You are on page 1of 252

Australian Mineral

Economics
A Survey of Important Issues

Monograph 24

Edited by

Philip Maxwell
with the assistance of

Pietro Guj

Published by

THE AUSTRALASIAN INSTITUTE OF MINING AND METALLURGY


Level 3, 15 - 31 Pelham Street, Carlton Victoria 3053 Australia
© The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy 2006

The Institute is not responsible as a body for the facts and opinions advanced in any of its publications.

ISBN 1 920806 47 4

Desktop published by:


Jenni Stiffe for The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy

Compiled on CD ROM by:


Visual Image Processing Pty Ltd
PO Box 3180
Doncaster East VIC 3109
Preface
The minerals and energy sector plays a major role in the Australian economy. It is surprising, therefore
that there has been no significant Australian monograph in the field of mineral economics since the
mid-1980s. Prior to that time Don Barnett’s Mineral and Energy in Australia was published in 1979 and
two volumes of edited readings appeared in 1984. These were The Minerals Sector and the Australian
Economy edited by Cook and Porter, and Peter Lloyd’s Mineral Economics in Australia.

In endeavouring to fill a perceived gap in the literature, we responded positively to a request from our
colleague, Peter Lilly in late 2003, to consider compiling such a study on behalf of The Australasian
Institute of Mining and Metallurgy.

The field of mineral economics owes its origins in part to engineering economics, a course taught for
more than half a century in many engineering schools around the world. Engineering economics
combines traditional economic analysis applied to the resources sector with associated fields such as
project evaluation, risk analysis and management. Since this is a volume aimed broadly at mineral
sector professionals, our approach has been, at least in part, to embrace this approach.

We have drawn inspiration from other places as well. The AIME volume, The Economics of the
Mineral Industries, which appeared in four editions, is an interesting model. Additionally, the published
notes of Brian Mackenzie, who delivered an annual short course in mineral economics for WMC
Resources and the Australian Mineral Foundation for more than two decades, offers many further
useful insights.

Perhaps the greatest influence, however, has been the experience of offering our own coursework
Master’s program in Mineral Economics at the Western Australian School of Mines (Curtin University
of Technology) since 1993. The opportunity to interact with mining executives and professionals for
more than a decade has shaped the approach for this volume.

After the initial introductory chapter, the remainder of the volume is divided into four main sections.
They are:

• Minerals and the World Economy;


• Minerals — Consumption, Production and Markets;
• Mineral Finance and Investment; and
• Minerals and Public Policy.

The first, second and fourth sections have a distinct economics flavour, while the third section focuses
on financial analysis, project evaluation and risk analysis.

The material in the 18 chapters of this volume reflects in major part the contributions of our Mineral
Economics program’s resident staff. Pietro Guj has played the major role in authoring and coordinating
the finance section, while Philip Maxwell has played this role in the three economics sections.

Yet several other authors have also contributed, five of whom have lectured on the Master’s program as
visiting faculty. They are Phillip Crowson, Rod Eggert, Frank Harman, Peter Howie and Gavin Jahn.
Rick West has also contributed a chapter to the volume.
We would like to express our gratitude to The AusIMM for supporting this project. Don Larkin, Jenni
Stiffe, Brigette Hall, Angie Spry, Kristy Pocock and Jenny Hall deserve particular thanks.

Completing this project has been possible as a result of a twice-interrupted period of academic study
leave for Philip Maxwell from Curtin University. During a six-month leave period, he made visits to
Deakin University in Geelong and to Edith Cowan University at Joondalup. Bruce Clayton, Bill
Dimovski and Carol Adams at Deakin, as well as Laurie and Gunn Carlson were very helpful in making
the Geelong visit a great success. Dave Allan was a considerate and supporting host at Edith Cowan.

Pietro Guj has finalised his contribution while holding a joint position in the WASM Mineral
Economics program and at the Centre of Exploration Targeting, which operates as a joint initiative
between the University of Western Australia, Curtin University and the mining industry with the
financial support of the State of Western Australia.

It is important also to thank the small group of senior colleagues who have joined us in reviewing key
parts of the monograph. These include Graham Davis (Colorado School of Mines), John Tilton
(Colorado School of Mines and Catholic University of Santiago), Phillip Crowson (University of
Dundee), Richie Howitt (Macquarie University), Don Larkin (The AusIMM), Allan Teede (Economic
Research Consultants) and Michael Doggett (Queen’s University).

We are very grateful for the financial support of Mannkal Economic Education Foundation and the
Adelaide, Kalgoorlie, North Queensland, Perth and Southern Queensland Branches of The AusIMM,
who have made the publication of this monograph possible through their generous sponsorship.

Last but certainly not least, we thank our wives, Mary and Luisa, for their support and encouragement.

We trust that our final product makes a positive contribution to the appreciation of mineral economics
issues in Australia and more broadly.

Philip Maxwell and Pietro Guj


May 2006
GLOSSARY OF TERMS

Barriers to entry
A Any factor that prevents an entrepreneur from immediately
creating a new firm.
Accrual accounting
A method of financial accounting that matches all revenue and Base-case model
expenditure transactions recognised in each accounting period, See assumed certainty models.
irrespective to whether the corresponding cash consideration has
changed hands during the period or not.
Bayesian (dependent) probabilities
Ad valorem royalties Probability of an event given that another event, on which it is
dependent, eventuates.
A royalty levied on the financial value of a produced mineral
resource.
β index
Amortisation β is the covariance between the returns on the security and that
on the market portfolio divided by the variance of the returns on
Similar to depreciation but relating to intangible assets.
the market portfolio. An index displaying whether and by how
much an individual security in the market portfolio amplifies
Annual equivalent value (AEV) overall market movements. A β index >1 signifies that a security
The ratio between a capital investment and the annuity factor for is sensitive to market movements.
the life of the asset at an appropriate rate of discount. AEV allows
the comparison of the capital cost of alternative assets with Binomial lattices
different effective lives on an annual basis.
A graphical representation of the change in a variable that can
either go up or down in each time-step. Binomial lattices can
Annuity
portray all the possible values of an asset underlying an option,
A series of cash flows all of the same amount in each period. allow the calculation of the option value for each possible state
of nature (eg up, up-up, up-down, etc) and of the present value of
Anti-trust legislation the option after risk neutralisation using techniques such as ‘state
A range of laws implemented by governments around the world prices’ or ‘risk-free probability’.
to limit the market power of firms and control how they compete
with one another. The ‘anti-trust’ terminology originates from Buying pressure
the United States. This arises where consumers wish to consume more than
producers wish to produce at a given price.
Artisanal and small-scale mining
The traditional form of labour-intensive mining that continues to By-product
persist in developing nations with significant minerals
A product so unimportant that its price has no influence on a
endowments and which provides employment for many people
mine’s output.
in poor and otherwise backward regions.

Assets
Stores of future benefits to be derived beyond the current period,
which are material and owned or controlled by the firm.
C
Call option
Assumed-certainty models The right, but not an obligation, to buy an asset for a specified
A DCF model in which single-point input values are assumed to price on or before a specified date.
be realised with certainty. If the input values are expected or
mean values, the model will generate single-point expected Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
outputs and is often referred to as a base case. A method to estimate the cost of equity (RE) necessary to attract
funds to a specific security by adding to the risk-free rate of
Average cost interest a risk-premium commensurate with the risk of the
The ratio of total cost to the number of units of output that a firm security relative to that of a balance market portfolio.
produces.
Capital budgeting
The process of evaluating and prioritising capital investment
B opportunities.

Backwardation Capital Efficiency Index (KE)


A situation in which cash prices for immediate delivery of A measure of the value added by each dollar invested, ie NPV/
minerals in a market exceed the forward price. CAPEX.

Balance of payments Cartel


The balance of a nation’s exports, imports, income and capital A group of producers which explicitly agrees to coordinate its
flows in a given period. production and selling activities in a given market.

Australian Mineral Economics 215


Cash bidding Consumption
Auctioning the exploration and development rights of The process of individuals, households, business and government
well-defined tenements either for an upfront cash payment, or an using up goods and services.
ongoing ad valorem royalty or some combination of upfront cash
and royalty payments. Contango
Markets are in contango when prices for future delivery of
Cash cleared minerals exceed cash prices by a margin that represents the costs
Users of the market do not have to contribute additional cash of storage and insurance, and the rate of interest, or the time
when their contracts are making losses, nor can they take out value of money.
profits ahead of the prompt date. Rather, the contracts are cleared
against bank guarantees, with brokers granting credit to their Contingent claim
clients. Another term to signify an option.

Cash costs Contributory share


All fixed and variable costs sustained in cash rather than as Shares where only part of their issue value has be contributed by
ledger entries when operations are taking place. They include all shareholders who can later be called upon to contribute the as yet
site costs of mining such as stripping, processing, concentrating, unpaid balance of the issue value.
but also incorporate sales and marketing.
Co-product
Certainty equivalent Where two or more mined products affect a mine’s viability,
The price to be received with certainty at which the holder of a they are considered to be co-products.
risky investment opportunity is indifferent as to whether to sell it
or to invest in it taking cognisance of their risk tolerance. Corruption
The abuse of office for private gain.
Classical or objective probabilities
Probability distributions which can be unambiguously Cost-based valuation
determined by mathematical model of the relevant processes or A method of evaluation that uses the cost of acquiring an asset as
by the frequency distribution of comprehensive time series or of a proxy for its market price.
rigorous and statistically significant trials.
Cost of debt (RD)
Collusion Minimum rate of return necessary to satisfy the expectations of
Agreements, either tacit or explicit, between firms in an industry providers of debt funds (lenders) to induce to lend their funds to
on either pricing or other policies, or both, that reduce a firm or project consistent with the degree of security
competition between them. underpinning the borrowed funds.

Community indifference curve Cost of equity (RE)


A curve which shows different combinations of goods and Minimum rate of return necessary to satisfy the expectations of
services corresponding to the same level of welfare in a providers of equity funds (shareholders) to induce to commit
community, with a given distribution of income. their funds to an investment/project and bear its ultimate risk.

Company income tax Created demand


A tax on Australian companies currently computed by applying a Demand generated by continuing promotion for a final product
30 per cent tax rate to taxable company income determined (eg jewellery) in which a particular mineral (eg gold) is an input.
according to the provisions of the Income Tax Assessment Act.
Cross-price elasticity of demand
Comparative advantage This shows how the quantity demanded of one mineral changes
if the price of another mineral changes.
Countries tend to export those goods and services where their
margin of superiority is greater, or their margin of inferiority
smaller, than their trading partners.
D
Competition policy
Dealer market
A range of laws implemented by governments to limit the market
Markets facilitated by individual dealers or commodity houses.
power of firms and control how they compete with one another.
Similar to anti-trust legislation but this terminology is used more
widely in Europe. Depreciation
An accrual financial accounting convention to attribute the
historical, lumpy, cash capital cost incurred at the time of
Competitive markets
acquisition of a fixed asset to the degree to which its value
Markets in which prices are determined by the free interplay of decreases over successive periods while being utilised to
supply and demand and in which no individual producers or generate revenue in the period.
buyers have the ability to influence the market clearing price.
Derived demand
Complements Demand arising because minerals, with their unique physical and
A mineral used jointly with another mineral to produce a final chemical properties, are used as an input into one or more final
good. commodities.

216 Australian Mineral Economics


Developed nations Economic sustainability
Those nations with high per capita incomes and well developed Sustaining improvements in human living standards or human
economic, governmental and social institutions. material wellbeing.

Developing nations Economics


Nations with less developed economic, governmental and social The most widely used definition is that of Robbins, which argues
institutions. that economics is the science that studies human behaviour as a
relationship between ends and scarce means which have
alternative uses.
Development
A process involving major changes in social structures, popular Economies in transition
attitudes and national institutions, as well as the acceleration of Former socialist (communist) economies that have been moving
economic growth, the reduction of inequality and the eradication towards a more capitalist system.
of absolute poverty.
Elasticity of demand
Differential rent A measure of the quantitative impact on the amount of a good
Arises where the mineral resources available for exploitation demanded arising from a change of one of the other factors
differ in quality and grade. Different producers make different affecting demand (own price, income or the price of related goods).
levels of above normal profit and generate different levels of
economic rent. Elasticity of supply
A measure of the way in which the amount of minerals supplied
Discount factor to a market respond to changes in key influencing factors, such
Factor by which a sum to be received in the future is multiplied as the price of the mineral.
years
by to obtain its present value, ie 1/(1 + discount rate) .
Engineering economics
Discount rate An area of study concerned largely with the financial analysis of
engineering decisions, incorporating project evaluation, risk
Rate of interest used to obtain the present value of a sum to be analysis and related techniques.
received in the future.
Environmental sustainability
Discounted cash flow (DCF) model Sustaining environmental quality and the stock of natural
A financial model of an investment or project, which discounts resources.
the net cash flows over the whole life of the investment back to
their present value. Excess capacity
This arises in established mines and smelters as a result of
Discounted payback period (DPBP) reduced consumption of minerals or less than expected growth in
A measure of how long it would take for an investment/project to consumption. It has tended to act as a key barrier to entry of new
repay the initial capital investment with interest compound at the mines and mineral processing facilities.
appropriate rate of discount.
Exchange rates
Distribution The rate at which a unit of one nation’s currency will exchange
for that of another nation.
The way in which a country’s citizens share the proceeds of their
production. Exercise (implementation) cost (X)
The present value (discounted at an appropriate time and
Dutch disease risk-adjusted discount rate) of the initial capital investment and
The effects arising from the uncomfortable co-existence of of all successive sustaining capital investments in a project.
booming and lagging sectors in an economy, which often brings
significant structural adjustment, typically following the Expanded NPV or ENPV
discovery and initial exploitation of major new mineral The sum of the project static DCF/NPV and of its real option
resources. value (ROV) not captured by conventional DCF analysis.
Expected monetary value (EMV)

E Also mean value. The mean of all possible outcomes weighted


by their probability of occurrence.
Economic growth Export levies
The growth in total production over a given period or in per Taxes on exports by a host government. These may be a way to
capita production of the average citizen over a given time period. encourage downstream production.

Economic rationality
An investor is said to be economically rational if they maximise
their wealth, minimise their risk, but trade risk for returns.
F
Farm-out
Economic rent The contractual process of divesting of equity in a project in
The payment that any good (commodity) or service receives in consideration of cash or other forms of payment and/or
excess of its supply price when a market is in equilibrium. It is a commitment to fund necessary project expenditure in preparation
surplus in excess of the minimum profit required by shareholders for the establishment of a proper joint venture once the desired
in a company or firm to stay in business. level of equity is reached.

Australian Mineral Economics 217


Final product Frequency distribution
A product that is produced for its final user and not as a Probability distributions generated from comprehensive time
component of another good or service. series or rigorous and statistically significant trials.

Financial leverage
Enhancement of the return on equity brought about by the use of
debt in the financial structure of a firm. Leverage occurs because
G
of the lower cost of debt relative to equity and of the Gearing
tax-deductibility of the relevant interest expenses, albeit with the See financial leverage.
introduction of financial risk.
Gender balance
Financial risk
The tendency for equal numbers of men and women to work in
Additional risk introduced by the use of debt in the financial the same industry, or reside in the same area.
structure of a firm or project.
Generalised scarcity
Financial structure
The idea that a product is in short supply relative to its demand.
The relative proportion of equity and debt used by a firm to
finance its activities. Gold loan
An arrangement whereby a gold producer borrows gold, sells it
Financing decision
to fund its gold mine development and repays the loan in gold
A decision as to which level of debt in the funding structure of a out of future production. While the loan is outstanding the
project would bring about the optimal level of leverage to the borrower must pay a gold leasing fee, which is lower than
provider of equity consistent with their willingness to bear the corresponding loan interest rates but not tax deductible.
additional relevant financial risk.
Gross Domestic Product (GDP)
Fiscal policy
A measure of the market value of final goods and services
This refers to the efforts of government to use its spending, produced in an economy during a given period.
taxing and debt-issuing authority to smooth out the business
cycle and otherwise influence economic performance.

Fixed costs H
These are costs that do not change with the level of output that a Hedging
firm produces. They cannot be varied or avoided in the short term. The elimination of market price uncertainty for a mineral or
currency at a known cost.
Fixed exchange rates
The situation where a nation’s currency is set at a specific level Hicks-Marshall laws of derived demand
in relation to other key currencies. A series of four propositions attributed to Alfred Marshall and John
Hicks that describe the relationship between own price elasticity of
Floating exchange rates demand (for a mineral) and a range of other influencing factors.
Exchange rates that vary continuously to ensure that a nation’s
exports, imports, international income flows and capital Historical demand
movements are always in balance. Demand for minerals such as gold which arises from historical
tradition.
Flow-through share
A tax system that allows the subscriber of equity to qualifying Homogeneous products
Canadian junior exploration companies to deduct their Products which buyers perceive to be identical.
contributions from their individual taxable income in Canada.
Homogeneous regions
Fly-in, fly-out (FIFO) Regions identified because of their homogeneous economic
A working pattern in mining operations involving workers characteristics.
travelling long distances from their normal residences to remote
locations, working several days at the site where food and Horizontal equity
accommodation are provided, and then travelling home for Implies equal treatment of equals and asks questions such as ‘are
several days of leave. miners who generate the same amount of economic rent all
paying the same amount of tax?’
Forward contract
A binding contractual commitment to deliver (or take delivery) Hybrids
of a specified quantity of a given commodity at a specified time Capital-raising instruments with the characteristics of both equity
in the future for a price determined with certainty in the present. and debt, eg convertible unsecured notes and preference shares.

Forward price
The certainty equivalent of the expected, hence risky, spot price
on the delivery date. While the price risk has been fully
I
neutralised the forward price still needs to be discounted by the Immediate run
risk-free rate to compensate for the time-value of money and A period in which the market conditions facing a mining firm are
bring it to its present value. fixed, and it is not possible to change the current rate of production.

218 Australian Mineral Economics


Income-based valuation Investment
Also technical or fundamental valuation. A method of evaluation Spending on capital formation, both physical and human.
that equates the market price of an asset to its expected net
present value. Investment decision
A decision as to whether to invest or not based on a DCF model
Income elasticity of demand under 100 per cent equity assumptions.
This measures how the quantity demanded of a mineral changes
if consumer income increases.

Indigenous communities J
Households or families with an ancient and cultural attachment
Joint venture
to the land where mining occurs or has an impact.
A form of unincorporated or corporate contractual arrangement,
Indigenous populations where participants share the costs of a project and the products
‘Existing descendants of the peoples who inhabited the present (not the profits) of the project according to agreed formulae
territory of a country wholly or partially at the time when (generally in proportion to their equity). Joint ventures are
persons of a different culture or ethnic origin arrived there from distinguished from partnerships in that JV participants,
other parts of the world, overcame them, and by conquest, individually and severally, are liable and taxable.
settlement or other means, reduced them to a non-dominant or
JORC Code
colonial situation; who today live more in conformity with their
particular social, economic and cultural customs and traditions Australasian code for reporting of mineral resources and ore
than with the institutions of the country of which they now form reserves prepared by the Joint Ore Reserve Committee (JORC)
a part, under a state structure that incorporates mainly the comprising The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy
national, social and cultural characteristics of other segments of (AusIMM), the Australian Institute of Geoscientists (AIG) and
the population that are predominant …’ (UNESCO, 1982). the Minerals Council of Australia (MCA).

Individual demand curve


A graphical representation of the quantity of a good or service
that each individual demands, at various prices of this good or L
service, other influencing factors being held constant. Law of demand
Individual product The proposition that, other things being equal, if price goes up,
quantity demanded will decrease; and if price goes down,
A geological occurrence where it is profitable only to recover quantity demanded will increase.
one mineral commodity from the material mined or drilled.
Liabilities
Inelastic demand
Future sacrifices of financial benefits that the firm is presently
When a percentage change in an influencing factor leads to a less obliged to make to other entities as a result of past transaction or
than proportional increase in quantity demanded. other events.
Initial public offering (IPO) Liquidity
The process of listing a company on the stock exchange for the The capacity of a firm to satisfy its debt and liabilities with cash
first time by offering shares in the company to the public through when they fall due.
the issuing of a prospectus, with or without the offer being
underwritten by a stockbroker. List prices
Intensity of use The publishing of indicative mineral prices, mainly for minor
metals and some industrial minerals. This often takes place in
The demand for a mineral (usually measured in physical units industry newsletters or other trade journals.
like tonnes) per unit of income discounted.
Location rent
Intergenerational equity
A similar concept to differential rent.
In the minerals and energy sector this is concerned with whether
depletion of mineral resources leaves future generations without London Metal Exchange (LME)
the ability to earn comparable levels of income as the asset stock
The leading terminal market for trading non-ferrous metals. It
inherited by future generations is diminished.
accounts for over 90 per cent of global exchange business for
Internal funding those metals it trades. These are aluminium, aluminium alloy,
copper, lead, nickel, tin and zinc.
Cumulative retained earnings and proceeds from asset sales.
Long run
Internal rate of return (IRR)
A period in which all the market conditions facing a mining firm
A measure of the return per dollar invested – the rate of discount can change. ‘New mines can be developed and processing
at which the NPV of an investment/project becomes zero. facilities built, and firms can expand the capacity of existing
operations’.
International trade
Trade that occurs between nations. Long-term contracts
These apply in mineral markets such as coal and iron ore. They
Interregional trade fix prices for agreed delivery of output for periods of a year or
Trade that takes place between regions within a nation. more, or they index prices according to an agreed formula.

Australian Mineral Economics 219


Market power
M The ability of a producer to set prices above competitive levels,
so that greater profit can be generated.
Macroeconomics
The study of the operations of national economies and the world Market premium (RM - RF)
economy. Its focus has been on measures of economic The degree to which the return on the balanced market portfolio
performance such as Gross Domestic Product, inflation, RM exceeds that on bonds RF.
investment, saving, economic growth and the balance of
payments. Market risk
Also systematic or non-diversifiable risk. That part of the
Main product volatility of the returns on an investment that is due to
A product so important to the economic viability of a mine that economy-wide factors and that cannot be diversified.
its price alone determines a mine’s output.
Market share
Management flexibility Obtaining and holding a nominated percentage share of a mineral
Management capacity to dynamically change the course of a market, a common corporate objective of many large and small
project in response to emerging information dispelling mineral producers.
uncertainty, ie learning with the benefit of hindsight.
Market structure
Marginal benefit The competitive nature of the market for a particular mineral is
The amount of money that someone is willing to pay to enjoy the influenced by the number of buyers and sellers and their
attributes of an additional unit of a good or service. respective market power. Markets can range from being perfectly
competitive with many buyers and sellers to monopolistic and
Marginal benefit curve monopsonistic.
A curve that plots marginal benefits for each additional unit of a
good or service. This is the same as an individual’s demand Market supply curve
curve for a good or service. This shows the total number of units of a good or service that
sellers are willing to deliver to the market at every possible price
Marginal cost during a given period.
The change in the total cost of production from producing an
Material composition of products
additional unit of output.
The amount of minerals used to produce goods and services in an
Marginal physical product economy.
This is the increase in output generated by adding an additional
Maximisation rule
unit of the variable input.
The value of an option is never zero, ie for a call max(S-X, 0)
Marginal revenue and for a put max(X-S, 0).
The change in total revenue that a producer receives from selling Microeconomics
an additional unit of output.
The study of economic decision-making by consumers,
Marginal revenue product households and firms, and the way in which these relate to the
operation of markets.
The additional revenue associated with adding a further unit of a
variable factor of production (eg a mineral). Mineral economics
Market-based valuation The application of economics in the study of all aspects of the
mineral sector.
A method of evaluation based on observable or imputable market
prices. Mineral market demand curve
Market capitalisation This shows how much of a mineral buyers are willing to
purchase at every possible price during a given period. It is
The value placed by the stock market on a company, ie its typically not the horizontal sum of individual demand curves
number of issued shares times their current spot price. because of a ‘final product’ effect on mineral demand.
Market demand curve Mineral policy
This shows the total number of units of a good or service that Rational development of mineral and energy resources to
buyers are willing to purchase in a market at every possible price achieve the broad economic goals of government.
during a given period. It is also the sum of all individual demand
for a good or service. Mineral rent
The returns in excess of those needed to attract factors of
Market equilibrium production into the mining industry in the long run. It is the
A situation where the price of a good or service is such that the revenue remaining after all costs have been deducted. These
quantity that buyers want to buy is the same as the quantity that costs include exploration outlays, expenditures on mine
sellers want to sell. establishment and cash operating costs.

Market portfolio Mineral reserves


A portfolio containing all listed security balanced in terms of their Those ‘quantities of a mineral commodity in subsurface deposits
market capitalisation (eg All Ordinaries Index) and returning a that are known and profitable to exploit, given existing
rate of RM. technology and prices’.

220 Australian Mineral Economics


Mineral resources Net cash flow
Mineral reserves; together with deposits that are: economic but not The difference between all cash inflows and all cash outflows for
yet discovered; or expected to become economic as a result of new a specific asset over a specific period.
technology or other developments within the foreseeable future.
Net present value (NPV)
Modern asset pricing (MAP) The sum of the present values of all the net cash flows to be
An evaluation technique whereby the riskier revenue function is received from an investment/project in the future after
separated from the less risky cost function and its price risk discounting at an appropriate rate of discount.
neutralised by the use of forward prices. These are either obtained
from LME quotes or forecast using a Geometric Brownian Motion Net smelting return (NSR)
stochastic model. The two functions are then recombined and The value of concentrate free on board (fob) mine (free on board –
discounted to present value using the risk-free rate of interest to after deducting smelting and refining charges levied by the custom
compensate only for the timing of the cash flows. smelters and the relevant transport costs).
Monetary policy
New scrap
Deliberate action by government setting interest rates or
otherwise controlling the money supply to influence the ‘When metals are converted into shapes – bars, plates, rods,
performance of the economy. sheets, etc new scrap is generated in the form of turnings,
stampings, cuttings and off-specification materials’ (USGS).
Monopoly
New York Mercantile Exchange (Nymex)
A market in which there is one supplier who can control either
the amount supplied or the price of the product. Trades in futures and options contracts for crude oil, gasoline,
heating oil, natural gas, electricity, gold, silver, copper,
Monopoly rent aluminium and platinum; futures contracts for coal, propane and
palladium; and options contracts on the price differentials
The excess profits which monopolistic producers generate because
between crude oil and gasoline, crude oil and heating oil, Brent
they have induced scarcity or restricted supply of a good or service.
and West Texas Intermediate crude oil and various futures
contract months (calendar spreads) for light, sweet crude; Brent
Monte Carlo simulation
crude; gasoline; heating oil; and natural gas (Nymex, 2006).
A computer-assisted simulation based on generating a large number
of scenarios by sampling various inputs simultaneously and
No-arbitrage
randomly, but according to their respective probability distribution
of occurrence. Monte Carlo simulations generate a probability In frictionless and efficient markets assets generating cash flows
distribution of all possible values of the output being simulated. of the same magnitude and timing and having the same risk must
have the same market price. If this were not the case,
Multiple or chooser option arbitrageurs could buy a lower priced asset in one market and
sell it at a higher price in another, thus making a risk-free profit.
An option offering a number of mutually exclusive alternative
In reality arbitrage opportunities are short-lived, as prices rapidly
courses of actions, which must be exercised by the same expiry
adjust.
time, or continuation of the status quo.

Multipliers Nodal regions


A measure of the total impact on a variable such as spending, Regions identified according to the ‘magnetic’ attraction of a key
income or employment of a unit increment or decrement to this nodal centre for the economic and cultural activities of people
variable. living in the surrounding area.

Nominal money terms


Also historical dollars, dollars of the day or out-turn dollars.
N Monetary terms incorporating the effect of inflation.
Nationalisation Non-monetary values
The process of moving from private to public ownership of key Socio-economic values not directly measurable in monetary
industry sectors in a nation. terms, but through techniques known as shadow pricing. Also
see utility values.
Native title
Traditional rights of access, use, or occupation concerning lands Non-renewable resource
or waters. They are personal or group rights based on traditional
laws or customs (Horrigan). A resource with a rate of natural replenishment is so low that it
does not provide any hope of replenishment within a reasonable
Natural capital time period.
The stock of environmentally provided assets such as the soil,
No-recourse finance
minerals, the atmosphere, the forests, wildlife and water.
See project finance.
Negative externalities
Those costs of resource exploitation activity that are not borne Normal profit
by the mine operator in the form of costs of production which A profit level just sufficient to keep a producer operating in a
have to be covered by mine revenue. Rather they are costs borne particular industry and not moving to another competitive
by society as a whole through, for example, pollution or industry. Normal profits apply in competitive markets but above
environmental degradation. normal profits are typical in other market forms.

Australian Mineral Economics 221


Product composition of income
O A measure of the mix of goods being produced in an economy.

Occupational communities Production


Those households or families who derive all or most of their The process of converting economic resources to useful final
income from mining. goods and services.

Old scrap Production function


Mineral supply obtained from products that have reached the end Describes the technical relationship regarding the generation of
of their useful lives. final key factor inputs such as land, labour, capital and technology.

Oligopoly Production possibility curve


Markets dominated by a few selling firms, where there are A curve showing different maximum combinations of goods and
substantial barriers to entry. services that society can produce if all factors of production are
fully employed during a given period.
Oligopsony Project finance
A market in which there are a small number of buyers. A form of often syndicated, debt-financing package, tailor made
for mining project development and serviced and secured
Option primarily by the cash flow generated by the project it is funding.
The right but not the obligation to buy (or sell) an asset for a True no-recourse arrangements with no claim on the broad
specified price on or before a specified time. corporate assets of the company promoting the project are rare
because of covenants and other conditions often imposed by the
Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) lenders restricting the ability of the borrowers to further borrow
or raise equity and pay dividends.
The group of major oil producers, led by Saudi Arabia, which
has influenced oil prices and output in the world since the early Project risk
1970s.
Risk that is unique to a project given its characteristics.
Own-price elasticity of demand Prospectus
This measures how the quantity demanded of a mineral changes See initial public offering (IPO).
if its price changes.
Purchasing power parity
A measure of cost of living differences between nations and
P regions.

Price risk Put option


Risk attributable to the volatility of the price of the product/ The right but not an obligation to sell an asset for a specified
commodity produced. price on or before a specified date.

Price takers
A situation where mineral producers exert little or no influence
on the prevailing market price for their production. This occurs
Q
particularly in purely competitive markets. Quasi-rents
Rents that emerge because of changes in consumer tastes, new
Price volatility products and new methods of production but which eventually
disappear as more production comes on stream.
The tendency for market prices to move up and down and by
large relative amounts in relatively short time periods.

Price wars R
A situation in which cartel and non-cartel members undercut Real money terms
nominated cartel prices, typically during periods of reduced
product demand in a business cycle downturn. Such actions may Monetary terms disregarding the effect of inflation, ie attributable
lead to the effective end of cartel arrangements or other collusion to the acquisition power of the currency at a specified point in
between producers. time and kept constant over successive periods irrespective of the
presence and magnitude of inflationary effects.
Probabilistic models Real option value (ROV)
DCF models in which probability distributions of possible input The value of the inherent or designed managerial flexibility in
values are used instead of single-point estimates. These models projects. It arises because decision-makers can dynamically
are used to carry out Monte Carlo simulations generating change their actions in response to emerging information
probability distributions of outputs. resolving uncertainty as the project unfolds, ie learning and
acting with the benefit of hindsight. ROV is not captured by the
Producer pricing static DCF/NPV view of the project and must be added to the
A market in which dominant companies nominate the selling NPV to obtain a more realistic measure of project value, ie of its
price of a mineral. Expanded NPV or ENPV = NPV + ROV.

222 Australian Mineral Economics


Registered warehouses
In 2004 the London Metal Exchange maintained a series of 36
warehouses in major centres around the world, serving as stores
S
for the metals which it traded. Saving
The amount of money generated from abstaining from
Renewable resource consumption in any given period.
A resource that can be replenished naturally with the passage of
time. Scenario analysis
The determination of the effect on a model output of changing the
Replicating portfolio value of selected combinations of inputs, generally pessimistic or
For each optional claim on a risky asset one can construct a optimistic, to portray possible future State of Nature.
portfolio made up of a risky asset and risk-free bonds that
exactly replicated the cash flow outcome of the risky asset. Securitise
The process whereby arrangers of syndicated project finance
Residential communities
hedge some or most of the project risk in order to enable them to
Households or families who live in the geographical area affected borrow at lower secured rates of interest on the Eurobond or
by mining. other similar financial markets.
Resource curse Selling pressure
The paradoxical finding that natural resource abundance is This arises where consumers wish to consume less than
negatively related to an economy’s economic performance. producers wish to produce at a given price.
Resource rent tax
Sensitivity analysis
A tax that seeks to identify economic rents by allowing the
deduction of all costs of production from revenue, including The determination of the effect on a model output from changing
normal profit, and then taking a share of any resulting rents. the value of any input.

Risk Sequential/compound options


The extent to which the uncertainty of a variable affects the A series of options with successively longer expiry times, where
returns on an investment or project. exercise of longer-term options is conditional on having
exercised earlier shorter-term ones on which they are dependent.
Risk attitudes
Also risk profile. The influence on an investor of the chance of Shareholders’ equity
making a monetary loss underlying a risky investment. If the Also net worth. The difference between all the assets and all the
magnitude of the potential loss is large relative to the investor’s liabilities of the firm. In accounting terms shareholders’ equity
wealth, the investor will display a risk-averse attitude otherwise comprised the equity capital contributed by the shareholders and
he will be risk-neutral, ie indifferent to money. cumulative earnings retained by the firm.

Risk-free probability Short run


A user-friendly and versatile mathematical algorithm designed to A period in which the market conditions facing a mining firm are
neutralise risk and to discount binomial lattice option values to fixed. These include the firm’s lease, its existing production
their present value of an option. capacity, employment contracts, and several other operating
conditions. A firm can vary its rate of production but it cannot
Risk-free rate of interest (RF) exceed its current mine capacity.
The rate of return necessary to attract investment to risk-free
borrowing instruments, typically government bonds. Shorter-term contracts
Contracts less than a year, which set prices for agreed purchases
Risk management of mineral output.
A set of corporate rules designed to minimise the potential
impact of risk, ie the severity of consequences of possible events Single option
weighted by their probability of occurrence. An option offering a new course of action or continuation of the
status quo.
Risk-neutral
A risk-neutral investor will select investment opportunities with
Social and cultural sustainability
the maximum expected value irrespective of the underlying risk.
Fairness in the distribution of benefits and burdens associated
Risk of Gambler’s ruin with economic activities to all participating interest groups.
The probability that the risk capital is insufficient to support a
large enough number of risky investments providing sufficient Social impact analysis (SIA)
confidence that the returns generated will be adequate to sustain The process of assessing or estimating, in advance, the social
the financial viability of the firm thus avoiding bankruptcy. consequences that are likely to follow from specific policy
actions or project developments.
Risk-tolerance
The degree to which an investor can bear risk, as measured by its Socio-economic indexes
risk capital or risk tolerance coefficient (RT). Measures typically computed by central statistical agencies such
as the Australian Bureau of Statistics, which measure particular
Risk-tolerance coefficient – See risk tolerance social characteristics of a population.

Australian Mineral Economics 223


Solvency Term of option (t)
A firm is solvent if the value of its assets exceeds that of its Time during which managerial flexibility is open.
liabilities.
Terms of trade
Sovereign risk The ratio of the prices of the goods and services that a nation
This arises when host governments arbitrarily change the laws to exports to the price of the goods and services that it imports.
impose tax burdens, or other operating rules and regulations that
were not indicated originally. Terra nullius
Specific royalties Land belonging to no one.
A royalty levied on the physical rather than the financial measure
of a mineral resource. Tornado diagram
An effective diagrammatic way of portraying the results of
Spider web diagram sensitivity analyses, based on possible ranges of input values, in
An effective diagrammatic way of portraying sensitivity analyses. a manner that ranks the tested inputs in order of decreasing
influence on the output of the model.
Spot price or project payoff (S)
The present value (discounted at an appropriate time and Trade
risk-adjusted discount rate) of all net, after-tax operating cash A process of exchange between individuals, business and
flows generated by the project over its whole life. governments, which generally makes each participating party
better off as a result of the transaction.
State price
What an investor is prepared to pay for a ‘state asset’, ie for a Trade liberalisation
contingent claim that pays $1 with certainty if the up state is The movement towards freer trade between nations.
realised at the end of the period or zero if the down state eventuates.
Trade-Weighted Index
Substitute good
A weighted average of a basket of currencies that reflects the
A good that be used as an alternative to another good because it importance of the sum of a nation’s exports and imports of goods
possesses a similar range of attributes. by country.
Sustainable development
Transfer prices
The simultaneous pursuit of sustained or enhanced: environmental
These apply where firms, who control different stages of
quality, economic growth and social justice.
downstream processing of a mineral through vertical integration,
Swap make sales of mineral output at agreed prices to other branches
of the firm. Governments monitor these prices closely to try to
A contractual arrangement to pay a slightly higher rate of fixed ensure that their levels do not reduce profits and the ability of a
interest to convert a variable-interest-rate loan into a fixed-rate one. firm to pay company taxes.
Systematic risk
Risk that depends on economy-wide factors and cannot be
diversified away by the portfolio effect. U
Utilitarian philosophy
The view that each person makes decisions with the objective of
T maximising his or her happiness, both intellectual and sensual.
Tax base Utility
The object from which a tax is being sought. Each expected dollar value (X) has a reduced ‘utility’ value u(X),
which depends on an individual investor’s preferences and risk
Tax neutrality tolerance coefficient (RT).
This arises when the system that collects economic rent from a
mining company has no effect on its production decisions. Utility function
Tax rate An algorithm that derives the utility value u(X) as a negative
exponential function of the expected monetary value to be
The rate applied to the base to calculate mineral revenue proceeds.
received (X) divided by the individual investor’s risk tolerance
coefficient (RT).
Taylor’s rule
An empirical method to estimate the optimal mine life based on
diluted mining reserves, ie mine life (years) = 6.5 * (diluted
0.25
mining reserve (Mt)) . The mine life is generally reduced by
up to 25 per cent if mining is carried out by contractors.
V
VALMIN Code
Terminal markets Code for the technical assessment and valuation of mineral and
Mineral markets such as the London Metal Exchange and the petroleum assets and securities for independent expert reports,
New York Mercantile Exchange where prices are set, at least on prepared by the VALMIN Committee, a joint committee of The
a daily basis, to balance that day’s marginal offerings and Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy (AusIMM), the
demand. These markets also perform a variety of other functions. Australian Institute of Geoscientists (AIG) and the Mineral

224 Australian Mineral Economics


Industry Consultants Association (MICA), with the participation Venture capital
of the Australian Stock Exchange Limited (ASX), the Australian Forms of unlisted equity funding to address the high-risk initial
Securities and Investment Commission (ASIC), the Minerals stages of projects provided by venture capitalists.
Council of Australia (MCA), the Petroleum Exploration Society
of Australia (PESA), the Securities Institute of Australia (SIA) Vertical equity
and representatives from the Australian finance sector. Concerned with whether miners who generate different amounts of
economic rent are treated differently in the amount of tax they pay.
Value adding argument
The proposition that mineral producers should engage in Very long run
downstream processing of these minerals within their borders to A period in which the constraint imposed by existing known
increase the benefit to the nation’s citizens. mineral deposits no longer holds and firms have the time to
conduct exploration and find new deposits. In this time period
Value additivity emerging technology, induced either by the exhaustion of known
Different elements of a DCF model can be separated, appropriately deposits or higher metal prices or both, may also permit the
discounted and recombined to derive a project NPV. exploitation of new types of deposits.

Value at risk (VaR) Volatility (σ)


A probabilistic method to determine the maximum possible loss Standard deviation of the logarithm of the return from holding an
that may be incurred at a given level of confidence over a asset.
specified time horizon.

Value consistency
In arbitrage-free markets assets generating cash flows of the
same magnitude and timing and having the same risk must have
W
the same market price. Weighted average cost of capital (WACC)
A method to estimate the corporate cost of capita (RC). It weights
Variable costs the cost of debt (before or after tax) by the proportion of debt to
These are costs that change with the level of output that a firm total funds and the cost of equity in proportion to total funds in
produces. the financial structure of the firm.

Australian Mineral Economics 225


Contents
1. Mineral Economics — An Introduction Philip Maxwell

Definitions of Economics and the Economic Way of Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1


Economics and Mineral Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
The Focus of Mineral Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
Some Key Questions in Mineral Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
The Structure of this Volume . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

Minerals and the World Economy

2. Minerals, Growth and Development Philip Maxwell

Some Foundations – Mineral Exploitation, Production, Distribution, Consumption, Trade and Related Economic
Concepts. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Economic Growth and Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Periods of History and Minerals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Economic Development and Mineral Resources – The Traditional View . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
The Australian Experience . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Complicating Factors with Mineral Production and Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
Appendix – A Classification of Developed and Developing Nations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

3. Minerals and the Developing Nations Philip Maxwell

Mineral Dependent Developing Nations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17


The Impact of New Mineral Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
External market forces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Internal economic stresses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Distorted processes of policy making. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
The Resource Curse Hypothesis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Institutional and Policy Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

4. Trade in Minerals Philip Maxwell

Why Trade Takes Place . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27


The World Economy, International and Interregional Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
Recent World Production and Trade in Minerals and Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
Australian Production and Trade in Minerals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Transport Costs and the Direction of Minerals and Energy Trade. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
Minerals Trade and Exchange Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
Minerals — Consumption, Production and Markets

5. Mineral Demand — The Theory in Practice Peter Howie

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
The Final-Product Demand Curve and the Level of Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
Final-product demand and its determinants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
Mineral Resources and Derived Demand. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
The mineral demand curve . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
Shifts of the mineral demand curve . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
Elasticity of Mineral Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
Own-price elasticity of mineral demand in the short run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
Income elasticity of mineral demand in the short term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
Cross-price elasticity of mineral demand in the short term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
Elasticity of mineral demand in the long run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

6. Mineral Supply — Exploration, Production, Processing and


Recycling Philip Maxwell

Some Introductory Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49


Short-run and long-run supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
The mineral supply process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Supply curves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Resources and Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Mineral Supply – Individual Products, Main Products, Co-Products and By-Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
Key Determinants of New Mineral Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
Individual and main products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52
By-products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
Co-products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
Secondary Materials – The Economics of Recycling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
The supply of new scrap minerals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
Old scrap mineral supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
Total Mineral Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

7. Mineral Markets, Prices and the Recent Performance of the


Minerals and Energy Sector Phillip Crowson

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
Market Structure – Competitive Markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
Market Structure – Oligopolistic Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
The Rise and Fall of Cartels. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
Producer Pricing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Terminal Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
The London Metal Exchange . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
Recent Trends in Mineral Markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
8. The Mineral Sector Workforce Philip Maxwell

A Global Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
The formal mining sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
Artisanal and small-scale mining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
Mineral Sector Employment in Australia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
Historical trends . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
Employment, value added and capital intensity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
Salaries, wages and employment levels . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
Occupational and educational structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Location issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Important Mineral Sector Workforce Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
Gender imbalance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
Maintaining a supply of well-trained professionals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
The growth of fly-in, fly-out workforces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
Summary and Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

Mineral Finance and Investment

9. An Introduction to Mineral Finance Pietro Guj

Financial Objectives and Financial Management. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87


The role of financial managers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
Sources and Application of Funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
General considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
Main sources of funds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Sources of Equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
General considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Off-market sources of initial equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
On-market sources of equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
Resource sector IPOs are generally small . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
Criteria for inclusion in a stock market index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Innovative investment vehicles for the resources industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Fiscal incentives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Joint venture farm-outs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
Specialty finance (royalty) companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
The Cost of Equity: Balancing Risk and Return . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
Sources of Debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
Some general considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
Long-term debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
Short-term debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
Hybrids Between Equity and Debt. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
Project Finance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
Some introductory considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
Risk underpinning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
The Financial Structure of Mining Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Cost of debt, financial leverage and financial risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Financial structure of mining companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

10. Mineral Project Evaluation — An Introduction Pietro Guj

What is it Worth? – Types and Uses of Financial Valuations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99


General issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
Market and cost-based evaluations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100
Fundamental or technical evaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100
Income-Based Valuations and Discounted Cash Flow (DCF) Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100
The basic DCF model structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100
Constructing a simple DCF model of a mine . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .101
Project valuations are at a point in time – discounting cash flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .103
Reconciling cash and financial accounting accrual figures in a DCF model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .104
Modelling Debt and Financial Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .105
Comparison of Mutually Exclusive Projects with Different Lives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .107
Lease or buy? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .108
Inherent Weaknesses and Common Traps in DCF Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .109
Identifying and Quantifying Financial Risk: Expected Value, Sensitivity and Scenario Analyses . . . . . . . . . . . . . .110
Probabilistic Models and Financial Simulations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .111

11. Preliminary, Prefeasibility and Feasibility Studies Rick West

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .113
The Phases of a Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .114
Testing the Data – Technical Due Diligence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .114
Types of Evaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .115
The feasibility study is an iterative process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .115
Scoping or conceptual studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .115
The prefeasibility study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .116
The feasibility study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .117
Bankable feasibility studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .117
Definitive project cost estimates. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .118
Owner management activities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .118
Project management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .118
Applicable codes and professional competency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .118
Costs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
Capital costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .119
Operating costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .120
Market Surveys and Commodity Prices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .121
Financial Evaluation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .121
The cash flow . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .121
Project optimisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .122
Some Comments on Cut-Off Grades and Other Cut-Off Points . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .122
Risks and Sensitivities Associated with Feasibility Studies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .123
Risks associated with the project’s resource base . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .123
Mining and processing risks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .123
Project design and construction risks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Financial and marketing risks. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Capital costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Operating costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Commodity prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Project sensitivities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124
Managing risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .125
Managing the Feasibility Study Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .125
Feasibility Study Reports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .125
Appendix – Checklist of the Main Sections of Feasibility Study Reports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .126

12. Mineral Project Evaluation — Dealing with Uncertainty and Risk Pietro Guj

Introduction: Beyond DCF/NPV Analysis. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .129


Attitudes to Risk – From Expected Value to Expected Preference Value (Certainty Equivalents) and Pricing of
Risky Projects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129
Understanding the nature of risk and risk-neutral expected returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .129
From risk-neutral to risk-averse investment decisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .130
Risk exposure and value at risk (VaR) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .131
Risk preferences and the price of risky investment opportunities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .131
Risk Spreading Through Joint Ventures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .133
Bayesian Decision Trees and Progressive Risk and Value Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .134
Modern Asset Pricing (MAP) Using Commodity Forward Prices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .137
No-arbitrage and replicating portfolios principles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .137
Commodities forward prices as certainty equivalents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .138
From Static DCF/NPV to Dynamic Real Option Valuations (ROV) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .140
A different logic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .140
Types of real options in mining projects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .140
The market has been effective at setting real option values – considering the case of Sally Malay . . . . . . . . . .141
Estimating the real option value of the Sally Malay project in September 2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .142
Using Binomial Lattices in Real Option Valuations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .142
Valuing an Expansion Option with the Binomial Lattice Method Using the ‘Risk-Free Probability’. . . . . . . . . . . .144
Valuing Tonnage-Grade Trade-Offs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .145
Evaluating the Sequential and Compound Real Option Value of Mineral Exploration Farm-In/Options
Agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .146
Strategic ROV Considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .148
Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .148
Minerals and Public Policy

13. Mineral Policy — An Introduction Philip Maxwell and Pietro Guj

The Aims and Practice of Economic Policy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .153


The Context of Mineral Policy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .154
Mineral Policy in Practice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .155
The Transition of Mineral Policy since 1950 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .156
The post-1960 surge in public ownership. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .157
The swing back to private ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .158
Some current policy realities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .158
Towards a competitive regulatory and fiscal regime for exploration and mining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .158

14. The Legal and Regulatory Environment of Mining Gavin Jahn

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .161
The Australian Federation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .161
Inconsistency Between State and Federal Laws. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .162
The meaning of law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .162
Commonwealth Power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .162
The corporations power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .162
Industrial relations power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .163
Export power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .163
External affairs power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .164
Race power and native title . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .164
Native title legislation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .165
Native title claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .165
Validity of the tenements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .165
State Legislation – The Western Australian Situation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Mining Act 1978 (Western Australia). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Mining tenements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
The mining lease (ML) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
The exploration licence (EL). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Renewals and extensions of tenements. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Special agreement acts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Mine Safety and Inspection Act 1994 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .166
Aboriginal Heritage Act 1972 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .167
Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
Appendix – Validity and Consistency Under Section 109 of the Australian Constitution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .168
Invalid. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
The tests for inconsistency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .168
Repugnancy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .168
The Commonwealth permits or confers: the state prohibits or deprives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .168
Covering the field test. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .168
The field. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .169
Coverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .169

15. Mineral Taxation and Royalties Frank Harman and Pietro Guj

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .171
Minerals sector taxation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .171
Contents of this chapter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .171
A note on terminology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .172
Why are there special taxation and royalty regimes for the minerals sector? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .172
Economic Rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .172
Economic rent and normal profit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .172
Economic rent and scarcity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .173
Economic rent, scarcity and the minerals sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .173
Pursuing economic rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .174
Relevant Constitutional Powers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .174
Ownership and control of mineral resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .174
Powers to raise mineral taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .175
Design Principles for the Taxation of Mineral Rents. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .175
Economic efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .175
Equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176
Administrative cost. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .176
Transparency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .176
Stability. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .176
Current Mineral Taxation Regimes in Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .176
Taxes designed to capture economic rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .176
Tax and royalty regimes in the Australian states, the Northern Territory and the Commonwealth. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
. 77
Queensland . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .177
New South Wales. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .177
Victoria . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .178
Tasmania . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .178
South Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .178
Western Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .178
Northern Territory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .179
The Commonwealth of Australia. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .179
Other issues in the collection and use of economic rents in Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Export levies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Rail freight rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Pipeline licence fees . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Infrastructure contributions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Cash bidding . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Government equity participation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .180
Hybrid resource rent tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Using economic rents for the future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Net impact of Australian federalism on state royalty revenues. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Evaluating Australian Mineral Taxation and Royalty Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Assessment of different taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Specific royalties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Ad valorem royalties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Profit based royalties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .181
Rent-based regimes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .182
Problem areas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .182
Commonwealth Company Income Tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .182
Deductibility of exploration expenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .182
Depreciation of capital expenditures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .183
Other issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .183
Mineral Revenue Policies for the Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .183

16. Mining, Sustainability and Sustainable Development Roderick Eggert

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .187
Sustainability and Sustainable Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .187
Mining and Environmental Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .188
Mining and Economic Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .189
Mining and Social Justice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .189
Public Policy: Principles and Concepts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .190
Putting Sustainability and Sustainable Development into Practice in Mining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .192
Final Thoughts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .193
Appendix A – The Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development Project . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .193
Nine key challenges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .193
Appendix B – Summary Findings of the Extractive Industries Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .194
Appendix C – Ten Principles of the Global Compact . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .194
Human rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .194
Labour . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194
Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .194
Anti-corruption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .194

17. Mining and Indigenous Populations Philip Maxwell

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .195
Aboriginal Australia – Some Historical Background. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .196
Aboriginal Australia – Some Recent Comparative Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .197
Mining and Aboriginal Australia – Pre Mabo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .199
Howitt’s study of Roebourne . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .199
Dillon’s study of Argyle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .201
Mining and Aboriginal Australia – The Mabo Case and Recent Developments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .202
The trend towards negotiated agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .204
Looking to the Future. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .204
18. Minerals and Regional Development Philip Maxwell

Some Introductory Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .207


Mining – Towns, Cities and Regions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .208
The Australian Regional Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .209
Mining and Australian Regional Development – A Historical Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .210
Socio-Economic Indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .210
Assessing Economic Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .212
Assessing Social Impacts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .213
Fly-In, Fly-Out and Regional Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .213

Glossary of Terms 215

Subject Index 227

Name Index 247


CHAPTER 1

Mineral Economics — An Introduction


Philip Maxwell

Definitions of Economics and the Economic Way of Thinking


Economics and Mineral Economics
The Focus of Mineral Economics
Some Key Questions in Mineral Economics
The Structure of this Volume

DEFINITIONS OF ECONOMICS AND THE examines that part of individual and social action
ECONOMIC WAY OF THINKING which is most closely connected with the
attainment and with the use of the material
Economics, and the economic way of thinking, have had an requisites of wellbeing.
important influence on business and government affairs for at
Thus it is on the one side a study of wealth; and
least the last two centuries. The Scottish author Adam Smith
on the other, and more important side, a part of
espoused the foundations of modern economic thought in 1776
the study of man.
(Smith, 1976 [1776]). His famous volume – The Wealth of
Nations1 – ushered in a revolution in economic thinking. His This is a broad definition and, as such, it attracted debate. In
ideas formed the basis of the new academic field of political seeking to clarify the nature of economics, Robbins (1932, p 16)
economy, which writers such as William Stanley Jevons renamed offered a different perspective with his so-called ‘scarcity’
as economics some 100 years later. definition as opposed to Marshall’s ‘materialist’ definition. This
In the early pages of his book, The Worldly Philosophers, was that:
Heilbroner (1972) traces the rise of economics to the emergence
Economics is the science which studies human
of the market system in the wake of the Industrial Revolution,
behaviour as a relationship between ends and
which began in the middle of the 18th century. Prior to that time,
scarce means which have alternative uses.
the organisation and survival of society had largely depended on
tradition and authoritarian rule. Most writers of modern principles economics textbooks have
The discipline of economics developed strongly during the embraced this scarcity definition. Without scarcity, there would
20th century, with economists applying its principles to many be no need for markets. Everything would be free and
areas and industries. One of these industries was mining. For at uncontested. It provides a reference point for new students to
least the last 50 years, undergraduate students in mining consider and digest the subsequent theories and models of
engineering programs around the world have taken one or more classical and neoclassical economics, the two major schools of
courses in mineral economics or engineering economics as part thought. They present it in a slightly extended version such as:
of their curriculum. Graduate coursework programs in mineral Economics is the study of how people and society
economics have also developed in a number of well-known choose to employ scarce productive resources to
universities. produce goods and services and distribute them
As one might expect, mineral economics is ‘the application among various groups in society (Waud et al,
of economics in the study of all aspects of the mineral sector’ 1996, p 6).
(MacKenzie, 1987, p 2). To understand its focus more clearly, This is, however, not the last word. Non-traditional
however, it is necessary briefly to consider the definition of economists, such as John Kenneth Galbraith take an even broader
economics, and its evolution. view. In his volume The New Industrial State, Galbraith (1978,
One of the most widely used early definitions of economics p 417) notes that:
was that of Alfred Marshall, in his influential volume, The
Principles of Economics. Marshall (1890, p 1) notes that: In economics:
POLITICAL ECONOMY or ECONOMICS is the • Economic theory – the study which deals with
study of man in the ordinary business of life; it the way prices, output and incomes of
individuals, firms and the economy at large
are decided – is one area of specialisation.
1. Its full title is An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations (Smith, 1976 [1776]). • The corporation is another.

Australian Mineral Economics 1


CHAPTER 1: MINERAL ECONOMICS — AN INTRODUCTION

• Decision theory – how decisions are reached TABLE 1.1


in complex organisations – is yet another and The size of the minerals sector in selected economies and the
more modern field. extent of international minerals trade – 2001. Source: World Bank
(2004), various.
Writers in the field of mineral economics such as MacKenzie
(1987), and practitioners more generally, have tended to embrace Country Minerals Total GDP Minerals Mineral
a broader definition in the Galbraithian mould. Why and how this GDP (US$ B) GDP/Total exports/Total
has happened is considered in the third section of this chapter. (US$ B) GDP exports
Before doing so, consideration is given to the place of mineral USA 150 9780.8 0.015 0.04
economics in the broader context of the study of economics more Japan 81.4 4523.3 0.018 negligible
generally.
Germany 40.2 1939.6 0.021 0.007
China 45 1131.2 0.04 0.04
ECONOMICS AND MINERAL ECONOMICS
India 14.5 477.4 0.03 0.09
The rise of economics during the 20th century has occurred in
Australia 17.2 410.0 0.042 0.36
several dimensions. At one level there has been division of the
discipline between microeconomics and macroeconomics. Brazil 7.6 508.9 0.015 0.21
Microeconomics is the study of economic decision-making by Canada 25.2 681.6 0.037 0.18
consumers, households, firms and government, and the way in South Africa 8.6 121.9 0.081 0.274
which these relate to the operation of markets. Its focus has been Chile 10.5 66.5 0.158 0.42
on areas such as supply and demand, on the organisation of
markets and on industry regulation. Peru 4.1 53.0 0.077 0.46
Macroeconomics, by contrast, is concerned with the Papua New 0.8 3.0 0.250 0.80
operations of national economies and the world economy. Its Guinea
focus has been on measures of economic performance such as Botswana 1.9 5.3 0.360 0.59
Gross Domestic Product, inflation, investment, saving, economic Namibia 1.4 3.5 0.200 0.62
growth, the balance of payments and the distribution of income
and wealth. It is concerned as well with the formulation of fiscal, Ghana 0.9 5.7 0.250 0.49
monetary and other areas of national economic policy to manage Zambia 0.7 3.3 0.200 0.74
these variables. Indonesia 13.0 144.7 0.090 0.29
There has also been strong interest in areas such as
Nigeria 6.7 37.1 0.180 1.00
international trade and finance, economic development, financial
markets and institutions, public finance, labour markets, Saudi Arabia 56.1 181.1 0.310 0.95
economic systems, urban and regional economics, natural
resource economics, environmental economics, economic
history, law and economics, and the history of economic thought.
Many economists make their careers by specialising in one of Minerals differ widely in their characteristics. The standard
these fields2. classification of metals, non-metals and energy minerals
provides one pointer to these differences. An appreciation of the
In a rather different way, there has also been a growing interest
in the economics of many major industries. Fields such as diversity of minerals produced and consumed is possible by
agricultural economics, transport economics, health economics, reviewing relevant web pages of the United States Geological
communication economics, tourism economics, cultural Survey or Natural Resources Canada. The list in Table 1.2
economics, and mineral economics also are now distinct (derived from United States Geological Survey web pages)
sub-disciplines. shows that there are at least 50 metals, 50 non-metals and seven
The study of these areas has emerged because of: or eight major energy minerals that are mined or drilled on a
regular basis around the world. They vary widely in value with
• the overall size of these industries; oil being worth several hundred billion dollars annually, while
• their importance to specific economies and regions; and some of the smaller minerals would be worth perhaps as little as
• different specific characteristics which make them worthy of US$ 10 million each year.
separate analysis. MacKenzie (1987, p 6) argues that the main special
characteristic of the minerals sector that justifies its study as a
The minerals sector currently accounts for around US$ 700 separate sub-branch of economics relates to the issue of
billion of world production. This is a little more than two per cent geological endowment. The implications of a fixed endowment
of the world’s estimated gross product. Perhaps more importantly, for economic analysis relate to patterns of optimal use, the
international minerals trade has consistently accounted for more optimal timing of this use, increasing scarcity and conservation.
than ten per cent of the value of world merchandise trade since He notes in particular that mineral deposits are:
1960. Mineral production and trade is of great significance in as
many as 50 nations, and it is the dominant industry in many • initially unknown (they must be discovered);
sub-national regions around the world. Some indication of this • fixed in size (they are non-renewable);
importance for selected economies can be seen in Table 1.1.
• variable in quality (they often must be extracted using new
A difference between minerals and many other commodities is technologies); and
that they are factor inputs rather than final consumer goods. With
one or two notable exceptions, manufacturers demand them • fixed in location (they may be discovered in remote locations
because of the particular attributes they possess – qualities such and need to be moved to intermediate and end-use markets).
as strength, ductility, heat conductivity, and resistance to An associated supply-side matter of interest is recycling. While
corrosion to produce final consumer and producer goods. most energy minerals can be consumed only once, metals and
some non-metals can be profitably recycled using old-scrap and
2. It can also be noted that the broader discipline of finance has become new-scrap sources. Recycling may also be more environmentally
an area of applied microeconomics in the past three decades. friendly.

2 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 1: MINERAL ECONOMICS — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 1.2 4. they have unusually large local environmental, social and
A classification of mineral resources – metals, non-metals and economic impacts; and
energy. Source: United States Geological Survey (2006).
5. their national economic impact varies greatly over
Metals Non-metals Energy relatively short periods of time.
Aluminium Abrasives Black coal
Antimony Aggregates Brown coal THE FOCUS OF MINERAL ECONOMICS
Arsenic Bromine Crude oil While one can justify the study of mineral economics in terms of
Asbestos Cement LNG the rise of the economics discipline, the emergence of mineral
Bauxite and alumina Clays LPG economics has also been influenced by the development of
parallel sub-disciplines such as engineering economics. In their
Barite Corundum Uranium preface to a successful US text in the area, Riggs, Bedworth and
Beryllium Crushed stone Randhawa (1996, p xv) note that:
Bismuth Diamond The curriculums of most professional schools (of
Cadmium Dimension stone engineering) include a course in applied
Cesium Feldspar economics under such titles as engineering
economy, financial management, managerial
Chromium Fluorspar
economics and economic decision-making.
Cobalt Garnet
Copper Gemstones
These courses typically appear in the latter part of the
undergraduate curriculum. In mining schools, they were initially
Gallium Graphite often called mining economics. Their emphasis was typically on
Germanium Gypsum decision-making at the operational level, usually with a focus on
Gold Helium minimising or optimising costs in the context of investment
Indium Iodine
decisions. Students completing these courses often then expect
that subsequent study of mineral economics will largely be
Iron Lime focused on issues or project evaluation and related areas of
Lead Limestone applied financial analysis.
Lithium Mica While this emphasis from the operations side has been an
Magnesium Peat important influence on the development of mineral economics,
Schanz (1990) points to a broader emerging interest in the
Manganese Perlite
economics of the mineral industry in the United States in the
Mercury Phosphate rock early 1930s. The Brookings Institute commissioned lectures in
Molybdenum Potash the area in 1931 and faculty members at universities such as
Nickel Pumice
Penn State and Columbia began offering courses in the late
1930s. The origins of the formal study of mineral economics
Niobium Quartz crystal appear to have come from concerns over the implications of the
Platinum group metals (6) Salt fixed geological endowment for strategic mineral supply in the
Rare earths (14) Sand and gravel United States during the Cold War. In 1946 the College of
Mineral Industries at Penn State formed a separate small
Rhenium Sandstone
department to offer the first degrees in mineral economics.
Silver Scoria Several other mineral economics programs have emerged over
Tantalum Selenium the past half-century (and some of these have disappeared). As
Thallium Silica this volume is written there are six or seven active programs
spread around the world. They are at institutions such as the
Thorium Slate
Colorado School of Mines, Curtin University of Technology, the
Tin Sodium sulfate University of the Witwatersrand, Michigan Tech, the University
Titanium Sulfur of Chile, the Luleå University of Technology and the Pontificia
Vanadium Talc
Catholic University of Chile.
Post-professional programs in mineral economics tend to
Zinc Tungsten
contain a strong emphasis on financial analysis. They combine
Zirconium Vermiculite this with study of mainstream economic issues, which arise from
the special nature of mineral markets, and the other features that
the geological endowment constraint places on the study of the
Garnaut (1995) adds a further perspective on the special nature of
discipline. One view is that the key contribution of mineral
minerals when he describes five characteristics of mines that make
economics has been systematically to analyse the benefits and
them a special focus of government policy and administration.
costs at project level, for the firm and for society.
These are:
Many professionals, who take mineral economics courses, are
1. they can generate economic rent3; seeking to move into more senior managerial roles. It seems
2. they are often established most efficiently on a very large desirable therefore, that any comprehensive treatment of the area
scale; should address the strategic, operational and human resource
management issues that relate specifically to resource sector
3. their development is often highly capital intensive; companies, as well as providing a suitable overview of the legal
environment in which these firms operate. These elements relate
3. Chapter 13 later shows that this ‘is a surplus in excess of the minimum quite neatly to Galbraith’s broader definition of economics, with
profit required by shareholders in a company or firm to stay in its focus on economic theory, the corporation and decision-
business’. Mineral rents receive further attention also in Chapter 15. making.

Australian Mineral Economics 3


CHAPTER 1: MINERAL ECONOMICS — AN INTRODUCTION

It is instructive to complete this introductory discussion by THE STRUCTURE OF THIS VOLUME


making one further important point. MacKenzie (1987, p 8)
identifies two main requirements for the practice of mineral In compiling this monograph, our aim is to provide a balanced
economics. They are: and up to date view of the approaches and techniques which
mineral economists use to appreciate the resources sector. While
• knowledge of the principles of economics and associated the bias of this volume is towards the Australian mineral and
analysis techniques; and energy sector, the discussion often takes a broader perspective.
• understanding of the technical characteristics of the mineral We live in a ‘global village’ and if this volume is to provide value
sector that are of significance from an economic viewpoint. to its readers, it must be internationally relevant.
The focus of discussion in this chapter has been on the first of The 17 chapters that follow this introduction are organised in
these issues. However, the second point is also important. It is four main sections:
often necessary to appreciate the technical issues relating to a • Minerals and the World Economy (three chapters);
mining or energy project to apply economic and other principles
to its analysis. Business, law and economics graduates will find it • Minerals: Consumption, Production and Markets (four chapters);
difficult to undertake the depth of analysis necessary to analyse • Mineral Finance and Investment (four chapters); and
minerals sector issues unless they extend their technical • Minerals and Public Policy (six chapters).
knowledge in areas such as geology, mining methods and
mineral processing. Philip Maxwell has played the coordinating role with the first,
A well-trained mineral economist will apply economic second and fourth sections. Pietro Guj is responsible for the
principles, in combination with suitable technical knowledge, to Mineral Finance and Investment section. Each of us contributes
analyse resources available in a fixed endowment. He or she will on an ongoing basis to the Graduate Coursework program in
consider issues such as how to use minerals, when to use them, Mineral Economics in the Western Australian School of Mines.
how to mine them, when to recycle them and how to regulate One of the features that has assisted the quality of our program
them. offerings over the past decade has been the contributions from
colleagues from other institutions, both in Australia and
overseas. It is particularly appropriate, therefore, that several of
SOME KEY QUESTIONS IN MINERAL these visiting faculty, together with other selected colleagues, are
ECONOMICS also contributing to this volume. Others have acted as reviewers.
This short section is something of an aside. It seemed a good Their insights enhance the quality of the pages ahead. We thank
idea to pose some of the questions that we are seeking to address them for their contributions.
in this volume. The aim is to whet your appetite for the journey
ahead. Here they are! REFERENCES
Galbraith, J K, 1978. The New Industrial State, third revised edition,
Does an abundance of mineral resources make a country rich? (Houghton Mifflin: Boston).
What effects do mineral-based resource booms have on Garnaut, R, 1995. Dilemmas of governance, in Mining and Mineral
different economies? Resource Policy in Asia-Pacific: Prospects for the 21st Century (eds:
D Denoon, C Ballard, G Banks and P Hancock) pp 61-66 (Australian
What factors influence the discovery and exploitation of National University: Canberra).
minerals around the world? Heilbroner, R, 1972. The Worldly Philosophers, fourth edition (Simon
and Schuster: New York).
What did the discovery of gold do to the Australian economy? MacKenzie, B, 1987. Mineral Economics: Decision-Making Methods in
Why has the resources sector been important to economies the Mineral Industry (Australian Mineral Foundation: Adelaide).
such as Australia, Canada and Chile in the recent past? Marshall, A, 1890. The Principles of Economics.
Riggs, J L, Bedworth, D B and Ranhawa, S U, 1996. Engineering
What factors determine the contribution of mineral production Economics, fourth edition (McGraw-Hill: New York).
to sustainable economic wellbeing? Robbins, L, 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic
What influence has greater environmental regulation had on Science (Macmillan: London).
the supply of minerals? Schanz, J J Jr, 1990. Mineral economics and mineral economists –
Origins of the species, Working Paper 90-13, Department of Mineral
What forces have been driving change in mining’s interaction Economics, Colorado School of Mines, 41 p.
with local communities? Smith, A, 1976 [1776]. An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations (eds: R H Campbell, A S Skinner and W B Todd)
How important is international trade in minerals and energy?
(Oxford University Press: Oxford).
What role has major changes in transport costs played in United States Geological Survey, 2006. Commodity statistics and
international minerals trade? information [online]. Available from: <http://minerals.usgs.gov/
minerals/pubs/commodity>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
How does recent growth in mineral and energy trade Waud, R N, Maxwell, P, Hocking, A, Bonnici, J and Ward, I, 1996.
compare with growth in other areas of international trade? Economics, third Australian edition (Longman: Melbourne).
What are the sources of competitive advantage of the World Bank, 2004. World Development Indicators (Oxford University
Australian minerals sector? Press: New York).

What are the key factors that influence the demand for
different minerals?
How important are joint production issues in the analysis of
mineral supply?
How has recycling affected the supply of major metals in
the recent past?

4 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 2

Minerals, Growth and Development


Philip Maxwell

Some Foundations – Mineral Exploitation, Production, Distribution, Consumption, Trade and


Related Economic Concepts
Economic Growth and Development
Periods of History and Minerals
Economic Development and Mineral Resources – The Traditional View
The Australian Experience
Complicating Factors with Mineral Production and Consumption
Appendix – A Classification of Developed and Developing Nations

SOME FOUNDATIONS – MINERAL EXPLOITATION, Hence it may be hypothesised that:


PRODUCTION, DISTRIBUTION, CONSUMPTION,
TRADE AND RELATED ECONOMIC CONCEPTS Economic output = f (Land, Labour, Capital, Environment)
Several processes always occurring within any economy
determine the economic wellbeing of its citizens. They include But what do economists mean by land, labour and capital?
production, distribution, consumption and trade. The focus of Land refers to all of the natural resources used in production. As
this volume is how minerals and energy impinge on these well as the land itself it includes water, forests, fisheries, oil, gas
processes. and mineral deposits. Labour refers to the skills and capabilities
It is typical, initially at least, to think of the ways in which used by humans in the production process. Capital describes all
people use minerals and energy in the process of producing goods of the manufactured aids used in the process of production1.
and services. The distribution of the proceeds of resource wealth The environment reflects the quality of the natural world
and the consumption of mineral and energy resources are very around us. It is responsible for quality of the air that we breathe,
important as well. Furthermore, the sale and purchase of minerals the water that we drink and the way that we utilise it affects the
and energy through interregional and international trade plays an food that we eat and the materials that we use to build shelter for
important role in increasing people’s welfare. ourselves. The services that the environment provides are an
Let us begin by taking a production view of things. Over any input to production. It is also a ‘sink’ for our wastes and if this
given period, what an individual, firm, region, nation or the aspect is overused, the environment can adversely affect our
world produces in terms of a production function in which the ability to produce.
output generated is a function of the economic resources used as Critics might argue that most mining and oil companies
inputs. Economists have typically denoted these resources as neglected their surrounding environment until quite recently2.
land, labour and capital. The state of technology may also be Companies did so because their main focus was on profits and
added as an additional factor but in the short term at least this dividends to shareholders, and governments did not actively
may be reflected in the nature of the capital stock and the quality regulate pollution. They were not alone in their practices. Many
of the labour force. More recently it has also become common to manufacturing firms did little to treat wastes, discharging them
include the environment (or environmental services) among this into the nearby atmosphere, or into rivers, lakes or the ocean with
group of inputs. minimal treatment. Also, in many parts of Australia, past farming
practices have resulted in erosion and reduced soil fertility.
The following statement by McDivitt and Jeffrey (1976, p 16)
reflects an interesting additional economic perspective about the
1. It has become increasingly common practice to identify land as impact of mining on production:
natural capital, labour as human capital and capital as physical mineral development can contribute to the three
capital. major factors of production – land, through
2. This criticism continues to apply to the activities of most small-scale bringing into action otherwise dormant resources
and artisanal miners in developing nations. in the country; capital, both through attracting

Australian Mineral Economics 7


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

outside investment capital to the country and Where mineral windfalls involve labour-intensive mining
through providing new money some of which can activity there is increased opportunity to share income and
be used for local investment; and labor, through wealth more equally4. But as minerals then become less
upgrading local skills and implanting concepts of amenable to labour-intensive mining and require greater amounts
entrepreneurship. of capital, there is potentially the reverse tendency for the
distribution of income and wealth to become more unequal.
That is, mining uses machines, labour, and ore to produce
metals that produce further capital (buildings, bridges). Through A continuing issue regarding our future concerns the way in
the process, worker skills are upgraded, enhancing the labour which production and consumption relate to one another.
pool for mining’s own use or for use in other sectors. If they were Consumption involves individuals and households (the private
rewriting this passage today, the two authors may also have sector) and also government using up goods and services.
included a reference to environmental quality issues. If a society consumes less than it produces (ie spends less than
its income) in any given time period, its members (both the
In any economy, the issue of distribution is also important –
private and public sector) can save the residual and invest it to
the way in which different individuals or groups share
ensure production continuing in the future. Saving and
production. Issues relating to the fairness or equity in the
investment are important additional concepts in the economist’s
distribution of income and wealth generate controversy. This lexicon. Saving refers to the amount generated from abstaining
happens within families, regions and also between nations on the from consumption in any given period, while investment is
world stage. Governments use the proceeds of taxation and spending on capital formation, both physical and human.
royalty collection to redistribute this income and wealth.
New investment that increases a nation’s or region’s physical
The discovery and exploitation of minerals often brings major and human capital typically provides the basis for further
new activity to mining regions. Issues quickly arise as to how economic growth and development. If citizens consume what
much of the windfall should be retained by local residents, how they produce, or more than they produce by borrowing against
much distributed to the investors (often from other places) who future expected production, their capital stock will fall and so
have taken risks and incurred large past expenditures to develop will production, if other things are equal. It is typical to be
new oil wells or mines, and how much redistributed by impressed by ‘economic miracle’ nations whose strong growth
government to citizens in other regions or states. These and development is attributable to saving, followed by wise
controversies are often the source of continuing disquiet. Where investment in new physical and human capital. The economic
resolved in a satisfactory fashion, major new mineral and energy performance of Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Hong Kong
production has the potential to be shared widely for the benefit of and now China in the latter part of the 20th century have drawn
many people in the state where a mining region is located, and in great praise from most commentators.
the nation more generally3. Where nations have large mineral and energy resource
Hence one might argue that the great mineral wealth of the endowments, much of which may have only recently been
Pilbara, Eastern Goldfields and other mining regions of Western discovered, there also seems considerable potential to invest the
Australia have been distributed effectively over more than a profits from its exploitation. Such endowments form part of a
century. It has enhanced the income and general fortunes of the natural capital base. Some natural capital is renewable, while
average citizen of the mining regions. A large royalty stream, some is not. It is normal to think of agricultural land, forests,
together with payroll tax receipts, has assisted the finances of the fisheries and solar, wind and tidal energy as renewable
Western Australian government. Greater individual and company resources, and to classify minerals and many other energy
income taxes, as well as resource rent royalties, have also sources as non-renewable resources. Despite their finite nature,
contributed to the welfare of Australians more generally. and as noted earlier, it is possible to recycle many minerals in a
financially viable way.
Even without the hand of government to redistribute income
and wealth through the fiscal system, many past mineral If minerals are produced, and consumed, and they cannot be
discoveries have brought a more even distribution of income. recycled, their stock will decline5. How the citizens of a country or
This was the case with the Victorian, New South Wales and region allocate the proceeds of mineral exploitation to current
consumption and investment is an issue that has been of interest to
Western Australian gold rushes in the 19th century. Blainey
many people. Such debate is typically heard in discussions about
(2003, p 62) notes that: minerals and sustainable development.
Gold checked, and for a time, reversed The final key concept in this section is trade. Trade takes
Australia’s tendency to become a land that place because it makes individuals, companies and nations better
favoured the big man. Whereas Australia’s first off. By specialising in the things they can do best, these groups
natural asset, the sheeplands, was grasped by a can exchange part of their production for a variety of goods and
few thousand men, its second rich natural asset, services that will enable them to reach a higher standard of living
the goldlands was divided among hundreds of than without trade. Trade takes place within regions, between
thousands of men. regions and between nations. Trade in minerals and energy is
important. The nature and location of mineral deposits means
that not all nations or regions can be self-sufficient in minerals,
even if they want to be. With the exception of mineral production
3. An important associated point here relates to the intertemporal flow by firms that are vertically integrated6, most minerals and energy
of resources. A mine that is generating lots of production/profit in produced is traded either domestically or internationally.
2005 may not be generating enough to pay off the debt incurred in As will be discussed later, exports of minerals and energy play
building the mine. Yet the profits are often seen as a windfall. an important part in increasing the economic and social welfare
4. Elements of this argument apply widely to labour-intensive
of perhaps one quarter of all nations. Their importance to
small-scale mining activities in developing nations. Australia was particularly significant from the early 1840s until
the beginning of World War I. Though subsiding dramatically
5. Technology will of course make it more possible to access lower after 1914, mineral export trade rose again dramatically from the
grade deposits over time. 1960s onwards. Sustained international competitiveness in many
6. Vertical integration describes a situation in which ‘a firm participates sectors of the industry has underpinned Australia’s strong
in more than one successive stage of the production or distribution of economic performance in the last part of the 20th century and at
goods and services’. the beginning of the new millennium.

8 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

TABLE 2.1
Key production and growth indicators for selected economies. (Source: World Bank, 2005.)
Nation GDP in 2001 GDP per capita in 2001 GDP per capita at PPP in Real GDP growth
(US$ billion) (US$) 2001 (US$) 1990 - 2001 (per cent)
Major developed economies
United States of America 10 416 35 060 35 060 3.7
Japan 3978 33 550 24 076 2.3
Germany 1976 22 670 24 288 2.4
United Kingdom 1552 25 250 24 467 3.4
France 1409 22 010 22 716 2.0
Italy 1181 20 397 25 809 1.8
Korea 448 9471 15 087 5.6
Major developing economies
China 1237 940 4177 8.9
India 515 480 2929 7.9
Russia 346 2390 9385 -0.2
Indonesia 172 710 2900 5.6
Major mineral exporters
Canada 715 22 300 26 992 2.9
Brazil 452 2850 6569 2.9
Australia 410 19 740 24 451 4.3
South Africa 104 2600 10 067 2.7
Chile 64 4260 8206 6.2
Peru 57 2050 4634 3.7
Developing mineral economies
Papua New Guinea 2.8 530 2297 1.4
Ghana 6 270 2037 5.5
Tanzania 9.4 280 1321 3.0
Botswana 5.2 2980 7309 8.1
Zambia 3.7 310 752 2.8
Dem Rep of Congo 5.7 90 707 -10.9
Major oil producers
Saudi Arabia 187 8460 13 267
Venezuela 108 1710 6025 3.5
Iran 109 1680 5940 3.4
Nigeria 37 285 784 2.9

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT computing percentage changes in real Gross Domestic Product –
commonly known as GDP. The term ‘real’ is used to indicate that
When commentators discuss the economic growth of a nation, a the measure has been adjusted for changes in the rate of inflation.
region, or the world, they usually are referring to the percentage Gross Domestic Product is a measure of the market value of final
rate of growth in total production over a given period such as a goods and services produced in an economy during a given period7.
year (or a quarter).
Each nation’s central statistical agency typically has the role to
On some occasions, however, they may mean: compute official estimates of GDP. In the case of Australia, this
• the percentage rate of growth in per capita production of the organisation is the Australian Bureau of Statistics. Australia’s
average citizen over a given time period; and officially estimated GDP in the 2002-03 financial year was
• more recently, the rate of growth of productivity, or output around A$ 735 billion (or US$ 450 billion). This meant that GDP
per worker. per capita for each of Australia’s 19.7 million inhabitants was a
little more than A$ 37 000. Australia’s rate of real GDP growth
Following the widespread adoption and use of national during this period was 3.8 per cent.
accounting frameworks throughout the world since 1950, it has Some comparisons between the level of Australia’s GDP in
become standard practice to measure economic growth by 2001 and those of selected other nations, together with actual
GDP per capita, and GDP per capita at Purchasing Power
7. The GDP measure differs conceptually from Gross National Product, Parity (PPP) appear in Table 2.1.
which refers to the estimated value of final goods and services produced The PPP adjustment in GDP per capita allows for cost of
in a given period by a country’s citizens. International agencies such as living differences. The benchmark for the PPP measure is the
the World Bank have recently commenced using another measure cost of living in the USA. GDP per capita in the US was
(Gross National Income (GNI)) in making international comparisons of US$ 35 060 in 2001. Its GDP per capita at PPP was, of course,
economic size and growth between nations. also US$ 35 060.

Australian Mineral Economics 9


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

Compare this with the situation in Japan. Over the past two • is able, following a period of mediocre economic performance,
decades, most would judge that the cost of living in Japan has to bring about annual rates of growth exceeding five per cent; or
been high. While GDP per capita in Japan, at US$ 33 550, was
close to that in the US, that nation’s GDP per capita at PPP was • generates consistent growth in its real GDP per capita.
only US$ 24 076. The cost of living in the United States was Hence, according to the estimates reported in Table 2.1, it may
about 30 per cent less than in Japan. be argued that between 1990 and 2001 nations such as South
Think now about the average Australian, whose estimated Korea, China, India, Indonesia, as well as the two mineral rich
GDP per capita in 2002 was US$ 19 740. The purchasing power nations of Botswana and Chile experienced economic
of an Australian income earner was almost 24 per cent higher development.
than his or her counterpart in the United States. Australia’s But the Todaro view also seems implicitly to assume that the
estimated GDP per capita at PPP in 2002 was US$ 24 451. structure of such an economy will change, with the emergence of
These estimates are important for mining companies and major new and competitive industry sectors (eg manufacturing,
consultants in estimating the relative average living standards of services, etc). The achievements over a longer period of Japan
citizens, and potential operating costs, in nations in which they and the Asian Tigers and China, which have transformed their
may wish to invest or otherwise do business. In Chile, for economies, are examples of significant economic development
example, per capita GDP was only US$ 4206 in 2002. But, taking place. Historically, it would also seem that nations such as
because the cost of living was only about a half of that in the the United States, Britain, Germany, France, Canada and
United States, estimated GDP per capita at PPP was US$ 8206, Australia have experienced economic development surges in this
almost double this amount. way.
The GDP measure has several notable limitations. Importantly During the 1970s, a broader view emerged concerning the
it does not include adjustments for capital consumption, dimensions of the concept of economic development. Writers
depreciation of natural capital, or environmental degradation. It began to consider economic development in terms of reducing
fails to include estimates of the value of non-market goods such poverty, income inequality and unemployment when an economy
as work at home. Hence the contributions to production of was experiencing consistently strong real GDP growth over an
women and men who devote their lives to being homemakers and extended period.
raising families are not included. Also excluded is the work of In his extended definition, Todaro (1989, p 88) argues that:
volunteers who contribute generously to the functioning of many
Development must… be conceived as a
community organisations. In a 1987 study, the Australian Bureau
multi-dimensional process involving major
of Statistics estimated that Australians devoted just over 250
changes in social structures, popular attitudes and
million hours each week to paid work, and a further 303 million
national institutions, as well as the acceleration of
hours to unpaid work.
economic growth, the reduction of inequality, and
Notwithstanding the significant contributions to overall the eradication of absolute poverty.
production of these latter groups in a country such as Australia,
the size of these latter parts of the informal economy are of Associated with this interest in a broader definition of
considerably greater relative importance in developing nations. economic development, several economists have proposed the
Hence, even adjusting for Purchasing Power Parity, it is still use of broader socioeconomic indicators to measure
likely that any comparison of living standards using GDP per development. These began in the United Nations in the late
capita at PPP between an affluent developed nation, such as 1960s. One of the notable measures has been Morris’s Physical
Australia, and a poor developing mineral economy in Africa will Quality of Life Index (based on life expectancy at age one, infant
overstate the difference between them. While it is clear, mortality and literacy). Following in this tradition, the United
therefore, that the average citizen of a nation such as Tanzania is Nations Development Programme (UNDP) publishes its Human
very poor, his or her production will in reality exceed the Development Index (HDI) in its annual Human Development
estimate of $1321 in Table 2.1 by a higher percentage than it Report8. The HDI measure is based equally on life expectancy,
does for the average Australian citizen. GDP per capita at education levels and the average standard of living (UNDP,
Purchasing Power Parity comparisons between nations are at best 2003, p 340). The UNDP classifies countries as follows:
only an approximate indicator of differences.
Level of human development HDI value
These limitations have stimulated a number of alternative
approaches and adjustments to reflect a country’s economic size High 0.8 or above
and stage of development in a more effective manner. But this Medium Between 0.5 and 0.8
statement itself begs the question of what development really Low Less than 0.5
means.
Todaro (1989, pp 86-87) points to traditional views that Estimates of the HDI for 2000 appear in Table 2.2 for the same
development or economic development takes place over an selection of countries as in Table 2.1. The UNDP ranked 173
extended period (of say ten years or more) when an economy: nations in its 2000 list. It classified 55 nations as exhibiting high
human development, 83 with medium human development and 37
with low human development9. A complementary classification of
8. As this manuscript is written, the Human Development Report is developed and developing nations also appears in the Appendix of
readily available in downloadable form from the UNDP web site:
http://www.undp.org.
this chapter.
Most of the major developed economies (with Canada and
9. Through its promotion of the Millennium Development Goals the Australia also on this list) have Human Development Index
United Nations has focused attention over the past five years on ‘an
values greater than 0.910. These values had increased by
expanded vision of development… that vigorously promoted human
development as the key to sustaining social and economic progress’. approximately 0.1 between 1975 and 2000. Among the four
major developing nations, China and Russia had Human
10. Norway and Sweden (not listed in Table 2.2) were the top ranked Development Index levels above 0.7. While HDI levels had
nations in 2000 with HDI values of 0.942 and 0.941 respectively. consistently risen in China since 1975, they had fallen in Russia
11. It is important to acknowledge that because the goalposts are from 0.824 in 1990 to 0.781 a decade later. Both India and
renormed every year that intertemporal comparisons of HDI values Indonesia experienced rises of around 200 points in their HDI
should be interpreted with caution. levels between 1975 and 200011.

10 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

TABLE 2.2
Estimates of human development indices for selected economies in 2000. (Source: United Nations Development Programme, 2003.)
Nation Life expectancy Education GDP at PPP HDI GDP per capita
minus HDI rank
Major developed economies
United States of America 0.87 0.98 0.97 0.939 -4
Japan 0.93 0.93 0.93 0.933 2
Germany 0.88 0.97 0.92 0.925 -2
United Kingdom 0.88 0.99 0.91 0.928 7
France 0.89 0.97 0.92 0.928 6
Italy 0.89 0.94 0.91 0.913 -1
Korea 0.83 0.95 0.86 0.882 1
Major developing economies
China 0.76 0.80 0.61 0.726 0
India 0.64 0.57 0.53 0.577 -1
Russia 0.68 0.92 0.74 0.781 -2
Indonesia 0.69 0.79 0.57 0.684 1
Major mineral exporters
Canada 0.90 0.98 0.94 0.940 4
Brazil 0.71 0.83 0.72 0.757 -13
Australia 0.90 0.99 0.93 0.939 7
South Africa 0.45 0.88 0.76 0.695 -56
Chile 0.84 0.90 0.76 0.831 12
Peru 0.73 0.87 0.65 0.747 6
Developing mineral economies
Papua New Guinea 0.53 0.55 0.52 0.535 -9
Ghana 0.53 0.62 0.50 0.548 1
Tanzania 0.43 0.61 0.28 0.440 21
Botswana 0.25 0.75 0.71 0.572 -62
Zambia 0.27 0.68 0.34 0.433 12
Dem Rep of Congo 0.44 0.51 0.34 0.431 11
Major oil producers
Saudi Arabia 0.78 0.71 0.79 0.759 -26
Venezuela 0.80 0.83 0.68 0.770 10
Iran 0.73 0.75 0.68 0.721 -22
Nigeria 0.44 0.58 0.37 0.462 9

Among the somewhat diverse major mineral exporting country sub-Saharan Africa seems to undermine its value for anything
group, all except South Africa had experienced continuing more than a first pass appraisal by a mining company of the stage
increases in their HDI levels. While rising from 0.714 in 1990 to of development of any potential new investment destination.
0.724 in 1995, South Africa’s level dropped to 0.695 by 2000. Other things being equal, it should be more attractive to invest
Perusal of Table 2.2 suggests that the low value of 0.45 for the in a more developed nation, but making a judgment about
life expectancy component of the HDI was largely responsible development should involve assessing several other issues.
for this. There were similarly low levels for other African Consistent with the Todaro definition above, such things as social
mineral economies such as Botswana, Zambia, Tanzania and the and institutional stability and honesty, income and wealth
Democratic Republic of the Congo. This is a reflection of their distribution trends, and poverty levels interact with the status of
health crises arising from the HIV/AIDS epidemic. mineral policy and the extent of a country’s mineral endowment
in doing this in an effective and professional way.
The final column of Table 2.2 provides a summary analytical
tool in comparing perceived development as reflected in HDI
ranking, with the narrower production-based GDP per capita at PERIODS OF HISTORY AND MINERALS
Purchasing Power Parity. Positive entries indicate that the Minerals and energy have had a major role in the history of the
GDP-based measure may understate a country’s stage of world. This is apparent simply by noting that so many periods
development. Nations such as the United Kingdom, France, have been characterised by material or energy names. Reflecting
Australia, Chile and Venezuela might all be somewhat more the role of changing technology (apparent in the production
developed according to this metric. Brazil, South Africa, function) the use of key minerals as a principal ingredient of
Botswana, Papua New Guinea, Saudi Arabia and Iran are tools, or power, in periods bearing their names brought
apparently less developed. While this summary measure provides improvement in terms of human well-being, as measured by
a novel development indicator, the impact of the health crisis in population growth and other indicators.

Australian Mineral Economics 11


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

TABLE 2.3 created a global minerals economy, and as will be seen in the
Different periods in history. (Source: Derived from Wilson, 1994.) next chapter, have hastened the economic development of nations
such as Australia in a dramatic way.
Period Dates
Homo Erectus 500 000 years ago ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND MINERAL
Homo Sapiens 200 000 years ago RESOURCES – THE TRADITIONAL VIEW
Stone Age 30 000 to 4000 BC
A generally accepted view is that the presence of minerals should
Neolithic (New Stone Age) SW Asia 9000 to 6000 BC assist the economic fortunes of a nation or region. The greater
Europe to 4000 BC
the quantity of reserves available, up to some point, the more
Chalcolithic (copper-stone) period 4000 to 3000 BC economic growth should be generated and conversely, as reserves
Copper Age Began 3000 BC are used up, economic growth will be constrained. The
Bronze Age Began 2500 BC discussion then moves to sustainability issues. Wise investment
of the proceeds of mineral exploitation should ensure a different
Iron Age Began 1000 BC
but potentially sustainable economy after the lode has run out.
Coal Age Began AD 1600 Tilton (1992, p 1) notes that:
Industrial Revolution (based on AD 1750 to 1850
coal, iron and steam) …the returns from mineral exploitation can be
used to build airports and highways, stores and
Oil Age Began AD 1875
factories, schools and hospitals, and homes and
Atomic Age Began AD 1945 parks. They can enhance political stability by
Information Age Began AD 1960 addressing regional and tribal grievances and in
various ways bolster economic growth.
Mining and mineral processing can also
This shows up clearly in Table 2.3, a summary table adapted generate jobs, provide opportunities for the
from Wilson (1994). Wilson (1994, p xiii) also argues that: development of domestic skills, encourage the
The history of metals is the history of civilisation. creation of associated industries, and provide
The two are inseparable; each depends on the other beneficial side effects or linkages for the
other for its development; when one stumbles the local economy.
other falters. Ever since Neolithic man learned the He goes on to observe that:
secret of winning metals from ore-bearing rock,
metals have dominated the world’s political, History documents that mineral resources can
social and economic evolution. For 5000 years indeed facilitate economic development. The
they have been the major factor in the flowering of Industrial Revolution began in England and
a people’s culture, the key to their industrial quickly spread to Germany and the United States
power and their influence in world affairs. partly because these countries were well
endowed with coal and other natural resources.
There seems much to this argument, though modern oil and Saudi Arabia and other Middle East
gas producers would also associate themselves with these views. oil-producing countries are more recent
A brief review of ancient history illustrates how members of examples of the positive role mineral wealth can
the prominent civilisations effectively used new technologies in have in economic development.
processing metals such as copper, iron, gold, silver and tin as a
basis for enhancing both the quality of life of their citizens, as A major mineral windfall has the potential, if properly
well as their military strength. The emphasis on the latter area managed, to stimulate economic growth, raise incomes and allow
seems to have been of central importance in the domination of investment in human and physical capital, which will ensure a
surrounding populations. This applied in varying ways to the nation’s longer term economic and social success.
Sumerian, Babylonian, Assyrian, Persian, Greek, Carthaginian,
Roman and Chinese civilisations. With the fall of the Roman THE AUSTRALIAN EXPERIENCE
Empire around 450 AD, the use of metals dwindled as the world
Australia’s experience with minerals and energy seems to fit in
of Europe and the Middle East descended into the ‘Dark Ages’
period. well with this traditional view. The impact of major mineral
discoveries, and their subsequent exploitation, on Australia’s
Though new uses of minerals and energy began slowly economic performance during more than two centuries of
emerging after 1500, it was the emergence of the Industrial European settlement is an interesting case study. Perceived in
Revolution in the United Kingdom from about 1750 that
terms of the perspective of economic production and the factors
heralded the widespread modern uses on minerals and energy.
in the production function, described in the McDivitt and Jeffrey
The emergence of heavy industry, the widespread use of coal and
quotation at the beginning of this chapter, the discovery and
more recently oil and gas as its major energy sources, and the
rise of materials such as steel, aluminium and a range of more exploitation of minerals transformed Australia. It moved from
exotic metals, have all been part of this picture. The Industrial undeveloped to developed status over a relatively short period of
Revolution has led to consumer societies in which minerals and time.12 The further development of the resources sector
energy are used in ways and at levels that were previously underpinned development of the Australian economy for much
unimaginable. Associated with this have been major of the second half of the 20th century. This contribution is set to
technological advances in exploration, mining and particularly continue in the 21st century.
mineral processing. Advances in transport technology have also The major impact of mineral development did not emerge until
the 1840s, some 50 years after European settlement. The
discovery of copper in South Australia provided a strong
12. Several economic historians have written authoritatively about the stimulus for the fledgling new colony there. But it was the gold
topic. Notable among them have been Blainey (1966, 2003), Sinclair rushes in New South Wales and Victoria, only a decade later, that
(1976) and Shaw (1966). dramatically transformed the Australian colonies from struggling

12 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

TABLE 2.4
Mining and Australian population growth 1788 - 2001.
Year Total population (M)† M/F Main event in preceding period
1788 0.001 na Convict settlement
1800 0.005 2.63 Convict settlement
1820 0.034 2.44 Dominance of whaling, emergence of agriculture
1840 0.190 2.02 Decline of whaling, agriculture strong, new colonies (Victoria, South Australia, Western Australia)
1850 0.405 1.43 New colonies emerge, Irish famine, copper mines in South Australia
1860 1.146 1.40 Gold rushes (Bathurst, Ballarat, Bendigo, etc)
1870 1.648 1.21 Mining strong, emergence of railways, faster ships
1880 2.231 1.17 Continuation of above trends, emergence of Tasmanian mines, telegraph service
1890 3.151 1.16 Broken Hill rush, new gold finds, railway boom
1900 3.765 1.11 Major national recession, bank failures, Western Australia gold rush
1911 4.455 1.08 Federation, continued strength of mining
1921 5.435 1.03 First World War, copper boom
1933 6.629 1.03 Stock boom of 1920s, decline of mining towns, beginning of Depression.
1947 7.579 1.004 Effects of Depression, Second World War
1954 8.986 1.032 Post war boom, major new migration, promotion of manufacturing, uranium mines
1961 10.548 1.022 Strong economic growth, migration, manufacturing, major bauxite finds
1971 13.067 1.022 Continuation of above trends, new finds of iron ore, off-shore petroleum, nickel, coal
1981 14.932 1.005 Mining boom, stagflation, major rises in oil prices
1991 17.085 0.99 Deep recessions at beginning and end of decade, boom in middle, strong performance of mining, gold,
iron ore, coal, nickel, copper, etc
2001 19.5 0.975 Mining retains strong role with new discoveries continuing, Australian mining companies invest offshore

† Aboriginal population not included until 1971.

economic backwaters into much more desirable migration and It was a memorable day. Its effects were
investment destinations. Some of the factors that held back the tremendous. There was an immediate rush to
discovery and exploitation of minerals in Australia were poor New South Wales from the other colonies; to stop
roads, the lack of a railway system, unnavigable rivers and this, a committee of Victorian businessmen on
distance from major markets. 9 June offered a reward of £200 for the discovery
Yet it was an unlikely and short-lived geographical advantage of gold within 200 miles of Melbourne. It was
– the proximity of ports like Sydney to California – that acted as claimed next day. By the end of the year (1851)
a catalyst for the Australian gold rushes. The discovery of gold rich fields near Ballarat and Bendigo and other
near San Francisco in 1848 led to the California gold rushes. minor discoveries made Victoria, not New South
Although more than 10 000 km away on the other side of the Wales, the magnet for the diggers.
Pacific, the ten-week journey by ship from Sydney to San The summary information in Table 2.4 provides some insight
Francisco was less than the 13-week journey around Cape Horn into the effect of major mining discoveries and subsequent
from New York13. For a brief period Sydney became a significant mineral exploitation on Australia’s population growth. This
supply port for California. The Australians, who flocked across impact has been associated with sustained economic growth and
the Pacific to join the rush, noticed the similarity of the terrain associated economic development.
with that in New South Wales. Returning to Sydney in early Even though the British government established six colonies (in
1851, the entrepreneurial Edward Hargraves travelled to Hill End what were to become Australia’s six states at Federation) during
where he showed local shepherds how to search for gold. They the first 50 years of European settlement, the European population
soon discovered the yellow metal and on 3 April, Hargraves grew slowly until 1840, when it stood at 190 000. This growth
announced to the Colonial Secretary in Sydney that he had related particularly to Australia’s status as a convict destination,
discovered gold. the rise and fall of whaling and the development of agriculture.
The following quote by Shaw (1966, p 65) captures the Even though the population more than doubled to 405 000 by
atmosphere in a colourful way: 1850, partly due to the stimulus of the discovery of copper in
South Australia, it was gold that brought dramatic change.
On 3 April 1851, occurred an event which
radically changed the character of the Australian Sinclair (1976, p 79) notes:
colonies and tremendously hastened their …the discovery of alluvial gold must be regarded
development. Edward Hammond Hargreaves as a major discontinuity. The significance of this
officially notified the Colonial Secretary of New for the course of Australian economic
South Wales that he had discovered gold near development was heightened by the rapidity with
Bathurst. which gold was extracted from the ground.
Australia became the world’s leading gold producer as
13. There were no roads or railways across the United States at that time. production rose from zero in 1851 to more than 90 tonnes in 1856,
The Panama Canal was not completed until several decades later. then declined gradually around 50 tonnes per annum in 1865.

Australian Mineral Economics 13


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

14
13.2
12.8

12

10
8.7

6.2
(%)

6 5.5
4.9 5.1

3.8 3.8 3.7


4 3.4 3.3
3.2

2.0
2 1.6

0.4
0
s

0s

0s

0s

s
0s
70

80

90
30

40

50

60

40

50

60

70

80

90
0

3
18

18

18

18

18

18

18

19

19

19

19

19

19
19

19

19

19
-2

FIG 2.1 - Estimated percentage average real GDP growth in the Australian economy on a decade by decade basis – 1830 to 2000.

Blainey (2003, p 62) notes: World War I. The per capita incomes of Australian residents also
rose strongly. Maddison (1995) estimates that they were the
Possibly no other country in the world has been
highest in the world by 1870 and that they remained in that
so quickly transformed by metals; the normal
position for the next 30 years.
growth and achievement of several decades were
crammed into one. Australia ceased to be a land The fortunes of the mining industry, and of the Australian
of exile in British eyes and became a respectable economy, subsided during the first half of the new century. The
field of migration and [beginning with exceptions were the development of copper and other metals at
capital-intensive underground mining in 1886] Mount Isa, and of iron ore deposits around Iron Knob to supply
investment… The swift growth of population BHP’s newly emerging steel mills – first in Newcastle and later
widened the market for Australian manufactures in Port Kembla. But there were no other new major mineral
and foodstuffs. It stimulated farms and factories finds. Furthermore, international trade in minerals was disrupted
and workshops and cities. Gold drew population by the two World Wars and the Depression of the 1930s.
into the interior and attracted railways from the Although coal, gold iron ore and base metal mining continued in
ports. Bendigo and Ballarat in 1862 got the established areas such as the Hunter Valley, the Illawarra, the
continent’s first upcountry railways, and cheap Latrobe Valley, Broken Hill and the Eastern Goldfields of
transport stimulated farming… Western Australia, mining declined in its relative and absolute
importance. By 1960 the minerals and energy sector accounted
This shows up in an interesting way in the estimates of average for little more than one per cent of Gross Domestic Product and
annual real GDP growth, and GDP per capita growth, that appear only around five per cent of exports. This compared with the
respectively in Figures 2.1 and 2.2. The Australian government situation 100 years earlier in which Butlin (1962) estimated that
began producing the national accounts in a formal way during mineral production had accounted for more than 15 per cent of
the 1950s. The earlier estimates are derived from Butlin (1962) GDP and perhaps 80 per cent of exports.
and McLean (2004). They cover ten-year periods and hence do Two key events then occurred. In 1961, the British government
not reflect considerable annual variations in the rate of growth. decided to join the European Economic Community. This had an
In addition to stimulating the development of key industry almost immediate negative effect on the competitiveness of
sectors such as agriculture, manufacturing, construction and Australian agriculture. But offsetting this negative force was the
transport, the gold rushes of the 1850s inspired other major rise of the Japanese economy, followed by the emergence of the
mineral discoveries. These new finds included gold in many Asian Tiger economies of Korea and Taiwan, which created an
areas of Queensland from the late 1860s, tin in northern New opportunity for the Australian minerals and energy sector. There
South Wales during the 1870s, copper, gold and tin in Tasmania were major discoveries of:
between the 1870s and 1890s, gold in the Northern Territory in • coal (in New South Wales and Queensland);
the 1870s, and gold in Western Australia from the early 1880s. • iron ore in Western Australia;
By 1900, in the wake of the WA gold rushes, gold production had
risen to close to 100 tonnes per annum. • oil and gas in the Bass Strait, on the North West Shelf of
Western Australia and in the Cooper Basin in South Australia;
One recently used criterion (by Davis (1995) and others) is
that a country has a strong mineral economy if the ratio of the • bauxite in Western Australia and Queensland;
value added by its mineral production to total GDP exceeds eight • nickel in Western Australia and Queensland;
per cent. The Australian colonies satisfied this measure during
the period between 1851 and 1914. • copper and other base metals in Queensland and several
other states;
Not only did Australia’s Gross Domestic Product increase
dramatically during the 1850s. It grew strongly during every • diamonds in Western Australia; and
succeeding decade (except the 1890s) until the beginning of • mineral sands in Western Australia.

14 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

3.5

3.0
3.0

2.6 2.6
2.5 2.4

2.0
2.0 1.9
1.8
1.6
1.5
1.5 1.4
(%)

1.1
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.6 0.6
0.5
0.3

0.0
s

s
s

s
40

50

60

70

80

90

10

20

40

50

60

70

80

90
30

00

30
18

18

18

19

19

19
18

18

18

18

19

19

19

19

19

19

19
-0.5

-1.0

FIG 2.2 - Estimated percentage average real GDP per capita growth in the Australian economy on a decade by decade basis – 1830 to 2000.

Australia emerged as a world-class producer and exporter in economy is that these industries account for
many of these areas. This was particularly the case for iron ore, almost a tenth of national output (and an even
bauxite and alumina, and mineral sands, where it soon ranked as higher proportion of investment spending) while
either first or second in production. While Australia was not the employing just over two per cent of the workforce.
largest coal producer, the high quality of the hard coal in the East
Coast mines made it the leading exporter of this market. Even in During the 1960s, the proportion of mineral resource sector
the field of oil and gas, the significant finds in the Bass Strait and exports started to rise again. In 1974 they passed 30 per cent for
then off the North West Shelf gave Australia a greater level of the first time since the period immediately prior to World War I.
self-sufficiency in petroleum, and made it a significant exporter They have remained at this level for the past 30 years.
of natural gas. Not only has mining emerged domestically, Australian-based
As part of the Bretton Woods gold exchange standard that mining companies began investing internationally in a major
governed the international exchange rate system in the 1950s and fashion in the 1990s. In 1999, Australian-based companies were
1960s, gold had a fixed price of US$ 35 per ounce. Under this active in about 80 nations – see for example Maponga and Maxwell
regime Australian gold production languished. In the 1950s and (2000). The mining services sector has also emerged as an area of
international competitiveness, with Australian mining professionals
early 1960s at just over 30 tonnes per annum, it was less than a
now travelling throughout the world to provide their services.
third of what it had been in 1900. But worse was to come. The
rise of inflation in Australia, combined with a strong Australian Wright and Czelusta (2003) have recently argued that:
dollar in the early 1970s, made gold mining even more marginal.
Minerals constitute a high-tech knowledge
By 1976, Australian gold miners produced only 15 tonnes and in
industry in many countries. Investment in such
1980 only 17 tonnes. The twin towns of Kalgoorlie and Boulder,
knowledge should be seen as a legitimate
which had stood as the nation’s ‘gold capital’ for more than 80
component of a forward-looking economic
years, were surviving fortuitously on the newly emerging nickel
development program.
sector but not because of gold.
But the demise of the Bretton Woods system also led to a This situation seems clearly to have applied to Australia for
change in the status of gold, with citizens of many nations now much of the past century and a half.
able to purchase it as a private asset. In the uncertain 1970s,
dominated by unexpected events such as the OPEC oil price rises COMPLICATING FACTORS WITH MINERAL
and the Iran hostage crisis, the demand for gold rose, and so did
its price. By 1976 it had reached US$ 160 per ounce. By 1979 it PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION
was US$ 300 per ounce. In 1980, it peaked at US$ 800 per A variety of factors make the study of mineral production,
ounce. Furthermore, by this time, the value of the Australian mineral consumption and mineral economics generally more
dollar had also fallen back from its high levels in the mid-1970s. complex but also more interesting. As has been noted already in
Even though many of the near surface high-grade deposits had this chapter, one of these is the non-renewable nature of minerals
been exploited, the emergence of metallurgical processes such as and energy resources. Others include:
carbon in pulp leaching, in combination with greater exploration • the fixed locations of deposits (often in remote areas);
and the development of open cut mining in a major way, brought
a dramatic re-emergence of the Australian gold sector. With its • the economic rent that they generate;
price holding at around A$ 500 per ounce for much of the past • the impact of technological change on both the supply and
two decades, Australia emerged again as a major gold producer. demand side;
In 1990, its miners produced 244 tonnes, more than double the
amount of 90 years earlier. At its peak in 1997, Australian mines • the competitive behaviour of mineral producers and purchasers;
produced more than 300 tonnes. • effects of mineral development on indigenous populations;
Through its Industry Commission, the Australian government and finally
published a major study of the minerals and energy sector in • the environmental impact of mining and its mitigation.
1991. It noted that:
The relevance of each of these issues is discussed in the coming
An indication of the importance of mining and chapters – often on more than one occasion. The following table
early-stage minerals processing to the Australian provides a brief guide, should it be required.

Australian Mineral Economics 15


CHAPTER 2: MINERALS, GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

Issues Chapters Sinclair, W, 1976. The Process of Economic Development in Australia


(Longman Cheshire: Melbourne).
Locations of deposits and their 4 (trade), 6 (supply),
Tilton, J E (ed), 1992. Mineral Wealth and Economic Development
implications 8 (workforces)
(Resources for the Future: Washington).
Mineral rent 3 (developing nations), 13 (mineral Todaro, M, 1989. Economic Development in the Third World, fourth
policy), 15 (taxes and royalties) edition (Longman: New York).
Impact of technology 5 (demand), 6 (supply) United Nations Development Programme, 2003. Human development
Nature of competition 7 (markets) report 2003 [online]. Available from: <http://hdr.undp.org/reports/
global/2003>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Indigenous populations 17 Wilson, A J, 1994. The Living Rock (Woodhead: Cambridge).
Sustainable development 16 World Bank, 2005. Quick reference tables [online]. Available from:
Smaller regions 18 <http://www.worldbank.org/data/quickreference/quickref.html>.
Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Wright, G and Czelusta, J, 2003. Mineral resources and economic
REFERENCES development, in Proceedings Conference on Sector Reform in Latin
America (Stanford Center for International Development: Stanford).
Blainey G, 1966. The Tyranny of Distance (Sun Books: Melbourne).
Blainey, G, 2003. The Rush That Never Ended, fifth edition (Melbourne
University Press: Melbourne). APPENDIX – A CLASSIFICATION OF
Butlin, N G, 1962. Australian Domestic Product, Investment and Foreign DEVELOPED AND DEVELOPING NATIONS
Borrowing, 1861 - 1938/39, (Cambridge University Press: Cambridge).
Davis, G A, 1995. Learning to love the Dutch disease: Evidence from the Determining which nations are developed or developing is, in many
mineral economies, World Development, 23(10):1765-1799. respects, an arbitrary decision. Our approach has been to identify
Industry Commission, 1991. Mining and mineral processing in Australia, those nations with Human Development Index values of 0.850 or
Report No 7, February (Australian Government: Canberra) [online]. above as developed. There were 33 nations in this group in 2001.
Available from: <http://www.pc.gov.au/ic/inquiry/07mining/ Ranked in descending HDI order (with Norway as the most
finalreport/index.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
developed nation and Australia fourth), these nations were mostly
Maddison, A, 1995. Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992, located in Western Europe, North America and Oceania, though five
(Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development: Paris).
Asian nations (including Hong Kong) were also in the group.
Maponga, O and Maxwell, P, 2000. The internationalisation of the
Australian mineral industry in the 1990s, Resources Policy, The remaining 142 nations in Table 3.1 with HDI values less
26(4):199-210. that 0.850 are developing nations. They include all of Africa and
McDivitt, J and Jeffrey, W, 1976. Economics of the Mineral Industries, South America, and most of Asia. The 22 nations closest to
third edition (ed: W Vogely) (American Institute of Mining, developed in this group include the most affluent countries of
Metallurgical, and Petroleum Engineers, Inc: New York). Latin America and the Caribbean, Eastern European nations, and
McLean, I, 2004. Australian economic growth in historical perspective, some of the oil rich nations of the Middle East. The least
The Economic Record, September, 80(250):330-345. developed are mainly in Africa and their HDI values show they
Shaw, A G L, 1966. The Economic Development of Australia, fifth edition, have a long way to go before reaching the ‘developed’ status.
(Longman: Melbourne).

TABLE A2.1
A classification of developed and developing nations using the United Nations Development Program HDI Index for 2001.
(Source: United Nations Development Program, 2003.)
Value of HDI No of countries Countries
Developed nations
≥0.900 22 Norway, Iceland, Sweden, Australia, Netherlands, Belgium, United States, Canada, Japan, Switzerland,
Denmark, Ireland, United Kingdom, Finland, Luxembourg, Austria, France, Germany, Spain, New Zealand,
Italy, Israel
0.850-0.899 11 Portugal, Greece, Cyprus, Hong Kong, Barbados, Singapore, Slovenia, South Korea, Brunei, Czech Republic, Malta
Developing nations
0.800-0.849 22 Argentina, Poland, Seychelles, Bahrain, Hungary, Slovakia, Uruguay, Estonia, Costa Rica, Chile, Qatar,
Lithuania, Kuwait, United Arab Emirates, Bahamas, Latvia, Saint Kitts and Nevis, Cuba, Belarus, Trinidad
and Tobago, Mexico
0.750-0.799 31 Antigua and Barbuda, Bulgaria, Malaysia, Panama, Macedonia, Libya, Mauritius, Russian Federation,
Colombia, Brazil, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Belize, Dominica, Venezuela, Samoa, Saint Lucia, Romania,
Saudi Arabia, Thailand, Kazakhstan, Surinam, Jamaica, Oman, St Vincent and the Grenadines, Fiji, Peru,
Lebanon, Paraguay, Philippines, Maldives
0.700-0.749 22 Turkmenistan, Georgia, Azerbaijan, Jordan, Tunisia, Guyana, Grenada, Dominican Republic, Albania,
Turkey, Ecuador, Palestine, Sri Lanka, Armenia, Uzbekistan, Kyrgyzstan, Cape Verde, China, El Salvador,
Iran, Algeria, Moldova
0.600-0.699 18 Vietnam, Syria, South Africa, Indonesia, Tajikistan, Bolivia, Honduras, Equatorial Guinea, Mongolia, Gabon,
Guatemala, Egypt, Nicaragua, São Tomé and Principe, Solomon Islands, Namibia, Botswana, Morocco
0.500-0.599 15 India, Vanuatu, Ghana, Cambodia, Myanmar, Papua New Guinea, Swaziland, Comoros, Laos, Bhutan,
Lesotho, Bangladesh, Congo, Togo
0.400-0.499 19 Cameroon, Nepal, Pakistan, Zimbabwe, Kenya, Uganda, Yemen, Madagascar, Haiti, Gambia, Nigeria,
Djibouti, Mauritania, Eritrea, Senegal, Guinea, Rwanda, Benin, Tanzania
<0.400 15 Côte d’Ivoire, Malawi, Zambia, Angola, Chad, Guinea-Bissau, Democratic Republic of Congo, Central
African Republic, Ethiopia, Mozambique, Burundi, Mali, Burkina Faso, Niger, Sierra Leone
Total nations 175

16 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 3

Minerals and the Developing Nations


Philip Maxwell

Mineral Dependent Developing Nations


The Impact of New Mineral Development
The ‘Resource Curse’ Hypothesis
Institutional and Policy Issues

MINERAL DEPENDENT DEVELOPING NATIONS TABLE 3.1


Some recent classifications of mineral dependent nations.
With the demise of colonialism, the political geography of the
world has been changing. Australia recently celebrated its Author Criteria Number of
centenary of self-government. When Australia became (and year or period) countries
independent in 1901, there were perhaps 50 autonomous nations. Davis Minerals GDP/GDP ≥8% and Mineral exports/ 22
While many of today’s countries in Europe and the Americas (1995) Total merchandise exports ≥40% (1990)
were already sovereign states, Africa was still largely a colonial Eggert Mineral exports/Total merchandise exports 34
bastion, and much of Asia was in a similar position. (2001) >25% (1999)
A dramatic change began on the African continent from 1960 Eggert Non-fuel mineral exports/Total merchandise 37
onwards. There are now more than 50 independent countries in (2003) exports >10% (1990-99)
Africa. There have been parallel developments in Asia associated
with the independence of India and Pakistan in 1947, of the Domestic Product and almost 40 per cent of merchandise
South East Asian nations and more recently as a result of the exports. If one defined mining somewhat more broadly to include
break up of the Soviet Union. basic metal processing and mining services, the share of GDP
Teams from more than 200 nations marched at the opening rose to more than eight per cent.
ceremonies of the Olympic Games in both Sydney in 2000 and Using export data from the 1990s, there are 44 countries listed
Athens in 2004. While perhaps 30 members of this group are in Table 3.2 that meet this mineral dependence criterion. They
microstates (places such as Monaco and the Netherlands consist of 21 hard rock mining nations and 23 economies that
Antilles), Chapter 2 highlighted that the United Nations depend strongly on oil and gas production. Additionally, the
Development Programme now publishes estimated Human table includes 17 other marginal or potential mineral dependent
Development Index values for more than 170 nations in its nations. The criterion for marginal mineral dependence is a level
Human Development Report. Many of these have either of exports between ten and 25 per cent of total merchandise
significant mineral endowments or mineral dependence or both. exports. There are additionally a group of five or six African
While geologists estimate mineral endowments with statements nations that have either significant mineral potential that has yet
of reserves and resources, there are several ways of assessing to be developed or, if developed previously, have subsequently
mineral dependence. Three recent assessments (those of Davis, been adversely influenced by major political upheaval. Hence
19951 and Eggert, 2001, 2003) appear in Table 3.1. The final there are 59 countries on this list of actual, marginal or potential
contribution focuses only on non-oil and gas mineral producers. mineral dependent nations.
Our view is that where minerals and energy account for 25 per From an Australian and more general perspective, there are
cent or more of a country’s merchandise exports, its economy several reasons why these countries are of interest. At one level,
depends significantly on the non-renewable resources sector. there seems potential for those that experience a major mineral
For the second half of the 19th century, the first decade of the windfall to have the same economic development experience as
20th century and for much of the past 40 years, Australia has met Australia. In a similar fashion to the way the impact of the
most of the criteria for a mineral dependent economy. In the Victorian and New South Wales gold rushes dramatically
2002-03 financial year, for example, the mining sector, as changed the Australian economy, members of this mineral
defined in the Australian and New Zealand Standard Industry dependent country group could also be transformed.
Classification code, accounted for over four per cent of Gross At another level, the development of competitive mineral
economies in other nations may threaten the competitive position
of the Australian resources sector. This is not an issue that has
1. This taxonomy was also used by Nankani (1979), Gelb et al (1988) received much attention in the literature but it may have
and Auty (1993). implications for the economic fortunes of states and smaller

Australian Mineral Economics 17


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

TABLE 3.2
A revised classification of mineral dependent developing nations. Source: Eggert (2001, 2003); United Nations Development Programme (2003).
Value of HDI Countries
Hard rock Oil and gas Marginal or potential
0.800-0.849 Chile Qatar, Kuwait, UAE, Trinidad and Tobago Cuba, Belarus
0.750-0.799 Suriname, Jamaica, Peru Libya, Colombia, Venezuela, Bulgaria, Macedonia, Russia
Saudi Arabia, Kazakhstan Oman
0.700-0.749 Ukraine, Jordan, Uzbekistan Azerbaijan, Ecuador, Iran, Algeria Guyana, Armenia, Kyrgyzstan
0.600-0.699 South Africa, Tajikistan, Bolivia, Syria, Indonesia, Gabon, Egypt Morocco
Mongolia, Namibia, Botswana
0.500-0.599 Ghana, Papua New Guinea Togo
0.400-0.499 Mauritania, Guinea Cameroon, Yemen, Nigeria Zimbabwe, Tanzania, Senegal
<0.400 Zambia, D R Congo, Mali, Niger Angola Mozambique, Burkina Faso, Sierra Leone
Total nations 21 23 15

regions that depend on marginal mineral deposits for their With minerals and energy production more difficult in developed
economic wellbeing. It may also adversely affect Australian nations, either because mineral deposits are exhausted or factors
national welfare. such as greater environmental regulation are affecting their
In a more practical and positive vein, the development of development, the opportunity for this group to expand its share of
world-class mines and oil wells in other nations provides output, and benefit from it, seems significant unless their
opportunities for Australian companies to undertake investment comparative advantage shifts as they build capital stock.
abroad. As prospects at home become more limited, there is a Finally, Australian-trained mining professionals have been
natural tendency to focus attention on potentially profitable moving throughout the world, building their careers. The
ventures elsewhere. During the 1990s there was a strong internationalisation of Australian tertiary education has meant
movement of investment offshore by Australian mining that many of these graduates have come originally from
companies. Other developed nations with internationally developing nations, and will return home to build their own
competitive mining sectors, such as Canada and South Africa, country’s minerals and energy sectors.
also participated actively in this area2. Against this background it is a worthwhile exercise to reflect
The estimates in Table 3.3 provide one view of the status of the on recent views about the way in which the expansion or
current world mineral economy. Minerals and energy were contraction of minerals activity will influence developing
responsible for an estimated US$ 656 billion worth of national mineral economies.
product in 2001. This represented 2.1 per cent of estimated world
Gross Domestic Product. A key point of this table is that the
developed nations, with only 15.3 per cent of the world’s
THE IMPACT OF NEW MINERAL DEVELOPMENT
population, were responsible for more than half of the value of Chapter 2 pointed out that the so-called ‘traditional view’ suggests
world mineral and energy production in 2001. This was 1.5 per that when any nation decides to develop a major mineral
cent of their Gross Domestic Product. This seems to imply that the endowment there is a good possibility that this will bring major
countries of the developed world are depleting their mineral economic and social development. Hence, the exploitation of
reserves at a more rapid rate than those of the developing world. mineral and energy resources would seem to be a good thing. Yet,
In the 23 ‘major mineral producing’ nations, minerals and despite increases in measures such as the Human Development
energy product was 5.7 per cent of GDP. Although this group of Index in many mineral-rich developing nations, some influential
nations was responsible for only 13.3 per cent of world GDP, they observers have argued that the economic performance of the
were responsible for 39 per cent of world mineral production. world’s developing mineral economies over the past 40 years has
not been particularly impressive. This observation has led to much
2. See for example the paper by Maponga and Maxwell (2000) that further discussion of what has been happening.
discusses the Australian experience, and relevant chapters in Canadian In their recent review of this discussion the authors of
Minerals Yearbooks, Natural Resources Canada (various years) Breaking New Ground, MMSD Project (IIED, 2002) identify the
discussing the international activities of Canadian mineral companies.
interplay of three broad groups of factors influencing the
3. Eggert (2001) used a version of this taxonomy in his paper. process3. These are:

TABLE 3.3
The contribution of the mineral sector to gross domestic product in selected groups of nations 2001. Source: United Nations (2002).
Country group Population GDP Mineral sector GDP
(million) Per cent of (US$ Per cent of (US$ Per cent of Per cent of
total billion) total billion) total GDP in this
group
Developed nations (33) 935 15.3 24 959 79.5 375 57.2 1.5
Major developing mineral producing nations (23)† 3490 56.9 4184 13.3 256 39.0 5.7
Other developing economies (146) 1705 27.8 2257 7.2 25 3.8 2.0
World (202) 6130 100.0 31 400 100.0 656 100.0 2.1

† Countries in this group included Argentina, Azerbaijan, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, China, India, Indonesia, Iran, Mexico, Namibia, Nigeria, Papua New
Guinea, Peru, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, Syria, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago, Venezuela.

18 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

• external market forces such as declining terms of trade, as total exports, minerals have been Australia’s major export
well as mineral price volatility; category for the past four decades. The situation that has been
faced, with declining terms of trade, is similar to that of many of
• internal economic stresses, which in particular lead to the mineral dependent developing nations. Yet what matters is
reduced economic growth because of Dutch disease effects, profit (rent), not price. If the price of a commodity is falling
(as well as to changing fortunes of the different subnational more slowly than costs, the declining terms of trade could be
regions touched directly or bypassed by new mineral coincident with improving welfare. Another view of movements
developments); and in Australia’s terms of trade since the 1960s appears in Table 3.4.
• distorted processes of policy making, which foster
corruption and excessive rent seeking.
Each of these are now considered in turn. TABLE 3.4
Movements in Australia’s terms of trade since 1960.
Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2006.
External market forces
A nation’s terms of trade is the ratio of the prices of the goods Period Average level Standard deviation
and services that it exports to the price of the goods and services 1960s 116.5 3.6
that it imports. A fall in a country’s terms of trade means that it 1970s 113.8 4.5
needs to produce more of these goods to purchase the same
1980s 101.4 2.3
amount of imports as previously. A rise in a country’s terms of
trade means that it needs to produce fewer exports than before to 1990s 98.5 1.6
purchase the same amount of imports. 2000-01 100.0 na
It is typical for statistical agencies to publish these measures 2001-02 102.6 na
on a regular (say quarterly) basis. The Australian Bureau of
Statistics has conducted this exercise officially for much of the
past 50 years, though it has undertaken a study of trends in the The terms of trade of mineral and energy economies vary
terms of trade since Federation. The information in Figure 3.1 is widely. One indication of this comes from a review of terms of
derived from an Australian Bureau of Statistics study. trade estimates in World Bank (1993). The base year was 1987,
This graph shows a decline in Australia’s terms of trade over when terms of trade stood at 100.
the past century. During this time there have been two or three
notable spikes in the series (in 1924/25, 1950/51 and 1973/74) Group 1985 1991
and also some notable troughs (in 1931/32, 1943/44 and World 106 100
1986/87). But over the period, there has been an apparent fall in
our terms of trade from around 130 in the early years of the 20th High income nations (23) 97 101
century to about 100 at the beginning of the new millennium. Fuel exporters (12) 167 85
Note that the 1999-2000 financial year serves as the base year for Other mineral exporters (21) 122 94
the diagram. Throughout the century, natural resource-based
products (minerals, energy and agriculture) have accounted for
between 75 and 80 per cent of our exports. Manufactures have The volatility of mineral prices – their movement around a
accounted for a similar percentage of our imports. long-term price level or trend – is also an issue. This seems
While the terms of trade measure does not take account of particularly the case for gold, as well as for the mineral
changes in product quality (manufactured goods have been commodities traded in transparent markets such as the London
improving in quality over that period), it does provide a measure Metal Exchange (LME) and the New York Mercantile Exchange
of the perceived difficulties facing countries that depend on (NYMEX or COMEX). It is relevant both for government policy
natural resource-based exports. Averaging around 30 per cent of makers, as well as for mining and oil company executives.

Ratio (1999-2000 = 100) Ratio (1999-2000 = 100)


225 225

200 (b) 1950-51 200


(a) 1924-25
175 (e) 1973-74 175

150 150

125 125

100 100

75 75
(f) 1986-87
50 (d) 1943-44 50
(c) 1931-32
25 Butlin (1977) ABS National Accounts 25

0 0
1900-01 1920-21 1940-41 1960-61 1980-81 2000-01

FIG 3.1 - Movements in Australia’s terms of trade during the 20th century. Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2006.

Australian Mineral Economics 19


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

Governments prefer stable and predictable flows of taxes and mining services sector also entails ‘learning by doing’ for its
royalties to assist national economic management. During practitioners to establish and sustain a competitive edge.
periods of high mineral prices, politicians’ expectations about the Though identified for the Dutch economy and popularised by
future are typically optimistic. Indeed they may well be authors such as van Wijnbergen, the ‘Dutch disease’ has a much
over-optimistic. Governments in mineral-rich developing nations longer history and has applied in many other economies. There is
may be tempted to borrow large amounts to finance development now an extensive literature identifying the effect of the phenomenon
in other sectors of the economy, expecting that revenue flows in Australia, Nigeria, Indonesia and several other nations.
will easily meet debt repayments. Where mineral prices fall, this The Australian economy experienced some of the symptoms
often has brought major external debt problems. of Dutch disease in the resources boom period of the early 1970s,
Shareholders count on mining company executives producing when mineral exports increased dramatically. Exchange rates
healthy profits, while the broader community expects them to be rose strongly. In mid-1973 for example, the exchange rate
good corporate citizens, whether at local, regional or national between the Australian and US dollars was A$ 1 = US$ 1.51.
level. Part of this latter expectation relates to environmental Unsurprisingly at the time, manufacturing imports were very
management, part to contributing to local communities and cheap. Local manufacturers of things like motor vehicles and
regions, and part to paying taxes and royalties. Mining company white goods struggled. Australian farmers also faced difficult
workforces anticipate competitive working conditions in the times, typically accepting much lower prices than normal in A$
often remote and difficult conditions in which mines and oil for their internationally traded goods. In addition to this, there
wells are located. Senior managers and company boards face was a wage explosion and accompanying high rates of inflation
major challenges to satisfy each group of their stakeholders. soon followed.
In their study of metal price volatility for the six metals traded The short-term stress that Dutch disease places on a capitalist
on the London Metal Exchange between 1972 and 1995 economy will be greater if it is close to full employment when
(aluminium, copper, nickel, lead, tin and zinc) Brunetti and the major impact of new minerals-based development applies,
Gilbert (1995) found that volatility had remained relatively stable and it is not easy to supplement the labour force quickly through
over the period. There had been high volatility associated with migration. If there is large migration as a result of major new
two periods of tight demand. Nickel prices had tended to be the mineral development, this can assist the fortunes of lagging
most volatile and copper the least volatile among the group. industries. Where there is major stress on lagging industries, this
These findings were at odds with those of Slade (1991) who, in may however, be an optimal and welfare maximising response to
analysing data between 1970 and 1986, found greater volatility changes in a country’s resource endowments.
in the 1980s than the 1970s. The price volatility of key minerals
in the past decade seems likely to have increased.
Distorted processes of policy making
Internal economic stresses In addition to the potentially negative impacts of external
economic stress and internal economic pressures associated
Much of the discussion in this area has focused on whether or not with Dutch disease, mineral-rich developing nations may be
a nation experiences ‘Dutch disease’. Named after the experience subject to distorted policy making outcomes that arise from a
of the Dutch economy in the late 1970s, this is concerned with number of interrelated causes including:
the effects on an economy arising from the uncomfortable
co-existence of booming and lagging sectors, which often brings • excessive rent seeking,
significant structural adjustment, following the discovery and • corruption, and
initial exploitation of major new mineral resources. • an underdeveloped institutional framework.
A minerals or energy boom will increase a nation’s exports, and
it may also raise its exchange rate and drive up wages and Where political differences are large, the combination of these
inflation, at least in the short term. While the booming sector (say factors can even lead to civil wars where citizens of some regions
mining) will cope with this situation, ‘lagging’ domestically-based stand to derive great potential benefit from a mineral windfall,
tradeable-good industries (such as agriculture and manufacturing) yet national governments seek to redistribute the surpluses in a
may struggle to compete with imports. As a result, they may have way that is not favoured by the regional populations.
to close or severely contract their operations. When the boom Although it was noted that mines generate economic rent in
subsides, and exchange rates return to lower levels, there may be Chapter 1, the concept has not yet been discussed. Economic rent
difficulty to re-establish these industries4, 5. is the payment that any good (commodity) or service receives in
One justification for this view comes from the argument that excess of its supply price when a market is in equilibrium.
‘learning by doing’ occurs in producing manufactured goods, but In their well-known treatise, Garnaut and Clunies Ross (1983)
not minerals. This improves production efficiency to maintain provide the following definition of mineral rent:
and enhance industry competitiveness. When a minerals boom
Mineral rent may be defined as the returns in
leads to the complete or partial closure of a nation’s domestic
excess of those needed to attract factors of
manufacturing sector, the benefits from the learning effect of
production into the mining industry in the long
manufacturing will disappear. If the total benefits from
run. It is the revenue remaining after all costs
maintaining a manufacturing sector exceed those of mineral
have been deducted. These costs include
exploitation, the overall impact of mining on an economy would
exploration outlays, expenditures on mine
be negative. Yet much modern mining practice also involves
establishment and cash operating costs. Unlike
‘learning by doing,’ whether in the improvement of exploration
the accountant’s notion of costs, economic costs
practice, mining methods or mineral processing. In leading
include the returns on capital invested, which are
mineral-producing nations such as Australia, Canada and Chile,
just sufficient to attract the capital to the
mining is akin to early stage manufacturing. The associated
enterprise.
It is typical to illustrate economic rent using a diagram such as
4. Corden (1984) has provided one of the standard theoretical Figure 3.2, where the supply curve for producing mines is shown
explanations of what happens in economies during resource booms. by SS’, and the equilibrium price that clears the market is P. The
5. There are, however, no published empirical studies as yet to support economic rent generated in this case will be given by the area of
this argument. the triangle SPQ’.

20 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

governments, national governments, environmental lobby groups


S' and perhaps some other non-government organisations (NGOs).
Each group will have the ability to seek rent payments in varying
P P'
Q' degrees. Some of their demands may be so large that they
Range of undermine the profitability of the project. Senior executives will
mineral rents have to be confident that the project will be profitable if it is to
earned from proceed. There are many cases where companies do not proceed
producing mines with mineral resource development projects in developing
nations because they judge that claims on economic rent will be
excessive.
The potential of considerable new riches may also distort
Range of policy-making processes and encourage corruption. The
costs of organisation Transparency International provides annual
producing estimates in the perceived level of corruption in a broad
mines
S cross-section of countries. In their 2002 report they focused on
public sector corruption, defined as ‘the abuse of public office for
private gain,’ providing estimates of a Corruption Perception
Index for 102 nations. Their group included 26 of the 61
countries in the mineral economy taxonomy in Table 3.2. The
0 Q range of the TI measure is from zero (for the case of extreme
Volume of output corruption) to ten (a total lack of corruption.)
FIG 3.2 - The rent of mines in a competitive market. If mineral economies are more corrupt than non-mineral
economies, one might expect the relationship between perceived
Let us think for a moment what this means in the context of corruption and a measure such as the Human Development Index
the operation of the Western Australian gold industry. Suppose to reflect this. Assuming the Transparency International sample
that the current price of gold is US$ 400 per ounce. Suppose also of countries is representative of the entire population, and its
that there are 50 gold mines operating in the state. It is possible measure of perceived corruption is accurate, the analysis in Table
to generate a supply curve similar to SS’ for these producers. The 3.5 provides a rudimentary assessment. While this analysis is not
amount produced in the state has been around 200 tonnes per concerned directly with whether the windfall causes corruption,
annum (say six million ounces) for much of the past two it shows that the Unweighted Average Corruption Perception
decades. This corresponds to the distance 0Q. Index is in different HDI ranges for developed and developing
The lowest cost producer in the state has an average cost of say mineral- and non-mineral economies.
US$ 150 per ounce, while the most marginal mine produces at Perceived corruption is considerably less in developed than in
US$ 400 per ounce. The first producer will generate an economic developing nations. Yet it does not differ greatly between
rent of US$ 250 per ounce, while the second reaps no rent. developing mineral economies and non-mineral economies. High
While it is possible, in principle, for government to tax away levels of perceived corruption in several of the former Soviet
all of this rent and redistribute it to other parts of the economy, mineral economies meant that the unweighted average perceived
Chapter 15 shows that in practice, it is only possible to access corruption levels were higher in mineral economies in the HDI
part of this amount.
Equally, or even more important for the present discussion, are TABLE 3.5
the key points about mineral rent made by Garnaut (1995): Perceived corruption and stage of development – comparing HDI
• it can be absorbed by any party that has veto power over values for 2001 against the Transparency International Perceived
mine development; Corruption Index for 2002. Source: United Nations Development
Programme (2003); Transparency International (2002).
• it can be dissipated by uncertainty as conflict between
holders of the veto power raises the supply prices of inputs Value of HDI Mineral economies Non-mineral economies
into production; or
No Unweighted No Unweighted
• both of these things can happen. Average Average
Corruption Corruption
Any group that can delay or prevent the approval, construction, Perception Index Perception Index
or operation of mines or oil wells can exert this pressure.
Members of local communities close to a mine, for example, Developed nations
may wish to obtain more of the rent to ensure what they perceive ≥0.900 2 8.8 22 7.94
to be their long-term sustainability. Members of nearby 0.850-0.899 - - 7 6.03
indigenous populations may take a similar view. Where new
Developing nations
mineral development interferes with their cultural heritage, they
may try to prevent it from taking place. Conservation and 0.800-0.849 3 5.73 10 4.17
environmental groups may seek either greater environmental 0.750-0.799 6 2.98 9 3.34
regulation, which is more costly to the mining companies, or 0.700-0.749 4 2.90 10 3.31
propose that mines not proceed at all because they will cause
irreparable long-term damage to the surrounding physical 0.600-0.699 6 4.12 6 3.05
environment. 0.500-0.599 1 3.90 2 1.95
Whether rent-seeking behaviour is excessive or not depends 0.400-0.499 4 2.46 5 2.10
largely on how each stakeholder perceives the outcome of <0.400 2 2.15 3 3.03
negotiations about the sharing of rent. If a company is
considering starting a new mine in a developing nation such as Total developing 26 3.40 45 3.26
nations
Papua New Guinea, Fiji or Tanzania, there will be negotiations
with local indigenous and other communities, regional Total nations 28 74

Australian Mineral Economics 21


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

range between 0.700 and 0.799. Perceived corruption in the the economic performance of nations with a
desperately poor mineral economies with HDI values less than significant mineral (or other natural resource)
0.400 was also greater than in their non-mineral counterparts. In endowment may be worse than those without
other HDI ranges, however, perceived corruption was greater in such endowments.
non-mineral economies than in mineral economies.
Atkinson and Hamilton (2003, p 1793) perceive that it is:
The message for any company considering resource sector
investment in a developing mineral economy is clear. Expect the paradoxical but seemingly robust finding of a
greater levels of corruption than if investing in a developed negative and significant relationship between
nation. But the situation in developing mineral economies does natural resource [abundance]7 and the growth
not seem to differ greatly from that in non-mineral developing rate of per capita gross domestic product (GDP).
countries6. Sachs and Warner (2001, p 827) describe ‘the curse of natural
A stable government and well-formed institutions in any resources’ simply as: the observation that countries rich in
nation are more likely to facilitate the orderly development of a natural resources tend to perform badly.
competitive minerals and energy sector. When such institutions If growth in real GDP, or real GDP per capita, is a reasonable
do not exist, or they have been undermined because of political proxy for economic performance, then it would seem that minerals
change, excessive rent seeking and corruption may emerge. may have been a curse since 1970 for those nations that possess
When the African nations became independent, most had few them. The combination of external market forces, internal
properly formed institutions and there were few university economic stresses and distorted processes of policy making during
graduates with the background and experience to lead them the last three decades combined to bring this about.
effectively. In a somewhat different fashion, the demise of the
Soviet Union has been associated with institutional breakdown, One could describe such an outcome in terms of the simple
the rise of criminality and corruption in many of its former diagram depicted in Figure 3.3. After the initial upward impact
republics. of the new resource development, the negative impacts
associated with falling mineral prices, price volatility, Dutch
Where newly independent mineral-rich nations consist of disease, corruption and poor policy decisions come into play. By
disparate ethnic and cultural populations, institutional structures the time that the economy has adjusted, it is behind where it
are poorly formed and human capital levels are low, there appears would have been without the resources windfall. It then begins to
to be a tendency towards civil wars. Ross (2001) identifies 14 civil grow at the same rate as it would have without the mineral
wars in resource-rich nations that have taken place over the past 35 windfall. This is the key assumption – that it is behind where it
years. Nine were in Africa (in nations such as Angola, Nigeria, the would have been.
Democratic Republic of the Congo (formerly Zaire), Liberia and
Sierra Leone), two in Indonesia (Aceh and West Papua), two in the
Middle East (Iraq and Yemen) and one in Oceania (the Economic Without
Bougainville conflict in Papua New Guinea). activity resource
The practice of colonising nations of drawing geographical windfall
boundaries, which did not coincide with ethnic and cultural Negative impacts of
homogeneity, in combination with weak institutions has also External market forces,
often been associated with military coups and poor government. Internal economic stresses,
Distorted policy making
With resource
THE RESOURCE CURSE HYPOTHESIS windfall
It became apparent in the late 1970s that the economic Initial
performance of several developing nations with large mineral impact
and energy endowments, measured particularly in terms of real Economy
finally
GDP growth, did not coincide with traditional expectations. recovers
Nankani (1979) observed this generally for all mineral exporting
economies, while Gelb (1985) considered the situation in oil-rich Time
economies. Although Gelb found mixed outcomes in his country
case studies, Gelb et al (1988) subsequently posited the existence FIG 3.3 - A simple view of the resource curse hypothesis.
of a ‘resource curse’ thesis for the oil-rich developing nations.
Auty (1993) extended the argument that a resource curse applied
One way of classifying the empirical studies about whether
also in most ‘hard rock’ developing mineral economies. In an
minerals have been a curse or a blessing is to use the following
econometric study of the economic growth experiences of 97
three-part taxonomy:
nations between 1970 and 1989, Sachs and Warner (1995)
provided further empirical insight. They have subsequently 1. the case study-based analyses of growth in real GDP per
published further papers in the area and several other authors capita of by Gelb (1985) and Gelb et al (1988) and by Auty
have written about these issues. (1990, 1991, 1993 and 1994);
Before proceeding further, it is useful to reflect on the 2. the regression-based econometric analysis of growth in
generally understood meaning of the resource curse hypothesis. real GDP per capita associated particularly with the key
Auty (1993, p 1) argues that the essence of the resource curse study by Sachs and Warner (1995), several further studies
view is that: by the same authors, and a series of related studies by
authors such as Gylfason (2001), Atkinson and Hamilton
(2003) and Lederman and Maloney (2002); and
6. On a different but somewhat related note, Transparency International
(2002) reports that mining is not a major industry in foreign 3. the more broadly-based comparative data analyses of authors
jurisdictions where senior public officials solicit bribes or where the such as Davis (1995).
size of bribes paid is particularly high for mining companies. The studies by Gelb and his colleagues focused on the oil-rich
7. The absence of ‘abundance’ or a similar word from the definition economies that had emerged in the wake of the OPEC oil price
appears to have been a typographical oversight. rises in the 1970s. Though Auty’s initial papers were on oil and

22 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

gas-rich nations, much of his subsequent work has concentrated Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, Singapore – while
on non-oil ‘hard rock’ mineral economies. Both Gelb and Auty many resource-rich economies such as the
argued that the average GDP per capita growth of mineral and oil-rich countries of Mexico, Nigeria, Venezuela,
energy rich nations from the 1970s onwards had been have gone bankrupt.
disappointing. Their contributions have attracted considerable
Even though there are problems with the availability of
attention.
reliable historical data on Gross Domestic Product and natural
Yet it has been the subsequent contributions of Jeffrey Sachs resource intensity between nations, Lederman and Maloney
and Andrew Warner that have had the greatest impact so far on (2002) have recently taken up the empirical issue of considering
the debate about whether minerals are a blessing or a curse in their relationship in earlier periods. They use the GDP data of
developing nations. In their 1995 study, they used multiple Maddison (1994) during five periods:
regression analysis for a cross-section of 97 developed and
developing nations between 1971 and 1989 and considered • 1820 to 1870 (19 countries),
factors that explained differences in real GDP per worker growth • 1870 to 1913 (23 countries),
(for the economically active population). While interested • 1913 to 1950 (32 countries),
particularly in the impact of natural resource dependence (among
which minerals are a major contributor) they also considered a • 1950 to 1973 (37 countries), and
number of other variables. Their model takes the form: • 1973 to 1989 (37 countries).
They also assume (probably somewhat unrealistically) that the
Growth in real GDP per capita = γ (Log GDP per capita in initial ratio of natural resource exports to GDP for the nations involved
(of economically active year) + between 1820 and 1970 had remained constant at 1970 levels.
population) α (Natural resource exports/GDP) + Because of data limitations, they did not include additional
β’ (Additional variables) variables in the specification of their model.
They found a positive relationship between real GDP growth
The first of these variables, the logarithm of GDP per capita in and natural resource exports as a percentage of GDP between
the initial year, has been used in many studies to allow for the 1820 and 1870, and between 1913 and 1950. There were
observed tendency of affluent countries to grow more slowly negative relationships between 1870 and 1913; 1950 and 1973;
than poor countries. Their additional initial variables reflected: and 1973 and 1989. But t values were only significant at the five
per cent level in the final two periods. While tentative, these
• trade policy openness; findings question the validity of the resource curse hypothesis
• average annual rates of change in the terms of trade; over longer periods. Despite their preliminary nature, these
• gross domestic investment as a percentage of GDP; findings seem consistent with what has happened in countries
such as Australia.
• bureaucratic efficiency (indicating ‘corruption, red tape and Two other empirical studies by Gylfason (2001) and Torvik
judicial independence’); and (2002) have extended the Sachs and Warner analysis. Gylfason
• income inequality. argued that, on average, nations with higher percentage levels of
In their later studies, they have reported results for slightly natural capital9 (subsoil mineral and energy assets, farming and
different variables and time periods. After allowing for the grazing land, forests and fisheries) experienced slower growth in
impact of all of the above factors, Sachs and Warner find that a real GDP per capita between 1965 and 1998. He posited that
negative relationship remains between resource abundance and natural capital apparently ‘crowds out’ human capital in these
economic growth. This is the ‘resource curse’ effect. nations, with fewer resources allocated to education spending. In
his paper, Torvik argued that natural resource abundance crowds
With more widespread availability of key macroeconomic data
out entrepreneurial activity.
from nations around the world since 1970 it is now possible to run
the Sachs and Warner regressions to cover three decades. Such Many commentators have expressed doubt about whether GDP
regressions generally continue to support the Sachs and Warner is the most appropriate measure of total production. For example,
initial conclusions for the period between 1970 and 19898. it excludes productive non-market activities, as well as those in the
informal economy. Any measure of production should also allow
In the light of the above historical observations about the
for the capital depreciation. For these reasons, national accounting
positive impact of mineral development of nations such as
systems struggle to measure production in developing nations.
Australia, these findings come as a surprise. But Sachs and
Hence, comparing GDP per capita levels between nations is often
Warner (1995, p 1) argue also that:
misleading, even after allowing for purchasing power parity
The oddity of resource-poor economies differences. A more fundamental critique of GDP accounting has
outperforming resource-rich economies has been arisen from ecological economists whose alternative measures
a constant motif of economic history. In the 17th suggest that production is declining.
century, resource-poor Netherlands eclipsed An alternative approach is to explain and analyse variations in
Spain, despite the overflow of gold and silver a broader range of variables that reflect economic and social
from the Spanish colonies in the New World. In development. Since development involves several dimensions
the 19th and 20th centuries, resource-poor other than income growth, this might involve econometric
countries such as Switzerland and Japan surged modelling that seeks to explain variations in factors other than
ahead of resource-rich countries such as Russia.
income (eg human development indices). At a more rudimentary
In the past 30 years the world’s star performers
level it may simply involve broad data comparisons.
have been the resource-poor Newly
Industrialising Economies (NIEs) of East Asia – Using this later approach, Davis (1995) focused on the
experiences of 79 developing nations (largely in the period
between 1970 and 1990). Using the criteria outlined in Table 3.1,
8. The basis of this claim is from regressions undertaken by he defined 22 as mineral economies throughout the period, while
al Rawashdeh (2004).
57 were ‘never mineral’ economies. A summary of his findings
9. The source of Gylfason’s natural capital data was World Bank (1997). appears in Table 3.6.

Australian Mineral Economics 23


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

TABLE 3.6 considerable attention in academic literature11. Others such as


The development progress of long-term mineral economies and Ghana, Namibia, Peru and Tanzania can be added to this list.
‘never mineral’ economies – results from Davis (1995). Chile’s recent experience is of particular interest because, as
Mean values 22 mineral 57 ‘never mineral’ well as exhibiting strong economic growth, the nation’s record
economies economies with other development indicators has been impressive. Poverty
Life expectancy 31.5 26.2 has fallen appreciably, life expectancy has risen to levels similar
(% increase – 1960-91) to those of developed nations, literacy rates are high and the level
of post-secondary education has been rising significantly. A
Infant mortality rate 48.9 36.5
(% decline – 1970-90) summary of some of these trends appears in Table 3.7.
Calorie supply increase per capita 21.1 9.1
(% increase – 1965-90) TABLE 3.7
Primary school enrolment 20.7 16.0 Relative movements of key quality of life indicators in Chile.
(% increase – 1970-90) Source: Maxwell (2004).
Adult literacy rate 47.9 36.0 Indicator Chile High income World
(% increase – 1970-90) nations
Human Development Index 23.1 20.3 Life expectancy (years)
(% increase – 1970-90) 1977 67 75 64
1990 72 77 66
Davis found greater progress in increased life expectancy,
infant mortality decline, nutritional increase, primary school 2000 75.3 78 67
enrolment and adult literacy rate increases among the developing Infant mortality rate (no per ‘000 live births)
mineral economies than their ‘never mineral’ counterparts. The 1970 78 20 85
percentage increase in the Human Development Index between
1990 17 8 52
1970 and 1990 among developing mineral economies was also
higher than among the ‘never mineral’ developing economies 2000 10 6 45
sample10. While these findings focus on alternative measures, Adult literacy rate (per cent)
they may not be at odds with the resource curse view. In the 1990 93 95.5 60
above empirical tests in might be argued that the resource curse
only refers to trends in economic welfare and not their levels. It 1999 95.5 na 64
may be possible to have slow growth and yet have higher Percentage of age group in tertiary education
development indicators. 1970 13 36 13
So where does this leave the empirical debate? Despite the 1990 15.6 33 11
important contributions of authors such as Sachs and Warner in
developing a body of econometric analysis about the impact of 1999 37.5 na na
minerals and energy development on economic growth, much Percentage income share of top quintile
remains to be considered. Further econometric analysis might 1989 48.9 ≈25 na
profitably be extended to consider variations in a wider range of
1998 39.1 ≈25 na
development indicators. If such analysis supports the findings of
authors such as Sachs and Warner, whose major interest has been in Percentage of population below the poverty line
explaining variations in GDP and GDP per worker growth, then the 1992 21.6 na na
resource curse hypothesis will be on stronger ground. Supporters of 1998 21.2 na na
the traditional view doubt that such analysis is possible.
Human Development Index Leading nation Gap
1975 0.702 0.859 0.157
INSTITUTIONAL AND POLICY ISSUES
1990 0.782 0.901 0.119
Despite the prognosis of the resource curse hypothesis, the
2000 0.831 0.942 0.111
historical experiences of nations such as Australia, which moved
from developing to developed status over a relatively short time
period suggests that the combination of a favourable mineral Also, notwithstanding the continuing strength of the copper
endowment, well organised and operated institutions and industry, other parts of the economy have been developing
appropriate government policy can and has led to favourable strongly and several are now competitive.
development outcomes. It is to these later elements that we now One way to assess the economic experience of such nations is
turn. The discussion in this section also has links to a more in terms of the rudimentary framework of Weber-Fahr (2002),
detailed review of mineral policy in Chapters 13 and 15. which suggests that economic performance (encompassing
If one embraced the resource curse hypothesis, mineral-rich somewhat more than strong economic growth) in mineral-rich
developing nations would be better off not to exploit their nations will depend on both the quality of economic
mineral wealth. Yet, as well as the apparently depressing list of management and the quality and stability of key institutions.
bad news stories associated with the economic fortunes of The quality of economic management in any nation depends
mineral economies, several developing nations have derived on a number of factors. The calibre and experience of the civil
positive benefit from mining in the past two decades. Two of the
service is important. So is the integrity and training of the
most prominent are Chile and Botswana. Each has received
politicians who make up the government. This will come under
significant challenge if Dutch disease accompanies a resources
10. This trend is unlikely to have continued since 1990 because of the boom. A simple conceptual formulation might be that:
adverse impacts of the HIV/AIDS epidemic on life expectancy in
many mineral-rich African nations. Quality of = f (Quality of civil service and politicians, level
economic of corruption, nature of policy, relative size of
11. See for example Auty (2001) on the situation in Botswana, and
management resources windfall)
Maxwell (2004) for a discussion about Chile.

24 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 3: MINERALS AND THE DEVELOPING NATIONS

Factors affecting the quality and stability of a nation’s Garnaut, R, 1995. Dilemmas of governance, in Proceedings Mining and
institutions include the size of its human capital stock, national Mineral Resource Policy in Asia-Pacific: Prospects for the 21st
ethos about issues of equity such as poverty, income and wealth Century (eds: D Denoon, C Ballard, G Banks and P Hancock), pp
61-66 (Division of Pacific and Asian History, Australian National
inequality and the extent of ethnic and cultural differences within University: Canberra).
the population.
Garnaut, R and Clunies Ross, A, 1983. Taxation of Mineral Rents
It is possible, therefore to hypothesise a relationship of the (Clarendon Press: Oxford).
form: Gelb, A H, 1985. Are oil windfalls a blessing or a curse? Policy exercises
with an Indonesia-like model, discussion paper, Research
Institutional quality = f (Human capital stock, poverty and inequality, Department, World Bank.
and stability cultural homogeneity, political harmony)
Gelb, A H and Associates, 1988. Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse?
(Oxford University Press: New York).
Joining these two equations together, one might therefore argue Gylfason, T, 2001, Natural resources, education and economic
that: development, European Economic Review, 45:847-859.
International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), 2002.
Economic = f (Policy environment, relative size of resources Breaking New Ground, Mining, Minerals, and Sustainable
performance windfall, human capital stock, poverty and inequality, Development – The Report of the MMSD Project (Earthscan
cultural homogeneity and political harmony) Publications: London) [online]. Available from: <http://www.iied.org/
mmsd/finalreport/index.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
where the policy environment variable incorporates a Lederman, D and Maloney, W, 2002. Open questions about the link
combination of the quality of the civil service, political between natural resources and economic growth: Sachs and Warner
decision-makers and policies formulated, as well as a lack of Revisited, Natural Resources and Growth Conference, Bank of Chile,
January [online]. Available from: <http://www.bcentral.cl/eng/std
corruption. pub/studies/workingpaper/htm/141.htm>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
The policy environment, human capital stock and extent of Maddison, A, 1994. Explaining the economic performance of nations,
cultural homogeneity and political harmony are all positively 1820-1989, in Convergence of Productivity: Cross-National and
related to the process of development. The relative size of the Historical Evidence, (eds: W Baumol, R Nelson and E Wolff) pp
resources windfall and the level of poverty and inequality are 20-61 (Oxford University Press: New York).
inversely related. How a nation develops its mineral energy Maponga, O and Maxwell, P, 2000. The internationalisation of the
resources will depend on the interaction of these positive and Australian mineral industry in the 1990s, Resources Policy,
negative forces. In the case of Chile, it seems clear that the 26(4):199-210.
nation has been able to perform well in each of the factor areas Maxwell, P, 2004. Chile’s recent copper-driven prosperity: Does it
that affect the development process12. provide lessons for other mineral-rich developing nations? Minerals
and Energy, 19(1):16-31.
Some other notable recent contributions to the discussion
Nankani, G, 1979. Development problems of mineral exporting countries:
about public policy have been from the World Bank mining A background study for World Development Report 1979, World
group and Richard Auty (the former seem to ascribe more to a Bank Staff, Working Paper No 354, Washington.
resource blessing view of minerals, while the latter sees them Natural Resources Canada, various years. Canadian Minerals Yearbook,
more as a curse). [online]. Available from: <http://www.nrcan.gc.ca/mms/cmy/index.
htm>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
12. For a more detailed discussion on this issue see Maxwell (2004). Ross, M, 2001. Extractive sectors and the poor, September, Oxfam
America Report: Boston.
Sachs, J and Warner, A, 1995. Natural resource abundance and economic
REFERENCES growth, development discussion paper no 517a, Harvard Institute for
International Development.
al Rawashdeh, R, 2004. Personal correspondence.
Sachs, J and Warner, A, 1997. Sources of slow growth in African
Atkinson, G and Hamilton, K, 2003. Savings, growth and the resource economies, Journal of African Economies, 6(3):335-376.
curse hypothesis, World Development, 31(11):1793-1807.
Sachs, J and Warner, A, 2001. Natural resources and economic
Australian Bureau of Statistics, various years. [Online]. development: The curse of natural resources, European Economic
<http://www.abs.gov.au>. Review, 45:827-838.
Auty, R M, 1990. Resource-Based Industrialization: Sowing the Oil in Slade, M E, 1991. Market structure, marketing method, and price
Eight Developing Countries (Oxford University Press: New York). instability, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106:1309-1340.
Auty, R M, 1991. Managing mineral dependence: Papua New Guinea Torvik, R, 2002. Natural resources, rent seeking and welfare, Journal of
1972-89, Natural Resources Forum, May, pp 90-99. Development Economics, 67:455-470.
Auty, R M, 1993. Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The Transparency International, 2002. Corrupt political elites and
Resource Curse Thesis (Routledge: London). unscrupulous investors kill sustainable growth in its tracks,
Auty, R M, 1994. Industrial policy reform in six large newly industrialized highlights new index, press release, 28 August, Berlin.
countries: The resource curse thesis, World Development, 12:11-26. United Nations, 2002. Economic statistics [online]. Available from: <http://
Auty, R M, 2001. The political state and the management of mineral rents unstats.un.org/unsd/economic_main.htm>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
in capital surplus economies: Botswana and Saudi Arabia, Resources United Nations Development Programme, 2003. Human development
Policy, 27:77-86. report 2003 [online]. Available from: <http://hdr.undp.org/reports/
Brunetti, C and Gilbert, C L, 1995. Metals price volatility, 1972-95, global/2003>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Resources Policy, 21(4):237-254. Weber-Fahr, M, 2002. Treasure or Trouble? Mining in Developing
Corden, W M, 1984. Booming sector and Dutch disease economics: Countries (World Bank and International Finance Corporation:
Survey and consolidation, Oxford Economic Papers, 36:359-380. Washington).
Davis, G A, 1995. Learning to love the Dutch disease: Evidence from the World Bank, 1993. World Development Report 1993; Investing in Health
mineral economies, World Development, 23(10):1765-1779. (Oxford University Press: Oxford) [online]. Available from:
Eggert, R G, 2001. Mining and economic sustainability: National <http://www.worldbank.org>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
economies and local communities, Report No 19, October, Mining, World Bank, 1997. Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of
Minerals and Sustainable Development Project (International Environmentally Sustainable Development (World Bank Publications:
Institute for Environment and Development: London). Washington DC) [online]. Available from: <http://www.worldbank.
Eggert, R G, 2003. The mineral economies: Performance, potential org>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
problems and policy challenges, UNCTAD Module One, June, 31 p.

Australian Mineral Economics 25


CHAPTER 4

Trade in Minerals
Philip Maxwell

Why Trade Takes Place


The World Economy, International and Interregional Trade
Recent World Production and Trade in Minerals and Energy
Australian Production and Trade in Minerals
Transport Costs and the Direction of Minerals and Energy Trade
Minerals Trade and Exchange Rates

WHY TRADE TAKES PLACE Minerals


When people, companies or nations freely trade goods and
services with one another, they increase their respective levels of After
economic welfare. They normally use money1 – serving in its D B trade
MB
role as a medium of exchange and a unit of account – to facilitate C
these exchanges. A simple diagrammatic analysis, such as that in MC
Figure 4.1, illustrates how two parties, who choose to trade with A
one another at an agreed rate of exchange, can move to a higher MA
level of welfare. For the purposes of this example, assume that Before
one of the parties sells minerals, while the other sells all other trade
final goods and services. Only the first party is considered to
keep the example as simple as possible.
Assuming a production possibility curve DBAE, the economic
actor (person, company or country) will initially be at point A on
the production possibility frontier. Let us call this actor Smith.
Smith has the opportunity to trade with another actor, Jones, at O GB GA GC E Other goods
and services
an exchange rate given by the slope of the line BC. Smith
chooses therefore to move around on the production possibility
curve from A to B, producing more minerals and less other goods FIG 4.1 - The gains from trade – a simple view.
and services. Smith then sells MBMC of minerals to Jones for
GBGC of other goods and services, thereby moving along the more complex because different countries often have different
trading possibilities curve BC to the point C. At point C, Smith currencies, and may erect trade barriers2.
receives more minerals and other goods and services than before
trade and is clearly better off. By using the same methodology it The extent of interregional and international trade has grown
is possible to draw a diagram to show that Jones will also be over the past two centuries as the world has moved more and more
better off as a result of trade. towards becoming a global economy. From time to time these
trends have been reversed by war, politics and the business cycle.
Whether this trade takes place within a nation, in an
intraregional framework (eg within the Sydney metropolitan There is now a broad field of specialisation within economics
area) or interregional context (eg between the Pilbara region of that considers the area of international trade. The pioneer of
Western Australia and the Illawarra region of New South Wales), modern international trade theory was David Ricardo who, in
or it flows across international frontiers (between the Pilbara and The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation in 1817,
China), does not matter in a welfare changing sense. Yet developed the idea of comparative advantage. He used this
movements of goods and services internationally are typically concept in his classical theory to explain trade between nations
such as England and Portugal. According to Ricardo, a countries
tend to export those goods and services where their margin of
1. It is also possible to undertake barter trade or counter trade to superiority is greater, or their margin of inferiority smaller, than
achieve a similar result, though the use of money tends to eliminate their trading partners. Even though Portugal was a more efficient
the ‘coincidence of wants’ condition. producer of both wine and cloth, he argued that each country
2. It is also possible for trade barriers to exist between states within would gain from trade when Portugal exported wine (and
nations. imported cloth) and England exported cloth (and imported wine).

Australian Mineral Economics 27


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

One limitation of the original Ricardian model was that it was 8 7.5%
restricted to differences in the productivity of just one factor of Exports
production (labour). Also it did not explain the determinants of 6.1% Production
comparative cost differences. In developing the neoclassical 6
theory of international trade, three economists (Heckscher, Ohlin
and Samuelson) extended Ricardo’s theory. They did this by 4.5%
recognising that countries are endowed with many factors of 4.1%
3.8%

(%)
4
production but in different proportions, and arguing that these 3.5%
explain differences in international costs and form the basis for 2.7%
international specialisation. 2.4%

In his explanation of the Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model, 2


Grubel (1981, p 24) states that:
A country exports goods which intensively use
the factor of production with which it is relatively 0
well endowed, and imports the good using Total Agriculture Mining Manufacturing
intensively the factor with which it is relatively
poorly endowed. FIG 4.2 - Average growth rates of world exports (by volume)
and production – 1950 to 2003. Source:
Remembering the nature of the economist’s production World Trade Organization (2004).
function, what this implies is that a country relatively rich in
capital will export capital-intensive goods and import
labour-intensive goods. In a similar vein a natural resource 10000
intensive country such as Australia will export minerals (and
agricultural goods) and import manufacturing goods. Although Manufacturing

the theory of international trade has now moved considerably Total


beyond the neoclassical model3, there is general agreement that merchandise
this view normally provides a reasonable explanation of why trade

both international and interregional minerals trade takes place. 1000 Mining
Against this background, the focus for the remainder of this Agriculture
chapter is in considering the importance and direction of
minerals and energy trade and in assessing Australia’s role as a
major mineral exporter. The following sections consider these
issues in further detail. Because transport costs play an important 100
role in mineral trade, this issue is discussed in the fifth section of
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
the chapter, prior to the brief concluding commentary. The final
section focuses on the importance of exchange rates as a
determinant of comparative advantage in minerals trade. FIG 4.3 - The growth of international trade – 1950 to 2003.

THE WORLD ECONOMY, INTERNATIONAL AND certainly appear to be the case within nations. But it has not been
INTERREGIONAL TRADE the case with international trade. The estimates in Figure 4.2 show
that international mineral trade grew at an average of 4.1 per cent
Despite the limitations discussed in Chapter 2, it is common per annum, while real GDP grew at 3.8 per cent.
practice to use Gross Domestic Product as the standard measure Also, as can be seen from Figure 4.3, international mineral
of the size of an economy in any given period. Chapter 3 noted trade has grown at a faster rate than trade in agricultural goods
that the United Nations estimated World GDP to be US$ 31 400 but more slowly than manufacturing trade and total merchandise
billion in 2001. As can be seen in Table 3.3, the 33 developed trade over this extended period.
economies, with a little more than 15 per cent of the world’s Several factors seem to have contributed to the more rapid rise
population, generated almost 80 per cent of this total, while the in international trade than production over the past half century.
remaining 169 developing nations produced just over 20 per cent. Let us consider some of them briefly:
This table showed as well that the minerals sector, defined
narrowly, was responsible for 2.1 per cent of world GDP in that • In the aftermath of World War II and the Depression of the
1930s, international trade in 1950 stood at rather low levels.
year.
In a subsequent period of relative peace in the world
National and international statistical agencies have been making economy, one would expect the rate of international trade to
GDP estimates consistently since about 1950. Since that time, real increase strongly.
GDP has grown on average at about 3.8 per cent per annum.
Mineral production has increased at 2.7 per cent per annum, • There has also been the continuing rise of the number of
agriculture at 2.4 per cent and manufacturing at 4.5 per cent. nation states. There were fewer than 100 nations in 1950 and,
as noted in the previous chapter, there are now more than
Because minerals are inputs into final goods and services, most
200. With more countries, it seems obvious that more
mineral production is traded either within regions, between
international trade will take place.
regions or between nations. The exception is where firms use
vertical integration to control different parts of the production • With the demise of Communism in the early 1990s, many
process and trade does not formally take place. Since mineral developing nations have now embraced export-oriented
production has grown more slowly than total production, one policies, rather than import-replacement strategies, as a way
would expect mineral trade also to grow more slowly. This would of seeking to promote development. This has provided a
further stimulus to international trade.
3. For a further discussion of international trade theory it is useful to
• Additionally there has been a recent movement towards
consult one or more of a large number of international economics lowering of trade barriers throughout the world. Free trade
textbooks. leads to more trade.

28 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

TABLE 4.1 • There has also been a major revolution in bulk shipping
Estimated world new mineral production – 2002. Source: costs, a factor which will be returned to later.
United States Geological Survey, 2006; Natural Resources
Canada, 2006; US Energy Information Administration, 2006.
RECENT WORLD PRODUCTION AND TRADE IN
Energy minerals Amount Price/unit Value MINERALS AND ENERGY
(US$) (US$ M)
Narrowly defined, the value added by mineral and energy
Hard coal (Mt) 4000 38 152 000
production (its contribution to World Gross Domestic Product)
Brown coal (Mt) 886 20 17 720 amounted to US$ 656 billion in 2001. This was approximately 2.1
Crude oil (‘mill bpd) 77.9 26 739 271 per cent of total GDP. Periods of higher minerals and energy prices
Natural gas (tr cu ft) 95 650 61 750 (as in 2004) would increase this percentage, as would a broader
view of the resources sector, which includes all basic mineral
LNG 55 000
processing as part of mining (rather than in manufacturing).
Uranium (t) (2001) 36 800 20 938 771
One can obtain another view of world mineral usage by
Total fuel 1 026 512 estimating the annual value of new production of the energy
Metals minerals, major metallic minerals, and non-metals. Such an
Aluminium (kt) 25 900 1430 37 037 exercise depends on a number of assumptions concerning the
degree of processing of key minerals and without considerable
Antimony (kt) 143 3300 472
discussion and qualification should be seen only as indicative,
Beryllium (t) 132 716 300 95 rather than authoritative. The results of such an exercise appear
Chromite (kt) 4650 200 930 in Table 4.1. The value of fuel mineral production in 2002 was
Cobalt (t) 47 600 15 229 725 more than US$ 1000 billion. The value of newly mined metals
was slightly more than US$ 150 billion and of newly mined
Copper (kt) 13 600 1670 22 712 non-metals a little more than US$ 50 billion. It should be noted
Gold (t) 2550 9 734 300 24 822 that steel production is not included in this calculation and
Heavy mineral sands 920 neither is cement. Their inclusion would significantly increase
Iron ore (Mt) 1050 30 31 500 the estimates of the value of production in the metals and
non-metals areas.
Lead (kt) 2910 452 1315
The World Trade Organization publishes estimates of
Lithium (t) 12 500 7980 100 international trade in its annual publication, International Trade
Magnesium (kt) 508 2535 1288 Statistics. A summary of its estimates in key product groups for
Molybdenum (kt) 121 9.2 1113 2002, and their growth since 1995, appears in Table 4.2. These
Nickel (kt) 1340 6772 9074
data show that minerals trade has been accounting for over a
tenth of world merchandise trade in the recent past. Although
Niobium (kt) 32.8 14.5 476 part of this trade involves the movement of recycled metals and
Platinum group metals 3963 non-metals, by comparing data in Tables 4.1 and 4.2, it is clear
Silicon 4028 from 2002 data that much new mineral production now flows
across international borders.
Silver (t) 20 000 144 606 2892
Tantalum (t) 1480 66 700 99
TABLE 4.2
Tin (kt) 209 4500 941
International merchandise trade 1995 - 2002.
Tungsten (t) 58 800 7300 429 Source: World Trade Organization (2003).
Vanadium (t) 50 500 3520 178
Category Value Per cent Annual percentage
Zinc (kt) 8930 880 7858 (US$ B) share change
Other (estimate) 2100 2002 1995 2002 1995- 2001 2002
Total metals 155 063 2000
Non-metals Agricultural products 583 11.7 9.3 -1 0 5
Asbestos (kt) 1970 308 607 Mining products 788 10.7 12.6 10 -9 -1
Boron (kt) 4550 500 2275 Ores and other minerals 63 1.2 1.0 1 -4 1
Bromine (kt) 548 1600 877 Fuels 615 7.3 9.8 13 -9 0
Diamonds 8000 Non-ferrous metals 110 2.2 1.8 3 -10 -2
Gypsum (Mt) 101 12 1212 Manufactures 4708 74.3 75.1 5 -4 4
of which:
Iodine (t) 20 700 12 700 263
Iron and steel 142 3.1 2.3 -1 -6 7
Nitrogen fertiliser (Mt) 108 155 16 740
Chemicals 660 9.7 10.5 4 3 10
Phosphate rock (Mt) 137 27.5 3768
Unspecified products 194 3.0 3.0 na na na
Potash (Mt) 44.1 110 4851
All products 6272 100 100 5 -4 4
Salt (Mt) 217 25 5425
Sand and gravel (Mt) 110 2500
Other (estimate) 5000 As can be seen in Table 4.3, the ratio of international trade in
non-fuel minerals to their total new production stood at 0.84.
Total non-metals 51 517
Even though many nations make strong efforts to enhance their
Estimated total mineral 1 233 092 self-sufficiency in the supply of the energy minerals, almost 60
production per cent of new production was traded internationally in 2002.

Australian Mineral Economics 29


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

TABLE 4.3 Australia’s Mineral Reserves


International trade in minerals as a share of new mineral
production 2002. Source: World Trade Organization (2003). Despite its extended exploitation and the finite nature of
Australia’s mineral endowment the Australian Bureau of
International trade New production Ratio Statistics (2000) reported that:
Non-fuels 173 206 0.840
Given its relatively small population, this statement implies
Fuels 615 1027 0.599 that Australia is likely to continue to be a significant
Mineral products 788 1233 0.639 mineral producer and exporter for a large number of
minerals in the foreseeable future (ie for most of the 21st
century).
AUSTRALIAN PRODUCTION AND TRADE IN Australia continues to rank highly as one of the world’s
MINERALS leading mineral resource nations. It has the world’s largest
Economic Demonstrated Resources (Reserves) of:
Chapter 2 highlighted the important role that minerals and
energy have played in the development of the Australian
economy since European settlement. Initiated particularly by the lead mineral sands
gold rushes in the 1850s, by Federation in 1901 the new nation’s nickel (ilmenite, rutile and zircon)
mineral economy had expanded into a number of other areas.
tantalum silver
Although minerals production and trade subsided in importance
in the first half of the 20th century, a major resurgence from 1960 zinc uranium
until the present time has re-established Australia as one of the
world’s leading mineral producing and exporting nations. As the In addition, Australia’s EDR is in the top six worldwide for:
insert on the following page shows, recent best estimates show
that Australia’s mineral reserves4 are presently at high levels for
a wide range of minerals. bauxite black coal
The Australian Bureau of Statistics publishes official data on brown coal copper
Australian mineral production and trade. In the production area cobalt gold
its publications Australian Mining Industry 1998-99 (Australian iron ore lithium
Bureau of Statistics, 2000) and Mining Operations Australia
2001-02 to 2002-03 (Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2004) manganese ore rare earth oxides
present the most recent available official information as this industrial diamond vanadium
chapter is compiled. The ABS publication International Trade in
Goods and Services, Australia (cat no 5368.0) provides current
information on the commodity composition and direction of Coal mining and the oil and gas sector stand out with sales in
Australian international trade in minerals and energy. The both sectors exceeding A$ 16 billion. Though considerably
material in Table 4.4, for the 2002-03 financial year, is derived smaller, iron ore and gold were also both major sectors with sales
from Australian Bureau of Statistics (2004). more than A$ 5 billion. Copper, silver-lead-zinc, bauxite and
nickel were also major sectors. Other important areas, though
much smaller in size, were mineral sands (generating sales of
TABLE 4.4
A$ 869 million) and diamond mining (A$ 771 million)5.
Australian mineral production 2002-03.
Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics (2004). With the exception of oil, Australia is self-sufficient and a
potential exporter in each of the major mineral sectors listed in
Sales and Wages and Industry Table 4.4. Yet, because minerals are typically inputs into the
service income salaries value added
manufacture of final goods, it does not necessarily follow that a
($ M) ($ M) ($ M)
major mineral-producing nation will also export these resources.
Coal mining 16 862 1921 8254 An alternative is to establish downstream processing, which then
Oil and gas extraction 17 225 779 15 263 provides a platform for manufactured exports. These will add
Iron ore mining 5307 500 3779 potentially greater value and profit for domestic producers.
Although policymakers and commentators have actively
Copper ore mining 2223 211 825 promoted the value adding argument in many mineral-
Gold ore mining 5932 670 2718 producing nations, the realities of comparative advantage are that
Mineral sand mining 869 108 369 such manufactures (whether produced for export or as import
replacements) tend not to replace mineral exports in any
Silver-lead-zinc ore 1775 216 679
mining significant fashion unless they are in countries with major
internal markets.
Bauxite, nickel and metal 2750 240 1367
nec Consider, briefly, the case of iron ore. Together with Brazil,
Australia has been one of the two major producers of high
Other mining† 3996 479 1941 quality iron ore to world steel producers since the 1960s. The
Services to mining 6530 1562 2451 overwhelming majority of Australian production has come from
Total mining 63 473 6694 37 644 the remote Pilbara region in Western Australia.
Gross Domestic Product 731 021 In a hypothetical exercise, Stewardson (1992, p 3) considered
Australian iron ore and steel exports for the 1990-91 financial
Mining GDP/GDP 5.1%
year. He estimated that if Australian producers converted all of
† Includes construction material mining and mining not elsewhere their iron ore exports into steel, and then sold this into the world
classified. market, export values would increase from $2.83 billion to
$16.75 billion. This would have represented a third of the
internationally traded steel market. Stewardson argued that
4. There is further discussion about mineral reserves in Chapter 6. achieving this level was not possible because of factors such as
5. These data appear in Department of Industry and Resources (2003). market structure, transport costs, the availability of other factors

30 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

of production, speed and flexibility of response to demand, the TABLE 4.5


market for by-products and, most importantly, costs of Key mineral and energy exports – Australia 2002-03.
production. All of these factors made the comparative advantage Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics (2004).
in steel production lie with nations such as Japan, Taiwan and
Korea. It has recently moved to China in a most significant way. Commodity Value (A$ M) Per cent
Even when Australian-based companies such as BHP Billiton Coal 11 946 10.4%
have made partial attempts at downstream processing of iron ore, Crude petroleum oils, etc 5881 5.1%
they have struggled to make profits. The difficulties with high Gold (non-monetary) 5584 4.8%
construction costs at the Port Hedland hot briquette iron plant,
and ongoing technical difficulties with its operation, provide a Iron ore and concentrates 5328 4.6%
topical recent example of the challenges in changing comparative Aluminium 4059 3.5%
advantage. While change over time does take place, the nature of Aluminium ores and concentrates 3587 3.1%
the process is often difficult to predict. It may happen gradually,
Natural gas 2620 2.3%
suddenly, or not at all.
Other petroleum oils 2441 2.1%
Against this background, the data in Table 4.5 reflect the recent
importance of key mineral exports, while Figure 4.4 shows the Copper 1327 1.2%
continuing strong performance of Australian mineral and energy Base metal concentrates (other 1216 1.1%
exports since 1970. The Australian Bureau of Statistics presently than Fe, Cu, Ni, Al, U and Th)
publishes monthly estimates of Australia’s exports and imports in Other minerals 14 517 12.6%
its International Trade in Goods and Services.
Total merchandise exports 115 142 100.0%
In 2003-04 eight of the top 12 export commodities6 were
related to the minerals and energy sector. They were iron ore and
concentrates, aluminium ore and concentrates, coal, crude 60%
petroleum oils, refined petroleum oils, natural gas, aluminium
and non-monetary gold. Several other mineral commodities 50%
including copper, nickel, other base metals, mineral sands and
diamonds also make important contributions to merchandise
40%
exports.
The significance of minerals and energy exports since 1970
30%
stands out in Figure 4.4. Following the entry of Britain to the
European Common Market (now the European Union) in 1960,
20%
Australian farmers faced difficult trading conditions. The
manufacturing sector subsequently struggled as the Australian % of merchandise exports
Government reduced tariffs. The strong export performance of 10%
% of total exports
the minerals and energy sector in this changed environment has
been impressive. Minerals have consistently contributed more 0%
than 40 per cent of Australia’s merchandise exports, and more 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
than 30 per cent of Australia’s international trade in goods and
service since 1975. In the past five years it has been on average FIG 4.4 - The key role of Australian resource sector exports
in excess of A$ 50 billion per annum. This seems destined to 1969-70 to 2003-04.
continue in the foreseeable future.
Once this ore is mined, producers must send it to a port where it
TRANSPORT COSTS AND THE DIRECTION OF will be shipped to the customer in a city such as Kobe, Anshan or
MINERALS AND ENERGY TRADE Pohang. The producer typically bears the cost of delivering the
mineral to the port, while the buyer is responsible from that point
Discussion about the economics of value adding, in the preceding onwards. The cost of transporting iron ore has the potential to be
section, laid some of the groundwork for analysing the direction of more than its sale price. Historically this has meant that
Australia’s mineral and energy trade. Comparative advantage is steelmakers in places such as North America and China have
the key to understanding this. If Australian iron ore producers favoured local mines, even though their ore is inferior to that
despatch most of their output to China, Japan, Korea and Taiwan, coming from high-grade mines in distant nations.
while Brazilian producers send most of their ore to Europe and
North America, this is a reflection of the respective comparative Gold can travel easily all over the world. Even though it is less
advantage that producers in each nation hold. valuable – around US$ 1500 per tonne – it has been recently
profitable to ship Australian nickel concentrate (say ten to 15 per
An important factor that influences comparative advantage and cent nickel metal) from ports such as Esperance in Western
the extent of resources trade is a mineral commodity’s value to Australia to Finland and Canada. A similar situation applies with
weight ratio. Sending Australian gold anywhere in the world is mineral commodities such as alumina, zinc concentrates, copper
comparatively inexpensive. Even though security may be an concentrates, lead, ilmenite and rutile. Lower value commodities
issue, it is a relatively straightforward matter to send a bar of such as coal and iron ore have traditionally been more
gold to London, New York, Mumbai or Hong Kong and sell it constrained in their movements. Large shipments of Australian
there. The cost of transport is relatively small. iron ore to Europe must compete with supplies from closer
By contrast, trading lower value commodities profitably across places (Sweden, Ukraine, Mauritania, Brazil, India, South
international frontiers is a more contentious issue if a business is Africa, etc). This has the capacity to make it less than
trying to make and maximise profits. While the price of gold competitive.
may be US$ 500 per ounce, the price of a tonne of high quality While, at one end of the spectrum precious mineral producers
iron ore mined in the Pilbara will be perhaps US$ 50 per tonne. sell gold, diamonds and the platinum group minerals in global
markets, industrial minerals such as gravel, sand, cement and
6. The ABS used the three-digit level of the Standard International aggregates typically trade only in local and regional markets.
Trade Classification (SITC) in developing this list. Only occasionally do they move across international frontiers.

Australian Mineral Economics 31


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

($US/t)
The simple inverse relationship between the market value of 65
minerals and the transport cost to value ratio in Figure 4.5 60 Shipping costs
provides an indicative insight into the importance of transport 55
Rail/Port costs
costs. This may be described as a transport cost market value 50
Mining costs
curve. While the transport cost to value ratio for gold and 45

platinum group metals may be 0.01 or 0.02, even from faraway 40

places, the value of this ratio for commodities such as iron ore 35
30
and coal from remote parts of the world is often greater than one.
25
20
Market
15
value
10
Gold, PGMs 5
0
Base metals Queensland NSW NSW surface North & Central Wyoming South Africa Indonesia
surface underground Appalachia surface surface surface
underground
Base metal concentrates A
($US/t)
Oil and gas 60
55 Shipping costs
Iron ore
50
Rail/Port costs
Coal, fertilisers 45
Mining costs
40

35
Construction materials
30

25
Transport cost
20
to value ratio
15
10
FIG 4.5 - Mineral commodity values and transport costs.
5

0
For example, the cost of transporting a tonne of coal from an Queensland
surface
NSW
underground
NSW surface North &
Central
Wyoming
surface
Colombia
surface
South Africa
Surface
Indonesia
surface
Appalachia
open cut mine in Central Queensland to Europe may be as much B underground
as twice the cost of mining it. For international trade to occur in a
case such as this: FIG 4.6 - The importance of production and transport costs for coal
sold in the Japanese and European markets in 1995. (A) Japan,
• either the quality of the distant mineral commodity must be (B) Europe.
considerably higher than that available from nearer to the
market place;
either by higher quality, or more certainty of long-term supply, or
• transport costs must have fallen; or both, from the Australian mining regions. The non-Australian
• both factors must apply. producers had a more pronounced cost advantage to European
In his influential paper on bulk trade and maritime transport destinations as illustrated in Figure 4.6b.
costs, Lundgren (1996) observes that: One feature that stands out for most producers is that domestic
rail and port costs are typically greater than international
Since the 1950s a transport revolution has shipping costs, involving travel over greater average distances.
occurred comparable to events of the late 19th While this implicitly points to the great improvements in
century when sailing ships were replaced by efficiency of bulk shipping since 1950, there is a continuing
steam vessels. Freight rates for bulk products challenge of making domestic transport links more efficient. This
have decreased 65 - 70 per cent due to improved issue was associated in early 2005 with a broader debate about
maritime technology. Formerly separate markets the relative levels of exports and imports and the size of the
for bulk products have been unified globally. current account deficit in Australia.
Reduced maritime transport costs in the immediate post World Another way of viewing this data is to compute the percentage
War II period led to a leftward shift in the transport cost market contribution of transport costs to the total costs of coal. As can be
value curve and a corresponding increase in the potential size of seen in Figure 4.7a and b, these often exceed 50 per cent.
markets for minerals produced in previously remote locations. Major improvements in transport technology have a significant
Parallel reductions in internal transport costs (rail and road), effect on country and company competitiveness in the minerals
and increases in the efficiency of ports in mineral producing sector. The present and future status of the transport system
nations, tended to lag behind the dramatic reductions in shipping determines the countries with which producers of lower value
costs. Yet in nations such as Australia, the implementation of a commodities such as iron ore, coal and fertilisers are able to
national competition policy in the early 1990s sought to increase trade profitably.
efficiency and thereby establish greater competitiveness in this The data presented in these figures provide a useful
area as well. background to explain why Australia trades many of its higher
Crowson (1998) provides one insight into the importance of valued commodities throughout the world, while its lower value
transport costs in the exporting of coal to major markets in the commodities have more limited markets. Hence, its major
mid-1990s. His data show rail/barge, shipping and average markets for coal and iron ore are in major Asian nations, while it
mining costs in US dollars from key producing regions to both faces more serious competition in Europe from African and
the Japanese and European markets. These are reproduced in South American producers. Yet transport costs alone do not
Figure 4.6a for Japan and Figure 4.6b for Europe. In the case of entirely explain the direction of minerals trade. The quality of a
Japan, the sum of production and transport costs from the two nation’s or region’s mineral endowment is also important,
main Australian coal mining regions (Queensland and New together with the status of environmental policy, its regulatory
South Wales) was slightly higher than for Wyoming, South environment and the absolute and relative levels of exchange
Africa and Indonesia at this time. Presumably this was offset rates and movements in them.

32 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

90% fixed, ie the value of the local currency is set at a certain level in
80% relation to other key currencies, a nation’s Central Bank will use
its reserves to buy and sell currency to ensure that this stable
70%
relationship continues. Foreign exchange markets reflect current
60% levels of exchange rates. The values of these exchange rates are
50%
readily available in newspapers or on the internet.
As well as reflecting its value in terms other specific currencies
40%
(eg A$ 1 = US$ 0.75, A$ 1 = 0.61 Euro, A$ 1 = £St 0.41, or A$ 1
30% = $NZ 1.10), another way to view the value of a country’s
20%
currency is in terms of the value of a Trade-Weighted Index. The
authors of Reserve Bank of Australia (2002) note that:
10%
The TWI is a weighted average of a basket of
0%
Queensland NSW NSW surface North & Central Wyoming South Africa Indonesia currencies that reflects the importance of the sum
A surface underground Appalachia
underground
surface surface surface
of Australia’s exports and imports of goods by
100% country. The TWI is often used as one indicator
90% of Australia’s international competitiveness and
80%
is a useful gauge of the value of the Australian
dollar when bilateral exchange rates exhibit
70%
diverging trends.
60%

50%
The Reserve Bank has computed this measure on a daily basis
for the Australian dollar since 1970, when its value was set at
40%
100. The graph in Figure 4.8 shows movements in the index
30%
measured in December of each year between 1970 and 2004. The
20% Reserve Bank revises these weights annually to reflect changing
10% trading patterns.
0%
Queensland NSW NSW surface North & Wyoming Colombia South Africa Indonesia
140
Surface Underground Central Surface surface surface surface
Appalachia
B underground 120

100
FIG 4.7 - The percentage contribution of transport costs for coal
sold in the Japanese and European markets in 1995. (A) Japan, 80
(B) Europe.
60

The combinations of changes in environmental legislation and 40


increased difficulties in gaining mining permits in Europe and
North America have adversely affected the ability of companies 20
to open and operate mines in several nations on these continents. 0
As this has occurred, it has been necessary to import minerals 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
from other parts of the world to meet domestic needs.
FIG 4.8 - Movements in Australia’s Trade-Weighted Index since
1970. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia, 2005.
MINERALS TRADE AND EXCHANGE RATES
Suppose that Australians decide to import goods or services Three phases stand out in this diagram:
from Japan. Typically they must pay for these either in yen or • a rising currency associated with the period of the resources
sometimes with a third currency such as the US dollar. They will boom in the early 1970s;
typically use their Australian dollars to buy these. The reverse • a consistent decline in the value of the currency between
situation applies when Australian resource companies export 1973 and 1985 (the period in which members of the
their ore, concentrate, metal or liquefied natural gas to Japan. Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries exerted a
They usually want to be paid in Australian dollars. Japanese major influence on the world economy); and
customers will use yen to buy Australian dollars.
A nation (or company or individual) can obtain the foreign • a period of relative stability at new lower levels since 1985.
currencies needed to make payments for imports in two ways: Currency weights for September, 2004, obtained from the
• by exporting goods and services to other nations, thereby Reserve Bank’s web page, appear in Table 4.6. Of particular note is
earning the foreign currency needed to make the transactions; the importance of Asian nations such as China and Japan in the
basket. It is useful to remember that the weights given to Japan
and
would have been minimal in 1960 and China did not feature in the
• by attracting international investors to undertake new basket until the implementation of its ‘open door’ policy after 1978.
investment in a venture in the nation (or owned by the While movements in the Trade-Weighted Index are important, it
company or individual). is more common to report movements of the Australian dollar
Any nation’s total payments to other nations must be equal to, again the United States dollar. This is a reflection of the
or balanced by, the total payments received from other nations. importance of the US economy to the rest of the world. In the case
There are recorded in the balance of payments accounts. of minerals and energy, most prices are denominated in US$.
The exchange rates between one country’s currency and those The profitability of mines and oil wells in any nation will be
of its trading partners typically generate a balance of payments. affected significantly by the value of exchange rates, unless these
Where exchange rates are floating, as they have been in move up and down with mineral and energy prices. This has
Australia since December 1983, international payments will tended to happen in Australia over time, though there are periods
always be in balance. Exchange rates adjust up and down where the correspondence has not applied. The case of gold
automatically to ensure that this takes place. Where they are provides an interesting recent example.

Australian Mineral Economics 33


CHAPTER 4: TRADE IN MINERALS

Movements in exchange rates have fortuitously worked as a


TABLE 4.6
‘natural hedge’ against downward price movements in US
Currency weights in the Trade-Weighted Index of the Australian
dollar in September, 2004. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia
dollars. From time to time economists reconsider the question of
(2005). whether the Australian dollar is a ‘commodity currency’. Given
how important mineral exports have been as a percentage of the
Currency Percentage weight Australia’s total exports in the past 40 years, the Australian
Japanese yen 16.0616 dollar has tended to depreciate when mineral prices fall and
appreciate when they rise. Yet over a longer time period mineral
European euro 13.5177
producers should not take these movements for granted.
United States dollar 13.1603
Chinese renminbi 11.3042 REFERENCES
South Korean won 5.9748
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2000. Australian mining industry 1998-99
New Zealand dollar 5.8800 (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Available from:
UK pound sterling 4.7279 <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2004. Mining operations Australia 2001-02
Singapore dollar 3.6558 to 2002-03 (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online].
Taiwanese dollar 3.1755 Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Malaysian ringgit 3.0999 Australian Bureau of Statistics, various issues. International trade in goods
and services (Catalogue No 5368.0) (Australian Bureau of Statistics:
Indonesian rupiah 3.0208 Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date
Thai bhat 2.5910 accessed: 8 May 2006.
Crowson, P, 1998. Inside Mining: The Economics of the Supply and
Indian rupee 2.6227
Demand of Minerals and Metals (Mining Journal Books: London).
Hong Kong dollar 1.7666 Department of Industry and Resources, 2003. Western Australian Mineral
Canadian dollar 1.6244 and Petroleum Statistics Digest 2002-03 (Western Australian
Government: Perth) [online]. Available from: <http://www.doir.wa.
Saudi Arabian riyal 1.2299 gov.au/documents/mineralsandpetroleum/statsdigest0203.pdf>. Date
South African rand 1.1964 accessed: 8 May 2006.
Vietnamese dong 1.1311 Grubel, H G, 1981. International Economics, revised edition (Irwin:
Homewood).
PNG kina 0.9960 Lundgren, N-G, 1996. Bulk trade and maritime transport costs: The
Swedish krona 0.8788 evolution of global markets, Resources Policy, 22(1/2):5-32.
United Arab Emirates dirham 0.8614 Natural Resources Canada, 2006. [Online]. <http://www.nrcan.gc.ca>.
Reserve Bank of Australia, 2002. Developments in the Trade-Weighted
Philippine peso 0.7576
Index, Reserve Bank of Australian Bulletin, October, pp 1-6.
Swiss franc 0.6132 Reserve Bank of Australia, 2005. Statistics: Trade-Weighted Index
[online]. Available from: <http://www.rba.gov.au>.
For much of the past 20 years, movements in the gold price Ricardo, D, 1817. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (J M
have been largely in unison with the exchange rate. In most of that Dent and Sons: London).
period, spot gold prices have hovered around A$ 500. During Stewardson, R, 1992. Value adding in Australia, Australian Bureau of
1997, however, there was a dramatic downward movement in the Agricultural and Resource Economics National Agricultural and
US$ price of gold, due in part to the decisions of several Central Resources Outlook Conference (ABARE: Canberra).
Banks (including the Reserve Bank of Australia) to sell all or part US Energy Information Administration, 2006. [Online].
of their gold holdings. As the market price sank below US$ 300 <http://www.eia.doe.gov>.
per ounce, the Australian dollar also declined, but not at the same United States Geological Survey, 2006. [Online].
rate. Soon Australian dollar spot gold prices stood close to A$ 400 <http://minerals.er.usgs.gov/minerals>.
per ounce. Many gold producers were in trouble. Some switched World Trade Organization, various years. International trade statistics
[online]. Available from: <http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/
to ‘high grading’ and most slashed exploration budgets to stay statis_e.htm>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
viable. Fortunately for local gold producers, the A$/US$ exchange
rate continued to fall and the A$ price of gold moved back towards
A$ 500 per ounce.

34 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5

Mineral Demand — The Theory in Practice


Peter Howie

Introduction
The Final-Product Demand Curve and the Level of Consumption
Mineral Resources and Derived Demand
Elasticity of Mineral Demand
Conclusions

INTRODUCTION curves. Economists define a final product as a product that is


produced for its final user and not as a component of another good
It is important to have information on current mineral or service. For example, a Nokia mobile telephone, a pair of gold
consumption, and its likely response to price and income earrings and gold bullion used for investment are all final products;
changes, government policies, economic development and but the copper wiring in the mobile telephone and the gold in the
technological change. Because the demand for minerals is earrings are intermediate products or inputs. To help with the formal
multifaceted, it is also essential to have a good knowledge of the development of the final-product demand curve, let us introduce the
fundamentals that affect mineral demand to analyse and forecast scenario that the Human Resource Director at Komatsu Australia is
output and price behaviour. interested in purchasing gold earrings for the upcoming year.
One way to categorise the demand for minerals is as derived, Since most goods are scarce and the Human Resources
created or historical. Industrial demand derives from the unique Director cannot have everything that she wants, she must make
physical and chemical properties of minerals that enable their use tough choices. The science of economics tells us that every time
in varied applications. Discussions of mineral demand a person makes a choice, something else must be given up. That
particularly recognise this characteristic. There is a strong link is, when the Human Resources Director purchases one good she
between mineral uses and economic growth. This relationship is is giving up the opportunity to purchase another good or service
likely to continue into the future. with the money she spends. Furthermore, economics provides a
Jewellery demand is created and requires constant promotion. set of tools that can help the Human Resources Director make
The growth in demand for jewellery is highly correlated with the best decision available. This set of tools is based upon the
demand for gold and other precious metals in the USA, Asia and philosophy of utilitarianism. The foundation of utilitarian
the Middle East. Consumers in the developed markets of the West philosophy is:
buy jewellery primarily for adornment and often for sentimental
reasons. In the developing markets of Asia and the Middle East, Actions are right in proportion as they tend to
they purchase it for investment, as well as adornment. promote happiness; wrong as they tend to
Investment demand is historical and relies on international produce the reverse of happiness (Mill, 1863).
currency movements and inflation. The monetary demand for gold In other words, utilitarian philosophy suggests that the Human
and, to a lesser extent, other precious metals has derived value Resources Director makes decisions with the ultimate objective
from providing stability and security to overall investments. of maximising her happiness, both intellectual and sensual.
This chapter is organised to permit an orderly presentation of Commonly people believe that choices they make are in the form
the basic topics of mineral demand separated into four parts. The of answers to the questions: ‘Which and how many pairs of earrings
first presents the concept of final-product demand and introduces should I purchase?’ The answer is believed to be that the Human
some of the economics required to understand subsequent Resource Director decides to purchase the pairs of earrings that she
sections. The second focuses on the derived demand for minerals likes the best as long as they are within her budget.
and the characteristics of such demand. The third introduces the Economists suggest that such questions should be answered by
concept of elasticity and progresses with an in-depth comparing all the costs, not only money costs but also the costs
examination of the sensitivity of mineral demand to changes in associated with inability to do something else. Therefore, when
prices and income. This section also examines the effect of time the Human Resource Director purchases earrings, economists
on mineral demand. The fourth section concludes. suggest that she compares all costs and benefits. Often, however,
it is difficult or impossible to list all the available purchase
THE FINAL-PRODUCT DEMAND CURVE AND options within a person’s budget. Luckily, economics provides a
THE LEVEL OF CONSUMPTION simple way to approach this problem. It suggests that we break
the question ‘How many and which pairs of gold earrings
This section presents some necessary economic tools and generates should the Human Resource Director purchase?’ into a series
both individual consumer, as well as market final-product, demand of further questions.

Australian Mineral Economics 37


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Before doing this, let us make two simplifying but realistic The Human Resource Director’s marginal benefit curve from
assumptions that help in discussing the answers: gold earrings (or any individual product or service) is identical to
1. The Human Resource Director budgets a certain amount of her individual demand curve for gold earrings. That is, the
money to buy gold earrings and she spends all of this demand curve for gold earrings shows the marginal benefits of
money either on gold earrings or on another product. gold earrings to her.
It is also possible to derive the market demand curve for gold
2. Benefits from the purchases are expressed in terms of earrings. Table 5.2 provides a simplified picture of the gold
money. This means that all benefits, both sensual as well as earrings market if there are only two consumers. At $130 per pair
intellectual, from the purchase of gold jewellery are of earrings, consumer A demands five pairs per period and
measured in terms of equivalent money value. consumer B demands six pairs per period. Therefore, the market
The questions to be asked are: demand for gold earrings at $130 is 11 pairs of earrings.
Similarly, at $100 per pair of earrings, consumer A demands six
• How much is the Human Resource Director willing to pay
pairs and consumer B demands eight pairs. Therefore, the market
for her first pair of earrings?
demand is 14 pairs. This procedure of generating the market
• How much is the Human Resource Director willing to pay demand is often described as ‘announcing a price and adding up
for a second pair? the individual quantities demanded at that price’. This procedure
• How much is the Human Resource Director willing to pay is the same whether there are only two consumers in a market or
for each subsequent pair of gold earrings? many millions.
Figure 5.2 provides a graphical representation of the market
This type of questioning examines the effects of changes in
happiness with each additional purchase. It allows us to demand for gold earrings outlined in Table 5.2.
determine the number of dollars the Human Resource Director
regards as equivalent to each pair of earrings. It is a direct TABLE 5.2
measurement of the benefits she receives from each pair. Individual and market demand.
As Table 5.1 shows, the Human Resource Director derives
Price Consumer A’s Consumer B’s Market demand
$300 worth of benefit from one pair of earrings, $550 from two
($/pair) demand demand
pairs, and so on. So she receives $300 of benefit from the first
pair of earrings, $250 from her second pair, and so on. The 160 4 4 8
benefits that a consumer receives from consuming the next unit 130 5 6 11
of a product is the ‘marginal benefit.’ 100 6 8 14
70 7 10 17
TABLE 5.1
40 8 12 20
Marginal and total benefits.
Pairs of earrings Total benefits ($) Marginal benefits ($) A’s Demand B’s Demand Market Demand
0 0 -
1 300 300 $/unit $/unit $/unit

2 550 250
3 754 204
4 918 164 130

5 1048 130 100


6 1148 100

For the Human Resource Director, marginal benefits are the Q/t Q/t Q/t
5 6 6 8 11 14
amounts of money that she is willing to pay to enjoy the
attributes of an additional pair of gold earrings. For example, the
marginal benefit from the third pair of earrings is $204. FIG 5.2 - Individual and market demand curves.
Table 5.1 also shows that, as she buys more and more pairs, the
benefits she derives from each additional pair will be less than It is important to understand why the market demand curve is
that from the previous pair. Therefore, the graph of her marginal drawn as it is. Along the demand curve only price is allowed to
benefits from earrings is downward sloping (see Figure 5.1). change. Income and the prices of related goods are held constant.
Furthermore, there are two independent reasons for the market
350 quantity demanded to fall as prices increase. One is that many
people will switch to a substitute good. If the price of gold
300
jewellery rises, some consumers will switch to platinum
Marginal benefits (dollars)

250 jewellery, others to silver jewellery. A second reason people buy


less when price rises is that they are not able to buy as much as
200 before. Incomes usually do not fluctuate with the price of an
individual product. Therefore, when the price of a product goes
150
up, it is not possible to buy as much as before unless we purchase
100 less of something else.
Similar to the market demand curve, the market supply curve
50
represents the behaviour of suppliers during a given time period.
0
The market supply curve shows the total number of units of a
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 good or service that sellers are willing to deliver to the market at
Pairs of gold earrings per period every possible price during a given period. Market supply curves
generally slope upward, indicating that sellers are willing to
FIG 5.1 - Marginal benefit curve. supply a higher quantity as the price rises.

38 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

When the price of a good or service is such that the quantity monsoon (World Gold Council, 2004b). The increased demand
that buyers want to buy is the same as the quantity that sellers for 18 carat white gold in China during 2003 is believed to have
want to sell, the market is in equilibrium. If consumers wish to been stimulated by the high price of platinum, a substitute for
consume more than producers wish to produce at a given price, gold (World Gold Council, 2004b).
there will be buying pressure and the quantity demanded will Expectations play a key role in investment demand. While
exceed the quantity supplied. Prices will rise. Conversely, if gold is a volatile investment, it provides good hedge against
consumers wish to consume less than producers wish to produce, inflation or a fall in the US dollar. Remember that gold
there will be selling pressure and the quantity supplied will transactions are denominated in US dollars. Consider the actions
exceed the quantity demanded. Prices will fall. Such changes of speculators during the last half of 2003. Throughout this
continue until equilibrium is achieved – quantity demanded period, they bet heavily that the price of gold would rise by
equals quantity supplied. The price that accomplishes this is the purchasing futures contracts on gold1. This purchasing trend
equilibrium price and the corresponding quantity is the topped-out during the first week of September, 2003 when they
equilibrium quantity. negotiated almost 123 000 contracts to buy about 12.3 million
ounces of gold. This was the largest historical weekly position in
Final-product demand and its determinants the Commodity Futures Trading Commission data going back to
1983 (Fuerbringer, 2003).
Recall that the demand curve shows that if there is an increase in
the price of a product, consumers will purchase less of it, all
other things being equal. In other words, if price goes up, MINERAL RESOURCES AND DERIVED DEMAND
quantity demanded will go down; if price goes down, quantity So far in this chapter discussion has focused on the consumer
demanded will go up. This is the law of demand. It indicates demand for final goods and services. But most minerals are not
that if there is an increase in the price of a product, then there final goods. While consumers demand precious metals and gems
will be a leftward movement along its demand curve and vice as final goods, these only account for a small fraction of total
versa. Economists refer to movements along the demand curve as mineral demand. The main use of minerals is as inputs for final
changes in the quantity demanded. goods and services. Therefore, the demand for most minerals is
It is important to realise that the demand curve by itself derived from the demand for the final goods and services that
isolates the impact of price on the quantity of a product they produce. Economists describe it as a derived demand. For
demanded. Because the law of demand is one-dimensional (that example, the demand for copper in mobile telephones is derived
is, it only examines the impact of quantity demanded caused by from the demand for mobile telephones. Consumers of mobile
changes in the price of the good and vice versa) it leaves out telephones are not concerned about which inputs are used as long
factors that shift the demand curve. For example, the law of as the mobile telephone meets their needs.
demand cannot fully explain the increase in the price of gold
since September 11, 2001. That is because the quantity of gold The mineral demand curve
consumed and produced is not solely determined by its price.
One key to the higher gold price on the demand side lies in There is a clear relationship between final-product demand and
changes of investors’ preferences for gold due to the decay of the derived demand of a mineral to make these final products.
global economic health, in particular that of the US economy Recall that determining final-product demand involves the
(Kitco, 2004). In the period following September, 2001 investors ultimate objective of maximising a consumer’s happiness
became increasingly worried about the safety of their US determined by the prices of goods and by the income available to
dollar-denominated money and there was an increase in the purchase them. By contrast, for our mobile telephone
preference to hold gold as an alternative. manufacturer, who requires inputs for its production, mineral
demand is a special case of demand in which the purchased
In addition to growing investment demand for gold bullion,
goods are the inputs for production.
gold jewellery demand also increased due to changes in
consumer tastes. Even with a 20 per cent increase in the price of As a result, the demand for minerals is linked closely with a
gold during 2003, the World Gold Council estimated that the firms’ production processes. Our firm’s mobile telephone
consumer demand for gold was up 12 per cent in tonnage terms production process, and its demand for copper, expresses a
(or 30 per cent in dollar terms) (Humble, 2004; World Gold relationship between its inputs and its outputs. Economists
Council, 2004a). formally represent this production relationship by the
production function (see Chapter 2).
A change in the preferences of consumers (ie consumers of
gold jewellery) and investors who are consumers of gold bullion The production function is a non-monetary relationship that
is only one of several non-price factors that change the quantity correlates physical inputs to physical outputs. Prices and costs
consumed. These non-price factors shift the demand curve. The are not considered. A typical production function for a firm with
demand curve: only one variable input, say copper, and a set level of fixed inputs
appears in Figure 5.3. In this example, fixed inputs (those inputs
• shifts to the right if a non-price factor causes the quantity whose quantities cannot be readily changed in an effort to alter
consumed to increase; and the rate of output) include pieces of equipment and machinery,
• shifts to the left if a non-price factor causes the quantity the factory space available for production, the know-how of
consumed to decrease. managerial personnel, and all labour. The vertical axis shows the
total output and the horizontal axis shows the units of copper
Other non-price factors that shift the demand curve include
employed. All points above the production function are
level of income, prices of related goods, and expectations.
unobtainable with current technology, all points below are
The level of income and prices of related goods are very technically feasible, and all points on the function show the
important to gold jewellery demand. A large proportion of the maximum quantity of output obtainable at the specified levels of
21 per cent increase in gold jewellery demand in India during inputs. From the origin, through points A and B, the production
2003, the world’s largest consumer of gold jewellery, was due to function is rising, indicating that as additional units of copper are
higher rural income as a result of the year’s generally good used, the quantity of mobile telephones produced are increasing.
From the origin to point A, as the firm uses additional units of
1. A futures contract on gold is an agreement to buy or sell a specific copper, the number of mobile telephones produced increases at an
amount of a gold at a particular price on a stipulated future date. increasing rate. The increase in output generated by adding an

Australian Mineral Economics 39


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Quantity of mobile MPP curve from now on, our focus is on the downward sloping
telephones per time period portion in Stage 2.
The next step is to determine how many units of copper our
profit-maximising firm will employ. The answer is
straightforward: our firm will employ any unit of copper that
B
produces greater value than it adds in cost. That is, the firm will
use an additional unit of copper when the benefits from it are
greater than its costs. For simplicity let us assume that:

A 1. the added cost equals the market price of the copper (which
implies that the buyer of copper is a price taker); and
Units of copper
per time period 2. the price of mobile telephones is constant.
X The value that copper contributes to the mobile telephone
manufacturer depends on two things:
Y
• how much the output of mobile telephones increases by
adding an additional unit of copper; and
APP
• the extra revenue that each additional mobile telephone
brings to the firm.
In economics, the value that an extra unit of variable input
MPP Units of copper contributes is called the marginal revenue product (MRP), as
per time period opposed to the MPP. The MRP of copper is simply the added
Stage 1 Stage 2 revenue or benefit of employing an extra unit of copper. For our
mobile telephone manufacturer, this benefit equals the MPP of
copper multiplied by its market price.
FIG 5.3 - The production function. The cost of the copper, by the above assumption, equals its
market price. Therefore, the mobile telephone manufacturer will
additional unit of the variable input is called the marginal employ additional units of copper until the benefit that an extra
physical product (MPP). For the mobile telephone manufacturer, unit of copper contributes (the MRP) equals the market price or
MPP is the increase in output of mobile telephones caused by cost of an extra unit of copper.
increasing the input of copper by one unit. As the number of
A numerical example clarifies this idea. Suppose the mobile
mobile telephones is increasing at an increasing rate from the
telephone company, Nokia, has a factory in Indonesia. It pays
origin to point A, the firm’s MPP is also increasing as shown by
A$ 12 per kilogram for copper wiring. Suppose Nokia receives
the increasing MPP of copper from the origin to point X. The
A$ 12 for each telephone, and adding another kilogram of copper
average amount of telephones generated by each unit of copper
will allow it to make two more mobile telephones per hour. Is it
employed – the average physical product (APP) – is rising along
worthwhile to add another kilogram of copper? Using the above
the production function between the origin and point A.
rule, the extra value to Nokia is 2 × A$ 12 or A$ 24. The extra
Point A defines the starting point beyond which the number of cost to Nokia of another kilogram of copper is A$ 12. Hence, it
mobile telephones increases at a decreasing rate when additional is in Nokia’s interests to add more copper. After this kilogram of
units of copper are employed. This corresponds to declining copper is added, Nokia finds that adding another kilogram of
MPP of copper beyond point X. copper will add only one more mobile telephone. Now the
Beyond point B the average number of telephones generated company is indifferent to adding an extra kilogram because to
by each additional unit of copper employed starts to decrease. generate an extra A$ 12 of income costs A$ 12. From now on,
This trend is shown by the decline of the APP curve beyond Nokia will not use additional units of copper because the extra
point Y. value that they generate is less than their price.
To simplify this interpretation of a production function, it is An important characteristic of the MRP curve of a mineral is
common to divide its range into two stages. In Stage 1 (from the that it corresponds to a manufacturer’s demand curve for it. Our
origin to point B) the average number of mobile telephones firm’s mineral demand curve identifies the amount of copper it
produced by the variable input (here copper) and the fixed inputs chooses to employ at different prices, holding everything else
is rising reaching a maximum at point B. Because the average constant including the price of mobile telephones.
number of mobile telephones generated by both the variable and Now let us examine the market demand curve for copper.
fixed inputs is increasing throughout Stage 1, the firm will Unlike final-product market demand curves, market mineral
always try to operate beyond this stage. It turns out that in Stage demand curves are generally not the horizontal sum of individual
1, fixed inputs are under utilised. firm mineral demand curves. This is because of the derived
In Stage 2, the output of mobile telephones increases at a nature of the demand for minerals.
decreasing rate. That is, both the additional mobile telephones Changes in the market price of copper bring about changes in
generated by each additional unit of copper used and the average the cost of producing mobile telephones. When all mobile
amount of mobile telephones generated by each unit of copper telephone manufacturers experience this, there are changes in the
employed are decreasing. However, the average amount of quantity of mobile telephones available in the market and their
mobile telephones generated by the fixed inputs is still rising. It price. The price of mobile telephones must be held constant for
turns out that the optimum copper/mobile telephone combination horizontal summing to be appropriate. If the price of copper
will be in Stage 2. Therefore, a profit-maximising firm will increases, then the market price of mobile telephones will
always operate somewhere in Stage 2. When referring to the increase and most likely vice versa2. When this ‘final-product
effect’ is taken into account, the copper demand curve for each
individual mobile telephone manufacturer will be steeper. This
2. Arguing more broadly the outcome depends on the overall market
for mobile phones, on the degree of competition therein, on profit market demand curve will have a steeper slope than the one
margins, and on copper’s share of the costs. The rise in copper prices obtained from the unmodified individual firm copper demand
could easily be absorbed in profit margins. curves (Campbell, 1985).

40 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

We now have a view of one half of the market for minerals – extraction electro-winning (SX-EW) process. This has allowed
mineral demand. We now need briefly to look at the supply side the recovery of copper from mine tailings, as well as a higher
of the minerals market3. We can once again use the mobile percentage of metal to be ultimately recovered from orebodies.
telephone producer example and attempt to put ourselves in the The process cut the tonnes of waste per tonne of ore mined by
positions of the mineral suppliers – the copper producers. If the over 35 per cent in 1995 in comparison to 1970 (Olewiler, 2002).
price of copper increases, producers are willing to supply more However, the end result was a rightward shift in the copper
copper to the market. As a result, the mineral supply curve is supply curve, which caused the quantity demanded of copper to
positively sloped. That is, at a higher price there will be a greater increase. Therefore, a change in technology within the copper
supply of copper. If this supply information is combined with the mining industry will only shift the copper supply curve and as a
information on mineral demand we would get a diagram such as result increase the quantity of the copper demanded (see Figure
Figure 5.4, which describes the achievement of equilibrium in 5.5). But note that this change in technology has not shifted the
the mineral market. copper demand curve.

$/unit
S
$/unit S1
S2

P*

D
D
Increased
Q/period Q/period
Q* mineral
demand

FIG 5.4 - Equilibrium in a mineral market. FIG 5.5 - Shifting supply curves and increased mineral demand.

This analysis is similar to our earlier supply-demand analysis In contrast to technological change in copper mining,
for gold earrings. The market tends toward the equilibrium price technological change in a manufacturing process that uses
where mineral supply equals mineral demand. At any other price copper as an input will cause a shift in the copper demand curve.
there will be a shortage (price too low) or a surplus (price too Two types of technological changes in manufacturing may cause
high) and there will be adjustments in the price to bring the this shift:
market to equilibrium. • the refinement and improvement of existing processes, and
Shifts of the mineral demand curve • the development of new products.
The steel smelting industry provides a good example of
We have already discussed factors that shift the final-product refinement and improvement technological change. During the
demand curve in the section above. There is a parallel discussion early 1960s, technological innovation in the injection of
for the factors that shift the mineral demand curve but some of pulverised coal into blast furnaces reduced coking coal rates by
these are different from the factors that shift the final-product 36 per cent per tonne of steel. By the beginning of the 1990s
demand curve. These different factors reflect the derived nature of injection rates of coking coal had declined by an additional
the input demand curve. Three seem particularly important: 15 per cent per tonne (Mitchell, undated).
• a change in demand for the final product, When technological change permits the use of a smaller
• a change in technology, and quantity of mineral inputs to obtain a given level of output, the
final-product production function (here the production function
• a change in the mix of inputs. for steel) shifts leftward as shown in Figure 5.6 and the mineral
First, consider a change in consumer demand for the final demand curve will shift to the left.
product. As one might expect, there is a direct positive
relationship between final-product demand and mineral demand. Quantity of steel output
That is, an increase in the demand for mobile telephones will per time period
increase the demand for copper. On a graph, this translates to a
rightward shift of the mineral demand curve. A decrease in the
Production Production function
demand for mobile telephones will reduce the demand for function after before technological
copper. On a graph, this translates to a leftward shift of the technological change
mineral demand curve. change
Second, contemplate the impact of a change in technology.
The production function in Figure 5.3 assumes a constant state of
technology in both the minerals industry and the final product
industry. But within the minerals industry, changes in technology
have led to better capital equipment and processes. They have Units of coal
also reduced non-productive work hours. For example, a major per time period
innovation in the copper industry has been in the solvent
FIG 5.6 - Technological change shifting final-product production
3. This will be examined in more detail in Chapter 6. function.

Australian Mineral Economics 41


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Even though refinement and improvement technological such as prices and income. The concept of elasticity can, for
change directly reduced the demand for coal in the production example, help answer questions such as:
of steel, it also indirectly increased the demand for coal in steel • Will an additional unit of output make our firm more or less
production. An important result of refinement and improvement profitable?
technological change is its ability to lower the cost of delivering
an extra unit of steel to the market. This will increase the • Will this consumer’s happiness rise or fall if consumption
quantity of steel demanded which will also increase the demand changes slightly?
for coal. Other things being equal, the coal demand curve will There are three main types of elasticity of mineral demand:
shift to the right. As a consequence, the final result of refinement
and improvement technological change on a specific mineral’s • own-price elasticity of demand, which measures how the
demand curve is not always easy to assess in an accurate fashion. quantity demanded of a mineral changes if its price changes;
Technological change that develops new products can either • income elasticity of demand, which measures how the
increase or decrease the demand for a mineral. Consider some of quantity demanded of a mineral changes if income changes;
the ways this is affecting the demand for copper. Optical fibre and
cables, which are now used widely in telecommunications, have • cross-price elasticity of demand, which shows how the
replaced huge tonnages of copper wire. Comparisons indicate quantity demanded of one mineral changes if the price of
that an optical fibre can carry over a quarter of a million times another mineral changes.
more information than a similarly sized copper wire (Dulay,
2004). By contrast Power Economics (2003) estimates that new The following discussion of elasticity is separated into two
wind turbine projects to meet Kyoto Protocol targets should parts because elasticity is determined, in part, by the time period
increase copper demand in the European Union by an annual involved. After further discussion of the concepts of elasticity of
10 000 tonnes4. mineral demand, part one applies the concepts of elasticity to the
short run. Part two then shows how the elasticities of mineral
The third factor that causes the mineral demand curve to shift demand change over time and presents how economists use
is a change in the price of other inputs, which causes a change in long-run elasticities.
the mix of the inputs used. The effect of a change in the price of
one mineral, say aluminium, on the demand for another mineral, The short run is a period in which market conditions are
say copper, is also difficult to estimate in an accurate way. considered fixed. Campbell (1985) argues that a firm’s lease, its
Aluminium and copper are often used together in coaxial cable existing production capacity, employment contracts, and several
with a copper centre conductor and aluminium shield. In this use other operating conditions are inflexible in the short run.
they are complements (or complementary inputs). In other cases, The long run has no such fixed costs and conditions –
aluminium is a substitute for copper. This occurs in several everything is free to change. Given more time, manufacturers can
applications. develop new strategies for adjusting production processes such as
substituting aluminium for tin. Also consumers can adjust
When aluminium is a complement of copper, a decrease in the
personal consumption expenditures such as by purchasing motor
price of aluminium causes a rightward shift in the mineral
cars that either run on natural gas or are hybrid in their model of
demand curve for copper. An increase in the price of aluminium
operation. An important consideration between the short- and
causes a leftward shift in the copper demand curve.
long-run is that the definitions do not include a definite time
Price changes for a substitute mineral are more complicated. period. They are based on the degree of flexibility that firms have
There is a direct effect as well as an indirect effect of the price to change inputs and consumers have to change their lifestyles.
change. A higher price of aluminium destined for the electrical A consequence of these definitions is that the relevant time
industry, relative to the price of copper, results in a direct period that distinguishes the short run from the long run will vary
increase in the use of copper because copper will be substituted from industry to industry.
for aluminium. However, the higher price of aluminium may
cause copper use to decline indirectly because copper may not be
able to replace all aluminium completely. The indirect effect of Own-price elasticity of mineral demand in the
the increase in the price of aluminium is caused by the increase short run
in the cost of producing the final product, which in turn leads to The own-price elasticity of demand of a mineral is the
lower production and less demand for both aluminium and percentage by which quantity demanded changes if its price
copper. The final result of a price change for a substitute mineral increases by one per cent, all other things being equal. The
depends on which effect is larger, the direct or indirect, and simple formula is:
varies from product to product.
own-price elasticity of demand =
ELASTICITY OF MINERAL DEMAND per cent change in quantity demanded
When there are price movements along the demand curve as well per cent change in price
as shifts in demand, it is important to have an estimate of the
magnitude of those changes. Economists use the concept of Own-price elasticity of demand is negative because of the
elasticity of demand to indicate the quantitative impact of the inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded as
factors affecting demand. Even though it is a simple concept, indicated by the law of demand5. When a percentage reduction
elasticity is one of the most powerful devices that economists in price leads to a less than proportional increase in quantity
use. It is simple because it is no more than a measure that tells demanded, demand is inelastic, and when the quantity demanded
how sensitive one variable is to another. It is powerful because of changes proportionally more than the change in price, demand is
elastic. Inelastic own-price elasticity of demand is defined as a
the way economists make use of it in analysing how benefits and
value of greater than minus one, and elastic own-price elasticity
costs change as a result of small changes in specific variables
of demand is a value of less than minus one.
Generally, demand for luxury goods is price elastic. The demand
4. An average one-megawatt wind turbine contains 4.4 tonnes of copper for essential products such as petrol and food is usually inelastic.
(Power Economics, 2003). People generally buy these products even if the price goes up.
5. An alternative way to define own-price elasticity is by placing a Interestingly, demand for consumer goods such as household
negative sign before the right-hand term in the formula. This converts appliances and motor vehicles also have a high price elasticity, since
the magnitudes to positive values. people can easily find substitutes or do without them.

42 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Gold Jewellery: Petrol:


Elastic Demand Inelastic Demand
$/unit $/unit

small percentage
change in quantity
large percentage change demanded large
in quantity demanded percentage change
small percentage change in price
in price
P2 P2
P1 P1
DAu
DPetrol
Au2 Au1 QAu/period Pet2 Pet1 QPetrol/period

FIG 5.7 - Sensitivity of mineral demand to price changes.

Figure 5.7 illustrates two demand curves, one for gold In contrast, a higher gold price will cause a person to buy
jewellery and the other for petrol. From the diagram, when the fewer pairs of new gold earrings or other jewellery if their
price of gold jewellery rises from P1 to P2, the per cent change in own-price elasticity of gold is elastic. A rise of five per cent in
the quantity demanded of gold jewellery – from Au1 to Au2 – is the price of gold jewellery will cause the consumer to reduce
greater than the per cent change in price. Therefore, gold consumption of gold jewellery by more than five per cent.
jewellery is own-price elastic at point Au1. Conversely, when the A good way to examine the factors affecting the own-price
price of petrol rises from P1 to P2, the per cent change in the elasticity of the mineral demand curve is to use concepts
quantity demanded of petrol – from Pet1 to Pet2 – is less than the developed in the four Hicks-Marshall laws of derived demand –
per cent change in price. Therefore, petrol is own-price inelastic
named after their originators, John Hicks and Alfred Marshall. In
at point Pet1.
his classic treatise, Principles of Economics (published in 1890),
Before discussing the determinants of own-price elasticity of Alfred Marshall formulated four rules about the determinants of
mineral demand, it is important to understand own-price own-price elasticity of derived demand. In re-examining
elasticity in an intuitive way. Suppose our mobile telephone Marshall’s four rules, Hicks (1966) described own-price
manufacturer spends a part of its budget on copper wiring. If the elasticity of derived demand for labour in terms of
price of copper wiring rises by five per cent, the manufacturer substitutability of inputs and own-price elasticity of final-product
may buy less. But does he or she buy six per cent less or just two
demand6. While full statements of the four laws are complex,
per cent less? In the first case, demand will be own-price elastic.
brief and simplified versions of them yield valuable insights into
In the second it will be own-price inelastic. Clearly in the case of
the determinants of the own-price elasticity of mineral demand.
petrol, and most likely copper wiring, a rise of five per cent in
the price of petrol would not cause a buyer to reduce his The Hicks-Marshall laws conclude that own-price elasticity
consumption of petrol by more than five per cent. That is, there is of mineral demand, of say copper will be relatively high when:
a small effect of a price change on rates of consumption. A brief • own-price elasticity of demand for the final product is
summary of these cases is as follows: relatively high;

Copper wiring Petrol


• it is relatively easy to substitute other inputs for copper;
Case One Case Two Likely case • own-price elasticity of supply of other production inputs is
relatively high; and
Price rise 5% 5% 5%
Quantity fall 6% 2% Say 1%
• copper accounts for a relatively large share of total costs of
producing the final product.
Own-price elasticity -1.2 -0.4 -0.2
of demand Each of these laws will now be examined in turn. The first
Hicks-Marshall law states that own-price elasticity of mineral
Result Elastic Inelastic Highly
demand demand inelastic
demand will be elastic when own-price elasticity of demand for
demand the final product is relatively high. Economists traditionally
examine the response of the mineral demand to a final-product
price change by assuming that the proportions of inputs are fixed.
The demand curves for most minerals are own-price inelastic – When the demand for the final product is own-price elastic, say
that is, steeply sloped – if considering the short run. This is -1.5, then the demand for the final product changes 50 per cent
because manufacturers and consumers who use minerals as more proportionally than the price. However, when the demand
inputs are constrained from changing by their existing plants, for the final product is own-price inelastic, say -0.5, then quantity
equipment, and vehicles. demanded of the final product changes only half as much
proportionally as the price. Therefore, when the demand for a
6. Hicks (1966, pp 241-247) provides a complete mathematical final-product is own-price elastic, there will be a greater
derivation of the four rules of derived demand. reduction in the use of all inputs.

Australian Mineral Economics 43


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Elastic Supply Inelastic Supply


$/unit $/unit

P2
S
P2
P1 P1

D D‘ D D

Q1 Q2 Q/period Q1 Q 2 Q/period

FIG 5.8 - Own-price elasticities of supply.

A good example is the use of silver in jewellery and dental The third Hicks-Marshall law states that own-price elasticity
filling alloys. The estimated own-price elasticity of demand for of mineral demand will be relatively high when the supply of
silver jewellery is highly price elastic, (Venkatesh, 2002; GFMS other factors of production is relatively own-price elastic. It is
Limited, 2004) whereas the own-price elasticity of demand for worth digressing for a moment to discuss own-price elasticity of
dental services is price inelastic (Eriksson, 2003; Grytten, 2003; supply. The responsiveness of supply to changes in price of a
Manning and Phelps, 1978)7. As the own-price elasticity of good or service is its own-price elasticity of supply as illustrated
demand for silver jewellery is relatively high, an increase in the in Figure 5.8. The definition of own-price elasticity of supply is
price of silver jewellery will result in a large reduction in the the percentage by which a product’s quantity supplied would
quantity of silver jewellery demanded. This will cause a large change if its price increased by one per cent, all other things
reduction in the supply of silver jewellery and in turn cause a equal. The simple formula is:
large reduction in the use of silver. Therefore, an increase in the
own-price elasticity of supply =
price of silver jewellery will result in a large reduction in the
quantity of silver demanded for silver jewellery. By contrast, an per cent change in quantity supplied
increase in the price of silver dental fillings will result in only a per cent change in price
small reduction in the quantity of silver demanded for silver
dental filling alloys. When supply is relatively inelastic, a change in demand affects
The second Hicks-Marshall law states that own-price the price more than the quantity supplied. The reverse is the case
elasticity of mineral demand is elastic when it is relatively easy when supply is relatively elastic – a change in demand is met
to substitute other inputs to replace the mineral under with a small change in market price.
consideration. One measure of substitutability between inputs The Hicks-Marshall third law examines the case with which a
considers how much input proportions change when the price of mineral can be substituted by other inputs. From the discussion
one of the inputs, say copper, changes, holding output of the final of the second Hicks-Marshall law it can be seen that substitution
product fixed. When it is easy to substitute other inputs for between a mineral and other inputs generally depends on
copper, a small change in relative price of copper will cause a technology and relative prices. However, substitution of one
large change in the proportion of the inputs used. On the other mineral for another can also be affected by spare capacity in an
hand, when it is difficult to substitute other inputs for copper, a input industry as well as the level of stocks or inventories of the
small change in the price of copper is probably not going to other inputs. If there is plenty of spare capacity with the
cause a firm to replace a unit of copper with a unit of another availability of another input or if the stocks of this input are high,
input. a manufacturer will find it more beneficial to substitute this other
Decisions about the substitution between a mineral and other input for copper, all other things being equal.
inputs depend on two general factors, technology and relative Spare capacity and high level of stocks correspond to elastic
prices. Different combinations of inputs will produce different supply. If the price of copper increased and the supply of another
levels of output. How a manufacturer combines copper and the input, say molybdenum, was own-price elastic, the increase in
remaining inputs reflects the technology available. demand for molybdenum would have little effect on its price.
An example of the second Hicks-Marshall law is naturally A manufacturer may significantly increase his profits by using
occurring rutile being substituted by synthetic rutile (which is more molybdenum and less copper.
produced from ilmenite) in the titanium dioxide white pigment, However, if the supply for the other input, say aluminium, was
metal and welding-rod coatings markets (Consolidated Rutile inelastic, an increase in demand for aluminium would
Limited, 2004). As it is relatively easy to substitute synthetic substantially increase its price and the additional quantity of
rutile for naturally occurring rutile, a price increase in naturally aluminium supplied to the market would be small. In this case, a
occurring rutile could result in a large reduction in the quantity manufacturing firm would not increase profits by increasing its
demanded of it. use of aluminium and decreasing its use of copper.
A good example for the third Hicks-Marshall law is the
7. In their study of the USA, Manning and Phelps estimated that situation of heavy machinery manufacturing in the Former Soviet
own-price elasticity for dental visits was -0.7. Union (FSU). One of the impacts of inefficient Soviet central

44 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

planning was that industry became heavily dependent on energy elasticities of demand. These are a direct result of high income
priced far below world levels (Platts, 2004; European Bank of elasticities of demand for the final products in which minerals
Reconstruction and Development, 2002). Since the start of are used as inputs. These final products – things such as motor
transition, energy consumption has fallen principally as the result cars, houses and refrigerators – are items that consumers are
of the severe decline in output in the early 1990s. For example, more inclined to buy during economic upturns. Purchases of
Kazakhstan’s net energy consumption decreased by 45 per cent these durable goods (often known also as discretionary goods)
between 1992 and 1998 (United States Energy Information usually increase when consumers feel wealthier.
Administration, 2003). At present there is abundant excess However, some minerals such as crude oil and industrial
capacity in electricity generation in many former republics of the minerals have income elasticities between zero and one. Such
former Soviet Union. As a result the supply of electricity is quite goods are called income inelastic. The demand for these and
elastic. If there was a large increase in demand for electricity in other necessities tend to be relatively less income elastic than the
the FSU, it would result in a large increase in electricity use and demand for discretionary products. Consider, for instance the
a relatively small increase in price. demand for residential electricity as compared to gold jewellery9.
By contrast, when the supply of electricity is relatively Purchasing gold jewellery is more discretionary than purchasing
inelastic, as recently in Australia, an increase in the demand electricity for home use. Accordingly, we expect the demand for
drives up its price by a relatively large amount but has a electricity to be income inelastic and the demand for gold
relatively small effect on the quantity of electricity used by jewellery to be income elastic (see Figure 5.9).
industry (Brennan, 2002). When this occurs, the increase in the
price of electricity limits the amount of additional electricity that Quantity Quantity
can be used as a substitute for a mineral. Therefore, a demanded demanded
manufacturer in the FSU may experience elastic demand for
Normal good: Normal good:
some minerals whereas a manufacturer in Australia may income elastic income inelastic
experience inelastic demand for the same minerals.
The fourth Hicks-Marshall law states that own-price elasticity
of demand for a mineral is relatively large when the mineral
accounts for a relatively large share of total costs. In this situation,
a price increase of the mineral will have a large effect on a
manufacturer’s costs and therefore a large effect on the price of the
final product. With this large increase in the price of the final Income/period Income/period
product, the decrease in the quantity of the final product
demanded would be large and, consequently, the reduction in the FIG 5.9 - Income elasticities of demand.
mineral’s use would also be large, all other things being equal.
Therefore, an increase in a given mineral’s share of total costs will
result in a higher own-price elasticity of demand for this mineral. Resource economists commonly apply the concept of income
The use of aluminium and palladium in motor cars explain the elasticity of demand to analyse the effect of changes in national
ideas in the fourth Hicks-Marshall law. In 2003, a typical family income levels – using measures such as Gross Domestic Product
car contained 124 kilograms of aluminium and between three (GDP) – on the demand for minerals. For example, how do
and four grams of palladium (Corbett, 2003; Johnson Matthey, changes in national income influence iron ore demand? The
2004). If palladium costs account for 0.25 per cent of total year-to-year instability in mineral demand is due, in part, to the
automobile costs, a doubling of its price will only increase the strong link between it and the state of countries’ economies,
total cost of an automobile by about 0.25 per cent. On the especially investment expenditures. Large fluctuations in
contrary, if aluminium costs account for 1.5 per cent of total investment are often considered the driving force of business
costs, a doubling of its price will increase total costs by 1.5 per cycles – fluctuations of GDP over time. Expansions and booms
cent. As a result, aluminium has a higher own-price elasticity of are generally characterised by high levels of investment,
demand vis-à-vis palladium for the automobile industry8. whereas, in troughs there are generally low levels of investment.
During economic downturns mineral demand is commonly low
Income elasticity of mineral demand in the short as investment spending on buildings and structures,
term transportation equipment, heavy machinery and consumer
durables has fallen away. Conversely, mineral demand tends to
Income elasticity of demand is a measure of the sensitivity of be high during economic upturns as the consumption of capital
demand to changes in consumers’ income. It is the percentage by goods and consumer durables swells. This pattern suggests that,
which demand will change if consumer income changes by one at least in the short term, mineral demand in most developed
per cent, all other things being equal. Its simple formula is: countries is highly income elastic.
income elasticity of demand = For mineral producing countries, such as Australia, a high
short-term income elasticity of mineral demand has notable
per cent change in quantity demanded implications. Generally, this causes the mineral demand curve to
per cent change in income shift sharply over the business cycle prompting mineral output,
prices, revenues and profits to fluctuate greatly (Pei and Tilton,
For most products, as income rises, demand increases. Goods 1999). The resulting volatility can have significant impact on a
and services with income elasticities more than one are called country’s management of its macroeconomy because of sudden
income elastic. Many minerals possess relatively high income swings in exchange rates and in tax revenues from the mining
sector (Humphreys, 2000).
8. Palladium and platinum are close substitutes for one another in the In addition, because Australia is a commodity exporter and an
production of automobile capacitors. A rise in its price has often importer of consumer durables and investment goods, its
caused massive substitution between these two metals. This is not the economy does not always conform to the general country-level
effect, however, described in the above example. models. Australia’s mineral sector is to a great extent linked with
9. Relevant empirical studies show that non-monetary demand for gold is the manufacturing, construction and transportation sectors of
income elastic and the demand for residential electricity is strongly other countries. Gruen and Shuetrim (1994) found that a one per
income inelastic (eg Bernard et al, 1996; Veneroso and Costelloe, 2002). cent change in GDP levels in OECD10 member nations led to a

Australian Mineral Economics 45


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

1.2 per cent increase in Australian GDP. As a result, the linkage palladium, is sensitive to the prices of gold, silver, and palladium
between income levels and the demand for minerals in the case (Gillett’s Jewellers, 2004). Therefore, if the price of palladium
of Australia should be examined at a multi-country scale. rose by 50 per cent, the demand for gold would decrease, as is
illustrated in Figure 5.10.
Cross-price elasticity of mineral demand in the Cross-price elasticity of demand is a common analytical tool
short term to identify markets in anti-trust inquiries. By examining the
cross-price elasticity of demand it is possible to measure how
It is also possible to use the concept of elasticity to indicate the much a firm can raise its prices without consumers defecting to
effect of price changes in related products. The relevant concept some substitute and other firms altering their production
here is cross-price elasticity of demand. For example, the processes and supplying similar products at lower prices. If there
cross-price elasticity of demand relates the percentage change in are close substitutes, then the price increase initiated by the firm
quantity demanded for a mineral with the percentage change in will lead to a large reduction in its sales and its profits will fall as
the price of another product, all other things being equal. The a consequence.
simple formula is: The 1956 US anti-trust case against Du Pont is a classic
cross-price elasticity of demand = example of the use of cross-price elasticity of demand. Du Pont
argued that cellophane was not a separate market, since, at
per cent change in quantity demanded of good ' A'
prevailing prices, there appeared to be a high cross-price
per cent change in price of good ' B' elasticity of demand between it and aluminium foil, wax paper
and polyethylene. This meant that what seemed to be a single
The cross-price elasticity of demand can be positive or seller or monopoly of the cellophane market looked like a much
negative, depending on whether we observe a change in the price more modest share of something that might be called ‘the
of a substitute or a complement. If two minerals are substitutes, wrappings market’. The court found that Du Pont did not have
an increase in the price of one will increase the demand for the monopoly power despite control of 100 per cent of the
other, so the cross-price elasticity would be positive. For cellophane market because cellophane made up only 20 per cent
example, gold and platinum are substitutes in the jewellery of the wrappings market (Cueller, 2000).
market. This is shown by the six per cent increase in the
consumption of gold jewellery in China during 2003 which was,
in part, caused by the 40 per cent increase in the price of Elasticity of mineral demand in the long run
platinum (Bailey, 2004; Johnson Matthey, 2004; World Gold Because minerals are inputs in durable and non-durable final
Council, 2004a)11. Figure 5.10 illustrates a positive cross-price products – from construction of buildings to the manufacture of
elasticity of demand for gold with respect to platinum. prescription drugs – it is important to discuss the effect of
By contrast, if two minerals are complements, an increase in adjustment time on the elasticities of mineral demand. Because
the price of one will reduce the demand for the other; therefore, economists generally examine only long-run own-price and
the cross-price elasticity would be negative. The demand of income elasticities of mineral demand12, the discussion in this
18-carat white gold, which is an alloy made by mixing 75 per section is limited to these concepts.
cent gold with 25 per cent other metals, such as silver and A significant percentage of industrial minerals is used in
non-durable final products. These include clays in animal
$/unit feedstuffs and medicines, as well as limestone in paper.
Price of palladium, a Price of platinum, a Generally, for non-durable final products, the longer the time
complement mineral, substitute mineral, rises. that buyers have to adjust, the larger will be the response to a
rises. Demand for gold Demand for gold increases. price change. Accordingly, the demand for such goods will be
decreases. Negative Positive cross-price more own-price elastic in the long run than in the short run.
cross-price elasticity of elasticity of demand
Figure 5.11 illustrates the short and long run demand for a
demand non-durable good.
A non-durable final product worth highlighting is petrol. To
the extent that petrol has no short run substitutes, the short run
demand is relatively own-price inelastic. The short run effect of
price changes on the quantity demanded will work through
discouraging people from purchasing an additional car or driving
to work. Over time, however, they will purchase more
$/unit
D1 D2
D0

Quantity of gold/period

FIG 5.10 - Cross-price elasticity of demand.

10. The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development


(OECD), which has about 30 member nations.
long run
demand
11. In 2003, China accounted for approximately 18 per cent of global
demand for platinum (Johnson Matthey, 2004).
12. However, over the long run, minerals also exhibit some cross-price
responsiveness because certain equipment choice decisions include short run
the consideration of minerals, especially fuel minerals. An example demand
is the decision to use oil heaters rather than natural gas water heaters.
Thus, some equipment choices are based on more than just the price Q* Q/period
of a single mineral and result in measurable long run cross-price
elasticities. FIG 5.11 - Short and long run demand for a non-durable product.

46 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

tonnes/billion US $ of GDP
fuel-efficient automobiles and find alternative means of
transportation. Accordingly, the demand for petrol will be 30
relatively more own-price elastic in the long run. Espey (1998)
estimated that the global short- and long-term own-price 20
elasticities of petrol were -0.23 and -0.43, respectively. If this
information is combined with the first Hicks-Marshall law –
own-price elasticity of mineral demand will be elastic when 10

tonnes
own-price elasticity of demand for the final product is relatively
high – then the long run own-price elasticity of demand for crude 0
oil, which is used as an input in petrol, will be higher than the 0 1000 2000 3000 4000
short run own-price elasticity of demand for crude oil.
Per capita GDP (US $)
Even though many minerals are used in the manufacturing of
non-durable final products, the predominant use of minerals, FIG 5.12 - Intensity-of-use curve.
especially metals, is as inputs in the manufacturing of durable
final products, such as motor cars and new homes. The effect of
adjustment time on the demand for many durable final products incomes rise. At low levels of development (low levels of per
is different than for non-durable final products. Similar to capita GDP), when subsistence agriculture predominates, mineral
non-durable final products, durable final products are more use tends to be minimal. Urbanisation and industrialisation propel
own-price elastic in the long run than in the short run as buyers an increase in mineral demand to build basic infrastructure such as
need time to adjust to new prices. However, an opposing effect roads, railways, bridges, factories, pipelines and power grids. As
development continues and per capita GDP increases further, the
can lead final-product demand to be relatively more elastic in the
need for basic infrastructure declines (the replacement frequency
short run. This opposing effect is especially strong for large
for basic infrastructure is very low) and consumer demand shifts
changes in income. That is, the income elasticity of demand for increasingly towards services and non-durable final products,
some durable final products tends to be greater in the short run which are less mineral-intensive. The transition from a
than in the long run. As a consequence, the income elasticity of manufacturing-based economy to a service-based economy slows
demand for minerals used in some durable final products is likely and eventually reverses the trend of consumption of minerals as a
to be higher in the short run than in the long run. function of income.
A second example involving motor vehicles illustrates that the The material composition of products refers to the amount of
adjustment time for durable final products is somewhat different minerals used to produce particular goods or services. Changes
to that for non-durable final products. Commonly, people in the material composition of products are driven by material
purchase new cars at intervals of several years. Now, suppose substitution and technological advancement. One major caveat of
that there is a fall in income. Some buyers will defer their plans the relationship shown in Figure 5.11 is that per capita GDP is
to replace their cars, keeping their present model a little longer. not a reasonable proxy for the underlying forces (technological
Therefore, a decrease in income will cause purchases of new cars progress) that determine the trend in changes in the material
to fall, all other things being equal. In the long run, buyers composition of products. This trend is more likely correlated
eventually need to replace their cars and the effect of a decrease with time than with income. As a result, the inverted U-shape is
in income may be minimal. As a result, a decrease in income will not stable, but rather typically shifts downward over time
cause demand for minerals used in motor cars to decrease more (Guzman, Takashi and Tilton, 2005). Therefore, there is no
sharply in the short run than in the long run. Similarly, if income simple relationship between long run mineral demand and
rises, people will replace their automobiles more frequently. income. The true relationship is complicated by a complex
Therefore, an increase in income will tend to cause demand for interaction between price differences between materials,
minerals used in cars to increase more sharply in the short run technological change, material life-cycles, consumer tastes,
than in the long run. changes in lifestyle and other such factors (Campbell, 1985).
Consequently, the difference between short and long run The Japanese economy provides a clear example of a change
elasticities of demand for minerals used in durable products in the product composition of income. In 1984, for every
depends on the interaction between the time needed to adjust to inflation-adjusted billion yen of industrial production, Japan
the new final-product prices and the replacement frequency for consumed only 60 per cent of the raw materials that were
the final products. consumed for the same volume of industrial production in 1973
We have just seen how time can affect the elasticities of (Drucker, 1986). This trend corresponds to the switching away
mineral demand. Now let us examine if the nature of income from heavily material-intensive products to more high-
elasticity of mineral demand over the long run can help make technology products.
long-range forecasts about the demand for minerals. It was The change in the material composition of products is clearly
concluded above that economic booms tend to increase the visible with the trend towards more use of aluminium and
demand for minerals in the short run; however, prolonged plastics and less steel in motor cars. In 1960, an average
economic growth – that is, continual increases in Gross automobile consisted of two per cent aluminium and one per cent
Domestic Product – can correspond with a decrease in the plastics, while in 1986 these percentages had increased to four
demand for minerals per person in the very long run. per cent for aluminium and seven per cent for plastics
Industry analysts commonly make mineral demand forecasts (Kandelaars and van Dam, 1998). The substitution of aluminium
by examining a mineral’s intensity-of-use. Intensity-of-use and plastics for steel in automobiles has caused a reduction in the
reflects the demand for a mineral (usually measured in physical use of steel per automobile produced.
units like tonnes) per unit of income discounted over time for
inflation (usually measured in billion dollars of gross domestic
product). In general, a country’s intensity-of-use of a mineral CONCLUSIONS
follows an inverted U-shape when plotted against per capita gross As identified earlier, most minerals are demanded as inputs for
domestic product. Figure 5.12 shows a representative curve. final products such as motor vehicles, buildings, transportation
Tilton (2003) identifies two factors that cause this U-shape for infrastructure, mobile telephones, jewellery and so forth. As a
intensity-of-use curves They are changes in the product result, there are characteristics of mineral demand that are
composition of income and changes in the material composition different from usual final-product demand. In particular, mineral
of products. The product composition of income mix change demand is strongly dependent on existing production technologies
occurs because of changes in consumer preferences as per capita and competing and complementary inputs of production.

Australian Mineral Economics 47


CHAPTER 5: MINERAL DEMAND — THE THEORY IN PRACTICE

Furthermore, the demand for minerals depends on changes in Gillett’s Jewellers, 2004. White gold versus platinum: white gold and
demand for final products, changes in technology and changes in platinum information [online]. Available from: <http://www.gilletts.
the mix of inputs. com.au>. Date accessed: 5 August 2004.
Discussion in this chapter has also demonstrated that elasticity Gruen, D and Shuetrim, G, 1994. Internationalisation and the
macroeconomy, in Proceedings International Integration of the
of mineral demand is important from the standpoint of
Australian Economy (eds: P Lowe and J Dwyer) pp 309-363
understanding the magnitude of changes in mineral demand (Reserve Bank of Australia: Sydney). Available from:
caused by changes in price, income and the prices of related <http://www.rba.gov.au/PublicationsAndResearch/Conferences/1994
products. The short run demand for most minerals is own-price /GruenShuetrim.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
inelastic because manufacturers and consumers who use minerals Grytten, J, 2003. Models for financing dental care [online]. Available from:
as inputs are constrained by their existing plants, equipment, and <http://www.odont.uio.no/om/iko/samfunnsodontologi/forskning/Jyv
vehicles. Also, the short run demand for most minerals is highly askyla_Grytten_shv.ppt>. Date accessed: 3 August 2004.
income elastic. These high elasticities are a direct result of high Guzman, J I, Takashi, N and Tilton, J E, 2005. Trends in the intensity of
income elasticities of demand for final products in which copper use in Japan since 1960, Resources Policy, 30(1):21-27.
minerals are used as inputs. The combination of short-run Hicks, J R, 1966. The Theory of Wages, second edition (St Martin’s Press:
inelastic own-price elasticity of demand and elastic income New York).
elasticity of demand results in many minerals having steeply Humble, L, 2004. Platinum, at 24-year-high, seen peaking as jewellery
sloped demand curves that experience significant shifts over the demand drops, Bloomberg, 21 March.
business cycle. Two important consequences of these features are Humphreys, D, 2000. Mining as a sustainable economic activity, paper
severe fluctuations in the market prices of minerals and profits presented at the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
for mineral industry firms. Development (OECD), Paris, 9 February.
To complete the discussion of elasticity of mineral demand it Johnson Matthey, 2004. Platinum 2004 [online]. Available from:
is important to examine the effects of time. Own-price elasticities <http://www.platinum.matthey.com/publications/1084795390.html>.
Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
of mineral demand tend to be greater over the long term because
buyers have more time to adjust their behaviour. Also, the Kandelaars, P and van Dam, J D, 1998. An analysis of variables
income elasticity of demand for some minerals – those used as influencing the material composition of automobiles, Research
Memorandum 1998-51S (Amsterdam Free University).
inputs in durable final products – are likely to be more income
elastic in the short run than in the long run. Kitco, 2004. What really drives the gold price? Dropping supplies the
trigger for higher prices? Part 2 [online]. Available from: <http://www.
Finally, this chapter has demonstrated that the demand for kitco.com/reports/am/am_jul07_2004.pdf>. Date accessed: 23 July
minerals is multifaceted. Understanding the demand side of the 2004.
mineral markets is essential for both analysts and policymakers Manning, W G and Phelps C E, 1978. Dental care demand: point
so that they can understand the economic implications of estimates and implications for national health insurance, Rand
changes in mineral markets. Corporation Document No R-2157-HEW.
Marshall, A, 1920. Principles of Economics, eighth edition (Macmillan:
REFERENCES London) [online]. Available from: <http://www.econlib.org/library/
Marshall/marP1.html>. Date accessed: 20 September 2004.
Bailey, S, 2004. Speculators will drive platinum market [online]. Available Mill, J S, 1863. Utilitarianism [online]. Available from: <http://www.
from: <http://www.mineweb.net/sections/platinum/323433.htm>. utilitarianism.com/mill1.htm>. Date accessed: 20 July 2004.
Date accessed: 5 August 2004.
Mitchell, G D, undated. Coal utilization in the steel industry [online].
Bernard, J-T, Bolduc, D and Belanger, D, 1996. Quebec residential Available from: <http://www.steel.org/AM/Template.cfm?Section=
electricity demand: A microeconometric approach, Canadian Journal Home&template=/CM/HTMLDisplay.cfm&ContentID=12302>.
of Economics, 29(1):92-113. Date accessed: 6 May 2006.
Brennan, T, 2002. Checking for market power in electricity: the perils of Olewiler, N, 2002. Natural capital and technological change: impacts on
price-cost margins [online]. From: <http://www.ipa.org.au/pubs/ productivity growth and natural resource and environmental
Moranwebpapers/brennan.pdf>. sustainability, Simon Fraser University working paper.
Campbell, G A, 1985. Theory of mineral demand, in Economics of the
Pei, F and Tilton, J E, 1999. Consumer preferences, technological change
Mineral Industries (ed: W A Vogely) (American Institute of Mining,
and the short-run income elasticity of metal demand, Resources
Metallurgy and Petroleum Engineers: New York).
Policy 25:87-109.
Consolidated Rutile Limited, 2004. Downstream processing [online].
Platts, 2004. Country profiles – Kazakhstan [online]. Available from:
Available from: <http://www.consrutile.com.au/aboutcrl/dwnstream.
<http://www.platts.com/Electric%20Power/Resources/News%20Feat
asp> Date accessed: 28 November 2004.
ures/worldcap/kazakprofile.html>. Date accessed: 5 August 2004.
Corbett, B, 2003. ‘04 breakthrough year for aluminum usage in
Power Economics, 2003. Copper going for Kyoto gold, Power Economics,
automobiles, Ward’s Auto World, 1 September 2003.
7(1):8.
Cueller, S S, 2000. Is Microsoft a monopoly? Sonoma State University
Tilton, J E, 2003. On Borrowed Time? Assessing the Threat of Mineral
working paper.
Depletion (Resources for the Future: Washington DC).
Drucker, P F, 1986. The changed world economy, Foreign Affairs,
United States Energy Information Administration, 2003. Kazakhstan
63(4):768-791.
country analysis brief [online]. Available from: <http://www.
Dulay, N, 2004. Fiber optic interconnections within computer systems eia.doe.gov/emeu/cabs/kazak.html>. Date accessed: 5 August 2004.
[online]. Available from: <http://www.doc.ic.ac.uk/~nd/surprise_97/ Veneroso, F and Costelloe, D, 2002. Gold derivatives, gold lending,
journal/vol3/si1/answer.html>. Date accessed: 1 September 2004. official management of the gold price and the current state of the
Eriksson, R, 2003. The effects of deregulating prices for dental services, gold market, paper presented at Fifth International Gold Symposium,
Swedish Institute for Social Research working paper. Lima, Peru, 17 May.
Espey, M, 1998. Gasoline demand revisited: An international Venkatesh, R, 2002. India’s consuming interest in silver, Alchemist, 28. The
meta-analysis of elasticities, Energy Economics, 20(3):273-295. London Bullion Market Association (LBMA) [online] Available from:
European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, 2002. Transition <http://www.lbma.org.uk/publications/alchemist/alch28_india.pdf>.
Report 2001: Energy in transition (European Bank of Reconstruction Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
and Development: London). World Gold Council, 2004a. WGC reports gold consumer demand up Q1
Fuerbringer, J, 2003. Gold rush may continue, but with tempered 2004 [online]. Available from: <http://www.gold.org/pr_archive/pdf/
expectations, New York Times, 26 November. supply_demand010604.pdf>. Date accessed: 24 July 2004.
GFMS Limited, 2004. Platinum and palladium survey 2004 [online]. World Gold Council, 2004b. Liberalization of the China gold market:
Available from: <http://www.gfms.co.uk/media_centre_press_ implications for the gold sector, paper presented at Australian Gold
releases_2004.htm>. Date accessed: 3 August 2004. Conference, Perth, Australia, 19 April.

48 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 6

Mineral Supply — Exploration, Production, Processing


and Recycling
Philip Maxwell

Some Introductory Remarks


Resources and Reserves
Mineral Supply – Individual Products, Main Products, Co-Products and By-Products
Key Determinants of New Mineral Supply
Secondary Materials – The Economics of Recycling
Total Mineral Supply

SOME INTRODUCTORY REMARKS • The short run – as a time when mining companies ‘have
time to vary their output but not their capacity’.
Chapter 1 quoted from MacKenzie (1987), who noted the
importance of geological endowment in influencing the supply of • The long run – as a period when ‘new mines can be
minerals. Mineral deposits are: developed and processing facilities built’ and ‘firms can also
expand the capacity of existing operations’.
• initially unknown (they must be discovered and there is a
cost involved in doing this); • The very long run – as a period in which the ‘constraint
imposed by existing known... deposits no longer holds and
• fixed in size (they are a finite stock and with depletion are firms have the time to conduct exploration and find new
eventually exhaustible);
deposits. New technology induced by the exhaustion of
• variable in quality between and within deposits (this is known deposits and higher metal prices may also permit the
determined by grade, depth of deposit, mineralogy and other exploitation of new types of deposits’.
factors); and
A conceptual diagram showing the relations between these
• fixed in location (geological factors have often created these periods appears in Figure 6.1.
deposits in remote locations and they need to be moved to
intermediate and end-use markets).
Chapter 1 also highlighted that it is common practice to Immediate Short Long
classify mineral commodities into three categories – metals, run run run Very
non-metals and energy minerals. There are approximately 40 long run
metals, 40 non-metals and seven or eight energy minerals (see
Table 1.2). Also noted was that it is possible to recycle metals
and some non-metallic minerals from old-scrap and new-scrap
sources. This has the effect of postponing, and possibly even
preventing, their eventual depletion.
Despite consistently increasing consumption over the past
century, the issue of adequate mineral supply has been a
relatively infrequent source of concern. Where such discussions
about mineral supply have occurred, they typically take place
from both short-term and long-term perspectives.

Short-run and long-run supply Output Capacity Constraint of Quantity


constraint constraint current reserves (tonnes per period)
Using a standard textbook approach, Tilton (1985, pp 395-399)
defines the following periods:
• The immediate run – as an interval so short that mining FIG 6.1 - An interpretation of the relevance of different time
companies ‘do not have time to alter their rate of production’. periods to mineral supply.

Australian Mineral Economics 49


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

Mineral supply has often been an issue in wartime, during The world’s mineral stock is also affected by new discoveries,
strikes, and in periods of high mineral prices such as that in the by technological advancements in mineral processing that make
1970s when the OPEC cartel constrained world oil supply. previously uneconomic deposits profitable, and by variations in
Whenever oil and other mineral prices rise to high levels, as has prices, which may add to or reduce the size of current mineral
been the case in 2004 and 2005, commentators also become reserves.
concerned. Generally, however, they seldom debate this issue in
an active way because mineral prices have remained rather stable Supply curves
or have moved lower in real terms1. This has happened in large
part because geologists have utilised advancing technology to In addition to geological endowment, a variety of other factors
also influence mineral supply. They include whether a mineral is
ensure that mineral reserves remain at manageable levels, mining
an individual product or joint product, the price of the mineral,
methods have become more efficient and there have been major
input costs, transport costs, government policy, institutional
technical developments in mineral processing.
efficiency, technological change, the impact of strikes and other
The issue of mineral supply in the very long run has attracted disruptions and market structure.
even less attention over the past two centuries. Some notable The familiar supply curve framework is utilised to explain the
contributors have been Jevons in his 1865 Essay on the Coal relevance and importance of the above key determining factors.
Question, and more recently commentators such as Meadows and Students in Economics Principles classes learn about supply
‘The Limits to Growth’ school in the early 1970s. Authors such functions and curves in the early weeks of their course. The
as Tilton (2003) and Krautkraemer (1998) provide useful surveys typical initial presentation of supply is as an upward sloping
of the associated discussion. Perhaps the most notable theoretical curve on a diagram such as Figure 6.2, where price per unit is
contribution has been by Hotelling (1931) in his paper, The plotted on the vertical axis and quantity produced per period is
Economics of Exhaustible Resources. on the horizontal axis. As prices rise, producers will be
Given the state of current technology, there is a general encouraged to produce more because it is profitable to do so. As
consensus that the world has enough minerals for the next 50 price falls, they will produce less.
years. After that, the situation seems less clear. In his recent In this presentation, price is a variable and all of the other
analysis of this issue, Tilton (2003) argues that four groups of factors that affect the quantity supplied are held constant. If their
factors will influence the situation: geology, the demand for values change, the supply curve will shift to the left or right as in
primary mineral commodities, and changes in technology and Figure 6.2b.
input costs.
While acknowledging this broad debate, the main focus of this RESOURCES AND RESERVES
chapter is more concerned with the short run and the long run,
seeking to highlight the distinct features of mineral supply in At any given time, the level of estimated resources and reserves
these periods and, in conjunction with the preceding discourse on provides a benchmark for the status of mineral supply.
mineral demand by Peter Howie, building the foundations for the Discussion will now begin from this base, before considering the
discussion of mineral market outcomes described by Phillip nature of mineral supply using the above supply curve model.
Crowson in the next chapter.
Price
S
The mineral supply process
A simple view of new mineral supply, following MacKenzie P2
(1987), is to see it as a process involving exploration, project
development, mining, processing and transportation to the
market. The flow of minerals supplied in a given period
P1
generally involves the depletion of a finite mineral stock. One
can view this in terms of the following equation that shows the
relationship between current mineral reserves, new mineral
S
supply, recycled materials and additions to stocks from new
discoveries, technological change or changes in prices.
Q1 Q2 Quantity per
Mineral = Mineral - New mineral + Amount of mineral A time period
reserves reserves consumption recycled last
this period last period last period period
+ New mineral S1
reserves Price
S
discovered or
available last S2
period

P1
While the world’s minerals are fixed in supply and technically
non-renewable, it is possible to recycle many of them.
Significant percentages of current supplies of metals such as
aluminium, copper, nickel, lead and zinc come from the S1 S S2
recycling of old and new scrap. If the demand for a mineral falls
away, it is even conceivable that recycled materials could meet
all new mineral demand and it would not be necessary to produce Q1 Q Q2 Quantity per
newly mined material. B time period

1. See, for example, Peter Howie’s estimates of Real Prices for Selected FIG 6.2 - A typical supply curve. (A) Price changes and quantity
Mineral Commodities, 1870-1997 in Tilton (2003). changes, and (B) changes in other factors and quantity changes.

50 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

Mining companies publish information about the mineral The information in Figure 6.3 outlines ‘the framework for
reserves and resources associated with their projects, while classifying tonnage and grade estimates so as to reflect different
national agencies such as the United States Geological Survey, the levels of geological confidence and different degrees of technical
British Geological Survey and Geoscience Australia2 generate and economic evaluation’. Because the geological and modifying
parallel estimates for individual nations and the world as a whole. factors change on an almost continuous basis, statements of
Reasonably standard definitions of resources and reserves reserves and resources regularly change.
(Tilton, 2003, p 19) are as follows: It is interesting to consider further the relationship of a
Reserves are those ‘quantities of a mineral commodity in framework for resources and reserves such as the JORC Code, to
a supply curve model for newly mined minerals. The diagrams in
subsurface deposits, that are known and profitable to exploit,
Figure 6.4 illustrate one attempt to do this. They are adapted
given existing technology and prices,’ while:
from the work of Chavez-Martinez (1983), as reported in Harris
Resources include reserves, together with deposits that are: (1985). Looking at Figure 6.4a, it can be seen that in a given
• economic but not yet discovered; or period, the market will clear at a price of P1, where q1 of the
mineral, say copper or iron ore, is mined and produced. This
• expected to become economic as a result of new technology corresponds in Figure 6.4b to the marked amounts of cumulative
or other developments within the foreseeable future. production and current reserves.
The major mineral producing nations use their own generally At current levels of technology and factor (input) prices,
similar definitions of resources and reserves. While the most increments to new supply are possible with new capital
common classification system is probably the McKelvey ‘Box’ investment but only at higher prices. These are shown in
of the United States Geological Survey, the JORC Code is the Figure 6.4c. Technological advancement in exploration, mining
standard in use in Australia. This is the product of a collaborative methods, mineral processing and recycling, as well as changes to
effort within the Joint Ore Reserves Committee of The mineral demand, will affect the level of reserves and potential
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, the Australian future supply. In a JORC view of the world, only proved mineral
Institute of Geoscientists and the Minerals Council of Australia. reserves appear in the ‘Reserves’ rectangle.
Details of the code appear in JORC (2004).
MINERAL SUPPLY – INDIVIDUAL PRODUCTS,
2. A relevant recent reference is to Geoscience Australia (2004). MAIN PRODUCTS, CO-PRODUCTS AND
BY-PRODUCTS
Their geological occurrence is such that sometimes it is
Exploration results profitable only to recover one mineral commodity (an individual
product) from the material mined or drilled. In Australia’s major
mining regions, companies produce bauxite, coal, gold, iron ore
Mineral Resources Ore Reserves and diamonds as individual products. Some of the less
fashionable minerals such as many construction materials,
Inferred gypsum, limestone, salt and talc also are extracted in this way.
Increasing level On other occasions, there is joint production. Here miners
of geological
knowledge and Indicated Probable extract mineral commodities as main products, co-products or
confidence by-products. It is important to appreciate the meanings of each
Measured Proved
of these terms.
Following Tilton (1985, p 393):
a main product is so important to the economic
Consideration of mining, metallurgical, economics, marketing, viability of a mine that its price alone determines
legal, environmental, social and government factors a mine’s output; and
(the “modifying factors ”)
a by-product …. is so unimportant, its price has
no influence on mine output; and
FIG 6.3 - The general relationship between exploration results, when prices of two or more (minerals) affect
mineral results and ore reserves (JORC Code, 2004). output, the (minerals) are co-products.

Price Price Price

S”
S0 S1 S’

P3

P1 P2
Cumulative

D0
production

D1
Reserves

Potential
supply

q1
Quantity per Quantity of stock Changes in supply
unit time

(a) (b) (c)

FIG 6.4 - One view of current new mineral supply, mineral reserves and potential mineral supply.

Australian Mineral Economics 51


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

TABLE 6.1 price of a mineral rises, a mining company will tend to increase
Estimated value of production of Australian nickel industry 2003. its supply. When it falls, it will reduce supply. The industry will
Source: Western Australian Government (2004). respond in the same way. Where the global price of a commodity
is expressed in terms of another currency, eg United States
Mineral Value ($ million) Percentage dollars, exchange rate variations have a similar effect to
Cobalt 140 5.1 changes in price.
Platinum 4 0.1 In the short run, however, capacity constraints in existing mines
Palladium 4 0.1 will inhibit the ability of supply to increase as prices rise. A
company can employ more workers and expand its operations
Nickel 2607 94.7 within current mining tenements but its ability to increase supply
Total 2755 100.0 will be limited. With the need for regulatory approvals, and major
capital investment for mines, mills and supporting infrastructure
A good way to distinguish between these terms is to consider such capacity constraints can apply for several years.
the mining of nickel in Australia during 2003. All of Australia’s Input costs, particularly wages and energy costs, are
nickel mining currently occurs in Western Australia. As can be important factors affecting mineral commodity supply. When
seen in Table 6.1, the Western Australian Department of Industry they rise, it becomes more difficult for producers to make profits.
and Resources (Western Australian Government, 2004) reported While wage levels of mining workers are high, their relatively
that the value of nickel industry production in 2003 stood at small numbers probably make the effects of rising wages less
$2755 million. But as well as nickel, mining companies also important than changes in energy prices. These are particularly
produced platinum, palladium and cobalt at their operations. important, for example, in transforming bauxite into aluminium.
Platinum and palladium were clearly by-products. Cobalt also Producing aluminium requires so much electric power that it has
seems to be very much a by-product because it contributed only sometimes jokingly been described as ‘frozen electricity’.
about five per cent of the total value of production, even though The positive impacts of technological change on mineral
this amounted to $140 million. supply through more sophisticated mineral exploration, better
Most nickel in Western Australia comes from nickel sulfide mining methods and innovations in mineral processing have been
deposits. Yet in the mid-1990s there was considerable excitement substantial. They have more than offset the depletion of
about the potential of producing nickel and cobalt as co-products higher-grade deposits and the subsequent movement to lower
grades. With positive impacts of open cut mining and the
from dry laterite deposits at places such as Murrin Murrin,
implementation of carbon in pulp leaching and associated
Cawse and Bulong. Mining began at each of these deposits but
advances in mineral processing, it has become possible to
Murrin Murrin was the only mine producing in this way in 2003.
produce gold from deposits containing much less than one gram
It produced just over 32 000 tonnes of nickel metal in 2003 (with
per tonne. Profitable extraction was previously possible only at
a value of $437 million) and 2160 tonnes of cobalt metal (valued much higher grades.
at $58.5 million). In this mine, the value of cobalt production
A variety of disruptive events such as strikes, accidents in
was 11.8 per cent of the value of total mineral production. While
major mines, major equipment failure in mineral processing
it is an arbitrary judgment, most analysts would agree that cobalt
plants, natural disasters such as bush fires, floods and cyclones
was a by-product at Murrin Murrin in 2003. If the price of nickel (known elsewhere as hurricanes or typhoons), civil disturbances
fell by 50 per cent and the price of cobalt doubled, cobalt would or even terrorist attacks can disrupt mineral supply.
then become very much a co-product.
During 2004, for example, when the price of oil rose from
Examples which could typically be thought of are co-products around US$ 30 per barrel to US$ 55 per barrel, the disruptive
from base metal mines around places such as Mount Isa and impacts of events in Iraq were one source of concern about oil
Broken Hill. Another good example of an Australian mine where supply. Threatened supply disruption associated with strikes by
co-products are most likely to be produced is Olympic Dam. oil workers in Venezuela and Nigeria during the year added to
According to the WMC Resources website (WMC Resources, this impact.
2005), this mine produced 89 000 ounces of gold, 862 000 Canada has been the major nickel producing nation for the past
ounces of silver, 225 000 tonnes of copper and 4404 tonnes of century. Strikes by workers in its key nickel mining region
uranium in 2004. around Sudbury have disrupted world supply on several
occasions. Because such disruption tends to drive up prices,
KEY DETERMINANTS OF NEW MINERAL SUPPLY Australian producers derived considerable benefit.
Northern Australia has a cyclone season every year from about
January to April. Even though they are in remote and often quite
Individual and main products arid areas, large operating mines sometimes are badly affected by
A standard way to consider the supply function of an individual the aftermath of these major storms. This occurs unexpectedly in
mineral commodity such as coal, bauxite, iron ore, gold, and areas such as North West Queensland, the Northern Territory, the
nickel and copper when they occur as main products, is in the Pilbara, the Kimberley, and even as far south as the Goldfields
following terms: region of Western Australia.
A graphic example of the impact of disruptive events on the
Mineral = f (own price, input costs, technological change, disruptive fortunes of one mining company in the mid-1990s applied to the
supply events, government activities, market structure) large mineral sands producer, Consolidated Rutile. The firm was
forced to close its operations in Sierra Leone, when several key
operational personnel were kidnapped. About a year later, a
This specification follows Tilton (1985) and includes most of major bush fire disrupted their key operations on Stradbroke
the important influencing variables. It implicitly assumes that Island in Queensland.
there are sufficient reserves of the mineral available for
The activities of governments also have a major impact on
exploitation. mineral supply. The mineral policy of a state or nation has a
It is useful to briefly reflect on the influence of these factors. central effect on its ability to supply minerals, assuming that it
According to the standard theory of the firm, a company will has a significant mineral endowment. Hence the clear and stable
maximise its profits by producing at a point where the costs of regulatory framework in Australia has served the nation well as
the last (marginal) unit of output just offsets its price. When the far as mineral sector competitiveness is concerned. It has been

52 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

assisted by strong government support of organisations, such as TABLE 6.3


Geological Surveys that maintain significant databases and Market structure and degree of competitiveness in selected
Departments of Mines that administer the operation of the mineral industry sectors.
minerals and energy sector. In Australia, the states also collect
royalties from companies with operating mines. Number of buyers
Significant policy changes may, of course, affect this situation. Number of sellers Small Large
For example, the introduction of more stringent environmental Small Iron ore, nickel, tin Oil, many less
regulations can adversely affect mineral supply. If such significant minerals
regulations are less onerous in mineral-rich foreign political (eg lithium, platinum)
jurisdictions, the principals of resources companies will be more
Large Aluminium Gold, copper, zinc
tempted to invest in these regions. The Mabo judgment in the
Australian High Court in 1992, and the subsequent passage of
Native Title legislation in the Australian Parliament in 1993, is Economists often analyse the selling side of markets by
another recent example of how new policy may potentially computing concentration ratios and indexes. The Raw Materials
influence mineral supply. Group, based in Stockholm, has specialised in this area. Some of
The end of the colonial era in the 1960s and 1970s, was their data show how, for example, the percentage shares of iron
associated with the emergence of state-owned mining industries ore producing companies have increased over the past 30 years –
in many of the new nations. Political leaders wished to channel see Table 6.4. Yet it is also notable that rising concentration
the economic rent from the resources sector to build other parts levels have been accompanied by increasing globalisation of the
of their emerging societies. Where foreign companies operated in iron ore industry. To some extent this has mitigated against the
these nations, they often faced requirements to purchase supplies rise in market power that the concentration ratio growth suggests.
from domestic producers, or to process ores or concentrates
within the national boundaries, or both. Another common
practice was, and continues to be, the requirement to engage TABLE 6.4
citizens of the host nation in professional and managerial roles The consolidation of iron ore production 1975 to 2003.
within resource companies. Working visa limitations for Source: Ericsson (2002, 2004); Anonymous (2004).
expatriates seek to facilitate the impact of this. In several cases, a
lack of investment and human capital led to the decline of the Year Percentage share of production
mineral industry in these nations. Since 1985, more than a Western world† Largest Largest three Largest ten
hundred nations have made major changes to mineral policy to company companies companies
enhance their appeal to new mineral investment.
1975 8.0 17.2 40.8
Other favourable government policies that sometimes apply to
encourage new mineral production include commitments to build 1990 15.4 31.4 58.3
infrastructure such as roads, ports and communications systems. 1995 15.5 34.2 60.5
Another policy is to offer low interest loans. Where mines or 2001 23.2 46.2 70.2
mineral processing plants are struggling, government may also
2002 23.2 47.6 72.1
provide operating subsidies.
Market structure also has an important influence on the World
supply of individual and main products. This is a particular focus 2002 14.8 30.3 36.3
of attention in the next chapter. When there are few mineral 2003 18.2 45.9 54.2
producers, they exert greater influence on supply and price.
While the influence of state-owned mining corporations has † Difficulties in obtaining data from nations in the former Communist
declined since the early 1980s, there has been a significant trend bloc meant that world production data estimates have not been
towards greater concentration in many of the major minerals reliable until quite recently. Western world data was reported instead
sectors since the middle of the 1990s. The number of buyers is before this time. This practice reflects one of the many difficulties
also an important influence on market structure and the that professionals have faced in obtaining accurate mineral
competitive state of particular mineral markets. Few buyers tend production (and consumption) data.
also to exert large amounts of market power. Interestingly the
combination of few buyers and sellers can generate market They suggest growing market power among large producing
outcomes similar to those where there are many buyers and companies, as their percentage shares of production have risen.
sellers. The simple matrix in Table 6.2 provides a rudimentary These large producers face a number of large buyers from
view of how these influences tend to apply. different nations such as Japan and now China to negotiate iron
It is instructive to reflect on how different mineral commodities ore contracts on an annual basis. Phillip Crowson’s discussion in
have traditionally fitted into this matrix. The entries in Table 6.3 the next chapter extends the discussion of the importance of
provide some indication in this regard. It has been typical to market structure for mineral supply across the resources sector.
consider the gold and copper sectors as relatively competitive, Where producers exert large amounts of market power, they
while there are few buyers (steel mills) and few sellers (major iron tend to set prices – so called producer prices in a producer
ore companies) of iron ore. market. Such prices will typically guarantee producers a healthy
profit. They may be based on some multiple of average total
TABLE 6.2 costs of production, or alternatively on some other criterion that
Market structure and competition – a rudimentary view. will return a greater than normal profit to the producer. At the
other end of the scale lies a competitive outcome where firms are
Number of buyers price takers and adjust their output to generate optimum profit.
Number of sellers Small Large They will produce when they can make a surplus, but will cease
Small Market power on each Strong market power on operations if they cannot cover their average variable costs.
side tends to offset one selling side An alternative view regarding this standard textbook result is
another and outcomes that this is not necessarily true in the mining industry because
may be competitive of high closure costs particularly because of environmental
Large Strong market power on Competitive considerations and other factors. This has been one of the
buying side arguments about why the price of mineral commodities, such as

Australian Mineral Economics 53


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

zinc and lead, have remained so depressed over long periods, supply curve is horizontal, as is the case for producer pricing
producing an inadequate rate of return to investors. well before capacity constraints are approached, own price
As prices rise, higher cost producers will begin producing, elasticity is effectively infinite. With the passage of time, the
though production constraints apply because of: elasticity of supply tends to increase. Hence the own price
elasticity of supply will be greater in the long run than it is in the
• current output and inventory levels in the very short run; and immediate run or short run.
• mine capacity in the short run, and the size of reserves in the
long run. By-products
In the very long run, new discoveries and technologies may Because mineral by-products are so unimportant to a mine and
drive down production cost, and therefore the prices that their price has no influence on their output, their supply
producers are willing to accept. A standard view of the position functions differ from those of individual or main products.
of competitive producers (following Tilton, 1985) appears in Crowson (1998, p 81) has argued:
Figure 6.5. By contrast, firms in producer markets set prices for
That many metals and minerals are produced
given periods of time, often annually. If this is the case (again
partly or solely as by-products introduces great
following Tilton, 1985) a set of horizontal cost-based curves,
rigidities to their supply. It means that their
such as those that appear in Figure 6.6, could be expected. output will not always respond to changes in
Price Immediate Short Long
their own prices, but is often more influenced by
run run run the prices of the main products with which they
are associated.
This seems to be the case in much of the Australian industry
Very where specific mines produce more than one mineral commodity.
long run In Western Australia, for example, in 2003, payable mineral
by-products were worth an estimated A$ 173.1 million – see
Table 6.5. While this value was significant, it was less than one
per cent of the value of the state’s mineral and energy production
in that year. At mines in other parts of the country selenium and
tellurium is produced with copper, indium and germanium with
zinc, bismuth with lead, gallium with bauxite, zircon with
ilmenite, molybdenum with copper and silver with base metals.
Output Capacity Constraint of Quantity
constraint constraint current reserves (tonnes per period)
TABLE 6.5
FIG 6.5 - Mineral supply curves during different time periods in Estimated value of mineral by-products in Western Australia, 2003.
competitive markets. Source: Western Australian Government (2004).

Main or By-product Place† Value


co-products (A$ million)
Gold Copper Goldfields 8.3
Long run Nickel Cobalt Goldfields 60.2
compounds
Very long run Nickel Cobalt metal Goldfields 79.3
Short run
Nickel Palladium Coolgardie 4.0
Immediate
run
Nickel Platinum Coolgardie 4.3
Various Silver Statewide 15.4
Copper and zinc Lead Yalgoo 1.6
Total value of by-products 173.1
Output Capacity Constraint of Quantity
constraint constraint current reserves (tonnes per period)
† District, region or local government area.

FIG 6.6 - Mineral supply curves during different time periods in


producer markets. Consider, for example, the relevance of Crowson’s statement
for cobalt produced in Western Australia. Mines in the state were
These representations imply certain assumptions about the responsible for about 11 per cent of newly mined cobalt
way in which the quantity that producers supply will respond to production in 2003 – just over 5100 tonnes of the world total of
price changes. The usual way to assess such responsiveness is in 46 900 tonnes. All of this was produced in association with
terms of the elasticity of supply. This is a parallel concept to the nickel, whose production value exceeded $2.6 billion in 2003.
elasticity of demand discussed in the last chapter. In the three dry-laterite nickel operations (Murrin Murrin,
Bulong and Cawse) that produced nickel and cobalt metal as end
Economists typically focus on own price elasticity of supply. products, nickel accounted for about 85 per cent of the value of
The simple formula for this for a particular mineral in a given total production.
period (say a year) is:
Because of the relative unimportance of by-products, only the
per cent change in quantity supplied costs that are specific to their production affect their supply.
Es =
per cent change in own price Companies allocate the joint costs of producing main products
and by-products only to the main products. This means that the
Supply is elastic when Es is greater than one, and is inelastic average cost of by-product production is typically very low.
when it is less than one. As production approaches capacity It may even approach zero, if in producing the main product, the
constraints, and the mineral supply curve becomes vertical, own company naturally separates out the by-product, which requires
price elasticity of supply approaches zero. Where the mineral no further processing.

54 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

Yet the price of a by-product does influence its production in Co-products


one notable way. If the price of the by-product falls below the
production costs specific to its production per se, the producer As outlined above, when the prices of two or more minerals
will have an incentive to discard the by-product as waste rather produced by a mine affect its output, they will be co-products.
than process it to a saleable product. The price of the co-product must cover its specific production
Technological change can, of course, change the status of a costs and an appropriate share of its joint production costs with
by-product to that of a co-product or even reverse the main other co-products.
product/by-product relationship. Price movements can also have The range of factors that affect the supply of a co-product from
this effect. Consider again the situation of the Murrin Murrin a mine lies between those that influence main products and
nickel mine. In promoting this project in the mid-1990s, the by-products.
Directors of Anaconda Nickel argued that nickel and cobalt It therefore seems reasonable to argue that the mineral
would be co-products. At the time the price of cobalt stood at co-product supply function would take the following form:
over A$ 60 per kilogram, while nickel was selling for A$ 10 per
kilogram. Mineral = f (own price, co-product prices, specific co-product
Assuming 2003 production rates (32 125 tonnes of nickel co-product input costs, technological change, disruptive events,
metal and 2300 tonnes of cobalt metal), the mine would have supply government activities, market structure)
generated annual revenue of A$ 460 million in that year. About
70 per cent would have come from nickel and 30 per cent from Co-product supply curves will have a similar look to the main
cobalt. In such a scenario, most commentators would accept that product supply curves depicted in Figures 6.5 and 6.6, though the
these metals were co-products. By 2003, however, the average sharing of joint production costs may mean that they are a
price of cobalt had declined to A$ 27.50 per kilogram, while ‘pushed-down’ version of these curves until the various output,
nickel stood at A$ 13.60 per kilogram. Of the annual mine capacity and known deposit constraints are reached in the
revenue, over 87 per cent came from nickel and less than immediate run, short run and long run respectively.
13 per cent was from cobalt. Cobalt was now a by-product.
Against this background it seems reasonable to argue that the
mineral by-product supply function would take the following form:
SECONDARY MATERIALS – THE ECONOMICS OF
RECYCLING
Mineral = f (by product price, main product price, specific Newly mined minerals, which deplete finite mineral resources,
by-product by-product input costs, technological change, disruptive traditionally have made up the majority of mineral production.
supply events, government activities, market structure)
But in recent times, recycling of minerals, particularly metals,
has also become an important alternative source of supply3 . This
If one draws by-product supply curves in the usual way (see is particularly the case in developed nations where public policy
Figure 6.7) with price on the vertical axis and quantity on the makers are encouraging recycling more and more.
horizontal axis, immediate run and short run curves are initially While authoritative data about mineral recycling are not
elastic but then quite quickly inelastic as they come up against available on a world basis for all minerals, the US Geological
output and capacity constraints. There is greater initial own price Survey provides annual estimates of its importance for most key
elasticity of supply in the long run and very long run, though minerals in the United States (see United States Geological
again this changes when the by-product constraint is reached. Survey, 2003). Although these rates may not carry entirely across
to Australia, they do provide some indicative ideas about the
Price Long run importance of the use of secondary materials in mineral supply,
Immediate Short
run run and given that the United States is a major mineral consumer4. The
very long run
estimates for ten key minerals appear in Figure 6.8. Recycling
rates for materials such as lead (mainly for batteries, at 72 per
cent), iron and steel (58 per cent), nickel and magnesium (both
45 per cent), titanium (40 per cent) and aluminium (36 per cent)
are all significant. Recycling of metals such as gold and silver is
also important.
While many of the above percentages are high, it is important
By-product also to realise that they are derived from two broad categories –
constraint so-called new scrap and old scrap. The authors of United States
C1 Geological Survey (2003, p 62.1) advise that metal ‘new scrap’
O comes from pre-consumer sources while ‘old scrap’ originates
Output Capacity Quantity from post-consumer sources. Hence:
constraint constraint (tonnes per period)
…when metals are converted into shapes – bars,
plates, rods, sheets, etc new scrap is generated in
FIG 6.7 - Supply curves for mineral by-products. the form of turnings, stampings, cuttings and
off-specification materials.
3. During the Cold War, another source of mineral supply for nations Because much ‘new scrap’ supply is derived from new mine
such as the United States was strategic stockpiles. These have
production, it hardly seems to be secondary supply. ‘Old scrap’,
become less important in recent times.
by contrast, comes from products that have reached the end of
4. As noted earlier, the United States economy’s GDP has recently their useful lives – from old cars, computers, household
stood at around 30 per cent of world GDP, implying that the US is appliances, car batteries and many other products. The
responsible for a significant amount of mineral consumption. Given availability of ‘old scrap’, as a percentage of total mineral use,
the nature of the intensity of use of mineral commodities during the
stages of economic development, it seems reasonable to argue, will depend on the lives of products in which it has been an
however, that consumers in the United States are unlikely to be input, the cost of recycling and the rate of recovery of the
consuming equivalent percentages of mineral commodities. mineral in question.

Australian Mineral Economics 55


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

100%
90%
80%
72%
70%
58%
60%
50% 45% 45%
40%
40% 36%
29% 30%
30% 26%
20%
20%
10%
0%

um
n
m

nc
m

l
m
pe

ee

ke

Ti
a
iu

iu

iu

Zi
Le

ni
st

ic
op
in

om

ta
N
ne
&
m

Ti
hr
lu

ag
n
Iro
C
A

M
FIG 6.8 - Estimated US recycling rates for selected metals – 2002.

100%

90%
80%

70%
60%

50%
40%

30%
20%

10%
0%
Aluminium Copper Lead Magnesium Tin Zinc
New scrap 21.7% 24.4% 2.3% 29.1% 7.0% 22.3%
Old scrap 14.5% 6.0% 69.5% 16.3% 12.5% 3.3%

FIG 6.9 - Estimated rates of recycling new and old scrap for six selected minerals in the United States of America – 2002.

Suppose that the supply (and consumption) of a mineral grows Some supply of new scrap takes place in reasonably
at an annual rate of three per cent per annum over a quarter of a competitive markets, though vertical integration strategies for
century. After that period, the products in which it has been an other minerals may ensure that producer pricing continues to
input becomes obsolete and can be recycled. Suppose further that prevail in this area.
it is profitable to recycle half of the metal in these worn out A reproduction of Tilton’s view of the supply of new scrap in
goods. It is a straightforward exercise to calculate that about competitive markets appears in Figure 6.10.
23 per cent of mineral supply at the end of this period can come What stands out in this representation is the similarity of the
from ‘old scrap’ material. It is interesting to note in Figure 6.9 immediate run, the short run and the long run and very long run.
that, for the six metals whose secondary supply is separated into One would assume that the recycling cost would be pushed down
new scrap and old scrap, only lead stands out as having a highly over time by small amounts. Although not shown in the diagram
significant rate of old scrap recycling. it is also possible to assume that the capacity constraint could be
pushed out a bit by technological advance in the long run/very
long run. However, the message of this diagram is elastic low
The supply of new scrap minerals cost supply that is subject to a capacity constraint.
This supply will be relatively cheap to recycle and reasonably
elastic until it comes up against a capacity constraint. As Tilton Old scrap mineral supply
(1985, p 402) notes with respect to metals, the factors affecting
In the example at the beginning of this section, we referred to a
this constraint are: flow of any mineral to secondary supply resulting from products
• ‘current overall metal consumption; coming to the end of their service lives. Usually there is also a
stock of old scrap material containing different minerals that has
• the distribution of this consumption by end uses; and
built up over time and has not yet been recycled. This is typically
• the percentage of consumption resulting in new scrap for each because the price of newly mined minerals has been less than the
end use’. cost of recycling from this old scrap.

56 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

different forms of production are likely to change. By contrast,


Price Availability for a mineral such as coal that occurs only as an individual
constraint product and is not recyclable, this exercise will be much more
Short straightforward.
run To illustrate the construction of a total mineral supply curve
without going into excessive complexity, suppose that we have a
Immediate mineral that occurs as a main product and a by-product and
run that can be recycled from old scrap. A metal such as cobalt
might provide a good example of such a mineral. Even though
cobalt is not traded on the London Metal Exchange or the New
Long run and York Mercantile Exchange, there are enough producers and users
very long run to suggest that a reasonably competitive market exists for this
metal. Its long run supply in a competitive market place is
considered in Figure 6.11. The components are shown separately
in Figure 6.11a and summed horizontally in Figure 6.11b. In this
Quantity latter diagram a simple version of a long-run mineral supply
curve is derived.

FIG 6.10 - The supply of new scrap minerals in competitive


markets. Old By-product
Price scrap Main
Although subject to less of a supply constraint because the product
stock of old scrap may be large, the cost of processing material is
considerable for most minerals. This is because it needs to be
collected and then processed. Where collection and processing
P0
are cheap, and consumption of a mineral has been growing
slowly, the supply of a mineral from old scrap can be significant. P3
Capacity
This is the case for the recycling of lead from lead acid batteries, constraints
the main current use of lead. With the removal of lead from paint P2
and as a petrol additive contributing to static recent levels of
consumption, it is easy to understand why the percentage of lead P1
recycled from old scrap is so high.
It is possible to construct indicative short run and long run A Quantity
supply curves for secondary materials from both the flow and
stock of old scrap, and then add them to derive an old scrap supply Total
curve – see Tilton (1985, pp 403-405). Because the process is Price Supply
somewhat complex, it will not be developed here. Such curves will curve
be upward sloping in the usual way and relatively inelastic.

TOTAL MINERAL SUPPLY P0

The total mineral supply that becomes available in any period is P3


the sum of new mineral supply and secondary supply. The
newly mined supply of a mineral may appears as: P2
• an individual product, P1

• a main product, Quantity


B
• a by-product, or
• a co-product. FIG 6.11 - A total long run supply curve for a mineral produced
Secondary supply can emerge from the flow of old scrap or as a by-product, from old scrap and as a main product. (A) Old
the current stock of old scrap material available. The concept of scrap, by-product and main product supply curves, and (B) total
new scrap is often added to this, though it is arguable that such supply curve.
‘new scrap’ may alternatively be considered to be part of newly
mined supply. It is interesting to compare the shape of a mineral supply curve
A typical way of visually representing a total mineral supply such as that in Figure 6.11b, or perhaps more suitably of a
function is to horizontally sum supply curves for each of the corresponding short run mineral supply curve, with that of the
components of new supply and secondary supply for various cost curves that mining executives can obtain on a regular basis
periods: for widely traded individual and main product minerals from a
number of prominent industry consultants. These are based on
• the immediate run, cash costs.
• the short run, In discussing the behaviour of firms economists commonly
• the long run, and distinguish between their fixed costs and variable costs. The latter
vary with output while the former are the same regardless of the
• the very long run. level of output. Yet this distinction is often blurred in the mining
Conducting this exercise for a metal such as gold or silver, that process as Crowson (1998) notes. Operators of many mines seek
occurs in all of these forms, will be quite a complicated though to spread their costs over as great an output as possible. Also
necessary exercise. As one moves from the immediate run to the annual purchase contracts for fuel and supplies blur the distinction
longer run views, all of the factors that affect each of the between mining and its associated first-stage processing.

Australian Mineral Economics 57


CHAPTER 6: MINERAL SUPPLY — EXPLORATION, PRODUCTION, PROCESSING AND RECYCLING

Average Cost
per tonne

$9,000
$8,000
$7,000

$6,000
$5,000

$4,000
$3,000

$2,000
M1 M2 Mine 3 Mine 4 Other mines
By-
$1,000
product

$0
0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000
Quantity (kt)

FIG 6.12 - A hypothetical total average cost (supply) curve for newly mined nickel in a recent time period.

It has therefore become common practice to distinguish Ericsson, M, 2002. Mining M&A reaches record levels in 2001, Minerals
between cash costs and other costs within the mining industry. and Energy, 17(1):19-26.
They refer to all fixed and variable costs sustained in cash rather Ericsson, M, 2004. Iron ore – The world market, The AusIMM Bulletin,
than as ledger entries when operations are taking place. They 5:70-75.
include all site costs of mining such as stripping, processing, Geoscience Australia, 2004. Australia’s Identified Mineral Resources
concentrating, but also incorporate sales and marketing. 2004 (Australian Government: Canberra). [online]. Available from:
<http://www.ga.gov.au/image_cache/GA5476.pdf>. Date accessed:
Industry analysts produce average short run cash cost and 8 May 2006.
total cost data for different mines for various mineral sectors. Harris, D P, 1985. Mineral resource information, supply and policy
They have not typically also included data on recycling. As an analysis, in Economics of the Mineral Industries, fourth edition (ed:
example, an indicative short run operating cost curve for newly W A Vogely), pp 181-224 (The American Institute of Mining,
mined nickel might look like the curve in Figure 6.12. Such Metallurgical, and Petroleum Engineers: New York).
curves provide an approximation for a short run supply curve for Hotelling, H, 1931. The economics of exhaustible resources, Journal of
newly mined production5. They provide useful competitiveness Political Economy, 39(2):139-175.
benchmarks for new and existing producers. Yet because these Joint Ore Reserves Committee (JORC), 2004. Australasian Code for
data are usually commercially sensitive and collected by only a Reporting of Mineral Resources and Ore Reserves (The JORC Code),
few organisations, they are not widely available in the public The Joint Ore Reserves Committee of The Australasian Institute of
domain. Indeed they tend to be prohibitively expensive to Mining and Metallurgy, Australian Institute of Geoscientists and
Minerals Council of Australia. [Online]. Available from: <http://www.
observers who do not depend on them to generate significant
ausimm.com/codes/jorc0105.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
income streams.
Krautkraemer, J A, 1998. Non-renewable resource scarcity, Journal of
In summary, the discussion in this chapter has sought to Economic Literature, 36:2065-2107.
introduce the discussion of mineral supply in a fashion that MacKenzie, B, 1987. Mineral Economics: Decision-Making Methods in
integrates it with the preceding review of the elements of mineral the Mineral Industry, 5 - 17 July (Australian Mineral Foundation:
demand. When combined, it is hoped that they will be found to Adelaide).
provide a useful framework for Phillip Crowson’s discussion of Tilton, J E, 1985. The metals, in Economics of the Mineral Industries,
mineral markets in the next chapter. fourth edition (ed: W A Vogely), pp 383-416 (The American Institute
of Mining, Metallurgical, and Petroleum Engineers: New York).
5. It should be acknowledged that the sum of producer marginal cost Tilton, J E, 2003. On Borrowed Time? Assessing the Threat of Mineral
curves, rather than average cost curves, are the components of an Depletion (Resources for the Future: Washington).
industry supply curve for producers in any competitive industry. United States Geological Survey, 2003. Recycling – Metals, US Geological
Survey Minerals Yearbook 2002 (United States Geological Survey:
Washington). [online]. Available from: <http://minerals.usgs.gov/
REFERENCES minerals/pubs/myb.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Anonymous, 2004. Note: Corporate control in iron ore mining in 2002, Western Australian Government, 2004. Western Australian Minerals and
Minerals and Energy, 19(2):36-38. Petroleum Statistics Digest 2003 (Western Australian Government,
Department of Industry and Resources: Perth) [online]. Available
Chavez-Martinez, M L, 1983. A potential supply system for uranium
from: <http://www.doir.wa.gov.au/documents/mineralsandpetroleum/
based on a crustal abundance model, PhD dissertation, University of
statsdigest2003.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Arizona, Tucson.
WMC Resources, 2005. [Online]. <http://www.wmc.com>.
Crowson, P, 1998. Inside Mining: The Economics of the Supply and
Demand of Minerals and Metals (Mining Journal Books: London).

58 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7

Mineral Markets, Prices and the Recent Performance of


the Minerals and Energy Sector
Phillip Crowson

Introduction
Market Structure – Competitive Markets
Market Structure – Oligopolistic Markets
The Rise and Fall of Cartels
Producer Pricing
Terminal Markets
Recent Trends in Mineral Markets

INTRODUCTION Leaving aside the complications flowing from the existence of


inventories, other than normal working stocks, prices will settle
The two preceding chapters examined the diverse influences on in the near term where demand and supply intersect. Other
demand for mineral products and the various forces acting on the factors being equal, a rise in demand or a fall in supply will
supply side. In essence, prices are determined by the interaction prompt a rise in prices and a fall in demand, or a rise in supply
of these opposing forces in the market place. The geographical
will prompt a fall in prices until equilibrium is restored. In
location of demand, the end uses and the nature and sources of
supply differ for each product, and these differences in market practice, prices will tend to fluctuate around the equilibrium
structure dictate precisely how demand and supply interact to set level, because conditions are continuously changing. Prices will
the prices of individual products. The nature of the pricing gravitate towards the industry’s marginal cost of production: the
mechanism is strongly influenced by the ease with which new cost of production of the last (or most expensive) unit of supply
suppliers can enter the market (in other words by the barriers to from whatever source, which is required to balance the market.
entry). In the short to medium term price levels can be affected by The nature of the supply curve in competitive markets and its
political, economic and social conditions in mineral-producing and interaction with demand and price are illustrated in Figure 7.1.
consuming countries, but the main factors are geological and
technical. Where ore deposits are readily discovered and easily
exploitable with existing technology at prevailing price levels the
barriers to entry are low. Conversely, a scarcity of exploitable
deposits keeps the barriers high. Changes in exploration or D1
extraction and processing technology can rapidly change the
conditions of entry.
P1
MARKET STRUCTURE – COMPETITIVE MARKETS D
Price
Where the barriers to market entry are low there is likely to be P
a relatively large number of suppliers. The more present and D2
prospective suppliers there are, the more competitive they are P2
likely to be with each other. Price in such competitive markets is
determined by the free interplay of supply and demand, and it
will fluctuate to the extent needed to clear the market. The
demand curve facing each individual supplier is, to all intents
and purposes, flat rather than downward sloping to the right like
the industry’s demand curve. Producers are price takers and Q2 Q Q1
have little or no influence over the prevailing price. They can, Quantity
Capacity
however, alter the amount they supply to the market, and each
supplier will produce as much as possible as long as their cash
costs are fully covered. FIG 7.1 - Short-run supply and demand in competitive markets.

Australian Mineral Economics 59


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

When prices are very low there is no supply, as costs exceed developments by privately owned companies through much of
prices. Higher prices allow producers to cover their costs and the 1960-1990 period, especially where such companies were
enter the market until supply is constrained by the available foreign-owned. Many countries prevent the mining of known ore
capacity. Then no additional supplies can be immediately deposits in national parks or wilderness areas. Unstable political
forthcoming, no matter how high prices rise. It takes time for conditions increase the risks of mineral exploration in many
new capacity to be developed, whether that comes from the regions, but particularly in Africa and parts of Asia, to
expansion of existing operations or from new facilities. The price unacceptable levels. These various influences, either alone or in
and the quantity supplied settle at the point where the supply and combination, raise the barriers to entry and limit the number of
demand curves intersect (P and Q when the demand curve is D). producers.
If the demand curve rises to D1, higher cost producers will be As Table 7.1 illustrates, there are typically relatively few
able to supply and the price and quantity will rise to P1 and Q1. significant suppliers to the market for a wide range of minerals
Conversely, when demand drops back to D2 (perhaps because of and their first stage products. The table shows the shares of the
economic recession or some technological change in end-use largest firms in the global production of a range of mineral
markets) higher cost producers will be unable to cover their costs products, split between those that are traded in terminal markets
and price and output will fall to P2 and Q2 respectively. and those whose prices are fixed in other ways. Platinum appears
This assumes that suppliers merely have regard to near-term in both groups, as producers directly sell most production to
demand and prices. In practice their reactions will be much more users at list prices that lag terminal market prices. The degree of
complex. If they believe that a price fall is temporary they may industry concentration is a major influence on pricing, but not
be prepared to stockpile rather than reduce their output, or to the only one. Often there are also relatively few major users.
incur losses for a period. The costs of closure, including the
repayment of debt, environmental remediation and redundancy
payments, may exceed the costs of continued operation. Also, TABLE 7.1
many suppliers may have more complex objectives than short- Concentration in mineral markets: percentage shares of largest
term profit maximisation and may be prepared to produce at a firms in world production 2002. (Source: Raw Materials Group,
2004.)
loss. Over the longer term, when the constraint of existing
capacity is lifted, the supply curve will shift to the right, with its Leading Top 3 Top 5 Top 10
level dictated by technological change and shifts in the political
and regulatory climate. Metals traded on terminal markets
The non-ferrous metals, gold and silver, are the mineral Silver 8 22 29 41
products whose markets most closely approximate the Gold 9 23 32 47
competitive model. They are typical commodities, in the sense Platinum 42 76 89 98
that the products of different producers are reasonably
homogeneous and any individual supplier’s product can readily Copper metal (2003) 10 24 34 49
substitute for that of another. There are many customers and a Zinc metal 14 31 42 60
variety of end uses, each with common standards and Aluminium 13 32 43 60
specifications. Producers can exert little or no influence over the
Nickel 16 39 49 68
markets for their products, which are usually regional or global,
and there is hardly any after-sales service, such as technical Negotiated or list prices
support. Prices are uniform for the standard grades and the Zinc mine 9 23 30 43
producers concentrate on controlling their relative costs. There Lead mine 10 25 34 48
are many suppliers spread throughout the world and no single
producer can influence the level of prices, except for very short Copper mine 12 25 37 58
periods. There are many ore deposits being exploited or under Iron ore (2003) 18 37 46 58
development, it appears relatively easy to discover new ones, Manganese 9 26 36 52
secondary materials are readily available and transport costs are
Alumina 15 33 46 71
generally low relative to product prices. Information about recent
and prospective trends in supply and demand is rapidly and Bauxite 16 34 49 68
widely diffused and the markets are reasonably transparent. Chromite 21 49 64 83
That prices and volumes will settle at the unique point where Diamond value 29 64 76 82
the demand and supply curves intersect does not describe the
Titanium minerals 24 53 70 85
actual process of price discovery, except in an auction market.
There bids and offers are made in public until a price is derived Lithium 23 68 77 83*
that just clears the market. At that price all purchasers and Mercury (1997) 39 87 90†
suppliers are satisfied. The method is similar for gold, silver and
Niobium 40 83 94 98‡
the non-ferrous metals in that their prices are settled in terminal
markets. The characteristics of such markets are explained in a Platinum 42 76 89 98
later section of this chapter.
Notes: † top 4, ‡ top 7, * top 9.
MARKET STRUCTURE – OLIGOPOLISTIC
MARKETS Where there are only a few major producers the suppliers do
not have to take the demand curve as given and their actions can
The markets for most mineral products depart in varying degrees have some influence on prices. Rather than a demand curve that
from the competitive model. The geological availability of many is flat, they face one sloping downwards to the right, just like the
products is much more limited than for the non-ferrous metals or industry. As there are usually few suppliers the supply curve is
the technology needed for their extraction and processing is far likely to be stepped. Producers can exert some control, even if
more complex. The accessibility of ore deposits for commercial strictly limited, over the prices they receive by differentiating the
mining may be restricted by a variety of political, environmental characteristics of their products from those of their competitors.
or economic factors. For example, many developing countries In many instances there is considerable competition in the
either totally prohibited or severely circumscribed mineral non-price dimensions of the product, such as technical service or

60 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

delivery schedules. The chemical and physical characteristics of


the product are varied not just for particular end uses, but often
also for individual users. There is a wide variation in grades and Marginal
Cost Average
specifications, which is reflected in widely differing prices for
apparently similar products. The costs of mining the raw ore are Cost
less important than its characteristics and the methods whereby it P1
can be modified to serve the end-uses that offer the highest
prices. Even producers of commodity metals and minerals look
for ways to upgrade and differentiate their products from those of Price Demand
their rivals in order to achieve a premium over the basic market
prices. Their objective, which is sometimes attained, is to create
a market for their own output that is distinct in some way from
the market as a whole. Marginal
Where prices settle will clearly still depend on how and where Revenue
demand and supply intersect, no matter the precise structure of a
product’s market. Since the costs of most suppliers are lowest at Q1
or near their maximum possible output they will tend to produce Quantity
to capacity. Without the safety valve of terminal markets
however, the costs of stockpiling excess supplies usually forces FIG 7.3 - Long run market equilibrium for a ‘representative’
suppliers to reduce their offerings in periods of weak market producer.
conditions. The short run market conditions facing a
‘representative’ producer are shown in Figure 7.2. The shapes of marginal costs of production and any monopoly profits are
the demand and supply curves have been deliberately gradually whittled away. The theoretically relevant marginal
exaggerated. costs are those likely to pertain over the long run. In other words,
they will incorporate the opportunity costs of capital of the
facilities just needed to meet expanding demand over the long
Marginal term. In practice prices tend to gravitate, at least in the
Cost competitive markets, towards the cash break-even costs of
existing marginal producers. New entrants will aim to have much
Average
P Cost
lower cash costs than these and to cover their full costs at
Above-normal expected prices.
profit
Markets with only a few suppliers are described as oligopolies,
Price Demand and those with only a few customers, are given the less common
description of oligopsonies. In many such markets there may be
a penumbra of smaller suppliers or users around the few large
firms. Small customers are liable to absorb an unduly large
Marginal amount of time and effort from the suppliers’ sales staff and they
Revenue are often serviced through distributors. Although small producers
are unlikely to produce a full range of products, their persistence
Q in selling their own grades can undermine established price
Quantity structures. Major suppliers of many industrial minerals and
minor metals therefore have to take full account of their activities
FIG 7.2 - Short run market equilibrium for a ‘representative’ and potential actions. The power of the major producers to
producer. control their markets is accordingly circumscribed. In all cases
each producer has to take account of the possible impact any
As the producer faces a downward-sloping demand curve for decisions about pricing and production volume may have on
output, the marginal revenue from additional sales will also competitors and of their likely policies. How those differ will
decline with increasing output. Assuming that the producer aims partly depend on each producer’s relative costs and available
to maximise profits, they will produce to the level of output (Q) capacity.
where marginal revenue equals marginal cost of production. In some instances the smaller producers may sell through
The price (P) is rather higher than would be set in a completely merchants, who may also acquire supplies from other sources.
competitive market and the producer would earn above-normal These may include releases from redundant government
profits. That is not a stable position because such profits would stockpiles, scrap and secondary recovery and in previous times
induce a variety of competitive responses. Exploration and new imports from state trading countries that were on the fringes of
mine development would be stimulated and technological the global market economy. Particularly when market conditions
research on lower-cost processes encouraged. On the demand are weak, merchants have been able to re-purchase excess
side, the use of substitutes would be encouraged. In consequence supplies from the customers of the major suppliers. Although the
the demand curve facing the ‘representative’ producer would be producers naturally discourage resale of their products, they
pushed downwards, lowering the level of output associated with cannot always prevent it.
a given level of prices. Subject to the ease or difficulty with At the theoretical extreme of a market with just one supplier,
which the barriers to entry could be surmounted the excess or pure monopoly, the demand curves of the supplier and the
profits would eventually be eliminated by competition and the industry are the same. Monopolists can choose that combination
long run equilibrium shown in Figure 7.3 would be attained. of price and volume that best suits their objectives. Assuming
The producer would still maximise profits at the point where that their objective is profit maximisation they will produce to
marginal cost equalled marginal revenue, but with only a the point where the marginal revenue equals the marginal cost.
‘normal’ rate of profit. Also, the level of output would be rather The short run position shown in Figure 7.2 would hold for the
lower than would be reached in a perfectly competitive market, monopolist over the long run. In practice there are no instances
were that to exist in the real world. As markets develop, and the of natural total monopoly in the mineral industries on a global
number and range of producers expand, prices drop towards the scale, although there have been cases of contrived monopoly

Australian Mineral Economics 61


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

through cartels and similar collusive actions in restraint of trade. more widespread. In effect, the producer acts like a monopolist,
The availability of secondary materials and of substitutes of offering to sell at a given price, with an implicit assumption that
varying degrees of effectiveness for most mineral products output will be reduced to maintain that price when market
means that any individual supplier’s power to raise prices by conditions are weak, and that some customers may be unsatisfied
holding back supplies is strictly limited. when demand runs against the limits of capacity. Other producers
That substitutes exist and that there are usually competing may voluntarily decide to follow the lead set by the price-setting
suppliers to global markets does not rule out the probability of producer and accept satisfactory rather than maximised profits.
more restricted monopolies. The key is the height of any barriers In other instances producer pricing may be sustained through
to entry. These can be artificially raised for domestic producers collusive behaviour, ranging from informal discussions to formal
in a national market by protection against imports through tariffs cartels. The recent history of cartels is also described later in this
or quotas. Over the post-war years there was a steady trend in all chapter.
major economies towards dismantling quotas and other Where there are only a few major participants on each side of
quantitative restrictions and lowering tariff barriers on most the pricing equation (which is true for many mineral products)
products. This gradually eroded local monopolies, often against prices are largely determined by negotiation. Each participant
the strong resistance of the previously favoured suppliers. Some has to take account not only of the likely responses of the
developing countries still have highly protective tariffs against customer to their actions, but also of the possible reactions of
imports, although there are continuing pressures for their existing and potential competitors. Such intelligence is usually
reduction. The cost of transport provides a less penetrable more important for the producers than the purchasers. Each
barrier, especially for bulk products with a low value to weight mineral product effectively forms a small village where all the
ratio. major participants know each other. This village-like nature of
Accordingly, the markets for sand and gravel remain largely global mineral markets facilitates the rapid transmission of
local, even in the US and Western Europe. For bulk products like gossip and information and the sense of prevailing market
coal and iron ore, however, sharply declining costs of ocean conditions, even where there is no explicit market place.
shipping during the decades following the Second World War How companies behave when negotiating prices largely
opened up local and national markets to international depends on the point reached in the business cycle and on the
competition, which had consequent repercussions on the market strength of any barriers to entry. A tougher negotiating stance is
structure and pricing of such products. more appropriate when markets are tightening than when they
As demand for a product develops and expands from its initial are in the recessionary phase of the cycle. Where there are few, if
niche markets, new entrants are attracted over the prevailing any, viable undeveloped ore deposits, or where complex
barriers to entry. The more suppliers there are, the more difficult proprietary technology is required in the production process, the
it becomes for any one of them to control, or even influence, existing producers’ bargaining position is strong. It weakens
prices. In the initial stages of a product’s life cycle there may be markedly where there is ample existing and prospective capacity
only a limited number of uses, or perhaps only one. Users will be and technology is readily available.
prepared to pay high prices to satisfy their needs. The owners of Thus the differing availability of ore deposits probably favours
the more accessible deposits are able to cream off monopoly manganese producers over iron ore producers in their dealings
profits, especially where they also control innovative processing with the steel mills. Neither has a very strong position however,
technology. These profits naturally attract the envious attentions compared with the existing producers of titanium dioxide
of other companies, stimulating both exploration and research feedstock during the 1980s and early 1990s. They benefited from
into processes. Often both are successful and the initially high
high barriers to entry in both ore reserves and technology. Their
barriers to entry are reduced.
market power was constrained by the comparative strengths of a
New entrants can piggy-back off the marketing activities of the few large purchasers. Mutual deterrence is as much a feature of
initial pioneers. Capacity expands, probably at a faster rate than some mineral markets as of international relations.
demand, which remains dependent on specialist uses. Sooner or
History suggests that price wars, once started, are difficult to
later potential supply exceeds demand and prices come under stop and that they normally benefit only the customers. Even that
pressure. The initial producers will have probably recouped their benefit may be strictly short term if lower prices inhibit
investment several times over and be prepared to drop prices both investment in additional capacity to meet growing demand.
to stimulate demand and to choke off new entrants. Conversely, Much depends on whether the major producers concentrate their
the latter may be forced into price cutting in order to gain market attention on maximising prices and profitability, or on volume.
share. Often they may be able to withstand lowered prices The pursuit of market share is a common corporate objective,
because their deposits or processes are superior to those of the on the assumption that it can enhance a company’s market
pioneers. Normally production starts at those deposits that are power. It does not usually appear to have been accompanied by
known or readily accessible, rather than at those with the long-term profitability when it has been followed in the minerals
potentially lowest costs. Followers building completely new industry. One possible argument in favour of maximising
facilities may be able to exploit process improvements more volume, even at the expense of weaker prices, is that it enables a
easily than the originators in their established plants. producer to achieve the designed economies of scale from
Military needs in wartime have often forced large increases in existing capacity. The structure of costs may be such that the
the capacity to produce many mineral products and metals, often burden of fixed costs per unit of output rises sharply when the
irrespective of profitability. The physical need has been mine and equipment are not fully utilised. The gains from
paramount. When military demand has dropped, producers have increasing the volume of sales may more than outweigh any fall
been forced to develop new uses in order to keep their capacity in prices.
running, often with price reductions. Changing technology has Trade-offs like those are typical of the iron ore producing
also been a driving force. In all cases rapidly expanding markets industry. Producers of iron ore, like those of other minerals,
have allowed producers to exploit economies of scale. never look solely at one dimension of their sales contracts but at
The ways in which market prices, other than those fixed in them all simultaneously. Concessions on price may be set against
terminal markets, are actually determined varies widely between increased volume, but these are not the only dimensions of sales.
different mineral products. Prices for some are posted by Quality, including such features as the grade and the physical and
producers, almost on a ‘take it or leave it’ basis. Such producer chemical composition of the ore, is becoming increasingly
pricing, which is discussed later in this chapter, was once much important. Quality involves far more than the ore itself. The

62 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

perceived reliability of a supplier and its susceptibility to strikes People of the same trade seldom meet together,
and other disruptions is another aspect of quality. The provision even for merriment and diversion, but the
of technical service to customers is not really important for the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the
producers of metallic ores, but it can be a valuable competitive public, or in some contrivance to raise prices.
tool for suppliers of industrial minerals. The terms on which
credit is granted to purchasers and the extent to which prices may The same factors that facilitate producer pricing – namely a
vary with the prices of the customer’s products are also relevant, relatively limited number of producers – tend to encourage
especially in the markets for base metals concentrates. restrictive agreements to limit output or raise prices. The history
of the minerals and metals industry is littered with attempts to fix
In iron ore and coal, as in many other products, pricing has
prices through cooperative actions. These have met with varying
evolved over the past 30 years. When many exporting mines
degrees of success, but most have ultimately failed. Some have
were first established, trade was mainly based on long-term
worked through producer pricing whilst others have operated
contracts with prices fixed over long periods or indexed to
through terminal markets. Many, but by no means all, were
general indicators according to agreed formulae. Such contracts started in periods of over-supply as defensive reactions to
have evolved into shorter term contracts covering several self-defeating price cutting. Those were often introduced with
years, but with periodic price negotiations. The volumes can also the active support of or at least implicit connivance of,
vary within predetermined limits, depending on market governments.
conditions. Negotiations do not start from scratch every year, but
Attitudes to cartels between producers are much affected by
from the prevailing prices, which roll over until a new agreement
prevailing political philosophies. During the period between the
is reached. In some product markets, and especially in industrial
First and Second World Wars, many governments accepted the
minerals, prices are negotiated for the life of the contract, which need for concerted action to restrict output in conditions of acute
may be for three to five years. Provision may be made for prices excess capacity and weak demand in order to sustain prices.
to move over the life of the contract in step with agreed indices, In the decades following the Second World War such attitudes
such as US wholesale prices. When the contracts expire, the two persisted and they were reinforced by the widespread acceptance
parties will negotiate a new agreement taking into account of government intervention and regulation of economic activity.
changes in the balance between supply and demand and the
The Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries
extent to which the expiring contract favoured one side or the
(OPEC) was one of many producer-based organisations
other. Very often one party will be keen to offset any established during this period. It was founded in 1960 by five
disadvantages it suffered during the previous contract term. countries, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia and Venezuela and a
Usually agreement is eventually reached because there is a further eight oil producing countries had joined by 1973. For the
mutual interest in a continued relationship, but discussions first decade of its existence OPEC achieved very little, but its
occasionally break up in acrimony, with the parties resorting to members chipped away at the power of the international oil
arbitration. companies that effectively controlled their production. Strongly
More frequent negotiation of prices tends to prevent such rising international demand for crude oil, partly driven by the US
disruptions since contract prices then move more closely with moving from a production surplus to a deficit, enabled the
market conditions. Sometimes prices are changed half-yearly or producers to achieve moderate price increases in 1971. The
even quarterly, as in sulfur and some fertiliser materials. Annual Arab-Israeli war of October 1973 and its aftermath encouraged
price negotiation is now the general rule in iron ore, coal and OPEC to go much further in gaining control of pricing and
base metals concentrates. Large producers may divide their production. The move was driven by political rather than
contractual volumes, even with one customer, into blocks whose economic considerations, as a means of putting pressure on the
prices are negotiated at different times. That softens the impact industrial countries. The price of oil quadrupled, transforming
of any large price movements resulting from the annual the international oil market and prompting serious economic
negotiating round. The outcome of the annual bargaining dislocation in the global economy. The Iranian revolution in
naturally depends on the relative strengths of the buyers and 1979, coupled with political upsets elsewhere, led to a further
sellers, but also on the changing objectives of individual round of sharp price rises in 1979-80.
producers. The first major price settlement reached in the annual The initial price increases held because the short run demand
bargaining round usually sets the tone for the entire market and for oil was highly price inelastic, but by the early 1980s
other suppliers quickly follow. The same supplier and customer alternative sources of oil were being developed, partly under the
may lead the market for several years running, but the leadership stimulus of the higher prices then ruling. There had also been
often changes. Published prices are normally only one facet of a wholesale substitution away from oil to alternative fuels and
settlement that also includes arrangements on tonnage. The energy-saving measures of all types. By the late 1990s OPEC
producer that settles first in a weak market may have supplied about two-fifths of the global production of crude oil
counterbalanced concessions on price with increased sales compared with well over half in the early 1970s. Although OPEC
volumes, but the followers seldom derive those benefits. introduced formal quotas on production in 1982 in order to
Participants in the market have to weigh up all the alternatives in sustain prices, there was widespread cheating and crude oil
their negotiating strategies. Obviously they will need to take prices drifted downwards from the mid 1980s. The first Gulf War
account of the size of their own and their competitors’ in 1991 had but a temporary impact on oil prices.
inventories and of the balance between the capacity and output of By the late 1990s global demand was again starting to outstrip
each producer. Eventually a global consensus about prices is the available capacity to produce and OPEC’s production quotas
reached and prices in the main regional markets are closely became more effective. The collapse of Iraqi production in 2003
linked. Sometimes such a consensus is reached quickly, whereas helped OPEC to sustain crude oil prices. Most of the surviving
in other years the negotiations can drag on for months. members of OPEC (Ecuador left in 1992 and Gabon in 1995) are
Islamic states with a similar political outlook, although the
similarities between theocratic Iran, a feudal monarchy like
THE RISE AND FALL OF CARTELS Saudi Arabia and Nigeria or Indonesia should not be overstated.
Even where prices are negotiated between major producers and OPEC’s successes have sprung not so much from its own policies
users of a product, there may be scope for collusive action and actions as from the global market conditions it faces.
between producers. Adam Smith (1976) [1776] remarked on this OPEC’s share of world oil production between 1965 and 2004 is
tendency over 200 years ago: shown in Figure 7.4.

Australian Mineral Economics 63


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

100
Where costs of production diverge widely there is little
OPEC Non-OPEC community of interest between the lower and higher cost
80
producers. Similarly, a wide diversity of sources of production
and undeveloped reserves raises the prospect of new entrants
million barrels/day

60 undermining the cartel. In essence, the barriers to entry need to


be fairly high and not just in the short run. There should be few
40
viable substitutes in the product’s major uses and the
price-elasticity of demand should be very low.
Even during their heyday in the late 1970s, producer
20
associations formed merely to increase or stabilise prices were
unlikely to succeed, because some or all of the necessary
0 pre-conditions for success were lacking. Table 7.2 outlines the
1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 fate of several international producer groups that were formed or
A gained prominence during the 1970s.
60
Bauxite was perhaps the nearest parallel to petroleum in the
early 1970s and producing countries such as Jamaica raised their
50
returns from local bauxite production. That was a temporary
success however, because there were ample alternative resources
% share of world total

40
and the barriers to entry were relatively low. The raising of prices
provided leeway for potential producers in other countries such
30
as Brazil to develop new mines. Jamaica’s share of global
bauxite output fell from around 18 per cent in 1973-74 to eight
20
per cent by the mid-1980s.
Morocco and the other members of the putative phosphate
10
cartel were unsuccessful in sustaining their price increases
because farmers effectively went on strike and delayed the
0
application of phosphatic fertilisers. Many of the
1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
B inter-governmental producer groups that were formed during the
1970s did not survive changes in market conditions and
FIG 7.4 - (A) World crude oil production and OPEC’s share of prevailing political philosophies. The International Bauxite
world production. (Source: British Petroleum, 2004 – the data Association, for example, saw a gradual loss of members before
cover crude oil, shale oil, oil sands and natural gas liquids). collapsing in 1995. In copper, CIPEC saw many members
(B) OPEC’s percentage share of world oil production. withdraw and contracted, leaving its residual coordinating
functions carried out in Chile.
OPEC’s apparent success in raising crude oil prices in the
early 1970s prompted the formation of similar international Even if the necessary preconditions for cartels had been in
producer groups for a variety of mineral products, such as place, the marked change in global political conditions that
phosphates, bauxite, iron ore, mercury and tungsten. Less formal gathered force during the 1980s would have made their lives
arrangements covered manganese, lead and zinc. Many groups, difficult. The emphasis moved from collective to individual
nominally at least, excluded any discussion of prices from their action and to the primacy of market forces. Government
agenda. The articles of the World Phosphate Institute, for intervention became unfashionable with the view that prices
example, were framed in such a way as to leave the three US should be allowed to find their own levels in response to
company members free of any anti-trust action. Australia only competitive forces, which should be facilitated by effective
joined the bauxite and iron ore associations on the understanding competition policies.
that they would not attempt to increase prices unilaterally. A major defect of producer cartels is that they do not explicitly
Nonetheless, the smoothing of price fluctuations was always an take account of the interests of consumers. Governments of
important objective of most members of all these producer commodity-consuming countries are, therefore, wary of their
groups and of the copper producers’ group, CIPEC, which was creation, especially where companies rather than governments
formed in 1967. Most were inter-governmental bodies, although are involved. Both the US and the European Union came out
the phosphate, mercury and tungsten organisations had strongly against any effective cartels, whether these were
individual company members. Most lacked the wider common organised by individual producing companies (private or state
interests that created the strong cohesiveness of the Arab owned) or by governments. This opposition was less than total,
members of OPEC. Weak market conditions from 1974 onwards however, as the United States has explicitly allowed cartels that
prevented most producer associations from exploiting any power enable US exporters to compete internationally. Thus US
they might have had. In any case, the basic economic conditions exporters of phosphates and soda ash combine to sell in overseas
that allowed OPEC to boost oil prices do not exist in most markets. Similarly, joint purchasing arrangements amongst
commodities. consuming companies are also acceptable. Examples include the
There are several preconditions for successful cartel action: Japanese smelter pool, which arranges imports of copper
• members should share some common interests and objectives; concentrates and joint purchasing by both the Japanese and the
German steel mills. One company may take the lead in dealings
• there should not be a wide range of grades or qualities of the
with producers, with the ensuing agreement shared by all. Joint
product involved, but different producers’ output should be
closely substitutable (the scope for cheating tends to vary purchasing can tip the scales in the purchasers’ favour, even
inversely with the homogeneity of the product); where they have an apparently weak initial bargaining position.
Until the mid-1970s only the US had strong anti-trust
• a high level of concentration of production and reserves is legislation and non-US companies were prepared to collude to
required; and maintain prices. The important proviso was that such collusion
• the cost structures of each producer should be broadly did not affect US commerce, otherwise it would have brought
comparable. those involved under the reach of the extra-territorial provisions

64 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

TABLE 7.2
International producer associations in the minerals industry.
Bauxite International Bauxite Association (IBA)
Formed March 1974 and by 1975 members controlled 85 per cent of non-socialist world output. Jamaica, Surinam, Dominican
Republic and Guinea successfully raised bauxite mining taxes, but Australia did not. The countries that did lost market share and the
IBA became increasingly ineffective. Jamaica withdrew in mid-1994 and the IBA collapsed in 1995.
Copper Conseil Intergouvernmental des Pays Exportateurs de Cuivre (CIPEC)
Formed in June 1967 by Chile, Peru, Zaire and Zambia. Yugoslavia and Indonesia joined later and Australia and Papua New Guinea
became associates. In 1974-76 CIPEC unsuccessfully tried to stabilise copper prices through production cuts, but its members
controlled too small a share of the global market. CIPEC dwindled in importance with the collapse of Central African copper
production, the withdrawal of several members and the establishment of an International Copper Study Group in 1993. Its residual
coordinating functions moved to Chile’s Copper Commission.
Iron ore Association of Iron Ore Exporting Countries (APEF)
Developing country members pressed for attempts to set export prices in 1975, but Australia and Sweden refused. Neither Brazil nor
Canada joined. APEF collected statistics on market trends until its suspension in 1989. Its statistics gathering role was taken over for
a period by an UNCTAD Trust Fund.
Phosphate rock World Phosphate Rock Institute
Morocco, the leading producer outside the USA, joined with Algeria, Brazil, Jordan, Senegal, Syria, Togo and Tunisia in 1973.
Morocco sharply raised export prices in 1974 and several other members followed suit. The United States’ export cartel, Phosrock,
also raised its prices. The global market collapsed in 1975 when the effects of recession were exacerbated by farmers ceasing to
apply phosphatic fertilisers.
Mercury Mercury Producers’ Association (Assimer)
Formed in 1975 by Algeria, Turkey, Mexico, Italy, Spain and Yugoslavia. Most production was state-owned. In late 1977 Assimer
announced attempts to control the market with sales restrictions, followed by price increases. Its control was undermined in 1982 by
falling consumption, increased secondary supplies and sales from US stockpiles, but was reasserted for a brief period in the late
1980s. Growing concerns about the adverse impact of mercury on human health and the environment have led to even tighter
regulations on consumption. These have also boosted recycling and greatly reduced any pricing power of the primary producers.
Tungsten UNCTAD Committee on Tungsten, Primary Tungsten Association
International Tungsten Industry Association
An Ad Hoc Committee on Tungsten, an inter-governmental body, was established under the auspices of the United Nations in 1963.
One of its tasks was to examine ways of stabilising prices. In due course, the Committee and its various offshoots moved under the
UNCTAD umbrella. Its main role was the collection of statistics but it also attempted to reach agreement on means of stabilising the
market, especially during the late 1970s. It was complemented by a producer organisation, the Primary Tungsten Association (PTA),
established by major producing companies in 1976. With changing attitudes to market intervention, the UNCTAD Committee was
replaced in October 1992 by an Inter-governmental Group of Experts on Tungsten, whose remit was solely statistical. The PTA was
replaced by the International Tungsten Industry Association in early 1988. This brought together mining companies, processors,
consumers and traders in a research organisation under Belgian law.

of the US anti-trust laws. It was reasonable to assume that involve governments in ways of tackling the problems raised by
producer pricing outside the US was beyond reach as long as the the sudden and unexpected outflow of aluminium metal from the
US was self-sufficient in the affected products. Imports into the former Soviet Union in the late 1980s and early 1990s. The
US of many minerals and metals began rising strongly in the Memorandum of Understanding signed between Russia and
early 1970s however, for a variety of different (usually specific) certain major aluminium-producing countries in early 1994 was
reasons. That led the US Department of Justice to examine an inter-governmental agreement. It provided a fig leaf behind
possible breaches of anti-trust laws by foreign companies. which the companies could shelter when they cut their output in
Simultaneously, the European Union’s competition policy was order to restore market balance. Those cuts coincided with an
being developed and enforced through case law. influx of speculative funds into purchasing non-ferrous metals,
International zinc producers were amongst the first to especially aluminium. During 1994 prices rose sharply, by far
experience the changed climate. Companies who had established more than anyone had forecast, and some aggrieved users of
and maintained the well-publicised European Producer Price aluminium attempted to sue the US producers for anti-trust
system for zinc from 1964 onwards with the tacit approval of violations.
their host governments were questioned by the US anti-trust The diamond market provides the longest running example of
authorities in 1976 and a case was brought against them by the a price setting cartel that has been treated as unlawful in the US.
European Competition Directorate. That eventually resulted in For many years De Beers operated an effective cartel amongst
fines and the effective collapse of the system of zinc producer the mining countries and controlled market prices through its
prices, which had been enforced through an agreement to sales policies and by stockpiling. The US anti-trust authorities
stockpile, intervene on the London Metal Exchange and reduce were strongly antagonistic and would have prosecuted both the
output when necessary. The vestiges of the system lingered on company and its officers had they ever been within US
for some years, but without the previous effectiveness. Even jurisdiction. That was not however, a sufficient impediment,
when it was fully operational those involved in the system had notwithstanding the considerable funds that had to be raised to
been quite prepared to cheat their colleagues if they could. Also finance stocks during periods of weak demand such as the early
during the late 1970s the European Competition Directorate 1980s and early 1990s. The collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991
successfully prosecuted a group of companies who had and the development of new mines outside De Beers’ control
collectively purchased all exports of aluminium from Eastern weakened its influence. Australian production, mainly of
countries in order to keep them off the London Metal Exchange industrial diamonds, began in the early 1980s and the Australian
and damage the prevailing producer price structure. producers became increasingly assertive towards the De Beers
These actions, and others in different industries, made Central Selling Organisation. Gradually De Beers’ tight grip on
suppliers of minerals and metals into North America and the global diamond marketing weakened, especially with the start-up
European Union much more careful about the anti-trust rules. of Canadian production in 2001. A considerable degree of
For example, the major aluminium producers took great pains to market discipline remains however, largely because of the nature

Australian Mineral Economics 65


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

of the market for diamond gems. Consumers, perhaps even more most phases of the business cycle, which in turn means that
than producers, have an interest in maintaining high prices for a really effective producer pricing is only achievable in those
product whose value is as a status object rather than for its markets where there are only a few strong companies. High
intrinsic properties in use. If the global diamond market is barriers to entry into the market and a perceived community of
cartelised, it is a cartel in which consumers are as guilty of interest in price stability between the suppliers are usually
conspiring as producers. That makes diamonds very much a preconditions for success.
special case. Even in diamonds, a form of producer pricing does Producer pricing has been strongest and most tenacious in
not eliminate the need for careful analysis of market trends, for a national or regional markets that are protected in some manner
willingness to stockpile, or for a need for production cutbacks in from imports. The basic cost structures of producers within one
periods of weak demand. country may differ, but they are subject to similar variations in
Notwithstanding strong anti-trust legislation in major costs and demand and to a common regulatory framework. Often
minerals-consuming countries, collusive actions to restrict the producers of the primary materials may be integrated with
competition persist. In 2003 for example, the European Union downstream users of their products. That means that the actual
fined European producers of copper tube for price fixing. It also price of the raw materials is not of great importance, but it
began an investigation into the copper concentrate market jointly merely indicates where profits are recorded for accounting
with the relevant Canadian and US agencies. There were purposes. The tax authorities will have some interest in ensuring
suggestions that meetings to discuss market conditions and that transfer prices between the various stages are not being
industry statistics provided a front for price fixing. The used to evade taxes, but that need not impinge on market prices.
investigations were eventually dropped without any actions being The list prices for the raw materials may only be paid on the
taken. The nature of the markets for minerals and their first-stage modest portion of sales, often to small users, made outside the
products means that producers will always seek ways of integrated network. That was the case in the US primary
restricting competition. The search inevitably intensifies during aluminium industry and largely still is. The prices of
prolonged periods of weak market conditions. Most collusive semi-fabricated products are infinitely more important to the
agreements are likely to prove temporary because demand is not major US aluminium producers than the price of ingot. The
sufficiently price inelastic over the medium to long term and progressive reductions in tariffs and other barriers to trade
because the barriers to entry are not high enough. between major metal producing and consuming countries in the
1960s and 1970s lowered barriers to foreign competition and
PRODUCER PRICING made the defence of domestic producer prices much harder:
prices could be more easily undercut by imports.
Collusive action of any type is not a pre-requisite of producer Even where producers are able to tailor their production to
pricing. Where there are only a few suppliers to a market but fluctuating demand, the fit will rarely be perfect. Individual
many end-uses and customers, producers may quote list prices. producers may be unable to bear the burden of financing large
Such producer prices may be set by a dominant producer or inventories, even with accommodating financial institutions.
price leader and followed fairly closely by the other suppliers. When markets are weak for extended periods the patience of
They may have similar cost structures and have learned from such institutions soon becomes strained and their willingness to
bitter experience that vigorous price competition brings only grant additional credit distinctly limited. Hence, recourse has to
temporary gains in market share that are usually whittled away in be made to production cutbacks, which are seldom easy to
the next round of price cuts, to the benefit of users rather than engineer unless one supplier is prepared to shoulder the entire
producers. Concentration on the other competitive dimensions, burden. Individual producers may believe that they have an
such as product quality, marketing or technical service, may be inherent cost advantage that enables them to carry on producing
more effective means of attracting and retaining customers. at a profit when others make losses. They may expect an
Where producers set prices they tend to keep them fixed for imminent improvement in market conditions, or they may be
long periods. They often set them not by reference to marginal loath to countenance any drop in market share that might flow
costs, whether their own or those of the industry, but to some form from their cutbacks. This all means that collusion between the
of average cost. Prices change in response to clear external suppliers has often been necessary to ensure the appropriate
stimuli, like movements in the costs of major raw materials such cutbacks. This might be no more than following the example set
as crude oil. They are also responsive to their setter’s financial by a dominant market leader, such as International Nickel in
needs and changes in productive capacity, which often go together. nickel, or the former Amax in molybdenum. More than that
Customers claim to like producer prices because of their invites a legal riposte. The US has long had legislation
apparent stability and their air of predictability. The infrequent prohibiting collusive action in restraint of trade, but the diligence
changes enable consumers to plan ahead with confidence, with which it has been enforced has varied. The legal sanctions
especially where their purchasing is subject to annual cash include possible imprisonment of those individuals found guilty
budgeting. That has been the typical pattern not just for and the threat of triple damages for any aggrieved parties.
state-owned companies and government departments but also for Even where producers’ published list prices have been
major purchasers such as automobile producers. In the apparently stable for long periods, the prices at which business is
immediate post-war decades, producers set prices for most actually transacted can diverge markedly. Large customers may
minerals and metals and true market-related pricing was enjoy volume discounts that rise when market conditions
relatively rare. deteriorate and other forms of incentive then creep in. When
The stability of producer pricing was (and is) more apparent demand presses against the limits of capacity and redundant
than real. It is impossible to maintain complete control over both plant has been brought into service premiums may be imposed
prices and the volume purchased, except under total monopoly. on groups of customers, or even on all. Moreover, rationing will
No matter how clever the forecasters, there are always sometimes be introduced, with long-established customers
unexpected changes in the balance between supply and demand. favoured over casual trade. That naturally creates a constituency
Stable prices are only realisable where suppliers are prepared to amongst the aggrieved parties in support of potential new
reduce their offerings when markets are over-supplied and to entrants. It was International Nickel’s inability to supply nickel
expand their offerings rapidly in times of shortage. That in turn during a strike in 1969, and the ensuing acute shortages, that
means a willingness to stockpile and even reduce production in triggered a massive exploration boom and the subsequent
weak markets and to raise output rapidly in the boom. This development of new mines elsewhere. That in turn undermined
implies that there will be a degree of over-capacity throughout International Nickel’s hold on the nickel market.

66 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

Typically producers’ list prices have tended to rise over time, TABLE 7.3
at least in money terms, with cost-justified, or market-driven, The history of producer pricing in major non-ferrous metals.
increases much more common than price cuts introduced when
Aluminium: The US Producer Price (Alcoa) was dropped in 1986.
conditions are bad. The burden of those is taken more on Alcan’s World Price was the yardstick for pricing outside the US to the
volumes supplied. The benefits of productivity improvements of end of 1988. It co-existed with various free-market quotations. LME
all types are not fully passed on to customers, except when new pricing began in 1979 and progressively superseded producer pricing.
entrants threaten to undermine the established order. Indeed, Copper: Central African and Chilean producers set a producer price
effective producer pricing may discourage suppliers from between 1961 and 1966, when it collapsed. Most sales outside the US
pursuing productivity as aggressively as those who are forced have subsequently been based on LME prices. Within the US producer
continuously to lower their costs to survive in periods of falling pricing continued until well into the 1980s.
market prices. The inherent discipline of market pricing is one Lead: Within the US posted producer prices persist, but the vast
reason why producers always nostalgically incline towards majority of the lead industry has long used LME prices as their pricing
producer pricing. basis.
The ability of producers to set prices has been gradually Nickel: International Nickel posted its world producer price until
weakened not just by trade liberalisation but also by the spread December 1987. LME quotations began in late 1978. For much of the
of demand away from its traditional locations, and by the 1970s there was heavy discounting from posted producer prices, and
development of new facilities to meet that rising demand. In the free market prices were more reliable guides to transaction prices. LME
quotations now dominate.
immediate post-war decade the US was the dominant producer
and user of minerals and metals, and prices were heavily Tin: Prices in the London and Penang markets, which were the basis of
most trade in tin, were effectively controlled by the operations of the
influenced by the actions of US companies. Gradually, first
International Tin Council (ITC) between 1956 and October 1985. With
Western Europe, then Japan and more recently other countries, the collapse of the ITC, prices became entirely market-determined.
emerged to challenge the US hegemony. Simultaneously, the
Zinc: Most global business is now based on LME prices. Within the
nationalisation of foreign-owned mines and processing plants by
US producers posted prices until 1993. Elsewhere most producers
many countries, particularly (but not exclusively) in the nominally used the International Producer Price from its inception in
developing world, weakened the ability of US companies to July 1964 until its final demise in 1988. Its hold weakened from the
control supply. The newly state-owned companies were often mid 1970s, as described in the main text.
mainly concerned with maximising their throughput and revenues.
Also, new mines and plants were established in developing demise of the European producer pricing system for zinc during
countries, often by state enterprises. These lacked any established the late 1970s. It was, however, already suffering from
marketing experience and they were initially content to sell differences of interest between the different suppliers. Given its
through merchants, who could grant credit as well as obtain access fungible nature, there is nothing to distinguish between metal of
to markets. Aluminium was far from alone in this regard, although a given quality from different producers. Some are fully
investment in new aluminium smelters was stimulated by the oil integrated from mine to refinery, whereas others are not. Custom
price rises and changing energy costs of the 1970s. smelters face a fluctuating market for their raw materials as well
Another nail in the coffin of producer prices for products that as for their products. Costs of production, responsiveness to
are produced and sold in a range of countries was the collapse of fluctuating exchange rates and ability to vary output varied
the post-war system of fixed exchange rates that culminated in widely between producers. There was no long-term community
the devaluation of the US dollar in 1971. This ushered in a of interest between the different producers that would persuade
regime of floating exchange rates that was initially them to tailor their supply to demand for long periods, or to build
accompanied by rampant cost and price inflation. Although up their own stocks rather than sell into the market, and cheating
currencies could (and did) change their parities under the regime was rife. There was a tendency to set producer prices at a high
of fixed rates, such changes were infrequent. The prevailing enough level to placate the least efficient producer. That
assumption, broadly justified by experience, was of stability. discouraged consumption and provided scope for the more
Nearly all producer prices were denominated in US dollars, efficient to expand. It also eased the path for new entrants who
which had been regarded as a completely stable yardstick. may have been outside the system. Excess capacity inevitably
Floating exchange rates soon undermined that faith and resulted. The aftershocks of the collapse of producer pricing
contributed to diverging interests between producers with reverberated around the zinc industry for years.
different currencies, let alone between them and consumers. There was always a tendency for all producer prices to be too
What was a stable price in one currency was not necessarily inflexible in response to changing market conditions and over the
stable in another, which meant that fixed dollar prices no longer long term to be set too high. The world copper producer price of
provided unequivocal signals about the changing balance the late 1950s and early 1960s probably accentuated the
between supply and demand. Producers with appreciating over-supply of the early 1960s. The European zinc producer
currencies saw their receipts shrink in their own currencies, price and the stable nickel producer prices of the 1970s also
sometimes even when dollar prices rose. Conversely, those with tended to create excess capacity during the 1970s. Inevitably
some countries or companies will not actively participate in
devaluing currencies saw their domestic revenues rise even when
producer price schemes but will exploit them to full advantage.
markets were oversupplied and dollar prices eased. The stability
These, rather than the active participants, gain the most. Over the
of producer pricing, and hence one of its basic rationales, was
longer term there is a tendency to cheat and to discount in
undermined. Domestic prices still diverge even when global periods of weak demand.
prices are market-determined and currencies fluctuate, but no
one has ever claimed that market-driven prices are stable. Aside from any tendency for over-rigid producer prices to
encourage excess capacity, there is a need to fund large stocks in
A summary of the history of producer pricing in non-ferrous periods of weak demand. If producer prices are to be credible
metals appears in Table 7.3. compared with free market quotations, the latter must be
Collusive action to fix prices has long been illegal in the US, supported, however thin the market. In a severe recession almost
but overseas markets had not been subject to similar anti-trust limitless funds and nerves of steel are needed to support a given
legislation. That changed during the early 1970s, with the price. Unless the support level is carefully chosen, the available
development of the European Union’s competition policy. As funds will run out, market prices will plunge and the participants
discussed in the previous section, anti-trust actions forced the will be faced with large book losses.

Australian Mineral Economics 67


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

That collusive action amongst suppliers to enforce list prices Comex Division, the Tokyo Commodity Exchange started an
is illegal in the major industrial economies by no means rules out aluminium contract in 1997, Kuala Lumpur trades tin and
producer pricing. Some other countries lack effective anti-trust Shanghai deals in several metals. New York, Tokyo, Hong Kong,
rules, or may accept that the resultant price stability is beneficial São Paulo and the London Bullion Market trade precious metals.
to their export earnings. The publication of list prices, even Crude oil and natural gas are quoted by Nymex and the
without collusive action, is still common in the minor metals International Petroleum Exchange in London.
and some industrial minerals. It often co-exists with a dealer
(or merchant) market in which prices are far more volatile. This The London Metal Exchange
is not just because the latter quickly reflects changes in the
balance between the global supply and demand, but also because The London Metal Exchange was first established in 1877. It was
merchants will gain access to varying proportions of the total extensively re-organised in 1987 following the default of the
supply over the course of the business cycle. In good times International Tin Council and the passage of the United
producers will control a much greater share of the total supply Kingdom’s Financial Services Act, and became a limited
than when conditions are depressed. Customers may have more company owned by its shareholders in 2001. Its activities are
than they need and offload the excess onto merchants. closely related to the physical metals trade, but it had to be fitted
When merchant prices diverge from list prices in either into the framework established under the Financial Services Act.
direction for extended periods, the producers’ list prices become It is a Recognised Investment Exchange regulated directly by the
merely nominal and of little practical relevance. In time they may Financial Services Authority, which closely defines the
be completely withdrawn and all pricing then becomes based on conditions under which the Exchange operates, and above all
the merchant market. Prices are usually indicated through regular requires that it maintains orderly markets in all its contracts. In
compilations in the technical press of the averages or ranges of its activities in the US, such as the listing of approved
the quotations of individual merchants for specified grades and warehouses, the Exchange is governed by the relevant US
volumes. No matter how assiduous and careful the compilers of legislation and by the Commodities and Futures Trade
such prices, there is no guarantee that much trade actually takes Commission (the CFTC). It is also subject to any relevant
place at them. They are indicative at best. On occasion, market Directives of the European Union. The Exchange is responsible
participants have raised strong concerns about the validity of for maintaining and policing its trading rules and regulations.
some published prices. A branch of the Financial Services Authority regulates the
For many market participants, price transparency is a mixed commercial and ethical conduct of its members. Although the
blessing. There is often dispute about the relevance of published Exchange is based in London, foreign companies ultimately own
prices to particular trades. Those purchasers who have managed most of its members and it is a truly global market.
to obtain special deals and their suppliers, often prefer secrecy A historical summary of LME contracts appears in Table 7.4.
rather than publicity. Prices are something agreed between The copper, lead and zinc contracts have a long history, as do
consenting adults in private, rather than blazoned over the pages those for tin. Trading in the latter, however, was halted after the
of the technical press. Traders also thrive where they can exploit collapse of the International Tin Council in October 1985 and
their unique knowledge of market conditions. Even so, the next only resumed in 1989. The zinc contract was given new leases of
logical step from a large merchant-based market with opaque life by the final demise of European producer pricing in the
price formation is the transfer of the process of price discovery to 1980s and by the adoption of an LME pricing base by the US in
some form of terminal market. That not only enhances 1993. Trading in aluminium started in 1978 and nickel followed
in 1979. Their respective industries initially shunned both
transparency, but offers opportunities for hedging price risk.
contracts and it was some years before they were fully accepted

TERMINAL MARKETS
The essence of terminal markets is that prices are set at least on a TABLE 7.4
daily basis to balance that day’s marginal offerings and demand. London Metal Exchange contracts.
Directly or indirectly, those prices govern all that day’s Copper: 1877, with specification periodically changed. First official
transactions, whether or not they are actually made through the LME contract 1883. Present Grade A contract June 1986.
exchanges. The offerings and demand may come not only from
Tin: 1877, with specifications periodically changed. Contract
industrial companies, whether producers or users, but also from suspended 25 October 1985 and re-introduced June 1989. First official
merchants and investors of all types. Thus supply and demand in LME contract 1883.
these markets are much broader than production (whether of
Pig iron: 1877 until 1920s.
primary or secondary material) and industrial usage.
Lead: 1920, but traded unofficially before then. The specifications
Terminal markets may have four main interlocking functions, have been periodically changed.
which they fulfil in varying degrees. These are:
Zinc: 1920, but traded unofficially before then. The specifications have
• the determination of daily reference prices for the products been periodically changed. Present Special High Grade 99.995%
traded; contract introduced June 1986.
• the provision of facilities for hedging against price risk; Aluminium: December 1978, with the contract changed to High Grade
in August 1987.
• acting as a market of last resort through a dedicated
warehouse network; and Nickel: April 1979, with specifications periodically changed.

• giving opportunities for investment in metals as assets. Silver: 1969 until mid 1989. New contract in May 1999 suspended in
March 2002.
Each exchange has its different methods and traditions. The Aluminium alloy: October 1992.
leading terminal market for trading non-ferrous metals is the
London Metal Exchange (LME), which accounts for over 90 North American Special Aluminium Alloy Contract (NAASC):
March 2002.
per cent of global exchange business for those metals it trades.
These are aluminium, aluminium alloy or secondary aluminium, Index: April 2000. Based on the six major metals.
copper, lead, nickel, tin and zinc. The New York Mercantile Polypropylene and linear low density polyethylene: 27 May 2005.
Exchange (Nymex) trades copper and aluminium through its

68 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

as being representative. The contract for aluminium alloy began traded today. The contracts specify minimum standards, which
trading in early 1992 and was also slow to gain acceptance. It many producers easily exceed. The daily prices do not
was joined by a North American aluminium alloy contract distinguish between the individual registered brands, but brokers
(NASAAC) in March 2002. Pig iron was traded for a period until and traders may pay premiums for particular brands that are
the 1920s and trading in silver began in 1969, ceased in mid especially in demand. Similarly, the price is for delivery into or
1989, resumed on a new basis in May 1999 and was suspended out of any registered warehouse, no matter where it is located,
once more in March 2002. The relative importance of each and premiums may be established for specific locations.
contract varies annually depending on the market conditions for Whether they are concluded on or off the ring, all LME
each metal. In 2003 aluminium accounted for almost 39 per cent
contracts are cleared through the London Clearing House.
of the total number of lots traded, copper for nearly 28 per cent
Before the clearing arrangements were introduced in 1987,
and zinc for 15 per cent. Lead and nickel each provided around
brokers acted as principals, which meant that the market’s users
six per cent of the lots traded, and the two aluminium alloy
faced a risk of their broker defaulting. The clearing mechanism
contracts for roughly two per cent. Trading in two plastics
contracts started in May 2005. offers security to all users of the market that their contracts will
be honoured, even if the initiating broker were to go bankrupt.
Only a very small percentage of the volume of non-ferrous The prime distinguishing feature of LME contracts is that they
metal produced and traded is physically delivered into LME are not cash cleared. In other words, users of the market do not
registered warehouses, but the bulk of the world’s non-ferrous have to contribute additional cash when their contracts are
metals are traded by reference to LME prices, and the LME making losses, nor can they take out profits ahead of the prompt
captures by far the greater share of hedging business. Trading is date; rather the contracts are cleared against bank guarantees,
by open outcry across a ring, in which the dealers sit and shout
with brokers granting credit to their clients. Most trade users also
their bids or offers. This is backed up by a telephone-based
do not insist that their business is segregated. These features
inter-dealer market outside ring trading sessions and by a screen
make the Exchange particularly useful for trade users, who do
trading system, LME Select, which system was first introduced
not have to commit variable and uncertain amounts of working
in early 2001 and has been gradually refined. Like the telephone
capital to use the market.
market, it is only open to trading between LME member brokers.
The share of total LME business transacted through the Ring Other exchanges that trade in metal futures or in energy
itself has gradually declined to under two-fifths. products, like the New York Mercantile Exchange, are cash
cleared. It was the ability to take out paper profits when prices
The basic contract for each metal is for three months forward, were rising that enabled the Hunt Brothers to drive up silver
with each working day being good for delivery against the prices so dramatically in 1979-80, when they were attempting to
prompt, or delivery dates. Daily cash prices are also fixed, with corner the silver market. They could reinvest their paper profits
additional prices for 15 months ahead for lead and tin, going to in margins on yet more futures contracts. When the bubble burst
27 months for nickel, zinc and aluminium alloys and to and prices started falling, repeated calls for additional cash
63 months for aluminium and copper. The period for those two margin accelerated and accentuated the decline of genuine
was extended from 27 months in September 2002. The prices are hedging as well as speculative business.
strictly forward prices for future delivery on specified dates
rather than the futures prices traded in most other markets such Credit clearing makes it easier for the metals industry to use
as Nymex. This is one of the LME’s distinguishing features. All the market to hedge against price risks. Hedging is the
prices are fixed in US dollars, the prime currency of the elimination of uncertainty at a known cost. Users of the market
non-ferrous metals industry, but with facilities for also clearing with future commitments for purchase or delivery of physical
in sterling, Japanese yen and euros. metal can buy or sell an equivalent and offsetting forward
The prices established by open outcry at the close of the contract that matures at the same time. The prices are known
second or official rings become the official settlement prices for today. When the time comes to deliver or buy, the user can close
each day’s trading. These rings concentrate bids and offers from out the forward contract and take either a loss or a profit to set
the whole world into one brief and orgasmic trading session, against the offsetting profit or loss on the physical contract. The
which reaches its climax at the closing bell. The prices reflect the liquidity of each contract tends to diminish rapidly the further
marginal tonnage offered and demanded that day, no matter the forward they go beyond three months.
source or the destination. They inevitably fluctuate daily, but In addition to conventional forward contracts, the LME also
broadly reflect, under normal circumstances, the global markets’ trades options. These give the purchaser or the seller the right, but
balance of supply and demand. not the obligation, to buy or sell at the strike price. The premium
Trade is conducted in lots rather than tonnes, with each lot of paid for this right varies inversely with the amount by which the
aluminium, copper, lead and zinc amounting to 25 tonnes. Nickel strike price varies from prevailing price levels. It is like an
is traded in six tonne lots, tin in five tonnes and aluminium alloys insurance premium to protect against a known event. The LME’s
in 20 tonnes. Prices are set for metal that meets the prevailing traded options are mainly so-called European options, which
contract specifications, which are established with reference to refer to prices on specified future dates, the third Wednesday of
the needs of the producing and using industries. Individual each month. Most users are much more interested in achieving
producers’ brands that meet the contract specifications can be average prices over a period, such as a month or a year. Until 1997
registered and are good for delivery once they have been tested the substantial and fast growing business in Asian options of this
and accepted. The contract for each metal sets out the shapes, type was conducted ‘over the counter’ (OTC) in deals specifically
weights and methods of strapping. The contract specifications tailored for the individual users. The LME introduced traded
are not for the lowest common denominator of industry’s needs, average price options (TAPOs) in early 1997, initially for
but for that quality and shape which is most widely traded and aluminium and copper but now for all the metals, to provide the
demanded. Specifications have tended to rise over the years. In protection of the clearing mechanism to such widely used
the 1980s, for example, the aluminium specification was raised contracts, and to increase market transparency by bringing them
from a minimum of 99.5 per cent aluminium to 99.7 per cent, into the open. Most OTC options deals are denominated in US
and the copper contract moved from wirebars to Grade A cents per pound of metal, whereas LME contracts are expressed in
cathode. The quality of zinc has been progressively raised, US dollars per tonne. The LME strike prices have, therefore, been
initially from good ordinary brand to high grade, and then the too coarse and inconvenient for it to attract as much business to its
special high grade with minimum 99.995 per cent zinc that is contracts as it initially expected.

Australian Mineral Economics 69


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

Metal brokers can provide an infinite variety of combinations of We always have to be cautious in attributing sharp and
forward prices and options to cover virtually any eventuality. The unexpected shifts in prices to the speculators. However good the
underlying mathematics and the jargon of these price derivatives statistics about consumption and production in the recent past,
can be complex, but their basic function is to enable producers and prices also reflect expected trends. We do not always have
users of metals to eliminate the risk of uncertain volatile prices at sufficient knowledge about the present and the future. Forecasts
a known cost. The use of options overcomes one of the basic usually cluster together and they are often wrong, perhaps
problems of forward contracts, which lock in specified prices. Use because of random shocks. Sometimes market sentiment can
of those denies the seller the benefit of any upside if prices at the change dramatically, almost overnight, and prices have to catch
time of delivery greatly exceed the contract’s forward price, and up. Sharp and apparently inexplicable price movements can often
the purchaser the benefit of any fall below the forward price. The
be explained retrospectively by fundamental forces. Speculative
latter is particularly important for fabricators who are actively
investment tends to even out over time and prices do broadly
competing for business and operating on tight margins. One of
their major concerns is that their competitors do not buy their raw reflect relative shifts in supply and demand. At times, however,
materials on more favourable terms. No matter what combination ‘investment’ in metals as such can become substantial and prices
of hedging mechanisms is used, it is always the responsibility of can then be driven up or down more than might seemingly be
the user’s management to ensure that it is aware of exactly what is warranted by underlying trends in supply and demand.
being done and of the potential risks involved. The well-publicised Much of the LME’s turnover arises from its use as a market of
incidents in which companies have lost heavily in metals trading last resort. LME contracts provide for physical delivery, and in
have all been ultimately traceable back to lax management in the support there is a network of registered warehouses throughout
affected companies. the world (see Figure 7.5). The Exchange itself does not own or
The growth of options trading has been of especial value to operate the warehouses nor does it own the metal they contain. It
investors in metals, who are known pejoratively as speculators. approves warehouse locations, with the objective of having a
There always have to be individuals or firms who are prepared to widespread network throughout the world in all important areas
invest in metals in order to provide adequate liquidity to the of net consumption. Warehouse locations must have appropriate
market. Without such liquidity, the costs of hedging could fiscal and regulatory systems, be served by a good transport
become prohibitive. Moreover, prices could periodically swing network, have the facility to store goods without payment of duty
uncontrollably in one direction or another unless there were and enjoy political and economic stability. These requirements
always people who were willing and able to take contrary views rule out some apparently desirable locations. Once locations
to the market as a whole. Trade use of the LME still accounts, on
have been decided, warehouse companies may apply to open
average, for around 80 per cent of its total business, but the
Exchange’s turnover greatly exceeds the global production and facilities. The contract between the Exchange and those
use of each metal. In 2003 the multiples of LME turnover to companies that satisfy its criteria sets out the warehouse
global output varied from 17 for lead, up to 34 for copper, with company’s rights and obligations and provides for a disciplinary
nickel at 22, aluminium at 26 and zinc at 28. The multiples were procedure. Metal of approved brands may be delivered into a
much lower (three to six) for the aluminium alloy contracts. warehouse to satisfy delivery commitments in exchange for LME
These large multiples by no means reflect the amount of warrants. These are bearer documents giving title to a specific
speculative activity. A proportion of LME turnover comes from parcel of metal in a specified warehouse. The terms on which
brokers adjusting contract dates and volumes to meet the precise metal is delivered and stored are agreed between the warehouse
needs of their customers. companies and the companies who deliver it.

5 locations in the UK; all metals. 19 th century to 1994

12 locations, 6 countries in Europe: all metals 1962 to 1995

2 locations in Korea; not zinc 2001


7 locations in USA; all metals 1991 -98
4 locations in Japan; aluminium 1989

2 locations in Malaysia; all metals 2004

Singapore; all metals 1987

Dubai; not aluminium 1999 -2001

FIG 7.5 - LME registered warehouse locations in 2004. Note: the number of locations was increased during the 1990s to cope with an inflow of
metal associated with the collapse of the former Soviet Union and a global recession, and several little-used locations were recently de-listed.

70 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

When markets are over-supplied, metal flows into warehouses When, for one reason or another, there is a shortage of metal
and moves out again when markets tighten. Movements in the for immediate delivery, prices move into a backwardation. That
stocks held in LME-registered warehouses are thus useful means that cash prices for immediate delivery rise above the
bellwethers of market conditions. Over the years there has been a forward prices. There may be sound fundamental reasons for a
progressive move towards placing a greater proportion of surplus backwardation, like a prolonged shortage of supply relative to
metal in LME warehouses. This partly reflects the growing use buoyant demand, perhaps caused by transport disruptions or a
of the Exchange for hedging and as a price reference and the strike at a major producer. The only cure is an influx of metal
extension of the warehouse network. Warehouses were originally into LME warehouses that is sufficient to restore balance. A
confined to the UK, with locations first authorised in mainland backwardation often makes it worthwhile for those who have
Europe during the 1960s. Singapore and Japan followed in the excess tonnage, however temporarily, to deliver into warehouses
late 1980s and the US in 1991. Dubai and Korea were added in in order to earn a rate of return that may greatly exceed the cost
2001, although Dubai was good for silver delivery from 1999 to of finance. The emergence of bubbles in the pattern of prices is,
2002, and Malaysia was being registered in 2004. Some locations however, often a sign that someone is attempting to squeeze the
may not store particular metals, either because they are close to market. In other words, they may have gained control of the
major producing areas such as Singapore was historically with greater part of the available LME inventory and also have large
tin (until the LME lifted this limitation in 2002), or because of
long positions which give them potential access to far more
local restrictions on trade. Thus Japanese warehouses only store
metal than they need to meet their future commitments. Those
aluminium, Dubai does not take aluminium and Korea may not
who are short will have to pay the backwardation or borrow
accept zinc. LME copper trading only commenced in the US in
metal at a cost in order to meet their commitments. Occasionally
1995.
a merchant may inadvertently ‘squeeze’ the market, but more
The growth of LME stocks relative to total reported usually there will be deliberate manipulation, which offends
inventories is also part of, and primarily mirrors, a global trend
against the preservation of orderly markets, one of the LME’s
towards reducing the amount of working capital tied up. If metal
is held in LME registered warehouses, there is much less need to prime functions as a Recognised Investment Exchange.
hold stocks in producers’ or consumers’ yards, and no need for Backwardations raise the costs of hedging for physical users of
the metals industry itself to arrange their financing. LME the market, sometimes prohibitively. They can also distort the
warehouses became magnets for surplus metal during the validity of LME quotations as reference prices for the global
recessions of the early 1990s. Excess western supplies were metals industry. The LME’s Rules and Regulations give it
greatly augmented by outflows from eastern countries. Although considerable powers to prevent manipulation and punish any
much of the latter was not registered for LME delivery, it partly members who break those rules. Unfortunately, although it is
displaced metal that was, allowing the latter to be delivered into relatively easy for market participants to suspect when a price is
warehouses. Had the surplus metal not gone into LME being manipulated, proof is usually difficult. Also, the Exchange
warehouses, most of it would have been absorbed elsewhere and has no jurisdiction over either the parallel physical market or
there would have been little, if any, cutback in production beyond non-LME business. Squeezes may often be engineered in the
what actually occurred. From 1994 onwards the tonnage of metal over-the-counter market rather than in LME contracts, although
held in warehouses contracted, but the withdrawals did not
they find their full flowering in the behaviour of LME
necessarily flow into final consumption. Much was taken out of
quotations. The best defence against market manipulation is the
LME-registered facilities, partly to reduce its visibility and
influence prices. The expectation was that final demand would greatest possible transparency in all types of trade. Since
soon rise sufficiently to absorb excess stocks. In actuality mid-1996 the LME has greatly increased the amount of
demand rose less than expected and LME stocks levelled out. information that it publishes, but it always faces a difficult
The spread of the LME’s warehouse network from its balancing act. An excessive insistence on transparency could
predominantly European focus changed LME prices from mainly lead to trade drying up or being driven offshore, or to
reflecting European balances between supply and demand into over-the-counter markets that are outside the scope of any
global indicators. That in turn altered the structure of premiums regulation. That would not necessarily be in the users’ best long-
over and above LME prices for delivery in particular locations. term interests.
The LME’s settlement prices will inevitably reflect the balance The LME’s main competitor, the New York Mercantile
between deliveries of metal into warehouses and shipments out. Exchange, has claimed that it has lost trade to the LME because
There may be net inflows in some locations at the same time as the latter has been less tightly regulated. Close inspection
metal is flowing out elsewhere. Not all locations and warehouses indicates that the methods of regulation in London and New York
are equally accessible or convenient and the charges for are certainly very different, but that the LME is no less tightly
removing metal vary. The warehouse companies in the less controlled and policed than its US counterpart. The main reason
favoured locations have sometimes offered inducements to that the LME captured most of the global business in non-ferrous
traders to place metal in their warehouses, and once it is there it metals is that its contracts and methods of trading have been
tends to stick. more suited to the needs of trade users than those operated in
The wider the warehouse network, the easier it becomes to New York. The LME’s main attractions include its system of
deliver metal onto warrant when markets are tight. When markets prompt dates, its extensive warehouse network and its credit
are well supplied they are usually in contango. In other words, rather than cash clearing. It also straddles the three main global
prices for future delivery exceed cash prices by a margin that time zones, picking up the close of business in Asian markets
represents the costs of storage and insurance and the rate of early in the day and overlapping with New York in the afternoon.
interest, or the time value of money. To the extent that warehouse Finally, the UK does not have a large domestic mining and
companies offer any special deals on rents, the normal contango smelting industry with vested interests, but it has a long tradition
will be reduced. Other things being equal, a rise in warehouse of open markets and liberal trading. The Comex Division of the
rents or interest rates would be accompanied by a widening of New York Mercantile Exchange has much lower liquidity, with
the contango. Often, however, such an adjustment would be trade concentrated on hedging by domestic US companies and on
swamped by other influences on prices. The further forward the speculative investment business. A considerable amount of its
quoted price, the greater the margin above cash prices, although trading is conducted on their own account by ‘locals’, rather than
a lack of liquidity for the far forward dates could influence the for trade clients. Arbitrage between the London and New York
relationship. Without any extraneous shocks, the relationship markets has ensured that their respective prices rarely step too far
between prices for the different delivery dates is stable. out of line with each other.

Australian Mineral Economics 71


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

The present systems will only survive, however, as long as the From 1999 onwards global growth was much greater than that of
markets’ users are content that they give prices that are properly the advanced economies, but the world economy was knocked by
representative of market conditions. The prices set are far more the latter’s recession in 2001-02. The upswing in 2003-04 was
chaotic and seemingly more haphazard than producer pricing unexpectedly strong, with overall activity rising rapidly in 2004.
systems, but more transparent and reflective of changing market Growth continued in 2005 at a slower rate (International
conditions. Monetary Fund, 2005). The strength of global activity over the
Some criticise LME prices as being excessively volatile, under period owed much to the strength of the Asian economies,
the influence of investment in metals by financial institutions of especially of China. The buoyant Chinese economy has been one
all types, often grouped under the general description of of the main forces driving demand for mineral products over the
‘speculators’. Certainly, prices can move markedly even within past decade. Its share of world output (measured on a purchasing
the course of a day, let alone from one day to the next. The power parity basis) rose from 10.2 per cent in 1988 to 13.2 per
explosive growth of options-related business also appears to have cent in 2004. This has been partly at the expense of growth
introduced extra volatility. Much of that business, however, is elsewhere, with Chinese exporters benefiting from a low cost base
conducted on the behalf of producers and fabricators insuring and an undervalued currency, but it mainly reflects strongly
against adverse future price trends. To the extent that a growing internal demand, led by heavy investment in plant,
significant proportion of annual production is protected for equipment and infrastructure.
months (or even years) ahead, that much will be less responsive The relationship between overall economic activity and the
than it might previously have been to weakening prices. The mineral and metals industry is brought out in Figure 7.7, which
protected producers will have no immediate need to cut their compares annual percentage changes in global GDP, the usage of
output because they are incurring cash losses. That in turn means refined copper and the output of crude steel. Although demand
that the burden of any excess supplies in recessions is thrown for each mineral and metal product is driven by different end-use
more heavily than in the past on prices rather than volumes. That
markets, all follow broadly similar trends. Many depend directly
alone will give the appearance of increased price volatility, but it
on the performance of the steel industry. Copper usage grew
owes nothing to speculative activity. Any genuine evidence that
particularly strongly in 1999-2000 when the US economy was
prices of non-ferrous metals have become more volatile in recent
years because of speculative activity is rather tenuous. Those booming, but it fell in 2001 and grew more slowly than global
who assert that prices have become more volatile have usually activity in 2002-03. By contrast steel production was relatively
looked at trends over relatively short periods and have failed to weak in 1998-99, but has grown much more strongly than global
allow fully for the many factors influencing prices. GDP since 2001. Its strength derives from China’s burgeoning
output, which increased by 23 per cent in 2004 alone. China’s
production of crude steel rose from 115 Mt in 1998, under 15 per
RECENT TRENDS IN MINERAL MARKETS cent of the total, to 272 Mt (26 per cent of global production) in
At the start of the new millennium most sectors of the minerals 2004. It accounted for 57 per cent of the growth in global steel
industry seemed set for a prosperous decade. The major output over the six year period. Inevitably this rapid growth has
international political tensions that had persisted since the spilled over into strongly increased demand for raw materials
Second World War were largely resolved, market capitalism had from overseas and in that regard steel has been typical of most
seemingly triumphed over more dirigiste systems and the global minerals, including fuels.
economy was becoming increasingly unified. It had quickly 10
shrugged off the Asian crises of 1997-98 and had resumed
World GDP Refined copper usage Crude steel output
apparently healthy expansion, inflation had been tamed, currency
% change on previous year

8
markets were relatively stable and oil prices remained subdued.
Subsequent events showed that any complacency was sadly 6
misplaced and that turbulence was developing beneath an
apparently smooth surface. Led by the US, the major industrial
4
economies were on the brink of recession and new political
tensions and uncertainties were developing in the world at large.
2
Demand for mineral products is driven by economic activity,
which faltered in 2001 after a strong start to the decade.
0
Figure 7.6 shows the annual rates of change of output, both
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
globally and in the major advanced economies (Canada, USA,
Japan, France, Germany, Italy and the UK) from 1998 onwards. -2

6 -4
World
FIG 7.7 - Global GDP, copper usage and steel output, percentage
5 Major advanced economies per annum changes 1998-2004. (Sources: International Monetary
Fund, 2005; International Copper Study Group, 2005; International
Iron and Steel Institute, 2005.)
% per annum change

3
A strong global economy not only boosted demand for
non-fuel minerals, but also for fuels including petroleum. World
demand for crude oil, shown in Table 7.5, rose by 3.4 per cent in
2
2004 (the largest percentage increase for many years) forcing
demand against the constraints of effective capacity. Iraq’s output
1 had not recovered from the ravages of war and some members of
OPEC held back production. The OECD countries, led by the
0 US, raised their consumption in 2003 and 2004 after several
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 years of stagnation. The US accounts for 25 per cent of global
off-take, OECD Europe for 19 per cent and Japan for seven per
FIG 7.6 - The growth of economic activity (gross domestic product), cent. China (eight per cent) and India (three per cent) were major
1998-2005. (Source: International Monetary Fund, 2005.) contributors to the 6.7 per cent rise in non-OECD demand.

72 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

130

TABLE 7.5
World oil demand (million barrels per day).

Index numbers. January 1998=100


120
(Source: International Monetary Fund, 2005.) Major currencies

Year World OECD Non-OECD


110
1998 74.7 46.6 28
1999 76.1 47.4 28.8 US trading partners
100
2000 76.9 47.6 29.3
2001 77.4 47.5 29.9
90
2002 78.2 47.6 30.6
2003 79.6 48.1 31.5
80
2004 82.3 48.8 33.6 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

The effects of this strong growth of demand on prices were FIG 7.9 - Effective monthly average real exchange rates of the
accentuated by existing political tensions in the Middle East and US dollar. (Source: US Federal Reserve Board, 2005.)
by fears that unrest is spreading to major producers like Saudi Prices of most minerals and metals are denominated in US
Arabia. Speculative pressures were further influences in driving dollars and the US exchange rate is a strong influence on those
crude oil prices up to their highest levels in real terms since the prices. Other things being equal, a strengthening of the US dollar
1970s. In money terms, prices have never been higher. Their leads to falling dollar prices, and a weakening dollar to rising
behaviour from 1999 onwards, as expressed in the spot price of dollar prices. Many producers whose currencies strengthened
Brent crude on the International Petroleum Exchange in London, against the dollar also saw rising costs and falling margins in
is illustrated in Figure 7.8. 2000-02 to the point where they were forced to suspend or curtail
operations. The adverse impact of the currency squeeze was
60
accentuated by the simultaneous weakening of demand because
of recession. Capital spending of all types, but especially on
50 exploration and grassroots projects, was pared back as the
industry strove to minimise costs. These years witnessed a surge
40 in mergers and consolidations in many sectors of the industry,
with a pronounced peak in 2001 (Raw Materials Group, 2004).
US $/barrel

30 The gold industry was especially hard hit by weak prices in the
late 1990s and early 2000s. Exploration spending of all types, but
20
especially on gold, had peaked in 1997, and it subsequently
plummeted, not just in response to weak markets, but also
10
because of the adverse effects of the Bre-X fraud (where a gold
project in Indonesia had been hyped on the basis of non-existent
ore reserves) and the competing lure for speculative investors of
0
dot com projects. The trough in exploration spending was
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
reached in 2002, with that on gold down from 1997’s US$ 2.6
billion to under US$ 0.8 billion. Exploration for other products
FIG 7.8 - Monthly average prices of crude oil (US$/barrel for dropped from US$ 2.5 billion to US$ 1.1 billion over the same
Brent crude). (Source: International Petroleum Exchange, 2005.) period. The recovery in prices from their recessionary trough
brought a corresponding revival of exploration, with spending on
Prices had weakened in 2001-02 in response to recession, with gold rising to US$ 1.9 billion in 2004, and that on other products
the attack on the World Trade Centre in September 2001 having up to US$ 3.8 billion (Metals Economics Group, 2005).
no real impact. The Iraq war caused a minor blip in 2003, but The inverse relationship between real US dollar exchange rates
prices really only started to rise strongly during 2004. Whereas and gold prices is illustrated in Figure 7.10. Gold prices averaged
prices around the $30/barrel level had been regarded as below US$ 400 per ounce throughout the 1990s and had fallen
acceptable, their rise to over $50/barrel has raised concerns about sharply from 1996. The recovery began in late 2001, after the
possible adverse effects on global inflation and levels of attacks on the World Trade Center, and it was fostered not just by
economic activity. Forecasts of economic growth were the weakening US dollar, but also by rising international
consequently being shaved down in early 2005. Not only do high tensions. Rising oil prices and fears of resurgent inflation gave an
oil prices have potentially adverse effects on demand for mineral added boost from late 2004.
products but they also directly raise production costs. Prices of non-ferrous metals lagged behind gold prices in
In part, the rise in oil prices was initially justified by an 2002-03. In some cases capacity had outstripped demand,
accompanying weakening of the US dollar in currency markets. notwithstanding mine and plant closures and cutbacks. There
Some oil producing countries tailored their supply in order to were also large inventory overhangs, particularly in the most
raise prices sufficiently to offset the dollar’s decline, but such visible form of Exchange stocks. Their existence initially
fine-tuning is seldom possible. The performance of the US dollar moderated the impact of improving supply/demand balances on
has been a major influence on the prices of all internationally price levels. Table 7.6 shows the end-year levels of LME
traded mineral commodities. Figure 7.9 plots two measures of warehouse inventories from 1998 onwards.
the real effective exchange rate since January 1998. It LME warehouses are not the only sources of readily available
strengthened by 21 per cent against a weighted average basket of metal and stocks have moved substantially within each year.
major currencies (those of Australia, Canada, ‘Euroland’, Japan, Nonetheless, Table 7.6 gives a broad indication of the changing
Sweden, Switzerland and the UK) between October 1999 and pressures of demand for the various metals. They all danced to
February 2002. It followed a similar trend, but to a less marked the beat of economic activity, but with different timings and
extent against the currencies of a much larger group of its trading variations. Speculative activity by financial institutions of all
partners, partly because some of those currencies are pegged to types, including hedge funds, may have hastened (and even
the dollar itself. enhanced) some price rises, but the basic determinants were

Australian Mineral Economics 73


CHAPTER 7: MINERAL MARKETS, PRICES AND THE RECENT PERFORMANCE OF THE MINERALS AND ENERGY SECTOR

160
Until recent years, demand grew relatively slowly and producers
150
were fairly reluctant to invest in capacity in anticipation of future
Gold price sales. In consequence the 2003-04 spurt in demand created
Index numbers January 1998=100

140 supply bottlenecks and suppliers seized their advantage with


sharp price rises. Mine expansions and new capacity are under
130 construction that will improve the market balance within a few
years, but markets will remain tight in the interim. Contractual
120
US dollar prices of internationally traded thermal coal rose by
110
nearly 70 per cent in 2004, whilst those of coking coal rose by
about 26 per cent in 2004 and by roughly 116 per cent for 2005
100 deliveries. Prices of iron ore also jumped for 2005 deliveries, but
by a more modest 71.5 per cent. Even allowing for the
90
weakening of the US dollar, producers are earning handsome
80
profits at these prices and potential new entrants are jostling for
35796 35977 36161 36342 36526 36708 36892 37073 37257 37438 37622 37803 37987 38169 38353 position. Figure 7.12 compares yearly index numbers of prices of
iron ore and of base metals. Iron ore had lagged until the 2005
FIG 7.10 - Index numbers of monthly average gold prices and real price settlements.
effective exchange rates of the US dollar against major currencies. 260
(Source: US Federal Reserve Board, 2005; London Bullion Market
240 Iron ore
Association, 2005.) (Hamersley fines to Japan f.o.b.)
220

Index numbers 1999=100


200
TABLE 7.6
Inventories in LME warehouses at year-end, 1998-2004 180

(thousands of tonnes). (Source: London Metal Exchange, 2005.) 160

Year Aluminium Copper Lead Nickel Tin Zinc 140

1998 635 592 108 66 8 317 120

1999 774 790 176 47 9 279 100


Non-ferrous metals
2000 322 357 131 10 13 195 80 (The Economist index)
2001 821 799 98 19 31 433 60
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
2002 1241 856 184 22 26 651
FIG 7.12 - Index numbers of prices of iron ore and non-ferrous
2003 1423 460 109 24 14 740
metals, re-based on 1999 = 100. (Sources: The Economist, 2005;
2004 695 49 40 21 8 629 Metal Bulletin, 2005; Mining Journal, 2005.)

improving demand and a weakening US dollar. Figure 7.11 Many commentators in late 2004 and early 2005 were
shows the behaviour of a weighted average index of non-ferrous heralding a lengthy period of strong prosperity for the metals and
metal prices from the start of 1999. Prices rose during 1999, but minerals industry. Few had properly observed the lessons of
levelled out in 2000 and fell back between September 2000 and history that barriers to entry are fairly low and that demand is
late 2001. The recovery did not really get into its proper stride dependent not just on the performance of a single country
until after May 2003. (however bright its prospects might seem) but on a complex
That the rise in prices sprang from much more than speculative interplay of global forces. Profitability depends on the ratio
activity in a terminal market was shown by the simultaneous between prices and costs and many of the factors that lowered
improvement of the prices of many minor metals, of industrial costs in the preceding decade or so have worked themselves out,
minerals and of bulk minerals, including coal and iron ore. The or have even reversed.
latter two have greatly benefited from China’s burgeoning
demand, but their latest price increases should be judged against REFERENCES
their lacklustre performance for much of the preceding decade.
British Petroleum, 2004. BP statistical review of world energy [online].
Whereas the non-ferrous metals are priced on terminal markets, Available from: <http://www.bp.com>.
which provide both opportunities for hedging price risk and a
International Copper Study Group, 2005. [Online] <http://www.icsg.org>.
market of last resort, producers of bulk minerals have neither.
International Iron and Steel Institute, 2005. [Online]
160
<http://www.worldsteel.org>.
International Monetary Fund, 2005. World economic outlook database,
150 April [online]. Available from: <http://www.imf.org>.
140 International Petroleum Exchange, 2005. [Online] <http://www.ipe.com>
Index numbers 2000=100

now listed under Intercontinental Exchange: <http://www.theice.com>.


130 London Bullion Market Association, 2005. [Online]
120 <http://www.lbma.org.uk>.
London Metal Exchange, 2005. [Online] <http://www.lme.co.uk>.
110
Metal Bulletin, 2005. [Online] <http://www.metalbulletin.com>.
100 Metals Economics Group, 2005. [Online]
<http://www.metalseconomics.com>.
90
Mining Journal, 2005. [Online] <http://www.mining-journal.com>.
80 Raw Materials Group, 2004. Database, May, Stockholm, Sweden.
70 Smith, A, 1976 [1776]. An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Jan-99 Jan-00 Jan-01 Jan-02 Jan-03 Jan-04 Jan-05 Wealth of Nations (eds: R H Campbell, A S Skinner and W B Todd)
(Oxford University Press: Oxford).
FIG 7.11 - The Economist index of non-ferrous metal prices. The Economist, 2005. [Online] <http://www.economist.com>.
Monthly averages, 2000 = 100. (Source: The Economist, 2005.) US Federal Reserve Board, 2005. [Online] <http://www.federalreserve.gov>.

74 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 8

The Mineral Sector Workforce


Philip Maxwell

A Global Perspective
Mineral Sector Employment in Australia
Important Mineral Sector Workforce Issues
Summary and Conclusion

A GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
In those developed nations with strong non-renewable resource More
sectors, mining operations are capital and technology intensive. Capital
(and technology) Major Large mines
While only employing small numbers, these operations require intensive mineral in developed
highly professional workforces. The wages and salaries of such exporters nations
personnel are high. The combination of professional workforces,
large capital investment and modern technology has ensured that Factor Large mines
intensity in
countries such as Canada and Australia have maintained their developing
international mineral sector competitiveness in the last half of the in mines
nations
Large mines in
20th century and into the new millennium. transition
Recall the nature of the economist’s production function: economies

Artisanal and
Output = f (land, labour, capital, environment) More small-scale mining
labour
intensive

Capital, land (mineral endowment) and technology are More


Less
relatively more important factors than labour, though the developed developed
personnel employed need to be well-trained and professional.
Stage of national development
The situation is often different in developing nations that have
strong mineral economies. In the ‘formal’ mining sector, lower
wage structures typically mean that workforces are larger and FIG 8.1 - Relative capital and labour intensity in operating mines.
that managers can use more unskilled labour. Capital intensity is
not so high. Hence, a large mine may employ a workforce of 400 A conceptual view of mineral sector employment and its
people in countries like Australia or Canada, but a mine relationship to the capital (and technical) intensity in mines
producing a similar level of output in Indonesia, Papua New appears in Figure 8.1. The upward arrows reflect recent and
Guinea or Tanzania, might employ, say, 2000 people. There are continuing trends towards greater substitution of capital and
some developing nations (such as Chile and Peru) that have work technology for labour.
forces more typical of the developed countries than those like
PNG or Indonesia. The formal mining sector
It is also important to mention mining employment in those
While the International Labour Organisation (ILO) collects
economies in transition between socialism and capitalism, most employment data for most nations in a systematic way, there are
of which now meet our definition of developing nations. In the presently no comprehensive official estimates of the size of the
resource-rich nations of the former Soviet Union and Eastern world’s mining sector workforce. The indicative data for the year
Europe, and in countries such as China, Vietnam and Mongolia, 2001 shown in Table 8.1 come from the ILO and the work of
mines typically employ relatively large workforces. This is a Hilson (2002). They cover Europe, North and South America and
legacy of a previous system that ensured full employment for the Australia in a reasonably comprehensive way but there are
populace, even though wage levels were low. notable gaps for Africa and for many Asian nations. The estimate
As will be seen, artisanal and small-scale mining is also of just over one million people for employment in large and
important in many developing nations. This is labour-intensive medium mines in these other nations may be low. Recognising
mining with little use of sophisticated physical capital or these limitations, our estimates suggest that there were more than
technology. 19 million people employed in mining in 2001.

Australian Mineral Economics 75


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

mining sector to be much higher. Employment in the iron ore


TABLE 8.1
industry makes an important contribution to the total.
An indicative estimate of the world’s mining workforce in
2001, including metals, non-metals and energy minerals. At first glance, it seems surprising that Canada’s mineral
(Source: International Labour Organization, 2004; Hilson, 2002.) sector employment of more than 170 000 in 2001 is more than
twice that of Australia’s. As in the US, well over half of this is
The formal mining sector based in the oil and gas sector, while only around 46 000
European nations ’000 Major exporters ’000 represent employment in coal, uranium and the non-fuel minerals
Bulgaria 37 Australia 75
sectors.
Among the developing nations, China stands out dramatically
Czech Republic 67 Brazil 118
with its formal mining sector workforce of almost 2.5 million
France 41 Canada 174 people. From the available data, nations such as India, Mexico,
Germany 138 Chile 72 Colombia, Saudi Arabia and Kazakhstan also have significant
resource sector workforces. As better information becomes
Greece 16 South Africa 405
available it will be possible to add many other nations to the list
Italy 56 Peru 47 in Table 8.1.
Norway 13 Table 3.3 showed that the estimated population of the 33
Poland 273 Other Americas developed nations in our classification (those with HDI values of
0.850 and above in 2001) was 935 million people. This was 15.3
Russia (estimate) 1000 United States 606 per cent of the world’s population of just over 6.1 billion. They
Romania 149 Mexico 127 produced more than half the value of the world’s minerals and
Serbia and Montenegro 42 Colombia 191 energy output. Although the major mineral producers – the
United States, Canada and Australia – number among this list,
Slovakia 22 Venezuela 50 the developed nations accounted for an estimated 1.46 million of
Spain 61 Ecuador 42 the world’s 18 million minerals and energy sector workers, only
Sweden 7 eight per cent of the total. Mine workers in these nations were
located in the top two blocks (ovals) in Figure 8.1.
Turkey 89 China 2440
Ukraine 637 India 550 Artisanal and small-scale mining
United Kingdom 73
Artisanal and small-scale mining has historically been the most
Other Europe (estimate) 79 Saudi Arabia 326 traditional form – for example, the gold rushes in Australia were
Kazakhstan 166 largely driven by small-scale mining, which gave way to more
Total Europe 2800 capital intensive and larger mining operations when easily
obtainable deposits became less available. Even today in
Other formal (estimate) 1011
Australia, individuals or small groups still hold small tenements
Total formal 9200 as they search for a bonanza that will solve all their financial
Small-scale and artisanal 10 000 woes. Similar stories apply in many other nations.
Total minerals and energy 19 200 In many developing nations with considerable mineral
endowments, artisanal and small-scale mining has a more
significant economic and social role. As Hilson (2002) notes, it
In Europe, for example, most mining and/or oil and gas provides employment to many people in remote regions where
extraction is for domestic consumption. The minerals sector in few other opportunities exist, and it also contributes positively to
the 19 developed nations of Western Europe employed around foreign exchange earnings and mineral export bases.
550 000 people in 2001, yet economies such as Ukraine, Poland Unlike the formal mining sector in which larger companies
and Romania and Russia that were previously part of the Soviet participate, artisanal and small-scale mining often exists outside
bloc still have significant mining workforces – more than two any public sector regulatory framework. Such unregulated
million people were employed in the minerals and energy sector operations typically cause considerable damage to the physical
in these transition economies. Hence the European resources environment, while workers are exposed to unsafe and unhealthy
sector alone employed an estimated 2.8 million people at the turn working surroundings. Such mining can also lead to cultural
of the new millennium. conflicts where outsiders invade the traditional lands of
The United States has been a leading mineral producer for indigenous communities.
much of the last 150 years. With exceptions in industries such as As developing nations have opened up to foreign investment in
gold, copper and some coal, most production now focuses on the mineral sector since the late 1980s, small-scale and artisanal
domestic needs. The large majority of the value of US production miners have come more into conflict with the formal mining
is in oil and gas, but of the estimated 591 000 workers in the sector. It is now quite common for large mines in the formal
sector in 2004, only 66 000 worked in the oil and gas sector, sector to exist side-by-side with traditional artisanal miners. This
while 87 000 were in coal mining, 107 000 in non-metallic is happening more often in Africa and nations such as Indonesia
mining and quarrying and 75 000 in metal mining. and Papua New Guinea.
Among the major mineral exporting nations, Australia’s Estimates of the importance of the level of employment in
mineral sector employment is small in comparison with those in small-scale mining vary. At the high end, the World Bank
South Africa, Brazil and Canada. The higher employment in website (World Bank, 2004) states that:
South Africa is a reflection of its status as a developing nation,
with the substitution of labour for capital. Yet, in the aftermath Today, an estimated 13 million people in about
of the apartheid regime, mining employment has fallen 30 countries across the world are small-scale/
consistently. Given Brazil’s developing country status, large land artisanal miners, with about 80 million to 100
area, and major population base of 170 million people (in 2001) million people depending on such mining for
one might intuitively expect employment in its large-scale their livelihood.
Hilson (2002) has provided some more detailed estimates for
1. Where Hilson provides a range in his estimates, the mid-point has 25 selected nations. The data in Table 8.2 are derived from his
been selected. figures1. His list excludes several African nations in which

76 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

TABLE 8.2 Gold checked and for a time reversed Australia’s


Estimates of employment in small-scale and artisanal mining in tendency to become a land that favoured the big
2001. (Source: Derived from Hilson, 2002). man. Whereas Australia’s first natural asset, the
Country Estimated Country Estimated sheeplands, was grasped by a few thousand men,
employment employment its second rich natural asset, the goldlands, was
(’000) (’000) divided among hundreds of thousands of men.
Argentina 6 Mali 200 During the gold rushes, mining employed appropriately 20 per
Bolivia 70 Mexico 30 cent of Australia’s workforce. The exhaustion of alluvial gold
meant that more capital-intensive large-scale mining replaced
Brazil 1000 Mozambique 60 labour-intensive small-scale mining. In the wake of the Western
Burkina Faso 60 Pakistan 230 Australian gold rushes, mineral sector employment still stood at
China 4000 Papua New Guinea 55 eight per cent of total employment in 1901, but as Figure 8.2
shows, there was a dramatic decline in mining employment as a
Colombia 150 Peru 20
percentage of total employment during and after the First World
Ghana 200 Philippines 200 War. This downward trend has continued ever since. Even the
Ecuador 92 South Africa 18 Resources Boom in the 1960s did not reverse it. By the turn of
the new millennium, the sector accounted for approximately 0.8
Guyana 15 Tanzania 525
per cent of total employment – a tenth of its percentage level a
Haiti 5 Vietnam 38 hundred years earlier.
India 500 Zambia 30 The Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) publishes detailed
Indonesia 465 Zimbabwe 200 information about the minerals and energy sector in its annual
survey, Mining Operations Australia. It also provides useful
Malawi 40 Other (estimate) 1800 small area data on mining employment at the five yearly national
Total 10 000 census. The following discussion draws from the 2001 Census
and from Mining Operations Australia 2000-01.
artisanal and small-scale mining takes place. Among them are
Angola, Cameroon, Democratic Republic of Congo, Guinea, 8
Per
Niger, Nigeria and Togo. Also excluded are several Asian nations cent
and the majority of countries in the former Soviet bloc. The 7
numbers in the modified Hilson list add up to a little more than
seven million people. If one allows for some of the additional 6
nations, our view is that the numbers are likely to be closer to
nine million people2.
5
Interaction between artisanal and small-scale miners and
foreign mining companies in developing nations has become
4
much more common in the past 15 years. There is potential for
misunderstanding and conflict between each group. Balancing
the interface between small and large mining interests, as well as 3
regulating small-scale mining in an appropriate way, are major
policy challenges in mineral-rich developing nations. 2

MINERAL SECTOR EMPLOYMENT IN AUSTRALIA 1

Historical trends 0
1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000
As has been seen in the preceding section, the resources sector in
Australia now employs a relatively small workforce. This has not FIG 8.2 - Mineral sector employment as a percentage of total
always been the case. In discussing the gold rushes of the 1850s, employment, Australia, 1900 - 2001.
Blainey (2003, p 62) comments that:
Employment, value added and capital intensity
2. While somewhat lower than the World Bank estimate, the difference In Mining Operations Australia, the ABS reports employment data
may be due to us estimating more people in the formal mining sector by management unit and not by establishment. Management
than they have done. units are companies (which often operate more than one mine)
and joint ventures. In 2000-01, the ABS estimated that there were
3. These were the latest data available as this chapter was written.
66 677 people employed in 1340 management establishments3.
4. This seems an underestimate because, in the words of this publication This included 13 823 ‘contractors’ who provided services to
(ABS, 2002a, p 28): mining4.
Many of these contractors are classified to industry As can be seen from Table 8.3, these workers contributed
categories such as construction and transport that are out almost $34 billion to Gross Domestic Product (about 4.7 per cent
of the scope of the mining collection. of the total). The average value added per employee was
The publication acknowledges a higher estimate of 16 069 full-time $509 000. There was wide variation between sectors, with the
equivalent contractors by the Minerals Council of Australia. This average worker in oil and gas responsible for adding over
would place the total workforce employed in Australian mineral $2.5 million. This was more than three times the next highest
ventures at close to 70 000 in 2000-01. This compares with the sector (iron ore) where value-added per employee was $710 000.
estimate of 75 100 reported in the 2001 national census. The latter
figure may have been inflated by a small but significant group of The figure in the coal industry was $326 000 and in gold only
Australian residents who fly in and out of mines in other nations (eg $226 000. The histogram in Figure 8.3 highlights the wide
Indonesia, Papua New Guinea and several African nations). differences between sectors.

Australian Mineral Economics 77


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

TABLE 8.3
Value added and total assets per employee in the Australian mineral industry 2000-01. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002a.)

Industry sector Employment Value added Value added per Total assets Total assets per
($ M) employee ($ M) employee
($’000) ($ M)
Coal mining 17 256 5625 326 17 780 1.03
Oil and gas extraction 6714 16 907 2518 41 041 6.11
Iron ore mining 4525 3211 710 7355 1.63
Copper ore mining 3864 1526 395 6225 1.61
Gold ore mining 8096 1833 226 8903 1.10
Mineral sands mining 1679 600 357 1632 0.97
Silver/lead/zinc 2265 912 403 4079 1.80
Other metal mining 2628 1518 578 6357 2.42
Other mining 5827 891 153 3074 0.53
Services to mining 13 823 934 68 5577 0.40
Total 66 677 33 958 509 102 023 1.53

2600

2400

2200

2000

1800

1600
(A$,000)

1400

1200

1000

800

600

400

200

0
Coal Oil and Iron ore Copper Gold Mineral Silver- Other Other Services
gas sands lead-zinc metal mining to mining

FIG 8.3 - Value added per employee in key mineral sectors – Australia 2000-01.

The final columns of Table 8.3 provide another reflection of ($50 798) at the bottom. One of the main segments of the ‘Other
the capital-intensive nature of the industry. Oil and gas again mining’ group are workers in the mines and quarries near to
stand out, with average total assets per employee at more than major cities, who extract and process industrial minerals. As well
$6 million. The next group was ‘Other metal mining’, which as oil and gas, workers in the coal, iron ore, silver/lead/zinc and
included most nickel mines. It had less than half the amount other metal mining (which includes nickel) areas had incomes
of assets at $2.42 million per employee. Silver/lead/zinc above the mining average. These high wages reflect payment for:
($1.8 million), iron ore ($1.63 million) and copper ($1.61 million) • working in harsh environments;
were next, while gold trailed with $1.1 million.
• living in, or commuting to, remote locations; and
Salaries, wages and employment levels • recognition of specialist training and responsibility in
operating expensive capital equipment.
As the estimates in Table 8.4 and Figure 8.4 reveal, mineral In combination with these factors, volatile mineral prices and
sector employees are the best paid among the major industry wide swings in the mining business cycle have ensured that there
groups in Australia. While the ABS estimated that average tend to be greater movements of labour in and out of the minerals
annual incomes of Australian workers stood at $33 500 in sector. This has particularly influenced the exploration sector and
November 2000, the average mining income was estimated at the fortunes of geologists. The high level of wages and salaries also
$78 400 – more than double. There was wide variation across the reflect these movements, which has led at times to skilled mining
sectors, with oil and gas at the top with average wages more than professionals and other personnel being able to derive ‘quasi rents’
$105 000 and mineral sands ($45 861) and other mining because they are in short supply for specific time periods.

78 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

TABLE 8.4
Average employment levels and salaries in Australian mineral industry – 2000-01 financial year. (Source: ABS, 2002a.)

Industry sector No of units Employment Employment per unit Wages and salaries Average wages (A$)
(A$ M)
Coal mining 108 17 256 160 1641 95 097
Oil and gas extraction 50 6714 134 710 105 749
Iron ore mining 19 4525 238 412 91 050
Copper ore mining 14 3864 276 290 75 052
Gold ore mining 89 8096 91 481 59 412
Mineral sands mining 11 1679 153 77 45 861
Silver/lead/zinc 9 2265 252 216 95 364
Other metal mining 17 2628 155 222 84 475
Other mining 554 5827 11 296 50 798
Services to mining 469 13 823 29 885 64 024
Total 1340 66 677 50 5229 78 423

120

100

80
(A$,000)

60

40

20

ce
g
l

al
s

g
c

g
d
oa

pe
or

in
ga

in
nd

in
ol

in
et

or
C

in
-z
G

in

in
op

m
sa
n
d

kf
ad

lm
m
m
Iro
an

er

or
al

- le

er

to

ta
th

lw
er
il

th
O

er

To
O

s
in

ta
ce
O
lv
M

To
Si

r vi
Se

FIG 8.4 - Average wages and salaries in the Australian mineral industry 2000-01.

Occupational and educational structure


TABLE 8.5
The best source of these data is the national census conducted The occupational structure of employment in the Australian
every five years. The information in Table 8.5 shows the strong mineral industry at the 2001 census. (Source: Australian
representation of professionals (15.5 per cent), associate Bureau of Statistics, 2002a).
professionals (10.4 per cent) and blue-collar workers (57.1
per cent) in the industry at the time of the 2001 census. The large Category Number Percentage
majority of these groups work in operational roles, though some Managers and administrators 6469 8.6
professionals are in head office positions. One would expect
white-collar workers in the industry to be more heavily Advanced clerical and service workers 1765 2.3
represented in head office positions. Intermediate clerical, sales and service 3881 5.2
Using 2001 census data, Hall (2003) estimates that the number workers
of mineral sector workers who held university degrees was Elementary clerical, sales and service 461 0.6
12 930. Representing 17.3 per cent of the workforce, these workers
compares with the national average of 28 per cent. It reflects the White collar 12 576 17.0
reality of a small, well-trained and professional workforce that
Professionals 11 646 15.5
has enabled Australia to establish and sustain an internationally
competitive resources sector. Associate professionals 7798 10.4
Professional 19 444 25.9
Location issues Tradespersons and related workers 15 258 20.3
Workers in the minerals and energy sectors generally live in the Intermediate production and transport 24 956 33.2
states or territories where they work. The data5 in Table 8.6, also workers
Labourers and related workers 2946 3.9
5. Data presented in ABS (2002a) excluded employment in the services Blue collar 43 160 57.1
to mining sector from their state and territory employment table and
hence census data has been used instead. Total 75 178 100.0

Australian Mineral Economics 79


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

derived from the 2001 census, reflect the quite different


TABLE 8.6
economic geography of the resources sector in comparison with
Mineral sector employment in Australian states and territories – the remainder of the Australian economy. Western Australia and
2001 census. (Source: ABS, 2002b).
Queensland, which accounted for less than 30 per cent of
State Mining employment Total employment national employment, had more than 60 per cent of mineral
sector employment.
2001 % 2001 %
Census Census While the majority of mining professionals and workers
(’000) generally lived outside of metropolitan areas, the influence of
fly-in, fly-out work patterns is reflected somewhat by the
New South Wales 14 875 19.85 2748 33.13
information in Table 8.7. Interestingly, more than half of the
Victoria 4456 5.95 2082 25.10 metro-based managerial and professional mining workforce
Queensland 19 256 25.69 1569 18.92 resided in Perth.
South Australia 3825 5.10 635 7.66
Western Australia 28 736 38.34 829 9.99
IMPORTANT MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE
ISSUES
Tasmania 1600 2.13 182 2.19
Australian Capital 67 0.09 160 1.93 Gender imbalance
Territory
Mining has traditionally been a male-dominated industry in
Northern Territory 2200 2.94 90 1.08 Australia. This shows through strongly in the 2001 census. As
Total 75 015 100 8295 100 can be seen from Table 8.8, the ABS estimated that 86.4 per cent

TABLE 8.7
Residence patterns of mining personnel at the 2001 national census. (Source: ABS, 2002b).

Area Managers Professionals Other operational Other administrative Total


Sydney 364 393 1156 278 2191
Melbourne 463 788 765 428 2444
Brisbane 542 963 1325 549 3379
Perth 1660 3632 6389 1664 13 345
Adelaide 203 526 741 286 1756
Canberra 7 23 38 6 74
Hobart 11 25 79 8 123
Darwin 42 89 372 49 552
Total metro 3292 6439 10 865 3268 23 864
Newcastle 216 820 2973 158 4165
Wollongong 98 292 946 47 1383
Geelong 13 11 56 5 85
Ballarat 10 14 23 8 55
Bendigo 18 37 49 6 110
Gold Coast 40 75 172 44 329
Sunshine Coast 21 55 129 8 213
Toowoomba 12 13 101 13 139
Rockhampton 16 37 163 28 231
Mackay 64 149 707 66 996
Townsville 54 224 292 47 617
Cairns 25 85 151 17 278
Launceston 12 33 122 8 175
Mandurah 42 186 741 65 1034
Major other urban 641 2051 6625 455 9810
Eastern Goldfields 247 879 2187 212 3525
Broken Hill 35 67 424 18 544
Mount Isa 104 401 1493 92 2090
Port Hedland 70 280 683 54 1087
Karratha 70 324 764 117 1275
Regional mining centres 526 1951 5551 493 8521
Other 1947 1112 28 150 1767 32 983
Total non-metro 3114 5094 40 326 2780 51 314
Australia 6406 11 533 51 191 6048 75 178

80 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

TABLE 8.8 TABLE 8.9


Gender balance in the Australian mining industry – 2001 census. Gender balance in selected Australian mining towns 2001.
(Source: ABS, 2002b). (Source: ABS, 2002a).
Men Women Total % Male Men Women Male/Female
New South Wales 13 777 1148 14 925 92.3 ratio

Victoria 3588 932 4520 79.4 Western Australia


Goldfields
Queensland 16 974 2156 19 130 88.7
Kalgoorlie Boulder 15 258 13 561 1.13
South Australia 3286 661 3947 83.3
Coolgardie 2314 1926 1.20
Western Australia 24 073 4953 29 026 82.9
Yilgarn 1123 811 1.38
Tasmania 1468 111 1579 93.0
Leonora 2123 829 2.56
Northern Territory 1607 246 1853 86.7
Laverton 1560 504 3.10
ACT 61 8 69 88.4
Pilbara
Total 64 834 10 215 75 049 86.4
Roebourne 8762 7214 1.21
Port Hedland 7192 5903 1.22
of workers in the industry were men. Though this percentage has
apparently been falling, it reflects continuing male domination. Ashburton 3860 3030 1.27
It is important, however, to see this in a broader context. The East Pilbara 4091 2708 1.51
percentages of men in the formal mining sector in Australia are Murchison
not dissimilar with those in the major mineral exporting nations
such as Canada, Brazil and Chile. Indeed, the Australian male Meekatharra 1113 699 1.59
percentages appear to be slightly less than in these nations. South West
Because the mining industry dominates the economies of Collie 4242 4158 1.02
many remote towns in Australia, male to female ratios in excess New South Wales
of one and sometimes as high as two or three are not unusual.
With their broader employment bases, the larger mining towns Broken Hill 9923 10 348 0.96
reflect a more even balance between the sexes. A brief indication Cobar 2700 2462 1.10
of this continuing imbalance appears in Table 8.9, derived from Queensland
the Extended Regional Profiles of Local Government Areas at
Mount Isa 11 545 10 090 1.14
the 2001 Census. There is further discussion about Australian
mining towns in Chapter 18. Cloncurry 3097 1733 1.79
If gender balance in the industry is a desirable goal, then Belyando 5467 4418 1.24
progress towards it has been slow. More women now study in Tambo 342 300 1.14
disciplines such as geology (perhaps a third of students entering South Australia
classes) and metallurgy than previously but the professional
mining disciplines remain dominated by men. Roxby Downs 2190 1620 1.35
Tasmania
Maintaining a supply of well-trained Queenstown 2961 2557 1.16
professionals Northern Territory
Because it plays a leading role in the world mining industry, Jabiru (NT) 904 867 1.04
Australia has become a major supplier of mining professionals. Tennant Creek 1637 1651 0.99
Like their Canadian counterparts, large and small Australian
mining and exploration companies now operate throughout the
world. Maponga and Maxwell (2000) observed that, by 1995, member companies of the Minerals Council of Australia began
Australian-based resource companies operated in more than showing major concern by the late 1990s6.
seventy nations. While the Asian economic crisis and an Their response was to produce a major report, Back from the
associated drop in mineral prices in 1997 led to a dramatic Brink: Reshaping Minerals Tertiary Education (Minerals
decline in offshore activity, there has since been a strong Council of Australia, 1998). Quoting from the work of Nemitz in
recovery. his contribution to this report, Brady (p 140) observed that
The cyclical nature of mining and the general decline of the universities in the European Union produced about 700 mining
industry in Europe and the United States have, in recent years, engineering graduates in 1990, universities in the USA and
adversely affected the supply of new mining graduates from Canada produced about 250 and Australian universities about
these places. Because Australian mining schools were struggling 1007. Yet, the output from European schools, which provided
to meet the shortfall previously supplied from these sources, their graduates to a broader range of areas than mainstream
mining, then entered a period of major decline, with many
closing or merging with one another. In response, Brady
6. The Minerals Council of Australia is the national representative body estimated that the numbers of graduates from Australia’s six
of state-based Chambers of Minerals and Energy that represent the mining departments had only grown to an estimated 175 by
major mining companies. They account for the large majority of
19978.
production and employment in the Australian mining sector.
The authors of one of the other appendices, ‘Minerals Tertiary
7. Barry Brady was, at this time, Professor of Mining Engineering at Education – A Snapshot’ (Minerals Council of Australia, 1998,
the University of Queensland. pp 99-120) estimated that in 1995, 1996 and 1997, the six
8. University of Queensland, University of New South Wales, university mining engineering departments produced 104
University of Wollongong, University of Ballarat, University of graduates annually. The nine metallurgy/materials departments
South Australia and the Western Australian School of Mines (Curtin produced 160 graduates per year and the 23 geology departments
University of Technology). produced 463 graduates annually.

Australian Mineral Economics 81


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

TABLE 8.10 The growth of fly-in, fly-out workforces


Changes in the employment of geologists and mining engineers
between the 1996 and 2001 national censuses in Australia. A notable recent trend in the formal mining sector has been the
(Source: Hall, 2003; ABS, 2002a). rise of ‘fly-in, fly-out’ work practices. Storey (2001a) defines
fly-in, fly- out (FIFO) mining operations as:
1996 2001 % change
those which involve work in relatively remote
Geologists/Geophysicists locations where food and lodging accommodations
Mining 2701 2441 -9.6 are provided for workers at the worksite, but not
Consulting engineering services 344 366 6.4 their families. Schedules are established whereby
employees spend a fixed number of days working at
Other business services 1350 1303 -3.5
the site, followed by a fixed number of days at
Other industries 941 957 1.7 home. What differentiates this form of organization
Total geologists 5336 5067 -5.0 from other work involving periodic absences from
Mining engineers home are the regular patterns of work onsite
followed by a period offsite and the nature of the
Mining 950 1148 20.8 accommodation arrangements.
Consulting engineering services 254 367 44.5
As Storey and others have noted, the FIFO terminology is
Other business services 101 90 -10.9 misleading because some workers do not fly to the mine site or
Other industries 324 363 12.0 the oil rig at which they work. They drive in, travel by bus and
Total mining engineers 1528 1878 22.9 some even come by boat or hovercraft.
The incidence of FIFO work practices has become more
pervasive over the past 20 years, with perhaps 70 mines in
While recognising the positive record of Australian remote parts of Australia now fully staffed in this way. The
universities in producing more graduates in the mining-related practice now applies more and more throughout the world such
disciplines in the preceding two decades, the authors made some as in Canada, South America, Asia and Africa. It means
major recommendations that sought to serve the local industry in particularly that cities like Perth, but also Brisbane, Melbourne,
the longer term. Townsville, Mandurah and Cairns, provide the residences of
An important result of these recommendations was the managers, mining professionals and other operational personnel.
establishment of the Minerals Tertiary Education Council
The rise of the FIFO work camp has been driven in part by
(MTEC). Utilising significant contributions from member
market forces and the unwillingness of government to contribute
companies in the Minerals Council, MTEC has worked to
enhance the quality of undergraduate and postgraduate minerals to the development of short-lived and even long-term remote area
education. In particular it has done so by supporting the activities mining towns.
of selected universities that have agreed to pursue its agenda for Storey (2001a, p 136) identifies five key factors in the rise of
change and improvement. FIFO arrangements. These are:
During the intervening period, the cyclical nature of the • the absence of government financial support for new town
mining industry has continued. Precipitated by the Asian crisis, development;
and in the wake of poor mining company profits over several
years, there was a dramatic decline in mineral exploration • longer lead times needed for new town approvals and
budgets in the late 1990s and the early years of the new construction;
millennium. This led to a dramatic decline in employment of • environmental implications of new town construction;
geologists and an associated departure of many, either into other
• administrative implications of managing a town as well as a
parts of the industry or away from it all together. During 1998
mine; and
and 1999, as many as 1000 geologist positions may have
disappeared throughout Australia. • increased costs associated with town closure, once the
Utilising data from the 1996 and 2001 national censuses, Hall resource is exhausted and is no longer economic.
(2003) generates the data in Table 8.10. These show a decline of He points also to five further factors that have encouraged the
269, or five per cent, in the number of geologists employed practice. They are:
between 1996 and 2001. Almost all of this decrease was due
directly to mining operations. Other areas, including business • Improved quality and a relative decline in communication
services (geological consultants), remained relatively steady. The costs (ie telephone, fax, email and internet facilities).
number of mining engineers employed increased by 20.8 per cent • Improvements in aircraft and aircraft safety, and relatively
over the same period, while the number of consulting mining lower air travel costs. This has led to dramatically increased
engineers increased by almost 45 per cent. air traffic flows from places like Perth, both for scheduled
A general impression is that Australian universities coped and charter carriers. One relevant example of this is the rise
better in meeting domestic mining industry requirements for in air travel to cities such as Kalgoorlie.
professionals during the 1997-2001 period. However, this was a • A lower turnover and level of absenteeism in FIFO
period of depressed activity. The fortunes of the industry workforces than in resource towns. Unless workers are really
changed significantly after 2002. Driven by China’s voracious sick, they will tend to fly to site for extended work periods.
demand for minerals and energy, the prices of major minerals
rose dramatically and remained high between 2003 and 2005. • Access to a larger supply of qualified labour, for example to
With large investment in new mines, expansion of existing the more than 60 per cent of Australia’s population that lives
operations and increased exploration activity, a national and in the five main cities. FIFO provides access to a much
global shortage on mining professionals emerged again. Captains broader potential group of workers.
of industry lamented the situation. • A preference for metropolitan over rural living by many
While the activities of MTEC and the Australian universities workers and their families. This arises in particular because
have been moving forward, it is clear that providing a steady of better health, educational and social services in major
stream of well-trained professionals to the mining industry is a centres. Major cities and coastal centres typically also have
continuing challenge. better climates.

82 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

We also need to see FIFO work practices in a broader context. Yet, people who choose this form of employment often do so
Working patterns have been changing throughout society, with because they like it. Sibbel (2004) reports that FIFO workers
many forms of ‘non-traditional’ work patterns now common. In typically see both positive and negative points about the practice.
his monograph, Workers Without Traditional Employment: An In following typical 14/7 (14 days on, seven days off), 9/5,
International Study of Non-standard Work, John Mangan points 5/2/4/3 and other rosters they see the following positive points
to a wide variety of newer working arrangements include leased about FIFO. Work and home are separate. Salaries are excellent.
or franchised workers, outworkers, teleworkers, freelancers and Longer breaks provide an opportunity to socialise. There is more
portfolio workers. He argues that: opportunity to play a supervisory role on the job. Because
residences are set, it is quite easy to change employers. Families
Those in alternative employment relations are
are often very supportive.
now in such numbers that they can no longer be
regarded as peripheral to the main labour Negative points include roster impacts on relationships,
market. missing out on family activities (birthdays, children’s sporting
events, etc), less involvement with the community, inability to
FIFO began to oil-rigs in the Gulf of Mexico in the late 1940s. attend to home emergencies, time-consuming travel, general
It has been widely used in the offshore oil and gas sector ever tiredness because of long shifts, fear of flying, and the problem
since that time, in the North Sea, the Atlantic, off Indonesia and of binge drinking at the end of work rosters.
in the Bass Strait and on the North West Shelf. The first onshore
FIFO work practices began at Polaris in Canada’s High Arctic SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
region. In Australia, the first mine to utilise the practice was the
Argyle mine in the Kimberley region of Western Australia (WA). Discussion in this chapter considered the size and distribution of
It began operations in 1982. Since that time, the number of FIFO the global minerals and energy sector workforce. It then focused
mines in Australia has grown to about 70. more particularly on the Australian industry’s workforce and a
There was quite dramatic growth in the practice during the range of forces that have recently been influencing it. In
1980s. The then WA Department of Mines reported in 1991 that conducting this exercise, a major aim has been to appreciate
there were 26 FIFO operations in that state employing 4220 some of its dimensions more closely.
people. Our estimates are somewhat higher than that. They It was noted earlier that the labour and capital intensity of
suggest a figure of closer to 7000 people following FIFO rosters mining differs between nations, depending on their stage of
at that time in WA (see Table 8.11). economic development and the extent of their transition from
socialist to free enterprise operating environments. Also noted
was the difference in labour intensity between the formal and
TABLE 8.11 small-scale mining sectors.
Estimates of FIFO workforces in Western Australia. (Source: Our indicative estimates suggested that the world’s mining
WA Department of Industry and Resources, Western Australia workforce in 2001 was almost equally divided between the formal
Minerals and Petroleum Statistics Digest, 1990-91 and 2003-04). and small-scale and artisanal sectors. Although close to 20 million
people worked in the minerals and energy sector throughout the
1989/90 2002/03
world, the workforces in major mining nations such as Australia,
Estimated number of workers Canada and Chile are small and will remain that way.
Resident 29 506 19 000 Even though the sector has recently contributed more than four
FIFO 7021 17 000 per cent annually to GDP in Australia and more than 30 per cent
of our exports, it now employs only about 0.7 per cent of the
Total 36 527 36 000
workforce. This contrasts with the situation at the turn of the
20th century when mining employed an estimated eight per cent
By 2003-04 the number of FIFO mine and oil-rig workers in of the workforce.
WA had risen to 19 000 – more than 50 per cent of total mining The value added per employee in the Australian minerals
employment. There were 51 mines in WA following FIFO rosters sector now exceeds $500 000 per annum. Despite wide swings in
and about 20 in the rest of the country. FIFO work practices are the mining cycle, the wages of workers in the sector are more
common in gold mining, oil and gas extraction, diamond and than double the national average. While this dramatic difference
nickel mining and for base metals exploitation in WA. They do reflects the specialist training of workers and their responsibility
not apply in the bauxite, mineral sands and coal sectors, which in operating expensive capital equipment, it is also a reward for
are located much closer to the Perth metropolitan area. Many working in harsh environments, and living in or commuting to
families of coal miners and base metal miners in Central and remote locations.
North Queensland prefer to live at the coast where the weather Discussion concluded with a review of some topical mineral
and services are much better. sector workforce issues. These included the historical issue of
There are elements of FIFO mining in Papua New Guinea, gender imbalance of mining sector workers, the challenges of
Chile, Indonesia, and in several African nations. There is maintaining a supply of well-trained professionals, the decline of
considerable potential for the practice in many of the nations of unionism and the growth of FIFO workforces.
the former Soviet Union. These and related issues will have an important continuing
There has been much discussion about the social implications influence on the structure of mineral sector workforces both in
of FIFO work practices in mining for workers and their families. Australia and more broadly as the economic geography of
Storey (2001b) argues that commentators perceive FIFO: mining moves towards other parts of the world in the coming
decades. The industry will continue to operate in a dynamic and
to have negative social consequences for changing environment. Those who choose to work in the sector
individuals, families, and by extension, for the will need to adapt continuously.
communities in which they live, by contributing to:
• greater alcohol and drug abuse, REFERENCES
• family violence and break-ups, Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002a. Mining operations Australia
2000-01 (Catalogue No 8415.0) (Australian Bureau of Statistics:
• parenting problems, and Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date
• reduced community involvement. accessed: 8 May 2006.

Australian Mineral Economics 83


CHAPTER 8: THE MINERAL SECTOR WORKFORCE

Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002b. National census of population and Sibbel, A, 2004. FIFO or residential: Choices for life?, presentation to The
housing 2001 (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy Perth Branch meeting,
Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. held 16 September, Curtin University of Technology, Bentley campus.
Blainey, G, 2003. The Rush That Never Ended: A History of Australian Storey, K, 2001a. Fly-in/Fly-out and fly-over: mining and regional
Mining, fifth edition (Melbourne University Press: Melbourne). development in Western Australia, Australian Geographer,
Hall, B, 2003. The size of the bucket 2001: Employment trends in the 32(2):133-148.
Australian minerals sector, report to The Australasian Institute of Storey, K, 2001b. FIFO mining in Australia: What do we really know
Mining and Metallurgy [online]. Available from: <http://www. about its social and economic impacts?, mimeo, November, 22 p.
ausimm.com.au/policy/bucket.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Western Australian Government, Department of Industry and Resources,
Hilson, G M, 2002. Delivering aid to grassroots industries: A critical various years. Western Australia Mineral and Petroleum Statistics
evaluation of small-scale mining support services, Minerals and Digest, 1990-91 and 2003-04 (Western Australian Government,
Energy: Raw Materials Report, 17(1):11-18. Department of Industry and Resources: Perth) [online]. Available
International Labour Organization, 2004. Yearbook of Labour Statistics from: <http://www.doir.wa.gov.au/mineralsandpetroleum/3B1F0B2
2004, 63rd issue (International Labour Organization: Geneva). F32EE4593BBAA44D2600B69CC.asp>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Maponga, O and Maxwell, P, 2000. The internationalisation of the World Bank, 2004. The World Bank Group website [Online].
Australian mineral industry in the 1990s, Resources Policy, <http://www.worldbank.org>.
26(4):199-210.
Minerals Council of Australia, 1998. Back from the brink: Reshaping
minerals tertiary education, Minerals Council of Australia, National
Tertiary Education Taskforce, Canberra, discussion paper [online].
Available from: <http://www.minerals.org.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/
8007/backfromthebrink_exec_summ.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.

84 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9

An Introduction to Mineral Finance


Pietro Guj

Financial Objectives and Financial Management


Sources and Application of Funds
Sources of Equity
The Cost of Equity: Balancing Risk and Return
Sources of Debt
Hybrids Between Equity and Debt
Project Finance
The Financial Structure of Mining Companies
Conclusions

FINANCIAL OBJECTIVES AND FINANCIAL Discussion will consider the general financial context within
MANAGEMENT which mines are successfully developed and operated and then
sets the scene for the following three chapters, which deal with
Most analysts maintain that the financial objective of an specific aspects of mine finance in more detail.
exploration or mining enterprise is to maximise the value in the Financial managers of mining companies are particularly
hands of its current ordinary shareholders. Whether decision
concerned with two distinct types of decision. These are:
makers in the enterprise achieve this objective depends, in the
first instance, on the quality of the orebody in terms of its size, • the investment decision, and
grade, metallurgical and geotechnical characteristics. A sound • the funding decision.
mine plan to achieve such an outcome, however, can only
become reality if mine managers and professionals are Another important decision concerns the proportion of profits
competent, labour is skilled, plant, equipment and materials are devoted to shareholder dividend payments. Traditionally, the
appropriate, and, above all, there is adequate investment and capital-hungry mining industry has tended to be parsimonious in
working capital. terms of dividends. Many exploration and small mining
Because of its capital-intensity and the requirement for large companies never pay dividends and their shareholders must
initial investments in mine developments, the mining industry derive their return entirely from capital gains when selling their
has a voracious appetite for capital. Yet some common sources of shares.
borrowing are not easily accessible to it because of the inherent The investment decision is concerned with determining which
risk and the variability of its cash flows. Compared to other asset base is most appropriate to achieve the financial-return
sectors of the economy, mining companies generally must rely objectives of an enterprise. A company’s Board of Directors sets
more on either equity or specialised financial arrangements such this at a level sufficiently high to attract and retain adequate
as project finance, or both together.
investment capital from the owners or shareholders given the
The unique characteristics of the mining industry are also degree of risk that they face. To build, diversify and maintain an
reflected in the specific style of financial management that optimal portfolio of exploration, development and mining
characterises successful mining enterprises. projects and other assets entails occasional asset acquisitions and
The focus of this chapter is on four main areas: disposals. A diversified portfolio effect as will be discussed in a
1. the main financial management principles and their later section, means that the combination of selected assets:
relevance to the mining industry; • adds greater value for the shareholders than the sum of the
2. the various sources of both equity and debt funds used by returns on the individual projects; and
the mining industry, their cost and availability; • results in lower combined risk exposure; or
3. the more specific area of project finance; and • both of the above.
4. the financial structure of mining companies and the The process of selecting capital investments is sometimes
trade-off between financial leverage and financial risk. referred to as capital budgeting.

Australian Mineral Economics 87


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

So investment (and disinvestment) decisions are the main • Group accounting, including developing and implementing
determinant of the assets, which appear in a mining company’s financial policy and maintaining accounting systems
statement of financial position (balance sheet) and indeed of any supporting both consolidated financial accounting reports
enterprise. on an accrual basis and operational management
The time focus of investments is also a major consideration in accounting reports compiled on a cash basis.
financial management. While the mining industry is • Treasury operations, including both management of current
capital-intensive and its assets long-lived (ie fixed or non-current), assets and liabilities (ie cash management) to ensure an
it is also critical to manage cash and other short-term (current) appropriate level of continued liquidity and obtaining and
assets and liabilities to maintain adequate liquidity. servicing long-term finance through borrowing (including
Inability to satisfy any debt as it becomes payable, is often the project finance), leasing, retention of earnings after payment
reason why enterprises are placed under administration/liquidation. of dividends and issuing of shares and other securities. These
Liquidity problems, rather than lack of net asset worth also include managing relationships with corporate bankers.
(solvency), push companies into liquidation. This is because
most of their non-current assets are illiquid, ie not capable of • Tax services, including tax advice, compliance and
being sold on a short time scale. Liquidity is crucial in the case optimisation.
of mining because of the high variability of cash flows due to the • Corporate finance services, including the financial analysis
general volatility of commodity prices and revenue. and evaluation of exploration, development and mining
The funding or financing decision, by contrast is concerned projects and other investment opportunities, contribution to
with how to fund the above assets, whether with: the financial components of pre-feasibility and feasibility
studies and implementation of selected projects, advice on
• equity (ie owners’ or shareholders’) funds; or related strategic financing issues and on possible mergers and
• debt (bank loans or other financiers’ and creditors’ funds) in acquisitions.
various forms. • Risk assessment and management, relating to both project
These funding sources appear as liabilities (both short and and market risk. This involves identifying and assessing
long term) and as shareholders’ equity in the balance sheet. As sources of risk through internal audits to determine their
the name implies, the balance sheet must balance. As a potential impact and likelihood of occurrence. This helps in
consequence, total liabilities plus shareholders’ equity must formulating the company’s risk-management policy of
equate to the value of the corresponding assets. In effect, securing an appropriate level of insurance, commodity prices
shareholders’ equity represents the balancing item. Thus, the and exchange rates hedging to shelter from those risks that
shareholders have control of but bear the ultimate risk of the the company is less capable to or does not wish to bear.
enterprise, although their risk is limited to their investment in it • Investor relations with shareholders, investment analysts
and does not flow through to their other assets, personal or and the public as well as satisfying all the disclosure and
otherwise. Of course the value of the assets must equal or exceed other requirements of the Australian Stock Exchange (ASX).
that of the liabilities. When this is not the case, the enterprise is
insolvent. Directors who continue trading in the knowledge that • Financial planning, forecast and construction of corporate
their company is insolvent commit a punishable crime. and project financial models capable of generating short,
medium and long-term forecasts of the company’s finance
under different development scenarios and various economic
Assets = Liabilities + Shareholders’ Equity and other assumptions.
To the extent that this monograph focuses on economic and
is the fundamental financial accounting equation. Every financial financial analysis rather than financial accounting, further
transaction is either an asset, a liability or an equity account reference to this discipline is only made when it is relevant to the
entry in the chart of accounts (financial system) of the firm. first two topics.
The funding decision also encompasses determining which Most exploration and mining professionals probably require a
financial structure (ie which proportion of equity and debt) is relatively superficial knowledge of the principles and practice of
most appropriate for any specific company or project. To the financial accounting and the intricacies of reporting on an
extent that interest is a tax-deductible expense, using debt accrual basis. A reasonable understanding of management
reduces the amount of tax payable and as a consequence accounting on a cash basis generally satisfies their immediate
improves the return on the equity funds invested. This is the financial management needs. By contrast, to be effective
financial leverage effect. As discussed later in more detail, the strategic managers, they need a relatively deep understanding of
use of excessive debt introduces an additional element of risk. corporate finance, financial planning and project modelling and
This is known as financial risk. It differs from the technical and evaluation. Focus will therefore be on these latter topics in the
marketing risk inherent in any mining project. Project finance is rest of this, and in the following, chapters.
sometimes provided on a limited recourse basis in which case, as
discussed below, some of the shareholders’ risk is transferred to
the lenders. SOURCES AND APPLICATION OF FUNDS
As will be seen below, the search for an optimal financial
structure is a complex and somewhat ambiguous field of academic General considerations
research on which opinions are divided. Three types of activities, reported in the sources and
application of funds (or cash flow) statement, generate or
The role of financial managers consume funds (cash). They are:
Financial managers play a significant corporate role in securing • operations – hopefully generating more cash (through
the necessary funds and ensuring that they are used effectively revenue and depreciation) than they consume in the
and efficiently in achieving the financial objectives set by their corresponding recurrent expenses and tax payments;
Board of Directors. • investment activities – increasing tangible and intangible
Peirson et al (2004, p 7) provide an exhaustive list of their assets consumes cash, while asset sales and joint venture
duties and services. They include: farm-outs increase cash; and

88 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

• financing activities – either issuing new shares, or drawing • Debt (D) or banks’ or financiers’ funds, which are generally
down loans (ie increasing liabilities), or both activities, secured by:
generate cash, while repaying loan principal or returning
• a senior floating claim on the firm’s assets,
capital to the shareholders by means of share buy-backs
(while reducing liabilities) consume cash. • specific collateral,
The first two activities can be sources of internal funding, • the project to be funded, or
while the last will generate external funds. • are unsecured.
As can be seen in Figure 9.1, each year the Directors
appropriate cash (funds) from the company’s operations There is also a third (albeit quantitatively less significant)
equivalent to its profit less dividends (ie retained earnings for the category of hybrid funds, which includes financial instruments
year), plus depreciation, plus the difference between the opening displaying both the characteristics of equity and debt, such as
and closing balance of all the recurrent items accrued in the preference shares and convertible notes.
balance sheet. Major integrated mining houses with strong, diversified
balance sheets and large annual cash flows have little difficulty
in raising debt funds either on:
• their balance sheet (eg conventional loans, bonds, notes and
debentures); or
• from specific project loans.
Without the backing of a profitable operation, small to
medium-size exploration companies can only rely on equity as
their main source of funds even though its is complex and, as it
will be seen, expensive to raise.
The type of funding must be appropriate to the specific stage of
the project in the mineral cycle and its related risk. Companies
finance high-risk exploration primarily with equity. They use a
mixture of debt and equity for medium-risk development projects,
with high levels of debt early in the project life decreasing as the
FIG 9.1 - Schematic representation of the sources and application
project cash flow improves. Operators of lower-risk, established
of funds.
mining operations seek an optimal and steady balance between
They make further adjustments to account for the cash flow equity and debt that minimises taxes and leverages shareholders’
relating to investment and financing activities, which collectively returns at an acceptable level of financial risk.
will capture all changes in assets and liabilities generating or
consuming cash. For example, a reduction in non-cash assets (eg SOURCES OF EQUITY
the sale of a property or equipment) or an increase in liabilities
(eg the drawing down of a new loan) will generate cash. By
contrast an increase in fixed assets (eg a new mine development) General considerations
or a reduction in liabilities (eg repayment of a loan principal) The prevailing ‘outsider’ system of corporate ownership strongly
will consume cash. influences corporate financing in Australia (Trench, 2002). Similar
The cash outflows relating to the acquisition of significant situations apply in the United States, the United Kingdom and
depreciable capital items occur in discrete ‘lumpy’ amounts, even Canada. The Australian system is characterised by rapid
though these assets, as inputs to on-going mine production, have ownership dispersion, stock market floats and relatively weak
the capacity to generate benefits over future periods during their relationships between companies and financing institutions. By
useful lives. A fundamental principle of financial accounting is contrast in Germany, France, Japan and Chile (where an ‘insider’
to match revenue with the corresponding expenses incurred to system operates) ownership is concentrated with few share floats
generate it in each period. This includes the cost of ‘consuming’ and strong relationships with banks and financiers.
fixed assets acquired through lumpy investments in the past. This
item of expense, which is called depreciation, is not a cash cost, Furthermore, traditionally the exploration and mining sector
but merely an accounting convention attempting to match has relied largely on equity to fund its operations, with average
revenue and expenditure in each reporting period. debt for this sector historically seldom exceeding 40 or 50 per
cent of the total funds employed.
In the case of the mining industry, given its capital-intensity
and the presence of accelerated depreciation, the amount of cash The resources part of the equity market in Australia does not
appropriated each year against depreciation can be considerable. display what could be considered a ‘strong’ or even ‘semi-strong’
In some cases, particularly during its early years, the bulk of the form of efficiency in terms of the speed of price adjustments to
cash generated by a mining project is attributable to depreciation reflect emerging information (Brealey and Myers, 1996), with
and a company may have significant cash flow even if it makes a the price of mining shares appearing to lag emerging
financial accounting loss. information. This generates high price volatility and amplifies
Investment activities are central to the mining industry given general market movements and cycles.
its capital intensity and generally long project lives. The While equity markets in Australia are well developed and
investment characteristics at the exploration stages, however, are satisfy the significant demand arising from the mining industry,
very different, as will be seen in the coming chapters, from those companies also obtain significant funds off-market.
at the development and operational stages.
Off-market sources of initial equity
Main sources of funds
Aside from internally generated funds, which probably represent
A company’s main sources of financing fall into two broad classes: the lowest-cost source of capital, new off-market equity funds
• Equity (E) or owners’ or shareholders’ funds. Shareholders include:
have control over the affairs of the company but bear the • privately sourced seed and venture capital from ‘business
ultimate risk for the firm/project. angels’ and other venture capitalists;

Australian Mineral Economics 89


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

• other lower-risk and generally more significant off-market TABLE 9.1


placements; Equity funds raised on the Australian Stock Exchange in financial
2003-04. (Source: KPMG, 2004.)
• farm-outs/joint ventures; and
• royalty-based finance arrangements. Source A$ billion
‘Business angels’ are generally astute technical or financial IPO (150) 9.9
specialists investing up to a few hundreds of thousands of dollars Rights 10.2
for five to ten years to help detect and address any missing Placements 8.5
critical success factor and develop high-risk high-return
Dividends re-investment 5.2
opportunities to the point where they can seek formal external
funding or be profitably sold. Employees schemes 2.9
The main advantage of venture capital is that it is often the Total 37.0
only source of capital available to start up a mining project.
Based on a persuasive business plan, venture capitalists will • contributory or partly paid shares, while popular, are
invest amounts in the order of $0.5 to $10 million for between, quantitatively subordinate and are used to provide a reliable
say, three and seven years, aiming to achieve high capital gains future source of equity funds through calls on shareholders
by disposing of their investment at a favourable time, rather than when funds are actually needed;
maintaining their investment in the company and waiting for
eventual dividends. • preference shares conferring the payment of dividends, that
Venture capital has, however, some drawbacks. For instance are often fixed, to their holders ahead of ordinary
the original project promoters are likely only to being able to shareholders, are issued to attract funds from interested but
retain a minority position in their project. They also experience more risk-averse potential investors; and
the added pressures of working with an active board with a • options are frequently used as a sweetener for equity issues
contractual attitude towards management and a tendency to go or as a reward to executives and other employees designed to
well beyond the provision of general direction and governance encourage them to work in ways that enhance the company
into the sphere of day-to-day technical and managerial decisions. value.
From a company’s point of view, equity funding provided by Subsequent equity raisings include:
venture capitalists presents a number of significant advantages:
• right issues,
• Firstly, it may be the only way of funding higher-risk
projects. • placements,
• Secondly, unlike the obligation to pay interest on debt, there • dividend re-investment, and
is no obligation to pay a dividend on ordinary shares, even • employees’ schemes.
though this would be desirable at some stage in the project Bonus issues and share splits by contrast do not raise new
life – similarly there is no provision for repayment of initial equity, and even though they were once very popular, they are
shareholders’ capital contributions as contrasted to principal now very uncommon.
repayment at the maturity date of a loan.
In Australia capital raisings are generally highly regulated and
• Thirdly, the shareholders’ liability is also limited to their costly. The Corporation Act 2001 and ASX rules require
investment in the company. This means that their liability significant disclosure documentation in the form of a prospectus
does not extend to other personal assets if, in case of and either a profile statement or an offer information statement
liquidation, the total assets of the company are insufficient to (for raising small amounts generally less than $5 million). Some
satisfy all the creditors’ claims. offers are exempt from disclosure requirements.
There are, however, some disadvantages: According to Peirson et al (2004) the major costs in an IPO
include:
• Firstly, there is the dilution effect of additional equity issues.
By contrast debt finance does not cause dilution of ownership. • Compiling and printing a prospectus, including independent
experts’ reports at $300 000 to $500 000.
• Secondly, equity issues are complex and entail high
transaction costs relating to the preparation of a prospectus • Stockbroker underwriting of the IPOs or of subsequent share
and related underwriting. issues, or both. Underwriting costs can vary between over
one per cent and seven per cent of the size of the float. This
• Thirdly, funds may not be available when needed as their percentage depends on the standing of the company and
availability is a function of economic and commodity price whether the IPO price has been set at a realistic level and
cycles. Successful floats and issues are generally restricted to averages around four per cent.
boom times.
As a large proportion of floating costs is independent from the
size of the float, the total cost for a large float ranges between
On-market sources of equity two and six per cent, while small ones absorb a much larger
There are a number of ways to raise new equity ‘on-market.’ proportion of the funds raised (between 11 and 23 per cent).
These include initial public offerings (IPOs) and subsequent The general investor perception is that subscribing to an IPO is
equity raisings (see Table 9.1). a strategy for easy money. In reality, only 66 of the 150 IPOs in
For new mining companies, IPOs typically occur on the 2003-04 (44 per cent) were trading at or above issue value by the
end of 2004 even though market conditions were generally
Australian Stock Exchange (ASX) but also on overseas stock
buoyant.
exchanges such as the Toronto Stock Exchange in Canada or the
London Alternative Investment Market (AIM). The share issues Of the 150 IPOs in financial 2003-04, 55 were for exploration
and mining companies. Forty-seven of these were trading at a
in these IPOs can include:
premium within a few weeks of listing, in some exceptional
• ordinary fully paid shares generally represent the bulk of the cases having doubled or even trebled their values. This does not
equity funds sought and largely determine the financial necessarily indicate that exploration and mining IPOs perform
structure of the company; any better than those in other sectors. It may essentially reflect

90 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

IPO pricing mechanisms and dilemmas. During commodity


Australian Mining IPO s 1996 - 2004
booms, most resources stocks may open at a listing premium
relative to their issue price. This may be because the listing price 30
has been set too low under the risk-averse influence of the
under-writing stockbrokers. Underwriters have a propensity for 25 Frequency
curbing the project proponents’ excessive optimism and would 20

Frequency
sooner sacrifice the potential rewards of a higher-priced IPO than
being exposed to a potentially costly under-subscribed float. Less 15
risk-averse investors are willing to pay positive listing premiums More than
while general market sentiment is buoyant and appetite for 10
A$15M
cyclical stocks high.
5
As will be seen in Chapter 12, this difference between the
fundamental value of exploration and mining assets and their 0
market value (ie the market premium) may represent the

10

13
5

.5

.5
5.

8.
2.
so-called real option value (ROV) of the assets.

11

14
During periods of resources boom such as calendar 2004, there Money raised A$M
is generally a strong investor appetite for cyclical stocks such as
mining companies’ shares. The cyclicality of this demand is FIG 9.3 - Frequency distribution of size of IPOs over the period
clearly shown in Figure 9.2, which portrays the number of IPOs 1996-2004.
of new mineral exploration and mining companies during the
nine calendar years between 1996 and 2004.
Figures 9.4 and 9.5 show that 72.7 per cent (302) of Australian
listed exploration/mining companies have a market capitalisation
NUMBER OF IPOs - 1996 - 2004 (Estimated) of less than A$ 50 million, 22 per cent (91) a mid-capitalisation
45
range between $50 million and $1 billion and only 5.3 per cent
(22) of companies are capitalised at more than A$ 1 billion.
40 Number of IPOs
35
Number of IPOs

30 90
25 80 Frequency
20
Number of companies

70
15
60
10
5 50
0 40
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 30
Year 20
10
FIG 9.2 - Exploration and mining IPOs are cyclical.
0
0

0
00
5
10

20

30

40

50

75

e
10

20

50

or
There has been a recent trend for companies to finance their
10
M
mergers and acquisitions with shares rather than cash, particularly
late in an economic cycle. Depending on how the offers are Capitalisation A$ Million at Sept. 2004
written (Rappaport and Sirower, 1999) this type of deal is difficult
to evaluate. This is because of the ambiguous signals that the
management of the acquiring company sends to the capital market. FIG 9.4 - The market capitalisation of Australian listed mining
Logic dictates that if they truly believed that their shares were companies, September, 2004.
poised for a great leap forward, they would have been better off
using cash instead of script and benefiting from the impending
increase in its value. A possible interpretation is that they in fact 8
may have considered that their shares were overvalued. 7 Frequency
Number of companies

6
Resource sector IPOs are generally small
5
Excluding an exceptional IPOs raising more than $1 billion, the
4
average of the remaining 149 IPOs in Australia in financial
2003-04 raised just under $60 million. If only resources sector 3
IPOs in that financial year are considered, most resources IPOs 2
were in the $2.5 to $6 million class. Figure 9.3 shows that this is
consistent with a longer term frequency distribution of the size of 1
all exploration and mining IPOs over the period 1996 to 2004. 0
According to the Minmet/Intierra database, in September 2004
5

.5

.5

.5

.5

.5

.5

.5

.5
2.

7.

12

17

22

27

32

37

42

47

there were 415 exploration/mining companies listed in Australia,


of which: Capitalisation of companies with value in
excess of A$ 1 billion as at Sept. 2004
• 251 were producers (200 of these producers are also active
explorers) with a total capitalisation of A$ 221.6 billion; and
• the remaining 164 were pure explorers and accounted for FIG 9.5 - The size distribution of Australian resources companies
only A$ 10 billion in market capitalisation. with capitalisation in excess of A$1 billion, September, 2004.

Australian Mineral Economics 91


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

The size distribution of mining companies in Australia is It is clear that small to medium-size enterprises (SMEs) are at
highly positively skewed, with the top three companies a disadvantage because their low capitalisation falls well below
accounting for just under 50 per cent of total market that necessary to create portfolio critical mass, even though
capitalisation, while the top ten account for 75 per cent. Thus, a during resource booms they can display very high levels of
quarter of the value is dispersed among 405 small to growth and rates of return.
medium-size companies, most of which are not large enough to
become part of the Standard and Poors or ASX index. Innovative investment vehicles for the resources
This provides an indication of how the relative importance of industry
the resources sector has decreased in recent years and of how the It is possible to achieve critical capitalisation for inclusion in an
Australian market has evolved from being a resources-dominated appropriate index by aggregating the value of a number of the
market to a financial-dominated market. The authors of Australian shares of small and medium size companies using innovative
Stock Exchange (2004) report that in 1980, resources represented investment vehicles, such as specialised listed investment
approximately 62 per cent of the share market. By 31 December companies (LICs). Such a strategy can make them meaningful
2003 this had fallen to approximately 17 per cent. investment targets for large institutions.
The concept of LICs raising equity funds for investment in
Criteria for inclusion in a stock market index diversified portfolios of shares, debt securities, property and
other assets is not new. Yet, Australian LICs have traditionally
Few mining companies are included in any of the main stock been small compared with those in the UK and USA. There has
market indices in Australia. To be included, a company share recently been significant growth both overseas and in Australia
must display: in LICs of various sizes specialising in resources stocks.
• liquidity,
• free float, and Fiscal incentives
• high capitalisation. There has been significant political debate in many resources-rich
countries, including Australia, about the fiscal treatment of small
These three investable weight factors (IWF) determine which and medium size companies.
of the companies listed on the ASX are captured by its various From time to time, this results in government policy makers
indices. In September 2004 there were 1540 companies listed on introducing specific fiscal incentives for this sector. Two notable
the exchange. examples are:
Only the five largest mining companies are included in the • the Canadian ‘flow-through’ shares, and
S&P/ASX 50 and through it in the Standard and Poors Global
1200 index, thus gaining international exposure. • the Australian pooled development funds (PDFs).
A further ten companies (ie a total of 15) make it to the A flow-through share scheme has been in place in Canada
S&P/ASX 200 index, which capture 90 per cent of market since 1983. It has allowed deduction of 100 per cent (enhanced
capitalisation and is used by many domestic passive fund to 115 per cent in 2000) of eligible exploration expenses from
managers. Thus the majority of exploration companies are not on the taxable income of private investors. This has assisted Canada
the ‘radar screen’ of large index-using, institutional investors. to become the world’s largest mineral explorer for much of this
period. In 2003, for example, annual mineral exploration in
In aggregate 36 out of the total listed 415 mining companies Canada amounted to an estimated US$ 488 million.
(ie 21 more than in the S&P/ASX 200) appear in the S&P/ASX
Even though there has been considerable political lobbying in
300. They are typically small to medium-size mining companies
the past two decades, the Australian government has not pursued
and their cumulative value is very low given that the additional
such a scheme. This is presumably because a similar scheme
100 companies only account for an extra one per cent of market
operating in the boom of the late 1960s and early 1970s was
capitalisation. The remaining 215 small explorer/producers and open to abuse.
just about all of the 164 pure exploration companies do not
appear in any significant index at all. The Australian government has, however, allowed the
establishment of pooled development funds (PDFs) to provide
Most equity funds are sourced from investment institutions equity capital for eligible activities of Australian SMEs under
including: stringent compliance rules. The Pooled Developed Funds Act
• superannuation funds, 1992 requires that a PDF must invest 65 per cent of the capital it
raises within five years. There must be a minimum of ten per
• life insurance companies,
cent equity in new Australian companies with total assets less
• unit trusts, and than $50 million. This initiative is designed to establish an
• investment companies. eligible business or substantially expand existing capacity or
markets.
Some fund managers actively manage their funds with the The Australian Government taxes PDFs at a concessionary
objective of maximising returns, albeit under some risk exposure. rate. Their taxable income has the following components:
But many funds are passively managed or index-bound. That is,
their managers seek to achieve returns equivalent to movement in • SME income, which is taxed at 15 per cent (instead of 30 per
a relevant index. Furthermore, most institutional fund managers cent); and
are often constrained to invest in certain main S&P/ASX index • unregulated (ie non-SME) income, which is taxed at 25 per
shares by risk-management policy or regulation or by cent as an incentive for PDFs to invest uncommitted funds in
rate-of-growth objectives in combination with the sheer SMEs instead of in interest-bearing securities.
magnitude of the funds to be invested. As a result, institutional In addition, capital gains on disposal of PDF shares and PDF
investors do not represent a good source of equity funds for small dividends are tax-exempt.
to medium-size exploration and mining companies.
One notable recent example of a PDF is the Lion Selection
Even general public investors, who leverage their portfolios Group Ltd. Its strategy is to invest in precious and base metals
using margin loans, are constrained by the banks to select shares projects, which are close to development or at the advanced
from the benchmark S&P/ASX 300 index. exploration stage. It seeks also to invest:

92 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

• $5 to $10 million each in ten to 15 SMEs with outstanding exposure, but that, depending on their degree of ‘risk-aversion’,
people, value and growth potential; will (within limits) be willing to trade risk for higher returns.
• half if its funds in Australia and the other half in Africa and Thus, a rational investor would not shift money from riskless
South-East Asia; and Government Bonds (returning the risk-free rate of return (RF))
to a risky project unless he or she receives a suitable risk
• no more than 30 per cent of its total capital in any single premium for bearing the additional risk.
project. The risk of any individual investment is characterised by two
Etheridge and Uttley (2003) have proposed the ‘dedicated drill components:
fund’ concept as a highly specialised form of PDF. They argue • idiosyncratic risk, which is unsystematic and unique and
that Australian junior company exploration programs have been depends on the characteristics of the specific investment and
unnecessarily long and protracted because of their struggle to which can be diversified away (see Figure 9.6) by
secure drilling funds. Yet, the first mineralised drilling constructing a portfolio of a reasonable number of
intersection is usually when most value is added to an investments (15 to 20), the return of which is ideally poorly
exploration/mining project as reflected in rapidly rising share correlated; and
prices. Good examples of this may be found in the dramatic rise
in the share prices of Jubilee Mines NL or of Minotaur
• systematic or market risk, which depends on broader
movements in the economy at large and which is
Resources Ltd following their discovery of the Cosmos nickel
non-diversifiable away by portfolio effects (see Figure 9.6).
sulfides in Western Australia and of the Prominent Hill
copper-gold deposit in South Australia respectively.
In their subsequent argument, Etheridge and Uttley advocate
the establishment of dedicated ‘drill funds’ – spending in excess
of 80 per cent of the funds raised on drill-testing robust targets.
The concept envisages a major company partnering the fund with
an option to acquire between 50 and 60 per cent of high-value
discoveries. While such ‘drill funds’ remain at the proposal stage,
the concept may deserve serious consideration from government.

Joint venture farm-outs


A joint venture (JV) is as a contractual arrangement where two or
more parties cooperate to enhance the potential performance of a
project that no one of them would develop on their own. Joint
ventures include two stages:
• A farm-in/farm-out stage, where the ‘farming in’ party
progressively acquires a predetermined percentage of the
equity in a project from the diluting ‘farming out’ party for a
specific consideration, which frequently includes a FIG 9.6 - Diversified portfolio effect. (Source: Deer, 1987.)
commitment to fund exploration or development work. In
this respect as a source of funds, the farm-out stage of a joint Trench (2002) points out how the performance of a
venture is similar to a partial asset sale. nickel-producing company is correlated with demand derived
• A joint venture proper stage, which commences after the from the steel industry, which in turn is one of the best indicators
joint venture participants reach the desired level of equity of aggregate economic activity. Its risk is therefore mainly
ownership. During this stage participants contribute to the systematic. By contrast, the success of a nickel exploration
joint venture’s expenses and share its produce (not profit) company and a possible new nickel mine development project is
generally in proportion to their equity. As a consequence, the dependent on whether the relevant exploration drill holes are
joint venture ceases to be a source of funds for the diluting mineralised or barren, and on the local ground conditions. The
company, unless the agreement is ‘geared’ or includes major part of its risk is unique and independent of economic
progressive payments unrelated to dilution of equity. conditions.
An investor in a diversified market portfolio (ie in a portfolio
Specialty finance (royalty) companies including all securities weighted by their respective market
capitalisation, say the All Ordinaries Index) would legitimately
Specialty finance (royalty) companies provide funds for expect to receive a return on the market portfolio (RM)
acquisition, development or expansion mainly of operating gold adequate to compensate for bearing the market or systematic risk
mines or advanced projects in exchange for an appropriate gold but not any unique risk. Naturally, RM should be greater than the
royalty on production. This source of funding differs from gold risk-free return (RF), ie should incorporate a market premium
loans (discussed below in the debt sources of funds section) in (RM – RF).
that the financiers share in the risk of the project. The market portfolio premium has varied over time, with a
tendency to a gradual decrease. For instance, according to
THE COST OF EQUITY: BALANCING RISK AND Officer (1989 in IPRT-NSW, 2002) from 1882 up until 1987 the
RETURN market risk premium averaged around 7.9 per cent on an
arithmetic mean (or more correctly 6.6 per cent on a geometric
The utility theory would suggest that ‘economically rational’ mean). If the average is extended to 1997, these value drop to 7.1
investors would select among the various opportunities open to per cent and 5.7 per cent respectively. In post World War Two
them the course of action that maximises their utilities times (until 1991) the arithmetic mean has fallen to 6.6 per cent
(Hirshleifer, 1980). To the extent that the magnitude of (Hathaway, 1996 in IPRT-NSW, 2002). A number of recent
individuals’ utilities is, among other things (see Chapter 10), a surveys display a high level of annual variability, with recent
function of their risk tolerance, one could say that investors will annual or shorter arithmetic means in the range of three per cent
tend to maximise their wealth, while minimising their risk to 7.1 per cent.

Australian Mineral Economics 93


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

An average of six per cent is generally used as a general • Type of interest rate, whether fixed or variable. Nowadays,
approximation, even though it may be naive to assume that future swaps are commonly used to convert variable rate to fixed
market performance will necessarily follow a linear extension of rate loans.
the past.
From a company’s point of view, debt finance has a number of
To the extent that the idiosyncratic risk is diversifiable, financial advantages. Firstly, funds are available flexibly and when
markets neglect it in determining the return that equity investors
actually needed. Secondly, the transaction cost of establishing a
should expect to justify investing or maintaining their funds in
loan are lower than those of equity and, because of the
specific securities/projects, also known as the cost of equity (RE).
tax-deductibility of interest expenses, debt leverages returns on
Different investments within the market portfolio, however,
respond differently to overall economic influences. In some cases shareholders’ equity. Finally, contrary to the providers of equity,
they are sensitive to and amplify general market movements, while lenders do not acquire ownership of and control over the
in others they react less than average to them. Investors must be borrowing firm, thus there is no dilution of ownership.
compensated for this range of variations in the behaviour of There are, however, a number of disadvantages including the
different investments by providing a higher risk premium for fact that, as interest expenses are unrelated to fluctuating profit
investments that are more volatile than the market portfolio and levels, higher levels of debt bring about additional ‘financial
vice versa. This adjustment is achieved through the use of a risk’. Also, floating security over a company’s assets extends
β (beta) index reflecting how the return on the project is sensitive financial risk to projects other than the one being funded with
to and would amplify or abate general market movements. Thus, debt. Even in project finance, restrictive covenants may limit the
the applicable risk premium becomes β*(RM – RF), where a β>1 capacity to use other company assets as security to raise funds
denotes sensitivity to market. for new projects.
The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) captures this While senior lenders have no formal control over the company
relationship between risk and the related cost of equity funds: as long as it regularly services its debt, they can acquire a critical
influence on its affairs if there are liquidity problems.
Cost of equity (RE) = RF + β(RM - RF) To make use of debt, a company must either have currently
positive net cash flows or expect to become cash-flow-positive in
a sustainable way in the foreseeable future. Small to
where: medium-size exploration companies, without the backing of a
profitable operation are not cash-flow-positive and consequently
RE is return on equity
cannot service debt. They must therefore rely entirely on equity
RF is risk-free rate of return to fund their operations, even though it is complex and expensive
RM is return on the diversified market portfolio to raise. This is the case at least until they make a discovery and
can secure project finance by convincingly establishing project
β is index of the sensitivity of a security returns to market feasibility. Major integrated mining houses, by contrast, with
So if the risk-free rate of interest (RF) is five per cent and the strong, diversified balance sheets and large annual cash flows,
beta (β) index of a specific exploration company is 1.35, ie have little difficulty in raising debt funds both on their balance
reasonably sensitive to market. Assuming an average market risk sheet (eg conventional loans, bonds, notes and debentures) or
premium of six per cent the cost of equity would be: project-backed. But even exploration subsidiaries of major
integrated mining houses display the highest level of investment
Cost of equity (RE) = 5% + 1.35 * 6% = 13.1% in exploration at times of boom when new equity is easy to raise
in the capital markets.
SOURCES OF DEBT
Long-term debt
Some general considerations
Companies use long-term debt for mine construction and
In raising debt funds either for their operations or for new development and for ongoing corporate funding needs. In most
developments, or both, companies have access to essentially two cases, lenders ensure that it is secured by a senior claim on the
types of lending: firm’s assets.
• corporate finance, where a bank lends to the company as a Long-term debt can be either marketable or non-marketable. It
whole and has recourse to secure its debt on the company’s includes:
total assets and on the company’s cash flows to service its
debt; and • Long-term commercial bank loans, mostly at a variable-rate,
fully drawn advances with terms of one to ten years. Variable
• project finance, where the capital investment involved will interest rates are based on the government bond rate plus a
be repaid and serviced only by the cash flows generated by margin between 1.5 per cent and four per cent depending on
the project with no (in reality generally limited) recourse on the lender’s level of perceived risk. Fixed-rate bank loans, by
all the other company’s assets. contrast, tend to have shorter terms of one to five years. In
Irrespective of its type, debt can be characterised by its: both cases interest is generally calculated on a daily basis and
charged monthly in arrears. Loans are mostly on an
• Term, either short term (ie with maturity of less than interest-only basis with balloon principal repayments. On rare
12 months) or long term (ie with maturity of more than occasions a schedule of progressive principal repayments
12 months). The terms of loans should ideally match the life (credit foncier typical of the mortgage loans frequently used
of the investments they are funding. by property developers) applies.
• Degree of security, whereby loans can either be secured, Although banks are reluctant to grant long-term debt at a
senior or un-subordinated (ie guaranteed by specific assets or fixed rate of interest, it is possible to utilise a swap
by a floating claim against the borrowing firm’s assets) or agreement to achieve the same result as if the loan had been
unsecured or subordinated. issued on a fixed rate. While no principal changes hands, if
• Marketability, ie whether the relevant debt instruments can in any period the variable rate rises above the agreed swap
be traded on secondary capital markets, where, by contrast rate, then the merchant bank providing the swap will remit
with primary markets, no new funds are raised. the difference to the borrower. Swaps are desirable because

94 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

they make a company’s liabilities more predictable thus the Emily Ann nickel project in the Southern Goldfields
reducing the perception of financial risk in the eyes of region of Western Australia (Rothschild and Son (Australia)
institutional investors. Limited, 2000) and Jinchuan financing the Sally Malay nickel
• Specific project finance, secured mainly by the fortune of project in the Kimberley region. In some cases, to support
the project, which is becoming an important source of funds desirable developments, customers have actually bought and
to the resources industry for mine development. paid for future production in advance. This practice is known
as customer finance.
• Marketable long-term debt papers that are issued directly
to lenders and traded on secondary markets.
Short-term debt
• Debentures, which are long-term (one to five years),
fixed-interest instruments mostly written by finance Short-term borrowing – that is debt instruments with maturity of
companies, secured by specific assets or floating charge over less than 12 months – is the main tool for day-to-day liquidity
the company’s assets. Debentures require the issuing of a and operational cash management. This is because the
prospectus and ASX listing and are therefore expensive. operational cash flows of many mining operations are seldom
Furthermore, the trust deed imposes restrictions on further smoothly distributed over time and accurately predictable and the
senior debt and on the company’s level of total liabilities. To consequences of lack of liquidity at times of peak demand on the
obviate these difficulties, companies often combine a bank company’s cash are potentially dire. There are a number of
loan with a swap instead to achieve long-term fixed interest. short-term debt facilities, which, aside from trade credit (the
As a consequence, debentures are becoming a less popular cheapest form of borrowing) include:
means of raising funds. • overdraft accounts;
• Corporate bonds, issued by large companies, with a credit • loans secured by the inventories or by the accounts receivable
rating of AA+ or better. They are generally placed with (factoring) and similar very short-term instruments;
private or institutional investors. Hence, there is no need for a
prospectus, making this source of funds cheaper than • bridging finance; and
debentures. They are generally issued at a fixed interest and • marketable debt papers including promissory notes, bills of
are unsecured. Australian dollar denominated Eurobonds are exchange, bank bills (often as revolving facilities) and non-bank
sometimes issued on medium to long terms outside Australia. bills, all of which are sold at a discount to their face value.
While their interest rates may be comparatively low, it is
advisable to hedge against exposure to currency risk.
HYBRIDS BETWEEN EQUITY AND DEBT
• Unsecured notes, which are similar to debentures but, as the
name implies, they are unsecured. The trust deed is less There are a number of hybrid financial securities that display the
restrictive and hence they are more risky, Consequently, characteristics of both equity and debt.
lenders are justified in demanding a higher rate of interest. These include preference shares, which are legally equity but
• Financial leases, which are normally used to fund purchases which financially, display more the characteristics of debt. They
of plant and equipment. The mining company (the lessee) have preference over ordinary shares in terms of receiving
obtains the right to use the plant and equipment, which dividends and capital repayments. Dividends are often fixed and in
remains the property of the lessor, by paying rental with no many ways resemble interest payments. Generally, they can be
immediate requirement for significant capital outflows. There converted into ordinary shares at any time or at the end of a
may or may not be an opportunity to purchase the equipment specified term. In some cases, the contributed capital can be
at expiry of the lease. In the past it was possible to structure redeemed. This is not dissimilar from the repayment of a loan
the lease agreement in a manner that did not generate a principal, making this type of shares very similar to a
liability in the lessee’s balance sheet. This arrangement is fixed-interest loan. The main difference is that preference shares
referred to as an operating lease. Lenders generally recognise are less secure, ranking after other creditors in case of liquidation,
that lease agreements generate a definite liability for the that the quasi-interest dividends are not deductible for the purpose
lessee. They are generally recognised in balance sheets as a of assessing income tax and that, in some cases, they have a right
financial lease. While there are a number of desirable aspects to participating with ordinary shares in profit distributions.
to sourcing funding through leasing, the implicit interest rate They also include unsecured convertible notes that can be
may be higher than that of an equivalent loan. An effect converted into ordinary shares or redeemed at maturity. From a
similar to leasing is achieved by contracting out aspects of legal point of view, these are initially treated as debt, but
mine development or operations to a contractor that supplies ultimately after conversion into shares they become equity. As
the use of the necessary plant and equipment. convertible notes generally have definite terms and fixed rates of
interest, they are effectively equivalent to a fixed-term loan plus
• Commodity (gold)/derivative loans and advance sales an option. The value of this option makes it possible for
contracts. Companies have used gold loans for construction companies to issue convertible notes at a lower level of interest
and development of gold mines when a very high gold price than would have applied to a corresponding conventional
contango (see Chapter 7) and low gold leasing rates made this fixed-interest term loan.
approach extremely cheap, even though the latter was not
tax-deductible in spite of being a form of interest. The bank
would buy gold and lend it to the company. The company PROJECT FINANCE
would then sell this gold to finance the development of the
project, pledging to deliver gold to the bank at a future date Some introductory considerations
from its production. Commodity/derivatives linked facilities
A standard definition of project finance is:
have become less frequent due to lower contangos. More
recently as it will be seen, merchant banks have made it a Financing of project development based on a
requirement of project finance packages for the development financial structure with no, or more often limited,
of nickel and base metal mines for the proponents to sell recourse on the corporate assets of the sponsoring
forward a significant proportion of their production while the company, where project debt and equity used to
loan is outstanding. In some cases customers (off-take parties) finance the project are secured only by the project
have contributed to the development funding of projects to assets and serviced and repaid from the project
secure supplies for their smelters, for example, Inco financing cash flows.

Australian Mineral Economics 95


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

Few, if any, current project finance deals are truly no-recourse In carrying out due diligence, banks review source data,
as the relevant arrangements may include significant restrictive construct their own models and project cash flows focusing
covenants on further encumbering company assets without the mainly on the ‘downside’ of the project. They tend to disregard
consent of the project lenders. This may entail limits being sponsor tendencies to focus primarily on the ‘upside.’
placed on further borrowings, on the issuing of shares and on the If a project’s proponents are to be successful in obtaining
amount of dividends to be paid, etc. project finance, the project must satisfy a number of financial
Companies negotiate most current project finance (PF) ratios tests, the most critical of which (Amos, 1995, p 15) are:
arrangements to share risks, under-pinning financial structures to • the project life ratio, ie the net present value (NPV) of the
shift some, but not all, risk from the corporation to the lender. operating surplus for the life of the project at the end of the
Lenders may receive some reassurance from a requirement for period divided by the loan principal outstanding at the
borrowers to provide project completion guarantees backed by beginning of the period; and
equity (hurt money) and to maintain specific financial ratios
while the loans are outstanding. • the loan life ratio, ie the NPV of the operating surplus for
the life of the loan at the end of the period divided by the
Much initial project finance focused on large projects and loan principal outstanding at the beginning of the period.
companies but more recently small to medium-size enterprise
(SME) promoters have become more sophisticated and Acceptable values for these ratios depend on the commodity,
persuasive in their approaches to merchant banks. Project finance location, sovereign risk, the size of the project and the individual
arrangements often come into play when venture capitalists bank’s strategic objectives (Amos, 1995).
realise their gains by vending into an initial public offering or to The final ratio of importance is the debt service ratio of which
other equity investors. there are a number of formulations. Generally banks require a
Merchant banks have also become more effective in minimum cash debt cover ratio of 1.5, calculated as follows:
identifying and valuing potential assets and growth opportunities
irrespective of the influence of their corporate owners. In this (Annual cash flow + interest expenses + principal
context they have gone up-stream and taken a project facilitation repayments) / (interest expenses + principal repayments)
role by:
• locating initial sources of venture capital,
This measure differs from the corresponding and frequently
• identifying and introducing potential joint venture participants, quoted interest cover ratio based on financial accounting accrual
and rather than cash figures, calculated as follows:
• protecting juniors from potential takeovers.
There have even been instances of merchant banks providing (Earnings before interest and tax) / interest expenses
minor participation funds prior to finalisation of feasibility
studies, subject to risk-reward considerations and repayment at
the earliest opportunity. The rewards for successful relationship Project finance packages are project specific, highly structured
banking with project sponsors may go beyond the project finance and take into account tax implications. They are generally
fees by securing additional business, such as supporting a syndicated packages of different loan facilities provided by different
possible listing, hedging arrangements and margins and foreign lenders and coordinated by a lead merchant bank. Packages offer
exchange transactions. flexibility to match the varying funding needs of different stages of
the project development, commissioning and initial operations over
As with equity, the availability of project finance is somewhat time. As a result they are typically a mix of short- and long-term,
cyclical and dependent on market sentiment and commodity booms. floating or fixed rate loans with different principal repayment
Whether funds are available depends on the strength of the profiles, currency denominations and related details.
project and on a detailed and robust (bankable) feasibility study. Banks tailor the terms and repayment schedules to fit
Lead advisor banks generally have specialised mining analysis prospective, but conservatively estimated, cash flows from the
departments, which will carry out thorough technical and project. Naturally, the project must have the capacity to provide
discounted cash flow modelling and evaluation of the project and an expected rate of return sufficient both to ensure that the
risk analysis on a 100 per cent equity basis prior to project borrowing is adequately secure and serviced as well providing a
finance negotiations. reasonable return on equity funds. Thus, determination of an
Banks generally require free access to and time to digest appropriate discount rate to be used in the evaluation may be a
additional information particularly about: challenge. In packages requiring a substantial proportion of
• the grade and size of the resources and reserves and related forward sales, the discount rate to be used must be reduced
models and on the prospectivity of the surrounding accordingly to recognise the fact the major source of risk, ie
tenements; commodity price volatility, has been hedged.
From a lender’s risk-minimisation point of view payout
• the technical feasibility of the mining design proposed and periods and repayment profiles must be as short as possible
the realism of the related capital and operating cost without hindering the success of the project. This may mean that
estimates; debt has to be serviced preferentially to equity.
• the potential position of the proposed operation on the supply Sponsors often push for as much debt as possible, while merchant
(cost) curve for its commodity; banks usually insist on as much equity (‘hurt money’) as possible to
• the reputation, experience and track record of the company underpin some of the risks. Nevertheless, project finance loans
management and its consultants in managing similar between 75 per cent and 85 per cent of total development funds
developments and operations; have been common in recent mineral boom times.
• how sensitive the financial performance of the project would
be to variations in the value of its main inputs and to changes Risk underpinning
in the mining design adopted; and In the majority of recent project finance loans, banks have
• the realism of various schedules of production under retained some recourse on the sponsor’s balance sheet, at least
different scenarios that must display a sufficiently long tail of until physical completion of the project. After this point their
ore beyond the life of the PF loans. interests are secured mainly by the fortune of the project.

96 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

Banks insist on stringent specifications regarding physical THE FINANCIAL STRUCTURE OF MINING
completion and acceptable pre-defined operational performance. COMPANIES
They insist that the sponsor should bear the risk of achieving the
relevant milestones on time and on budget. Cost of debt, financial leverage and financial risk
Junior sponsors must be able to raise adequate equity capital to
cover feasibility costs and possible project cost over-runs, if they A prudent amount of secured borrowing by credit-worthy
are to qualify for project finance. Sponsors may react by companies is inherently significantly cheaper than the cost of equity.
transferring some of this risk to contractors through turn-key The cost of debt (RD) is further reduced after tax as the
contracts, but this may add significantly to project costs. Even relevant interest expenses before tax (I) are deductible in
after successful completion tests, banks may insist on stringent determining the company’s assessable income. The result is that
risk-management measures being in place before lessening or the rate of return on equity (RoE) generated by a project funded
relinquishing recourse to sponsors. with debt is higher than that from a project funded entirely with
equity. This effect is known as financial leverage. On a financial
When the project has passed the physical completion and accounting accrual basis, gearing (borrowing) will leverage
operational performance tests, the banks become partially or return on equity on a period-by-period basis by a factor of:
fully exposed to a variety of major risks including those relating
to whether:
PBIT/(PBIT – I)
• The operations proceed according to plan, with projected
production schedules being achieved and ore reserves and
The profit before interest and tax (PBIT) must be greater than
grade estimates being reconciled with the metal produced.
the interest expenses after tax (I*(1-t)), where t is the tax rate.
• Producers sell the mine’s output at the estimated prices, Conversely, on a cash basis the overall internal rate of return
keeping in mind the issue of commodity price volatility and (IRR) of a project will also significantly increase with gearing,
that the lead time to production may have been between two subject to the condition that in any period PBIT plus depreciation
and four years. Banks may make it a condition that some of plus the difference between the opening and closing balance of all
this marketing risk be mitigated by an appropriate level of other balance sheet items over the period must be greater than the
hedging while the loans are in place. corresponding after-tax interest expenses (I*(1-t)) for the period.
• Management is competent and operates the project Hence, in theory at least, it would be in the shareholders’ interest
successfully. to make use of as much debt as prudently possible. One might
• There is compliance with the necessary legal conditions to expect to find relatively high levels of debt in the balance sheet of
secure and maintain valid title, and other statutory and most mining companies. However, this does not appear to be the
environmental requirements. There may also be exposure to case in practice because borrowing introduces a new dimension of
some sovereign risk, which in its mildest form may express financial risk, particularly if PBIT is close to I*(1-t).
itself as bearable changes in the regulatory and fiscal regime
affecting returns over time, while at the limit may culminate Financial structure of mining companies
in expropriation of the project.
The average amount of debt on total assets [D/(D + E)] differs
Rather than being a true non-recourse source of funding, widely from industry to industry. However, the risk inherent in
project finance may be more of a risk-sharing mechanism. For it the resources sector, when compared with the additional
to be successful and result in lower cost of funds, the relevant financial risk brought about by increasing levels of borrowing,
arrangements should convey various sources of risk to those seems to act as a disincentives to borrow. Because of their high
parties better equipped to bear it. The matrix suggested by Deer level of risk, exploration companies have generally low or zero
(1987) illustrates the process of risk attribution well. A version of levels of debt, while mining companies, on average, have only
this appears in Table 9.2. moderate debt levels.
If a project is large and reasonably secure, the lead bank may In surveying 30 large global mining companies,
decide either to unbundle or accept (or securitise) the project PricewaterhouseCoopers (2004) revealed that on average their
credit risk, or both, so that syndicate investors can raise money debt:equity ratio is relatively low at 28.4 per cent, ie that only
by selling secured bonds domestically or source funds from 22.2 per cent of total funds employed were constituted by debt.
low-interest euromarkets and other global capital markets. This does not mean that individual mining projects may not
display significantly higher or lower levels of debt. Indeed, the
level of debt used is not constant over time. It is generally high at
TABLE 9.2 the start of project developments. As already noted, project
Project-finance risk-sharing. (Source: Deer, 1987.) finance packages for individual developments in Australia often
cover between 75 per cent to 85 per cent of total funds, but are
Type of risk Banks Borne by Other subject to repayment in the early stages of production.
borrower Overall ongoing levels of the corporate debt of mining
Reserves X companies in Australia seldom exceed half of total assets.
(subject to audit) This behaviour is consistent with the ‘traditional’ view that the
Completion X or X proportion of debt in the financial structure of a company can
(eg contractors) increase with beneficial leverage effects until both shareholders and
Operating X X lenders become anxious about the increasing financial risk and
(following (depending on expect rapidly increasing returns to compensate for it. Even secured
completion test) conditions) lenders become anxious because they know that the realisable value
Marketing X X or X of a mining company’s assets in case of a liquidation fire sale may
(limited) (eg customers) be much lower than its book value. As Figure 9.7 shows, the
weighted average cost of capital (WACC or RC) after-tax will fall
Management X for a while with increasing debt, then plateau and start rising rapidly
Legal X again when suboptimal levels of debt are reached.
Force majeure X X Modigliani and Miller (1963), by contrast, maintained that
(limited) theoretically, in frictionless capital markets, the risk-adjusted

Australian Mineral Economics 97


CHAPTER 9: AN INTRODUCTION TO MINERAL FINANCE

3. As a consequence only a few resources companies qualify


for inclusion in the main S&P/ASX 300 index and large,
index-using institutional investors tend not to be interested
in them.
4. Mergers, takeovers, listed investment companies (LICs) and
PDFs are effective strategies to overcome this handicap and
tap into institutional funds.
5. Different financial structures are appropriate to different
project stages:
a. on account of its risk, exploration up to feasibility is
funded primarily by equity;
b. development and construction make use of significant
levels of debt mainly in the form of project finance, but
banks will require early repayments and risk mitigation
by way of some equity to guarantee project completion
and possible cost over-runs; and
FIG 9. 7 - Optimising the after-tax weighted average corporate cost c. ongoing operations are funded with a lower (generally
of capital traditional view. less than 50 per cent), appropriate and stable proportion
of debt.
return expected by both shareholders and lenders would
gradually adjust upwards as the level of debt increases and that, 6. Use of an appropriate but prudent level of debt in the
for this reason, in the final analysis the actual level of debt used financial structure of a project will increase/leverage the
to fund a project/company should not matter. return on the equity invested in the project (RoE or IRR)
because of the tax deductibility of interest expenses.
Calculating the after-tax WACC, ie:
7. Increased debt will however increase financial risk and
WACC = (D/D+E) * RD * (1- t) + (E/D+E) * RE consequently the after-tax WACC of the firm.
8. No-recourse or limited recourse project finance is becoming
the prevalent way of funding new mine developments, with
is a relatively simple matter as the following example illustrates
lead merchant banks putting together flexible, generally
using the following assumptions:
syndicated, packages of loans to best match the timing and
• cost of equity (RE) = 13.1 per cent, nature of the project funding needs and to attribute risk to the
• cost of debt (RD) = 6.5 per cent, parties best equipped to manage it efficiently and effectively.
• tax rate (t) = 30 per cent, and
REFERENCES
• debt (D) as a percentage of total funds = D/(D + E) = 40 per cent.
Amos, Q G, 1995. Debt finance: The technical factors, in Proceedings
After-tax WACC = 6.5% * 0.4 * (1- 0.3) + 13.1% * 0.6 = 9.68% PACRIM ‘95 Congress (eds: J L Mauk and J D St George), pp 13-18
(The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
Note how the after-tax weighted average cost of capital at 9.68 Australian Stock Exchange, 2004. Understanding the indices, Sydney.
per cent, is considerably lower than the corresponding cost of
Brealey, R and Myers, S, 1996. Principles of Corporate Finance, fifth
equity at 13.1 per cent. edition (McGraw-Hill: New York).
In Chapter 10 it will be argued that the before-tax WACC is a Deer, P W, 1987. Project financing of Australian resources, in
suitable discount rate if project risk is similar to that of the firm as a Proceedings Pacific Rim Congress ‘87, pp 689-695 (The Australasian
whole and the project is going to be funded with a mixture of debt Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
and equity. The before-tax WACC should be used as the discount Etheridge, M and Uttley, P, 2003. Uncertainty, decision-making and value
rate instead of the after-tax WACC, because the DCF model will measurement – The fundamentals of the business of exploration, in
deduct the interest expenses before calculating the taxable income Proceedings AIG Conference on Risk Analysis and Management in
and related tax, hence the tax shield due to the deductibility of Mineral Exploration and Development (The Australian Institute of
interest expenses is incorporated in the model output. Geoscientists: Perth).
In the early stages of project evaluation, however, it is Hirshleifer, J, 1980. Price Theory and Applications (Prentice-Hall: London).
customary to assess the financial robustness of a project by Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal of New South Wales, 2002.
assuming 100 per cent equity funding and using the cost of equity Weighted average cost of capital, discussion paper DP 56 [online].
(RE) as the discount rate, particularly if the project is to be funded Available from: <http://www.ipart.nsw.gov.au> Date accessed: 8 May
primarily with share issues and/or from retained earnings. 2006.
KPMG, 2004. Capital market survey.
Modigliani, F and Miller, M H, 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost
CONCLUSIONS of capital: A correction, American Economic Review, 53(3):433-443.
1. Financial objectives and management of exploration and Peirson, G, Brown, R, Easton, S and Howard, P, 2004. Business Finance,
mining companies differs from that of other sectors of the eighth edition (McGraw-Hill Irwin: Sydney).
economy only in so far that their resources and reserves are PricewaterhouseCoopers, 2004. Review of Global Trends in the Mining
depleting, they are capital-intensive, and that, particularly Industry. Available from: <http://www.pwcglobal.com>.
exploration, is very dependent on the availability and cost Rappaport, A and Sirower, M L, 1999. Stock or cash? The trade-offs for
of raising equity funds. buyers and sellers in mergers and acquisitions, Harvard Business
Review, 77(6):147-160.
2. In spite of a high number of IPOs in times of boom, the Rothschild and Sons (Australia) Limited, 2000. Getting Financed,
mining sector is becoming a less important component of presentation.
the ASX capitalisation because the amounts raised (ie $2.5 Trench, A, 2002. Mine finance and accounting 282, course notes for unit
to $6 million) and capitalisation of exploration and mining 282 (Curtin University of Technology, Western Australian School of
companies is relatively low. Mines: Perth).

98 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10

Mineral Project Evaluation — An Introduction


Pietro Guj

What is it Worth? – Types and Uses of Financial Valuations


Income-Based Valuations and Discounted Cash Flow (DCF) Models
Modelling Debt and Financial Leverage
Comparison of Mutually Exclusive Projects with Different Lives
Inherent Weaknesses and Common Traps in DCF Analysis
Identifying and Quantifying Financial Risk: Expected Value, Sensitivity and Scenario Analyses
Probabilistic Models and Financial Simulations

WHAT IS IT WORTH? – TYPES AND USES OF The first two approaches are more frequently applied at the
FINANCIAL VALUATIONS exploration stages, the last after mineral resources have been
indicated and some initial concept of how they can be developed
and mined formulated and costed in a preliminary way.
General issues
There has been major development and standardisation in the
The type of financial valuation methodology used for a mineral/ field of project evaluation since 1990. The adoption of the
mining project depends on the stage of the project in the mining Australasian Code for Reporting of Identified Mineral Resources
cycle. Valuing an early or advanced exploration project presents and Ore Reserves (JORC code) in 1993, and of the Code and
very different challenges, from a development project at the Guidelines for Assessment and Valuation of Mineral Assets and
pre-feasibility or feasibility study stage to the evaluation of an Mineral Securities for Independent Expert Reports (VALMIN
established operating mine. code) in 1995, were major milestones. There have been similar
The most suitable methodology will also depend on the developments in other major mining countries such as the USA,
intended use of the valuation. While an investor is interested in Canada and South Africa that have promoted greater
the potential financial performance of a project and return on his reasonableness, materiality and transparency in project
or her equity over its entire life, banks may only be concerned evaluation.
with the capacity of a project’s cash flows to service the interest This has been accompanied by a more disciplined approach
and repay the loan principal over the early years of the project and greater accountability on the side of corporate governance
life while debt is outstanding. Banks are essentially unconcerned and valuers. Bourassa (2001, p 78) provides a useful review of
if after the loan has been repaid the project becomes unviable. the international legal requirements and standards for mineral
Government on the other hand, is concerned with the valuations.
economic performance of a project. This encompasses both In Australia, while not specifically mandating the use of the
monetary values and socio-economic measures of benefit, many VALMIN code, the Corporation Act 2001 and the Australian
of which are non-monetary. This type of evaluation may be of
Securities and Investment Commission (ASIC) Act 2001, make
critical importance to a company seeking government approval
reference to experts’ reports and valuations and there is evidence
of a project, if its possible development proves politically
controversial with sections of the community or specific that this code is a benchmark for best practice in the compilation
stakeholders or pressure groups. of prospectuses, takeovers and related documentation.
Setting aside for the moment the complex subject of how to In its listing rules, the Australian Stock Exchange (ASX)
determine the broader economic value of a project (a process mandates that all reports dealing with resources and reserves
sometimes involving econometric models, cost-benefit analysis must be drafted in compliance with the JORC code under the
and input-output and impact matrices), financial evaluations fall supervision of a ‘competent person.’ While not mandating
essentially into three distinct categories. Lawrence (2001, p 115) compliance with the VALMIN code, it supports its general
describes these as: principles.
• market-based, Lawrence (2001) argues that the ‘fair market value’ of
infrequently traded mining projects, does not necessarily equate
• cost-based, and to their ‘price’, which may be realised under specific industry or
• income-based. corporate circumstances. It is fair to say that internationally there

Australian Mineral Economics 99


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

is still some confusion about the meaning of such terms as ‘fair • its capacity to generate future net income,
market value’, ‘price’, ‘value in exchange’ and ‘value in use’
based on the highest and best use concept. • the magnitude and timing of such income, and
The VALMIN definition of market value in Australasia is the • the probability of its realisation.
estimated amount of money (or the cash equivalent of some other Income-based valuations are often referred to as ‘technical’
consideration) for which the mineral asset should change hands or ‘fundamental’ valuations. This is because they form the basis
on the valuation date. It must be between a willing buyer and a from which a market premium (or discount) is added to achieve a
willing seller in an arm’s length transaction in which each party fair market value. The market premium is generally positive in a
has acted knowledgeably, prudently and without compulsion. bull market and accounts for any strategic, specific corporate or
‘real option’ value, if the project is leveraged to the volatility of
Market and cost-based evaluations rising demand, commodity prices, exchange rates or other
influencing factors.
Market and cost-based valuations circumvent the difficulty
inherent in embarking in income-based valuations when a project Fundamental valuations, generally based on discounted cash
is still at the exploration stage and there is considerable scarcity flow (DCF) financial models of projects over their entire lives,
of critical information and uncertainty about the input factors while more objective, may still be biased by their deterministic,
essential to reliably modelling its future potential cash flows. static character and by the weakness inherent in the estimation of
and use of a single discount rate in comparing projects with often
Given the local influence of real estate valuers, market-based significantly different risk profiles. We explore these issues in
methods are generally favoured in the US to value and compare some detail in the following sections that deal with risk analysis
essentially very different mineral projects. Lawrence, (2001, and advanced project evaluation methodologies.
p 123) observes that there is a continuing debate about the
appropriateness of this approach. He subsequently discusses the In practice, many of the above valuation methods are not
benefit and considerable drawbacks of various market-based mutually exclusive and valuers should attempt more than one
approaches, including the ‘comparable sales’, ‘yardsticks’ and approach if they have relevant information to support it at hand.
‘joint venture (JV) terms’ methods. The introduction of the JORC and VALMIN codes was
The ‘comparable sales’ and ‘JV terms’ methods have certain accompanied by the publication of a large number of relevant
conceptual similarities in that they establish a fair market value papers and guidelines, collated in a number of key AusIMM
by comparison with: publications. Prominent among them are the Proceedings of the
VALMIN 1994 and 2001 conferences. Many of the methodologies
• consideration that changed hands in recent transactions; or discussed in these papers are now in common use in the mining
• with firm joint venture expenditure commitments and other industry. Torries (1998) provides a useful summary and
consideration to farm into a given level of equity in a project; description of these methods.
which are then grossed up to the implicit value for 100 per cent As a consequence the rest of this chapter assumes a degree of
of the project. familiarity with basic valuation methodologies. It is dedicated
primarily to considering how to avoid common pitfalls and
The problem is that comparable transactions are infrequent,
discussing recent developments in constructing and interpreting
their precise terms generally confidential and they are influenced
DCF models of mining projects as an aid in their fundamental
by market sentiment at the time of the transaction. Apart from
the fact that no two mining projects are alike, evolving bull or valuation.
bear market influences make comparison of values derived at
different times unreliable. INCOME-BASED VALUATIONS AND
Besides having the above weaknesses, ‘yardsticks’ and DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW (DCF) MODELS
‘transactional rules-of-thumb’, often relating to resources (eg
ounces of gold) in the ground, also suffer from the variety of The basic DCF model structure
differences that inevitably arise between gross and net values of
different transactions, given their different potential profitability Investment is the commitment of funds in the expectation of
due to differences in grades, recoveries, unit mining and receiving returns in the future sufficient not only to repay the
processing costs, logistics and other factors. investment, but also to generate an acceptable net surplus. Thus,
Roscoe (2001) discusses the cost-based approach, and in the overriding corporate objective for the management of a
particular the Australian ‘multiple of exploration expenditure mining project is to maximise the value-added to the current
(MEE)’ and Canadian ‘appraised value’ methods in a owners (shareholders) of the enterprise.
comprehensive way. He observes that both methods attempt to To assess the returns and in particular the value added by a
determine a fair market value of exploration properties in which project one must construct a techno-financial model simulating
no potentially commercially viable mineral deposit has yet been its financial performance over its whole life. This model
discovered. They utilise the amount of past exploration contains:
expenditure and of justifiable further investment in exploration to • a range of input variables, the value of which must be
test a project’s residual mineral potential as the basis for its estimated or forecast; and
value. In the case of MEE these figures are then adjusted by a • a series of interactive algorithms, which manipulate the
prospectivity enhancement multiple. Roscoe also reviews the inputs and generate a range of model outputs or results.
Canadian appraised value method with reference to comparable
exploration property transactions. Financial models have three components:
As with the market-based approach the validity of these • technical – selection of the most suitable mining method and
methods ultimately relies largely on the judgement of ‘expert’, design;
ideally registered, valuers. • financial – determination of an optimal annual mine
throughput which maximises the value added for the owners;
Fundamental or technical evaluation and
Irrespective of the approach used, the value of a mineral project • risk analysis and management – identification and
originates from: quantification of:

100 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

• market/price risk derived from the volatility of In simplified models, it is normal to assume that initial
commodity prices, exchange rates and demand; instantaneous investments, say the purchase of an operating
project or a piece of equipment ready for use, occur in year 0.
• project risk relating to the geological, geotechnical, Year 0 by convention has no duration.
metallurgical and engineering characteristics of the
mineral deposit and its preferred mode of development; In analysing a project it is possible to build a model in either:
and • nominal money terms (also known as historical dollars or
• financial risk arising from the amount of debt as a dollars of the day) using figures that incorporate forecast
proportion of total funds (gearing) used in funding the inflation; or
project. • real money terms, which do not incorporate the effect of
Risk analysis enables decision-makers to determine the firm’s inflation.
risk-management policy, ie which elements of risk should be The relationship between real and nominal dollars figures is:
hedged or insured, contracted out to third parties better suited to
bear them, or borne by the firm.
Real dollars = nominal dollars/(1 + inflation rate expressed
Financial models underpin three fundamental categories of
in decimals)y
decisions:
1. the investment decision – determining the worth of the
Where y is the number of years between the present (year 0)
project assuming 100 per cent equity funding;
and the time when the nominal dollar cash flow will occur.
2. the financing decision – determining the optimal level of There are both advantages and disadvantages in the use of
gearing to leverage the return to equity holders consistent with either nominal or real money models. For instance building a
their willingness to bear the additional financial risk; and model in real dollars makes estimates of input variables using
3. the portfolio decision – determining the desirability of the today’s dollars more meaningful to planning and cost engineers
project in light of possible synergies with other existing and easier to communicate to company decision-makers. Both
corporate assets, ie its capacity to: groups relate more easily to current prices and costs than to their
• either increase the combined expected returns, future values, which often need to be highly inflated.
Using nominal dollars, by contrast, makes it easier to reconcile
• decrease the combined risk, or DCF models with forecast financial accounting figures and
• a combination of both. related financial ratios and measures of return. Banks often use
It is possible to construct financial models in two ways: these to assess loan applications. It also helps circumvent
difficulties that arise in real dollar DCF models in handling
1. Under assumed certainty using single-point, expected depreciation and amortisation figures correctly. Although
estimates of input variables, which generate single-point depreciation of tangible assets and amortisation of intangible
expected model outputs. Single-point models can assets are accrual expenses and not cash items, because of their
determine: tax deductibility, they nonetheless influence cash outflow
• the inputs to which the project performance is most relating to the tax paid in each period.
sensitive, deserving more in-depth investigation Irrespective of whether one uses real or nominal money values,
(sensitivity analysis); and the result of any DCF analysis should be the same. In practice,
• the project’s performance under various scenarios, ie evaluation errors arise because analysts inadvertently mix real
under combinations of likely or extreme input values, to and nominal dollar values.
test the project robustness under pessimistic conditions Finally future inflation can either be estimated on average or
or its ‘blue sky’ under optimistic ones. occasionally using a cyclical forecast. The latter approach
2. Under probabilistic conditions using probability generates different inflation rate forecasts at various stages in the
distributions (not single-point estimates) of possible input economic cycle and consequently creates complexities when
values, and carrying out Monte Carlo simulations in which discounting cash flows to their present value, as individual
all input variables are sampled randomly and nominal discount rates have to be used for each period.
simultaneously, according to their respective probability of
occurrence, during a large number of model iterations. Constructing a simple DCF model of a mine
Besides the expected value, this approach generates the
surrounding distributions of all possible values for each Project optimisation is an iterative process to determine the
model output. optimal mining method and design, and therefore annual mine
throughput which adds the maximum value for the owners of the
Analysts who construct models under assumptions of certainty project compatible with the level of risk they are prepared to
using single-point expected input values often refer to the bear.
exercise and results from it as the project base case.
An initial assessment of ore reserves leads to a range of
While DCF models must cover the whole life of the project, it technically feasible mine methods, mine sizes and related costs.
is an important decision to determine an appropriate period
These in turn determine the related cut-off grade on the basis of
break-up for the model. Initially most mining projects analysts
which the initial ore reserves are refined.
usually select a yearly period. Once selected, the timing of
individual cash flows within a period loses its significance. Hopefully the outcome is a mining method and rate of
Analysts typically assume that cash flows take place at the stroke production, which realises economies of scale without creating
of midnight of the last day of the period, though infrequently excessive operating leverage. The final mine life is heavily
they assume that they occur mid-period. influenced by the need to optimise capital recovery under the
Such coarse periods may not be suitable for some models. An prevailing tax regime.
example is the situation where it is necessary to persuade a bank This task is facilitated by powerful mine modelling and
that a project may generate free cash flows sufficient to service optimisation software which, given a body of mineralisation,
monthly interest and periodic loan principal repayments. In such accurately determines the size and shape of possible mines at
a case analysts should select a monthly or more frequent interval. different realisable prices and operating costs.

Australian Mineral Economics 101


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

While there are no real short cuts to the iterative nature of Consider a company wishing to acquire an operating open cut
mine life optimisation, the process needs to start with an initial gold mine with residual diluted mining reserves of 2 Mt at a
approximation which can be obtained by using Taylor’s grade of 4 g/t Au for a price of $40 million. The asset can be
empirical formula (Taylor, 1978): depreciated on a straight line over the life of the mine and it is
expected that it will be sold for $10 million after the mine closes.
Mine life in years = 6.5 * (diluted mining reserves in Taylor’s formula suggests a mine life of five years with annual
million tonnes)0.25 ore throughputs of 0.4 Mt per annum. Assuming a waste to ore
ratio of four, removal of waste will average 1.6 Mt per annum.
This formula, which has been severely criticised on both an A simple nominal dollar model of this investment appears in
empirical and theoretical basis, was claimed to provide an initial Table 10.1. This assumes a gold price of US$ 368 per ounce, an
estimate of the optimal mine life within a band of confidence of exchange rate of A$ 1 equal US$ 0.70, and gold recovery of
plus or minus 20 per cent irrespective of the mine method or 95 per cent.
commodity involved. Contract operations result in faster mine lives The operation will produce the following annual quantity of
of the order of 75 to 80 per cent of those suggested by the formula. gold and revenue:
The structure of a financial DCF model consists of three
groups of cash flows: • 48 869 ounces of gold, ie (0.4 Mt or ore * 4 g/t Au * 95 per
cent recovery) / 31.10345; and
• those from operations,
• revenue of $25.69 million, ie 48 869 ounces at A$ 525.71 per
• those from investment activities, and ounce.
• those from financing activities. If we assume mining costs of $2 for each tonne of both ore and
The sum of these cash flows for a specific project over each waste moved, with milling cost of $12 per tonne and
period represents its net cash flow (NCF). administration cost of $2 per tonne of ore treated, the annual
There is a close relationship between the NCF of a project in a operating and maintenance cost will be:
specific period and the sources and applications of funds (cash • $9.60 million (ie 0.4 Mt of ore + 1.6 Mt of waste) * $2 per
flow) statement in the financial accounts of the firm holding the tonne mining cost + 0.4 Mt of ore * ($12 per tonne of ore
project for the same period. milling cost + $2 per tonne of ore administration cost).
Irrespective of whether preliminary or detailed production
schedules have been estimated, the net cash flows from Some further assumptions are: that inflation will average
operations in each period depend on the interplay of: three per cent per annum over the life of the mine; that it will
affect both revenue and costs to the same degree; and that cash
• the recurrent revenue function (which is quantity sold times flows occur at the end of each yearly period. Both revenue and
realised price); and cost must be inflated in models using nominal dollars. As a
• the recurrent cost function (which is normally quantity times consequence the annual revenue and cost estimates in year 0
variable unit cost plus fixed period cost). dollars of $25.69 million and $9.60 million respectively must
The performance of most projects is very sensitive to factors be multiplied by one plus the inflation rate (ie by 1.03) for each
affecting revenue (eg tonnages, grades, metallurgical recovery, year in the future becoming (see Table 10.1) $26.46 and 9.89
prices, exchange rates, etc) and to a lesser extent to capital and million respectively in year 1, $27.26 and 10.18 million in year
recurrent costs. 2 and so on.

TABLE 10.1
A simple nominal dollar model of an operating gold mine.
Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Total
All ($ million)
Sales revenue 26.46 27.26 28.08 28.92 29.79 140.51
Capital gain on salvage 10 10
Less:
Royalty at 2.5% -0.66 -0.68 -0.7 -0.72 -0.74 -3.51
Operating expenditure -9.89 -10.18 -10.49 -10.8 -11.13 -52.5
Depreciation -8 -8 -8 -8 -8 -40
Profit before tax 7.92 8.39 8.88 9.39 9.91 10 54.5
Less tax at 30% -2.37 -2.52 -2.67 -2.82 -2.97 -3 -16.35
Profit after tax 5.54 5.87 6.22 6.57 6.94 7 38.15
Add back depreciation 8 8 8 8 8 40
Net cash flow – NCF -40 13.54 13.87 14.22 14.57 14.94 7 78.15
Discount factor 1 0.8826 0.7790 0.6876 0.6068 0.5356 0.4727
Present value of NCF -40 11.95 10.81 9.78 8.84 8 3.31
Cumulative DCF -40 -28.05 -17.24 -7.46 1.38 9.38 12.69
Net present value at 13.3% discount 12.69
Internal rate of return 24.65%
Discounted pay back period 4
Capital efficiency index 0.32

102 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

Many mines produce and sell concentrate (eg copper or A net present value of zero means that the investment only
lead-zinc concentrate) to a custom smelter rather than metal to a returns the compound rate of discount. Projects with negative
terminal market such as the London Metal Exchange. Estimating NPVs will consume value and should not attract investment.
their revenue, ie their net smelting return (NSR) or value of In the example described in Table 10.1 the operating mine
concentrate fob mine (free on board - after deducting smelting adds $12.69 million after paying 13.3 per cent interest on the $40
and refining charges levied by the custom smelters and the million investment compound over the five-year life of the mine.
relevant transport costs) becomes more complex as the terms of The mine is clearly a good investment.
custom smelting are different for various types of concentrates. However, as Figure 10.1 shows, its NPV at discount rates in
For copper concentrates they include: excess of 24.65 per cent becomes negative. If the required rate of
return of a company were higher than this, then the project would
• a unit deduction of between one and 2.5 per cent;
be rejected. Thus, whether a project is acceptable or not is a
• a fixed smelting charge per tonne of concentrate; function of the discount rate that has been applied to it.
• a variable refining charge as a function of the contained copper;
• a price participation factor if the LME copper price falls beyond Sensitivity of NPV to changes in discount rates
a neutral zone between US$ 0.70 and 0.90 per pound; and
50.00
• credits and penalties for associated metals (eg gold).
More often than not, in preliminary evaluations a percentage 40.00
smelter return (eg 75 per cent of the value of the payable copper NPV at 13.33% discount = $12.69 M
contained in the concentrate less transport cost) is used to 30.00

NPV $ million
simplify calculations.
20.00
Detailed revenue and cost engineering estimates are beyond IRR = 24.65%
the scope of this paper, but will be discussed again briefly in the 10.00
next chapter.
0.00
Project valuations are at a point in time – 0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40%
-10.00
discounting cash flows NPV = 0

A modern way of looking at cash flows is to consider them like -20.00


commodities, the value of which is determined by two criteria: Discount rate %
timing and risk.
NPV $ million
Let us assume that there is no risk attached to future cash
flows. A rational investor would prefer early rather than later
cash flows of equal magnitude because he or she could invest FIG 10.1 - Sensitivity of NPV to changes in discount rates.
them and generate interest income. By receiving the cash flows
later the investor would forego interest and incur an ‘opportunity The discount rate at which the NPV becomes zero (ie 24.65
cost’ equal to the so-called ‘time-value of money’. per cent), known as the internal rate of return (IRR), is a
measure of the project return on equity.
To compensate for the opportunity cost, future cash flows are
therefore discounted to their present value at a rate equal to the Although popular, the IRR has considerable theoretical and
return the investor would have derived had he or she invested in computational difficulties (particularly when the project
the next best opportunity available. generates alternations of positive and negative cash flows).
Analysts should use it, at best, as a subsidiary criterion of value.
Rates of discount can be expressed as either decimals or
percentages. In the example described in Table 10.1, there was a In addition, the IRR is a measure of return per dollar invested.
nominal discount rate of 0.133 or 13.3 per cent. As such, it is of limited use in comparing projects of significantly
different scope. An exhaustive discussion about the pros and
A compounding factor is the sum of one plus a rate of interest
cons of using IRR is beyond the scope of this paper but can be
or discount (eg 1 + 0.133 = 1.133 is the compounding factor at
found in Torries (1998, pp 41-47).
13.3 per cent for one period, 1.1332 for two periods and 1.133t
for t periods). The reciprocal of a compounding factor (eg Other subsidiary criteria of value are:
1/1.133 = 0.882613 for one year) is the discounting factor for • the capital efficiency index (KE = NPV / PV of CAPEX),
the same number of periods (eg 1/1.133t for t periods). which measures the value added per dollar invested (in the
Most readers will be familiar with the process of discounting, above example, KE was $0.32 per dollar invested); and
which entails determining the present value (PV) of cash flows • the pay back period, which represents the time that a project
to be received or disbursed at various periods (t) in the future by takes to repay the initial investment. This can be calculated
multiplying them by the discount factor appropriate for the either as a discounted pay back period (DPBP) period, ie
relevant period (ie 1/(1+discount rate)t ). including interest equal to the compound rate of discount
To the extent that the corporate objective of an enterprise is during the period of payback or on an undiscounted basis. In
maximising shareholders’ wealth, it seems that the paramount the above example the investment is repaid with interest
criterion of value must be the net present value (NPV) or sometime before the end of the fourth year. To be more
value-added. NPV is the sum of all the net project cash flows precise a finer (say monthly) time period would have had to
after discounting them to their present value: selected to construct the model.
Establishing an appropriate discount rate is a complex and
ambiguous process both from a theoretical and practical point of
NPV = Σ 0t t
(CFt / (1 + discount rate) )
view, with there being a serious danger of introducing bias in
evaluations. This issue will be discussed in greater depth later,
If the NPV is positive the investment is acceptable because it while dealing with risk.
adds value after having returned the discount rate on a compound For the time being it is sufficient to recognise that firms face
basis on the capital invested. different costs for their:

Australian Mineral Economics 103


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

• equity, and For some other items the lags between the timing of accrual
and cash transactions and the relevant amount may be significant
• debt capital. enough not to be neglected, other than in the most preliminary of
As seen earlier, in Chapter 9, a common tool for determining the evaluations. For example mineral royalties and taxes accrued in
cost of equity (RE) is the capital asset pricing model (or CAPM): the first year of operations are payable in quarterly instalments
within 28 days of the end of each quarter. In effect the fourth
RE = RF + β ∗ (RM – RF) quarterly payment is deferred by around four months into each
following year with the last quarterly payment due four months
after the mining operation ceases to produce taxable income.
Where RF is the risk-free rate of interest and β ∗ (RM – RF) is Given the capital intensive nature of mining and the relatively
the risk premium which is the product of the premium on a long life of its asserts, by far the most significant lags between
balanced ‘market portfolio’ (RM – RF) and of the β index cash and accruals occur between lumpy cash out flows relating to
reflecting the sensitivity of the returns on a specific asset to the purchase of capital assets (eg plant and equipment, mining
movements in the market portfolio.
rights etc) and their recovery over their useful life by way of
Use of the cost of equity RE as a discount rate is appropriate if annual depreciation and amortisation charges against revenue in
the DCF model has been constructed under 100 per cent equity the profit and loss account.
assumptions.
Asset depreciation and amortisation relate to their original,
The after-tax cost of debt (RD*(1-t) where t is the tax rate) is historical acquisition cost as recorded in the firm’s balance sheet.
generally lower than that of equity, because loans are in most Over time the asset register will contain a mixture of historical
instances secured and the related interest expenses are
values of different years. Furthermore, selected assets are
tax-deductible. This leads to financial leverage, ie to enhanced
periodically re-valued while others are kept at their historical
returns to equity holders, at least as long as the level of debt in
the funding structure of the firm (ie its debt to equity ratio) does value until fully written off.
not rise to a point where it engenders excessive financial risk and While depreciation is not a cash cost (as the cash outflow to
concerns on the side of both the equity and debt providers. establish the asset occurred in a previous period) it does however,
Analysts frequently use the weighted average cost of capital on account of its deductibility from taxable income, influence the
(WACC) as the basic discount rate in evaluations involving the income tax payable and eventually paid and therefore the project
use of debt in the funding structure of a project. Its formula is: cash flows. There is a strong case, if one wishes to avoid the
chance of making depreciation related mistakes, for constructing
DCF models in historical or nominal dollars, as there is less
WACC = D/(D+E) * RD * (1-t) + E/D+E * RE danger of underestimating income tax.
Further complexities in modelling a mining project and in
where: attempting to reconcile it with the related financial accounting
measures arise because the effective lives allowed by the ATO
D is debt
for certain mining assets for fiscal purposes are shorter compared
E is equity to their actual useful lives in the mining operations and related
Its before-tax equivalent (ie D/D+E * RD + E/D+E * RE) is depreciation in their financial accounts. As a consequence the
frequently used as the basic discount rate in evaluations accelerated fiscal rates of depreciation lead to deferral of some
involving the use of debt in the funding structure as the model tax liabilities.
will automatically compute the interest tax shield. Further complexity is created by the degree of directorial
discretion as to whether and when exploration expenditure
Reconciling cash and financial accounting should be capitalised or expensed.
accrual figures in a DCF model Irrespective of whether a model is constructed in real or
nominal dollar terms, its results over the whole life of the mine
As their name implies, DCF models deal exclusively with cash must be the same. If this is not the case, there has been a
and not with commonly encountered financial accounting figures computational error.
typically compiled on an accrual (not cash) basis. Accrual
The financial accounting treatment of mineral reserves and
accounting conventions aim at matching revenue with the related
costs in each period. Erroneous mixtures of cash and non-cash resources in the ground is also an area froth with considerable
figures are commonly the source of potentially significant errors in complexity and ambiguity. If a company, for instance, discovers
project evaluations. and develops a mining project, the value of the project is
generally recorded in the company’s balance sheet at the
Occasionally because of the need to satisfy both financial
historical cost of its exploration and development. The potential
accounting and DCF performance criteria, sophisticated models
value of the resources, which have been delineated in the
are constructed in a way that broadly reconciles these two views.
This implies modelling the time lags between ‘recognising’ (ie process, is initially not captured in the balance sheet, because it
accruing) a transaction in the financial accounts and the time is deemed that its realisation is uncertain and cannot be
when the relevant cash actually changes hands. unambiguously measured. A list of mineral reserves and
resources may, however, be provided in the company annual
As financial accounts are written in historical or nominal
report to substantiate the success of its exploration activities.
dollars, it is generally more practical to build this type of model
in nominal dollars. If on the other hand, another company acquires the same
In steady operations, the differences between the related mining project, its acquisition cost, presumably incorporating the
opening and closing balances accrued in the balance sheet for value of the relevant mineral resources and reserves, will appear
some recurrent items (eg accounts receivable and accounts in its balance sheet. The difference between the acquisition cost
payable, inventories, work in progress, annual leave and other and the fair value of identified tangible assets (eg of exploration
provisions etc) may not be very significant given the general and development) represents an intangible asset (a form of
band of error of preliminary DCF mine models and can therefore goodwill) called mineral rights. The amortisation of mineral
be ignored. However, sometimes significant operational cash rights together with the depreciation of tangible assets will be
flow may be capitalised in the balance sheet, as for instance in shown in the profit and loss statement in determining the profit
the case of a large build up of unsold inventories, and may need for the year, but unlike depreciation is generally not
to be taken into account in the DCF model. tax-deductible.

104 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

Needless to say, these aspects cause difficulties in properly While the individual annual undiscounted profit and net cash
comparing many conventional financial accounting measures of flow figures are vastly different, their cumulative figures at the
value, relying as they do on annual profit, which is a function of end of year 5 (ie $41.85 million) are the same. This would have
depreciation and amortisation, rather than on cash flows. been the case even if the company had paid dividends during its
This is illustrated in Table 10.2 which provides a comparison five-year life. In other words matching of annual revenue and
of the annual profits that would be reported by a different owner expenses in the accrual accounting financial statements does not
of the same mine with a life of five years and with gross annual alter the aggregated cash value of the project over its whole life.
revenue of $100 million and recurrent expenses of $60 million As a result, the shareholders’ equity at the end of year 5 at $41.85
before depreciation, tax and amortisation. million, ie the sum of the retained earnings ($31.85 million) and
The first column relates to the mine being operated by the the capital originally contributed ($10.00 million), corresponds
discoverer after a capital investment of $30 million in to the year 5, closing cash amount of $41.85 million in the
exploration and development. The second relates to a company balance sheet.
that acquires the mine at start of production for $140 million. It As already pointed out borrowing will progressively leverage
is interesting to note how on the basis of a year-by-year
the expected return on shareholders’ equity (RoE) by a factor of:
comparison, the discoverer would post a much higher profit than
the acquirer (ie $23.8 versus $1.8 million), even though their
annual cash flow is the same. Clearly just comparing PBIT / (PBIT – I)
performance measures based on annual profits in isolation will
not give a potential investor a proper appreciation of the worth of
this project. where PBIT is the annual profit before interest expenses (I) and
taxes (T).
MODELLING DEBT AND FINANCIAL LEVERAGE In the previous example, for instance, 75 per cent debt as a
proportion of total funds invested (gearing) generates the
Returning to our previous DCF example of Table 10.1, let us now leverage described in Table 10.4, compared to the same project
assume that the company only issues ten million shares of $1 at
modelled on a 100 per cent equity funding assumption.
par to acquire the $40 million operating mine, funding the
remaining $30 million in acquisition cost with a fixed-interest- Such a direct comparison, however, is naïve because increases
rate loan at ten per cent per annum repayable after the end of in debt are accompanied by additional financial risk. It is
year 3. therefore inappropriate to compare highly geared and ungeared
Also assume, to simplify the exercise, that with good financial projects with significantly different risk characteristics using the
management the opening and closing balances of most accrued same time and risk-adjusted discount rate.
items in the balance sheet would be virtually unchanged, ie that Empirical evidence suggests that initially, as the level of debt
annual accrual and cash figures for these items are roughly the increases, both providers of equity and debt are not unduly
same. Under these assumptions, the main focus of the model will concerned about the marginally higher financial risk. After all,
be on the critical items relating to capital assets, the associated shareholders benefit handsomely from leverage effects and the
depreciation and salvage and on how to handle loan principal
bank loans are generally secured. However, as gearing increases
drawdowns and repayments, fixed interest expenses and retained
earnings. shareholders, who bear the ultimate risk of the firm, become
more concerned. Their expectations in term of return on equity
The DCF model of this mine is constructed in parallel with
will rise steeply to compensate for the additional risk. Also, as
and using the corresponding forecast financial accounting
gearing continues to rise, even the providers of secured debt
statements, as displayed in Table 10.3. The most convenient
order is first to compile the profit and loss statement using become nervous and expect higher interest rates. They fear not
forecast recurrent revenue and expenditure figures, as they will being able to fully realise the value of the assets provided as
accrue in the annual financial accounts of the firm. It is possible collateral in case of a fire sale. As already seen earlier, in
to convert these to the corresponding cash figures in a forecast Chapter 9, these expectations for higher returns will soon erode,
sources and applications of funds statement and finally and overcome the tax benefits from the lower after-tax cost of
combine them in the related balance sheet. debt vis a vis that of equity.

TABLE 10.2
Comparing reported profits for ‘discoverer owned and developed’ and acquired mines.
Discoverer Acquirer
($ million) ($ million)
Mine life (years) 5 5
Tangible assets: exploration and development 30 30
Project acquisition price 0 140
Intangible assets: mining rights = price premium paid by acquirer 0 110
Gross revenue 100 100
Recurrent expenditure -60 -60
Tax-deductable depreciation -6 -6
Net operating income before tax 34 34
Less tax at 30% 10.2 -10.2
Non-tax-deductable amortisation of mining rights 0 -22
Net profit after tax 23.8 1.8
Net cash flow after tax 29.8 29.8

Australian Mineral Economics 105


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 10.3
Reconciling a nominal money discounted cash flow model with financial accounting statements.
Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Total
All ($ million)
PROFIT AND LOSS STATEMENT
Sales revenue 26.46 27.26 28.08 28.92 29.79 140.51
Salvage 10.00 10.00
Less
Royalty -0.66 -0.68 -0.70 -0.72 -0.74 -3.51
Operating and maintenance expenditure -9.89 -10.18 -10.49 -10.80 -11.13 -52.50
Depreciation -8.00 -8.00 -8.00 -8.00 -8.00 -40.00
Interest expenses -3 -3 -3
Profit before tax: 4.92 5.39 5.88 9.39 9.91 10.00 45.50
Less tax at 30% -1.47 -1.62 -1.77 -2.82 -2.97 -3.00 -13.65
Net profit after tax: 3.44 3.77 4.12 6.57 6.94 7.00 31.85
NOTE – Fixed nominal annual rate of interest 10.00%
SOURCES AND USES OF CASH (CASH FLOW) STATEMENT
Net cash flow from operations 0.00 11.44 11.77 12.12 14.57 14.94 7.00 71.85
Cash flow – investment activities -40.00
Cash flow – financing activities 30.00 -30.00 0.00
Net project cash flow -10.00 11.44 11.77 12.12 14.57 14.94 7.00 48.15
BALANCE SHEET
Current assets:
Cash 0.00 11.44 23.22 35.33 19.91 34.85 41.85
Fixed assets:
Mine at acquisition cost 40.00 40.00 40.00 40.00 40.00 40.00
Less accumulated depreciation 0.00 -8.00 -16.00 -24.00 -32.00 -40.00
Written down value of mine 40.00 32.00 24.00 16.00 8.00 0.00 0.00
Total assets 40.00 43.44 47.22 51.33 27.91 34.85 41.85
Liabilities: Repaid after the end of year 3
Loan 30.00 30.00 30.00 30.00 30.00
Less loan principal repayments 30.00
Loan principal outstanding 30.00 30.00 30.00 30.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Shareholders’ equity:
Contributed capital 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00
Retained earnings 0.00 3.44 7.22 11.33 17.91 24.85 31.85
Total shareholders’ equity 10.00 13.44 17.22 21.33 27.91 34.85 41.85
DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW ANALYSIS
Net cash flow – NCF -10.00 11.44 11.77 12.12 -15.43 14.94 7.00
Discount factor 1 0.882613 0.779005 0.687559 0.606849 0.535612 0.472738
Present value of NCF -10.00 10.10 9.17 8.33 -9.36 8.00 3.31
Cumulative DCF -10.00 0.10 9.27 17.60 8.24 16.24 19.55
NPV at 13.3% 19.55 IRR (%) 97.32 DPBP 1 KE 1.96

It is also important to note (see Table 10.5) that the NPV of the
TABLE 10.4 project at $19.55 million is the same irrespective of whether the
Leverage effects of gearing. model is constructed in nominal or real dollars, provided the
Gearing NPV IRR (%) DPBP KE
nominal dollar cash flow is discounted by the nominal discount
(%) ($ million) (nominal) (Years) ($NPV/Capex) rate of 13.3 per cent and the real model by the corresponding real
rate of ten per cent.
0 12.69 24.65 4 0.32
It could be argued that a more appropriate discount rate for the
75 19.55 97.32 1 1.96 nominal model of Table 10.3 could have been the nominal
before-tax WACC = 0.75*10 per cent + 0.25*13.3 per cent =
10.83 per cent per annum. This would result in an increase in
These issues will be expanded upon later, when introducing NPV from $19.55 million to $21.30 million. As the average
the concept of ‘price of risk’. annual inflation was assumed to be three per cent, this

106 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 10.5
The real dollar model equivalent of a reconciled nominal mine model.
Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Total
All ($ million)
Sales revenue 25.69 25.69 25.69 25.69 25.69 128.47
Salvage 8.37 8.37
Less:
Royalty at 2.5% -0.64 -0.64 -0.64 -0.64 -0.64 -3.21
Operating and maintenance expenses -9.60 -9.60 -9.60 -9.60 -9.60 -48.00
Depreciation -7.77 -7.54 -7.32 -7.11 -6.90 -36.64
Interest expenses -2.91 -2.83 -2.75
Profit before tax 4.77 5.08 5.39 8.34 8.55 8.37 40.51
Less tax at 30% -1.43 -1.52 -1.62 -2.50 -2.57 -2.51 -12.15
Profit after tax 3.34 3.56 3.77 5.84 5.99 5.86 28.36
Add back depreciation 7.77 7.54 7.32 7.11 6.90 36.64
Loan principal drawdown and repayments 30.00 -26.65
Net cash flow – NCF -10.00 11.11 11.10 11.09 -13.71 12.89 5.86 38.34
Real discount factor at (1.133)/(1.03) -1 = 0.1 1 0.9090 0.8264 0.7513 0.6830 0.6209 0.5645
Present value of NCF -10.00 10.10 9.17 8.33 -9.36 8.00 3.31
Cumulative DCF -10.00 0.10 9.27 17.60 8.24 16.24 19.55
NPV at 10.00% 19.55 DPBP 1
Real IRR 91.57% KE 1.96

Note – The nominal internal rate of return (IRR) in Table 10.3 (ie 97.32%) differ from the corresponding real one in Table 10.5 by the inflation factor for
one year, ie:
[(1 + Nominal IRR in decimals) / (1 + Inflation rate in decimals)] − 1 = (1 + 0.9732 ) / (1 + 0.03 ) − 1
= 0.9157 or 91.57%

corresponds to a real before-tax WACC rate of 7.60 per cent, amount for annual depreciation expenses as in Table 10.3.
which, in turn, should have been used to discount the real dollar Similarly, if no further borrowing takes place, the same figure as
cash flows in the model of Table 10.5: in Table 10.3 will appear in the financial accounts of successive
years for fixed interest expenses. As, by definition, financial
Real rate = [(1 + Nominal rate of discount in decimals) / accounts use historical or nominal dollars, these figures are
(1 + Inflation rate in decimals)] - 1 correctly used in the nominal dollar model.
= [(1 + 0.10825) / (1 + 0.03)] - 1 The same NPV was obtained in the real dollar model because
inputs with constant amounts in the nominal model, such as
= 0.07597 or 7.60%
depreciation, salvage value, fixed interest expenses and loan
principal repayment, were correctly deflated in Table 10.5 to
This approach to discounting would be valid if it was the reflect their progressively diminishing power of acquisition.
company policy to maintain an overall constant rate of gearing Had this not been the case, the NPV of the real dollar model
and to use its corporate WACC as the rate of discount for project would have been different and incorrect. The error of using
evaluation irrespective of the funding structure adopted for each nominal depreciation or salvage in real dollar models occurs
individual project. frequently. It leads to underestimation of the tax liability and the
One might, on the other hand argue that, in the case of a overvaluation of projects.
single-project company, the cash flows generated in the year Similar mistakes in the handling of fixed interest expenses and
beyond the time of repayment of the loan should not be loan principal repayments, by contrast, severely punish the value
discounted at 10.83 per cent nominal or 7.60 per cent real but at
of the project.
the cost of 100 per cent equity funding, ie 13.3 per cent nominal
or ten per cent real. This approach, which would decrease the Weakness in the handling of the return of working capital at
NPV of the project somewhere between $19.55 and $21.30 the end of operations (not included in the above tables) is another
million, to the author’s knowledge, has not yet been adopted in area likely to bias the result of a model. Working capital is
relevant financial literature. generally estimated in real dollars at the start of the project.
The discounted pay back period of one year and capital
efficiency index of 1.96 are also the same in the nominal and real COMPARISON OF MUTUALLY EXCLUSIVE
dollars models. Obtaining the same results, irrespective of the PROJECTS WITH DIFFERENT LIVES
money terms used, provides confidence that the model
computations are internally consistent and it is a good form of Project evaluation has to do with choices. Even when one values
quality control. a single project using DCF analysis, its acceptability as an
If the straight-line depreciation method, based on the historical investment depends on the return on the project, exceeding the
cost of the asset and its useful life, has been adopted, the alternative of investing the money in the next best alternative, or
financial accounts in successive years will show the same at the limit leaving the money in the bank.

Australian Mineral Economics 107


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

Engineers often have to make a choice between two alternative


Comparison of assets with different lives
pieces of plant or equipment with different capital and operating
costs and expected useful lives. -30000
0% 5% 10% 15% 20%
As an example, we shall consider a decision whether to -35000
purchase one of two pumps, A and B, with four and six years
expected lives and prices of $15 000 and $20 000 respectively. In -40000

Total PV cost $
the first instance, let us assume that their operating cost is the
same. -45000
It is not possible to make a correct choice consistent with one’s
-50000
required discount rate without first making the capital cost of the
two pumps comparable on a per-unit-of-time basis. -55000
This can be done by converting the acquisition costs of the two Pump A
pumps into their annual equivalent values (AEV) and selecting -60000
Pump B
the lower of the two. The AEV is obtained by dividing the capital
expenditure of each pump by the annuity factor for a number of -65000
years equal to its expected life at the required discount rate. Discount rate %
The annuity factor in arrears at an interest rate of i for n years is:
FIG 10.2 - Comparing assets with different lives.
i -n
A n years = [1 –(1 + i) ] / I

Lease or buy?
which is the same the sum of the individual discount factors for
interest i for year 1, 2, 3…n. Leasing is an alternative to borrowing funds to purchase a new
If the required discount is ten per cent, pump A with an annual capital asset. The lessee acquires the right to use the asset but not
equivalent value of $4732 (ie $15 000/3.1699) is more expensive its ownership, which legally remains with the financier (lessor).
than B with an AEV of $4592 (ie $20 000/4.3552). If the There are essentially two types of leases:
operating cost of the two pumps were the same, the investor • operating leases are cancellable, their terms are shorter than
would select pump B. the effective life of equipment leased, can include
The choice would, change if pump A cost $1500 annually to lessor-provided maintenance and they do not create a liability
operate and pump B $1700 annually, because their respective in the lessee’s balance sheet; and
total annual equivalent costs would become $6232 for pump A • finance leases are non-cancellable their terms are longer and
and $6292 for pump B. closer (>75 per cent) to the effective life of equipment
This choice could have been reached by constructing, as in leased, transfer risks and benefits of asset from lessor to
Table 10.6, the DCF model of repeating the investment in pump lessee and create a liability in lessee’s balance sheet.
A three times and in pump B twice, thus reaching a comparable Genuine lease rentals for income-generating assets are, like
combined life over the same period of 12 years and choosing the interest expenses, deductible for tax purposes from a lessee’s
pump with the lower combined present value cost, ie A at -$42 taxable income. However, the relevant asset depreciation is
463. As can be seen in Figure 10.2 this choice is a function of the deductible by the lessor who is the legal owner of the asset but
discount rate selected. At a discount below approximately eight not by the lessee.
per cent, pump B would be preferable. Lessors can also leverage their leases by making significant
A similar model structure could be used to optimise the lives use of borrowed funds to fund the necessary assets.
of assets, ie to determine when the present value of maintaining As entering into a lease uses some of the lessee’s capacity to
an asset reaches a level that makes replacing it with a new one of borrow, the evaluation of a lease from a lessee’s point of view
similar capacity the most economic choice. The validity of should use the firm’s cost of debt, unless some specific funding
maintain or replace models can be ambiguous because is very source is envisaged for individual assets.
dependent on the accuracy of both the historical cost records of Table 10.7, which makes use of an example from Peirson et al
the asset to be replaced and above all the realism of the (2002), portrays the comparison between leasing or buying a
performance expectations for the new one. capital item, say a large bulldozer, worth $600 000 in year 0,

TABLE 10.6
Comparison of the total cost of assets with different lives.
Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Pump A, lasting four years
Acquisition capital cost -15 000 -15 000 -15 000
Annual operating cost -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500
Total cost -15 000 -1500 -1500 -1500 -16 500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -16 500 -1500 -1500 -1500 -1500
Present value of pump A cost -42 463
Pump B, lasting six years
Acquisition capital cost -20 000 -20 000
Annual operating cost -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700
Total cost -20 000 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -21 700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700 -1700
Present value of pump A cost -42 873

108 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 10.7
Incremental value analysis of leasing versus buying (after Peirson et al, 2002).
Lease or buy (nominal dollars)
Lessee’s point of view assumptions
Cost of asset ($) 600 000
Annual lease rentals ($) 100 000 in advance
Fiscal depreciation life (y) 3
Tax rate (%) 30.00%
Real corporate cost of debt (%) 4.50%
Annual inflation (%) 3.00%
Nominal corporate cost of debt (%) 7.63%
Year 0 1 2 3 4 5
Incremental cost of leasing versus buying
Savings of purchase of asset 600 000
Purchase of asset at end of lease
After-tax salvage of asset
Lease rentals -100 000 -100 000 -100 000 -100 000 -100 000 -100 000
Tax savings on lease rentals 30 000 30 000 30 000 30 000 30 000 30 000
Depreciation tax savings foregone -60 000 -60 000 -60 000
Net cash flow 530 000 -130 000 -130 000 -130 000 -70 000 -70 000
Present value of lease 92 151

which the lessor can fully depreciate over three years. The inherent weaknesses in DCF analysis. This is because a
annual lease rental is $100 000 in advance for six years and the DCF/NPV approach values and compares projects with
nominal corporate cost of debt of the lessee is 7.63 per cent. inherently different risk characteristics using the same risk-
The model is constructed on an incremental level, ie it and time-adjusted discount rate.
captures the difference in cost and savings to the lessee between This leads to a view that larger, faster production rates will, in
buying and leasing the asset. Thus in year 0 there is a saving of the majority of cases, generate economies of scale and therefore
$600 000 which the lessee would otherwise had to pay if he/she are the best alternative. If ‘the larger, the sooner, the better’ belief
had purchased the bulldozer. The tax deductible $100 000 lease is pushed to the limit, in the presence of large ore reserves and
rental in advance also generates a $30 000 tax saving and so on disregarding possible market saturation effects on the price of the
for following years. commodity mined, the value of a mine will be optimised by
Under the assumption made, the incremental cash flows of expanding capacity indefinitely. This, however, does not happen
leasing have a net present value of $92 151 after discounting at in practice.
7.63 per cent. As a consequence, in this case, leasing appears as There is evidence that as the initial capital investment becomes
the best alternative. substantial, management becomes uncomfortable and intuitively
Financial leases are popular (about 25 per cent of new capital starts doubting the realism of its basic optimisation beliefs. Their
assets in Australia are leased) because there is a widely held behaviour is easy to justify. This is because the variability of
perception (Peirson et al, 2002) that: project cash flows increases with the capital-intensity of
alternative project designs and is very sensitive to the levels
• the cost of capital may be lower than that of other sources of demand in terms of sales tonnages for the metal produced, as the
funds; following simplified example of Table 10.8 illustrates.
• suppliers’ finance involves lower transaction costs; Table 10.8 displays two alternative ways of developing a
• as the lease is secured by the asset, the firm’s credit project producing 30 000 tonnes per annum of a metal currently
availability is not affected; priced $3000 per tonne. The first (A) is a capital-intensive design
resulting in $30 million annual fixed costs but in a low variable
• capital may be conserved; unit cost of $1000 per tonne of metal produced. The second (B)
• taxation may potentially be lower; and is a labour-intensive design with a relatively low annual fixed
cost at $10 million but high variable unit cost of $1667 per tonne.
• there are comparative advantages in asset disposal. At the current level of demand in terms of sales tonnages both
However, a valid theoretical argument may be constructed projects generate the same gross annual cash flow of $30 million.
(Peirson et al, 2002) that in an efficient finance market the point However the cash flows of the capital-intensive project are more
of view of a lessor may in fact be a mirror image of that of a sensitive to changes in volumetric demand than those of the
lessee, and that many of these perceived advantages may prove in labour-intensive project. If sales tonnages fall or rises by 25 per
the long-run to illusory. cent, the cash flow of project A falls to $15 million, or rises to
$45 million respectively. The volatility of its cash flows at 40.82
INHERENT WEAKNESSES AND COMMON TRAPS per cent is much higher than that of project B at 27.22 per cent.
IN DCF ANALYSIS Table 10.9 depicts the case where the same gross annual cash
flow of $30 million is achieved by two different projects, the unit
Aside from the common error of mixing nominal and real dollar production cost of which are fully variable but different. In the
term items in the same model, particularly when dealing with example the unit cost of production of project A, at $2000 per
depreciation and fixed-interest loans, there are other fundamental tonne is lower than that of project B at $2500 per tonne. For

Australian Mineral Economics 109


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 10.8
Comparing the risk of projects with different capital intensity.
Company A B A B
Capital intensive Labour intensive Capital intensive Labour intensive
Price ($/t) 3000 Tonnage demand volatility 25.00% pa
Production (t * ‘000) 30 30
Revenue ($‘000) 90 000 90 000 Sensitivity of gross CFs to changes in tonnage demand
Variable cost of production ($/t) 1000 1666.666667 30 000 30 000
Annual fixed cost ($‘000) 30 000 10 000 Low tonnage 22.5 15 000 20 000
Total annual cost of production ($‘000) 60 000 60 000 Base case 30 30 000 30 000
Gross annual cash flow ($‘000) 30 000 30 000 High tonnage 37.5 45 000 40 000
Standard deviation of CFs ($‘000) 12 247 8165
Standard deviation of CFs (%) 40.82% 27.22%

TABLE 10.9
Comparing the risk of projects with different unit operating costs.

Company A B A B
Low High Low High
Price ($/t) 3000 Price volatility % pa 25.00%
Cost of production ($/t) 2000 2500
Annual production (t * ‘000) 30 60 Sensitivity of gross CFs to price changes
Annual revenue ($‘000) 90 000 180 000 Low price 2250 7500 -15 000
Annual operating cost ($‘000) 60 000 150 000 Base case 3000 30 000 30 000
Annual gross cash flow ($‘000) 30 000 30 000 High price 3750 52 500 75 000
Standard deviation of CF ($‘000) 18 371 36 742
Volatility of CF (%) 61.24% 122.47%
Price of risk = percentage discount per 1.00% of CF volatility = 0.10% 6.12% 12.25%

project B to generate the same gross cash flow as A, it must Additional bias may also arise in DCF analysis by using a
produce twice the sales volume of A, ie 60 000 tonnes per annum single discount rate for both the riskier revenue and less risky
instead of 30 000 tonnes. cost function of an individual financial model.
A single discount rate attributes the same value to the annual The variability of the price of some commodities can be as
cash flow of both these projects. However, the high-cost project high as plus or minus 100 per cent in a single year. This plays
B is more sensitive to variations in commodity prices than A. A havoc with the realism of revenue estimates. It is for this reason
commodity price volatility of 25 per cent leverages the cash flow that commentators describe mining projects as ‘price-risked’.
variability of project B to 122.47 per cent, much more than that By contrast, much of the capital investment is in the present
of project A at 61.24 per cent. and relatively easier to estimate correctly. One would also have
It would not be objective to compare the values of projects A to be a very poor project planner and manager if one were to
and B in the two scenarios portrayed using a single discount rate incur recurrent operation and maintenance cost over-runs of say
unless in the first case we had a take or pay contract and in the over ten per cent. In addition management can generally devise
second 100 per cent of production were hedged, thus neutralising and implement strategies to keep costs on average on budget.
risk. To be more objective and still use conventional DCF Depending on the relative timing of revenue inflows and cost
analysis we would have to apply progressively higher and higher, outflows choices may be biased against investing capital now to
‘risk-loaded’ discount rates to compensate for the increasing risk save recurrent costs later and/or favouring future and more risky
created by high operating leverages. patterns of revenue inflows.
One could ‘price’ the variability or risk of the cash flows of a This source of bias can be eliminated, as will be seen in
project by determining a specific discount rate for each Chapter 12, by discounting the less risky operating costs of a
percentage level of cash flow volatility. Table 10.9 for instance project at a lower rate than that of its riskier revenue using a
shows what risk discount rates appropriate to project A (6.12 per technique called modern asset pricing or MAP for short.
cent) and B (12.25 per cent) would have had to be if a discount
rate equal to 0.1 per cent of the cash flow variability were to be IDENTIFYING AND QUANTIFYING FINANCIAL
applied in addition to the risk-free rate of interest. Salahor (1998)
has demonstrated how this concept of ‘price of risk’ can be
RISK: EXPECTED VALUE, SENSITIVITY AND
derived and how it is in fact consistent with the risk-adjusted rate SCENARIO ANALYSES
of discount derived using the popular capital asset pricing model A financial model constructed under an assumption of certainty
(CAPM) logic. The derivation of ‘prices of risk’ is well beyond and based on single-point measurements and expected or mean
the scope of this discussion. estimates of various input variables generates single point
The consequence of using the same discount rate is that riskier expected results. As already noted, this type of model is often
projects may be overvalued compared with less risky ones. referred to as the base case.

110 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

Most inputs are, however, uncertain and the actual value, Sensitivity Analysis - Tornado

which will eventuate in nature according to their probability


Exchange Rate (US$:A$) 0.8 0.55
distribution of occurrence, may be significantly different from
Price (US$/oz) 320 440
that used in the base case model.
Headgrade (g/t Au) 3.6 4.5
From the base case one can determine the sensitivity of the
CAPEX (A$ million) -47 -35
project results to:
Diluted Mining Reserves (Mt) 1.8 2.2
• changes in the value of individual inputs (sensitivity Recovery % 0.9 0.97
analysis); or Mining Cost ($/t ore & waste) 2.4 1.8

• likely or extreme combinations of input values (scenario Milling Cost ($/t ore) 13 11.5

analysis); Waste:Ore Ratio 4.4 3.8

irrespective of their relevant probability distributions of -5.00 0.00 5.00 10.00 15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 35.00 40.00

occurrence. NPV

Sensitivity and scenario analyses have been greatly facilitated


by the capacity to construct interactive models on computer FIG 10.4 - A tornado diagram.
spreadsheets and by specialised risk analysis software. The
degree to which models can accommodate changes in input inputs such as exchange rates and prices. If the potential
variables is, however, limited to ‘relevant ranges’ beyond which consequences of their downside multiplied by their respective
results become nonsensical. For instance one cannot test the probabilities of occurrence are too severe, the only course of
sensitivity of a project to a wide range of ore throughputs without action is to manage the related risk by hedging or by rejecting
eventually having to change the size and capital cost of mining the investment.
and milling equipment and related unit operating costs. In other
words many project outcomes are not a continuous function PROBABILISTIC MODELS AND FINANCIAL
of input values, but rather step functions. For instance at a SIMULATIONS
reasonably high price for a commodity it may be optimal to plan
a large-scale open pit to achieve economies of scale, but if the In both the spider and tornado diagrams increments and ranges of
price of the commodity were to fall the need may arise to possible input values were used without any reference to their
high-grade production in a manner that would initially entail a respective probability of occurrence.
vastly different pit design. A sophisticated pit optimisation model Analysts, however, are never completely ignorant and can do
may handle a modest degree of price variability. However, more better than attributing the same probability of occurrence (the
significant price falls would make an open cut unfeasible and an Laplace criterion) to any of the possible values for an input. For
underground selective operation may be the only way to realise the majority of inputs they have some knowledge of how their
some value out of the resources. Very few models are in reality values are likely to distribute, ie of the probability with which
various input values may occur. At worst they know their most
so sophisticated as to withstand extreme levels of variation in key
likely (modal), minimum and maximum possible values.
inputs.
Depending on the nature of an input, its probability
Within acceptable ranges, however, sensitivity analysis distribution may be:
provides significant insights into the project risk, by determining
which input variable the project is most sensitive to. The ‘spider • discrete or continuous;
diagram’ of Figure 10.3 shows how the mine project of Table • symmetrical (eg rectangular, triangular, normal); or
10.1 is typically highly sensitive to variation in factors affecting
its revenue (eg grades, prices, exchange rates, etc). • asymmetrical/skewed (eg triangular, log-normal, binomial,
exponential).
If one can estimate realistic ranges of possible input values, a
‘tornado diagram’, such as that of Figure 10.4, can be helpful to Many natural phenomena (eg grades, size of mineral and
assess and rank their impact and better focus the value of further petroleum accumulations, commodity prices) are characterised
information. For instance one could firm up grades and tonnages by positively skewed lognormal distributions, in which the
with some more drilling and a more refined resources model. logarithm of possible values distribute normally. Handling
Alternatively a value study could be undertaken to trim the lognormal distributions correctly requires considerable practice
capital investment estimates. and care. As an alternative, analysts often use an asymmetrical
triangular distribution as a surrogate.
No amount of further research unfortunately will resolve the
uncertainty surrounding some of the inputs that are subject to It is a relatively straightforward exercise to substitute the
chance and to which the project is most sensitive. These include distributions of occurrence for selected inputs into the base case
model to replace original single-point estimates. This enables the
CAPEX model for financial Monte Carlo simulation using sophisticated
Sensitivity Analysis - Spider (A$ million) risk analysis software.
180% Diluted Mining
Reserves (Mt) The risk analysis software samples the various inputs
160% randomly, according to their respective probability distribution of
Headgrade
% Change in NPV

140% (g/t Au) occurrence over a very large number (thousands) of iterations of
120% Recovery % the model, in effect generating thousand of random scenarios.
100% This process not only generates the expected or mean values for
Price (US$/oz)
80% the various model outputs, but also the surrounding distribution
60% Exchange Rate of all possible outcomes and a range of relevant statistics.
40% (US$:A$)
Consider, for example, the result of a simulation carried out on
20% Mining Cost
($/t ore & waste) the mine model of Table 10.1, where probability distributions for:
90% 95% 100% 105% 110%
% Change in Input Value
Milling Cost • gold prices (lognormal),
($/t ore)
• exchange rates (uniform),
FIG 10.3 - A spider web diagram. • grades (triangular),

Australian Mineral Economics 111


CHAPTER 10: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — AN INTRODUCTION

• recoveries (triangular), of distorting results, risk analysis software provides facilities to


truncate them, preventing sampling below or above realistic
• capital investment (uniform), and minimum and maximum values. In addition there may be some
• mining and milling costs (triangular), correlation between the values for a single type of input over
have been used as inputs. successive years. These correlations and autocorrelations can be
incorporated in the model using modern risk analysis software,
After 10 000 iterations the simulation generated an expected which takes them into consideration during simulation and
NPV for the project of $12.89 million (very close to the base case adjusts the results accordingly.
NPV of $12.69 million), within a positively skewed distribution
with a standard deviation of $8.68 million. The histogram of Ideally the expected value derived from a Monte Carlo
Figure 10.5 shows that minimum and maximum NPVs of -$17.50 simulation should, as in the example, be of the same order of
million and $64.43 million are possible, albeit with infinitesimal magnitude as that of the base case. A significant difference
probabilities of occurrence. The cumulative probability indicates either a degree of inconsistency between the two set of
distribution of Figure 10.6 shows that there is 5.78 per cent estimates, which should be reconciled, or a flaw in how the
probability of realising a negative NPV and 47.3 per cent probability distributions of the relevant variables have been
probability that the NPV will exceed the expected $12.89 million. handled.

REFERENCES
RiskSim Histogram, 02-Jun-04, 11:08 am
4500 Bourassa, M J, 2001. International legal requirements and standards for
4000 mineral valuation, in Proceedings Valmin 2001 – Mineral Asset
3500 Valuation Issues for the Next Millennium, pp 62-83 (The Australasian
3000 Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
Frequency

But also a lot


2500
There is a of “blue sky” JORC, 2004. Australasian Code for Reporting of Mineral Resources and
2000 chance of Ore Reserves (The JORC Code), The Joint Ore Reserves Committee
negative NPV
1500 of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Australian
1000 Institute of Geoscientists and Minerals Council of Australia. [Online].
500 Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/codes/jorc0105.pdf>. Date
0 accessed: 8 May 2006.
-20.00 -10.00 0.00 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 70.00
Lawrence, M J, 2001. An outline of market-based approaches for mineral
NPV, Upper Limit of Interval asset valuation best practice, in Proceedings Valmin 2001 – Mineral
Asset Valuation Issues for the Next Millennium, pp 115-137 (The
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
FIG 10.5 - Histogram of possible NPV values for the project.
Peirson, G, Brown, R, Easton, S and Howard, P, 2002. Business Finance,
eighth edition (McGraw-Hill Irwin: Sydney).
Roscoe, W E, 2001. Outline of the cost approach to valuation of mineral
exploration properties, in Proceedings Valmin 2001 – Mineral Asset
Valuation Issues for the Next Millennium, pp 138-146 (The
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
But also 47.3%
chance of
Salahor, G, 1998. Implications of output price risk and operating leverage
exceeding the for the evaluation of petroleum development projects, The Energy
There is 5.78%
expected NPV of Journal, 19(1):13-46.
chance of
$12.89M
NPV<0 Taylor, H K, 1978. Mine valuations and feasibility studies, in Mineral
Industry Costs (eds: J R Hoskins and W R Green) (Northwest
Mining Association: Spokane).
The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, 1994a. Australasian
code for reporting of identified mineral resources and ore reserves
FIG 10.6 - Cumulative frequency distribution of possible NPV (JORC code) 1993, in Proceedings Valmin 1994, Mineral Valuation
values for the project. Methodologies, p B115 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and
Metallurgy: Melbourne).
The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, 1994b. Code and
To ensure more accurate results, it is important to identify guidelines for assessment and valuation of mineral assets and
model inputs that are highly correlated, for example commodity mineral securities for independent expert reports (VALMIN code)
prices in US dollars and the exchange rate between the 1995, in Proceedings Valmin 1994, Mineral Valuation
Australian and US dollar, given the ‘commodity currency’ nature Methodologies, p B129 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and
of the former. There is also high correlation between grades and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
recoveries, grades and metal content of concentrates and related Torries, T F, 1998. Evaluating Mineral Projects: Applications and
net smelter returns. Clearly if in any iteration the computer were Misconceptions (Society for Mining, Metallurgy and Exploration:
to sample simultaneously anomalously high or low values at the Littleton).
extremes of the distribution for grades, prices, exchange rates VALMIN, 2005. Code for the Technical Assessment and Valuation of
and recoveries, it would generate erroneous extreme high or low Mineral and Petroleum Assets and Securities for Independent Expert
Reports (The VALMIN Code), The VALMIN Committee, a joint
values. While these should not impact the expected value of committee of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy,
outputs they will widen the spread of their distribution affecting the Australian Institute of Geoscientists and the Mineral Industry
the realism of the simulation. To prevent extreme tails of Consultants Association (The Australasian Institute of Mining and
distributions generating combinations of unrealistically high or Metallurgy). [Online]. Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/
low values (albeit at very low probability of occurrence) capable codes/valmin_2005.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.

112 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11

Preliminary, Prefeasibility and Feasibility Studies


Richard West

Introduction
The Phases of a Project
Testing the Data – Technical Due Diligence
Types of Evaluation
Costs
Market Surveys and Commodity Prices
Financial Evaluation
Some Comments on Cut-Off Grades and Other Cut-Off Points
Risks and Sensitivities Associated with Feasibility Studies
Managing the Feasibility Study Process
Feasibility Study Reports
Appendix – Checklist of the Main Sections of Feasibility Study Reports

INTRODUCTION The feasibility study is used both to establish technical and


economic feasibility to develop a project, and to establish
The objective of this chapter is to present both basic and advanced technical and economic feasibility to make changes to an
material on feasibility studies such that an inexperienced mining existing project.
industry professional can use it to upgrade their skills in the area It is dependent on the project’s mineral resource conditions,
of feasibility studies preparation and management. mining, metallurgical, other technical and marketing conditions
Key points covered include: and the project’s economics, corporate philosophies, strategies
and structuring as well as the identification and satisfactory
• items to be covered in the feasibility study process; mitigation of any serious project risks.
• selection of cut-off grades, and initial estimation of grades A key factor for a meaningful feasibility study is the integrity
and production schedules; of the underlying database. To demonstrate this, it is important to
• estimation and verification of capital and operating costs undertake some form of ‘due diligence’ testing or auditing of
(fixed and variable costs); data, preferably on an independent basis.
• the use of scaling factors; Laird (1997) notes that:
• selection of commodity prices and other economic factors; Starting from a mineral resource database; the
feasibility study will define the ore reserves, the
• the cash flow model and financial assessment; mining methods, the mineral processing concepts
• financial verification of ore reserves; and the scale of the project.
• construction and production schedules including project start The mining industry professional’s role in any analysis of an
up and commissioning; existing or potential mining project is to provide technical advice
• sensitivity analysis and risk assessment; and information on parameters relating to design, extraction
methods, production costs recoveries, mining rates and the many
• orders of accuracy; other variables, which will be used to technically and financially
• feasibility study reports layout and content; appraise the project. To be a competent person, he or she must
understand the interrelationships and trade-offs between the
• legal requirements, professional competency, ethics, various project variables, the potential risks and problems
standards of practice; and associated with those variables and must understand and
• items to be included in a feasibility study report. demonstrate how the project can address and manage risk.

Australian Mineral Economics 113


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

Feasibility studies are an iterative process of deposit evaluations • construction and commissioning,
extending from the initial ‘prefeasibility study’ through to the
‘definitive estimate’ undertaken with the objectives of: • production, and
• establishing the proved and probable reserves and the overall • project decline and closure.
measured, indicated and inferred resources; The professionals involved in the project obtain the bulk of the
information about the deposit and its ore characteristics and
• proving the technical viability of the mine and extraction
decide on its method of exploitation during the first three of
methods;
these phases.
• defining the features and capacity of the facilities; The exploration phase includes a series of steps from
• estimating the development, capital and operating costs of conceiving potential orebody models, through exploration to
the mine over the economic life of the reserves; delineate favourable targets (where such orebodies may be) and
testing of those targets. It concludes with the reporting of the
• establishing the market opportunities for the commodity quantity and grade of mineralised material in the targets.
produced by the project;
Should this assessment indicate that exploitation will not be
• completing financial assessments of the selected project permitted, or that there is little possibility of discovering
configurations; mineralisation in a potentially profitable tonnes and grade
• assessing the economic sensitivity of the proposed combination, there is no point in undertaking any further work.
development to various factors; and Even though there may be significant mineral resources, there
are no ore reserves.
• setting a framework for the implementation of the capital Professionals involved in the evaluation and development
investment in the development. conduct project scoping, select production rates, estimate plant
A feasibility study’s authors will utilise a mine financial and equipment size, assess costs and structure the project to
model, based on these plans, to calculate the effects of changes cover investment, return borrowed funds and provide funds for
in recovered grades, production rates with resulting mine life resource replacement.
changes and other important factors. In using this model they
typically seek to maximise the project’s net present value TESTING THE DATA – TECHNICAL DUE
together with an acceptable rate of return of investment funds. DILIGENCE
In this process they conduct sensitivity analyses to test for
The resource base is of great importance because
viability with increased strip ratios (in the case of open cut
it is the one element that cannot be changed. If
mines), increased dilution, reduced recoveries, varying inflation
the process route is proved not to be suitable it
and escalation rates, commodity price movements, capital and
can be optimised or changed, if clear title is
operating cost variations, grades resulting from changed cut-off challenged it can be legally defended, if the
grades, effects of changes in production rates and mine life and quality of management is not suitable then new
possibly project gearing. In addition it is important to test for the people can be introduced to the project, but if the
sensitivity to grade changes. It is critical to understand and resource base is flawed and the mineralisation is
discuss the potential impacts of these and associated risks in the not in the ground in a quantity that warrants
final report. extraction then there may be nothing which can
Once these studies indicate that the project is viable, it is be done (Amos, 1998).
possible to report publicly the project’s ore reserves for that part
Determining a project’s mineral resource is the result of a
of the resource planned to be mined, together with any diluting
complex accumulation of data derived from a variety of technical
material (which the production scheduling has indicated will be
and interpretational methods and processes. Audit testing is
mined and delivered to the metallurgical treatment plant or essential to provide assurance of the quality of data used, and
stockpiled for direct selling). that it is representative. It is also necessary to assess geological
Preparing definitive cost estimates is usually the final stage of interpretations of structure, grade and mineral zoning, and
project development or the first stage of construction, depending mineral continuity. Furthermore, as the mineral resource moves
upon whether the decision to proceed with project construction is towards ore reserve status, it is vital to weigh up the validity of
made before or after the preparation of these estimates. It is used additional technical assumptions, eg the metallurgical
to provide the basis for project capital cost control and as an aid characteristics of the resource.
in the establishment of and checking of construction contract Failure to thoroughly test key data at this stage may prove to
prices. As such, it is usually based on non-detailed site, layout be a fatal flaw to the project. In particular, it is essential to take
and engineering drawings and specifications. At this stage of the great care when data come from third party sources with
project some quotations may have been called and the unknown standards of technical diligence. This testing must
construction schedule estimated such that the estimate can be encompass all aspects of the data gathering and storage, database
used as a bankable document for funds raising each of the papers validation checking drill hole surveys and appropriateness of
for further references to sections of this complex subject. sampling and assaying techniques and records.
The technical due diligence program will probably require new
THE PHASES OF A PROJECT data to confirm previous results and to support interpretations.
Budgeting should allow for this.
The progression of an exploration discovery to
an operating mine took place in a phased and Where they are to make major investment decisions, directors
iterative series of studies with identified decision and external financiers may require an independent third party to
points (Yeates and Adams, 1998). test and audit these data.
Gilfillan (1998) describes the requirements for due diligence
The major phases of a project are: review of geological data. Testing of all technical data is
• exploration, important. However, the audit of data underlying the mineral
resource, and later the ore reserve, is critical since these form the
• evaluation and development, basis of the project.

114 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

Shillabeer (1998) has suggested that such audits should be optimisation of scope criteria from ‘reasonable
done twice, at different stages of the projects development. The assumption’ through to ‘optimised design or
exploration period may cover many years, utilise a variety of plan’ (Northcote, 1998).
methodologies and a large number of people with different skills
During the late stages of exploration, and long
and standards, therefore requiring review and recompilation.
before a feasibility study is formally initiated, the
exploration geologists will have started to
TYPES OF EVALUATION develop a geologic model of the mineralised
The most critical step of any project is the structure. This will be expanded into a
feasibility study. Unfortunately the concept of the preliminary resource estimate, which will guide
term feasibility study has expanded to include a their continuing exploration activities and
whole range of activities varying from scoping provide an early indication of the potential of the
studies to the final feasibility study (Laird, 1997). discovery. Ideally, this is an iterative process as
the results of drilling campaigns are manipulated
Evaluation studies generally evolve (as more exploration, by the geologists and the geostatisticians,
technical and financial data become available and the project’s additional information requirements are
risks and sensitivities become better understood) through the quantified and new drilling programs are
phases of: implemented (Laird, 1997).
• scoping or conceptual study; Evaluation of all mineralisation discoveries should be an
• prefeasibility study; ongoing iterative process throughout the exploration phase. As
part of this there is a need to carry out a single or series of
• feasibility study (the bankable feasibility study is an preliminary feasibility studies to test:
extension to the feasibility study that considers the project
from the bank’s perspective); and • if mining will be permitted;
• definitive estimate. • if mining will be permitted, when and what restrictions are
likely to apply to any specific target;
After each stage of development, conducting further
delineation and test work will generally be required before the • exploitation will be profitable; and
next stage of feasibility assessment can commence. In best • exploitation will be technically possible.
practice situations there is close cooperation and liaison between
the exploration crews and the personnel preparing and refining This is an essential part of the normal exploration review
the feasibility study. process. Where these studies indicate that a profitable venture
could be developed, it often becomes desirable to direct
Accuracy levels typically resulting from predevelopment exploration toward testing for extensions of the mineral resources
studies are: within profitable ore haulage distance around proposed treatment
• scoping or conceptual, ± 30-40 per cent; plant sites. Where studies indicate located deposits to be
• prefeasibility, ± 20-25 per cent; marginal or unviable, it is necessary to reassess the area.
Prior to making a positive commitment in key risk areas, a
• feasibility, ± 10-15 per cent; and project owner must also conduct a series of technical, social,
• definitive, ± 5-10 per cent. environmental and economic assessments. It is common practice
The costs of feasibility studies can vary significantly. Some of to commission consultants with specialist expertise in these areas
the key factors that influence this cost include the owner’s to produce the reports in these areas.
management approach, methodology, type of resource, project When such evaluation indicates that the project is potentially
location and size and amount of consultant use. On some profitable, the project owners will then assemble a technical team
occasions the cost of evaluation can be as high as ten per cent of to prepare a detailed feasibility study. This study contains more
the total overall cost. in depth production planning and assessment of the quality and
quantity of ore including diluting material, which will be mined,
treated and sold. It also assesses the overall profitability of the
The feasibility study is an iterative process
project.
Evaluation of mineral discoveries usually become an iterative
process that commences in the early stages of exploration to aid Scoping or conceptual studies
the scoping of the potential project and continues throughout the
exploration phase as more data become available. Scoping or conceptual studies, to identify the general features
and order of magnitude parameters of the project, typically take
Project planning is also iterative in its nature. It involves
place soon after geologists have identified a potential mineral
working and reworking this data, commencing with sensible
resource. These studies identify technical issues requiring further
financial assumptions, mining and treatment factors and ore
investigation or test work, as well as the costs and time required
cut-off grades. The mining engineer will consider the general to undertake further predevelopment.
geometry of the orebody, including size and shape of all
geological features together with the nature of the breaking of With respect to scoping studies, White (1997) argues that:
the ore, that may have an influence on the selection of the mining This term is typically applied when only a very
methods, ore recoveries, dilution grade distribution and other preliminary examination is needed or in the
influencing factors. He or she refines conclusions as additional absence of specifics regarding the particular
data become available. project.
The following quotations by Northcote (1998) and Laird Where scoping studies indicate a venture may be profitable,
(1997) add emphasis to these points: the direction of exploration may be changed to focus on those
The iterative approach to project development areas developed early in the project’s life.
underscores the significance of feasibility efforts Where they indicate deposits to be marginal or not to be
as a value improvement process. The capacity of viable, it is necessary to reassess the area. This will include
this process to add value is realised via estimating and defining economic cut-off grades for resource

Australian Mineral Economics 115


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

assessment and testing methods of developing the project with • developing capital and operating cost
differing operating parameters. estimates,
By following this process it is possible to refine many
assumptions, test sensitivities and assess areas of risk. The costs • testing the marketability of the commodity,
and financial evaluations in these studies are only indicative or • assessing the economic viability, and
‘ball park’ and are rarely sufficiently accurate to produce a
• determining what further efforts are required
meaningful assessment of the viability of the project.
to allow the predevelopment activities to
There should be close liaison between the exploration team advance.
and the evaluating team in order to develop the project’s
operating criteria and objectives. The scope of the project will Prefeasibility studies are generally sufficiently accurate to
evolve, as more data become available. allow a comparative analysis of the financial viability for
A well-constructed scoping study should: alternative capacity and project configurations.
Ground conditions including jointing, faults, areas of shear,
• develop the project criteria and objectives and outline its stress directions, weathering and unweathered areas in addition
scope; to orebody thickness may dictate the use of specific mining
• establish the probable type of mining operation and assess if methods. Both surface and underground conditions will often
mining will be technically possible; dictate the siting of key items as the shafts, treatment plant,
• establish the probable type of treatment route; power station and other supporting infrastructure.
The early mine planning and ore reserve estimation for metal
• establish a metallurgical testing program to assess if mines initially overlap with one another. This early phase
treatment will be technically possible; consists of planning the method of extraction usually, based on
• establish the probable marketing strategy; an assumed breakeven cut-off grade, producing a production
• make a preliminary assessment of environmental factors that schedule. Consideration of ore quality and contaminants
could make it necessary to modify or drop the project; becomes very important in determining the limits of minable
orebodies in the case of non-metallic, coal and some metallic
• make a preliminary assessment of the project risks; and commodities.
• assess the potential for the discovery of resources capable of The sales return from the planned production schedule, less
supporting the proposed project. various royalties and taxes will indicate the project’s cash flow
Based on conceptual capital and operation costs, the study and its likely viability under the assumed production conditions.
should assess: As we have seen it is normal practice to convert these to present
money values.
• the probable economic structure and operating criteria, As more information becomes available, the re-assessment
• probable cut-off grades and other cut-off points, and refines the production schedule and the ore reserve.
• minimum deposit grades to return an acceptable return. As with the identified mineral resources computer modelling,
project analysts may alternatively utilise manual modelling to
Scoping or conceptual studies usually are not sufficiently plan the production schedule and optimise the mining and
accurate to carry out a meaningful assessment of the economic treatment operations, as well as model the financial
viability of any project. Rather, their role is to determine characteristics and estimate the ore reserves.
whether, and how much, further predevelopment efforts are
warranted. A project may evolve considerably as a result of an initial
prefeasibility study, reflecting corporate philosophies, structures
and development strategies.
The prefeasibility study The prefeasibility study may become a long iterative series of
The prefeasibility study seeks to establish technical and evaluations being progressively updated and modified as
economic feasibility to develop a new project or to make changes exploration data and the exploration geologists progressively
to an existing project. It is a non-detailed evaluation based on report mineral resources. Analysts usually investigate project
preliminary planning and engineering and associated ore reserve financing during this time.
assessment. Such a study takes place prior to setting up a Prefeasibility studies are more detailed than scoping studies.
high-powered and probably high cost engineering project team. They include:
It is dependent on a first-pass estimate of the likely conversion of
the mineral resources delineated during exploration into possible
• determining operating costs, considering operating and
mining reserves, mining, metallurgical, other technical and maintenance labour, power and other services, consumables
marketing conditions. and maintenance spares;
The project’s financial analysis should take account of • determining capital costs, including working and
corporate philosophies, strategies and structuring of the project. replacement capital;
It should also identify and suggest satisfactory mitigation of • assessing the mining methods, treatment routes and
major project risks. identifying cut-off factors, recoveries, dilution and losses in
Cusworth (1993) suggests the following: both mining and treatment;
Once sufficiently accurate information is • assessing potential reserves out of delineated resources based
available on the mineral resource (see later for on non-detailed mine planning and production scheduling;
guidelines) prefeasibility studies can be • outlining probable plant, infrastructure, services and other
undertaken with the objectives of: facilities;
• assessing the probable reserves and the • producing a summary development structure and timetable;
approaches to recovery,
• developing a philosophy of plant quality (including
• identification of the techniques and rates of maintenance philosophy);
extraction,
• evaluating the specification and marketability of the
• outlining the possible features of the facilities, commodity;

116 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

• setting up the economic evaluation model; and • identifying the market for the commodity;
• determining financial viability. • estimation of capital costs based on non-detailed engineering
Cusworth (1993) notes that: planning and estimates and some quotations;

Based on the alternative sizes and configurations


• estimation of operating costs considering operating and
maintenance labour, power and other services, consumables,
evaluated during the prefeasibility stage, one size
maintenance spares and where possible quotations for
and configuration is generally selected and the
contract works;
technical and economic feasibility established
within the accuracy limits of the available data. • assessing project risk areas, economic sensitivity to those
areas and action that may be used if the risk becomes a
Prefeasibility studies are generally sufficiently accurate to
problem;
allow a comparative analysis of financial viability for alternative
capacity and project configurations. They usually include a • completing economic assessments of the selected project
review and evaluation of development alternatives, a report on configurations;
liaison with government departments and often also with bankers • developing financial models showing cash flows showing
or other potential financiers. sales revenues, capital and operating costs, proposed project
During each iterative cycle of the study, analysts should assess gearing, revenues, loan servicing and payback and project
what further exploration, mining tests and metallurgical tests and sensitivity to financial and operating sensitive areas; and
other studies are required to allow the predevelopment activities
advance to the stage where a full feasibility study is possible. • setting a framework for the implementation of the capital
An important point is reached when a prefeasibility study investment in the development.
indicates that a project is financially viable, and there are no Analysts use a mine financial model based on these plans to
social, political, environmental or other reason why mining and calculate the effects of changes in recovered grades, production
treatment will not be permitted, At that time a company in rates (with resulting mine life changes) and other variable
Australia can publicly report as ore reserves under the JORC Code parameters, until they produce a maximum present value,
(2004) that part of the resource, together with any diluting material together with an acceptable rate of return of investment funds. As
(which planning has indicated will be mined and delivered to the mines differ in so many ways (some having unique features)
metallurgical treatment plant or stockpiled for direct selling). tailoring of the model is usually required.
Ground conditions (including jointing, faults, areas of shear,
The feasibility study stress directions, weathering and unweathered areas) in addition
Feasibility studies take place at two levels: to orebody thickness may dictate the use of specific mining
methods. Both surface and underground conditions will often
• for internal final assessment purposes, or dictate the siting of key items as the shafts, treatment plant,
• for obtaining external funding. power station and other supporting infrastructure.
The latter type is a bankable feasibility study. Both the physical and chemical nature of ore, its contained
While prefeasibility studies evaluate alternative sizes and gangue and mine waste can potentially have serious effects on
configurations, feasibility studies generally concentrate on one the environment in the immediate area of a mine. In high rainfall
size and configuration, seeking to establish technical and areas this can also extend a considerable distance down stream in
economic feasibility within the accuracy limits of the available neighbouring streams and rivers. It is important to recognise this
data. early in the resource definition phase. It may affect the siting of
A team of multidisciplined persons, possessing complimentary mine towns, site access roads, power lines supporting
skills normally carry out such feasibility studies. There is input infrastructure, dumps, tailings dams and other infrastructure.
from mineral economists, metallurgists, mining engineers, During detailed feasibility studies sensitivity is essential to test
construction engineers, geologists, environmentalists, and for viability with increased strip ratios, increased dilution,
marketers and others. reduced recoveries, varying inflation and escalation rates,
Feasibility studies have the objectives of: commodity prices, capital and operating costs, grades resulting
from changed cut-off grades, effects of changes in production
• defining the mine’s plant, equipment and infrastructure rates and mine life and possibly project gearing. In addition it is
requirements and capacities;
important to test the sensitivity to grade changes.
• establishing the proved and probable reserves;
• assessing project alternatives and selecting the desired Bankable feasibility studies
development route;
• evaluating and defining the role of the owner during Mine development often requires the injection of more funds
development; than the mining company can, or wishes, to raise as equity.
• establishing legal and governmental conditions and Prior to providing funds to a mining project, a banker will
requirements for approvals to proceed; require disclosure of cash flows showing sales revenues, capital
and operating costs, proposed project gearing, revenues and
• proving the technical viability of the mine and extraction proposed loan servicing and payback, all of which should be in
methods; the feasibility study.
• defining the management control and timing of the project A prospective banker also requires evidence that a company’s
development and construction; management team has the ability effectively to manage and
• defining the commissioning of the project, recruiting and coordinate the various phases of the project.
training of the management team and crew and hand over at They also require reports from independent sources, covering
the conclusion of construction; selected areas already covered in the feasibility study. They use
• estimating the development, capital and operating costs of these independent reports both for initial due diligence purposes
the mine over the economic life of the resource; and for project monitoring during the preproduction phase.

Australian Mineral Economics 117


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

The most commonly requested independent reports cover: costs. A project’s principals will view this either as the final
• verification of resources and ore reserves; stage of project development or the first stage of construction,
depending upon whether they have decided to proceed with
• capital and operating cost estimates; project construction before or after the preparation of these
• technical feasibility of mining methods; estimates.
• geotechnical and groundwater considerations; A definitive project cost estimate provides the basis for project
capital cost control and aids in establishing and checking
• processing technology and predicted metallurgical construction contract prices. As such, it is usually based on
performance; non-detailed site layout and engineering drawings and
• management capability of the operator for both the specifications. At this stage of the project some quotations may
construction and production phases; have been called and the construction schedule estimated such
that the estimate can be used as a management control budget
• technical reviews of environmental impact statements; during construction.
• availability and security of essential services such as power The construction phase of the project effectively commences
and water; following the decision to develop the project. It includes the
• risks associated with transporting and selling product; detailed mine, metallurgical planning and detailed engineering
design. From this follows procurement of equipment, the
• risks associated with natural disasters; engineering construction and mine development.
• political, social and industrial risks; Mining and treatment commence with project commissioning.
• product marketing; This phase includes recruiting and training the operating crew
and sorting out operational and equipment ‘bugs’ such that the
• environmental impact and permitting; and operations settle down to become routine. This is the point at
• access and land rights matters. which the project enters the production phase.
A banker will also usually develop a cash flow model based on Planning and evaluating the following activities contribute to
a production schedule derived from the project’s resources and generating the definitive project cost estimate:
reserves, prepared by an independent mining consultant.
He or she will use this model to test sensitivity to operating Owner management activities
and capital cost overruns, production and recovery variations,
commodity price and exchange variations and the combination of • Establish the project personnel and management information
several variations. When these have been completed, he or she systems;
will appraise the basic strengths of the project and offer the • set the project implementation strategy including the
borrower alternative loan packages. contracting plan, commissioning, operating structures and
A banker requires a project life, which exceeds the term of the the preproduction approach; and
loan and he or she will build in contingencies for cost overruns, • call tenders, select and appoint consultants or contractors
production and recovery short falls and market fluctuations. and/or engage the project execution team.
The extent to which a project depends on input from
independent sources depends on many factors. From a banking
perspective, the requirement for independent reports depends
Project management
very much on the risk profile of the project, the track record of • Specify the scope of work, design criteria and quality
the project sponsor, the type of bank, its credit culture and its parameters for the project;
in-house ability to assess mining project risk.
• complete sufficient engineering design to eliminate technical
For a single bank financing, there may be no specific risks, allow accurate quantity and derive labour hour
requirement for independent reports. However, for syndicated estimates;
financings, it is usual for banks to request a significant level of
independent reports to be prepared, both for initial due diligence • obtain and evaluate firm quotations for the supply of large or
purposes and for project monitoring during the preproduction key equipment items;
phase and the period of loan payback. • obtain and evaluate firm quotations for the supply,
The depth of investigations is influenced by the perceived fabrication and transport of a large proportion of bulk
competence of the mining company, the existence of assets besides materials;
those of the specific project, type of commodity, nature of the
proposed project and any related environmental and political factors.
• obtain firm tenders for the erection and installation
construction works of the larger or critical contracts;
Early exposure of bankers to the project through presentations
by the exploration and project evaluation team, usually enhance • accurately define the costs of remaining engineering and
loan negotiations. Bankers are reassured when they carry out due construction management services; and
diligence activities, if there has been a significant amount of • set the schedule for all remaining works to develop a series
independent work undertaken on the project, particularly in of firm completion dates for supply, construction,
respect of key risk areas. commissioning and pre-production activities.
It is important to consider carefully the preparation of
independent reports during the early stages of project Applicable codes and professional competency
development to avoid duplication of effort and reduce evaluation
costs and time. Anticipating a banker’s likely requirements will The JORC Code (2004) and the VALMIN Code (2005) currently
be of significant benefit to the project. represent best practice standards in the Australian minerals
industry. Although feasibility studies are usually internal
Definitive project cost estimates company documents, extracts from them usually become
appended to various public documents and should be regarded as
It is possible to prepare a definitive project cost estimate after the being in the public domain. Thus it is highly desirable that they
completion of a feasibility study. This requires accurate estimates accord with and follow both the JORC Code (2004) and the
of design, supply, transport, construction and preproduction VALMIN Code (2005). As there is always a possibility that

118 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

information not conforming with these codes could get in the Capital costs usually include:
public arena, it is important that feasibility studies note and • tenement acquisition;
explain formally the reasons for such departure from the norm.
A team of multidisciplined competent professionals having • exploration (if not offset against other operations);
complementary skills, including mineral economists, • feasibility studies and planning (from the end of exploration);
metallurgists, mining engineers, geologists, environmentalists
and marketers, usually carries out evaluation studies.
• environmental studies;
The competent person signing off the report, must understand • mine development;
the interrelationships and trade-off between the various project • mine plant and equipment;
variables, the potential risks and problems associated with those
variables and possess the planning ability to compensate for or to • site preparation;
reduce the effects of such problems as they occur. They must • treatment plant;
understand and manage risk and should incorporate ‘best
practice’ in their work.
• tailings disposal;
The basic principles that apply to a properly conducted • workshops, offices, warehouses;
feasibility study are similar to those in the VALMIN Code (2005) • power supply;
– due diligence, materiality, transparency, reasonableness and
professional competence. • water supply;
• site support infrastructure;
COSTS • accommodation and amenities;
Factors such as the selected production rate, the selected mining • design and engineering expenses;
methods, waste to ore ratios, the mine’s geometry, treatment • temporary construction facilities and plant;
route, infrastructure requirements and the propensity of some
engineers to place best quality ahead of just achieving fitness for • owner’s costs;
purpose (the Rolls Royce factor) will all influence a project’s • a contingency for items not included (this is not a buffer for
capital and operating costs. holding money to give cover for bad estimation); and
A common way to design a project with low operating costs is
to install robust mining, treatment and infrastructure facilities. • working capital (this includes the initial stock of spares, first
This incurs a substantial capital cost but may be appropriate fill, recruiting and training during commissioning and
where the project has a long life and the product is ‘low value operating costs until regular returns on sales are established –
and high volume. it is often equivalent to four months of operating costs).
The opposite case of low capital with a high operating cost Other items of capital that are often overlooked include:
may be more suitable for a short life small production high value • replacement capital during operations, and
product mining operation.
The range of factors that will influence the capital and • mine closure costs offset against salvage value at mine
operating cost profile of a new mine include the company’s closure.
corporate policy, the nature of the deposit, its potential life, Replacement capital includes the cost to replace major items
production rate, the company’s need and ability to raise capital, of plant and equipment (mine trucks, excavators, bulldozers and
the company’s perceived risk profile and its ability to repay so on) during the life of the project.
borrowings. Post-production capital includes the cost to remove mine plant
Establishing the various relationships between costs and a and equipment, remove foundations, to make the area safe and to
project’s production capacity involves identifying fixed, clean and complete rehabilitation of the area at mine closure.
semi-fixed and variable cost elements throughout the mining and This is offset against any plant and equipment salvage payments
treatment routes. It also involves defining appropriate and recovery of working capital.
dependencies to aid the development of factoring methods.
A schedule of capital expenditure should be compiled initially
As production activities increase or decrease, so does the total
cost. Where a given component of the total cost changes in direct on an annual basis then as the estimates become more detailed
proportion to the production rate, it is a variable cost. Where a quarterly or monthly for the construction and initial operating
given component of the total cost remains unchanged for a given years.
time despite variations of production, it is known as a fixed cost. There usually are insufficient data available for more than
There are some costs that remain fixed costs until there is a preliminary planning and engineering in the early stages of
major change in production. These are stepped costs. They are feasibility assessment, and the project’s scope of work rarely is
usually fixed costs until there is a radical variation in production. fully defined. Thus, often it is only possible to prepare an ‘order
As part of specifying the most cost effective production rate of magnitude estimate’ of the project’s capital costs.
and design for a project, it is necessary to select a series of In this early stage of cost estimation, it is common to use a
production rates, estimate their capital and operating costs then factoring procedure to equate capital costs from recently
assess the combination, which maximises the project’s net constructed projects to the new project. The analyst may use the
present value. experience of similar operations to estimate capital and operating
cost and then apply factoring to estimate the costs at other
Capital costs production rates. However, as more scoping and engineering
design proceeds, the project may be broken down into elements
In the mining industry, the capital cost of a project generally
means the total investment required to bring the property into and the cost of each element may be factored for changes in
production. It includes the estimated costs of all phases of production.
development, construction, the management of these phases and There are many forms of factoring. One commonly used
project commissioning. On many occasions, capital expenditure formula for adjusting the variation of capital costs with
will continue after mining operations have been commenced and production is the seven tenths formula (exponential capacity
optimised. factoring) below.

Australian Mineral Economics 119


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

C2 = (P2/P1)7/10 C1 Accuracy levels typically resulting from predevelopment cost


estimates are:
where:
C2 = cost estimate of project 2 at production P2 Percentage
Scoping ± 30-35
C1 = cost estimate of project 1 at production P1
Prefeasibility ± 20-25
P2 = installed production rate of project 2
Feasibility ± 10-15
P1 = installed production rate of project 1 Definitive ± 5-10
The factor varies from 5/10 to 9/10 but for mining project
Source: Cusworth (1993).
capital costs is generally around 6.5/10 to 7.5/10.
In the early stages a global capital cost from a similar project Operating costs
may be modified using this factoring system, keeping in mind
that these rule of thumb are only order of magnitude and in some Estimating operating costs is generally more difficult than
cases can be quite inaccurate. estimating a project’s capital costs. This is due to the uniqueness
Typical individual factors are: of a deposit, mining and treatment method, location and each
company’s operating philosophies. Yet cost engineers often pay
• mine 0.65-0.85 less attention to estimating operating costs than to capital costs.
• treatment plant 0.55-0.75 Most mining companies collect their costs in the following
• town, site accommodation 0.65-0.75 major areas:
• workshops 0.65-0.8 Exploration
• power station 0.75-0.9 Mining
• surface works 0.75-0.85 Surface mining
• offices, warehouses, buildings 0.7-0.8 Waste and over burden removal

Attempts to use rules of thumb and factoring methods based Ore extraction
on linear and log-linear trends to provide a quick indication of Surface mining general (general pit dewatering, day works and
the probable capital cost of a project, including: haul road maintenance, etc)
• the turnover ratio method, Underground mining
• the module cost method, and Mine and stope development
Ore extraction
• installed capital cost per tonne of annual production,
Ore transportation ex mine
are not appropriate over large production rate differences and can
in some cases lead to significant errors. They should never Underground mining general (ventilation, dewatering, access
replace estimates based on more detailed planning and maintenance, research, overheads)
engineering carried out by professionals experienced in the Mine general (supervision, mine planning, grade control, immediate
specific areas and commodities. mine area exploration research, safety, training, overheads)
The resource type, size, the capital cost, the approach, Treatment
structures, resources and time allocated for each stage will Crushing
dictate the costs of predevelopment.
Grinding
Projects with high environmental, industrial or market
sensitivities require higher predevelopment costs in areas such as Concentration
feasibility studies and planning (from the end of exploration) Tails and waste disposal
metallurgical testing, mining studies, environmental studies and
Dump restoration
the owner’s expenses during this period.
The program of development can also significantly affect the Treatment general
‘standing’ costs of the owner’s personnel allocated to the Administration
predevelopment stage. Corporate
The contingency allowed in a feasibility study is the amount
assigned by experienced estimators to cover costs that will occur, Some companies have a separate engineering operating cost
but for which it is not possible to establish a specific scope from section. Others may include engineering as a separate area or
available drawings, specifications or schedules. A contingency is include it as part of the exploration, mining and treatment.
to allow for changes in scope, capacity or schedule. Members of
the feasibility study team estimate it from experience based on It is usual to divide the above cost areas further into:
the quality of definition available at the time of the estimate • salaries and on costs;
preparation. It is a true estimated cost over which no discretion
can be applied as to whether it will or will not be expended. • wages and on costs;
Contingency amounts applied to capital cost estimates at • contractors;
various stages of feasibility study are as follows: • consultants;
Contingency Percentage of capital cost • services (power, water, compressed air, communications);
Scoping and conceptual 20-25 • fuel and lubrication;
Prefeasibility 15-20 • consumables;
Feasibility 10-15 • spares and tools;
Definitive 5-10 • reclamation;
Source: Cusworth (1993). • royalties and taxes;

120 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

• administration, general office, accounting and legal costs; • size of the market;
• public relations; • rate of demand growth or decline;
• recruitment and training; • rate of supply growth or decline;
• safety; • possible events, new technologies, replacement materials that
• accommodation; could influence market and possible net effect;
• transport; and • the pattern of commodity prices over the past several years
and considering the above points, a projection of future
• marketing and selling. trends; and
Depending on how companies collect costs, they may • the prospects for selling forward to reduce the risks of
separately report areas such as maintenance, supervision, commodity price downturns during the early production
accommodation, reclamation, off lease transport and marketing. years of the project.
Another possibility is to consolidate them into administration.
A key part in any mineral market survey is an estimate of
These costs are usually further split up into direct or variable future price trends. There are several possible approaches to
costs that are related directly to production and fixed annual identify these trends. While these are usually commodity
costs or indirect costs that are independent of production and are specific, they usually include:
dependant on time.
• a review of the past price trend cycles, with an assessment of
In practice, changed output rates will usually have a minor
future economic conditions over the anticipated project life;
effect on the fixed costs.
The fixed annual cost component usually includes: • estimates of the costs of competitive producers, relative to
the project’s predicted costs, to assess the relative chance of
• salaries and on costs; survival of the project during commodity price downturns;
• some wages and on costs; and
• part of services (power, water, compressed air, communications); • associated econometric models that quantify relationships
between supply, demand, commodity inventories, the various
• training and safety; and
producers’ technical factors and expected future price trends.
• corporate overheads.
All these methods aid the estimation of future prices, their
Where there are major changes to the production rate, the fluctuations and trends during the life of the project.
salaries and wages costs should be treated as stepped costs rather Based on these and the project’s production schedules and
than fixed costs. recoveries, it is possible to prepare revenue forecasts. These
The variable component usually includes: should contain potential down-side and up-side levels,
assessment of risk areas and plans for contingent action.
• some wages and on costs;
Uncertainties in predicting commodity prices include
• part of services (power, water, compressed air, communications); associated escalation, the effect of exchange rate movements and
• contractors; capital and operating cost inflation. Some market studies
incorporate factors to handle these uncertainties while others
• consultants; resort to using constant dollar conditions and use reduced interest
• a major part of services (power, water, compressed air, rates when estimating their present values of the project. It is
communications); more realistic to assume an escalating dollar and analyse
sensitivities to different capital and operating costs and
• fuel and lubrication; commodity prices to test the effects on the project viability.
• consumables; and
• spares and tools. FINANCIAL EVALUATION

MARKET SURVEYS AND COMMODITY PRICES The cash flow


The interaction of the forces of supply and demand determine The cash flow of a mining project is the after tax funds available
mineral prices. An important part of any feasibility study is the to the company. It is usually based on annual cost figures.
market survey. This should indicate the probability of contractual However, at project construction and in the early stages of
sales under forward conditions. It also should report smelter and operations, it may be necessary to prepare the cash flow over
refining charges (depending on the type of commodity being shorter periods for cost control purposes. These are usually
sold) and other selling costs, charges and commissions. These reported annually.
data establish the net revenue received on sales from the project’s A project’s after tax cash flow includes the following
production. components:
Sometimes the banks financing a project will not fully • net revenue from sales after selling expenses;
understand the nature of a mine’s production, or the markets in • plus other income (toll treatment, earnings from investments,
which the project will operate. In these cases they may require etc);
independent market studies to address specific market issues.
A mineral market survey usually addresses the following • less operating costs, exploration costs, state royalties, interest
matters: and GST;
• product specification and risk contaminants; • less taxation;
• quality control and penalty criteria; • plus borrowed funds and equity injections;
• current market suppliers and purchasers; • less capital expenditure;
• geographic location of main market areas relative to the • less principal loan repayments; and
project and their influence on the project; • equals after tax cash flow.

Australian Mineral Economics 121


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

A project’s depreciation does not reduce its cash flow. • whether real (constant) or nominal money values incorporating
However, it is a legitimate deduction in each period to determine the effect of expected inflation are being used; and
tax payable.
• company corporate policy.
When gearing is included in the cash flow, assumptions are
necessary about the timing and the amounts to be paid back to The theory underlying the determination of the cost of equity
the lenders and the interest to be paid on the outstanding loans. using the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and the
methodology for computing the weighted average cost of capital
The project payback period (ie the point in time when the (WACC) have already been covered in some depth in Chapter 10
cumulative net cash flows from production balance the project to which the reader is referred.
development and construction outlays on an undiscounted or
Generally, discount rates are higher when a project is at an
discounted basis) is an important break-even point to the project
earlier stage and the inherent project risks are higher. So at a
lenders and owners.
scoping conceptual stage the real rate of discount may be as high
Lenders are primarily concerned about the realism of a project as 17 to 27 per cent. As more project data become available and
cash flow capacity to service its debt and repay the related the feasibility study becomes more detailed, the risks reduce and
principal over the period while their loans are outstanding. While the discount rates fall accordingly. At the definitive stage real
not overly concerned about the project whole-of-life discount rates could fall to as low as eight to 12 per cent or less.
performance beyond repayment of their loans, would consider The project owners normally compute and set the discount rates
projects with a long operating life beyond the project payback as a matter of policy, with the agreement of the professional
period more favourably. Their risks of loans default are much signing off the feasibility study.
reduced if there is no project commissioning slippage, as there
would also be reduced risk with the accuracy of predictions Project optimisation
about future commodity prices, exchange rates and costs.
As discussed in Chapter 10, in order to obtain a meaningful Optimising a mine plan requires a sound workable plan, which
minimises cost and maintains the various project risks at a
valuation of the project, it is necessary to take into account the
manageable level, while achieving maximum profit in present
time value of money by bringing back to the present time, each value terms. A major component of this is understanding the
period (usually annual) of future cash flow produced during the characteristics of the mineral resource project development
planned life of the project. The present or initial period is not capital options, mining parameters and conditions and
discounted. This is known as the present value (PV) method of metallurgical conditions, considering that these conditions may
measuring the value of the project. The formula for calculating change during the production period. Computer modelling can
the present value of cash flow in each period is: enhance this understanding.
Present value = cash flow/(1+discount rate)t During a detailed feasibility study, the optimisation process
includes assuming various production plans on a timed basis
It may also be expressed as: such that the variables, which have an effect on the project’s
profitability, are varied in differing combinations to maximise
Present value = cash flow*(1+discount rate)-t
profit. This requires considering different mining plans and
where: extraction sequences to test for increased profitability with
increased strip ratios, increased dilution, grade variation, reduced
t is the number of time intervals from the start of the project to recoveries, commodity prices, capital and operating costs, grades
the particular cash flow being discounted to its present value resulting from changed cut-off grades, effects of changes in
In the initial year from which the time periods are being production rates and mine life and possibly project gearing. As
measured, t = 0 and the cash flow for that period is the present an illustration of this process, Christie (1997) presents a useful
value. case study in data interpretation, orebody definition, and
The sum of all the present values of each period net after-tax optimisation at the Red Dome deposit in Queensland.
cash flows is the net present value (NPV) of the project. Thus,
the NPV of a project is the total sum of money in today’s money SOME COMMENTS ON CUT-OFF GRADES AND
values of the present and future cash flows discounted at a OTHER CUT-OFF POINTS
specified interest rate, ie:
It is a misconception that only the cut-off grade will directly
determine which blocks of the identified mineral resource should
NPV = ∑ t=0 to n (CFt / (1+discount rate)t) be mined. Ground conditions, including jointing, faulting
shearing, areas of weathering, orebody geometry and physical
depth will usually dictate the use of specific mining methods.
Mine access to areas, ground support requirements and other
At mine closure, project buildings, plant, equipment, residual
mining constraints often dictate the mining of lower grade
stocks in the warehouse and the working capital have a residual
material or the leaving of some higher grade material such as
value. However, expenditure is necessary to clean up and unrecoverable pillars in underground mines. Where such pillars
rehabilitate the project site. These expenditures should be are left and no plan exists to recover the pillars then the pillars,
included in the cash flow. They appear either in the last year of while part of the mineral resource, are not part of the ore reserve.
operation or in the following year depending on plans to carry In addition, as a result of deposit geometry, some ore may be
out the project closure and clean up. They, as part of the cash left and there may be a need to mine barren or sub-grade
flow, must also be discounted to their present value. material. These together with the spalling of weak barren wall
The setting of the project’s discount rates must be matched to material will result in the ore being diluted and ore recovery
the factors included in the cash flow model. Such factors include: being reduced. It is essential to take account of this dilution and
• the corporate cost of raising equity funds, with cognisance of the recovery of ore from within the mineral resource envelope in
assessing the ore reserves.
perceived project risk;
In most mines the marginal cut-off grade in the stope in an
• the corporate cost of borrowing funds; underground mine and in the working bench in an open cut mine,
• the amount of debt as a proportion of total funds employed is assumed to be equal in value to the variable costs when the
and the effective corporate tax rate; treatment losses and other factors are taken into account.

122 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

It is normal practice to send material between the operating • mining and processing risks,
cut-off grade and the marginal cut-off grade to a low-grade
stockpile. This is treated at times of reduced mine production to
• risks associated with the project’s supporting infrastructure,
maintain the mill at its optimum production rate. Processing • financial and marketing risks,
surplus material also takes place as mining operations slow • management and industrial risks,
toward the end of the economic mine life. Treating marginal
grade material, early in the life of the mine instead of ore above • environmental risks, and
the design cut-off grade will reduce the project’s NPV. • project specific risks.
It is necessary to mine some material, which has sufficient The following discussion reviews several of these in more
grade to allow it to be treated covering the variable treatment detail.
cost, but has insufficient grade to be classified as marginal
material. This permits the mining of profitable ore. This is Risks associated with the project’s resource base
usually stockpiled as low-grade ore for treatment either when
there is an ore supply problem in the mine or at some future time The resources drive our projects and our
when the project’s economic conditions are more favourable. resources are driven by geology, the resource
Having made this point, a mine’s managers should avoid causing models we generate should therefore also be
negative cash flow and mining and treating material that does not driven by geology rather than geostatistics.
cover variable costs. Understanding the strengths and weaknesses of a
resource model is fundamental to understanding
a project well (Rozman, 1998).
RISKS AND SENSITIVITIES ASSOCIATED WITH
FEASIBILITY STUDIES A project’s estimated mineral resource are only an estimate.
Not only are there interpretive errors in assessing the continuity,
Any evaluation of a project’s robustness must take into account geology and structure, but there will also be variability in the
its various risk areas and the potential for adverse interaction of assay data, sample density assessment, the surveying of the
those risks on the project. sample points and allocation of areas of influence. After any
Butler (1994) argues that: calculation of mineral resources the professional carrying out the
feasibility study must be assured that it is the right order of
The cash flow model will then be run under a magnitude prior to assessing ore reserves, or have a good
number of sensitivities with each of the critical understanding of the risks in this area.
parameters (for example costs, commodity
It is important to use common sense and experience and
prices) varied separately and systematically to
understand orders of accuracy when one is assessing quantitative risk.
test the project’s robustness to variations in these
factors. The risks associated with the resource halo include:

Feasibility studies provide the opportunities to evaluate risk • reliability of the base data;
factors prior to developing a mineral project and, in this way assist • surveying,
in maximising the success of the venture. Such studies are based • sampling,
upon a series of assumptions about future mining, treatment,
market and economic conditions, all of which carry risk. • assaying,
But some other comments are worthy of note. Rozman (1998) • density determination;
notes that: • deposit continuity;
The resources business like so many others is all • grade variability;
about managing risk. If all we do is minimise
risk, many a viable business opportunity will be
• lower than predicted grades;
lost. • density variability within and across geological subsets; and
Seymour (1998) argues: • geological interpretation.
The key objective of a mining company in to
maximise shareholder contribution within Mining and processing risks
acceptable risks. In order to achieve this, the Mining risks are associated with:
mine planning process must be adequate to
deliver the ‘promise’ and to protect the future of • mining methods and equipment sizing,
the mine. • ground conditions,
Effective risk analysis allows consideration of both anticipated • strip ratios,
problems and unexpected occurrences. During the feasibility • mining ore losses,
stage there is usually a relatively minor cost to plan for the
ability and flexibility to take contingent action to handle • mining ore dilution,
unexpected conditions and to rectify or control problems. If this • fixed plant and equipment,
planning does not take place unexpected problems during • environmental matters, and
production may lead to major expenditure and production losses.
• unexpected cost pattern changes and equipment replacement
The most common factors or risks, that contribute to or reduce
timing during the mine life.
the estimated value and success of any mining project, include:
Feasibility studies involve conceiving the most practical
• risks associated with the project’s resource base, mining system, mine layouts and production schedules, the
• land access risks, treatment process and the marketing possibilities for the
products. It is not possible to complete in any sensible way
• sovereign risks,
studies for mineral production independent of mine design,
• risks associated with project construction and commissioning, production scheduling and through these, ore reserves.

Australian Mineral Economics 123


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

Ground conditions including jointing, faults, areas of shear, Financial and marketing risks
stress directions, deposit geometry, weathering conditions, zones
There are many factors, as well as cost inflation, that both
of secondary enrichment and water flow may dictate the use of
directly and indirectly influence capital costs during construction
specific mining methods and selected equipment size should be and can influence the operating costs once the mining and
evaluated for risk. processing are in production. Also, there are many uncertainties
Drilling, costeaning and other exploration activities may in the prediction of commodity prices, commodity escalation
provide valuable information that will assist in evaluating these rates and exchange rates.
risks. The field geologists should record any potentially useful These may include:
information and early involvement of mining and metallurgical
personnel during the exploration will aid this process. All such Capital costs
information should be available to the technical team
undertaking the feasibility study. • Cost over runs,
Processing risks can be associated with: • key component delivery delays,
• treatment methods and equipment sizing, • unforseen costs (meant to be covered by the contingency),
• unexpected ore conditions, • government policy changes,
• changed crushing and grinding conditions, • industrial delays or excessive allowance claims,
• reduced recoveries, • key component failures during installation, and
• increased reagent utilisation, • unexpected litigation.
• increased plant wear and maintenance,
Operating costs
• unexpected contaminants,
• Cost over runs,
• tailings disposal problems,
• unforseen costs due to unplanned events,
• treatment water problems, and
• unforseen government charges,
• waste water disposal.
• unexpected industrial delays,
Metallurgical risk assessment will generally require bench
scale and possibly larger scale tests on drill core and bulk sample • unexpected plant and equipment failures,
material. These will generally provide basic plant design criteria. • unexpected high interest rates on borrowed funds, and
It is important to assess the risk of failing to achieve those • unexpected inflation.
criteria when the project is in production, together with what
contingent plans can be initiated to eliminate or reduce the
Commodity prices
effects on the project’s return.
• Unexpected commodity price falls,
Project design and construction risks • unrealistic market size predictions,
The design, construction and commissioning phase includes the • unexpected contaminant penalties,
detailed mine planning, metallurgical planning and detailed • unexpected currency parity changes,
engineering design. From this follows procurement of
equipment, the engineering construction, mine development and • unexpected changes in product transportation costs, and
the crew training and project commissioning and fine-tuning. • unforseen political and social factors affecting the markets.
Project construction risks may be associated with: The risk of failing to achieve those criteria assumed in the
• access (sovereign and land title); financial modelling, when the project is in production, must be
assessed together with what contingent plans can be put in place,
• infrastructure; including forward sales, to control the effects on the project’s
• construction manning and availability of skilled labour; sales returns.
• project management (coordination, procurement, budgetary
control, time management and control); Project sensitivities
• environmental; It is important to identify project risks and discuss their
satisfactorily mitigation, especially in areas of high project
• sociological; sensitivity, in all relevant areas of the feasibility study reports.
• technical (electrical, mechanical, civil, mining and metallurgical Sensitivity analysis is not about adjusting a number of
design); and supposedly key variables up or down by ten percent, one at a
time and tracking the change in the end financial result. The real
• poor cost estimates and cost over runs. world is never that simple. Variables do not change one at a time,
The definitive cost estimates and supporting time estimates nor are they limited to ten per cent movements. This kind of
require inclusion of assessments of project risks and measures to ‘analysis’ tends to show the obvious, that mining projects are
cater for such risks. sensitive to exchange rates, product prices, levels of capital
High quality management, construction coordination and tight expenditure and the like. Astute market practitioners and
participants do not need to be told this. They intuitively
cost control should control project risk. recognise the sensitive areas of a project.
Time slippage during construction is a major risk in many Stirzaker (1997) notes that another limitation to sensitivity
projects. Such slippage results in delayed commencement of analysis is that it can only deal with the variables, which have
production with associated delays in commencement of positive already been, identified as having an impact on the financial
cash flow. Such slippages usually result in increases in capital viability of the project. It will not pick up factors that are not
costs, compounding the financial losses. included in the financial model.

124 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

Using Monte Carlo simulations has become a widely used tool His paper covers the scoping, management and co-ordination
to assist in the assessment of risk in mining projects. The of the feasibility process and discusses the allocation and control
following two quotations highlight its use in feasibility studies. of responsibility, time, budget and the study quality.
In addition to the normal project-based cash flow The first step in the preparation of any feasibility study is to
analysis, advanced Monte Carlo risk analysis prepare a clear scope of work to be carried out, orders of accuracy
techniques are increasingly being used to assess to be reached, time schedules for that work, a responsibility chart
the downside risk and the upside potential of for personnel responsible for the various areas in the study. The
projects. This has the advantage of minimising procedure of pulling all sections together, controlling areas of
the inherent bias that may be allowed to creep overlap and liaison should be the responsibility of a project
into the study, and leads to a far better coordination team under the project manager.
understanding of the project (Laird, 1997).
FEASIBILITY STUDY REPORTS
The use of computers provides the opportunity
for iterative analysis of resource projects, A feasibility study report should provide an overview of the
allowing the sensitivity of projects to be rapidly project, all key facts of the project and present a logical and
and easily estimated. Monte Carlo style workable scheme for its development and exploitation. The
probabilistic analysis is a computerised project’s various advantages, risks, capital cost and its financial
technique, which can be effectively used to model returns should be clearly and openly discussed.
and subsequently represent the financial and To achieve best practice, a feasibility study report must be a
production permutations likely to result from a clearly written stand-alone document enhanced by meaningful
resource project. The use of probabilistic pertinent diagrams. It must fairly summarise all key data, test
analysis is recommended and as a further check, results, listings of resources, and technical, legal tenure and
forces the user to thoroughly assess the strengths environmental consents and financial matters that are pertinent to
and weaknesses of the data compiled for use in the development of the project. However, there should not be
the analysis of a project (Rozman, 1998). excessive amounts of data included in the main body of the
report as these both confuse the reader and detract from the
thrust of the report. Relevant listings of data can be included in
Managing risk supporting appendices.
It is important to be proactive in managing risk in all projects and Information on the different methodologies utilised to estimate
directing this toward areas of greatest risk potential and of the project’s ore reserves, production schedules, cash flow
magnitude. Assessment must be of whether there is a risk of a assessments and valuations together with comment on base data
gradual problem or a sudden problem, the nature, extent and reliability will aid the reader’s understanding and evaluation of
possible chain effect of the problem on other areas and the the project.
magnitude of the effect of the problem on the overall project. The report must be written with the objective of disclosing
A valuable tool to aid seeing and understanding of risk is to assumptions made about the inclusion of any inferred resources
prepare a risk assessment and management spreadsheet or chart. or ‘blue sky’ ore in the production schedule including applied
This should catalogue and rank the risks from those of greatest to probability factors and other factors that have significant
those of minimum influence together with a summary column of influence on the valuation.
possible contingent actions to control or minimise potential Reference to both upside and down side valuation must be
influences on the project. Matters of safety, environment, included such that the reader understands the projects
production and cost should be incorporated into the chart to sensitivities, potential risks and the most likely valuation. The
provide management with a clear overview of the risk situation. reader must understand the project’s sensitivity to changes in
Assessing the technical and financial viability of a mining recoveries, dilution, exchange rates, commodity prices costs and
project requires consideration of risks involved in bringing a the many other factors likely to cause variation in the valuation
mineral deposit into production and maintaining that production during the planned operating life of the project; such that he may
during the planned life. Sensitivities can be applied to quantify be able to either accept the study recommendations or make a
the effects of ‘what ifs’ on the project viability, but risk modified judgement.
assessment requires the input of competent professionals in their
areas of project expertise. These include geologists, mining REFERENCES
engineers, metallurgists, commodity traders and financiers.
Effective risk analysis is required to allow the building into a Amos, Q G, 1998. Resources and risk – the lender’s view, in Proceedings
project the flexibility and means to handle both anticipated Ore Reserves and Finance Seminar, pp 57-64 (The Australasian
Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
problems and the unexpected occurrences. It can usually be built
into the project planning at relatively minor cost during the Butler, P, 1994. A banker’s view of cash flow methods in mineral valuation,
feasibility phase but may require major expenditure and in Proceedings Mineral Valuation Methodologies 1994, pp 47-62 (The
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
production losses during production.
Christie, M A, 1997. Orebody definition and optimisation, in Proceedings
Mindev ‘97, pp 47-56 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and
MANAGING THE FEASIBILITY STUDY PROCESS Metallurgy: Melbourne).
Cusworth, N, 1993. Predevelopment, in Cost Estimation Handbook for
Because the feasibility study process can cost up to a ten per cent
the Australian Mining Industry, (eds: M Noakes and T Lanz) pp
of the overall project cost, it should be scoped and managed with 252-259 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy:
the same care as the project. Most importantly a poorly managed Melbourne).
feasibility study can lead to the wrong development decision. Gilfillan, J F, 1998. Testing the data – the role of technical due diligence,
The feasibility study is one of the early activities in a project. It in Proceedings Ore Reserves and Finance Seminar, pp 33-42 (The
requires the employment and coordination of a team of multi- Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
disciplined competent professionals having complimentary skills. JORC, 2004. Australasian Code for Reporting of Mineral Resources and
Northcote (1998) notes that: Ore Reserves (The JORC Code), The Joint Ore Reserves Committee
of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Australian
Feasibility studies are themselves of similar Institute of Geoscientists and Minerals Council of Australia. [Online].
structure to projects and therefore project Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/codes/jorc0105.pdf>. Date
management techniques can be applied. accessed: 8 May 2006.

Australian Mineral Economics 125


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

Laird, A M, 1997. How to develop a project, in Proceedings Mindev ‘97, 5. Geology


pp 3-8 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy:
Melbourne). Brief history of previous exploration and production in the
Northcote, A E A, 1998. Scoping of feasibility studies, in Proceedings immediate project area;
The AusIMM Annual Conference ‘98, pp 105-110 (The Australasian
Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne). exploration carried out including geophysical and
Rozman, L I, 1998. Measuring and managing the risk in resources and geochemical surveys, drilling, sampling, logging;
reserves, in Proceedings Ore Reserves and Finance Seminar, pp 43-56 regional and detailed deposit geology and deposit
(The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne). mineralogy, together with supporting diagrams and maps;
Seymour, C, 1998. Risk analysis in open pit mine planning, in
Proceedings The AusIMM Annual Conference ‘98, pp 129-134 (The mineral resources including a summary of the evaluation
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne). methodology;
Shillabeer, J H, 1998. Lessons learned preparing mining feasibility studies, the potential for the discovery of additional mineral
in Proceedings The AusIMM Annual Conference ‘98, pp 111-115 (The resources within the tenements; and
Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
Stirzaker, M, 1997. Feasibility studies – Risks and sensitivities, in mineralogy of the ore and comments on the foot wall,
Proceedings Mindev ‘97, pp 35-37 (The Australasian Institute of hanging wall and surrounding country rock.
Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
VALMIN, 2005. Code for the Technical Assessment and Valuation of 6. Mining
Mineral and Petroleum Assets and Securities for Independent Expert
Reports (The VALMIN Code), The VALMIN Committee, a joint Brief mining overview;
committee of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy,
the Australian Institute of Geoscientists and the Mineral Industry mining conditions and methods;
Consultants Association (The Australasian Institute of Mining and mine design criteria including recovery and dilution;
Metallurgy). [Online]. Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/
codes/valmin_2005.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. ore reserves (include proposed mining methods and general
White, M E, 1997. Feasibility studies – scope and accuracy, in economic parameters assumed in planning their mining);
Proceedings Mindev ‘97, pp 27-34 (The Australasian Institute of
Mining and Metallurgy: Melbourne).
planned production schedule and the probability of these
being achieved when they exceed the ore reserves;
Yeates, G and Adams, M H, 1998. Resource and reserve reporting for BHP
Cannington, in Proceedings Ore Reserves and Finance Seminar, pp geotechnical considerations;
19-27 (The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy:
Melbourne). access;
development schedule;
APPENDIX – CHECKLIST OF THE MAIN mine plan and schedule;
SECTIONS OF FEASIBILITY STUDY REPORTS equipment including support for selection and availability;
The list below is a checklist of the main sections of a feasibility staffing, manning and rosters;
study reports. It will require modification to make it project
mine services – water, power, communications, explosives,
specific.
compressed air, ventilation;
mine waste and overburden disposal;
1. Introduction
dump and mine area refoliation;
Scope of the report; and
other project specific matters;
simple introduction to the project covering its location,
topography, climate, land use and access to the area. environmental matters; and
areas of potential risk and advantage.
2. Summary
Summary description of the key points of the project;
7. Treatment
areas of predevelopment requiring further investigation or Brief treatment overview;
evaluation; process selection and route;
the anticipated project financial situation; testwork;
summary of the reports conclusions; facility capacity criteria;
recommendation of whether or not to proceed with the facility design and quality criteria;
development of the project; and
process design and operational features;
summary of project risks and opportunities.
layout;

3. Tenements and ownership equipment sizes and specifications;


facility control;
Summary of the tenements, equity holders and parties
having any interest in the project; and staffing, manning and rosters;
if possible tenement location plans should be included. services – power, water, sewerage, communications, fire,
waste disposal;
4. Location materials – foundations and construction material sources;
Information on the location, access, nature of the site, any tailings disposal and eventual refoliation;
special requirements or unusual conditions; tailings water recovery and surplus water disposal;

126 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

other project specific matters; air,


environmental matters; and land use and rights of other parties to land,
areas of potential risk and advantage. impact assessment,
mitigation proposals,
8. Project infrastructure socio-economic impacts,
Roads, other project specific matters,
drainage, environmental matters, and
sewerage disposal, areas of potential risk and advantage.
water supply,
power supply, 11. Project development and management
communications, Construction sequence;
transport, contracting strategy;
warehousing, project structure and organisation;
mobile equipment, time and expenditure schedules;
spare parts, schedule of changing workforce (size, type and source);
maintenance equipment, planning and engineering design;
administration buildings, staffing;
laboratory, industrial relations matters of significance and site awards;
staffing, manning and rosters, temporary infrastructure requirements (power, other services
accommodation);
services,
project management, coordination and administration
accommodation, (procurement, time and cost control);
other project specific matters, recruitment and training of operating personnel;
environmental matters, commissioning and hand over;
areas of potential risk and advantage, fine tuning at start of operations;
temporary services, and safety and security matters;
temporary accommodation. environmental matters; and
areas of potential risk and advantage.
9. Offsite infrastructure
Roads, 12. Operations
rail, Structure,
air, workforce – size, type and source,
power, rosters,
communications, employee relations,
water, recruitment and selection,
workforce accommodation, administration,
export facility, accommodation,
logistics and transport, training,
staffing manning and rosters, availability, and
other project specific matters, cost rates.
environmental matters, and
areas of potential risk and advantage. 13. Capital and operating costs
assumptions (exchange rates, escalation, etc),
10. Environmental financial over view of project,
Climate and meteorology, methodology,
terrain, contingency and accuracy,
flora, capital costs:
fauna, basis,
surface water, exchange rates,
ground water, owner costs to establish,
acoustic, preproduction development,

Australian Mineral Economics 127


CHAPTER 11: PRELIMINARY, PREFEASIBILITY AND FEASIBILITY STUDIES

engineering, procurement and construction supervision: marketing risks and contingent action,
plant and equipment, market strategy and implementation, and
infrastructure, revenue forecasts.
equipment building materials,
construction labour, 15. Project risks and opportunities
transport, Mineral resources, ore reserves and geological,
indirect costs, land rights,
government fees and charges, sovereign and social,
administration, mining,
owner project direct and indirect costs, treatment,
insurances, other technical,
commissioning, other operating,
working capital including first fill and insurance spares, environmental,
capital cost risks and contingent action, construction,
operating costs: commissioning,
basis, marketing risks,
operating spares, financial,
labour, areas of cumulative risk and possible contingent actions, and
consumables, areas of catastrophic risk and possible contingent actions.
replacement capital,
government royalties and levies,
16. Financial evaluation
administration, Basis of evaluation,
marketing, assumptions,
transport, economic evaluation and model,
agent fees, sensitivity and risk factors,
insurances, cash flow, present values and pay back periods, and
rehabilitation, and financial conclusions.
operating cost risks and contingent action.
17. Conclusions and recommendations
14. Marketing Overall study conclusions,
Commodity specification, recommendations as to the next stages of activity,
current market demand and sources, overall costs and times to carry out the recommendations,
supply demand and price forecasts, timing to achieve recommendations, and
quality control and criteria, major risks, sensitivities and areas of project advantage.

128 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12

Mineral Project Evaluation — Dealing with


Uncertainty and Risk
Pietro Guj

Introduction: Beyond DCF/NPV Analysis


Attitudes to Risk – From Expected Value to Expected Preference Value (Certainty Equivalents)
and Pricing of Risky Projects
Risk Spreading Through Joint Ventures
Bayesian Decision Trees and Progressive Risk and Value Analysis
Modern Asset Pricing (MAP) Using Commodity Forward Prices
From Static DCF/NPV to Dynamic Real Option Valuations (ROV)
Using Binomial Lattices in Valuing Real Options in Practice
Valuing an Expansion Option with the Binomial Lattice Method Using the ‘Risk-Free Probability’
Valuing Tonnage-Grade Trade-Offs
Evaluating the Sequential and Compound Real Option Value of Mineral Exploration Farm-In/
Options Agreements
Strategic ROV Considerations
Conclusions

INTRODUCTION: BEYOND DCF/NPV ANALYSIS related attitude to risk, which is typically strongly influenced
by their level of wealth.
Much of Chapter 10 dealt with evaluations under assumptions of Discussion in this chapter will explore how static DCF
certainty. However, the only thing one can be certain about is that valuations, backing risk-neutral investment decisions based on
virtually all the estimates of inputs are in fact uncertain and they expected monetary value (EMV), can be analysed and modified
will not occur at the estimated level as the project evolves. to account for individual risk-aversion, generating risk-adjusted
More often than not, the performance of a project is very or certainty equivalent (Cx) measures of value.
sensitive and deeply affected by the volatility of critical inputs. The transfer of option valuation methodologies from the field
Yet it may still be quite attractive to invest in a project that of financial derivatives to that of real options inherent in many
incorporates a number of uncertain inputs, provided the project is tangible but risky resources projects will be further addressed.
designed to anticipate likely eventualities and appropriate This is an area of rapid and exciting development in the field of
risk-management strategies are in place, recognising that project project evaluation.
performance is not static, as the deterministic nature of standard
DCF analysis would imply.
A decision to invest in a project based exclusively on ATTITUDES TO RISK – FROM EXPECTED
DCF/NPV would imply that the investor is inflexibly committed VALUE TO EXPECTED PREFERENCE VALUE
to the project plan, irrespective of unfolding future events. Very (CERTAINTY EQUIVALENTS) AND PRICING OF
few projects evolve strictly according to plans. RISKY PROJECTS
Managers can generally react to events, whether anticipated or
not and modify their action in such a manner as to minimise the Understanding the nature of risk and risk-neutral
impact of uncertainty or risk. The science of anticipating and
planning strategies to alleviate or even neutralise the potentially
expected returns
negative impacts of uncertain events is known as risk In Chapter 10, sensitivity and scenario analyses were used to
management. The extent to which investors manage risk is a identify and quantify those input variables to which the
function of their individual or corporate risk tolerance and performance of the discounted cash flow mine model of Table

Australian Mineral Economics 129


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

10.1 was most sensitive. A Monte Carlo simulation was then Risk-neutral investors should now be, in theory, indifferent
applied to produce its: between project A and B because they have the same EMV of
• expected monetary value (EMV) (ie NPV = $12.89 million). $16 million, irrespective of their different risk characteristics.
This represents the mean of the distribution or the sum of all Project A has a lower chance of a higher return, but a higher
possible NPV values weighted by their respective probability chance of a lower loss than B and vice versa. Risk-neutral
of occurrence, ie: investors would not differentiate between investing in a larger
number of type-A projects or in a lower number of type-B ones,
as long as they have the same expectation of an EMV of $16
Mean = Σ n i= 0 (x i * p i ) million.
Such an attitude, however, seems unrealistic in real life. The
• and risk, as measured by the standard deviation around this choice becomes more complex because investors are not
mean (ie $8.98 million), the relevant formula is: indifferent to the underlying risk exposure and are generally
risk-averse.
Standard deviation = [ Σ n i= 0 (x i − mean)2 * p i ]0 .5
From risk-neutral to risk-averse investment
decisions
• defining the probability distribution of all possible net Returning to the coin-tossing game, its expected return would
present values under the probabilistic input assumptions used still be 50 per cent if the wagers were to be progressively
in the Monte Carlo simulation. increased to:
Similarly, the expected value of a game of tossing a fair coin, • $200 and -$100,
where the bank pays $2 if a head (H) comes up and where the
gambler pays $1 if a tail (T) comes up is, from the point of view • $2000 and -$1000,
of the gambler: • $20 000 and -$10 000,
• $20 million and -$10 million, and so on.
EMV = 50% * $2 + 50% * (-$1) = $0.50
However, as the wagers rise relative to an investor’s wealth,
or an expected return = $0.5/$1 = 50% their attitude will soon swing from risk-neutral to risk-averse.
This happens because, as capital at risk as a proportion of wealth
increases, they become increasingly sensitive to exposure to the
In this case, the discrete classical or objective probability of risk of gambler’s ruin.
these two events are known to be (p(H) = p(T) = 50 per cent), Consider an exploration company with a budget of $1 million
which are mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive. No embarking in a series of projects costing $0.2 million each in a
other event can happen and therefore their cumulative probability geological terrain with a mineral endowment which results in ten
of occurrence must be one. While there is an expectation that, on per cent chance of success in each trial (PS). The company is in a
balance, one would win $0.5, there is nonetheless a reasonably position of withstanding five successive failures, after which it
high chance of losing $1 in each trial. will go out of business.
In finance, risk is defined with reference to expectations. It has A discrete probability distribution of mutually exclusive events
both an upside and a downside, which includes, but is not limited of the type success and failure is the binomial distribution:
to, risk in its colloquially accepted meaning as the chance of
making a monetary loss.
Probability of x successes in n trials = Pxn = (C nx ) + Px *(1 − P)n − x
On the basis of the expected return on each dollar invested, the
game represents a good investment opportunity. No one would
have any hesitation in investing in it. This, at least, would be the where:
case provided there were no competitors offering a similar game PS = probability of success in any trial
with a higher EMV, (say one that paid $4 instead of $2 for the n
same $1 bet, ie with an EMV of $1.50). (C ) = n!/[x!*(n-x)!],
x

It is common to have to choose between, say two mutually where:


exclusive exploration projects, such as: n! = 1*2…*n and
• project A, which has a potential gross value of $105 million 0! =1
with a ten per cent probability of discovery and an
exploration cost of $5 million; and Hence, the probability of survival, ie of at least one success
in five trials (P15 ) will be the sum of the probabilities of:
• project B which has a potential gross value of $70 million
with an 80 per cent probability of discovery and an • one discovery in five trials, a reasonably likely event, plus
exploration cost of $40 million. • two discoveries in five trials, plus
Their respective expected monetary values (EMVs) are: • three discoveries in five trials, plus
• EMV(A) = 0.1 * ($105 M - $5 M) + 0.9 * (-$5 M) = $5.5 M; and • four discoveries in five trials, plus
• EMV(B) = 0.8 * ($70 M - $40 M) + 0.2 * (-$40 M) = $16 M. • five discoveries in five trials, a most unlikely event.
Rational investors are wealth maximisers. Using a strictly Thus:
risk-neutral criterion (ie if they were indifferent to the different
risk exposure inherent in the two projects) they would select the
project with the highest EMV – that is project B. But let us now P15 = [5!/(1!*4!)]*0.1*0.94 + [5!/(2!*3!)]*0.12*0.93 +
assume that exploration on project A leads to an improvement in …+[5!/(4!*1!)]*0.14*0.9 = 0.4099 or 40.99 per cent
its chance of discovery from ten per cent to 20 cent. The EMV of
project A now becomes: A similar figure could have been obtained by using the
• EMV(A) = 0.2 * ($105 M - $5 M) + 0.8 * (-$5 M) = $16 M. continuous exponential approximation of the binomial

130 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

distribution, ie Pxn = 1 - e-nPs or P15 = 1 - exp(-5*0.1) = 1 - 0.6065 2. What is the maximum loss that could be experienced with a
= 0.3935 or 39.35 per cent. one per cent probability (or the VaR at one per cent) if the
As a consequence the probability of gambler’s ruin, ie company selection of exploration projects proves poor?
1 minus the probability of at least one success in five trials (P15 ) =
1- 0.4099 = 0.5901 or 59 per cent. It is a straightforward exercise to answer these questions
either:
Clearly the company would have food for thought and ask
themselves whether they are in the right game. • with the help of the standard normal distribution or z tables, or
If anything, this estimate of the probability of failure is • by drawing the distribution using a personal computer
conservative because it is based on the inherent assumption that spreadsheet as shown in Figure 12.1.
the probability of discovery in a single trial does not decrease
with successive discoveries, this is equivalent to exploring in a
terrain with a very large pool of undiscovered orebodies or
statistically sampling with replacement.
A better approximation could be obtained using a hyper
geometric distribution, provided one could estimate the rate at
which the initial probability of discovery in each trial decreases
with each successive discovery as the area matures, ie sampling
without replacement.
These statistics naturally do not take into account any
‘learning’ effects from both one’s own and others’ successes and
failures influencing the probability of success (and its perception
in explorers’ minds) in successive trials.
The magnitude of the potential adverse consequences of a
downside outcome multiplied by its probability of occurrence
represents the severity of the impact of the risk to which one
would be exposed when embarking into any uncertain venture.
Any company should seriously assess the corporate consequences
of such an impact in establishing a sound risk management FIG 12.1 - Calculation of value at risk.
policy to determine their future strategies in line with a level of
risk exposure acceptable to their shareholders. The $80 million point in the normal distribution rests at a
value of z = µ/σ = (30 per cent * $90 M) / (40 per cent * $90 M)
If the project is already one of their assets they can:
= 0.75. As can be seen in Figure 12.1, 15.20 per cent of the area
• sell it to a party better equipped to handle its risk; or under the curve falls to the left of z = 0.75 or of $80 M, ie there
• spread the risk by farming out some equity through a joint is a 15.20 per cent chance of losing more than $10 million or an
venture. 84.80 per cent probability that at the end of the year the asset
will be worth $80 million or more.
If, on the other hand, the project represents a new investment
opportunity they can: To determine the VaR at one per cent one follows the reverse
process, calculating the z value that corresponds to an area of 0.5
• bear the risk; – 0.01 = 0.49 under the standard normal density curve. This z
• hedge or insure against elements of it, if possible; value is 2.333. Hence the cut-off value will be:
• shift some of the risk to another party through contractual
arrangements; $117 M – 2.333 * $36 M = $33.012 M
• spread the risk by farming in at a level of equity lower than
100 per cent by means of a joint venture; or This means that there is a one per cent probability that up to
• reject the project. $33.012 M are at risk, or conversely, at the end of the year it is
expected that the asset will be worth $56.988 million (ie $90 M -
Risk exposure and value at risk (VaR) $33.012 M) or more with a 99 per cent level of confidence.
Modern risk exposure policy makes use of a measure called Applying VaR to a security portfolio entails estimating the
value at risk (VaR). Value at Risk is the worst loss that is mean and variability of the returns on each asset and constructing
possible under normal market conditions on any asset during a a computationally intensive variance-covariance matrix. A more
given period at a given level of confidence, eg VaR at one per practical alternative approach to determine the value at risk of a
cent. The longer the period under consideration the greater the portfolio of exploration and mining projects is to run a Monte
VaR becomes. Carlo simulation of all the projects simultaneously and
The concept of VaR is clearly discussed in Benninga (2000, determining their collective expected value and surrounding
pp 209-215) who provides both the basis of how to calculate VaR distributions of possible aggregated outcomes, taking into
for a single asset, and of how this can be extended to the primary consideration any significant level of correlation among the
use of VaR in managing a portfolio of various projects/investments inputs of various projects. This type of analysis, which is
with different risk characteristics. common in the treasury functions of banks and other financial
Suppose the possible returns on an exploration company institutions, is currently being adapted by some of the major
currently capitalised at $90 million are normally distributed and mining houses as a strategic planning tool.
that, on the basis of past performance, its capitalisation is
expected to grow on average by µ = 30 per cent but within a Risk preferences and the price of risky
standard deviation of σ = 40 per cent per annum. One might investment opportunities
wonder:
The level of risk-aversion varies from investor to investor as a
1. What is the probability of a loss of more than $10 million
function of:
by the end of the year? That is, that the capitalisation of the
company will be less than $80 million. • their individual wealth/risk capital; and

Australian Mineral Economics 131


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

• other individual or corporate traits that are a function of The best practical example of a certainty equivalent in the
the culture of the organisation, its management and past context of mining is the forward contract price for a
risk-exposure experiences. commodity. The binding nature of forward sale contracts means
that the seller will receive the exact agreed forward amount at
It is possible to overcome the shortfalls of using the expected maturity with certainty thus neutralising any price risk. This can
value criterion (ie assuming risk-neutrality) in risky investment be stated as:
decisions by using the ‘utility’ function. This function, unique to
each investor, captures the way he or she assesses the inherent
risk characteristics of a project, ie their risk-aversion. C x = − RT ln{Σ n i = 1 pi e − xi / RT }
Most utility functions in modern decision analysis are
exponential and, if the payoff is desirable, ie to be maximised, where:
take the form:
pi is the probability of outcome i
xi is the value of outcome I
u(x) = 1 - e-x/RT
n is the total number of possible outcomes
where: For example, if the firm has a risk tolerance coefficient (RT) of
$100 million, the certainty equivalent value (Cx (A)) of project A is:
RT is the risk tolerance coefficient
Cx (A) = -$100 M * ln(0.2 * e-$100 M/100 + 0.8 * e$5 M/100) = -100 M
x is the monetary payoff1 variable
* ln(0.073576 + 0.841016) = -100 M * (-0.089277) = $8.9277 M
e = 2.7182818 is the exponential constant
A value of $11.54 million can be obtained for project B in a
It is normal practice to scale risk profile curves in such a similar manner. Thus, if the firm had a RT of $100 million, it would
manner that the utility value on the y-axis, as in Figure 12.2, select project B because its Cx value at $11.54 million is higher than
ranges between –1 and 1. that of A at $8.93 million (Figure 12.3), even though the expected
values of these two projects are the same at $16 million.
0.2 $M
Mineral Discovery A
$100
Explore Project A $105 $100
1 0.63
-$5 $8.93 0.8
0.8 0.09 Barren
Progressive wins -$5
0.6 do not feel as $0 -$5
2 The CE of Project B is -0.05
0.4 good….. 11.54 higher than that of A 0.8
Utility Value

0.11 Mineral Discovery B


0.2 $30

0 Explore Project B $70 $30


0.26
-10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25 -$40 $11.54 0.2
-0.2 0.11 Barren
-$40
-0.4 $0 -$40
…as losses feel
-0.6 bad as one
Risk Tolerance Coefficient RT = $100 -0.49

-0.8 approaches A risk-averse investor would prefere to invest in Project B because its has
Gambler's Ruin a higher certainty equivalent (i.e. $ 11.54M) than that of Project A (i.e. $ 8.93M)
-1 given his RT of $ 100M, even though their expected value is the same ($ 16M)
Monetary payoff
FIG 12.3 - Risk-averse comparison of certainty equivalent values
Exponential Utility Function
of projects A and B.

FIG 12.2 - A typical risk profile curve for an investor or firm. At an RT of $100 million the company would be indifferent
between selling project B for any price in excess of $11.54
million, or attempting to achieve its EMV of $16 million. They
Risk-neutrality, ie a straight line, is only approximated for would view the potential net success value of $30 million as
relatively small potential losses and gains beyond which desirable even though it comes with a smaller, but still significant
risk-aversion rapidly sets in. Indeed the utility function is highly chance of losing $40 million.
concave to the pay-off or x axis. It is worth noting from Figure 12.4 that investors with risk
You could say that a win does not feel as good as the loss of an tolerances (RTs) lower than about $40 million would still value
equivalent amount feels bad. This is particularly so, after a series both projects for sale at a minimum of around $3.5 million even
of consecutive losses, as one approaches one’s venture capital though they would not be in a position to invest in project B. At
limit and the likelihood and fear of gambler’s ruin increases. In RTs lower than $40 million project A becomes more valuable
the example a loss of -5 has a utility value of around -0.95, until at a RT of around $33 million the Cx of project B becomes
roughly double that of a win of a similar magnitude of +5. negative followed by project A at a RT of around $22 million.
The individual risk tolerance coefficient (RT) is also the main The fact that investors with different levels of risk-aversion
determinant of the selling price at which the holder of a risky will value the same project differently creates a potentially
project would be prepared to divest, in exchange for secure cash significant range of acceptable negotiating prices. These range
in hand. This secure cash price represents the ‘certainty between a floor set by the more risk-averse company and a cap
equivalent (Cx)’ of the otherwise uncertain expected value of the reflecting the preferences of the less risk-averse one. For this
reason deals are often perceived as win-win.
project.
Aside from risk, project size is another major strategic
consideration in the determination of the price that major
1. If the payoff is undesirable, ie must be minimised, then the utility companies, finding it hard to maintain a growth rate acceptable
function takes the form: u(x) = 1 - ex/RT to their shareholders, are prepared to pay for a project. As a

132 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

10.00
10

5.00
Certainty Equivalent (Cx)

Cx $M
0.00
0 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
0 20 40 60 80 100 -5.00

-5 -10.00
% JV Equity
-10
Risk Tolerance Coefficient (RT) Cx $M

Project A Project B
FIG 12.5 - Certainty equivalence as function of percentage joint
venture equity.
FIG 12.4 - The sensitivity of certainty equivalents (Cx) to
risk tolerance coefficients (RT).
It peaks in value at about $5 million for equity levels of around
35 per cent. With this information, the company is now in a
result of these considerations and a host of other strategic better position to determine whether and to what level of equity
objectives, projects of different size and with different levels of they should farm in this project.
underlying risk (irrespective of their potential up-side value) tend Many companies have reasonably stringent policies as to the
to get in the hands of companies of appropriate size to handle minimum equity they are prepared to acquire in projects. Large
them. Schodde (2005) calls these ‘natural project owners’. companies generally prefer in excess of 50 per cent with
This dichotomy, of course, is in some ways inconsistent with management of the joint venture and resident status. In the
the notion of a single fair market value as espoused by the present example while positive, the value of acquiring majority
VALMIN code (2005), as the fairness of the price relates to equity is sub-optimal compared to 35 per cent equity.
individual risk profiles. If one were to farm out 50 per cent of a risky project in
Thus, the expected preference value rule is for any value of RT consideration of a commitment by the farming-in participant to
to select the investment with the highest certainty equivalent Cx. contribute 50 per cent of future expenditure, this would allow
An empirical approximation of the risk tolerance coefficient exploration of two similar projects per unit of money invested
(RT) is twice the maximum bet that an individual or a instead of only one. It does not follow, however, that such a
corporation would be prepared to place on the earlier game of strategy would double the company’s cumulative chance of
tossing a coin, generating benefits twice as large as the discovery and therefore its survival.
corresponding costs with a probability of 50 per cent-50 per cent, This is because the cumulative probability of discovery (Pn)
ie with an expected return of 50 per cent. This maximum bet can adheres to a binomial distribution, which is not a linear function
generally be established through a structured interview process, of either the number of trials (n) or the probability of success in a
related Delphi techniques and crosschecking for consistency with single trial (Ps). The non-linear nature of the change in the ratio
previous actual investments, all of which is far from between the cumulative probability of discovery for 100 per cent
unambiguous. equity exploration and that for a double number of trials under a
50 per cent joint venture as a function of changing Ps is
RISK SPREADING THROUGH JOINT VENTURES emphasised if plotted on log-normal graph paper as in Figure
12.6 (modified after Burn, 1984, p 60).
Different companies may wish to embark in joint ventures for a The figure shows three companies, with exploration budgets of
variety of reasons. Besides budgetary and risk spreading, these $1 million, $2 million and $10 million respectively. Assuming
include tax minimisation and strategic commodity, geographical that the average cost of an exploration trial is $0.2 million, the
and/or technological diversification. companies could either undertake five, ten or 50 exploration
A good application of certainty equivalents, in the context of projects respectively on a 100 per cent equity basis or ten, 20 or
risk spreading, is in determining the equity participation
appropriate to companies with specific individual levels of risk
tolerance.
This can be illustrated by an example where a company with a
exploration trial through 50%
Times chance of discovery is

RT of $100 million is offered an exploration project with 50 per 2


improved by doubling

cent probability of discovering an orebody worth $100 million 1.8


net of the exploration costs and 50 per cent probability of losing 1.6
$40 million in exploration.
JV

1.4
Although the expected monetary value (EMV) of this project
1.2
is $25 million, the corresponding certainty equivalent (Cx) is
-$8.29 million. As a consequence acquisition of 100 per cent of 1
the project is out of question. 0.0001 0.001 0.01 0.1 1
Probability of discovery in a single trial (Ps)
However, from Figure 12.5, which shows how the Cx varies as
a function of acquisition of progressively lower percentage P(10/5) P(20/10) P(100/50)
equity in the project, it can be observed that the Cx becomes
positive once the equity participation falls below 70 per cent.
FIG 12.6 - Joint venture risk trade-off.

Australian Mineral Economics 133


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

100 projects on a 50 per cent joint venture basis. It can be generates an anomaly P(D/A) will increase from one per
observed how the relevant ratios, eg P(10/5), P(20/10) and thousand to 1.86 per cent, nowhere close to most people intuitive
P(100/50), are close to two only at relatively low levels of Ps. As estimate. This happens because P(D/A) is Bayesian, ie:
Ps increases the number of times by which joint venturing
increases the cumulative probability of discovery falls rapidly. P(D/A) = P(D) * [P(A/D) / P(A)]
For instance at a probability of success (Ps) of ten per cent, the
cumulative probability of at least one discovery in ten trials is
0.6513. This is only 1.59 times as high as that on five trials, ie This relatively low level of improvement can be demonstrated
0.4099. using the case of a geophysical survey covering 10 000 graticular
For a Ps of ten per cent, the minimum expected value per dollar blocks as follows:
invested for a target worth $50 million will be: Because:
• an EMV (of 100 per cent exploration) = 0.4099 * $50 M + P(A) = P(A/D) + P(A/no D)
0.5901 * (- $1 M) = $19.90 M; versus = (9.5 +499.5)/10 000
• an EMV (of 50 per cent joint venture exploration) = 0.6513 * = 0.051
$25 M + 0.3487 * (-$1 M) = $15.93 M.
then:
These are the minimum EMVs, because 40.99 per cent and
65.13 per cent are the probabilities of at least one (not exactly P(D/A) = 0.001 * [0.95/0.015]
one) discovery in five and ten trials respectively. For a more = 1.86%
correct figure one would have to weight the probability of
exactly one discovery, exactly two discoveries and so on up to The first impulse to rush to drill the most intense anomalies
five or ten trials respectively. would not be the best strategy. It may be better to run the
Thus, under the assumptions, to reduce the chance of geophysical survey with a coarser detection threshold to reduce
gambler’s ruin from 59.01 per cent to 34.87 per cent, one would the number of false anomalies. Hayward (2003) concludes that
have to forego a minimum of $3.97 million (ie $19.90 M - the ‘best targeting parameter is not the one that captures the most
$15.93 M) in expected value. As for all forms of insurance or deposits’. One should also devise some alternative means of
hedging there is a cost to spreading risk through joint ventures. quickly reducing the number of false anomalies through different
It is obvious that, if the contributions to a joint venture costs and unrelated exploration techniques and selection criteria.
are to match a participant’s equity, the minimum loss of Decision trees are useful tools to structure, display and analyse
expected return occurs on the more risky side of the project risk and returns in chronological sequential order. A
spectrum. Thus, under these conditions, there is a rationale for decision-tree consists of a sequence of:
farming out risky projects and for farming into as much • decision nodes (squares) or possible alternative actions at
equity as possible in those with higher probability of success, various points in time which are under the control of and at
and farming into low-risk project justifies an adequate premium. the discretion of management; and
Projects of potential size and with lower risk of failure are also
likely to absorb most of the exploration investment capital • probability or event nodes (circles), which are subject to
available in the market at any time. Those firms, which are less chance (state of nature) and on which management has no
subject to ‘capital rationing’ or which have ready access to equity influence.
are most likely to undertake these expenditures. Contrary to DCF/NPV, which entails a single static decision of
the invest/reject type at the point of evaluation, decision trees are
BAYESIAN DECISION TREES AND dynamic in that they consider all the main possible future
decisions open to management following each relevant chance
PROGRESSIVE RISK AND VALUE ANALYSIS
event.
In exploration and mining projects successive probability events Thus a decision tree model values the effect of combinations
and related decisions are generally dependent on one another or of probabilistic events.
Bayesian in nature. Bayesian, or dependent, probabilities Let us assume that it costs $250 000 for a geophysical survey,
systems, as opposed to independent ones, can often lead to which has a 50 per cent probability of outlining a target. Assume
counter-intuitive results. also that an adequate delineation drilling program and feasibility
Hayward (2003) considers the case of a new airborne study, costing $5.5 million, in turn, has a five per cent probability
geophysical technique that, traverses and samples adjacent map of leading to the discovery of a large orebody worth $400 million
graticules in a systematic manners and generates ‘true’ anomalies and a 25 per cent probability of a small orebody worth $40
over 95 per cent of the map graticules containing a mineral million. The owners of the project must also consider whether to
deposit, as well as ‘false’ anomalies over five per cent of the attract a joint venture participant to earn 50 per cent equity by
barren map graticules it traverses. Thus, the probability of fully funding the drilling program.
getting a true anomaly given that a deposit is present (ie P(A/D)) By working out and rolling back the expected monetary
is 0.95 and that of a false anomaly given that no deposit is value of individual outcomes at each stage in the decision tree of
present, ie over barren terrain (ie P(A/no D) is only 0.05. Figure 12.7, the owners can determine that, in their current
Because systematic pattern drilling in the region leads on scenario and on a risk-neutral basis, the optimal decision is to
average to the discovery of one orebody for every thousand small carry out the geophysical survey and drilling program in-house,
graticule blocks drilled, the probability of discovery without the thus retaining 100 per cent equity in the project.
use of the new geophysical technique is P(D) = 0.001. This decision would, however, tip over to carrying out the
The question is by how much does the probability of discovery reconnaissance in-house and then farming out the prospect if the
increase if a geophysical survey is run on the tenements to chance of success were to be perceived as lower and/or the
generate drilling targets, ie what is the probability of discovery estimated cost of drilling as higher.
given an anomaly P(D/A)? Most geologists will intuitively tend If the firm, however, had a limited exploration budget and was
to guess that P(D/A) improves dramatically compared to P(D), risk-averse (eg had a risk tolerance coefficient RT of $100
with many guessing probabilities higher than 50 per cent. In million), certainty equivalent values could be substituted as
reality the probability of discovery after the geophysical survey shown in Figure 12.8. Notice that, on a risk-averse basis, the

134 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

EXAMPLE OF EXPLORATION DECISION TREE TO DETERMINE WHETHER TO FARM OUT AT DRILLING STAGE
On a risk-neutral expected monetary value (EMV) basis the decision would be to drill the project out
0.05
Risk tolerance coefficient RT 10000000000 Large orebody
394.25
400 394.25
3.9425E-08
0.25
Drill 100% Small orebody
34.25
-5.5 24.25 40 34.25
2.425E-09 3.425E-09
0.7
Barren
0.5 -5.75
Target defined 0 -5.75
1 Risk-neutral project -5.75E-10
0 24.25 owners will prefer to 0.05
2.425E-09 fund the drilling and Large orebody
retain 100% equity in 199.75
the project 200 199.75
1.9975E-08
0.25
50% JV Small orebody
Detailed Geophysics 19.75
0 14.75000012 20 19.75
-0.25 12.00 1.475E-09 1.975E-09
1.2E-09 0.7
Barren
-0.25
0 -0.25
-2.5E-11
1 Carry out 0.5
12.00 geophysics and No target
1.2E-09 drilling in house -0.25
0 -0.25
-2.5E-11

Relinquish
0
0 0
0

FIG 12.7 - Example of exploration decision tree to determine whether to farm out at drilling stage.

EXAMPLE OF EXPLORATION DECISION TREE TO DETERMINE WHETHER TO FARM OUT AT DRILLING STAGE
A decision based on the certainty equivalent value Cx would be to farm the project out
0.05
Risk tolerance coefficient RT 100 Large orebody
394.25
400 394.25
0.981
0.25
Drill 100% Small orebody
34.25
-5.5 8.35 40 34.25
0.080 0.290
0.7
Barren
0.5 -5.75
Target defined 0 -5.75
2 A JV is preferred by -0.059
0 9.02 the risk-averse 0.05
0.086 project owners Large orebody
199.75
200 199.75
0.864
0.25
50% JV Small orebody
Detailed Geophysics 19.75
0 9.02 20 19.75
-0.25 4.28 0.086 0.179
0.042 0.7
Barren
-0.25
0 -0.25
-0.003
1 Carry out 0.5
4.28 geophysics in No target
0.042 house and -0.25
drilling under JV 0 -0.25
-0.003

Relinquish
0
0 0
0

FIG 12.8 - Certainty equivalents corresponding to the expected value tree of Figure 12.7.

Australian Mineral Economics 135


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

owners would prefer to farm out 50 per cent equity in the project, consequence the relevant ‘risk-adjusted’ cash flows need only be
now worth a Cx of $9.02 million in exchange for the necessary discounted to present value to account for the ‘time-value of
drilling funds, as the option of funding 100 per cent of the money’ but not for risk. In this light the appropriate discount rate
drilling expenditure is now worth a lower Cx of $8.35 million. is the risk-free rate of interest.
Now consider (Figure 12.9) from the point of view of a party Constructing a decision tree is not difficult. The challenge
potentially interested in farming into the project. The company’s rests with estimating the probability distributions of various
initial reconnaissance will have resolved some risk. Not only is events.
the expected value of $14.75 million desirable (see Figure 12.7), Estimates of probabilities are generally subjective, ie based on
but also its corresponding certainty equivalent (Cx) of $3.77 (see experience and informed advice.
Figure 12.9) million is also attractive. An alternative way of estimating the order of magnitude of
In constructing a decision tree it makes sense to estimate the relevant probabilities is to use frequency distributions derived
duration of various activities and to place them in chronological either from statistically significant experimental trials or more
order in the correct intervals of time. It is also important to often, from statistical analysis of historical time series.
specify in which dollar terms, ie whether nominal or real, are the Lord, Etheridge and Uttley (2003) have applied this latter
various inflows and outflows expressed. approach on Placer Dome’s relatively mature gold exploration
The next logical step in using a decision tree as a project districts in the Laverton area of the Eastern Goldfield of Western
evaluation tool, would be to apply an appropriate discount rate to Australia. The material in Table 12.1, reproduced from their
obtain the expected present value of the project. This process, paper, shows how, by spending $54.6 million over 13 years,
however is froth with complexity for mainly two reasons: Placer generated 290 projects. They conducted systematic
drilling on 26 of these, discovered over ten million ounces of
• firstly, as various actions resolve project uncertainty, in theory gold and established 12 mines.
the risk-and-time adjusted discount rate should decrease as
progression is made from left to right in tune with the Thus in the Laverton district the average chance of discovering
decreasing risk; and 833 333 ounces of gold would have been of the order of:

• secondly, different branches of a decision tree are characterised • 12/156 = 7.7 per cent, given a prospect has been defined; and
by different levels of risk and should, in theory, be discounted at • 12/26 = 46.2 per cent, given that initial exploration has been
different rates. encouraging enough to justify systematic drill testing.
It must be kept in mind that the certainty equivalent values in a The tree of Figure 12.10 shows that, if one were to assume that
decision tree, by definition, have already been ‘discounted’ by the ten million ounces target had a net value of $1 billion, ie
the risk factor inherent in the utility function of the firm. As a using current prices and a total cost of extraction and processing

CERTAINTY EQUIVALENT POINT OF VIEW OF PARTY FARMING IN

0.05
Risk tolerance coefficient RT 100 Event 3
194.5
All $ million 200 194.5
0.857
0.25
Enter 50% JV Event 4
14.5
-5.5 3.77 20 14.5
0.037 0.135
0.7
A risk-averse investor Event 5
1 would consider -5.5
3.77 entering into a 50% JV 0 -5.5
0.037 attractive -0.056541

Reject project
0
0 0
0

FIG 12.9 - The certainty equivalent point of view of the farming-in party.

TABLE 12.1
Historical exploration by Placer Dome in Laverton district (modified after Lord, Etheridge and Uttley, 2003).
Exploration stage Number of prospects Expenditure (A$ M) Average cost/prospect Probability of advancing
1987-99 (A$ M) from previous stage
Project generation 290 2.7 0.01
Prospect definition 156 11.4 0.07 53.79%
Systematic drill testing 26 6 0.23 16.67%
Resource delineation 15 6.9 0.46 57.69%
Feasibility 13 27.6 2.1 86.67%
Mine 12 92.31%

136 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

of A$ 450 per ounce, then, neglecting tax effects, the expected

-54.6
945.4

-20.1

-14.1

-2.7
-27

0
undiscounted value of this exploration campaign would be a
mere $30 million. This value could well turn negative if certainty
equivalents and an appropriate discount rate are applied. This
945.4

-54.6
would lend credence to the contention of Etheridge and Uttley
Uneconomic projects

(2003) that, in recent times, exploration has not created


12 Commercial mines

competitive value for mining companies.


92.31%

7.69%

0
1000.0

The tree also corroborates their view, (on the basis of the
observed frequency distributions that show that 58 per cent of
drilling targets led to resources delineation and that 87 per cent
of these justified feasibility studies resulting in 12 mines), that
868.5

-27

the maximum value is added at the time of the first economically


significant intersection of mineralisation and subsequent
Devepol mines

systematic drilling testing of 26 soundly selected targets, the


-27.6

0
Abandon

expected value of which is A$ 423.7 million.


On this basis they also suggest that ‘drilling investment funds’
that provide major contributors with a right to buy back 50 to 60 per
1

1
Do not justify feasibility
868.5

-27

cent project equity in case of large discoveries, could be an


attractive investment vehicle to major companies for the purpose of
13 Justify feasibility

specifically drill-testing robust targets. It is possible to justify this


86.67%

13.33%
0

FIG 12.10 - Assessing Placer Dome’s historical gold exploration in the Laverton area. view as long as there continues to be a reasonable supply of such
targets from the activities of juniors and middle-size exploration
companies, which majors, equity investors or both might adequately
fund. A progressive disappearance of readily available targets will
Resources delineation

-20.1
749.1

presumably have the effect of increasing the cost of grass-roots


exploration and the value of defined drilling target.
-6.9

0
Abandon

MODERN ASSET PRICING (MAP) USING


COMMODITY FORWARD PRICES
1

1
749.1

-20.1

No-arbitrage and replicating portfolios principles


15 Mineralisation

A fundamental assumption underlying option valuations is that


57.69%

42.31%
0

0
Barren

financial markets are frictionless and display relatively high


levels of efficiency, ie relevant information is rapidly
disseminated and incorporated in the price of assets. Under these
circumstances (Salahor, 1998), assets with similar risk
423.7

-14.1
Systematic drilling

characteristics and producing the same cash flows at the


same times in the future should have the same price.
-6

0
After 13 years and $54.6 M in exploration expenditure Placer discovered 12 deposits containing in excess of 10 million ounces of gold worth A$ 1 billion

Abandon

If this value consistency principle did not apply, then


arbitrageurs would have an opportunity to make a risk-free profit
by buying undervalued assets and selling overvalued ones.
1

Arbitrage opportunities are infrequent and short-lived. This is


423.7

-14.1
26 Drill target identified

known as the no-arbitrage or one-price principle. Thus cash


No drill target

flows can be viewed (Bradley, 1998) as commodities, with


16.67%

83.33%
0

timing and risk as criteria of value.


Furthermore, according to the value additivity principle, the
components of a cash flow model (eg revenue and costs) can be
PLACER'S HISTORICAL GOLD EXPLORATION ACTIVITY IN THE LAVERTON AREA

separately evaluated, appropriately discounted and recombined.


-2.7
58.9
OF THE EASTERN GOLDFIELDS OF WESTERN AUSTRALIA (After Lord, 2003 )

Prospect definition

In this light, as discussed below, the present value of holding a


claim on a future cash flow, irrespective of the underlying assets
0
-11.4

Abandon

from which it is derived, can be simulated by a replicating


portfolio of different investments, as long as they provide the
same present value.
at current prices assuming a A$450/oz. total cost of extraction and processing

Under no-arbitrage conditions Samis (2002) visualises a


No prospects identified
58.9

-2.7
156 Prospects identified

mining project producing a highly price-volatile commodity as a


set of contingent claims on future cash flows providing the same
53.79%

46.21%
0

value as a replicating portfolio2 composed of:

2. In theory, the holder of proven mineral reserves in the ground,


No grassroot exploration
30.4

supported by a strong bankable feasibility study, would not need to


290 Projects generated

develop a physical mine to achieve the same cash flows results. For
commodities such as gold, the prices of which are dominated by
-2.7

contango (ie with futures prices higher than the corresponding spot
prices) a ‘virtual mine’, made up of a series of rolling forward sales
matching the production schedule of the mining plan in the
feasibility study, would have the same cash flow effect. The main
1
30.4

reason why ‘virtual mines’ do not exist is because the fiscal regime,
while tolerating rolling over of forward sales as a legitimate hedging
in tune with future physical production, acts as a disincentive to pure
speculation.

Australian Mineral Economics 137


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

• A series of forward contracts, with quantities and delivery • discounting them for their timing using the risk-free
dates matching the mineral production schedule of the mine. rate of interest.
After all, the present value of a unit of production at various The MAP modelling methodology, which is an elementary
times in the future is exactly replicated by the corresponding form of real option valuation (Salahor, 1998, p 15; Laughton,
forward prices, which incorporate discounting for risk. 1998), is easy to apply and gives good, generally conservative,
• Issuing a series of bonds with principal repayments of a estimates of the value of a project under the assumption that the
magnitude and maturity matching the estimated annual cash bulk of its risk is linked to the volatility of the price of the
outflows related to the emerging capital and operating costs commodity produced. As discussed later, there are other forms of
of the project. This approximation is broadly warranted real option valuations that ‘neutralise’ the volatility not just of
because capital and operating costs can be estimated with a the revenue but of the overall cash flows of a project
higher degree of confidence and can, to some degree, be kept encompassing all other sources of risk besides price risk.
on budget by sound technical and financial management. For some commodities forward prices quotes are readily
available on the London Metal Exchange (LME) for deliveries
up to 27 months in the future. This makes MAP evaluation of
Commodities forward prices as certainty short-lived mining operations very accurate and convenient as
equivalents the following example will illustrate.
Commodities forward sales are a form of ‘certainty In Table 12.2 we will calculate the MAP/NPV of a nickel mine,
equivalents’ because the binding nature of forward contracts with 27 months (nine quarters) remaining productive life by
means that a seller must deliver and a buyer accept delivery of ‘neutralising’ the nickel price risk using forward prices for various
the mineral commodity units contracted for at a price and on a delivery dates as quoted on the LME. On 30 August, 2005, when
delivery date firmly agreed in the present. In other words the the spot price for nickel was US$ 14 950 per tonne, the three, 15
and 27 months deliveries were quoted at US$ 14 850, US$ 13 700
seller will receive the agreed price in cash and with certainty at
and US$ 12 400 per tonne respectively, as shown in Figure 12.12.
the time of delivery. Forward prices take into account and At a conversion factor of 1 kg equal 2.204623 pounds, these
compensate for the potentially high volatility of the spot forward quotes convert to US$ 6.78, US$ 6.21 and US$ 5.62/lb
commodity price in the future and are adjusted for convenience respectively.
yields (ie any possible leasing/dividend cash inflow net of related
storage, insurance and financing costs of holding the commodity FORWARD Ni PRICE CURVES
that accrue to the holder of the physical stock). 30 August 2005 Estimates
As a consequence, one can build models of mining projects $18,000.00
that separate the revenue function from the cost function and by $16,000.00
Ni Price ($US/t)

using forward prices as the relevant price input determine the


$14,000.00
project revenue cash flows with certainty. As the use of secure
forward contract sales removes the main component of risk (ie $12,000.00
the price risk) from the estimate, it would then be inappropriate $10,000.00
to use a risk-and-time-adjusted discount rate to obtain the present
$8,000.00
value of future revenue cash flows. If such an approach, which
obviates the need for risk discounting, is adopted, then the only $6,000.00
discount to be applied is the risk-free rate to compensate only 0 2 4 6 8
for the time-value of future cash flows. Time (years)
Sophisticated project modelling and evaluation methodologies,
such as: Expected spot price ($/unit) Forward price ($/unit)
• modern asset pricing (MAP), and Lower 10% confidence Upper 10% confidence
• real options valuation (ROV), Average LME Forward Quote Calibration
discussed below, instead of using a single time and risk-adjusted
discount rate entail (see Figure 12.11) a two-step process of: FIG 12.12 - Projected spot and forward nickel price curves as of
• determining certainty equivalents for the undiscounted 30 August 2005.
cash flows through various forms of risk neutralisation;
and then Lets further assume that the mine produces two million pounds
of payable nickel per quarter at a cash cost of US(Year 0)$3.00/lb
under a turn-key mining and processing contract with unit costs
rising in line with the inflation rate estimated at three per cent
per annum. The company has committed its full production
forward with sales in quarters 1, 5 and 9. Undepreciated capital
assets with a fiscal written down value of US$ 10 million can be
depreciated on a straight line over the nine quarters. Nickel
royalties are 2.5 per cent and corporate tax is 30 per cent. The
nominal risk-free rate of interest is 5.68 per cent per annum.
As the model is built on quarterly periods, care must be
exercised to make sure that relevant inputs are also on a
quarterly basis. So the quarterly rate of inflation becomes
[(1 + 3 per cent)0.25] - 1 = 0.74 per cent and the nominal
quarterly risk-free rate of interest 1.39 per cent.
From Table 12.3 it can be seen that, under the assumptions, the
MAP/NPV of this project, subject to discounting by the risk-free
rate because of elimination of the price risk through the use of
FIG 12.11 - Differences between discounting in DCF analysis and forwards prices and of operational risk through the turn-key
in real options valuations (after Dias, 2002). mining contract, is $24.37 million.

138 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

TABLE 12.2
Comparison between the DCF/NPV and MAP/NPV of an operating nickel mine.
MAP MODEL – Time (quarters) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Sales (lb*million) 2.00 8.00 8.00
Forward price (US$/lb) 6.78 6.21 5.62
Total revenue (US$ million) 13.56 49.71 45.00
Less royalty at 2.5% 0.34 1.24 1.12
Unit cost of production (US$/lb) 3.02 3.11 3.21
Total cost of production (US$ million) 6.04 24.90 25.65
Depreciation 1.11 4.44 4.44
Profit after 30% tax 4.25 13.39 9.64
Net cash flow 5.36 17.83 14.09
Risk-free discount factor 0.9863 0.9333 0.8832
MAP discounted CFs (US$ million) 5.29 16.64 12.44
MAP/NPV (US$ million) 24.37
DCF MODEL – Time (quarters) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
Sales (lb*million) 2.00 8.00 8.00
Expected spot price (US$/lb) 6.75 6.54 6.25
Total revenue (US$ million) 13.51 52.35 50.00
Less royalty at 2.5% 0.34 1.31 1.25
Unit cost of production (US$/lb) 3.02 3.11 3.21
Total cost of production (US$ million) 6.04 24.90 25.65
Depreciation 1.11 4.44 4.44
Profit after 30% tax 4.21 15.19 13.06
Net cash flow 5.32 19.63 17.50
Risk-and-time-adjusted discount rate per quarter (%) 3.57%
Risk-and-time-adjusted discount (RTAD) pa (%) 15.07% Risk-premium 9.39%
Risk-and-time-adjusted discount factor 0.9655 0.8390 0.7291
Discounted CFs 5.14 16.47 12.76
DCF/NPV (US$ million) 24.37

TABLE 12.3 of a risk-free interest component of 5.68 per cent and of a


risk-premium of 9.39 per cent. If a further assumuption is made
Calculation of the real option value of Sally Malay using the
Black and Scholes formula. that the market portfolio premium inherent in it were the
medium-term average of 6.5 per cent, then it is possible to
C = Value of real option (ROV) (A$ million) 21.33 conclude that the company holding this project has a β of around
d1 0.8578 1.4; not an unlikely result for a small mining company.
d2 -0.1040 Of course in practice most companies do not attempt to carry
out MAP evaluation of their projects to derive an appropriate
S = Spot price = PV of net after-tax operating cash flows 43.94 discount rate (even though it would be wise to do so), but use
(A$ M)
discount rates determined by directorial policy which may or
X = Exercise price = PV of capital investments (A$ M) 53 may not relate to the firm’s WACC. In general if a firm selects a
t = Time to expiry (years) 11 discount rate lower than that implicit in a MAP valuation, it
σ = Cash flow volatility 0.29 would discount less its operating and maintenance costs and tend
to favour, equal being the revenue inflows, more capital intensive
δ = Convenience yield 0
solutions and vice versa.
Risk-free interest percentage 0.05
For operations with longer mine lives, analysts must forecast
ENPV = Enhanced NPV = NPV + ROV (A$ million) 12.27 forward commodity prices beyond the longest available delivery
quotation available on the LME (ie 27 months) using stochastic
The corresponding conventional DCF model can now be (probabilistic) models of their market behaviour. Under normal
constructed by estimating (as discussed below) and inputting the market conditions, prices generally distribute log-normally and
expected spot prices for quarters 1, 5 and 9 (ie US$ 6.75, US$ 6.54 follow a geometric Brownian motion (GBM) around a mean
and US$ 6.25/lb respectively) instead of the LME forward prices trend or drift. GBM means that in any interval of time, prices
quotes. An approximate nominal rate of risk-and-time adjusted will never be negative and can either go up or down
discount can initially be input and then by iteration (using the randomly as a function of their volatility.
Excel goalseek function) the risk and time adjusted discount rate Furthermore, following any unusual price-shock, the prices of
can be determined, which gives a DCF/NPV of $34.37 million, ie most mineral commodities (see the nickel example in Figure
the same as that obtained in the fully hedged MAP model. This 12.12) gradually revert to their mean trend or drift because
nominal risk-and-time adjusted discount rate is, in this example, market forces react by bringing new supplies into production in
15.07 per cent. Recalling the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) the case of significant price increases, or reduce supplies for falls
discussed in Chapter 9, it is clear that this discount rate is made up in price.

Australian Mineral Economics 139


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

Figure 12.12 was constructed using the standard GBM for options, in that they create opportunities but no obligations to
continuous spot price changes (dS) including reversion to the invest. Yet many of these projects continue to be under-funded
mean and error factors, ie: and often unwisely rejected. Even worse, projects involving new,
untested technology may sometimes be commissioned without
adequate piloting in the hope of shortening their lead times and
dS = [α * +0.5 σ 2 − γ ln( S / S*)]S dt + σ S dz lowering their overall capital cost. This frequently leads to
disastrous results.
where: This type of error occurs because investors do not fully
recognise and value management flexibility to keep their future
α* is short-term growth rate of the price median options open to progressively learn and adjust their actions as a
S is current spot price project unfolds, depending on emerging circumstances and
information dispelling uncertainty.
S* is current long-term price median Consider the following example of this fallacious logic,
σ is short-term price volatility adapted from Copeland and Keenan (1998). Assume an
opportunity to invest in a $100 million project that has:
γ is ln(2)/half-life = reversion factor
• a 50 per cent chance of success of realising a present value of
z is standard random variable $150 million in future net after-tax operating cash flows; and
If a very high half-life value is input in the γ formula, then the • a 50 per cent chance of failing, such that only $10 million
value of γ tends to zero and the GBM algorithm can be used to would be salvaged.
forecast the behaviour of the price of non-reverting commodities
such as gold. The gold price non-reverting behaviour, which is As the expected monetary value (EMV) is negative:
more akin to that of financial securities rather than that of other
mineral commodities, represents a notable exception, which can EMV = 50% * ($150 M - $100 M) + 50% * ($10 M - $100 M)
be explained by the quasi-monetary role played by gold in the = -$20 M
financial system.
More details about this price forecast model can be found in
DCF-logic would lead to rejecting this project.
articles by Baker, Mayfield and Parsons (1998), Salahor (1998),
and Samis (2002), who deal with its various mathematical Now assume that the company can build and test a pilot plant
components and derivation. for $10 million. If the pilot plant were effective in resolving an
adequate level of project uncertainty then the EMV of the project
would become positive. At the limit, if the pilot plant were to
FROM STATIC DCF/NPV TO DYNAMIC REAL dispel all the uncertainty the EMV would become:
OPTION VALUATIONS (ROV)
EMV = 50% * ($150 M - $110 M) + 50% * ($0 - $10 M)
A different logic = $15 M
For resources projects:
• with healthy NPVs, low volatility in their cash flows; and Real-option logic would lead to the decision of investing in
• where management has limited flexibility, ie the opportunity the pilot plant. If it is successful, then the company should
invest in the project. If not, it can abandon the investment at a
to change their course of action during operations in light of
relatively low cost and with no regret of having missed out on a
emerging circumstances,
potentially lucrative investment opportunity.
DCF analysis will continue to provide the dominant investment DCF/NPV analysis is deterministic and static. It assumes that
decision-making criteria. an investment is irreversible and it compares investing ‘now or
Interestingly, lack of managerial flexibility in the presence of never’ (Dixit and Pindyck, 1995). In DCF models there are no
high volatility is indeed what differentiates a bet (ie put your inherent or planned contingencies to delay development, expand
money down and wait for the outcome) (Copeland and Keenan, or contract production rates. In reality, and irrespective of
1998), from an investment in a project capable of offering a whether the decision to invest was taken on the basis of
range of strategic options. DCF/NPV criteria, projects evolve according to unfolding
However, many projects may feature low or even negative circumstances that often require unexpected and costly changes.
NPV because analysts have discounted them at excessively high At least this is the case unless possible future eventualities were
rates to compensate for high volatility in their cash flows. Much already anticipated and incorporated in the project plan to soften
of this CF volatility typically comes from high volatility in the the effect of uncontrollable chance events.
price of the commodities they produce (price risk) and of other
uncertain inputs. Types of real options in mining projects
Yet such projects can be very valuable if their inherent Most real options in the context of the mining industry entail the
characteristics or their design provides management flexibility managerial flexibility to undertake actions such as:
to take advantage of up-swings (eg rising prices) and avoid or
minimise the effect of downswings. If for a period of time the 1. delay mine development and learn;
decision-makers have the right but not the obligation to 2. embark in a pilot project and learn;
proceed with the initial or successive investment phases in a
project only if conditions prove favourable, the project is said to 3. commence development and production on a staged basis,
offer real option value (ROV) and the project volatility can be learn and, if warranted alter the rate of production, by
the source of significant value. exploiting grade-tonnages trade-offs, ie:
As the words imply real options (RO) have to do with real a. expand to include lower grade resources into reserves, or
assets such as exploration and mining projects, rather than the b. contract by high-grading the reserves;
financial assets, which underpin traded derivatives.
4. suspend or recommence production temporarily; or
Mineral and petroleum exploration, research and development
and, pilot studies, for instance, have the characteristics of real 5. abandon a project altogether.

140 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

The first three (up to 3a) are call options; while 3b and 5 by To illustrate the point we will use the example of Sally Malay
contrast are more akin to put options, conferring the right but not Mining Ltd, which in 2001 was a prospective nickel mining
the obligation to ‘sell’ the project to generate savings or avoid company holding sub-economic nickel resources in the Kimberley
future potential losses (S), for a predetermined price (X) (eg care region of Western Australia. Soon after its Initial Public Offering
and maintenance, abandonment, severance and rehabilitation (IPO) in September 2001, when the price of nickel was around
costs) at or before a predetermined time (t). The fourth option, US$ 5000/tonne, the company had a market capitalisation of
known as a switching option, is a combination of call if around A$ 12.2 million. This value arose in part because:
recommencing production and put if suspending it.
Depending on the nature of the project it is possible to • The project was based on a commodity (ie nickel) with high
distinguish between: price volatility. (London Metal Exchange price data show the
volatility of the nickel price to be between 20 and 25
• Single options, when there is only one possible decision or per cent).
the alternative is delaying investment at each node.
• Additionally, there was still, under prevailing mining
• Multiple and chooser options (Mun, 2002), when at any tenements rules, a reasonable length of time before the
node there is more than one possible decision as opposed to company had to make a decision to develop the mine or risk
delaying the investment. In the case of the chooser option the that the relevant mining leases would not be extended by the
alternative decisions are mutually exclusive. government for a further 21-years term. During this period
• Sequential/compound options, when there is a series of the company was in a position to delay the investment in
decision nodes in chronological order (eg exploration project mine development at the relatively low cost of simply
stages), where each successive decision may or may not be keeping the mining tenements in valid legal standing.
conditional or compound on a previous one. Interested investors also hoped that during this time of
It is therefore possible to view most projects as a series of real potentially rising nickel prices, further drilling might lead to
options to defer and learn, commence, expand, contract or extensions to existing reserves and conversion of previously
suspend production or finally abandon the project, the value of uneconomic indicated resources into additional ore reserves.
which is not captured by the traditional static NPV. This can be If the nickel price current in September 2001 (ie US$ 5000/t)
modelled as a tree-like structure of sequential possible future were to be input in a deterministic DCF model of this mining
scenarios with probability nodes representing ‘states of nature’,
deposit, containing 3.4 million tonnes of diluted mining reserves at
not under management control. The branches that emanate from
a grade of 2.32 per cent nickel equivalent, its resulting net present
each node, in turn lead to distinct groups of possible future
scenarios. Each branch represents a possible action, which value would have been very low or even negative. For instance,
managers may decide to undertake ‘with the wisdom of assuming capital costs of A$ 53 million (including A$ 7 million in
hindsight’ to optimise the returns from the project, depending on working capital), cash operating and maintenance and concentrate
emerging circumstances and the arrival of new information over transport costs of A$ 3.00 per pound of sellable nickel in
time resolving uncertainty at each successive node. concentrate, average recoveries, smelter returns and exchange
By waiting for new information before selecting a course of rates, a modest salvage value, etc would have resulted in a
action, managers can learn and make dynamic decisions on the negative NPV of the order of -$9.0 million using a real discount of
basis of the ‘bad and good news principle’, ie participate in six per cent and allowing for inflation averaging three per cent.
positive outcomes and avoid negative ones. This, however, would have been a rigid, irreversible view of
the project future and its value, equivalent to being committed to
The market has been effective at setting real start and operate the project for five years through possible good
option values – considering the case of Sally and bad times, irrespective of what happened to the price of
Malay nickel. It implied no merit in holding the project and no capacity,
once the decision to develop was taken, to avoid or at least
If we could assume that new information is quickly disseminated mitigate the likely adverse impact of potential future price falls.
in the market place and incorporated in prices (ie if opportunities
However, there was a widespread perception that an economic
for arbitrage were few and short-lived), an objectively assessed
NPV of a project should also closely match its fair market value recovery was just around the corner. The price of nickel was at
(Lawrence, 2001). Yet examination of actual mining project historically low levels and it was likely to rise strongly. When
transactions often shows significant differences (generally a these expectations were incorporated into discounted cash flow
premium) between their stock market and their fundamental models, they produced healthier net present values, justifying the
(DCF/NPV) valuations. decision by investors to purchase Sally Malay Mining’s Ltd
Lawrence (2001) attributes this difference to the widespread shares and its market capitalisation of A$ 12.2 million. The idea
international use of reporting guidelines that encourage of relinquishing the tenements would have been preposterous
valuations primarily based on proven and probable reserves (as even at the end of 1999 when nickel prices stood at a mere
categorised in the Australasian Joint Ore Reserves Committee’s US$ 3600 per tonne. Indeed the previous owner, Helix Resources
JORC code, 2004). This approach, he argues, disregards the NL, sold it to the current owners around that time for a
potential contribution to revenue from more uncertain and lower significant cash consideration.
grade resources categories and tends to underestimate the The static NPV completely disregarded the fact that the
potential project value in fundamental DCF calculations. company had the flexibility to delay development until the
Irrespective of the categories of resources used, if one follows nickel price conditions indicated that the project would add
strict JORC logic to the limit, any company holding tenements rather than consume value. There are in theory no negative NPV
over a marginal deposit with a negative NPV at current scenarios when one has the option to delay investment because,
commodity prices would be justified in relinquishing them. As a at worst, the value of the project is zero (or close to it if there are
consequence, the value of the company shares should fall to zero costs in keeping the option open as for instance retention leases
in the absence of other significant assets in its portfolio. fees). This is a dynamic view of the project future and the basis
The stock market, however, has traditionally placed a value on to value its inherent managerial flexibility to only develop if high
option creation, particularly by non-dividend-paying mineral and nickel prices eventuate. As will become clearer later, this value,
petroleum exploration companies. Until recently quantitative which is not captured by conventional DCF/NPV, can be very
methodologies to measure this value have been lacking. significant.

Australian Mineral Economics 141


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

Prior to dramatic increases in nickel prices in late 2003, the T is time to exercise in years
situation at Sally Malay had all the characteristics of an
out-of-the-money American call option, conferring the right but r is risk-free rate of interest annual percentage expressed as
not the obligation at the discretion of its owners: decimal
• to defer or proceed with a A$ 53 million capital investment N(d) is cumulative standard normal distribution density function
in development of the project and sustaining capital, which is with upper integral limit d
analogous to the exercise (or strike) price (X) of this option;
δ is convenience yield (dividend) in percentage per annum
• to develop at any time on or before the expiry date of the expressed as decimal
mining leases in 11 years, which is analogous to the term (t) In addition to the assumptions already discussed, the volatility
of the option; and of the cash flows of this project was estimated to be 29 per cent,
• to derive a net benefit equal to the present value of all future much of which was represented by the volatility of nickel prices
net after-tax operating cash flows amounting to A$ 43.94 and the rest by a variety of other uncertain project inputs. Another
million, which is analogous to the spot price of the underlying necessary input was the risk-free rate of interest (RF), which was
asset (S). estimated at five per cent, ie at a premium of 0.25 per cent above
the 4.75 per cent RBA cash rate prevailing at the time.
Naturally development can proceed only if S-X is positive;
otherwise it is preferable to defer it. This means that the option On this basis, the real option value (ROV) of this project was
value of the project can only be positive ie the maximum assessed at $21.33 million, as shown in Table 12.3.
between S-X and zero. The net present asset value (NPAV) or expanded net present
As the price of nickel increased to around US$ 7000 per tonne value (ENPV) (Mun, 2002, p 168) of the project/company,
by the end of 2002 on its climb to US$ 16 000 per tonne by the assuming no other significant assets in its portfolio at that time, is
end of 2003, the option got well ‘in the money’ and it warranted then the sum of its NPV and ROV, ie:
being exercised. That is, it became profitable to develop the Sally ENPV = NPV + ROV = -$9.06 million + $21.33 million =
Malay mine. $12.27 million
The NPV of the project had improved from marginal at 2001
prices to between A$ 51 to A$ 58 million by the middle of 2003 This figure is remarkably close to the company’s market
using realistic nickel prices of US$ 6500 and US$ 7000 per capitalisation at the time, ie around A$ 12.2 million, but very
tonne, at a nominal discount rate of 7.5 per cent. sensitive to the estimates of the various inputs particularly the
difficult-to-compute volatility of project net after-tax operating
The company’s market capitalisation, of around A$ 115
cash flows.
million in March, 2004, reflected:
In addition, it must be borne in mind that the B-S formula was
• the project sensitivity to continued increases in nickel prices specifically devised to value financial derivatives and not real
late in 2003; options and is based on a range of assumptions some of which
• the positive market sentiment about the exploration potential may be too restrictive and unrealistic in the context of real options.
in the areas surrounding the mine at these price levels; and For instance the lack of continuous direct frictionless trading
• tempered by the hedging effect of forward sales. and market valuations of mining project underlying a real option,
falls a lot shorter than its financial securities counterparts, where a
It also reflected, the realisation that nickel prices had stabilised lot of the necessary metrics can be easily derived from market
and an expectation that they would start to progressively fall, records. Mining projects, by contrast are, infrequently traded and
reverting to their long-term mean, as indicated by the London their underlying value for the purpose of ROV modelling can only
Metal Exchange forward contracts and futures quotes. be assumed, according to Copeland and Antikarov (2003, p 94), to
be their DCF/NPV at an appropriate risk-and-time adjusted rate of
Estimating the real option value of the Sally discount. This assumption is known as the ‘marketed asset
Malay project in September 2001 disclaimer’ or MAD.
The volatility of returns from a mining project cannot, as it is
The only way to capture investors’ expectations at the time of the case with financial securities, be simply generated from the
Sally Malay’s initial public offering in 2001, which justified a ASX statistics and may require complex forecasts and Monte
$12.2 million capitalisation for this company, well in excess of Carlo simulations.
its deterministic NPV of -$9.07 million, would have been by
Furthermore the B-S formula also implies that option values are
estimating its real option value (ROV).
always positive, thus not helping where there are abandonment
Determination of this ROV was easy in this case because of costs in mining projects. The assumption of constant volatility and
the call nature of the real option inherent in this project, which risk-free interest, exercise at expiry, etc inherent in the Black and
lent itself to be handled effectively using a close-form equation, Scholes formula also make determination of real option values
namely the Black and Scholes (B-S) formula (Peirson, Brown, using this type of closed-form equation unreliable other than in the
Easton and Howard, 2002, p 633): most simplified option models such as in the case of the Sally
Malay delaying option, where it provides a reasonable order of
Price of call = C = SN(d1) – X e-rT N(d2) magnitude ROV.
In many cases where real options have more complex multiple,
where: sequential and compound structures use of the B-S formula with
d1 = (ln(S/X) + (r – δ + σ2/2) T) / (σT0.5) its limitations and constraints may become infeasible, then more
complex but more versatile methods, such as the binomial
d2 = d1 - (σT0.5) lattice method, will need to be used instead.

USING BINOMIAL LATTICES IN VALUING REAL


S is spot price
OPTIONS IN PRACTICE
X is exercise price
While price volatility is the predominant source of volatility in
σ is standard deviation of the logarithm of stock returns the cash flows of many mining projects, it is not the only source
percentage expressed as decimals of uncertainty. A significant degree of uncertainty may be

142 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

attributable to other revenue input components, to which the • the relatively friendly ‘risk-free probability’ method,
performance of the project is highly sensitive. These include
uncertainty surrounding the estimates of: • the ‘state prices’ method, and
• grade and tonnages of ore reserves; • the somewhat less friendly ‘replicating portfolio’ method.
• metallurgical recovery (taking into account its correlation Binary systems with two possible, mutually exclusive
with grades); and outcomes of the type success or failure (or up or down) generally
adhere to the discrete binomial probability distribution, which
• exchange rates between the Australian and United States explains its importance in option analysis. In discrete binomial
dollars (making allowance for a degree of correlation systems:
between US$-denominated prices and the Australian dollar
given its so-called ‘commodities currency’ characteristics; • success means the price will rise in any unit of time by a
and so on. factor (1 + σ), where σ is the measure of volatility per unit of
time (T in years); while
While it is mathematically possible through complex
stochastic calculus and partial differential equations to build • failure means that the price will fall by a factor of 1/(1 + σ).
specific project models that take into account and combine the If a smaller (at the limit infinitesimal) time interval is selected
volatility of the various project inputs, as their number increases (∆t = T/n, where T is the time to expiry and n is the number of
the construction of a realistic mathematical model for application time subdivisions), the discrete binomial distribution lattice tends
in MAP or to generate a closed-form equation becomes very hard to become finer-grained, continuous and exponential with:
to handle in practice.
A more friendly way to construct a real option model of a up factor: Up = exp(σ*∆t 0.5); and
project is by using the volatility of its future net after-tax cash
flows, rather than the individual volatilities of various inputs. down factor: Down = 1/UF = exp(-σ*∆t 0.5).
After all, the volatility of the project cash flows is a complexly
‘weighted’ function of the volatility of all the project inputs.
Mun (2002) shows that these exponential formulae provide a
Such an approach provides more accurate results, as long as
reasonable approximation of the corresponding discrete binomial
one is able to estimate the cash flow volatility (σ) with some distribution even when the time intervals are reasonably coarse.
degree of confidence. Methods to estimate volatility, as described For this reason he recommends the binomial lattice as the most
in Copeland and Antikarov (2003, pp 244-269) and Mun (2002, practical way of modelling real options.
pp 197- 202), can be problematic at times and probably represent
Of the three ways of neutralising risk, he also recommends the
the greatest challenges in carrying out real option valuations.
‘risk-free probability (p)’ approach as the most practical and
They include:
versatile. Its formula is:
• the logarithmic present value approach;
• the management assumption approach; and p = [exp((r-b)*∆t) – Down] / (Up – Down)
• the market proxy approach, where the project under
consideration is similar to those of a number of companies where r is the risk-free rate of interest, and b represents any
traded on the stock exchange.
continuous dividend payout, if applicable, expressed as decimals.
The logarithmic present value method entails: An alternative to ‘risk-free probabilities’ is to use ‘state
1. determining the function X = ln[(PV at t=1 of Σ t=1 to n net prices’. A ‘state asset’ is a claim that pays a future cash flow of
operating CFs)/ PV at t=0 of Σ t=0 to n net operating CFs)]; then $1 if a particular state of nature occurs, with no loss if the desired
state of nature does not eventuate. A ‘state price’ is the amount
2. running a Monte Carlo simulation on the numerator only an investor would be prepared to pay today for a state asset. It is
to define the volatility (σ) of X, which in fact is the
in effect the risk- and time-discounted value of $1 to be received
volatility of the project cash flows.
if the relevant state of nature eventuates, with no alternative loss.
All these methods require the use of sophisticated risk-analysis Benninga (2000, pp 253-273) describes this method and its
simulation software. relationship to a ‘replicating portfolio’ and the Black and Scholes
The alternative of carrying out dynamic optimisation formula, in easily understandable terms.
techniques based on simulation, while appropriate for some Each of these methods seeks to ‘neutralise’ risk by analysing
specific applications, has generally proved to be somewhat and mathematically manipulating the individual risk characteristics
impractical when modelling mining projects.
of each project/investment opportunity. Proof of the
By contrast, once the cash flow volatility of a project has been risk-neutralisation capacity of these techniques is beyond the scope
estimated, it becomes possible to make use not only of of this chapter. Benninga (2000) provides a simple introduction to
established closed-form equations (of which the B-S formula is a the concept of replicating portfolio and state prices, while Copeland
well-known example) but also of the more versatile and friendly and Antikarov (2003) discuss ‘risk-neutral’ probabilities. Mun
binomial lattice methods. (2002) identifies a number of distinct steps in the process of
Ito’s Lemma states that a dependent variable (such as the determining the ROV of a project. These are essentially:
revenue cash flows of a project), which is a function of a
1. constructing a static DCF base case model of the project;
stochastic process (eg commodity prices) is itself a stochastic
process. As a consequence, the NPV of a project can also either 2. carrying out a Monte Carlo simulation of its outputs (eg its
go up or down over an interval of time along a path determined expected NPV and volatility of net, after-tax, operating
by its mean and volatility which in turn are a function of the cash flows) to be used as inputs in the real option valuation;
combined volatility of the price of the commodity produced and 3. identifying and modelling the real option(s);
of all other significant uncertain variables.
Mun (2002) describes several possible real option valuation 4. applying an appropriate real option valuation method and
optimising choices/decisions; and
approaches based on the binomial lattice (and related trinomial
and multinomial) methods including: 5. reporting and communicating the results effectively.

Australian Mineral Economics 143


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

VALUING AN EXPANSION OPTION WITH THE This represents a potential 60 per cent expansion, which would
BINOMIAL LATTICE METHOD USING THE increase the NPV by a factor of 1.6 minus the acquisition
(exercise) price of $40 million. The option is at present not ‘in
‘RISK-FREE PROBABILITY’ the money’ because, if exercised, the value of the expanded
The binomial lattice with ‘risk-free probabilities’ is the simplest enterprise would be 1.6 * $60 million minus $40 million ie
and most versatile next step in overcoming complexity and $56 million which is less than the NPV of not expanding the mill
achieving greater realism. This will be illustrated by valuing an currently worth $60 million.
expansion option. Given the high volatility and long time to its expiry, this does
Consider a gold custom mill with an annual capacity of one not mean that the option is worthless. To the contrary both the
million tonnes of ore and a static NPV of $60 million. Following buyer and the writer of the option need to determine how much
Mun (2002, p 198), the volatility of the logarithmic returns on its the option may be worth as a basis for negotiations.
future cash flows is estimated using a Monte Carlo simulation to This classical expansion option lends itself to being solved by
be 35 per cent. applying the ‘risk-free probability’ to the relevant binomial
The owners of the mill have been successful in attracting ore lattice of the asset.
to their facility and they envisage that within the next few years it Firstly, one must calculate the:
may be possible to significantly increase the current volumes of • up factor Up = exp(σ*∆t 0.5) = 1.419;
ore treated. As a consequence they are seriously considering
expanding their capacity.
• down factor Down = exp(-σ*∆t 0.5) = 0.705; and
They have now become aware that a mine in the region is • ‘risk-free probability’ p = [exp((r-b)*∆t) – Down] / (Up –
approaching exhaustion and that its owners would be agreeable Down) = 0.515.
to sell their mill with a 0.6 million tonnes annual capacity at any Then one must construct, as in Table 12.4, the binomial lattice
time during the next five years for $40 million, and if necessary displaying the effect of various combinations of ups and downs
letting the acquirer treat their remaining ore on a custom basis. on the NPV of the underlying asset.

TABLE 12.4
Expansion option evaluated using a binomial lattice with the risk-free probability method.

Expansion option binomial lattice


Asset value ($) 60 Stepping-time (dt) 1
Implementation cost ($) 40 Up-step size (up) 1.419
Maturity (years) 5 Down-step size (down) 0.705
Risk-free rate (%) 7.00% Risk-neutral probability (p) 0.515
Dividend (%) 0.00% Continuous time discount factor 0.932394
Volatility (%) 35.00%
Lattice steps 5
Expansion factor 60.00%
Time 0 1 2 3 4 5
Possible outcomes
Certain u 2u 3u 4u 5u
d du d2u d3u d4u
2d 2du 2d2u 2d3u
3d 3du 3d2u
4d 4du
5d
Value of possible outcomes
60.0 85.1 120.8 171.5 243.3 345.3
42.3 60.0 85.1 120.8 171.5
29.8 42.3 60.0 85.1
21.0 29.8 42.3
14.8 21.0
10.4
Expanded NPV including option value
63.0 101.4 158.3 239.6 352.0 512.4 Expand
31.7 56.0 95.8 156.0 234.3 Expand
10.6 22.2 46.2 96.2 Expand
0.0 0.0 0.0 End
0.0 0.0 End
0.0 End

144 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

An option valuation lattice is then constructed as shown in


Table 12.4, by first determining in column 5 under which
combinations of ups and downs it would be optimal to expand.
For instance, expansion is warranted in the case of five ups, four
ups and one down and three ups and two downs, because 1.6
times the relevant value of the underlying asset at $60 million
less the implementation cost of $40 million is greater than the
value of not expanding, ie:
1.6 * 345.28 – 40 = 512.44 > 345.28
similarly for 234.33 versus 171.46 and 96.23 versus 85.14. From
two up three down to five down the value of expanding is lower
than continuing with the single mill and the expansion option is
consequently let to expire.
The next step is to roll back the values in the option valuation
lattice from right to left starting from the step 5 column. For
instance 352.0 in step 4 is obtained by applying the ‘risk-free’ FIG 12.13 - Multiple (chooser) real options due to grade-tonnage
probability (p) to 512.4 and (1-p) to 234.3 and then by trade-offs in mining (after Samis, 2002).
discounting by one year as follows:
(512.44 * 0.515 + 234.33 * (1 – 0.515)) * exp(- 0.07 * 10.5) = 352.00 prices continue to rise the project becomes increasingly more
profitable until when prices exceed B, it is financially justifiable
where: to mine ‘run-of-the-mill’ grade ore. When prices rise above C an
exp(- r * square root of (∆t)) = exp (- 0.07 * 10.5) = 0.93239 is the expansion of production to the low-grade ore is optimal.
continuous time discount factor at a rate of seven per cent per Let us consider the options open to the manager of a mining
annum, ie for ∆t = 1 operation worth $100 million, which is currently producing
As each pair of figures in each column is rolled back to the left ‘run-of-the-mill’ ore. Further assume that for five years,
in a similar manner, the combined value (or expanded net present depending on the direction and severity of commodity prices
value (ENPV)) of $63.0 million is easily obtained. The difference changes, he or she can:
between the ENPV at $63.0 million and the basic NPV of the
project prior to expansion (ie $60 million), amounting to $3 1. continue to mine ‘run-of-the-mill’ ore requiring no capital
million, is the real option value (ROV) of a possible, currently investment;
uneconomic, 60 per cent mill capacity expansion. 2. expand production by 30 per cent by mining lower grade
This type of lattice can be done relatively simply using a ore at a capital cost of $20 million;
personal computer spreadsheet as shown in Table 12.4, but more
3. contract production by ten per cent by mining high-grade
complex options may require specialised software which also
current ore reserves at a saving of $25 million; or
allows the construction of more accurate, multi-step lattices with
greater granularity (Mun, 2002, p 154). 4. abandon production and sell the project for $85 million.
Table 12.5 shows that this chooser option would add $17.3
VALUING TONNAGE-GRADE TRADE-OFFS million to the $100 million static NPV of this project even at a
modest level of 15 per cent volatility in the cash flows of the
Analysts are often required to capture the option value of projects
project and at a risk-free rate of interest of five per cent.
with significant potential grade-tonnages trade-offs. Traditional
JORC code-based DCF/NPV valuations, including only proven The process in Figure 12.13 is the same as that used in the
and probable ‘run-of-the-mill’ reserves, generally do not recognise previous expansion model as far as the lattice of values of
possible outcomes is concerned, but uses a different
managerial flexibility and the price leverage inherent in these
maximisation rule to determine the end members of the lattice of
reserves and in the surrounding halo of lower grade resources. option values, ie:
They, therefore grossly undervalue such projects.
A number of sophisticated models to assess the optimal timing Max (continue, expand, contract, abandon)
for expansion, contraction and abandonment of mining projects Thus, the expansion option is the most valuable outcome in the
as a function of commodity prices have been developed case of five successive up states of nature, as it is higher than the
following the paper by Brennan and Schwartz (1985). These value of the underlying asset under the same states of nature but
include, among others, modelling the price, cost and reserves without expansion, ie:
uncertainty of a generic copper mine by Cortazar and Casassus
(1998) and by Poulin, Samis and Laughton (2001) and of the [(value of underlying asset if five ups occur) * (1 + expansion
East Rand gold mine by Samis (1995). factor)] - implementation cost = (($211.7 M * (1 + 30 per cent)) -
$20 M) = $255.2 M is higher than
Figure 12.13, which has been adapted from Samis (2002),
displays the possible payoffs for the options inherent in a mining (present value of project in year 0) * (up factor compound over
project with a small core of high-grade reserves, within a large five years) = $100 M * exp(σ * T 0.5) 5 = $211.7 M
volume of ‘run-of-the-mill’ ore, adjacent to a significant As a matter of fact the value of the expansion option under
low-grade resource. Grade-tannages trade-offs give rise to what these states of nature is higher than any of the other options open
is known as a multiple or chooser option (Mun, 2002, p 181), as to the investor. The option value lattice of Figure 12.13 shows the
the investor can choose among more than one possible course of expansion option has the maximum value even if there are four
actions at any one time. ups and one down (ie $183.9 million) or three ups and two downs
At a commodity price below A the project is subeconomic and (ie $131.0 million), after which the contract option produces the
development would be delayed or if the mine is currently maximum value (ie $102.5 million). In the case of one up and
operating it should close. If prices rise above A it becomes four downs and five down, the course of action that maximises
justifiable to develop the project to mine the high-grade core. As value is to sell the project for $85 million.

Australian Mineral Economics 145


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

TABLE 12.5
Estimating the value of a miner’s chooser option to expand, contract or abandon production.
Chooser option binomial lattice
Continue Expand Contract Abandon
Change in NPV 0.00% 30.00% -10.00% -100.00%
Asset value ($) 100 Stepping time (dt) 1
Implementation cost ($) 0 20 -25 -85 Up-step size (up) 1.162
Maturity (years) 5 Down-step size (down) 0.861
Risk-free rate (%) 5.00% Risk-neutral probability (p) 0.633
Dividend (%) 0.00%
Volatility (%) 15.00%
Lattice steps 5
Time 0 1 2 3 4 5
Possible outcomes
Certain u 2u 3u 4u 5u
d du d2u d3u d4u
2d 2du 2d2u 2d3u
3d 3du 3d2u
4d 4du
5d
Value of possible outcomes
100.0 116.2 135.0 156.8 182.2 211.7
86.1 100.0 116.2 135.0 156.8
74.1 86.1 100.0 116.2
63.8 74.1 86.1
54.9 63.8
47.2
Expanded NPV including option value
117.3 136.1 158.7 185.8 217.9 255.2 Expand
101.2 116.1 134.2 156.5 183.9 Expand
89.8 100.9 114.7 131.0 Expand
83.2 91.4 102.5 Contract
80.9 85.0 Abandon
85.0 Abandon

The roll back process then involves the progressive application A discussion on how to overcome the conceptual complexity and
of risk-free probability and continuous discounting for timing as computational difficulty in recognising and modelling such
in the expansion option of Table 12.4. switching options is, however, well beyond the scope of this paper.
This chooser option value of $117.3 M - $100 M = $17.3 M is
not the equivalent to the sum of the individual single options to
expand, contract or/and abandon, but is derived as a chooser EVALUATING THE SEQUENTIAL AND
option combination of the three. COMPOUND REAL OPTION VALUE OF
This model as well as option models previously discussed, MINERAL EXPLORATION FARM-IN/
however, would determine a fair project value while the option is OPTIONS AGREEMENTS
open, they do not imply that the project maintains this value at
any stage after any of the multiple options is exercised. For A real option is said to be:
instance if the expansion option were exercised after price • compound when its value is contingent on two interacting
increases, then the mine owner would only have the option to optional decisions with the same expiry term; and
regress to mining ‘run-of-mill’ ore or abandon. This chooser
option would have a vastly different value. A higher level of • sequential and compound when there is a series of
complexity is also created by the fact that, in real life, all of these chronologically sequential decision (eg project stages) where
options should also be reversible and that management generally each decision is conditional on a previous one.
has the flexibility of placing from time to time the mine on care Sequential/compound options are typical of multi-stage
and maintenance when price falls make it uneconomic to operate. projects, where progress to successive stages is dependent on the
This type of option is addressed in Slade’s (2001) model of all outcome of preceding ones. For example, mining entails:
the Canadian copper mines operating between 1980 and 1993,
which includes a facility, albeit mathematically complex, to value
• mineral exploration;
the option of implementing temporary suspension and resumption • if exploration is successful, then resources delineation and
of production in response to changes in commodity prices. feasibility studies follow, otherwise the project is relinquished;

146 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

TABLE 12.6
Evaluation of the sequential/compound option inherent in a mineral exploration farm-in agreement.

Binomial lattice using the risk-free probability method


Sequential two-stages three- and one-year options
Three-year option 2
Asset value ($) 5 Stepping-time (dt) 1
Implementation cost (X2) ($ M) 7 Up-step size (up) 1.492
Maturity T2 (years) 3 Down-step size (down) 0.670
Risk-free rate (%) 7.00% Risk-neutral probability (p) 0.490
Dividend (%) 0.00%
Volatility (%) 40.00%
Lattice steps for option 2 3.00
Time 0 Step 1 Step 2 Step 3
Value of possible outcomes for underlying asset
5.0 7.5 11.1 16.6
3.4 5.0 7.5
2.2 3.4
1.5
Option 2 value disregarding option 1
1.0 2.2 4.6 9.6
0.1 0.2 0.5
0.0 0.0
0.0
One-year option 1
Implementation cost (X1) ($ M) 0.56 Option 1
Maturity T1 (years) 1 Option 2
Lattice steps for option 1 1.00
First year values of option 2 are used as underlying assets for option 1, which are then rolled back to their present
value ROV
Sequential/compound ROV 0.7 1.6 4.6 9.6
0.0 0.2 0.5
0.0 0.0
0.0
Decisions
Open Invest in 1 Open Invest in 2
Do not invest Open Invest in 2
Do not invest Do not invest
Do not invest

• if feasibility is demonstrated then construction and • by funding statutory exploration commitments amounting to
development of the mine can take place, otherwise the $30 000 it can carry out surficial exploration and shallow
project is mothballed; and RAB drilling for one year;
• only if all the above is realised will the mine progress to the • at the end of year 1, by paying $0.5 million and guaranteeing
production stage. funding of statutory expenditure commitments for the next
At the conclusion of each successive phase of an exploration two years, it acquires the right but not the obligation to drill
test the project over the following two years; and
program, for instance, explorers have the option but not the
obligation to: • at the end of year 3 the company can acquire 100 per cent equity
in the project by paying $7 M or walk away with no penalty.
• progress to the next stage;
The project is the only asset held by a junior company, which
• defer further exploration if they can hang onto the is debt-free, has little cash in the bank and is capitalised at $5 M.
exploration license at low cost; It has been estimated that the average volatility of return on
• farm-out part of the project to an interested potential joint holding stock of similar single-project, junior exploration
venture participant; or companies under foreseeable market conditions is 40 per cent.
• abandon the project. Following an example provided by Mun (2002, p 191) we can
generate the lattice of possible asset values and the option value
Lets consider the example of an exploration company, which is lattices for the two component options as shown in Table 12.6.
offered the following farm-in option: For instance, the capitalisation of the company holding the

Australian Mineral Economics 147


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

project, and therefore the value of the project, could range While the ROV methodology is generally complex and
between $16.6 million if the up state is realised three times in relevant skills scarce or proprietary at this stage, the cost of
succession and $1.5 million if the down state occurs in three carrying out a ROV evaluation model is relatively low compared
successive years. The applicable risk-free rate is seven per cent. to significant leverage in terms of value added.
The binomial lattice for the longest-term component option It is also fallacious to consider that ROV is the exclusive realm
must first be constructed, ie the three-year’s term, 100 per cent of financial analysts. Value is added primarily by the recognition
acquisition stage, as if exploration had been successful justifying of potential real options in a project, which by and large depends
final exercise of this option. The value of this simple call option on good geological, mining engineering and metallurgical
would be $1.0 million as shown in Table 12.6. analytical skills.
We then need to superimposed on it the shorter-term (one year) Furthermore, there is initially no need to construct an
component option, ie the option to drill test the project taking into extraordinarily complex model, as an initial indication of whether
account its implementation cost at the end of year 1 of $0.5 M there could be ROV and of its order of magnitude may be obtained
payment plus $60 000 in statutory expenditure commitments. The with a simplified model provided its structure is sound.
underlying asset values for option 1 are the values in the year 1
column of option 2. These are rolled back to their present value Finally, even in the development of new mineral resources, a
ROV as usual using the risk-free probability and continuous degree of knowledge of ROV methodology on the side of design
discount factor. engineers will lead to more flexible and therefore more robust
From Table 12.6 it can be seen that the combined present value designs, capable of better withstanding some of the hard times
of the sequential/compound mineral exploration farm-in option is that inevitably any mining operation will cross over its life.
$0.7 million. The model allows for the sensitivity of this ROV The strategic advantage of mastering ROV will, in the opinion
value to be tested in different combinations of option payments of the author, soon be better recognised by shrewd operators in
and volatilities of returns and can thus assist in conducting better the mining industry in shaping both their acquisitive and
informed negotiations. divestment strategies.
The model could also be easily modified to evaluate a joint A further significant challenge in real option evaluations
venture farm-in by changing its current 100 per cent equity frequently arises from the resistance on the side of management
acquisition to any desired lower proportion of equity in the project. to accept the result of ROV analyses if they do not have a degree
of familiarity with this methodology. In absence of some
STRATEGIC ROV CONSIDERATIONS understanding it becomes very difficult for the analyst to explain
the methodology and to communicate the results in simple
Recognising and correctly estimating the value of real options
language often under severe time constraints. It seems likely that
has significant strategic value. Analysts in the petroleum industry
communication problems may have been the main cause for the
have been the first to recognise and take advantage of these
relatively slow rate of acceptance up to date of this otherwise
powerful techniques.
powerful and more realistic way of valuing mining projects.
Lesley and Michaels (1997) for instance describe how British Much can and should be done to demystify the subject and
Petroleum (BP) made significant use of ROV when carrying out increase understanding and acceptance. It is hoped that this paper
a rationalisation of its North Sea oil tenements at times of may facilitate this process.
relatively low oil prices. Their real option valuations militated
against relinquishing a number licenses which were subeconomic
at the time but which, with the wisdom of hindsight, proved to be CONCLUSIONS
very valuable.
In summary, it can be concluded that:
Smith and McCardle (1999) and Claeys and Walkup (1999)
suggest ways to recognise option values in oil projects, while 1. Discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis will continue to
Faiz (2001) discusses possible approaches to integrate ROV in provide valid decision-making criteria if a project has low
the strategic planning and optimisation strategy of a large expected cash flow volatility and low management
integrated oil company. flexibility.
In the last few years precious metals analysts have made 2. Investment decisions based on risk-neutral maximisation of
systematic use of real option valuations to explain the equity expected monetary values (EMV) are unrealistic in most
premium on the share price of gold and platinum-group circumstances and greater awareness and use should be
metal-producing companies (Morgan, 2005; Dinham, 2005). made of risk-averse investment criteria based on expected
Of particular interest is the recent application by Flores (2004) preference values or certainty equivalents (Cx).
of binomial lattices and risk-free probabilities to estimate the
value of gold exploration projects. 3. DCF analysis may introduce bias and at times severe
Asides from brokers, there have been relatively few published distortion, particularly when valuing financially marginal
practical applications of ROV to the mineral exploration and projects based on very price-volatile commodities. The
mining industry in spite of the appearance of several academic reasons for this are manyfold and include the application of
papers on the subject. This may not mean that such studies and a single risk- and time-adjusted discount rate:
applications are not carried out in the industrial arena, but may a. to compare projects with inherently very different risk
just be the reflection of the highly proprietary and confidential characteristics; and
nature of these studies.
b. simultaneously to the revenue of a project, which is
As the saying goes ‘mines are not found, they are made’. generally subject to considerable price risk beyond
Many successful mines have been developed on the ashes of management control, and to its less risky and more
previous unsuccessful attempts. The main challenge is in controllable cost function.
recognising the real options inherent in a project that current
owners have failed to spot. 4. Deterministic DCF analysis does not capture the value of
Invariably the price expectations in the mind of the frustrated managerial flexibility to adjust their decisions and actions as
and risk-averse owners of projects, which are sub-economic at new information progressively dispels uncertainty during the
current prices, tend to be low. This generates realistic unfolding of the project. Managerial flexibility has all the
opportunities for acquisition and value adding through more characteristics of a real option to take actions beneficial to
creative and flexible design, application of emerging technology the firm with the wisdom of hindsight and avoid negative
and innovative financing. outcomes.

148 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 12: MINERAL PROJECT EVALUATION — DEALING WITH UNCERTAINTY AND RISK

5. Methods for the valuation of financial derivatives can be JORC, 2004. Australasian Code for Reporting of Mineral Resources and
Ore Reserves (The JORC Code), The Joint Ore Reserves Committee
effectively adapted to the valuation of ‘real options’ of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy, Australian
inherent or deliberately planned in risky resources projects. Institute of Geoscientists and Minerals Council of Australia. [Online].
6. A deterministic DCF/NPV model of the project (asset) Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/codes/jorc0105.pdf>. Date
accessed: 8 May 2006.
underlying a real option can be used to circumvent the lack
Laughton, D G, 1998. The potential for use of the modern asset pricing
of frequent trading in the project and to derive the volatility methods for upstream petroleum project evaluation: introductory
of its cash flows as the main inputs necessary to build a real remarks, The Energy Journal, 19(1):1-11.
option model of the project. Lawrence, R D, 2001. Should discounted cash flow projections for the
7. Of the various methods to value real options, the use of determination of fair market value be based solely on proven and
probable reserves? Mining Engineering, 53(4):51-56.
binomial lattices whether solved using ‘risk-free’
probabilities or ‘state prices’ is generally the most friendly Lesley, K J and Michaels, M P, 1997. The real power of real options, The
McKinsey Quarterly, 3:4-24.
and versatile approach. A binomial lattice model bypasses
Lord, D, Etheridge, M and Uttley, P, 2003. Risk and value in mineral
many of the unrealistic assumptions and limitations exploration – Case studies on the application of risk analysis,
inherent in the use of closed-form equations (eg Black and presented at Risk Analysis and Management in Mineral Exploration
Scholes formula) to derive a project ROV as well as the and Development Seminar, November (The Australian Institute of
mathematical complexity of stochastic calculus and/or Geoscientists: Perth).
partial-differential-equation-based models. Morgan, J P, 2005. South African gold and platinum sector update,
African Equity Research, 10 May 2005.
8. Communicating in simple language and in a persuasive
Mun, J, 2002. Real Options Analysis: Tools and Techniques for Valuing
manner the methodology and results of a ROV analysis to Strategic Investments and Decisions (John Wiley: Hoboken).
unfamiliar decision-makers is a major challenge and Peirson, G, Brown, R, Easton, S and Howard, P, 2002. Business Finance,
probably one of the main causes of the relatively slow rate of eighth edition (McGraw-Hill Irwin: New York).
penetration and acceptance of this analytical tool in everyday Poulin, R, Samis, M R and Laughton, D G, 2001. Valuing a multi-zone
practice in the mineral exploration and mining sector. mine as a real asset portfolio: a modern asset pricing (real option)
approach, Corporate Finance Abstracts: Valuation, Capital Budgeting
and Investment Policy Working Paper Series, pp 4-29.
REFERENCES
Salahor, G, 1998. Implications of output price risk and operating leverage
Baker, M P, Mayfield, E S and Parson, J E, 1998. Alternative models of for the evaluation of petroleum development projects, The Energy
uncertain commodity prices for use with modern asset pricing Journal, 19(1):13-46.
methods, The Energy Journal, 19(1):115-148. Samis, M R, 1995. An option pricing analysis of the 1990 capital structure
Benninga, S Z, 2000. Financial Modelling, second edition (The MIT of the East Rand proprietary mine, in Proceedings CAMI 95 – Third
Press: Cambridge). Canadian Conference on Computer Applications in the Mineral
Bradley, P G, 1998. On the use of MAP for comparing alternative royalty Industry, (ed: H S Mitri) (McGill University Press: Montreal).
systems for petroleum development projects, The Energy Journal, Samis, M R, 2002. Resources sector finance 602, 2002 course notes
19(1):47-82. (Western Australian School of Mines: Kalgoorlie).
Brennan, M and Schwartz, E, 1985. Evaluating natural resources Schodde, R, 2005. Personal communication.
investment, Journal of Business, 58(2):135-157. Slade, M E, 2001. Valuing managerial flexibility: an application of real
Burn, R G, 1984. Exploration risk, CIM Bulletin, October, pp 55-61. option theory to mining investments, Journal of Environmental
Claeys, J and Walkup, G, 1999. Discovering real options in oilfields Economics and Management, 41:193-233.
exploration and development, in Proceedings SPE Hydrocarbon Smith, J and McCardle, K, 1999. Options in the real world: lessons learned
Economics and Evaluation Symposium (Society of Petroleum in evaluating oil and gas investments, Operations Research, 47:1-15.
Engineers: Dallas). VALMIN, 2005. Code for the Technical Assessment and Valuation of
Copeland, T and Antikarov, V, 2003. Real Options (Texere LLC: New York). Mineral and Petroleum Assets and Securities for Independent Expert
Copeland, T and Keenan, P T, 1998. How much is flexibility worth? The Reports (The VALMIN Code), The VALMIN Committee, a joint
McKinsey Quarterly, 2:38-49. committee of The Australasian Institute of Mining and Metallurgy,
Cortazar, G and Casassus, J, 1998. Optimal timing of a mine expansion: the Australian Institute of Geoscientists and the Mineral Industry
Implementing a real option model, The Quarterly Review of Consultants Association (The Australasian Institute of Mining and
Economics and Finance, 38:755-769. Metallurgy). [Online]. Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/
codes/valmin_2005.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Dias, M A G, 2002. Stochastic processes with focus in petroleum
applications [online]. Available from: <http://www.puc-rio.br/marco.
ind/stochast.html>. Date accessed 8 May 2006. FURTHER READING
Dinham, N, 2005. Platinum sector: new valuation method, Andisa Amram, M and Kulatilaka, N, 1999. Real Options: Managing Strategic
Securities, 22 April 2005. Investment in an Uncertain World (Harvard Business Press: Boston).
Dixit, A K and Pindyck, R S, 1995. The options approach to capital Guj, P, 2004. Resources sector finance 602, 2004 course notes (Western
investment, Harvard Business Review, 73(3):105-115. Australian School of Mines: Kalgoorlie).
Etheridge, M and Uttley, P, 2003. Uncertainty, decision-making and value Jacoby, H and Laughton, D, 1992. Project evaluation: a practical asset
measurement – The fundamentals of the business of exploration, pricing method, The Energy Journal, 13:19-47.
presented at Risk Analysis and Management in Mineral Exploration
and Development Seminar, November (The Australian Institute of Laughton, D G, 1998. The management of flexibility in the upstream
Geoscientists: Perth). petroleum industry, The Energy Journal, 19(1):83-114.
Faiz, S, 2001. Real-options application: from successes in asset valuation Luehrman, T A, 1998a. Investment opportunities as real options: getting
to challenges for an enterprisewide approach, Journal of Petroleum started on the numbers, Harvard Business Review, July-August.
Technology, 53(1):42-47. Available from: <http://www.spe.org/ Luehrman, T A, 1998b. Strategy as a portfolio of real options, Harvard
elibinfo/eJournal_Papers/spe/2001/JPT/01/00068243/00068243.htm> Business Review, September-October.
Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Samis, M R, 2000. Multi-zone mine valuation using modern asset pricing
Flores, V, 2004. Standing on a gold mine? HSBC Global Research, (real options) techniques, unpublished PhD dissertation, University
Precious Metals, December 2004. of British Columbia.
Hayward, N, 2003. Risk behaviours and intuition traps, presented at Risk Samis, M R and Davis, G A, 2004. Actively recognising cash flow
Analysis and Management in Mineral Exploration and Development uncertainty within the net present value calculation, MEMS Newsletter,
Seminar, November (The Australian Institute of Geoscientists: Perth). 31, winter.

Australian Mineral Economics 149


CHAPTER 13

Mineral Policy — An Introduction


Philip Maxwell and Pietro Guj

The Aims and Practice of Economic Policy


The Context of Mineral Policy
Mineral Policy in Practice
The Transition of Mineral Policy since 1950

THE AIMS AND PRACTICE OF ECONOMIC It is not possible to produce above (to the right of) the
POLICY production possibility curve, given the limited factors of
production available and the current state of technology.
From the viewpoint of policymakers and citizens more generally, In this simple view of the world, a series of community
the most desirable state of society is a situation where there is indifference curves can also be drawn that show different
maximum economic and social wellbeing. combinations of goods and services corresponding to the same
Randall (1987, p 132) describes this as: level of welfare1. As we move from CIC1 to CIC2 to CIC3 the level
A condition in which society is as well off as it of consumer welfare is increasing. Society will strive to reach the
can possibly be, given its resource base, its highest community indifference curve, with its current production
productive technology and the tastes and possibility curve. This is achieved at the point E where the
preferences of its members. production possibility curve just touches (is tangential to) CIC2.
The role of government in society is to seek to ensure that
It is possible to describe this in a very simple static welfare society reaches this point and stays there over time.
economics framework in terms of the production possibility/
The real world differs in complexity and detail from this simple
community indifference curve diagram shown in Figure 13.1.
static world. In countries with capitalist economic systems such as
Recall that the production possibility curve shows different
Australia, government operates in a dynamic and uncertain
maximum combinations of goods and services that society can
environment seeking to balance production, distribution and
produce if all factors of production are fully employed during a
sustainability. Following Waud et al (1996, pp 65-78), we note that
given period. With less than full employment of all factors of
government performs four main functions:
production, society will operate below the curve.
1. managing a legal and institutional structure in which
markets operate;
Goods Community
indifference 2. intervening in the allocation of resources in areas where
curves public policy deems it beneficial to do so;
3. seeking to provide stability in economic conditions; and
4. redistributing income and wealth.
E
CIC3 The three levels of government in Australia – federal, state and
local – share these roles.
CIC2 While it is instructive to discuss these functions in little further
Production detail at this point, the authors of the following two chapters
possibility CIC1 focus on the first two areas as they relate particularly to
curve Australia’s minerals and energy sector.
In Australia, government manages the legal and regulatory
structure in which markets operate in a variety of ways. Its
Services
various branches are responsible for areas such as:

FIG 13.1 - Maximising society wellbeing.


• trade practices legislation,
• environmental protection legislation,
1. These curves implicitly assume a given distribution of income. • marketing schemes and subsidies for primary producers,

Australian Mineral Economics 153


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

• tax concessions and development restraints in mining, • fiscal policy (varying and directing government expenditure,
• tariff and quota protection in manufacturing, and raising and lowering taxes);
• legislation regulating the operation of the financial sector, • monetary policy (setting interest rates);
• legislation regulating mining operations, • exchange rate policy (setting exchange rates at fixed rates
relative to other currencies or letting them float);
• ensuring occupational and community health and safety
standard, • tariff policy (using a range of policies to facilitate or restrain
international trade);
and the list goes on.
• wages policy (setting minimum wages); and
It allocates resources through its spending activities, its tax
policies, and its own production of certain goods and services. • environmental policy (setting emission standards for
The first two of these areas – spending and taxation – are the key factories to discharge wastes into the air, nearby landfills,
elements of fiscal policy. The third involves operating public rivers and the sea, establishing and maintaining wilderness
enterprises in ‘natural monopoly’ situations. In Australia this has areas and rules about land use).
traditionally covered areas such as provision of water, gas, It is also common to see a national or state government’s
electricity, postal services, telecommunications and even policy stance described in terms of a set of policy tool settings
financial institutions. In recent decades there has been a major applied to particular industry sectors. Hence reference to
movement towards commercialisation and privatisation of these agricultural policy, mineral policy, manufacturing policy,
areas. Government is also a major provider of education and transport policy, communications policy, health policy, education
health services. policy, tourism policy and so on, can be seen. These policies,
Governments seek to provide stability in economic which are sometimes described formally in published
conditions in areas such as prices, employment, economic documents, typically reflect economic, social and political views.
growth, external viability and economic conditions generally.
It is convenient to think of policy settings in a matrix format in
Sound economic management, which inspires confidence in the
which some or all of the elements of a government’s policy tools
economy by the private sector and the outside world, is necessary
are applied to influence the performance of different industry
to achieve this outcome.
sectors. The checked boxes in the simple matrix in Table 13.1
Finally, government pursues objectives of social equity and provide one classification of how some policy tools directly
redistributes income and wealth. In developed nations such as affect particular sectors.
Australia, this occurs largely through applying progressive rates
of income tax and wealth-related taxes, and using the social Any nation’s or region’s mineral policy should in general
security system to provide age and disability pensions, child terms be concerned with the rational development of mineral and
endowment, unemployment benefit payments and in areas such energy resources to achieve the broad economic goals of
as support for single parents and needy students undertaking government and society.
post-secondary education. It also takes place through the This policy involves a combination of fiscal, exchange rate,
preferential tax treatment of the superannuation system, which tariff, wages, specific occupational health and safety, and
requires workers to save for their retirement years. environmental policies. The typical list of economic goals includes
Any government’s current policy stance will reflect its efforts high (or full) employment, price stability, sustainable economic
to achieve maximum economic and social wellbeing, given the growth over time, external stability, a clean and safe environment,
political ideologies of its constituency. For example, a Labor an equitable distribution of income, an equitable taxation system,
party government at Federal or State level in Australia will economic security and economic freedom. Some of the key fiscal
typically seek an equitable distribution of income and wealth aspects of a mineral policy relate to the application of mineral
entailing greater equality as a higher priority than a conservative taxes and royalties, which will be examined more closely in
government. Its policy settings will seek to achieve this outcome. Chapter 14.
It is instructive also to recall Garnaut’s five key characteristics
THE CONTEXT OF MINERAL POLICY of mines2 (Garnaut, 1995) mentioned previously in Chapter 1.
These are that:
Governments use a range of policy instruments (tools) to achieve
their objectives. The typical list includes: 1. they can generate economic rent;
2. they are often established most efficiently on a very large scale;
3. their development is often highly capital intensive;
2. It has been assumed that mines also include oil and gas wells in the
context of this discussion. This view is consistent with the definition 4. they have unusually large local environmental, social and
of mining used by the Australian Bureau of Statistics (2005, p 493). economic impacts; and

TABLE 13.1
The application of economic policy instruments in industry sector policies.
Policy instruments
Fiscal Monetary Exchange rate Tariff Wage Environmental
Agricultural x x x x x
Mineral x x x x x
Manufacturing x x x x
Health x x
Education x x
Housing x x x
Tourism x x x x

154 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

5. their national economic impact varies greatly over gross product of a nation or region in a short time period. But
relatively short periods of time. their closure will also dramatically reduce local incomes unless
there is a sustainable alternative economy in place.
The concept of mineral rent was introduced in Chapter 3 and
In the late 1980s for example, new mineral developments
Frank Harman and Pietro Guj discuss the concept in considerable
seemed to have the potential to more than triple the Gross
detail in Chapter 15. It is useful to briefly review the meaning of
Domestic Product of Papua New Guinea within five years. This
the concept again at this point. Economic rent is the payment that
did not happen, in part because of the sudden closure of the large
any resource receives in excess of its supply price where there is
Panguna copper mine in the middle of 1989 when a civil war
a market equilibrium. Mineral rents are one type of economic
erupted. In combination with relatively wide movements in the
rent.
price of gold and copper, there has been considerable uncertainty
As was seen in Chapter 3, Garnaut and Clunies Ross (1983) and difficulty in managing the Papua New Guinea economy over
provide the following definition: the past 15 years.
Mineral rent may be defined as the returns in
excess of those needed to attract factors of MINERAL POLICY IN PRACTICE
production into the mining industry in the long
run. It is the revenue remaining after all costs As just noted, any nation’s or region’s mineral policy should be
have been deducted. These costs include concerned with the rational development of mineral and energy
exploration outlays, expenditures on mine resources to achieve the broad economic goals of government. In
establishment and cash operating costs. Unlike Chapters 2 and 3 the soundness of such development was
the accountant’s notion of costs, economic costs discussed, while giving consideration to the recent debate about
include the returns on capital invested which are whether resources are a blessing or a curse. Notwithstanding the
just sufficient to attract the capital to the position one takes in this debate, it is likely that the citizens of
enterprise. any nation or region, that possesses a significant mineral
endowment, will wish to extract that endowment in the cause of
It could be argued that government can, in principle, tax rent national development.
away without reducing economic output. It is therefore an
In seeking to do this effectively, policymakers are operating in
attractive source of potential public revenue in any mineral rich
a competitive environment where they aim to maximise the net
economy. But as Garnaut (1995) also notes, stakeholders who
have veto power over mine (and oil well) development, also have present value of all future benefits derived from mining (Tilton,
the ability or potential ability to access economic rent. 2004, p 147). This will typically involve objectives such as job
Furthermore such rent: creation, regional development and sustaining the viability of the
mining industry over time by encouraging exploration for new
can be dissipated by uncertainty as conflict deposits. It is unlikely to coincide with maximising the rent
between holders of the veto power raises the extracted.
supply prices of inputs into production. Determining the optimal proportion of the rents appropriate to
Garnaut’s second and third points relate to the large scale and achieve optimality is not an easy task. Any mineral policy
capital intensity of the modern formal mining sector. Many new position will depend on the collective view of government about
mining ventures, often in remote areas, involve investments of the relative desirability and efficiency of the private and public
hundreds of millions or even billions of dollars. Western sectors. It will also depend on where government places a
Australian nickel mining ventures such as Murrin Murrin, Mount ‘ring-fence’ in terms of the social and economic impact of its
Keith and Ravensthorpe, and the poly-metallic Olympic Dam policies. This issue relates to the ways in which the benefits
mine in South Australia are good examples of large-scale, should be shared by the nation, regions and local communities
capital-intensive mines. There are many other such mines around directly affected by the mine or oil or gas well, as well as on time
the world. They include copper mines such as Escondida and preferences in terms of inter-generational equity.
Collahuasi in Chile, the Yanacocha gold mine in Peru, the Ekati While an optimal allocation of resources within a geographic
and Diavik diamond mines and the Voisey’s Bay nickel mine in area ensures economic efficiency, ie for those sectors of the
Arctic Canada, the Grasberg copper/gold mine in Indonesia and economy that given a certain level of income generate the
the Porgera gold mine in Papua New Guinea. These are large, greatest output of goods and services that society demands, it
long-life mines in which the capital investment per employed does not necessarily ensure economic equity. With change there
worker is very high. will always be differential impacts on various sectors of society,
The environmental, social and economic impacts in local in other words winners and losers. This generates political
areas near to a new mine, or in the surrounding state or region, tension and, because governments wish to be re-elected, in
can be dramatic, although the extent of these impacts has practice economic policy change is seldom if ever optimal but
recently been affected significantly by the continued growth of seeks second-best solutions. Government economic policy is
fly-in, fly-out work practices3. They are particular dramatic when generally influenced by the Pareto optimality principle that
they disrupt the lifestyles and livelihoods of residents of the reallocation of resources should only proceed if at least one
mining area, particularly if these people have a long traditional sector is better off while none is worse off. More frequently the
association with the local area. Attention by large mining Kaldor-Hicks criterion applies whereby if some sectors are worse
companies to world-class environmental practice, even in poor off, then re-allocation of resources should only proceed if the
developing nations, is now a major issue, as is the pursuit of overall benefit from it is large enough for the negatively affected
sustainability strategies to assist local populations once a mine parties to be compensated so they are not disadvantaged, while
has closed. still achieving an aggregate level of societal benefit which is
The volatility of national and regional impacts over higher than if re-allocation had not taken place.
relatively short periods is also an important issue. This is The objectives of private companies will never completely
particularly the case for developing nations, or even smaller coincide with the aims of government. The former must serve the
regions or states in developed nations such as Australia or needs of shareholders, their financial backers and their workforce
Canada. New mining ventures will significantly increase the while the latter represents the interests of the broader
community. One way of perceiving this is in terms of Figure
3. These impacts are also discussed in Chapter 8 and Chapter 18. 13.2. The extent of overlap between company and community

Australian Mineral Economics 155


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

Government Mining/Exploration companies TABLE 13.2


Company rankings of investment criteria for mineral exploration
Optimisation of Maximising shareholder
and mine investment stage (out of a choice of 60 possible criteria).
community benefits benefits Source: derived from survey conducted by Otto (1992), reproduced
in Otto (2005).
Ranking Decision criteria based on
Exploration Mining
Trade Common Trade stage stage
offs ground offs
1 na Geological potential for target mineral
na 3 Measure of profitability
2 1 Security of tenure
Economic, social Market 3 2 Ability to repatriate profits
& political forces forces 4 9 Consistency and constancy of mineral policies
5 7 Company has management control
6 11 Mineral ownership
FIG 13.2 - The coincidence and divergence of public and private
strategic objectives. 7 6 Realistic foreign exchange regulations
8 4 Stability of exploration/mining terms
goals is likely to be greater if large numbers of shareholders live 9 5 Ability to predetermine tax liability
in the area in which a mining company has its operations. Yet,
10 8 Ability to predetermine environmental
where this does not occur, professional managers will recognise obligations
the necessity of being ‘good corporate citizens’ to maintain their
‘licence to operate’ within the region, the nation and even 11 10 Stability of fiscal regime
globally over extended periods. 12 12 Ability to raise external financing
There is, of course the option for governments to choose to 13 16 Long-term national stability
develop mineral resources themselves. In this way there could 14 17 Established mineral titles system
be, at least in theory, a complete correspondence between
15 na Ability to apply geological assessment
company and government objectives. The difficulty with this
techniques
strategy is that such public enterprises are usually less efficient
and effective than those that are privately owned. While this may 16 13 Method and level of tax levies
be due in part to political influences, governments in developing 17 15 Import-export policies
nations often do not have access to sufficient investment funds 18 18 Majority equity ownership held by
for new resource developments. It is no surprise, therefore, that company
there has been a recent trend have been towards privatisation of
19 21 Right to transfer ownership
government trading enterprises.
The challenge for any nation, state or region is to develop a 20 20 Internal (armed) conflicts
policy structure that attracts investment and also ensures that its 21 14 Permitted external accounts
policy objectives are achieved. This requires a clearly understood 22 19 Modern mineral legislation
regulatory framework, which may be underpinned by a formal
mineral policy document4. While specific mining legislation is na: not applicable
an important part of this, a variety of other laws relating to land, Note: decision criteria appearing in bold typeface may be controlled or
taxation, imports and exports, water, foreign investment, foreign influenced by government actions or inactions.
exchange, labour practices, occupational health and safety and
the environment also play a key role. Organisations such as the Vancouver-based Fraser Institute
The settings of any mineral policy, and its role in assisting the annually rank mining regions and nations on the attractiveness of
achievement of major economic and social goals, will depend their mineral policy and mineral endowment for exploration
significantly on the richness of a country’s, or region’s, mineral investment. In their 2004-05 survey of 1121 companies – Fraser
endowment. When the quality of mineral reserves is high, a Institute (2005) – they reviewed the attractiveness of 64
government may be more demanding in its dealings with jurisdictions. The coverage of their study and the relative
companies, whose potential profits will also be high. rankings of the Australian states appear in Table 13.3.
It is important also to appreciate the views of mining and While the rankings of the Australian states and the Northern
exploration companies. In a study for the United Nations, Otto Territory ranged between ten and 25 for mineral policy
(1992) conducted a survey of 39 large and small mining attractiveness, their overall mineral potential (which takes
companies to determine the importance of various investment account of the attractiveness of policy and geological
endowment) in the minds of company decision-makers was
criteria to them in the mineral exploration and mine development
higher, with three Australian jurisdictions – Western Australia,
phases. His findings are reproduced in Table 13.25. Of particular
the Northern Territory and Tasmania ranking in the top ten.
note is his assessment that 17 of the 22 factors (those marked in
bold typeface) on the list are ‘controlled or influenced by
government actions or inactions’. A nation’s mineral policy
THE TRANSITION OF MINERAL POLICY
settings clearly are important in assisting its competitiveness as a SINCE 1950
destination for new mineral sector investment. There have been several notable trends over the past 40 years in
the structure of the world mineral industry. In the immediate post
World War II period much of the mining of metals in the
4. See Otto (1997) on the importance of national mineral policies and
developing world stood in private hands. The public sector, was,
associated policy documents.
however, responsible for all mining in the socialist world and
5. This table is taken directly from Otto (in press). Other studies have there were significant public ownership positions in the mineral
generated similar rankings of factors. industries of several European nations. Many coal mines in

156 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

TABLE 13.3 Governments in developing nations became major mineral


The relative attractiveness of mineral policy and mineral potential. producers during the 1960s and 1970s. By the early 1980s
(Source: Fraser Institute, 2005.) state-owned mineral producers accounted for one third of overall
capacity in the developing world. According to Radetzki (1990),
Jurisdictions this was an increase from 2.5 per cent in the 1960s.
Area Jurisdictions Descriptions Mines and mineral processing facilities became part of a
Canada 12 Twelve provinces and territories broader development arm of government. More importantly,
United States 14 Fourteen states
state-owned mining companies became principal sources of
revenue for development projects. Their activities often
Australia 7 Six states and the Northern subsidised other sectors but this often had unfortunate
Territory longer-term consequences for the resources sector.
Oceania 4 Indonesia, New Zealand, Papua In his study for Resources for the Future, Radetzki (1985)
New Guinea and the Philippines argued that, despite some initial dislocation following
Africa 9 Botswana, Burkina Faso, DR nationalisation, the performance of state-owned mining
Congo, Ghana, Mali, South Africa, companies would then improve. After ten or 15 years, while their
Tanzania, Zambia, Zimbabwe efficiency would be still slightly inferior to that in private
Latin America 8 Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, companies, the benefits from state ownership to the entire
Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, Venezuela community would more than compensate for this. A simple view
Eurasia 10 China, Finland, India, Ireland, of the Radetzki vision appears in Figure 13.3. One might argue
Kazakhstan, Mongolia, Russia, that the success of state owned mining enterprises such as
Spain, Sweden, Turkey Codelco in Chile, Outokumpu in Finland, MMC in Malaysia,
Total 64 LKAB in Sweden and Pechiney in France provides examples to
support this view.
Rankings of Australian regions Yet because of falling mineral prices, poor management and
State or Territory Policy potential Mineral potential
underinvestment, state operation of mineral enterprises was
unsuccessful in many nations with large mineral endowments.
New South Wales 19 13 This appears to have been particularly the case in nations such as
Northern Territory 25 8 Zambia, Bolivia, Jamaica, Peru and Papua New Guinea. The
Queensland 18 11 ‘Caribbean model’ outlined by Auty (1993) seems more in line
with these experiences (see Figure 13.4). Despite large mineral
South Australia 15 18 endowments, the economic performance of these nations has
Tasmania 10 6 been disappointing.
Victoria 23 23
Efficiency
Western Australia 12 4

countries such as Britain and Australia were also publicly owned.


The motivations for such ownership, as Radetzki (1990, pp 132 -
133) notes, arose from factors such as:
• ‘the widespread perception of mineral wealth as a national
patrimony’;
• the relative ease of exploiting mineral resources because of
the immobility of deposits;
• the existence of high rents, which would have been more Pre Post nationalisation
difficult to appropriate using the fiscal system (taxes, royalties
etc) where they were privately owned or operated; and
• the perceived strategic importance of a national mineral industry. Time
The post-1960 surge in public ownership FIG 13.3 - State ownership and mining company efficiency –
the Radetzki view.
During the 1960s and 1970s there was a movement towards
widespread public ownership of mineral production, Efficiency
particularly among newly independent nations. The logic behind
this was that it enhanced political independence and that it would
facilitate development. The success of OPEC in raising prices of
oil in 1973 and 1979, as well as the sense of impending scarcity
created by the Limits to Growth thesis strengthened the appeal of
resource nationalism in many countries during the 1970s. This
was even apparent to some extent in Australia during the years of
the Whitlam Federal Labor government.
These sentiments were accompanied, during the cold war, by
the perceived need to secure supply of strategic minerals and the
establishment of significant strategic stockpiles. Pre Post nationalisation
The modes and extent of resource nationalism varied from
country to country. In some it included restricted foreign
ownership, as well as restraints on dividend remittance and profit Time
repatriation. In others there was a complete government takeover
of mines. Some governments took direct equity ‘free carry’ FIG 13.4 - State ownership and mining company efficiency –
positions in mines and mining companies. the Auty ‘Caribbean model’.

Australian Mineral Economics 157


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

Furthermore political instability, sovereign risk and the fear of dominated by a small number of large transnational mining
nationalisation by foreign companies resulted in major companies (oligopolies). Their market power is counteracted in
disinvestment from new African nations particularly but more several places by oligopsony (a small number of influential
generally from other developing nations. Changes in ownership buyers of mineral output for downstream production).
rules and regulations on dividend and profit remittances
additionally created an unstable investment climate particularly Some current policy realities
during the 1970s.
During this period, established mineral producers such as Relationships between large mining companies and the nations
Australia, the United States, Canada and South Africa were that host their investments have now become important in
favoured strongly by established mining and exploration economic and social terms. Andrews (1998) points out, for
companies. While they received 60 per cent of world mineral example, that the size of mining transnationals often compares
exploration spending in the 1960s, this had risen to 80 per cent favourably with the size of the economies of the small nations in
two decades later. which they operate.
Africa’s mineral production capacity gradually declined as a Consider the cases of BHP Billiton and Rio Tinto. In 2004, the
result of under-investment in the sector and because of the lack reported turnover of BHP Billiton amounted to almost US$ 18.3
of technical and human capacity in independent nations. Mineral billion, while that of Rio Tinto was US$ 11.8 billion. Both had
sector reinvestment fell, as profits from the sector became a operations in 13 nations. BHP Billiton was arguably larger in
source of revenue for other development objectives. Major economic size than three of the countries in which it operated –
technical problems emerged at most state-owned mines and this Surinam, Mozambique and Bolivia. Rio Tinto may be larger
adversely affected production. Important support services such as economically than Papua New Guinea and Namibia, the two
the collection of basic geological information also were smallest nations where it has operating mines.
adversely affected as decision-makers transferred resources from Such companies provide a major source of government
profitable mining companies to boost agriculture and newly revenue through their payment of taxes and royalties and they
emerging manufacturing industry. make major contributions to the development of remote regions.
BHP Billiton and Rio have been particularly influential in places
The swing back to private ownership such as the Pilbara. The interaction between mining companies,
national and regional governments and local communities is
Beginning in the mid-1980s a counter trend back towards important.
privatisation of mineral development and production began Particularly in developing nations, but also in developed
emerging in many nations. Policymakers recognised that only nations, central or provincial governments may be unable or have
new foreign investment would enable the orderly development of no interest in providing suitable infrastructure facilities to the
their mineral sectors. The demise of communism in the Soviet local communities close to the area of mining operations. In such
Union and Eastern Europe strengthened this view and many case companies must sometimes act as a surrogate government in
nations moved to revise their national mineral policies. the local communities in which they operate. This may involve
Otto (1997) notes that, in the ten years after 1985, almost a the provision of roads, housing, schools, health services,
hundred nations introduced or began serious work on revising electricity and other community infrastructure. In some cases (eg
their mineral related legislation. This resulted in the publication Porgera in Papua New Guinea), national governments may be
of many revised national mineral policies, which reduced or willing to reduced taxation if the mining company builds and
completely removed any discrimination applying to foreign maintains local infrastructure. The effective management of
investment. The process has continued since the mid-1990s. relations with local communities is a key factor in determining
As a result of this change, there has been growing foreign whether a mining operation is successful or not.
investment in mineral exploration and mining ventures in Africa, In the current world of competition for foreign investment,
Latin America, Asia and Oceania. Australian and Canadian mineral policies must be framed in a competitive way by host
mining companies have been prominent in this development. governments. Yet all of the stakeholders must be satisfied if
Maponga and Maxwell (2000) observed for example that by the mining is to be a success. This includes company shareholders,
mid-1990s, Australian mining companies had interests in more local communities, workforces, indigenous populations, financial
than eighty nations. Canadian mining investment seems to have backers, regional and national governments. It is and will
been even more widespread. By 1998, the 80/20 split of continue to be a major task to manage these interactions
exploration spending between the established mining nations effectively. Good mineral policy has an important role to play in
(Canada, the United States, Australia and South Africa) and the facilitating this outcome.
rest of the world had changed to an estimated 37/63 split.
Part of this dramatic change has been associated with a range Towards a competitive regulatory and fiscal
of policy forces in developed nations, which have discouraged regime for exploration and mining
the development of the mining sector. In describing a ‘Global
Policy Revolution that is Affecting Access to Minerals’ Otto (in So, how does government translate all this in practice? The task
press) points to issues in developed nations such as changed land is difficult because, as already mentioned, different levels of
use priorities, reduced security of tenure, nimbyism, native title government, ie federal, state and local, as well as other
legislation, permitting delays and exploration maturity as stakeholders with a legal or perceived power of veto, lay separate
negatively affecting mineral extraction activity. claims to parts of the mineral rent. As a consequence there are
Other important factors in the evolution of mineral exploration few, if any, government policy documents that clearly state and
and development during this period have been the liberalisation quantify the desired level of aggregate government revenue.
of financial markets and the easy availability of equity funds There is however significant evidence of the types of
through stock exchanges particularly in Australia, USA, Canada regulatory and fiscal regimes that have generated strong mineral
as well as the demonetarisation of gold. exploration and large mining sectors in their countries. All of
In the wake of these policy changes, large companies strongly them seem to have certain common characteristics.
expanded their influence. Operations in different sectors of the A pre-requisite to success is that a nation or region should
mineral industry have become much more concentrated. As generate a perception of high geological prospectivity. A
noted in Chapter 7 above, many sectors of the industry are now perception of prospectivity is distinct from an actual mineral

158 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 13: MINERAL POLICY — AN INTRODUCTION

resources endowment, although evidence of previous mineral Interestingly, with globalisation and the opening of many
discoveries and an abundance of successfully operating mines countries encouraging foreign investment in mineral exploration
provides an encouraging base. Government can however, and mining, there has seen a flurry of drafting of new mining acts
enhance the perception of prospectivity in the eyes of potential and regulations, or at least of revisions of the old ones. In this
investors by facilitating effective collection and inexpensive process the legislation of traditional, successful mining countries
dissemination of regional geoscientific data and information as such as Australia and Canada as been used as a model. As a
well as the reports relating to previous exploration programs result there has been a tendency for regulatory and fiscal
carried out by private industry. Thus a fundamental policy ‘packages’ to become more similar.
component is good strategic planning and resourcing of the The ultimate decision of whether to invest in a country may
activities of the relevant Geological Survey organisations and increasingly depend on the degree to which the country’s
support of related research institutions. administrative reality reflects the invariably laudable intents of
Another critical policy aspect for industry is the presence of its legislation. There is now emerging evidence that many
sound, fair, and predictable legislation to regulate the awarding administrative structures are failing to effectively enforce what in
and maintenance in good standing of exploration and mining better-organised countries would be excellent legislation. In
titles. Allocation of titles should be fair and non-discriminatory many cases it will take many years for the relevant institutional
strengthening to take place and for the administrative systems to
(eg on a first-in-time basis). There should be clear provisions for
work in an effective and efficient manner. This may be a
the transition from exploration to mining titles, giving the
symptom of potentially a more serious inadequacy and instability
discoverer a guaranteed right to develop and mine. Ideally the
in the country’s general political and administrative capacity. If
mining legislation should not be capable of being subverted by
so, it can bring greater sovereign risk and a significant
other laws or at least there should be in place clear protocols to disincentive to invest in a nation in spite of it having all the right
resolve any potential conflict. This may arise with respect to attributes on paper.
rights of other land-users, community stakeholders including
land owners and indigenous communities and the state of the
environment. REFERENCES
The conditions under which a mine can be developed and Andrews, C B, 1998. Emerging trends in mining industry partnerships,
operated throughout its life should be clearly stated, understood Natural Resources Forum, 22(2):119-126.
and agreed when the development is approved. These should Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2005. Year Book Australia 2005
reflect community expectations for occupational health and (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Available from:
safety, and technical and environmental management of the <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
project, including stringent rules for progressive or final Auty, R M, 1993. Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The
rehabilitation of the mine site. The various regulatory roles of Resource Curse Thesis (Routledge: London).
government in this context should be well coordinated and Fraser Institute, 2005. Annual survey of mining companies 2004/2005
(Fraser Institute: Vancouver) [online]. Available from: <http://www.
ideally there should be a ‘one-stop-shop.’ While legislation
fraserinstitute.ca/shared/readmore.asp?sNav=pb&id=738>. Date
should embody adequate penalties for breach of tenement accessed: 8 May 2006.
conditions, the philosophy of the regulatory institutions should Garnaut, R, 1995. Dilemmas of governance, in Proceedings Mining and
not be that of a policemen. Rather they should support and Mineral Resource Policy in Asia-Pacific: Prospects for the 21st
encourage effective, outcome-focussed planning and Century (eds: D Denoon, C Ballard, G Banks and P Hancock), pp
management by industry, with a progressive shift from policing 61-66 (Division of Pacific and Asian History, Australian National
to an advisory and auditing role to ensure that appropriate University: Canberra).
systems are put in place. Garnaut, R and Clunies Ross, A, 1983. Taxation of Mineral Rents
Fiscal arrangements should be competitive and stable. Given (Clarendon Press: Oxford).
the capital-intensity and up-front nature of mining investment Maponga, O and Maxwell, P, 2000. The internationalisation of the
and the ‘captive’ nature of mining operations, industry values Australian mineral industry in the 1990s, Resources Policy,
26(4):199-210.
fiscal stability more than just lower but uncertain tax rates. When
Otto, J M, 1992. A global survey of mineral company investment
considering fiscal arrangements, one cannot value their preferences, Mineral Investment Conditions in Selected Countries
components in isolation. A more objective view will come from of the Asia-Pacific Region, New York, United Nations ST/ESCAP/
analysing the ‘package’ of all government-levied imposts. As 1197:330-342.
discussed in detail in Chapter 15, these can be divided into: Otto, J M, 1997. A national mineral policy as a regulatory tool, Resources
• those fiscal measures that are in common with all other Policy, 23(1-2):1-8.
tax-payers; and Otto, J M, in press. Competing for investment – Competitive position of
countries seeking exploration and development investment,
• provisions which are specific to the mining industry. Economic Geology.
The latter include mineral royalties, which in Australia are Radetzki, M, 1985. State Mineral Enterprises: An Investigation into
Their Impact on International Mineral Markets (Resources for the
typically levied by the states and a host of mining-specific
Future: Washington DC).
provisions embodied in the Australian income tax legislation,
Radetzki, M, 1990. A Guide to Primary Commodities in the World
primarily providing for immediate write off of exploration Economy (Basil Blackwell: Oxford).
expenditure and accelerated depreciation of some mining assets. Randall, A, 1987. Resource Economics: An Economic Approach to
In terms of broader investment, policy provision for Natural Resource and Environmental Policy (Wiley: New York).
repatriation of profits and dividends overseas, for unlimited Tilton, J E, 2004. Determining the optimal tax on mining, Natural
foreign equity in mining projects and the absence of mandatory Resources Forum, 28:144-149.
government equity participation have served Australia well in Waud, R N, Maxwell, P, Hocking, A, Bonnici, J and Ward, I, 1996.
attracting foreign investors. Economics, third Australian edition (Longman: Melbourne).

Australian Mineral Economics 159


CHAPTER 14

The Legal and Regulatory Environment of Mining


Gavin Jahn

Introduction
The Australian Federation
Inconsistency Between State and Federal Laws
Commonwealth Power
State Legislation – The Western Australian Situation
Conclusion
Appendix – Validity and Consistency Under Section 109 of the Australian Constitution

INTRODUCTION The Australian Constitution (Commonwealth of Australia, 1900)


effectively grants specific power to the Commonwealth to make
This chapter provides a brief overview of some of the more laws on certain areas. Topics not covered under the Australian
important legal issues within the mining environment. More Constitution fall to the states known as the residual power. This
specifically, the discussion takes into consideration how the chapter examines some of the laws made by the Commonwealth
mining industry is directly and indirectly affected by the specific under the specific power granted under the Australian Constitution
powers of the Commonwealth of Australia and the residual and laws that fall to the state under the residual power.
powers of the state of Western Australia. The situation in
Western Australia has parallels in the other Australian states.
THE AUSTRALIAN FEDERATION
It is not possible to cover all parts of the law in detail and not
all areas of the law are in fact detailed herein. However, the Australia is a federation of six sovereign states1. The Australian
writer considers that those topics covered are the major areas that federal system of government is based partly on the Westminster
impact upon the industry. model and partly on the United States model2 and it also has
The Australian legal system relies upon judge made law, also some unique Australian elements.
known as common law, and statute law or laws made by There are two aspects of the Australian Constitution in
parliament. Laws pertaining to the mining industry fall largely particular that are important. These are:
within the ambit of statute law. Statute law can be made by either 1. the separation of powers between the legislature, executive
the Commonwealth Parliament or alternatively state parliament. and the judiciary3; and
2. the division of powers between the Commonwealth
1. Prior to 1 January 1901, six British colonies. Parliament and the states.
2. Known popularly as the ‘Washminster system’. This chapter deals with this aspect of Australian ‘federalism’,
which owes much to the United States model by conferring
3. The Constitution provides for a Westminster system of executive specific powers on the Commonwealth with residual powers
government (with no strict separation of powers between the
legislature and executive) engrafted onto a United States system of
residing in the states4.
strict separation of the judicial power and a federal legislature of The Australian Constitution confers some exclusive specific
House of Representatives and Senate. powers on the Commonwealth (eg section 122 – power over the
Australian Capital Territory). Other specific powers are
4. The political theory attributed to Montesquieu is that the specific
powers are limiting and the strong power lies in the residue. The conferred in section 51 jointly on both the Commonwealth
Canadian model essentially gives specific powers to the provinces and Parliament and on the states, but section 109 of the Constitution
the residuary power to the federal government. Wide judicial provides that, in the event of conflict between the
interpretations of some specific powers have rendered the theory otiose. Commonwealth and state laws, the Commonwealth law shall
prevail and the state law is invalid to the extent of the
5. Inconsistency may be due to direct or indirect conflict where the
Commonwealth has expressly or impliedly expressed an intention to inconsistency5. Further inroads into state residuary power have
‘cover the field’ (Clyde Engineering v Cowburn, 1926). Thus, occurred because of permitted application of the external affairs
Commonwealth and state laws can be inconsistent even when both power within Australia and by the wide interpretation of the
laws say the same thing. incidental scope of the Corporations power.

Australian Mineral Economics 161


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

The words in the Constitution may possess two meanings: Doctrine8 the delegated legislation may be either simply ultra
• That referrable to the main grant of power analogous to an vires or it may be qualified in some way by the enabling
‘umbra’. Acts. Section 109 is therefore otiose. Consequently only if
the delegated legislation is intra vires or unqualified will
• That referrable to the incidental power analogous to a section 109 be relevant.
‘penumbra’. Incidental powers may be either express or
implied. Section 51(xxxix) expressly confers legislative • Is common law a ‘law’ for the purposes of section 109?
power ‘with respect to…matters incidental to the execution Federal common law would be replaced by state statute law
of any power vested by…Constitution in the Parliament…’6. (Jackson v Gamble, 1983). Neither is there inconsistency
In addition, the High Court recognises a common law where a state lacks power to legislate over a federal matter
incidental power impliedly ‘included in the grant of every (eg the Commonwealth common law crime of defrauding the
power and every control the denial of which render the grant Commonwealth). State common law is overridden by any
itself ineffective’ (D’Emden v Pedder, 1904). valid Commonwealth statute.
Judicial interpretation of the Constitution can be characterised A valid law is assumed at both state and federal levels before
by literalism or progressivism. Literalism has been the dominant section 109 becomes effective. Section 109 is not effective if the
method, which reads words according to their natural sense and Commonwealth fabricates inconsistency by exceeding its
in documentary context and then gives the words full effect powers. This is also the situation if the state law exceeds its
(Craven, 1992; Blackshield and Williams, 1998). Progressivism powers. On the other hand s 109 is self-executing. For example
applies judicial legislation to achieve economic and social both the Commonwealth and News South Wales had enacted
outcomes (Craven, 1992 p 23). racial discrimination laws. The High Court had then held that
while there was no direct conflict between the Commonwealth
and New South Wales laws, the Commonwealth law had
INCONSISTENCY BETWEEN STATE AND intended to cover the field and the New South Wales law was
FEDERAL LAWS therefore inconsistent (Viskauskas v Niland, 1983). Subsequently,
the Commonwealth Parliament had legislated to reverse
The Constitution provides a mechanism for resolving conflicts
retrospectively that decision. The High Court then held that due
between state and federal laws, the ultimate resolution being in
to the self-executing nature of s 109, once the court has found
favour of the latter, much to the chagrin of the former.
that s 109 applied, the federal Parliament was constitutionally
Section 109 of the Constitution provides: impotent to legislate retrospectively to reverse that finding
When a law of a State is inconsistent with a law (Wollongong University v Metwally, 1984).
of the Commonwealth, the latter shall prevail Lane (1997, p 770) states that logically the court would firstly
and the former shall to the extent of the examine the validity of the Commonwealth law and only if it
inconsistency be invalid. were valid would the court then apply Section 109. While this
This is not a rule of ultimate desperation but is a primary and logical sequence has at times been followed (eg Johnston v
important explicit constitutional provision. If there is an Krakowski, 1965), it is less time-consuming to argue Section 109
inconsistency, section 109 immediately renders state law first. If there is no inconsistency then the validity of the
ineffective and neither the Commonwealth nor state Parliaments Commonwealth law need not be examined for these purposes.
can frustrate that automatic overreaching consequence. Issues concerning validity and consistency are further considered
Section 109 is about the interpretation of two sets of laws and in the Appendix at the end of this chapter.
the interaction between those laws once they are interpreted.
Namely section 109 is not about: COMMONWEALTH POWER
• the constitutional limits of Commonwealth and state powers
enabling those laws; nor The corporations power
• the mode of interaction between those powers. The corporations power is conferred by section 51(xx), which
states:
The meaning of law The Parliament shall…have power to make laws
It is important to appreciate the meaning of the word ‘law’ for with respect to … foreign corporations, and
the purposes of section 109. trading or financial corporations, formed within
the limits of the Commonwealth.
• Clearly statute law is fundamental.
The Commonwealth corporations power is limited. Firstly it is
• Delegated legislation, ie regulations, ministerial orders and
limited to foreign corporations and to Australian ‘trading or
industrial awards have also been included in the definition of
financial’ corporations (eg bare holding companies are not
‘law for these purposes’7. All delegated legislation must be
included). Secondly the High Court has consistently adopted a
read pursuant to the enabling Acts. Under the ultra vires
narrow interpretation of the main grant of the Corporations
power. In Huddart Parker and Co Ltd v Moorehead (1909) the
6. Confirmed by the High Court in Grannall v Marrickville Margarine High Court held that the word ‘formed’ in Section 51(xx) meant
Pty Ltd (1955) 93 CLR 55 at 77. The cases indicate that the scope of already formed (ie registered under state law). The High Court
the incidental power is subjective depending on the judges. also questioned whether mining and investment companies fell
within Section 51(xx). For the whole of the 20th century,
7. Not so clearly in the case of industrial awards, which have an aura of
Corporations law was state law albeit with attempts to achieve
the quasi-judicial despite also being clearly legislative in the sense
that awards make rules to operate in futuro. Nevertheless, clearly uniformity9. Due to differential state interpretations of the laws,
awards are ‘law’ pursuant to their enabling statutes. the Commonwealth moved unilaterally and enacted the
Corporations Act 1989 (Cth), the constitutional validity of which
8. Under this doctrine delegated legislation that exceeds or abuses the was examined by the High Court in New South Wales v
power conferred by the enabling Acts is void. Commonwealth (1990). In that case the High Court followed
9. The Uniform Companies Acts 1961, the companies (name of state) Huddart Parker and invalidated key sections of the 1989 Act,
codes of the 1980s known as the Cooperative Scheme. particularly those empowering the formation of companies.

162 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

The Commonwealth was forced to negotiate with the states, the prevention and settlement of industrial
confining the 1989 Act to the Australian Capital Territory (ACT) disputes extending beyond the limits of any one
with the states enacting the ACT Act as ‘The Corporations (Name state.
of State) Law’ 1991 (called the Corporations Law Scheme).
Constitutional difficulties with federal authorities enforcing state The Industrial Relations power is therefore limited. First, it is
law made the Corporations Law Scheme unworkable. limited to conciliation and arbitration11 and not collective
bargaining per se. Second, while ‘prevention’ enables early
In 2000 the states (and the Northern Territory) referred their
intervention (eg a threatened, pending or probable dispute) the
Corporations powers to the Commonwealth pursuant to
major import is focused on ‘settlement’. Third, there must be an
s 51(xxxvii) subject to state termination (Corporations Act 2001
(Cth) Part 1.1): ‘industrial dispute’, which requirement promotes industrial
confrontation. Last, there must be an interstate dispute12. This
• Under a five year sunset clause. final requirement has led to vibrant state industrial systems in
• If the Commonwealth used the corporations power to enact most states to deal with intrastate disputes.
new industrial laws. The Corporations Law was re-enacted However, current Commonwealth Industrial law is based
with incidental changes as Commonwealth law in largely on the Corporations power in section 51(xx). Despite the
Corporations Act 2001 (Cth), which undeniably covers consistently narrow interpretation given by the High Court to the
mining companies and continues to provide for ‘no liability’ main grant of the Corporations power (Huddart Parker and Co
mining companies where this form of corporate organisation Ltd v Moorehead, 1909; New South Wales v Commonwealth,
is desired to facilitate equity fundraising. 1990) the High Court has, since Strickland v Rocla Concrete
The Corporations Act 2001 (Cth) provides inter alia for: Pipes Ltd (1971), given wide incidental interpretation to the
Corporations power so as to permit extensive Commonwealth
• Registration of corporations. control over multifarious economic activities. The current
• Fundraising by equity and debt securities. Primary trading in Workplace Relations Act 1996 (Cth) goes far beyond the scope of
securities to the retail market requires a disclosure document section 51(xxxv) to cover industrial relations activities by
(eg a prospectus) while private placements to the wholesale employer corporations. Further, the 1996 Act has:
market are exempt. On-market secondary trading requires • reduced the role of the Australian Industrial Relations
continuous disclosure under the ASX listing rules. Off-market Commission by limiting the number of matters able to be
secondary trading generally does not require disclosure but settled by award to 20;
there are exceptions for the retail market (eg direct or indirect
sales by a controller to the retail market and secondary trading • provided for Australian workplace agreements approved by
to the retail market that is treated as primary trading may the employment advocate;
require disclosure in stated circumstances). • allowed non-union certified agreements;
• Corporate governance. • empowered freedom of association; and
• Takeovers regulation. • reduced union roles in enterprise bargaining and industrial
• External administration (eg receivership, voluntary administration matters overall (Wheelwright, 2003).
and liquidation). Media reports attendant upon the control of the Senate by the
federal Liberal-National Coalition as from 1 July 2005, have
Industrial relations power speculated upon the stated intention of the Commonwealth
Government to enact new industrial laws based on the
Effective Industrial Relations legal and regulatory systems assist Corporations power, which will expressly cover the field and
both employers and employees and significantly contribute to invalidate state industrial laws. The Premier of Queensland has
economic stability. Australia has both federal and state industrial been reported as threatening to terminate (pursuant to
relations systems10. Corporations Act 2001 (Cth) Part 1.1) that state’s coverage by
The Commonwealth ‘Industrial Relations’ power is conferred the Corporations Law 2001 (Cth)13. The current High Court
by Section 51(xxxv) of the Constitution, which states that: appears to be conservative and legalistic. It is likely that the High
The Parliament shall … have power to make laws Court may restrict the recent wide incidental interpretations of
the Corporations Act 2001 (Cth) in the interests of preserving the
… with respect to conciliation and arbitration for
balance of Australian federalism.
The Western Australian industrial relations system has been
10. Subject to some reservations, Victoria referred its industrial relations the subject of considerable recurrent changes resulting from
power to the Commonwealth – Commonwealth Powers (Industrial changes in state governments. Enterprise bargaining is effected
Relations) Act 1996 (Vic); Workplace Relations Act 1996 (Cth) Pt XV. under the Industrial Relations Act 2002 (WA). A more
11. The Conciliation and Arbitration Act 1904 (Cth) was enacted contentious approach through statutory individual workplace
accordingly. agreements was provided for under the Workplace Agreements
Act 1993 (WA). These registered employer-employee agreements
12. This must be a real and not merely a paper or sympathy dispute.
were given paramountcy over relevant awards and were not
13. It is interesting to speculate the effects if the Premier’s threat is subject to the ‘no disadvantage test’14. However, the agreements
carried out. Firstly the Corporations Act 2001 (Cth) will not ‘cover had to comply with the Minimum Conditions of Employment Act
the field’ with respect to Queensland, leaving that state free to enact 1993 (WA).
its own corporations (or similar) legislation. Secondly, quaere Following the election of a Labor Government in 2001, the
whether new Commonwealth industrial laws based on the
Corporations power are capable of application in a state that is no Workplace Agreements Act 1993 (WA) was repealed15. However,
longer bound by Commonwealth Corporations laws? a form of employer-employee agreement is still available in
certain cases (see Industrial Relations Act 1979 (WA)).
14. This public interest test applied to other industrial applications and
provided that the workplace agreements would not be
disadvantageous when compared with relevant awards. Export power
15. Pursuant to the Labour Relations Act 2002 (WA) which also This constitutional power of the Commonwealth over mining, in
provided for a regulated phasing out of the individual agreements. particular uranium mining, is manifested in the control of exports
(See generally Wheelwright, 2003, p 249). (section 51(i) of the Australian Constitution):

Australian Mineral Economics 163


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

The Parliament shall … have power to make laws This a phrase of wide import covering not only treaties and
… with respect to: trade and commerce with international conventions but also any kind of relations abroad.
other countries, and among the states. There can be little doubt that under this external affairs power,
the Commonwealth does have substantial scope to make
While the actual mining of particular ores in Western environmental laws. After all, where a law can be characterised
Australia, including uranium, is covered under the Mining Act of with respect to a particular subject matter under section 51 of the
Western Australia 1978 the Commonwealth may refuse to grant a Constitution, it is irrelevant that the law may have environmental
licence to export the particular ore using its Constitutional power. purposes. The Commonwealth’s use of its legislative powers for
In particular, uranium may not be exported without a licence. environmental purposes has not been without controversy, in
Australian customs (section 51 (ix) of the Australian particular, its use of the external affairs power.
Constitution) will enforce the prohibition of exporting uranium During the 1980s, the High Court, in a series of decisions in
without a licence (Customs Act). particular Tasmanian dams (Commonwealth v State of Tasmania,
The Commonwealth’s power over exports is extremely 1983), brought a significant widening of the scope of the external
important because uranium is only mined in Australia for export. affairs power. It did this by allowing the Commonwealth
Numerous mines have not commenced productions simply effectively to take control of vast tracts of land from states for the
because the Commonwealth refused to grant approval for the purpose of implementing the terms of the Convention for the
exportation of uranium. This was particularly evident during the Protection of World Cultural and Natural Heritage (World
currency of the so-called three mines policy under the Hawke Heritage Convention) within Australia.
and Keating Labor governments. In 1999 the Australian parliament passed the Environment
In particular it should be noted that the Commonwealths role Protection and Biodiversity Act which is an attempt to provide
in the uranium debate takes a very special position in respect to the Commonwealth with laws on the environment. To date, the
the mining of uranium in the Northern Territory. Although Commonwealth has not sought to take full responsibility for
self-government was granted in 1978, the Commonwealth environmental regulation in Australia. Yet, if Australia is to
retained control and ownership of uranium (Northern Territory remain true to the commitments it made as a participant at the
(Self Government) Act 1978 s 69(4)). Rio conference, in particular, to enact ‘effective environmental
The power over exports is the foundation for the legislation’, it may be that at some time the Commonwealth will
Commonwealth role in appraisal of the environmental be called upon again to use its legislative powers to override
implications of proposals to mine uranium. Environmental matters environmental and developmental policies of individual states.
are, however, not the only reason for Commonwealth interest in The purpose of this paper is to discuss the extent to which the
mining of uranium. There are significant security reasons as well. Commonwealth would be able to rely upon the external affairs
power to meet Australia’s commitments under the Rio
The Commonwealth Minister for Industry, Tourism and
Declaration. First, there will be an examination of the framework
Resources is responsible for administering export controls on of international law and relations and of where the international
uranium pursuant to the Customs (Prohibited Exports) community’s interest in environmental protection as expressed in
Regulations 1958 (Schedule 9 of Regulation 11). Under the the Rio Declaration (and Agenda 21) fits into it. Second, there is
‘three mines policy’ export permits for uranium were only issued a brief description of the evolution of international environmental
for uranium mined at ‘listed’ mines, namely Nabarlek, Ranger law. Third, High Court decisions on the external affairs power is
and the Olympic Dam Operation. analysed and a conclusion drawn as to the extent to which the
The policy of the Liberal-National Party Government elected Commonwealth may utilise the external affairs power for
in March 1996 is to approve mining and export of uranium from environmental purposes.
any project which meets stringent environmental, heritage and In an era of globalisation one could argue that the external
nuclear safeguards obligations. Uranium mining has become a affairs power has not yet been fully explored and that it is
very topical discussion of late with the federal government becoming of great significance for the Commonwealth. However,
recently deciding to re-examine the financial benefits of the impact of the external affairs power has been felt by the
exporting uranium. It should however be noted that Australia is a mining industry through environmental protection legislation.
signatory to the Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty16. The cost of compliance has significantly increased and in
addition the focus of pure mining has been somewhat distracted
External affairs power by having to consider the practicalities of compliance with the
likes of the Environment Protection and Biodiversity Act 1999.
The external affairs power is another power that the In addition the Atomic Energy Act 1953 now requires the
Commonwealth utilised to influence its power over the states. Minister for Industry, Tourism and Resources to take account of
The Australian Constitution does not directly grant to the the requirements of the Environment Protection and Biodiversity
Commonwealth any power to make laws with respect to ‘the Conservation Act 1999 when dealing with project approvals or
environment’: issuing export permits.
The Parliament shall … have power to make laws
… with respect to: matters incidental to the Race power and native title
execution of any power vested by this Constitution Of particular importance to mining within the states is the native
in the Parliaments or in either house thereof, or in title issue and to a lesser extent racial discrimination. While
the Government of the Commonwealth, or in the racial discrimination and native title may fall under the external
Federal Judicature, or in any department or officer affairs power s 51 (xxix) of the Australian Constitution, the main
of the Commonwealth (Australian Constitution, constitutional power for native title falls under s 51(xxvi):
section 51(xxix)).
The Parliament shall … have power to make laws
… with respect to: the people of any race, other
16. See the text of the Treaty online at: http://disarmament.un.org:8080/ than the Aboriginal race in any state, for whom it
wmd/npt/npttext.html. The treaty was entered into force in 1970 by is deemed necessary to make special laws.
188 countries including Australia and reaffirmed in 2000. Among
other things, the Treaty was entered into inter alia to promote It should be noted that the words in bold were deleted from the
cooperation in the peaceful uses of nuclear energy. Constitution after a referendum was held in 1967.

164 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

Native title legislation Claims that fail to meet the registration test are recorded on the
Schedule of Applications Received. Such claims may be entered
Judicial recognition of native title at common law occurred in on the register at a later date if additional information is provided
Mabo v Queensland (1992) (No 2) (Mabo), a decision of the by the claimant that satisfies the registration test.
High Court of Australia on 3 June 1992. Generally these native
title rights to land will be recognised where:
Validity of the tenements
1. the claimants can establish that they have maintained a
continuous connection with the land in accordance with 1. Tenements granted prior to 1 January 1994 – the Native
their traditional laws and customs since British settlement Title Act permits a State to validate ‘past acts’. Western
in 1788; and Australia, New South Wales and Queensland all have
legislation that gives effect to this provision of the Native
2. the native title rights have not been lawfully extinguished. Title Act. Mining tenements granted in Western Australia
After Mabo, considerable uncertainty existed about the validity prior to 1 January 1994 are deemed to be valid. To the
of proprietary rights in Australia, including rights in and to mining extent that the exercise of native title rights and interests is
tenements. To address those uncertainties, the Commonwealth inconsistent with the exercise of the rights conferred by
Parliament responded by passing the Native Title Act 1993 (Cth) those tenements, the rights under each particular tenement
(‘NTA’). The Native Title Act came into operation in January 1994 will have priority for the term of the relevant grant.
and was substantially amended in 1998 in response to the decision 2. Tenements granted between 1 January 1994 and
of the High Court in Wik v Queensland (1996). The Wik case 23 December 1996 – these are known as ‘intermediate period
recognised that the granting of a pastoral lease did not necessarily acts’. The 1998 amendments to the Native Title Act provided
extinguish all native title rights, some of which could coexist with scope for the states and territories to validate these acts.
the rights under a pastoral lease.
3. Tenements granted since 23 December 1996 – mining
In Mabo, the High Court held that native title rights can be tenements granted since 23 December 1996 which affect
lawfully extinguished by certain government legislation and native title rights and interests will be valid provided that
executive actions which are not inconsistent with native title. In the future Act procedures set out below were followed by
order for extinguishment to be lawful it must comply with the the relevant parties.
obligations imposed by the Native Title Act.
Assuming that all future Act procedures were followed, the
In summary the Native Title Act: Tenements will be classified as valid future Acts under the NTA.
1. provides for recognition and protection of native title; 4. Future tenement grants – the valid grant of any tenement,
2. sets up mechanisms for determining claims for native title which may affect native title, requires full compliance with
such as the ‘right to negotiate’ which allows native title the provisions of the Native Title Act in addition to
claimants to be consulted in relation to certain mining and compliance with the usual procedures under the Mining
other developments; Act. The primary procedure prescribed under the Native
Title Act is the ‘right to negotiate’ process.
3. makes valid certain ‘past acts’ which would otherwise be
invalidated because of native title; The right to negotiate process involves the publishing or
advertising of a notice of the proposed grant of a tenement
4. establishes ways in which ‘future acts’ (for example the
followed by a period of negotiation between the state
granting of mining tenement applications and converting
government, the tenement applicant and the relevant
exploration licences and prospecting licences to mining
registered native title claimant. If agreement is not reached
leases) affecting native title may proceed and how native
title rights are protected, including rights to compensation; to enable the grant to occur, the matter may be referred to
and arbitration before the National Native Title Tribunal, which
has a further six months to reach a decision. The decision
5. provides a process by which claims for native title and of the National Native Title Tribunal may be reviewed by
compensation can be determined. the relevant federal minister.
The High Court decision of Ward v Western Australia The right to negotiate process is not required to be followed
established that where tenure such as a pastoral lease is granted in respect of a proposed future act in instances where the
on a mining tenement, native title is extinguished only to the expedited procedure applies. Under the Native Title Act, a
extent that it is inconsistent with the rights conferred by the future act is an act attracting the expedited procedure if:
pastoral lease.
1. the act will not interfere directly with the carrying on
of the community or social activities of the persons
Native title claims who are the holders of native title in relation to the
Persons claiming to hold native title may lodge an application for land; and
determination of native title with the Federal Court. Once a 2. the act is not likely to interfere with areas or sites of
native title claim has been lodged, the court will refer the particular significance, in accordance with their
application to the Native Title Registrar. The Native Title traditions, to the persons who are holders of the native
Registrar must determine whether the claim meets certain title in relation to the land; and
conditions concerning the merits of the claim, and certain 3. the act is not likely to involve major disturbance to any
procedural and other requirements set out by the NTA. land or waters concerned or create rights whose exercise
If the Native Title Registrar is satisfied the lodged claim meets is likely to involve major disturbance to any land.
the registration requirements set out in the Native Title Act When the proposed future act is considered to be one that
(‘Registration Test’) it will be entered on the Register of Native attracts the expedited procedure, the future act may be done
Title Claims maintained by the National Native Title Tribunal unless, within four months after the notification day, a native title
(‘Register’). Claimants under registered claims are afforded party lodges an objection with the National Native Title Tribunal
certain procedural rights under the Native Title Act including the against the inclusion of a statement that the proposed future act is
‘right to negotiate’. an act attracting the expedited procedure.

Australian Mineral Economics 165


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

If there is no objection lodged within the four-month period, The exploration licence (EL)
the act may be done. If one or more native title parties object to
the statement, the National Native Title Tribunal must determine An exploration licence (section 66 Mining Act) remains in force
whether the act is an act attracting the expedited procedure. If the for five years from the date of grant (section 61(1)) with the
possibility of renewal by the minister in certain circumstances.
tribunal determines that it is, the minister may do the future act
The holder of an exploration licence is required to expend certain
(for example grant an exploration licence).
amounts (section 62 and regulation 21) upon exploration
Further, the right to negotiate process does not have to be activities during the term with failure to do so leading to possible
pursued in cases where an Indigenous Land Use Agreement forfeiture of the licence.
(‘ILUA’) is negotiated with the relevant Aboriginal people and The holder of an exploration licence has, subject to the Mining
registered with the National Native Title Tribunal. In such cases, Act, the right to apply for and to have granted a mining lease over
the procedures prescribed by the Indigenous Land Use the land the subject of the exploration licence (section 67). The
Agreement must be followed to obtain the valid grant of the exploration lease also has similar conditions to that of a mining
tenement. These procedures will vary depending on the terms of lease including security, environmental conditions and geological
the Indigenous Land Use Agreement. record (sections 60, 63, 63AA and 68).
A further tenement recently introduced into the Act includes
STATE LEGISLATION – THE WESTERN the special prospecting licence (section 56(1)(1a)). The licence
AUSTRALIAN SITUATION can only be applied for 12 months after the grant of a prospecting
licence. A natural person can mark out a part (section 56A(6)(a)
Mining Act 1978 (Western Australia) – must not exceed ten hectares) of the prospecting licence as a
special prospecting licence for gold (section 56A(6)(b)). The
The Western Australian Mining Act 1904 adopted the philosophy
minimum term is three months with a four year maximum
that land should be used for purpose for which it is most
(section 56A(6aa)).
valuable. It was also seen within the Mining Act that no person
should be entitled to hold any mineral right without being
prepared to work that land. The Mining Act applied Renewals and extensions of tenements
predominantly to gold mining, which at that time was the only As with the granting of mining tenements, renewals and
real mineral of any value being mined. It was not until 1978 that extensions of mining tenements granted prior to 1 January 1994,
a new Mining Act (the Act) was introduced into Western to the extent the renewals were invalid due to native title, have
Australia to initiate laws that would cover the more modern or been validated by legislation.
sophisticated methods of mining.
Renewals of mining tenements granted between 1 January 1994
Under the Western Australian Mining Act 1904 there were and 23 December 1996 have been similarly validated provided
some 39 different types of titles. The Mining Act 1978 provides certain statutory criteria have been met.
for seven mining tenements (section 8). Under the current Act Renewals made after 23 December 1996 of tenements validly
there are three major tenements, which include one production granted before that date will not be subject to the right to
tenement (Mining Lease) and two investigatory tenements negotiate process provided:
(Exploration Licence and Prospecting Licence). The other four
tenements include the General Purpose Licence, Miscellaneous 1. the area to which the earlier right is made is not extended;
Licence, Retention Licence and the Special Prospecting Licence. 2. the term of the new right is not longer than the term of the
earlier right; and
Mining tenements 3. the rights to be created are not greater than the rights
Two of the new mining tenements introduced into the Act conferred by the earlier grant.
included the following. There is doubt about whether the right to negotiate process
applies to second and subsequent renewals but this matter is yet
The mining lease (ML) to be determined by the courts.
A mining lease (section 85 Mining Act 1978 (WA)) gives the Other than as stated above, renewals of mining tenements are
holder the exclusive right to find, extract and dispose of any subject to the same right to negotiate process as is described
minerals on the land the subject of that mining lease. The above.
maximum area over which a mining lease may be granted must
not exceed ten square kilometres (section 73). A mining lease Special agreement acts
remains in force for a period of 21 years (section 78) from the Under the Act the tenement holder is granted a right to prospect,
date of grant, the holder has an option to renew for another 21 explore or mine for minerals on the land17. If the minister
years on expiry and further renewals are possible. The mining considers it in the public’s interest (section 111A of the Act) the
lease entitles the holder to all minerals except iron ore unless grant may be made to mine only those minerals stated in the
ministerial approval is obtained (see Special Agreements infra). lease (section 110 of the Mining Act).
The tenement holder must be aware of conditions imposed on the The Mining Act specifically excludes the holder of a mining
title, which include expenditure (section 82 Mining Act and tenement from mining iron18. The State Government has
regulation 31 of Mining Regulations), conditions imposed by the controlled the development of iron ore deposits in Western
minister (section 71 Mining Act), environmental conditions Australia through the use of special agreement acts (eg Broken
(section 84), security (section 84A) and reporting requirements Hill Proprietary Steel Industry Agreement Act, 1952).
(section 82(1)(e) and regulation 32).
Mine Safety and Inspection Act 1994
17. Mining Act 1978 grant of prospecting licence s 40(1), grant of The Mine Safety and Inspection Act 1994 (WA) (the Act) was
exploration licence 59(6), grant of mining lease 75(6). drafted using legislation from other Australian states and more
18. Section 111 of the Mining Act specifically states that iron ore is particularly similar United Kingdom legislation as a model. The
excluded from mining tenements ss 48, 66, 70J and 85. main purpose of the Act is to promote and secure the safety and

166 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

health of those working in mining operations (section 3(a) Mines Mine inspectors have the power to lay charges (section 21 of
Safety and Inspection Act 1994) as well as to assist employers the Act) under the Act and institute or bring proceedings (section
and employees to identify and reduce hazards relating to mines, 96 of the Act) against an offender. However the general
mining operations, work systems and plant at mines (section 3(b) understanding of the Act is for all parties to work together to
Mines Safety and Inspection Act 1994). The Act also protects provide a safe working environment for all those engaged in
employees, fosters relationships between those involved in mining activities. The Act is designed to ensure the continued
mining operations as well as providing a process for employees improvement and education of a safe work place environment for
to contribute to the Act’s administration19.
all those involved in the industry. Failure to comply may result in
More importantly, the Act imposes a duty not only on the criminal prosecution.
employer but also the employee, self-employers persons,
managers of mines and certain designers manufactures and
Aboriginal Heritage Act 1972
suppliers. As the name of the Act suggests this piece of
legislation is designed to ensure that all parties take the necessary The Aboriginal Heritage Act 1972 (WA) (WA Heritage Act) is
precautions to ensure the safety of all parties20. specifically applicable to all of the tenements granted by the
Section 9 of the Act provides a duty on the employer to minister imposing a condition that the Act be observed. The WA
provide and maintain a working environment that is free of Heritage Act makes it an offence to alter or damage an
hazards. However, the paragraphs within section 9 state that such Aboriginal site or object on or under an Aboriginal site. An
an obligation is limited to providing a safe working environment Aboriginal site is defined to include any sacred, ritual or
‘as far as is practicable’ or in the alternate provide such training, ceremonial site that is of importance and special significance to
instruction or protective equipment to ensure the employee is persons of Aboriginal descent.
aware of the hazards of working within such an environment. There is no requirement or need for an Aboriginal site to be
Mine Safety Inspectors are proactive in the enforcement of registered in any public manner or, indeed, to be in any way
section 9 of the Act and employers are aware of the severe acknowledged as an Aboriginal site for it to qualify as an
consequences of a breach of the provisions. It should also be Aboriginal site for the purposes of the WA Heritage Act.
noted that non-employees on a mine site including subcontractors The tenement holders must ensure that any interference with
and visitors are also covered under the Act. The general duty of such sites is in strict conformity with the provisions of the WA
care is therefore imposed on the employer or mine owner to Heritage Act.
ensure the safety of anybody on the site (section 12 of the Mine
Safety and Inspection Act 1994 (WA)).
CONCLUSION
The Act is quite broad in its application and is not just
limited to a duty owed by the employer. Section 10 of the Act This chapter has examined some of the major pieces of
states that the employee is also responsible not only for his or legislation that affect the mining industry at both Commonwealth
her own safety but the safety of fellow employees through his and state level. While state legislation may grant tenements and
or her acts or omissions. Such breaches by the employee could the right to mine, subject to payment of royalties, mine safety,
result in a fine of up to $10 000 or $20 000 where a death or aboriginal heritage and special agreements the Commonwealth
serious injury results from the failure of the employee to act may prevent the export of minerals, oil or gas by utilising the
with due care or follow instructions of the employer. Under specific powers granted to Commonwealth under the
section 13 of the Act a mine manager21 has a duty to ensure that Constitution. This specific power granted to the Commonwealth
both the mine and access to and from the mine is free of assists in its ability to control the exporting of products from
Australia. More particularly the increasing expanse of the
hazards otherwise face similar penalties as those imposed on
external affairs power ensures that the Commonwealth’s grip on
the employee.
the mining sector is expanding. Such powers of the
Also designers, manufactures, importers and suppliers do not Commonwealth significantly reduce the power of the states to
escape liability. They have a duty to ensure that their equipment, control the use of their minerals that form the basis, particularly
actions or inactions and products do not expose those who use in Western Australia, of economic prosperity and benefit to the
such equipment or products are not exposed to and form of people of that state.
hazard or danger.
REFERENCES
19. Section 3(c) Mines Safety and Inspection Act 1994 states – to protect Amalgamated Society of Engineers v Adelaide Steamship Co Ltd, 1920.
employees against the risks associated with mines, mining 28 CLR 129 at 150.
operations, work systems at mines, and plant and hazardous Blackshield, T and Williams, G, 1998. Australian Constitutional Law and
substances at mines by eliminating those risks, or imposing effective Theory, p 245 (Federation Press: Sydney).
controls in order to minimise them. 3(d) to foster and facilitate
cooperation and consultation between employers and employees and Clyde Engineering Co Ltd v Cowburn, 1926. 37 CLR 466.
associations representing employers and employees, and to provide Colvin v Bradley Bros, 1943. 68 CLR 151.
for the participation of those persons and associations in the Commonwealth of Australia, 1900. The Australian constitution [online].
formulation and implementation of safety and health standards and Available from: <http://www.aph.gov.au/senate/general/constitution>.
optimum working practices. 3(e) to provide procedures for Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
employers and employees to contribute to the development and Commonwealth v State of Tasmania, 1983. 158 CLR 1.
formulation of safety legislation for mines and mining operations Craven, G, 1992. Australian Constitutional Perspectives (eds: H P Lee and
and to consult regarding its administration. G Winterton), p 2 (Law Book Company: Sydney).
20. BHP Billiton Direct Reduction Iron have been charged by the D’Emden v Pedder, 1904. 1 CLR 91 at 110.
Department of Industry and Resources under sections 9(1) and 9(8) Department for Disarmament Affairs, United Nations, 1970. Treaty on
(Duties of Employee) of the Mines Safety and Inspection Act 1994 in the Non-Proliferation of Nuclear Weapons (NPT) [online]. Available
regard to explosions at the Port Hedland Boodarie Hot Briquette Iron from: <http://disarmament2.un.org/wmd/npt/>. Date accessed: 8 May
(HBI) plant. 2006.
21. Under section 4 of the Act means the registered manager for the Grannall v Marrickville Margarine Pty Ltd, 1955. 93 CLR 55 at 77.
mine. Section 33 of the Act requires the manager of the mine to be Huddart Parker and Co Ltd v Moorehead, 1909. 8 CLR 330.
registered. Jackson v Gamble, 1983. 1 VR 552.

Australian Mineral Economics 167


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

Johnston v Krakowski, 1965. 113 CLR 552. In Mabo (1988) Queensland law extinguished the traditional
Lane, P H, 1997. Lane’s Commentary on the Australian Constitution, land rights of certain Torres Strait Islanders without similarly
second edition (Law Book Company: Sydney). adversely affecting the land rights of other Queenslanders
Mabo v Queensland (No 2) (Mabo), 1992. 175 CLR 1. generally. Commonwealth law prohibited discrimination on
Mabo v State of Queensland, 1988. 166 CLR 186. racial grounds resulting in inconsistency and invalidation of the
McLean (Ex p) 1930. 43 CLR 472 at 483. Queensland law.
Mining Act (WA) 1978. (Western Australian Government Printer: Perth). However there is no collision if it is possible to obey both
New South Wales v Commonwealth, 1990. 8 ACLC 120. State and federal laws. In Clyde Engineering Co Ltd v Cowburn
O’Sullivan v Noarlunga Meat Ltd (No 1), 1954. 92 CLR 565. (1926) the High Court accepted that it was possible for a worker
Strickland v Rocla Concrete Pipes Ltd, 1971. 124 CLR 468. to earn part of his wages under federal 48 hour week laws and
Viskauskas v Niland, 1983. 153 CLR 280. the other part of his wages under State 44 hour week laws
Ward v Western Australia.
(although inconsistency was found on other grounds). The
converse of course is not always true – there may still be
Wenn v AG (Vic) 1948. 77 CLR 84.
inconsistency even when both laws say the same thing (Clyde
Wheelwright, K, 2003. Labour Law, second edition, p 15 (LexisNexis Engineering Co Ltd v Cowburn, 1926).
Butterworths: Sydney).
Wik v Queensland, 1996. 187 CLR 1.
Williams v Hursey, 1959. 103 CLR 30.
The Commonwealth permits or confers: the state
Wollongong University v Metwally, 1984. 158 CLR 447. prohibits or deprives
Commonwealth law may permit an action or confer an immunity
FURTHER READING while the state prohibits the action or deprives the immunity. In
Colvin v Bradley Bros (1943) a federal award gave qualified
Fisher, D E, 1987. Natural Resources Law in Australia: A Macro-Legal permission for the employment of females on milling machines
System in Operation (Law Book Company: Sydney). while a New South Wales law prohibited it. The High Court held
Forbes, J R S and Lang, A G, 1987. Australian Mining and Petroleum that the New South Wales law was inconsistent.
Laws, second edition (Butterworths: Sydney).
In Williams v Hursey (1959) two Tasmanian waterside workers
Hanks, P, 1994. Australian Constitutional Law Materials and Commentary,
fifth edition (Butterworths: Sydney).
refused to pay a political levy supporting the Australian Labor
Party. Federal law permitted the levy but Tasmanian law prohibited
Hunt, M, 1997. Minerals and Petroleum Law (Butterworths: Sydney).
it. The High Court found the Tasmanian law to be inconsistent.
Hunt, M, 2001. Mining Law in Western Australia, third edition (The
Federation Press: Sydney). The nature of the Commonwealth permission is important. Is
Lee, H P and Winterton, G, 1992. Australian Constitutional Perspectives
this a positive express authority to do something irrespective of
(Law Book Company: Sydney). state law (as in Colvin v Bradley Bros, 1943) or is this a bare
negative licence to do an act where that act is not otherwise
permitted? What is the content of the Commonwealth
APPENDIX – VALIDITY AND CONSISTENCY permission? Federal law may expressly exclude state law which
UNDER SECTION 109 OF THE AUSTRALIAN may be effected by enacting words such as: ‘the provisions of
CONSTITUTION this [name of Act] shall apply to the exclusion of [name of state
Acts]’. Federal law may also implicitly exclude state law (as in
Williams v Hursey, 1959).
Invalid
Conversely there is inconsistency where the state permits and
‘Invalid’ in section 109 does not mean absolutely void and the Commonwealth prohibits or the state confers and the
probably does not mean ‘invalid’ at all but merely ‘ineffective’. If Commonwealth deprives.
the Commonwealth law should cease to apply for any reason (eg
the Commonwealth law is repealed), then the state law would Covering the field test
take effect.
The ‘covering the field test’ has been particularly welcomed by
The Commonwealth legislation renders inconsistency irrelevant the Commonwealth but despised by the states for its blatant
by showing an intention to admit state law as either co-existing enhancement of Commonwealth power even to the point of
with or subsidiary to Commonwealth law. Commonwealth paramountcy. The test is imprecise, Lane (1997
p 413) stating that this ‘law for any purpose, not just for a section
The tests for inconsistency 109 purpose’ is a slippery exercise.
The first hint of such a test came in Amalgamated Society of
The possibility of inconsistency depends on there being
Engineers v Adelaide Steamship Co Ltd (1920) but it was not until
commonality of underlying subject matter. For example, there is 1926 that it was firmly stated by Isaacs J in Clyde Engineering Co
no inconsistency if the Commonwealth imposes taxes for Ltd v Cowburn (1926). Its most definitive statement however was
Commonwealth purposes and the states impose taxes for state delivered in 1930 by Dixon J in McLean (1930):
purposes (eg the States have power to impose income taxes).
The converse however does not necessarily apply. There need [inconsistency] depends upon the intention of the
not be inconsistency although there is underlying commonality. paramount legislature to express by its enactment,
For example, state and federal police may investigate the same completely, exhaustively or exclusively, what shall
matter but for different purposes. be the law governing the particular conduct or
matter to which its attention is directed … When a
The tests applied by the courts to determine inconsistency are federal law discloses such an intention, it is
not mutually exclusive but fall into different characterisations inconsistent with it for a law of a state to govern
with overlaps. the same conduct or matter.

Repugnancy Lane (1997 p 413) cites two weaknesses with this test:

Repugnancy involves a direct collision between state and federal 1. What constitutes the ‘field’ covered by federal law?
law. It is impossible to obey both laws. Obedience to the one is 2. When is the federal ‘coverage’ effected completely, exhaustively
disobedience to the other. or exclusively?

168 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 14: THE LEGAL AND REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT OF MINING

The field In Wenn v AG (Vic) (1948) both Commonwealth and state laws
gave employment preference to World War Two ex-servicemen.
The scope of the field depends on the characterisation of the The Commonwealth law dealt with ex-servicemen seeking
Commonwealth law; that is ‘what exactly is the Commonwealth employment and reinstatement, while a Victorian Act dealt with
law about?’ This focuses on the legal meaning of the law and not promotion within existing employment. The High Court, in
the pragmatics of the way in which the law operates. finding inconsistency, said that the federal law made:
elaborate provisions for the benefit of
Coverage ex-servicemen … [and] deals extensively with
many aspects of rehabilitation (Wenn v AG (Vic)
Exclusions 1948, p 103).
As noted above, federal law may either expressly or impliedly Width and detail was also discussed in Noarlunga Meat22. South
show an intention to exclude state law, which incidentally Australian law required state registration of slaughtermen while a
indicates the coverage of a field. Since the several tests are not Commonwealth law dealing with export meat slaughtering
mutually exclusive, express and implied exclusion may be applied required Commonwealth registration of slaughtermen. The High
in their own right or as components of the covering the field test. Court described the width and detail of the federal law as:
The width and detail of Commonwealth law: extremely elaborate and detailed … almost every
The width and detail cannot be restricted by Commonwealth detail is prescribed (O’Sullivan v Noarlunga
omission. There can be an inconsistency even where federal law Meat Ltd (No 1) 1954, pp 591-592).
does not cover matters covered by state law. The Commonwealth
The South Australian law was judged inconsistent, thus
is considered to have tacitly adverted to the ‘whole’ relevant area
permitting a Commonwealth-registered slaughterman to work in
of law and to have declined to specifically legislate for part of a South Australian meat works without first obtaining South
that whole without diminishing the width and detail of the Australian registration.
coverage of that ‘whole’.
Virtually universally therefore, whenever the Commonwealth
legislates within its powers, state laws will be found to be
inconsistent and invalid to the extent of the inconsistency. To a
22. O’Sullivan v Noarlunga Meat Ltd (No 1) (1954) 92 CLR 565, significant extent the several tests of inconsistency necessarily
affirmed by the Privy Council in (1956) 95 CLR 177. predetermine that result.

Australian Mineral Economics 169


CHAPTER 15

Mineral Taxation and Royalties


Frank Harman and Pietro Guj

Introduction
Economic Rent
Relevant Constitutional Powers
Design Principles for the Taxation of Mineral Rents
Current Mineral Taxation Regimes in Australia
Evaluating Australian Mineral Taxation and Royalty Systems
Commonwealth Company Income Tax
Mineral Revenue Policies for the Future

INTRODUCTION regimes in Australia. This demonstrates how economic rents


arise in the minerals sector in unique ways relative to other
Minerals sector taxation sectors of the economy and it shows why economic rents in the
minerals sector are the object of special taxation regimes. This is
Along with other sectors of the economy, the minerals sector followed by a discussion about how governments, if they wish to
(including oil and gas exploration and production) is exposed to capture part of these rents, should have the constitutional powers
a variety of taxes and charges. These are levied by to do so through the ownership of mineral resources, and a legal
Commonwealth, state and local governments. A common range right to impose tax regimes on the minerals sector.
of taxes and charges is applied to all sectors of the economy, The next section argues that governments should use well-
though the details of state and local government taxes and established tax design principles to ensure that important social
charges may differ from place to place. objectives are achieved with the taxation of economic rents in the
There are significant differences between the taxation minerals sector. These principles include:
treatment of the minerals sector and all other industry sectors in • economic efficiency in the way in which minerals are extracted;
three areas. These are:
• fairness or equity in the way the tax burden is allocated;
• mineral royalties collected by the states and the Northern
Territory under a variety of statutory provisions and related • a low administrative burden in terms of the costs of
regulations; complying with and enforcing the tax system;
• taxation collected by the Commonwealth under the Petroleum • transparency in the liability for taxation from mining activity;
Resource Rent Tax Assessment Act 1987, and the royalties and
collected by the Commonwealth under the Petroleum • stability in the revenue flow to governments.
Submerged Lands Act 1967; and
The chapter then moves to a discussion of the various mineral
• company income tax collected by the Commonwealth taxation and royalty systems currently in place by the
Government under special provisions contained in division governments of the states, the Northern Territory and the
40 of the Income Tax Act 1997. Commonwealth, together with data on the economic significance
These special aspects of the government imposts on the of minerals sector taxation for government finances. These
minerals sector are the focus of this chapter. current systems are then reviewed in the light of the tax design
principles to assess the ability of the mineral sector taxation
systems to achieve social objectives.
Contents of this chapter
The provisions of the Commonwealth company income tax
Building on the foundation discussion in earlier chapters, this specifically formulated for the Australian mineral exploration
chapter begins with a detailed analysis of the concept of and mineral sectors are then explained and the chapter concludes
economic rent as the basis for the mineral taxation and royalty with a discussion of mineral taxation policies for the future.

Australian Mineral Economics 171


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

A note on terminology This argument, however, may be simplistic in that progressive


lowering of extraction costs will ensure that projects get
In the literature on the taxation of the minerals sector, the developed in sequence as a function of their profitability, which
discussion is frequently couched in terms of mineral royalties takes account of the prevailing taxation regime. Taxation of
rather than mineral taxes. The use of the term royalty goes back non-renewable resources ensures the consideration of
to the time when monarchs claimed a right to the so-called royal intergenerational issues in the social taxation equation. The
minerals of gold and silver. In its modern usage, royalty has question of an determining appropriate taxation rates, to achieve
come to mean a payment in return for awarding a right of some a desired level of intergenerational equity, is a matter for society
form. This has special meaning in the Australian context and, as to decide through the political process.
indicated below, there is a debate about whether the revenues
taken by the state governments from the mining industry
constitute a royalty (based on the states’ handing over the right to ECONOMIC RENT
extract minerals owned by the state) or a tax. For the purposes of
this chapter, royalties collected by state governments will be Economic rent and normal profit
considered as taxes, though reference will be made to mineral
It is important to be absolutely clear about the meaning of
taxation and royalty regimes. economic rent and normal profit.
Economic rent is the surplus revenue over and above costs of
Why are there special taxation and royalty production, where costs of production are counted as including
regimes for the minerals sector? the appropriate level of normal profit.
Australian governments give a number of reasons why the Normal profit is the financial return to investors necessary to
minerals sector should be subjected to a special taxation and attract and maintain their investment in a business activity. It is
royalty regime, in addition to the range of taxes normally determined by the return on alternative activities with the same
imposed on all business sectors in the economy. These relate to risk profile. In other words, it is the minimum rate of return to
investors that is acceptable, given other comparable investment
the sector’s capital intensity, the depletion of non-renewable
opportunities. Normal profit is an important concept in economic
resources, and the desirability to generate a return to the public theory, and it is sometimes described by other terms, such as the
as the original owners of natural resources. For example, the opportunity cost of capital and the threshold rate of return.
authors of Mineral Resources Tasmania (2004, p 11) state that:
Considering normal profit as a cost of production differs from
Royalty is not a tax but a payment to the the accounting treatment of profit, which sees it as an overall
community for the purchase of non-renewable surplus after costs – including interest expenses, but not normal
resources from the state. profit – have been recovered. The accounting framework does
not distinguish between normal profit and economic rent and it
At the most fundamental level, however, it is the existence of groups the equity return component of normal profit and
economic rent (ie a return on investment exceeding a normal economic rent together as accounting profit. Accounting profit
rate of return that would be sufficient to attract investment into (subject to some differences over the tax and accounting
the enterprise) in the minerals sector that provides the basis for treatment of a number of expenses such as depreciation) is the
the imposition of additional taxing regimes. Economic rent also measure of profit that forms the base for the imposition of
arises in many other sectors with the theory having its genesis in company income tax by the Commonwealth Government as
agricultural land. discussed later in the chapter.
Before undertaking an investment in the minerals sector, investors Normal profit as a cost of production is a notion that is
must have a realistic expectation that their investment will provide sometimes difficult to comprehend. An intuitive understanding
future returns commensurate with the magnitude of their investment can be grasped by looking instead at wages. What does an
and the risk that they will bear. Over time, the minerals sector employer have to pay workers to attract and hold them in the
generates variable profit levels and sometimes profits are at levels business? The answer is at least what they could get in wages
higher than the level of profit (normal profit) necessary to attract from another employer, that is, their opportunity cost and wages
and retain shareholders’ funds in the industry. This surplus are clearly a cost of production.
(economic rent) over the minimum profit level required by If entrepreneurial activity were separated from the ownership
shareholders represents the revenue on which government can, in of capital, a comparable question would be: What rate of return
principle, levy taxation without discouraging investment. do entrepreneurs have to pay the owners of capital to attract and
Naturally, a finite mineral resource may generate ‘economic hold capital in their business? The answer is at least the rate of
rent’ only over part of the mine life, with subnormal profits return that the owners of capital could get from another
occurring when commodity prices are low. In theory the true entrepreneur with the same risk characteristics. This is the
level of profitability could only be assessed after the deposit has opportunity cost of capital (normal profit) and is comparable
been exhausted, following recovery of the initial investment and with wages as a cost of production. Consider the consequences if
achievement of ‘normal’ rate of return. an entrepreneur did not continue to pay the opportunity cost of
Now let us reflect on whether mining activity should be taxed labour and capital. The owners of labour and capital would
because it involves the depletion of non-renewable resources. transfer their labour and capital to other businesses and the
Consider the case of a mine that, before any special tax regime business would close. Paying both capital and labour their
(but with the same taxes as paid by every other economic opportunity cost is clearly a cost of keeping the business running.
activity), was producing a mineral with an average cost of Regulatory decision-making agencies such as the Australian
production (including normal profit and common taxes) equal to Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) use the
its average revenue. concept of normal profit widely. They typically refer to normal
If government imposes an additional tax on the basis that the profit as the weighted average cost of capital (WACC). The
mine operators are exploiting a non-renewable resource, then concept of normal profit is also used in economic evaluation
costs of production will exceed revenue. The mine will close. In techniques such as net present value (NPV) and economic value
the absence of some other compelling reason to close the mine added (EVA).
(for example environmental degradation), the imposition of a tax The origin of the term rent is in the application of the concept
results, in this case, in a loss of immediate mineral revenue to the of surplus to the earnings of landlords. With land in limited
community. supply, landowners could extract any surplus over costs of

172 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

production from tenant farmers (where their cost of production Economic rent, scarcity and the minerals sector
would include the opportunity cost of the tenant farmers’ own
labour) through the rent they charged. More fertile land would It is possible to refine further the concept of economic rent in the
yield higher rents than less fertile land. minerals sector by considering the several sources of scarcity that
give rise to economic rents.
Where land was of such limited fertility that the cost of
producing crops to the tenant farmer (excluding rent to the Firstly, there is the idea of generalised scarcity that arises
landlord) was equal to the revenue from their sale, there could be because a product is in short supply relative to its demand. This
no rent for the landowner. This is the marginal farm, and this generalised scarcity can be either a short-run or long-run
concept, recast as the marginal mine, has an important phenomenon depending on whether, in the long run, increased
application in the design of mineral taxation systems. supply can alleviate a short term scarcity.
In the modern minerals sector, the application of the concept • In the minerals sector an increase in demand for a particular
of rent is the same. The owner of mineral resources has the product, without an increase in supply, will give rise to
ability to acquire economic rents either by undertaking mining economic rents in the short term as a result of price increases
activity directly, or through the terms and conditions imposed on that flow from the scarcity induced by the increase in
any proposed mineral extraction by another party. Where the demand. This is common in the minerals sector as its capital
government is the owner of the resource, it has the same intensive nature creates long lead times in the development
capability of extracting rents as any private owner. In recent of new sources of supply. The substantial investment
times, however, governments have generally been reluctant to required to develop new operations further adds to the
engage in mining activity directly and they rely on extracting reluctance of businesses to increase production rapidly.
rents through taxation systems imposed on private sector mining • In the longer term, these demand and price increases should
activities. encourage an increase in the supply and a reduction in, or
even an elimination of, the economic rents as long as
Economic rent and scarcity previously untapped mineral resources are available at a
competitive cost of production.
In general, economic rent is the result of scarcity due to the
following factors: • If new resources are not available, prices can increase
alarmingly, creating surging rents because of the increasing
• changes in supply and demand for a product; scarcity as the currently exploited reserves are depleted.
• the deliberate actions of governments or businesses to restrict • At some point, the rising prices may make substitutes
supply and hence generate higher prices;
worthwhile, and the depletion process will then stop with the
• the introduction of new technologies or products; and switch to the substitutes.
• the parsimony of nature (high-grade ores are not as common This analysis of generalised scarcity for the mineral sector is
as low-grade ores and all ores are in limited supply). associated with the work of Hotelling (1931)1.
All of these factors give rise to either higher prices or lower Secondly, there is the situation where mineral resources are
costs, or both, and so are able to generate a surplus over costs of available for exploitation, but they differ in quality, some high
production. It is important to note that economic rent does not grade and others low grade. The owners of high-grade resources
determine price, but rather that price determines economic rent. will receive differential rents. They arise because high quality
Economic rents are not restricted to the minerals sector, but the resources have a lower cost of extraction and yet the uniform
minerals sector classically generates and can maintain economic final product sells for the same price regardless of the original
rents because of some of its unique characteristics. These quality of the resource. At the limit, there is the marginal mine
include: that earns no rent2.
If there is a fall in final product prices, low-grade resources may
• Volatility in both the demand and supply of mineral products, lose their economic rent and become marginal, but the operations
leading to large fluctuations in mineral prices independent of
based on high-grade resources will continue to earn economic
costs of supply.
rent. What was previously the marginal mine now becomes
• Differences in the quality of mineral resources, where sub-marginal and no longer earns sufficient revenue to pay all
differences in the quality (grades) result in differences in the costs of production, including normal profit, and will close down.
cost of producing a standardised unit of product – with the Figure 15.1 illustrates the relationships between generalised
same market price for the product, low-cost producers will rents, differential rents and the no rent case for a given market
achieve higher surpluses over costs of production including price.
normal profits.
• The high entry costs in the industry creates the natural
High-grade Low-grade Marginal
conditions for the formation of cartels which then can
mine mine mine
operate successfully in a way that generates a higher price (zero rent)
than the competitive market price. The OPEC cartel is the
obvious example. As the cartel manages supply it increases Generalised Generalised
price for all producers, the surplus is enhanced. rent rent
Politicians and political commentators describe the rents that
Differential
result from these factors as excess profits or windfall profits, but rent Cost of Cost of
Price
‘economic rent’ is the preferred analytical and policy-relevant production production
term.
Cost of
1. The original Hotelling analysis was not widely appreciated until the production
oil crisis of the 1970s (see Solow, 1974).
2. The concept of differential rent is associated with the 19th century
economist David Ricardo and differential rents are also referred to as FIG 15.1 - Generalised rents, differential rents and zero rents for
Ricardian rents. different mines.

Australian Mineral Economics 173


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

Thirdly, there is the possibility of a location rent. This is an That all participants in the economy pursue economic rent is a
extension of the previous case of differential rent: central focus of economic analysis generally, not just in the
• two mining operations may have the same quality resource, mineral sector. The difference is that, in the wider economy, such
and the same extraction technology applied equally rents are usually only short term in nature. Economists call these
efficiently to the resource, and sell at the same price in the rents quasi-rents and they generally appear because of:
market; • changes in consumer tastes,
• if, however, one is closer to the point of sale of the final • new products, and
product than the other, its total costs, including transport • new methods of production.
costs, will be lower, resulting in a location rent.
Quasi-rents will disappear in the short or long term where
Finally, there is the case of monopoly rents where producers there is no constraint on the long-term supply of goods and
artificially induce scarcity by restricting supply and increasing services, and no restriction on entry by new companies into the
the price, hence increasing the economic rent: rent earning sectors and depending on how quickly economic
• the classic way this has occurred in the minerals sector is resources can be moved to overcome scarcity.
through cartel-type arrangements where a number of This is because owners of land, labour and capital currently
producers (and all producers if the cartel can organise it) invested in a sector that does not have any economic rents – only
agree to accept reductions in production through the use of normal profit – will shift their resources into the rent-producing
quotas; sector in an attempt to capture rents. The existence of economic
• the consequent contrived scarcity may be sustained as long rents thus acts as an important signal about how resources should
as the producers in the cartel stick to their quotas, and the be allocated between sectors of the economy, and the pursuit of
higher prices do not encourage non-members or new entrants these rents brings about a desirable reallocation of economic
to expand output; resources in an economy.
• generally, cartel activities are illegal and they do suffer from As a general principle it is not appropriate for governments to
cheating by members and increased production by tax quasi-rents. To do so stifles the economic resource
non-members. reallocation process that these quasi-rents induce and leads to a
lower level of social wellbeing as a result of the failure to bring
about a reallocation of economic resources in accordance with
Pursuing economic rent the demands of consumers.
Given the existence of sustained economic rents in the minerals The foregoing analysis, however, is predicated on the
sector, it is not surprising that governments wish to share in the assumption of a perfectly elastic supply of mineral resources and
rents. The preferred method to do this is through the taxation the free movement of labour and capital in the long run. In the
system. As will be seen below there are other methods available, minerals sector these conditions do not apply. Hence the
although these are less satisfactory from an economic argument for government accessing mineral sector rents (or at
perspective. In addition, other participants in the minerals sector least a proportion of them) differs from any argument about
also try to gain access to economic rents. For example, accessing all economic rents, including quasi-rents.
employees will seek higher levels of wages for their labour, and It is important to acknowledge that it is not necessary to devise
suppliers of other inputs into mining operations will attempt to a special taxation regime to collect economic rents. The
increase their prices. The development of native land title rights company income tax has a tax base that includes both the return
in Australia is also seeing rents flowing towards Aboriginal to the equity component of normal profit and any economic rent.
people, sometimes quite explicitly as a royalty. Similarly, the This tax collects some economic rents. The company income tax,
transfer of mineral rights between businesses will sometimes however, is primarily designed as a tax on the income accruing to
include provisions that indirectly relate to the economic rent of the owners of capital in all corporate sectors of the economy. It is
the deposit. not designed as an efficient tax on economic rents in the minerals
Pursuing economic rents that initially accrue to mining sector3.
companies is possible because economic rents are a surplus,
rather than a cost of production. Theoretically, then, the RELEVANT CONSTITUTIONAL POWERS
extraction of economic rents through taxation or higher input
prices should not change the optimal level of production activity Ownership and control of mineral resources
of the mining operation because costs of production, including
normal profit, will still be covered. This theoretical outcome is The Australian Constitution confers on the Commonwealth
based on rent-seekers being able to extract the economic rent Government specific powers in areas such as defence, customs and
without reducing the ‘normal profit’ flowing to the company. excise, and monetary and fiscal management. Where the
Naturally the mining companies would prefer to keep the rents Constitution is silent, however, relevant powers rest with the states.
for themselves. As a consequence, the states have ownership and control of
For governments, the source of economic rent is captive in the mineral and petroleum resources within their jurisdiction.
sense that, once mineralisation has been discovered or a mine has The Northern Territory is not in the same constitutional
been established, its locality cannot be changed. This contrasts position as the states as it is a territory that derives its powers
with manufacturing, which can physically relocate to a region from the Commonwealth Government under the Northern
with lower taxes. However, a heavy rent taxing regime relative to Territory (Self-Government) Act 1978. Although the Territory has
the tax regime in other states or countries with comparable extended powers of self-government, major powers retained by
geological prospectivity and mining opportunities can discourage the Commonwealth include rights in respect of Aboriginal land,
investment in mineral exploration. the mining of uranium and industrial relations.
The Seas and Submerged Lands Act 1973 declared
Commonwealth Government ownership of mineral resources as
3. A company income tax could be an efficient tax on economic rents if extending to the high water mark of the seas adjoining the states.
it had the design principles of the Brown tax (see Garnaut and The High Court upheld the constitutional validity of this
Clunies-Ross, 1983). legislation in 1975.

174 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

There is, however, an agreement between the Commonwealth has interpreted this clause broadly, so that the states are effectively
and the states, the offshore constitutional settlement (OCS), precluded from using any tax applied on goods and services.
(concluded at the premiers’ conference in 1979), which provides The consequence is that when they seek to extract rents from
the basis for an agreed division of powers between the mining operations, it is necessary for the states to assert that what
Commonwealth and the states in relation to coastal waters and in is being imposed is not a tax, but instead a charge on
relation to, amongst other matters, the regulation of offshore private-sector mining companies relating to the conversion of
petroleum exploration. The Commonwealth assumed ownership, public property into private property (Crommelin, 1996).
legislative powers over, and management of, offshore petroleum Calzada (2000) discusses the legal arguments over the issue of
resources including natural gas, subject to a number of whether royalties constitute a tax or a charge.
compensatory measures and royalty-sharing provisions with the
states. Included in these powers was that of setting and collecting Generally the states have imposed these charges through the
mineral and petroleum royalties. relevant administrative department that deals with the minerals
sector. The charges then appear in state budgets as departmental
Under the settlement the Commonwealth has given some de
revenues rather than tax revenues.
facto sovereignty to the states by recognising both a baseline that
determines the extent to which any waters are under state States can also obtain revenues as a result of a statutory
jurisdiction, and the concept of a territorial sea extending three agreement with a specific company, where the enabling statute
nautical miles (5.6 km) out from a baseline4. This gives the states contains a mineral royalty provision based on the transfer of
control over mining activities on the landward side of the minerals from public to private ownership. Statutory agreements,
territorial sea border, including the right to impose tax and sometimes referred to as state agreements, are particularly
royalty regimes. relevant in Western Australia, but there are also instances in other
In the offshore areas under exclusive Commonwealth states.
jurisdiction, states, under the OCS, have an administrative role At the Commonwealth level, the relevant legislation provides
(as designated authorities) determining mineral extraction directly for the collection of revenue through the taxation of the
activities and there is a sharing of some of the revenues collected mineral sector. The main tax instrument of the Commonwealth is
by the Commonwealth. These arrangements currently only apply the petroleum resource rent tax (PRRT) which, as the name
to the oil and gas industry. suggests, applies only to petroleum (oil and natural gas). Because
It was only in the late 19th century that the Australian colonies the mineral rights were transferred under the pre-existing royalty
adopted the principle of Crown ownership of sub surface mineral regime the Commonwealth has exempted the north west shelf
rights (effectively state government ownership) (O’Hare, 1971). area from the PRRT and instead retains taxes based on the value
Prior to this time, owners of freehold title (land alienated from of production rather than the value of economic rents.
the Crown) had rights both to the surface and to subsurface
minerals. The number of cases in this situation still prevailing is DESIGN PRINCIPLES FOR THE TAXATION OF
small and in some circumstances the Crown has resumed
subsurface rights5.
MINERAL RENTS
Holders of surface rights in the Australian states have only a There are a number of well established principles for the design
limited ability to influence the extent of exploration and mining of a good tax system. They are: economic efficiency, equity,
activity on their land. Generally, this is restricted to the granting administrative cost, transparency and revenue stability.
of permission to access the land to explore and to the recovery of
compensation for any costs the landowner may incur due to Economic efficiency
exploration and mining activity. In some cases, however, the
compensation process and related potential delays may amount One objective of a taxation system designed to collect economic
to a de facto power of veto. rents for a government should be to ensure that, as far as
possible, there is no impact on the exploration and production
Where land has been granted native title under the Native Title
activities of mining operations. That is, the same activities would
Act 1993, the Crown maintains subsurface rights, but native
occur whether the rent-collecting tax was in place or not. This is
titleholders can insist on compensation for any disturbance to
the condition of neutrality, meaning that the system being used
surface rights and compensation may be paid. A negotiation
to collect economic rent does not change the behaviour or
process involving native title claimants, mining companies and
decisions of a mining company.
state governments can give rise to indigenous land use agreements.
These agreements do not confer native title on the land, but they This neutrality concept is also encapsulated by the terms
grant recognition to the interests of Aboriginal people that are efficient and non-distorting. Efficient in the sense of allocative
parties to the agreement. In these agreements, a wide range of efficiency, where the tax does not change the way economic
outcomes is possible that can give rise to Aboriginal people resources are employed away from the optimal market allocation.
effectively obtaining access to economic rents (Denolder, 2000). By contrast, rent-collecting systems that do not achieve this
One of the most recent and relevant agreements is that negotiated condition are non-neutral, inefficient and distorting. In practical
over a diamond mining operation in the Kimberley region of terms, a non-neutral, inefficient or distorting system gives rise
Western Australia (The Australian, 2005a). to either:
• extracting too much of the resource (over-exploitation), or
Powers to raise mineral taxes • not extracting enough (high-grading),
Section 90 of the Commonwealth Constitution proclaims that relative to what would be the case in the absence of the tax
‘duties of customs and excise shall be the exclusive responsibility system.
of the Commonwealth Government’. The Australian High Court Unless there is a case for over- or under-extraction based on
some criteria other than collecting economic rents, these results
4. The baseline has been drawn to incorporate offshore islands into state are undesirable where the only objective of government is raising
jurisdictions. revenue through the collection of economic rents.
5. The New South Wales Coal Acquisition Act 1981 vested ownership of
There are circumstances where imposing a tax that changes the
all privately owned coal in the Crown and provided for compensation behaviour of a mining operation is in the social interest. This
where appropriate. applies particularly where negative externalities would otherwise

Australian Mineral Economics 175


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

apply. Negative externalities are those costs of mining activity Administrative cost
that are not borne by the mine operator in the form of costs of
production covered by mine revenue, but rather costs that are Administrative cost has two components. First, there is the issue
borne by society as a whole through, for example, pollution or of whether the cost to government of operating the tax system is
environmental degradation. high relative to the revenue received. In a worst-case outcome, a
tax system may cost more to run than it receives in revenue.
Negative externalities are examples of market failure where Ideally, the cost should be as low as possible consistent with the
competitive market forces alone do not deliver a socially optimal other objectives of a tax system.
outcome. In these circumstances, policymakers often consider
The second element is the cost to the mining company of
some form of social intervention through taxation or other complying with the tax requirements, other than the revenue
appropriate regulatory instruments. actually handed over to the government. Compliance costs
There may be an arguable case that the operation of include the administrative, accounting and legal costs borne by a
competitive markets for minerals in the face of uncertainty about mining company and similarly should be kept as low as possible
the future: consistent with the goals of the tax.
• leads to over-exploitation of non-renewable mineral resources
in the current period; and Transparency
• fails to consider the interests of future generations. This principle relates to whether miners are fully informed about
The consequence is that future generations may be relatively the tax liabilities that may follow from any proposed activity.
impoverished because the stock of non-renewable resources Transparency also refers to the openness of the taxation
passed on to them is lower than otherwise. This issue has been arrangements and collections to examination by the community.
the subject of long-standing discussion and any firm conclusions The transparency case argues for liabilities to be predictable and
are generally deferred while the prospects of making new (ideally fixed for the life of the mine) before any proposed
discoveries through further exploration exist (Tilton, 2003). mining activity takes place. Subsequent changes to the mining
tax regime create additional costs for the miners like all taxation
changes in the economy. Near full compliance with this criterion
Equity is found in the statutory state agreements discussed below. By
The equity issue is concerned with whether a tax is fair on contrast, where governments arbitrarily change the laws to
impose tax burdens that were not indicated originally, then the
taxpayers. There are a number of dimensions to fairness. The
condition of sovereign risk applies.
first is whether the tax is fair with respect to horizontal equity.
Horizontal equity implies equal treatment of equals and would
ask the question ‘are miners who generate the same amount of Stability
economic rent all paying the same amount of tax?’6. By contrast, Finally, governments often see stability in their revenue flows as
vertical equity is concerned with whether miners who generate desirable. This is because large inflows of revenues in one period
different amounts of economic rent are treated differently in the in a highly volatile context may encourage government spending
amount of tax they pay. The principle of vertical equity is programs or cuts to other taxes that cannot be sustained when
violated when a tax system fails to discriminate between high revenues from mining taxes fall away.
rent and low rent operations and instead imposes a tax on a base The problem with these criteria is that their application may give
that does not give explicit recognition to the levels of economic rise to conflict between them. For example, a tax designed to meet
rents associated with different mining operations. the efficiency criterion may suffer from high administrative costs, or
Another dimension to equity is fairness over how the tax be subject to unstable revenue flows. This leads to trade-offs in the
revenues raised from economic rents are utilised. In particular, design of mineral taxation systems so that the criteria set out above
whether the revenues should be combined with all other revenue are never fully maximised in a mineral taxation system. The nature
and dispersed in the normal budgetary processes, or of the trade-offs accepted in any particular mineral taxation regime
appropriated, at least in part by the local government or reflects the administrative capabilities of the taxation authorities,
communities of the various areas hosting the mining operations. and the strength of the influence of the minerals sector in the
political decision-making process.
There has recently been a build-up of political pressure for the
return of some of the rents directly to the regions and the
communities affected by mining. The payment of royalties to CURRENT MINERAL TAXATION REGIMES IN
Aboriginal communities is one reflection of this pressure. AUSTRALIA
Company contribution towards locally based community services
In designing any mineral taxation regime, the critical ingredients
is another example of the results of this pressure.
are the tax base and the tax rate. The tax base refers to the object
The final aspect is intergenerational equity. Depletion of from which tax revenue is being collected, while the tax rate is
mineral resources has the potential to leave future generations the proportion to be applied to the base to calculate mineral
without the ability to earn comparable levels of income as the revenue proceeds. Ideally, in the context of the minerals sector, the
asset stock inherited by future generations is diminished. base should be the economic rent derived from mining activity,
Intergenerational equity is an aspect of economic sustainability. and the tax rate should be the optimal rate at which economic
The general policy prescription for sustainability, where income rents are shared between the government and a company subject to
initially depends on the exploitation of natural resources that face a mineral taxation regime. While in principle it should be possible
eventual depletion, is that the economic rents should be used to for a government to take 100 per cent of any economic rent, in
acquire other income-earning assets that will ensure a flow of reality, governments take something less so as to maintain the
income to future generations when the natural resources are incentive for efficiency in mining operations and to account for the
depleted (Hartwick, 1977). complexity in correctly measuring the level of economic rent.

Taxes designed to capture economic rent


6. Until 1991, profits from gold mining were exempt from the
Commonwealth company income tax, but not other mining profits. There are several types of tax that attempt to capture economic
Only recently has gold mining been subject to a royalty in Western rents in the minerals sector. They include specific (unit-based)
Australia and there is no royalty on gold mining in Victoria. royalties, ad valorem royalties, profit taxes and resource rent

176 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

taxes. Some other taxes, such as the company income tax, also All of these methods are discussed below in the context of the
capture some of the available economic rents, but they are not mining taxation systems that have been used in the Australian
designed specifically for the minerals sector. At the same time, as states, the Northern Territory and the Commonwealth. While
will be demonstrated later, even those taxes ostensibly designed to there is stability in the basic design of mineral taxation systems
capture economic rents do not always succeed in their objective as in the states, there are frequent changes to the detail in response
they are only approximately targeted on economic rent and instead to industry submissions and greater sophistication in the design
have the effect of being taxes on costs of production. of taxation regimes.
Specific (unit-based) royalties – Here, the royalty is levied on a Any amount that a mining company pays to a state
base relating to the physical rather than the financial measure of a government in the form of mining royalties is deductible as an
mineral resource. The most common form is as dollars per unit expense in the calculation of Commonwealth income tax
measure of weight or volume (dollars per tonne, dollars per barrel). liabilities. With the current company tax rate of 30 per cent, for
In some cases, the specific royalty may be subject to an adjustment every dollar paid in royalty to a state government, the
over time according to changes in the price of a mineral. Commonwealth effectively foregoes 30 cents. If there were no
Ad valorem royalties – In their simplest form, ad valorem state government royalties, the Commonwealth Government
royalties consist of a uniform percentage (the rate) of the gross would have collected those 30 cents. In effect, every dollar of
sale price (the base) of a mineral product where the sale is made royalty paid to a state government only costs the mining
by the entity that extracted the resource. For example, copper company 70 cents as long as it has a company income tax
produced in Western Australia attracts a royalty of 2.5 per cent of liability. The same position applies with payments due under the
its realised value. Commonwealth’s petroleum resource rent tax. These are also
Although the ad valorem form is a relatively straightforward deductible in the calculation of company income tax.
concept, when it comes to its application, governments introduce This interaction between Commonwealth and state systems is
complexities to achieve other objectives. For example, they may always important in considering the impact of taxation generally
reward further local processing with a reduced level of royalty. on mining companies.
In many jurisdictions, there is an allowance for the deduction
of those costs associated with the domestic transport of the Tax and royalty regimes in the Australian states,
mineral from the mine to the point of sale if processed the Northern Territory and the Commonwealth7
domestically or from the port of embarkation to the point of sale
if exported. Such a system attempts to generate an approximate Queensland
ex-mine value. A similar situation occurs in the petroleum
sector, where the royalty is based on the well-head value, which In Queensland the details on the royalty regime are found in the
is the point where the petroleum reaches the top of the well. The Mineral Resources Regulation (2003).
well-head value then is the revenue from sales after deducting The royalty on coal, the most important mineral in
costs downstream from the well-head. Queensland, is seven per cent of the sale value, less a number of
Also governments may accept the sale value as the actual deductions, but not rail and road haulage costs. The ad valorem
amount displayed by the company invoices, or alternatively the rate for base and precious metals can be either fixed or variable,
value determined independently using a market price for the subject to the mining company’s choice. There are also
mineral product rather than the price actually received by the concessions for small mines and discounts where further
company. Where forward sales are involved, the government processing takes place. The fixed ad valorem rate is 2.7 per cent,
may, or may not, take the gains or losses on forward sales into while the variable rate is between 1.5 per cent and 4.5 per cent of
account in determining the base. the market price of the mineral as quoted on various metal
Profit regimes – Profit regimes are based on a measure of markets. As an example, for copper, lead and zinc, the value is
profit, which normally includes both normal profits and economic determined by the settlement price on the London Metal
rent. This tax base may not be comparable with the accounting Exchange on the relevant trading days. Similar values apply for
profit base on which general company income tax is levied. gold and silver. By using the sale price in long-established
A profit regime may incorporate a minimum specific or ad markets as the value base, the Queensland system does not take
valorem royalty component to limit the risk that government may into account any revenues or losses that may be related to
collect no revenue if there are no taxable profits and to ensure a hedging in forward markets. The variable rates system enables
minimum stability of revenue. Such systems are referred to as adjustment to the royalty rate to take into account fluctuations in
hybrid regimes. the value of the Australian dollar.
Resource rent tax – Resource rent taxes seek to identify For the purpose of determining the royalty for base and precious
economic rents by allowing the deduction of all costs of metals there are certain allowable deductions. These include
production from revenue, including normal profit, and then exchange gains and losses under a fluctuating exchange rate and
taking a share of any resulting rents. Measurement problems ocean freight costs. They do not include rail and road haulage
occur when defining an appropriate measure of the level of costs and other marketing costs. Other lower-value commodities,
‘normal profit’ to be allowed. by contrast, attract specific unit-based rates of royalty.
Other methods – Australian state governments have used Queensland also operates a ten per cent well-head value royalty
other less orthodox methods in the past in seeking to capture system for petroleum and coal bed methane (Queensland
economic rent. These include rail freight rates, pipeline licence Government, 2005).
fees, export levies and government equity. Cash bidding for
exploration tenements is a common system of extracting some Revenues from minerals and petroleum royalties in
upfront economic rent, though it is rarely used in Australia. Cash Queensland in 2004-05 were $965.7 million.
bids can be unconditional or can be part of a subsequent taxation
system based on economic rent or other tax mechanism. New South Wales
In New South Wales, coal is the dominant mineral that provides
7. A summary table, though somewhat dated, of royalty systems in the revenue to the state government (New South Wales Government,
Australian states, The Northern Territory and the Commonwealth is 2005). Until 2004, the state raised revenue through a specific
available at: http://www.industry.gov.au/assets/documents/itrinternet/ royalty of $1.70 a tonne for underground mines and $2.20 a
18_Minerals_Taxation20050316170636.pdf tonne for open cut mines.

Australian Mineral Economics 177


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

In the new regime effective from 1 July 2004, the royalty Tasmania
system is based on coal prices. Deep underground mines will pay
a royalty of five per cent of the pre-transport value of coal, The Mineral Resources Development Act 1995 prescribes, through
underground mines six per cent and open cut mines seven the Mineral Resources Regulations 1996, a complex combination
per cent. of ad valorem and profit-based royalties for most metallic mining
products (Tasmanian Government, 2005a). The ad valorem rate is
For other minerals, the royalty rate is four per cent of the 1.6 per cent of net sales, while the profit component provides
ex-mine value, where an ex-mine value is calculated as the sale additional revenue, up to a maximum of five per cent of net sales.
value less allowable deductions. In the case of low-value In addition, there is a rebate system for those mining operations
minerals, specific royalty rates of 35 cents per tonne or 70 cents that undertake significant downstream processing.
per tonne apply. Schedule 1 of the Hellyer Mine Agreement Ratification Act
New South Wales also has a profit-based royalty system, 1987 prescribed a 3.5 per cent ad valorem royalty based on sales
which applies only to specific mining operations in Broken Hill. revenue plus a complex profit component (Tasmanian
In the petroleum sector, the royalty rate is ten per cent of the Government, 2005b). The mine closed in June 2000.
well-head value, though this is only applicable after ten years, Specific royalty rates of between $0.60 and $2.40 per tonne
with rates rising from zero in the first five years to six per cent in apply to most non-metallic and quarry product, with $5.00 per
the sixth year up to ten per cent in the tenth year. The same cubic metre for building and dimension stone. Petroleum royalty
regime is in place for methane extracted from coal seams when rates are set within a band of 11 to 12.5 per cent of the well-head
the extraction is not associated with coal mining. When value onshore under the Petroleum (Submerged Lands) Act 1982.
associated with coal mining, no royalty applies. The Tasmanian Government collected royalties totalling $9.0
As can be seen in Table 15.1, revenues from minerals and million during the 2003-04 financial year (Tasmanian
petroleum royalties in New South Wales in 2004-05 were $396 Government, Mineral Resources Tasmania, 2004).
million.
South Australia
TABLE 15.1 From 1 January 2006, royalties in South Australia will be
New South Wales Government mining royalty collections, payable on an ad valorem basis of 3.5 per cent (previously 2.5
2004-05 financial year ($ million). (Source: New South Wales per cent) of the value of the minerals as assessed by the Minister
Department of Mineral Resources Annual Report 2004-05.) as empowered by the Mining Act (1971) (South Australian
Government, 2005). Value assessments are on a case-by-case
Sector Revenue ($ million)
basis, with reference to the market value of the mineral output or
Coal 354 concentrate.
Non-coal 42 The Roxby Downs (Indenture Ratification) Act 1982, was
Total 396 specifically designed for the Olympic Dam copper, uranium and
gold project. It provides for an ad valorem royalty of 3.5 per cent
of minesite revenue and, in addition, a profit-based royalty is
Victoria payable once a threshold rate of return is reached (South
The Mineral Resources Development Regulations 2002 based on Australia Government, 2004).
the Mineral Resources Development Act 1990, prescribe a 2.75 A petroleum royalty of ten per cent of well-head value came
per cent ad valorem royalty to the net market value of all into operation in 2002 and applies to state coastal waters within
minerals, except for gold which is royalty free (Victorian three nautical miles. A royalty of 2.5 per cent applies to the
Government, 2005). The net market value relates to prices well-head value of geothermal energy.
prevailing at the time when the mineral is first sold, transferred In 2003-04, the South Australian Government collected $46.74
or disposed of, less any costs reasonably, necessarily and directly million in petroleum royalties and $28.45 million from other
incurred in connection with the sale, transfer or disposal mineral royalties, for a total of $75.17 million (South Australian
(including insurance, freight and marketing expenses) of mineral Government, 2004).
products.
The specific royalty rate for brown coal was set in June 1993 Western Australia
at $0.0239 per gigajoule with values subsequently indexed by the In Western Australia, the Mining Act (1978) and related Regulations
CPI. Specific royalty rates applying to quarry products from (1982) specify two general royalty systems for minerals that are not
Crown land are prescribed under the Extractive Industries the subject of statutory state agreements (Western Australian
Development Act 1995. A petroleum royalty for onshore oil and Government, Department of Industry and Resources, 2005a):
gas is set at ten per cent of well-head value under the Petroleum
(Submerged Lands) Act of 1982 (Vic) and the Petroleum Act • a specific royalty, mostly of $0.30 or $0.50 per tonne, is
(1997). applied to most low-value, bulk, generally non-metallic
mining products;
The value of mineral royalties in the 2003-04 financial year,
which amounted to $20.9 million, appears in Table 15.2. • an ad valorem royalty is applied to the value of most
higher-value, generally metallic minerals, with the rate of
royalty reducing as a function of increased downstream
TABLE 15.2 processing of the product sold:
Victorian Government mineral royalties by sector, 2003-04
financial year. (Source: Department of Primary Industries, • crushed and screened, bulk material: 7.5 per cent;
Minerals and Petroleum Statistical Review 2003-2004.) • concentrates: 5.0 per cent; and
Sector Revenue ($ million) • metal: 2.5 per cent.
Mining 16.0 There are, however, many special cases that do not fit into the
Extractive 3.3 two general categories. These include coal, gold, cobalt and
copper if sold as nickel by-products, ilmenite concentrates used as
Onshore petroleum 1.6 feedstock into an ilmenite beneficiation plant in Western Australia,
Total 20.9 tantalum and tin when sold in any form other than metal.

178 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

The Western Australian Government has used state agreements under Commonwealth jurisdiction, it is administered by the
Acts as the preferred method of setting out terms and conditions state as the designated authority. The north west shelf project
(including obligations on the government) under which specific is the major oil and gas producer in Western Australia and it
mining and minerals processing projects proceed (Western generates substantial revenue under these royalty arrangements.
Australian Government, 2005). These agreements cover most of Sixty per cent of the primary ten per cent royalty is returned
the important mining projects in Western Australia in iron ore, to the state, while the Commonwealth keeps the balance. In
nickel, diamonds, mineral sands and bauxite-alumina. Their addition, the state is returned 100 per cent of the secondary
statutory nature means that the obligations are legally binding 2.5 per cent royalty, bringing the total split to 68 per cent to
and, where expressly designated, can only be changed by mutual the state and 32 per cent to the Commonwealth.
agreement followed by legislative amendment.
Table 15.3 sets out mineral royalties received by the Western
However, when either of the parties is seeking changes to
Australian Government, net of any remittance to the
agreement conditions trade-offs can occur and by agreement a
Commonwealth.
variation to the Act of Parliament can be made. In 2005, the
renegotiations of iron ore special agreements with BHP Billiton
and Rio Tinto to amend them for production expansion and TABLE 15.3
development of new mines gave the state government an Western Australian mining and petroleum royalties, 2004-05
opportunity to renegotiate the applicable royalty rates. The state financial year. (Source: Western Australian Government,
sought to increase the rate from the original concessional rate for Department of Industry and Resources, 2005b).
iron ore fines of 3.75 per cent to 5.625 per cent, the normal rate Sector Revenue ($ million)
paid by other iron ore miners under the regulations (Hansard,
2005; The Australian, 2005b). By contrast, the Argyle diamond Iron ore 380
project achieved a change to the royalty regime in its state Petroleum 550
agreement as it embarks on a less profitable underground extension Alumina 55
of the previously open cut project (The Australian, 2005c).
Diamonds 33
Royalty arrangements have always been an integral component
Mineral sands 27
of state agreements, as the royalty obligations have always been
negotiated in the context of other obligations imposed on the Nickel 93
mining or processing project that is the subject of the agreement. Gold 73
These other obligations have variously included requirements to
Other 46
provide township and transport infrastructure and commitments
to further processing of mineral products. Bradley (1986) Total mineral royalties† 1256
referred to these other obligations as de facto royalties.
† Excludes royalties collected on behalf of the Commonwealth (North
The royalty regimes in the state agreements are of the specific, West Shelf).
or a hybrid specific ad valorem type ($ per unit adjusted by
changes in market price of a metal) or standard ad valorem. In
the cases of the Argyle Diamond and Ellendale Diamond Northern Territory
projects, a profit-based royalty of 22.5 per cent applies over the The Northern Territory has a profit-based royalty regime for
life of the project, subject to a minimum ad valorem royalty minerals (Northern Territory Government, 2005). The system
payment of 7.5 per cent in any year. applies a rate of 18 per cent to the net value of minerals, where
Petroleum royalties in Western Australia are levied under four the net value is the gross realisation value (or sale value), less:
different Acts. Following the offshore constitutional settlement in
1979 and successive negotiations, the state and Commonwealth • operating costs,
governments agreed to allocate petroleum royalties derived from • a capital recognition deduction on eligible expenditure,
onshore and territorial sea production, Barrow Island production
• eligible exploration expenditure, and
and the offshore north west shelf (under Commonwealth
jurisdiction but administered by the state as the designated • any additional deduction approved by the minister.
authority) as set out below: The capital recognition deduction combines depreciation and
• Petroleum production on-shore and in coastal waters out to normal profit. Normal profit is defined as the long-term bond rate
the landward limit of the territorial sea attracts a ten to 12.5 plus two per cent.
per cent well-head value royalty under the provisions of the Because ownership of uranium still rests with the
Petroleum Act 1967. These royalties are 100 per cent Commonwealth Government, the Commonwealth collects
appropriated by the state. royalties on uranium mined in the Northern Territory and returns
• A similar royalty is applied to petroleum production within a them to the Northern Territory. The Commonwealth royalty on
defined state territorial sea, under the Petroleum (Submerged uranium is an ad valorem royalty of 5.5 per cent. The Northern
Lands) Act 1982. The Commonwealth takes 40 per cent of Territory Government receives a royalty equivalent from the
Commonwealth of 1.25 per cent while the Commonwealth pays
these royalties.
the balance to the Aboriginals benefit trust account (ABTA).
• The Western Australian Barrow Island Royalty Variation A ten per cent wellhead ad valorem royalty applies to petroleum
Agreement Act 1985 applies a resource rent type tax to production.
production from Barrow Island. This regime arose from
Revenue generated from mining activity (including petroleum
negotiations between the WAPET Consortium, the state and
production) in 2003-04 was $41.3 million.
the Commonwealth to replace a complex well-head royalty
and excise system that had previously applied. The state
keeps only 25 per cent of revenues from the tax, and remits The Commonwealth of Australia
the remaining 75 per cent to the Commonwealth. The petroleum resource rent tax (PRRT) was first introduced in
• Offshore production from the North West Shelf project areas, 1987 and has been amended significantly since then. As already
covered by permits WA-1P and WA-28P, attracts a ten to discussed, the petroleum resource rent tax does not apply to the
12.5 per cent well-head value royalty under the Petroleum area covered by the north west shelf project, which has an ad
Submerged Lands (Royalty) Act 1967. Although this area is valorem excise regime.

Australian Mineral Economics 179


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

The important characteristic of rent-based taxation regimes is revenues, they were finally captured in 1999 and treated as a
that costs of production, including normal profits, are deducted quasi-royalty. Subsequently, the Queensland Government phased
from cash flow before determining the tax base. Current and out excess rail charges and introduced a single royalty regime for
capital outlays are deductible in the year in which they are made, all coal mines (Commonwealth Grants Commission, 2003).
and so depreciation does not feature as a cost. Interest is not
counted as a deductible cost as it is part of the normal profit that Pipeline licence fees
is included in the calculation of total cost. The Commonwealth
has also introduced a special allowance for remote area In Victoria, in 1981, the state government attempted to impose a
exploration, whereby 150 per cent of exploration expenses may pipeline licence fee on onshore pipelines carrying crude oil from
be deducted from any revenue subject to resource rent tax the Bass Strait oil fields. The licence fee was set at $20 million.
(Commonwealth Government, 2005a). The oil producers appealed against the legality of the fee to the
For years in which costs are greater than revenues, the negative High Court. Its judges ruled in favour of the oil producers8. The
cash flow is carried forward into the following year after being Victorian Government was forced to repay money raised by the
increased by the rate of return. In effect, the legislation treats fee to Esso/BHP.
negative cash flows as an investment upon which the operator is
allowed to earn the required rate of return, or normal profit Infrastructure contributions
before paying tax.
In Western Australia, Bradley (1986) identified the practice of
The level of normal profit set in the PRRT legislation is the
the government, by means of state agreements, requiring mining
combination of a risk-free rate of return (the Commonwealth
operations to fund social infrastructure and to enter into further
ten-year bond rate) and a premium of 15 per cent for
expenditures associated with exploration, or five per cent for mineral processing commitments. Bradley referred to these
expenditures associated with development and production. requirements as de facto royalties and argued that their
consequence was effectively to reduce the formal royalty
The result is that there is no liability for tax payments under arrangements.
the PRRT until the petroleum field operator has recovered all
outlays, including any investment in the form of negative cash
flows and a normal return on that investment. Outlays on Cash bidding
unsuccessful exploration in Australia are also deductible from One method rarely used in Australia is to auction the exploration
the revenue generated by an individual project before and development rights of well defined tenements either for an
determining the resource rent tax base. Any surplus then arising upfront cash payment, or an ongoing ad valorem royalty or some
is taxable and is divided between the operator and the combination of upfront cash and royalty payments. Bidding
government on a 60:40 basis using the tax rate of 40 per cent. systems are in common use in the United States, particularly for
Revenue to the Commonwealth in 2004-05 from the petroleum petroleum tenements on the outer continental shelf.
rent royalty tax was $1460 million, while excise revenue in the The argument in favour of cash bidding is that it allocates
form of the ad valorem royalty on areas not subject to the PRRT tenements to those prepared to make the highest bid. This should
(predominantly the north west shelf project) was $309 million. indicate that the exclusive rights to exploration and development
of mineral tenements are held by those who have the best
Other issues in the collection and use of understanding of the prospectivity of a tenement and who have
economic rents in Australia the ability to operate it efficiently, or at least have the financial
resources to do so.
In the past, constitutional provisions and policy approaches have
led to the development of innovative indirect ways of collecting The cash bid should reflect the present value of the expected
mineral revenues other than through the standard mineral economic rents from a tenement and, unlike production or
revenue collection systems outlined above. In addition, there cash-flow-based systems, gives the government money at the
have been suggestions to use alternative or modified approaches start of the mining process. In addition, being a sunk cost, the
to conventional royalty regimes. This section also discusses how cash bid will have no impact on later investment and production
the states that raise revenue through tax or royalty regimes on the decisions, and therefore has the desirable attribute of neutrality.
mining sector do not always get to keep their revenues. By contrast, ad valorem royalty bidding systems are subject to
all of the same criticisms that apply to ad valorem royalties
Export levies generally.
Provision for an up-front cash bidding approach to the
In 1975, the Australian Government imposed levies on coal allocation of petroleum tenements exists in the Commonwealth
exports. As these exports came from resources in Queensland Petroleum (Submerged Lands) Act 1967, but it has been used
and New South Wales, the Commonwealth could not have sought sparingly. It was last used in 1993 (Commonwealth Government,
to collect what it perceived to be economic rents in the coal 2004).
export business directly, but could do so through constitutionally
appropriate, though economically inefficient, export levies. The The Australian states have not adopted cash bidding. Even
relevant state governments were not able or willing to extract though up-front bidding has significant benefits relative to the
these rents for themselves. The levy was abolished from 1 July other methods of allocating petroleum exploration tenements, the
1992. states have preferred to stick with the work commitment bidding
approach that gives emphasis to maximising the quantity of
exploration activity rather than the collection of economic rents.
Rail freight rates
For a number of years, the Queensland Government extracted Government equity participation
rents from the coal industry by imposing a surcharge on rail
freight rates for coal. Although initially omitted from Rather than rely on a tax system that may be inadequate to
Commonwealth Grants Commission calculations for mineral collect part of the available rents, governments in a number of
jurisdictions throughout the world have taken direct equity in
mining operations. For the most part, this is free equity given to
8. Hematite Petroleum Pty Ltd v Victoria (1983) 151 CLR 599. the government in return for the right to mine.

180 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

In recent years in Australia there has only been one case of The proceeds of the GST collected by the Commonwealth
government equity participation as a means of accessing and Government are distributed to state governments, not on the basis
distributing rents directly to citizens. This was in the context of the of equal per capita amounts, but on the basis of ability to raise
Argyle diamond mine in Western Australia. The original their own revenue and the costs of supplying state government
exploration joint venture included, along with the majority services. The objective is to achieve some degree of
participant CRA, a small company known as Northern Mining comparability in the standard of government services between
with a five per cent participation. When the project turned from an the states. Where a state raises considerable revenue out of its
exploration to a mining activity in 1983, the Western Australian mineral sector relative to that raised in other states, it effectively
Government bought Northern Mining. The company was does not keep all of that revenue. The Grants Commission
subsequently sold on the stock exchange as the Western Australian methodology has the effect of reallocating part of that revenue to
Diamond Trust. In 1989 the trust was bought out by CRA. those states that have a less than national average ability to raise
money from the mining and other sectors. This is achieved by
Hybrid resource rent tax reducing the share of GST allocation to the mineral
revenue-earning state9.
The Bradley Report into mineral revenues in Western Australia
recommended that the existing systems of royalties in Western
Australia be replaced by a resource rent type tax in combination
EVALUATING AUSTRALIAN MINERAL TAXATION
with an ad valorem system. The benefits claimed for this hybrid AND ROYALTY SYSTEMS
approach were that, as well as providing a more efficient and
equitable tax regime, the government would receive an early Assessment of different taxes
flow of income from new mining projects, thus producing a more
An important way to assess the operation of the Australian
stable and certain revenue flow to government. The ad valorem
mineral taxation and royalty systems is on the basis of the
royalty would be set at a low rate and apply only until the
criteria discussed earlier – that is, on the grounds of efficiency,
company had recovered all of its outlays and was generating equity, administrative cost, transparency, and revenue stability.
economic rent. Amounts paid initially under the ad valorem
system would then be repaid to the company through reduced
resource rent tax payments until all ad valorem payment was Specific royalties
returned. In effect, the ad valorem payment was a loan made by A levy based on physical measures such as dollars per tonne
the company to the government against future rent tax payments offends notions of efficiency and equity as it adds to costs of
and subsequently repaid. production and fails to discriminate between high rent, low rent
and no rent operations. This type of royalty leads to high-grading
Using economic rents for the future with ore left in the ground that would, in the absence of the
royalty, be extracted. It may be relatively easy to administer and
While it is granted that known mineral resources are being comply with and as long as production remains constant it will
depleted, there is a long-term question about the future of deliver a steady flow of income. Revenue will remain constant
mineral revenues as mining activity proceeds. There is the irrespective of whether the unit price of the relevant mining
prospect that price increases will offset a declining resource base product rises or falls significantly. As a consequence, politically
and thus maintain mineral revenues. There is also the prospect of difficult royalty rates adjustments become inevitable from time
the known resource stock being enhanced through further to time. Because of these considerations, specific royalties are
exploration, or technological changes that make lower grade generally applied to low- value, bulk mining and quarry
orebodies economic to mine. products.
In any case, the ultimate reduction in the flow of mineral
revenues and the corresponding effects on state or
Commonwealth income levels can be offset if the mineral
Ad valorem royalties
revenues are reinvested in new human or physical capital along These suffer, albeit to a lesser degree, from the same problems as
the lines of the suggestion by Hartwick (1977). the specific royalty with respect to efficiency and equity, and
To some extent this approach has been implemented by the they may become complex to administer if governments attempt
Alberta Heritage Fund (2005), the Alaska Permanent Fund to tailor the royalty to achieve efficiency and equity objectives.
(2005), and the Government Petroleum Fund in Norway (2005). The amount of royalty payable does rise and fall in line with
Yet, the experience of Nauru suggests that mineral revenues put movements in commodity prices, giving the ad valorem system
into a central fund opened the possibility of corrupt and an advantage over the specific royalty, but the ad valorem system
uneconomic use of those revenues, prompting the view that it still fails to discriminate between high rent, low rent and no rent
would be better to direct the funds to individual or family units mining operations, thus failing the equity criterion. The system
that might make more efficient choices (Hughes, 2004). also fails the efficiency criterion because the ad valorem system
is a tax that adds to costs of production. It adds to costs of
production because, as a tax on sale revenue, the tax applies to
Net impact of Australian federalism on state royalty both the costs of production and any economic rents that are
revenues included in sale revenue.
The net value of royalties to state governments in Australia is
influenced by the Commonwealth Grants Commission (CGC) Profit based royalties
process. The Commission recommends the formula for
These, in theory, should be an improvement over the previous
distributing revenues from the goods and services tax (GST)
two systems from an economic efficiency and equity point of
between the states on the basis of a state’s overall tax effort,
view, but still have the problem of taxing costs of production by
fiscal capacity and revenue need.
taxing normal profits as well as economic rents. This approach
may, however, introduce significant administrative complexity,
9. For a discussion of the issues associated with mineral taxation by ambiguity, compliance cost and potential for litigation. These
state governments and the procedures of the Commonwealth Grants outcomes arise because the profit calculation on which the
Commission, see Committee for the Review of Commonwealth- royalty is based generally has significant differences from
State Funding (2002). conventional profit calculations and it is also different from the

Australian Mineral Economics 181


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

calculation of net income used for the purpose of levying income imposts that are applied across all industrial sectors that
tax. A profit-based regime may also have a negative effect in incidentally raise revenue from any economic rents. These
terms of government’s revenue stability objectives. include stamp duty, payroll tax, fuel excises, and most
importantly, company income tax.
Rent-based regimes The company income tax liability is computed by applying a
30 per cent tax rate to taxable company income determined
Rent-based regimes should be efficient and equitable as long as according to the provisions of the Income Tax Assessment Act
the estimate of the rate of normal profit is accurate. If the rate is 1997.
set too high, then there is an implicit subsidy and an incentive to
over-explore and over-produce. If set too low, there will be a The majority of the income tax provisions embodied in the
disincentive to explore and produce. From the perspective of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1997 (as amended) are applicable to
community, the long delay in the receipt of revenues is a hazard, taxable income irrespective of its origin. There are, however, a
though it can be offset through the use of hybrid varieties. There number of special taxation arrangements in the company income
is debate over the extent to which a rent-based approach acts to tax system that have the effect of reducing the income taxes that
deter new investment based on the change brought about in the companies in the minerals sector pay relative to companies in
probability distribution in the risk/return trade-off (Smith, 1999). other sectors.
These special arrangements have the objective of encouraging
mining companies to undertake more exploration, and in some
Problem areas
cases development, than they would otherwise have carried out.
Taxation and royalty systems based on values or revenues can The capital-intensive and upfront nature of exploration and
give rise to administrative problems with transactions, which are development outlays, together with the risks inherent in the
not at arm’s-length, particularly for commodities not frequently industry, have traditionally been recognised as the reasons why
traded on recognised markets. Some companies may seek to the minerals sector should receive more favourable treatment.
manipulate the values on which taxes and royalties are based to
produce lower revenue for the jurisdiction in which mining takes Deductibility of exploration expenditures
place. Hughes and Singh (1978) have noted that high levels of
vertical and horizontal integration combined with Division 40 of the Income Tax Assessment Act 1997 contains the
transjurisdictional operations (mining in one jurisdiction, provisions that are relevant to mineral (including petroleum)
processing in a second and selling in a third) in some parts of the exploration and quarrying and mining activities. Subdivision
mineral sector can give rise to transfer and monopoly pricing 40-H allows immediate deductibility for exploration and
systems that effectively transfer economic rents to other prospecting expenditure. The definition of exploration or
jurisdictions, particularly those with low or zero tax. prospecting is very wide and includes (in section 40.730):
Governments have recognised this problem and have • For minerals generally:
responded by incorporating provisions in mineral revenue • geological mapping, geophysical surveys, systematic
systems to establish values for mineral production or economic search for areas containing minerals or quarry materials,
rent, based not on the prices as declared in royalty returns but on and the search by drilling or other means for minerals or
a deemed value. Where mineral commodity markets are thin, and materials within those areas; and
the value of commodity contract prices difficult to obtain or
confidential, government may make use of independent experts • the search for ore within, or near, an orebody or search
to advise on values. For some intermediate mineral products (raw for quarry materials by drives, shafts, cross-cuts, winzes,
ores and concentrates) for which markets may not exist, a rises and drilling.
suitable proxy may be provided by determining the value of the • For petroleum particularly:
product sold on the basis of the value of the actual metal
contained in it at the price prevailing at the time of shipment. • geological, geophysical and geochemical surveys; and
This practice is common for many commodities including nickel • exploration drilling and appraisal drilling.
and gold in Western Australia as well as for copper and cobalt • Feasibility studies to evaluate the economic feasibility of
when contained as co or by-products in nickel concentrates. mining minerals (including petroleum) once they have been
There is also a transfer pricing problem with a resource rent discovered.
type mineral revenue system, even if the mining, processing, and
sale are carried out in the same jurisdiction. Where a raw mineral • Obtaining mining, quarrying or prospecting information
goes straight into processing, the issue of its value for the associated with the search for, and evaluation of, areas
purpose of calculating the economic rent tax liability arises. containing minerals or quarry materials.
Where there are competitive markets for the raw mineral that are Subdivision 40-H also allows immediate deduction for
alternative supply options instead of direct processing, then expenditure on mining site rehabilitation (section 40.735.) and
government can use these market values. Where there are not immediate deduction for environmental protection activities
good proxy values based on competitive markets, government (section 40.755). Additional deductions are available as a result
must find some alternative mechanism. of Tax Ruling 95/36. In particular the removal of overburden in
In the case of natural gas that goes into integrated liquefied mining operations is a deductible expense.
natural gas projects, the Australian Government has incorporated a In strict accounting terms, exploration expenses are directed
netback approach into the PRRT. This approach deducts costs of towards the accumulation of knowledge about the geological
processing from the sale price to arrive at a value prior to further characteristics of a specific area and therefore represent the
processing that can then be used to calculate PRRT liability acquisition of (intellectual) capital. In the case of other
(Commonwealth Government, 2005b). industries, the tax authorities would not normally allow this type
of expenditure as a current deduction in the calculation of
COMMONWEALTH COMPANY INCOME TAX taxable income in the year in which it has been incurred, but
would require that it be depreciated or amortised over time. Yet,
The discussion so far has focused on those taxation and royalty as shown above, for mining companies, the Australian
systems explicitly designed to raise revenue from the economic Government does allow the deduction of exploration expenses in
rents from the minerals sector. There are a number of other the year in which they are incurred.

182 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

Depreciation of capital expenditures Other issues


Subdivision 40-I-deals with capital expenditure that is deductible It is possible to rationalise the special tax treatment of
over time. Capital expenditures on mining incurred after 30 June exploration using the concept of positive externalities. When a
2001, is deductible as a project amount through a project pool company undertakes exploration activity at its own cost:
over ten years the lifetime of the project, whichever is least. • it adds to geological knowledge by doing so, and
Mining capital expenditure is capital expenditure incurred on:
• that knowledge is available to all other mineral explorers.
• carrying out eligible mining or quarrying operations;
Exploration therefore creates a spillover effect or positive
• site preparation; externality. Other exploration companies will be able to use that
• necessary buildings or improvements; geological knowledge in adjoining areas and conduct exploration
• provision of water, light or power to the site of those at a lower cost than if the initial exploration had not been
operations; undertaken. The activity of one company therefore reduces costs
for another, but the company that incurred the initial costs is not
• building used directly for operating or maintaining treatment able to benefit from this information spillover because it does not
plant; have property rights to the information.
• buildings and improvements for storing minerals or quarry For this to be true it is, however, important that the
materials for treatment; and geoscientific information generated by the mineral exploration
• housing and welfare – except for quarrying operations. industry be properly collated, managed and widely and freely
distributed by the relevant state institutions, generally the
Transport capital expenditure is depreciable over ten years. It geological surveys.
includes capital expenditure on: In the light of this mismatch between costs incurred by the
• a railway, road, pipeline, port or other facility used initial exploration and benefits generated for the initial explorer
principally for mining or quarrying transport; and all other explorers, the amount of exploration without some
• obtaining a right to construct or install such a facility; form of subsidy would be less than what was socially desirable.
The special tax treatment of exploration expenses provides a
• compensation for damage for constructing or installing such benefit to exploration companies that reflects the benefits they
a facility; provide to the exploration sector as a whole when they carry out
• earthworks, bridges, tunnels or cuttings; and exploration activities.
• contributions made in carrying on business to someone else’s Another area of federal taxation that bears a strong influence
expenditure on the above items. on the viability of mining projects is the treatment of hedging
gains and losses on forward sales. In recent years, many
There may, therefore, be significant differences between commodity markets have tended to be in contango rather than in
shorter asset lives used to determine income tax payable and the backwardation. Recall from Chapter 7 that contango is a state of
longer asset lives used, according to accounting standards, to affairs whereby the forward price of a commodity is higher in
determine the annual profit in the financial statements in a succeeding months than in the nearest delivery month.
company’s annual report. Where shorter asset lives are allowed Backwardation is the opposite situation.
in the determination of company tax liabilities, the result is that With contango in place, mining companies selling forward, part
some tax is deferred. or the whole of their production, may realise higher prices than if
The Australian depreciation provisions for mining may not be they sold on the spot market. They derive this benefit, however, by
attractive compared to some of the other fiscal regimes with foregoing the benefit that they would have derived if the spot price
which Australia competes for investment in the industry. Recent on the delivery date were to exceed the corresponding forward
changes have seen the removal of accelerated depreciation for price. Aside from neutralising market risk, however, hedging has
mining activities and a move to establish common depreciation been used as a funding mechanism for mining operations.
principles (the Uniform Capital Allowance system) across all Providers of project finance may insist on part of the first few
sectors of the economy. years’ production to be sold forward to reduce potential revenue
Current taxation laws discriminate in favour of large integrated volatility while their loans are outstanding and therefore at risk.
companies compared with pure explorers. The former can write The Australian Taxation Office draws a clear distinction between
off their exploration and prospecting expenditure in the year in companies or individual making use of forward or future sales for
which they incur it against taxable income generated by a related speculative purposes and genuine mining companies using a
company, thus accelerating cash flows. A related company is one schedule of successive forward contracts as an insurance and
that either owns or is owned by the exploration company or funding mechanism. In the latter cases, companies are allowed to
which is co-owned by a common parent company. By contrast, a roll contracts over for a specified and clearly planned period of
pure explorer may lack any taxable income against which to time without incurring a tax liability on the gain realised at each
write off its exploration expenditure, and can only capitalise it rollover. By contrast, in the case of speculators, each contract
and, in effect, carry forward the relevant loss until the company closure would engender a tax liability.
generates some taxable income or is sold. This may take many
years, during which cash flow is delayed and, under inflationary
conditions, the tax-shield effect of exploration expenditure is
MINERAL REVENUE POLICIES FOR THE FUTURE
gradually eroded. The prevailing situation in Australia at the time of writing is one
It is for the foregoing reasons that small and middle-size of stability. The Commonwealth is committed to the use of the
exploration companies have lobbied strongly but unsuccessfully resource rent approach, which currently applies to offshore
for the introduction of a ‘flow-through share scheme’ whereby petroleum projects, but it is prepared to be flexible and respond
exploration expenditure would become a legitimate tax to industry concerns (Commonwealth Government, 2005c).
deduction in the hands of shareholder subscribing equity funds to State governments are unwilling to move out of the dominant
the company. The introduction of such a scheme in Canada has specific and ad valorem modes, though they are making them
resulted in a marked revival of exploration investment in that more effective through the removal of exemptions, and through
country (Hall, 2003). better determination of the value base, moving it closer to a net

Australian Mineral Economics 183


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

value of the minerals, and thus creating a less distorting result was a major contribution to the economics literature of the
approach. There are currently no resource rent-based mineral time, which focused on the meaning of economic rent and the
(excluding petroleum) royalties in Australia, while the means by which governments might share in economic rents. A
application of profit-based royalties is an exception. number of issues were settled in the academic literature of that
While the theoretical analysis is fairly unanimous in considering time, such as the theoretical preference for rent-based mineral
resource rent-based systems as the most economically efficient revenue systems over production- or value-based systems.
and equitable, there is a question as to why their degree of Since that time, the literature has been largely confined to
acceptance by state governments has been so low. tidying up the earlier analysis with no great innovations or
Given that governments are aware of the underlying economic perspectives coming to the fore. This pattern in the literature was
theory, there are a number of reasons that may explain their mirrored in the actions taken by governments in the same period.
acceptance of the inefficiency of currently applied systems. There were major government inquiries and many legislative
These include: innovations. By the end of the 20th century, this process had
halted, with established positions being maintained and little
• Administrative complexity and potential for ambiguity and
litigation inherent in profit and rent-based royalty systems. external pressure for change. Only in those countries where
These stem from the determination of the rent base on which previously there was no attempt to capture economic rents, for
the tax is to be applied. Few government instrumentalities are example in Chile and Peru, is there a current interest in the
currently adequately resourced to administer the prevailing design of rent-collecting systems.
royalty systems, let alone alternative profit- or rent-based
systems. While it may be the case that the addition of REFERENCES
resources to royalty-collecting agencies has the potential for
Alaska Permanent Fund, 2005. [Online] <http://www.apfc.org>.
improving returns, governments have been reluctant to do so.
Alberta Heritage Fund, 2005. [Online] <http://www.finance.gov.ab.ca/
• Variability in revenue due to the volatility of commodity business/ahstf/index.html>.
prices over time. Bradley, P G, 1986. Report of the Mineral Revenues Inquiry, Volumes 1
and 2 (Western Australian Government: Perth).
• Delays in revenue flows due to the ability to carry forward
and increase early project losses. Calzada, M, 2000. State government mining royalties: requited taxes or
duties of excise? Murdoch University Electronic Journal of Law,
• Complexity and cost of compliance on both industry and 7(3). [online]. Available from: <http://www.murdoch.edu.au/elaw/
government. There is an obvious difference between the cost issues/v7n3/calzada73.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
of administering a specific royalty based on weight alone and Committee for the Review of Commonwealth-State Funding, 2002. Review
auditing the allowable deductions of exploration and of Commonwealth-State funding, the final report [online]. From:
development projects of an oil company in Australia. Only <http://www.reviewcommstatefunding.com.au/library/finalrep.pdf>.
projects with significant size, unit price for their output and Commonwealth Government, 2004. Cash bidding system in Australia,
gross value of production (especially petroleum projects) [online]. Available from: <http://www.industry.gov.au/assets/
may justify high compliance costs. documents/itrinternet/Cash_biddingJun0420040702090134.pdf?CFI
D=12760506&CFTOKEN=64966678>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Nonetheless, small forays have been made with the Commonwealth Government, 2005a. Details of the petroleum resource
introduction in 2000, in Western Australia, of a new hybrid rent tax [online]. Available from: <http://www.industry.gov.au/
royalty system for vanadium pentoxide. This featured a net back content/itrinternet/cmscontent.cfm?objectid=4A1DE71A-BF9F-4DE
approach subject to a minimum 1.5 per cent ad valorem D-B1667CC766651FA7&indexPages=/content/azindex.cfm,/content/
azindex.cfm?keyword=taxation>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
component. Unfortunately the Windimurra vanadium mine to
which this system applied has since closed down for unrelated Commonwealth Government, 2005b. Gas transfer price methodology
[online]. Available from: <http://www.industry.gov.au/assets/
reasons; hence not much has been learned from this experiment. documents/itrinternet/Gas_Transfer_Price_Methodology_-_050527_
One might argue that governmental reluctance to move to V0120050531141500.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
profit or resource rent based systems is denying the opportunity Commonwealth Government, 2005c. Recent changes to the PRRT regime
to return rents to the citizens either in the form of lower taxation [online]. Available from: <http://www.treasurer.gov.au/tsr/content/
in other areas or increased government expenditures. State pressreleases/2005/054.asp>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
governments are also denying themselves the opportunity to use Commonwealth Grants Commission, 2003. Mining revenue,
the rents from the minerals sector to create substitute assets that Commonwealth Grants Commission Draft assessment paper 2003/13
[online]. Available from: <http://www.cgc.gov.au/State_Downloads/
could maintain the flow of income into the future, given that R2004/daps/DAP%202003_13%20Mining%20Revenue.pdf>. Date
existing income levels are based on a depleting asset base. With accessed: 8 May 2006.
the high levels of foreign ownership in the Australian mining Crommelin, M, 1996. State agreements: Australian trends and
industry, leaving the rents with the companies seems unlikely to experience, Australian Mining and Petroleum Law Association
generate investment that would provide income earning assets for Yearbook, pp 328-349 (AMPLA Limited: Melbourne).
the citizens of the Australian states from which the rents are Denolder, T, 2000. Terms of the deal: native title agreements, Australian
derived. Based on her analysis of the situation in Nauru, Hughes Mining and Petroleum Law Association Yearbook, pp 537-556
(2004) suggests that the best approach is to return the rents to the (AMPLA Limited: Melbourne).
citizens directly and allow them to make investment decisions. Garnaut, R and Clunies-Ross, A, 1983. Taxation of Mineral Rents,
(Clarendon Press: Oxford).
With respect to the company income tax, the trend will
Government Petroleum Fund, 2005. [Online]. Available from:
probably be towards further harmonisation of the conditions <http://www.norges-bank.no/english/petroleum_fund/reports/1999/3.
relating to mining with those applying to all other industries. html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Hall, B, 2003. Canadian incentives for mineral exploration and mining,
NOTE ON REFERENCES [online]. Available from: <http://www.ausimm.com/policy/canadian
03.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
The oil price increases of the 1970s and early 1980s, as well as Hansard, 2005. Legislative Assembly, Thursday, 2 June 2005, p 2712.
the concern over the apparently limited supply of metallic Hartwick, J M, 1977. International equity and the investing of rents from
mineral resources provoked an interest in the economic rents that exhaustible resources, American Economic Review, 66(5):972-974.
were or would be accruing in the face of apparent scarcity. The Hematite Petroleum Pty Ltd v Victoria, 1983. 151 CLR 599.

184 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 15: MINERAL TAXATION AND ROYALTIES

Hotelling, H, 1931. The economics of exhaustible resources, Journal of FURTHER READING


Political Economy, 392:137-175.
Hughes, H, 2004. From riches to rags: what are Nauru’s options and how Argyle, R E S, 1984. Resource rent tax-the Commonwealth’s proposals,
can Australia help? Issue Analysis, Centre for Independent Studies, Australian Mining and Petroleum Law Association Yearbook,
50:18. pp 296-309 (AMPLA Limited: Melbourne).
Hughes, H and Singh, S, 1978. Economic rent: Incidence in selected Bambrick, S, 1979. Australian Minerals and Energy Policy (Australian
metals and minerals, Resources Policy, 4(2):135-140. National University Press: Canberra).
New South Wales Government, 2005. New South Wales royalty system, Bartlett, R H, 2004. Native Title in Australia, second edition (LexisNexis
[online]. Available from: <http://www.dpi.nsw.gov.au/minerals>. Butterworth: Sydney).
Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Church, A M, 1985. Natural Resource Taxation Policies (Centre for
Northern Territory Government, 2005. Overview of the mineral royalty Research on Federal Financial Relations: Canberra).
scheme [online]. Available from: <http://www.nt.gov.au/ntt/revenue/ Commonwealth of Australia, 1900. The Australian Constitution [online].
overmra.shtml>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Available from: <http://www.aph.gov.au/senate/general/constitution>
O’Hare, C W, 1971. A history of mining law in Australia, The Australian Date accessed 8 May 2006.
Law Journal, 45(June):281-293. Flint, D, 1982. Resource taxation and the Mining Royalty Act 1982 (NT),
Queensland Government, 2003. Mining royalties [online]. Available from: Australian Tax Review, 11:202-216.
<http://www.nrm.qld.gov.au/mines/royalties/mining_royalties.html> Fraser, R, 1993. On the neutrality of the resource rent tax, Economic
Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Record, 69(204):56-60.
Queensland Government, 2005. Action policy no 68 [online]. Available Fraser, R, 1998. Lease allocation systems, risk aversion, and the resource
from: <http://www.nrm.qld.gov.au/about/policy/documents/468/ rent tax, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,
min_68.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. 42(2):115-130.
Smith, B, 1999. The impossibility of a neutral resource rent tax, Working Fraser, R, 1999a. An analysis of the relationship between uncertainty-
Papers in Economics and Econometrics, No 380 (Faculty of reducing exploration and resource taxation, Resources Policy,
Economics and Commerce, Research School of Social Sciences, 24(4):199-205.
Australian National University: Canberra). Fraser, R, 1999b. An analysis of the Western Australian gold royalty,
Solow, R W, 1974. The economics of resources or the resources of Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,
economics, American Economic Review, 64:1-14. 43(1):35-50.
South Australian Government, 2004. The Schedule, Section 32, Roxby Fraser, R, 1999c. The state of resource taxation in Australia: An
Downs (Indenture Ratification) Act 1982, Primary Industries and inexcusable folly for the nation? The Australian Journal of
Resources South Australia, Annual Report 2003-2004 [online]. Agricultural and Resource Economics, 43(3):259-278.
Available from: <http://www.pir.sa.gov.au/byteserve/showcase/ Fraser, R and Kingwell, R, 1997. Can expected tax revenue be increased
ann_rep/2004/ar2003_04.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. by an investment – preserving switch from ad valorem royalties to a
South Australian Government, 2005. South Australian royalty regime, resource rent tax?, Resources Policy, 23(3):103-108.
[online]. Available from: <http://www.pir.sa.gov.au/pages/minerals/ Garnaut, R and Clunies-Ross, A, 1975. Uncertainty, risk aversion, and the
legislation/legislation_royalties.htm>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. taxing of natural resource projects, Economic Journal, 85(2):272-287.
Tasmanian Government, 2004. Mineral Resources Tasmania, Annual Garnaut, R and Clunies-Ross, A, 1979. The neutrality of the resource rent
Review 2003/2004, p 10, [online]. Available from: <http://www.mrt. tax, Economic Record, 55(150):193-201.
tas.gov.au/pls/portal/docs/PAGE/MRT_INTERNET_PAGE_GROUP/ Hogan, I, 2003. Australia’s petroleum resource rent tax: An economic
MRT_ABOUT_MRT/MRT_ANNUAL_REVIEWS/AR2003_2004_ assessment of fiscal settings, ABARE Report 03.1 (Department of
COLOUR.PDF>. Date accessed: 8 June 2006. Industry, Tourism and Resources: Canberra).
Tasmanian Government, 2005a. Tasmanian royalty regime [online]. Hogan, I and Donaldson, K, 2000. Mineral royalties – net economic
Available from: <http://www.thelaw.tas.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May benefits of mining to Australia, Australian Commodities, (7):519-531.
2006.
Leyland, P, 1978. Optimal risk sharing and the leasing of natural
Tasmanian Government, 2005b. The Hellyer Mine Agreement Ratification resources, with application to oil and gas leasing on the OCS,
Act 1987 (No 67 of 1987) [online]. Available from: <http://www. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92(2):413-438.
thelaw.tas.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 June 2006.
Lloyd, P J, 1984. Mineral Economics in Australia (George Allen and
The Australian, 2005a. Diamond deal gives blacks $50m, The Australian, Unwin: Sydney).
9 June 2005.
Manley, K, 1987. Federalism and the taxation of crude oil in Western
The Australian, 2005b. BHP to follow Rio on higher ore royalties, The Australia: a case study of the Barrow Island resource rent royalty,
Australian, 12 July 2005. unpublished economics Honours dissertation, Murdoch University.
The Australian, 2005c. Cut royalties, miner pleads, The Australian, 13 June McCarthy, S B, 2000. Comments on a critical evaluation of the Petroleum
2005. (Submerged Lands) Act, Australian Mining and Petroleum Law
Tilton, J E, 2003. On Borrowed Time? Assessing the Threat of Mineral Yearbook, pp 125-137 (AMPLA Limited: Melbourne).
Depletion (Resources for the Future: Washington DC). Northern Territory Department of Mines and Energy, 1981. Green Paper
Victorian Government, 2005. Victorian royalty regime [online]. Available on Mining Royalty Policy for the Northern Territory, Darwin.
from: <http://www.dpi.vic.gov.au/dpi/nrenmp.nsf/Home+Page/ Parker, K H, 1984. Implications of the pipeline case for state resource
7390C9B7D9AAC9F4CA256E69001834C1?open>. Date accessed: revenue, Australian Mining and Petroleum Law Yearbook, pp 1-21
8 May 2006. (AMPLA Limited: Melbourne).
Western Australian Government, Department of Industry and Resources, Pett, R, 1980. Taxation of the Australian Minerals Industry, unpublished
2005a. Western Australian royalty regime [online]. Available from: economics Honours dissertation, Murdoch University.
<http://www.doir.wa.gov.au/mineralsandpetroleum/0A3F7FC391AA
4CC08487D56234500D7C.asp>. Date accessed: 8 June 2006. Ricardo, D, 1821. On the principles of political economy and taxation,
Chapter 2 [online]. Available from: <http://econlib.org/library/Ricardo/
Western Australian Government, Department of Industry and Resources, ricP1a.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
2005b. Mineral and petroleum statistics [online]. Available from:
<http://www.doir.wa.gov.au/documents/StatisticsDigest/royaltyreceip Stevenson, G, 1976. Mineral Resources and Australian Federalism,
ts0405.xls>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. (Centre for Research on Federal Financial Relations: Canberra).
Western Australian Government, 2005. State agreements [online]. Trevison, S, 1995. North Flinders Mine Ltd vs Neil Conn as
Available from: <http://www.slp.wa.gov.au/statutes/swans.nsf/html/ under-treasurer of the Northern Territory Treasury, Australian Mining
agency+doir+acts?opendocument>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. and Petroleum Law Yearbook, pp 508-519 (AMPLA Limited:
Melbourne).

Australian Mineral Economics 185


CHAPTER 16

Mining, Sustainability and Sustainable Development


Roderick Eggert

Introduction
Sustainability and Sustainable Development
Mining and Environmental Sustainability
Mining and Economic Sustainability
Mining and Social Justice
Public Policy: Principles and Concepts
Putting Sustainability and Sustainable Development into Practice in Mining
Final Thoughts
Appendix A – The Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development Project
Appendix B – Summary Findings of the Extractive Industries Review
Appendix C – Ten Principles of the Global Compact

INTRODUCTION Sustainability perhaps is best thought of as a one-dimensional


concept and comes in at least three forms. Environmental
Mining inevitably affects the natural environment and local sustainability is a physical goal – sustaining environmental
communities. The economic benefits of mining sometimes come quality and the stock of natural resources. One can imagine
with significant environmental and social costs to mining managing a renewable resource, such as a fishery, in such a way
communities and regions. Balancing the economic, that the rate of harvest does not exceed the rate of natural
environmental, and social benefits and costs of mining is the regeneration; thus the stock of the resource is sustained
focus of the quest for sustainable development in mining. indefinitely. Or a set of natural resources – such as an ecosystem
Popular and professional interest in sustainability and with plants, animals, water, soil, air, and so on – could be
sustainable development stems from concerns that many current managed in such a way that the overall stock of the set of
activities may be unsustainable – that is, that some current resources is at least maintained. Still another version of
economic activities, including some mines, may result in such environmental sustainability involves maintaining air quality or
significant environmental and social damage and disruption that water quality at some prescribed level (which might be measured
they will leave future generations worse off than the current as a maximum allowable rate of pollution emissions into the air
generation. or water). Maintaining biodiversity is an important issue is this
This paper provides an overview of sustainability and form of sustainability. Environmental sustainability emphasises
sustainable development as they relate to mining. It begins by maintaining the ability of the natural environment to provide
defining the various aspects and dimensions of sustainability and life-sustaining and aesthetic services, such as clean air and water,
sustainable development generally. The paper then suggests how the energy and mineral resources necessary for the human
these concepts apply to the mining sector. It concludes by economy, and so on. It also emphasises the belief that the natural
outlining an appropriate role for government in ensuring that environment should be preserved for its own sake, independent
mining is consistent with sustainability and sustainable of how human beings use the natural environment for their
development and by noting several of the more significant efforts activities.
to promote sustainability and sustainable development in mining. Economic sustainability emphasises sustaining improvements
in human living standards or human wellbeing. Narrow measures
SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE of economic sustainability are the level and growth rate for a
nation’s gross domestic product per capita, the estimated
DEVELOPMENT per-person value of a nation’s output of goods and services,
The concepts of sustainability and sustainable development mean which in turn is equivalent to per-capita income. Broader
different things to different people. Thus they often lead to measures of economic sustainability include indexes that attempt
discussions that are more bewildering than enlightening. to capture other (less purely economic) aspects of human living

Australian Mineral Economics 187


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

standards, such as literacy rates, life expectancy, income activity also leads to environmental damage that could over a
distribution, and other indicators of economic development. One period of decades lead to possible increased sickness in some
such index is the Human Development Index of the United people and even a small number of deaths. Or, to be less
Nations Development Programme (http://hdr.undp.org/statistics). dramatic, the commercial activity leads to the reduction of scenic
Another conceptual measure of economic sustainability is what vistas or elimination of pristine wilderness, again over a period
economists call the capital stock – the total value of inputs to the of decades. What is the most appropriate way to balance the
production of goods and services, including natural resources, economic benefits received today with the possible future
labour, buildings, equipment and processes. The larger the damages to the human health or the environment?
capital stock, here defined broadly to include natural resources Economists typically use the process of discounting to balance
and environmental quality, the larger the capacity of an economy benefits and costs that occur over an extended period of time. All
to generate income and economic wellbeing. current and future benefits and costs – economic, as well as
Social and cultural sustainability, a third form of social and environmental – are identified and estimated. All
sustainability, emphasises social justice. This form of future benefits and costs are then discounted at a rate that
sustainability focuses primarily on the search for fairness in the represents society’s rate of time preference. A dollar of benefits
distribution of benefits and burdens associated with economic or costs today is worth more than a future dollar – for two
activities. It also focuses on the process through which decisions reasons. The first is simply that humans are impatient and thus
are made about whether and how new commercial activities give higher values to current rather than future benefits and costs.
occur. The distribution of the benefits and costs of commercial The second, and perhaps more significant, justification for
activities is rarely equal across society. For example, a large new discounting is based on opportunity costs or capital growth. That
commercial development may be beneficial for a national or is, by waiting to receive a benefit in the future, a person foregoes
provincial economy overall and yet leave the local community or the opportunity to put money to a productive use today that
indigenous peoples in the vicinity of the new investment entirely grows in value over time. The opportunity for capital growth is
indifferent (and even arguably worse off) than before the new lost. The higher the discount rate, the more valuable the present
investment. This raises questions such as what level and form of is relative to the future. Critics of the first justification of
compensation, if any, is appropriate for local communities or discounting argue that impatience is inherently unethical and
indigenous peoples to receive for the social disruption, loss of unfair to future generations. Critics of the second justification
cultural identity, or environmental damage caused by the new
(capital growth) argue that, while discounting may be appropriate
commercial activity? Also how should the affected local
for evaluating commercial investment opportunities with benefits
communities or indigenous peoples share in the net benefits of
the new commercial activity? and costs that largely affect the current generation, discounting is
fundamentally inappropriate for decisions involving future
Sustainable development, in contrast to sustainability, is generations and environmental resources that arguably are
inherently and explicitly multidimensional. It can be considered critical to the survival of these future generations. For more
as the simultaneous pursuit of sustained or enhanced: discussion on discounting and how to define what is fair for
environmental quality, economic growth, and social justice. In future generations, see Portney and Weyant (1999).
other words, sustainable development represents economic
This general introduction to sustainability and sustainable
development that is consistent with society’s preferences for
development sets the stage for the next section of the chapter,
environmental quality and social justice. There is no single
which focuses on the implications of sustainability and
measure of progress toward sustainable development; rather sustainable development for mining.
there are various indicators of progress in the three different
realms of sustainability. Progress toward sustainable
development involves striving for all three types of sustainability MINING AND ENVIRONMENTAL SUSTAINABILITY
simultaneously – inevitably leading both to conflict among Environmental resources include the stock of natural resources as
competing environmental, economic, and social goals and to the well as environmental quality. Environmental sustainability,
search for common ground. While progress toward the three therefore, has two important dimensions for mining.
forms of sustainability individually can be (relatively easily)
The first is the physical sustainability of mineral
measured, progress toward sustainable development is more
production. At the scale of an individual mine, mining is
difficult to measure and requires much attention be paid to the
inherently unsustainable. A mineral deposit contains a finite
institutions and processes through which decisions are made.
amount of mineral ore, and mining eventually will deplete this
Whether one is concerned about sustainability or sustainable ore. Nevertheless, mineral production is more sustainable than it
development, there are several important issues that cut across all appears initially. Rarely is the full extent of a mineral deposit
versions of these concepts. The first is the issue of scale. Are we known at the time mining commences. Mining companies
concerned about the sustainability or sustainable development of routinely extend mine lives by exploring for and developing
a local community? A subnational state or province? A nation? additional reserves at existing mines. At a broader scale, mining
Some other scale of focus independent of human-imposed companies extend mineral production and support
political boundaries, such as a transnational ecosystem? Or the ever-increasing rates of mineral consumption by discovering and
world as a whole? developing previously unknown mineral deposits. Improved
A second cross-cutting issue is the magnitude of human technologies (for exploration, mining and mineral processing)
activity relative to the carrying capacity of the natural also serve to sustain mineral production by making it technically
environment to support this activity. Most people would agree and commercially feasible to mine mineral resources that
that the lower the level of human activity, the greater the ability previously were technically or commercially infeasible to mine.
of the natural environment to absorb environmental degradation In a broader sense, recycling sustains the benefits of mineral use
and to regenerate itself. Where people disagree, however, is how even if it does not sustain mine production.
great the current level of human activities is relative to carrying The second dimension is the sustainability of environmental
capacity. quality, which can be considered the ability of the natural
A third cross-cutting issue is how to be fair both to the environment to provide life-supporting and aesthetic services to
current generation and to future generations. For example, humans, plants, and animals. Mining inevitably disturbs the
consider a new commercial activity that raises the incomes and natural environment. During mineral exploration and mine
helps improve the overall wellbeing today of impoverished development, environmental damage typically is localised and
people in a poor country. Further imagine that this commercial relatively easy to minimise. Mining and mineral processing,

188 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

however, are associated with more extensive environmental 1. ownership of mineral resources and mining operations;
disturbances, the exact nature and extent of which vary
considerably from mine to mine. Mining disturbs surface land, 2. land access and security of tenure for mineral exploration
typically more so for surface mines than underground mines. and mine development, including preproduction approvals
Mining creates solid waste in the forms of overburden, waste and the role and rights of local communities in the
rock and tailings. The volume of solid waste is large because mine-development process;
recoverable metal usually represents only a small weight percent 3. mineral royalties and taxation; and
of the rock moved during mining. Some types of mining create
acid-mine drainage when water interacts with newly exposed 4. environmental protection, including post-mining requirements
mineralised surfaces of mined rock, affecting water quality, for closure and rehabilitation.
plants, and animal habitats. Metallurgical processing, such as The second requirement for economic sustainability is that the
smelting and refining, often creates air pollution. After mining economic benefits of mining be made permanent through
and mineral processing ends, environmental damage can investment in assets that will continue to generate economic
continue if a site is not rehabilitated; this is especially true for wellbeing as mining declines or ceases. In other words, the
acid-mine drainage and the aesthetic damage of unsightly depleting mineral asset in the ground needs to be replaced with a
landscapes. Sustaining an appropriate level of environmental sustainable, man-made asset. These substitute man-made assets
quality has both short-term and long-term aspects. In the short can take a variety of forms. At the scale of a community or
term, the appropriate level of environmental quality should be region, investments might be made in other types of business for
determined by finding the appropriate balance between the which the community or region has a competitive advantage. Or
benefits and costs of environmental protection. Over the longer rather than investing in a specific line of business, local or
term, technical innovations in mining and mineral processing national governments might invest in social infrastructure that
hold forth the possibility of reducing both production and facilitates economic activities generally, including education,
environmental costs. health care, transportation, water, electricity, and technological
research and development.
MINING AND ECONOMIC SUSTAINABILITY The third requirement for economic sustainability is that a
region, or nation, avoids the potentially negative macroeconomic
The degree to which mining contributes to the creation and and political consequences of mineral development. These
sustainability of economic benefits in a community, region, or potential consequences can take a variety of forms. One form
nation depends on three factors, as suggested by Tilton (1992). involves income instability (boom and bust) and associated
First, minerals in the ground must be developed; otherwise they problems resulting from unstable mineral prices and arguably
represent a dormant asset. Second, an appropriate portion of the excessive dependence on mineral production. Another form is
proceeds from mining must be invested in activities that will the adjustment problem associated with a booming natural
sustain the economic benefits created by mining once mining resource sector. Sometimes called the Dutch disease, this
ceases. Third, an economy (whether local, regional, or national) problem leads to a shrinking of the non-boom sectors of an
must avoid the potentially negative macroeconomic and political economy (often agriculture or manufacturing) even as overall
consequences of mineral development. Let us consider each of national output and income increase. Still another potential
these three factors in turn. problem involves incentives. The argument is that the presence of
Whether the private sector develops a nation’s or a region’s surplus revenues or rents from mineral production invites
mineral wealth depends on a variety of factors, including competition among special interest groups over sharing of the
importantly the nation’s or region’s institutional framework. surpluses, diverting efforts away from creating the surpluses in
Some of this framework is common to all commercial activities the first place. An aspect of this phenomenon is the seeming
in a particular political jurisdiction – the rules, regulations, propensity for some mineral-dependent economies to be corrupt.
customs, government institutions, and risk perceptions that Finally, mineral dependence may encourage the illusion of
define the jurisdiction’s legal, fiscal, and business environment. plenty, leading to irresponsible economic and political decisions,
See the World Bank’s World Development Report 2002 for a too much consumption, and too little investment. Although there
comprehensive examination of how institutions influence is considerable ongoing debate about the seriousness and
inevitability of these potentially negative consequences of
markets (World Bank, 2002). More narrowly, an important part
mineral dependence, the predominant view is that they are
of a jurisdiction’s institutional framework is specific to the
avoidable with appropriate public policies.
mining sector. Public policies influence the availability of basic
geologic information upon which private investors make
decisions about mineral prospecting and exploration. Most MINING AND SOCIAL JUSTICE
economists believe that the private sector alone will under-invest Social and cultural sustainability, the quest for social justice, is
in the collection of basic geologic information, either because it largely a moral and ethical issue. It is much more difficult to
is more risk averse than society as a whole toward risky ventures define and measure than environmental and economic
or because the benefits of collecting basic information are sustainability because it requires agreement on what is fair, just,
difficult to appropriate or capture fully. Sometimes governments and ethical. Although there are considerable disagreements about
directly fund the provision of basic geologic information through how to define environmental and economic sustainability, at least
geological surveys. At other times, governments subsidise the these types of sustainability lend themselves readily to
private collection and dissemination of this type of information. quantification (eg using a physical measure of environmental
Mineral policies also help define an institutional framework degradation to measure environmental quality, using monetary
for mining. What constitutes mineral policy varies considerably values of income to estimate net economic benefits).
from place to place. Some political jurisdictions have single Much of the discussion and disagreement around this form of
comprehensive documents with all or most relevant rules. In sustainability involves distribution – that is, what is the fair
other cases, mineral policy simply represents the overall set of distribution of benefits and costs associated with mining. Many
rules governing mining as set forth in separate policies governing of the benefits and costs of a mine are ‘private’ in the sense that a
land use, taxes, environmental regulation, and so on. In any case, mining company incurs costs from mining (construction, labour,
mineral policy can be thought of as legislation and rules management, raw materials, etc) in exchange for which it
governing: receives revenues from the sale of minerals. Other benefits and

Australian Mineral Economics 189


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

costs, however, are ‘external’ to a mining company in the sense Neither mining companies nor local communities should
that it does not directly receive the benefit or incur the cost. expect a simple set of rules or a specific allocation scheme to be
External benefits can include: regional economic development viewed as equitable in all circumstances. Rather, most
coming in the form of, for example, local purchase of food and approaches to achieving equitable outcomes focus on a process
other inputs by the mine and local spending of mining wages on that involves all interested parties to mineral development. Not
food, entertainment, furniture, clothing, and other goods and only does a mining project need to be economically (or
services; and improved educational and health-care systems from commercially) and environmentally feasible, it needs to be
spending on schools and hospitals. External costs can include: socially feasible as well.
environmental degradation; social problems often accompanying
frontier development such as increased rates of alcoholism, PUBLIC POLICY: PRINCIPLES AND CONCEPTS
prostitution, and teenage delinquency; and cultural disruption
when indigenous peoples are confronted with mine development. Governments – whether local, regional, or national – play a
A major source of contention is the distribution of mining’s critical role in defining how a society balances the
benefits and costs between national governments and local environmental, economic, and social and cultural goals of the
communities. Many of the benefits of mineral development go to various forms of sustainability and sustainable development.
mining companies (as revenues) and to national governments (as Without a philosophy of government, it is almost impossible not
taxes and royalties). Many of the costs are external and borne by to become lost in the thicket of issues under the umbrella of
local communities in the form of environmental degradation and sustainability and sustainable development.
costs of social disruption. To be sure, local communities benefit One starting point for this philosophy of government in a
from mining. But the critical issues are: market economy argues that governments need to find the right
balance of government and private activities such that the
• Are local communities appropriately compensated for the
political unit (local community, state or province, or nation)
external costs they bear from mining?
satisfies five conditions (World Bank, 1997):
• Do local communities receive an appropriate portion of the
net benefits of mining, relative to mining companies and Condition #1 A foundation of law and property rights
national governments?
Condition #2 A non-distortionary policy environment, including
It is easy to say that local communities should be compensated macroeconomic stability
for the external costs that they bear. This begs the question, Condition #3 Investment in people and infrastructure
however, of how exactly to quantify and value the magnitude of
Condition #4 Protection of the vulnerable
these external costs and how to design institutions, policies, and
regulations to facilitate appropriate compensation. Nevertheless, Condition #5 Protection of the environment
the concept of compensation for external cost or damage is not
controversial, even if compensation mechanisms are difficult to Most economists, in turn, believe that governments should
establish. focus their efforts on the following types of activities in defining
The same cannot be said, however, about the second question – government’s role in meeting each condition:
defining and ensuring the appropriate distribution of mining’s net
benefits. Eggert (2004), drawing on Young (1994), writes that
• Facilitating market activities by establishing and maintaining
well-defined property rights and a money and banking
achieving equitable distributions of mining surpluses is promoted
system (see condition 1).
by institutional arrangements that answer the following
questions: • Promoting economic efficiency by intervening in situations in
which markets by themselves do not function well. Such
• What are the eligibility criteria? Who is eligible to share in
situations include: lack of sufficient competition, providing
the surpluses of mining and on what basis?
the economic basis for antitrust policy; provision of public
• What determines the relative priority among several eligible goods, which typically will be under-provided by the private
parties? Contributions to the project, such as financial capital sector alone, including national defence, education, and
or land? Need, such as when the mining region has higher various types of infrastructure (see condition 4); correction of
poverty rates than the nation as whole? Whether an entity negative externalities or spillover effects, such as
(such as a local community) receives direct compensation for environmental pollution (see condition 5).
environmental or social costs of mineral development or,
alternatively, would rather share in the surpluses?
• Promoting equity (or fairness) in the distribution of income
and wealth and of the benefits and costs of human activities
• What are the relevant precedents? Are there existing (see condition 4).
allocation schemes for similar circumstances elsewhere that
How do these general principles relate and apply to public
might form the basis for a new scheme?
policy toward mining, sustainability, and sustainable
• How should competing principles and criteria be reconciled? development? It is useful to organise the various policy issues
Many allocation schemes incorporate more than one around four aspects of mineral development.
principle. For example, surpluses might be allocated both Firstly, government plays an important role in the creation of
according to need (eg elimination of poverty) and according mineral wealth (following from the earlier discussion in this
to contribution to the project. If the overall surplus is large, paper on mining and economic sustainability). Mineral wealth is
there may not be any conflict between the competing created when there is sufficient knowledge of minerals in the
principles. But if the surplus is small, which principle takes ground for someone to purchase exploration, development, or
priority? mining rights, leading ultimately to mining. Government’s role
• What incentives does a rule or allocation scheme create? For here is primarily to facilitate market activities. Most of this
example, what effect might an allocation scheme have on facilitating role involves the legal and regulatory framework
mineral exploration if it awards a larger share of surpluses to governing mineral exploration, mine development, and mining.
local communities than to a mining company? Or conversely, Important aspects of this framework include rules governing:
what effect does an allocation scheme have on community ownership of mineral resources in the ground and of ownership
support for mining if it awards almost all surpluses to a of mineral-production facilities; collection and dissemination of
mining company? basic geologic information, including the roles of government

190 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

geological surveys; land access and security of tenure; and mining and yet share inappropriately in mining’s surpluses;
mineral royalties and taxation. The material in Chapters 13 to 15 mining companies and national governments, in this perspective,
in this volume covers many of these issues in further detail. are seen as unfairly benefiting from mining’s surpluses.
Secondly, government plays an important role in ensuring The core of this issue is: defining what is fair. The previous
that mineral development occurs in an economically efficient discussion in this chapter on social justice identified several
manner – that is, not simply efficient in a technical or practical issues in defining fairness. At a more conceptual level,
engineering sense but also consistent with society’s preferences the philosophers Aristotle, Jeremy Bentham, and John Rawls –
for environmental quality and social/cultural values. In terms of although not writing about mining in particular – offer three very
the list of microeconomic roles for government (above), the issue different definitions of fairness in the context of distributing
primarily is identifying and dealing with the potential negative surpluses (see Young, 1994).
externalities of mineral development, which in turn relate to The Aristotelian approach would be to distribute surpluses
mining and both environmental and social sustainability according to each party’s contribution to the creation of the
(introduced earlier). Externalities can be thought of as spillover surplus (sometime called proportionality). Business partners share
effects on third parties that might not be sufficiently considered in profits in proportion to the financial contribution they provide to
a project. In the case of mining, putting proportionality into
by private entities involved in decision making about mining, at
practice is more difficult. To be sure, those entities providing
least not without the involvement of government. Another way to funding for the mine deserve to share in the surpluses in
view negative externalities is as unpaid costs. In this view, public proportion to their financial contributions. But governments can
policy plays an important role in making sure that these costs argue that they are deserving when they provide some of the
ultimately are paid (which might come in the form of infrastructure used by the mine, including roads, electric power,
compensation to those parties negatively affected). sanitation facilities, and workers educated at publicly funded
Environmental damage and the social disruptions that sometimes schools and universities. Even more broadly, society as a whole
accompany mining are possible negative externalities. (including local communities) can claim that a mineral deposit is a
Developing public policies and procedures ensuring that these gift of nature and thus belongs to society at large.
potential externalities are sufficiently considered is not simple The Bentham approach would be to distribute surpluses such
and straightforward. At a conceptual level, one can think of that the distribution created the greatest good for the greatest
project approval as depending on the requirement that expected number (sometimes called utilitarianism). Although appealing, it
net social benefits from a project are positive. Net social benefits is difficult to know how to put this into practice at a mine. In
include the private revenues and costs that a private investor whose hands is the greatest good created? In the hands of a
would consider in assessing commercial feasibility, augmented to mining company, which might invest in additional mineral
include any positive and negative external benefits important to exploration and mine development? In the hands of a local
society at large. (Positive external benefits might include community, which might invest in schools and hospitals? In the
hands of a national government, which might invest the surpluses
spillover regional economic activity, such as local purchase of
on the highest national needs, including to reduce poverty in
mining inputs, stimulated by mining.) other regions of the nation? In principle, one should be able to
In practice, at the level of a single mining project, the critical estimate social rates of return for each alternative use of the
policy issues are: Who decides whether proposed mineral surpluses, but again such calculations are difficult to make in
development occurs? On what basis? Through what process? One practice.
could imagine two basic models for decision-making. One model The Rawls approach would concentrate the surpluses from
would require that each mining project undergo a separate and mining on the least well-off groups in society. However, his
public process, on a stand-alone basis, through which social approach is more complicated than it appears. His theory
preferences were elicited and after which a decision would be recognises that allocation schemes that redistribute resources
made on whether to permit mine development. At the other from rich to poor may reduce incentives for creating surpluses in
extreme, the second model would establish objective and the first place. Thus Rawls seems to argue that priority should go
transparent rules and criteria for permitting and other to those who are least well off in such a way that mining
preproduction approvals for environmental compliance, water companies do not, at the same time, lose the incentive to create
availability and quality, activities to offset potentially negative surpluses in the first place.
social consequences of mining (eg increased rates of divorce and
Fourthly, government plays an important role in ensuring that
alcoholism), and so on – in other words a ‘checklist’ of
the benefits of mining are sustained even after a mine closes –
requirements necessary for approval of mine development. After a
by investing an appropriate portion of the revenues from mining
mining project satisfied the checklist, government automatically
in sustainable assets so that, in effect, the depletable mineral
would give approval to the mining project. In practice, most
asset in the ground is made permanent and converted into a
political jurisdictions use a combination of the two models,
sustainable asset. This is an important part of mining and
involving both public participation and a ‘checklist’ of necessary
economic sustainability discussed earlier. The idea is akin to a
pre-production activities. Social benefit-cost analyses (described
trust fund that wealthy families sometimes use to pass along their
above) and environmental and social impact assessments are two
wealth to their children or to an endowment that universities use
types of study that often serve as analytical tools to frame issues
to fund educational activities: save and invest a portion of current
and aid decision making about mineral development.
income, spend (or consume) only the income on the investment,
Thirdly, government plays an important role in ensuring that and in so doing sustain the ability of the original investment to
the surpluses from mining are distributed fairly among private fund spending indefinitely into the future.
mining companies, national governments, local governments and
With respect to investing a portion of the proceeds from
communities, and other organisations (the quest for social justice
mining, several issues are important (Hanneson, 2001):
discussed earlier under social and cultural sustainability). Mines
sometimes generate economic surpluses, often called rents, even • How much to save and invest? Answering this question
after they provide compensation for the negative environmental requires identifying the investment goal. Is it to sustain the
and social consequences of mining (or alternatively, undertake current level of wellbeing? Or to sustain growth in the level
activities to minimise or avoid these consequences). During the of wellbeing? The more ambitious the goal, the higher the
past decade, how these surpluses are distributed has come into required saving rate. In addition, it is important to consider
question. As noted earlier, the frequent concern is that local the expected rate of return on investments. The higher the
communities suffer most of the environmental and social costs of rate of return, the lower the necessary saving rate.

Australian Mineral Economics 191


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

• By whom? There are several possibilities here. Mining reports to shareholders, summarising efforts related to
companies might invest in sustaining mining operations environmental protection and how they operate in and interact
through mineral exploration and reserve-development with local communities.
activities. Governments might invest in non-mining assets At a broader, multi-participant level, there have been several
that facilitate economic activities and are likely to be significant efforts aimed at or with implications for mining,
underprovided by the private sector acting along, such as sustainability, and sustainable development. Between 2000 and
physical infrastructure (roads, electric power systems), 2002, a group of multinational mining companies carried out the
education, health care, and basic scientific and technological global mining initiative (GMI), studying and attempting to
research. Partnerships involving mining companies, clarify the roles of mining in sustainability and sustainable
government, and civil society (non-governmental and development. The GMI had three principal activities. The first
non-company organisations) also are a possibility. was to commission an independent study of the key issues.
• In what? Should savings be invested in assets that earn a Initiated through the World Business Council on Sustainable
financial return, such as business enterprises, real estate, and Development and carried out by the International Institute for
financial assets like stocks and bonds? Or should savings be Environment and Development, this project was known as the
invested in assets with less-visible, harder-to-evaluate, and Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development Project
broader social returns, such as physical infrastructure, (MMSD). The MMSD process, as it came to be known, involved
education, health care, and basic research? There is general regional partnerships focusing on specific issues of importance in
consensus that governments should not invest in commercial southern Africa, South America, Australia, and North America;
enterprises or target specific industries with their saving. As 23 global workshops and expert-group meetings involving some
Auty and Mikesell (1998) note: 700 people from diverse backgrounds; and some 175 pieces of
commissioned research1.
The historical evidence suggests that directly This work culminated in the publication of the book Breaking
productive investment to diversify the economy is New Ground (IIED, 2002), which summarises the work and
best achieved by the private sector (with presents findings and recommendations in all three dimensions
subsidies, if any, being minimal) rather than, as of sustainability and sustainable development (environmental,
was fashionable in the 1970s, by the public economic, social) with special focus on public policy and
sector. Only if there are strong externalities, as governance. The executive summary of the MMSD Project
with education and infrastructure, can a clear identifies nine challenges for the mining sector (see Appendix
case by made for public investment. A). The second GMI activity was to organise a global conference
However, governments also may find it difficult to invest in Toronto in May 2002, at which the findings of the MMSD
appropriately in infrastructure, education, health care, and other Project were presented and discussed. The third and arguably
public goods precisely because the full social benefits and costs most significant GMI activity was to establish an industry
of these investments are difficult to quantify. The result is that association to carry on the work investigated by the MMSD
such projects are open to manipulation by special-interest Project; this organisation is the London-based International
groups. The key here is to develop formal mechanisms for Council on Mining and Metals (www.icmm.com).
evaluating social projects and including open and public A recent initiative associated with this third activity has been
participation in the evaluation process. the Mineral Council of Australia’s ‘enduring value’ project that
• Where? In the mining community or region? Somewhere else sets out a framework for mining companies operating in
in the nation? In another country? Hanneson (2001) suggests Australia to pursue sustainable development goals – (see
that the appropriate location of investment will vary from www.minerals.org.au/enduringvalue/enduring_value). By early
situation to situation, depending on: the size of the economy 2006, 29 companies were signatories to this project.
(the larger the economy, the more likely there are to be The Extractive Industries Review, although not strictly speaking
productive investments within the economy); the level of an effort to put sustainable development into practice, resulted in a
economic development in the economy (the lower the level, number of recommendations that speak to sustainability and
the larger the potential returns to social infrastructure sustainable development. The review assessed the role of the World
investments in the domestic economy but the less developed Bank in the extractive industries, including the oil, gas, and mining
financial institutions may be and the lower the capacity to industries. Commissioned by the World Bank, the review was
absorb domestic investment); and the degree of mineral carried out by an independent group that facilitated communication
dependence (the more dependent an economy is on mineral among the various interested parties to the extractive industries
production, the greater the urgency of domestic investment worldwide – governments, non-governmental organisations,
that over the longer term will allow the economy to diversify). indigenous peoples, local communities, industry, academia, and
There is a fifth aspect of public policy and mineral development: labour unions, among others. The review was a response to strong
managing the potentially negative macroeconomic and political criticisms of the World Bank’s role in financing and facilitating the
consequences of mining, as noted earlier in this chapter. extractive industries. It asked the question, are the extractive
industries consistent with the goals of sustainable development and
poverty alleviation? The World Bank critics argued that the
PUTTING SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE
extractive industries are inconsistent with these goals – that is,
DEVELOPMENT INTO PRACTICE IN MINING actually often promote unsustainable development and create
Most governments and mining companies have specific efforts poverty. The review was carried out between the middle of 2001
aimed at incorporating aspects of sustainability and sustainable and the end of 2003. A summary of the findings is contained in
development into common practice. Many national governments Appendix B and available at: http://www.eireview.org. The World
have policy documents focused at a philosophical – even if not at Bank’s response is available at: http://www.worldbank.org/ogmc.
an operational – level, on making mining consistent with A group of mineral industry professionals convened
sustainability and sustainable development. Likewise, most large international conferences in 2003 and 2005 on Sustainable
mining companies have annual documents, similar to annual Development Indicators in the Minerals Industry
(http://www.sdimi.org). With plans for a third meeting in 2007,
1. Papers associated with the Australian workshops and expert-group this group aims to develop operational measures or indicators of
meetings appear on The AusIMM website (http://www.ausimm.com). progress toward sustainable development in the mining industry.

192 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

Two other initiatives are not aimed directly at mining but National Research Council, 1999. Our Common Journey: A Transition
nevertheless have important implications for the mining sector. Toward Sustainability (National Academy Press: Washington, DC).
The Equator Principles are a voluntary set of guidelines adopted Otto, J M and Cordes, J (eds) 2000. Sustainable Development and the
by a number of banks and financial institutions, committing the Future of Mineral Investment (United Nations Environment
signatories to follow environmental and social guidelines Programme and Metal Mining Agency of Japan).
developed by the World Bank’s International Finance Corporation Pezzey, J C V and Toman, M A, 2005. Sustainability and its economic
(2005) on all development projects with capital costs of US$ 50 interpretations, in Scarcity and Growth Revisited: Natural Resources
million or greater. As of August 2005, 30 large institutions had and the Environment in the New Millennium (eds: R D Simpson, M A
adopted the principles, including ABN Amro, Banco de Brasil, Toman and R U Ayres) (Resources for the Future: Washington DC).
Bank of America, Barclays, Citigroup, Credit Suisse, Dresdner Portney, P R and Weyant, J P (eds) 1999. Discounting and
Bank, ING, J P Morgan Chase, and Royal Bank of Canada. The Intergenerational Equity (Resources for the Future: Washington, DC).
Global Compact is an initiative of the United Nations (2005) and Tilton, J E, 1992. Mineral wealth and economic development: an
is a voluntary network of business and other organisations overview, in Mineral Wealth and Economic Development (ed: J E
Tilton) (Resources for the Future: Washington, DC).
promising to adhere to a set of practices consistent with
appropriate corporate citizenship in the areas of human rights, United Nations, 2005. The global compact [online]. Available from:
<http://www.unglobalcompact.org>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
labour practices, the environment, and corruption reduction and
prevention. Appendix C summarises the ten principles of The World Bank, 1997. World Development Report 1997: The State in a
Changing World (World Bank and Oxford University Press: Oxford)
Global Compact.
[online]. <http://www.worldbank.org>.
World Bank, 2002. World Development Report 2002: Building
FINAL THOUGHTS Institutions for Markets (World Bank and Oxford University Press:
New York) [online]. <http://www.worldbank.org>.
Proponents of sustainability and sustainable development aim to
World Bank, 2003. World Development Report 2003: Sustainable
elevate the role that environmental and social considerations play Development in a Dynamic World (World Bank and Oxford
in decisions about mineral development – that is, that these University Press: New York) [online]. <http://www.worldbank.org>.
considerations should be evaluated alongside more traditional World Bank, 2004. Extractive industries review (EIR) [online]. Available
business and economic considerations. from: <http://www.eireview.org>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
However, there still is no consensus on exactly what is to be World Bank’s International Finance Corporation, 2005. Equator principles
sustained, for whom, and through what process. Progress requires [online]. Available from: <http://www.ifc.org/equatorprinciples>. Date
both better measures of sustainability and better processes for accessed: 8 May 2006.
eliciting social preferences for how to balance the environmental, World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987. Our
economic, and social benefits and costs of mining. Otherwise, Common Future (Oxford University Press: Oxford).
sustainability and sustainable development will remain popular Young, H P, 1994. Equity: In Theory and Practice (Princeton University
slogans without sufficiently practical implications for company Press: Princeton).
decisions and government policies.
APPENDIX A – THE MINING, MINERALS AND
NOTES ON THE LITERATURE SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT PROJECT
This chapter draws significantly on three earlier papers from the
author (Eggert, 2000, 2001, 2004). Nine key challenges (IIED, 2002)
Readers interested in the topics of sustainability and sustainable 1. Viability of the minerals industry. The minerals industry cannot
development in general should read Our Common Future (World contribute to sustainable development if companies don't
Commission on Environment and Development, 1987), often survive and succeed. This requires a safe, healthy, educated and
referred to as the Brundtland report and credited with invigorating committed workforce; access to capital; a social license to
and launching popular and professional discussion of sustainable operate; the ability to attract and maintain good managerial
development (National Research Council, 1999; World Bank, talent; and the opportunity for a return on investment.
2003; Pezzey and Toman, 2005). 2. The control, use and management of land. Mineral
For more information on how sustainability and sustainable development is one of a number of often competing land
development relate to mining see: Auty and Mikesell (1998), Otto uses. There is frequently a lack of planning or other
and Cordes (2000) and Breaking New Ground (IIED, 2002). frameworks to balance and manage possible uses. As a
result, there are often problems and disagreement around
REFERENCES issues such as compensation, resettlement, land claims of
indigenous peoples and protected areas.
Auty, R M and Mikesell, R F, 1998. Sustainable Development in Mineral
Economies (Clarendon Press: Oxford). 3. Minerals and economic development. Minerals have the
Eggert, R G, 2000. Sustainable development and the mineral industry, potential to contribute to poverty alleviation and broader
Chapter 1, in Sustainable Development and the Future of Mineral economic development at the national level. Countries have
Investment (eds: J M Otto and J Cordes) (United Nations realised this with mixed success. For this to be achieved,
Environment Programme and Metal Mining Agency of Japan). appropriate frameworks for the creation and management
Eggert, R G, 2001. Mining and Economic Sustainability: National of mineral wealth must be in place. Additional challenges
Economies and Local Communities, monograph commissioned by the include corruption and determining the balance between
Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development Project; available on
the CD ROM accompanying Breaking New Ground: Mining, Minerals local and national benefits.
and Sustainable Development, 2002 (Earthscan Publications: London). 4. Local communities and mines. Minerals development can
Eggert, R G, 2004. The mineral economies: performance, potential also bring benefits at the local level. Recent trends towards,
problems and policy challenges, in Managing Mineral Wealth, pp 7-48 for example, smaller work forces and outsourcing affect
(United Nations Economic Commission for Africa: Addis Ababa). communities adversely. The social upheaval and
Hanneson, R, 2001. Investing for Sustainability: The Management of inequitable distribution of benefits and costs within
Mineral Wealth (Kluwer Academic Publishers: Boston).
communities can also create social tension. Ensuring that
International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), 2002.
Breaking New Ground, Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development improved health and education or economic activity will
– The Report of the MMSD Project (Earthscan Publications: London) endure after mines close requires a level of planning that
[online]. Available from: <http://www.iied.org/mmsd/finalreport>. has too often not been achieved.

Australian Mineral Economics 193


CHAPTER 16: MINING, SUSTAINABILITY AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

5. Mining, minerals and the environment. Minerals activities At the local-community level, the World Bank should:
have a significant environmental impact. Managing these • require companies to obtain free and informed consent from
impacts more effectively requires dealing with unresolved local communities and other affected parties;
issues of handling immense quantities of waste, developing • require revenue sharing with local communities;
ways of internalising the costs of acid drainage, improving
both impact assessment and environmental management • require the use of poverty indicators that are monitored frequently;
systems and doing effective planning for mine closure. • encourage the establishment of public-health goals in all
extractive projects;
6. An integrated approach to using minerals. The use of
minerals is essential for modern living. Yet current patterns • encourage non-governmental organisations to help build
of use face a growing number of challenges, ranging from community capacity; and
concerns about efficiency and waste minimisation to the • encourage companies to set up independent grievance
risks associated with the use of certain minerals. mechanisms.
Companies at different stages in the minerals chain can Second, stronger environmental and social requirements for
benefit from learning to work together exploring further extractive projects, including:
recycling, reuse and remanufacture of products and
developing integrated programs of product stewardship and • required integrated environmental and social impact assessments;
supply chain assurance. • updated and fully implemented natural habitat policy;
7. Access to information. Access to information is key to • updated and fully implemented resettlement policy;
building greater trust and cooperation. The quality of • revised disclosure policy;
information and its use, production, flow, accessibility and
credibility affect the interaction of all actors in the sector. • sector-specific guidance for tailings disposal, waste
Effective public participation in decision-making requires management, and use of toxic substances (including an
information to be publicly available in an accessible form. outright ban on riverine tailings disposal and extreme caution
on submarine tailings disposal);
8. Artisanal and small-scale mining. Many millions of people • guidelines for integrated closure planning;
make their living through artisanal and small-scale mining
(ASM). It often provides an important, and sometimes the • guidelines for emergency prevention and response; and
only, source of income. This sector is characterised by low • responses to legacies of the past.
incomes, unsafe working conditions, serious environmental
Third, respect for human rights, verified by third parties and
impacts, exposure to hazardous materials such as mercury including adoption of the Core Labour Standards of the
vapours and conflict with larger companies and government. International Labour Organization (World Bank, 2004).
9. Sector governance: roles, responsibilities and instruments for
change. Sustainable development requires new integrated APPENDIX C – TEN PRINCIPLES OF THE
systems of governance. Most countries lack the framework for
GLOBAL COMPACT
turning minerals investment into sustainable development:
these need to be developed. Voluntary codes and guidelines,
stakeholder processes and other systems for promoting better Human rights
practice in areas where government is unable to exercise an Principle 1 Businesses should support and respect the protection
effective role as regulator are gaining favour to address these of international human rights within their sphere of
problems. Lenders and other financial institutions can play a influence; and
pivotal role in driving better practice.
Principle 2 make sure they are not complicit in human rights abuses.

APPENDIX B – SUMMARY FINDINGS OF THE Labour


EXTRACTIVE INDUSTRIES REVIEW
Principle 3 Businesses should uphold the freedom of association
The Extractive Industries Review finds that the World Bank has a and the effective recognition of the right to collective
role to play in the oil, gas and mining sectors, but only if its bargaining;
activities promote sustainable development and poverty Principle 4 the elimination of all forms of forced and compulsory
alleviation, which in turn only can occur if three enabling labour;
conditions are met: Principle 5 the effective abolition of child labour; and
First, pro-poor public and corporate governance, measured by
criteria such as: quality of the rule of law, absence of armed conflict Principle 6 the elimination of discrimination in respect of
or of a high risk of such conflict, respect for labour standards and employment and occupation.
human rights, recognition of and willingness to protect the rights of
indigenous peoples and government capacity to promote sustainable Environment
development through economic diversification.
Principle 7 Businesses should support a precautionary approach
Other characteristics of good governance that the World Bank to environmental challenges;
should promote include: Principle 8 undertake initiatives to promote greater environmental
• transparency of revenue flows; responsibility; and
• disclosure of project documents; Principle 9 encourage the development and diffusion of
environmentally friendly technologies.
• capacity to manage fluctuating revenues;
• capacity to manage revenues responsibly; Anti-corruption
• modern policy and regulatory frameworks; and Principle 10 Businesses should work against corruption in all its
• integrated public participation in local and national decision forms, including extortion and bribery (United Nations,
making. 2005).

194 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17

Mining and Indigenous Populations


Philip Maxwell

Introduction
Aboriginal Australia – Some Historical Background
Aboriginal Australia – Some Recent Comparative Data
Mining and Aboriginal Australia – Pre Mabo
Mining and Aboriginal Australia – The Mabo Case and Recent Developments
Looking to the Future

INTRODUCTION 3. they are, even if only formally, placed under a


state structure, which incorporates national,
The Webster’s Dictionary (Gove, 1971) defines indigenous as:
social and cultural characteristics, alien to
‘living naturally in a particular region or environment’. Yet such
theirs.
a definition tends to romanticise and simplify this notion.
The United Nations adopted a more complex but complete Authors such as Burger (1990) estimated that there were about
definition in 1982. This is that: 265 million indigenous people in the world. At that time, the
world’s population stood at around 5.35 billion. Indigenous
Indigenous populations are composed of the populations made up about five per cent of the world’s
existing descendants of the peoples who population. Indigenous people are spread across more than 85
inhabited the present territory of a country nations, with about 60 per cent of the total living in China or
wholly or partially at the time when persons of a India. They include the Inuit and Sami people of the High Arctic,
different culture or ethnic origin arrived there a wide range of highland and lowland American Indian peoples
from other parts of the world, overcame them,
in both North and South America, Saharan peoples, pastoral,
and by conquest, settlement or other means,
hunter/gatherer, rainforest people in other parts of Africa, 32
reduced them to a non-dominant or colonial
scheduled tribes in India and Sri Lanka, 55 national minorities in
situation; who today live more in conformity with
their particular social, economic and cultural China, mountain peoples and hill tribes in Asia, at least 33
customs and traditions than with the institutions distinct groups in South East Asia, Australian Aboriginal people,
of the country of which they now form a part, Maoris in New Zealand, Polynesian and Melanesian peoples of
under a state structure that incorporates mainly the Pacific, Mongol peoples, about 40 distinct minority groups in
the national, social and cultural characteristics the former Soviet Union, and the Ainu in Japan.
of other segments of the population that are The growth of industrial capitalism since the beginning of the
predominant. Industrial Revolution has been associated with the strong
expansion of mineral exploitation throughout the world. This has
Although they have not suffered conquest or inevitably led to a growing interface between mining companies
colonisation, isolated or marginal groups existing and communities in remote areas. It has often had unfortunate
in the country should be regarded as covered by consequences for indigenous peoples. This outcome has taken a
the notion of indigenous populations’ for the much higher profile in countries such as Australia in the past two
following reasons: decades and prominently with the recognition by the High Court
1. they are descendants of groups which were in of Native Title in the Mabo Case in 1992. Equally, as foreign
the territory of the country at the time when (including Australian) mining companies have moved around the
other groups of different cultures or ethnic world, it has also taken on considerably greater importance.
origins arrived there; Warden-Fernandez (2001, p 4) notes that:
2. precisely because of their isolation from other For the indigenous communities their relationship
segments of the country’s population they with the land is deep-seated and is frequently
have preserved almost intact the customs and based on religious beliefs forming part of their
traditions of their ancestors which are similar heritage. It is difficult for Western societies to
to those characterised as indigenous; understand the strong connection between the

Australian Mineral Economics 195


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

indigenous people, their land, and its resources. TABLE 17.1


There is a big cultural chasm that in many Stakeholders in resource sector investments.
instances can only be bridged with difficulty.
Writing earlier on ‘How to balance the Aboriginal interest in Affected group Economic Social and Potential total
impact cultural impact impact
resource development,’ Coombs (1982, p 239) put this sentiment
somewhat more dramatically, stating that: Local communities

It is not clear what precisely is meant by the title Indigenous Potentially Threatening and Threatening and
positive even potentially even potentially
of this chapter, a title which I did not choose. But catastrophic catastrophic
the use of the word ‘balance’ suggests that what
is sought is some kind of equality in sacrifice and Residential Potentially Potential loss Potential small
benefit between the Aborigines concerned and positive gain or loss
those who direct and profit from the exploitation Occupational Positive Minimal Positive
of the resources concerned. Frankly, I doubt Others
whether, in any real sense, such equality is
National Positive Variable Positive
possible. What the mining entrepreneur puts at government
risk is the opportunity to use his capital and
entrepreneurial skill elsewhere and what he Total population Positive Variable Positive
gains is the extra return he obtains by using Shareholders Positive None Positive
those resources in the chosen mining venture. On Financial Positive None Positive
the other hand, what the Aborigines put at risk is institutions
a whole lifestyle; a lifestyle which they have
demonstrated over 200 years that they prefer to
that offered by the white Australians: what he empirical aspects. We then move to consider ways in which
‘gains’ is financial and material benefit which mining has impacted on Aboriginal populations in remote areas
past experience suggests will prove destructive of by reviewing a small selection of relevant literature. The fifth
that lifestyle and of the Aboriginal values it section is devoted to a discussion of the changed environment
embodies. following the High Court decision in the Mabo case during the
early 1990s. This is followed by some brief concluding remarks.
While acknowledging that many Aboriginal people would like
to incorporate some components of European society into their
lifestyles, he argued that those living in a traditional lifestyle ABORIGINAL AUSTRALIA – SOME HISTORICAL
should have: BACKGROUND
• the right to refuse to negotiate; At the time of European settlement in 1788, the British
• the right to reject proposed agreements; and Government took the view that the Australian land mass had
been terra nullius – ‘land belonging to no-one’. This allowed the
• access to proper advice and expertise concerning the likely colonising power to claim all of the land mass and to set up a
impacts of proposed developments. property rights regime that largely excluded the indigenous
As seen in earlier chapters, there are many stakeholders in any population. In combination with a view that indigenous
new or continuing mineral sector investment. Most of these Australians were, at best, ‘second-class’ citizens the results were
groups are likely to gain from new mineral exploitation. Yet, as disastrous for their ensuing development. Indeed it was only in
the suggested taxonomy in Table 17.1 implies, there is potential 1967 that Aboriginal people were granted full citizenship rights.
for the interests of other stakeholders to overwhelm those of The following brief comment from Mick Dodson (1998)
indigenous populations in any politically driven decision-making provides a stark perspective on this historical marginalisation:
process to undertake new resource development.
It is important, however, to acknowledge that mining Before 1967, Aboriginal and Torres Strait
companies (particularly those with a global focus) have become Islander peoples were… not free, for example, to
travel between imposed state borders nor within
much more culturally aware of indigenous populations in mining
states – no matter where the borders of our
regions in the past 20 years. Many have developed policies and
country lay – and we were not entitled to an
expertise in their interactions with these groups.
Australian passport although many of us had
The focus in this chapter is on Aboriginal Australia1. There is already fought and died overseas in two world
a major interface between mining and Aboriginal Australians in wars. We had to have permission to marry and we
places such as the eastern and northern goldfields of Western were not even counted in the census of the people
Australia, the Pilbara, the Kimberley, the Murchison, all of the of this country. In fact, for more than a century of
Northern Territory, outback Queensland in places such as Weipa, non-indigenous presence in our country, our
Mount Isa and Cloncurry and in outback New South Wales. This humanity was actively denied – in many places the
is the continuation of a process that began in the middle of the births of our children were recorded on livestock
19th century. records… Only if we were prepared to embrace
Although the situation is changing as major academic the dominant status quo and renounce our identity
literature develops, there has previously been a lack of could we have access to the spoils of citizenship –
appreciation of the economy and society of Aboriginal Australia. education, health care, housing and paid
The next section endeavours to identify briefly some historical employment, to name just a few.
background and the third section considers some of the recent Studies by anthropologists suggest that the Aboriginal
population of Australia in 1788 stood somewhere in a range
between 315 000 and more than a million (Horton, 1993). Over
1. Technically there are two distinct indigenous populations in
Australia – Aborigines and Torres Strait Islanders. Unless specified the next century and a half, the impact of conflict with European
to the contrary, however, the term ‘Aboriginal’ applies to both groups settlers, land dispossession, disease and general social and
in the general chapter discussion. cultural disruption led to a major decline in their numbers.

196 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

500,000
In their recent paper on the health of indigenous Australians,
Howitt, McCracken and Curson (2005) argue that: 450,000
400,000
Prior to their colonial encounter with Europeans,
Aboriginal Australians enjoyed a level of health 350,000
higher than that enjoyed in many parts of Europe 300,000
at the same time. 250,000
They were apparently free of many of the infectious diseases 200,000
prevalent in Europe, such as smallpox, measles, whooping
150,000
cough, syphilis, scarlet fever, tuberculosis and influenza and did
not suffer from conditions such as diabetes, hypertension, renal 100,000
failure, coronary disease and cancer that have plagued their 50,000
recent health profile. 0
Their relative good health disappeared over the next few 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000
decades, affected in part by their lack of immunity to many of
these European-based diseases, as well as by displacement and FIG 17.1 - Estimated movements in Australia’s Aboriginal
colonisation by the dominant European society. population 1901-2001.
Butlin (1983, p 175) estimated that, by 1850, the combined
impact of resource competition and introduced disease resulted Overall, we conclude that there has been steady,
in a situation in which the Aboriginal population of South East although not spectacular improvement in outcomes
Australia stood at only ten per cent of its level in 1788. At a over time. These improvements are especially
national level, it was not until the immediate post-World War II marked for education, although other areas have
period that this situation stabilised and the Aboriginal population seen some gains.
began rising again. Some details of these movements since
Federation appear in Figure 17.1.
It is important to acknowledge that major mining activity did ABORIGINAL AUSTRALIA – SOME RECENT
not begin in eastern Australia until the 1850s and in Western COMPARATIVE DATA
Australia until the 1890s. Despite this, as will be seen later in the At the 2001 census, the estimated resident population of
chapter, the interface between the mining industry and Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islanders in Australia was 459 000.
Aboriginal Australia has been of considerable significance, This was an estimated 2.4 per cent of the total resident
particularly in the past 50 years. Before taking up this theme, population. It had grown at a rate of 2.3 per cent per annum since
however, it is important to consider some aspects concerning the the 1996 census (compared with the national growth rate of 1.2
recent economic and social status of Aboriginal people in per cent per annum)4. This recent growth is more similar to that
Australia. Altman, Biddle and Hunter (2004) have recently in developing than developed nations.
compiled a report focusing on socioeconomic change among
Australian indigenous people at a national level2 covering the As can be seen from in Table 17.2, over half of the Aboriginal
three decades between the 19713 and 2001 national censuses. population lives in New South Wales and Queensland. There are
Considering a range of indicators of employment, income, also significant populations in Western Australia and the Northern
housing, education and health, they observe: Territory. Relatively few Aboriginals live in Victoria, South
Australia, Tasmania or the Australian Capital Territory. Almost 30
per cent of the population of the Northern Territory is Aboriginal.
2. While acknowledging ‘significant variations in indigenous The highest percentage in the states is around 3.5 per cent (in
socioeconomic status at sub-national, state, section-of-state, and Western Australia, Queensland and, surprisingly, Tasmania). The
regional levels’ data difficulties precluded meaningful analysis at comparison in the final two columns of the table provides an
these levels over this period.
alternative way of recognising that the percentage shares of
3. Covering a longer period was not possible because the Australian indigenous people in Queensland, Western Australia and the
government did not count Aboriginal people in the National Census Northern Territory are higher than the shares of those areas in the
until 1971. national total, while those in the other states and territories are
4. While it is clear that the rate of natural increase for Aboriginal lower.
people has recently been greater than in the overall population, one Another useful way to assess the fortunes of Australian
factor contributing to this difference is that some Australians, who Aboriginal people is by considering the component parts of the
had not done previously, may have identified themselves as Human Development Index – life expectancy, income levels and
Aboriginals in 2001. educational achievement.

TABLE 17.2
The distribution of Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander Australians at the 2001 census. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003.)
State and territory Indigenous population Total population Percentage of state or Percentage of Percentage share of
‘000 ‘000 territory population indigenous population total population
New South Wales 135 6575 2.1 29.4 34.0
Victoria 28 4804 0.6 6.1 24.9
Queensland 126 3629 3.5 27.5 18.8
South Australia 26 1486 1.7 5.6 7.7
Western Australia 66 1835 3.5 14.4 9.5
Tasmania 17 471.8 3.7 3.8 2.4
Northern Territory 57 197.8 28.8 12.4 1.0
ACT 4 315.4 1.2 0.9 1.6
Australia 459 19314 2.4 100.0 100.0

Australian Mineral Economics 197


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

The average life expectancy for Aboriginal Australians in TABLE 17.4


2001 was 57 years5, as opposed to 78 years for the general Formal education experiences of indigenous and non-indigenous
population. The average life expectancy in developing Australians 2001. (Source: Altman and Hunter, 2003; Australian
economies in 2002 was 64.6 years – almost eight years more Bureau of Statistics, 2003.)
than for Aboriginal Australians. Some further details about the Category Indigenous Non-indigenous
age distribution of Australia’s indigenous population at the 2001
census appear in Table 17.3. It was, on average, younger than the Did not go to school (%) 3.2 1.0
total population with a median age of 20.5 years (as opposed to Left school at <15 years (%) 33.4 18.0
36.1 years of the non-indigenous population). This was similar to In full time education
the situation with Maoris in New Zealand (22 years as opposed
15 to 17 year olds (%) 65 88
to 33 years). There was almost double the percentage of children
and less than a quarter of the percentage of older people (2.9 per 18 to 24 year olds (%) 17 41
cent versus 12.8 per cent) in comparison to the non-indigenous Hold post-school qualification (%) 27.9 44.7
population.
• workforce participation rates were lower,
TABLE 17.3
• full-time employment rates were lower, and
Data on age distribution of indigenous and non-indigenous
Australians 2001. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003.) • unemployment rates were higher.
Aboriginal and Torres Non-indigenous While 73 per cent of the non-indigenous population either
Strait Islander people population owned or were purchasing their homes, only a third of
indigenous households were doing so.
Median age (years) 20.5 36.1
As can be seen from Table 17.5, the nature of Aboriginal
Percentage under 15 38.9 20.0 households differed in type and size to the total population in
years
2001. They also owned fewer motor vehicles.
Percentage 65 years 2.9 12.8 In some ways Aboriginal Australians seem to be becoming
and over increasingly urbanised, where the word ‘urban’ typically refers to
living in settlements with populations of 1000 or more. As Table
Every individual respondent in the census is expected to 17.6 shows, 73.6 per cent of Aboriginal people lived in major
complete a question about income before tax. The Australian cities and inner regional areas in 2001. This compared with 87
Bureau of Statistics reports these data in income ranges in per cent of the total population. At the 1991 census, an estimated
various geographical classifications from collection districts 67.6 per cent of Aboriginal people lived in urban areas. Yet much
(groups of around 100 households) to the national level. It also of the increase in urbanisation may be due to a greater
publishes estimates of median incomes for individuals and willingness of people in cities and towns to identify themselves
families. At the 2001 census the estimated median individual as Aboriginals, rather than signifying a migration to urban areas.
annual incomes for indigenous Australians aged over 15 years The main interface of the resources sector in Australia with
stood at just under $11 800. This was about 60 per cent of the Aboriginal people in the recent past has been in those outer
median individual income for all Australians of $19 675. regional areas that the Australian Bureau of Statistics describes
Percentages for Aboriginal people varied between states and
territories, with Tasmania (84 per cent) and Victoria (80 per cent)
being the closest to parity with the total population6. The figure TABLE 17.5
in Western Australia was 60 per cent. The lowest figure was in Selected characteristics of Aboriginal and non-Aboriginal
the Northern Territory, at 47.2 per cent. households in Australia 2001. (Source: Australian Bureau of
Statistics, 2003.)
Median incomes in Aboriginal family units stood at $32 800
per annum, just over 72 per cent of the national family median of Aboriginal people Total population
$45 200. But it is important to emphasise that the average Household type
Aboriginal household contained 3.7 people, compared with the
average of 2.7 persons nationally. There were considerable One family (%) 86.6 76.2
variations between the states and territories in these percentages. Multiple family (%) 6.2 1.2
The participation of Aboriginal Australians in the formal Lone person (%) 7.2 22.6
education system in 2001 also was notably less than for the Number of persons per 3.7 2.7
non-indigenous population. The data (derived from Altman and household
Hunter (2003) and the Australian Bureau of Statistics) illustrate Motor cars per household 1.0 1.4
some key differences. As can be seen from Table 17.4:
• more than a third of Aboriginals left school before age 15
(against 18 per cent for the non-indigenous population); TABLE 17.6
• only 65 per cent of the 15 to 17 year old cohort was still at The geographic distribution of Aboriginal Australians and all
Australian residents 2001. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics,
school (versus 88 per cent of the non-indigenous cohort); and 2003.)
• seventeen per cent of 18 to 24 year old Aboriginals were in
full-time education (as opposed to 41 per cent of the Indigenous Indigenous Total
remainder of the population in that age group). population (%) population (‘000) population
Major cities 30.3 139.1 66.3
As well as income, health and education, the Altman and Hunter
(2003) also considered housing and labour markets. They found: Inner regional 42.3 194.2 20.7
Outer regional 27.4 125.8 13.0
5. This estimate appears in Altman and Hunter (2003, p 7). Remote 9.8 44.2 8.5

6. Indeed, the median Tasmanian income for all of its population was Very remote 17.7 81.2 4.5
not much higher than 84 per cent. Total 100.0 459.0 100.0

198 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

as ‘remote’ or ‘very remote’. The estimated indigenous was also smaller. In remote areas it is arguable that cattle and
population of these areas was just over 125 000 and as Altman sheep station development exerted considerably greater influence
(2004, p 518) notes, there are about 1200 indigenous than mining in disturbing Aboriginal lifestyles.
communities in these areas. In this part of the country the related There was a significant change with the onset of the resources
issues of land rights, native title and economic development have boom in the early 1960s. At this time major new development
become much more important. took place in regions such as the Pilbara, Central and North
The Australian Bureau of Statistics reported that in 2000-01 Queensland, the eastern and northern goldfields of Western
there were 871 management units conducting mining operations Australia and in the Kimberley. Altman and Nieuwenhuysen
in Australia. Given the economic geography of the resources (1979, p 41) noted that:
sector, the data in Table 17.7 provide an indicative view of the
interaction between the resources sector and remote indigenous A small number of extremely remote missions
communities. In addition to this, there was considerable mineral and settlements have come into sudden
exploration activity, most of it focused in Western Australia, prolonged contact with the Western world owing
Queensland and Northern Territory, where the interface with to discoveries of minerals at or near Aboriginal
remote settlements was greatest. In 2001-02, for instance, more reserves. The major discoveries to date have
than half of the estimated $1.5 billion of mineral and petroleum been bauxite at Gove in the Arnhem Land and at
exploration expenditure took place in Western Australia about Weipa in the far north of Queensland, and
ten per cent in Queensland and approximately 15 per cent in the manganese at Groote Eylandt off the Arnhem
Northern Territory. Land coast. Large extractive plants have been
established by Nabalco, Comalco and GEMCo (a
subsidiary of BHP) respectively. The
TABLE 17.7 communities that have suddenly found these
Operation of mining operations in remote parts of Australia. companies on their doorsteps (literally in some
(Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002.) cases) are Yirkkala mission at Gove, Weipa and
Aurukun in Queensland, and Angurugu mission
Industry sector No of units Operation in
remote areas
and Umbakumbu on Groote Eylandt.
Coal mining 108 some These new projects dramatically enhanced the economic
growth of Western Australia, the Northern Territory and
Oil and gas extraction 50 some
Queensland. They bolstered national export growth and, during
Iron ore mining 19 considerable the early 1970s, increased the exchange rate. Yet, at the local
Copper mining 14 some community level, there seemed a general indifference by mining
Gold mining 89 considerable companies towards nearby Aboriginal communities. There was
minimal economic contact, though there tended to be some
Mineral sands mining 11 little social interaction. Rogers (1973, p 133) found that in 1968, there
Silver-lead-zinc 9 some were only 193 Aboriginal people employed by 23 large and
Other metal mining 17 some medium-size mining companies throughout Australia. While it is
unreasonable to blame mining companies for adverse social and
Other mining 554 little
economic effects, the clash between the globally focused
Total 871 Western capitalist system and traditional Aboriginal
communities was almost destined to generate such an outcome.
MINING AND ABORIGINAL AUSTRALIA – There is now a broad literature about this area7. In this review,
PRE MABO we consider the case studies by Howitt (1989) and Dillon (1991).
Howitt describes the impacts of mining development of the
As discussed earlier, Australia’s Aboriginal population declined Pilbara on the Aboriginal population in the established town of
substantially from the beginning of European settlement until the Roebourne. Dillon (1991) provides a parallel account of the
end of 1945. The impact that the expansion of mining had on experience of Aboriginal people with diamond mining in the
surrounding Aboriginal communities must have been significant Kimberley. The discussion below considers their findings and
following the establishment of large mineral industry based seeks to extend them to the present.
towns such as Newcastle, Bathurst, Ballarat, Bendigo,
Wollongong, Broken Hill, Kalgoorlie and Mount Isa, as well as a
variety of smaller mining towns and settlements.
Howitt’s study of Roebourne
For example, in their centenary history of Kalgoorlie Boulder Between 1960 and 1980 the development of the iron ore industry
and the eastern goldfields of Western Australia, Webb and Webb dramatically changed the nature of the economy of the Pilbara.
(1993, pp 176-226) report several cases in which gold miners and This followed on from the setting up of the Wittenoom asbestos
prospectors came into violent conflict with Aboriginal groups. mines and the somewhat earlier establishment, but equally as
Blainey (2003) records similar experiences relating to the gold impressive subsequent development, of the oil and gas sector.
rushes in the Northern Territory. During these two decades, Australia rose from being a small iron
Following the exhaustion of alluvial gold, one factor militating ore producer to one of the two major iron ore exporting nations.
against excessive contact between Europeans working in the By 1980, the Pilbara iron ore mines were responsible for around
mining sector and Aboriginals was that mining (as opposed to a quarter of world iron ore exports.
pastoral and agricultural activities) disturbed a small land area. The pastoral industry had been established in the region since
Furthermore, a substantial part occurred in arid environments the 1860s. The small non-Aboriginal population dominated the
where surrounding environmental impacts tend to be lower. With local economy during this period and many Aboriginal people
the decline of the industry between 1914 and 1960, its impact worked on cattle stations. They were generally treated as
second-class citizens, with many of their rights constrained. A
notable historical milestone in response to poor treatment on
7. See for example the volumes of Cousins and Nieuwenhuysen (1984), pastoral stations came in 1946 with the first major strike and
Howitt, Connell and Hirsch (1996), Connell and Howitt (1991), station walk off by Aboriginals. Some relocated to Roebourne,
Rumsey and Weiner (2004) and Langton et al (2004). one of the few very small towns in the Pilbara (with places such

Australian Mineral Economics 199


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

FIG 17.2 - The Shire of Roebourne and the Pilbara region.

as Port Hedland and Onslow) at that time. In the ensuing years 18000
cash payments became more frequent for station workers and
16000
employment conditions made some improvement.
During this period, the town of Roebourne attracted aboriginal 14000

people from outlying parts of the region and its society became
12000
fragmented. A strong presence of Christian fundamentalist Aboriginal people
groups apparently contributed to this situation. At the 1961 10000
Total population
census, the Shire of Roebourne (one of the four shires in the 8000
Pilbara) (see Figure 17.2) had a population of only 568 people,
though notably this figure did not include Aboriginals. 6000

Several events then occurred to facilitate the Pilbara region’s 4000


integration with the global economy. They included the
election of a Liberal state government in Western Australia in 2000

1959 that perceived resource development as a key to the state’s 0


industrialisation, the emergence of the Japanese economy as a 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

favoured customer for raw materials8, and changing transport


technology that facilitated bulk shipping of low value materials. FIG 17.3 - Estimated population in the Shire of Roebourne –
Between 1962 and 1975 major mining companies such as 1961-2001.
BHP, Hamersley Iron (a Rio Tinto company) and Robe River
(also now associated with Rio Tinto) built ten new company The rapid influx of a construction workforce
towns9, four new railways, three new deepwater ports, and dominated by single men, a vastly expanded cash
associated infrastructure. The population of the Pilbara, and of economy and exclusion from company towns
the Shire of Roebourne (which included the new towns of combined with a downturn in the rural sector and
Karratha, Dampier and Wickham), both increased dramatically. significant policy changes to further destabilise
Data for the Shire of Roebourne appear in Figure 17.3. fragile community structures. In comparison to
The majority Aboriginal population in the early 1960s the relative material wealth of the new towns, the
changed to become a small minority with less than five per cent poverty and powerlessness of most Aborigines
of the Shire’s population ten years later. By 2001 the Aboriginal
was reinforced.
population had recovered to be just over ten per cent of the
Shire’s population. Few Aboriginals were employed on iron ore projects. This was
The key projects affecting the Shire and Town of Roebourne apparently reinforced by a request from the state Country (now
were the Hamersley Iron and Robe River developments with National) Party to the companies to recruit workers directly from
their associated company towns, railways and ports. The the cities to avoid disrupting the local pastoral industry.
dramatic growth of the shire’s economic base had little initial Construction of port facilities and associated infrastructure
effect on the Aboriginal population of Roebourne. In the early began at Dampier in 1965. Even though it was about 50 km
stages Howitt (1989, p 160) notes that: away, the Roebourne Hotel was the only conventional hotel in
the area. Hamersley employees widely used its facilities. Not
8. This placed pressure on the Australian government to remove export unexpectedly liaisons developed between these workers and local
restrictions on iron ore that had been introduced in 1938. young Aboriginal women and there was an increase in childbirths
9. Several of these company towns have subsequently been closed (eg as a result. These placed an additional burden on the local
Goldsworthy and Shay Gap). Others such as Newman and Karratha community and few construction workers took responsibility for
have become open towns. their children.

200 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

In the ensuing years there were major problems with juvenile


delinquency, general social breakdown, excessive alcohol
consumption, exclusion of Aboriginals from the workforce and
from nearby company towns, and major differences in the quality
of community infrastructure between Roebourne and the nearby
towns of Karratha, Dampier and Wickham.
In terms of the suggested impacts of resource developments in
Table 17.1, the potentially positive economic impacts for
indigenous communities did not materialise, and the threatening
social and cultural impacts did emerge. In the first area, local
Aboriginal people were not recognised as stakeholders and were
therefore unable to share in the large economic rents emerging.
They also had little opportunity to gain employment and earn Argyle Diamond mine
incomes that would have improved their material wealth.
Significant themes in the period since Howitt’s paper have
been the Reconciliation movement and the Native Title era
following the Mabo Case. The assessment by Altman and Hunter
(2003) suggested only marginal improvement in the material
wellbeing of indigenous Australians during the 1990s and at the
turn of the new millennium. At the 2001 census the relative
economic positions of indigenous and non-indigenous
populations in the Shire of Roebourne still differed dramatically.
Median individual incomes for Aboriginal people were about 45
per cent of those of the non-indigenous population, family
incomes 43 per cent and household incomes 67 per cent. In a FIG 17.4 - The Argyle diamond mine and nearby communities.
local government area in which official unemployment rates
were low (5.5 per cent) the indigenous population had an
unemployment rate of 18.3 per cent (or 26.7 per cent if The focus of the study by Dillon (1991) was on the Argyle
employment in the Community Development Employment diamond mine, located 80 km south of Kununurra (see Figure
Projects (CDEP) scheme was excluded). The relative economic 17.4). Argyle Diamond Mines has operated the mine since 1981.
disadvantage remained at apparently similar levels to where it The company was initially a joint venture between Ashton
had been 40 years earlier. Mining, Conzinc Rio Tinto of Australia (CRA) and the Western
Australian Diamond Trust. The company is now fully owned by
This apparent lack of progress in economic terms does, Rio Tinto.
however, overlook a distinct change in view and activities about
indigenous relations within many large mining companies since The mine is large and highly productive. Since it reached
the early 1990s10. While acknowledging that: full-scale production in 1986, the annual average value of its
output has been around $500 million. The company has paid
In the Pilbara region, the mine, rail and port royalties varying between $40 million and $70 million per
developments were carried out in the early 1970s annum to the Western Australian state government. It has
with no reference to Aboriginal people, consistently employed around 1000 people. Yet, throughout its
Harvey (2002) describes this change for Rio Tinto. There is now life, the mine has largely used a fly-in, fly-out workforce. It is
explicit recognition of social and cultural issues in local now entirely a fly-in, fly-out (75 per cent) and drive-in drive-out
communities by the company and with it a new willingness to (25 per cent from Kununurra and surrounding areas) operation.
employ indigenous people who live near resource developments. The impact of the mine has been important for the Shire of
In March 2005, the Rio Tinto website reported that eight per cent Wyndham East Kimberley, and of some significance for the Shire
of the Hamersley Iron workforce was indigenous Australians of Hall’s Creek. But the growth of tourism and the continuing
with a goal of 12 per cent by 2005. With more than 2000 people importance of agriculture has meant that mining has affected the
working in their Pilbara operations, the indigenous workforce is area’s economy relatively less than the situation in the Pilbara.
now close to 200 people. The economic implications for As Figure 17.5 shows, population growth in the East Kimberley
Aboriginal people living in Roebourne are much more positive has been substantial since 1976 but it has not been explosive and
than they were in the early 1970s. overwhelmed the strong indigenous influence.
16000
Dillon’s study of Argyle Indigenous
14324
14000
Europeans first settled the East Kimberley region in the 1880s. Non-Indigenous 12062
Families such as the Durack’s initiated the pastoral industry, and 12000 Total
10741
there was a gold rush in areas such as Hall’s Creek at about the
10000
same time. During this period, the small port of Wyndham and 8593
the inland settlement of Hall’s Creek were established. The next 7800
8000
major development came in the 1960s, when there was major 6005
public investment to develop the Ord River irrigation scheme. 6000
5249
Using water from the newly constructed Lake Argyle, the largest
4000
man-made lake in Australia, this scheme sought to convert 4018 4088
3799
70 000 hectares of rangeland and pasture to irrigated farming 2000 3194
land. The new town of Kununurra was established to service the 2438

Ord River scheme. 0


1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

10. This has formed part of their more recent focus on sustainable FIG 17.5 - Population movements in the Shires of Wyndham East
development. Kimberley and Hall’s Creek, 1976-2001.

Australian Mineral Economics 201


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

Dillon was concerned with the physical, social and economic While the town of Kununurra has emerged as a significant
impacts of the mine on local Aboriginal people. In a relative sub-regional centre, Dillon (1991, pp 144-45) points to the
sense the physical impacts have been small. Even though the interesting and positive associated development of Aboriginal
mine is large, it is isolated and remote. The nearest Aboriginal people establishing outstation communities. He perceives this as:
population at Mandangala is 10 km away. There are other small
…a partial reaction to non-Aboriginal urbanisation
Aboriginal communities at Doon Doon (25 km away) and
Warmun (35 km from the mine). and the pervasive dominance of non-Aboriginal
forms of ‘development’.
Because of its remoteness and small area of operation, the
physical impact of the mine, in comparison to the Ord scheme Cultural impacts are primary land-related. In its early years
and the land degradation of pastoral activities has been minimal. the Argyle site generated considerable controversy because of
The social, economic and cultural impacts have been of greater the conflict between sites of significance (as set out in the 1972
concern. Aboriginal Heritage Act) and the political and economic
Economic impacts on balance appear to have been positive, imperatives of the state government pursuing policies of vigorous
yet Dillon perceives them to be relatively modest. At one level resource development.
the company, through its ‘good neighbour policy’, supplemented The action of CRA11 of undertaking exploration work on three
infrastructure in the nearby communities and apparently made sites of significance in 1980 brought planned court action. The
small royalty payments to nearby Aboriginal groups for two plaintiffs were unable to proceed with this because the WA
decades. This policy tightened up during the 1990s to try to Museum refused to act to obtain evidence that CRA had
ensure that local communities used such payments productively. breached the Heritage Act. The company subsequently
One assessment of the economic status of indigenous people in negotiated a financial agreement with local Aboriginal people at
the Wyndham East Kimberley Shire can be gained from the 2001 Mandangarla and later with members of the Doon Doon and
census indigenous peoples profile by comparing labour force, Warmun communities. This led to the ‘good neighbour’ policy
education and income data (see Table 17.8). While Aboriginal already mentioned. This has not adversely affected the long-term
people have lower workforce participation rates (55.2 per cent development of the mine but it highlighted the sites of
against 70 per cent) and higher unemployment rates (ten per cent significance issue and the Aboriginal relationship to the land,
against three per cent), these differences were not as large as which has become so important in the past decade.
between indigenous and non-indigenous groups in the Shire of In summary, the impact of the mining industry on the welfare
Roebourne. By contrast, however, there are real gaps in of local indigenous communities in remote Western Australia has
educational attainment between Aboriginal and non-Aboriginal so far been marginal. While this situation appears at last to be
people. Relative income levels of indigenous people were similar changing, a lot of hard work seems to lie ahead.
to those in the Pilbara. Unless, or until, indigenous people in the
East Kimberley increase their human capital, major differences
seem likely to remain in the economic status of indigenous and MINING AND ABORIGINAL AUSTRALIA – THE
non-indigenous groups. MABO CASE AND RECENT DEVELOPMENTS
In the wake of the emerging focus of mining companies on The discussion of the preceding section conveniently sidestepped
sustainable development, the key stakeholders – traditional
the issue of land rights. Deriving from the doctrine of terra
landowners, Argyle Diamonds and the Kimberley Land Council
– recently negotiated the Argyle Participation Agreement. With nullius the ownership of mineral resources in Australia is largely
its focus on economic participation and regional development, vested in the Crown. The essence of the prevailing regime is
the movement towards greater indigenous employment is described quite effectively by the following quote from Industry
reflected in this document. According to Rio Tinto (2005) Argyle Commission (1991):
Diamonds’ indigenous workforce is currently 21 per cent. It aims In Australia ownership of mineral resources
to increase this to 40 per cent by 2007, although it is not clear generally lies with the Crown (in practice
whether this change will come about as a result of a reduced State/Territory and Commonwealth governments),
mining workforce or not.
regardless of who owns the land on the surface.
This seems to reflect a widely held belief that
TABLE 17.8 mineral deposits are a fortuitous ‘gift of nature’
Labour force, educational and income data for indigenous and and that any net benefits flowing from their
non-indigenous populations, Wyndham East Kimberley Shire, exploitation should accrue to the community as a
2001 census. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003.) whole rather than to whoever happens to own the
surface rights.
Indigenous Non-indigenous
Labour force indicators Subsequent development of these resources is based on the
‘regalian’ system where the Crown ‘leases the rights to exploit
Participation rate (%) 55.2 70.2
these resources to private firms under set conditions’.
Unemployment rate (%) 10.0 3.0
When he authored the report of the Aboriginal Land Rights
Education Commission in 1974, Justice Woodward noted that:
Did not go to school (%) 7.2 0.3
At the beginning of the year 1788, the whole of
Completed year 12 (%) 7.6 40.8 Australia was occupied by the Aboriginal people
Bachelor degree and above (%) 1.5 15.2 of this country. It was divided between groups in
Median weekly incomes a way which was understood and respected by
all.
Individual ($) 180 550
Family ($) 550 1100
Over the last 186 years, white settlers and their
descendants have gradually taken over the
Household ($) 550 900 occupation of most of the fertile and otherwise
useful parts of the country. In doing so, they have
11. Conzinc Rio Tinto Australia was the earlier name of Rio Tinto in shown scant regard for any rights in the land,
Australia. legal or moral of the Aboriginal people.

202 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

Always an underlying issue in the relationship between TABLE 17.9


indigenous and non-indigenous Australians, land rights emerged Landmarks regarding native title and resource development.
strongly as a key issue in the 1970s and 1980s. The matter
impinged on the resources sector as miners extended their Date Event Result
activities into more remote areas. 1788-1992 Terra nullius doctrine Indigenous Australians had no
The matter reached a high point in 1992 when the High Court in force land rights.
of Australia brought down the Mabo judgement. This followed a 1992 Mabo judgement by Recognition of the existence of
series of earlier court cases and the passage of Aboriginal land High Court native title.
rights legislation in the Northern Territory and South Australia. It 1993 Commonwealth National regime for native title
has been succeeded by two major pieces of Commonwealth Native Title Act including ‘right to negotiate’ for
legislation, as well as some further High Court judgements. native title claimants.
In rejecting the doctrine of terra nullius the High Court judges 1997 Wik judgement in Native title could co-exist with
recognised native title in certain situations. This judgement High Court pastoral leases.
signalled potential and actual change to the position of 1998 Ten point plan and Native Sought to overcome
indigenous Australians as stakeholders in mineral development. Title Amendment Act complexities in initial
Mason (1996, p 3) describes the decision in the following terms: legislation. Tended to favour
The High Court held that indigenous inhabitants government and business
interests.
of Australia held customary native title in their
traditional lands in unalienated Crown land in
Australia so long as it had not been validly The entries in Table 17.9 provide a brief summary of recent
extinguished by legislative or executive action, developments.
provided they have not surrendered their title or
The Mabo judgement and the subsequent Commonwealth
lost their connection to the land.
Native Title Act passed by the Keating government in December
Explaining native title, Horrigan (2003, p 19) argues that: 1993 came as a shock to the Australian mining industry. Over the
Native title rights are traditional rights of access, next few years it introduced growing uncertainty with respect to
use, or occupation concerning lands or waters. mineral exploration in greenfield areas and encouraged many
They are personal or group rights based on companies to focus their exploration activity on current mining
traditional laws or customs. The traditional land leases instead. As time went by, this uncertainty added to the
rights of indigenous Australians survive unless attractiveness of Australian-based companies exploring in other
the government lawfully takes them away, they nations12.
are surrendered, or the indigenous connection The major industry criticisms of the new Commonwealth
with land according to traditional laws and legislation, and the requisite state acts to support it, related to
customs is otherwise severed. their complexity, the delays involved in processing claims for
native title compensation and the impact of this on the
At the time, there was major concern in the resources sector profitability of projects in a period in which mineral prices and
that this judgement would adversely affect mineral exploration exchange rate movements were unpredictable. Also while native
and mine development as Australia moved to a ‘post-colonial title had been extinguished on freehold land, uncertainty
view of the world’. remained about the relationship between pastoral leases and
Yet even with recognition of limited native title rights, the native title.
Crown continues to claim virtually all subsurface mineral rights.
In the Wik case judgement in 1997 and some later decisions,
Commentators such as Howitt (2005) observe that:
the High Court established that when government grants pastoral
It is this claim, rather than the claims of leases, this does not necessarily extinguish surviving native title.
individual mining companies to have rights Importantly, however, when these two forms of title co-exist,
derived from various state agencies, to mine leaseholder rights take priority. This judgement had application
lands that are subject to claims of indigenous as well to situations in which there were mining titles on
ownership, that underpins tensions between the leasehold land.
industry and indigenous groups. Competing native title claims over mineral prospective areas
further confused the situation facing miners. Financial
Despite these tensions, in his recent review paper, Horrigan institutions were also indecisive in their views about providing
(2003, p 17) argues: finance and security requirements.
Yet, after more than a decade of Australian With its historical sympathies towards resource sector
native title law, at least ten landmark High Court development, the newly elected Howard Coalition government
cases, native title legislation in every Australian sought to ‘strike a fair balance between respect for native title
jurisdiction, and millions of dollars of legal and security for pastoralists, farmers and miners’ in 1997 when it
advice on native title matters across the introduced the Native Title Amendment Act based on its ten-point
community, farmers have not lost their land or plan. As Horrigan (2003, p 21) explains, this covers the
any existing rights across the board because of following areas:
native title, miners have not lost their mining • extinguishment of native title,
titles wholesale on native title grounds, lawful
commercial rights still prevail over competing • validation of pre-Wik actions,
native title rights, and relatively few native title • facilitation of public infrastructure and government actions,
claims have succeeded in court.
• interaction between tenure rights and native title,
• restrictions on indigenous rights to negotiate,
12. Perhaps this was a positive event because it encouraged domestically • frameworks for indigenous land use agreements, and
focused entrepreneurs to look more widely at potentially profitable
opportunities. • ‘just terms’ compensation.

Australian Mineral Economics 203


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

The legislation changes the balance away from indigenous and already hold mining leases granted before the Mabo decision,
towards business and commercial interests. Despite this but where they decide to negotiate such agreements because
assessment, one can also argue that mining companies have of company policy.
accepted that indigenous Australians are now stakeholders in the The authors identify the Aboriginal Land Rights (Northern
mineral development process. Almost all now opt to negotiate Territory) Act 1996 as an important example of the first
directly with Native Title claimants, rather than pursue legal/administrative context, while the Commonwealth Native
time-consuming judgements through the court system. The Title Act 1993 provides the main illustration of the second
resulting indigenous land use agreements combine some situation. In the first context, Aboriginal negotiators are in a
recognition of social and cultural issues, limited access to stronger bargaining position than in the second, all things being
economic rents and some potential for Aboriginal people to equal.
benefit from surrounding economic development.
The third legal/administrative context is also important. Even
And, as discussed elsewhere in this volume, there has been an though they are not legally required to do so, large companies
apparently inexorable trend towards mines operating as ‘fly-in, may choose to negotiate agreements with local indigenous
fly-out’ operations and in remote and even not so remote people for a variety of reasons. The most important seems to be
hinterland areas since the 1980s. One benefit of this practice is that such policies are more likely to ensure their continuing
that it provides minimal interference with the societies and licence to operate in a broader global environment over the long
cultures of nearby indigenous communities. term. The decision by Rio Tinto in the 1990s to follow such a
Furthermore, as long as mining companies can adjust their practice is noteworthy in this regard though it seems to have been
work practice requirements, and members of indigenous followed as well by other large companies.
communities are amenable to training and would like Despite this apparently positive change for indigenous
employment, there are potential economic development populations, there has been some broad criticism of the
opportunities available for them. Particularly in periods of high outcomes. The recent papers by O’Faircheallaigh and Corbett
mineral demand, when labour turnover in traditional mining (2005) and Lawrence (2005) provide two examples of such
workforces is high, the opportunities for indigenous workers in analysis. In focusing on indigenous participation in the
nearby local communities to establish themselves as alternative environmental management of mining projects, O’Faircheallaigh
cost-efficient and stable sources of labour increase significantly. and Corbett consider 45 agreements using a range of assessment
As mining companies recognise this option, they become much criteria. They conclude that:
more amenable to using their services.
While agreements certainly have the potential to
The above case studies for the town of Roebourne and for the
enhance Aboriginal participation in environmental
Argyle diamond mine confirm that large companies such as Rio
management, a majority do not have that effect,
Tinto have been recognising and taking advantage of this
reflecting the weak negotiating position of many
potential. These developments follow from similar successful
Aboriginal peoples in their dealings with mining
efforts in places such as the Red Dog zinc mine in Alaska and in companies.
remote areas of Canada such as the North West Territories where
the Ekati and Diavik diamond mines are now in production. Mining professionals who work in these environments must
Global mining corporations are now following similar practices now recognise the key importance of appreciating and respecting
in many developing nations. social and cultural differences between indigenous populations
and global capitalism.
The trend towards negotiated agreements
LOOKING TO THE FUTURE
Against this background, an important associated trend in recent
years has been a move away from the community management/ The interface between global capitalism and indigenous
good neighbour policies13 associated with projects such as the populations with new and existing mining projects is destined to
Argyle diamond mine, towards formal negotiated agreements continue. An optimist might suggest that the progress that is now
with local Aboriginal populations. Such frameworks hold being made in places such as the Pilbara and the East Kimberley
apparent promise for Aboriginal populations to claim economic will also continue. As a result, indigenous Australians will
rent in a more effective manner, while also addressing important emerge during the next two or three decades as successful
social and cultural issues. stakeholders in a world-class mining industry. Yet they will also
O’Faircheallaigh and Corbett (2005, p 634) classify the need to be provided with greater educational and occupational
emergence of such agreements in Australia in three distinct opportunities so that they can pursue alternative lifestyle
legal/administrative contexts. These are: opportunities when the mines in their areas become exhausted.
• those resulting from legislation that recognises Aboriginal Whether they can withstand the seductive appeal of global
ownership of land and does not permit mineral development capitalism and maintain their cultural identity remains a major
without formal agreement between Aboriginal landowners question. Governments may be able to assist their cause by
and mining companies; putting in place sympathetic policies. But in many ways,
Australian Aboriginal people will have their future in their own
• those in which legislation ‘creates an opportunity for hands.
negotiation of agreements, but allows mining to proceed in
the absence of consent from Aboriginal landowners’; and The general discussion of this chapter about the interface of
mining with Australia’s indigenous population will happen with
• those in which mining companies have no legal requirement much greater intensity in many other countries in the future.
to negotiate with traditional Aboriginal owners because they Australian mining professionals, many of who will be working in
remote areas and mineral rich developing nations will face the
difficult, though stimulating challenge of operating in close
13. A typical academic critique of such policies is that they patronise
local indigenous populations in a demeaning way. Lawrence (2005) proximity with indigenous people. Maintaining social and
provides such an analysis in her assessment of employment and cultural diversity, while delivering economic benefits and
training programs available to the Warlpiri people in the Central economic opportunity to generate sustainable economic
Australian gold mining industry. outcomes, will continue to be a major task.

204 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 17: MINING AND INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS

REFERENCES Harvey, B, 2002. Sociology before geology: The development of social


competencies at Rio Tinto, Minerals Council of Australia
Altman, J C, 2004. Economic development and indigenous Australia: Sustainable Development Conference, 15 p.
contestations over property, institutions and ideology, The Australian Horrigan, B, 2003. Australian native title law, policy and practice – A
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 48:3:513-534. report card, Economic Papers, 22(4):16-27.
Altman, J C, Biddle, N and Hunter, B, 2004. Indigenous socioeconomic Horton, D R, 1993. Unity and diversity: The history and culture of
change 1971-2001: A historical perspective, discussion paper no 266, Aboriginal Australia, Year Book Australia 1994, pp 397-415
Centre for Aboriginal Policy Research (Australian National (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra).
University: Canberra). Howitt, R, 1989. Resource development and Aborigines: the case of
Altman, J C and Hunter, B, 2003. Evaluating indigenous socioeconomic Roebourne, Australian Geographical Studies, 27(2):155-169.
outcomes in the reconciliation decade, 1991-2001, Economic Papers, Howitt, R, 2005. Personal communication.
22(4):1-15.
Howitt, R, Connell, J and Hirsch, P (eds), 1996. Resources, Nations and
Altman, J C and Nieuwenhuysen, J, 1979. The Economic Status of Indigenous Peoples: Case Studies from Australasia, Melanesia and
Australian Aborigines (Cambridge University Press: Cambridge). Southeast Asia (Oxford University Press: Melbourne).
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 1999. Aboriginal and Torres Strait Howitt, R, McCracken, K and Curson, P, 2005. Australian indigenous
Islander Australian: A statistical profile from the 1996 census, Year health: What issues contribute to a national crisis and scandal?
Book Australia 1999 (Catalogue No 1301.01) (Australian Bureau of unpublished paper.
Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.
au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006. Industry Commission, 1991. Mining and minerals processing in Australia,
Report No 7, 25 February (Australian Government Publishing Service:
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002. Mining operations Australia Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.pc.gov.au/ic/inquiry/
2000-2001 (Catalogue No 8415.0) (Australian Bureau of Statistics: 07mining/finalreport/index.html>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date
accessed: 8 May 2006. Langton, M, Tehan, M, Palmer, L and Shain, K, 2004. Honour Among
Nations? Treaties and Agreements with Indigenous People (Melbourne
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003. 2001 National census community University Press: Melbourne).
profile series (Catalogue No 2005.0) (Australian Bureau of Statistics:
Canberra) [online]. Available from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date Lawrence, R, 2005. Governing Warlpiri subjects: indigenous employment
accessed: 8 May 2006. and training programs in the central Australian mining industry,
Geographical Research, 43(1):40-48.
Blainey, G, 2003. The Rush That Never Ended, fifth edition (Melbourne
University Press: Melbourne). Mason, A, 1996. The judge as law-maker, James Cook University Law
Review, 1.
Burger, J, 1990. The Gaia Atlas of First Peoples: A Future for the
Indigenous World (Penguin: Melbourne). O’Faircheallaigh, C and Corbett, T, 2005. Indigenous participation in
environmental management of mining projects: The role of
Butlin, N G, 1983. Our Original Aggression: Aboriginal Populations of negotiated agreements, Environmental Politics, 14(5):629-647.
Southeastern Australia, 1788-1850, (George Allen and Unwin: Sydney).
Rio Tinto, 2005. [Online]. <http://www.riotinto.com>. Date accessed:
Connell, J and Howitt, R (eds), 1991. Mining and Indigenous Peoples In 24 March 2005.
Australasia (Sydney University Press: Sydney).
Rogers, P H, 1973. The Industrialists and the Aborigines – A Study of
Coombs, H C, 1982. How to balance the Aboriginal interest in resource Aboriginal Employment in the Australian Mining Industry (Angus
development, in Resource Development and the Future of Australian and Robertson: Sydney).
Society (eds: C Kissling, et al) pp 239-251 (Centre for Resource and
Environmental Studies, Australian National University: Canberra). Rumsey, A and Weiner, J (eds), 2004. Mining and Indigenous Lifeworlds
in Australia and Papua New Guinea (Sean Kingston: Wantage).
Cousins, D and Nieuwenhuysen, J, 1984. Aboriginals and the Mining
Industry: Case Studies of the Australian Experience, (George Allen Warden-Fernandez, J, 2001. Indigenous communities and mineral
and Unwin: Sydney; [for the] Committee for Economic Development development, Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development project
of Australia). Report No 59, April, (International Institute for Environment and
Development: London) [online]. Available from: <http://www.iied.
Dillon, M, 1991. Interpreting Argyle: Aborigines and diamond mining in org/mmsd/mmsd_pdfs/059_warden-fernandez.pdf>. Date accessed:
northwest Australia, in Mining and Indigenous Peoples in Australasia 8 May 2006.
(eds: J Connell and R Howitt) pp 139-152 (Sydney University Press:
Sydney). Webb, M and Webb, A, 1993. Golden Destiny: The Centenary History of
Kalgoorlie Boulder and the Eastern Goldfields of Western Australia,
Dodson, M, 1998. Culture + citizenship (keynote address), paper presented (City of Kalgoorlie Boulder: Kalgoorlie).
to Culture + Citizenship Conference, Griffith University, November.
Gove, P B (ed), 1971. Webster’s Seventh New Collegiate Dictionary (G C
Merriam Company: Springfield).

Australian Mineral Economics 205


CHAPTER 18

Minerals and Regional Development


Philip Maxwell

Some Introductory Remarks


Mining – Towns, Cities and Regions
The Australian Regional Framework
Mining and Australian Regional Development – A Historical Perspective
Socio-Economic Indicators
Assessing Economic Impacts
Assessing Social Impacts
Fly-in, Fly-out and Regional Development

SOME INTRODUCTORY REMARKS As the level of analysis proceeds from smaller to larger
regions, the economic and social fortunes of local communities
Exploitation of minerals and energy has been closely associated tend to receive less sympathy from policymakers as they take a
with the growth and development of the world economy broader regional perspective. This was the case, for example,
throughout its recorded history; yet there is considerable debate when the Western Australian government decided to introduce a
about the effect of mineral development on small regions. This gold royalty in 1998. Even though producers of other minerals
comes in part because minerals are non-renewable. It is also paid such royalties, gold producers had always been exempt. The
influenced by the fact that mines and oil wells generate protestations of impending doom from gold producing areas
economic rent, which may be claimed by stakeholders in a were largely ignored as the government phased in a royalty
variety of ways – some productive and some not. A more recent regime, which paralleled that of other non-industrial minerals.
consideration is the rise of ‘fly-in, fly-out’ work practices. While
A rather different example of local regional impacts, which
a particular interest in this final chapter is in the impacts of
minerals and energy exploitation on the fortunes of mining towns has had wider ramifications, relates to the fortunes of the Ok
and communities, and their subsequent sustainability, it also Tedi copper mine in Papua New Guinea. The communities
recognises the impacts of mineral development on larger downstream from the mine clearly seem to have lost out because
sub-national regions. of the discharge of wastes into the Sepik River. Their misfortunes
have been the subject of rulings in Australian courts. In seeking
The authors of Breaking New Ground (IIED, 2002) for to retain its public image as a responsible global mining
example, take a small region focus, when they suggest the company, BHP Billiton, gave up its share of the joint venture that
following taxonomy to assist consideration of the social and operates the mine. One possible outcome from the episode was
economic status of communities affected by mining at the small the closure of the mine. Yet, particularly because it provided and
area regional level: still provides an important source of revenue to the national
• occupational communities – households or families who coffers, the government in Port Moresby chose to continue to
derive all or most of their income from mining; allow its operation.
• residential communities – households or families who live Analysts take a variety of perspectives in considering the
in the geographical area affected by mining; and impacts of mining in regions. These include economic, social
and health, cultural and environmental. From an economic
• indigenous communities – households or families with an perspective regional governments typically receive royalty
ancient and cultural attachment to the land where mining streams and perhaps also taxation receipts from new mine
occurs or has an impact. developments. Those residents displaced by new mines will also
Each of these communities (living in small regions) will be receive financial compensation but typically will forfeit their
affected by mining in different ways. Acceptable policy homes and access to their land. New mines also generate
outcomes from new mineral development will presumably satisfy potential employment opportunities and higher incomes in a
each of these groups, moving them from a less desirable to a region. Employment and income multipliers, which are discussed
more desirable social and economic status. Where this does not in the next section, provide opportunities for regional business.
happen conflict is likely to arise. Another benefit comes with the improvement of infrastructure

Australian Mineral Economics 207


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

(airports, roads, railways, water supplies, sanitation systems, framework. The fourth section reflects on the social impacts of
electricity), which can often be used by local industries that mining, while the fifth considers ways in which economists
otherwise would not be established. typically assess the impacts of activities such as mining. The
New mines may also improve the social fabric of a region by focus of the final section is specifically on assessing the impacts
generating revenue to alleviate poverty, malnutrition, illiteracy of ‘fly-in, fly-out’ work practices on regional development.
and poor health in previously depressed areas. Yet they may also
increase social problems because of the displacement of nearby MINING – TOWNS, CITIES AND REGIONS
communities as a result of pollution or by migrant workers,
acting as a disruptive influence with respect to local social Minerals and energy have driven major economic development
control. Some of the adverse social influences associated with and growth in many large regions. The list includes places such
mining regions can arise from greater consumption of alcohol as South Wales, Yorkshire, Tyneside, the Ruhr, Silesia,
and other drugs, increased gambling, prostitution and greater California, Pennsylvania, Texas, Oklahoma, Nevada, Alberta, the
levels of domestic violence. Transvaal (now Gauteng), Chile’s Antofagasta region, and
probably every Australian state. Blainey (2003) provides an
Workers with higher incomes are able to afford better health
excellent historical account of the regional impacts of minerals
services and better nutrition. Yet, because many miners have
and energy discovery and exploitation on Australian economic
tended to lead excessive lifestyles, associated with some of the
development.
adverse social influence just mentioned, this has undermined
their health. Also, populations in isolated regions (particularly Many major cities owe much of their initial and even current
indigenous populations) tend to be vulnerable to outside diseases prosperity to an association with the minerals and energy sector.
brought in by the miners. Places such as Houston, Dallas, Denver, San Francisco and
Pittsburgh, Toronto, Calgary and Vancouver, Lima, Santiago and
As seen in the last chapter, foreign cultural values may clash
Belo Horizonte, Johannesburg, and Melbourne, Perth and
with the cultural identity of local aboriginal populations. This
Brisbane might all be included in this list. Additionally, many
can dramatically influence traditional ways of life. If it is
regional cities have depended more directly on mining for some
possible, local populations should negotiate to retain their
or all of their history. This group includes places such as
customs. This has been happening more and more since the
Newcastle in England (coal), Sudbury in Canada (nickel),
recognition of native title in Australia after 1991. The emergence
Kimberley in South Africa (diamonds), and Antofagasta and
of fly-in, fly-out work practices in remote locations also appears
Calama in Chile (copper).
to have had a positive effect in this regard.
Although their formal education has been concerned almost The list of significant towns and cities in regional Australia
entirely with developing technical competence, mining that owe much to mineral resources includes:
executives operate in a challenging world where an • Newcastle, Wollongong, Morwell/Moe/Yallourn, Mackay
understanding of the socio-economic impacts of mineral and Collie (all coal);
development in smaller and larger regions is critical. To obtain
• Bathurst, Ballarat, Bendigo and Kalgoorlie (all gold)1;
and then retain a ‘licence to operate,’ they must appreciate the
initial socio-economic status of people living of the region in • Broken Hill, Mount Isa and Port Pirie (base metals);
which they operate, and regional populations need to be • Port Hedland, Karratha2 and Whyalla (iron ore); and
convinced that their presence will improve their quality of life.
Given the social and economic circumstances of potential mining • Sale (oil and gas).
regions, mining company professionals also need to be In many cases, these towns serve as the major centre for a
convinced that they can operate profitably. substate region. Among the 60 or so such regions in Australia,
The subsequent discussion is divided into four parts. The next more than ten are either current or former mining towns.
two sections are concerned with describing mining towns and And then there are the smaller mining (or ex-mining) towns.
regions, and setting them within the broader Australian regional These are located in every state. An indicative list appears in
Table 18.1. While not including all such towns, it identifies
another 60. Intuitively, it seems that the mining industry has
1. Kalgoorlie has, of course, also derived great benefit from nickel made a significant contribution to Australian regional
mining since 1967. development. The entries in this table do not include either ghost
2. Karratha is also an oil and gas centre. towns or company towns that have closed and cease to exist.

TABLE 18.1
Some current and former small mining towns in Australia.

State or Territory Current Former


New South Wales Cobar, Tibooburra, White Cliffs Blayney, Emmaville, Glen Innes, Gulgong, Inverell,
Tenterfield, Lithgow
Victoria Castlemaine, Beechworth, Beaufort, Chiltern, Clunes,
Daylesford, Heathcote
Queensland Blackwater, Moranbah, German Creek, Biloela, Gympie, Mary Kathleen, Mount Morgan, Stanthorpe
Cloncurry, Charters Towers, Weipa
South Australia Andamooka, Coober Pedy, Roxby Downs, Leigh Creek Iron Knob, Kadina, Kapunda, Burra, Moonta
Western Australia Southern Cross, Norseman, Coolgardie, Kambalda, Northampton
Leonora, Laverton, Wiluna, Meekatharra, Mount
Magnet, Cue, Newman, Tom Price, Leinster,
Parraburdoo, Pannawonnica, Capel, Pinjarra,
Greenbushes, Eneabba
Tasmania Queenstown, Beaconsfield, Rosebery Zeehan
Northern Territory Gove, Jabiluka, Pine Creek, Tennant Creek Batchelor

208 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

Taking a cultural heritage perspective, Moore (1998) provided THE AUSTRALIAN REGIONAL FRAMEWORK
a useful survey of current and former mining towns in Western
Australia. His list contained: There has been a largely consistent and widely accepted substate
regional framework in operation in Australia for the past three
• three regional centres (Kalgoorlie Boulder, Port Hedland and decades. The genesis of this system came largely from the work
Karratha); of geographers such as Malcolm Logan, associated with the
• six towns classified as subregional centres; Growth Centres program initiated by the Whitlam Federal
Government in the early 1970s. They generated a taxonomy of
• four company towns; substate regions based on standard classification criteria of
• 27 small towns; homogeneity and nodality. In this system local government
areas do not overlap substate regional boundaries. While one can
• 17 notable former mining towns; and question some of the substate regional definitions on grounds
• 114 other gazetted mining towns. that meaningful regions traverse state borders (eg Albury-
Wodonga, Richmond-Tweed/Gold Coast), the system has
In Western Australia, the Australian state that depends most on
generally worked well.
mining, there were 131 towns (‘Ghost towns’) that no longer
exist, and 40 that are currently still operating. This observation is For the past six censuses since 1976, the Australian Bureau of
a reflection of the finite nature of resources and the historical Statistics has reported a wide range of consistent economic and
reality that, in many cases, mining has not generated sustainable social data for Statistical Divisions (generally equivalent to
economic activity in small regions3. substate regions), Statistical Subdivisions and Local Government
Areas, and some other areas. These data sets cover areas such as
A factor complicating the situation further has been the rise of demography, income, marital status, education, religion, ethnicity,
‘fly-in, fly-out’ work practices. Although the final section of the housing, labour market activity, and motor vehicle use. There were
chapter focuses specifically on this issue, it is important at this 57 Statistical Divisions at the 2001 census.
point to define clearly what it means. Storey (2001a) defines
With the passage of time, the depopulation of the hinterland in
‘fly-in, fly- out’ (FIFO) mining operations as: certain states, and the continuing significant movement of
those which involve work in relatively remote population to coastal areas, adjustments to this framework may
locations where food and lodging now be overdue. The classification provided in Table 18.2 uses
an adjusted version of the ABS framework4. The net result is a
accommodations are provided for workers at the
decrease in regions from 57 to 56.
worksite, but not their families. Schedules are
established whereby employees spend a fixed A summary table, Table 18.3, highlights those substate regions
number of days working at the site, followed by a that are sources of major mineral production. Although the
fixed number of days at home. What classification is somewhat intuitive5, 11 regions have been listed
differentiates this form of organisation from in this table. Two are in New South Wales, two in Queensland
other work involving periodic absences from five in Western Australia and two in the Northern Territory.
There is significant mineral production in several other regions.
home are the regular patterns of work onsite
followed by a period offsite and the nature of the
accommodation arrangements. TABLE 18.2
A taxonomy of Australian substate regions – 2004.
As Storey and others have noted, the FIFO terminology is (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002.)
misleading because some workers do not fly to the mine site or
the oil rig at which they work. They drive in, travel by bus and State Regions Names of regions
some even come by boat or hovercraft. New South Wales 12 Sydney, Hunter, Illawarra,
Richmond-Tweed, Mid-North Coast,
The incidence of FIFO work practices has become more
Northern, North Western, Central-West,
pervasive over the past 20 years, with perhaps 70 mines in South Eastern, Murrumbidgee, Murray,
remote parts of Australia now fully staffed in this way. The Far West
practice now applies more and more throughout the world – in Victoria 11 Melbourne, Barwon, Western District,
Canada, South America, Asia and Africa. It means that cities Central Highlands, Wimmera, Mallee,
such as Perth, but also to a lesser extent Brisbane, Melbourne, Loddon, Goulburn, Ovens-Murray, East
Townsville, Mandurah and Cairns provide the residences of Gippsland, Gippsland
managers, mining professionals and other operational personnel. Queensland 11 Brisbane, Gold Coast, Sunshine Coast,
As much as 50 per cent of the mining workforces in Western Wide Bay-Burnett, Darling Downs,
Australia and the Northern Territory now appear to be FIFO, and Fitzroy, Central and South West,
the percentage is also high in Queensland. Mackay, Northern, Far North, North
West
South Australia 7 Adelaide, Outer Adelaide, Yorke and
Lower North, Murray Lands, South East,
3. For a more detailed discussion of these towns see also Maxwell Eyre, Northern
(2004).
Western Australia 9 Perth, Peel, South West, Great
4. The adjustments are splitting the Moreton Statistical Division in to Southern, Midlands, South Eastern,
Gold Coast (south of Brisbane) and Sunshine Coast (north of Central, Pilbara, Kimberley
Brisbane), dividing the South West Statistical Division in Western
Australia into Peel (based around Mandurah) and a smaller South Tasmania 3 Hobart and Southern, Northern,
West (based on the Bunbury, Busselton, Collie and Margaret River Mersey-Lyell
areas), merging South West and Central West in Queensland; Northern Territory 2 Darwin, balance of Northern Territory
merging Lower Great Southern and Upper Great Southern in
ACT 1 Canberra
Western Australia, and merging Hobart and Southern in Tasmania.
Total regions 56
5. Small area data are not readily available for regional product or
exports that have been used to classify mineral economies at national
level. Note: Regions that differ from statistical divisions appear in bold typeface.

Australian Mineral Economics 209


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

TABLE 18.3 Australian primary school children in the 1950s learned about
Australian mining regions 2004. how the mines at Iron Knob had underpinned the economy of the
Iron Triangle towns of the Northern region of South Australia
Mining regions Main centres Main minerals Per cent (and supplied BHP steelworks at Newcastle and Port Kembla, as
mining well as at Whyalla). But is was the exploitation of deposits in the
employment
Pilbara at places such as Mount Whaleback, Tom Price,
Hunter (NSW) Newcastle Coal 3.08 Parraburdoo and Pannawonnica that stimulated the development
Far West (NSW) Broken Hill Silver, lead, 6.76 of that remote region after the early 1960s.
zinc Oil and gas wells in Bass Strait have played a strong role in the
Mackay (Queensland) Mackay Coal 7.77 regional prosperity of East Gippsland, while oil and gas on the
North West Mount Isa Copper, lead, 15.23 North West Shelf has had an equal, if not greater, role than iron
(Queensland) zinc, phosphate ore in the impressive economic fortunes of the Pilbara.
South West (WA) Bunbury Coal, mineral 4.27 In summary, it is clear that, in addition to the 11 mining
sands regions specified, perhaps eight other regions, particularly in
Peel (WA) Mandurah Bauxite 5.21 Victoria and New South Wales, formerly held that status. In these
later cases, the closure of mines led to the need for regions to
South Eastern (WA) Kalgoorlie Gold, nickel 18.17
redefine themselves in an economic way. In some cases they
Boulder
found difficulty in achieving this, enduring high unemployment
Pilbara (WA) Port Hedland, Iron ore, oil 24.74 rates and lower incomes for extended periods after mines had
Karratha
closed.
Kimberley (WA) Broome, Diamonds, base 2.95 It is instructive to mention one other important set of trends
Kununurra metals
before completing this section. First there has been what appears
Balance of Northern Alice Springs Gold 3.86 as an inexorable movement towards greater metropolitan
Territory dominance in Australia during the past century. One view of this
can be seen in Figure 18.1, which shows an increase in the
percentage population share of each state capital city by at least
20 percentage points between 1909 and 1999. More recently
MINING AND AUSTRALIAN REGIONAL there has also been noticeable movement of population into
DEVELOPMENT – A HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE desirable coastal communities within easy driving distance of the
large cities.
In Chapter 2, it was argued that gold and other minerals had
strongly facilitated Australian economic development from the
1850s onwards. An important dimension of that process related
initially to populating hinterland regions, the associated
development of a strong agricultural sector and the development
of associated infrastructure (roads, railways, power and water
supply, hospitals, schools, etc).
The Gold Rushes of the 1850s facilitated the economic
emergence of towns such as Ballarat, Bendigo and Castlemaine
in Victoria, and Bathurst and Orange in New South Wales, as
centres of prosperous mining and agricultural regions.
With the exhaustion of alluvial gold, the prospectors moved on
to places such as Young, Forbes and Gulgong in New South
Wales. They then progressed north into Queensland with rushes
at Gympie, Mount Morgan, Charters Towers and the Palmer
River. Having reached the tropics, they moved west, arriving at
Pine Creek in Northern Territory by the early 1870s. By the early
1880s, they had reached Halls Creek in Western Australia. The
FIG 18.1 - Percentage metropolitan populations in Australian states
search then moved south, reaching Kalgoorlie by 1893. The
– 1909 and 1999. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics.)
discovery and exploitation of gold brought European settlers to
many of our current regions – Central Highlands, Loddon,
Goulburn and Ovens-Murray (in Victoria), Central West (in New A belated parallel development now beginning to emerge is
South Wales), Northern and Far North (in Queensland) and the movement of population back into the hinterland in New
Central and South Eastern (in Western Australia). The final two South Wales and Victoria, the two most populous states. Traffic
regions encompass the Goldfields, the Yilgarn and the Murchison congestion, high housing prices, the impact of technology and
in WA. the malaise of large metropolitan areas may finally now be
Though hardly as glamorous as their gold mining compatriots, reversing what appeared to be an inexorable trend towards
Cornish copper miners had initiated a successful industry in suburban living in the major metropolises.
South Australia in the 1840s. Prospering for three decades, it In the face of these trends, mineral and energy-based regions
provided an early economic base for the colony around Adelaide. have struggled to retain their populations, even though the
Subsequent major discoveries of base metals at Broken Hill and resources sector has been performing well.
Cobar, and at Mount Isa, stimulated regional development in the
remote Far West region on New South Wales, and in North West SOCIO-ECONOMIC INDICATORS
Queensland, as well as in distant metropolitan centres.
Tasmania’s economic prosperity in the final part of the 19th Having established an historical and geographical perspective,
century came in significant part from metals such as copper and some of the broader social and economic impacts of mining, in a
tin. It stimulated long-term development in the Mersey-Lyell and regional context, are considered. The regional definition
Northern regions. implicitly favoured in the preceding discussion is that of the

210 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

statistical division (with minor variations) in the Australian BOX 18.1 – THE PILBARA – A COMPARATIVE
context. It is also possible to consider larger or smaller regional SOCIO-ECONOMIC SNAPSHOT AT THE 2001
areas. In their studies of Australian ‘regions,’ many authors and
policy advisors have used, and continue to use, the states and
CENSUS
territories as their units of analysis. Equally it is also possible to The following social and economic indicators provide an
consider regions in a more micro fashion, comparing the social assessment of some of the differences between the structure
and economic fortunes of local government areas with one of a typical mining region and the nation. They are derived
another. One’s level of analysis is a matter of deciding where to from the Basic Community Profile tables from the 2001
draw the ‘ring fence,’ using colloquial public policy jargon. National Census. The dimensions presented are as follows:
One way of appreciating these different levels of analysis in
the Australian context, is to note that there are six states and two Broad Indicator Pilbara Australia Pilbara
internal territories6, 56 substate regions and more than 800 legal dimension as % of
local government areas. Australia
Whenever a mining company considers operating in a region, Demographic Average age (years) 31 35 88.6
it is important to: Cultural Aboriginality (% of 12.7 1.9 668.4
population)
• understand the initial economic and social environment it
faces; and then Social Health/Community 5.7 9.7 58.8
services (% of health
• manage the operation of a new or established mine in a and community
manner acceptable to its occupational, residential and workers )
indigenous communities. Social Residential stability 39.6 55.2 71.7
There is a range of socio-economic indicators potentially (% at same address
available in small areas and regions to appreciate the surrounding as last census)
environment. The main source of these data in Australia is from Socio-economic High school 30.1 40.9 73.6
the national census. At the 2001 census, for example, the ABS graduates (% of
generated data on: adult population)
Socio-economic Internet use (% of 75.4 38.9 193.8
population, age, birthplace, citizenship, education, population)
ethnicity, housing, incomes, employment by
industry, Internet access, indigenous status, labour Economic Participation rate (% 68.3 59.6 114.6
of adult population)
force, language, marital status, motor vehicle
ownership, occupation, qualifications, religion and Economic Income (weekly $1300 $750 173.3
travel to work household income)

for people living and working in these small areas and regions. It The population of the Pilbara is younger than the average
is possible to analyse these data separately or together to assess for the nation by four years and there are more than six
differences in economic and social conditions between regions. times as many aboriginal people as nationally. The region
Many of these data are now also available for several censuses. performs well on economic dimensions – areas such as
Thoughtful analysis can therefore provide an appreciation of average incomes and participation rates, there are mixed
recent social and economic trends in these smaller regions. results on socio-economic dimensions – education levels
A simple conceptual analysis considering some cultural, (low) and Internet access (high) – and relatively poorly on
social, socio-economic and directly economic dimensions of a some key social indicators – such as the residential
typical remote resource-rich region (the Pilbara) in comparison stability of the population and the percentage of health and
to the nation appears in Box 18.1. community workers.
The Australian Bureau of Statistics also produces a range of Mining has made a positive contribution to the economic
summary indicators under the banner of Socio-Economic Indices welfare of residents of the Pilbara region, but some of its
for Areas (SEIFA). At the 2001 census it compiled four indexes social impacts are more open to question. Any definitive
in this group (Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003). These were: assessment of this should involve comparisons with the
• the Index of Advantage/Disadvantage – a continuum of fortunes of other non-metropolitan regions. Such an analysis
advantage to disadvantage… available for both urban and may indicate directions for remedial policy.
rural areas… it takes into account variables relating to
income, education, occupation, wealth and living conditions; • the Index of Education and Occupation – based on
• the Index of Disadvantage – derived from attributes such as variables relating to the educational and occupational
income, educational attainment, unemployment and characteristics of communities, such as the proportion of
dwellings without motor vehicles… focuses on low income people with a higher qualification or those employed in a
earners, relatively lower educational attainment and high skilled occupation.
unemployment; Developed using Principal Components Analysis, each of
• the Index of Economic Resources – based on variables such these measures provides a standardised normal distribution with
as income, expenditure and assets of families, such as family a mean of 1000 and a standard deviation of 1007.
income, rent paid, mortgage repayments, and dwelling size; In its promotional brochure, the Australian Bureau of Statistics
and (2003) claims that:
SEIFA 2001 has a number of applications for
government, business and research use. For
6. Such regional analysis typically overlooks activities in Australia’s Local, State and Commonwealth Government
external territories.
agencies, SEIFA 2001 is an invaluable tool for
7. Observations within two standard deviations of the mean (between helping to determine the allocation of funding
800 and 1200) cover more than 95 per cent of the population. and services. Businesses will find SEIFA 2001

Australian Mineral Economics 211


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

extremely helpful for targeting marketing and show low HDI values for remote regions and high values for
promotional campaigns, determining locations affluent areas in the major metropolises. Access to summary
for outlets, and conducting consumer research. measures such as these can provide a useful initial source of data
Researchers will find SEIFA 2001 useful in for a mining company which is trying to assess the financial
constructing models involving socio-economic viability and risks associated with developing or purchasing
status. mines in a developing nation.
Lower than average values in a potential mining region might By way of example, a student in the University of Chile
suggest the desirability of importing workers from other regions Mineral Economics program has recently been working with a
or making strategic investments in key infrastructure or human small company on a project to mine limestone for cement in one
capital development. Higher values might be useful in promoting of the poorer communes (local government areas) of Southern
mining areas as relatively desirable places to live and work. Chile. The commune in question was Lonquimay, based around a
Estimates of these indices for Australia, Western Australia, small town in Chile’s Ninth region (some 1000 km south of
Western Australian regions, and selected mining and non-mining Santiago). He was concerned about the working environment in
local government areas appear in Table 18.4. Despite a the small region, given its estimated HDI value of 0.618 ranked it
traditional image as being less desirable places to live and work, 305th in Chile’s 333 communes. The range of HDI values in
most mining areas show values of two of these indices: Chile’s communes was between 0.565 and 0.924. The national
HDI in 2003 was 0.834. Remember that Australia’s HDI in 2003
• the index of advantage/disadvantage, and
was 0.939.
• the index of economic resources, Located at high altitude in the foothills of the Andes close to the
as generally being above the average. Argentinian border, Lonquimay has been a depressed economic
While estimates of the other two indices: region. The new mine seemed to offer new development and
income potential for indigenous and non-indigenous communities
• the index of disadvantage, and
alike. Yet its cultural, social and economic profile made it difficult
• the index of education and occupation, to attract well-qualified resource sector personnel. Despite the
are below average; they are generally within one standard further questions that a low value for such a measure might
deviation of the mean. Values tend to be lower in small remote provoke, it provides potential investors with interesting summary
mining towns. The values of all of these indices for mining information about the ‘playing field’ in which they will be
compare favourably with parallel measures in other rural regions. operating.
An alternative information source available in some
developing nations is to compare Human Development Index ASSESSING ECONOMIC IMPACTS
(HDI) values for local areas and larger regions. Recall from
Chapter 2 that these summary measures are based equally on Against this background it remains an interesting challenge to
income, life expectancy and levels of education. Offices of the assess the effect of new mine developments on their surrounding
United Nations Development Program in several developing regions. Two broad approaches have emerged. The first is
nations have computed these measures on a regional basis, often economic impact assessment, the second the more broadly
in association with the host country governments. They typically focused social impact assessment. The use of each approach has

TABLE 18.4
ABS estimates of socioeconomic indices at the 2001 census. (Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003.)

Area Index of Index of disadvantage Index of economic resources Index of education and
advantage/disadvantage occupation
Australia 1004.9 1002.1 1009.3 1001.2
Western Australia 1006.8 1003.6 1006.7 998.5
Metro Shires
Perth (City of) 1102.4 1031.5 1055.4 1155.1
Nedlands 1196.8 1130.9 1166.4 1206.5
Key regional centres
Albany 952.6 986.3 934.0 968.2
Mandurah 929.7 949.3 952.4 917.1
Bunbury 957.8 960.1 978.6 947.1
Collie 907.2 925.0 919.5 877.6
Goldfields
Kalgoorlie Boulder 1016.0 986.0 1085.5 951.0
Coolgardie 969.9 934.1 1051.7 888.5
Leonora 1028.9 975.6 1098.3 947.0
Yilgarn 983.5 995.6 995.0 943.1
Pilbara
Port Hedland 1042.5 969.9 1114.6 960.5
Roebourne 1053.3 1002.1 1128.1 960.9
Ashburton 1031.2 983.2 1107.7 935.6
East Pilbara 1010.2 916.0 1067.2 933.4

212 Australian Mineral Economics


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

been influenced recently by the rise of the sustainable The size of these estimated multipliers seems relatively high.
development concept, with its focus on the triple bottom line – This must be due in part to the size of the region and the fact that
the economic, environmental and social/cultural changes there are fewer income leakages from it than from a small region
associated with such development – over an extended period. such as a remote mining town or a fly-in, fly-out mining camp.
New mineral investment, or the closure of a mine or a mill,
will generate a series of direct, indirect and induced effects on its ASSESSING SOCIAL IMPACTS
surrounding regional economy. An active exploration program, The origins of the social impact assessment (SIA) are from the
followed by the building and operation of a mine, concentrator, discipline of sociology. The technique, which has evolved since
smelter or refinery will directly provide income and jobs for the 1970s, emerged as a by-product of the environmental impact
workers living nearby. Local firms will typically also supply assessment process. Practitioners also now apply the technique in
transport and commercial services for the mine or mill – an its own right in a variety of countries to new resource projects.
indirect impact. Also the arrival of a large mine in a region will A simple definition of SIA is:
generate a larger demand by the workers for health, education,
better shopping, entertainment and a variety of other services. The process of assessing or estimating, in
Analysts typically describe these as induced effects. advance, the social consequences that are likely
Regional scientists and economists have been responsible for to follow from specific policy actions or project
developing a range of techniques to estimate the multipliers developments. (Interorganizational Committee
(measuring the total impact on a region of a small increment or for Guidelines and Principles for SIA, 1994).
decrement to investment) associated with new resource In compiling a set of guidelines for its more consistent use, the
investment or the closure of a mine. Analysts have used: ICGP suggested the following stages in its application:
• economic base analysis, • alternatives identification;
• Keynesian income-expenditure models, • baseline data collection;
• regional econometric models, • issues scoping;
• input-output models, and • prediction of impacts (direct, indirect, induced, cumulative);
• computable general equilibrium models. • development of mitigation measures; and finally
to estimate the size of income, output and employment • the design of monitoring and audit procedures.
multipliers associated with these investments.
Joyce and MacFarlane (2001) note its advocacy by the
The nature of these models varies from the rather simplistic European Union, and its requirement in association with
economic (or export) base models, from which one can quickly environmental impact statements by the US Council on
estimate indicative multipliers, through to input-output models Environmental Quality. It is also used in Canada. The World
(sometimes complemented with computable general equilibrium Bank (and some NGOs) utilise its principles.
models) that may be expensive to build but which provide a
broader range of more complete multiplier estimates. In commenting on its application, they state that:
It is beyond the scope of this volume to review these The underlying tension that cuts across all of the
techniques in detail, but authors such as Armstrong and Taylor issues associated with Social Impact Assessment
(2000) and Hoover and Giarratani (1984) provide interesting and is the difference between its potential (currently
readable introductions to them, discuss the ways in which they realised in a small percentage of projects) and its
are estimated and consider their limitations. general current use. The difference can be
While the initial direct impacts on a small region of mineral extreme. At one end, the SIA is a dynamic,
investment may be substantial, the size of the multipliers ongoing process of integrating knowledge on
associated with investment in small areas tends to be low. This potential and real social impacts into
arises particularly because of the weak backward and forward decision-making and management practices; at
linkages of mines or oil wells into local economies. Hence the the other end, it is a static, one-shot technocratic
income multiplier from a new mine near Mount Isa on the North assessment undertaken to gain project approval
West region in Queensland may only be 1.3. Its impact on the or financing, with little or no follow through.
Queensland economy might be larger, say 1.6. Most SIAs fall somewhere along a continuum
between the two.
In an input-output study of the Western Australian economy,
commissioned by the Chamber of Minerals and Energy of While reference to social and economic impacts tends to be
Western Australia, Clements and Ye (1995) generated the associated with environmental impact assessments for proposed
following estimates of output, income and employment new resource sector projects in Australia, the systematic use of
multipliers for various mining and mineral processing activities SIA as an integrative tool to assist management has been limited.
for Western Australia. Its application has been more of the ‘one-shot technocratic’
variety that other more active versions in which monitoring and
revision takes place during the life of a project.
Output Income Employment
Yet, as has been argued earlier, mining has been historically
Mining associated with the significant development of the Australian
Metallic minerals 2.1 3.0 4.1 hinterland throughout its European settlement. The introduction of
Coal, oil and natural gas 1.8 2.2 3.6 active and dynamic formal social impact assessment techniques
would require greater political and community will. If this
Services to mining 3.0 3.1 3.2 happens, as we have seen, the Australian Bureau of Statistics
Mineral processing provides a range of social and other statistics to assess this.
Basic metal products 2.3 3.4 4.7
Chemical, petroleum and 1.9 3.8 4.3 FLY-IN, FLY-OUT AND REGIONAL
coal products DEVELOPMENT
Average for all sectors of 2.2 2.4 2.6 As noted in Chapter 8, the rise of fly-in, fly-out work patterns has
WA made a significant difference to the lifestyles of many Australian

Australian Mineral Economics 213


CHAPTER 18: MINERALS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

mining professionals. Rather than having their families live close In the mean time, there are some policy initiatives that may
to mines in small remote towns such as Mount Magnet, Moranbah, assist regional centres to become more attractive to mining
Tennant Creek, Newman, Leonora or Kambalda, growing numbers company workforces and therefore enhance regional
fly-in and out (or drive in and out) to work on a variety of rosters development. Perhaps most important in this area is ensuring that
from big cities like Perth and Brisbane, or large regional centres such centres have good quality schools, hospitals and other
such as Mackay, Townsville and Cairns. health services and recreational facilities available and also
The evolution of work rosters has been making modern fly-in, ensuring that transport and communications frameworks are
fly-out mining professionals more and more like commuters to a strong and competitive. If these facilities are in place, the
Central Business District from dormitory suburbs. The individual decision to locate a mining company’s workforce in a town or
and their families spend most of their incomes in the areas where district becomes much easier. It also makes the services that local
they live. While on the job in their 9/5 or 5/2/4/3 rosters, businesses provide much more competitive.
professionals spend little and employers typically deposit their
salaries into a local bank account. The towns in the remote REFERENCES
regions where they work see less and less of the income that they
make. The income, output and employment multipliers from Armstrong, H and Taylor, J, 2000. Regional Economics and Policy, third
edition (Harvester Wheatsheaf: New York).
such projects in these regions has recently been in decline.
Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2002. Census of population and housing,
In his paper on Western Australia, Storey (2001b) perceives its 2001 (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Available
impact on regions in the following terms: from: <http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
• companies benefit from resources in the regions but, by Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2003. Socio-economic indexes for areas
basing their workforces in Perth, give little back to those 2001: A comprehensive profile of the Australian people (Australian
Bureau of Statistics: Canberra) [online]. Available from:
regions;
<http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
• businesses in the regions fail to benefit from FIFO as most of Australian Bureau of Statistics, various years. Year Book Australia
the benefits go to service and supply companies in Perth; (Australian Bureau of Statistics: Canberra). [online]. Available from:
<http://www.abs.gov.au>. Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
• FIFO arrangements harm the regions by contributing to
Blainey, G, 2003. The Rush That Never Ended, fifth edition (Melbourne
population decline and associated federal grant decreases,
University Press: Melbourne).
and negative business decisions such as the closure of bank
Clements, K and Ye, Q, 1995. A New Input-Output Table for Western
branches. Australia (Economics Research Centre, University of Western
While state governments can frame policies which partially Australia: Perth).
influence these issues, the costs of doing so is likely to be high. Hoover, E and Giarratani, F, 1984. An Introduction to Regional
Accepting market-driven behaviour from companies operating in Economics, third edition (Alfred A Knopf: New York).
a global industry has often seemed easier to tolerate than framing International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), 2002.
policies that might drive them offshore. Breaking New Ground, local communities and mines, Chapter 9,
Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development – The report of the
In states such as Western Australia, there are many worthy MMSD Project (Earthscan Publications: London) [online]. Available
claims on royalty and tax revenue from mining activities – both from: <http://www.iied.org/mmsd/mmsd_pdfs/finalreport_09.pdf>.
inside and outside mining regions. Even though these revenues Date accessed: 8 May 2006.
generated by mining will typically finance active regional Interorganizational Committee for Guidelines and Principles for SIA
policies in mining regions, political decision-makers typically (ICGP), 1994. Guidelines and principles for social impact assessment
choose to spend the proceeds more broadly. The justification of (US Department Commerce: Washington).
such decisions will depend on value judgments arising from their Joyce, S A and MacFarlane, M, 2001. Social impact assessment in the
particular ideologies. Commitment to a sustainable development mining industry: current situation and future directions, Mining,
strategy may, for example, see the development of services such Minerals and Sustainable Development project Report No 46,
as health, education, transport and communications infrastructure December (International Institute for Environment and Development:
or other emerging industries more appropriate for the long run London) [online]. Available from: <http://www.iied.org/mmsd/
mmsd_pdfs/social_impact_assessment.pdf>. Date accessed: 8 May
than strong support of mining regions. 2006.
While fly-in, fly-out is significant from larger cities in Western Maxwell, P, 2004. Mining and sustainable communities – a Western
Australia, Queensland and the Northern Territory, it is less Australian perspective, Sustaining Regions, 3(2):19-28.
important in states such as New South Wales and Victoria. In Moore, G, 1998. Mining Towns of Western Australia (Chamber of
these areas, mining workforces reside more often in surrounding Minerals and Energy: Perth).
regional towns. The size and congestion in major metropolitan Storey, K, 2001a. FIFO mining in Australia: what do we really know
centres such as Sydney and Melbourne, has apparently pushed about its social and economic impacts? mimeo, November, 22 p.
the balance in favour of regionally based workforces for mines Storey, K, 2001b. Fly-in/fly-out and fly-over: mining and regional
such as Cadia, Cowal and Girilambone. When cities such as development in Western Australia, Australian Geographer,
Perth and Brisbane become larger and more congested, their 32(2):133-148.
attractiveness for workforces and companies may well subside.

214 Australian Mineral Economics


NAME INDEX

Index Terms Links

Adams, M H 114
al Rawashdeh, R 23
Altman, J C 197 198
199 201
Amos, Q G 96 114
Andrews, C B 158
Antikarov, V 142 143
Armstrong, H 213
Atkinson, G 22
Auty, R M 17 22 24 157
192 193

Bailey, S 46
Baker, M P 140
Bedworth, D B 3
Belanger, D 45
Benninga, S Z 131 143
Bernard, J-T 45
Biddle, N 197
Black, F 143
Blackshield, T 162
Blainey, G 8 12 14 77
199 208
Bolduc, D 45
Bonnici, J 1 153
Bourassa, M J 99
Bradley, P G 137 179 180
Brady, B 81
Brealey, R 89
Brennan, M 145
Brennan, T 45
Brown, R 88 90
108 109 142

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Brunetti, C 20
Burger, J 195
Burn, R G 133
Butler, P 123
Butlin, N G 14 197

Calzada, M 175
Campbell, G A 40 42 47
Casassus, J 145
Chavez-Martinez, M L 51
Christie, M A 122
Claeys, J 148
Clements, K 213
Clunies Ross, A 20 155 174
Connell, J 199
Coombs, H C 196
Copeland, T 140 142 143
Corden, W M 20
Corbett, B 45
Corbett, T 204
Cordes, J 193
Cortazar, G 145
Costelloe, D 45
Cousins, D 199
Craven, G 162
Crommelin, M 175
Crowson, P 32 54 57
Cueller, S S 46
Curson, P 197
Cusworth, N 116 117 120
Czelusta, J 15

Davis, G A 14 17 22 23
24
Deer, P W 93 97
Denolder, T 175
Dias, M A G 138
Dillon, M 199 201 202

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Dinham, N 148
Dixit, A K 140
Dodson, M 196
Drucker, P F 47
Dulay, N 42

Easton, S 88 90 108 109


142
Eggert, R G 17 18 190 193
Ericsson, M 53
Eriksson, R 44
Espey, M 47
Etheridge, M 93 136 137

Faiz, S 148
Flores, V 148
Fuerbringer, J 39

Galbraith, J K 1 20 21 154
155 174
Garnaut, R 3 20 21 154
155 174
Gelb, A H 17 22
Giarratani, F 213
Gilbert, C L 20
Gilfillan, J F 114
Gove, P B 195
Grubel, H G 28
Gruen, D 45
Grytten, J 44
Guzman, J I 47
Gylfason, T 22 23

Hall, B 79 82 183
Hamilton, K 22

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Hanneson, R 191 192


Harris, D P 51
Hartwick, J M 176 181
Harvey, B 201
Hayward, N 134
Heilbroner, R 1
Hicks, J R 43
Hilson, G M 75 76 77
Hirsch, P 199
Hirshleifer, J 93
Hocking, A 1 153
Hoover, E 213
Horrigan, B 203
Horton, D R 196
Hotelling, H 50 173
Howard, P 88 90 108 109
142
Howie, P 50
Howitt, R 197 199 200 203
Hughes, H 181 182 184
Humble, L 39
Humphreys, D 45
Hunter, B 197 198 201

Jeffrey, W 7 12
Jevons, W S 1 50
Joyce, S A 213

Kandelaars, P 47
Keenan, P T 140
Krautkraemer, J A 50

Laird, A M 113 115 125


Lane, P H 162 168
Langton, M 199
Laughton, D G 138 145

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Lawrence, M J 99 100
Lawrence, R 204
Lawrence, R D 141
Lederman, D 22 23
Lesley, K J 148
Lord, D 136
Lundgren, N-G 32

Mabo, E 165 203


MacFarlane, M 213
MacKenzie, B 1 2 4 49
50
Maddison, A 14 23
Maloney, W 22 23
Mangan, J 83
Manning, W G 44
Maponga, O 15 18 81 158
Marshall, A 1 43
Mason, A 203
Maxwell, P 1 15 18 24
25
81 153 158 209
Mayfield, E S 140
McCardle, K 148
McCracken, K 197
McDivitt, J 7 12
McLean, I 14
Meadows, D 50
Michaels, M P 148
Mikesell, R F 192 193
Mill, J S 37
Miller, M H 97
Mitchell, G D 41
Modigliani, F 97
Moore, G 209
Morgan, J P 148
Mun, J 141 142 143 144
145 147
Myers, S 89

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Nankani, G 17 22
Nieuwenhuysen, J 199
Northcote, A E A 115 125

O’ Faircheallaigh, C 204
O’ Hare, C W 175
Olewiler, N 41
Otto, J M 156 158 193

Palmer, L 199
Parson, J E 140
Pei, F 45
Peirson, G 88 90 108 109
142
Pezzey, J C V 193
Phelps, C E 44
Pindyck, R S 140
Portney, P R 188
Poulin, R 145

Radetzki, M 157
Randall, A 153
Ranhawa, S U 3
Rappaport, A 91
Ricardo, D 27 173
Riggs, J L 3
Robbins, L 1
Rogers, P H 199
Roscoe, W E 100
Ross, M 22
Rozman, L I 123 125
Rumsey, A 199

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Sachs, J 22 23
Salahor, G 110 137 138 140
Samis, M R 137 140 145
Schanz, J J, Jr 3
Schodde, R 133
Scholes, M 143
Schwartz, E 145
Seymour, C 123
Shain, K 199
Shaw, A G L 12 13
Shillabeer, J H 115
Shuetrim, G 45
Sibbel, A 83
Sinclair, W 12 13
Singh, S 182
Sirower, M L 91
Slade, M E 20 146
Smith, A 1 63
Smith, B 182
Smith, J 148
Solow, R W 173
Stewardson, R 30
Stirzaker, M 124
Storey, K 82 83 209 214

Takashi, N 47
Taylor, H K 102
Taylor, J 213
Tehan, M 199
Tilton, J E 12 45 47 49
50 51 52 54
56 57 155 176
189
Todaro, M 10
Toman, M A 193
Torries, T F 100 103
Torvik, R 23

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Trench, A 89 93

Uttley, P 93 136 137

van Dam, J D 47
Veneroso, F 45
Venkatesh, R 44

Walkup, G 148
Ward, I 1 153
Warden-Fernandez, J 195
Warner, A 22 23
Waud, R N 1 153
Webb, A 193
Webb, M 193
Weber-Fahr, M 24
Weiner, J 199
Weyant, J P 188
Wheelwright, K 163
White, M E 115
Williams, G 162
Wilson, A J 12
Woodward, Justice 202
Wright, G 15

Ye, Q 213
Yeates, G 114
Young, H P 190 191

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


SUBJECT INDEX

Index Terms Links

Aboriginal Australia
historical background 196
interface with mining 199
Aboriginal Heritage Act 1972,
Western Australian 167
Aboriginal Land Rights Commission 1974 202
above normal profits 61
accounting profit 172
accounting treatment of mineral reserves and
resources 104
accrual accounting 104
administrative cost, taxation and 176
amortisation 104
annual equivalent value (AEV) 108
appraised value 100
appropriate period break-up 101
Argyle
Dillon’s study of 201
fly-in, fly-out at 201
assumed certainty 101
Australian Constitution
allocation of powers 161 174
validity and consistency under Section 109 168
Australian gold rushes 13
Australian mining in 20th century 14
Australian mining operations, companies and
joint ventures 77
Australian mining
employment and value added 77
fly-in, fly-out work pattern growth 82
gender imbalance 80
location of employees 79
occupational and educational structure 79
salaries and wages 78

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Australian mining (Cont.)


shortage of professionals 81
Australian mining workforce 77
historical trends 77
authoritarian rule 1

backwardation 71 183
balance of payments 33
bankable feasibility studies 117
barriers to entry
falling and decline of monopoly power 62
low 59
raised 60
benefits, marginal and total 38
binomial distribution 130
binomial lattice method 142
Black and Scholes (B-S) formula 142
Breaking New Ground 207
bridging finance 95
buying and selling pressure 39
by-product mineral supply
determinants 54
examples in Australia 54

capital study of 7
capital asset pricing model (CAPM) 94
capital assets 104
capital budgeting 87
capital costs, components of 119
capital efficiency index 103
capital expenditure, tax deductibility of 182
cartels 63
history of mineral 63
preconditions for successful 64
rise and fall of international producer groups 64
cash bidding, as mineral taxation 180
cash clearing 69
cash costs 57 58 59

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

cash flows of a mining project 121 129 138


certainty equivalent (CX)
checklist, feasibility study 126
Chile, development experience 24
civil wars 22
closed-form equation 142
commodity (gold)/derivative loans and advance
sales 95
common law 161
community indifference curve 153
company income tax 182
comparable sales valuation 100
comparative advantage 27
comparison of mutually exclusive projects with
different lives 107
competitive markets 59
competitive policy regimes, ingredients of 159
computable general equilibrium models 213
concentration in mineral markets 60
conditional (Bayesian) probabilities 134
consumption 8
contango 71 183
contingency allowed in feasibility study 120
continuous time discount factor 144
contributory shares 90
copper cartel (CIPEC) 64 65
co-product mineral supply, determinants 55
corporate bonds 95
corporate finance services 88 94
corporate objectives 100
corporations power, under Australian
Constitution 162
corruption
HDI index and 21
perceived 21
cost function 102 97
cost of debt (RD) 94
cost of equity (RE)
weighted average cost of capital (RC) 104
customer finance 95

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

cut-off grades 122

DCF model
in nominal money terms 106
in real money terms 107
dealer markets 68
debentures 95
debt 89 104
debt service ratio 96
decision nodes 134
decision trees 134
demand curve
consumer tastes and 39
created 37
derived 37
expectations and 39
final product 37
historical 37
income and 39
individual 38
law of 39
market 38
shifts in demand 39
depreciation 104
derived demand 37
for minerals 39
Hicks-Marshall laws of 43
developed nations, classification 16
developing nations, classification 16
development 10
diamond cartel, De Beers and 65
discounted pay back period 103
discounted cash flow (DCF) 100
discounting and sustainable development 188
disruptive events, as determinant of mineral
supply 52
distribution 7
social justice and 189
diversified portfolio effect 87

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

down factor 143


Dutch disease 20 189

economic base analysis 212


economic development 10
economic efficiency 155
taxation and 175
economic equity 155
economic growth 9
economic policy
aims of 153
practice of 153
economic rent 172
pursuit of 174
scarcity and 173
taxes designed to capture 176
economic sustainability, and mineral policy 189
economically rational investor 93
economics 1
education, Aboriginal Australian 198
elasticity of mineral demand
cross price 46
income 45
long run 46
own price 42
elasticity of supply 54
employment in mining, Aboriginal 199 202
engineering economics 3
environment 7
environmental laws, external affairs power and 164
Equator Principles 193
equilibrium
market 39
mineral market 41
equity 89 104
equity, taxation and 176
exchange rate policy 154
exchange rates
and mineral prices 34

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

exchange rates (Cont.)


and producer pricing 67
as determinant of mineral supply 52
fixed or floating 33
mineral trade and 33
trade weighted index 33
expanded net present value (ENPV) 142
expansion option 144
expected monetary value (EMV) 129 134
exploration licences, Western Australian 166
exploration spending
positive externalities and 183
tax deductibility of 182
export levies, as minerals taxation 180
export power, under Australian Constitution 163
external affairs power, under Australian 164
Constitution
externalities
negative 175 191
positive 183
external market forces 19
Extractive Industries Review, World Bank 192 194

factor 143
fairness to current and future generations 188
farm-in/farm-out stages 93
farm outs/joint ventures 90
feasibility studies
objectives of 114 117
reports 125
types of 115
few producers
effect on prices 60
market demand and 61
final product 37
finance lease 95 108
financial leverage 88 97 105
financial planning 88
financial risk 88 97 101

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

financial structure 88 97
financing decision 101
(also see funding decision) 88
fiscal policy 154
fixed costs 57
flow-through shares 92
fly-in, fly-out
regional impacts of 213
work patterns 82
formal mining sector 75
forward contract price 132
Fraser Institute survey of mining executives 156
frequency distribution 136
fundamental financial accounting equation 88
fundamental or technical valuation 100
fundamental value 91
funding decision 88
(also see financing decision) 101

geological endowment
nature of 2 49
geometric Brownian motion (GBM) 139
Global Compact 193 194
Global Mining Initiative 192
government activities, as determinant of mineral
supply 52
government equity participation 180
government, functions of 153
government philosophies 190
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 9
estimates 18
growth of 28 72
limitations of measure 10
mineral contribution to 18
per capita at PPP 9
recent growth and metal usage 72
group accounting 88

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

health, Aboriginal Australian 196


Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model 28
hedging, taxation and 183
home ownership, Aboriginal Australian 198
horizontal equity 176
human activity versus carrying capacity 188
Human Development Index (HDI) 10 188
hybrids 89

idiosyncratic, unsystematic or unique risk 93


immediate run 49
income, Aboriginal Australian 198 201 202
income based valuation, cost based valuation 99
income distribution 154
independent reports, required in feasibility
studies 118
indigenous people
definition 195
interests of 195
locations of 195
population 195
Industrial Relations power
under Australian Constitution 163
under Western Australian law 163
initial public offerings (IPOs) 90
input costs, as determinant of mineral supply 52
input-output analysis 213
institutions and mineral development 189
intergenerational equity 176
internal economic stresses 20
internal rate of return (IRR) 103
International Bauxite Association 64 65
International Council on Mining and Metals (ICMM) 192
international trade
distribution of 29
factors affecting 28
growth of 28

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

investment 8
investment decision 87 101
investor relations 88
issues of scale, with sustainability 188
iterative nature of feasibility studies 115

Joint Ore Reserves Committee (JORC) 51


joint venture proper stage 93
joint venture terms valuation 100
JORC code 99 118
reporting reserves under 117

Kaldor-Hicks criterion 155


Keynesian income-expenditure models 213

labour 7
land 7
large mining companies and small economies 158
law, meaning of 162
‘learning by doing’ 20
legal and regulatory framework, managing 153 154
life expectancy, Aboriginal Australian 198
liquidity 88
list prices 68
loan life ratio 96
local communities, benefits of mining to 190
log-normal distribution 111
London Metal Exchange (LME) 68
basic contract 69
contracts 68
hedging in 69
history 68
options in 69
registered warehouses 70
warehouse inventories 73
long run 49

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

Mabo judgement of Australian High Court 165 195 203


as determinant of mineral supply 53
macroeconomics 2
management flexibility 140
marginal benefit curve 38
marginal physical product (MPP) 40
marginal revenue product (MRP) 40
marketable debt papers 95
marketable long-term debt papers 95
market-based valuation 99
market demand curve
final product 38
mineral 40
market equilibrium
in competitive markets 59
in oligopolistic markets 61
market portfolio 93 93
market premium (RM - RF)
market/price risk 101
market structure, as determinant of mineral
supply 53
market surveys 121
market system 1
maximisation rule 145
mean 130
microeconomics 2
Mine Safety and Inspection Act, Western Australian 166
Mineral Council of Australia, Enduring Value
project 192
mineral demand
elasticity of 42
prices of substitutes and complements and 42
shifts in 41
technology and 41
mineral dependent nations 17
mineral development, public approval processes 191
mineral economics
defined 1
key questions 4

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

mineral demand (Cont.)


practice of 4
mineral endowment, institutions and government 24
policy
mineral markets, recent trends 72
mineral policy
attractiveness of 157
context of 154
dimensions of 189
economic sustainability and 189
in practice 155 156
transition since 1950 156
mineral production
Australian 30
environmental quality and 188
physical sustainability of 188
world 28 29
mineral products, homogeneity of 60
mineral rents 191
mineral reserves 51
Australian 30
mineral resource, determining a project’s 114
mineral resources 51
mineral revenue policies, future 183
mineral royalties and taxes 104
mineral sector, size 2
mineral supply
by-products 51
co-products 51
curve 50
during different time periods 54
individual and main products, determinants 51 52
process 50
total 57
mineral taxation
current regimes in Australia 176
design principles 175
evaluation of Australian system 181
less orthodox methods 177
power to raise 175

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

mineral trade
Australian exports 31
international 29
mineral endowment and 32
minerals and economic development
factors affecting 18
traditional view 12 15 18
minerals and history 12
minerals, standard classification of 3
mines, characteristics of 3 154 155
Mining Act 1978, Western Australia 166
mining
and Australian regional development 210
and economic sustainability, factors affecting 189
and sustainability in practice 192
and sustainable development, traditional view 189
mining, distributing proceeds 191
mining economics 3
mining, environmental sustainability and 188
mining leases, Western Australian 166
Mining, Minerals and Sustainable
Development Project (MMSD) 192 193
mining operations, factor intensity in 75
mining towns, Australian 208 209
mining workforce
artisanal and small scale 76
estimated size in 2001 76
in developed nations 75
in developing nations 75
in transition economies 75
modern asset pricing (MAD) 137
monetary policy 154
monopolies
effect of growing demand on 62
effects of quotas and tariffs on 62
local 62
objectives of 61
pricing and 62
Monte Carlo simulation 111
multiple of exploration expenditure valuation 100

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

multiple or chooser option 141 145


multipliers, mining investment 214

native title 195


Native Title Act 1993 165 203
Native Title Amendment Act 203
native title claims, mining tenements and 165
native title legislation 165
natural capital 8
negotiated agreements, trend towards 204
negotiated prices in mineral markets 62
net present value (NPV) 103 122
net smelting return (NSR) 103
new scrap supply
defined 55
determinants of 56
New York Mercantile Exchange (Nymex) 68 71
no-arbitrage (one-price) principle 137
nominal money terms 101
non-renewable resources 8
normal profit 172

off-market placements 90
oil, recent demand growth and prices 73
old scrap supply
defined 55
determinants of 56
oligopolies
defined 61
oligopolistic markets 60
oligopsonies, defined 61
one-price principle 137
operating costs, estimation of 120
operating lease 108
option scenario tree 141
options 90
ordinary shares 90
Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

(OPEC) 63
overdrafts 95
own price, as determinant of mineral supply 52

Pareto optimality 155


pay back period 103 122
phases of a mining project 114
pipeline licence fees, as mineral taxation 180
political geography, changing 17
pooled development funds (PDFs) 92
population, Aboriginal Australian 196
portfolio decision 101
prefeasibility studies 116
preference shares 90 95
present value (PV) 103
price of risk 110
price takers 59
price wars 62
prices, recent rises in mineral 73
pricing
long-term contracts 63
short-term contracts 63
private ownership of mines, swing back 158
probabilistic models 101 111
probability of survival 130
probability or event nodes 134
proceeds of mining, principles of investment 191
producer pricing in mineral markets 62 66
average costs and 66
competition policy and 67
excess capacity and 67
exchange rates and 67
history in major non-ferrous metals 67
nationalisation and 67
stability of 66
trade liberalisation and 67
production 7
production function 7 39 75
production possibility curve 153

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

profit and loss statement 105


profit maximisation 61
project base case 101
project cost estimates, definitive 118
project finance 94 95
project life ratio 96
project optimisation 122
project risk 101
public ownership, rationale 157
public policy
facilitating market activities 190
net social benefits of 191
principles and concepts 190
promoting efficiency 190 191
Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) 9 11

quasi-rents 174

race power, under Australian Constitution 164


rail freight rates, as mineral taxation 180
real money terms 101
real option 129
real option valuation 100
real option value (ROV) 91 138 140 142
recycling 2
extent of mineral 55
regional impacts of mining, dimensions 207 208
regions, Australian 209 210
relevant range 111
remoteness, and mining operations 199
renewable resources 8
rent
differential 173
economic 20 172
generalised 173
location 174
mineral 20
monopoly 174

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

replicating portfolio 137


replicating portfolio method 143
resource allocation as policy activity 154
resource curse hypothesis 22
resource rent tax 175 177 181
hybrid 180 93
return on the market portfolio (RM)
revenue function 102
risk 130
risk-and-time-adjusted discount rate 109
risk assessment and management 88
risk-averse criterion 130 134
‘risk-free’ probabilitymethod 143 93
risk-free rate of return (RF)
risk management 129 131
risk, managing 125
risk-neutral criterion 130
risk neutralisation 138
risk of gambler’s ruin 130
risk premium 93
risk spreading through joint ventures 133
risk tolerance 129
risk tolerance coefficient (RT) 132
risk underpinning 96
risks
associated with feasibility studies 123
financial and marketing 124
mining and processing 123
project design and construction 124
resource base 123
Roebourne, Howitt’s study of 199
royalties
ad valorem 177 181
origin of term 172
profit-based 177 181
specific 177 181
royalty-based finances 90

saving 8

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

scenario analysis 111


scoping studies 115
secondary materials, recycling 55
seed and venture capital 89
selling price of a risky investment 132
sensitivities
associated with feasibility studies 123
project 124
sensitivity analysis 111
sequential/compound option 141 145
short run 49
single option 141
small regions, taxonomy of 207
social impact assessment (SIA) 213
social justice, mining and 189
social justice philosophies, Aristotle, Bentham
and Rawls 191
socioeconomic indicators 210 212
Human Development Index 212
SEIFA 211
solvency 88
sources and application of funds (cash flow)
statement 88 105
sovereign risk 97 176
special agreement acts, Western Australian 166
specialised listed investment companies (LICs) 92
spider diagram 111
stability in revenue flow, taxation and 176
stakeholders in resource sector investments 196
standard deviation classical or objective
probability 130
state and federal laws, inconsistency between 162
state legislation and mining, the Western
Australian situation 166
state mining enterprises 67
state ownership of mining
Auty model 157
efficiency of 157
Radetzki model 157
state prices method 143

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

statute law 161


stochastic (probabilistic) models 139
stock market indices 92
subjective probabilities 136
substitute goods 38
supply curve
market 38
by-product 55
sustainability
economic 187
environmental 187
social and cultural 188
sustainable development, dimensions of 188
swaps 94
systematic or market risk 93

tariff policy 154


tastes, consumer 39
tax base 176
tax rate 176
tax services 88
taxation, different treatment of mineral sector 171
Taylor’s formula 102
technological change, as determinant of mineral
supply 52
ten point plan 203
terminal markets 60 68
functions of 68
terms of trade 19
tornado diagram 111
trade 8
international and interregional 27 28
neoclassical theory 28
reasons for 27
trade-offs, price, quantity and quality 62
tradition 1
transfer prices 66
transparency, taxation and 176
transport cost market value curve 32

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

transport costs, mineral trade and 31


treasury operations 88
types of real options 140

unemployment, Aboriginal 198 201 202


unsecured convertible notes 95
unsecured notes 95
uranium mining, export power and 164
urbanisation, Aboriginal Australian 198
utilitarian philosophy 37
utility function 132

VALMIN code 99 118


value adding 30
value additivity principle 137
value at risk (VAR) 131
value consistency principle 137
value to weight ratio 31
valuing tonnage-grade trade-offs 145
variable costs 57
vertical integration 29
very long run 49
mineral supply in 50
volatility 140
estimates using the logarithm present value
approach 143
estimates using the management assumption
approach 143
estimates using the market proxy approach 143
mineral price 19

wages policy 154


wealth distribution 154 97
weighted average cost of capital (RC)
Wik judgement of Australian High Court 165 203
World Phosphate Institute 64 65

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.


Index Terms Links

yardsticks valuation 100

zinc cartel, demise of 65

This page has been reformatted by Knovel to provide easier navigation.

You might also like