 23. Ibid., p. 120, and American Council on Inter-
Baumgartner, “Policy Attention in State and governmental Relations, Significant Features of
Nation: Is Anyone Listening to the Laboratories Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 38.
of Democracy?” Publius 41 (March 2011), 24. As derived from data in American Council on
pp. 286–310. Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features
10. Richard D. Bingham, “Innovation, Bureaucracy, of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52. Figures
and Public Policy: A Study of Innovation Adop- are for 1952 and 1957.
tion by Local Government,” Western Political 25. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism, p. 7.
Quarterly 31 (June 1978), pp. 178–205. 26. Ibid., p. 6.
11. Henry S. Reuss, Revenue-Sharing: Crutch or 27. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Catalyst for State and Local Governments? (New Relations, The Federal Role in the Federal System,
York: Praeger, 1970), pp. 53–56. p. 120.
12. Mike Maciag, “‘Fragmented’ School Districts: 28. American Council on Intergovernmental
A Complicated and Controversial Issue,” Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal
Governing.com (April 2016). Figures are for the Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 38.
2013–2014 school year. 29. As derived from data in ibid., p. 52.
13. President Franklin Pierce, quoted in David B. 30. As derived from data in ibid. and Walker, The
Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism: Slouching Rebirth of Federalism, p. 227. Figures are for
Toward Washington, 2nd ed. (New York: Chatham 1957 and 1977.
House, 2000), p. 69. 31. Norton Long, as quoted in William R. Barnes,
14. As derived from data in ibid., p. 74. The quotation “Beyond Federal Urban Policy,” Urban Affairs
is on p. 75. Review 40 (May 2005), pp. 575–589. The quota-
15. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental tion is on p. 578.
Relations, The Federal Role in the Federal System: 32. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
The Dynamics of Growth, A Crisis of Confidence Relations, Federal Regulation of State and Local
and Competence, A-77 (Washington, DC: U.S. Governments: The Mixed Record of the 1980s,
Government Printing Office, 1980), pp. 120–121. A-126 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
16. Barbara Floersch, “Federal Grantmaking: The Printing Office, 1993), pp. v, 46, 52.
Long View of History,” Grantsmanship Magazine 33. As derived from data in National Academy of
(Summer 2001), pp. 1–12. Figure (p. 3) is for Public Administration, Beyond Preemptions: Inter-
1929. governmental Partnerships to Enhance the New
17. As derived from data in American Council on Economy (Washington, DC: Author, 2006), p. 16.
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features 34. Alan Greenblatt,“The Hand-off,”Governing (April
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2 (Washington, 2011), pp. 24–28. Figure (p. 26) is for 1983–1986.
DC: Author, 1998), p. 52. 35. Pew Research Center for the People & the Press,
18. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Distrust, Discontent, Anger and Partisan Rancor:
Relations, The Federal Role in the Federal System, The People and Their Government (Washington,
pp. 120–121. DC: Author, 2010), Sections 2 and 1. Figure is for
19. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism, p. 99. Grants 1997–2010.
grew from twelve to twenty-six, 1932–1937, 36. Gallup, “Majority in U.S. Prefer State Over
and  their annual number remained in the Federal Government Power,” Gallup.com (July
mid-twenties until the 1940s. Funding figure is 11, 2016). Current figure is for 2016.
for 1933–1939. 37. Pew Research, State Governments Viewed
20. Floersch, “Federal Grantmaking,” pp. 3, 5. Exact Favorably as Federal Rating Hits New Low
figure is 39 percent. (Washington, DC: Author, 2013). Figure is for
21. As derived from data in American Council on 2013.
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features 38. Gallup, Trust in Government (Washington, DC:
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52. Author, 2016). Figures are for 2016.
22. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 39. As derived from data in American Council on
Relations, The Federal Role in the Federal System, Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features
pp. 120, 121. of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, pp. 38, 52.
488 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Figures are for 1978–1988, which, with some 51. Robert Jay Dilger, Federal Grants to State and
exceptions, continued their decline through 1990. Local Governments: A Historical Perspective
40. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental on Contemporary Issues (Washington, DC:
Relations, Federal Regulation of State and Local U.S.  Congressional Research Service, 2015),
Governments, pp. 46, 53, 56. p. 7.
41. Tim Conlan, “From Cooperative to Opportunistic 52. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, ProQuest
Federalism: Reflections on the Half-Century Anni- Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016
versary of the Commission on Intergovernmental (Bethesda, MD: Author, 2016), Table 463.
Relations,” Public Administration Review 66 53. Dilger, Federal Grants to State and Local
(September/October 2006), pp. 663–676. The Governments, p. 7.
quotation is on p. 668. 54. Iris J. Lav, “Piling on Problems: How Federal
42. Barnes, “Beyond Federal Urban Policy,” pp. 576, Policies Affect State Fiscal Conditions,” National
582, 575. Tax Journal 56 (September 2003), pp. 535–554.
43. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal 55. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census,
Assistance: Illustrative Simulations of Using Stati- Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2011,
stical Population Estimates for Reallocating Certain Table 429. Medicaid figure is for 2005–2008.
Federal Funding, GAO-06-567 (Washington, DC: 56. U.S. Bureau of the Census, “Table 1.
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2006), Highlights Summary of State and Local Finances by
page. Figure is for FY 2004. Level of Government:  2002–2003,” Census
44. U.S. General Accounting Office, Electronic of Governments, 2002 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Government: Initiatives Sponsored by the Office Government Printing Office, 2004), and U.S.
of Management and Budget Have Made Mixed Bureau of the Census, “Table 1. Summary of State
Progress, GAO-04-561T (Washington, DC: U.S. and Local Finances  by Level of Government:
Government Printing Office, 2004), p. 7. 2006–2007.” In 2002–2003, federal grants
45. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of accounted for 26  percent of total state revenue,
the United States, 2011, 130th ed. (Washington, falling to 20 percent in 2006–2007. Direct
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011), federal grants contributed 4 percent  of total
Table 429. Figures are for 2008. local  revenue  in both fiscal years. In 2002–
46. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil 2003, federal grants accounted for 26 percent
S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public of total  state revenue, falling to 20  percent in
Administration Across the 50 States: Linking 2006–2007. Direct federal grants  contributed
Practice, Theory, and Research through the 4  percent  of total local revenue in both fiscal
American State Administrators Project, 1964– years.
2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental 57. Daniel C. Vock, “How Obama Changed the
Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 22. Figure, Relationship Between Washington, the States and
79 percent, is for 2004. the Cities,” Governing.com (June 2016).
47. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the 58. As derived from data in Pew Charitable Trusts,
Census, “Table 1. Summary of State and Local “Federal Spending in the States, 2005 to 2014,”
Finances by Level of Government: 2006–2007,” Pewtrusts.org (March 3, 2016).
Census of Governments, 2007 (Washington, DC: 59. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Manage-
U.S. Government Printing Office, 2009). Figures ment and Budget, “Historical Tables,” Budget of
are for 2006–2007. the United States, Fiscal Year 2017 (Washington,
48. Donald F. Kettl, “Those Were the Days,” Gover- DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016),
ning (October 2011), pp. 18–19. Table 12.1.
49. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of 60. As derived from data in Pew Charitable Trusts,
the United States, 2011, Table 429. Figure, 66 “Federal Spending in the States, 2005 to 2014,”
percent, is for 2009, when entitlement grants’ Pewtrusts.org (March 3, 2016), and U.S. Bureau
share of grant dollars peaked. of the Census, “State and Local Government
50. American Council on Intergovernmental Rela- Finances by Level of Government and by
tions, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, State: 2013,” Census of Governments, 2013
1995, Vol. 2, p. 38. (Washington, DC: Author, 2016). Current figures
Intergovernmental Administration 489

are for FY 2014 for states and FY 2013 for for Federal Funding Allocations, GAO-08-230T
localities. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
61. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal Office, 2007), Highlights page. Figure is for
Grants: Improvements Needed in Oversight 2000.
and Accountability Processes, GAO-11-773T 74. As derived from data in U.S. Government Ac-
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing countability Office, Federal Grants: Improvements
Office, 2011), p. 3. Figures are for FY 2010. Needed in Oversight and Accountability Pro-
62. Dilger, Federal Grants to State and Local Govern- cesses, p. 4. Figure is for 2011.
ments, p. 10. Figures are for FY 2014. 75. U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on
63. As derived from data in U.S. Office of Manage- House Administration, Congressional Member
ment and Budget, “Historical Tables,” Table 12.1. and Staff Organizations (Washington, DC: U.S.
64. Kenneth N. Vines, “The Federal Setting of State Government Printing Office, 2013).
Politics,” Politics in the American States, 3rd ed., 76. Phil Kerpen, Taxpayer-Funded Lobbying: Big
Herbert Jacob and Kenneth N. Vines, eds. (Boston: Government Growth Machine (Washington, DC:
Little, Brown, 1976), pp. 3–48. Data are on p. 16. Americans for Prosperity Foundation, 2007), p. 2.
Figures are for 1902. To avoid double counting, Figures are for 1998–2006, and do not include
these and the following figures in this section do $32 million spent in 2006 by about 300 state uni-
not include federal grants, but do include military versities.
and foreign relations spending. 77. National Association of State Budget Officers,
65. Russell L. Hanson, “Intergovernmental Relations,” Budget Processes in the States (Washington, DC:
Politics in the American States: A Comparative Author, 2008), p. 3, and Dan Nowicki, “Ducey
Analysis, 9th ed., Virginia Gray and Russell L. to Shutter Arizona’s Washington, DC, Office,”
Hanson, eds. (Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2008), Azcentral.com (January 3, 2015).
pp. 30–60. The datum is on p. 37. 78. Julia DiLaura, Your Tax Dollars at Work—on
66. Vines, “The Federal Setting of State Politics,” K Street (Washington, DC: Center for Public
p. 16. Figures are for 1938. Integrity, 2006), p. 1. Figure is for 1998–2003.
67. Hanson, “Intergovernmental Relations,” p. 37. 79. Kerpen, Taxpayer-Funded Lobbying, p. 2. Figures
68. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC, Proquest are for 1998–2006, and do not include $34
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016, million spent by transportation and water author-
Tables 480, 481, 482, 492. Figures are for FY ities in 2006.
2012. State total deletes “intergovernmental 80. Center for Public Integrity, as cited in Jodi
general expenditure,” and local total deletes Rudoren and Aron Pilhofer, “Hiring Federal
“intergovernmental revenue.” Lobbyists, Towns Learn Money Talks,” New York
69. Sean Nicholson-Crotty, Governors, Grants, and Times (July 2, 2006). Figures are for 2006.
Elections: Fiscal Federalism in the American States 81. As derived from data in Elaine S. Povitch, “Esche-
(Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2015), wing Lobbyists, States Advocate for Themselves,”
pp. 111–131. Stateline (July 10, 2014). Figure is for 2010–2013,
70. As derived from data in ProQuest LLC. ProQuest and refers to paid lobbyists representing “civil
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 2016, service and public officials.”
Table 463. Figures are for FY 2014. 82. Bruce Katz, “How Washington Made Itself Irr-
71. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grant elevant,” Washington Post (December 4, 2014).
Program Consolidations: Lessons Learned and 83. Anthony J. Nownes, Clive S. Thomas, and
Implications for Congressional Oversight, GAO- Ronald  J. Hrebenar, “Interest Groups in the
15-125 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government States,” Politics in the American States: A
Publishing Office, 2014), p. 5. Comparative Analysis, 9th ed., Virginia Gray and
72. As derived from data in U.S. Government Account- Russell L. Hanson, eds. (Washington, DC: CQ
ability Office, Federal Grants: Improvements Press, 2008),  pp. 98–128. The quotation is on
Needed in Oversight and Accountability Pro- p. 111.
cesses, pp. 3–4. Figures are for 2011. 84. David Lowery, Virginia Gray, John Cluverius, and
73. U.S. Government Accountability Office, 2010 Jeffrey J. Harden, “Explaining the Anomolous
Census: Population Measures Are Important Growth of Public Sector Lobbying in the American
490 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

States, 1997–2007,” Publius 43 (October 2013), Management Association, 1977), pp. 180–192.
pp. 580–599. Figures (pp. 183–184) are for 1976.
85. Kristen M. Daum, “Michigan Government Spent 98. Deborah A. Carroll, Robert J. Eger, III, and Justin
$556K to Lobby Itself,” Lansing State Journal Marlowe, “Managing Local Intergovernmental
(February 24, 2013). Figures are for 2012. Revenues: The Imperative of Diversification,”
86. As derived from data in Glenn Abney, “Lobbying International Journal of Public Administration
by Insiders: Parallels of State Agencies and Inter- 26 (December 2003), pp. 1495–1519. Refers to
est Groups,” Public Administration Review 48 federal and state grants.
(September/October 1988), pp. 911–917. Figures 99. James R. Hines, Jr. and Richard H. Thaler, “The
are for 1987. Flypaper Effect,” Journal of Economic Perspectives
87. John D. DiIulio, Jr., “Want Better, Smaller 9 (Winter 1995), pp. 217–226.
Government? Hire Another Million Bureaucrats,” 100. Russsell Sobel and George Crowley, “Do Inter-
Washington Post (August 29, 2014). Figures are governmental Grants Create Ratchets in State and
for 1960–2013. Local Taxes?” Public Choice 158 (January 2014),
88. Floersch, “Federal Grantmaking,” p. 2. pp. 176–187. The quotation is on p. 176.
89. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 101. Therese A. McCarty and Stephen J. Schmidt,
Relations, Federal Grant Profile, 1995: A Report “Dynamic Patterns in State Government Finance,”
on ACIR’s Federal Grant Fragmentation Index, Public Finance Review 29 (July 2001), pp. 208–
SR-20 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 222. The quotation is on p. 220.
Printing Office, 1995), p. 7. 102. Steven C. Deller and Craig S. Maher, “Categorical
90. As noted in the introduction to Part IV, the con- Municipal Expenditures with a Focus on the
servative estimate is 3 million federal grantee jobs Flypaper Effect,” Public Budgeting & Finance
in state and local governments. In 2015, there 25 (September 2005), pp. 73–90. Refers to state
were almost 22 million state and local employees. grants.
91. As derived from data in Paul C. Light, Fact 103. Dennis O. Grady, “American Governors and
Sheet on the New True Size of Government, State-Federal Relations: Attitudes and Activities,
(Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 2003), 1960–1980,” State Government 57 (3, 1984),
p. 5. Grantee jobs grew by 444,000, 1990–2002. pp. 106–112.
92. As derived from data in American Council on 104. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features Relations, State Administrators’ Opinions on
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52. Administrative Change, Federal Aid, Federal
93. Chung-Lae Cho and Deil S. Wright, “Perceptions Relationships, M-120 (Washington, DC: U.S.
of Federal Aid Impacts on State Agencies: Government Printing Office, 1980), pp. 52, 45.
Patterns, Trends, and Variations across the 20th Figures are for 1978.
Century,” Publius 37 (Winter 2007), pp. 103–130. 105. Cho and Wright, “Perceptions of Federal Aid
The figure and quotation are on p. 108. Impacts on State Agencies,” p. 109.
94. As derived from data in American Council on 106. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features Change in Public Administration Across the 50
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52. States, pp. 23–24. In seven of the eight surveys,
95. Cho and Wright, “Perceptions of Federal Aid 1974–2004, 45 to 58 percent said this. In 2008,
Impacts on State Agencies,” p. 108. 36 percent said this, which “may reflect the
96. Jeffrey L. Brudney, Cynthia J. Bowling, and Deil greater scrutiny agencies typically receive during
S. Wright, Continuity and Change in Public economic downturns.”
Administration Across the 50 States: Linking 107. Brian K. Collins, “Redistributive Policy and
Practice, Theory, and Research through the Devolution: Is State Administration a Road Block
American State Administrators Project, 1964– (Grant) to Equitable Access to Federal Funds?”
2008 (Auburn, AL: Center for Governmental Journal of Public Administration Research and
Services, Auburn University, 2010), p. 24. Theory 16 (October 2006), pp. 613–632. The
97. Albert J. Richter, “Federal Grants Management: quotations are on p. 613.
The City and County View,” Municipal Year 108. As derived from data in American Council on
Book, 1977 (Washington, DC: International City Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features
Intergovernmental Administration 491

of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52. Figure is Cities and States and the Metropolitan Agenda
for 1978–1988. (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2004), p. 20.
109. Robert W. Gage, “Intergovernmental Change: 122. John Yinger, “States to the Rescue? Aid to Central
A Denver Area Perspective,” Intergovernmental Cities Under the New Federalism,” Public Budget-
Perspective 14 (Summer 1988), pp. 14–17. ing & Finance 10 (Summer 1990), pp. 27–44.
110. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal Grants: 123. As derived from data in National Academy of Public
Design Improvements Could Help Federal Resour- Administration, Beyond Preemptions, p. 16.
ces Go Further, GAO/AIMD-97-7 (Washington, 124. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1996), p. 2. Relations, Federal Court Rulings Involving State,
111. Nicholson-Crotty, Governors, Grants, and Elect- Local, and Tribal Governments, Calendar Year
ions, p. 88. 1994, M-196 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
112. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Comm- Printing Office, 1995).
unity Development Block Grants: Program Offers 125. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting
Recipients Flexibility but Oversight Can Be Office, Federalism: Comments on S.1214—The
Improved, GAO-06-732 (Washington, DC: U.S. Federalism Accountability Act of 1999, GAO/T-
Government Printing Office, 2006). GGD-99-143 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
113. Deller and Maher, “Categorical Municipal Expen- Printing Office, 1999), p. 4. Figures are for 1996–
ditures with a Focus on the Flypaper Effect.” 1998.
114. Donald F. Kettl, “Boutiques for the Poor,” Gover- 126. As derived from data in: Light, Fact Sheet on the
ning (June 1999), p. 14. New True Size of Government, p. 4, and U.S.
115. As derived from data in Council of State Govern- Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the
ments, Book of the States, 2016 (Lexington, KY: United States, 1999, 119th ed. (Washington, DC:
Author, 2016), Table 2.1. Figures are for FY U.S. Government Printing Office, 1999), Table
2013. 534. Figures, 28 and 15 percent, respectively, are
116. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism, p. 228. for 1996–1997.
117. As derived from data in American Council on 127. David R. Berman, “State-Local Relations:
Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features Authority, Policies, Cooperation,” Municipal
of Fiscal Federalism, 1995, Vol. 2, p. 52, for Year Book, 1999 (Washington, DC: International
1970–1994 data, and U.S. Bureau of the Census, City/County Management Association, 1999),
“Table 1” (2004, 2009, 2011). Summary of State pp. 47–61. Data are on p. 50.
and Local Finances by Level of Government,” 128. Joseph Zimmerman, “The Discretionary Author-
Census of Governments, 2004, 2009, 2011 ity of Local Governments,” Urban Data Service
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Reports 13 (November 1981), pp. 1–13. Datum is
Office, 2006, 2011, 2013). on p. 11.
118. Bruce A. Wallin, Budgeting for Basics: The Chan- 129. Osbin L. Ervin, “Understanding American Local
ging Landscape of City Finances (Washington, Government: Recent Census Bureau and ACIR
DC: Brookings, 2005), p. 5. Per capita federal aid Contributions,” Public Administration Review
to these cities decreased by 59 percent, and state 55 (March/April 1995), pp. 209–212. Figures
aid increased by 46 percent, 1977–2000. (p. 210) are for 1978–1990.
119. Mike Maciag and J. B. Wogan, “With Less State 130. Berman, “State-Local Relations: Authority,
Aid, Localities Look for Ways to Cope,” Gover- Policies, Cooperation,” p. 49.
ning.com (February 2017). 131. Ann Bowman and Richard Kearney, “Are U.S.
120. As derived from data in Walker, The Rebirth of Cities Losing Power and Authority? Perceptions
Federalism, p. 227, and U.S. Bureau of the Census, of Local Government Actors,” Urban Affairs
“Table 1” (2009). Figure is for 2006–2007. We Review 48 (July 2012), pp. 528–546. The quota-
have computed this rough estimate on the assump- tion is on p. 528.
tion that Washington continues to earmark about 132. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
one-third of its assistance to the states as pass- Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern-
through grants. ment and Administration, M-186 (Washington,
121. Hal Wolman, Todd Swanstrom, Margaret Weir, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1993),
and Nicholas Lyon, The Calculus of Coalitions: p. 20.
492 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

133. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 145. National Conference of State Legislatures,
Relations, Federally Induced Costs Affecting State Mandate Monitor, p. 1. Figure is for 2010.
and Local Governments, M-193 (Washington, 146. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994), p. 3. Mandates: Identification Process Is Complex and
134. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Agency Rules Vary, GAO-05-401T (Washington,
Relations, Regulatory Federalism: Policy, Process, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2005),
Impact, and Reform, A-95 (Washington, DC: U.S. p. 14. Figure is for 2001–2002.
Government Printing Office, 1984), Appendix I. 147. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
135. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Mandates: Few Rules Trigger Unfunded Mandates
Relations, Federal Statutory Preemption of State Reform Act, GAO-11-385T (Washington,
and Local Authority: History, Inventory, and DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2011),
Issues, A-121 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Highlights page. Figures are for 2001–2002.
Printing Office, 1992), p. 9. 148. As derived from data in Jerri Killian and Enamul
136. The typology is described more fully in U.S. Choudhury, “Continuity and Change in the Role
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental of City Managers,” Municipal Year Book, 2010
Relations, Regulatory Federalism, pp. 7–10. Washington, DC: International City/County
137. Timothy J. Conlan and David R. Beam, “Federal Management Association, 2010), pp. 10–18.
Mandates: The Record of Reform and Future In 2010, state mandates ranked ninth as an
Prospects,” Intergovernmental Perspective 18 “influence,” and federal ones ranked sixteenth
(Fall 1992), pp. 7–11. The quotation is on p. 8. (p. 13).
138. Janet M. Kelly, “Lessons from the States on 149. Richard C. Kearney, Jodi E. Swicegood, and Ann
Unfunded Mandates,” National Civic Review 84 O’M. Bowman, “Second-Order Devolution?
(Spring 1995), pp. 133–139. What City Managers Have to Say,” Municipal
139. Kiki Caruson and Susan A. MacManus, Year Book, 2011 (Washington, DC: International
“Mandates and Management Challenges in the City/County Management Association, 2011),
Trenches: An Intergovernmental Perspective pp. 13–23. Figures are for 2000–2010. The quo-
on Homeland Security,” Public Administration tation is on p. 17.
Review 66 (July/August 2006), pp. 522–536. 150. Rodney E. Hero and Jody L. Fitzpatrick, “State
140. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Mandating of Local Government Activities: An
Relations, Changing Public Attitudes on Gover- Exploration,” Paper presented at the Annual
nments and Taxes, 1991, S-20 (Washington, DC: Meeting of the American Political Science Asso-
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1991), p. 10. ciation (Washington, DC, August 28–31, 1986),
141. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental p. 18.
Relations, Federal Mandate Relief for State, Local, 151. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
and Tribal Governments, A-129 (Washington, Relations, State Mandating of Local Expenditures,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995), A-67 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
p. 4. Office, 1978), p. 41. Data are for 1976.
142. Richard T. Moore and Don Balfour, National 152. Janet Kelly, “Unfunded Mandates: The View from
Conference of State Legislatures, “Unfunded the States,” Public Administration Review 54 (July/
Federal Mandates,” Memorandum of November August 1994), pp. 405–408. The quotation is on
16, 2010, to Senator Lamar Alexander. p. 405.
143. National Conference of State Legislatures, 153. Task Force on Local Government Consolidation
Mandate Monitor (Washington, DC: Author, and Unfunded Mandates, Delivering Efficient,
November 17, 2010), p. 1. Effective, and Streamlined Government to Illinois
144. U.S. Conference of Mayors/Price Waterhouse, Taxpayers (Springfield, IL: Author, 2015), pp. 2,
Impact of Unfunded Mandates on U.S. Cities: A 5, 7.
314 City Survey (Washington, DC: U.S. Confer- 154. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
ence of Mayors, 1993), p. 2, and National Asso- Relations, Mandates: Cases in State-Local Relat-
ciation of Counties/Price Waterhouse, NACo ions, M-173 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Unfunded Mandates Survey (Washington, DC: Printing Office, 1990), p. 7.
National Association of Counties, 1993). 155. Kelly, “Unfunded Mandates,” pp. 405–406.
Intergovernmental Administration 493

156. Linda Wagar, “A Declaration of War,” State 170. Victoria Gordon, “Home Rule and Improved
Government News (April 1993), pp. 18–22. The Fiscal Health: Perception or Reality?” Municipal
quotation is on p. 18. Year Book, 2006 (Washington, DC: International
157. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental City/County Management Association, 2006),
Relations, Federally Induced Costs Affecting State pp. 33–38. The quotation is on p. 37.
and Local Governments, p. 7. 171. Kearney, Swicegood, and Bowman, “Second-
158. David R. Berman, “State-Local Relations: Auth- Order Devolution?” pp. 16–17. Figure is for
ority, Finances, Cooperation,” Municipal Year 2000–2010.
Book, 2002 (Washington, DC: International 172. Pew Research Center for the People & the
City/County Management Association, 2002), Press, Distrust, Discontent, Anger, and Partisan
pp. 45–61. The quotation is on pp. 49–50. Rancor,  Section 2. Data are for 1964, when 40
159. As derived from data in National Academy of percent thought this, and 2010, when 58 percent
Public Administration, Beyond Preemptions, did.
p.  16. Data are for 1790–2004. The quotations 173. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grant
are on pp. 1–2. Program Consolidations: Lessons Learned
160. Grady, “American Governors and State-Federal and Implications for Congressional Oversight,
Relations,” p. 107. pp. 5–6.
161. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 174. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Federal
Relations, State Administrators’ Opinions on Grants: Improvements Needed in Oversight
Administrative Change, Federal Aid, Federal and Accountability Processes, pp. 10–11. And
Relationships, p. 52. Figure is for 1978. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grants
162. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Management: Action Needed to Improve the
Relations, Federal Statutory Preemption of State Timeliness of Grant Closeouts by Federal
and Local Authority, p. 34. Data are for 1988. Agencies, GAO-12-360, and Grants Management:
163. Catherine H. Lovell, et al., Federal and State Man- Actions Needed to Address Persistent Grant
dating on Local Governments: An Exploration of Closeout Timeliness and Undisbursed Balance
Issues and Impacts (Riverside: Graduate School of Issues, GAO-16-362 (Washington, DC: U.S.
Administration, University of California, 1979), Government Printing/Publishing Office, 2012
p. 82. and 2016), Highlights pages. “About $1 billion”
164. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental was found in 2006, “more than $794 million”
Relations, Regulatory Federalism, p. 175. Figures was found in 2011, and “approximately $994
are for 1981. million” in 2015.
165. Kearney, Swicegood, and Bowman, “Second- 175. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grants
Order Devolution?” p. 13. Figures are for 2000– Management: Actions Needed to Address
2010. Persistent Grant Closeout Timeliness and
166. Gregory Streib and William L. Waugh, Jr., “The Undisbursed Balance Issues, Highlights page.
Changing Responsibilities of County Govern- 176. Loren Berlin, “Money on the Table,” Land Lines
ments: Data from a Survey of County Leaders,” 29 (Winter 2017), pp. 18–25. The quotations are
American Review of Public Administration 21 on pp. 23–25.
(June 1991), pp. 139–156. Figures (p. 144), 93 177. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Improper
and 31 percent, respectively, are for 1989. Payments: Recent Efforts to Address Improper
167. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federalism: Com- Payments and Remaining Challenges, GAO-
ments on S.1214—The Federalism Accountability 11-575T (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Act of 1999, p. 4. Data are for 1996–1998. Printing Office, 2011), p. 3. Figures are for FY
“Federalism assessments” are required by the 2010.
Unfunded Mandates Reform Act and Executive 178. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grant
Order 12612. Program Consolidations: Lessons Learned and
168. Greenblatt, “The Hand-off,” p. 26. Implications for Congressional Oversight, p. 33.
169. Kearney, Swicegood, and Bowman, “Second- 179. William T. Gormley, Jr., “Money and Mandates:
Order Devolution?” pp. 16–17. Figures are for The Politics of Intergovernmental Conflict,”
2000–2010. Publius 36 (Fall 2006), pp. 523–540.
494 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

180. Donna Milam Handley, “Strengthening the 191. The cases are Nevada v. Hibbs (2003); Tennessee
Intergovernmental Grant System: Long-Term v. Lane (2004); and Gonzales v. Raich (2005).
Lessons  for the Federal-Local Relationship,” 192. The case is Gonzales v. Oregon (2006).
Public Administration Review 68 (January/ 193. The case is National Federation of Independent
February 2008), pp. 126–136. The quotation is Businesses v. Sebelius.
on pp. 126–127. 194. Dale Krane and Heidi Koenig, “The State of
181. As derived from data in U.S. General Accounting American Federalism, 2004: Is Federalism Still a
Office, Federal Assistance: Grant System Contin- Core Value?” Publius 35 (Winter 2005), pp. 1–40.
ues to Be Highly Fragmented, GAO-03-718T The quotation is on p. 1.
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing 195. Robert S. Allen, ed., Our Sovereign State (New
Office, 2003), pp. 5, 15. Figures are for 2001. York: Vanguard, 1949), p. vii.
182. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grant 196. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
Program Consolidations: Lessons Learned Change in Public Administration Across the 50
and Implications for Congressional Oversight, States, p. 4.
Highlights page. Figures are for 1990–2012. 197. Cynthia J. Bowling and Deil S. Wright, “Public
183. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grants Administration in the Fifty States: A Half-
Management: Programs at HHS and HUD Collect Century Administrative Revolution,” State and
Administrative Cost Information but Differences Local Government Review 30 (Winter 1998),
in Cost Caps and Definitions Create Challenges, pp. 52–64.
GAO-15-118 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government 198. As derived from data in Katherine Barrett
Publishing Office, 2014), Highlights page. and Richard Greene, “Grading the States: The
184. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax Mandate to Measure,” Governing (March 2008),
Compliance: Thousands of Organizations pp. 24–93. Grade is for 2008.
Exempt from Federal Income Tax Owe Nearly 199. As derived from data in Katherine Barrett
$1 Billion in Payroll and Other Taxes, GAO-07- and Richard Greene, “Grading the Cities: A
563 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Management Report Card,” Governing (February
Office, 2007), p. 18. Figure is for FY 2006. 2000), pp. 22–91. Grade, B-, is for 2000.
185. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Tax 200. Katherine Barrett, Richard Greene, and Michelle
Compliance: Federal Grant and Direct Assistance Mariani, “Grading the Counties: A Management
Recipients Who Abuse the Federal Tax System, Report Card,” Governing (February 2002),
GAO-08-31 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government pp. 20–89. Grade, C+, is for 2002.
Printing Office, 2007), Highlights page. Figures 201. Brudney, Bowling, and Wright, Continuity and
are for FY 2006. Change in Public Administration Across the 50
186. As derived from data in U.S. Government Ac- States, pp. 3, 2. In 1959, there was an average of
countability Office, Medicare: Thousands of fifty-one agencies per state. In 1959, there was an
Medicare Providers Abuse the Federal Tax System, average of fifty-one agencies per state. Current
GAO-08-618 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government figure is for 2008.
Printing Office, 2008), Highlights page, p. 19. 202. John Bohte and Kenneth J. Meier, “The Marble
Figures are for FY 2006. Cake: Introducing Federalism to the Government
187. U.S. Government Accountability Office, Grant Growth Equation,” Publius 30 (Summer 2000),
Workforce: Agency Training Practices Should pp. 35–46. The quotation is on p. 44.
Inform Future Government-wide Efforts, GAO- 203. U.S. General Accounting Office, Federal
13-591 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Assistance: Grant System Continues to Be Highly
Printing Office, 2013), Highlights page, pp. 3, 8. Fragmental, GAO-03-718T (Washington, DC:
Figures are for FY 2012. U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), p. 3.
188. Gormley, “Money and Mandates.” 204. Alice M. Rivlin, “A New Vision of American
189. Linda Greenhouse, “States Are Given New Legal Federalism,” Public Administration Review 52
Shield by Supreme Court,” New York Times (June (July/August 1992), pp. 315–320.
24, 1999). 205. Paul E. Peterson, “Who Should Do What? Divided
190. The case is Northern Insurance Company of New Responsibility in the Federal System,” Brookings
York v. Chatham County. Review 13 (Spring 1995), pp. 6–11.
Intergovernmental Administration 495

206. Ibid. 224. McDonald, “Does the Charter Form Improve the
207. Alice M. Rivlin, “Rethinking Federalism for More Fiscal Health of Counties?”
Effective Governance,” Publius 42 (July 2012), 225. Lawrence L. Martin and Ronald C. Nyhan,
pp. 387–400. “Determinants of County Charter Home Rule,”
208. Rivlin, “A New Vision of American Federalism,” International Journal of Public Administration
p. 320. 17 (May 1994), pp. 955–970.
209. Peterson, “Who Should Do What?” 226. Jerry Anthony, “Do State Growth Management
210. Ibid. Regulations Reduce Sprawl?” Urban Affairs
211. Rivlin, “A New Vision of American Federalism.” Review 39 (January 2004), pp. 376–397.
212. As derived from data in Saundra K. Schneider, 227. Pew Charitable Trusts, The State Role in Local
William G. Jacoby, and Daniel C. Lewis, “Public Government Financial Distress (Washington, DC:
Opinion Toward Intergovernmental Policy Author, 2013), p. 5.
Responsibilities,” Publius 41 (Winter 2011), 228. Megan Mullin and Dorothy M. Daley,
pp.  1–30. Data and quotation are on pp. 9, 21, “Working with the State: Exploring Interagency
respectively. Data are for 2006. Collaboration within a Federalist System,” Journal
213. Ibid., pp. 10, 21. Data are for 2006. of Public Administration Research and Theory 20
214. Sanford F. Schram and Carol S. Weissert, “The (October 2010), pp. 757–778.
State of American Federalism, 1996–1997,” 229. Deil S. Wright, Understanding Intergovernmental
Publius 27 (Spring 1997), pp. 1–26. The quota- Relations, 2nd ed. (Monterey, CA: Brooks/Cole,
tion is on p. 1. 1982), p. 389.
215. Alan Greenblatt, “Obama and the Cities,” 230. G. Ross Stephens, “State Centralization and the
Governing (April 2009), pp. 23–28. The quota- Erosion of Local Autonomy,” Journal of Politics 36
tion is on p. 24. (February 1974), pp. 44–76, and G. Ross Stephens,
216. William Kevin Voit, Interstate Compacts and “Patterns of State Centralization/Decentralization
Agencies, 1998 (Lexington, KY: Council of State during the Last Half of the Twentieth Century,”
Governments, 1999). Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the
217. Ann O’M. Bowman, “Horizontal Federalism: Southwestern Political Science Association
Exploring Interstate Interactions,” Journal of (Austin, TX: March 18–21, 1992). Current figure
Public Administration Research and Theory 14 for centralized states is for 1992.
(October 2004), pp. 535–546. 231. Tad Friend, “Contract City,” The New Yorker
218. Ibid. (September 5, 2011), pp. 34–40.
219. Alan Greenblatt, “The Story Behind the Prominent 232. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange-
Rise of State AGs,” Governing.com (June 2015). ments and the Transfer of Functions,” p. 195.
220. Adam Coester, Dillon’s Rule or Not? (Washington, 233. George C. Homsy and Mildred E. Warner, “Inter-
DC: National Association of Counties, 2004, municipal Cooperation: The Growing Reform,”
updated 2016). Figures are for 2016; states with Municipal Year Book, 2014 (Washington, DC:
home rule include West Virginia, which has a International City/County Management Associat-
pilot home rule program that expires by the end ion, 2014), pp. 53–65. “Decline” refers to 2002–
of 2017. 2014.
221. Edgar E. Ramirez de la Cruz, “County Form of 234. As derived from data (p. 31) in Rowan Miranda
Government: Trends in Structure and Composit- and Karlyn Andersen, “Alternative Service Deli-
ion,” Municipal Year Book, 2009 (Washington, very in America, 1982–1992,” Municipal Year
DC: International City/County Management Book, 1994 (Washington, DC: International
Association, 2009), pp. 21–27. Figure (p. 21) is City/County Management Association, 1994),
for 2007. pp. 26–35.
222. As derived from data (p. 611) in Bruce D. 235. Mary K. Marvel and Howard P. Marvel,
McDonald, “Does the Charter Form Improve the “Shaping the Provision of Outsourced Public
Fiscal Health of Counties?” Public Administration Services: Incentive Efficacy and Service Delivery,”
Review 75 (July/August 2015), pp. 609–618. Public Performance & Management Review 33
223. Ramirez de la Cruz, “County Form of Govern- (December 2009), pp. 183–213. The quotations
ment,” p. 22. Figures are for 2007. are on p. 202.
496 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

236. Mary K. Marvel and Howard P. Marvel, 251. Roland Zullo, “Does Fiscal Stress Induce Privati-
“Government-to-Government Contracting: zation? Correlates of Private and Intermunicipal
Stewardship, Agency, and Substitution,” Inter- Contracting, 1992–2002” Governance 22 (July
national Public Management Journal 11 (2, 2009), pp. 459–481.
2008), pp. 171–192. The quotation is on p. 171. 252. Ibid.
237. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange- 253. James C. Clingermayer, Richard C. Feiock, and
ments and the Transfer of Functions,” pp. 197– Christopher Stream, “Governmental Uncertainty
198. Figure, 55 percent, is for 1983. and Leadership Turnover: Influences on Con-
238. Timothy J. Burns and Kathryn G. Yeaton, Success tracting and Sector Choices for Local Services,”
Factors for Implementing Shared Services in State and Local Government Review 35 (Fall
Government (Washington, DC: IBM Center for the 2003), pp. 150–160. The data are on p. 158.
Business of Government, 2008), pp. 6, 16, 18, 34. 254. Skip Krueger and Ethan M. Bernick, “State Rules
239. Feather O’Connor Houstoun, “Shared Services and Local Governance Choices,” Publius 40
and the Velveteen Rabbit Factor,” Governing (October 2010), pp. 697–718.
(September 26, 2012). 255. Kelly LeRoux, Paul W. Brandenburger, and Sanjay
240. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental K. Pandey, “Interlocal Service Cooperation in U.S.
Relations, Intergovernmental Service Arrange- Cities: A Social Network Explanation,” Public
ments for Delivering Local Public Services: Update Administration Review 70 (March/April 2010),
1983, A-103 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government pp. 268–278.
Printing Office, 1985), pp. 2, 55, 62. Figures are 256. Kelly LeRoux, “Nonprofit Community Con-
for 1976–1983, and include some transfers from ferences: The Role of Alternative Regional Insti-
and to companies, agencies, and other govern- tutions in Interlocal Service Delivery,” State
ments, such as special districts and states. and Local Government Review 40 (Fall 2008),
241. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental pp. 160–172.
Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern- 257. LeRoux, Brandenburger, and Pandey, “Interlocal
ment Structure and Administration, p. 9. Figure is Service Cooperation in U.S. Cities,” pp. 273, 268.
for 1990. In 1978, thirty-nine states did so. 258. Michael McGuire and Chris Silvia, “The
242. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- Effect of Problem Severity, Managerial and
tion,” p. 59. Figure is for 2012. Organizational Capacity, and Agency Structure
243. Ibid. Figure is for 2012. on Intergovernmental Collaboration: Evidence
244. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange- from Local Emergency Management,” Public
ments and the Transfer of Functions,” p. 196. Administration Review 70 (March/April 2010),
Figure is for 1983. pp. 279–288. The quotations are on p. 279.
245. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- 259. Kelley LeRoux and Sanjay K. Pandey, “City
tion,” p. 59. Figure is for 2012. Managers, Career Incentives, and Municipal
246. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange- Service Decisions: The Effects of Managerial
ments and the Transfer of Functions,” p. 196. Progressive Ambition on Interlocal Service
Datum is for 1983. Delivery,” Public Administration Review 71 (July/
247. Rhys Andrews and Tom Entwistle, “Does Cross- August 2011), pp. 627–636.
Sectoral Partnership Deliver? An Empirical Explo- 260. Meeyoung Lamothe and Scott Lamothe, “To
ration of Public Service Effectiveness, Efficiency, Trust or Not to Trust? What Matters in Local
and Equity,” Journal of Public Administration Government-Vendor Relationships?” Journal of
Research and Theory 20 (July 2010), pp. 679–701. Public Administration Research & Theory 22
248. Ibid., p. 692. (October 2012), pp. 867–892. The quotation is
249. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera- on p. 867.
tion,” p. 59. Figure is for 2012. 261. Trevor L. Brown, “The Dynamics of Government-
250. Pascale Joassart-Marcelli and Juliet Musso, to-Government Contracts,” Public Performance
“Municipal Service Provision Choices within a & Management Review 31 (March 2008),
Metropolitan Area,” Urban Affairs Review 14 pp. 364–386. The quotations are on p. 364.
(March 2005), pp. 492–519. The data are on 262. Homsy and Warner, “Intermunicipal Coopera-
p. 516. tion,” p. 60. Data are for 2012.
Intergovernmental Administration 497

263. Norman Krumholz, “Regionalism Redux,” Public 279. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange-
Administration Review 57 (January/February ments and the Transfer of Functions,” p. 202.
1997), pp. 83–89. The quotation is on p. 83. Figures are for 1983.
264. Allan D. Wallis, “Inventing Regionalism: The First 280. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Two Waves,” National Civic Review 83 (Spring Relations, Intergovernmental Service Arrange-
1994), pp. 168–169. Figures are for 1964–1977. ments for Delivering Local Public Services, p. 97,
265. Patricia S. Atkins and Laura Wilson Gentry, tracks these trends for 1965–1983, and Joassart-
“An Etiquette for the 1990s Regional Council,” Marcelli and Musso, “Municipal Service Provision
National Civic Review 81 (Fall/Winter 1992), Choices within a Metropolitan Area,” p. 516, con-
pp. 466–487. tinues the tracking, at least among local govern-
266. David B. Walker and Albert J. Richter, “Regional- ments in Southern California, for 1982–1997.
ism and the Counties,” County Year Book, 281. David Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs (Washington,
1975 (Washington, DC: National Association of DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 1993), p. 5.
Counties and International City Management 282. David Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, 4th ed.
Association, 1975), pp. 14–19. (Baltimore: MD: Johns Hopkins University Press,
267. Sherman W. Wyman, “Profiles and Prospects: 2013), p. 7.
Regional Councils and Their Executive Duties,” 283. Todd Swanstrom, Colleen Casey, Robert Flack,
Municipal Year Book, 1994 (Washington, and Peter Dreier, Pulling Apart: Economic Segre-
DC: International City/County Management gation among Suburbs and Central Cities in Major
Association, 1994), p. 53. Figure is for 1990. Metropolitan Areas (Washington, DC: Brookings,
268. Richard Hartman, A Report to the Membership 2004), p. 4.
(Washington, DC: National Association of 284. Elizabeth Kneebone and Natalie Holmes, U.S.
Regional Councils, 1979), p. 4. Concentrated Poverty in the Wake of the Great
269. Wyman, “Profiles and Prospects,” p. 49. Data are Recession (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2016).
for 1990. 285. Paul Taylor and Richard Fry, The Rise of
270. Patricia S. Atkins, “From the Mauling to the Residential Segregation by Income (Washington,
Malling of Regionalism,” Public Administration DC: Pew Research Center, 2012).
Review 53 (November/December 1993), 286. Brookings Institution, Racial Change in the
pp. 583–586. In 1977, federal support accounted Nation’s Largest Cities: Evidence from the 2000
for 75 percent of councils’ budgets, and in 1988, Census (Washington, DC: Author, 2001), p. 4.
45 percent. 287. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 10. Emphasis is
271. Grigsby, “Regional Governance and Regional original.
Councils,” p. 55. Figure is for 1992. 288. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, 4th ed.
272. Wyman, “Profiles and Prospects,” pp. 52–53. 289. Lingwen Zheng and Mildred E. Warner, “Local
Figures are for 1990. Economic Development, 1994–2004: Broadening
273. Ibid., p. 56. Strategies, Increasing Accountability,” Municipal
274. Allan D. Wallis, “The Third Wave: Trends in Year Book, 2010 (Washington, DC: International
Regional Governance,” National Civic Review 83 City/County Management Association, 2010),
(Summer–Fall 1994), pp. 294–298. pp. 3–9. The quotation is on p. 7, and the data are
275. Neal R. Peirce, with Curtis W. Johnson and John on p. 9.
Stuart Hall, Citistates: How America Can Prosper 290. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of
in a Competitive World (Santa Ana: CA: Seven the United States, 2001, 120th ed. (Washington,
Locks Press, 1993), p. 318. Emphasis is original. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2001),
276. Wyman, “Profiles and Prospects,” p. 56. Table 31. Figure is for 1998.
277. Henderson, “Intergovernmental Service Arrange- 291. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the
ments and the Transfer of Functions,” pp. 196, Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States,
198. Data are for 1983. 2011, Table 24. Figure, 84 percent, is for 2009.
278. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 292. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Relations, Intergovernmental Service Arrange- Relations, Metropolitan Organization: Compari-
ments for Delivering Local Public Services, p. 62. son of the Allegheny and St Louis Case Studies,
Data are for 1972–1983. SR-15 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government
498 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Printing Office, 1993), p. 3, and ProQuest LLC, 304. Pierce, with Johnson and Hall, Citistates, p. 6.
ProQuest Statistical Abstract of the United States, 305. Reuss, Revenue-Sharing, pp. 59–60.
2016, Appendix II, p. 921. Current figure is for 306. Ibid., pp. 58–59. The quotation is on p. 59.
2013. In 1942, there were 140. 307. Darcy Rollins and Antoniya Owens, Empirical
293. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Evidence of the Effects of Government
Relations, Metropolitan Organization, pp. 3, 7. In Fragmentation (Boston: New England Public
1942, 10 percent of all local governments were Policy Center, 2006).
in metropolitan statistical areas, and, in 1992, 39 308. James A. Christianson and Carolyn E. Sachs,
percent were. “The Impact of Government Size and Number
294. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the Census, of Administrative Units on the Quality of Public
Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1994, Services,” Administrative Science Quarterly 25
114th ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government (March 1980), pp. 89–101.
Printing Office, 1994), Tables 462 and 39, and 309. Ruth Hoogland De Hoog, David Lowery, and
U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1992 Census of William A. Lyons, “Metropolitan Fragmentation
Governments, Table 26. Figure is for 1992. and Suburban Ghettos: Some Empirical
295. Donald Boyd, Layering of Local Governments & Observations on Institutional Racism,” Journal of
City-County Mergers (Albany, NY: Nelson A. Urban Affairs 13 (October 2008), pp. 479–493.
Rockefeller Institute of Government, 2008), 310. MeriTalk, Uncle Sam at Your Service (Alexandria,
pp.  5–7. Figures are for 2000, except for the VA: Author, 2011), p. 12. Figures are for 2010–
number of general-purpose local governments, 2011.
which is for 2007. 311. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, pp. 34, 31.
296. Osborne M. Reynolds, Jr., Local Government 312. Benedict S. Jimenez, “Separate, Unequal, and
Law, 3rd ed. (St. Paul, MN: West, 2009), p. 33. Ignored? Interjurisdictional Competition and
297. As derived from data in U.S. Bureau of the the Budgetary Choices of Poor and Affluent
Census, 2002 Census of Governments, Vol. 1, Municipalities,” Public Administration Review 74
No. 1, Government Organization (Washington, (March/April 2014), pp. 246–257.
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2002), 313. Elizabeth Kneebone and Alan Berube, Reversal of
Tables 10, 15. Figures are for 2002, and include Fortune: A New Look at Concentrated Poverty in
dependent school systems. Thirty-seven percent the 2000s (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2008).
of special districts and 15 percent of “public 314. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 43.
school systems” (or school districts plus depend- 315. Ibid., pp. 56–57.
ent school systems) did not respond to this 316. Ibid. and U.S. Advisory Commission on
question. Intergovernmental Relations, Metropolitan
298. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Organization, p. 7.
Relations, The Organization of Local Public 317. Robert C. Wood, “The New Metropolises: Green
Economies, A-109 (Washington, DC: U.S. Belt, Grass Roots versus Gargantua,” American
Government Printing Office, 1987), p. 49. Political Science Review 52 (March 1958),
299. The term is Reuss’s, in Revenue-Sharing. pp. 108–122.
300. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental 318. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 89.
Relations, Metropolitan Organization, p. 5. 319. For a summary of early reports, see Reuss,
301. As derived from data in Rusk, Cities Without Revenue-Sharing, pp. 55–63. For a more current
Suburbs, 4th ed., pp. 7, 116. Figure is for 2010. example, see New York State Commission on
302. Vincent Ostrom, Charles M. Tiebout, and Robert Local Government Efficiency & Competitiveness,
Warren, “The Organization of Government 21st Century Local Government (Albany, NY:
in Metropolitan Areas: Theoretical Inquiry,” Author, 2008).
American Political Science Review 55 (December 320. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, pp. 85, 34, 40–41.
1961), pp. 831–842. Emphasis added. See also the three articles by
303. J. Eugene Grigsby, III, “Regional Governance and Mark S. Rosentraub, Timothy D. Mead, and
Regional Councils,” National Civic Review 85 Arnold Fleischmann in State and Local Gover-
(Spring–Summer 1996), pp. 53–58. The quotation nment Review 32 (Fall 2000) for additional evi-
is on p. 55. dence of urban interdependency.
Intergovernmental Administration 499

321. As derived from data in Organisation for 332. Ibid., p. 96.


Economic Co-operation and Development, The 333. NACo, as cited in Povitch, “History, Politics and
Metropolitan Century: Understanding Urbani- Pride.” Figure is for 2016.
sation and Its Consequences (Brussels: OECD 334. Suzanne M. Leland and Kurt Thurmaier, “Lessons
Publishing, 2015), pp. 52, 56. Data are for 2000– from 35 Years of City-County Consolidation At-
2010. tempts,” Municipal Year Book, 2006 (Washington,
322. Richard Florida, “Rise of the Fragmented City,” DC: International City/County Management
Citylab.com (April 28, 2015). Association, 2006), pp. 3–10. Consolidated gov-
323. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental ernment figure is for 2004.
Relations, The Organization of Local Public 335. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 92.
Economies and Metropolitan Organization; 336. David Rusk, as cited in Kate Linebaugh, “Threats
Robert Bish and Elinor Ostrom, Local to Town Hall Stir Voter Backlash,” Wall Street
Government in the United States (San Francisco: Journal (June 8, 2011).
ICS Press, 1988); and Rollins and Owens, 337. As derived from data in Rusk, Cities Without
Empirical Evidence of the Effects of Government Suburbs, p. 92. Twenty-nine consolidations oc-
Fragmentation. All are literature reviews. curred, 1947–2004.
324. See, for example, U.S. Advisory Commission on 338. Boyd, Layering of Local Governments & City-
Intergovernmental Relations, Intergovernmental County Mergers, p. 19. Figures are for 1800–
Service Arrangements for Delivering Local Public 2006.
Services, p. 93. 339. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
325. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, pp. 89, 88. Empha- Relations, State Laws Governing Local Govern-
sis added. ment Structure and Administration, pp. 25–26.
326. Rudiger Ahrend, Catherine Gamper, and Data are for 1990.
Abel Schumann, “The OECD Metropolitan 340. Leland and Thurmaier, “Lessons from 35 Years of
Governance Survey: A Quantitative Description of City-County Consolidation Attempts,” p. 9.
Governance Structures in Large Urban Agglo- 341. Jamie L. Palmer and Greg Lindsey, “Classifying
merations,” OECD Regional Development State Approaches to Annexation,” State and
Working Papers (Brussels: OECD Publishing, Local Government Review 33 (Winter 2001),
2014). Data are for 2000–2006. pp. 60–73. Data are for “the 1970s”–1997.
327. Elaine S. Povitch, “History, Politics and Pride: 342. David Rusk, Annexation and the Fiscal Fate of
Why Small Cities, Counties Rarely Merge,” Cities (Washington, DC: Brookings, 2006), p. 1.
Stateline.com (March 10, 2016). 343. As derived from data in Walker, The Rebirth
328. Task Force on Local Government Consolidation of Federalism, p. 292, and Rodger Johnson,
and Unfunded Mandates, Delivering Efficient, Marc Perry, and Lisa Lollock, “Annexation and
Effective, and Streamlined Government to Illinois Population Growth in American Cities, 1990–
Taxpayers, p. 5. 2000,” Municipal Year Book, 2004 (Washington,
329. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental DC: International City/County Management
Relations, Intergovernmental Service Arrange- Association, 2004), pp. 3–7. During the 1990s,
ments for Delivering Local Public Services, p. 98. cities annexed 36 percent more land and 62
330. Kevin Klinkenberg, Why I Walk (Gabriola Island, percent more people than they did, on average, in
BC: New Society, 2014), p. 27. each of the preceding two decades.
331. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 95. Figures are 344. Walker, The Rebirth of Federalism, p. 292. Figure
for 1990. We are using Rusk’s definition of metro is for 1970–1989.
government, and a universe of all 320 metro areas 345. Rusk, Cities Without Suburbs, p. 10. Figure is for
as of 1990. 1950–1990.
CHAPTER

13

Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic

S o long as there were “principles” of public


administration, ethics were irrelevant to its prac-
tice; “science,” on which the field was purportedly
the public professions (and, therefore, confronts
knotty problems in writing a uniquely broad ethical
code), rejected attempts to adopt a code of ethics
based, is, after all, neither ethical nor unethical. By in 1938 and 1949. It first adopted a code in 1984,
the mid-twentieth century, as scholars reconsidered revised it in 1994, and, in 2013, adopted a new code
this paradigm, their views on the legitimacy of ethics that reaches out to those in specialized public pro-
began to alter, and today a concern with ethical fessions.
behavior occupies a prominent place in the field. That critical component of professionalism, the
universities, also have recognized the importance of
public ethics. The field’s national accrediting body
CODES AND COMMISSIONS: THE requires graduate education in ethics, and all intro-
ductory public administration textbooks include
RISE OF PUBLIC SECTOR ETHICS a  discussion of ethics.1 (This text, the reader may
An underappreciated fact about the development have noticed, contains several such discussions
of  a bureaucratic ethic is that practicing public throughout.)
administrators, not scholars or elected officials,
introduced it.
Ethics for Governments
Governments lagged behind the public professions
Ethics for the Public Professions in recognizing ethics, but, by the mid-twentieth
What is now the International City/County century, they were catching up. Today, more gov-
Management Association adopted the first code of ernment workers (47 percent) than either non-
ethics for a public profession in 1924. The code profit employees (44 percent) or businesspeople
reflected the anti-corruption values of the munici- (38 percent) report that their organization has a full
pal reform movement of the period, and essentially ethics and compliance program in place.2
held up efficiency as its ethical touchstone. Despite
its initial narrowness, the city managers’ code was Federal Ethics Congress first imposed a general
groundbreaking and other public professions fol- code of ethics on federal administrators in 1958,
lowed suit. All the associations that represent the and, twenty years later, with the passage of the Ethics
profession’s major specializations now have codes in Government Act of 1978, expanded the code and
of, and provide training in, ethics for their members. founded the Office of Government Ethics and the
The American Society for Public Administration, Office of Independent Counsel, charged with investi-
which is the most representative association of all gating federal officials over ethical concerns. Also in

500
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 501

that year, Congress enacted the Civil Service Reform 68 percent, received grades of “D” or “F” from a
Act, which listed for the first time Merit System national investigation.7
Principles and Prohibited Personnel Practices; Weak codes of ethics derive from state policies
several of these principles and practices pertain to that protect state officials from public knowledge.
ethical, or unethical, actions. In 1992, the Office Disclosure of tax returns is not required for state offi-
of Government Ethics released the federal govern- cials in any state. “In most states, the personal finan-
ment’s first comprehensive set of standards of ethical cial records of candidates for state office and elected
conduct, composed of some forty pages that focus officials . . . are hidden behind arcane rules and
mostly on conflicts of financial interest and impar- labyrinthine accessibility”; in nineteen states, finan-
tiality. In 2016, the Office of Government Ethics cial disclosure forms completed by legislators are
issued a revised code that required educating new unavailable online. Three states—Idaho, Michigan,
hires in ethics, providing specific ethics responsibili- and Vermont—do not require any financial disclo-
ties for supervisors, and strengthened the ethical role sures from state elected officials.8 And, in those few
of inspectors general. states that do require elected officials and candidates
In 2008, Congress, largely as the result of to submit financial disclosure forms to ethics com-
a lobbying scandal, established an Office of missions, perhaps not even 10 percent of the forms
Congressional Ethics, which has been commended receive a “substantive review” due to a lack of funds.9
as “a proven force for good on Capitol Hill.”3 Largely because of the widespread adoption of
Evidence of this judgment may be found in the the reformist council manager plan, a remarkable 86
House of Representatives, which, on the very first percent of cities and counties have codes of ethics,
day of the new Congress that convened in 2017, covering 79 percent of staffers and 83 percent of
voted to gut the office; angry constituents flooded elected officials.10 Local elected officials in twenty
representatives with phone calls and emails, causing states, a growing number, are subject to state-
a quick reinstatement of the office. imposed ethics codes.11
Nearly 9,000 federal employees work, at least
sometimes, in ethics programs.4 In part, this large
number derives from the facts that “Congress has PRACTICING ETHICAL
enacted laws and presidents have issued executive PUBLIC AND NONPROFIT
orders that have produced a deeply layered and
extraordinarily cumbersome regulatory scheme ADMINISTRATION
designed to insure the integrity of federal employ- Practicing public and nonprofit ethics have their
ees,” and clarity, simplicity, and straightforwardness own unique challenges.
suffer.5

Grass-Roots’ Ethics The first general code of Ethical Environments


state ethics was legislated in 1954 by the New York Public administrators toil on slippery ethical slopes.
general assembly, and now forty-seven states have For nearly two decades, virtually all public admin-
some form of written ethics code. As ethics codes go, istrators in federal, state, and local governments
they are less than satisfactory. In more than half the have agreed that they “encounter ethical dilemmas
states, codes do not address even as many as four at work,”12 14 percent of whom feel pressured to
out of six basic areas of ethics legislation, to wit: the compromise their ethics, an increase of two-fifths
presence of an ethics code (pretty basic, that); man- from four years earlier,13 compared with 11 percent
datory financial disclosure; and limits on honoraria, of nonprofit employees14 and 10 percent of busi-
gifts from lobbyists, post-government employment, nesspeople.15 The longer that one works in the
and representation of clients before state agencies.6 federal government, the likelier that one will per-
Forty-one states have established commissions ceive a worsening ethical climate, although promo-
to oversee ethics issues. Most are largely tooth- tion to “supervisory status attenuates this negative
less, vulnerable, reactive, fragmented, symbolic, effect”16—perhaps because they are now part of
and underfunded, and twenty-eight of them, or what they had earlier perceived to be the problem.
502 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Yet, there are also heartening ethical signs. The who also possess higher levels of education and pro-
proportion of public administrators at all govern- fessionalism) is approximately twice that of manag-
mental levels who think that their supervisors are ers who register lower ethical levels (17 percent).27
under pressure to compromise their personal stand-
ards has declined by more than two-fifths, from A Higher Ethical Standard Public administra-
50 percent to 35 percent, over seventeen years.17 tors’ ethical commitment is all the more remarkable
Although declining from 55 percent over five years, because large majorities see themselves as adher-
52 percent of federal employees think that “my ing to a higher ethical standard than just about
organization’s leaders maintain high standards of anybody else—elected and appointed officials, senior
honesty and integrity.”18 And all—100 percent— government managers,28 businesspeople,29 and even
high-level municipal officials report that their the taxpayers who pay their salaries (public admin-
managers “demonstrate” ethical conduct,19 a most istrators express much greater umbrage over govern-
satisfying number in light of empirical research mental scandals than does the general public).30
which reveals that employees’ views of their leaders’ Public administrators do not claim a higher
personal conduct (e.g., strong character, keeping morality than their nonprofit counterparts, and with
promises) drives their perceptions of their ethical reason; nonprofit employees are significantly less
leadership, perceptions that can render organiza- likely than either public- or private-sector workers
tions more—or less—ethical.20 to say that their “job requires violating [their] con-
As with cities, nonprofit organizations exude science.”31
“moral leadership,” and their employees “have a
considerably more positive view of their employ- Walking the Ethical Walk More than half of all
er’s morality than do employees in the other two public employees, almost exactly the same propor-
sectors,” as demonstrated by the “amazing 82%” of tion as in the nonprofit and private sectors, state
these employees who thought that their employer that they have observed “misconduct,” ranging from
had “strong moral values and principles,” compared “Internet abuse” to theft, in their workplaces during
with 60 percent of private-sector employees and “a the previous year. What is important in this context
mere 30%” public-sector workers.21 is that government workers are much more likely to
report such misconduct than are their nonprofit and
business counterparts, and their willingness to do
Committing to Ethics so is steadily growing. Whistle blowing “was by far
Public administrators are committed to ethics. more prevalent among public sector employees who
Graduates of the top public administration programs had observed some form of misconduct,” with 87
rank “maintaining ethical standards” as the single percent of them blowing the whistle, compared with
most important “skill,” by far, for achieving success, 59 percent of nonprofit workers and a modest 46 of
regardless of where they are employed—govern- for-profit employees.32
ments, businesses, or nonprofit organizations.22 Public administrators are not only talking the
Skills must be honed. In the case of public-sector ethical talk, but also are walking the ethical walk.
ethics, “ethics training [provided by 54 percent of
local governments23], interaction with ethics offi-
cials, and perceived knowledge about ethics topics DO MORALS MATTER?
consistently influence perceptions of ethical climate Do ethics matter? Are governments and their bureau-
and advice-seeking behavior in a positive way.”24 crats more effective because they are ethical?
More than three-quarters of federal, state, and Among governments, a low “ethical climate”
local managers believe that “ethical concerns can be associates with greater damage and injury to cit-
empowering in organizations” (only 7 percent dis- izens  and businesses, more complaints from the
agree), up from two-thirds a decade earlier.25 City public,33 and a tendency to “disregard accountabil-
managers display a solid knowledge of their profes- ity and responsiveness” in governing.34
sion’s code of ethics,26 and, happily, the number of By contrast, a high ethical climate (that is,
city managers with higher ethics (“about one-third,” managers who set a good ethical example, and
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 503

communicate and enforce high ethical standards) channel bureaucrats into making decisions that are
correlates with fewer employees who take sick leave democratic, ethical, legal, and fair. Hence, not to
and take less of it, workers who are more likely to worry; nothing more is needed.
think that their departments provide customers with
better value for their money, employees who plan Internal Constraints and External Controls Just
to keep working in their departments,35 and govern- what these restraints are depends on the scholar.
ments that experience fewer lawsuits, better bond Some argue that internal constraints, whether
ratings, and are more likely to implement state-of- founded on their professional socialization40 or stem-
the-art productivity improvements.36 ming from their own “moral foundations,”41 inhibit
As these findings suggest, high ethics and high public administrators from committing unethical
administrative competence waltz gracefully together. acts. Others contend that external controls—laws,42
An empirical analysis of public administrators con- courts,43 publicity,44 legislative surveillance,45
cluded that “the concepts of virtue and competence bureaucratic decentralization,46 and citizen par-
are, in practice, very similar . . . because virtue is ticipation in bureaucratic decision making47—assure
an integral feature of managerial competencies.”37 ethical behavior. Still others maintain that a combi-
Public executives who have high ethical standards nation of internal and external variables reinforce
also win more “policy debates” with colleagues.38 one another to the benefit of the public interest.48
In short, high ethics associate with better gov-
ernance and more successful public careers. What Do Public Administrators Use? How reflec-
tive this literature is of the real bureaucratic world
is, at best, unclear. Some research finds that internal
BUREAUCRACY’S BANE: inhibitors are salient; those agencies in which the
DETERMINING THE PUBLIC values of efficiency, effectiveness, quality, excellence,
and teamwork are dominant associate with high
INTEREST ethical expectations and standards.49 Another inves-
Central to a bureaucratic ethic is this singular ques- tigation concludes the opposite, finding that public
tion: How do public administrators determine what administrators rely heavily on an external control,
is in “the public interest”? Regrettably, “little of the the law itself, as their principal guide in dealing with
literature of public administration reflects on the ethical issues; internal constraints—personal belief
nature of the public interest.”39 systems and professional values—run a very distant
In the legislature, the public interest is deter- second.50
mined by majority vote. The courts commonly rely
on stare decisis, or judicial precedent, which provides A Missed Point The bureaucratic-accountability
an evolutionary system of legal principles through writers have usefully listed attitudes and mecha-
which the public interest is fulfilled. When we nisms that may prevent, correct, or punish public
approach government’s executive branch, however, administrators for making decisions that are not in
we find no similarly clear-cut method of determining the public interest. But they have not recommended
the public’s interest, though public administration- any systematic and proactive practice (and certainly
ists have tried, contradictorily, to both rationalize none with the elegant simplicity and practical utility
that such a method is unnecessary and to develop of majority vote and judicial precedent) that bureau-
such a method. crats actually could use to make such decisions.
Moreover, as the scant empirical evidence on the
topic suggests, there is no systematic practice.
Bureaucratic Accountability: Skirting the
Question
The academic effort to avoid the question of how Organizational Humanism: Addressing the
public administrators should make decisions that are Question, but Irrelevantly So
in the public interest is called bureaucratic account- In contrast to the students of bureaucratic account-
ability, or the study of how various restraints safely ability, another band of public administrationists
504 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

does posit a systemic ethical framework for bureau-


cratic decision making. These are the organizational CAN NORMATIVE THEORY HELP?
humanists. FOUR PHILOSOPHIES OF THE
“The Ends of Man”: The Ultimate Bureaucratic
PUBLIC INTEREST
Value Organizational humanism is a philoso- So the problem remains: the public administrator
phy of public ethics that is founded on the precept (and, for that matter, the nonprofit administrator)
that personal dignity is “the ultimate value,” and, needs a simple and operational articulation of the
therefore, the public interest is to always treat each public interest that permits him or her to make a
person humanely. Organizational humanism, in its decision, based on rational thinking, that is in the
more candid mode, “forwards the proposition that public interest.
the ends of man are the ends of man. . . . it is not Should we move beyond the confines of the
willing to compromise its human values on any scholarly community of public administration in
grounds.”51 addressing this issue? Can the world’s great philos-
The organizational humanists are attractive ophers help?
because they make no bones about what they think There are four philosophies of the public inter-
is important. The school’s problem lies in its applica- est that are relevant to bureaucratic decision making.
tion. Devils always lurk in the details.

Applying Organizational Humanism: A Non-


Intuitionism: Morally Muddling Through
Starter Consider, for example, how organizational One is intuitionism, advocated by Aristotle, among
humanism would treat affirmative action. There are others, which expounds a plurality of first princi-
two, value-based positions in this controversy. ples, all of them, no doubt, admirable. As a prac-
One is that government should make special tical matter, however, these principles can conflict
efforts, including the reduction of entrance and pro- with one another when applied to specific situations,
motion standards, to hire and advance members of and intuitionism offers no method, other than one’s
those segments of society that have endured unfair intuition, for choosing which principle should take
discrimination through no fault of their own. precedence.
The other position is that no “lowering of stand- Intuitionism amounts to morally muddling
ards” should be considered, regardless of the appli- through. Would intuitionism help us in resolving our
cant’s past tribulations, because government owes dilemma of affirmative action? As with organiza-
the best governance possible to all the governed, tional humanism, who knows?
deprived people included.
Would the organizational humanists be for or
against affirmative action? Who knows?
Perfectionism: Promoting Perfect People
Organizational humanism states only that “the Another germane philosophy is perfectionism,
ultimate value” in bureaucratic decision making is which, in contrast to intuitionism, has no problem of
“the ends of man.” Is humanity best served by hiring ambiguity. Perfectionism contends that the sole prin-
a deprived-group member who does not execute his ciple in determining the public interest should be the
or her duties satisfactorily, or is it best served by not promotion of excellence in art, science, and culture.
hiring that same person? This dilemma can be ren- Any misfortune for society’s less abled segments that
dered even more exquisite when an incompetent, or results is morally justified because the entire society
even just a less competent, deprived-group member is lifted that much nearer to perfection.
applies to an agency charged with ending discrimi- Friedrich Nietzsche is exemplary of a perfec-
nation against deprived groups. tionist perspective. As Nietzsche put it so pithily,
It seems reasonably apparent that organiza- the deepest meaning that can be given to the human
tional humanism does not offer much of a guide to experience is “your living for the rarest and most
the public administrator in formulating a decision valuable specimens,”52 and Nietzsche evidently
that is in the public interest. included himself among those specimens.
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 505

Unsurprisingly, perfectionism’s opinion of is to have an equal right to the most extensive


affirmative action is clear: To hell with it. basic liberty compatible with a similar liberty for
others,” and (2) that “social and economic inequal-
ities are  to be arranged so that they are both (a)
Utilitarianism: The Most Benefits for the reasonably expected to be to everyone’s advan-
Most People tage,  and (b) attached to positions and offices
A third ethical framework for the determination of open  to all.”54  Should these principles come into
the public interest is utilitarianism, represented by conflict,  the second is expected to yield to the
John Stuart Mill, among others. Utilitarianism holds first; thus, just as in organizational humanism, the
that if a public policy makes most people better dignity of  the individual person is of paramount
off, even if some people are left worse off, then the importance.
public interest is served. Rawls’s theory of justice goes further, however.
Utilitarianism differs from intuitionism in that it His principles necessarily lead to the conclusion that
is systematic in its logic, and from perfectionism in inequalities of wealth, authority, and social oppor-
that it is democratic in its values. tunity “are just only if they result in compensating
An example of a utilitarian policy would be one benefits for everyone, and in particular for the least
that raised everyone’s taxes and sent the resultant advantaged members of society. These principles
revenues to physicians. Such a policy would make rule out justifying institutions on the grounds that
everyone healthier (that is, better off) by encour- the hardships of some are offset by a greater good in
aging more people to enter the medical profession. the aggregate. It may be expedient but it is not just
Even though society’s least well off taxpayers would that some should have less in order that others may
lose money under this arrangement, the policy prosper.”55
nonetheless would be in the public interest because In short, as Rawls observes, his principles in
everyone’s net balance of health would be enhanced, essence are a rigorous statement of the traditional
including that of the least well off. Anglo-Saxon concept of fairness.
Utilitarians would reject affirmative action as a
policy reflective of the public interest because it does Applying Fairness: A Real Starter Rawls’s and
not, in theory, make everyone better off. Under util- Popper’s theories argue for affirmative action
itarianism’s criteria, affirmative action makes only because not hiring society’s most deprived people
certain groups better off. would deprive them further. Hiring them, on the
other hand, would facilitate the full realization of
their “basic liberty” without encroaching on the
Fairness: A Theory of Justice basic liberty of others, and would help assure that all
Utilitarianism has much going for it, but there offices are open to all and that the privileges innate
remains the gnawing issue of what to do about the to such offices would continue to work toward the
bottom of society, a stratum that utilitarian policies advantage of all in a reasonably equal way.
slap in the chops.
The Unique Usefulness of Fairness as the Public
A Philosophy of Fairness In 1945, Karl Popper Interest When applied with the rigor brought by
suggested that, “Instead of the greatest happiness Rawls and Popper, fairness offers the public admin-
for the greatest number [as the utilitarians advo- istrator a workable, rational way for determining the
cate], one should demand, more modestly, the least public interest. So, for that matter, do perfectionism
amount of avoidable suffering for all; and further, and utilitarianism (but not organizational human-
that unavoidable suffering . . . should be distributed ism and intuitionism, which have severe problems of
as equally as possible.”53 workability or logic). We think, however, that per-
A generation later, John Rawls extended fectionism and utilitarianism are not appropriate for
Popper’s ideas, contending that the public interest American public administrators because the former’s
can be discerned in most situations by applying values are incompatible with the dominant values of
two “principles of justice”: (1) that “each person American society, and the latter’s logic permits the
506 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

least advantaged people in society to be disadvan- that levy a progressive tax on personal income,
taged further. Readers, of course, are free to disagree. and no government imposes a regressive income
tax, whether personal or corporate. Mainstream
personal income tax codes are purposely designed
Does Philosophy Matter? to assure that the least well off are not made less
We have reviewed four philosophies of the public well off, a principle that is central to Rawls’s and
interest. So what? Does the ivory tower matter in the Popper’s theory.
corridors of power? Even in the dank recesses of governmental
We remind those who might sneer, No, in bureaucracies, philosophy flourishes.
answering our question that to be both cynical and
unworldly is a particularly unattractive combina-
tion. Philosophy does, in fact, affect bureaucratic WHAT IS TO BE DONE?
decision making and public policy, and it does so in IMPLEMENTING ETHICAL
deep and meaningful ways.
Aristotle’s intuitionism pervades the public PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
sector. Its popularity, however, is not due to its intel- In 1902, the Russian Communist, V. I. Lenin,
lectual force. Rather, intuitionism is singularly easy demanded, “What is to be done?” about the plight
to choose as a theory of the public interest, in part of the proletariat, and promptly answered his own
because most public administrators are unaware question with: Revolution!
that they are choosing it. Most public adminis- Something akin to a revolution may be needed
trators, like most of us, make decisions on the basis to cope with government’s most egregious and
of what seems to be the most nearly right at the destructive form of unethical behavior, corruption, a
time. This, in essence, is what intuitionism is all suppurating public pustule that inspired the found-
about. ing of public administration itself. Perhaps it is time
Nietzsche’s perfectionism has been consciously to return to our roots.
selected by the National Science Foundation as its An irony in the endless American effort to curtail
operating philosophy of the public interest. The corruption is that its locus seems to have shifted over
Foundation’s mission of financing “pure” scientific the course of the twentieth and twenty-first centuries
research—that science should be funded for the sake from state and local governments to the federal one.
of science—is a clear expression of the perfectionist The nearly universal professionalizing of state civil
principle. services and the dominance of the council-manager
Utilitarianism is the official, if unacknowl- plan in local governments clearly correlate with the
edged, premise on which policy choices are made dramatic decline in corruption in these jurisdictions.
by the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, and likely by As we reviewed in Chapter 11, however, Washington
many other agencies, too. The Corps has adopted appears to be awash in conflicts of interest and spe-
“benefit/cost analysis” as its method of deciding cial-interest influence—corruption that Congress
which engineering projects are in the best inter- has legally tolerated.
ests of the nation, and benefits and costs are cast in Nowhere are Washington’s conflicts-of-interest
terms of dollars saved or lost. Hence, proposed pro- and special-interest influence more glaringly evident
jects, such as flood control, that protect trailer parks than in the administration of President Donald
and poor people, rather than McMansions and rich J. Trump. Contrary to past presidents, President
people, would not make the cut because manors are Trump refuses to release his tax returns; he is both
worth more than mobile homes. To protect cheaper landlord and tenant of a Washington hotel, a hotel
homes at the expense of costlier ones would violate that foreign rulers and diplomats are growing
benefit/cost precepts—and utilitarian precepts as increasingly fond of inhabiting (some paying five
well.56 times more than the normal room rate57) and he
Rawls’s and Popper’s theory of justice is widely owns more than 400 condos that are on the market
implemented; it furnishes the philosophic founda- for about $90 million; any would-be presidential
tion for the vast majority of American governments influencer could happily pay considerably more
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 507

than top dollar for one or many. There is far more, particularly among those public administrators who
none of it good. Unsurprising, perhaps, early in its are at the forefront of protecting the public inter-
presidential term the Trump administration backed est from the predations of private interests.60 This
out of its scheduled ethics training for its top execu- problem is especially acute in the federal govern-
tives, training similar to that which the two previous ment, where regulation and privatization—two huge
administrations had taken. and sprawling areas that are uniquely susceptible
We are not suggesting that all state and local to graft—expanded radically during the twentieth
governments are angelic; far too many have yet to century and into this one.
ascend to purgatory. But the grass-roots govern- The city-state of Singapore exemplifies the
ments do seem to have cultivated more successfully public benefits brought by competitive public sal-
than their federal cousin two qualities (detailed in aries. Its government’s ministers (i.e., cabinet-level
Chapter 1) that are vital to ethical—and effective— executives) are paid more than $1 million, with
governing. They are: Public trust in government, and comparably competitive salaries down the line.
popular esteem for those who govern. Prior to 1990, Singapore was “one of the more
How can public trust and esteem for gov- corrupt countries on the planet,”61 but now boasts
ernment be raised? Aside from legislating ethical “one of the world’s least corrupt and most efficient
behavior for the current president, increasing public bureaucracies.”62 With just over five million people,
administrators’ compensation would be a start, Singapore has impressively vast financial reserves of
as higher incomes correlate not only with higher more than $250 billion, a starkly solid sign of good
social status for those who earn them, but also with governance.
greater trust in government; recall from Chapters Raising public pay is not a cakewalk. After
9 and 12 that state and local public administrators California mandated that municipal salaries be made
not only earn more, on average, than their federal public, in 2010, those city managers whose salaries
counterparts, but that their governments also are had not been disclosed earlier “experienced average
more trusted than the federal government. The con- compensation declines of approximately 8 percent”
nections among higher public trust, higher public relative to city managers whose salaries had been
esteem, and higher public pay are real. disclosed before the state mandate. The decline was
There are additional benefits. In a unique study, the result of wage cuts, which had nothing to do with
it was determined that “higher wages attract more budgetary stress or whether salaries were out of line,
able applicants as measured by their IQ, person- but was “more consistent with a ‘populist’ response
ality, and proclivity towards public sector work to perceptions of excessive salaries”; following the
. . . higher wage offers also increased acceptance salaries’ public posting, “the city manager quit rate
rates.”58 increased by 75 percent.”63
As noted in the introduction to Part III, A whopping 68 percent of Americans believe
greater pay also reduces corruptive temptations,59 that private-sector employees work harder than

THE PASSION OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION

Although, as we observed at the beginning of this Robert Moses is sometimes called “America’s greatest
book, constraint is the dominating characteristic in the builder,” and the term is not hyperbolic. He confided
culture immersing America’s public administrators, to friends his grand plans to transmogrify New York
they nonetheless make large—sometimes very large— as early as 1914, while still in his twenties, and began
decisions. Consider the case, and the ethics, of New his career as a “Goo-Goo,” that dismissive term
York’s Robert Moses, who transitioned from dreamy used by Tammany Hall politicians to describe “good
idealist to one of the preeminent power brokers of the government” reformers.
twentieth century. (continued)
508 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

(continued)
Throughout his entire career (1924–1968), Moses There was, however, a dark side to his genius.
never held an elected office. Instead, he secured To build, Moses destroyed. His projects, which, with
appointments to head numerous public authorities, few exceptions, were built for the middle class and the
basking in such modestly-titled positions as wealthy, required razing the homes of a half-million
“Coordinator,” or as an authority’s board member— people, most of them poor. Asked if he had ever
but often its only member. At his peak, Moses considered altering his projects to save their homes, Moses
headed fourteen state and city authorities at the same retorted, “‘Nah’ . . . I can still hear the scorn in his voice
time. as he said it . . . scorn for me who had thought it necessary
Moses added to the city 416 miles of parkways; to ask about them” (Caro, “The City Shaper,” p. 52).
15,000 acres through his shoreline projects; and over Moses routinely employed deception, slander, libel,
a thousand apartment buildings housing more people blackmail, and thinly-veiled bribery to achieve his
than lived in Minneapolis. goals, tactics that resulted in “some of the greatest
In the state, Moses built all but one of its major scandals of twentieth century New York, scandals
expressways; seven of the nine bridges linking almost incredible . . . for the colossal scale of their
Manhattan with the mainland; a number of huge power corruption.” Moses boasted (jokingly, one hopes)
dams; and parks. By the time Moses had finished, New that “nothing I have ever done has been tinged with
York owned 45 percent of all the nation’s acreage legality” (Caro, “The City Shaper,” p. 42). Though
devoted to state parks. personally “money honest” (to employ a term for a
Nationally, Moses was instrumental in drafting complex reality that only New Yorkers could express
the life-changing Interstate Highway Act and the so succinctly), his “Moses men,” his closest allies and
controversial Urban Renewal program. His interest administrators, became multimillionaires.
in Urban Renewal was understandable: Moses, who Being money honest, however, did not mean that
controlled all such projects in New York, spent more this particular bureaucrat subsisted in a low-profile
than twice the amount of federal Urban Renewal life of genteel modesty. Indeed, Moses’s positions
dollars than did all other cities combined. came with a multitude of expensive and enviable perks,
As the urban scholar, Lewis Mumford, one of including a yacht, skippered by three captains, for his
Moses’s most tenacious foes, stated, “In the twentieth personal use, and four dining rooms scattered around
century, the influence of Robert Moses on the cities of the city, each with its own full-time staff, who served
America was greater than that of any other person” only Moses and his guests. The secretaries who worked
(Caro, The Power Broker, p. 12). in his authorities were not only paid more than New
Was Moses good or bad for New York—and the York City’s commissioners, but also were given bigger
nation? cars, driven by chauffeurs who were on call twenty-four/
To his everlasting credit, Moses rammed through seven.
titanic projects that employed thousands, moved Through some adroit, if ethically questionable,
hundreds of thousands, and created greenswards maneuvering by New York’s governor, Moses lost all his
enjoyed by millions. And “rammed” is the apt verb. power in 1968. But Moses never gave up. As a labor
Moses manifested a “savage energy” that would erupt leader put it, “They want him to get tired and to go
into a “fury” when his plans were frustrated. He “would away and get lost. But I say, ‘Forget it!’ This guy don’t
lunge out of his chair and begin, as one aide put it, blow away” (Caro, “The City Shaper,” p. 53).
‘waving his arms, just wild,’ pick up the old-fashioned Robert Moses died in 1981. He was ninety-two, still
inkwell on his desk and hurl it at aides so hard that a fighter.
it shattered against a wall; how he would pound his
Sources: Robert A. Caro, The Power Broker: Robert Moses
clenched fists into the walls hard enough to scrape the and the Fall of New York (New York: Knopf, 1974) and
skin off them, in a rage beyond the perception of pain” Robert A. Caro, “The City Shaper,” The New Yorker (January
(Caro, “The City Shaper,” pp. 48–49). 5, 1998), pp. 42–53.
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 509

those in the public sector (just 9 percent think other- University Press, 2005), pp. 5, 10–11. Data are for
wise),64 and only 13 percent agree that the salaries of 1996.
public administrators should be raised “to encour- 7. David Zalubowski, Policing the Politicians: State
age the best people to go into government.”65 Yet, Ethics Commissions Lack Muscle (Washington,
for the sake of that very citizenry, the challenge must DC: Center for Public Integrity, 2013). Figures are
be faced. for 2013.
8. Elaine S. Povich, “State Financial Disclosure
Antiquated, Inaccessible,” Stateline (October 27,
2016). Data are for 2016.
BIG BUREAUCRACY, BIG 9. Robert W. Smith, “Enforcement or Ethical Capacity:
DECISIONS Considering the Role of State Ethics Commissions
It is fitting to close this book with a thought about at the Millennium,” Public Administration Review
63 (May/June 2003), pp. 283–295.
the ultimate duty of the public and nonprofit admin-
10. International City/County Management Asso-
istrator. That duty is to make ethical decisions.
ciation, ICMA State of the Profession 2012 Survey
Public and nonprofit administrators’ decisions can
Results (Washington, DC: Author, 2016), Q. 8–9.
be immensely far-reaching, or affect just one person. 11. U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
But each of them changes people, for good or ill. Relations, State Laws Governing Local
We request that, if you enter these fields or are Government Structure and Administration, M-186
now in one, you remember to ask yourself how (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
people will be helped or hurt by your decisions. Few Office, 1993), p. 33. Figure is for 1990. In 1978,
questions are more important in any context, but in seventeen states imposed ethics codes.
the contexts of the public and voluntary life of your 12. James S. Bowman and Claire Connolly Knox,
nation, none is more important. “Ethics in Government: No Matter How Long and
Dark the Night,” Public Administration Review 68
(July/August 2008), pp. 627–639. The quotation is
NOTES on p. 628. Ninety-seven percent said this in 1989,
1. James S. Bowman, Evan M. Berman, and Jonathan 1996, and 2006.
P. West, “The Profession of Public Administration: 13. Ethics Resource Center, National Government
An Ethics Edge in Introductory Textbooks?” Public Ethics Survey: An Inside View of Public Sector
Administration Review 61 (March/April 2001), Ethics (Arlington, VA: Author, 2008), p. 6. Figure
pp. 194–205. is for 2007. In 2003, 10 percent of government
2. Ethics Resource Center, National Nonprofit Ethics workers said this.
Survey: An Inside View of Nonprofit Sector Ethics 14. Ethics Resource Center, National Nonprofit Ethics
(Arlington, VA: Author, 2008), pp. 22, 2. Figures Survey, p. 16. Figure is for 2007.
are for 2007. 15. Ethics Resource Center, National Business Ethics
3. The Editors, “Congress’s Unpopular Watchdog,” Survey: An Inside View of Private Sector Ethics
New York Times (September 21, 2012). (Arlington, VA: Author, 2008), p. 16. Figure is for
4. Robert W. Smith, “Corporate Ethics Officers and 2007.
Government Ethics Administrators: Comparing 16. Eric D. Raile, “Building Ethical Capital: Perceptions
Apples with Oranges or a Lesson to Be Learned?” of Ethical Climate in the Public Sector,” Public
Administration & Society 34 (January 2003), Administration Review 73 (March/April 2013),
pp. 632–652. The quotation is on p. 639. Figure is pp. 253–262. The quotation is on p. 253.
for 1998. 17. Bowman and Knox, “Ethics in Government,”
5. National Commission on the Public Service, Urgent p. 629. Figures are for 1989–2006.
Business for America: Revitalizing the Federal 18. U.S. Office of Personnel Management, 2016 Federal
Government for the 21st Century (Washington, Employee Viewpoint Survey Results (Washington,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 2003), DC: U.S. Government Publishing Office, 2016),
pp. 21–22. Q. 54. Figures are for 2012–2016.
6. Beth A. Rosenson, Shadowlands of Conduct: Ethics 19. Mary Ann Feldheim and Xiaohu Wang, “Ethics
and State Politics (Washington, DC: Georgetown and Public Trust: Results from a National Survey,”
510 PA R T I V Implementing Public Policy

Public Integrity 6 (Winter 2003–2004), pp. 63–75. 37. Michael Macaulay and Alan Lawton, “From
Figures (p. 70) are for 2000. Virtue to Competence: Changing the Principles of
20. Ethics Resource Center, Ethical Leadership: Every Public Service,” Public Administration Review 66
Leader Sets a Tone (Arlington, VA: Author, 2014). (September/October 2006), pp. 702–710. The quo-
21. Joyce Rothschild, “The Fate of Whistleblowers tations are on pp. 701, 709.
in Nonprofit Organizations,” Nonprofit and 38. Jason L. Jenson, “Getting One’s Way in Policy
Voluntary Sector Quarterly 42 (5, 2013), pp. 886– Debates: Influence Tactics Used in Group Decision-
901. The quotations are on p. 896. Figures are for Making Settings,” Public Administration Review
2013. 67 (March/April 2007), pp. 216–227.
22. Paul C. Light, The New Public Service (Washington, 39. Eugene D. Dvorin and Robert H. Simmons, From
DC: Brookings, 1999), p. 110. Amoral to Humane Bureaucracy (San Francisco:
23. International City/County Management Asso- Canfield Press, 1972), p. 61.
ciation, ICMA State of the Profession 2012 Survey 40. Carl J. Friedrich and Taylor Cole, Responsible
Results, Q. 10. Bureaucracy (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
24. Raile, “Building Ethical Capital,” p. 253. Press, 1949).
25. Bowman and Knox, “Ethics in Government,” 41. Kathryn Denhardt, “Unearthing the Moral
p. 628. Figures are for 2006 and 1996. Foundations of Public Administration: Honor,
26. Greg Streib and Mark Rivera, “Assessing the Benevolence, and Justice,” Ethical Frontiers in
Ethical Knowledge of City Managers,” Public Public Management, James S. Bowman, ed. (San
Integrity 12 (Winter 2009/2010), pp. 9–23. Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1991), pp. 256–283.
27. Evan M. Berman and Jonathan P. West, 42. John A. Rohr, Ethics for Bureaucrats: An Essay
“Responsible Risk-Taking,” Public Administration on Law and Values, 2nd ed. (New York: Marcel
Review 58 (July/August 1998), pp. 346–352. Dekker, 1989).
28. James S. Bowman and Russell L. Williams, “Ethics 43. K. C. Davis, Administrative Law (St. Paul: West
in Government: From a Winter of Despair to a Publishing, 1951).
Spring of Hope,” Public Administration Review 57 44. Gordon Tullock, The Politics of Bureaucracy
(November/December 1997), pp. 517–526. (Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press, 1965).
29. Bowman and Knox, “Ethics in Government,” 45. Charles S. Hyneman, Bureaucracy (New York:
p. 629. Harper & Row, 1950).
30. James S. Bowman, “Ethics in Government: A 46. Dwight Waldo, “Development of a Theory of
National Survey of Public Administrators,” Public Democratic Administration,” American Political
Administration Review 50 (May/June 1990), Science Review 46 (March 1952), pp. 81–103.
pp. 345–353. 47. L. Von Mises, Bureaucracy (New Haven, CT: Yale
31. Philip H. Mirvis and Edward J. Hackett, “Work University Press, 1944).
and Work Force Characteristics in the Nonprofit 48. Terry L. Cooper, The Responsible Administrator
Sector,” Monthly Labor Review 106 (April 1983), (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1990).
pp. 3–12. The quotation is on p. 10. Data are for 49. Donald C. Menzel, “The Ethical Environment of
1977. Local Government Managers,” American Review
32. Rothschild, “The Fate of Whistleblowers in of Public Administration 25 (September 1995),
Nonprofit Organizations,” p. 896. Figures are for pp. 247–261.
2013. 50. Harold F. Gortner, Ethics for Public Managers
33. Colleen G. Waring and C’Anne Daugherty, (New York: Praeger, 1991).
“Auditing Ethics—Make Them an Offer They 51. Dvorin and Simmons, From Amoral to Humane
Can’t Refuse,” Journal of Government Financial Bureaucracy, p. 61, 60. The authors are explaining
Management 53 (Spring 2004), pp. 34–40. what they call “radical humanism,” which appears
34. Berman and West, “Responsible Risk-Taking,” to be a more plainly-spoken version of organiza-
p. 349. tional humanism.
35. Waring and Daugherty, “Auditing Ethics—Make 52. Friedrich Nietzsche, as quoted in J. R. Hollingsdale,
Them an Offer They Can’t Refuse.” Nietzsche: The Man and His Philosophy (Baton
36. Berman and West, “Responsible Risk-Taking,” Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1965),
p. 349. p. 127.
Toward a Bureaucratic Ethic 511

53. Karl Popper, The Open Society and Its Enemies: Corruption and the Rate of Temptation:
Vol. I, The Spell of Plato, 5th ed. (Princeton, NJ: Do Low  Wages in the Civil Service Cause
Princeton University Press, 1966), p. 285. The set Corruption?  (New York: International Monetary
was first published in 1945. Fund, 1997).
54. John Rawls, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge, MA: 60. Gary S. Becker and George J. Stigler, “Law
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1971), Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of
p. 60. Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies 3 (January
55. Ibid., pp. 14–15. 1974), pp. 1–18.
56. Laura Mumford, “Policy Analysis and the U.S. 61. Patrick Raden Keefe, “Corruption and Revolt,”
Army Corps of Engineers.” Paper submitted The New Yorker (January 19, 2015), pp. 30–36.
to a graduate course in public administration, The quotation is on p. 30.
December 11, 1984, School of Public Affairs, 62. James Surowiecki, “The Regulation Crisis,” The
Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona, Nicholas New Yorker (June 14 & 21, 2010), p. 56.
Henry, instructor. 63. Alexandre Mas, Does Transparency Lead to Pay
57. Jonathan O’Connell and Mary Jordan, “For Compression? (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
Foreign Diplomats, Trump Hotel Is Place to Be,” of Economic Research, 2014), p. 1.
Washington Post (November 8, 2016). 64. Rasmussen Poll, 68% Say Private Sector Employees
58. Ernesto Dal Bo, Frederico Finan, and Martin A. Work Harder Than Government Workers
Rossi, Strengthening State Capabilities: The Role (Washington, DC: Author, 2013).
of Financial Incentives in the Call to Public Service 65. Kevin Merida, “Americans Want a Direct Say
(Stanford, CA: Stanford University, 2013), p. 1. in Political Decision-Making, Pollsters Find,”
59. Caroline Van Rijckeghem and Beatrice Weder, Washington Post (April 17, 1994).
512 INDEX

INDEX

access 43 pervasiveness 150–1; political Goodnow, Frank J. 36


adaptive systems 66–7 corruption 144–5 governance 47
Administrative Behavior see Simon, cutback management 265–7 government corporations 425
Herbert cybercrime 168–71; cyber espionage government inefficiency 193–7;
administrative man 115 170; hacking 169; ransomware 169 fundamental reasons 193; political
administrative procedure acts 94 cybersecurity 171–4 reasons 193–6
affirmative action 336–7, 344–6 The Government Performance and
analytics 157–8 decision support system 157 Results Act Modernization Act of
Articles of Confederation and Perpetual deficit 246 2010 47
Union 10 Dillon’s rule 477 government-sponsored enterprise 425
direct democracy 16 governmental fragmentation 482–3
benchmarking 206–7 discretionary power 20 graft see corruption
Bentley, Arthur F. 383 disjointed incrementalism 382 green tape 99
biennial budget 269 distributive power arena 384 gross debt 250
bounded rationality 80 diversity management 346 group model of policymaking 383
broadbanding 325 Downs, Anthony 96; see also law of groupthink 81
budget 258 hierarchy guerrilla government 89
budgeting-by-objectives 263 dual federalism 462–3 Gulick, Luther H. 37
budget rollover 270
bullying 64 Easton, David 383 Hamilton, Alexander 10–1
bureaucracy 95–6 effectiveness 197 Hawthorne experiments 60
bureaucratic accountability 503 efficiency 197; see also evolution of Herzberg, Frederick 61
public efficiency hierarchy 96–7
city-county consolidation 485 e-government 174–7; benefits of 175–6; home rule 477
civil rights 335–6 federal.gov 174; local.gov 175; and human capital management 294; see also
Civil Service Act of 1883 303 public fraud 176–7; state.gov 174–5 personnel administration
Civil Service Reform Act of 1978 324, elite/mass model human services nonprofits 430
331, 501 enterprise risk management 157 hybrids 122
civil service system 298; see also merit environmental determinism 92
system Equal Employment Opportunity Act of identity theft 166–7
Classification Act 302 1972 337 implementation tactics 84; see also edict;
closed model of organizations 56–9; Equal Employment Opportunity intervention; participation; persuasion
administrative management 58; Commission (EEOC) 335 income taxes 241–2
bureaucratic theory 57; characteristics Ethics in Government Act 500 incompetence 327–31
56; scientific management 57 evolution of public efficiency 198–201 incrementalist paradigm 382
collective bargaining 314 influences on administrative behavior
collective system 312 federal expenditures 233–4 117–21; birth order 117; national
common-pool good and services 389 The Federalist Papers 10, 192 culture 119–20; turning points 118
comparable worth 340 federal system of governance 460–1 inherently governmental activity 401
competitive federalism 464–5 fiscal federalism 466–9; block grants inspectors general 214–5
competitive sourcing 401 466; grants-in-aid 466; lobbying 467; institutionalist model 383
Congressional Budget and Impoundment state grants 469 institutionalists 121
Act of 1974 272–3 FOIA Improvement Act 93 insurance trusts 234
constituent power arena 384 Follett, Mary Parker 59 intergovernmental relations 460
co-optative federalism 463 Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) 93 intergovernmental revenue 234
cooperative federalism 463 Friedrich, Carl J. 383 intergovernmental service transfer 479
corruption 3–5, 143–51, 413–4; interlocal service contracts 478–9
evolution of 147–8; independent general revenue 232, 234, 235, 237 intersectoral administration 397
sector fraud 146; inhibiting fraud Gilbreath, Frank and Lillian 58 interstate compact 476
149–50; national culture 143; good government 6 interstate conflict 477
INDEX 513

interstate cooperation 476–7 (NASPAA) 45; see also National privatization 397, 417–9, 423–4
intuitionism 504 Association of Schools of Public privatization reasons 397–9
iron triangles 196 Affairs and Administration productivity 197
nonprofit sector 55 professional public administration
Jefferson, Thomas 11, 192 system 323–6
joint service agreement 479 OMB Circular A-76 401 program evaluation 211–9; defining the
open government 178 problem 216; designing the evaluation
knowledge management best practices open model of organizations 59–67; 216–7; implementation 217–9;
166 characteristics 59; human relations inspectors general 214–5; selecting
60–5; organization development evaluators 215–6; types of analysis
law of hierarchy 96 65–7 212–3
leadership 123–32; leadership theory organizational culture 126 program/performance budgeting 260–1;
125–8; in organizations 128–30; organizational humanity 504 see also performance budget
within sectors 124 organizational incivility 63 property tax 243–4
lessons on administering 91 organizations 56 protected classes 335–7
Lewin, Kurt 65, 125 organized anarchy model 384–6 public administration 7
Lindblom, Charles E. 382 other than general revenue 234, 236, public and nonprofit management 143
line-item budget 259–60 239 public authority 426
line-item veto 247 outsourcing outcomes 416 public debt 251
lobbying 403–7 own source revenue 234 public finance 232
local expenditures 239 public goods and services model 388–9
Lowi, Theodore J. 383 Papers on the Science of Administration public human capital management
see Gulick, Luther H., Urwick, Lyndall 295–8
Madison, James 192 perfectionism 504 public policy 381
managed competition 422 performance appraisal 326 public policy analysis 381
management 42–3 performance audits 208 public sector 55
management information system 157 performance-based budgeting 267–9 public service motivation 113
Marvick, Dwaine 121; see also performance budget 261 public-serving organizations 429
institutionalists; specialists performance management 201–6, 334–5;
Maslow, A.H. 61 benefits 201–2; better performance quotas 338
Mayo, Elton 60; see also Roethlisberger, management 334–5; federal
Fritz J. performance 202–3; limitations 202; rational choice model 387
McGregor, Douglas 68; see also Theory local performance 204; nonprofit rational interest 68
X and Theory Y performance 204; state performance rationalist paradigm 386
mechanisms of administrative control 90 203–4 Rawls, John 505
member-serving organizations 429 performance measures 205, 208–11 red tape 96, 97–9
merit system 298; see also civil service performance pay 331 redistributive power arena 383
system personal power 90 regulative power arena 384
metropolitan government 484 personnel administration 294; see also regulatory federalism 469–72; costs
metropolitan statistical areas 482 human capital management 471–2; mandates 470; state mandates
Mills, C. Wright 382 planning-programming-budgeting 471; unfunded mandates 470–1
Models of Man see Simon, Herbert system 261–2 reverse discrimination 338
multistate legal actions 476–7 political executive system 317–21 Roethlisberger, Fritz J. 60
municipal annexation 486 policymaking power 20–1
municipal bond 254–5 politicized experts see hybrids sales tax 242–3
politics/administration dichotomy 36–7, self-actualization 61
National Academy of Public 39–40 sexual harassment 341
Administration 44 Politics and Administration see shared service agreement 479
National Association of Schools of Goodnow, Frank J. Simon, Herbert 40–1, 81, 89, 115
Public Affairs and Administration Popper, Karl 505 social capital 13
(NASPAA) 45; see also Network of position power 90 social contract 10
Schools of Public Policy, Affairs, and power 68–9; see also personal power; social insurance and retirement receipts
Administration position power 233
National Labor Relations Act 312 Principles of Public Administration see specialists 121
neo-institutionalist model 383 Willoughby, W.F. specialized public professional system
Network of Schools of Public Policy, private goods and services 388–9 322–3
Affairs, and Administration private sector 55 state expenditures 236
514 INDEX

strategic decision making 80 telework 164 volunteering 436–7


strategic measurement 209 test validity 339 vouchers 437–8
strategic philanthropy 392 theory of justice 505–6
strategic planning 390–3 Theory X and Theory Y 68; see also Wagner Act see National Labor
sunshine laws 93 McGregor, Douglas Relations Act
systems model 383 toll goods and services 389 Weber, Max 25, 57, 70
whistleblowers 305–9
Taft-Hartley Act 315 ultralocalism 482–4; see also White, Leonard 36
target base budgeting 264–7 governmental fragmentation Willoughby, W.F. 37
tax and expenditure limitations (TELs) uncertainty avoidance 119 Wilson, Woodrow 35
237, 240 Urwick, Lyndall 37
taxes 232–3, 235, 237–8, 240–6 user fees 234 zero base budgeting 263–4
Taylor, Frederick 58 utilitarianism 505 “zone of privacy” 167

You might also like