You are on page 1of 7

Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment

Author(s): Janet L. Yellen


Source: The American Economic Review , May, 1984, Vol. 74, No. 2, Papers and
Proceedings of the Ninety-Sixth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association
(May, 1984), pp. 200-205
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1816355

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment

By JANET L. YELLEN*

Keynesian economists hold it to be self- Consider an economy with identical, per-


evident that business cycles are characterized fectly competitive firms, each firm having
by involuntary unemployment. But construc- a production function of the form Q =
tion of a model of the cycle with involuntary F(e( X )N), where N is the number of em-
unemployment faces the obvious difficulty of ployees, e is effort per worker, and X is the
explaining why the labor market does not real wage. A profit-maximizing firm which
clear. Involuntarily unemployed people, by can hire all the labor it wants at the wage it
definition, want to work at less than the chooses to offer (see Joseph Stiglitz, 1976a;
going wage rate. Why don't firms cut wages, Robert Solow, 1979), will offer a real wage,
thereby increasing profits? W*, which satisfies the condition that the
This paper surveys a recent literature which elasticity of effort with respect to the wage
offers a convincing and coherent explanation is unity. The wage w* is known as the effi-
why firms may find it unprofitable to cut ciency wage and this wage choice mini-
wages in the presence of involuntary unem- mizes labor cost per efficiency unit. Each
ployment. The models surveyed are variants firm should then optimally hire labor up
of the efficiency wage hypothesis, according to the point where its marginal product,
to which, labor productivity depends on the e(w*)F'(e(co*)N*), is equal to the real
real wage paid by the firm. If wage cuts harm wage, w*. As long as the aggregate demand
productivity, then cutting wages may end up for labor falls short of aggregate labor sup-
raising labor costs. Section I describes some ply and w* exceeds labor's reservation wage,
of the general implications of the efficiency- the firm will be unconstrained by labor
wage hypothesis in its simplest form. Section market conditions in pursuing its optimal
II describes four distinct microeconomic ap- policy so that equilibrium will be char-
proaches which justify the relation between acterized by involuntary unemployment. Un-
wages and productivity. These approaches employed workers would strictly prefer to
identify four benefits of higher wage pay- work at the real wage w* than to be unem-
ments: reduced shirking by employees due to 'ployed, but firms will not hire them at that
a higher cost of job loss; lower turnover; an wage or at a lower wage. Why? For the
improvement in the average quality of job simple reason that any reduction in the wage
applicants; and improved morale.' Section paid would lower the productivity of all em-
III explains how the efficiency-wage hy- ployees already on the job. Thus the efficiency-
pothesis, with near rational behavior, can wage hypothesis explains involuntary unem-
explain cyclical fluctuations in unemploy- ployment.
ment. Extended in simple ways this hypothesis
also explains four other labor market phe-
I. The Efficiency Wage Hypothesis nomena: real wage rigidity; the dual labor
market; the existence of wage distributions
The potential relevance of the efficiency- for workers of identical characteristics; and
wage hypothesis in explaining involuntary discrimination among observationally dis-
unemployment and other stylized labor mar- tinct groups. Concerning real wage rigidity,
ket facts can be seen in a rudimentary model. in the simple model just described, real
shocks which shift the marginal product of
*University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720. I am labor alter employment, but not the real
indebted to George Akerlof, David Estenson, Michael
wage. In more elaborate versions of the model
Reich, and James Wilcox for invaluable discussion and
comments.
discussed below, such shocks will change the
'For a previous survey of portions of this literature, real wage, but not sufficiently to leave un-
see Guillermo Calvo (1979). employment unaltered.
200

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 74 NO. 2 INFORMA TION AND MA CROECONOMICS 20]

Dual labor markets can be explained by II. Microfoundations of the


the assumption that the wage-productivity Efficiency-Wage Model
nexus is important in some sectors of the
economy, but not in others. For the primary Why should labor productivity depend on
sector, where the efficiency-wage hypothesis the real wage paid by firms? In the LDC
is relevant, we find job rationing and volun- context, for which the hypothesis was first
tary payment by firms of wages in excess of advanced, the link between wages, nutrition,
market clearing; in the secondary sector, and illness was emphasized. Recent theoreti-
where the wage-productivity relationship is cal work has advanced a convincing case for
weak or nonexistent, we should observe fully the relevance of this hypothesis to developed
neoclassical behavior. The market for sec- economies. In this section, four different mi-
ondary-sector jobs clears, and anyone can croeconomic foundations for the efficiency-
obtain a job in this sector, albeit at lower wage model are described and evaluated.
pay. The existence of the secondary sector
does not, however, eliminate involuntary un- A. The Shirking Model
employment (see Robert Hall, 1975), because
the wage differential between primary- and In most jobs, workers have some discre-
secondary-sector jobs will induce unemploy- tion concerning their performance. Rarely
ment among job seekers who choose to wait can employment contracts rigidly specify all
for primary-sector job openings. aspects of a worker's performance. Piece rates
Theorists who emphasize the importance are often impracticable because monitoring
of unemployment due to the frictions of the is too costly or too inaccurate. Piece rates
search process have frequently found it dif- may also be nonviable because the measure-
ficult to explain the reasons for a distribution ments on which they are based are unveri-
of wage offers in the market. The efficiency- fiable by workers, creating a moral hazard
wage hypothesis also offers a simple explana- problem. Under these circumstances, the
tion for the existence of wage differentials payment of a wage in excess of market clear-
which might motivate the search process em- ing may be an effective way for firms
phasized by Edmund Phelps and others. If to provide workers with the incentive to
the relationship between wages and effort work rather than shirk. (See Samuel Bowles,
differs among firms, each firm's efficiency 1981, 1983; Guillermo Calvo, 1979; B. Curtis
wage will differ, and, in equilibrium, there Eaton and William White, 1982; Herbert
will emerge a distribution of wage offers for Gintis and Tsuneo Ishikawa, 1983; Hajime
workers of identical characteristics. Miyazaki, forthcoming; Carl Shapiro and
The efficiency-wage hypothesis also ex- Stiglitz, 1982; and Steven Stoft, 1982.) The
plains discrimination among workers with details of the models differ somewhat, de-
different observable characteristics. This oc- pending on what is assumed measurable, at
curs if employers simply prefer, say, men to what cost, and the feasible payment sched-
women. With job rationing, the employer ules.
can indulge his taste for discrimination at Bowles, Calvo, Eaton-White, Shapiro-Stig-
zero cost. As another possibility, employers litz, and Stoft assume that it is possible to
may know that the functions relating effort monitor individual performance on the job,
to wages differ across groups. Then each albeit imperfectly. In the simplest model,
group has its own efficiency wage and corre- due to Shapiro-Stiglitz, workers can decide
sponding "efficiency labor cost." If these whether to work or to shirk. Workers who
shirk have some chance of getting caught,
labor costs differ, it will pay firms to hire first
only employees from the lowest cost group. with the penalty of being fired. This has been
Any unemployment that exists will be con- termed "cheat-threat" theory by Stoft be-
fined to labor force groups with higher costs cause, if there is a cost to being fired, the
per efficiency unit. With fluctuations in de- threat of being sacked if caught cheating
mand, these groups will bear a dispro- creates an incentive not to shirk. Equilibrium
portionate burden of layoffs. then entails unemployment. If all firms pay

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
202 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1984

an identical wage, and if there is full employ- argue that a major part of the productivity
ment, there would be no cost to shirking and slowdown is attributable to loss of employer
it would pay all workers, assumed to get control due to a reduction in the cost of job
pleasure from loafing on the job, to shirk. In loss. The shirking model also offers an inter-
these circumstances, it pays each firm to pretation of hierarchical wage differentials,
raise its wage to eliminate shirking. When all in excess of productivity differences (Calvo
firms do this, average wages rise and employ- and Stanislaw Wellisz, 1979).
ment falls. In equilibrium, all firms pay the All these models suffer from a similar the-
same wage above market clearing, and un- oretical difficulty-that employment con-
employment, which makes job loss costly, tracts more ingenious than the simple wage
serves as a worker-discipline device. Unem- schemes considered, can reduce or eliminate
ployed workers cannot bid for jobs by offer- involuntary unemployment. In the cheat-
ing to work at lower wages. If the firm were threat model, the introduction of employ-
to hire a worker at a lower wage, it would be ment fees allows the market to clear effi-
in the worker's interest to shirk on the job. ciently as long as workers have sufficient
The firm knows this and the worker has no capital to pay them (see Eaton-White and
credible way of promising to work if he is Stoft). Unemployed workers would be will-
hired. ing to pay a fee to gain employment. Fees
The shirking model does not predict, coun- lower labor costs, giving firms an incentive to
terfactually, that the bulk of those unem- hire more workers. If all firms charge fees,
ployed at any time are those who were fired any worker who shirks and is caught knows
for shirking. If the threat associated with that he will have to pay another fee to regain
being fired is effective, little or no shirking employment. This possibility substitutes for
and sacking will actually occur. Instead, the the threat of unemployment in creating work
unemployed are a rotating pool of individu- incentives. Devices which function similarly
als who have quit jobs for personal reasons, are bonds posted by workers when initially
who are new entrants to the labor market, or hired and forfeited if found cheating, and
who have been laid off by firms with declines fines levied on workers caught shirking. The
in demand. Pareto optimality, with costly threat of forfeiting the bond or paying the
monitoring, will entail some unemployment, fine substitutes for the threat of being fired.
since unemployment plays a socially valu- Edward Lazear (1981) has demonstrated the
able role in creating work incentives. But the use of seniority wages to solve the incentive
equilibrium unemployment rate will not be problem. Workers can be paid a wage less
Pareto optimal (see Shapiro-Stiglitz). than their marginal productivity when they
In contrast to the simple efficiency-wage are first hired with a promise that their earn-
model, the shirking model adds new argu- ings will later exceed their marginal produc-
ments to the firm's effort function-the aver- tivity. The upward tilt in the age-earnings
age wage, aggregate unemployment, and the profile provides a penalty for shirking; the
unemployment benefit. The presence of the present value of the wage paid can fall to the
unemployment rate in the effort function market-clearing level, eliminating involun-
yields a mechanism whereby changes in labor tary unemployment.
supply affect equilibrium wages and employ- As a theoretical objection to these schemes,
ment. New workers increase unemployment, employers would be subject to moral hazard
raising the penalty associated with being fired in evaluating workers' effort. Firms would
and inducing higher effort at any given have an obvious incentive to declare workers
wage. Firms accordingly lower wages and shirking and appropriate their bonds, collect
hire more labor as a result. In a provocative fines, or replace them with new fee-paying
recent paper, Thomas Weisskopf, Bowles, workers. In Lazear's model, in which the firm
and David Gordon (1984) have used the pays a wage in excess of marginal product to
presence of the unemployment benefit in the senior workers, there is an incentive for the
effort function to explain the secular decline firm to fire such workers, replacing them
in productivity in the United States; they with young workers, paid less than their pro-

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 74 NO. 2 INFORMATION AND MACROECONOMICS 203

ductivity. The seriousness of this moral ment or training fee scheme could be em-
hazard problem depends on the ability of ployed without the problem of moral hazard.
workers to enforce honesty on the firm's It is no longer in any firm's interest to dis-
part. If effort is observable both by the miss trained workers; explicit contracts could
firm and by the worker, and if it can be veri- probably be written to insure that training is
fied by outside auditors, the firm will be actually provided to fee paying workers. Al-
unable to cheat workers. Even without out- though moral hazard thus appears to be a
side verification, Lazear has shown how the less formidable barrier to achieving neoclas-
firm's concern for its reputation can over- sical outcomes via fees or bonds than in the
come the moral hazard problem. Sudipto shirking model, capital market imperfections
Bhattacharya (1983) has suggested tourna- or institutional or sociological constraints
ment contracts that also overcome the moral may in fact make them impractical.
hazard problem. The firm can commit itself
to a fixed wage plan in which a high wage is C. Adverse Selection
paid to a fraction of workers and a low wage
to the remaining fraction according to an ex Adverse selection yields further reason for
post, possibly random, ranking of their effort a relation between productivity and wages.
levels. By precommitting itself to such a plan Suppose that performance on the job de-
with a fixed wage bill, any moral hazard pends on "ability" and that workers are het-
problem on the firm's part disappears. erogeneous in ability. If ability and workers'
reservation wages are positively correlated,
B. The Labor Turnover Model firms with higher wages will attract more
able job candidates. (See James Malcolmson,
Firms may also offer wages in excess of 1981; Stiglitz, 1976b; Andrew Weiss, 1980.)
market clearing to reduce costly labor turn- In such a model, each firm pays an efficiency
over. (See Steven Salop, 1979; Ekkehart wage and optimally turns away applicants
Schlicht, 1978; and Stiglitz, 1974.) The for- offering to work for less than that wage. The
mal structure of the labor turnover model is willingness of an individual to work for less
identical to that of the shirking model. than the going wage places an upper bound
Workers will be more reluctant to quit the on his ability, raising the firm's estimate that
higher the relative wage paid by the current he is a lemon. The model provides an ex-
firm, and the higher the aggregate unemploy- planation of wage differentials and different
ment rate. If all firms are identical, one layoff probabilities for observationally dis-
possible equilibrium has all firms paying a tinct groups due to statistical discrimination
common wage above market clearing with if it is known that different groups have even
involuntary unemployment serving to di- slight differences in the joint distributions of
minish turnover. ability and acceptance wages. However, for
The theoretical objection to the prediction the adverse-selection model to provide a con-
of involuntary unemployment in this model vincing account of involuntary unemploy-
again concerns the potential for more sophis- ment, firms must be unable to measure effort
ticated employment contracts to provide and pay piece rates after workers are hired,
Pareto-superior solutions. As Salop explains, or to fire workers whose output is too low.
the market for new hires fails to clear be- Clever firms may also be able to mitigate
cause an identical wage is paid to both trained adverse selection in hiring by designing self-
and untrained workers. Instead, new workers selection or screening devices which induce
could be paid a wage equal to the difference workers to reveal their true characteristics.
between their marginal product and their
training cost. A seniority wage scheme might D. Sociological Models
accomplish this, although, if training costs
are large and occur quickly it might prove The theories reviewed above are neoclassi-
necessary to charge a fee to new workers. In cal in their assumption of individualistic
contrast to the shirking model, an employ- maximization by all agents. Solow (1980) has

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
204 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1984

argued, however, that wage rigidity may more cause significant business cycle fluctuations,
plausibly be due to social conventions and is consistent with near rationality in an econ-
principles of appropriate behavior that are omy with efficiency wage setting. Any firm
not entirely individualistic in origin. George that normally chooses its wage as part of an
Akerlof (1982) has provided the first ex- optimizing decision will incur losses that are
plicitly sociological model leading to the only second-order if it follows a rule of thumb
efficiency-wage hypothesis. He uses a variety in adjusting nominal wages which leads to a
of interesting evidence from sociological real wage error. At the point of maximum
studies to argue that each worker's effort profits, the profit function relating wages to
depends on the work norms of his group. In profits is flat. Thus, in the neighborhood of
Akerlof's partial gift exchange model, the the optimum wage, the loss from wage errors
firm can succeed in raising group work norms is second-order small. This implies that firms
and average effort by paying workers a gift with sticky wages have profits that are insig-
of wages in excess of the minimum required, nificantly different from firms with maximiz-
in return for their gift of effort above the ing behavior. Furthermore, if firms have
minimum required. The sociological model price-setting power because of downward-
can explain phenomena which seem inexpli- sloping demand curves, for similar reasons,
cable in neoclassical terms-why firms don't price-setting errors also lead to insignificant
fire workers who turn out to be less produc- losses.
tive, why piece rates are avoided even when In the Akerlof-Yellen model, firms are
feasible, and why firms set work standards efficiency-wage setters and monopolistic
exceeded by most workers. Akerlof s paper competitors. In the long run, wages and prices
in this issue explores alternative sociological are set by all firms in an optimal way. In the
foundations for the efficiency wage hypothe- short run, in response to aggregate demand
sis. Sociological considerations governing the shocks, some firms keep nominal wages and
effort decisions of workers are also em- prices constant, while other firms choose
phasized in Marxian discussions of the ex- these variables optimally. In this model, a
traction of labor from labor power (see, for cut in the money supply causes a first-order
example, Bowles, 1983). change in employment, output, and profits.
But the behavior of nonmaximizers is near
III. Explaining the Business Cycle rational in the sense that the potential gain
any individual firm could experience by
Any model of the business cycle must abandoning rule of thumb behavior is sec-
explain why changes in aggregate demand ond-order small. And thus the efficiency-wage
cause changes in aggregate employment and hypothesis can be extended into a full-fledged
output. A potential problem of the efficiency- Keynesian model of the business cycle gener-
wage hypothesis in this regard is the absence ated by sticky prices and wages.
of a link between aggregate demand and
economic activity. In an economy with IV. Concluding Remarks
efficiency-wage setting, there is a positive
natural rate of unemployment and real wage It has been widely observed that the ex-
rigidity. But the economy's aggregate output istence of excess labor supply does not lead
is independent of price at this natural rate. to aggressive wage cutting by workers and
These models have no wage or price sticki- firms. Firms appear content to pay workers
ness to cause real consequences from aggre- more than the wages required by their poten-
gate demand shocks. However, for a natural tial replacements. The models surveyed here
but subtle reason, the efficiency-wage model offer several different and plausible explana-
is consistent with nominal wage rigidity and tions of this seemingly paradoxical fact. In
cyclical unemployment. This reason (sug- addition to accounting for the persistence of
gested by Stoft), is explored in depth by involuntary unemployment in competitive
Akerlof and myself (1983), where we argue markets, these efficiency wage models can
that sticky wage and price behavior, that will explain why unemployment varies in re-

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 74 NO. 2 INFORMATIONAND MACROECONOMICS 205

sponse to aggregate demand shocks. In sum, American Economic Review, September


these models provide a new, consistent, and 1981, 71, 606-20.
plausible microfoundation for a Keynesian Malcolmson, James, "Unemployment and the
model of the cycle. Efficiency Wage Hypothesis," Economic
Journal, December 1981, 91, 848-66.
Miyazaki, Hajime, "Work Norms and In-
REFERENCES voluntary Unemployment," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, forthcoming.
Akerlof, George, "Labor Contracts as Partial Salop, Steven, "A Model of the Natural Rate
Gift Exchange," Quarterly Journal of Eco- of Unemployment," American Economic
nomics, November 1982, 97, 543-69. Review, March 1979, 69, 117-25.
,_ "Gift Exchange and Efficiency Wage Schlicht, Ekkehart, "Labour Turnover, Wage
Theory: Four Views," American Economic Structure and Natural Unemployment,"
Review Proceedings, May 1984, 74, 79-83. Zeitschrift fur die Gesamte Staatswissen-
and Yellen, Janet, " The Macroeco- schaft, June 1978, 134, 337-46.
nomic Consequences of Near Rational, Shapiro, Carl and Stiglitz, Joseph, "Equilibrium
Rule of Thumb Behavior," mimeo., Uni- Unemployment as a Worker Discipline
versity of California-Berkeley, September Device," mimeo., Princeton University,
1983. April 1982.
Bhattacharya, Sudipto, "Tournaments and In- Solow, Robert, "Another Possible Source of
centives: Heterogeneity and Essentiality," Wage Stickiness," Journal of Macroeco-
mimeo., Stanford University, March 1983. nomics, Winter 1979, 1, 79-82.
Bowles, Samuel, "Competitive Wage De- ,_____ "On Theories of Unemployment,"
termination and Involuntary Unemploy- American Economic Review, March 1980,
ment: A Conflict Model," mimeo., Univer- 70, 1-11.
sity of Massachusetts, May 1981. Stiglitz, Joseph, "Wage Determination and
_ , "The Production Process in a Com- Unemployment in L.D.C.'s: The Labor
petitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hob- Turnover Model," Quarterly Journal of
besian and Marxian Models," mimeo., Economics, May 1974, 88, 194-227.
University of Massachusetts, May 1983. , (1976a) "The Efficiency Wage Hy-
Calvo, Guillermo, "Quasi-Walrasian Theories pothesis, Surplus Labour, and the Distri-
of Unemployment," American Economic bution of Income in L.D.C.s," Oxford Eco-
Review Proceedings, May 1979, 69, 102-07. nomic Papers, July 1976, 28, 185-207.
and Wellisz, Stanislaw, "Hierarchy, , (1976b) " Prices and Queues as
Ability and Income Distribution," Journal Screening Devices in Competitive Mar-
of Political Economy, October 1979, 87, kets," IMSSS Technical Report No. 212,
991-1010. Stanford University, August 1976.
Eaton, B. Curtis and White, William, "Agent Stoft, Steven, " Cheat-Threat Theory: An Ex-
Compensation and the Limits of Bonding," planation of Involuntary Unemployment,"
Economic Inquiry, July 1982, 20, 330-43. mimeo., Boston University, May 1982.
Gintis, Herbert and Ishikawa, Tsuneo, "Wages, Weiss, Andrew, "Job Queues and Layoffs in
Work Discipline and Macroeconomic Labor Markets with Flexible Wages,"
Equilibrium," mimeo., 1983. Journal of Political Economy, June 1980,
Hall, Robert, "The Rigidity of Wages and the 88, 526-38.
Persistence of Unemployment," Brookings Weisskopf, Thomas, Bowles, Samuel and Gordon,
Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1975, 301 David, "Hearts and Minds: A Social Model
-35. of Aggregate Productivity Growth in the
Lazear, Edward, "Agency, Earnings Profiles, U.S., 1948-1979," Brookings Papers on
Productivity, and Hours Restrictions," Economic Activity, 1984, forthcoming.

This content downloaded from


139.47.88.110 on Sat, 25 Mar 2023 12:15:15 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like