You are on page 1of 10

43.

TRADE AND POWER IN LATE BRONZE AGE CANAAN


by Michael Sugerman

T HE Late Bronze Age (1500—1150 B.C.E.) in


Israel and Palestine has been a focus of research
for over a century. A wealth of data from numerous
Finkelstein and Na»aman differ slightly in their inter-
pretations of certain aspects of the Amarna letters
(e.g., Finkelstein 1996:222; Na»aman 1997:603), and
archaeological and philological investigations creates more significantly, in their predispositions toward
the illusion that the cultures of the period are well seeing “city-states” as centered on cities of different
known and understood. In reality, our interpretations sizes. Thus, Finkelstein (1996:223) posits fewer city-
of the period are based on (1) ceramic chronologies states with larger urban centers and Na»aman (1997:
based largely on imported fine wares from the Ae- 605) suggests more city-states with smaller centers.
gean and Cyprus, (2) stratigraphic descriptions of a Each of them, however, uses a similar set of assump-
number of sites with LB phases, and (3) political and tions to interpret the textual sources from Amarna,
economic reconstructions extrapolated from texts which are so often called upon to buttress arguments
found primarily in Egypt and Syria. Very few re- about LB society in Canaan. Both Finkelstein and
searchers have undertaken a detailed study of mate- Na»aman state that the writers of all of the Amarna
rial culture from multiple sites to investigate socio- letters sent from Canaan must have been rulers of
cultural processes in the region. Instead, scholars of city-states (Na»aman 1997:601). Finkelstein also pre-
LB Canaan have relied on historical, rather than ar- sents a corollary to this argument: that the Amarna
chaeological, methodologies to develop a framework archive is representative enough to enable “a full, or
for understanding the cultures of this period. almost full reconstruction of the territorial map of
Late Bronze Canaan” (Finkelstein 1996:224).
Modeling Political Society in LB Canaan In order to build such a territorial map, Finkelstein
divides the region into Thiessen polygons (figure 1).
Many analyses begin with the supposition that the Each polygon is centered on a large, theoretically
region was part of an Egyptian province in Asia (see urban, site and contains the hinterland that he consid-
references in Na»aman 1999:31), although there is ers necessary to support the center (Finkelstein
some debate over the extent and coherence of this 1996:228, 230, 241). Though he recognizes that there
province (Lemche 1991; 1996; 1998). In a recent were areas that could not be effectively controlled by
synthesis, one scholar describes the entire 350-year the city-state rulers, and that nonsedentary segments
span almost exclusively in terms of hypothesized of society were also important in this period, Finkel-
Egyptian political and military activity in the region stein (1996:226) argues that control of the whole re-
(Gonen 1992). She concluded her analysis with a gion comprising modern Israel and Palestine was
survey of artifactual and architectural typologies, divided among thirteen or fourteen neighboring poli-
with little discussion of the cultures, economies, or ties with abutting boundaries.
political structures of the region. In numerous other Na»aman opposes Finkelstein’s interpretation and
studies of the period, changes in settlement patterns, argues that hinterland territory is not a necessary fea-
population density, and material culture have also ture of an independent city-state. Using Egyptian
been explained as results of historical events de- texts to support his arguments, Na»aman contends
scribed in Egyptian or biblical texts (e.g., Aharoni that during the Thirteenth Dynasty (eighteenth cen-
1967; Helck 1971; Na»aman 1975; 1981). tury B.C.E.), there were as many as four kingdoms
Paralleling the debate over Egyptian activities in within the limited geographical confines of the Akko
LB Canaan, there has been some disagreement over Valley, none of which could have controlled the hin-
how to determine the political boundaries of the terland that Finkelstein claimed was necessary to
“city-states” or “kingdoms” that filled the territory of support an urban center (Na»aman 1997:605). Eco-
Canaan in the latter half of the second millennium nomic resources, including staples, could be obtained
B.C.E. In recent years, the debate over the structure of by the inhabitants of settlements in key zones, who
politics and economy in LB Canaan has been argued therefore did not have to rely on local agricultural
mainly by two scholars, Israel Finkelstein (1993; production. Port cities and settlements situated on
1996) and Nadav Na»aman (1986; 1992; 1997; 1999), major trade routes—most notably those on the junc-
and has been based on the classic works of Albrecht tions of trade routes—fit this description. Another
Alt (1939; 1953; 1954) and Wolfgang Helck (1971). important implication of Na»aman’s argument is that,
440 Michael Sugerman

given the smaller sizes of his proposed political units, many settlements were abandoned in favor of pas-
many small cities and towns would have existed out- toral lifeways. Given the lack of surplus labor—as
side the control of any city-state. If that was the case, discerned by the absence of major building projects
not all politically independent polities were states or during this period—it is difficult to hypothesize that
even cities. the urban elites were able to muster militias of the
size necessary to enforce their proposed jurisdictions.
Textual descriptions of the military forces gathered in
Canaanite cities on military maneuvers list dozens or
hundreds, rather than thousands, of fighters (ANET3
p. 237). It appears that large standing military forces
were not an integral part of LB urban politics.
Beyond the issue of local “jurisdiction” there is, as
noted above, some debate over the question of re-
gional dominance as well. Thus Finkelstein (1996:
225–26) argues that the populations in Canaan were
all under the jurisdiction of the ruling Canaanite el-
ites, while Na»aman (1997:619) argues that “Egypt
governed Canaan and the real power was in the hands
of the Egyptians.” Neither of these arguments defines
the nature of the governance nor the means by which
the proposed rulers were supported.

City-States Problems

Underlying these omissions is a methodological


problem. These scholars use, as have many others in
the past, the model of the “city-state” to characterize
the urban-centered polities that they propose com-
prised the LB political landscape of Canaan. The
city-state model links the phenomenon of the state
with a particular kind of settlement pattern that to-
gether form “small, territorially based, politically
independent state systems, characterized by a capital
city or town, with an economically and socially inte-
grated adjacent hinterland” (Rihll and Wilson 1991:
60; Charlton and Nichols 1997:1). Other definitions
of city-states include the concept that the polity is
economically self-sufficient and perceived as being
ethnically distinct from other, similar systems (Trig-
ger 1993:8–14; 2003:92–103). It has been argued
Figure 1. Thiessen polygons defining proposed Late that, historically, city-states frequently occurred in
Bronze Age city-states in Canaan groups of somewhat evenly spaced units that were all
of similar sizes (Renfrew 1975:12–20).
Na»aman’s critique highlights an important flaw in The city-state construct has been the target of criti-
Finkelstein’s model: the issue of control. Although cism in recent years. In many of the cases where the
Finkelstein acknowledged that there would have been term has been applied, one or more core features of
“marginal” areas outside the control of the city-states the model’s definition have been changed to fit the
in a practical sense, he considered all of the territory case. In some cases, researchers have reinterpreted
to be under the “jurisdiction” of the nearest ruling the data to fit the model (D’Altroy 2000:851; Yoffee
Canaanite city (1996:225–26). No mention is made 2004:42–62). In the case of Canaan, the model has
of the structure of this control or how this “jurisdic- been used so often to describe so many different con-
tion” was maintained. Stager (1985) and Bunimovitz ditions that it has very little utility for characterizing
(1994a) have argued that the LB in southern Canaan any particular political or economic situation. By
was characterized by a shortage of manpower after using a poorly defined model and applying it uncriti-
Trade and Power in Late Bronze Age Canaan 441

cally across a widely variable social, political, and designs of Egypt during the following centuries led to
geographical map, Finkelstein, Na»aman, and others a response in which the diminished urban elite in-
who use the city-state model obscure the heterogene- dulged in orgies of conspicuous consumption in an
ous nature of political society in LB Canaan. attempt to maintain power within an impoverished
In two recent surveys of archaeological incarna- and unstable region (Bunimovitz 1995:326). At the
tions of city-states in many cultures, perhaps the most same time, the rural inhabitants of the country, previ-
useful result was the argument that researchers need ously the productive foundation of the region’s
to explore the variability within the model and ex- wealth, responded to the rising demands of the elites
plain significant divergences from the model when and the instability of the political structure by “voting
they are encountered in the archaeological or histori- with their feet.” Agrarian populations shifted to non-
cal data (Nichols and Charlton 1997; Yoffee 1997: sedentary lifestyles in which their produce could not
256; Hansen 2000). Although there may be evidence easily be taxed by the urban authorities (Bunimovitz
in LB Canaan for city-states of the type defined 1995:327–28; also Braudel 1972:85–101; Marfoe
above, the range of variation in settlement size and 1979). In this model, the wealth listed in Egyptian
type in the region was great. No understanding of the tribute texts is explained by the activities of the urban
society of the LB is complete without an exploration elite, while the pattern of depletion, destruction, and
of the way urban and nonurban settlements, as well poverty indicated by the region’s archaeological re-
as nonsedentary segments of the population, were cord is attributed, in part, to a large-scale shift from
integrated into the political and economic systems sedentary agriculture to nomadic lifeways.
extant during this period. Both of these syntheses deal differently with the
evidence for concentrations of wealth as described in
Modeling the LB Local Economy Egyptian records and apparent in some aspects of LB
Canaanite material culture. While arguing that an
The apparently conflicting archaeological and textual Egyptian occupation brought about “the decline of
data used to investigate LB Canaan have led to two the Canaanite city,” Gonen also argued that, in the
schools of thought, in which scholars choose to em- LB, Canaan was producing large quantities of high-
phasize their interpretations of the texts, on the one prestige products, including monumental stone sculp-
hand, or the archaeological data, on the other—but ture, richly dyed textiles, ornamental jewelry, carved
not both. The archaeologically based interpretation ivory figurines, and inlaid furniture and boxes. In
proposes that the combination of Egyptian military support of this apparent dichotomy between “de-
occupation and internal conflicts caused a long proc- cline” and wealth, Gonen (1992:247) asserted only
ess of economic decline in Canaan, until it reached a that Canaan was an active participant in the broader
low point during the thirteenth century B.C.E. (Knapp eastern Mediterranean economy, without explaining
1989a; 1989b; 1992). The alternative, textually sup- how such an economically depleted region played an
ported interpretation, is that the rulers of the Eight- active economic role. Bunimovitz’s (1995:326) ex-
eenth Dynasty received rich tribute from the kings of planation is more instructive, implying that the activi-
Canaanite city-states, which led to intensification of ties of the urban elite in concentrating wealth, both
Egyptian military and economic activities there, for themselves and as tribute gifts to Egypt, were
which in turn caused the local Canaanite economies short term in nature and could not have been sup-
to expand so that by the thirteenth century the region ported for an extended period. Indeed, their activities
was flourishing (Bienkowski 1989; Na»aman 1981: were curtailed in the thirteenth century, at the end of
185). the LB.
Other recent syntheses have attempted to harmo- Unfortunately, neither synthesis presents a satisfy-
nize these conflicting points of view with only slight ing approach to the political economy of the LB be-
success. Gonen (1984; 1992) downgraded some of cause they both ignore the patterns of production and
the textual evidence from Amarna in favor of ar- distribution of goods within the region during that
chaeological data that indicate the presence of de- period.
pleted urban settlements. Bunimovitz (1993; 1994b;
1995) used settlement-pattern studies and models of Lateral Directions in Bronze Age Trade
peer-polity interaction together with the textual evi-
dence from Amarna to identify multiple responses to Recent analyses of the archaeological data available
Egypt’s impact on Canaan during the LB. He argued for the Early and Middle Bronze Age have identified
that the collapse of the socioeconomic system at the settlement patterns in which sites are oriented along
end of the Middle Bronze Age and the imperialistic drainages running east-west from the inland high-
442 Michael Sugerman

lands to the Mediterranean coast (Harrison 1993; Ilan military forces; and (3) it situates the individual den-
1995; Marcus 1991; 1995; Raban 1985). Although dritic systems within a larger context in which they
this pattern has been related to the significance of are competing for the attention of an “overseas” mar-
maritime trade in the economy of Bronze Age Ca- ket (Bronson 1977:44–45). In the case of southeast
naan (Stager 1992; 2000), it is notable that this orien- Asia, those markets were in China and Java. In the
tation was already in existence in the Chalcolithic case of LB Canaan, those markets were found in
period (4500–3500 B.C.E.), when maritime trade was Egypt, the northern Levantine coast, and Cyprus.
less important (Levy 1995:229). Ilan (1995:302) has Bronson’s model focuses on a subset of dendritic
argued that the drainage systems, with estuarine models, an exchange network along a drainage that
ports, large inland urban sites, and small rural pro- opens to the sea with the following elements (see
ductive sites, comprised a unified polity. Although figure 2):
such a model might explain the distribution of goods
among the coastal and inland sites, it does not go so A the “center” at the mouth of the drainage
far as to explain how the economy worked, and why
it worked. It also fails to address the same key issue B and C second- and third-order centers located
inadequately addressed in the political models pre- upstream from A and at the junctures of
sented by Finkelstein and Na»aman, namely, control. other drainages
Ilan’s model assumes a great deal of coercive con-
trol over the areas of rural production and less habit- D the most distant upstream center in the
able areas of resource collection in the hill country. system; a concentration point for goods
In the Middle Bronze Age, the period about which
Ilan wrote, the population sizes may have been large E and F the ultimate producers or collectors of the
enough to allow for the kind of coercive control that products that are concentrated at D; they
is indicated by his arguments (Ilan 1995:309). How- may be centers in a different kind of non-
ever, in the subsequent Late Bronze Age, with its market exchange system involving goods
pronounced reduction in sedentary population and of which only part are involved in the A-
thus in workforce, it is unlikely that the rulers of the based system
urban centers were able to coerce the hinterland
populations into providing goods for their markets by X an overseas center that serves as the main
force. Rather, the centers had to have something to consumer of A’s exports and the main sup-
offer that would have brought the nonurban segments plier of its imports
of the population into the system by choice.
In the 1970s, economists developed a model that A1 other coastal centers some distance away,
describes these “dendritic market systems” as a varia- A2 dominating systems similar to A’s
tion on classical central place models. The dendritic
model was initially used to investigate long-distance Aside from these elements, this model also oper-
wholesale trade in America during the sixteenth ates under three other constraints: (1) X, the overseas
through twentieth centuries (Vance 1970). The model center, is economically stronger than A, has a larger
was almost immediately applied to market systems in population, and a more productive economy; (2) the
developing economies (Johnson 1970) and then to countryside between the drainages is such that
historically known cases, such as the political and movements of goods outside of the drainages is not
economic structures of early coastal states in south- feasible; and (3) the drainage basin cannot support its
east Asia (Bronson 1977; Hall 1985). More recently, population based solely on agriculture, thus making
Stager (2000) adapted Bronson’s work to develop an the profits derived from trade of central importance
understanding of Early and Middle Bronze Age Ca- (Bronson 1977:43–44).
naan that he calls the “port power” model. In the case of LB Canaan, the first constraint is
applicable. New Kingdom Egypt to the south—and
Coastal Approaches to Trade Networks even Ugarit to the north—was wealthier and more
populous than any coastal city in Canaan. The second
A dendritic model is useful for the purposes of this constraint is not as good a fit in that the land between
study for several reasons: (1) it is designed to explain the drainage systems does not preclude the passage of
the relations between sites in a networked trade sys- goods. Rather, the geography simply makes the use
tem; (2) in most cases, it describes intersite relations of the drainages the easiest choice in many areas,
that are noncoercive and do not necessitate extensive though it allows producers and traders to cross-cut
Trade and Power in Late Bronze Age Canaan 443

Figure 2. Idealized depiction of a dendritic trade system anchored in a port center (after Bronson 1977)

the drainage-based economic systems. This flexibility Hierarchies of sites have been identified in this
puts certain pressures on the centers (especially B, C, region by other scholars, though they have not been
and D) to make themselves as attractive as possible to set into this type of economic system. Gittlen (1993:
the upstream groups to avoid losing their patronage. 367–68) defined a three-tiered LB hierarchy of site
The third constraint can only be applied to Canaan types consisting of walled cities, baronial estates, and
in a limited manner. While the spring-fed lowlands of unfortified settlements. Ilan’s MB hierarchy con-
southern Canaan can be successfully dry-farmed, the tained regional centers and gateways, subregional
risk of drought and starvation has more than once led centers and/or loci of specialist production or service
sedentary populations to abandon agriculture and (e.g., cult), villages, and farmsteads (Ilan 1995:305).
take up a pastoral lifestyle dependent on a more het- Knapp, in characterizing a similar economic system
erogeneous set of resources (Finkelstein 1988; Ilan for Middle and Late Bronze Age Cyprus, defined a
1995:314; Marfoe 1979:9). Thus, while it was possi- hierarchy in which he assigned a variety of functions
ble for the urban elite in the coastal plain to support to each type of site: primary coastal centers (com-
themselves by extracting produce from a farming mercial, ceremonial, administration, production);
population, such a state of affairs was unlikely to last secondary inland towns (administration, production,
for an extended period. Slight variations in the cli- transport); tertiary inland sites (ceremonial, produc-
mate, population growth, disease, or changes in other tion, transport, storage); and mining sites, pottery-
aspects of the socioeconomy of the region continually producing villages, and agricultural support villages
undermined the possibility of developing a true peas- (production, storage, transport) (Knapp 1997:56–61).
ant culture in Canaan. As a result, as Bronson’s The variety of functions that Knapp attributes to
model would predict, the revenues derived from trade each type of site provides a more detailed image of
became extremely important to the urban centers that the human activities taking place throughout the net-
controlled the flows of goods both into and out of works of production and exchange, but the relation-
Canaan. ships among the sites in his model are no more well-
444 Michael Sugerman

defined than in other models that have been proposed Mirsim. Each of the southern sites are B- or C-level
for Canaan. Knapp’s primary and secondary centers sites in the trade networks of the LB.
somehow “control” production of inland agricultural While the A-level sites were probably trading
and mineral resources, and transport the products these imports upstream to the B- and C-level part-
from the production centers out to the coastal capi- ners, it is the third segment of Leonard’s data that
tals. Knapp (1997:62) hints at the possibility of a best supports the argument that these secondary cen-
“king” overseeing the entire system, and of a govern- ters were using exotic goods to entice upstream in-
ing elite, but again the nature of that dominance is not habitants into the network. At forty-eight sites (70
defined. percent of the sample), ten or fewer examples of
In each of these models, what is missing is the Mycenaean pottery were found. In Canaan, these
impetus for the hinterland communities to take part in sites range from Tel Dan in the north to Tell el-
the exchange network. Contrary to political or eco- Far«ah (South). This class of sites also includes six
nomic models that assume coercive relations between sites in Jordan, indicating, along with the Amman
high- and low-order centers within a state-level sys- finds, that there was an eastern overland extension to
tem, dendritic models consider relations between the networks that ran from the sea to the Jordan Val-
sites on either end of the system to be somewhat ley (Leonard 1976:465).
egalitarian (Bronson 1977:44). Since D-level sites are Leonard’s analysis of Mycenean ceramic imports
simply concentration points for goods often produced undermines the economic arguments of the city-state
by mobile populations, military solutions to problems model by showing that the majority of these elite
in the trading relationships would be impractical. One artifacts were found at port centers. In fact, these arti-
method to bring peripheral populations into the net- facts are present in much smaller numbers at many of
work would be to offer manufactured or exotic goods the settlements that have been proposed as centers of
that are otherwise unavailable and that might induce city-states (Leonard 1976; 1987). The pattern of dis-
“D” to enter the network voluntarily. tribution identified by Leonard runs counter to the
argument that symbols of wealth were amassed by
Tracing the Networks the rulers of urban city-states in shows of conspicu-
ous consumption (Bunimovitz 1995:326). A recent
It is clear that exotic goods were transferred from the comprehensive study of Mycenean pottery in the
coastal centers to the upstream sites in LB Canaan, as Levant argues the opposite: in urban economic cen-
demonstrated by Leonard’s work on the distribution ters, these imports are found in residences associated
of Mycenean pottery in the Levant (Leonard 1976; with a wide range of socioeconomic groups. Their
1981; 1987). Of the sixty-nine sites discussed by distributions at smaller centers are less clear, in part
Leonard, six produced more than one hundred because of the lack of data about these smaller sites,
Mycenaean vessel lots (or minimum number of ves- but these imports seem to be limited to elite social
sels). Of those six, three are important coastal centers contexts at lower-order inland sites (van Wijngaarden
where such finds would be expected: Ugarit, Byblos, 2002:109–24).
and Tell Abu Hawam. Two more sites are secondary The routes upon which imports were carried are
centers on major trade routes: Kamid el-Loz and Me- conspicuous archaeologically because the colorfully
giddo. The sixth site is Amman, east of the Jordan decorated Aegean sherds can be seen easily among
River. While this might be seen as an unexpected the plain wares common to LB Canaan. But were
addition to the previous five, perhaps it illustrates the these same routes used to carry goods in the opposite
high status of such goods when they were moved direction? The dendritic model posited here focuses
inland away from the coastal centers, because all 150 primarily on the “bulking” of goods: the increasing
items at that site were excavated in the temple dis- concentration of goods at successive notes along the
covered on the site of the Amman airport (Hankey network. In order to support this side of the argu-
1974; for other arguments on the status of Mycenean ment, we must be able to identify that process
ceramics in Levantine sites, see also Leonard and archaeologically. While exotic goods may be seen as
Cline 1998; van Wijngaarden 1999; 2002). one method of enticing lower-order sites into the
Fourteen sites on Leonard’s list produced between network, utilitarian goods and raw resources are the
ten and one hundred vessel lots, and again these are likely objectives of those in the higher-order sites
not surprising sites: the coastal centers Tell Sukas, downstream. Utilitarian—or staple—goods include
Sarepta, Ashdod, Ashkelon, and Gaza, and the inland those that are (1) found in a range of socioeconomic
sites Alalakh, Hazor, Ta«anach, Beth-shean, She- contexts, indicating that they were common artifacts
chem, Gezer, Beth-shemesh, Lachish, and Tell Beit used in daily life; (2) found at many sites, indicating
Trade and Power in Late Bronze Age Canaan 445

a role as an item of trade; and (3) suitable for prove- ters and small coastal settlements. The political, eco-
nience analysis, making it possible to map the routes nomic, and geographic diversity of the sites provided
of that trade. the basis for a comprehensive test of the city-state
Canaanite jars, one of the most common artifact and dendritic models. The detailed results of my
types excavated at LB sites in Israel and Palestine, petrographic analyses of those samples have been
are one type of artifact that conforms to all of these presented elsewhere and strongly support the predic-
criteria. By identifying the proveniences of Canaanite tions of the dendritic model (Sugerman 2000). In
jar samples collected from many sites, it should be each of the 273 samples of Canaanite jars that were
possible to ascertain the routes over which these analyzed, the provenience of the sample was identi-
transport and storage jars were carried. The patterns fied as either east of its archaeological findspot or—
of distribution and the directionality of trade should in the case of some coastal sites—to the north. The
reflect these jars’ role in the economic system of the great majority of the ceramic groups were distributed
LB. within bounded ranges that, with the exception of the
The two models already discussed here each posit samples found at coastal sites, did not spread far to
different types of trade relations among sites and re- the north or south of the latitude in which they were
gions within Canaan. City-states are characterized as produced (Sugerman 2000:122).
having “a capital city…with an economically and
socially integrated adjacent hinterland” (Charlton and Further Investigations of LB Economic Structures
Nichols 1997:1). The capital city thus accumulates
goods produced in a number of dependent settle- The sources of data most often used to model the
ments—possibly a very large number of settlements, political and economic structures of LB Canaan are
depending on the extent of the hinterland controlled elite artifacts and architecture, and documents from
by the capital. As a result, ceramic samples collected royal or other elite contexts. The city-state model
from capital cities should exhibit a wide variety of commonly used as a baseline for modeling Canaanite
production sources (reflecting both regional differ- political economy can be supported only by restrict-
ences in the composition of the clays and technical ing the types of data used in one’s analysis. The
choices on the part of the potters), while samples documentary support for this model is based largely
from satellite settlements should show less variation. on the assumption that “each person who wrote either
In addition, trade among capital cities should not be to Pharaoh or to his officials was a city-state ruler”
limited to any particular direction. (Na»aman 1997:602), even though only a small num-
Alternatively, the port-centered, dendritic trade ber of the archaeologically known LB settlements can
model posits a process in which the transport of local be identified in the Amarna archives. Most scholars
goods and resources is largely a one-way journey. are willing to assume that all of the other known set-
Goods collected in the hinterlands are consolidated at tlements must have been subordinate to the settle-
small settlements far upstream. Those goods are then ments documented in the archives (for example,
joined to shipments from similar sites and funneled Finkelstein 1996:224).
downstream through higher-level nodes until they The Amarna archive has also been used to support
reach the port center that dominates the economy of the argument that Canaan was an extension of impe-
the network. As a result, ceramic samples collected rial Egypt during the New Kingdom and that the rul-
from downstream sites should indicate a large variety ers of the city-states were largely governing on behalf
of proveniences, and samples from the port center of the pharaoh. Along with these documents, scholars
should show the greatest amount of variation. Con- have suggested that Egyptian artifacts excavated in
versely, samples collected from upstream sites should Canaan—pottery, scarab seals, alabaster vessels, and
indicate fewer production sources. In contrast to the jewelry—are evidence for New Kingdom domination
city-state model, local ceramics should indicate a or outright military occupation of the region
strong directionality in their distribution. Samples (Weinstein 1981:20–22). The presence of these high-
from downstream production centers should not be prestige Egyptian artifacts at a given site is often ar-
found in large quantities at upstream sites. gued to be evidence for Egyptian governance (Bietak
In a recent project, I collected samples of Canaan- 1993; Dever 1985; Hoffmeier 1989:189). But the
ite jars from Deir el-Balaḥ, Lachish, Ashdod (south evidence in support of this model of Egyptian politi-
shore), Tel Miqne-Ekron, Tel Batash, Tel Ta«anach, cal domination is actually quite weak; I will address
Tel Nami, Tel Megadim, Tell Abu Hawam, Hazor, the issue in a forthcoming article titled “Competition
and Tel Dan. This sample includes large urban inland or Colonization? Disruption and Destruction in the
settlements, small inland settlements, large port cen- Late Bronze Age Levant.”
446 Michael Sugerman

The limitations and assumptions noted above have Canaan is drawn from documentary sources. Data
made it difficult to model the political economy of resulting from archaeological assessments of elite
Canaanite society coherently, and have led archae- goods do not unambiguously undermine the city-state
ologists to construct conflicting and inconsistent model, but they do support a dendritic systems
models based on either limited textual sources or model, with networks anchored in wealthy port cen-
limited archaeological datasets. The belief common ters (Leonard 1976; 1987). When archaeological data
among archaeologists that the LB is one of the “best that reflect the staple economy are brought into the
illuminated” periods (Gonen 1992:211) results from mix, the evidence for a dendritic system increases
ignoring these constraints. The absence of investiga- greatly. In order to test further the utility of either
tions of the staple economy of Canaan has created a model for explaining the economy of LB Canaan,
bias toward seeing economic behavior and power archaeologists need to continue to add to the range of
reflected only in an artificially constrained range of data available, and to shift our economic focus from
artifact types and data sources. The majority of the urban centers and eye-catching exotic goods to the
data used to support the city-state model for LB archaeology of ordinary things.

BIBLIOGRAPHY
Aharoni, Y. Bunimovitz, S.
1967 The Land of the Bible: A Historical Geography. 1993 The Study of Complex Societies: The Material
Philadelphia: Westminster. Culture of Late Bronze Age Canaan As a Case
Study. In Biblical Archaeology Today, 1990:
Alt, A. Proceedings of the Second International Con-
1939 Erwägungen über die Landnahme der Israeliten gress of Biblical Archaeology, ed A. Biran and J.
in Palästina. Palästina-Jahrbuch 35:8–63. Aviram, 443–51. Jerusalem: Israel Exploration
1953 Kleine Schriften zur Geschichte des Volkes Is- Society.
rael. Munich: Beck. 1994a The Problem of Human Resources in Late
1954 Neue Berichte über Feldzüge von Pharaonen an Bronze Age Palestine and Its Socioeconomic Im-
der phönikischen Küste und im syrischen Bin- plications. UF 26:1–20.
nenland. Zeitschrift des Deutsches Archaeolo- 1994b Socio-political Transformations in the Central
gisches Vereins 70:97–133. Hill Country in the Late Bronze–Iron I Transi-
tion. In From Nomadism to Monarchy: Archaeo-
Bienkowski, P. logical and Historical Aspects of Early Israel, ed.
1989 Prosperity and Decline in LBA Canaan: A Reply I. Finkelstein and N. Na»aman, 179–202. Jerusa-
to Leibowitz and Knapp. BASOR 275:59–61. lem: Israel Exploration Society.
1995 On the Edge of Empires—The Late Bronze Age.
In The Archaeology of Society in the Holy Land,
Bietak, M. ed. T. E. Levy, 320–31. New York: Facts on File.
1993 The Sea Peoples and the End of the Egyptian
Administration in Canaan. In Biblical Archae- Charlton, T. H., and D. L. Nichols
ology Today, 1990: Proceedings of the Second 1997 The City-state Concept: Development and Appli-
International Congress of Biblical Archaeology, cations. In The Archaeology of City-States:
ed A. Biran and J. Aviram, 292–306. Jerusalem: Cross-Cultural Approaches, ed. D. L. Nichols
Israel Exploration Society. and T. H. Charlton, 1–15. Washington, D.C.:
Smithsonian Institution Press.
Braudel, F. D’Altroy, T. N.
1972 The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World 1999 Review of The Archaeology of City-States:
in the Age of Philip II. Translated by Siân Rey- Cross-Cultural Approaches, by D. Nichols and T.
nolds. 2 vols. New York: Harper and Row. Charlton. AA 101:850–52.

Dever, W. G.
Bronson, B. 1985 Relations between Syria-Palestine and Egypt in
1977 Exchange at the Upstream and Downstream the “Hyksos” Period. In Palestine in the Bronze
Ends: Notes Toward a Functional Model of the and Iron Ages: Papers in Honour of Olga Tuf-
Coastal State in Southeast Asia. In Economic Ex- nell, ed. J. N. Tubb, 69–87. London: Institute of
change and Social Interaction in Southeast Asia: Archaeology, University of London.
Perspectives from Prehistory, History, and Eth-
nography, ed. K. L. Hutterer, 39–52. Ann Arbor, Finkelstein, I.
Mich.: Center for South and Southeast Asian 1988 The Archaeology of the Israelite Settlement. Jeru-
Studies, University of Michigan. salem: Israel Exploration Society.
Trade and Power in Late Bronze Age Canaan 447

1993 The Sociopolitical Organization of the Central Johnson, E. A. J.


Hill Country in the Second Millennium B.C.E. In 1970 The Organization of Space in Developing Coun-
Biblical Archaeology Today, 1990: Proceedings tries. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
of the Second International Congress of Biblical Press.
Archaeology; Supplement: Pre-Congress Sympo-
sium, ed. A. Biran and J. Aviram, 119–31. Jerusa- Knapp, A. B.
lem: Israel Exploration Society. 1989a Complexity and Collapse in the North Jordan
1996 The Territorial-Political System of Canaan in the Valley: Archaeometry and Society in the Middle–
Late Bronze Age. UF 28:221–55. Late Bronze Ages. IEJ 39:129–48.
1989b Response: Independence, Imperialism, and the
Gittlen, B. M. Egyptian factor. BASOR 275:64–68.
1993 Response to “Trade and its Renewal in the Iron 1992 Independence and Imperialism: Politico-
Age.” In Biblical Archaeology Today, 1990: Pro- economic Structures in the Bronze Age Levant.
ceedings of the Second International Congress of In Archaeology, Annales and Ethnohistory, ed. A.
Biblical Archaeology, ed A. Biran and J. Aviram, B. Knapp, 83–98. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
367–69. Jerusalem: Israel Exploration Society. versity Press.
1997 The Archaeology of Late Bronze Age Cypriot
Gonen, R. Society: The Study of Settlement, Survey and
1984 Urban Canaan in the Late Bronze Period. BASOR Landscape. University of Glasgow, Department
253:61–74. of Archaeology Occasional Paper Series 4. Glas-
1992 The Late Bronze Age. In The Archaeology of gow: University of Glasgow.
Ancient Israel, ed. A. Ben-Tor, 211–57. Trans-
lated by R. Greenberg. New Haven, Conn.: Yale Lemche, N. P.
University Press 1991 The Canaanites and Their Land: The Tradition of
the Canaanites. JSOTSup 110. Sheffield, Eng-
Hall, S. R. land: JSOT Press.
1985 Maritime Trade and State Development in Early 1996 Where Should We Look for Canaan? A Reply to
Southeast Asia. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Nadav Na»aman. UF 28:767–72.
Press. 1998 Greater Canaan: The Implications of a Correct
Reading of EA 151:49–67. BASOR 310:19–24.
Hankey, V.
1974 A Late Bronze Age Temple at Amman. Levant 6: Leonard, A.
131–78. 1976 The Nature and Extent of the Mycenaean Pres-
ence in the Southeastern Mediterranean during
the Late Bronze Age. Ph.D. diss., University of
Hansen, M. H., ed.
Chicago.
2000 A Comparative Study of Thirty City-State Cul-
1981 Considerations of Morphological Variation in the
tures: An Investigation. Historik-filosofiske
Mycenaean Pottery from the Southeastern Medi-
skrifter 21. Copenhagen: Kongelige Danske
terranean. BASOR 241:87–101.
Videnskabernes Selskab.
1987 The Significance of the Mycenaean Pottery
Found East of the Jordan River. In Studies in the
Harrison, T. P. History and Archaeology of Jordan, vol. 3, ed. A.
1993 Economics with an Entrepreneurial Spirit: Early Hadidi, 261–66. Amman: Department of Antiqui-
Bronze Trade with Late Predynastic Egypt. BA ties of the Hashemite Kingdom of Jordan.
56:81–93.
Leonard, A., and E. Cline
Helck, W. 1998 The Aegean Pottery at Megiddo: An Appraisal
1971 Die Beziehungen Ägyptens zu Vorderasien im 3. and Reanalysis. BASOR 309:3–39.
und 2. Jahrtausand v. Chr. 2d ed. Ägyptolo-
gische Abhundlungen 5. Wiesbaden: Harras- Levy, T. E.
sowitz. 1995 Cult, Metallurgy, and Rank Societies—Chalco-
lithic Period (ca. 4500–3500 B.C.E.). In The Ar-
Hoffmeier, J. K. chaeology of Society in the Holy Land, ed. T. E.
1989 Reconsidering Egypt’s Part in the Termination of Levy, 226–44. New York: Facts on File.
the Middle Bronze Age in Palestine. Levant 21:
181–93. Marcus, E.
1991 Tel Nami: A Study of a Middle Bronze Age IIA
Ilan, D. Period Coastal Settlement. M.A. thesis, Haifa
1995 The Dawn of Internationalism—The Middle University.
Bronze Age. In The Archaeology of Society in the 1995 A Petrographic Analysis of Storage Jars from Tel
Holy Land, ed. T. E. Levy, 297–319. New York: Nami, Israel: Ceramic Production and Trade
Facts on File. Networks of the Middle Bronze Age IIA period
448 Michael Sugerman

(ca. 2000–1750 B.C.). Materials Issues in Art and Study.” In Biblical Archaeology Today: Proceed-
Archaeology 4(352):597–603. ings of the International Congress on Biblical
Archaeology, Jerusalem, April 1984, ed. J. Ami-
Marfoe, L. tai, 83–86. Jerusalem: Israel Exploration Society.
1979 The Integrative Transformation: Patterns of So- 1992 The Periodization of Palestine from Neolithic
ciopolitical Organization in Southern Syria. through Bronze Age times. In Chronologies in
BASOR 234:1–42. Old World Archaeology, 3d ed., ed. R. W.
Ehrich, 1:22–41. Chicago: University of Chicago
Na»aman, N. Press.
1975 The Political Disposition and Historical Devel- 2000 Port Power in the Early and the Middle Bronze
opment of Eretz-Israel according to the Amarna Age: The Organization of Maritime Trade and
Letters. Ph.D. diss., Tel Aviv University. Hinterland Production. In Studies in the Archae-
1981 Economic Aspects of the Egyptian Occupation of ology of Israel and Neighboring Lands in Mem-
Canaan. IEJ 31:172–85. ory of Douglas L. Esse, ed. S. Wolff, 625–38.
1986 The Canaanite City-States in the Late Bronze SAOC 59. Chicago: Oriental Institute, University
Age and the Inheritances of the Israelite Tribes of Chicago.
[in Hebrew]. Tarbiz 55:463–88.
1992 Canaanite Jerusalem and Its Central Hill Country Sugerman, M.
Neighbours in the Second Millennium B.C.E. UF 2000 Webs of Commerce: The Archaeology of Ordi-
24:275–92. nary Things in Late Bronze Age Israel and Pales-
1997 The Network of Canaanite Late Bronze King- tine. Ph.D. diss., Harvard University.
doms and the City of Ashdod. UF 29:599–625. n.d. The Petrographic Proveniences of Some Canaan-
1999 Four Notes on the Size of Late Bronze Age Ca- ite Jars in Cyprus.
naan. BASOR 313:31–37.
Trigger, B. G.
Nichols, D. L., and T. H. Charlton 1993 Early Civilizations: Ancient Egypt in Context.
1997 The Archaeology of City-States: Cross-Cultural Cairo: American University in Cairo Press.
Approaches. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian In- 2003 Understanding Early Civilizations: A Compara-
stitution Press. tive Study. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Raban, A.
1985 The Ancient Harbours of Israel in Biblical Times. Vance, J. E.
In Harbour Archaeology: Proceedings of the 1970 The Merchant’s World: Geography of Whole-
First International Workshop on Ancient Medi- saling. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
terranean Harbours, Cesarea Maritima 24–
28.6.83, ed. A. Raban, 11–44. BARIS 257. Ox- Weinstein, J. M.
ford: British Archaeological Reports. 1981 The Egyptian Empire in Palestine: A Reassess-
ment. BASOR 241:1–28.
Renfrew, C.
1975 Trade as Action at a Distance: Questions of Inte- Wijngaarden, G. J. van
gration and Communication. In Ancient Civiliza- 1999 An Archaeological Approach to the Concept of
tions and Trade, ed. J. A. Sabloff and C. C. Lam- Value: Mycenaean Pottery at Ugarit (Syria). Ar-
berg-Karlovsky, 3–59. Albuquerque: University chaeological Dialogues 6/1:2–46.
of New Mexico Press. 2002 Use and Appreciation of Mycenaean Pottery in
the Levant, Cyprus and Italy (ca. 1600–1200
B.C.). Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
Rihll, T. E., and A. G. Wilson
1991 Modeling Settlement Structures in Ancient Yoffee, N.
Greece: New Approaches to the Polis. In City 1997 The Obvious and the Chimerical. In The Archae-
and Country in the Ancient World, ed. J. Rich and ology of City-States: Cross-Cultural Approaches,
A. Wallace-Hadrill, 59–95. London: Routledge. ed. D. L. Nichols and T. H. Charlton, 255–63.
Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution Press.
Stager, L. E. 2005 Myths of the Archaic State: Evolution of the Ear-
1985 Response to “Archaeology, History, and Bible. liest Cities, States, and Civilizations. Cambridge:
The Israelite Settlement in Canaan: A Case Cambridge University Press.

You might also like